Photo credit: Quang Nguyen
Vinh
50 Billion Euros: Europe's Child Labour Footprint in 2019
June 10, 2021
2
Title:
Prepared for:
Authored by:
50 Billion Euros: Europe’s Child Labour Footprint in 2019
Saskia Bricmont and The Greens/EFA Group
Chris N. Bayer, PhD
Claire Bright, PhD
Irene Pietropaoli, PhD
Eliana Gonzalez Torres
Justine Vinet, LLM
Derrill D. Watson II, PhD
Representing:
Development International e.V.
3
Acknowledgements
The authors wish to extend their deep appreciation to Saskia Bricmont, Green MEP and
INTA Member, who commissioned this study, and to Olivier Derruine, Assistant to Saskia
Bricmont, who provided invaluable technical and subject matter expertise.
A big thank you goes to the study’s reviewers, who provided insightful critique and input on
the draft document. They comprise Josje Beukema, Josette Hermans (Save the Children),
Jolijn Engelbertink (Lino Consulting), Emanuele Biraghi, Christopher Kip, Francesca Lazzaroni
(UNICEF), Ann-Evelyn Luyten (Starch Europe), Anita Sheth (Fairtrade International),
Fabienne Yver (Fair Trade Advocacy Office), and ILO representatives. Participation as a
reviewer, however, does not imply endorsement of methods, findings or recommendations.
Dr. Derrill D. Watson II conceptualised the economic underpinnings of the study. Drs. Claire
Bright and Irene Pietropaoli discussed pertinent legislative precedents and forthcoming due
diligence legislation. Justine Vinet investigated the manner in which child labour is currently
treated in EU trade instruments. Eliana Gonzalez Torres collated the data in order to
estimate the imports produced with child labour, and created an application visualising
those findings. Dr. Chris N. Bayer designed and executed the study. The result reflects our
combined expertise. Any errors remain our responsibility, and the views expressed do not
necessarily reflect those of The Greens/EFA Group.
4
Executive Summary
Total importation of goods from non-EU countries into the EU (EU28) reached €2.057 trillion
in 2019.1
Child labour footprint
Findings
Of the €2.057 trillion importation
total, an estimated €50.08 billion
constituted the importation of
products that were made with
child labour. In other words, the
EU’s footprint concerning child
labour imports was 2.433% – or
1/41 of all EU imports – in 2019
(see our application further
detailing these findings).
Definition
Child labour is work below the minimum age,
notably codified in ILO Convention 138. As
explained by USDOL (2020a), the term child
labour includes the worst forms of child
labour as per ILO Convention 182, but
excludes light work performed by children
who are above the minimum age and who
are not exposed to the worst forms of child
labour (see section A. Definitions for more
detail).
Forced/indentured child labour footprint – a subset of the child labour footprint
Findings
Of the €2.057 trillion
importation total, an
estimated €38.55 billion was
the value of imports by the EU
that were produced with
forced or indentured child
labour in 2019 (see our
application further detailing
these findings).
Definition
Forced/indentured child labour is a type of child
labour, and a type of the worst forms of child
labour. As explained by USDOL (2020a), “Children
older than the minimum age for work are in
forced child labor if work is involuntary and they
are under the menace of penalty. For children
younger than the minimum age, voluntariness
need not be established because children cannot
legally consent to work” (see section A.
Definitions for more detail).
Figure 1: % of Goods Entering the EU (Economic Value)
1
2.43%
1.87%
97.57%
98.13%
Without child labour
Without forced/indentured child labour
With child labour
With forced/indentured child labour
Based on EU Comext data (European Commission, 2021a), code: EU28_EXTRA - Extra-EU28 (= 'WORLD' 'EU28_INTRA')
5
The economic case against child labour
From the perspective of child labour reduction, a free-market economy is a two-edged
sword. On the one hand, vibrant trade has the power to lift entire societies out of poverty.
Economic openness “has helped integrate many developing countries into the world
economy, lifting hundreds of millions of people out of poverty and decreasing inequalities
between countries” (European Commission, 2021e). The macro context is also reflected at
the household level: caregiver income is the largest explanatory factor for the phenomenon
of child labour. On the other hand, a laissez-faire approach to child labour can actually
produce a vicious cycle: the supply of child labour expands the overall labour supply, holding
down adult wages, which in turn would prevent certain low-income households from
withdrawing their children from labour, and in doing so perpetuate inter-generational
poverty. Once the exporting country has reached a certain level of development, enabling
bilateral trade terms acting on the exporting country may actually liberate a trade partner
from a bad equilibrium, where child labour competes with adult labour to keep wages low.
Two further economic reasons speaking for intervention: (1) hazardous child labour can
produce morbidity and mortality outcomes that counteract short-term economic gains, and
(2) child labour results in less human capital formation over time, as school absenteeism
leads to forgone economic returns to education.
Importing countries also have a self-serving interest in the abolishment of child labour, as
goods made with child labour abroad may undercut the price of goods offered by domestic
competitors. This “unfair advantage,” associated with job losses in importing countries,
undermines the goal of equitable trade.
The good news is that with overall growing global prosperity and increasing attention over
the past decades, the international community now has a realistic chance of abolishing child
labour, despite of the inevitable setback due to COVID-19. Given globalised markets, the
rules of trade play a key role in shaping the outcomes of children’s well-being, including
child labour.
EU practice
The EU’s common commercial policy does not effectively leverage its purchasing power to
nudge exporting countries into making significant gains on their reduction of child labour.
While the EU’s approach to resolving issues in its trade agreements has evolved from a soft
approach based on dialogue (e.g. EU-Korea FTA in 2010) to a stronger approach that
includes a rebalancing mechanism (EU-UK Trade and Cooperation Agreement (TCA) of
2020), European expectations for labour rights performance is even more lax in FTAs than
its Generalised System of Preferences (GSPs). On account of their lacking an effective
enforcement mechanism and binding dispute settlement procedures, Trade and Sustainable
Development (TSD) chapters in FTAs have not been able to encourage trade partners to
meet their commitments under ILO convention ratifications, or prevent them from causing
market distortions through social dumping.
While the EU has global human rights sanctions regime (as per Council Regulation EU
2020/1998 and Council Decision CFSP 2020/1999), which allows it to freeze assets and issue
travel bans of designated individuals and entities, the EU does not currently have the
powers to stop the importation of tainted goods at its borders on the basis of their having
been produced with forced child labour.
6
U.S. practice
Unlike the EU, the U.S. has robust and enforceable labour rights provisions in its Free Trade
Agreements (FTAs). Furthermore, by presiding over the option of import bans as well as the
exclusion of goods from federal procurement, the U.S. has hard-line measures at its disposal
that allows it – based on child-labour-premised conditions – to intervene in the market. The
underlying legislation providing these powers are the following.
Table 1: Notable U.S. Legislation and Instruments
Scope
Child labour
Legislation
Trafficking Victims
Protection
Reauthorization Act
(TVPRA) of 2005
Instrument
Publication of: “List of
Goods Produced by
Child Labor or Forced
Labor”
Forced or
indentured
child labour
U.S. Tariff Act of 1930,
amended by the U.S
Trade Facilitation and
Trade Enforcement Act
of 2015, impacting Title
19 (Customs Duties)
CFR Section 12.42
U.S. Executive Order
13126 of 1999
Importation bans
(exclusion and/or
seizure), possible
criminal investigation
Publication of: “List of
Products Produced by
Forced or Indentured
Child Labor,” goods
excluded from federal
procurement,
consequences for
violations
Execution entity
U.S. Department of
Labor (USDOL)’s Bureau
of International Labor
Affairs (ILAB) publishes
list
U.S. Department of
Homeland Security
(DHS): U.S. Customs and
Border Protection (CBP)
issues Withhold Release
Orders (WRO) and
publishes findings
USDOL’s ILAB maintains
list of products and
pursues remedy
EU policy options
UNGPs Pillar I – Measures to Enhance the State’s Duty to Protect
How can the EU, leveraging its sizable aggregate purchasing power, effectively reduce child
labour globally? As unconditional trade bans and sanctions would likely lower child welfare
and increase child labour, ceteris paribus, this study proposes a 4-zones approach to trade
partner engagement on the issue, depending, largely on their degree of socio-economic
development (as proxied through GDP/capita). This reform would ensure that the EU would
not reverse the development – and thus the related reduction of child labour gains – of the
EU’s trade partners (in line with the ‘first, do no harm’ rule), but effectively nudge trade
partners towards the effective reduction of child labour, however mindful of market access
co-dependency.
7
Zone 1
Zone 2
Zone 3
Zone 4
< USD 3,000
GDP/capita
b/w USD 3,000 USD 7,000
GDP/capita)
b/w USD 7,000 11,000 GDP/capita
> USD 11,000
GDP/capita
•Carrots
•Conditional
carrots
•Select sticks
•Sticks
More specifically, this four-zone system of incentives and disincentives would pursue a
policy of progressive conditionality vis-à-vis child labour.
Table 2: Four-zone System of Incentives and Disincentives
carrots
Zone 1
Zone 2
Zone 3
Zone 4
X
X
X
X
X
sticks
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
A. Aid (empirically proven interventions): European aid programmes such as the
Neighbourhood, Development and International Cooperation Instrument (NDICI) may step
up interventions with demonstrated success in reducing child labour, such as the provision
of school meals, conditional cash transfers, and reducing the cost of education for
impoverished families.
B. Aid (conditional): Aid may be provided, however, premised on performance tied to
educational outcomes (e.g. of primary, secondary school enrolment) and/or monitoring
outcomes (e.g. the identification of child labour in high-risk sectors through child labour
monitoring systems and the establishment of child protection systems) and/or economic
outcomes (e.g. payment of living income/wages, price stabilisation, farm gate prices, etc.).
Also Aid for Trade (AfT) may be leveraged to this end.
C. Conditional market access and trade preferences: A licensing model (a form of a non-tariff
trade barrier), instituted through bilateral agreements or MOUs with countries exporting
commodities suffering from a high degree of child labour would serve to improve partnercountry standards of governance and law enforcement. Furthermore, TSD chapters should
include time-bound roadmaps and targets, with preferential trade conditions premised, in
turn, on trade partner performance.
8
D. Surgical import bans: The U.S. has the powers of blocking, on the basis of reasonable
suspicion, specific shipments containing products made with forced labour or forced child
labour. Yet, it does not have to come to a ban if importers then offer proof that their
products were not produced with labour prohibited under U.S. law. The provision thus shifts
the burden of proof on the importer to demonstrate its products to not produced with child
labour. Forced labour – including forced child labour – is prohibited according to ILO
Convention 182. All the world’s eligible countries – 187 out of 187 – have now ratified ILO
Convention 182. If the EU acquired similar powers – as a matter of last resort – it could act
systematically, surgically, and decisively on the practice of forced child labour, with a
particular emphasis on its worst forms. However, in light of the possible collateral damage
caused, it should apply these potential powers only in Zone 4 countries.
E. Public procurement measures: Under U.S. Executive Order 13126 of 1999, goods may be
excluded from federal procurement, and consequences assessed for violations. Also the
public sector in Europe could lead by example. Conversely, punitive measures may be
complemented with public procurement policy of buying by example. Such a policy would
entail government buyers meeting minimum criteria for legality and social and
environmental standards.
F. Creation of lists: The U.S. Department of Labor establishes and regularly updates a List of
Goods produced by child labour or forced labour and their source countries (under the 2005
TVPRA regulation), as well as a List of Products and their source countries produced by
forced or indentured child labour and their source countries (under Executive Order 13126).
A surgical (black)listing approach targeting products, countries, individuals and/or
companies is advised also for the EU, that would serve as a monitoring tool, inform public
procurement, as well as send “signals” to the market.
G. Rebalancing measures: As the EU-UK’s TCA features a “rebalancing measure” that offers a
clear mechanism for a trade partner to seek and – if need be, unilaterally – obtain redress
for a position of “unfair disadvantage.” In order to be in a position of credibly challenging a
trade partner on child labour outcomes, the EU should insert conditionality in re-negotiated
and future trade deals, which in turn could trigger “rebalancing measures.”
UNGPs Pillar II – Measures to Enhance the Corporate Responsibility to Respect
mHRDD
Four measures concerning mandatory human rights due diligence (mHRDD) are advanced in
this study. Needed in impeding EU legislation are the following six provisions:
A. An overarching human rights due diligence framework, accompanied by specific
guidance, performance standards and key performance indicators for certain
industries with widespread child labour in supply chains;
B. Due diligence obligations to reach entire value chains;
C. Responsible purchasing practices on the part of companies;
D. Meaningful stakeholder consultation throughout the due diligence process;
E. Dissuasive sanctions and strong enforcement mechanisms;
F. Coordination through the Chief Trade Enforcement Officer (CTEO).
9
IPAs
Lastly, we recommend that Investment Protection Agreements (IPAs) protecting private
sector Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) be reformed such that investments into sectors
steeped with child labour would only be protected if certain conditions were upheld,
notably the payment of living income/wages and the eradication of the Worst Forms of
Child Labour.
WTO
Based on a legal analysis of the provisions of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
(GATT), the EU has two legal theories premised on Article XX(a) “public morals” and Article
XX(b) “health protection,” with which it would have the best chances of securing
enforcement in its bilateral trade agreements, as well as justifying surgical import bans.
If these suggested reforms were implemented, the EU would be in a position to properly
leverage its purchasing power in order to advance the cause of children worldwide and
show resolve vis-à-vis the issue of child labour. This study provides an empirical and childcentric blueprint for the EU to do its part.
After all, Article 3.5 of THE TREATY ON EUROPEAN UNION reads:
In its relations with the wider world, the Union shall uphold and promote its values
and interests and contribute to the protection of its citizens. It shall contribute to
peace, security, the sustainable development of the Earth, solidarity and mutual
respect among peoples, free and fair trade, eradication of poverty and the protection
of human rights, in particular the rights of the child, as well as to the strict
observance and the development of international law, including respect for the
principles of the United Nations Charter.
10
Table of Contents
Acknowledgements.................................................................................................................... 3
Executive Summary.................................................................................................................... 4
Acronyms ................................................................................................................................. 14
Foreword by Saskia Bricmont .................................................................................................. 17
I. Introduction .......................................................................................................................... 20
II. Research Objectives ............................................................................................................. 23
III. Methodology ....................................................................................................................... 25
IV. Problem Statement............................................................................................................. 25
A. Definitions ........................................................................................................................ 25
B. Child labour lists ............................................................................................................... 26
1. USDOL’s “List of Goods Produced by Child Labor or Forced Labor” ............................. 26
2. USDOL’s “List of Products Produced by Forced or Indentured Child Labor” ................. 27
C. Sectors and geographies with child labour practices ....................................................... 28
D. Share of child labour exposure in products imported to the EU ...................................... 30
1. Methodology applied ................................................................................................... 30
2. Example child labour commodities .............................................................................. 33
3. Child labour footprint findings ..................................................................................... 36
4. Forced/indentured child labour findings ...................................................................... 45
E. Factors of child labour ...................................................................................................... 51
F. Child labour vs. trade ........................................................................................................ 54
1. Does trade itself lower the phenomenon of child labour? .......................................... 54
2. How could unconditional trade bans and sanctions lower child welfare? .................. 57
G. Laissez-faire vs. intervention............................................................................................ 58
1. Morbidity and mortality of hazardous labour .............................................................. 59
2. Foregone economic returns of education .................................................................... 60
3. Labour substitutability, multiple equilibria .................................................................. 60
H. Implications of child labour models ................................................................................. 62
Dimension 1: Income and Basic Needs............................................................................. 62
Dimension 2: Quality of the education system ................................................................ 63
Dimension 3: Government capacity ................................................................................. 66
V. UNGPs Pillar I – Measures to Enhance the State’s Duty to Protect .................................... 68
A. EU trade policy enforcement vis-à-vis child labour .......................................................... 68
1. Trade and Sustainable Development Chapters ............................................................ 68
2. Stringency of child labour provisions ........................................................................... 73
3. Local impact dimension of TSD chapters...................................................................... 75
4. EU-UK Free Trade Agreement ...................................................................................... 76
5. EU “essential elements” human rights clause .............................................................. 77
6. EU trade sanction instruments ..................................................................................... 78
B. U.S. trade policy enforcement vis-à-vis child labour ........................................................ 79
1. DHS mechanism ............................................................................................................ 80
2. EO mechanisms............................................................................................................. 87
3. List of Goods, coordination of enforcement ................................................................ 89
11
4. U.S. Trade Policy ........................................................................................................... 93
C. EU support for trade partners .......................................................................................... 96
1. Support through Aid for Trade ..................................................................................... 96
2. Support through dialogue and cooperation platforms ................................................ 98
3. Support through the Neighbourhood, Development and International Cooperation
Instrument ...................................................................................................................... 101
D. U.S. support for trade partners ...................................................................................... 104
E. Multilateral support to nation-states ............................................................................. 105
1. ILO ............................................................................................................................... 105
2. IPEC+ ........................................................................................................................... 108
3. Child Labour Monitoring Systems .............................................................................. 110
VI. UNGPs Pillar II – Measures to Enhance the Corporate Responsibility to Respect ........... 111
A. Legislative precedents of mandatory due diligence....................................................... 111
1. France ......................................................................................................................... 111
2. The Netherlands ......................................................................................................... 114
B. Forthcoming mandatory due diligence legislation ........................................................ 117
1. Germany ..................................................................................................................... 117
2. Switzerland ................................................................................................................. 119
3. Norway........................................................................................................................ 120
4. European Union .......................................................................................................... 120
C. EU Investment Protection Agreements .......................................................................... 121
VII. Policy Options .................................................................................................................. 122
A. Progressive conditionality in bilateral trade agreements .............................................. 122
1. Zone 1: (< USD 3,000 GDP/capita): Only carrots – no conditionality ......................... 124
2. Zone 2: (b/w USD 3,000 - USD 7,000 GDP/capita): Conditional carrots .................... 124
3. Zone 3: (b/w USD 7,000 - 11,000 GDP/capita): Select sticks ..................................... 125
4. Zone 4: (> USD 11,000 GDP/capita): Only sticks ........................................................ 125
5. Use of other measures to justify exceptions .............................................................. 126
6. Suggested carrots and sticks ...................................................................................... 127
B. Mandatory corporate due diligence legislation ............................................................. 133
C. Lifting protection for investments into child labour sectors .......................................... 136
VIII. Linkages and interactions between proposed interventions ......................................... 136
IX. WTO compatibility ............................................................................................................ 136
X. About the Authors ............................................................................................................. 142
XI. About Development International e.V. ............................................................................ 143
Annex I – Child labour metrics ............................................................................................... 144
1. UNICEF ........................................................................................................................ 144
2. Maplecroft .................................................................................................................. 144
3. ILO ............................................................................................................................... 145
4. World Bank ................................................................................................................. 145
Annex II – EU imports associated with child labour .............................................................. 147
Annex III – Examples of TSD Chapters ................................................................................... 150
Bibliography ........................................................................................................................... 153
12
List of Tables
Table 1: Notable U.S. Legislation and Instruments ................................................................... 6
Table 2: Four-zone System of Incentives and Disincentives ..................................................... 7
Table 3: Pillars of United Nations Guiding Principles .............................................................. 24
Table 4: Top Five Exporting Industries with Risk of Child Labour in their Supply Chains, Direct
and Indirect Contributions, by Region (2015) ......................................................................... 30
Table 5: Product-level Methodology and Exceptions .............................................................. 32
Table 6: Top 20 In-Scope Countries Exporting to the EU with Child Labour (Ordered by the
Contribution to the Estimated EUR Value of Child Labour)..................................................... 37
Table 7: Top 10 In-scope Commodities Exported to the EU with Child Labour (Ordered by the
Contribution to the Estimated EUR Value of Child Labour)..................................................... 38
Table 8: Top 5 In-scope Countries and Goods Contributing to Child Labour in Eastern and
South-Eastern Asia ................................................................................................................... 39
Table 9: Top 5 In-scope Countries and Goods Contributing to Child Labour in Central and
Southern Asia ........................................................................................................................... 40
Table 10: Top 5 In-scope Countries and Goods Contributing to Child Labour in Latin America
and the Caribbean.................................................................................................................... 42
Table 11: Top 5 In-scope Countries and Goods Contributing to Child Labour in Northern
Africa and Western Asia........................................................................................................... 43
Table 12: Top 5 In-scope Countries and Goods Contributing to Child Labour in Sub-Saharan
Africa ........................................................................................................................................ 44
Table 13: Top 10 In-Scope Countries Exporting to the EU with Forced/Indentured Child
Labour (Ordered by the Contribution to the Estimated EUR Value of Forced/Indentured
Child Labour) ............................................................................................................................ 46
Table 14: Top 10 In-scope Commodities Exported to the EU with Forced/Indentured Child
Labour (Ordered by the Contribution to the Estimated EUR Value of Forced/Indentured
Child Labour) ............................................................................................................................ 46
Table 15: Decrease in School Absenteeism, Country Examples .............................................. 65
Table 16: U.S. Policy to Impose Sanctions or Other Actions on the Grounds of Child Labour
and Other Labour Rights Violations ......................................................................................... 80
Table 17: Ratification of ILO Standards C138 and C182, and the UN CRC ............................ 106
Table 18: Comparison Between German Draft Lieferkettengesetz and FDVL ...................... 118
Table 19: Possible Carrots ..................................................................................................... 127
Table 20: Possible Sticks ........................................................................................................ 130
Table 21: Membership and Ratifications............................................................................... 141
Table 22: EU Imports Associated With Child Labour – Example of Cocoa, Cotton, Rice, Sugar
Cane, and Tobacco ................................................................................................................. 147
Table 23: Treatment of Child Labour in TDS Chapters .......................................................... 150
13
List of Figures
Figure 1: % of Goods Entering the EU (Economic Value) .......................................................... 4
Figure 2: Children’s Involvement in Child Labour and Hazardous Work, Percentage and
Absolute Number of Children, 5-17 Age Range, 2000-2016 ................................................... 20
Figure 3: Nowcast of Extreme Poverty, 2015-2021 ................................................................. 21
Figure 4: Child Labour and Hazardous Work by Region, Percentage and Absolute Number (in
Thousands) of Children, 5-17 Age Range, 2016 ....................................................................... 28
Figure 5: Estimated of Child Labour and Value Added for Exported Goods and Services and
Domestic Demand by Region (2015) ....................................................................................... 29
Figure 6: Child Labour Bubble Map ......................................................................................... 36
Figure 7: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Child Labour by Region
.................................................................................................................................................. 38
Figure 8: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Child Labour from
Countries in Eastern and South-Eastern Asia Region .............................................................. 40
Figure 9: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Child Labour from
Countries in Central and Southern Asia Region ....................................................................... 41
Figure 10: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Child Labour from
Countries in Latin America and Caribbean .............................................................................. 42
Figure 11: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Child Labour from
Countries in Northern Africa and Western Asia ...................................................................... 43
Figure 12: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Child Labour from
Countries in Sub-Saharan Africa .............................................................................................. 44
Figure 13: Forced or Indentured Child Labour Bubble Map .................................................... 45
Figure 14: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Forced or Indentured
Child Labour ............................................................................................................................. 47
Figure 15: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Forced or Indentured
Child Labour from Countries in Eastern and South-Eastern Asia Region ................................ 48
Figure 16: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Forced or Indentured
Child Labour from Countries in Central and Southern Asia ..................................................... 48
Figure 17: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Forced or Indentured
Child Labour from Countries in Sub-Saharan Africa ................................................................ 49
Figure 18: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Forced or Indentured
Child Labour from Countries in Latin America and Caribbean ................................................ 50
Figure 19: Impact of Export Growth on Child Labour.............................................................. 56
Figure 20: Demand for Labour ................................................................................................. 61
Figure 21: Child Labour Prevalency vs. Multidimensional Poverty ......................................... 63
Figure 22: India, Children Out of School vs. Income (GDP/capita, PPP, $ Inflation Adjusted) 64
Figure 23: EU Trade Agreements With Third Countries, 2019 ................................................ 69
Figure 24: ILAB’s Organisational Chart .................................................................................... 93
Figure 25: Evolution of U.S. Labour Commitments ................................................................. 96
Figure 26: Five Categories of Civil Society Mechanisms for TSD Chapters.............................. 99
Figure 27: Approvals for IPEC+ Child Labour and Forced Labour Projects (Extra-budgetary
Allocations) ............................................................................................................................ 109
Figure 28: FUNDAMENTALS Branch Structure ...................................................................... 110
Figure 29: Due Diligence, Legislative and Movement Initiatives in Europe .......................... 112
Figure 30: GDP Per Capita vs. Life Expectancy, Zone 1-4 ...................................................... 123
Figure 31: GDP Per Capita vs. Share of Children in Employment, 2012; Zone 1-4................ 123
14
Acronyms
AAT
AFET
AfT
BAFA
BoP
CACL
CBP
CETA
CFR
CIR
CLMRS
CLMS
CLP
CO2
COVID19
CRC
CRS
CSR
CTEO
DAG
DCFTA
DCI
DCLDDA
DEVE
DHS
DOL
DOS
DRC
EBA
EDF
EDH
EEAS
EESC
EFA
EFSD+
EIDHR
ELM
ENI
EO
EPA
EU
EUR
Advanced-Afghan Trade
Committee on Foreign Affairs
Aid for Trade
Federal Office for Economic Affairs and Export Control (Germany)
Balance of Payments
Campaign Against Child Labour
Customs and Border Protection (U.S.)
EU-Canada Free Trade Agreement
Federal Acquisition Regulations System (U.S.)
Common Implementing Regulation
Child Labour Monitoring and Remediation System
Child Labour Monitoring System
Child Labour Platform (ILO)
Carbon dioxide
Coronavirus Disease 2019
UN Convention of the Rights of the Child
Congressional Research Service
Corporate Social Responsibility
Chief Trade Enforcement Officer
Domestic Advisory Group
Comprehensive and Free Trade Areas
Development Cooperation Instrument
Dutch Child Labour Due Diligence Act
Committee on Development (European Parliament)
U.S. Department of Homeland Security
U.S. Department of Labor
U.S. Department of State
Democratic Republic of the Congo
Everything But Arms
European Development Fund
Enterprises pour les Droits de l'Homme
European External Action Service
European Economic and Social Committee
European Free Alliance
European Fund for Sustainable Development Plus
European Instrument for Democracy and Human Rights
External Lending Mandate
European Neighbourhood Instrument
Executive Order
Economic Partnership Agreement
European Union
Euro
15
EVFTA
FDI
FLEGT
FDVL
FPF
FTA
FY
GATT
GCLMS
GDP
GFEA
GNI
GNP
GSP
HRDD
HSI
ICE
ICT
IISD
ILAB
ILO
IMF
INP
INTA
IOE
IOM
IPA
IPEC
IPEC+
JEFTA
LFS
LSMS
MBM
MCC
MEP
MFF
MFN
mHRDD
MICS
MOU
NDICI
NORC
OCFT
ODA
European Union–Vietnam Free Trade Agreement
Foreign Direct Investment
Forest Law Enforcement, Governance and Trade
French Duty of Vigilance Law
Field Production Facility
Free Trade Agreements
Fiscal Year
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
Ghana Child Labor Monitoring System
Gross Domestic Product
Guarantee Fund for External Action
Gross National Income
Gross National Product
Generalised System of Preferences
Human Rights Due Diligence
Homeland Security Investigations
Immigration and Customs Enforcement (U.S.)
Information and Communication Technology
International Institute for Sustainable Development
Bureau of International Labor Affairs (USDOL)
International Labour Organization
International Monetary Fund
Indigenous Natural Product
Committee on International Trade (European Parliament)
International Organisation of Employers
International Organization for Migration
Investment Protection Agreements
International Programme on the Elimination of Child Labour
International Programme on the Elimination of Child Labour and Forced
Labour
Japan-EU Free Trade Agreement
National Labour Force Surveys
Living Standards Measurement Study
Market Basket Measure
Millennium Challenge Corporation
Member of the European Parliament
Multiannual Financial Framework
Most Favoured Nation
mandatory Human Rights Due Diligence
Multiple Indicator Cluster Survey
Memorandum of Understanding
Neighbourhood, Development and International Cooperation Instrument
National Opinion Research Center (University of Chicago)
Office of Child Labor, Forced Labor, and Human Trafficking
Official Development Assistance
16
OECD
OEM
OFAC
OHCHR
OHS
OIRER
OPHI
OTLA
PI
PPP
RBC
RICO
SC/ST
SDG
SIMPOC
TCA
TDA
TFTEA
TIP
TSD
TULRAA
TVPA
TVPRA
UK
UN
UNCTAD
UNDP
UNESCO
UNGA
UNGPs
UNICEF
U.S.
USD
USDOL
USMCA
USMCC
USTR
VCLT
VPA
WFCL
WRO
WSR
WTO
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
Original Equipment Manufacturer
Office of Foreign Assets Control (U.S.)
Office of the High Commissioner for Human Rights
Occupational Health and Safety
Office of International Relations and Economic Research
Oxford Poverty and Human Development Initiative
Office of Trade and Labor Affairs (U.S.)
Partnership Instrument
Purchasing Power Parity
Responsible Business Conduct
Racketeering Influenced Corrupt Organizations
Scheduled Caste and Scheduled Tribes
Sustainable Development Goals
Statistical Information and Monitoring Programme on Child Labour
Trade and Cooperation Agreement (EU-UK)
Trade and Development Act (U.S.)
Trade Facilitation and Trade Enforcement Act (U.S.)
Trafficking In Persons
Trade and Sustainable Development
Trade Union and Labor Relations Adjustment Act (South Korea)
Trafficking Victims Protection Act (U.S.)
Trafficking Victims Protection Reauthorization Act (U.S.)
United Kingdom
United Nations
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development
United Nations Development Programme
United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization
United Nations General Assembly
United Nations Guiding Principles
United Nations Children’s Fund
United States
U.S. Dollar
U.S. Department of Labor
U.S.-Mexico-Canada Agreement
U.S. Millennium Challenge Corporation
United States Trade Representative
Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties
Voluntary Partnership Agreements
Worst Forms of Child Labour
Withhold Release Order
Worker-driven Social Responsibility
World Trade Organization
17
Foreword by Saskia Bricmont
50 billion Euros. This is what I call the “European child labour footprint”. In 2019, we
imported goods tainted with child labour to fulfil our needs as consumers for an amount
representing close to 100 Euros per European. Yet, the 50 billion figure does not capture the
full extent of the child labour phenomenon since most children (about 80%) work on familybased farms producing goods that do not enter global supply chains.
When taking office, President of the European Commission, Ursula von der Leyen made the
strong pledge of “zero tolerance towards child labour”. Two years have passed, and to be
honest, we have not witnessed any meaningful steps to make this commitment concrete.
We are now in 2021, the UN Year for the Elimination of Child Labour, which unfortunately
coincides with a reversal of the global downward trend in child labour. Years of progress will
be wiped out by the pandemic that will increase millions of working children due to school
closures, job losses and deepening poverty.
This scourge is usually viewed through the lens of development and cooperation policy.
Here, it is worth noting that the commitment taken by the EU and its Members States to
devote 0.7% of their GNP in official development assistance has not been honoured: the
EU27 collective effort peaked at 0.49% of EU Gross National Income (GNI) in 2016 before
sliding to 0,41% in 2019. Only three Member States met their ODA commitments:
Luxembourg, Sweden, Denmark.
In front of the Members of the European Parliament, Commission Executive Vice-President
Valdis Dombrovskis, then candidate for the trade portfolio affirmed that “in today’s world,
trade is about much more than just trade. European trade policy must do more to help us
meet the great challenges of our time.” And as rightly stated by the European Commission,
“the EU as a main global trade partner has a crucial role to play towards the elimination of
child labour in global supply chains.”
Taking these assertions at face value, I commissioned this study to follow up on President
von der Leyen in view of coming forward with proposals putting the EU at the forefront
when it comes to the achievement of SDG 8.7 on the eradication of child labour, forced
labour and modern slavery by 2025 and in the context of this UN Year.
It is worth noting that against the backdrop of the UN Year, the EU is about to strike deals
with two countries flagged among the main countries featuring child labour: China (EUR 37
billion) and Brazil (EUR 908 million). It would be a missed opportunity and a moral failure
not to tackle child labour in these contexts.
This study demonstrates that a mere prohibition of the entry into the EU market of goods
produced with child labour may lead to a counterintuitive outcome: an outright prohibition
would push children further away in informal and dangerous activities in countries where
enforcement activity is defaulting and where there are no worthy alternatives such as
education and basic social protection.
18
Internationalisation can lead to a lowering of child labour participation firstly by increasing
incomes. Therefore, increasing tariffs as a sanction of badly behaving countries may even
aggravate the problem while they are intended to deter countries from using child labour.
The study also shows the importance of decent working conditions for women to avoid that
children are put to work. A 10% increase of their wages can lead to a 10% decrease of the
need to send girls to factories, mines or fields. The textile, leather and footwear but also the
agriculture sectors, where they comprise a major portion of the workforce, are a case in
point.
Therefore, it would make sense to enlarge the range of conventions referred to in TSD
chapters of our FTA’s (Free Trade Agreements) or in the GSP Regulation (that already covers
the Convention n°182 on Worst Forms of Child Labour) to Conventions n°138 on the
minimum age for employment, n°189 on domestic workers, n°156 on workers with family
responsibilities, n°190 on violence and harassment. The EU could help trade partners and
countries in implementing these instruments properly and foster capacity building, including
when it comes to collecting data to monitor progress. Drawing the lessons of the report of
the panel of experts that settled the dispute on social rights between the EU and South
Korea and drawing on the approach adopted in the political cooperation agreement with
Vietnam, it is important that trade agreements and the likes contain a roadmap with
milestones and concrete and verifiable objectives to come to terms with child labour.
If the COVID-19 pandemic has disruptive consequences, climate change could also
exacerbate child labour. The expected increasing number of natural disasters like floods or
droughts as well as severe and extreme heat events will cause even more temporary or
chronic emergency conditions, jeopardising family incomes and imperilling school
infrastructure.
The study opens different avenues to feed future legislative initiatives. Autonomous EU
measures could be designed along the lines of the U.S. Tariff Act of 1930, amended by the
U.S Trade Facilitation and Trade Enforcement Act of 2015. Up to 15% of children at work are
estimated to be active in global value chains. This is an issue that should be properly
addressed in the forthcoming due diligence legislation.
A surgical blacklisting approach targeting individuals and companies could be grounded on
the new EU Global Human Rights Sanctions Regime adopted in December 2020.
The EU is putting in place a robust framework for its climate and digital revolution. Yet, for
this to happen, the EU needs to secure its supply of raw materials, for which we are highly
dependent on the rest of the World. The EU identifies 30 raw materials as strategic, but 7 of
them are indicated as child labour-tainted in the U.S. List of Goods Produced by Child Labor
or Forced Labor (Cobalt, Coking Coal, Fluorspar, Natural Rubber, Tantalum, Tungsten, and
Natural Graphite). The recent EU action plan for critical raw materials evokes that “high
supply concentration in countries with low standards of governance not only poses a
security of supply risk, but may also exacerbate environmental and social problems, such as
child labour.” Therefore, to be coherent, it is also urgent that our trade relations with
countries richly endowed with such resources duly tackle this risk, for instance by designing
provisions in agreements in liaison with the ILO and local civil society organisations.
19
Objective 8.7 could be pursued through a plurilateral, innovative and trade-based initiative
backed by the EU and the members of the U.S.-Mexico-Canada Agreement (USMCA) in the
first place, since they represent about 45% of all import of goods and services and host
many multinational decision centres topping global value chains. The next stage could be to
gather the support of like-minded countries like Australia and New Zealand and possibly
Japan and South Korea. These four countries are close to the Eastern and South-Eastern
Asian region where child labour is the most prominent and members of the recent Regional
Comprehensive Economic Partnership, along with problematic countries.
Technology transfer fostering mechanisation in some sectors could decrease the demand
for child labour in some countries. This is where investment agreements come in that
promote such FDI. I note also that the authors “recommend lifting protection for Foreign
Direct Investment (FDI) into sectors steeped with child labour through the reform of
Investment Protection Agreements (IPAs).”
I am very grateful to the dream team of Development International e.V., their network of
committed researchers for this landmark study, and for their inclusive work that benefitted
from comments of leading experts from the ILO, UNICEF and NGOs.
I sincerely hope that this very valuable report and the recommendations will contribute to
making Europe the first “fair and ethical trade” continent.
20
I. Introduction
The good news is that the estimated prevalence of child labour dropped by almost 40% to
the begin of the new millennium. Between 2000 and 2016, according to the International
Labour Organization (International Labour Office, 2017a) estimates, the world witnessed a
net reduction of 94 million children exposed to child labour, from an estimated 246 million
to 152 million children.
Figure 2: Children’s Involvement in Child Labour and Hazardous Work, Percentage and Absolute Number of
Children, 5-17 Age Range, 2000-2016
Note: Bubbles are proportionate to the absolute number of children in child labour and hazardous work.
Source: Global estimates of child labour: Results and trends, 2012-2016, (International Labour Office, 2017a), URL
The bad news is that the trend of decreasing child labour will, however, likely be reversed
due to global economic contraction precipitated by the COVID-19 pandemic. One study
performed in Tamil Nadu exemplifies how the financial strains created by COVID-19 are
driving children to work: released by the Campaign Against Child Labour (CACL), a survey
conducted in 24 districts by child rights specialists R. Vidyasagar and K. Shyamalanachiar,
shows that the number of children in vulnerable communities (such as SC/ST) increased
from 231 to 650 compared to pre-COVID-19 levels (“Child Labour on the Rise,” 2021).
Indeed, an additional 86 million children are estimated to have fallen into poverty in 2020 as
their parents lost their source of income, forcing the children to interrupt their education
and some to work (United Nations Children’s Fund [UNICEF], 2020). According to World
Bank reporting, the number of people living in extreme poverty (living on less than $1.9 per
day) was steadily decreasing, but jumped by 119 million in 2020 (see Figure 3). From the
21
baseline of 2019, “the estimated COVID-19-induced poor is set to rise to between 143 and
163 million” (World Bank Blogs, 2021) in 2021.
Figure 3: Nowcast of Extreme Poverty, 2015-2021
Source: Updated estimates of the impact of COVID-19 on global poverty, (World Bank Blogs, 2021), URL
In a bid to step up efforts that reduce forced labour and child labour, the year 2021 has
been declared by the UN General Assembly as the Year for the Elimination of Child Labour.
The underlying unanimous United Nations General Assembly (UNGA) resolution called on
member states to “take immediate and effective measures to eradicate forced labour, end
modern slavery and human trafficking and secure the prohibition and elimination of the
worst forms of child labour, including recruitment and use of child soldiers, and by 2025 end
child labour in all its forms” (United Nations [UN], 2015a, p. 20).
As for the EU, the President of the European Commission, Ursula von der Leyen (2019), has
stated that EU trade policy should have ‘zero-tolerance’ for child labour. Prior to that
pronouncement, the Council Conclusions on Child Labour (Foreign Affairs Council, 2016) had
noted that the worst forms of child labour should have been eliminated by 2016 according
to the Roadmap (The Hague Global Child Labour Conference, 2010) adopted in The Hague in
2010 and reaffirmed in the Brasília Declaration on Child Labour (III Global Conference on
Child Labour, 2013) adopted in 2013. Furthermore, the Council had encouraged “the High
Representative and the Commission to explore how the EU can step up its contribution to
the realisation of SDG target 8.7 which calls for measures to [...] secure the prohibition and
elimination of the worst forms of child labour and by 2025 end child labour in all its forms”
22
(Foreign Affairs Council, 2016, p. 4).2 Lastly, the Council encouraged “the Commission, in line
with its ‘Trade for All: Towards a more responsible trade and investment policy’ strategy, to
continue exploring ways to use more effectively the trade instruments of the European
Union, including the Generalised Scheme of Preferences and Free Trade Agreements to
combat child labour” (Foreign Affairs Council, 2016, p. 4).
The European Parliament resolution of 7 October 2020 on the implementation of the
common commercial policy also treated the issue of child labour, notably in sections 54 and
55. Section 54 “calls on the Commission to monitor the progress made with respect to the
implementation of […] ILO conventions, and to set up without delay the interparliamentary
committee as agreed under the EVFTA, paying special attention to the prohibition of child
labour” (European Parliament, 2020b). Further, Section 55 “Recalls the need for an effective
action plan to implement the goal of zero tolerance of child labour in FTAs, by building a
strong partnership with NGOs and national authorities in order to develop strong social and
economic alternatives for families and workers, in coherence with actions taken under the
EU development policy.” Section 63 goes on to discuss the newly created role of the Chief
Trade Enforcement Officer (CTEO), chiefly “to monitor and improve compliance with the
EU’s trade agreements.” The section furthermore:
notes that rules under EU trade agreements should be properly enforced in order to
ensure their effectiveness and address market distortions; underlines the need for
this newly created post to focus on implementation and enforcement of our trade
agreements, as well as on breaches of market access and trade and sustainable
development commitments; is of the opinion that the CTEO should not only monitor
and enforce environmental and labour protection obligations under the EU trade
agreements with third countries, but also focus on implementation of all chapters of
trade agreements in order to guarantee that these are used to their full potential
(European Parliament, 2020b).
The extent to which child labour may simply be “eliminated” is, however, a matter of
contention. For one, an act of survival ought not be stigmatised. Two, target-setting should
be underpinned by a meaningful capacitation of beneficiaries. Stating that they could “no
longer continue blindly with the well-intended but unrealistic goal of eliminating child
labour by 2025” (“Open Letter: Change Course,” 2021) a group of 101 academics recently
called for the issue to be viewed rather through the lens of the UN Convention of the Rights
of the Child (CRC). The authors further cautioned that “eliminating child labour as a
resolution without addressing fundamental structural problems of poverty and inequality
will not be successful,” and that only removing children “from work is no help if this drives
them deeper into the famine and broken lives that the work was undertaken to mitigate”
(“Open Letter: Change Course”, 2021). Instead of a blanket prohibition of child work, the
aim, instead, should be to reduce truly harmful types of work, while, however, protecting
the utility of “beneficial work.” In response, the ILO highlights the fact that non-hazardous
child labour is also harmful; the empirical evidence showing that the practice is harmful to
children's education and future prospects (B. Smith, personal communication, May 20,
2 Indicator 8.7.1 of the UN Sustainable Development Goals is the
activity (%) – Annual.”
“Proportion of children engaged in economic
23
2021). Furthermore, the ILO notes that the CRC and ILO Conventions on child labour are in
no way at odds with each other (ibid).
To further compel exporting countries to root out the practice of child labour, one hard-line
option at the disposal of importing countries involves the imposition of trade conditionality
to the point of sanctions. For example, since the removal of the consumptive demand
exemption in 2016, the U.S. is banning goods from entering the country that are believed to
be produced with forced labour, including forced or indentured child labour. What began as
isolated sanctions against Xinjiang textile makers in August of 2020 (U.S. Department of the
Treasury, 2020) became a blanket ban on all Xinjiang cotton in January of 2021 – impacting
87% of China’s cotton crop and, consequently, one-fifth of the world’s supply (Dou et al.,
2021). Also the U.K. Government (2021) has taken measures to halting the importation of
goods that are linked to modern-day slavery in China.
Concerted supply chain action also at the individual corporate level – in the case of severe
human rights impacts – is e.g. also advised in the OECD Due Diligence Guidance for
Responsible Supply Chains of Minerals (OECD, 2016). Adopted in 2011, the OECD Guidance
features a due diligence framework for minerals production and trade, and Annex II
provides for companies to cease business relationships where their supply chains are linked,
inter alia, to the Worst Forms of Child Labour (WFCL).
II. Research Objectives
Overarching objective: This study seeks to provide evidence-based policy options that may
enhance the EU’s position to reduce child labour through its demand in traded goods, given
that current trade policy does not apply its own leverage on the issue to its full potential.
The EU’s leverage on the issue will be enhanced by introducing additional conditionality,
accountability, and corporate liability into future legislation, including bilateral trade
agreements and mandatory due diligence provisions. What are the relevant instruments at
the disposal of policymakers, as revealed by precedents? What toolkits would need to be
created? Scientific evidence and arguments will be furnished, resulting in an empirical basis
for such policy options. From the position of child wellbeing, maximally beneficial outcomes
will be proposed, mindful of externalities.
Overarching framework: Pillar I and Pillar II of the United Nations (UN, 2011) Guiding
Principles on Business and Human Rights (UNGPs) serve as the overarching framework of
this study. Unanimously endorsed by the United Nations Human Rights Council in 2011, the
UNGPs put forward 31 principles how nation-states and businesses should uphold human
rights, organised according to three pillars (see Table 3).
24
Table 3: Pillars of United Nations Guiding Principles
pillar
I
II
III
actor
State
Private sector
State + private sector
Duty
protect human rights
respect human rights
provide access to remedy for victims of business-related abuses
Study scope: Another way to describe the scope of this study is its application of 3 lenses:
--> EU-based legislative initiatives (ex novo or pipeline)
--> Application of the UNGPs as they apply to states, markets and victims
--> Products associated with child labour imported into the EU
In applying these three lenses, we must, however, add the caveat that the study will not
cover the full gamut of dimensions.
With the first and second pillar of the UNGPs serving as this study’s overarching framework,
the proposed legislative interventions advanced in this study align with the two pillars as
follows:
Pillar 1 – Protect: bilateral trade policy, multilateral engagement
Pillar 2 – Respect: mandatory due diligence legislation
To strengthen existing EU legislation vis-à-vis the UN Guiding Principles, and, in particular, to
leverage the market (e.g. trade block purchasing power, trade policy) toward that end, the
study will specifically focus on (1) bi-lateral trade agreements, (2) mandatory corporate due
diligence, and (3) investment codices.
Upon covering the research objectives (Chapter II) and research methods (Chapter III), this
report delves into the problem statement (Chapter IV), which notably covers sectors and
geographies where child labour is present, estimates the share of goods imported to the EU
made with child labour, as well as investigates the drivers of child labour and relevant
interventions through the eyes of scholarly works. Thereafter, the study investigates
measures related to the first UNGPs Pillar – i.e. the state’s duty to protect – and specifically
how the EU and U.S. treat the issue of child labour in trade policy and instruments, including
the use of sanctions targeting relevant corporate entities or goods to be imported (Chapter
V). Under the rubric of the second UNGPs pillar – i.e the corporate responsibility to respect
– the study assesses, in particular, existing and forthcoming supply chain due diligence
legislation (Chapter VI). Chapter VII ties our research findings to policy options, Chapter VIII
considers the interactions of the recommended reforms, and Chapter IX treats relevant
WTO provisions and potential approaches.
25
III. Methodology
The methodology pursued to carry out this study involved the following:
1.
Literature review: This study drew on primary and secondary literature. The
information obtained was triangulated between sources.
2.
Quantitative research: We consulted primary data provided by reputable sources in
order to estimate the value of goods entering the EU produced with child labour
(see section 1. Methodology applied for more details).
3.
Qualitative research: We conducted qualitative research methods to analyse data
sources and produce empirical findings.
4.
Peer review: the study was also peer-reviewed by notable experts in their
respective field of expertise.
IV. Problem Statement
A. Definitions
Considering the rightsholder point-of-view, it is imperative to distinguish between child
labour and the Worst Forms of Child Labour (WFCL), the latter however being a subset of
the former.
Child Labour: According to the International Labour Organization (ILO) Convention on the
Minimum Age (No. 138) of 1973, child labour is any employment or work below the age of
15 years of age (paragraph 3, Article 2). However, on the grounds of a country’s particular
economic development, poverty or lack of educational resources, the minimum age for
employment work may be lowered to 14 years (paragraph 4, Article 2).
ILO (1973) Convention 138 also establishes 18 as the minimum age for hazardous work:
“The minimum age for admission to any type of employment or work which by its nature or
the circumstances in which it is carried out is likely to jeopardise the health, safety or morals
of young persons shall not be less than 18 years” (paragraph 1, Article 3).
Yet, an optional "flexibility clause" was built into ILO Convention 138, of which countries
may avail themselves, pertaining only to hazardous work only. Employment or work above
the age of 16 years, however, does not qualify as child labour “on condition that the health,
safety and morals of the young persons concerned are fully protected and that the young
persons have received adequate specific instruction or vocational training in the relevant
branch of activity” (paragraph 3, Article 3).
Permissible light work: Under the age of 15 / 14, according to ILO (1973) C138, “light work”
is permitted for persons 13 to 15 years of age, which entails economic activity “(a) not likely
26
to be harmful to their health or development; and (b) not such as to prejudice their
attendance at school” (paragraph 1, Article 7). However, if the minimum age is set at 14,
light work may be permitted at the age of 12.
Worst Forms of Child Labour (WFCL): According to the ILO Convention on the Worst Forms
of Child Labour (No. 182) of 1999, the Worst Forms of Child Labour (WFCL) is work carried
out by persons below the age of 18 years that could likely harm the “health, safety or morals
of children.” Four types of WFCL are specifically called out in the convention: hazardous
work, slavery-like practices, use of children for commercial sexual exploitation, or in illicit
activities (Article 3).
Forced Labour: ILO Convention on Forced Labor (No. 29) of 1930 prohibits all forms of
forced or compulsory labour, which is defined as “all work or service which is exacted from
any person under the menace of any penalty and for which the person has not offered
himself voluntarily” (paragraph 1, Article 2).
Forced Child Labour: Under ILO (1999) C182, “forced child labor” is a type of the “worst
form of child labour.” Article 3a specifies that WFCL includes “all forms of slavery or
practices similar to slavery, such as the sale and trafficking of children, debt bondage and
serfdom and forced or compulsory labour, including forced or compulsory recruitment of
children for use in armed conflict.”
Referencing the ILO’s Revised Draft Guidelines (International Labour Office, 2018)
concerning the measurement of forced labour, USDOL defines forced child labour as follows.
Children older than the minimum age for work are in forced child labor if work is
involuntary and they are under the menace of penalty. For children younger than the
minimum age, voluntariness does not need to be established because children cannot
legally consent to work. Forced child labor also includes work performed with or for
the child’s parents for a third party under the threat or menace of any penalty
directly applied to the child or parents. All children who are made to work as a
result of parental forced labor are engaged in forced child labor (U.S. Department of
Labor, 2020a, p. 57).
B. Child labour lists
1. USDOL’s “List of Goods Produced by Child Labor or Forced Labor”
USDOL’s Bureau of International Labor Affairs (ILAB) “maintains a list of goods and their
source countries which it has reason to believe are produced by child labor or forced labor
in violation of international standards, as required under the Trafficking Victims Protection
Reauthorization Act (TVPRA) of 2005 and subsequent reauthorizations” (U.S. Department of
Labor, n.d.-a). As of September 2020, the biennial List of Goods comprised 144 goods
27
produced with child labour in 74 countries.3 Open-access resources include the full report
on the list of goods (U.S. Department of Labor, 2020a) and an interactive database (U.S.
Department of Labor, n.d.-a) disaggregating data per country and per good.
With respect to the context of this List of Goods, ILO (1973) Convention 138 serves as the
leading international standard in which each ratifying country – 173 to date (ILO, n.d.-c) –
undertakes to pursue a national policy designed to ensure the effective abolition of child
labour and to raise progressively the minimum age for admission to employment or work to
a level consistent with the fullest physical and mental development of young persons” (ILO,
1973). The terms and age limits of each age group are defined in section A. Definitions
above.
2. USDOL’s “List of Products Produced by Forced or Indentured Child Labor”
Pursuant to Executive Order 13126, ILAB also compiles the List of Products and their source
countries which it has “a reasonable basis to believe” they are “produced by forced or
indentured child labor” (U.S. Department of Labor, n.d.-c).
As of March 2019, the List of Products comprised 34 products from 25 countries. Available
resources include an interactive database per country and product. This list is then used to
ensure “that U.S. federal agencies do not procure goods made by forced or indentured child
labor” (U.S. Department of Labor, n.d.-c).
The broader context of this List of Products is the following:
1. With ILO Convention 182 – 187 ratifications to date (ILO, n.d.-c) – ratifiers “shall take
immediate and effective measures to secure the prohibition and elimination of the
worst forms of child labour as a matter of urgency” (ILO, 1999). The very definition of
the term Worst Forms of Child Labour, as per Article 3 of the convention, includes in
first place “(a) all forms of slavery or practices similar to slavery, such as the sale and
trafficking of children, debt bondage and serfdom and forced or compulsory labour
(…).”
2. With ILO Convention 29 – 179 ratifications to date (ILO, n.d.-c) – ratifiers undertake
to “suppress the use of forced or compulsory labour in all its forms within the
shortest possible period” (ILO, 1930).The term forced or compulsory labour is defined
as “all work or service which is exacted from any person under the menace of any
penalty and for which the said person has not offered himself voluntarily.”
3. With ILO Convention 105 – 176 ratifications to date (ILO, n.d.-c) – ratifiers undertake
to “suppress and not to make use of any form of forced or compulsory labour” (ILO,
3
The European Commission (2020d) prepared a list of critical raw material (CRM). In its last 2020 revision, the
EU list contains 30 materials which 7 of them were flagged by USDOL as produced with child labour: Cobalt,
Coking Coal, Fluorspar, Natural Rubber, Tantalum, Tungsten, and Natural Graphite (as part of “Stones”
exported in certain countries flagged by USDOL).
28
1957), including “(b) as a method of mobilising and using labour for purposes of
economic development.”
C. Sectors and geographies with child labour practices
In terms of economic domains, 70.9% of child labourers globally were engaged in
agricultural work (108 million). The remaining child labourers worked in services (17.2%),
and the others in some form of industry (11.9%) (International Labour Office, 2017a).
In terms of regional differences, the African continent is home to the highest number of
child labourers, as well as the highest number of children performing hazardous work (see
Figure 4). While Asia and the Pacific trail in second place, in absolute terms they do not have
far fewer child labourers than Africa.
Figure 4: Child Labour and Hazardous Work by Region, Percentage and Absolute Number (in Thousands) of
Children, 5-17 Age Range, 2016
Note: Bubble size is proportionate to absolute number of children in child labour and hazardous work in each region.
Source: Global estimates of child labour: Results and trends, 2012-2016, (International Labour Office, 2017a), URL
Agriculture and industry are domains that have supply chains also reaching the EU: IPEC+
estimated that between 5-15% of child labourers are estimated to be working in global
supply chains (ILO, 2017).
29
A study by Alsamawi et al. (2019) estimates the “extent to which child labour within a region
is estimated to contribute to exports” (p. 19). Applying the symmetric input-output table
method, the added value of products made with child labour destined for export is derived
through information including “compensation of employees, gross operating surplus, and
other taxes on production” (Alsamawi et al., 2019, p. 4).
Considerably more child labour occurs in production linked to domestic production and
consumption than production linked to exports, as Figure 5 depicts. This is particularly the
case in “regions where children in child labour are mainly involved in family-based
subsistence agriculture" (ILO et al., 2019, p. 8). Furthermore, the “added value” of child
labour in products destined for export varies from 12% in Sub-Saharan Africa and Central
and Southern Asia to 26% in Eastern and South Eastern Asia.
Figure 5: Estimated of Child Labour and Value Added for Exported Goods and Services and Domestic Demand
by Region (2015)
Source: Measuring child labour, forced labour and human trafficking in global supply chains, (Alsamawi et al., 2019), URL
Drilling down further, particular industries of global supply chains are particularly exposed
to child labour, as uncovered in a recent report by the ILO, IOM, OECD, and UNICEF, under
the aegis of Alliance 8.7 (ILO et al., 2019). Depicted in Table 4, for each of the above
featured regions, are the five exporting industries most at risk of having child labour present
in their exported products. The column “By DIRECT contributions” counts only direct
contributions in the final stage of production and the column “By INDIRECT contributions”
counts only indirect contributions from upstream inputs of the supply chain. The table
illustrates that child labour is a scourge that is found across regions and sectors, also where
the practice is less well documented.
30
Table 4: Top Five Exporting Industries with Risk of Child Labour in their Supply Chains, Direct and Indirect
Contributions, by Region (2015)
Region
Sub-Saharan Africa
Eastern and South-Eastern
Asia
Central & Southern Asia
Northern Africa and
Western Asia
Latin America and the
Caribbean
By DIRECT contributions
Agriculture
Wholesale and retail
Transport and storage
Textiles and apparel
Food products
Agriculture
Textiles and apparel
Wholesale and retail
Mining, energy
Transport and storage
Textiles and apparel
Agriculture
Wholesale and retail
Transport and storage
Food products
Agriculture
Wholesale and retail
Transport and storage
Mining, energy
Accommodation and food
Agriculture
Wholesale and retail
Accommodation and food
Transport and storage
Textiles and apparel
By INDIRECT contributions
Food Products
Mining, non-energy
Basic metals
Transport and storage
Wholesale and retail
Food and products
Textiles and apparel
Wood
Mining, energy
ICT and electronics
Textile and apparel
Food products
Wholesale and retail
Transport and storage
Other business services
Food products
Mining, energy
Textiles and apparel
Wholesale and retail
Agriculture
Food and products
Motor vehicles
Chemicals
Basic metals
Textiles and apparel
Source: Ending child labour, forced labour and human trafficking in global supply chains, (ILO et al., 2019), URL
D. Share of child labour exposure in products imported to the EU
1. Methodology applied
The question arises: What is the "Child labour footprint" of EU trade flows, the major
sectors concerned (e.g., cocoa, textile, mining, etc.), and the countries of origin? In the
absence of a child labour “added value” measure for each product imported into Europe, it
must be derived. For the purposes of estimating the volumes of child labour-tainted goods
exported to the EU, we applied the following methodology:
1. For child labour, we consulted the products listed in the USDOL List of Goods
Produced by Child Labor or Forced Labor 4 (U.S. Department of Labor, 2020a),
and for forced/indentured child labour we consulted USDOL’s “List of
4
USDOL List is updated biannually. Its latest publication was in 2020, which is used to apply the methodology
as it covers year 2019.
31
Products Produced by Forced or Indentured Child Labor” (U.S. Department of
Labor, n.d.-c).
2. We matched the EU import trade data5 per listed commodity and exporting
country for 2019 using Eurostat Comext (European Commission, 2021a).
3. We multiplied the trade data by the % of child labour value-added for
exported goods and services, by region – as per Alsamawi et al. (2019).
4. We aggregated the commodity-specific results.
The methodology we applied to match the commodities listed by USDOL with the codes of
products (as per Comext) was as follows:
1. We swept all codes potentially related to the commodity (by name, including
technical or scientific name).
2. We opted for the parent category (two digits codes in Comext) whenever a
commodity was well represented according to the USDOL term. In
exceptional cases, lower hierarchy codes (four, six, eight digits codes) were
used in combination with higher ones (two digits codes). E.g., for Copper,
Zinc, and Tin, higher categories involving “articles made of” were considered,
but also the minerals’ ore (lower). In addition, the following was taken into
account while applying this step:
a. We considered generic parent codes when USDOL-flagged products
were generic as well.6
b. We considered the commodity’s next step of value addition where
such scope was implied in the USDOL terminology, to assess whether
child labour may be involved or whether the commodity remains the
principal component of the category. However, codes representing
products that required a sophisticated industrial process or highskilled labour were excluded (as we assumed more supply chain
oversight). This did not apply when the USDOL flagged product
indicated otherwise.7
5 Importation into 28 EU member countries, including the UK, which, in 2019, was still part of the European
Union.
6
E.g. for Meat, the matching code selected was “02- Meat and edible meat offal”, as there were no further
specifications of the type of meat (bovine, fish, pig, etc.).
7
E.g. USDOL flagged “Leather” for Bangladesh, Pakistan and Viet Nam, “Leather Goods” for México, and
“Leather Goods/Accessories” for India. For the first commodity, the selected matching code was “Raw hides
and skins (other than furskins) and leather,” further processed products would involve clothing, accessories,
bags, etc. However, we considered that more sophisticated skills are needed, so no additional codes were
added. But, for Mexico and India, leather goods further processed were specifically flagged so, the selected
matching code was “Articles of leather; saddlery and harness; travel goods, handbags and similar containers;
articles of animal gut (other than silkworm gut).”
32
c. We performed a duplicate control per country to make sure that
there was no duplication of codes.8
d. Any other consideration or exception was marked and added as a
footnote in Table 5.
3. We opted for the next lower hierarchy category (four, six, eight digit codes) if
there were no matches in step 2. Also, the following method was applied:
a. We searched for codes that contain only the selected category.
b. In the event we did not obtain a clear 1=1 match, we proceeded to
analyse the codes containing the flagged commodity and up to one
non-flagged commodity (Table 5, step 2 exception e f h i shows
commodities where also two non-flagged commodities were
included). There, the working assumption was that similar production
behaviour regarding child labour would be present.
c. We considered the commodity in the successive step of value addition
(if applicable as per the USDOL designation) to analyse if child labour
could be involved or whether the commodity remains the principal
component of the category. However, codes representing products
that required a sophisticated industrial process or high-skilled labour
were excluded (as we assumed more supply chain oversight).
d. Any other consideration or exception was marked and added as a
footnote in Table 5.
Table 5: Product-level Methodology and Exceptions
Methodology
step applied
Step 2
8
Selection of parent
category
(two-digit codes)
Meat; Cereal Grains;
Cocoa; Tobacco;
Pyrotechnics; Rubber;
Leather; Leather
Goods; Timber;
Selection of next lower hierarchy category (four, six,
eight digit codes)
Exceptions
-
Textiles;
Copper*;
Zinc*; Tin*;
Electronics*
To ensure zero double counting, further controls were performed on the final list of codes. First, a control in
Excel prevented “Country-Commodity Code” duplication. Second, to each code we assigned a level of
hierarchy (1, 2, 3, 4), which allowed us to identify the next immediate previous hierarchy code, and with an
excel formula we searched in the final list for the combination “Country – Previous Immediate Hierarchy
Commodity Code.” Third, a similar step was applied for levels 3 and 4, to identify if in the final list there was a
higher category for level 1 and 2. Forth, any duplicate found was excluded, and in the case of higher and lower
categories, we opted to exclude the lower ones. Fifth, five commodities with multiple codes that had no flags
for duplicates were further investigated to prove that it was indeed correct that there were not any flags.
Application example: for code “country-07108070” (level 4) in the second step we looked for a match with a
code level 3 “country-071080.” In the third step, we searched for a match with level 2 “country-0710” and level
1 “country-07.”
33
Step 3
No matches
Cotton; Carpets;
Garments; Footwear;
Ceramics; Glass;
Furniture
-
Alcoholic Beverages; Baked Goods; Bamboo; Bananas;
Beans (soy)a;
Beans; Beef; Blueberries; Bovines; Brazil
Bidis b (handNuts/Chestnuts; Broccoli; Cabbages; Carrots; Cashews;
rolled c
Cattle; Charcoal; Chile Peppers; Citrus Fruits; Cloves;
cigarettes);
Coal; Cobalt ore; Coca; Coconuts; Coffee; Corn;
Bricks c;
Cottonseed; Cucumbers; Cumin; Diamonds; Dried Fish;
Thread/Yarn d;
Eggplants; Embellished Textiles; Fashion Accessories;
Sapphires e;
Fireworks; Fish; Flowers; Fluorspar; Footwear (sandals);
Rubies f;
Fruits (Pome and Stone); Garlic; Gems; Goats; Gold;
Toys g;
Granite; Grapes; Gravel (crushed stones); Gypsum;
Surgical
Hazelnuts; Hogs; Incense (agarbatti); Lettuce; Lobsters;
Instruments h;
Locks; Manioc; Matches; Melons; Nile Perch (fish); Oil
Emeralds i
(palm); Olives; Onions; Peanuts; Pepper; Peppers;
Pineapples: Poppies; Potatoes; Poultry; Pulses; Rice;
Salt; Sand; Sesame; Sheep; Shellfish; Shrimp; Silk Fabric;
Silver; Sisal; Soap; Soccer Balls; Stones; Limestone;
Pumice; Strawberries; Sugar Beets; Sugarcane; Sweet
Potatoes; Tantalum ore; Tea; Tin ore; Tomatoes;
Tungsten ore; Vanilla; Yerba Mate
Beans (green beans, yellow beans); Brassware; Bricks (clay); Furniture (steel); Glass Bangles;
Granite (crushed); Jade; Khat/Miraa (stimulant plant); Pornography; Tanzanite; Teak; Trona
Notes:
* Codes where lower hierarchy codes were used in combination with higher ones, however controlling for
double counting.
a
USDOL Flagged Beans (green, soy, yellow), as there were no matches for green or yellow beans, only soy was
considered.
b
For Bidis, matching selected commodity was “Cigars, Cheroots and Cigarettes of tobacco [..]” as we assume
bidis are included and the country mainly exports that type of cigarettes.
cdg
These commodities are manufactured goods (they are the result of industrial processes), we excluded
some codes that contained the commodity as we considered highly unlikely a child being involved in the
production e.g. refractory bricks.
efhi
Exceptional cases where up to two non-flagged commodities were included (due to Comext coding).
2. Example child labour commodities
In order to illustrate this method, we highlight five products amongst those listed in the
USDOL 2020 List of Goods,9 namely Cocoa, Cotton, Sugarcane, Rice and Tobacco. The value
in euros of importations of commodities to the EU was obtained by the EU database Comext
(European Commission, 2021a) for the year 2019 and matched with the data contained in
the 2020 USDOL List of Goods. Data for the third step were drawn from Alsamawi et al.
(2019), and countries were matched to the regional data using the UN Standard country or
area codes for statistical use (M49) (United Nations, 2020). The discussion below
summarises the findings of five example commodities, further enumerated for each
identified country in Annex I.
Cocoa: Cocoa has been identified as being produced by child labour in seven (7) countries
partners of the EU, i.e. Brazil, Cameroon, Ghana, Guinea, Côte d’Ivoire, Nigeria and Sierra
9
USDOL’s 2020 list was applied as it represents a biennial list. There was no list published in 2019.
34
Leone. Ghana and the Ivory Coast were the largest EU cocoa trade partners in 2019
(amounting to over EUR 1 billion and EUR 3 billion, respectively) and Brazil was the smallest.
Since Alsamawi et al. (2019) estimate that in Sub-Saharan Africa, 12% of exported goods and
services are produced with child labour, and 22% in Latin America, the total value of cocoa
flowing into the EU in 2019, produced with child labour, was worth approximately EUR 648
million. More than half of that value – an estimated EUR 373 million – was produced with
child labour in Côte d’Ivoire alone.10
Cotton: According to the 2020 USDOL List, 15 countries produce cotton with child labour,
with Turkey, China and India being identified by the Comext database as the largest
exporters in 2019 (amounting to over EUR 751 million, EUR 416 million and EUR 415 million,
respectively). Turkey, China and India had child labour value added of 9%, 26% and 12%,
respectively. Accordingly, Turkey’s share of cotton produced with child labour and imported
to the EU in 2019 was estimated to be EUR 67,641,399, that of China EUR 108,301,926,
whilst that of India estimated to be EUR 49,860,002. In total, the value added from child
labour for all 15 cotton-producing countries came to EUR 247 million in 2019.
Rice: In 2019, 5 countries grew rice with child labour according to USDOL: Brazil, Myanmar
(Burma), India, Philippines and Viet Nam. Among them, India and Myanmar were the largest
exports of rice to the EU, with exports worth EUR 223,058,929 and EUR 160,995,597,
respectively. Given the degree of child labour in each country, the rice value added by child
labour in Myanmar was EUR 41,858,855, and EUR 26,767,929 in India. Among the 5
identified countries, the total child labour value added for rice was an estimated EUR
76,164,154 in 2019.
Sugarcane: Nineteen (18) countries are identified by the 2020 USDOL List as producing
sugarcane with child labour, 17 of which exported to the EU in 2019. The Comext database,
which provides data on imports of cane sugar, identifies Belize and Brazil as the largest 2019
exporters of these products to Europe (with exports amounting to over 54 million and 76
million euros, respectively). Belize and Brazil produced an estimated EUR 12,011,958 and
EUR 16,771,052, respectively, each with child labour value added of 22%. In total, the
10 In 2019, Côte d’Ivoire exported 1,343,072,400 kg of cocoa
to the EU, a value of EUR 3,110,025,709. This
value is, in our methodology, multiplied by 12% in order to obtain the child labour value added. Yet in order to
double-check whether the 12% child labour value added estimate by Alsamawi et al. (2019) lines up with a
specific commodity sourced from Sub-saharan Africa, we draw on figures available from the cocoa sector of
Côte d’Ivoire. According to 2018/19 survey data reported by the child labour prevalence figures in the report
"NORC Final Report: Assessing Progress in Reducing Child Labor in Cocoa Production in Cocoa Growing Areas of
Côte d’Ivoire and Ghana"(Sadhu et al., 2020), data from agricultural households (with at least one child in the
5-17 age group) in the cocoa growing areas of Côte d’Ivoire indicate that an estimated 790,647 children were
engaged in child labour in cocoa production in Côte d’Ivoire. This works out to 38% of Ivorian children working
as child labourers in cocoa growing areas. Incidentally, almost all of these children – 770,000 or 37% – were
also exposed to at least one component of hazardous child labour in cocoa production. With an estimated
800,000 smallholder farmers (GIZ, 2021) in the country – between 700,000 and 1,000,000 cocoa producers in
2010 according to Ben Houassa (2011) – that works out to one child worker per smallholder (the average of 1
child labourer and 2.8 adults per cocoa-growing household is further corroborated by de Buhr et al. 2018, p.
20). The total output of a given farm X would be multiplied by 0.26316 in order to obtain an individual worker’s
output. One must, however, also take into account that adult workers are 2 to 3 times more efficient than
child workers. Thus, those 790,647 child labourers are responsible for 33%-50% of the workload. In sum, a 12%
child labour value added of total cocoa output certainly passes the plausibility test (0.26316 X 50% = 0.13158,
or 0.26316 X 33% = 0.8772).
35
sugarcane value added from child labour exported by 17 countries came to almost EUR 44
million (EUR 45,656,251) in 2019.
Tobacco: According to USDOL’s 2020 List, 17 countries produce tobacco with child labour.
Malawi and Brazil are identified by the Comext database as the largest 2019 exporters to
the EU (amounting to EUR 234 million and EUR 543 million, respectively). Child labour value
added to exports from Malawi was 12%, and in Brazil 22%. Accordingly, Malawi’s share of
tobacco produced by child labour and exported to the EU was estimated to be EUR
28,097,531, and that of Brazil estimated to be EUR 119,525,577. Altogether, the value of
tobacco produced with child labour and exported to the EU was worth an estimated EUR
264,401,759 in 2019.
36
Child Labour Footprint Findings
3. Child labour footprint findings
The USDOL List of Goods flagged 74 countries, 145 commodities, and a total of 395
combinations (country-commodity) produced with child labour in its last publication
covering for years 2019-2020. Out of those, the results of 102 commodities from 66
countries are displayed in Figure 6 (280 combinations). The omitted products and countries
are due to excluded commodities, whether because there was no importation of the flagged
commodity to the EU from the selected country, or they could not be matched with a
Comext category.11 As the study is focused on importation flows outside of geographical
Europe, Ukraine was not considered (as the only in-scope country as per the USDOL List of
Goods).
Figure 6: Child Labour Bubble Map
An estimated €50.08 billion was the value of imports by the EU produced with child labour
in 2019. Figure 6 depicts the value of in-scope goods exported to the EU produced with child
labour, where the bubbles’ size and colour vary according to the estimated amount of child
labour. The most prominent in-scope exporters to the EU (see Table 6) are China (EUR
143bn), Bangladesh (EUR 18.4bn), Turkey (EUR 13.4bn), Viet Nam (EUR 12.3bn), and India
(EUR 9.3bn). These countries are also the ones that contributed the most to the child labour
value estimated in EUR. In first place is China, with 74% (EUR 37.2bn) of the value
11
The countries, for which the value of imports of the in-scope product/s was null, are: Mauritania, Ethiopia,
Lesotho, Eswatini, Chad, and South Sudan.
Child Labour Footprint Findings
37
Child Labour Footprint Findings
mentioned above. In second place is Viet Nam 6% (EUR 3.2bn), in third Bangladesh 4% (EUR
2.2bn), followed by Turkey and India 2% each, in fourth (EUR 1.2bn) and fifth (EUR 1.1bn)
place, respectively. Table 6 presents the top 20 in absolute terms. For the full list, see our
application visualising those findings.
Table 6: Top 20 In-Scope Countries Exporting to the EU with Child Labour (Ordered by the Contribution to the
Estimated EUR Value of Child Labour)
Country
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
China
Vietnam
Bangladesh
Turkey
India
Brazil
Indonesia
Burma
Colombia
Côte d'Ivoire
Malaysia
Ecuador
Ghana
Thailand
Honduras
Bolivia
Philippines
Democratic Republic of the Congo
Nigeria
Cameroon
In-scope importations
(EUR)
143,172,279,621
12,323,108,894
18,391,656,557
13,373,033,536
9,304,000,608
4,128,323,323
3,114,678,094
2,646,794,974
1,908,292,867
3,147,419,697
1,080,557,144
1,145,583,785
1,200,922,370
509,234,377
597,939,665
426,093,855
322,087,243
638,691,318
517,172,701
506,894,944
Estimated value of child labour
(EUR)
37,224,792,701.46
3,204,008,312.44
2,206,998,786.84
1,203,573,018.24
1,116,480,072.96
908,231,131.06
809,816,304.44
688,166,693.24
419,824,430.74
377,690,363.64
280,944,857.44
252,028,432.70
144,110,684.40
132,400,938.02
131,546,726.30
93,740,648.10
83,742,683.18
76,642,958.16
62,060,724.12
60,827,393.28
The principal in-scope products imported with child labour (see Table 7) were Electronics
(EUR 35bn), Garments (EUR 5.4bn), Footwear (EUR 1.5bn), Coffee (EUR 1.1bn), and Toys
(EUR 1.1bn).
Child Labour Footprint Findings
38
Child Labour Footprint Findings
Table 7: Top 10 In-scope Commodities Exported to the EU with Child Labour (Ordered by the Contribution to
the Estimated EUR Value of Child Labour)
Goods
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
Electronics
Garments
Footwear
Coffee
Toys
Textiles
Oil (palm)
Cocoa
Furniture
Rubber
In-scope importations (EUR)
134,891,109,865
39,535,377,933
6,780,229,648
4,990,472,465
4,088,001,417
3,515,747,483
2,903,245,530
5,391,985,710
2,531,227,884
1,359,889,915
Estimated value of child labour
(EUR)
35,071,688,564.90
5,368,812,578.53
1,452,434,066.40
1,098,477,466.50
1,062,880,368.42
912,806,637.48
754,675,825.34
648,809,380.10
440,527,130.02
349,489,532.58
Applying the country categories as per the UN Methodology M49 Standard (United Nations,
2020), in-scoped countries can be grouped into five regions. The following figure shows the
value in Euros of the flagged commodities imported to the EU with and without child labour.
Figure 7: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Child Labour by Region
We observe that Eastern and South-Eastern Asia is the region which exports the most inscope goods to the EU with and without child labour. The region also represents almost 85%
of the calculated value of child labour. Central and Southern Asia contributes to that total
with 6.71%, Latin America and Caribbean with 4.12%, Northern Africa and Western Asia
2.43%, and last, Sub-Saharan Africa with 2.01%.
Child Labour Footprint Findings
39
Child Labour Footprint Findings
3.1 Eastern and South-Eastern Asia
Breaking down the analysis per region, Eastern and South-Eastern Asia exported to the EU
163.2 bn EUR of in-scope products. The principal commodities contributing to Child Labour,
as per Table 8, were Electronics, Garments, Footwear, Toys, and Textiles.
Table 8: Top 5 In-scope Countries and Goods Contributing to Child Labour in Eastern and South-Eastern Asia
Country
China
Vietnam
Indonesia
Burma
Malaysia
Goods
Electronics
Garments
Footwear
Toys
Textiles
Estimated value of child
labour (EUR)
37,224,792,701.46
3,204,008,312.44
809,816,304.44
688,166,693.24
280,944,857.44
%
contribution
87.74%
7.55%
1.91%
1.62%
0.66%
Estimated value of child
labour (EUR)
35,071,688,564.90
1,711,214,199.24
1,160,695,568.76
1,062,880,368.42
911,702,887.68
%
contribution
82.66%
4.03%
2.74%
2.51%
2.15%
USDOL justifies the inclusion of Electronics from China in its List of Goods on the following
grounds:
There are reports that children ages 13-15 are forced to produce electronics in China.
Based on the most recently available data from media sources, government raids,
and NGOs, hundreds of cases of forced child labor have been reported in factories in
Guangdong province, but the children are often from Henan, Shanxi, or Sichuan
provinces. In some cases, children are forced to work in electronics factories through
arrangements between the factories and the schools that the children attend in order
to cover alleged tuition debts. The forced labor programs are described as student
apprenticeships; however, the children report that they were forced to remain on the
job and not allowed to return home. Half of the students' wages are sent directly to
the schools, and the children receive little compensation after deductions are made
for food and accommodations. In other cases, children are abducted or deceived by
recruiters, sent to Guangdong, and sold to employers. Some children are held captive,
forced to work long hours for little pay (U.S. Department of Labor, n.d.-b).
Figure 8 graphically represents where child labour is concentrated: China (87.74%), for the
most part, and then Viet Nam (7.55%), Indonesia (1.91%) and Burma (1.62%). The
contribution of the rest of the in-scoped countries is minimal (less than 1% each).
Child Labour Footprint Findings
40
Child Labour Footprint Findings
Figure 8: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Child Labour from Countries in Eastern
and South-Eastern Asia Region
3.2 Central and Southern Asia
Central and Southern Asia region exported into the EU around EUR 28bn. Top five products
imported contributing to child Labour are Garments (81.01%), Footwear (6.42%), Leather
Goods/Accessories (4.85%), Carpets (1.75%), and Cotton (1.58%).
Table 9: Top 5 In-scope Countries and Goods Contributing to Child Labour in Central and Southern Asia
Country
Estimated value of child
labour (EUR)
2,206,998,786.84
1,116,480,072.96
26,340,959.40
3,788,356.68
2,558,448.00
%
contribution
65.69%
33.23%
0.78%
0.11%
0.08%
Goods
Estimated value of child
labour (EUR)
2,721,661,680.84
215,778,491.88
162,865,584.12
58,638,574.92
52,923,511.08
%
contribution
81.01%
6.42%
4.85%
1.75%
1.58%
Bangladesh
India
Pakistan
Iran
Nepal
Garments
Footwear
Leather Goods/ Accessories
Carpets
Cotton
Child Labour Footprint Findings
41
Child Labour Footprint Findings
Regarding countries, Figure 9 shows the amount of exports to the EU and the degree to
which each country contributes to the child labour total estimated in the region. Bangladesh
represents 64.77% (EUR 2.20bn) of the estimates, and India 34.16% (EUR 1.16bn).
Figure 9: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Child Labour from Countries in Central
and Southern Asia Region
3.3 Latin America and the Caribbean
For Latin America and the Caribbean, Figure 10 shows that in comparison to the previous
regions, a higher number of countries were flagged as producing with child labour.
Nevertheless, it remains third with respect to the regional contribution to the estimated
value of child labour. Another finding of note is that most of the commodities flagged by
USDOL correspond with raw goods, the top 5 contributing to child labour are Coffee,
Bananas, Corn, Coal and Gold.
Concerning the five principal country positions, Brazil exported a total of EUR 4.12bn,
Colombia EUR 1.9bn, Ecuador EUR 1.14bn, Honduras EUR 597M and Bolivia EUR 426M of inscope goods. A hotspot for child labour, as per Figure 10, is Brazil, with almost half (44%) of
the child labour estimated in the region. In second and third place are Colombia 20.34% and
Ecuador 12.21%.
Child Labour Footprint Findings
42
Child Labour Footprint Findings
Table 10: Top 5 In-scope Countries and Goods Contributing to Child Labour in Latin America and the Caribbean
Country
Brazil
Colombia
Ecuador
Honduras
Bolivia
Goods
Coffee
Bananas
Corn
Coal
Gold
Estimated value of child
labour (EUR)
908,231,131.06
419,824,430.74
252,028,432.70
131,546,726.30
93,740,648.10
%
contribution
44.00%
20.34%
12.21%
6.37%
4.54%
Estimated value of child
labour (EUR)
755,411,409.28
225,628,184.10
183,322,434.90
175,952,219.74
142,206,213.16
%
contribution
36.60%
10.93%
8.88%
8.53%
6.89%
Figure 10: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Child Labour from Countries in Latin
America and Caribbean
3.4 Northern Africa and Western Asia
The Northern Africa and Western Asia region follows fourth in terms of their regional
position, with only 5 countries considered for the study. The principal in-scoped
commodities exported to the EU with child labour were Garments, Furniture, Cotton,
Hazelnuts and Footwear.
Child Labour Footprint Findings
43
Child Labour Footprint Findings
Table 11: Top 5 In-scope Countries and Goods Contributing to Child Labour in Northern Africa and Western
Asia
Country
Turkey
Egypt
Sudan
Lebanon
Yemen
Goods
Garments
Furniture
Cotton
Hazelnuts
Footwear
Estimated value of child
labour (EUR)
1,203,573,018.24
9,975,919.41
2,633,356.80
1,585,251.99
486,440.55
%
contribution
98.79%
0.82%
0.22%
0.13%
0.04%
Estimated value of child
labour (EUR)
916,742,000.07
115,195,828.14
77,623,393.68
60,406,675.11
26,286,642.90
%
contribution
75.25%
9.46%
6.37%
4.96%
2.16%
Figure 11 shows that Turkey makes up for almost all exports with child labour, as in-scope
exports for the region was EUR 13.53bn, and for Turkey they were EUR 13.37bn.
Figure 11: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Child Labour from Countries in Northern
Africa and Western Asia
3.5 Sub-Saharan Africa
Sub-Saharan Africa is the region with most countries flagged as producing with child labour.
However, similar observations as in the Latin America region can be made: the main
commodities are raw goods without much further added value. The top five products are
Cocoa, Tobacco, Copper, Coffee and Diamonds.
Child Labour Footprint Findings
44
Child Labour Footprint Findings
Table 12: Top 5 In-scope Countries and Goods Contributing to Child Labour in Sub-Saharan Africa
Country
Côte d'Ivoire
Ghana
Congo, Dem. Rep.
Nigeria
Cameroon
Goods
Cocoa
Tobacco
Copper
Coffee
Diamonds
Estimated value of child
labour (EUR)
377,690,363.64
144,110,684.40
76,642,958.16
62,060,724.12
60,827,393.28
%
contribution
37.54%
14.32%
7.62%
6.17%
6.05%
Estimated value of child
labour (EUR)
644,912,971.32
76,256,525.88
71,828,178.00
52,883,867.52
49,759,733.40
%
contribution
64.10%
7.58%
7.14%
5.26%
4.95%
The hotspot for child labour is in Côte d’lvoire (EUR 377.7M), where 98.81% of the
estimated value of child labour for the country is due to Cocoa production also ranked first
in the top 5 commodities in the region.
Figure 12: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Child Labour from Countries in SubSaharan Africa
Child Labour Footprint Findings
45
Forced / Indentured Child Labour Footprint Findings
4. Forced/indentured child labour findings
USDOL’s List of Products Produced by Forced or Indentured Child Labour flagged 25 countries
and 34 commodities in 2019. Out of those, 25 commodities originating from 19 countries
are shown in Figure 13 (42 combinations). As previously mentioned, the omitted products
and countries are due to the fact that the flagged commodities were either not traded with
the EU, or that they could not be matched with an appropriate Comext category.
Figure 13: Forced or Indentured Child Labour Bubble Map
An estimated €38.55 billion was the value of imports by the EU produced with forced or
indentured child labour in 2019. Figure 13 presents the data of the value of in-scope
exported goods to the EU with forced or indentured child labour, where the bubbles’ size
and colour vary according to the estimated amount of forced or indentured child labour.
The five most prominent exporters of the in-scoped goods to the EU are China (EUR
139.5bn), India (EUR 5.5bn); Viet Nam (EUR 3.7bn), Côte d’Ivoire (EUR 3.1bn), and Nigeria
(EUR 517.1M). Four of the beforementioned countries also comprised the top 5 contributors
to the forced or indentured child labour value. China accounts for 94.05% of the EUR
38.55bn estimation, Viet Nam 2.48%, India 1.71%, Côte d’Ivoire 0.98%, and Thailand 0.34%.
The principal in-scope products imported with forced or indentured child labour were
Electronics (EUR 35.1bn), Garments (EUR 1.7bn), Toys (EUR 1.1bn) Cocoa (EUR 435M), and
Cotton (EUR 109M), as is depicted in Table 14.
Forced / Indentured Child Labour Footprint Findings
46
Forced / Indentured Child Labour Footprint Findings
Table 13: Top 10 In-Scope Countries Exporting to the EU with Forced/Indentured Child Labour (Ordered by the
Contribution to the Estimated EUR Value of Forced/Indentured Child Labour)
Country
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
China
Vietnam
India
Côte d'Ivoire
Thailand
Nigeria
Burma
Malawi
Bolivia
Sierra Leone
In-scope importations
(EUR)
139,452,666,511
3,674,196,997
5,503,535,602
3,147,419,697
508,937,034
517,098,775
164,853,748
234,146,098
99,446,711
54,283,473
Estimated value of
forced/indentured child labour
(EUR)
36,257,693,292.86
955,291,219.22
660,424,272.24
377,690,363.64
132,323,628.84
62,051,853.00
42,861,974.48
28,097,531.76
21,878,276.42
6,514,016.76
Table 14: Top 10 In-scope Commodities Exported to the EU with Forced/Indentured Child Labour (Ordered by
the Contribution to the Estimated EUR Value of Forced/Indentured Child Labour)
Goods
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
Electronics
Garments
Toys
Cocoa
Cotton
Rice
Tobacco
Stones
Brazil Nuts/ Chestnuts
Bricks
In-scope importations
(EUR)
134,891,109,865
9,162,148,008
4,088,001,417
3,627,123,298
422,303,997
384,054,526
234,146,098
189,072,186
99,439,184
71,102,951
Estimated value of
forced/indentured child labour
(EUR)
35,071,688,564.90
1,680,416,459.80
1,062,880,368.42
435,254,795.76
108,992,901.86
68,625,926.70
28,097,531.76
22,688,662.32
21,876,620.48
16,514,019.14
Grouping the countries according to the regions indicated by the UN (2020) Methodology
M49, Figure 14 shows the value in Euros of the flagged country-commodity pairs imported
to the EU with and without forced or indentured child labour. The figure notes that most of
the importation flow comes from the Eastern and South-Eastern Asia (EUR 143.8bn),
followed by Central and Southern Asia (EUR 5.6bn), Sub-Saharan Africa (EUR 4bn) and last,
Latin America and the Caribbean (EUR 100M). There were no products flagged for the
Northern Africa and Western Asia region.
Forced / Indentured Child Labour Footprint Findings
47
Forced / Indentured Child Labour Footprint Findings
Figure 14: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Forced or Indentured Child Labour
Concerning the analysis of each region, similar conclusions can be drawn as for the Child
Labour dimension. One notable change was that Sub-Saharan Africa went from last position
in the Child Labour dimension to third in the current analysed dimension.
4.1 Eastern and South-Eastern Asia Region
Eastern and South-Eastern Asia Region contributes to the aforementioned value with 37.4bn
(96.98%). The countries considered were China, Viet Nam, Thailand, and Burma. The
hotspot of forced or indentured child labour is concentrated in China, as per
Figure 15, contributing with EUR 36.3bn to the total estimation, after which comes Viet Nam
with 955.3M, and last the other two countries Thailand 132.3M, and Burma 42.9M. The
main in-scope commodities are Electronics, Garments, Toys and Cotton.
Forced / Indentured Child Labour Footprint Findings
48
Forced / Indentured Child Labour Footprint Findings
Figure 15: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Forced or Indentured Child Labour from
Countries in Eastern and South-Eastern Asia Region
4.2 Central and Southern Asia
In this dimension, the Central and Southern Asia region encompasses five countries,
detailed in Figure 16. Nearly 99% of the in-scope importation flow comes from India with
EUR 5.5bn, which is also where forced or indentured child labour is most concentrated.
Figure 16: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Forced or Indentured Child Labour from
Countries in Central and Southern Asia
With EUR 660.4M, India alone contributes the most to the estimated EUR value of forced or
indentured child labour in the region (a total of EUR 667.2M). The top 5 commodities for the
Forced / Indentured Child Labour Footprint Findings
49
Forced / Indentured Child Labour Footprint Findings
region are: Garments, Rice, Stones, Embellished Textiles, and Carpets. Next in the country
ranking comes Pakistan with 4M, and third Nepal 2.5M.
4.2 Sub-Saharan Africa region
For the Sub-Saharan Africa region, Figure 17 shows that the hotspot for forced or
indentured child labour is in Côte d’Ivoire, contributing with 377M. Second comes Nigeria
62M, third Malawi 28M and forth Sierra Leone 6.5M. Ghana, Burkina Faso, Benin and the
DRC did not reach 1% of the total estimated for the region. Regarding commodities, the top
five are Cocoa, Tobacco, Diamonds, Coffee and Fish.
Figure 17: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Forced or Indentured Child Labour from
Countries in Sub-Saharan Africa
4.2 Latin America and the Caribbean
Last, as can be seen in Figure 18, the Latin America and the Caribbean region features two
countries for this dimension: Bolivia and Argentina. Bolivia is the largest exporter, and also
the hotspot for forced or indentured child labour, accounting for 99.43% of the estimated
value calculated for the region (EUR 22M). There are only 3 commodities contributing to this
estimate: Brazil Nuts/Chestnuts (21M), Garments (124K) and Sugarcane (1K).
Forced / Indentured Child Labour Footprint Findings
50
Forced / Indentured Child Labour Footprint Findings
Figure 18: Value of In-scope Goods Imported by the EU With/Without Forced or Indentured Child Labour from
Countries in Latin America and Caribbean
Forced / Indentured Child Labour Footprint Findings
51
E. Factors of child labour
The phenomenon of child labour is inextricably linked to economic conditions at the
household and national level.
Indeed, the centrality of economic factors driving child labour is unmistakable: “Variation in
GDP per capita explains 73 percent of the variation in the economic activity rates of
children” (Edmonds & Pavcnik, 2005, p. 210).
Since children, as dependents, usually do not take life decisions autonomously, the family
unit of analysis is foundational.12 In economic terms, a family is considered as continuously
seeking to optimise its welfare (i.e. solving for the welfare optimisation problem), and at the
very least, ensuring its survival. Vulnerable families continuously weigh factors such as the
relative economic return of schooling and a child’s more immediate wages (Schultz, 1960).
There is further the issue that households may choose to send some children to work in
order to afford the schooling fees for their siblings. This “sibling complementarity” has
tended to favour sending older, female children to work so that younger, male siblings can
go to school (Basu & Tzannatos, 2003).
In general, as incomes improve, the family chooses to have their children work less. This
idea is central in Basu and Van’s (1998) seminal paper, where children only work when the
family cannot meet its subsistence needs. This “luxury axiom” Basu and Van (1998) define as
“a family will send the children to the labor market only if the family’s income from nonchild-labor sources drops very low” (p. 416). Indeed, a number of studies that have tracked
families over time almost universally found declines in child labour associated with
significant increases in family incomes: Edmonds (2001) found that for households at the
poverty line, increased income can explain 94% of the decline in child labour for households.
Conversely, as households resort to all available means to make ends meet, a rise of poverty
is a predictor for child labour (ILO & UNICEF, 2020). In a cross-sectional, multi-country study,
Edmonds (2010) found that a 1 percentage point rise in poverty leads to an estimated 0.72
percentage point increase in child labour. With a mother’s improved income, also the girl
child obtains better educational outcomes: studies by Levy (1985) and Rosenzweig (1980)
found that a 10 percent increase in women’s wage rates would decrease the girl child’s
labor force participation by as much as 10 percent. Though underexplored in the literature,
women’s socioeconomic position and bargaining power in governments, and presumably in
the household,13 have significant impacts on child labour rates (Güvercin, 2020). Both access
to remittance income as well as the opportunity to emigrate to earn greater income, reduce
12
Yet there are exceptions to this parameter. The majority of children live with at least one parent (whether
maternal or paternal). Yet in 2015, there were almost 140 million children (under 18 years of age) who had lost
one or both parents to any cause of death (UNICEF, n.d.). Children who live in households whose mother is not
biologically theirs – either due to divorce or new marriages or death – leave on their own accord to survive or
earn income. Furthermore, some minors (children) also engage in migrant work, and trafficked children
commonly leave without parental permission.
13
Intra-household bargaining models are a mainstay in development economics and have not been sufficiently
used in studying child labour. Generally, studies find that when women produce or control a greater share of
household income/wealth, more of that income is spent on child inputs beneficial to the child(ren). One
hypothesis in need of further investigation is that, holding income levels constant, the more control women
have over income, the less children would work.
52
child labour supply (Dimova et al., 2015). Sakellariou and Lall (1998), as well as Cartwright
(1998), reach similar conclusions. Together, these studies highlight the key role that income
plays with regard to the level of child labour. Ahmed (1999) summed it up as follows: “There
is by now a virtually unanimous view that poverty is the main, although not the only cause,
of child labor” (p. 1815).
Edmonds and Pavcnik (2005) explain how rising incomes may decrease child labour: with
“diminishing marginal utility of income, the value of the marginal contribution of the child’s
income decreases” (p. 209) as adult incomes rise. In addition, “higher family incomes may
facilitate the purchase of substitutes for child labor that may potentially lower the return to
child labor within the household. For example, a washboard, fertilizer spreader or a
combine harvester may replace child labor within the home” (Edmonds & Pavcnik, 2005, p.
209).
The explanatory power of parental caregiver income for child labour thus has implications
for minimum wage policy. Relevant here, for example, is a farm owner’s attainment of a socalled “living income” or, the ability e.g. of a seasonal/day labourer to earn a “living wage.”
The latter is defined as: “Remuneration received for a standard work week by a worker in a
particular time and place sufficient to afford a decent standard of living include food, water,
housing, education, healthcare, transportation, clothing, and other essential needs including
provision for unexpected events” (Global Living Wage Coalition, n.d.). The leading
methodology to measure living wages was developed by Richard Anker and Martha Anker
(2017), which benchmarks living wage levels in a multitude of sectors and geographies. The
payment of living wages may also benefit the employer and an entire economy, as is
modelled in wage efficiency theory and wage-led growth [see "shirking model" (Shapiro &
Stiglitz, 1984), “Gift Exchange” (Akerlof, 1982), "supervision model" (Rebitzer, 1995), and
wage-led growth (Lavoie & Stockhammer, 2013, pp. 29–34)]. Conversely, the practice of the
piece-rate pay system may place downward pressures on income if it is not designed to
reward workers “according to the difficulty and quality of their work, ensuring that
motivated workers can earn substantially more than the minimum wage” (Borino, 2018, p.
3).
While in some cases children work because their families are impoverished and depend on
the child’s income, and in other cases they work because the net benefits of attending
school are low relative to the rewards from work. Looking at the interplay of demand and
supply child labour determinants, Kis–Katos and Schulze (2006) query a data set of all
Indonesian villages and urban neighbourhoods, and find that child labour is:
significantly associated with poverty, natural and epidemic disasters, and with
unemployment. It is negatively associated with credit and school availability, only if
we correct for the existence of small industries in that village. Our results thus
confirm the importance of school availability and credit provision as policy
instruments to reduce child labor (p. 1).
Researchers have further identified household debt (Grootaert & Kanbur, 1995) and credit
constraints (Edmonds, 2006; Fatima, 2017; Guarcello et al., 2010; Nepal & Nepal, 2012) as
leading to higher child labour rates, underscoring the importance of social protection
measures (Güvercin, 2020). Because of these factors, child labour will also be more
53
prevalent in rural areas than urban because of lower incomes, fewer opportunities for
educational attainment, less access to credit and social protection, and fewer opportunities
for jobs that require even secondary education (Neumayer & De Soysa, 2005).
The relationship between increased income and decreasing child labour is, however, not
completely linear, and in some cases the practice proves to be “sticky.” Consider that at the
turn of the millennium, most economically active children – 94% – were found in lowincome countries (IPEC, 2002). Four percent of children were working in transition
economies,14 and two percent work in “developed” economies (IPEC, 2002). Yet in the ILO’s
2016 global estimates (ILO, 2017a), that picture had shifted: the majority of child labour was
found in middle income countries (the sum of lower-middle-income countries being 38.4%,
and of upper-middle-income countries being 17.3%).
Even at the same income level, intervening factors can lead to variation in the degree of
child labour between countries or even between households. The more prevalent child
labour is and the longer it has been practised, the greater the communal or social norm that
children are expected to work, as seen even in EU history EU history (Basu & Tzannatos,
2003). Some regard child labour as a type of workforce training not available in schools
(Zamfir, 2019b). Higher parental income is no guarantee for no child labour: a higherearning head of household may not share income with other members of the family, such
that children may also be prone to enter the labour market. In communities where children
are valued for their income support to their parents and grandparents, if the perceived
value of education is low and mortality rates are high, there will be a higher chance that
children will be sent to work so the family can appropriate income today rather than wait
for an uncertain future. An increase in child labour is also observed on larger farms that
require more labour but which do not have the ability to mechanise. The wages earned, in
fact, is not irrelevant: daily wage earned through child labour has a significant positive
impact on the hours of work for children (Bhalotra & Heady, 2003). Another source of child
labour is due to deliberate government-mandated work or apprenticeship/internship
programmes, e.g. as is the case of Kazakhstani cotton (Human Rights Watch, 2017a) or
Chinese electronics (Chamberlain, 2019), where school children are required to perform
non- or under-compensated work. Conversely, government enforcement of labour laws,
often premised upon the ratification of ILO conventions has an impact on child labour
prevalence (see section E. Multilateral support to nation-states).
Apart from identifying poverty as a strong determinant of child labour, Rahman and Khanam
(2012, p. 20) find that “parents’ education, credit market constraints, schooling
performance, child’s nutrition and health status, family size and birth order, higher
schooling costs, lack of quality education, employer’s attitude, inappropriate government
policy play major roles. It is also evident that child labour negatively affects child’s physical
and mental health, educational outcomes, adult employment, adult earnings and bargaining
power of adult workers.”
14 There are altogether 17 economies in transition: 5 countries in South-Eastern Europe (Albania, Bosnia and
Herzegovina, Montenegro, Serbia, The former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia), 11 countries within the
Commonwealth of Independent States (Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Republic of
Moldova, Russian Federation, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, Ukraine, Uzbekistan), as well as Georgia (UN, 2014).
54
Domestic government policies and capacity are essential factors as well, such as the degree
of law enforcement, and the lack thereof. A higher risk of child labour is commonly
accompanied by the government’s “lack of capacity to carry out labour inspections, poor
sector coverage and resourcing of anti-child labour programmes, as well as inadequate
penalties that do little to deter violations. In addition to this, widespread corruption in
government and law enforcement is seen as a severe issue aggravating the problem of child
labour" (Verisk Maplecroft, 2019, p. 8). A common denominator in countries where child
labour is prevalent, is that their governments rarely have the capacity and resources to
effectively enforce regulations on child employment (Edmonds & Shrestha, 2012).
Among the multiple factors associated with child labour is also national stability, i.e. the
presence of conflict or outright war. According to ILO, the “incidence of child labour in
countries affected by armed conflict is 77 per cent higher than the global average, while the
incidence of hazardous work is 50 per cent higher in countries affected by armed conflict
than in the world as a whole” (International Labour Office, 2017a, p. 12). But man-made
causes are not the only factors of displacement and livelihood disruption.
Apart from outright conflict, natural disasters can result in child labour by destroying school
infrastructure or by causing temporary or chronic emergency conditions within the family.
Indeed, a UNICEF (2015) publication observes that children “become more susceptible to
child labour following floods, droughts, severe weather and extreme heat events” (Myers &
Theytaz-Bergman, 2017, p. 8). Furthermore, the Terre des Hommes report documents how
climate change, e.g. in Burkina Faso – a Sahel region – “leads to unpredictable weather
patterns and soil depletion, which forces families to seek alternative sources of income”
(Myers & Theytaz-Bergman, 2017, p. 14). Similarly, in India, climate change has produced
intermittent crop failure, a decrease in grazing land, and consequently a decline in income
and employment, escalation of food prices, hunger and malnutrition (Patel, 2016). Believing
the need for child labour to be short-term, families may send their children to work to
support the family during the emergency, only to discover that conditions remain poor
longer than anticipated, that injuries or new trials, growing student disinterest in school
combine to make the absence from schooling permanent (Neumayer & De Soysa, 2005).
F. Child labour vs. trade
1. Does trade itself lower the phenomenon of child labour?
There are arguments that trade may either raise or lower child labour (Edmonds, 2005). The
standard textbook model of trade between higher- and lower-income countries is the
Heckscher-Ohlin model with the associated Stolper-Samuelson theorem. To be brief, the
Heckscher-Ohlin model assumes that countries differ because of their factor endowments.
Lower-income countries have abundant unskilled labour, including child labour. Higherincome countries have more physical capital and skilled labour. Therefore, lower-income
countries will tend to export goods that intensively use unskilled labour while higher-income
countries rely more on physical or human capital in their production.
The Stolper-Samuelson theorem expands on this model to uncover the impacts of trade on
inequality. To the extent trade increases demand for goods made with unskilled labour, it
55
will increase demand for unskilled labour and therefore the wages of the poor. This will tend
to decrease inequality in lower-income countries.
From there, however, less is certain. Foreign demand for exported goods in this model will
increase demand for child labour. Whether that results in an increase or decrease in child
labour depends on the slope of the child labour supply curve. What is certain either way,
however, is that trade ought to raise wages for adults and children, improving family
welfare unambiguously. The exact effect on the amount of child labour is less certain. If, as
Basu (1999), Basu and Van (1998) and Basu and Zarghamee (2009) contend, child labour
supply curves are downward sloping15 (see Figure 19), an increase in demand could actually
decrease the incidence of child labour.
Another chain of thought underscores that firms will tend to choose to produce in countries
with lower costs, holding all else constant. If they can obtain products of comparable quality
while utilising cheap child labour, then the opportunity to export their goods from countries
that allow child labour could result in a “race to the bottom.” In more extreme versions of
the argument, firms not only seek out countries with lower standards, but countries that are
more open to trade would lower their child labour standards in order to attract more firms
or to compensate domestic firms when trade brings increased foreign competition
(Martinez-Zarzoso & Kruse, 2019). Whether this has happened in practice is, as above, an
empirical question. Basu (1999) points out that, to the extent one is worried about a race to
the bottom, international action serves a coordinating function that improves outcomes for
children in each country. Though it may be in each country’s private interest to allow child
labour as that would attract more firms, all are better off economically if none do. In such a
case, EU-imposed child labour standards through trade could be very useful in the fight
against child labour.
Olarreaga, Saiovici, and Ugarte’s (2020) study of 26 low- and middle-income countries
demonstrates that industries with greater foreign trade participation tend to have lower
child labour participation. This is more particularly the case in industries that supply inputs
to foreign firms (forward linkages). Ul-Haq, Khanum, and Cheema (2020) show that lowering
tariffs in Pakistan decreased the incidence of child labour as well. This has been supported in
previous literature by Edmonds and Pavcnik (2004b, 2004a, 2005), Neumayer and Soysa
(2005), Davies and Voy (2009), and Bharadwaj, Lakdawala, and Li (2016). Importantly, while
Edmonds and Pavcnik (2005) find that trade lowers child labour primarily or exclusively by
increasing incomes, Olarreaga, Saiovici, and Ugarte (2020) show that as countries with child
labour increase their exports, child labour in those countries decreases even after
controlling for incomes. They speculate that this could be caused by firms in developed
countries having higher standards regarding child labour that they require of their
developing country suppliers.
15 A worker whose wage increases typically faces two effects: the income effect and the substitution effect.
The income effect tells them that they are richer and can afford more leisure time, so they should work less.
The substitution effect tells them that they can buy better stuff, so they should work more. Identifying when
and where one effect dominates the other has kept labour economists’ families fed and clothed for decades. It
is widely held that in developing countries, households’ primary goal is to achieve subsistence, such that the
income effect clearly dominates. Alternatively, only the poorest families send their children to work, creating
this downward-sloping portion of the labour supply curve even if it is upward-sloping at higher wages. Either
way, a child who gets paid more would then have to work less.
56
Figure 19: Impact of Export Growth on Child Labour
Source: “Child Labour and Global Value Chains”, (Olarreaga et al., 2020), URL
Conversely, Zhao, Wang, and Zhao (2016) find non-linear responses in China upon their
accession to the World Trade Organization in 2001. In the short run, child labour incidence
in China increased, particularly for “girls, older children, rural children, and children with
less-educated parents” (Zhao et al., 2016, p. 1). In the longer run, however, greater trade
openness allowed exporters to adopt labour-saving technology, reducing their demand for
child labour to its original level.
In conclusion, Edmonds and Pavcnik (2005) sum up the empirical landscape on trade vis-avis child labour as follows: “it is not inevitable that a growth in trade and employment
opportunities will increase child labor [across the board], nor is it inevitable that such
growth will decrease child labor either. The data, however, are clear on one point:
significant increases in family income are ceteris paribus strongly associated with reductions
in child labor” (p. 213).
Among the factors that will matter in determining the extent to which future trade
agreements lead to lower child labour rates is the inclusion and content of specific labour
provisions. Martinez-Zarzoso and Kruse (2019) examine a panel of 96 countries from 19952008 to demonstrate that the inclusion of labour provisions significantly increases the rate
at which increased trade can lead to improved labour outcomes, though they did not
examine child labour specifically. Among the problems of answering this question rigorously
is endogeneity: lower-income countries already making progress on reducing child labour
are likely to be more open to free trade agreements that include such provisions. The
literature on labour standards provision has thus far demonstrated that “sanctions are not
only trade-harming but also too indirect to effectively target labour standards” (MartinezZarzoso & Kruse, 2019, p. 977; Martin & Maskus, 2001; Maskus, 1997; Srinivasan, 1998).
57
2. How could unconditional trade bans and sanctions lower child welfare?
The above section has demonstrated that the impact of trade on child labour is multifaceted and may be positive or negative depending on the rules of trade, the time frame
considered, the industry, the wealth of the country, and other factors. Many activists,
however, implicitly assume that trade with countries, industries, or more certainly firms that
use child labour must increase demand for, and therefore use of, child labour. The obvious
assumption is that by refusing to purchase the products made with child labour, the use of
child labour will also decrease.
There are several problems with this line of thought. The weaker argument is the problem
of fungibility. Most individual buyers and even most countries are too small to have a
noticeable impact on global demand. Someone else will buy these goods, goes the
argument, and therefore the sanctioned party is made worse off for no material gain. In the
context of the European Union, however, it is much more likely that trade bans and
sanctions will, in fact, have a noticeable effect on demand for these goods. Lower demand
for these goods will likely lower global prices and profits for those who use child labour,
ultimately decreasing demand for child labour.
This is where a second, stronger argument comes into play. Consider again the above Figure
19 depicting the downward sloping child labour supply curve. If trade sanctions successfully
decrease demand for child labour, this will tend to lower the wages of child workers,
increasing the quantity supplied. This perverse effect lowers child welfare, first by making
those children who are already working worse off as their families have lower incomes to
purchase necessities, and second by inducing more children to spend additional time in
labour rather than education.
A third concern is that even if bans are successful in reducing child labour, that does not
immediately imply that these children are then better off. Because of the indigent
circumstances of the families sending children to work, the loss of the child’s income likely
means employment in a different, worse job rather than increased opportunities for
education and success in life. A fourth concern worth brief mention is that most developing
countries are suspicious of bans based on child labour, suspecting that they actually
constitute protectionism disguised as charity, making them less likely to cooperate.
Moving from the theoretical to the empirical, in 1992 Senator Harkin of the United States
proposed the Child Labor Deterrence Act (aka Harkin Bill), “with the laudable aim of
prohibiting the import of products made by children under 15” (UNICEF, 1997, p. 23). This
legislative initiative came on the heels of a 1991 ILO prognosis that “half of the 50,000
children working as bonded labor in Pakistan's carpet-weaving industry would never reach
the age of twelve – victims of disease and malnutrition” (Kelleher, 1994, p. 161).
With the prospect of a bill, needless to say, Senator Harkin had the attention of the
Bangladesh export garment industry, “and whose products – some $900 million in value –
were exported to the US in 1994” (UNICEF, 1997, p. 23). A Memorandum of Understanding
was signed in 1995 wherein the garment industry agreed to phase out all child labourers
58
and their families would be given a stipend to help prevent the necessity of their returning
to work. Rahman et al. (1999) report that before the introduction of the bill, most of the
jobs done by the children were light but monotonous, and the working conditions left much
to be desired in terms of sanitation and excessively long hours. More than half reported that
they could not attend school because of their poverty. Yet after the bill’s introduction
multiple studies (see: Powell, 2014; UNICEF, 1997) reported that most children who were
summarily dismissed from the garment industry did not return to school, but:
found alternative, less secure, and less lucrative employment in the informal sector
[including in prostitution]. … [The threat of the Harkin Bill] brought untold misery. …
[It] viewed one particular right in isolation from all the others. By limiting its vision to
the right to education, it threatened to violate the children’s fundamental right to
survival, leaving them in a more vulnerable position than before. (Rahman et al.,
1999, pp. 995–997)
Thereafter the ILO and UNICEF were asked to step in to assist. An agreement with the
employers’ association was established to determine the number of working children under
the age of 14; to implement a monitoring system aimed to remove them from work (the
original Child Labour Monitoring System (CLMS); to set up education programmes; and to
provide partial compensation for loss of income to children formerly in child labour and to
their families. As a result, more than 8,000 children were withdrawn from 800 garment
factories and enrolled in special education programmes.
In conclusion, Rahman et al. (1999) recommend instead compensating families to encourage
their children to go to school, such as the successful conditional cash transfers in Brazil and
Mexico, and reducing the cost of education for poor families to eliminate child labour.
G. Laissez-faire vs. intervention
Proponents of a laissez-faire approach to child labour regard it as a brute necessity for
survival along the arch a country’s development, pointing to its widespread practice in times
of the industrial revolution and agricultural contexts in the U.K. and U.S. The practice is
painted as a multidimensional problem and a stark “reality” in which there is no viable
alternative where the caretaker’s poverty is profound – e.g. due to endemic unemployment
or menial wages earned, or e.g. in the event of a caretaker’s death. This view is for example
represented by Thomas DeGregori (2002):
It is clear that technological and economic change are vital ingredients in getting
children out of the workplace and into schools. Then they can grow to become
productive adults and live longer, healthier lives. However, in poor countries like
Bangladesh, working children are essential for survival in many families, as they were
in our own heritage until the late 19th century.
This view thus treats child labour tantamount to a “necessary evil” – a stepping stone on a
country’s developmental path. A case against intervention is further argued by Edmonds
and Pavcnik (2005, pp. 217–218):
59
Might trade-related pressure help to reduce child labor? The U.S. government has
repeatedly considered restricting trade or trade preferences for countries where child
labor is endemic […]. At the international level, some advocate for the World Trade
Organization or the International Labor [sic] Organization to oversee harmonized
child labor standards, with violators to be punished via trade sanction [...]. At the
consumer level, boycotts of products produced by child labor and more generally
antisweatshop activism have become popular. Such campaigns seek to pressure
multinational producers of high-profile brand name products to improve their labor
practices. Although these trade policies have highlighted the issue of child labor on
the political agenda, there are several problems in using them in practice. First, if
these policies lead to trade sanctions that reduce average family income, they could
potentially increase the incidence of child labor. On the other hand, if the sanctions
are only implemented very rarely, then they will not be a credible threat. Second, the
recent history of trade sanctions aimed to promote broader political change does not
suggest much optimism about their efficacy (Elliott & Freeman, 2003). Third, it’s not
clear what specific action the trade pressures should be seeking to create. For
example, preventing children from working in one high-profile job may do nothing
more than force children to change employers—perhaps for the worse. Attempts to
require either bans on child labor or compulsory school attendance are subject to the
problems above. Fourth, it is difficult to distinguish whether these measures reflect
genuine interest in the well-being of children in poor countries or whether they are
just a palatable excuse for protectionism. Overall, it is difficult to make a strong case
for trade policy or consumer boycotts as an effective tool to combat child labor.
Consumer activism has brought the problem of child labor into the spotlight, but we
are not aware of any systematic empirical evidence of the effectiveness of consumer
activism in reducing child labor. It seems a blunt tool that is unlikely to reach the
typical child laborer who helps parents on the family farm and in domestic chores.
Yet the fundamental question arises whether a do-no-harm approach must translate into a
laissez-faire approach, or whether a smart mix of interventions can effectively curtail its
manifestation. Three economic effects of child labour, as a matter of fact, speak for
intervention: (1) direct bodily harm to the child, (2) negative economic consequences for the
child, and (3) the macro argument against child labour.
1. Morbidity and mortality of hazardous labour
Children working in hazardous conditions risk physical and psychological injury, as well as
death. Apart from the tragic human loss, such events are a great setback for a family’s
welfare optimisation. If significant child morbidity and mortality occurs, this would also
impact a country’s macroeconomic prospects at the aggregate level.
The case where health consequences bar child labourers from pursuing their education was
again illustrated in the recent NORC study on child labour in the cocoa sectors of Ghana and
Côte d’Ivoire: 12% of Ivorian children working in agriculture stated that they “could not go
to school” due to an injury sustained through farming (Sadhu et al., 2020).
Given the most drastic welfare losses occur where children are exposed to hazardous work,
some scholars argue that it should be a priority to withdraw children from WFCL. Mansoor
60
(2004) for example argues that: “As a matter of priority, less developed countries should
prohibit child labour in hazardous and unsafe activities, protect children from exploitative
bonded labour, and prohibit the employment of those who have not completed primary
education or are below the age of twelve.”
2. Foregone economic returns of education
Also non-hazardous child labour is economically harmful (International Labour Office,
2017a). Edmonds and Pavcnik (2005) observed that "Reported school attendance rates [...]
drop below 50 percent on average for children working more than 40 hours per week" (p.
205). In general, children “who attend school spend less time working than children who do
not attend school" (p. 205). A lack of education limits work options as adults, and at the
macro level also inhibits the effective formation of human capital. This, in turn, serves to
perpetuate the cycle of poverty, also over generations (United Nations Development
[UNDP] & Oxford Poverty and Human Development Initiative [OPHI], 2020). Given that
poverty and child labour are inextricably linked, a continuation of child labour to cure the
“disease” of poverty results in both poverty and child labour. Conducting a study on the
impact of schooling in Indonesia, Esther Duflo (2001) found that the economic returns to
education ranged from 6.8 to 10.6 percent. Worldwide, 36 million children ages 5–14 in
child labour – 32 percent of all children in that age range – were out of school, completely
deprived of education as per the latest estimates (International Labour Office, 2017a). If
assisting children exposed to non-WFCL child labour is not considered important, the vicious
cycle of poverty and child labour will never end.
3. Labour substitutability, multiple equilibria
Earlier it was shown the important conclusions that can be reached if the labour supply
curve is downward sloping. Basu and Van (1998) add an innovation to that model that
presents the possibility of multiple equilibria. One equilibrium includes children's work
competing for wages with adults (“substitution axiom”), while another equilibrium excludes
working children, resulting in higher adult wages. In the following discussion, it will be seen
that there is a critical income threshold – determined in part by credit and school
availability, law enforcement, cultural norms, and conflict as discussed above – below which
punitive measures designed to prevent child labour may harm the welfare of the very
children in need of help. Above that threshold, there will be multiple equilibria, and trade
sanctions or other measures may be useful in nudging an economy out of the equilibrium
that includes child labour to an equilibrium with less or none.
To see this, consider the following graph from Basu (1999). The demand for labour (DL) is a
normal, downward-sloping demand curve. That is, as workers become more expensive,
firms want to hire less labour. At the low levels of income prevalent in many developing
countries, however, the supply curve comes in three segments:
● if the wage is high enough (above wH in the graph) then adult wages alone are
sufficient to ensure family survival, resulting in the eradication of child labour;
● if the wage is low enough (below wL in the graph) then many families are forced to
send their children to work in order to survive;
● and in between those extremes (the curved segment) more and more families send
their children to work for longer and longer hours as wages decrease.
61
If it happens to be the case that demand for labour is high enough, then the only
equilibrium is one where only adults work and child labour is non-existent. This is the
situation in most developed countries. If labour demand is low enough, the only equilibrium
includes child labour. However, there is a special range in the middle, where labour demand
intersects the supply curve at three different points: E1 where there is only adult labour, E2
where there is a large amount of child labour; and an unlabelled point in the middle where
there is some child labour. In this intermediate range, because multiple equilibria are
present, it may be possible for outside influence to help jostle an economy loose from a bad
equilibrium (E2) to a good one (E1) with significantly less child labour. If labour demand - and
therefore incomes - are low enough, however, outside influence to reduce child labour may
make the situation worse. This is the fundamental argument that will be used in this paper
to support progressive conditionality, focusing policy efforts where they are most likely to
do the most good.
Figure 20: Demand for Labour
Source: “Child Labor: Cause, Consequence and Cure, with Remarks on International Labor Standards,” (Basu, 1999)
Some authors have proposed that these multiple equilibria may also interact with other
conditions in the country. Tanaka (2003) considers the interaction between income
inequality, income taxes, and child labour. Income taxes are used to pay for better
schooling, so the higher the tax rate is, the better schooling quality is, and therefore the
fewer children will be engaged in the labour force (both because the opportunity cost of
working is higher as school quality increases and because the payoff from child labour is
lower as taxes are higher). He argues, based on the median voter theorem, that if income
inequality is high that taxes will be low, school quality be low, and child labour will be high.
Doepke and Zillibotti (2005) similarly demonstrate that impoverished families with many
children will value child labour highly and therefore oppose efforts to reduce child labour,
while smaller households in less unequal societies will tend to favour policies that reduce
child labour.
62
H. Implications of child labour models
Based on the foregoing discussion, this paper advances a trade regime to reduce child
labour and WFCL, where, depending on a country’s level of income, a progressive system of
carrots and sticks is applied:
1. in lower middle-income countries and below (Zone 1), carrots (incentives) are relied
on exclusively;
2. in upper middle-income countries (Zones 2-3), sticks (e.g. sanctions and bans) are
progressively phased in with the phasing out of carrots;
3. in high-income countries (Zone 4), sticks are used exclusively.
This section introduces some of the possibilities that will be developed further in the policy
section (VII. Policy Options), as well as some of the criteria that could be used to determine
which particular country or trading partner belongs in which zone.
From earlier sections, the cases for Zone 1 and Zone 4 should be fairly clear. Zone 4
countries have sufficiently high wages that the vast majority of families should not have an
economic necessity for sending their children to school, the government possess the
capacity to ensure universal education through at least 14 years, and the legal system is
capable of enforcing child labour regulations uniformly across industries and geographic
areas. In such an economy, there are very few valid excuses for child labour to exist in any
harmful or meaningful way. Zone 1 countries, by contrast, are characterised by large swaths
of the population suffering from want and deprivation, lack adequate school facilities, and
the government is incapable of universally enforcing child labour regulations. In these cases,
trading bans, sanctions, or other economic punishments would be more likely to make the
problem of child labour worse, as in the case of the threatened U.S. Harkin Bill targeting
Bangladesh during the 1990s, when it had an inflation-and-PPP-adjusted GDP/capita of
$1,400.
Identifying where Zones 2 and 3 begin and end will require multiple judgement calls, that in
some cases may appear subjective. Basu and other authors have refrained from writing
clear structural equations that would enable policy makers to identify at what specific family
income E2 and E1 occur. Basu and Tzannatos (2003) do suggest in a footnote that China and
India (around 11% of children in the workforce) are unlikely to have a multiple equilibrium
situation, while Ethiopia and Nepal (41-85%) are much more likely. The characteristics of
countries in Zone 1 and Zone 4 described in the preceding paragraph, however, suggest
some vital dimensions that would likely play a role in such equations.
Dimension 1: Income and Basic Needs
There are several ways to measure or think about the level of income necessary for families
to survive without relying on child labour. At its quickest and most widely available, GDP per
capita adjusted for purchasing power parity can be used. GDP/capita will be highly
correlated not only with family incomes but with educational attainment and opportunity,
the value and returns to education, government capacity, and other variables of interest.
This is not a causal statement. Because of these correlations, GDP/capita can be reasonably
used as one measure.
63
It would be unwise to rely solely on GDP/capita for a number of reasons, the most
prominent of which for our purposes is that it fails to capture inequality or the size of the
informal economy where many children will find employment. Ideally, one would like
measures based on the extent to which households are able to meet their basic needs
(Watson, 2014). Many of these are still in the early development stages and are not widely
available for many countries – let alone communities – or across multiple years (e.g.
Canada’s MBM in: Dufour et al., 2021; Ram, 1982).
The Alkire and Foster (2011) method used by the Oxford Poverty and Human Development
Initiative (UNDP & OPHI, 2020) is perhaps the closest measure available for a large number
of countries (growing from 80-107 in the last decade, broken down to 625 subnational areas
in 2020). It aggregates ten measures of three dimensions of poverty: 1) health, based on
nutrition and child mortality; 2) education, based on school attendance and number of years
of schooling; and 3) standard of living, including cooking fuel, sanitation, drinking water,
electricity, housing, and assets. As can be seen in Figure 21, there is a strong correlation
between multidimensional poverty and child labour (with a coefficient of .86).
Figure 21: Child Labour Prevalency vs. Multidimensional Poverty
Note: N=65, corr=.86(p<0.001). The size of each bubble reflects the size of the population
Source: Global Multidimensional Poverty index 2020 – Charting Pathways out of Multidimensional Poverty: Achieving the
SDGs, (UNDP & OPHI, 2020), URL
Dimension 2: Quality of the education system
The better the quality of the education system, the more likely it is that parents will choose
to send their children to school rather than work. If the schooling system where a particular
family lives is non-existent or poor, then it matters very little what alternative policy is
64
chosen: their child will not be going to school. It makes very little sense then to use
penalties in places where the school system is very poor. Put another way, for EU trade
policy to have the greatest potential for improving child welfare standards, more energy
should be placed on those countries that have better school systems already in place or to
improving the education systems in areas with high amounts of child labour. Basu (1999)
has also pointed out that a law making education compulsory through the age of 14 is much
easier to measure (and therefore enforce) than a law banning child labour.
A number of countries achieved a remarkable increase in school attendance – and some in a
very short timeframe. India case in point: While between the years of 1983-2002, the
number of Indian children not in school decreased from 25 to 20 million, in just six years
from 2002-2008, the number of children not in school dropped from 20 to 4 million (see
Figure 22).
Figure 22: India, Children Out of School vs. Income (GDP/capita, PPP, $ Inflation Adjusted)
Source: Gapminder.org; CC-BY
A remarkable decrease in school absenteeism was also witnessed in Indonesia and Ethiopia,
whereas Bangladesh made steady progress over a longer stretch of time. As Table 15 also
highlights, all of these cases were associated with sustained, multi-year economic growth.
Measuring the quality of education systems, however, is not a simple proposition. A seminal
paper by Harvey and Green (1993) points out that educational systems have multiple
purposes – such as preparing people for the workforce, spreading and defending cultural
norms and values, preparing children for adulthood, and teaching people how to learn
throughout their lives – and multiple ways of identifying a “quality” system, be that value
for money efficiency, accurate sorting of students, high average scores on a standardised
test, or personal transformation. Spaull and Taylor (2012) point out that most measures
have either focused on access (enrollment) or on quality (some combination of inputs and
outputs), but exceptionally few consider both.
65
Table 15: Decrease in School Absenteeism, Country Examples
Country
India
Indonesia
Bangladesh
Ethiopia
Decrease in school
absenteeism
20 to 4 million
(-16 million)
5.4 to 0.6 million
(-4.8 million)
5 to 0.4 million
(-4.6 million)
6 to 3 million
(-3 million)
GDP per capita, PPP,
inflation adjusted
37% growth
($2850-$3910)
27% growth
($2690-$3420)
56% growth
($1270-$1990)
37% growth
($677-$928)
Timeframe
2002-2008
1975-1983
1987-2006
2004-2008
Source: Gapminder.org, CC-BY
To be brief, families need physical access to schools, including both geographic distance and
cost dimensions. Instruction needs to be in a language the child understands and there
needs to be sufficient supplies and inputs, including teachers who are trained both in
subject matter and in pedagogy. Quality educational systems will produce learners capable
of performing certain skills, particularly basic literacy and numeracy. Quality systems will be
more valued by parents that already have higher rates of education themselves, so quality
education systems may take generations to develop. They will also be more valued if there
are higher-paying jobs that specifically demand the skills being taught in schools and
families feel there is a chance their children could have access to these types of jobs. System
administrators will also need to consider that the needs of students may differ by gender,
minority status, income, and disability.
Getting measures on all these dimensions, or even some, is remarkably difficult. UNESCO’s
September 2020 data update contains a large Excel file that lists the years that different
measures of educational quality are available by country (UNESCO Institute for Statistics
[UIS], n.d.). In Kenya, for example, over half of the 561 proposed measures for Sustainable
Development Goal 4 have never been measured and some, like the percent of students who
finished particular milestones, have not been measured in the last ten years. In Mexico – a
country with six times the GDP/capita of Kenya – over 100 indicators have never been
measured, many have only been measured once, and the vast majority have not been
updated since 2018. Even that is doing much better than the United States, UK, France, or
Germany which can boast over 340 missing indicators each and statistics that have not been
updated since 2015. In fact, the average indicator of educational quality has 124 missing
observations out of 229 countries. 188 countries have never measured what percent of the
population has a minimum level of literacy.
These difficulties suggest a few points. First, most governments simply are not collecting
data on educational quality consistently. To the extent the EU can encourage governments,
including member governments, to collect and report data on educational quality, it will be
easier to identify where the gaps are to improve child welfare and reduce child labour.
Second, it will be difficult to craft trade conditionalities based on improved educational
outcomes (as a sign of reduced child labour) if those outcomes are not being measured.
Third, this highlights why GDP/capita is one of the first measures to be used, because other
measures simply are not widely available or updated in a timely fashion.
66
To the extent it can be identified that one country has a better educational system than
another, there can be greater confidence that children released from child labour will enter
the schooling system. That will encourage more use of bans than would be suggested from
income data alone. Countries that have worse educational systems, and especially those
where access is less widely available, should have conditionalities that focus more on
improving the education system than on child labour directly to ensure that there is a viable
option in place for families to choose.
Dimension 3: Government capacity
Government capacity will be an essential element in reducing the incidence of child labour.
Previous research on child labour has identified that partial enforcement may well be worse
than no enforcement.
Consider the following thought experiment from Basu and Van (1998). Suppose that a
government can enforce a child labour ban on one group of firms but not on another group,
which Basu calls red and green firms for purposes of generality. That might be a stand-in for
exporting firms vs. internal firms, formal vs. informal, urban vs. rural, firms in a particular
sector but not in others. The good news is that child labour will stop in the red firms, raising
adult wages in those sectors. If there are relatively few red firms, all the child labourers can
be absorbed by the green firms, and there is no change in adult or child wages. If green
firms are less safe or desirable in some way, this will actually make children worse off. This
exactly describes what happened in the 1990s, when the proposed U.S. Harkin Bill
prompted the Bangladeshi garment industry to ban child labour, and most of the children
ended up in worse working conditions than before. If there are many red firms such that the
green sector cannot absorb all the child labourers, however, there are more interesting and
complicated dynamics. Adult wages will tend to rise as child wages fall, which may make
families better off and reduce child labour (if adult wages rose enough to not need the child
work and child wages fell enough that schooling became more attractive) or may create
more complex trade-offs, with some families better off, other families worse off, and no
reduction in child labour. Basu and Van (1998) also mention that if the red firms are
exporters only, as would be the case with sanctions or a ban imposed from outside, it is also
possible that the higher costs this imposes on red firms could kill the exporting industry
itself if it runs on thin margins. That would make thousands of families lose their jobs and
tend to depress wages for both adults and children, making all families unambiguously
worse off.
This thought experiment highlights at least two facets of governance well worth considering.
Can the developing country government enforce child labour laws universally? To what
extent might corruption or a lack of the rule of law prevent such enforcement?
Of the various measures of corruption, the Corruption Perception Index by Transparency
International (2020) and the World Bank’s Control of Corruption measure by Kaufmann and
Kraay (2019) are perhaps the best known. Measures of state capacity have not been as
developed or widely accepted because of differing definitions in the political science
literature. Hanson and Sigman (2020) have attempted to combine the various measures and
identify what they share in common through latent variable analysis. Their new measure is
67
most highly correlated with the World Bank’s (2020) measure of Statistical Capacity, the
Political Risk Service’s (2018) measure of Bureaucracy Quality, and v-Dem’s measure of
Rigorous and Impartial Public Administration (Coppedge et al., 2021).
More can be expected of governments that have higher administrative amplitude. They will
have greater enforcement capacity for any conditionality, and holding all else constant,
ought to maintain lower levels of child labour. That does not necessarily change whether
incentives or deterrents are a better strategy, but that does change the rigour with which
conditionalities may be enforced. A more capable low-income country might be engaged
with stronger conditionalities earlier than other countries at similar levels of income.
Corruption is less clear cut. More corrupt regimes will both be less likely to uphold the
conditions to which they agree and less able to enforce those they attempt to follow
(Pinstrup-Andersen et al., 2011). They are also more likely to allow the worst forms of child
labour that should be most vigorously fought. The correlation between more corruption and
lower income also makes it more likely there will be more child labour. Holding GDP
constant, there should be less reliance on conditionalities (because they will be ineffective)
where there is more corruption.
The World Economic Forum’s (2020) Global Competitiveness Report attempts to measure
government and social capacity to adapt to changes and challenges. Among their 11
measures of global competitiveness, it would appear that 1) “Ensuring public institutions
embed strong governance principles”, 4) “Updating education curricula and expanding
investment in skills”, and 5) “Rethinking labour laws and social protection” are the most
relevant to this discussion. There are several problems. Their measures of public institutions
include judicial independence, but not the effectiveness or impartiality of law enforcement;
“business leaders’ perception of the strength of auditing and accounting standards” and
corruption perceptions, but nothing that addresses bureaucratic capacity or whether the
national government can enforce child labour laws. Their measures of upgraded education
are about providing digital skills rather than literacy, and “business views on employees’
skills” rather than accessibility for a wide range of the population. Finally, they are looking
for integrated health, education, and labour laws as complements of social support policies,
which goes well beyond the question of if social protection policies exist. On the positive
side, however, these measures are highly relevant, including social protection coverage,
guaranteed minimum income benefits, inequality-adjusted access to education, and
enforcement of minimum wage. While the Global Competitiveness Report is available for
only 37 countries, these measures provide good suggestions for more inclusive economic
measures that may be available for a wider range of countries, and the report’s emphasis on
inclusiveness and care for the poorest and most marginalised suggest a number of ways
forward in the countries for which such data can be obtained.
68
V. UNGPs Pillar I – Measures to Enhance the State’s
Duty to Protect
The very first charge for the State, under the United Nations Guiding Principles (UNGPs), is
the charge to protect its citizens inter alia through policy, legislation and regulation. Point 1.
under “A. Foundational principles” reads that “States must protect against human rights
abuse within their territory and/or jurisdiction by third parties, including business
enterprises. This requires taking appropriate steps to prevent, investigate, punish and
redress such abuse through effective policies, legislation, regulations and adjudication” (UN,
2011, p. 3).
This section therefore investigates to what extent EU and U.S. trade-related legislation
features and enforces measures to uphold human rights – and in particular the issue of child
labour.
A. EU trade policy enforcement vis-à-vis child labour
1. Trade and Sustainable Development Chapters
References to labour rights in TSD Chapters
Since its 2010 FTA with South Korea, the EU has included Trade and Sustainable
Development (TSD) chapters in its trade agreements, committing signatory parties to
uphold the economic, environmental and social pillars that comprise sustainable
development (European Commission, 2020c). By using the incentive of market access to
motivate trade partners to implement international labour and environmental standards,
these chapters seek to "maximize the leverage of increased trade and investment on issues
like decent work, environmental protection or the fight against climate change to achieve
effective and sustainable policy change" (European Commission Services, 2018, p. 1). Figure
23 visualises with which country the EU has concluded bilateral trade agreements (TSD
chapters are contained in Free Trade Agreements).
In contrast to the United States, which attaches more importance to national governance
and refers to a broader set of issues such as minimum wages, hours of work and
occupational safety and health,16 the EU has chosen to place an emphasis on ILO principles
and associated standards. This reference in EU trade agreements to multilateral standards
has evolved over the years to encompass as much the ILO conventions as other instruments,
such as the Agenda 21 on Environment and Development on Sustainable Development of
16 These standards are encompassed by the
“internationally recognized workers rights” protected under the
US Code (19 UCS § 2497 (4)), and the worst forms of child labour, protected under Sec. 2497 (6). They have
consistently been implemented in U.S. agreements; as an example, see Article 19.3 (2) of the Trans-Pacific
Partnership Agreement (TPP) concluded by the United States with eleven other countries in 2016. The
agreement specifies that “for greater certainty, this obligation relates to the establishment by a Party in its
statutes, regulations and practices thereunder, of acceptable conditions of work as determined by that Party.”
69
1992;17 the Johannesburg Plan of Implementation of the World Summit on Sustainable
Development of 2002;18 the Ministerial Declaration of the UN the Outcome Document of
the Economic and Social Council on Generating Full and Productive Employment and Decent
Work for All of 2006;19 the ILO Declaration on Social Justice for a Fair Globalization of
2008;20 the United Nations Conference on Sustainable Development of 201221 or The
Outcome Document of the United Nations Summit on Sustainable Development of 2015. 22
Although these conventions are general instruments, it is worth noting that the EU
Association Agreement with Central America also specifically mentions ILO Convention
182.23
Figure 23: EU Trade Agreements With Third Countries, 2019
Source: EU trade map: The state of EU trade, (European Union, 2019), URL
In addition to referencing the above cited instruments, TSD chapters also refer specifically to
fundamental human rights that the parties commit themselves to respect, promote and
realise. The effective abolition of child labour is consistently included amongst them (see
Annex III – Examples of TSD Chapters). However, this commitment remains limited, as there
are no provisions in the EU TSD chapters that would deter trading partners from not
respecting these principles.
17 See notably the EU-Korea FTA (2010), art. 13.1(1); EU-Ukraine Association Agreement (2014) article 289(1);
EU-Vietnam FTA (2019), art. 13.1 (2); EU-Singapore FTA (2018), art. 12.1 (1).
18 See notably the EU-Korea FTA (2010), art. 13.1(1); EU-Ukraine Association Agreement (2014) article 289(1);
EU-Vietnam FTA (2019), art. 13.1 (2); EU-Singapore FTA (2018), art. 12.1 (1).
19 See notably the EU-Korea FTA (2010), art. 13.1(1); EU-Ukraine Association Agreement (2014) article 289(1);
EU-Vietnam FTA (2019), art. 13.1 (2); EU-Singapore FTA (2018), art. 12.1 (1).
20 See EU-Singapore FTA (2018), art. 12.1 (1).
21 See EU-Vietnam FTA, art. 13.1 (2).
22 See EU-Vietnam FTA, art. 13.1 (2).
23 See EU-Central America Association agreement (2012), art. 286.2 (b).
70
Non-enforceability of TSD Chapters
On account of their lacking binding dispute settlement procedures, TSD chapters are not
enforceable. Moreover, TSD chapters are systematically excluded from the binding bilateral
dispute settlement mechanism anchored within the agreements. While TSD chapters
provide for consultations, exchange of information and cooperation, they are not subject to
a dispute settlement mechanism as are other matters in the agreement. This is for example
the case of the EU-Singapore FTA, already in force, the EU-Canada FTA (CETA), which is
being provisionally applied, and the EU-Mercosur agreement reached on June 28th, 2021. In
sum, TSD chapters lack “sticks” ensuring that the trading partner remains proactive in
improving human and labour rights.
The provisions for consultations are designed such that the parties establish a Panel of
Experts when no mutually satisfactory resolution is reached. This panel, composed of
independent trade, labour and environmental experts, prepares a public report with
recommendations, however it does not have the power to impose sanctions or fines in case
of non-compliance. After the Panel report is issued, it is up to the parties to discuss
appropriate measures to be implemented. In addition, a sub-committee created by the TSD
chapter is responsible for monitoring the implementation of the chapter, as well as the
Panel’s reports and recommendations. The right hand column in Annex III – Examples of TSD
Chapters notably references provisions of the TSD chapters in keeping with panels of
experts.
The mechanisms for ensuring follow-up to their reports are also deemed insufficient. On the
basis of the European Commission’s proposals to develop individual strategies for each
partnership (European Commission Services, 2017, p. 6), some authors thus highlight that it
would be necessary for the EU to “focus on the key concerns identified in each trade
partnership” (Barbu et al., 2017, p. 4).
The “enforcement” and monitoring of TSD chapters thus solely rely on soft mechanisms
enshrined in provisions which “do not link compliance to economic consequences but
provide a framework for dialogue, cooperation, and/or monitoring” (Ebert, 2013, p. 1). The
activation of these mechanisms notably hinges on civil society (which includes trade union
actors), so as to engage the dialogue on human rights issues. However, the role of civil
society participation remains limited on account of functional shortcomings, such as
resourcing constraints or difficulties of representation amongst trading partners. Some
academics therefore advocate to ascribe a more meaningful role as well as procedural rights
to civil society alongside trader partners and states (Barbu et al., 2017, p. 4; Harrison et al.,
2017, pp. 29–30).
Given these limitations, one debate currently waged concerns the question whether the
EU’s existing TSD model featuring dialogue and consultation effectively improves conditions
in partner countries. On the one hand, it is argued that the treat of levying sanctions for EU
71
partners in EU TSD chapters may act as a deterrence.24 One argument is that the threat of
sanctions motivates greater compliance with human rights standards, including child labour.
Evidence supporting this view is that upon threatening the revocation of their EU GSP+
status, El Salvador reportedly made demonstrated progress (European Trade Union
Confederation [ETUC], 2017). Also, the U.S. threatening to revoke Georgia’s GSP status
prompted a change to their labour code (ETUC, 2017). Once implemented, actual sanctions
can furthermore prompt the desired action, as in the case of U.S. removal of GSP for
Bangladesh, which “lead to changes in the law to allow freedom of association in the
garment sector” (ETUC, 2017). Yet the implementation of sanctions may not always lead to
the desired outcomes, as was the case in some U.S. agreements (Raess, 2018, p. 13).
Although several complaints have been filed, sanctions have hitherto not been applied in
cases involving non-compliance with labour and environment chapters. In the only labourrelated case subject to a WTO dispute settlement, the United States was not able to prevail
due an almost impossibly high standard of proof, i.e. that Guatemala’s violation of its labour
commitments had resulted in a substantial impact on trade flows25 (Barbu et al., 2017, p. 5;
International Labour Office, 2016, pp. 45–47; Lowe, 2019, pp. 2–3).
Some observers have cautioned against the introduction of sanctions in TSD chapters on
account of the harm they may cause to developing countries. As Moore and Scherrer (2017,
p. 14) posit, economic sanctions are more likely to harm citizens through job losses than
governments that have failed to meet their commitments. This is especially true of countries
with low GDP/capita, where sticks are not recommended and for which incentives
(“carrots”) are considered more suitable to encourage trade partners to abide by their
commitments under the agreements. Eventually, sanctions may have an adverse impact on
trade relations (European Commission Services, 2017, p. 9).
Therefore, the European Commission recommended in 2018 to improve the existing
cooperative mechanisms implemented in EU agreements rather than introducing sanctions
(European Commission Services, 2018). In its 2020 report on the implementation of EU
Trade Arguments in 2019, the Commission further reaffirmed the importance of
cooperation in the following terms:
Complying with trade and sustainable development commitments often involves
tackling long-standing and deeply rooted domestic issues and different policy priorities.
This calls for a long-term perspective on implementation, supported by enforcement and
the active involvement of civil society and business. Therefore, the implementation work
focuses also on building platforms for cooperation and joint initiatives on issues ranging
24
A 2019 publication by the Center for a New American Security concluded that the consensus in academic
literature is that conventional trade sanctions result in some meaningful behavioural change in the targeted
country in about 40% of cases, but narrower bans on the sale of luxury goods and sectoral sanctions have an
even lower success rate at about 20% (Peksen, 2019).
25
The bar was set extremely high in the Central America-United States Free Trade Agreement (CAFTA-DR),
ETUC (2017) explained, as the main condition for a complaining party to impose sanctions was “that the
violation occurred ‘in a manner affecting trade,’ which has never previously been interpreted by a trade panel.
The panel, in an effort to understand why this language, rather than the more usual ‘trade-related,’ was used,
decided that the use of ‘in a manner affecting trade’ was intended to set a higher bar. In other words, this
language was interpreted as a limitation to enforcement.”
72
from fair remuneration, working in a safe and healthy environment to promoting
climate-friendly technologies (European Commission, 2020b, p. 28).
However, in response to ongoing criticisms of the lack of enforceability of TSD chapters, the
European Commission announced in 2021 that it would consider implementing sanctions for
non-compliance with TSD chapters (European Commission, 2021c, p. 16). These changes are
being considered as part of the Commission's review of the 2018 15-point TSD Action Plan,
which aimed to encourage stronger enforcement of EU trade agreements and identify a “set
of targeted actions according to the specific priorities identified for each trading partner”
(European Commission, 2020b, p. 28). As explained by the EU Commission,
the review will cover all relevant aspects of TSD implementation and enforcement,
including the scope of commitments, monitoring mechanisms, the possibility of sanctions
for non-compliance, the essential elements clause as well as the institutional set-up and
resources required (European Commission, 2021c, p. 16).
In line with one of the 15 action points to facilitate “the monitoring role of civil society,” the
EU Commission also announced it would launch a new complaints system for reporting
market access barriers, open to all EU-based stakeholders – ranging from Member States to
individual companies, business/trade associations, civil society organisations and EU citizens
(European Commission, 2021c). The objective of this so-called “Single Entry Point” is to
“streamline internal processes to tackle market access issues and non-compliance with
TSD/GSP commitments and to be able to better prioritise enforcement action” (European
Commission, 2021b, p. 1). Stakeholders would therefore be able to play a direct role in the
implementation of TSD chapters.
Disputes involving child labour
No dispute settlement procedure has been activated concerning TSD chapters so far, insofar
as they strictly have relied on cooperative mechanisms.
However, it may be noted that some issues have been raised regarding labour rights, even
though they do not tackle child labour specifically. In January 2019, government
consultations were held under the TSD Chapter of the EU-South Korea trade agreements at
the request of the European Commission, due to South Korea’s non-implementation of the
agreement’s labour provisions since the entry into force in 2012. This claim represented the
first European initiative concerning the formal dispute settlement procedure. In July of the
same year, the EU requested the establishment of a panel of experts, on account of the lack
of efforts toward ratifying four ILO conventions (1930; 1948; 1949; 1957), i.e. Forced Labour
Convention, 1930 (No. 29); Freedom of Association and Protection of the Right to Organise
Convention, 1948 (No. 87); Right to Organise and Collective Bargaining Convention, 1949
(No. 98) and Abolition of Forced Labour Convention, 1957 (No. 105). The EU also claimed
that the provisions of the South Korean Trade Union and Labour Relations Adjustment Act
1997 (Government of Korea, 1997) were not consistent with the principles concerning
freedom of association implemented in Article 13.4.3 of the trade agreement. On 25 January
2021, the panel confirmed that South Korea had failed to make continued and sustained
efforts towards ratification of the above cited four ILO Conventions, and recommended that
South Korea bring TULRAA into conformity with the principles concerning freedom of
73
association (Jill Murray et al., 2021, p. 79). The panel notably pointed out that the provisions
on ratification of the ILO core conventions lacked a specific target date or particular
milestone and merely referred to the obligation to make “continued and sustained efforts
towards ratification” (Jill Murray et al., 2021, p. 74, §276). Accordingly, both parties had
under the agreement an “on-going obligation” to ratify the conventions, “affording leeway
for the Parties to select specific ways to make continued and sustained efforts” (Jill Murray
et al., 2021, p. 74, §278). Owing to this leeway, the panel therefore concluded that South
Korea had only violated its obligations under the agreement because it had not acted on this
on-going obligation to strive to ratify the four ILO conventions. However, the decision of the
panel emphasised the importance for the European Union to include provisions with timebound roadmaps accompanied with targets within future trade agreements. Such provisions
would indeed impose a strong obligation on the parties to ratify the instruments, in contrast
to the mere reference of “continued and sustained efforts towards ratification.”
While other issues have also been raised, they involved matters other than labour rights. For
example, the European Commission requested consultations with Ukraine on the country’s
export restrictions in January 2019, under the EU-Ukraine Association Agreement (European
Commission, 2020b, pp. 47–48).
2. Stringency of child labour provisions
Comparison between FTA and GSP provisions
The lack of enforceability of TSD chapters calls for a comparison with other similar trade
instruments, so as to draw good practice from these instruments in the event that they
would be more stringent than TSD chapters. In this respect, as GSP programmes allow for a
unilateral approach, they provide an alternative to trade agreements with TSD chapters in
the European Union.
The aim of GSP provisions is to remove or decrease import duties from products produced
by countries considered as being “vulnerable” (Regulation (EU) No 978/2012, Preamble,
para. 9-11, art. 9). By contrast to TSD chapters, which apply uniformly for both parties of the
agreement, GSP apply unilaterally.
Created following UNCTAD recommendations in 1971, the EU GSP reduces tariffs for
developing countries so as to generate an additional export revenue and thus create jobs
respecting internationally agreed standards. In the words of Borchert et al. (2020, p. 12), the
EU GSP is enshrined in the WTO system, whose Enabling Clause of 1979 legalises a positive,
pro-development form of trade discrimination. Indeed, it enables developed countries to
propose to developing countries more attractive tariffs than those of the most favoured
nation (MFN). As laid down in Article 4(1) of the Regulation, developing countries are
deemed as vulnerable as long as they are classified as having an income level below the
“upper middle income” by the World Bank, and are not already granted preferential
treatment under another agreement, such as FTAs (Regulation (EU) No 978/2012).
The EU GSP has evolved through several reforms in 1995, 2006 and 2014 (Council
Regulation (EC) No 3281/94, No 980/2005, No 978/2012), with the latter providing for the
74
current GSP regulation for ten years. As laid down in Article 1(2) of the Regulation,
preferential access to the EU market is made possible through three different programmes,
i.e. the standard GSP programme, the GSP+ programme and the Everything But Arms (EBA)
programme (Regulation (EU) No 978/2012).
Whilst the standard programme applies to countries with low- or lower-middle income, and
only enables them to get a reduction in duties below the MFN tariff treatment on about
66% of EU tariff lines, the second programme, introduced in 2006, provides for duty-free
tariffs on all products covered by the standard GSP. Both programmes had their scope cut
down, such that the standard GSP programme currently counts 15 countries, whereas the
GSP+ programme comprises 8 countries (Damen & Igler, 2020, pp. 2–3). The EBA
programme, introduced in 2001, eventually allows for duty-free and quota-free access to
the EU, with the exception of trade of arms and ammunition (Damen & Igler, 2020, p. 3).
This arrangement is only available for the least-developed countries. Comparing the
standard GSP, GSP+ or the EBA initiative, two observations can be made, which suggest that
the provisions of the GSP are more stringent than those of the TSD chapters.
First, GSP provisions are endowed with a strong pre-ratification mechanism. All GSP
programmes require the respect of fifteen core conventions on human rights and labour
rights, as laid down in 19(1)(a) of the Regulation (EU) No 978/2012. These conventions
comprise, inter alia: the Convention on the Rights of the Child of 1989 (United Nations
General Assembly, 1989); the Convention concerning Forced or Compulsory Labour of 1930,
no 29 (ILO, 1930); the Convention concerning the Abolition of Forced Labour of 1957, no
105 (ILO, 1957); the Convention concerning Minimum Age for Admission to Employment of
1973, no 138 (ILO, 1973); the Convention concerning the Prohibition and Immediate Action
for the Elimination of the Worst Forms of Child Labour of 1999, no 182 (ILO, 1999).
In addition, countries eligible for the GSP+ are required to comply with an additional
number of international conventions protecting human rights, the environment and good
governance. As provided in Article 9 of the Regulation (EU) No 978/2012, beneficiary
countries must indeed ensure the effective ratification and implementation of a set of 27
international conventions, and accept the reporting requirements under the Conventions as
well as monitoring and review of their implementation.
The requirements to ratify these conventions are thus much more specific than in TSD
chapters, which usually merely engage countries to respect fundamental labour and human
rights and strive to ratify ILO Conventions. Indeed, the language used in TSD chapters is
mostly non-binding (the parties aim to “promote”, “reaffirm their determination”, “make
efforts”, “undertake to cooperate”). It should also be noted that in contrast to TSD chapters,
which place parties on an equal footing, GSP programmes are specifically tailored for
providing market access to more vulnerable trade partners. GSP programmes thus provide
stronger ‘carrots’ than TSD chapters, as their ILO convention ratification is required: this
prerequisite, on the part of the EU trade partner, conditions the countries’ preferential
access to the EU market, which thus embodies a genuine incentive for ratification.
Second, as opposed to TSD chapters, which lack enforcement mechanisms, GSP’s
preferential arrangements may be withdrawn temporarily in cases of non-compliance.
Article 19 of the EU regulation thus provides that all preferential arrangements may be
75
withdrawn in cases of serious and systematic violation of these instruments (Regulation (EU)
No 978/2012). Paragraph 24 of the Preamble also states that:
The reasons for temporary withdrawal of the arrangements under the scheme should
include serious and systematic violations of the principles laid down in certain
international conventions concerning core human rights and labour rights, so as to
promote the objectives of those conventions. Tariff preferences under the special
incentive arrangement for sustainable development and good governance should be
temporarily withdrawn if the beneficiary country does not respect its binding
undertaking to maintain the ratification and effective implementation of those
conventions or to comply with the reporting requirements imposed by the respective
conventions, or if the beneficiary country does not cooperate with the Union’s
monitoring procedures as set out in this Regulation. (Regulation (EU) No 978/2012)
The threat of this withdrawal can be considered as a “stick,” which forces the trade partners
to comply with their commitments.
Accordingly, GSP provisions are designed to be more stringent than TSD chapters, for their
stick-carrot system is stronger: trade partners are encouraged to respect or improve respect
for human rights by the threat of withdrawal from the arrangements on the one hand (the
“stick”) and by the incentive of ratifying and respecting ILO conventions (the “carrot”) on
the other.
3. Local impact dimension of TSD chapters
The effects of TSD chapters are considered difficult to assess, on account of the promotional
nature of their provisions (ILO & International Institute for Labour Studies [IILS], 2013, p.
21). This may explain why no consensus has been reached so far on their role in improving
labour and human rights protection.
In response to the Non-paper of the European Commission Services (2017), which sought
feedback on its approach to TSD chapters, some scholars underlined that a number of
studies on this question “failed to find positive impacts of labour provisions for the situation
of workers in the EU or its trade partners. In two studies it was found that governments had
actually sought to weaken labour standards protection (Peru successfully and South Korea
unsuccessfully) since the trade agreements with the EU came into force” (Barbu et al., 2017,
p. 2).
They ascribe this lack of effectiveness to the shortcomings of TSD chapters, amongst which
the limited role of the EU actors involved in the implementation of the chapters; a lack of
systematic implementation of cooperative activities; the limited participation of civil society
and insufficient follow-up procedures and dispute resolution process. According to them,
academic studies concluding that FTAs have positive effects on workers’ rights tend to be
based on Brussels-based interviews and fail to identify TSD shortcomings.
This view is partly shared by Damian Raess (2018, pp. 9–10), who investigated the degree of
labour-related implementation after the signing of an FTA (ex-post effects). Unlike Postnikov
76
and Bastiaens (2014), whose study concluded that the EU's trading partners generally
accorded better protection to labour rights after signing the FTA, Raess’s study does not
offer a conclusion on labour-related FTA effectiveness. Raess explains the difference
between the studies by the fact that Postnikov and Bastiaens’ study covers the period 19802010, whereas his own study focuses on agreements made since the EU-Korea FTA in 2010,
from which the agreements' soft approach based on dialogue has shifted to a stronger
approach based on cooperation mechanisms. Raess, however, does suggest that there may
be evidence that trade agreements have an ex ante influence, i.e. before their ratification.
An ILO study (International Labour Office, 2016, pp. 72–104) led over the period 1991-2014
yielded similarly mixed results, and concluded that FTAs did not have any effects on working
conditions, although they improved labour force participation rates and reduced the gender
gap.
The European Commission’s own analysis of TSD chapters is insufficiently comprehensive to
determine whether TSD chapters have an impact on labour and rights protection (European
Commission, 2020b, pp. 28–30). In its report of 2020 on the implementation of EU Trade
Arguments in 2019, the Commission merely mentions Viet Nam as an example of progress
on trade and labour commitments, in particular with regard to the abolition of child labour
(which reduced more than 40% since 2012).
However, a positive impact of TSD chapters in EU trade agreements may be more apparent
in years to come,” as a review of the 15-point action plan has been scheduled for 2021
(European Commission, 2021c, p. 16).
4. EU-UK Free Trade Agreement
The EU-UK Trade and Cooperation Agreement (TCA) of 2020 established a tariff- and quotafree trade relationship between the EU and the UK, provisionally entered into force on the
1st of January, 2021 (TCA, 2020).
The TCA (2020) specifically treats child labour in Article 8.3 on “Multilateral labour standards
and agreements.” In particular, “each Party commits to respecting, promoting and
effectively implementing the internationally recognised core labour standards, as defined in
the fundamental ILO Conventions,” including “(b) the elimination of all forms of forced or
compulsory labour; (c) the effective abolition of child labour.”
Yet as, comparatively speaking, it is predominantly developing countries that struggle to
uphold these labour standards, the TCA also included a supply chain dimension. In Article
8.10 (TCA, 2020) on “Trade and responsible supply chain management,” the “Parties
recognise the importance of responsible management of supply chains through responsible
business conduct and corporate social responsibility practices and the role of trade in
pursuing this objective.” The EU and the UK are to encourage responsible business conduct
by “providing supportive policy frameworks that encourage the uptake of relevant practices
by businesses” (TCA, 2020). Further, the parties are to “support the adherence,
implementation, follow-up and dissemination of relevant international instruments, such as
the OECD Guidelines for Multinational Enterprises, the ILO Tripartite Declaration of
77
Principles concerning Multinational Enterprises and Social Policy, the UN Global Compact,
and the UN Guiding Principles on Business and Human Rights” (TCA, 2020).
Where significant divergences arise regarding the parties’ policies and priorities with respect
to labour, social, or environmental protection, and such differences cause material impacts
on trade and investment Article 9.4 in Title XI: Level Playing field for open and fair
competition and sustainable development of the TCA (2020) provides the option for one
party to impose on the other so-called “rebalancing measures,” i.e. a sanction (e.g., tariffs)
which are “designed to compensate one side for an unfair disadvantage” (Luyten, 2021).
Luyten (2021) explains the process:
In such a scenario, the party who intends to impose rebalancing measures must
notify the other party and consultations will take place to find a solution. If no
agreement is reached, after five days from the conclusion of the consultations, the
party can adopt necessary and proportionate rebalancing measures to remedy the
situation, providing that the other party has not requested the establishment of an
arbitration tribunal. If an arbitration tribunal is established, but does not deliver its
final ruling after 30 days, the party is allowed to adopt rebalancing measures. In
return, the other party can also take proportionate counter-measures until the
tribunal delivers its ruling. In enacting measures, the aim is to craft something so that
disruption to the trading relationship is minimized.
As this “rebalancing measure” in the TCA offers a clear mechanism to challenge a trade
partner on sustainability outcomes, it represents an improvement over existing TSD
chapters which do “not include the possibility to impose rebalancing measures against noncompliant third countries” (Luyten, 2021).
5. EU “essential elements” human rights clause
Apart from its TSD chapters, the EU has another “mechanism for incorporating human rights
into the EU's bilateral agreements” (Zamfir, 2019, p. 1). The “essential elements” human
rights clause “enables one party to take appropriate measures in case of serious breaches by
the other party.” By opening up “the path to dialogue and cooperation on human rights
issues,” the clause is reportedly “more than just a legal mechanism enabling the unilateral
suspension of trade commitments.” Given its existence as a measure of last resort, this
guillotine option has not been deployed:
So far, the EU has clearly preferred a constructive engagement to more restrictive
measures, and has not activated the clause to suspend trade preferences under any
of its trade agreements. Civil society and the European Parliament have, on the other
hand, encouraged the European Commission to use the clause in a more robust way
in order to respond to serious breaches of human rights and democratic principles
(Zamfir, 2019a, p. 1).
78
6. EU trade sanction instruments
In 2020, “the EU Council adopted a framework consisting of a decision (Council Decision
CFSP 2020/1999) and a regulation (Council Regulation EU 2020/1998), which establish a
global human rights sanctions regime” (“EU Targets Individuals,” 2020). Together,
the Council Decision and Regulation establish the first global and comprehensive human
rights sanctions regime to be enacted by the EU. Mirroring the U.S. Magnitsky Act, the new
sanctions regime provides the EU with a legal framework to target natural and legal
persons, entities and bodies – including state and non-state actors – responsible for,
involved in or associated with serious human rights violations and abuses worldwide,
regardless of where these might have occurred.26 The sanction regime applies to acts such
as genocide, crimes against humanity and other serious human rights violations, such as
torture, slavery, extrajudicial killings, arbitrary arrests or detentions. While child labour is
not specifically listed, other human rights violations can fall under the scope of the sanction
regime where those violations or abuses are widespread, systematic or are otherwise of
serious concern.27 In March, this new framework was, for example, used to target Chinese
officials in relation with Xinjiang (Council of the European Union, 2021).
The sanction regime allows EU member states to impose on designated individuals and
entities travel bans (applying to individuals) and asset freezes (applying to both individuals
and entities). The EU Council, acting upon a proposal from a member state or from the High
Representative of the EU for Foreign Affairs and Security Policy, is mandated to establish,
review and amend the list of those individuals and entities that are subject to the sanction
regime. Note that designating an individual or an entity will require a significant degree of
consensus, as the Council of the EU can only proceed with designations on the basis of
unanimity among all member states. Enforcing the sanction regime, including determining
the applicable penalties for the infringement of the restrictive measures, falls within the
competency of member states.
The EU traditionally imposed sanctions against third countries for human rights violations on
the basis of a sanctions framework linked to specific countries, conflicts or crises. Prior to
the adoption of the new framework, outside of this country-based regime, the EU had no
specific mechanism to impose sanctions on individuals or entities accused of human rights
abuses. Linking the possibility of sanctioning human rights violations to specific countries or
conflicts limited the EU’s ability to respond swiftly whenever a new crisis emerged. The new
regime may confer more flexibility and speediness to the EU’s response to significant human
rights violations. In addition, since the new regime put the emphasis on the individual
responsibility of designated persons and entities (rather than on their nationality), it may
reduce geopolitical tension compared to the country-based sanctioning and resulting
political, economic and strategic conflicts with third countries (Gibson Dunn, 2020).
26 Note that Canada and the UK, among other countries, also have
in place Magnitsky-like sanctions regimes.
In July 2020, the UK introduced into law the Global Human Rights Sanctions Regulations 2020, and designated
the first individuals under the Regulations in connection with their involvement in gross human rights
violations. The Regulations are made under powers in the Sanctions and Anti-Money Laundering Act 2018,
which was enacted in order to empower the UK government to introduce the UK’s own sanctions post-Brexit.
The list of financial sanctions targets in the UK includes forced labour allegations against seven entities (Office
of Financial Sanctions Implementation HM Treasury, 2021).
27
As regards the objectives of the common foreign and security policy set out in Title V Article 21 of the Treaty
on European Union.
79
Certain members of the European Parliament have called for a new EU instrument that
would allow for import bans on products related to severe human rights violations such as
forced labour or child labour (Vanpeperstraete, 2021). This tool could be a complementary
measure to the EU legislation on corporate human rights and environmental due diligence
along supply chains which is currently being developed.
A discussion paper released by the Greens/European Free Alliance (EFA) Group in the
European Parliament in March 2021 examines options for an EU mechanism on forced
labour and modern slavery. The paper analyses four options for introducing an import ban
via: EU foreign policy, such as the new EU Human Rights Sanctions mechanism; amending
EU Free Trade Agreements and other trade mechanisms; a new internal market mechanism;
or a new instrument with a legal trade basis (IISD, 2021). Such a mechanism would allow the
EU to immediately stop goods at the EU border when there is reasonable suspicion the
goods have been produced with forced labour. Although the EU is developing a proposal for
a law on corporate human rights and environmental due diligence, this law will not allow for
restrictions or bans on products linked to forced labour. The paper aims to examine
opportunities to complement the upcoming EU due diligence law with an import ban
instrument that would allow the EU an additional tool to ensure that no products sold in the
EU are linked to forced labour. While the EU’s Common Foreign and Security Policy includes
restrictive measurements like sanctions, the paper concludes it is not the best option
because of the “cumbersome and complex decision-making procedure driven by the
European Council” (Vanpeperstraete, 2021, p. 6), which would restrict specific sanctions to a
limited number of high-profile cases, provide limited recourse for individual complaints, and
be subjected to broader foreign policy objectives. The paper identifies a number of
challenges in relation to both the option of amending existing trade mechanisms – including
challenges with enforcement and variations in trade relations across the EU – and the
option of introducing a new internal market mechanism – similar to procedures against
illegal, unreported and unregulated fishing. The paper concludes that the preferred option is
a new EU instrument with a trade legal basis that establishes a mandate to withhold the
release of goods suspected to be made by or transported by forced labour. The paper
suggests such an instrument could draw from previous instruments such as the Regulation
banning instruments for torture for the substantive part and the Regulation protecting
intellectual property rights for the procedural aspect. To minimise adverse impacts for
workers and communities, the paper recommends targeting bans against individual
companies or specific products where there has been proven abuse rather than against
entire countries or sectors (Vanpeperstraete, 2021).
B. U.S. trade policy enforcement vis-à-vis child labour
The United States keeps hard-line policy options on the table, which the government uses to
threaten and actually impose sanctions or other actions on the grounds of child labour and
other labour rights violations. These tools include the blocking of goods entering the
country, the sanctioning and other actions against producers using child labour in their
operations and supply chains, the listing of goods produced by forced and child labour, and
monitoring trade policy for changes in child and forced labour prevalence.
80
Table 16: U.S. Policy to Impose Sanctions or Other Actions on the Grounds of Child Labour and Other Labour
Rights Violations
Legislation
Purpose
Instruments that initiate child-labour-premised trade action:
U.S. Tariff Act of 1930, amended
Provides for importation bans
by the U.S Trade Facilitation and
(exclusion and/or seizure), possible
criminal investigation
Trade Enforcement Act of 2015,
impacting Title 19 (Customs
Duties) CFR Section 12.42
Execution entity
U.S. Secretary of the Treasury to
promulgate necessary
regulations; U.S. Customs and
Border Protection (CBP) of the
U.S. Department of Homeland
Security (DHS) issues Withhold
Release Orders (WRO) and
findings
U.S. Executive Order 13126 of
Creation of List of Products,
The Bureau of International
1999
products are excluded from federal Labor Affairs (ILAB) of the U.S.
procurement, consequences for
Department of Labor maintains
violations
List of Products and pursues
remedy
U.S. Global Magnitsky Human
Sanction of individuals and entities U.S. Department of the Treasury:
Rights Accountability Act (2016)
freezes U.S. assets and bans
and U.S. Executive Order 13818 of
physical entry into the United
2017
States
Instruments that provide policy and information through which trade instruments are enforced:
U.S. Trafficking Victims Protection Creation of List of Goods,
U.S. Department of State, U.S.
Act (“TVPA”) 2000, and
coordination and enforcement
Department of Labor
successive reauthorisation acts
(TVPRA) of 2003, 2005, 2008,
2013, 2017
U.S. Trade Act of 2002
Trade policy which informs the
U.S. Congress, President of the
United States’ policy objectives
United States
U.S. Trade Promotion Authority
Accords labour issues the same
U.S. Congress, President of the
Act of 2015
dispute settlement mechanisms
United States
and penalties for labour violations
as for other FTA chapters, prohibits
“the diminution of labor standards
to attract trade and investment”
1. DHS mechanism
U.S. Tariff Act of 1930, amended by U.S. Trade Facilitation and Trade Enforcement Act of
2015
U.S. customs law has prohibited importing goods produced by certain categories of labour
since the end of the nineteenth century. Beginning in 1890, the United States prohibited
imports of goods manufactured with convict labour. In 1930, Congress expanded this
prohibition in Section 307 of the Tariff Act (1930) to include any (not just manufactured)
products of forced labour. Section 307 of the Tariff Act of 1930 prohibits the importation of
merchandise mined, produced or manufactured, wholly or in part, in any foreign country by
forced labour, including prison labour. Forced labour is defined in Section 307 as: “All work
or service which is exacted from any person under the menace of any penalty for its nonperformance and for which the worker does not offer himself voluntarily” with language
modelled on the ILO (1930) Forced Labor Convention.
81
Then, in 2000, Section 307 was amended by the U.S. Trade and Development Act (TDA) of
2000 to expand its scope, explicitly including forced or indentured child labour: “For
purposes of this section, the term ‘forced labor or/and indentured labor’ includes forced or
indentured child labor” (19 U.S.C. § 1307). The TDA furthermore authorised and directed
the U.S. Treasury Secretary to prescribe regulations necessary for the enforcement of the
provision to deny entry of all “goods, wares, articles, and merchandise mined, produced, or
manufactured wholly or in part in any foreign country by convict labor or/and forced labor
or/and indentured labor under penal sanctions” (ibid).
Although a few Members of Congress brought up humanitarian concerns during debate of
the Tariff Act of 1930, the central legislative concern was with protecting domestic
producers from competing with products made with forced labour. As such, Section 307
allowed the importation of certain forced labour-produced goods if the goods were not
produced “in such quantities in the United States as to meet the consumptive demands of
the United States” (Tariff Act, 1930, §1307). Under the original law, if goods could not be
sufficiently made available through domestic means, they could also not become a target of
sanction. In 2016, 86 years after its signing into law, this “consumptive demand” provision
of the 1930 Tariff Act was struck. The bi-partisan Trade Facilitation and Trade Enforcement
Act of 2015 amended the Tariff Act by eliminating the “consumptive demand” exemption
clause (19 U.S.C. § 1307).28
Enforcement
Under Section 307 of the Tariff Act, merchandise mined, produced or manufactured, wholly
or in part, in any foreign country by forced/indentured child labour is subject to exclusion
and/or seizure, and may lead to criminal investigation of the importer (U.S. Customs and
Border Protection [CBP], 2021). Enforcement of the Tariff Act is operationalised in Title 19
(Customs Duties) CFR Section 12.42. U.S. Customs and Border Protection (CBP) enforces the
prohibition (CBP, 2021).
CBP may initiate investigations into forced labour violations involving specific
manufacturers/exporters and specific merchandise based on internal allegations (through
information provided in a CBP Form 28 Request for Information, or by port directors) or on
allegations from an outside source (such as a third-party) (19 C.F.R. § 12.42 (a)-(d).). CBP
“encourages anyone with reason to believe that merchandise produced by forced labor is
being, or is likely to be imported into the United States, to communicate his or her belief to
any U.S. port director or the commissioner of CBP” (CBP, 2016a, 2021; 19 C.F.R. § 12.42).
This may be accomplished by submitting a detailed formal petition to CBP.29 Anyone – a
business, an agency, even a non-citizen – may submit to U.S. Customs (under the
Department of Homeland Security) a petition showing “reasonably but not conclusively”
that imports were made at least in part with forced labour (Bayer, 2016; CBP, 2021).
28 One entire sentence was struck: “The provisions of this section relating to goods, wares, articles, and
merchandise mined, produced, or manufactured by forced labor or/and indentured labor, shall take effect on
January 1, 1932; but in no case shall such provisions be applicable to goods, wares, articles, or merchandise so
mined, produced, or manufactured which are not mined, produced, or manufactured in such quantities in the
United States as to meet the consumptive demands of the United States” (19 U.S.C. § 1307).
29 Any such petition must completely satisfy the requirements of 19 C.F.R. § 12.42(b).
82
As required by 19 C.F.R. §12.42, port directors and other principal customs officers must
report such instances to the CBP Commissioner. Upon receipt of such a report, the
Commissioner of CBP is required to initiate an investigation “as appears warranted” by the
amount and reliability of the submitted information. If the Commissioner of CBP finds the
information “reasonably but not conclusively indicates” that imports may be the product of
forced labour, then the Commissioner is to issue a Withhold Release Order (WRO) of such
goods pending further instructions (CBP, 2021; 19 C.F.R. § 12.42 (e)-(g).). If the
Commissioner is provided with information sufficient to make a determination that the
goods in question are subject to the provisions of 19 U.S.C. § 1307, the Commissioner will
publish a formal finding to that effect in the Customs Bulletin and in the Federal Register
(CBP, 2021; 19 C.F.R. § 12.42 (f).). Immigration and Customs Enforcement can pursue
criminal investigations of Section 307 violations.
Furthermore, the Act charges the Commissioner to submit to the Committee on Finance of
the Senate and the Committee on Ways and Means of the House of Representatives a
report on compliance with section 307 of the Tariff Act of 1930 that includes:
1. the number of instances in which merchandise was denied entry pursuant to that
section during the 1-year period preceding the submission of the report,
2. a description of the merchandise denied entry pursuant to that section, and
3. other information as the Commissioner considers appropriate with respect to
monitoring and enforcing compliance with that section (Congressional Research
Service [CRS], 2021b).
In February 2019, and in response to recommendations from outside stakeholders, CBP
published a forced labour process, consisting of the following nine steps (CBP, 2019a):
1. Receipt of Allegation or Self-Initiation: The provisions of 19 C.F.R § 12.42 detail
who may submit information;
2. CBP Evaluation: CBP must determine or establish reasonable suspicion to issue a
Withhold Release Order (WRO) or conclusively demonstrate that merchandise is
prohibited to publish a finding;
3. Commissioner Review of WRO Issuance: If Commissioner approves a WRO, CBP
detains subject merchandise;
4. Issuance of WRO: Port directors instructed to withhold release of subject
merchandise;
5. Detention of Merchandise: CBP begins to detain all shipments within WRO
parameters;
6. Export, Contest, or Protest: Importer may export, contest, or protest; CBP may
release or exclude;
7. Finding/ Customs Bulletin and Federal Register: If a finding is published, subject
merchandise that has not been released from CBP custody shall be treated as an
importation prohibited by 19 U.S.C. § 1307;
8. Seizure – Subsequent FPF Process: CBP will seize merchandise. Violator may
petition for the release of merchandise; and
9. Judicial Forfeiture: CBP will commence summary forfeiture proceedings.
An importer has three months to contest a WRO and must demonstrate that it has made
“every reasonable effort” to determine both the source of and the type of labour used to
83
produce the merchandise and its components. If the importer does not successfully contest
the WRO and does not remove the merchandise at issue from the United States, CBP is to
seize and destroy it.
The forced labour import prohibition applies to all importers of goods to the United States.
According to published guidance, importers have a general obligation to exercise
“reasonable care” and to take all necessary and appropriate steps to ensure that goods
imported to the United States comply with all laws and regulations, including the Tariff Act
(CBP, 2017, para. 14).
While CBP generally does not target entire product lines or industries, CBP (and ICE) do
consider information that companies make available during their efforts to address forced
labour risks in their supply chains, as well as external reports (CBP, 2021; 19 C.F.R. §
12.42(e).). Following detention, CBP must determine whether to formally exclude the
merchandise, or deem it admissible and release it for importation into the United States. An
importer may submit information demonstrating that the detained subject merchandise
does not violate the Tariff Act. CBP may revoke a WRO if evidence shows that the subject
goods were not made with forced labour, are no longer being produced with forced labour,
or if the goods are no longer being, or likely to be, imported into the United States (CBP
2016b).
In addition to CBP’s civil enforcement actions, ICE’s Homeland Security Investigations (HSI)
may institute criminal investigations against individuals or companies for involvement in the
importation of prohibited goods. Since 2017, ICE has initiated 54 international cases on
forced labour, prompted 66 related international arrests, and seized 4,397 related goods
domestically and internationally (U.S. Immigration and Customs Enforcement [ICE], 2018).
Withhold Release Orders
Until 2016, Section 307 was rarely used to block imports. Between 2000 and 2016, CBP did
not issue any WROs. Observers generally linked the difficulties in enforcing Section 307 to
the “consumptive demand” clause. As more goods were manufactured exclusively abroad, it
became easier for importers to make use of the exception. CBP also attributed difficulties to
limited resources and a lack of sufficient evidence, caused in part by the infeasibility of spot
inspections that would provide evidence of forced labour (CRS, 2021a).
Repeal of the consumptive demand exception enhanced CBP’s ability to prevent products
made with forced labour from being imported into the United States. As of January 2021, it
has issued seven active findings and 47 WROs (CBP, 2021). While from 2000 to 2015 the CBP
had not issued any WRO, since 2016 it has issued 13 WROs. All WROs are publicly available
and listed by country on the CBP’s Forced Labor Withhold Release Orders and Findings page
(CBP, n.d.).
Although CBP does not generally publicise specific detentions, re-exportations, exclusions,
or seizures of merchandise that may have resulted from WROs, following the passage of the
TFTEA, CBP published six WROs that it issued targeting the imports of various goods, the
majority of which were from China, specifically: soda ash, calcium chloride and caustic soda;
potassium, potassium hydroxide and potassium nitrate; stevia and its derivatives; peeled
garlic; toys; and cotton from and products produced with Turkmenistan cotton (CBP, n.d.).
84
On November 1, 2019, the CBP issued a WRO against tobacco from Malawi. As the agency
explained: “CBP issued the WRO based on information collected by the agency that
reasonably indicates the tobacco from Malawi is produced using forced labor and forced
child labor” (CBP, 2019b). Since the announcement, the WROs are partially applied
(“active”), i.e. two companies (Alliance One International and Limbe Leaf Tobacco Company
Limited) have since been “removed” from the order and may continue to import tobacco
(CBP, n.d.).
In 2018, toys from one manufacturer in China and all cotton produced in Turkmenistan were
stopped at the U.S. border through U.S. CBP WROs. The banning of “all Turkmenistan cotton
or products produced in whole or in part with Turkmenistan cotton” (CBP, n.d.) is significant
as it is the first time that the U.S. government has banned all forms of a particular
commodity from an entire country, as opposed to banning products from specific
manufacturers.
The majority of WROs have been against China: Of the 61 issued since 1990, 43 (70%) were
against Chinese goods. Many orders were issued between 1991 and 1993, declining after
the U.S. and China negotiated agreements relating to goods made with prison labour,
notably a 1992 Memorandum of Understanding (MOU) and 1994 Statement of Cooperation.
These agreements provided for the exchange of information and requests for inspections.
However, China’s compliance has been inconsistent, and U.S. concerns over prison and
forced labour broadly, remain. Since 2016, China has again become a focus of Section 307
actions. Several WROs centre on concerns over systemic forced labour of ethnic Uyghurs
and other Turkic Muslims in Xinjiang. CBP has issued 16 WROs and one Finding against
goods from China since 2016, with the most recent WRO of January 2021, requiring the
detention of all cotton and tomato products originating from Xinjiang as well as any goods
that use cotton or tomato products from Xinjiang as an input (CBP, n.d.).
To date, CBP has predominantly issued WROs that target specific goods from specific
producers, and the agency has not generally targeted entire product lines or industries in
problematic countries or regions (CBP, 2021). As such, the WRO against goods from Xinjiang
is an exception.
In February 2021, the U.S. House of Representatives reintroduced the Uyghur Forced Labor
Prevention Act (2020), a bipartisan bill which passed in the House in 2020 that would ban
imports from China’s Xinjiang region unless it is certified they are not produced with forced
labour. The bill would also require financial disclosures by listed U.S. companies about
engagement with Chinese firms and entities engaged in abuses. At the heart of the bill is a
“rebuttable presumption” that assumes goods from Xinjiang are made with forced labour
and banned from the United States unless there is “clear and convincing” evidence to the
contrary (CRS, 2021a). While the legislation has had strong bipartisan support, congressional
aides say it has been the target of lobbying by firms with supply-chain links to Xinjiang. For
example, Apple, Coca-Cola and Nike were among companies lobbying the U.S. Congress to
alter the legislation arguing that it would disrupt supply chains and that investigating forced
labour ties in the region is difficult, given the opacity of Chinese supply chains and the
limited access of auditors to a region where the Chinese government restricts people’s
movements (Swanson, 2020).
85
Also, in February 2021, the United States offered qualified support for a new Australian bill
to ban imports from the Xinjiang region (Hurst, 2021a; U.S. Department of State, 2021). The
bill would prohibit the importation into Australia of goods from Xinjiang province “as well as
goods from other parts of China that are produced by using forced labour” (Hurst, 2021b).
Commentators expect the bill to pass given the Senate’s current composition (Maberry &
Torrico, 2021).
Effects of DHS mechanism
In 2020, the CBP increased its use of Section 307 and issued 12 WROs, and in the previous
twelve months, the CBP had issued only one WRO (CBP, n.d.).
UK online fashion company Boohoo is currently facing the possibility of a United States
import ban because of widespread allegations over the use of forced labour. Repercussions
of a 2020 exposé of Boohoo’s gross breach of Covid-19 regulations, exploitation of factory
workers and furlough fraud in garment factories in Leicester. The CBP “has seen enough
evidence to launch an investigation after petitions from a campaigning British lawyer”
(Brunt, 2021).
An emblematic WRO under the Tariff Act is the one for rubber gloves produced by two
subsidiaries of Top Glove in Malaysia, the world’s largest rubber glove company, issued in
July 2020 (Lee, 2020a). CBP issued the WRO based on reasonable belief that two of Top
Glove’s subsidiaries, Top Glove Sdn Bhd and TG Medical Sdn Bhd were using forced labour,
in this case debt bondage, to produce rubber gloves. In issuing this WRO, the CBP blocked all
imports of these rubber gloves into the United States, closing the companies’ access to the
American market. The import ban remained active even as the COVID-19 pandemic
significantly increased demand for rubber gloves (Vanpeperstraete, 2021).
The speed with which Top Glove and its subsidiaries attempted to remediate the harm the
workers suffered was surprising. In early August 2020, just two weeks after the WRO had
been issued, Top Glove agreed to refund foreign workers who had paid recruitment fees to
agents – as much as $34 million to be paid to 10,000 workers – and to improve workers’
accommodations (Choy, 2020; Lee, 2020b). It is possible that the quick action was related to
the large number of sales Top Gloves was going to lose – shipments from the two
subsidiaries constituted 12.5% of the group sales and half of its sales to the United States
(Brudney, 2020; Lee, 2020a).
In any case, the extent and speed of Top Glove’s response to the WRO demonstrates how
Section 307 “can be leveraged to protect workers, as a rights-promoting tool” – even if the
law was designed to protect American businesses, not workers abroad (Brudney, 2020). By
blocking access to the U.S. market, Section 307 can put pressure on companies to undertake
human rights due diligence across their value chains. Greater supply chain due diligence and
accountability by companies may be an important positive consequence of Section 307. It
may also have a preventive effect as other companies may take steps before a similar WRO
is issued against them. The remediation that CBP required from Top Glove may signal other
companies – especially other companies in the region – to change their practices in relation
to recruitment fees (ibid). For targeted companies, regaining access to the lucrative U.S.
market provides a significant incentive to remedy the situation on the ground. The action of
the CBP has been effective because the Tariff Act allows them to impose real and
86
substantial costs on abusive companies. These financial losses stimulate rapid company
remedy. In addition, “each impounding of goods also has a major benign multiplier effect:
business competitors fear similar action and act rapidly to remedy their own abuse”
(Bloomer, 2020).
There is no clear evidence, however, about the lasting consequences of these measures. In
March 2021, U.S. customs found forced labour practices in one of Top Glove’s subsidiaries
and directed its port to seize goods from the manufacturer (Reuters, 2021).
Companies importing goods to the United States should consider the risk of forced labour in
their supply chains, in particular companies involved in high-risk industries and/or countries.
Development and implementation of due diligence policies and procedures is essential for
ensuring supply-chain integrity and mitigating enforcement risk (Connellan et al., 2019).
Weaknesses of DHS mechanism
While congressional action to close the Section 307 consumptive demand provision should
be welcomed, there are a number of weaknesses and possible unintended consequences in
the use of this mechanism.
First, the WRO was originally developed as a protectionist tool meant to protect American
companies, not workers (Brudney, 2020). As such, it is a mechanism that simply stops the
goods at the border may not have real effects on addressing forced labour. Initially, the
mechanism was developed to protect American companies against unfair trade practices by
competing foreign companies. Once a WRO is issued, authorities mandate no further import
from entities involved in forced labour practices. For the most part, there are no
requirements to remediate forced labour abuses and improve working conditions. If issued
without accompanying remedial requirements, a WRO could even have adverse
consequences for workers. For example, “instead of dealing with the underlying forced
labour issues, companies may shut down and lay off their workers” (Brudney, 2020). This is
even more problematic in the case of child labour.
Second, the Tariff Act and recent WROs “are sometimes seen as an extension of other
(foreign) policy objectives” (Vanpeperstraete, 2021). For example, the majority of recent
WROs have been against Chinese companies: of the 13 WROs issued in 2020, nine were
against Chinese companies, all of them in Xinjiang linked to rights violations against the
Uyghur minority (Vanpeperstraete, 2021). The WRO, linked to state sponsored prison labour
in Xingjian Uyghur Autonomous Region, had initially targeted five economic entities, but
then was later expanded to the entire region for specific products, i.e. tomato and cotton
(CBP, n.d.).
Third, and related to the previous point, the scope of WRO may have negative
consequences for local economies, further exacerbating situations of poverty and resulting
in an increased risk of forced labour for local workers. A WRO’s scope may cover entire
countries, not just single companies – which can lead to adverse economic consequences for
local communities.
Fourth, the CBP enjoys wide discretionary powers in enforcement of the Act. In the words of
Luciano Racco: “CBP is acting as the investigator, judge and jury in these matters” (Shenoy,
87
2021). Whether to issue a WRO and its scope remains solely at the discretion of the CBP.
The CBP also decides when to require companies to remediate working conditions, and
what efforts constitute adequate remediation in order to lift a WRO. Also, there is a lack of
clear evidentiary standards required in petitions and transparency by CBP on explanations of
enforcement actions. The issuance of WROs might not be sufficiently evidence-based,
consistent and independent (Vanpeperstraete, 2021). The definition of sufficient remedial
steps remains discretionary, with limited space for input from rights holders or civil society.
The investigation remains largely non-public (Bell, 2016; Kuplewatzky, 2016). The initiative
of the U.S. Congress for an annual report by the Commissioner of the CBP is a critical first
step toward greater transparency and accountability (GoodWeave, 2017).
Fifth, there are still a relatively small number of actions. Although the CBP has increased its
enforcement actions, only twelve WROs have been issued in 2020. In order to make a real
impact on corporate behaviour, a higher and more regular number of WROs would need to
be issued (Vanpeperstraete, 2021). One of the reasons for the small number of actions may
be the customary practice of targeting individual producers and the difficulty of tracing
products back to the factory or farm using forced labour, given complex global supply
chains. Enhancing Section 307 enforcement would likely hinge on greater resources. CBP has
cited staff shortages as causing the agency to drop investigations and limiting its ability to
monitor existing cases (CRS, 2021a).
Finally, there may be unintended consequences for business. Industry groups caution that
broader WROs may disrupt supply chains, deter legitimate business with other suppliers,
and worsen the economic security of vulnerable workers. There may also be financial
repercussions. In March 2021, it was reported that Nike and H&M are facing backlash in
China over Xinjiang statements condemning forced labour – with Chinese social media
criticising the statements by the companies and Chinese celebrities cancelling contracts with
them (Standaert, 2021).
2. EO mechanisms
U.S. Executive Order 13126 of 1999
Executive Order (EO) 13126 of 1999 Prohibition of Acquisition of Products Produced by
Forced or Indentured Child Labor” seeks to ensure that U.S. federal agencies do not procure
goods made by forced or indentured child labour notably through the following means:
1. Policy (Section 1). Executive agencies “take appropriate actions to enforce the laws
prohibiting the manufacture or importation of goods, wares, articles, and
merchandise mined, produced, or manufactured wholly or in part by forced or
indentured child labor” (Executive Order No. 13126, 1999).
2. Publication of List (Section 2). The Department of Labor (DOL) publishes a list called
“Prohibition of Acquisition of Products Produced by Forced or Indentured Labor” – a
list of products, identified by their country of origin, that has “a reasonable basis to
believe might have been mined, produced, or manufactured by forced or indentured
child labor” (Executive Order No. 13126, 1999).
88
3. Procurement (Section 3). Each solicitation of offers for a contract for the
procurement of a product included on the list published by the DOL should include i)
a provision that requires the contractor to certify that it “has made a good faith
effort to determine whether forced or indentured child labor was used to mine,
produce, or manufacture any product furnished under the contract and that, on the
basis of those efforts, the contractor is unaware of any such use of child labor” and
(2) a provision that obligates the contractor to cooperate fully in providing
reasonable access to its records, documents, persons, or premises for the purpose of
determining whether forced or indentured child labor was used to mine, produce, or
manufacture any product furnished under the contract” (Executive Order No. 13126,
1999).
Termination of the contract, suspension of the contractor; or debarment of the contractor
for a period not to exceed three years are the remedies available for violations (48 CFR
§22.1504(b).). Since the EO’s issuing, USDOL accepts for review allegations of forced child
labour in the production of goods. The minimum standard of evidence involves recent,
credible, and appropriately corroborated information (Bayer, 2016).
U.S. Global Magnitsky Human Rights Accountability Act and U.S. Executive Order 13818 of
2017
In 2012, the United States adopted the Magnitsky Act which provided for governmental
sanctions on foreign individuals associated with human rights violations and corruption
(Russia and Moldova Jackson-Vanik Repeal and Sergei Magnitsky Rule of Law Accountability
Act, 2012). Intended to punish Russian officials responsible for the death of Russian tax
lawyer Sergei Magnitsky in a Moscow prison in 2009, the Act froze any U.S. assets they held
and banned them from entering the United States.
Building on the original Russia-focused Magnitsky law, in 2016 U.S. Congress enacted the
Global Magnitsky Human Rights Accountability Act – abbreviated GloMag – which allows
the executive branch to impose visa bans and targeted sanctions on individuals anywhere in
the world responsible for committing human rights violations or acts of significant
corruption. GloMag authorises the president to block or revoke the visas of certain “foreign
persons” (both individuals and entities) or to impose property sanctions on them. People
can be sanctioned (a) if they are responsible for or acted as an agent for someone
responsible for “extrajudicial killings, torture, or other gross violations of internationally
recognized human rights,” or (b) if they are government officials or senior associates of
government officials complicit in “acts of significant corruption” (Global Magnitsky Human
Rights Accountability Act, 2016). Sanctions deny individuals entry into the U.S., allow the
seizure of any of their property held in the country, and effectively prevent them from
entering into transactions with large numbers of banks and companies. Both American
companies and multinational companies with American subsidiaries run the risk of violating
U.S. sanctions if they do business with sanctioned people (Human Rights Watch, 2017b).
Building upon GloMag, Executive Order (EO) No. 13818 (2017) “Blocking the Property of
Persons Involved in Serious Human Rights Abuse or Corruption” was signed in 2017, finding
89
that the “prevalence of human rights abuse and corruption that have their source, in whole
or in substantial part, outside the United States, had reached such scope and gravity that it
threatens the stability of international political and economic systems.”
Actions pursuant EO 13818 can target “persons” – both individuals and entities. For
example, in July 2020, the U.S. Department of the Treasury’s Office of Foreign Assets
Control (OFAC) sanctioned one Chinese government entity and two current or former
government officials in connection with rights abuses against ethnic minorities in Xinjiang
(U.S. Department of the Treasury, 2020). As a result of such action, all property and
interests in property of those officials and entities that are in the United States or in the
possession or control of U.S. persons are blocked and must be reported to OFAC.
3. List of Goods, coordination of enforcement
U.S. Trafficking Victims Protection Act of 2000 and successive reauthorisation acts
During the process of developing the Palermo Protocol, and ultimately to provide for both
implementation of the Protocol and to fill gaps in U.S. law, Congress passed the bipartisan
Trafficking Victims Protection Act (TVPA) in 2000. The TVPA (2000) was created to “ensure
just and effective punishment of traffickers, and to protect their victims.” In particular, there
were three main components of the TVPA, commonly called the three P’s: Protection,
Prosecution, and Prevention.
In response to the growing human trafficking problem, the United States promulgated a
comprehensive domestic law to combat trafficking in persons. President Clinton signed the
TVPA into law on October 28, 2000. Both the Trafficking Victims Protection Reauthorization
Act of 2003, and the Trafficking Victims Protection Reauthorization Act of 2005
supplemented the TVPA. The Trafficking Victims Protection Act of 2008 (TVPA, 2008)
amended the TVPA. The TVPA’s purpose is “to combat trafficking in persons, a
contemporary manifestation of slavery whose victims are predominately women and
children, to ensure just and effective punishment of traffickers, and to protect their victims”
(TVPA § 102, 114 Stat. 1464 at 1466). Using the “three P’s” structure of protection of
trafficking victims, prosecution of those persons trafficking in human beings, and prevention
of human trafficking, the TVPA provides innovative measures for eliminating human
trafficking (Hendrix, 2010). It sets “minimum standards for the elimination of trafficking”
applicable to governments of countries that are places of “origin, transit, or destination for a
significant number of victims of severe trafficking” (TVPA § 108(a), 114 Stat. 1464 at 1480).
The TVPA of 2000 established methods of prosecuting traffickers, preventing human
trafficking, and protecting victims and survivors of trafficking. The Act further establishes
human trafficking and related offenses as federal crimes. It established the Office to
Monitor and Combat Trafficking in Persons, which is required to publish a Trafficking in
Persons (TIP) report each year. The TIP report describes and ranks the efforts of countries to
combat human trafficking. The act also established the Interagency Task Force to Monitor
and Combat Trafficking, which assists in the implementation of the TVPA.
90
The TVPA of 2000 inter alia required the U.S. Secretary of State to submit to Congress a
report on the status of human trafficking worldwide, including the United States. A notable
feature of the Trafficking in Persons (TIP) reports is that they, pursuant to TVPA, classify
countries according to three tiers, associating the third tier with countries that do not fully
comply with the law’s minimum standards and which are not making significant efforts to
bring themselves into compliance. Countries on Tier 3 may be subject to certain sanctions,
whereby the U.S. government may withhold or withdraw non-humanitarian, non-traderelated foreign assistance, even assistance channelled through the International Monetary
Fund (IMF) and the World Bank. Since 2000, the U.S. Department of State (DOS) has
published 15 TIP reports.
The Trafficking Victims Protection Reauthorization Act of 2003 (TVPRA, 2003) established
human trafficking as a chargeable crime under the Racketeering Influenced Corrupt
Organizations (RICO) statute. The Trafficking Victims Protection Reauthorization Act of
2005 (TVPRA, 2005) established a pilot programme for sheltering human trafficking victims
who are minors and provided grants to assist state and local law enforcement in combating
trafficking. The TVPRA of 2005 charged the U.S. Department of Labor (DOL) with issuing a
list of products that DOL believes are being made or harvested by child or forced labour (see
USDOL List of Goods Produced by Child Labor or Forced Labor). The law furthermore charges
the agency of working with producers of the goods on the list to set standards to eliminate
such practices, and to work with other U.S. government agencies to “ensure that products
made by forced labor and child labor in violation of international standards are not
imported into the United States” (TVPRA § 105(b), p. 119 Stat. 3567).
The William Wilberforce Trafficking Victims Protection Reauthorization Act of 2008 (TVPRA,
2008) expanded anti-trafficking prevention strategies and expanded protections available
with the T Visa. The TVPRA of 2008 built on the previous trafficking acts, notably including a
provision that establishes a two-year time limit for countries on Tier 2 special watch list
before they are re-classified (TVPRA, 2008). It also regulated that all unaccompanied alien
children be screened as potential victims of human trafficking. This bipartisan
reauthorisation extended and modified certain programmes that form the core of the
Department of Justice’s efforts to prevent and prosecute human trafficking and protect the
victims of trafficking, forced labour, and modern slavery, as well as the Department of
Labor’s efforts to better document and deter the trafficking problem.
The Trafficking Victims Protection Reauthorization Act of 2013 (TVPRA, 2013) establishes
and strengthens programmes to ensure that U.S. citizens do not purchase products made by
victims of human trafficking, and to prevent child marriage. The reauthorisation also
strengthened the collaboration with state and local law enforcement to ease charging and
prosecuting traffickers.
The TVPA continues to impose reporting mandates on U.S. federal agencies, such as the U.S.
Department of State’s Trafficking in Persons Report, and USDOL’s List of Goods Produced by
Child Labor or Forced Labor. The TVPA requires the U.S. government to establish
partnerships with community organisations, universities, enterprises, and others to ensure
that “US citizens do not purchase products made by victims of human trafficking.” The
findings and conclusions of these reports are often considered by the government in making
economic and trade policy decisions.
91
The TVPA list’s findings may lead to the blocking of imports from countries that do not play
by the rules. This model could be transposed to the EU and serve as an inspiration for the
new legislative proposals, for example around forced labour import bans and corporate
human rights due diligence, amendments of existing legislation, and for the newly
appointed Chief Trade Enforcement Officer, who, among other things, is mandated to
ensuring that countries the EU has trade agreements with meet the commitments they
make under them on workers’ rights (European Commission, 2020e).
ILAB’s lists of goods and reports
A number of government-issued lists and reports on forced labour measures are used to
inform and enforce forced labour measures in the United States. These lists and reports
contain country profiles and lists of goods suspected to have been produced by child or
forced labour. The outputs are published by the Bureau of International Labor Affairs (ILAB),
a department within USDOL, and notably include:
● USDOL’s List of Goods, required by the TVPRA of 2005 (Pub. L. 109-164), which
charged the DOL to work with producers of the goods on the list to set standards to
eliminate such practices, and to work with other U.S. government agencies to
“ensure that products made by forced labor and child labor in violation of
international standards are not imported into the United States.” This is a biannual
report that flags goods that agencies charged with enforcement duties should pay
attention to when enforcing federal law. For example, in 2021, this list identified five
goods produced by forced labour in Xinjiang, including textiles, thread/yam, and
tomato products. As such, DOL issued a business advisory to caution businesses
about the risks of supply chain links to entities that engage in human rights abuses,
including forced labour, in Xinjiang and elsewhere in China (Hurst, 2021a; U.S.
Department of State, 2021). According to ILAB, it “maintains the List primarily to
raise public awareness about forced labor and child labor around the world and to
promote efforts to combat them; it is not intended to be punitive, but rather to
serve as a catalyst for more strategic and focused coordination and collaboration
among those working to address these problems. Publication of the List has resulted
in new opportunities for ILAB to engage with foreign governments to combat forced
labor and child labor” (U.S. Department of Labor, n.d.-a).
● USDOL’s List of Products, mandated by EO 13126 of 1999, features products that
have been mined, produced, or manufactured by forced or indentured child labour.
The list “Prohibition of Acquisition of Products Produced by Forced or Indentured
Labor” (U.S. Department of Labor, n.d.-c) published annually by ILAB is intended to
ensure that U.S. federal agencies do not procure goods made by forced or
indentured child labour. The Department of Labor, in consultation with the
departments of State and Homeland Security, publishes and maintains the List. ILAB
released its first list in 2001.
● USDOL’s Findings on the Worst Forms of Child Labor is prepared in accordance with
the Trade and Development Act of 2000.
92
ILAB administration
Established in 1913, ILAB comprises five offices, three of which are technically specialised:
● Office of Child Labor, Forced Labor, and Human Trafficking (OCFT);
● Office of Trade and Labor Affairs (OTLA);
● Office of International Relations and Economic Research (OIRER).
ILAB promotes a strong U.S. trade policy by negotiating robust labour provisions in new
trade and investment agreements, and enforcing the eligibility criteria of trade preference
programmes, enforcing labour provisions of U.S. free trade agreements and trade
preference programs to ensure that no country gains an unfair advantage, and building the
capacity of other countries to enforce and improve labour protections (Bureau of
International Labor Affairs, n.d.-b).
ILAB’s research output includes annual reports on child labour and forced labour, which also
provide “recommendations to combat child labor in over 130 trade beneficiary countries”
(US Department of Labor, 2018, p. 2). ILAB’s two mobile applications, Sweat & Toil and
Comply Chain, allow stakeholders to “identify child and forced labor, and provide
compliance assistance in rooting out these labor abuses in global supply chains” (US
Department of Labor, 2018, p. 2).
ILAB further fosters U.S. trade interests through an approach that “combines monitoring
and engagement with targeted technical assistance to strengthen the rule of law in
countries that have the political will but lack the resources to comply” (US Department of
Labor, 2018, p. 2). This multifaceted approach has reportedly improved labour law
enforcement in trade partners including Honduras, Colombia, Guatemala, Viet Nam, and
Bangladesh ILAB’s output is the building of capacity (ibid). Taken together, ILAB has trained
over 50,000 labour inspectors and law enforcement officials (ibid). Figure 24 shows the
organisational chart of ILAB.
ILAB’s budget has decreased significantly since 2019, when it had $86,125 million with
which to work. Prior to 2019, ILAB had a similarly high budget (U.S. Department of Labor,
2020b).30 But in 2020, ILAB’s budget dropped to $18,500 million, and in FY 2021, ILAB’s
budget request was $18,660 million. Currently, the branch has 94 Full Time Equivalent
employees (U.S. Department of Labor, 2021). Staff was reduced reflecting the workload
decrease associated with the elimination of new grants as well as a reduction in other ILAB
work activities (U.S. Department of Labor, 2020b). ILAB now focuses available resources on
efforts to make U.S. trade agreements fair for U.S. workers by monitoring and enforcing the
labour provisions of free trade agreements and trade preference programmes to ensure a
fair global playing field for U.S. workers and businesses (U.S. Department of Labor, 2020b).
30
ILAB’s budget was $91,125 million in 2015, and $86,125 million in 2016, 2017, 2018 and 2019.
93
Figure 24: ILAB’s Organisational Chart
Source: Organization Chart, (Bureau of International Labor Affairs, n.d.-a), URL
4. U.S. Trade Policy
U.S. FTAs
The limitations of EU FTAs described – notably relating to the mere existence of flexible
mechanisms, the other to their activation – call for a comparison with the U.S. FTAs, whose
approach to compliance with human rights standards is substantially different. Most of the
U.S. agreements have indeed required the compliance with the internationally recognised
worker rights (Ebert, 2013, p. 31). By contrast to EU agreements, their enforcement relies
on dispute settlement procedures such as formal consultations or the establishment of
panels endowed with the ability to impose sanctions when the treaty requirements are not
met (Lowe, 2019, p. 2). These sanctions function as “sticks” for partner countries, as the
threat of their enforcement encourages these countries to respect their commitments
under the trade agreements.
94
Furthermore, the U.S. system also allows the aggrieved party to withdraw its trade
concessions if it demonstrates that the other party's non-compliance with its commitments
has had a substantial impact on trade flows. Both are made effective by the importance
attached to complaint mechanisms, which ensure substantial third-party participation and
give the U.S. Department of Labor the role of reviewing submissions (Barbu et al., 2017, p. 5;
European Commission Services, 2017, p. 7; Lowe, 2019, p. 2).
Recent U.S. FTAs commit countries to maintain laws on core ILO labour standards (ILO,
2009). For example, in its 2000 free trade agreement with Jordan, the trade partners agreed
to protect core ILO workers’ rights. Disputes over labour standards, e.g. if one country
weakened its labour laws or failed to bring its laws or enforcement into compliance with the
ILO core standards, could end with the other party unilaterally withdrawing trade benefits.
For the first time in a U.S. FTA, the United States-Mexico-Canada Agreement (USMCA) also
commits the parties to prohibit imports produced by forced labour and to cooperate in
identifying such goods. USMCA-implementing legislation created a Forced Labor
Enforcement Task Force, chaired by the Secretary of Homeland Security, to monitor and
report on broader enforcement of Section 307 (USMCA Implementation Act, 2020).
Incidentally, the Canadian system allows for the imposition of fines proportionate to the
adverse impacts on trade.
In addition, eligibility criteria for U.S. trade preference programs includes taking steps to
maintain internationally recognised worker rights. Some eligibility reviews and revocation of
developing country benefits by the U.S. Trade Representative have involved concerns over
labour practices. Trade agreements have expanded coverage of trade and labour issues in
part because the World Trade Organization (WTO) does not cover such rules (though it
provides exceptions to a country’s obligations for measures related to imports of products
of prison labour) (CRS, 2021a).
The aegis of monitoring and enforcing foreign government compliance with trade
agreements is principally held by the United States Trade Representative (USTR), which
“pursues enforcement using bilateral engagement, dispute settlement procedures, and the
full range of U.S. trade laws when appropriate.” USTR is supported by “relevant agencies,
including the U.S. Departments of Agriculture, Commerce, Justice, Labor, and State,” which
“help ensure that these agreements yield the maximum benefits by ensuring negotiated
market access, promoting adherence to international commitments, and advancing a free,
fair, and market-oriented trading environment” (USTR, n.d.-a).
Relevant legislation
The U.S. Trade Act of 1974 notably defines “internationally recognized worker rights” as
constituting “acceptable conditions of work with respect to minimum wages, hours of work,
and occupational safety and health” (Trade Act, 1974). The law furthermore provides
instruments to protect U.S. traders and workers against unfair trade practices. “Section 201
provides for safeguard actions in order to facilitate positive adjustment of U.S. domestic
industry to import competition. Section 301 may be used to enforce U.S. rights under
95
bilateral and multilateral trade agreements, and to respond to unreasonable, unjustifiable,
or discriminatory foreign government practices that burden or restrict U.S.
commerce” (USTR, n.d.).
The U.S. Trade Act of 2002 (H.R.3009) directs U.S. trade negotiators to:
● “promote respect for worker rights and the rights of children consistent with core
labor standards of the ILO”;
● “seek provisions in trade agreements under which parties to those agreements strive
to ensure that they do not weaken or reduce the protections afforded in domestic
environmental and labor laws as an encouragement for trade”;
● “promote universal ratification and full compliance with ILO Convention No. 182
Concerning the Prohibition and Immediate Action for the Elimination of the Worst
Forms of Labor.”
The U.S. Bipartisan Trade Promotion Authority Act of 2002 (Pub. Law 107-210) provides,
inter alia, for the President to “submit several reports to Congress related to any free trade
agreements entered into under the act,” including a report entitled “Laws Governing
Exploitative Child Labor” (USTR, n.d.-b). Eleven such reports have been published.
The U.S. Trade Promotion Authority Act of 2015, in effect through July 1, 2021, notably
included “the same dispute settlement mechanisms and penalties for labor as for other FTA
chapters;” required “the maintenance in laws and practice of principles stated in the ILO
Declaration;” prohibited “the diminution of labor standards to attract trade and
investment;” and limited “prosecutorial and enforcement discretion, as grounds for
defending a failure to enforce labor laws” (CRS, 2020). In section (10) LABOR AND THE
ENVIRONMENT, the Act affirms that the “principal negotiating objectives of the United
States with respect to labor and the environment are,” inter alia, “(C) to strengthen the
capacity of United States trading partners to promote respect for core labor standards (as
defined in section 111(7)). These core labour standards also concern “(C) the elimination of
all forms of forced or compulsory labor; (D) the effective abolition of child labor and a
prohibition on the worst forms of child labor” (Defending Public Safety Employees Act,
2015).
As presented in a Congressional Research Service (CRS) publication, the treatment of labour
rights in U.S. trade policy and FTAs has been of long-standing congressional interest, and has
become stricter in recent years (see Figure 25).
96
Figure 25: Evolution of U.S. Labour Commitments
Source: Worker Rights Provisions in Free Trade Agreements (FTAs), (CRS, 2020), URL
C. EU support for trade partners
1. Support through Aid for Trade
Launched at the Hong Kong Ministerial Conference in December 2005, the WTO established
a Task Force in 2006 with the aim of operationalising Aid for Trade (World Trade
Organization [WTO], n.d.-b). A decade later, the initiative was recognised “for supporting
developing country Members to build supply-side capacity and trade-related infrastructure”
(WTO, 2015).
Trade partners may be supported through aid programmes to either meet the human rights
standards required to benefit from trade agreements and schemes such as GSP programmes
and FTAs, or to enforce these standards and improve the country's human rights policies.
Although these programmes are generally stand-alone, there may be value in associating
them with trade agreements so that trading partners can be better supported, both at the
agreement negotiation stage and afterwards.
Several comments to this effect were made in relation to the EU Aid for Trade (AfT)
programme, on the occasion of its 2019 periodic review. The EU AfT Strategy was adopted
in October 2007 in response to the WTO-led AfT Initiative, which “encourages developing
country governments and donors to recognise the role that trade can play in development.
In particular, the initiative seeks to mobilise resources to address the trade-related
constraints identified by developing and least-developed countries” (WTO, n.d.-b).
97
In the words of the European Commission, the EU AfT strategy similarly aims at helping
“developing countries better integrate into the international trading system and take
greater advantage of the poverty-reducing benefits of economic openness and enhanced
trade efficiency” (European Commission, 2019, p. 5). The Strategy takes into account the
2030 Agenda and the EU trade and development policies to promote economic growth
along social and environmental objectives. In accordance with the WTO task force
recommendation on Aid for Trade of 2006, projects and programmes fall under the AfT
Strategy only if they are considered as trade-related development priorities for the
beneficiary country's national development strategies, i.e. trade policy and regulations,
trade-related infrastructure, productive capacity building, trade-related adjustment, or
other trade-related needs (European Commission, 2019, p. 5).
Albeit not tied to EU trade agreements and schemes, the EU AfT may help developing
countries to benefit from them and may also provide additional support. Some AfT
programmes have already shown some results in this regard. Whilst the EBA programme,
which benefitted to Afghanistan and enabled the country to be endowed with unilateral
trade preferences, proved insufficient to raise the effectiveness of its export sectors, the
Advanced-Afghan Trade (AAT) project enabled to support the improvement of the business
and investment related environment to boost competitiveness, and support regional
transit/connectivity (European Commission, 2019, p. 18). EU trade-related projects in Nepal
have also been instrumental in helping the country to better promote its exports, even
though Nepal already benefited from an EBA programme and had 90% of its exports
entering the EU market on preferential terms (European Commission, 2019, p. 20).
Such results may nonetheless be tempered by criticisms on EU AfT spending, which is
deemed to be too decentralised and fragmented. In its 2019 report, the EU Commission
indeed stressed the importance of better combining bilateral, regional and thematic tools
with aid modalities, both at EU and Member State level. In particular, the European
Commission proposed the following recommendations to help partner countries make the
most of the EU's trade agreements and schemes:
● Use the institutional monitoring mechanisms established by EU free trade
agreements, including EPAs, as an additional means to identify relevant aid for trade
activities;
● Include in EU free trade agreement implementation plans, including for EPAs,
targeted measures to help developing partner countries make better use of the
opportunities offered by EU trade agreements;
● Regularly assess the rate of preferences utilisation by partners of trade agreements
and beneficiary countries of the Generalised Scheme of Preferences; and analyse the
limiting factors, from both domestic supply-side and EU trade regime perspectives.
Direct EU Aid for Trade towards better addressing such constraints and, where
relevant, assess the need to take them into account in the evolution of trade
measures (European Commission, 2019, p. 20).
98
2. Support through dialogue and cooperation platforms
The role of dialogue and cooperation platforms pertaining to trade and sustainable
development has been growing over the past ten years, both in and out of the framework of
trade agreements and schemes. In the context of trade agreements, most dialogue and
cooperation platforms are established as civil society mechanisms, implemented in the
trade and sustainability chapters and also, in the case of some association agreements, for
the whole agreement (see in this regard the 2016 EU-Ukraine Association Agreement,
Article 470). It should be noted that this extension of the scope of civil society stakeholder
advice is likely to be generalised in future agreements, as the European Commission has
recognised the need for stakeholders to propose their recommendations on the
sustainability implications of other parts of agreements apart from TSD chapters (European
Commission Services, 2018, p. 6).
Although civil society mechanisms appear to be based on the same model in the TSD
chapters, they remain tailored to their trade agreements and therefore vary greatly from
one agreement to another, both in terms of their provisions and their implementation. In
the words of Orbie, Martens and Van Den Putte (2016, pp. 14–15), whose study well
explained these variations, civil society mechanisms can be broken down into at least five
categories (see Figure 26):
1. A Domestic Advisory Group (DAG) in which civil society organisations of one [trade]
Party meet;
2. A joint meeting of the domestic advisory groups (DAG-to-DAG meeting) of the
Parties:
3. In this constellation, the DAG-to-DAG meeting comes together with the
intergovernmental body;
4. An open civil society meeting where civil society organisations of the Parties meet
without the presence of the intergovernmental body;
5. Civil society from different countries meets with the intergovernmental body.
As domestic mechanisms, DAGs ideally comprise labour, environmental and business
representative organisations for each party (the EU and its trading partner(s)) and ensure a
balanced representation of economic, social and environmental stakeholders, including
employers and workers organisations, business groups and environmental organisations. As
transnational mechanisms, joint meetings of DAGs tend to meet once a year to discuss the
implementation of the TSD chapter and may also include, depending on the agreement,
other relevant stakeholders than those already represented by DAGs. These meetings thus
ensure that both parties are committed to cooperating together, although the modalities of
cooperation also tend to vary (Orbie, Martens, Oehri, et al., 2016, p. 528).
Despite the opportunities they offer in terms of dialogue and cooperation, civil society
mechanisms have been subject to many criticisms, which the European Commission is
reportedly working to address. Most of them concern their institutional shortcomings,
which make these dialogue and cooperation platforms of trade agreements less effective in
supporting the EU's trading partners. Indeed, the role of civil society is not as well
developed in the EU as in the U.S., as EU trade agreements do not establish a public
submission procedure for civil society bodies to file complaints (International Labour Office,
99
2017b, p. 47). Moreover, it is argued that their functioning is deficient, as their composition
and meetings need to be improved. The annual meetings are considered insufficient to
detect early problems and allow stakeholders to voice their demands. In this regard, Van
den Putte et al. (2015, p. 3) suggest multiplying the number of meetings, for example by
supplementing the annual meetings with four-monthly videoconferences. Further, the lack
of continuity and organisation between civil society groups was also denounced, particularly
due to the absence of a coordination mechanism (Orbie, Martens, Oehri, et al., 2016, p.
528). Whilst EU DAGs and DAG-to-DAG meetings are chaired by the European Economic and
Social Committee (hereinafter EESC), there is indeed no such body for EU trade partners
(Orbie, Martens, & Van Den Putte, 2016, p. 20). Finally, lack of funding is seen as an obstacle
to effective dialogue between trading partners. This issue has been partially handled by the
European Commission, which has raised a EUR 3 million project aiming at “encourag[ing]
the exchange of best practices between DAGs in different FTA partner countries’ and
‘improv[ing] interaction between TSD committees (i.e. governmental bodies) and civil
society bodies” (European Commission Services, 2018, p. 5). In 2021, the European
Commission also announced the implementation of the Single Entry Point, a new complaints
system enabling all EU stakeholders, including civil society, to play a direct role in the
implementation of TSD Chapters (European Commission, 2021b, p. 1).
Figure 26: Five Categories of Civil Society Mechanisms for TSD Chapters
Source: Civil society meetings in European Union trade agreements: features, purposes, and evaluation, (Orbie, Martens, &
Van Den Putte, 2016), URL
Beyond the sole framework of trade agreements, other initiatives have been developed so
as to promote dialogue and cooperation between the relevant stakeholders. These
initiatives, which tend to be more local and aim at ensuring an adequate representation of
workers, represent an interesting alternative to the civil society mechanisms of trade
agreements. Accordingly, there may be some value in connecting them to DAGs and joint
100
meetings or in implementing them as good practices in the functioning of civil society
mechanisms, so that their outcome better supports EU trade partners.
Some of these initiatives pertain to programmes valuing the dialogue of corporations and
governments with workers and trade unions. The importance attached to the opinion of
workers is essential to ensure that their rights would be adequately protected, both in the
framework of trade agreements and in company policies ensuring respect for human and
labour rights. These policies are often designed without taking into account the views of
workers, precisely when they are well positioned to identify the risks of violations and
propose mitigation measures and grievance mechanisms (ILO et al., 2019, p. 64). As for EU
trade agreements, it is argued that civil society bodies, which comprise trade unions and
workers, are not given a meaningful role in the implementation of the agreements (Barbu et
al., 2017, p. 1). This leaves very little space for workers to express their claims, all the more
so as the fear of reprisals often stands in the way of their requests (Weil, 2018, p. 444).
Programmes integrating the opinion of workers are therefore particularly valuable.
In this regard, it is worth mentioning the Worker-driven Social Responsibility (WSR)
approach, which deals with labour abuses affecting farmworkers. WSR programmes
establish a code of conduct in a variety of locations and sectors, which can be described as
being “based on binding and enforceable agreements between companies and workers'
organisations mandating companies to cover the costs of higher labour standards and
include workers in their design and implementation” (ILO et al., 2019, p. 65). These
agreements rely on six principles (Worker-Driven Social Responsibility Network, n.d.):
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
Labour rights initiatives must be worker driven;
Obligations for global corporations must be binding and enforceable;
Buyers must afford suppliers the financial incentive and capacity to comply;
Consequences for non-compliant suppliers must be mandatory;
Gains for workers must be measurable and timely;
Verification of workplace compliance must be rigorous and independent.
Given the success of some of these programmes, such as the Fair Food programme involving
corporate buyers of tomatoes, WSR is considered more efficient than the CSR approach with
regard to its impact on forced labour and improvement of working conditions (ILO et al.,
2019, p. 65).
Other initiatives have also sought to engage workers’ organisations in collaboration with
labour inspectorates in the enforcement of labour standards. These collaborations have
been considered as being quite fruitful in countries such as Australia, China and Sweden.
They are all the more relevant as the role of labour inspectorates has also been praised as
contributing together with child protection monitoring systems to combating child labour in
countries such as Brazil, Cambodia and Uganda (ILO et al., 2019, p. 34).
Another notable platform launched by an intergovernmental organisation is ILO-UN Global
Compact Child Labour Platform (CLP). The CLP “aims to identify the obstacles to the
implementation of the ILO Conventions in supply chains and surrounding communities,
identify practical ways of overcoming these obstacles, and catalyse collective action” (ILO,
n.d.-a). Described as cross-sectoral, the CLP promotes dialogue between business,
101
government, workers’ and employers’ organisations with regard to child labour, particularly
in supply chains. Its core activities notably provide a forum of exchange of experience and
know-how, training, create linkages with national- and local-level institutions and
programmes, contribute to research on child labour and enable to reach out to additional
companies (ILO, n.d.-e).
3. Support through the Neighbourhood, Development and International Cooperation
Instrument
Presentation of the NDICI
The Neighbourhood, Development and International Cooperation Instrument (hereinafter
NDICI) was established in the framework of the EU multiannual financial framework
(hereinafter MFF) for the 2021-2027 period, following a proposal of the European
Commission on 14 June 2018 (European Commission, 2018b). The text of the regulation was
approved in a joint vote of the European Parliament’s Development Committee (hereinafter
DEVE) and Committee on Foreign Affairs (hereinafter AFET) on 18 March 2021, and will have
to be formally adopted by the European Council at first reading (European Parliament,
2021c). The European Parliament will then be expected to vote at second reading on the
regulation during its plenary session next June or July, for the regulation’s last stage of
adoption (Immenkamp, 2021, p. 12).
The NDICI groups together all current EU instruments for development cooperation. Those
include the Common Implementing Regulation (hereinafter CIR); the Development
Cooperation Instrument (hereinafter DCI); the European Neighbourhood Instrument
(hereinafter ENI); the European Instrument for Democracy and Human Rights worldwide
(hereinafter EIDHR); the Instrument contributing to Stability and Peace (hereinafter IcSP);
the Partnership instrument (hereinafter PI); the European Fund for Sustainable
Development (hereinafter EFSD); the External Lending Mandate (hereinafter ELM); the
Guarantee Fund for External Action (hereinafter GFEA); macro-financial assistance and the
European Development Fund (hereinafter EDF). Its budget, which expired on 31 December
2020, was EUR 79.5 billion in current prices (EUR 70.8 billion in 2018 prices).
This clustering of instruments stems from the desire to simplify the structure of the EU's
external action architecture, whilst rationalising management and oversight systems
(Immenkamp, 2021, p. 5).
Pursuant to Article 4 of the EU Provisional agreement resulting from interinstitutional
negotiations (European Parliament, 2021a, p. 34), the structure of the instrument is based
on three pillars:
•
a geographical pillar (Article 4.2), covering programmes for (i) the European
Neighbourhood; (ii) sub-Saharan Africa; (iii) Asia and the Pacific; and (iv) the Americas
and the Caribbean. These programmes include areas of cooperation such as good
governance, democracy, rule of law and human rights; poverty eradication, fight against
inequalities and human development; inclusive and sustainable growth and decent
employment;
102
•
•
a thematic pillar (Article 4.3), covering thematic programmes on (i) human rights and
democracy; (ii) civil society organisation; (iii) Peace, Stability and Conflict Prevention;
and (iv) global challenges. Areas such as women and children, and decent work and
social protection, will also be covered;
a rapid response pillar (Article 4.4), designed for quick responses and aiming at (i)
contributing to peace, stability and conflict prevention in situations of urgency,
emerging crisis, crisis and post-crisis, including those which may result from migratory
flows and forced displacement; (ii) contributing to strengthening the resilience of
states, societies, communities and individuals and to linking humanitarian aid and
development action and, where relevant, peacebuilding; (iii) addressing Union foreign
policy needs and priorities.
Following Article 17 of the provisional agreement (European Parliament, 2021a, p. 37), a
cushion is also designed to address emerging challenges and priorities, and will (i) ensure an
appropriate response of the Union in the event of unforeseen circumstances; (ii) address
new needs or emerging challenges, such as those at the Union’s or its neighbours’ borders
linked to crisis, either natural or man-made, violent conflict and post-crisis situations or
migratory pressure and forced displacement; and (iii) promote new Union led or
international initiatives or priorities.
The role of the NDICI in the reduction of child labour
The NDICI will be the only instrument to implement the EU’s development cooperation
policy, which aims at realising the 2030 Agenda for Sustainable Development (hereinafter
2030 Agenda) and its Sustainable Development Goals (hereinafter SDGs), with which the
realisation of the children’s rights is closely linked. SDG 8.7 indeed urges to “take immediate
and effective measures to eradicate forced labour, end modern slavery and human
trafficking and secure the prohibition and elimination of the worst forms of child labour,”
whilst SDG 16.2 demands to “end abuse, exploitation, trafficking and all forms of violence
against and torture of children” (UN, 2015, pp. 20-25).
The NDICI thus raises some expectations on the commitment of the European Union to
address child labour. Some recommendations have already been made by various
stakeholders to improve the protection of children’s rights, both in the context of specific
projects and as part of a more global strategy on children. Following the EU's commitment
to develop a comprehensive Child Rights strategy, UNICEF recommended, together with
other organisations, that the EU institutions “develop and implement a Child Marker to
monitor and track impact on children of Neighbourhood, Development, and International
Cooperation Instrument (NDICI), ensuring that 25% of annual spending is focused on childspecific outcomes” (UNICEF et al., 2020, p. 18). Similarly, they stressed the need for the EU
to “prioritise specific resources that address the needs of children in most vulnerable
situations” (UNICEF et al., 2020, p. 19) and to “assist partner countries in building and
strengthening child protection systems through EU technical assistance” in line with the EU
Action Plan on Human Rights and Democracy 2020-2024 (UNICEF et al., 2020, p. 24).
Likewise, a report on the EU support for care reform for children in Uganda in the 20212027 period, also suggested practical steps for the EU institutions to ensure that the NDICI
103
will support a comprehensive reform of the childcare system in Uganda (Hope and Homes
for Children et al., 2020).
The text of the EU Provisional agreement (European Parliament, 2021a, p. 34) shows that
the European Union has every intention of respecting, through the NDICI, its commitments
to human rights, and in particular the rights of the child. Indeed, in the areas of cooperation
of both the thematic and geographic programmes, the agreement makes explicit references
to the core ILO labour standards and the ILO’s Global Agenda on Decent Work,31 as well as
social dialogue,32 the rights of the child and the fight against child labour,33 corporate social
responsibility and due diligence.34 A whole section in Annex III on the areas of intervention
for thematic programmes is also dedicated to children and youth, and notably emphasises
the necessity to focus on “health, nutrition, education, social protection and early childhood
development, including through dedicated youth friendly services” as well as on new
initiatives to ensure that “children get the best start in life and are protected in all areas
from violence, abuses and neglect, including by promoting the transition from institutional
to community-based care for children” (European Parliament, 2021a, p. 100).35
Furthermore, the NDICI should be understood as building on the instruments it brings
together, through which many projects and programmes have already been implemented in
relation to labour rights. Many of these projects have been aimed at fostering business and
human rights, as well as responsible business conducts. As an example, the Bangladesh
Sustainability Compact and the Myanmar Labour Rights Initiative sought to improve labour
rights and safety conditions for workers in the garment industries of Bangladesh and
Myanmar (OHCHR, 2020, p. 16). Other projects have been designed to improve labour
conditions in developing countries in specific value chains, both under the DCI and the EDF.
With regard to the garment and textile sectors, the European Union thus supported the ILO
and Food and Agriculture Organisation’s four-year “Clear Cotton Project”, which aimed to
eliminate child labour and forced labour in the cotton, textile and garment value chains in
Burkina Faso, Mali and Pakistan (ILO, 2018, p. 2). The project focused on strengthening
policy, legal and regulatory frameworks to combat child labour and forced labour in the
cotton, textile and garment sector (ILO, 2018). It also sought to assist local governments,
public services providers, and other relevant stakeholders to take effective action to stop
child labour, through very concrete actions, including due diligence, remedial mechanisms,
and the development of community-based multi-stakeholder monitoring. Several other
31
See notably Article 31 (European Parliament, 2021b) on the Scope and financing of the EFSD+, the budgetary
guarantees and financial assistance to third countries of the provisional agreement; see also Annex III on the
areas of intervention for thematic programmes, Part A, para. 6.b, and Annex V on the priority areas of the EFSD+
operations covered by the external action guarantee of the provisional agreement.
32
See notably Annex II on the areas of cooperation for the geographic programmes, para. 5.a and Annex III on
the areas of intervention for thematic programmes, Part A para. 6.b of the provisional agreement (European
Parliament, 2021b).
33
See notably Annex II on the areas of cooperation for the geographic programmes, para. 5.a and Annex III on
the areas of intervention for thematic programmes, Part A paras. 4 and 6.b of the provisional agreement
(European Parliament, 2021b).
34
See notably Article 38 on the implementation of External Action Guarantee agreements; Annex II on the areas
of cooperation for the geographic programmes, para. 4.g. and 5.e; the Annex III on the areas of intervention for
thematic programmes, Part A para. 6.b and Part C para. 1.h. of the provisional agreement (European Parliament,
2021b).
35 Annex III, Part A para. 4.a. and b.
104
projects have also been carried out under the “Increasing Knowledge, Awareness,
Transparency and Traceability for Responsible Value Chains in the Cotton and Garment
Sectors” programme, with the aim of reducing labour rights abuses by improving awareness
and transparency on production and consumption (OHCHR, 2020, p. 17). As it combines the
EU's various development and cooperation instruments, the NDICI should therefore be able
to fund such projects and support the EU's trading partners with concrete measures.
Finally, it should be noted that the European Union is willing to act upon its commitments,
as illustrated by a resolution of the EU Parliament on 11 February 2020 on child labour in
mines in Madagascar (European Parliament, 2020a). In this resolution, the European
Parliament notably recommended the future application of the NDICI “in the context of
child labour eradication, including in the area of social inclusion and human development”
and urged “the Commission and the EU delegations to ensure meaningful consultations with
local and international civil society organisations to ensure that evidence from programmes
and the experiences of working children will be taken into account by the NDICI
programming process” (European Parliament, 2020a).
D. U.S. support for trade partners
In the United States, the Millennium Challenge Corporation programme (hereinafter MCC
programme) represents another example of an aid programme that could help developing
countries meet the requirements of trade agreements and regimes, both before and after
ratification. As a foreign assistance agency created by the U.S. Congress in January 2004, this
programme is described as providing “time-limited grants promoting economic growth,
reducing poverty and strengthening institutions. The investments thus support stability and
prosperity in partner countries” (MCC, n.d.-a). The partnerships created with developing
countries remain formed as long as the partner countries are engaged in respecting the key
principles of the MCC programme, that is, good governance, economic freedom and
investing in their citizens.
Countries may only be candidates for MCC assistance if they are classified as low income or
lower middle income by the World Bank, and are not prohibited from receiving assistance
by federal law. Further, the Board also considers the country’s policy performance on 20
independent and transparent policy indicators, the opportunity to reduce poverty and
achieve sustainable economic growth within a country, as well as the availability of funds.
Candidate countries may then be selected as eligible to the programmes (MCC, n.d.-a).
Selected countries, if they agree to participate, then develop a Compact Proposal with MCC.
Progress is tracked to the application of select indicators featured on MCC’s scorecard
(MCC, 2021).
MCC’s selection criteria incentivise potentially eligible countries to reform policies,
strengthen institutions and improve data quality in order to boost their development
performance. Three types of grants are provided by the MCC. Whilst compact grants may
only be granted for five years for selected countries meeting MCC’s eligibility criteria,
smaller “Threshold Programs” grants may be proposed to countries which do not meet
these criteria, but demonstrate a genuine commitment to improving their policy
105
performance. Selected countries are thus assisted to become compact eligible and offered
the opportunity to demonstrate their commitments to MCC key principles. And finally, the
third MCC grant type – Concurrent Compacts for Regional Investments – promotes crossborder economic integration, and increases regional trade and collaboration.
Five countries in West Africa – Benin, Burkina Faso, Côte d’Ivoire, Ghana and Niger – were
selected for the first time as eligible countries to this third grant by MCC’s Board of Directors
in December 2018 so as to “allow MCC to work with the countries to determine if there are
projects that meet MCC’s strict investment criteria as well as evaluate the countries’ ability
to work with MCC and a partner country on a regional investment” (MCC, n.d.-b).
The MCC programme thus provides for a genuine incentive for U.S. trade partner countries
to improve their policies so as to benefit from both MCC grants and trade agreements with
the United States. Although not tied to trade agreements, MCC projects indeed aim at
resolving local and concrete issues faced by developing countries, such as electricity or clean
drinking water supplies. Whilst reducing the countries’ level of poverty and promoting
economic growth, these projects thus may have a positive impact on child labour, although
they do not necessarily address this issue in particular.
As an example, the MCC's $295.7 million Compact (2009-2014) in Namibia funded the $7.6
million Indigenous Natural Product (INP) Activity. In the words of the U.S. MCC (2017), the
activity “aimed to improve quality and increase quantity and sales of five native plant
products used in health and beauty markets to ultimately increase harvesters’ income, the
majority of whom are women.” The project enabled the training of over 9,000 harvesters
and also made sure that children would not be used to harvest the product (NORC at the
University of Chicago, 2014, p. 152).
In its 17 years of existence, the agency has inter alia trained 405,482 farmers, educated
291,144 students, provided self-sustaining electricity systems generating 21,275836
megawatt hours of electricity, formalised 320,722 land rights, built 3,935 kilometres of
roads, and constructed 1,191 water points.
E. Multilateral support to nation-states
1. ILO
Ever since its creation after World War I at the Treaty of Versailles, the ILO International
Labour Organization36 has established international labour standards in the form of
international treaties that countries ratify in order to set the minimum standards for
protections at the workplace. Given the ILO’s tripartite design, these standards are not only
drafted just by governments, but benefit from the “real economy” perspective of workers
and employers who also have a hand in their adoption.
Two ILO conventions that exclusively concern child labour are Convention 138 and
Convention 182 (ILO 1973; ILO 1999). In 1973, the International Labour Organization (ILO)
36
Its very name represents a compromise: while “Labour” is British English, “Organization” is American English.
106
adopted a Convention on Minimum Age (No. 138). While Convention 138 prohibits
hazardous work below the age of 18, the step taken by the ILO Convention on the Worst
Forms of Child Labour (No. 182) was to categorise it as one of the worst forms: C182
prohibits work that could likely harm the “health, safety or morals of children” (ILO, 1999).
Apart from hazardous work, C182 also designates slavery-like practices, trafficking, and
prostitution as the worst forms of child labour.
A substantial number of these child labourers are exposed to WFCL as they are engaged in
agricultural or mining work, where they are exposed to hazardous and forced labour. ILO
(2001) Convention 184 on the Safety and Health in Agriculture therefore specifically calls
out work which is “likely to harm the safety and health” of individuals, which may only be
performed by young persons 18 and older.
The progressive ratification of two ILO standards directly targeting child labour has had a
decisive impact in ratifying countries, as national laws and enforcement are shaped to
provide proper legal protection to children. Table 17 shows the ratification of The Minimum
Age Convention No. 138 and the Worst Forms of Child Labour Convention No. 182, as well
as the UN Convention on the Rights of the Child (CRC). The UN CRC (UN General Assembly,
1989) is another international instrument, having been ratified by 196 states (with only the
United States not having ratified it to date), that recognises primary education as
compulsory, and obliges member states to regulate the working conditions and hours of
children. Yet, the only standard which all eligible countries have ratified is ILO (1999) C182.
Table 17: Ratification of ILO Standards C138 and C182, and the UN CRC
convention
ratifications
countries which
have not ratified
convention
ILO C138
173 (out of 187
eligible)
Australia,
Bangladesh, Cook
Islands, Iran (Islamic
Republic of), Liberia,
Marshall Islands,
New Zealand, Palau,
Saint Lucia, Somalia,
Timor-Leste, Tonga,
Tuvalu, United
States of America
ILO C182
187 (out of 187
eligible)
--
UN CRC
196 (out of 197
eligible)
United States
Source: Ratification by Convention, (ILO, n.d.-c), URL & Convention on the Rights of the Child, (UN, 2021a), URL
Through the act of ratification, member states commit themselves to a progressive agenda.
Case in point ILO (1973) C138, Article 1:
Each Member for which this Convention is in force undertakes to pursue a national
policy designed to ensure the effective abolition of child labour and to raise
107
progressively the minimum age for admission to employment or work to a level
consistent with the fullest physical and mental development of young persons.
To date, 53 countries have stipulated the minimum age as 14 years, 78 countries at 15
years, and 44 at 16 years of age.37
With regard to the transposition of the standards into national laws, ILO and USDOL report:
Over the 15 years from 2004 to 2018, a total of 59 countries have developed, revised,
or updated their legislative framework to comply with the provisions of ILO
Conventions on child labour. Some countries had to change their national
constitutions to ensure that the rights of children are fully recognized in law and in
practice. Many of the adapted laws related to the establishment of a national list of
hazardous work for children below the age of 18. (ILO & U.S. Department of Labor,
2019)
By signing and ratifying relevant instruments, member states incur legal obligations to
improve the lot of children and to bring their national legislation into conformity with those
instruments. Furthermore, when countries ratify the convention, they accept being
monitored. A "supervisory mechanism" at the ILO holds governments to account, answering
the question whether a ratifying government is actually implementing its commitments.
Thus, the ILO’s child labour standards represent a rallying cry and a central fulcrum for
national implementation.
Its engagement of member states, in view of eliminating child labour, the ILO executes in
line with Convention 182 Art. 8 (ILO, 1999) and SDG 17 (UN, n.d.). Deliberately connecting
the dots between EU trade interests and labour standards in exporting countries, the ILO's
Trade for Decent Work Project "aims at improving the application of the ILO fundamental
Conventions in EU trading partner countries through improved labour relations and working
conditions." At the top of the list is the capacitation of key stakeholders: "Strengthening the
capacity of constituents to actively participate in national processes to comply with
International Labour Standards (ILS), particularly the Fundamental Conventions" (ILO, n.d.d). Moreover, the ILO supervisory bodies, including the independent Committee of Experts
on the Application of Standards, provide information on countries’ efforts to eliminate child
labour. Uzbekistan, which has virtually eliminated child and forced labour in its cotton
harvest, also benefitted from ILO supervisory action and technical assistance.
While two of the ILO conventions are focussed on child labour, one should keep in mind that
fundamental labour rights are indivisible and mutually supportive. Consider the possible
interactions on an individual case basis: discrimination against migrants or ethnic minorities
may be just as important a factor of child labour as household income; a lack of freedom of
association rights can increase inequality and prevent economic growth from delivering
social progress. Therefore, progress across all of the core labour rights and factors related to
political economy as well as economic indicators are relevant for child labour outcomes.
37 See ratifications of ILO conventions: (ILO, n.d.-a)
108
2. IPEC+
Created in 1992, the ILO’s International Programme on the Elimination of Child Labour
(IPEC) has led global efforts against child labour (ILO & Fundamental Principles and Rights at
Work Branch [FUNDAMENTALS], 2019). In 2015, IPEC was expanded to IPEC+, incorporating
also the issue of forced adult labour under its aegis, and the programme was placed in the
Fundamental Principles and Rights at Work Branch of the ILO. IPEC+ aims to eliminate child
labour in all its forms by 2025, as well as eradicate forced labour, modern slavery and
human trafficking by 2030. Mirroring the context in which child labour occurs, IPEC+’s three
thematic priorities are: (a) Rural and informal economies, (b) Enterprises and global and
domestic supply chains, and (c) Situations of crisis and fragility (ILO & FUNDAMENTALS,
2019).
Its strategy is to intervene in the following domains:
i. Public policies and governance,
ii. Empowerment and representation,
iii. Partnerships and advocacy, and
iv. Knowledge and data.
IPEC activities have reportedly engaged thousands of partners from all regions of the world,
including employers’ and workers’ organisations. Its direct action involves building capacity,
convening of constituents in the communities or workplaces where child labour exists, and
supporting the work of national trade unions (ILO & FUNDAMENTALS, 2019).
Summarising its output, the ILO (2017) concludes:
Working in more than 115 member States over 25 years, IPEC+ has raised awareness,
encouraged member States to put in place the necessary legal and policy
frameworks, pilot-tested interventions, supported public services, the social partners
and others in combatting child labour through prevention and remediation, and, in
the common family and beyond, it has advocated for appropriate attention to child
labour in wider development policies and programmes. These efforts and activities
have resulted in nearly 1 million children being withdrawn or prevented from
entering child labour through the provision of educational and other opportunities.
Over the past decade, with direct assistance from the ILO, more than 60 countries,
enacting almost 200 laws, have adapted their legal frameworks to bring them into
conformity with the ILO’s child labour Conventions. In 57 of these countries, the
changes have been implemented through 279 national action plans. In 45 countries,
child labour policies have also been integrated into wider national social
development frameworks or sectoral policies such as those on education, social
protection, agriculture, and the informal economy. Employers’ and workers’
organizations have also integrated child labour into their policies and actions,
contributing in many counties to the implementation of national action plans. (p.14)
IPEC+ also works with member states to devise or update action plans to tackle child labour
in all its forms. Through the Alliance 8.7 programme – for which the ILO provides its
secretariat – states may elect to become “Pathfinder Countries” and, by doing so, commit to
109
going further or faster to achieve target 8.7. This is notably achieved through the hosting of
workshops, resulting in joint plans of action that serve as Alliance 8.7 roadmaps in the
countries concerned. To date, 22 countries have signed up to become pathfinder countries
(B. Smith, personal communication, May 20, 2021).
Supporting countries implement their ratified conventions pays off: the ILO notes that since
2004, “in its regular review of the application of ILO Conventions No. 138 and No. 182, the
ILO’s Committee of Experts has increased seven-fold its comments noting progress with
satisfaction and interest” (ILO, 2017).
Due to the increase of child labour due to COVID, IPEC+ launched a project (COVID-19
impact on child labour and forced labour: The response of the IPEC+ Flagship Programme) to
reach around 1 million vulnerable children, communities and families in an additional 10
countries (ILO, n.d.-b, 2020a).
With respect to the resources allocated to IPEC/IPEC+, as Figure 27 demonstrates, the extrabudgetary allocations to IPEC have oscillated considerably between 2005 and 2019.
Figure 27: Approvals for IPEC+ Child Labour and Forced Labour Projects (Extra-budgetary Allocations),
2005-2019
Source: IPEC+ Global Flagship Programme Implementation: Towards a world free from child labour and forced labour, (ILO,
2020b), URL
Bringing together IPEC and the Department for the Promotion of the Declaration on
Fundamental Principles and Rights at Work (DECLARATION), and housed within the ILO
Governance and Tripartism Department, the ILO’s Fundamental Principles and Rights at
Work Branch (FUNDAMENTALS) was established in 2013. “The Branch promotes policy
development, carries out research, and provides technical advisory services on child labour,
110
forced labour, non-discrimination and freedom of association and collective bargaining”
(ILO, 2020c). Figure 28 depicts the FUNDAMENTALS organigram.
Figure 28: FUNDAMENTALS Branch Structure
Source: (B. Smith, personal communication, May 20, 2021)
3. Child Labour Monitoring Systems
A Child Labour Monitoring System (CLMS), pioneered by the ILO, systematically measures
and reports child work data on an ongoing basis for all children in a target community. As
data are obtained at the individual child level by trained data collectors, it is a vital and
indispensable tool to ascertain child exposure to hazards and risks associated with their
work. Upon receiving the data, a dedicated child labour committee (often comprising
community leaders) then takes further action, e.g. withdrawing a child from child labour or
WFCL. As such, CLMS is an extremely cost-effective and empowering method to detect child
labour in a time-sensitive manner (Bayer, 2014).
Various iterations of CLMS have emerged over the years, refined through practice. Originally
developed in the Bangladeshi textile sector, an industrial setting, CLMS has also been set up
in the agricultural sector. A basic CLMS, for example, was applied in Ghana – the Ghana
Child Labor Monitoring System (GCLMS)– having been previously piloted in the 2002-2006
West Africa Cocoa/Commercial Agriculture Programme to Combat Hazardous and
Exploitative Child Labour (Bayer, 2014). Fairtrade International practices, to date, a form of
CLMS that leverages youth participation and agency, notably embodied in its youth-inclusive
child labour monitoring in Belize sugar production (de Buhr, 2019). CLMS may also be linked
to private sector-led remediation, e.g. as practised in Nestle’s (2019) Child Labor Monitoring
and Remediation System (CLMRS) application.
111
VI. UNGPs Pillar II – Measures to Enhance the
Corporate Responsibility to Respect
A. Legislative precedents of mandatory due diligence
The second pillar of the UNGPs affirms that business enterprises should respect human
rights (UN, 2011, p. 13). It clarifies that the corporate responsibility to respect human rights
refers to all internationally recognised human rights, which include those expressed in the
International Bill of Human Rights and the principles concerning fundamental rights in the
eight ILO core conventions as set out in the Declaration on Fundamental Principles and
Rights at Work (UN, 2011, p. 13). The latter include the Conventions on the elimination of
forced labour (No. 29 and No. 105), the Conventions on freedom of association and the
effective recognition of the right to collective bargaining (No. 87 and No. 98), the
Conventions on the elimination of discrimination in respect of employment and occupation
(No. 100 and No. 111) and the Conventions on the prohibition of child labour (No. 138 and
No. 182). The UNGPs set out that, in order to meet their responsibility to respect human
rights, businesses should have in place a human rights due diligence (HRDD) process “to
identify, prevent, mitigate and account for how they address their impacts on human rights”
(UN, 2011, p. 16).
In recent years, a growing number of nation-states have adopted or considered the
adoption of legislation turning the “soft” HRDD requirement under the UNGPs into a legally
binding duty. The two main examples of existing legislation in this respect are the French
Duty of Vigilance Law and the Dutch Child Labour Due Diligence Act. In addition, a number
of legislative initiatives have been put forward by various EU member states and at the
European level (see Figure 29).
These new laws will have a significant impact on numerous private sector actors across
sectors. This will include for instance (amongst many other examples), the garment industry
in South Asia which supply European brands (or non-European brands selling products on
the EU market), or the small-scale farmers growing cocoa in Côte d'Ivoire and Ghana that
supply European food and beverage companies (or non-European companies selling
products on the EU market): while many such suppliers are already subject to some HRDD
processes, they are bound to intensify in the wake of mandatory HRDD laws.
1. France
The French Duty of Vigilance Law (FDVL) adopted on 2 February 2017 and enacted on 27
March 2017 (LOI n° 2017-399 du 27 Mars 2017), was the first legislation in the world to
introduce binding human rights due diligence requirements on certain companies through
the establishment of a duty of vigilance.
112
Figure 29: Due Diligence, Legislative and Movement Initiatives in Europe
CIVIL SOCIETY ACTION
Source: Human Rights Due Diligence: the State of Play in Europe, (Shift, 2021), URL
The FDVL has a twofold objective: (1) to enhance corporate accountability in order to
prevent business-related human rights or environmental harms, and (2) to improve access
to remedy for individuals and communities whose human rights have been adversely
113
affected by the activities of French companies. It requires large French companies38 to put in
place, disclose and implement a vigilance plan (plan de vigilance) detailing the “reasonable
vigilance measures to identify risks and prevent serious violations of human rights and
fundamental freedoms, health and safety and the environment resulting from the own
activities of the company or the companies under their control, or from the activities of
their subcontractors and suppliers with whom they have an established business
relationship” (LOI n° 2017-399 du 27 Mars 2017).39 Child labour would fall within the scope
of the law insofar as it constitutes a serious violation of human rights and fundamental
freedoms (Duthilleul & de Jouvenel, 2020).
The vigilance plan must include five elements, in particular (Code de Commerce art. L225102-4):
● a mapping of the risks involved, containing in particular the identification, analysis
and prioritisation of risks;
● procedures to regularly assess risks associated with the activities of subsidiaries,
subcontractors or suppliers with whom the company has an established business
relationship;
● actions to mitigate risks and prevent serious harm;
● a whistleblowing mechanism collecting reports of potential and actual risks and
effects, drawn up in consultation with the company's representative trade unions;
● a mechanism to monitor measures that have been implemented and evaluate their
effectiveness.
In case of non-compliance, the French Duty of Vigilance law provides for two judicial
enforcement mechanisms. First, any interested party can seek an injunction to compel a
company to establish, implement and publish a vigilance plan. Second, the legislation
provides that a company may incur civil liability, in the conditions set forth under French
Tort Law, whenever its failure to comply with the obligations set forth in the legislation give
rise to damage.
A number of studies have investigated the implementation of the law. The study by Ibañez
et al. (2020) found mixed corporate performance: “the compliance score average for the
134 companies was 66%, with a median to 76%.” Yet the “compliance levels and the quality
of reporting in general decreases for the latter requisites of the law, namely those
concerned with assessing and disclosing the adequacy of the plans to address the risks at
issue” (Ibañez et al., 2020, p. 4). According to a report from Enterprises pour les droits de
l'homme (EDH, 2018), the law prompted 70% of companies to start mapping risks of adverse
human rights and environmental impacts or to revise existing mappings and processes. In
addition, whilst only 30% of companies had a dedicated process of identifying risks of
adverse human rights impacts prior to the adoption of the law, the report found that 65% of
companies had a dedicated process following its adoption (EDH, 2018, p. 13). A 2019 report
38 The FDVL applies to companies incorporated or registered
in France for two consecutive fiscal years which
employ at least 5,000 people in France (either directly or through their French subsidiaries), or at least 10,000
worldwide (through their subsidiaries located in France and abroad).
39 In French Law, the notion of ‘established business relationship’ is characterised by its regularity, its stability
and the volume of business involved. See Cour de cassation, Chambre Commerciale, 15 septembre 2009, n°
08-19200, Bull. IV, n° 110.
114
by Shift highlighted that “the requirements of the Duty of Vigilance Law have pushed
companies to improve their reporting” (Shift, 2019, p.5). The report notes that, “overall,
55% of companies slightly improved the maturity of their disclosure, with an average overall
score of 2.58/5, up from 2.45/5 before the entry into force of the Law” (Shift, 2019, p. 5),
which is slightly higher than the average non-French company (Shift, 2018, p. 6). One study
found generally high levels of compliance with the legislation, and observed that the French
Duty of Vigilance has had some positive impacts on business practices (Duthilleul & de
Jouvenel, 2020).
However, a majority of companies seem to have adopted a compliance-orientated
approach, and to have focused on the risks to the business itself, rather than on the risks to
people and the planet (ActionAid et al., 2019). Furthermore, consultation with external
stakeholders (which is encouraged but not made compulsory under the FDVL) has remained
limited in practice (Barraud de Lagerie et al., 2020). To address some of these issues, a
recent report for the French Government recommended to nominate a public authority
which would be in charge of: (i) monitoring the promoting and implementation of the law;
(ii) contributing to the harmonisation of corporate practices; and (iii) promoting sectorial
and multi-party approaches (Duthilleul & de Jouvenel, 2020).
Finally, despite its objective to improve access to remedy for victims, the FDVL failed to
address a number of obstacles to accessing remedy faced by claimants in concrete cases. In
particular, the burden of proof remains on the claimant, who will need to prove that they
suffered damage as a result of a fault on the part of the parent company or lead company
(Bright, 2021).
2. The Netherlands
The Dutch Child Labour Due Diligence Act (DCLDDA) was adopted on 14 May 2019,40
although it has yet to enter into force.41 It is framed around a double objective of preventing
the use of child labour in supply chains thereby ensuring consumer protection (Enneking,
2020):
we have taken into consideration the desirability of enshrining in law that companies
that sell goods and services on the Dutch market should do everything within their
power to prevent their products and services from being produced using child labor,
so that consumers can buy them with peace of mind. (The Dutch Child Labour Due
Diligence Act, 2019, Preamble)42
Child labour is defined in Article 2 of the DCLDDA (2019) as meaning:
in any case, any form of work, whether or not under an employment contract,
40 The Netherlands Child Labour Due Diligence Act of 2019: “Wet van 24 oktober 2019 n. 401 houdende de
invoering van een zorgplicht ter voorkoming van de levering van goederen en diensten die met behulp van
kinderarbeid tot stand zijn gekomen (Wet zorgplicht kinderarbeid).”
41 Its exact date of its entry into force is to be determined by Royal Decree. It may, in fact, never enter into force
if the legislative proposal published in March 2021 is adopted as the latter would effectively replace it.
42 For an unofficial translation please see Ropes & Gray LLP publication (Littenberg & Blinder, 2019).
115
performed by persons who have not yet reached the age of 18 and which is included
among the worst forms of child labor referred to in Article 3 of the Worst Forms of
Child Labor Convention, 1999.
In addition, Article 2 specifies that if the work takes place in the territory of a State Party to
the Minimum Age Convention, 1973, child labour shall further be defined as “any form of
work prohibited by the law of that State in implementation of that Convention,” in the
alternative, the DCLDDA (2019) states that child labour shall be understood to mean:
i. any form of work, whether or not under an employment contract, performed by
persons who are subject to compulsory schooling or who have not yet reached the
age of 15, and ii. any form of work, whether or not under an employment contract,
performed by persons who have not yet reached the age of 18, insofar as such work,
by virtue of the nature of the work or the conditions under which it is performed, may
endanger the health, safety or morality of young persons.
However, child labour shall not include light work as defined in Article 7(1) of the Minimum
Age Convention (ILO, 1973), carried out for a maximum of 14 hours a week by persons who
have reached the age of 13.
The DCLDDA (2019) requires companies selling goods or supplying services to Dutch end
users (art. 4.1)43 to exercise human rights due diligence (art. 5). In particular, companies are
to investigate, on the basis of reliable sources that are reasonable known and accessible to
the company, whether there is a reasonable suspicion that the goods or services to be
supplied have been produced using child labour (art. 5.1). Should such a suspicion arise, the
legislation mandates companies to adopt and implement a plan of action (art. 51). The
legislation refers to the ILO-IOE Child Labor Guidance Tool for Business (ILO, 2015) as a
benchmark for the due diligence exercise (DCLDDA, 2019, art. 5).
Under Article 4 of the DCLDDA (2019), companies are required to declare that they exercise
due diligence in order to prevent goods or services from being produced using child labour
(art. 4.1). More specifically, they are to send a statement to a public supervising authority
who is in charge of supervising compliance with the law (art. 3.1). The public supervising
authority is to publish the declarations in a public register on its website (art. 4.5).
In case of non-compliance with the obligations laid out in the law, the public supervising
authority can issue binding instructions accompanied by a time limit for execution (art. 7.4),
and impose an administrative fine in case of continued non-compliance (art. 7). The
company can be fined up to €8,200 in case of failure to submit the statement in accordance
with Article 4, or up to 10% of the worldwide annual turnover in case of failure to exercise
due diligence in accordance with Article 5 (Littenberg & Blinder, 2019). In addition, repeat
offenders can incur criminal sanctions (DCLDDA, 2019, art. 9).
43 The legislation does not express any restriction in terms of size of the companies, turnover or in terms of
legal form of the companies falling in its scope but Article 6 provides that categories of companies may be
exempted from the legislation by general administrative orders. Under Article 4.4, companies that are merely
transporting goods are exempt from this requirement.
116
Anyone whose interests are affected by the actions or omissions of a company failing to
comply with the provisions under the DCLDDA (2019) can submit a complaint to the public
supervising authority (art. 3.2) on the basis of concrete evidence of non-compliance (art.
3.3), after having submitted it first to the company which has six months to address it (art.
3.4).
Although an important step towards addressing human rights harms in global supply chains,
the DCLDDA (2019) suffers from various limitations. First of all, the law applies to companies
(wherever they are registered) supplying goods and providing services to Dutch end-users,
but does not cover the goods sold and services provided in the Netherlands as part of valueaddition [i.e. excluding the pre-Original Equipment Manufacturer (OEM) level]. In addition, it
does not cover the goods and services sold or provided by Dutch companies outside of the
Netherlands (Bright, 2021). For these last two categories, issues of child labour remain
unaddressed by the legislation.
Secondly, the human rights due diligence obligation can be discharged simply by receiving
goods or services from a company which has issued a statement indicating that it exercised
due diligence. However, the reporting requirement is a one-off exercise, which does not
need to be repeated annually (Bright & Macchi, 2020), whereas the UNGPs call for a
continuous exercise of human rights due diligence.
Finally, in terms of enforcement mechanisms, the DCLDDA provides for the possibility for
the public supervisory authority to issue administrative fines, but the public supervising
authority does not have pro-active powers in this respect as only complaints submitted by
third parties can trigger enforcement (MVO Platform, 2019). In addition, the legislation does
not contain any civil liability mechanisms. Although administrative fines could, arguably at
least, play a deterrent function, they do not provide actual remedy for victims of child
labour. In this respect, it has been noted that “companies might do the absolute minimum
to meet the law’s requirements. For example, they may quickly get rid of child labourers if
discovered without taking responsibility for remediation of impacts that have already
occurred” (MVO Platform, 2019).
In addition to the DCLDDA, a legislative proposal in the Netherlands calling for a bill on
Responsible and Sustainable International Business Conduct was launched by four major
political parties in the Dutch parliament on the 11th of March 2021 (MVO Platform, 2021;
“New Bill Could Force Dutch Companies,” 2021). The bill provides for a duty of care on all
companies registered in the Netherlands or selling goods or providing services on the Dutch
market whereby “any enterprise that knows or can reasonably suspect that its activities may
have negative impacts on human rights, labour rights or the environment in countries
outside the Netherlands must take all measures that may be reasonably required of it to
prevent such impacts,” or mitigate or reverse them, or refrain from the relevant activity,
and, where necessary, to enable remediation.44 In addition, the bill would impose a duty to
exercise human rights due diligence (overarching and not limited to child labour) for
companies which exceed two of three thresholds: a balance sheet total of 20 million, a net
44 See Unofficial Translation of Dutch Bill for Responsible and Sustainable International Business Conduct,
Section 1.2. (n.d.)
117
revenue of at least 40 million or an average of 250 employees during the financial year.45 If
adopted, the law would be enforced by a public regulator, which would be able to issue
financial sanctions in case of non-compliance. Repeated failure within five years to prevent
activities that cause or contribute to adverse human rights impacts, or to provide remedy
would constitute a criminal offence. In addition, the bill also provides for the possibility for
third parties to hold companies liable in civil court for harms suffered as a result of a
violation of the law. If adopted, the law would replace the Child Labour Due Diligence Law.
B. Forthcoming mandatory due diligence legislation
1. Germany
Germany is now also poised to pass a law enhancing corporate accountability for
environmental and human rights outcomes, charging companies to take measures to
prevent, minimise or remediate negative impacts. Three German Ministers announced on
the 12th of February, 2021, that they had reached an agreement on the details of a due
diligence act. The March 3, 2021 “government draft“ (“Regierungsentwurf”) (Law on
Corporate Due Diligence in Supply Chains, 2021) will now be further negotiated in the
Bundestag.
The draft law provides for a corporate duty-of-care to avoid human rights issues in their
own activities and in their supply chains. In this respect, companies would be required to
exercise human rights due diligence in relation to their Tier 1 (direct) suppliers. Where
prompted by circumstances, the human rights due diligence obligation would extend
throughout the entire supply chain. This would be the case in particular where the company
obtains substantiated knowledge of a possible violation. The law’s scope takes a phased-in
approach: it would enter into force on January 1st, 2023, when it would first apply to
approximately 600 German companies with over 3,000 employees. On January 1st, 2024,
the law would then also apply to companies with over 1,000 employees, which currently
works out to a total of 2,891 companies” (Bayer, 2021).
At its core, the German draft law shares certain similarities with the 2017 FDVL (see Table
18).
The draft German Lieferkettengesetz includes the requirement for in-scope companies to
identify and manage risk related to adverse human rights impacts, with a specific focus on
11 adverse impacts, of which the first two concern child labour. These are:
(§)Article
(2)1. Child labour (ILO C. 138)
(2)2. WFCL (ILO C. 182)
(2)3. Forced labour
(2)4. Modern slavery
(2)5. OHS
45 See Unofficial Translation of Dutch Bill for Responsible and Sustainable International Business Conduct,
Section 2.1., and see also (Wilde-Ramsing et al., 2021).
118
(2)6. Freedom of association
(2)7. Employment discrimination
(2)8. Withholding of wages /minimum wage
(2)9. Environmental harm
(2)10. Land grabbing
(2)11. Misuse of security services
Table 18: Comparison Between German Draft Lieferkettengesetz and FDVL
# of subject
companies
Duty of care
scope
Enforcement
Loi de vigilance
German Draft Lieferkettengesetz
2019: 134
2023: 600
2024: 2891
own operations, tier 1 + (where prompted by
circumstance -- “Anlass”)47
own operations, tier 1 +
(“controlled entities” +
“established commercial
relationships”)46
judicial enforcement
mechanisms
enforcement and toolkit via a public regulatory
authority (BAFA), including fines but no specific
judicial enforcement mechanism
violation of duty of care (“Bemühenspflicht”)
Scope of
corporate
liability
Remedy
violation of duty of vigilance
(“obligation de moyens”)
undefined 48
up to 10% of the annual turnover49
Public reporting
yes
Yes
Source: The French Duty of Vigilance Law, (LOI n° 2017-399 du 27 Mars 2017), URL & Law on Corporate Due Diligence in
Supply Chains (2021), URL
46 The French Duty of Vigilance law (LOI n° 2017-399 du 27 Mars 2017) goes beyond tier 1. In particular, the
concept of control (in 'controlled entities') is defined in the French Commercial Code as ‘exclusive control’,
which enables the company to ‘have decision-making power, in particular over the financial and operational
policies of another entity’. The concept can refer to legal control, de facto control or contractual control. The
concept covers subsidiaries that are directly and indirectly controlled and therefore includes first-tier
subsidiaries and lower tiers of subsidiaries over which a company exercises decision-making power. The
concept of ‘established commercial relationships’ aims to limit the scope of suppliers and subcontractors that
a company must include in its vigilance plan. Under French Law, an established commercial relationship means
a ‘stable, regular commercial relationship, taking place with or without a contract, with a certain volume of
business, and under a reasonable expectation that the relationship will last’. It is therefore narrower than the
concept of business relationships referred to in the UN Guiding Principles insofar as it excludes ad hoc
relationships but does reach beyond tier 1.
47 The draft German law features a risk-based duty of care requirement (“risikobasierte Sorgfaltspflichten”)
encompassing 3 spheres:
1. own operations (“Eigener Geschäftsbereich”);
2. immediate suppliers / contractual business partners (“umittelbare Zulifererer” / “Vertragspartner”);
and
3. where prompted by circumstance (“Anlass”) associated with upstream suppliers that are not
contractually connected to the company (“mittelbare Zulieferer nicht vertraglich verbunden”).
48 The provisional fine provision was stricken from the draft law by the Conseil Constitutionnel. See: “Decision
no. 2017-750 DC of 23 March 2017.”
49 Subject to a pending decision by the Federal Ministry of Finance.
119
In terms of enforcement, the draft law opts for a public enforcement mechanism through a
public regulatory authority (BAFA). The designated public regulatory authority has the
power to issue fines in connection with non-compliance with the law. Furthermore, noncomplying companies can be excluded from the award of public procurement contracts
(Law on Corporate Due Diligence in Supply Chains, 2021).
Concerning the question of a business termination, the German draft law advances the
principle of engagement before disengagement (“Befähigung vor Rückzug”) as the advised
modus operandi, with business termination only to be employed as the very last option
(ultima ratio) (Law on Corporate Due Diligence in Supply Chains, 2021).
Unlike the French Duty of Vigilance Law, the German draft law does not establish a judicial
enforcement mechanism with a new civil cause of action for affected individuals. The two
types of enforcement mechanisms differ significantly: while enforcement through a public
supervisory body may play a very important role in ensuring compliance with the law, it fails
to provide remedy for affected individuals and communities, in line with the requirements
under the 3rd pillar of the UNGPs.
In March 2021, the author of the UNGPs – Professor John Ruggie – published a letter
addressed to German Ministers welcoming elements of the new draft German law whilst
expressing concerns about certain areas which are not so closely aligned with the UNGPs.
These include, inter alia, the fact that “the specific obligations on companies to proactively
identify risks and take action to address them apply only to the company’s own operations
and its direct suppliers – that is, to Tier 1 suppliers” which “for a significant number of
German companies [...] is not where the most severe risks lie.” Ruggie highlighted that “a
focus on Tier 1 alone would lead companies to focus on relationships that are less likely to
pose significant human rights risks, while ignoring others (beyond Tier 1) where the
probability of such risks is higher.” He also emphasised that the approach requiring to go
beyond Tier 1 if the company obtains “substantiated knowledge” of a possible violation is
not satisfactory insofar as identifying human rights impacts constitute the first step of the
HRDD process, and that if substantiated knowledge of a possible violation is already
available, then the company should determine the appropriate remedial action based on its
degree of involvement with the human rights harm (Ruggie, 2021).
2. Switzerland
In Switzerland, the Swiss Responsible Business Initiative launched in 2016 obtained a
popular majority in the vote of the 29th of November 2020, even though it was eventually
rejected for failure to obtain support from a majority of the cantons. As a result, the Indirect
Counter-Proposal of the Council of States will most likely enter into force. The latter
provides for reporting requirements whereby certain large Swiss public-interest
companies50 will be required to publish a non-financial report reporting on environmental
issues, including CO2 targets, social and employee-related matters, respect for human rights
and the fight against corruption (The Federal Assembly of the Swiss Confederation, 2020). It
50
Companies, whose registered office, central administration or principal place of business is in Switzerland
(see: Bueno, 2019).
120
also provides for due diligence obligations for Swiss companies in relation to “minerals and
metals potentially originating from conflict or high-risk zones"; as well as for "products or
services, for which there is a well-founded suspicion of child labor" (The Federal Assembly of
the Swiss Confederation, 2020)(in line with the Dutch Child Labour Due Diligence Act) (ibid).
3. Norway
In Norway, the Norwegian Draft Act “relating to transparency regarding supply chains, the
duty to know and due diligence” (Ethics Information Committee, 2019) was published in
November 2019, providing for transparency obligations – a “duty to know” of “salient risks
that may have an adverse impact on fundamental human rights and decent work, both
within the enterprise itself and in its supply chains” and to provide information to interested
third parties – for all companies importing goods or services into Norway, and for a duty to
exercise due diligence with regards to human rights and decent work for larger companies.51
The Draft Act also provides for a public supervisory authority in charge of monitoring and
ensuring compliance with the law.
4. European Union
The momentum in support of mandatory human rights due diligence legislation has been
building both at domestic levels and at the European Union. The EU is developing its own
mandatory human rights and environmental due diligence (mHRDD) law, with a legislative
proposal to be introduced in 2021. Both the EU Commission and the EU Parliament have
been extensively exploring options for mHRDD.
On the 10th of March 2021, the European Parliament adopted a resolution (the so-called
“Lara Wolters' Report”) with recommendations to the Commission on corporate due
diligence and corporate accountability (2020/2129(INL)) – including draft text for a suitable
EU directive. Article 4.1 of the report provides that:
Member States shall lay down rules to ensure that undertakings carry out effective
due diligence with respect to potential or actual adverse impacts on human rights,
the environment and good governance in their operations and business relationships.
(2020/2129(INL))
Lara Wolters’ Report refers specifically to “the situation of an estimated 152 million children
in child labour, 72 million of whom work in hazardous conditions, many of them being
forced to work through violence, blackmail and other unlawful means,” which is described
as “unacceptable and particularly worrying” (2020/2129(INL)). The report also refers to the
need to prepare non-binding guidelines with due account, inter alia, of the UN Committee
on the Rights of the Child General, Comment 16, on State “obligations regarding the impact
of the business sector on children's rights” (2020/2129(INL)). It cites the Children’s Rights
and Business Principles (UNICEF et al., 2012), developed by UNICEF, the UN Global Compact
51 Larger companies are defined in the draft act as those exceeding two of the following thresholds: sales
income of NOK 70 million; total assets of NOK 35 million; an average of 50 full-time employees in the
accounting year.
121
and Save the Children and the series of guidance documents developed by UNICEF as
sources of reference. Finally, it calls for “complementary measures such as the prohibition
of the importation of products related to severe human rights violations such as forced
labour or child labour; stresses the importance of including the objective of combating
forced labour and child labour in Trade and Sustainable Development chapters of Union
trade agreements” (2020/2129(INL)).
In terms of enforcement, the report provides for the need for each Member State to
designate a national competent authority responsible for the supervision of the application
of the Directive, with the power to impose sanctions. The text refers in particular to
“proportionate sanctions to infringements of the national provisions adopted in accordance
with this Directive” (art. 18). Article 18.2 further specifies that:
The competent national authorities may in particular impose proportionate fines
calculated on the basis of an undertaking’s turnover, temporarily or indefinitely
exclude undertakings from public procurement, from state aid, from public support
schemes including schemes relying on Export Credit Agencies and loans, resort to the
seizure of commodities and other appropriate administrative sanctions.
(2020/2129(INL))
The draft text also provides for a civil liability provision whereby “undertakings” should, “in
accordance with national law be held liable and provide remediation for any harm arising
out of potential or actual adverse impacts on human rights, the environment or good
governance that they, or undertakings under their control, have caused or contributed to by
acts or omissions” (2020/2129(INL), art. 19.2), which is coupled with a due diligence defence
(art. 19.3).
C. EU Investment Protection Agreements
Trade policy concerns just as much the international trade of goods and services as it does
cross-border investments. Net outflows of EU foreign direct investment were USD 246
billion in 2019 (BoP, current USD) (International Monetary Fund, n.d.). Signed on a bilateral
basis, investment protection agreements (IPAs) help “protect and promote investment of
European companies abroad” by protecting the assets of European companies “against
practices by the host State, which are prohibited in the EU” (European Commission, 2020a,
pp. 1–3). As of 2020, EU Member States were party to some 1400 IPAs with third countries
(European Commission, 2020a).
Such protection does not translate into a carte blanche for corporations operating abroad:
as the EU IPAs “only provide protection for investments that are in accordance with
domestic legislation,” companies “are therefore legally bound by all the obligations
contained in the domestic legislation of the host State, including environmental or labour
protection or respect of human rights” (European Commission, 2020a, p. 4). Yet in a
competitive investment climate, there is the real danger that exporting countries relax or
simply do not enforce labour standards “in order to attract foreign investment” in the first
place (Titievskaia et al., 2021, p. 2).
122
Thus, the EU could go one step further: existing and future Investment Protection
Agreements could foresee that investments that take undue profit from child or adult
labour would not be protected under the dispute settlement scheme established in the IPA,
unless they explicitly work toward improving working conditions and the payment of living
income/wages, with measurable and enforced milestones. Furthermore, IPAs could, in their
articles outlining the objectives, be conditioned upon the UN Principles for Responsible
Investment.
Existing IPAs may be retrofitted to reflect this reform. For example, the EU-Vietnam
Investment Protection Agreement, in Chapter 4: Institutional, General and Final Provisions,
ARTICLE 4.3, in section “Amendments”, explicitly states that the “Parties may amend this
Agreement” (European Commission, 2018c).
VII. Policy Options
A. Progressive conditionality in bilateral trade agreements
In translating the above findings into policy recommendations, the following propositions
are put forward.
Mindful of (1) Basu's adult-child labour substitutability condition, (2) harm done through
embargo externalities to child labour outcomes, (3) WFCL constituting a higher risk to child
survival and wellbeing than non-WFCL child labour, and (4) living income/wage
conditionality being as important as child labour conditionality for child labour outcomes (as
implied by leading child labour models), a progressive system of carrots and sticks is
advanced.
Zone 1
•Carrots
Zone 2
Zone 3
•Conditional
carrots
Zone 1: (< USD 3,000 GDP/capita):
Zone 2: (b/w USD 3,000 - USD 7,000 GDP/capita):
Zone 3: (b/w USD 7,000 - 11,000 GDP/capita):
Zone 4: (> USD 11,000 GDP/capita):
Zone 4
•Select sticks
•Sticks
Only carrots
Conditional carrots
Select sticks
Only sticks
Consider the below graph (Figure 30), drawn from Gapminder, that shows GDP/capita
(adjusted for inflation and purchasing power parity) in 2020 along the x-axis and life
expectancy on the y-axis. We have added lines indicating where each of the 4 zones begins
and where they end. Figure 31 also depicts the 4 zones, but through the vantage point of
GDP per capita against the share of children in employment.
123
Figure 30: GDP Per Capita vs. Life Expectancy, Zone 1-4
Source: Adapted from Gapminder.org, CC-BY
Figure 31: GDP Per Capita vs. Share of Children in Employment, 2012; Zone 1-4
Notes: Bubble sizes are proportional to the population of children aged 5-14 years. Lines have not been adjusted for
inflation.
Source: Children in employment, total (% of children ages 7-14), adapted from Understanding Children’s Work project,
based on data from ILO UNICEF and the World Bank (n.d.), URL
124
1. Zone 1: (< USD 3,000 GDP/capita): Only carrots – no conditionality
In our current formulation, countries below upper-middle income would most likely be in
Zone 1. Engagement should rely solely on carrots and avoid the use of sticks completely.
These countries are likely to have a very large share of the population suffering from severe
poverty, educational opportunities in rural areas will be missing or substandard, and the
government is very likely unable to enforce child labour standards universally.
Basu (1999) and Grootaert (1998) contend that first steps should be to encourage countries
to allow light work with schooling rather than an outright ban in order to protect poor
families' economic wellbeing and prevent child starvation.
The ILO/IPEC+ observes:
Child labour is a complex phenomenon influenced by a multitude of factors. Its
complexity means that there is no single or simple answer to it: the response must
address many parameters, for example through policies which promote social and
economic development, compulsory education in line with the minimum age for
employment, and decent work for adults and young people, as well as effective social
protection (ILO & U.S. Department of Labor, 2019, p. 8).
Investing in education, healthcare, and social protection in countries with high numbers of
child workers is one of the most effective ways of eradicating child labour (credit constraints
and temporary shocks furthermore underline the need for social protection lifelines).
Children are less likely to drop out of a quality education system in order to work, and
parents are less likely to financially rely on their children if they themselves have quality jobs
and are supported by adequate social protection.
If conditionality was attached to Zone 1 intervention, it could be done through processbased carrots, i.e. the condition of processes in place to address the problem at hand. Such
carrots could include: the identification of child labour in high-risk sectors (through CLMS
systems), the establishment of child protection systems, and building on public and private
sector efforts under the UN Guiding Principles.
The Neighbourhood, Development and International Cooperation Instrument – the fund
now to be used by the EU for international development – provides the Commission with an
opportunity to do this.
2. Zone 2: (b/w USD 3,000 - USD 7,000 GDP/capita): Conditional carrots
Between $3000-$7000, at the beginning of Zone 2, free trade agreements should include
labour chapters that spell out concrete, measurable actions that can be independently
monitored, evaluated, and verified.
Countries such as Kenya, Nigeria, and Tanzania in Africa, and Bangladesh, Nepal, and
Pakistan in Asia would take necessary action to reduce the incidence of child labour. Failure
125
to demonstrate progress would open the door to reducing the incentives provided – no
punishments per se, but a denial of benefits that had been offered previously. While there is
still deep and persistent poverty in many areas, the governments of these countries have
demonstrated at least some capacity at administering country-wide programs such as
moving towards universal education.
In these lower levels – Zone 1 and the beginning of Zone 2 – the focus is on encouraging
governments to provide meaningful alternatives to child labour that would ensure
household survival and stability. Basu et al. (1999, p. 1093) conclude:
Even if legal intervention in the child labor market is found to be undesirable, that
does not mean government should sit back and wait for natural economic growth to
gradually remove children from the labor force. Government can intervene in the
market to create a variety of incentives, such as providing better and more schools,
giving school meals, and improving conditions in the adult labor market, which result
in a reduction of child labor.
Complementary interventions should create progress towards reducing the worst forms of
child labour with supportive help from EU policies, including accommodative trade policies
that respect human and labour rights.
In addition to focussing directly on the eradication of child labour, carrots could be tied to
outcome-level outputs that work toward the end goals of abolishing child labour and
eradicating the Worst Forms of Child Labour, and feature metrics such as school attendance
and children in employment.
The primary difference in this regard between Zone 2 and Zone 3 is that Zone 2 provides for
additional incentives, the removal of which is unlikely to violate the spirit or letter of any
existing agreement, while Zone 3 features the introduction of penalties.
3. Zone 3: (b/w USD 7,000 - 11,000 GDP/capita): Select sticks
Between $7,000-$11,000, conditionality would begin introducing some specific negative
consequences. Countries such as Guatemala, India, Ukraine, Venezuela, and Viet Nam have
generally maintained more than 75% literacy rates, and though there is variation between
states or provinces in income, there are at least some areas of the country where less than
10% of the population is in absolute poverty in PPP terms. It is envisioned that the negative
consequences would be applied to the continued existence of the worst forms of child
labour, while carrots are still the focus to reduce other forms of child labour.
4. Zone 4: (> USD 11,000 GDP/capita): Only sticks
Above $11,000, literacy rates are near universal, suggesting sufficiently effective governance
to oversee the vast majority of formal firms and ensure child labour laws are being
enforced. In these countries, there will be relatively few carrots, while labour chapter
conditionalities will rely most heavily on the threat of imposed consequences.
126
5. Use of other measures to justify exceptions
While this discussion has focused on expected commonalities, attention should always be
paid to the specific context of each country and to prioritisation. Rather than imposing a
single standard for all countries within an income bracket, care should be taken to “play the
ball where it lies” (to use a golf metaphor). The focus is on making progress, first at reducing
and then removing the worst forms of child labour, then on ensuring safety and health
standards and that children are able to attend school regularly and consistently. Such a
process is also more likely to be accepted by the country – meaning both its government
and its people – than would the perception of outsiders forcing Western attitudes on an
unwilling populace.
As discussed earlier in this paper, it would be a mistake to rely solely on GDP/capita as the
one measure of how to address the problem of child labour. Basu and Tzannatos (2003)
mention particularly the ratio of child labourers to adult unskilled labour: since child labour
acts as a substitute for adult unskilled labour, the higher that ratio is, the greater the impact
on adult wages could be by reducing child labour. Therefore, the more likely it is there are
multiple equilibria, holding all else constant. The above four-zone recommendations provide
an outline, emphasising that GDP/capita is a proxy for better measures of poverty, good
governance, capacity, and quality of the education system where such data are not
available, not timely, or not reliable.
For example, Nigeria has a GDP/capita of more than $5,000, placing it in the middle of Zone
2. However, because of intense inequality and poverty, Nigeria’s multidimensional poverty
index score (.254) is more than twice as high as the Republic of Congo (.112) and 28% higher
than Pakistan (.198) (which are slightly poorer in GDP/capita terms) and on par with Malawi
(.243) and Rwanda (.259), who have less than half Nigeria’s GDP/capita. According to
Gapminder data, only two other countries with an income above $3000/year have higher
rates of extreme poverty, with 71% living below $3.20/day and 39% below $1.90/day. Their
adult literacy rate (62%) is similarly worse than in the Republic of Congo (82%), though
similar to Pakistan’s (59%). Nigeria’s statistical capacity increased from 44 to 73 from 20042012, but has fallen again to 53 by 2020 (see World Bank, 2020). Pakistan’s statistical
capacity has remained above 73 since 2004, while Congo has stayed around 49. In terms of
corruption, Nigeria ranks 149/180 by Transparency International, while there are many
poorer countries that perform much better. Because of this deep level of poverty and
history of government incapability, it would be reasonable to expect less from this country
than others at a similar level of GDP/capita.
In addition, recalling the first principle to do no harm, another caveat should be kept in
mind. With increasing wage disparities and inequality, extreme poverty has become an issue
of pockets of poverty within middle- and upper-middle income countries. In China, for
example, average incomes in Beijing and Shanghai are more than twice the national
average, while Gansu and Heilongjiang are only half the national average. It would certainly
be appropriate to treat firms operating in richer, better educated, eastern China under the
rules and expectations of the 4th Zone – and this accounts for the vast majority of those
firms hoping to export to the EU. However, the poorer provinces are closer in income to
127
Zone 2 or 3, and educational opportunities are similarly lacking. In those provinces, there
would be a greater danger that even a surgical use of sanctions, as in Section 307, has the
potential to push children into worse working situations. Discretion should therefore be
exercised in faithfully executing sanctions to ensure that no harm is done to marginalised
groups living in pockets of poverty of otherwise upper-middle income countries. Further
deliberations, however, may also consider to what extent national policies, e.g. with social
dumping ramifications, are deliberately fostering such domestic inequality, and whether a
moral hazard is left unpunished by not holding to account Zone 4 countries.
6. Suggested carrots and sticks
A four-zone system of incentives and disincentives is advanced, comprising a policy of
progressive conditionality that would allow the EU to responsibly and effectively exercise its
purchasing power on the matter child labour.
Possible carrots
We suggest that the following carrots be embedded into existing policy and instruments.
Table 19: Possible Carrots
carrots
Zone 1
Zone 2
Zone 3
Zone 4
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
A. Aid (empirically proven interventions): European aid programmes such as the
Neighbourhood, Development and International Cooperation Instrument (NDICI) may step
up interventions with demonstrated success in reducing child labour. Obviously, that aid
could take the form of direct assistance to the education system itself – providing the funds
to build schools, employ or train teachers, or reduce schooling fees. Another means of
supporting education systems is by following Brazil’s Bolsa Familia or Mexico’s Progresa
programmes, which provide income and food support to families who meet certain criteria.
These criteria most often include that all children are attending school. Dreze and Kingdon
(1999) have also demonstrated that school participation is higher when a meal is provided.
Food-for-education programs, therefore, can also directly improve the outcomes of
concern. Dammert et al. (2018) reveal the body of evidence for the effectiveness of
(conditional and unconditional) cash transfers.
128
B. Aid (conditional on performance): Aid may be provided, however premised on
performance tied to educational outcomes (e.g. of primary, secondary school enrolment),
and/or monitoring outcomes (e.g. the identification of child labour in high-risk sectors
through child labour monitoring systems and the establishment of child protection systems)
and/or economic outcomes (e.g. payment of living income/wages, price stabilisation,52 farm
gate prices, etc.). Also Aid for Trade (AfT) may be leveraged to this end. There is value in
creating a stronger association between existing aid programmes (such as the AfT and the
NDICI) and trade agreements/arrangements, as it would help trade partner countries make
better use of their agreements with the EU. Technical collaboration with the ILO is advised
for such engagement, given that a neutral referee would be needed to provide data and
judgement on performance.
Furthermore, the EU may use its role as a major importing bloc to exert influence by asking
the trade partners to make pre-ratification commitments, whereby they would demonstrate
their determination on the issue. In support, the EU could use its AfT and NDICI instruments
to provide future trade partners with expertise and the resources needed to implement the
measures and reforms needed.
C. Conditional market access and trade preferences: A licensing model (a form of a non-tariff
trade barrier), instituted through bilateral agreements or MOUs with countries exporting
the commodities suffering from a significant amount of child labour, in conjunction with the
above described financial and capacity-building assistance, would serve to improve
standards of governance and law enforcement.53
To further incentivise the necessary performance, trade preferences in FTAs could include
the dismantlement of barriers to trade, whether tariffs or non-tariff barriers.54 Tariff
reductions for specific child labour outcomes such as the progressive elimination of WFCL
and the reduction of child labour in EU trade partner countries may be considered, in line
with the Franco-Dutch non-paper suggesting the staging of tariff liberalisation (Direction
générale du Trésor, 2020).55 Furthermore, the institution of a minimum wage, for those
In “June 2019, Côte d'Ivoire and Ghana took an initiative on cocoa prices that led to an agreement with the
cocoa and chocolate industry to create a Living Income Differential (LID) to ensure decent revenue to local
farmers. At this stage, it is a US$400/ton premium paid beyond the price of the cocoa futures markets”
(International Partnerships, 2021). Meanwhile, the first payments have reportedly been paid to farmers in
Ghana.
53 A licensing system allowing a trade partner to meet the agreed-upon standards, as presented by Brack
(2019), “could be modelled after the Voluntary Partnership Agreements (VPAs) between the EU and timberexporting countries under the FLEGT Action Plan. VPAs are designed to ensure that all timber products
exported to the EU have been legally produced – once products are FLEGT-licensed, they gain easier access to
the EU market. Although it has proved difficult and time-consuming to establish the licensing systems, the
process of negotiating and implementing VPAs has in some cases significantly improved governance and law
enforcement, making the forest sector more transparent and accountable, and reducing illegal logging. This
model could be adopted to cocoa, either based on the legality of production or on wider objectives” (Brack,
2019).
54
Some in-scope countries/commodities, e.g. Ghana/Ivory Coast + cocoa, already enjoy tariff-free and quotafree trade.
55
The Franco-Dutch proposal on trade, socio-economic effects and sustainable development proposes that
parties “should introduce, where relevant, staged implementation of tariff reduction linked to the effective
implementation of TSD provisions and clarify what conditions countries are expected to meet for these
52
129
countries that do not have one, may be a step towards the attainment of a living
income/wages. Process-level outcomes may also be considered, such as CLMS coverage and
outcomes (child labour can and is being measured through various CLMS iterations). In
addition, a trade partner’s ratification and implementation of ILO conventions that
strengthen the parent’s – and especially the mother’s – position to earn a living is relevant
here. While the eight fundamental conventions C87, C98, C29, C105, C138, C182, C100, and
C111 are indeed foundational, a number of conventions directly target women (e.g. ILO
C189, C156, and C190). Especially for new FTAs, pre-ratification commitments (e.g. the
signing/ratification of core ILO standards) should be a feature. Last but not least, the
formalisation of the informal economy is another key measure to improve working
conditions and reduce child labour.
The reduction of these barriers should be conditioned on agreed-upon outcomes and
include time-bound roadmaps and targets. Each existing FTA should be retrofitted with a
time-bound roadmap and dispute settlement mechanism, which would include the
following specifications, and new ones would contain them by default. Establishing
roadmaps, milestones and concrete and verifiable objectives in the FTAs would allow the EU
to avoid the ambiguous language as formulated in the EU-South Korea FTA (see, e.g., EUKorea panel of experts).56 A dispute settlement would be included in the frame of new or
revised TSD chapters, where state-to-state dispute settlement would be authorised. A
dispute is triggered where there was no progress on an agreed-upon i.e. milestone was not
met. As child labour outcomes depend on the living conditions of their families,
strengthening the enforcement of labour-related provisions of the TSD chapters would be
imperative.
If a trade partner were to be found in violation of the conditions embedded in the trade
agreement, the trade benefit could also be withdrawn. However, here again, the withdrawal
of this carrot is only advised to be applied in Zone 2 countries, where it would not be likely
to further aggravate child labour and human rights abuses. In addition, one may envision a
grace period in which the trade partner would be subject to a probationary period during
which it would have to demonstrate its intention to remedy the violations of the trade
agreement.
To this end, TSD clauses in present FTAs would need to be reformed, and new TSD clauses
written into forthcoming FTAs. Existing bi- and multi-lateral agreements would need to be
reductions, including the possibility of withdrawal of those specific tariff lines in the event of a breach of those
provisions. This approach would allow the EU to bear the fruits of its cooperative approach, while
strengthening enforcement” (Direction générale du Trésor, 2020, p. 1).
56 The EU-SKo Report of the Panel of Experts (Jill Murray et al., 2021) found, in paragraph 276, that the
agreement had lacked time-bound measures to be taken by South Korea: “The Panel finds it significant that
the last sentence of Article 13.4.3 does not set a specific target date or a particular milestone for the
ratification process: the provision merely states that the Parties should make ‘continued and sustained efforts
towards ratification’. Nor have the Parties referred to any specific target dates or discernible schedules that
they have agreed, which may help guide the Panel’s analysis.” Thus, the EC has been advised that FTAs spell
out concrete, measurable actions, regularly monitored along milestones codified in TSD chapters. See, e.g.
recent Opinion of the International Trade Committee (European Parliament, 2021a), paragraph 4, advising
that: “trade and sustainable development (TSD) chapters include a roadmap with concrete and verifiable
commitments upon which progress in other chapters will be made.”
130
reviewed, aided by the fact that FTAs contain an amendment and review clause (due within
the 10th year of entry into force).57
With respect to the required monitoring and measurement such a regime would entail, the
appropriate executive powers must rely on independent metrics, measurement, and
enforcement. In order for the Chief Trade Enforcement Officer (CTEO) to act on the
information received through the “Single Entry Point,” codification by means of a decision or
regulation would be necessary such that the Chief Trade Enforcement Officer may
investigate and take the appropriate measures by activating the dispute settlement
mechanism or to envisage other penalties. And mutatis mutandis, same for GSP.” No easy
task, given the multitude of multilateral agreements to enforce. The CTEO would also liaise
with the European External Action Service (EEAS), and rely on a reputable 3rd party, such as
the ILO, to monitor and report on the agreed-upon conditions that could trigger the
application of conditional carrots.
Possible sticks
The following disincentives may be embedded into existing policy and instruments.
Table 20: Possible Sticks
Sticks
Zone 1
Zone 2
Zone 3
Zone 4
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
D. Surgical import bans: The U.S. has the powers of blocking specific shipments of specific
companies that produce goods with forced labour or child labour (through its Tariff Act
mechanism). If the EU acquired similar powers, it could act systematically, surgically, and
decisively on the practice of child labour – as a matter of last resort – with a particular scope
on its hazardous/worst forms.
Yet, in order to prevent doing more harm than good, the surgical import bans should only
be deployed within a set scheme of progressive conditionality, and preferably only be
57
For instance, see JEFTA (European Commission, 2018a):
ARTICLE 23.1 – General review: “Without prejudice to the provisions concerning review in other Chapters, the
Parties shall undertake a general review of the implementation and operation of this Agreement in the
10th year following the date of entry into force of this Agreement, or at such times as may be agreed by the
Parties.”
ARTICLE 23.2 – Amendments: “1. This Agreement may be amended by agreement between the Parties.”
131
deployed on Zone 4 countries in light of the possible collateral damage caused. We
furthermore would advise against the use of blanket (sector-wide) sanctions applied to the
most vulnerable countries. Company-specific sanctions, however, are defensible.
While also the EU, through a new legal framework (Council Decision CFSP 2020/1999 and
Council Regulation EU 2020/1998), has the powers to target natural and legal persons,
entities and bodies responsible for, involved in or associated with serious human rights
violations and abuses worldwide, designating an individual or an entity will require a
significant degree of consensus (the Council of the EU may only proceed with designations
on the basis of unanimity among all member states58). In addition, while slavery is explicitly
listed, child labour is not (yet the practice may fall under the scope of the sanction regime
where those child labour violations are widespread, systematic or are otherwise of serious
concern). Whereas the powers of the EU Council mirror those of the U.S. GloMag, no EU
powers are currently in place that would mimic the U.S. Tariff Act import ban mechanism.
Furthermore, the EU should apply a holistic effort where governments partner with civil
society and with industry to enhance and improve information collection, prevention,
enforcement, and remediation. In particular, the EU needs to address possible tension
between strict enforcement of the proposed legislation on import bans and accepted
principles related to human rights due diligence and remediation. These principles are
embodied in the UN Guiding Principles on Business and Human Rights, and as the EU moves
towards establishing a mandatory human rights and environmental due diligence directive,
any proposal on sanctions should be aligned with the UNGPs.
E. Public procurement measures: Under U.S. Executive Order 13126 of 1999, goods may be
excluded from federal procurement, and consequences, including debarment, assessed for
violations. Also the public sector in Europe could lead by example. This could occur through
the reform of public procurement laws, but also be enshrined in the chapters of the FTA.
In addition, punitive measures may be complemented with public procurement policy of
buying by example. Such a policy would entail government buyers meeting minimum criteria
for legality and social and environmental standards. Drawing on experience from the timber
industry, Brack (2019) explains: “All EU Member States are significant purchasers of food
and catering services, and most already possess frameworks for sustainable procurement;
many have adopted timber procurement policies to restrict buyers to legal and sustainable
timber products.” To this end, private certification systems may be engaged: “In practice,
applying this approach to cocoa would probably mean that public purchasers would need to
rely on [product] certification schemes and company programmes” (Brack, 2019).
F. Creation of lists: The U.S. Department of Labor establishes and regularly updates a List of
Goods produced by child labour or forced labour and their source countries (under the 2005
TVPRA regulation), as well as a List of Products and their source countries produced by
forced or indentured child labour and their source countries (under Executive Order 13126).
A surgical (black)listing approach targeting products, countries, individuals and/or
58 Enforcing the sanction regime, including determining the applicable penalties for the infringement of the
restrictive measures, falls within the competency of member states.
132
companies is advised also for the EU, that would serve as a monitoring tool, inform public
procurement, as well as send “signals” to the market.
G. Rebalancing measures: As the EU-UK’s TCA features a “rebalancing measure” that offers a
clear mechanism for a trade partner to seek and – if need be, unilaterally – obtain redress
for a position of “unfair disadvantage.” In order to be in a position to credibly challenge a
trade partner on child labour ultimate outcomes, the EU should insert conditionality in renegotiated and future trade deals, which in turn could trigger “rebalancing measures.” The
necessary monitoring and measurement underpinning the decisions could, as with C.
Conditional trade preferences above, be provided by the ILO in liaison with delegations of
the EEAS.
Before the step of introducing necessary rebalancing measures, further reform should be
undertaken on the existing cooperation mechanisms implemented in TSD chapters, and, in
particular, the conclusions of the expert panel, should be given more importance so that
consultations are not in vain. For example, consideration could be given to making the
panel's findings binding. To ensure that the EU's trading partners remain proactive in
improving human and labour rights, 'sticks' could be applied in cases where the panel's
recommendations have not been implemented within a reasonable timeframe. The
sanctions could include the provisional suspension of any commitments under the trade
agreement. However, these disincentives should be applied with caution to ensure that
sanctions do not harm citizens rather than the government that has failed to meet its
commitments. For example, sticks should be introduced in cases where the EU's trading
partner has ceased to show continuous and sustained efforts, rather than in cases where
human rights are not considered to be protected to the same level as in the EU.
Specifically with regard to Dialogue and Cooperation Platforms within FTAs, more attention
should be paid to existing platforms for dialogue and cooperation, and in particular to civil
society mechanisms. Civil society should have the opportunity to be involved at every stage
of the trade agreement process, from the negotiation stage to the implementation of the
agreement. In particular, the role of workers' organisations, which are distinct from other
groups in their representational capacity, have a key role to play in monitoring respect for
labour rights in FTAs (as is notably practised in the USMCA). The institutional shortcomings
of the agreements' civil society mechanisms should be addressed, for example, by increasing
the number of meetings, by giving more importance to the civil society's feedback and by
ensuring that the EU's trading partners are endowed with a mechanism akin to the
European Economic and Social Committee (EESC), which could enable the coordination of
the partner's DAGs. Better continuity should be established between the dialogue platforms
of the trade agreements on the one hand and workers' demands and initiatives
implemented at the local level on the other. In addition, the ILO could play a robust role in
supporting EU trade partner countries through Dialogue and Cooperation Platforms.
We would, however, purposefully advise against the re-establishment of tariffs as a
potential stick, e.g. a measure to introduce higher tariffs/embargos for goods associated
with child labour and WFCL (or trade volume based on conditions). Basu and Tzannatos
(2003, p. 167) point out the danger of such an approach:
133
“Once an instrument of global action is created that can impede the flow of
goods from nations that violate minimal labour standards, it will be used as a
protectionist instrument by industrial countries, as with other measures in the
past (…) . Second, (…) international action to stop child labour in the
production of traded goods will simply drive children into the nontraded
sector, which could be worse for them.”
B. Mandatory corporate due diligence legislation
In recent years, legislative developments have been taking place in a growing number of
countries, which have introduced or are considering the introduction of legislation on
mandatory human rights and environmental due diligence. A number of recommendations
may be made to this regard:
An overarching human rights due diligence framework, accompanied by specific guidance,
performance standards and key performance indicators for certain industries with
widespread child labour in supply chains
Amongst the laws and legislative proposals on mandatory human rights due diligence
requirements in Europe, certain ones are issue-specific (e.g. the Dutch Child Labour Due
Diligence Act), while others provide for a horizontal framework for all human rights and
environmental issues (e.g. the French Duty of Vigilance Law). In a recent study for the
European Commission on Due Diligence Requirements through the Supply Chain (TorresCortés et al., 2020), stakeholders voiced a strong preference for an overarching framework
as it was felt that a focus on a specific issue, sector or commodity would create
fragmentation and could detract companies’ attention from other potentially more salient
human rights or labour rights issues for the specific company (Torres-Cortés et al., 2020, p.
142). In addition, the overall preference emerged for a regulation which would apply
regardless of size of the company but which takes into account the specificities of the
sector, and the size of the company in the implementation. However, it is recommended
that specific guidance in relation to certain industries in which widespread issues of child
labour exist in supply chains (e.g. cocoa, cotton, etc.) be issued in order to assist companies
in the implementation of their due diligence duty (Brack, 2019).
Due diligence obligations to reach entire value chains
Amongst the examples of laws and legislative proposals on mandatory human rights due
diligence, certain aim to reach the entire supply chain (e.g. the Dutch Child Labour Due
Diligence Act), whilst others cover part of the supply chain (e.g. the French Duty of Vigilance
Law) and others mostly focus on first-tier suppliers (e.g. the Draft German
Lieferkettengesetz).
In a recent letter addressed to the German Ministers on the Draft German
Lieferkettengesetz, John Ruggie, the author of the UN Guiding Principles on Business and
Human Rights, noted that:
134
Although the draft law defines the concept of supply chain broadly to include the
entire value chain, the specific obligations on companies to proactively identify risks
and take action to address them apply only to the company’s own operations and its
direct suppliers — that is, to Tier 1 suppliers. In contrast, the UNGPs and the OECD
Guidelines cover the full spectrum of value chain actors, for the simple reason that
Tier 1 suppliers typically are not the biggest source of the problem. True, this can vary
by industry sector, but for a significant number of German companies this is not
where the most severe risks will lie – for example, in footwear and apparel, food and
beverages, automobile parts, and others. A focus on Tier 1 alone would lead
companies to focus on relationships that are less likely to pose significant human
rights risks, while ignoring others (beyond Tier 1) where the probability of such risks is
higher (Ruggie, 2021).
As a result, it is crucial – in line with the international standards such as the UNGPs – that
the due diligence obligations extend to entire value chains.
Responsible purchasing practices on the part of companies
Companies’ purchasing practices may significantly contribute to breaches of labour and
human rights standards in global value chains, and may also have adverse effects on child
labour outcomes. The interpretative guide on the corporate responsibility to respect human
rights issued by the Office of the High Commissioner for Human Rights (OHCHR) mentions an
example illustrating the situation in which a company may contribute to adverse human
rights impacts:
Changing product requirements for suppliers at the eleventh hour without adjusting
production deadlines and prices, thus pushing suppliers to breach labour standards in
order to deliver (OHCHR 2012, p. 17).
Indeed, purchasing practices such as cut-throat cost negotiations, cancelled orders and
delayed payments, can trigger an increase in business pressure resulting in worker layoffs,
worker overtime, as well as a decline in worker productivity. Sudden changes to orders are
commonplace in the garment industry, and especially recently as markets recoiled due to
COVID-19 (Lewis, 2020). Last-minute changes to purchase agreements is also common in the
cocoa industry (Niava & Bayer, 2018). The common cocoa-industry practice of “revolving”
(in which orders are deliberately placed over and above what any given supplier can handle,
only to cancel them last minute) weakens a supplier’s business and negotiation position
(ibid).
The centrality of responsible purchasing practices is also acknowledged in the resolution of
the European Parliament (2020/2129(INL), Considerant 1). It is therefore recommended to
include in mandatory human rights due diligence legislation requirements for companies to
examine their own purchasing practices, as is the case in the example of the Draft German
Lieferkettengesetz.59
59 See Letter from John Ruggie to German Ministers regarding alignment of draft supply chain law with the
UNGPs (Ruggie, 2021).
135
Meaningful stakeholder consultation throughout the due diligence process
A stakeholder mapping along entire value chains will reveal not only employee groups but
also communities that have a stake in the enterprise or outcomes. In order for such
stakeholders not to become “externalities,” or, in the worst cases, collateral damage to the
operations, stakeholder consultation throughout the due diligence process is necessary.
Dissuasive sanctions and strong enforcement mechanisms
Experiences of transparency legislations with weak enforcement mechanisms such as the UK
Modern Slavery Act of 2015 have shown that the lack of strong enforcement mechanisms
and deterring sanctions can be associated with widespread issues of non-compliance
(Bright, 2021). Existing legislation and legislative proposals on mandatory human rights due
diligence legislation usually opt for one of the following two enforcement mechanisms –
which are often presented as an either-or question – either the public regulatory authority
or judicial enforcement mechanisms. It is suggested that both are needed as they play on
different levels. The public regulatory authority is helpful to ensure the monitoring of the
compliance with the law and to clarify some aspects of the law, as shown by the French
experience with the Duty of Vigilance Law. In this respect, the recent report to the French
Government on the implementation of the law mentioned that it is currently impossible to
establish a reliable list of companies who are subject to the law, and that several areas of
legal uncertainty remain. A public regulatory authority could help clarify these areas of
uncertainty, and this is the reason why the report recommended to nominate a public
authority that would be in charge of: (i) monitoring the promoting and implementation of
the law; (ii) contributing to the harmonisation of corporate practices; and (iii) promoting
sectorial and multi-party approaches. In addition, the public regulatory authority can be
empowered to exclude companies from the award of public procurement contracts (such as
in the case of the Draft German Lieferkettengesetz) which could play an important
dissuasive function and incentivise compliance by companies of their due diligence
obligations. However, even in cases where the public regulatory authority has the authority
to give sanctions such as administrative fines to companies (as is provided in the Dutch Child
Labour Due Diligence Act and in the Dutch and German draft laws), the money of the fine
does not go to the victims and, as such, it simply does not provide compensation to the
victims for the harm suffered. In this respect, judicial mechanisms can play a key role in
enhancing access to remedy for victims and overcoming recurrent barriers faced by
claimants in concrete cases (Marx et al., 2019).
Coordination through the Chief Trade Enforcement Officer (CTEO)
The EU will also have to consider how to ensure proper coordination between government
agencies and how to provide technical assistance and support to businesses wanting to
remedy situations of child labour in their supply chains. To these ends, the office of the
Chief Trade Enforcement Officer (CTEO) could play a critical role.
136
C. Lifting protection for investments into child labour sectors
The EU should reform existing and future Investment Protection Agreements (IPAs) such
that investments that take profit from child labour would not be protected under the
dispute settlement scheme established in the IPA, unless they explicitly aim at improving
working conditions, with measurable and enforced milestones. Furthermore, IPAs could, in
their articles outlining the objectives, be conditioned upon the UN Principles for Responsible
Investment (www.unpri.org).
VIII. Linkages and interactions between proposed
interventions
Once in effect, the trade regime as envisioned in this study would reinforce responsible
business conduct (RBC) and Human Rights Due Diligence (HRDD) and vice versa. While HRDD
is conducted at the individual company level, scrutinising their at-risk supply chains, the
trade regime advances targeted support, incentives and disincentives for governmentdriven action. A re-invigorated engagement on the issue from the public and private sector
would create new opportunities for public-private cooperation and synergies.
Such reinforcing engagement would also directly affect child labour outcomes. The effective
roll-out of RBC and HRDD would result in more child labour ultimately being found in the
formal sector. For example, children exposed to the Worst Forms of Child Labour would be
identified and excluded from this work. To avoid such children simply being pushed into the
informal sector, the public-sector action would need to kick in. Where social services are
insufficiently capacitated to properly support families prompted to transition, aid and
knowhow may be required. This example illustrates the need for the advised reforms
related to UNGPs Pillar I and II to advance in tandem. With the EC expected to put forward
its proposal on RBC and Due Diligence in June, 2021, now is the time to consider the
“externalities” of increased scrutiny – and in some cases increased formalisation – of labour
inputs. As the act of adopting due diligence legislation is certainly no silver bullet, both
approaches must be developed in parallel. Furthermore, FTAs must stimulate national- and
local-authority cooperation and capacity-building, e.g. in supporting citizens and CSOs,
informing them about grievance mechanisms, and helping suppliers on the ground to live up
to new or enforced production standards.
IX. WTO compatibility
Given that the impact of trade on child labour and child welfare will depend on the rules of
trade, we would be remiss not to investigate the World Trade Organization (WTO) rules
currently in place. At the WTO, member states agree upon the rules of international trade,
which are then, in turn, enforced by the WTO.
137
Attempts have been made to bake labour standards – and with it, child labour standards –
directly into the rules of the WTO, as “human rights and labour rights do not feature
explicitly in the WTO mandate” (Titievskaia et al., 2021, p.2). Notably, at the Singapore
Ministerial Declaration of 1996, academics put forward reforms for WTO rules to include a
labour rights or social clause, propositions which were summarily rejected (Joseph, 2011,
Chapter 5). Instead, WTO members passed a resolution declaring that the WTO did not have
the competence to enforce labour rights and deferred to the ILO as the supranational
agency charged with developing and monitoring core labour standards: the ILO “is the
competent body to set and deal with these standards, and we affirm our support for its
work in promoting them” (WTO, 1996). Yet in its deferral to the ILO, the multilateral group
signalled that labour issues were effectively not material trade issues, given that the ILO, as
a 3rd party, would take no active part in WTO rulemaking, nor have bearing on bilateral
trade agreement framing or dispute resolution per se.60 A few years later, “when President
Clinton and some EU leaders tried to bring workers’ rights into the next round of
multilateral trade negotiations at the 1999 WTO ministerial meeting in Seattle, developing
countries rejected the initiative” (Burtless, 2001). In sum, efforts to introduce labour
standards into the trade equations at this multilateral platform have thus far fallen short.
Writing two decades ago, Mitro’s (2002, p. 1234) synopsis still characterises the present
situation:
Thus far, developing nations have argued effectively that core labor rights provisions
actually disguise protectionist policies and erode the competitive advantage
developing nations enjoy in labor costs. In response, developed countries argue that,
if structured to avoid protectionism, fundamental labor rights can and should be
included in the WTO.
With the treatment of broader labour standards yet to be codified into WTO rules, and its
dispute settlement bodies yet to deal with international human rights issues, a prediction as
to how potential legal battles might be resolved is, “at this stage, theoretical” (Titievskaia et
al., 2021, p. 3). Put another way, the “current wording of the WTO rules leaves room for
interpretation with regard to whether measures to protect human and labour rights can be
allowed or not” (Titievskaia et al., 2021, p. 8).
Indeed, existing WTO rules allow members “to depart from the key principles,” if the traderestrictive measures demonstrate “appropriate regulatory intent,” do not constitute
“arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination between countries where the same conditions
prevail,” and are “justified under one of ten 'general exceptions' (GATT Article XX)”
(Titievskaia et al., 2021, p. 4), which is meant to constitute an exhaustive list of exceptions.
For its part, the ILO’s treatment of matters involving trade and labour rights is based on the 1998 Declaration
on Fundamental Principles and Rights at Work, which stresses that labour standards should not be used for
protectionist trade purposes, and that nothing in the Declaration and its follow-up shall be invoked or
otherwise used for such purposes (ILO, 1998); in addition, it states that the comparative advantage of any
country should in no way be called into question by this Declaration and its follow-up. Furthermore, the 2008
Social Justice Declaration states that the violation of fundamental principles and rights at work cannot be
invoked or otherwise used as a legitimate comparative advantage and that labour standards should not be
used for protectionist trade purposes (ILO, 2008).
60
138
In the absence of multilaterally-agreed upon rules, bilateral trade agreements have
expanded coverage of trade and labour issues. The U.S., for example, introduces labourrelated conditionality in its FTAs, yet within the bounds of WTO rules.
Unilateral “measures” may be justified by drawing on four existing General Agreement on
Tariffs and Trade (GATT) provisions.
1. Social dumping and unfair competition
As our child labour footprint findings revealed, the EU imported EUR 36 billion worth of
goods from China in 2019 that were reportedly produced with forced or indentured child
labour (see Table 11). The institution of unpaid pupil/student work programs could be
considered by trade partners as constituting an unfair advantage, and certainly a far cry
from the WTO-celebrated condition of a “low-wage” “comparative advantage” [see
Singapore Ministerial Declaration in 1996 (WTO, 1996)]: “We reject the use of labour
standards for protectionist purposes, and agree that the comparative advantage of
countries, particularly low-wage developing countries, must in no way be put into question.”
More specifically, one could consider the systematic institution of child labour in industrial
processes a form of “social dumping.” This term, e.g. operationally defined as “unfair
competition due to the application of different wages and social protection rules to
different categories of workers” (European Parliament, 2015), is one of four types of
dumping recognised by the WTO (along with price, service, and exchange dumping) (WTO,
1994b).
In light of Basu’s “substitution axiom,” which features a scenario where children's work
competes for wages with adults, in a free trade context, the specific firms and the Chinese
government would also benefit from the practice, as they could produce products more
cost-effectively, and possibly out-compete otherwise equal international competitors,
ceteris paribus. Such a deliberate practice, in fact, is singled out in the U.S. Trade Promotion
Authority Act of 2015, which prohibits “the diminution of labor standards to attract trade
and investment.”
This example of an “unfair advantage” associated with child labour may run counter to
existing WTO principles of fair competition. The WTO GATT (Article 6) and Anti-Dumping
Agreement together stipulate when and how countries may take action against dumping.61
In response to an unfair advantage, if the injured trade partner can demonstrate a “causal
relationship between the dumped imports and the injury to the domestic industry” (WTO,
n.d.-a), the remedy proposed by the WTO is anti-dumping action involving “charging extra
import duty on the particular product from the particular exporting country in order to bring
its price closer to the ‘normal value’ or to remove the injury to domestic industry in the
importing country” (WTO, n.d.-c).
61
See definition of dumping as per the Agreement on Implementation of Article VI of the General Agreement
on Tariffs and Trade 1994, Part I: Article 2 – Determination of Dumping: “2.1 For the purpose of this
Agreement, a product is to be considered as being dumped, i.e. introduced into the commerce of another
country at less than its normal value, if the export price of the product exported from one country to another
is less than the comparable price, in the ordinary course of trade, for the like product when destined for
consumption in the exporting country” (WTO, 1994a).
139
It is, however, a big “if.” In the 2017 WTO Arbitral Panel established to arbitrate between
the Dominican Republic and the U.S. in their trade dispute, the panel noted that a “failure to
effectively enforce labor laws will not necessarily result in lower prices or altered trade
flows” (Arbitral Panel, 2017, para. 177).62 In a real-world scenario, for example, the social
dumping perpetrator could simply pocket the margin. Moreover, the panel observed that an
attempt to “establish that an effect on prices is due to a failure to enforce and not to such
other factors” would effectively comprise an effort in futility (Arbitral Panel, 2017, para.
178).63 Furthermore, “even if such information were available, the effects of a failure to
effectively enforce labor laws may be impossible to quantify with sufficient precision to
attribute any particular price reduction or increase in sales volumes to them.”
Yet one social dumping exception is explicitly permitted by GATT: Article XX(e) allows states
to exclude the products of prison labour – the only labour-related exception highlighted in
the GATT Agreement. In order to invoke the Article XX(e) exception from the mostfavoured-nation clause, the complaining party would have to prove the alleged violation
(Trebilcock & Howse, 1995). As interpreted by Mansoor (2004), “Article XX(e) was conceived
as protection against unfair competition deriving from the low costs of prison labour,” with
which “no private company would be able to compete.” However, as the text explicitly
refers to the products of prison labour rather then the labour conditions under which they
are produced – thus confirming its indifference towards the methods of production (Diller &
Levy, 1997) – it is uncertain whether the products of forced labour in a non-prison-context
may be also considered in-scope of Article XX(e), their market-distorting function
notwithstanding.
2. Child labour threatening the health of children
The practice of the worst forms of child labour – which includes labour that impairs the
health of the child – may be in-scope of a WTO rule exception. GATT Article XX(b) reads:
“nothing in this Agreement [the GATT] shall be construed to prevent the adoption or
enforcement by any contracting party of measures: (...) (b) necessary to protect human,
animal or plant life or health” (WTO, 1994c). In theory, a trade partner could unilaterally
take action (for instance, banning products made by child labour) and justify their action
under GATT Article XX(b), as long as the overriding “chapeau” was upheld, i.e. that the
country taking measures was not applying the exception “arbitrarily or unjustifiably[,]
“Cost savings resulting from a Party’s failure to effectively enforce may or may not be passed on to
customers. They may instead be retained as increased profits. Further, even if they were passed on to
customers, they may be counteracted by price effects in the opposite direction due to a myriad of factors such
as currency exchange rate fluctuations, increases in costs of material inputs, capital equipment or
transportation” (Arbitral Panel, 2017, para. 177).
63 Attempting “to establish that an effect on prices is due to a failure to enforce and not to such other factors
would often be so fraught with difficulty as to make proof of trade effects impossible. Even if information on
final product or service prices is available […] through public sources, information on such matters as costs of
material inputs, capital equipment or transportation will typically not be publicly available, but rather only
available from the employer or employers allegedly benefitting from the alleged failure to enforce. As
discussed in our preliminary ruling of February 17, 2015, the Agreement and the Rules do not grant powers to
a panel to compel disclosure of such information. Nor do they grant such powers to any other body. A
complaining Party may therefore find itself unable to obtain economic information from the relevant
employers. Further, even if such information were available, the effects of a failure to effectively enforce labor
laws may be impossible to quantify with sufficient precision to attribute any particular price reduction or
increase in sales volumes to them” (Arbitral Panel, 2017, para. 178).
62
140
resulting in discrimination between those countries where same conditions prevail and that
the measures [did] not amount to ‘disguised restrictions on the international trade’” (WTO,
1994c). In his analysis, Vanpeperstraete (2021, p.16) concludes that: “Article XX(b) can be
interpreted to cover policy concerns such as forced labour [and] child labour […], which can
be captured by either universal instruments or widely ratified conventions established by
the UN or the ILO. In such cases, a unilateral import ban will be likely to be considered an
acceptable policy tool.” Mitro (2002, p. 1242) further clarifies that for a legislative measure
to meet the Article XX(b) exception, “child labor must be a legitimate health concern and
the restriction contained in the [legislation] must be essential to achieving the stated
objective.”
3. Public morals
Furthermore, WTO members may restrict trade on moral grounds under Article XX(a)
regarding the protection of "public morals." Interestingly, with the insertion of the public
moral exception clause in the GATT in 1945, the drafters did not define or clarify the
meaning of “public morals” (Wu, 2008). This ambiguity thus offers some freedom of
interpretation. One example constitutes the case of seal products: “Article XX(a), was
invoked, for instance, by the European Communities to justify a general ban on the
marketing of seal products following the moral outrage caused by the inhumane killing of
seals. The WTO Appellate Body endorsed the EU ban in its final ruling, but emphasised that
the measure had to be fully non-discriminatory” (Titievskaia et al., 2021, p. 5). If WTO
members were to justify its measure under Article XX(a) – as with any invocation of “Article
XX(b), the requirements of the overriding “chapeau” must be satisfied.
Wu (2008, p. 221) observes that multilateral and bilateral agreements have routinely
included a public morals provision: “Today, incorporating a public morals exception clause
into an international trade agreement has become nearly a standard practice. Almost one
hundred trade treaties now include such a clause.” At the bilateral level, the U.S. and the EU
both commonly include a public morals exception into their trade agreements. To date, the
U.S. has banned products made with indentured child labour on the grounds of protecting
public morality, an exception to GATT not challenged by other states (Wu, 2008, p. 223). As
previously discussed, the U.S. is affecting import bans through the amended U.S. Tariff Act
of 1930, which explicitly targets and bans the importation of products having been
produced with forced or indentured adult or child labour. Furthermore, in 1997, U.S.
Congress banned products made by indentured child labor as per the Treasury and General
Government Appropriations Act (1997). This particular enforced “trade barrier” has not
been challenged in the WTO dispute settlement system. Thus, especially with regard to
cases involving the worst forms of child labour, which on a regular basis produces moral
outrage in its citizenry, the EU would stand on solid ground in its invocation of an exception
as per Article XX(a).
4. Law of Treaties and ILO C182
As explained by the European Parliamentary Research Service, one potential legal theory
involves the Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties (VCLT) (UN, 1969). Created in 1969
and entered into force in 1980, a principle enshrined in the VCLT “provides that 'any
relevant rules of international law applicable in the relations between the parties' have to
be taken into account when interpreting a treaty (Article 31(3)(c))” (Titievskaia et al., 2021,
p. 3). In its GATT Article XX, WTO rules do, in fact, recognise “measures” “to secure
141
compliance with laws or regulations which are not inconsistent with the provisions of this
Agreement” (WTO, 1994c, para. 562).64
However, a number of issues are associated with such an approach:
1) Only “those norms to which all WTO members have subscribed are relevant when
interpreting WTO rules” (Titievskaia et al., 2021, p. 4) (ILO Convention 182 would,
however, meet even such a strict interpretation – see Table 21 below).
2) “Not all countries have signed and ratified the Vienna Convention (including EU
Member States France and Romania)” (Titievskaia et al., 2021, p. 4).
3) The Law of Treaties 'applies to treaties between States' according to its Article 1, and
a “1986 extension of the convention to cover international organisations such as the
EU has not yet reached the necessary minimum number of ratifications to enter into
force and the EU has not signed it” (Titievskaia et al., 2021, p. 4).
Table 21: Membership and Ratifications
body / instrument
nation-states
WTO
164 members
Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties 1969
ILO C182
116 ratifications
187 ratifications (out of 187 eligible)
UN CRC
196 ratifications (out of 197 eligible, with only
the U.S. abstaining)
Source: Ratification by Convention (ILO, n.d.-c), URL; United Nations Treaty Collection: 11. Convention of the Rights of the
Child (UN, 2021a), URL; United Nations Treaty Collection: 1. Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties, (UN, 2021b), URL &
Members and Observers (WTO, 2016), URL.
Based on the above analysis, the EU has, in fact, two legal theories premised on GATT Article
XX(a) “public morals” and GATT Article XX(b) “health protection” with which it would have
the best chances of justifying (1) enforcement in its bilateral trade agreements, as well as (2)
surgical import bans.
Multilaterally-driven reform
Yet in order to create a more level, multilateral playing field for all actors at the trade table,
reform premised on sustainable development may be worth pursuing.
The Preamble to the agreement establishing the WTO refers to the objective of improving
living standards and sustainable development. In light of many existential threats to the
body, including “the fact that topics such as environmental degradation, climate change or
decent work are considered taboo” (European Commission, 2021d, p. 6), the EU Trade
64 GATT Article XX itself stipulates that “nothing in this Agreement
shall be construed to prevent the adoption
or enforcement by any contracting party of measures:” (…) “(d) necessary to secure compliance with laws or
regulations which are not inconsistent with the provisions of this Agreement, including those relating to
customs enforcement, the enforcement of monopolies operated under paragraph 4 of Article II and Article
XVII, the protection of patents, trade marks and copyrights, and the prevention of deceptive
practices[.]”(WTO, 1994c).
142
Policy Review argues that sustainability threats pose risks requiring concerted, all-hands-ondeck action:
As global challenges proliferate, WTO members should be able to coalesce around
the objective of addressing the most pressing problems they face: economic recovery
and development, free from competitive distortions, as well as environmental and
social sustainability as part of the green transition of economies. Addressing these
problems would be in line with the objectives of the UN Sustainable Development
Goals (the ‘SDGs’), to which all WTO members have committed (European
Commission, 2021d, p. 6).
Potential reform to the WTO, according to the EU, could recognise the role that labour
standards play in sustainable development:
Instead of trade policies focusing primarily on economic growth, broader trade policy
objectives that acknowledge the importance of human and labour rights could
accelerate the achievement of the United Nations sustainable development goals
(SDGs). In a globalised world, trade, economic growth, labour rights and human
rights are deeply intertwined. (Titievskaia et al., 2021, p. 2)
X. About the Authors
Dr. Chris N. Bayer is Principal Investigator at Development International e.V. He earned his
PhD in International Development from Tulane University in 2014.
Dr. Claire Bright is an Assistant Professor in Private Law at Nova Law School in Lisbon, as well
as an Associate Research Fellow at the British Institute of International and Comparative
Law (BIICL). She received her PhD in Law from the European University Institute in 2013.
Dr. Irene Pietropaoli is a Research Fellow at the British Institute of International and
Comparative Law (BIICL). She earned her PhD in Law at Middlesex University in 2017.
Eliana Gonzalez Torres is a graduate student pursuing a Master in International Accounting
at the Universidad de Buenos Aires.
Justine Vinet, LLM, is a trainee-lawyer in human rights and criminal law at the École de
Formation professionnelle des Barreaux du ressort de la cour d'appel de Paris (EFB). She
received a Master of Laws (LLM) King's College London in 2019, and a Master of Human
Rights and Humanitarian Law at the Université Paris 2 Panthéon-Assas in 2021.
Dr. Derrill D. Watson II is an Associate Professor of Economics & Department Head of the
Department of Accounting, Finance, and Economics at Tarleton State University in Texas. He
earned a PhD in Economics from Cornell University in 2009.
143
XI. About Development International e.V.
The non-profit organisation Development International (DI) e.V., registered in Germany,
implements research at the intersection of law, business and development since 2014. DI’s
mission is to provide independent and scientific assessment, clarity and accuracy on issues
with an empirical deficit, thus enabling constructive discussions. We also develop and
implement intervention strategies and evidence-based solutions to achieve sustainable
development outcomes, and build capacity to transfer knowledge and skills to other
stakeholders throughout the process.
On the web, DI is located at: https://www.developmentinternational.org
144
Annex I – Child labour metrics
The following four entities either themselves systematically collect data, and/or compile
primary data in order to create relevant metrics.
1. UNICEF
data issuer
United Nations International Children's Emergency Fund (UNICEF)
database name
UNICEF Data Warehouse
key metric
Child labour prevalence per country: “Percentage of children (aged 517 years) engaged in child labour (economic activities).”
Based on Multiple Indicator Cluster Survey (MICS) data.
underlying data
source(s)
year(s) of
availability
Notes
The Excel database features data from 2010-2019.
The MICS data include a number of child welfare indicators, including
infant mortality, education, water and sanitation, malnutrition,
immunisation, health, childbirth, family planning and child labour, but
current data are lacking for many countries.
MICS data on child labour concern children 5 to 17 years old, the type
of work and number of hours, but also concerns domestic work
(chores). While it is possible to separate out household chores from
economic activities, only a few countries are represented.
The MICS module on child labour has also been adopted by the
Demographic and Health Surveys (DHS) in its questionnaires.
2. Maplecroft
data issuer
Maplecroft
database name
Child Labour Index
key metric
An index measure of child labour risk (scale 1-10), comprised of 3
components: (1) legal framework, (2) enforcement, (3) frequency of
violations, provided for the following units:
● per country / subnational
● per industry / sector
● per commodity
The index is based on primary data drawn from the ILO, UN, USDOL,
U.S. State Department, World Bank, and others.
Updated quarterly, current.
underlying data
source(s)
year(s) of
availability
145
notes
This index is proprietary, the underlying methods are not public, and
thus not subjected to peer review.
3. ILO
data issuer
International Labour Organization (ILO)
database name
database: ILOSTAT explorer
key metric(s)
The ILOSTAT explorer features child labour prevalence estimates
provided by the ILO and UNICEF, disaggregated by country.
underlying data
source(s)
year(s) of
availability
notes
The ILO’s 2016 Global Estimates of Child Labour report features child
labour prevalence estimates, organised according to:
- region (rather than by country). It measures the incidence (along
with modalities including age, gender, sector), causes (low, middle,
high national income; fragility/crisis) and consequences of child
labour.
- sector: focused on agriculture, industry and services.
The ILOSTAT draws on data generated by its Statistical Information and
Monitoring Programme on Child Labour (SIMPOC).
However, the ILO’s 2016 report was produced also with other data
sources. It is based on national data sets from 105 countries, with the
majority referring to the target reference period 2012 to 2016. They
include national data sets derived from:
- child labour surveys implemented by the ILO;
- MICS, implemented with the assistance of UNICEF;
- demographic and health surveys (DHS);
- national labour force surveys (LFS).
The 2016 estimates were then compared with UNESCO data on school
attendance and national trend in child labour.
The periodicity is annual, providing a data range from 2010 to 2016.
According to UNICEF, SIMPOC estimates are calculated on the basis of
the definition used in the national legislation of individual countries.
Accordingly, the definition of child labour that is used to calculate child
labour estimates differs markedly among countries, as do the resulting
estimates.
4. World Bank
data issuer
World Bank
database name
Understanding Children's Work
146
key metric
Children in employment, total (% of children ages 7-14), per country.
underlying data
source(s)
The Understanding Children's Work project is based on household
surveys, working in conjunction with the ILO, UNICEF, World Bank and
national statistical offices. Pertinent World Bank data is drawn from
Living Standards Measurement Study surveys (LSMS).65
While the periodicity is annual, the most recent data are from 2016.
year(s) of
availability
notes
The metric “children in employment” refers to children involved in
economic activity for at least one hour in the reference week of the
survey.66
In order to derive the measure of child labour prevalence, representative data are required,
which in turn are derived from three types of surveys: (1) labour force surveys collecting
detailed information on the various types of work in which children participate, (2)
multipurpose household surveys (e.g. LSMS), which include details about the child’s
environment, and (3) population censuses, which commonly cover the economic activities
of the family, including children. The World Bank, ILO and UNICEF produce child labour
prevalence measures. Keeping track of child labour information published by 3rd-party
annual reports and collecting anecdotal evidence allows Maplecroft to provide quarterly
updates, which serves as a useful trend monitoring tool. Their Child Labour Index values are,
however, not designed to collect representative data on child labour.
65 LSMS is a type of survey which aims to “collect household data that can be used to assess household
welfare, to understand household behaviour and to evaluate the effect of various government policies on the
living conditions of the population. LSMS surveys, given their objective, collect data on many dimensions of
household well-being (consumption, income, savings, employment, health, education, fertility, nutrition,
housing and migration). Information on children’s activities is therefore available in economic activity and
other modules” (ILO/IPEC & SIMPOC, 2007).
66 “In line with the definition of economic activity adopted by the 13th International Conference of Labour
Statisticians, the threshold set by the 1993 UN System of National Accounts for classifying a person as
employed is to have been engaged at least one hour in any activity relating to the production of goods and
services during the reference period. Since children's work is captured in the sense of "economic activity," the
data refer to children in employment, a broader concept than child labor (see ILO 2009a for details on this
distinction)” (The World Bank, 2021).
147
Annex II – EU imports associated with child labour
Table 22: EU Imports Associated With Child Labour – Example of Cocoa, Cotton, Rice, Sugar Cane, and Tobacco
Commodity associated with
child labour as per USDOL
Country associated with
child labour as per
USDOL
Child labour prevalence (%)
as per UNICEF (year of
data)
Value of EU import possibly
produced with child labour
(EUR)
Cocoa
Brazil
no data
3,896,408.78
Cocoa
Cameroon
no data
60,827,393.28
Cocoa
Côte d’Ivoire
17,5 (2016)
373,203,085.08
Cocoa
Ghana
no data
142,485,459.72
Cocoa
Guinea
19,5 (2016)
2,606,866.08
Cocoa
Nigeria
28,7 (2017)
62,051,710.68
Cocoa
Sierra Leone
21 (2017)
Cotton
Argentina
no data
64,372.44
Cotton
Azerbaijan
no data
10,478.07
Cotton
Benin
17 (2018)
Cotton
Brazil
no data
7,091,689.44
Cotton
Burkina Faso
no data
251,378.04
Cotton
China
no data
108,301,926.98
Cotton
Egypt
no data
9,971,516.52
Cotton
India
no data
49,860,002.40
Cotton
Kazakhstan
no data
2,067,337.20
Cotton
Kyrgyzstan
20,1 (2018)
91,860.00
Cotton
Mali
10,4 (2017)
746,814.00
Cotton
Tajikistan
no data
169,598.28
Cotton
Turkey
no data
67,641,399.09
Cotton
Turkmenistan
0,3 (2016)
Cotton
Zambia
no data
11,357.40
Rice
Brazil
no data
117,920.88
Rice
Myanmar (Burma)
no data
41,858,855.22
Rice
India
no data
26,767,071.48
Rice
India
no data
224.9
3,738,456.48
269,998.56
734,713.20
148
Rice
Viet Nam
no data
7,420,081.5
Sugarcane/ canesugar
Belize
no data
12,223,664.64
Sugarcane/ canesugar
Bolivia
no data
1,655.94
Sugarcane/ canesugar
Brazil
no data
16,917,509.40
Sugarcane/ canesugar
Burma
no data
462.28
Sugarcane/ canesugar
Cambodia
no data
2,022,275.84
Sugarcane/ canesugar
Colombia
2,9 (2017)
5,017,867.36
Sugarcane/ canesugar
Dominican Republic
no data
1769.90
Sugarcane/ canesugar
El Salvador
no data
2,039,667.74
Sugarcane/ canesugar
Guatemala
no data
2,315,595.48
Sugarcane/ canesugar
India
no data
2,315,595.48
Sugarcane/ canesugar
Mexico
3,6 (2017)
Sugarcane/ canesugar
Paraguay
15,5 (2016)
Sugarcane/ canesugar
Philippines
no data
615,496.96
Sugarcane/ canesugar
Thailand
no data
77,309.18
Sugarcane/ canesugar
Uganda
13,2 (2017)
23,389.08
Sugarcane/ canesugar
Viet Nam
no data
27,319.24
Sugarcane/ canesugar
Zimbabwe
25,6 (2019)
Tobacco
Argentina
no data
15,261,920.96
Tobacco
Brazil
no data
119,525,577.60
Tobacco
Cambodia
no data
141,519.04
Tobacco
Indonesia
no data
34,566,121.20
Tobacco
Kenya
no data
2,204,863.92
Tobacco
Kyrgyz Republic
20.1 (2018)
Tobacco
Lebanon
no data
1,571,229.18
Tobacco
Malawi
no data
28,097,531.76
Tobacco
Mexico
3,6 (2017)
Tobacco
Mozambique
no data
15,620,809.08
Tobacco
Nicaragua
no data
3,262,928.02
Tobacco
Philippines
no data
11,390,374.06
Tobacco
Tanzania
no data
12,201,226.92
134.24
3,072,744.62
742,150.92
60,765.24
2,277,378.84
149
Tobacco
Uganda
13,2 (2017)
Tobacco
Viet Nam
no data
87,419.28
Tobacco
Zambia
no data
5,090,926.32
Tobacco
Zimbabwe
25.6 (2019)
See our application for further details on other goods and products.
242,625.00
12,798,542.88
150
Annex III – Examples of TSD Chapters
Table 23: Treatment of Child Labour in TDS Chapters
Partner
country
Type of
treaty
Year of
Signature
Dispositions on child labour in TSD chapters
(into force)
Disposition excluding dispute settlement
procedures
(TSD chapters as non-enforceable dispositions)
Korea
FTA
2010 (2015)
Chapter 13, art. 13.4 §3 (c): “The Parties, in accordance with the
obligations deriving from membership of the ILO and the ILO
Declaration on Fundamental Principles and Rights at Work and its
Follow-up, adopted by the International Labour Conference at its
86th Session in 1998, commit to respecting, promoting and
realising, in their laws and practices, the principles concerning the
fundamental rights, namely: (…)
(c) the effective abolition of child labour (…)”.
Art. 13.16: “For any matter arising under this Chapter, the
Parties shall only have recourse to the procedures provided for
in Articles 13.14 and 13.15”.
Art. 13.14 addresses government consultations, whilst art.
13.15 deals with a panel of experts.
Central
America
EU
Association
Agreement
(AA)
2012 (2013)
Title VIII, art. 286.1: the Parties “reaffirm their commitments to
respect, promote, and realise in good faith and in accordance with
the ILO Constitution, the principles concerning the fundamental
rights which are the subject of the fundamental ILO Conventions,
namely: (…) (c) the effective abolition of child labour”.
Art. 284.4: “The Parties shall not have recourse to dispute
settlement procedures under Title X (Dispute Settlement) of
Part IV of this Agreement and to the Mediation Mechanism
for Non-Tariff Measures under Title XI (Mediation Mechanism
for Non-Tariff Measures) of Part IV of this Agreement for
matters arising under this Title.”
Title VIII, art. 286.2: “the Parties reaffirm their commitment to
effectively implement in their laws and practice the fundamental
ILO Conventions contained in the ILO Declaration of Fundamental
Principles and Rights at Work of 1998, which are the following:
(…) (b) Convention 182 concerning the Prohibition and Immediate
Action for the Elimination of the Worst Forms of Child Labour”.
NB: in title III (Social development and social cohesion), art. 42
also states that: “The Parties agree to cooperate in order to
promote employment and social protection through actions and
programmes, which aim in particular to: (…)(f) ensure the respect
151
for the fundamental principles and rights at work identified by the
International Labour Organization's Conventions, the so-called
Core Labour Standards, in particular as regards the freedom of
association, the right to collective bargaining and nondiscrimination, the abolition of forced and child”.
In title IV (Economic development), art. 63.2 (on Cooperation and
Technical Assistance on Trade and Sustainable Development),
parties agree to cooperate on : “(…) (e) strengthening institutional
frameworks, development and implementation of policies and
programs regarding Fundamental Principles and Rights at Work
(freedom of association and collective bargaining, forced labour,
child labour, no employment discrimination) and the
implementation and enforcement of International Labour
Organization (hereinafter referred to as "ILO") conventions and
labour laws, as agreed by the Parties”
Georgia
AA inc. the
Comprehen
sive and
Free Trade
Areas
(DCFTA)
2014 (2016)
Chapter 13, art. 229.2 (c): same wording i.e. “commit to
respecting, promoting and realizing (…) the effective abolition of
child labour”.
Art. 242 (referring to art. 242 addressing government
consultations, and art. 243 dealing with a panel of experts).
Moldova
AA inc.
DCFTA
2014 (2016)
Chapter 13, art. 365.2 (c): ibid.
Art. 378 (referring to art. 378 addressing government
consultations, and art. 379 dealing with a panel of experts).
NB: in Chapter 27 (Cooperation in the protection and promotion
of the rights of the child), art. 238 (a) also states that: “such
cooperation shall include, in particular: (a) the prevention and
combating of all forms of exploitation (including child labour),
abuse, negligence and violence against children, including by
developing and strengthening the legal and institutional
framework as well as through awareness-raising campaigns in
that domain”.
152
Ukraine
AA inc.
DCFTA
2014 (2017)
Chapter 13, art. 291.2 (c): “The Parties shall promote and
implement in their laws and practices the internationally
recognised core labour standards, namely: (…) effective abolition
of child labour (…)”.
Art. 300.7 (referring to art. 300 addressing institutional and
monitoring mechanisms, and art. 301 dealing with the group
of experts).
Japan
Economic
Partnership
Agreement
(EPA)
2018 (2019)
Chapter 16, art. 16.3 (c): “(…) the Parties shall respect, promote
and realise in their laws, regulations and practices the
internationally recognised principles concerning the fundamental
rights at work, which are: (…) effective abolition of child labour
(…).”
Art. 16.17 (referring to art. 16.17 addressing government
consultations, and art. 16.18 dealing with a panel of experts).
Singapore
FTA
2018 (2019)
Chapter 12, art. 12.3 §3 (c): “commit to respecting, promoting and
realizing (…) the effective abolition of child labour”.
Art. 12.16: “In case of disagreement on any matter arising
under this Chapter, the Parties shall only have recourse to the
procedures provided for in Article 12.16 (Government
Consultations) and Article 12.17 (Panel of Experts).”
Viet Nam
FTA
2019 (2020)
Chapter 13, art. 13.4 §3 (c): “to respect, promote and effectively
implement the principles concerning the fundamental rights at
work, namely: (…) the effective abolition of child labour”.
Art. 13.16 (government consultations: “In the event of
disagreement on any matter covered under this Chapter, the
Parties shall only have recourse to the procedures established
under this Article and Article 13.17 (Panel of Experts). Except
as otherwise provided for in this Chapter, Chapter 15 (Dispute
Settlement) and its Annex 15-C (Mediation Mechanism) do not
apply to this Chapter. Annex 15-A (Rules of Procedure) applies
mutatis mutandis in accordance with paragraph 2 of Article
13.17 (Panel of Experts)”.
153
Bibliography
ActionAid, Les Amis de la Terre France, Amnesty International, Terre Solidaire, Collectif
Ethique sur l’Etiquette, & Sherpa. (2019). The Law on the Duty of Vigilance of Parent
and Outsourcing Companies – Year 1: Companies must do better.
https://respect.international/the-law-on-duty-of-vigilance-of-parent-and-outsourcingcompanies-year-1-companies-must-do-better/
Ahmed, I. (1999). Getting Rid Of Child Labour. Economic and Political Weekly, 34(27), 1815–
1822. https://www.epw.in/journal/1999/27/special-articles/getting-rid-childlabour.html
Akerlof, G. A. (1982). Labor Contracts as Partial Gift Exchange. The Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 97(4), 543. https://doi.org/10.2307/1885099
Alkire, S., & Foster, J. (2011). Counting and multidimensional poverty measurement. Journal
of Public Economics, 95(7–8), 476–487. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2010.11.006
Alsamawi, A., Bule, T., Cappa, C., Cook, H., Galez-Davis, C., & Saiovici, G. (2019). Measuring
child labour, forced labour and human trafficking in global supply chains: A global
input-output approach. Technical Paper.
https://www.ilo.org/ipec/Informationresources/WCMS_733916/lang--en/index.htm
Anker, R., & Anker, M. (2017). Living Wages Around the World. Edward Elgar Publishing.
https://doi.org/10.4337/9781786431462
Arbitral Panel. (2017). In the matter of Guatemala – Issues relating to the obligations under
article 16.2.1(a) of the CAFTA-DR - Final report of the Panel.
http://www.sice.oas.org/tpd/usa_cafta/Dispute_Settlement/final_panel_report_guat
emala_Art_16_2_1_a_e.pdf
Barbu, M., Campling, L., Ebert, F., Harrison, J., Martens, D., Marx, A., Orbie, J., Richardson,
B., & Smith, A. (2017). A response to the non-paper of the European Commission on
Trade and Sustainable Development (TSD) chapters in EU Free Trade Agreements
(FTAs). https://www.qmul.ac.uk/geog/media/geography/docs/research/workingbeyond-the-border/A-Response-to-the-Nonpaper-26.09.17.pdf
Barraud de Lagerie, P., Bethoux, E., Bourguignon, R., Mias, A., & Penalva-Icher, É. (2020).
Mise en oeuvre de la Loi sur le devoir de vigilance Rapport sur les premiers plans
adoptés par les entreprises [Implementation of the Due Diligence Act Report on the
first plans adopted by companies]. In Bureau International du Travail.
https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-02819496
Basu, K. (1999). Child labor: Cause, consequence, and cure, with remarks on international
labor standards. Journal of Economic Literature, 37(3), 1083–1119.
https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.37.3.1083
Basu, K., & Tzannatos, Z. (2003). The global child labor problem: What do we know and what
can we do?. World Bank Economic Review, 17(2), 147–173.
https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/lhg021
154
Basu, K., & Van, P. H. (1998). The Economics of Child Labor. American Economic Review,
88(3), 412–427. https://doi.org/10.4337/9781781953068.00025
Basu, K., & Zarghamee, H. (2009). Is product boycott a good idea for controlling child labor?
A theoretical investigation. Journal of Development Economics, 88(2), 217–220.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2008.09.002
Bayer, C. N. (2014). The Effects Of Child Labor Monitoring On Knowledge, Attitude And
Practices In Cocoa Growing Communities Of Ghana. In Tulane University.
https://digitallibrary.tulane.edu/islandora/object/tulane%3A27805
Bayer, C. N. (2016). Corporate liabilities for modern-day slavery in supply and service chains:
A transnational framework. https://www.ipointsystems.com/fileadmin/media_elrt/Downloads/eLRT_Liability_Framework_20161110
_WEB.pdf
Bayer, C. N. (2021). Duty of Care Also in Germany: The Impending Mandatory Due Diligence
Legislation [Blog Post]. IPoint. https://www.ipoint-systems.com/blog/duty-of-carealso-in-germany/
Ben-Houassa, K. E. (2011). Adoption levels of demand of fertilizer in cocoa farming in Cote
d’Ivoire: Does risk aversion matter? Paper Selected for Presentation at the CSAE
Conference on Economic Development in Africa Held at St Catherine’s College, Oxford.
Bell, S. L. (2016). The US Prohibition on Imports Made with Forced Labour: The New Law Is a
“Force” to Be Reckoned With. Global Trade and Customs Journal, 11(11/12), 580–583.
https://kluwerlawonline.com/journalarticle/Global+Trade+and+Customs+Journal/11.1
1/GTCJ2016073
Bhalotra, S., & Heady, C. (2003). Child farm labor: The wealth paradox. The World Bank
Economic Review, 17(2), 197–227. https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/lhg017
Bharadwaj, P., Lakdawala, L. K., & LI, N. (2016). Perverse Consequences Of Well-Intentioned
Regulation: Evidence From India’S Child Labor Ban. Discussion Paper Series, HIAS-E-25.
https://ideas.repec.org/p/hit/hiasdp/hias-e-25.html
Bipartisan Trade Promotion Authority Act, 19 U.S.C § 3801 (2002).
https://www.congress.gov/107/plaws/publ210/PLAW-107publ210.pdf
Bloomer, P. (2020). Europe’s new law to end corporate abuse should learn from Obama’s
legacy [Blog post]. Business & Human Rights Resource Centre. https://www.businesshumanrights.org/en/blog/obamas-legacy-for-europes-corporate-law/
Borchert, I., Conconi, P., Ubaldo, M. Di, & Herghelegiu, C. (2020). The Pursuit of Non-Trade
Policy Objectives in EU Trade Policy. Working Papers ECARES.
https://ideas.repec.org/p/eca/wpaper/2013-304060.html
Borino, F. (2018). Piece rate pay and working conditions in the export garment sector (No.
28; Discussion Paper). https://www.ilo.org/global/about-the-ilo/how-the-iloworks/departments-and-offices/governance/betterwork/WCMS_663063/lang-en/index.htm
155
Brack, D. (2019). Towards sustainable cocoa supply chains: Regulatory options for the EU
Executive Summary. https://fairtrade-advocacy.org/wpcontent/uploads/2019/07/Cocoa-Options-ExSum-web-A4.pdf
Bright, C., & Macchi, C. (2020). Hardening Soft Law: The Implementation of Human Rights
Due Diligence Requirements in Domestic Legislation. In M. Buscemi, N. Lazzerini, L.
Magi, & D. Russo (Eds.), Legal Sources in Business and Human Rights - Evolving
Dynamics in International and European Law. Brill.
https://brill.com/view/title/55086?contents=editorial-content
Bright, C. (2021). Mapping human rights due diligence regulations and evaluating their
contribution in upholding labour standards in global supply chains. In G. Delautre, E.
Echeverría Manrique, & C. Fenwick (Eds.), Decent work in globalised economy: Lessons
from public and private initiatives (p. 356). International Labour Office.
https://www.ilo.org/global/publications/books/WCMS_771481/lang--en/index.htm
Brudney, A. (2020). Using the Master’s Tools to Dismantle the Master’s House: 307 Petitions
as a Human Rights Tool [Blog post]. Corporate Accountability Lab.
https://corpaccountabilitylab.org/calblog/2020/8/28/using-the-masters-tools-todismantle-the-masters-house-307-petitions-as-a-human-rights-tool
Brunt, M. (2021). Boohoo facing possible US import ban after allegations over use of slave
labour. Sky News. https://news.sky.com/story/boohoo-facing-possible-us-import-banafter-allegations-over-use-of-slave-labour-12232343
Bueno, N. (2019). The Swiss Popular Initiative on Responsible Business. In Accountability,
International Business Operations, and the Law (pp. 239–258). Routledge.
https://doi.org/10.4324/9781351127165-12
Bureau of International Labor Affairs. (n.d.-a). Organization Chart. U.S. Department of Labor.
Retrieved May 13, 2021, from https://www.dol.gov/agencies/ilab/aboutus/organization#
Bureau of International Labor Affairs. (n.d.-b). Trade Negotiation & Enforcement. U.S.
Department of Labor. Retrieved May 13, 2021, from
https://www.dol.gov/agencies/ilab/our-work/trade
Burtless, G. (2001). Workers’ Rights: Labor standards and global trade. Brookings.
https://www.brookings.edu/articles/workers-rights-labor-standards-and-global-trade/
Cartwright, K. (1998). Child Labor in Colombia. In The Policy Analysis of Child Labor: A
Comparative Study. World Bank.
Chamberlain, G. (2019). Schoolchildren in China work overnight to produce Amazon Alexa
devices. The Guardian. https://www.theguardian.com/globaldevelopment/2019/aug/08/schoolchildren-in-china-work-overnight-to-produceamazon-alexa-devices
Child labour on the rise among vulnerable communities in T.N.: study. (2021). The Hindu.
https://www.thehindu.com/news/national/tamil-nadu/child-labour-on-the-riseamong-vulnerable-communities-in-tn-study/article33987590.ece
156
Choy, N. (2020). Top Glove to pay RM136m in remediation fees to migrant workers. The
Business Times. https://www.businesstimes.com.sg/companies-markets/top-glove-topay-rm136m-in-remediation-fees-to-migrant-workers
Code de Commerce [C. Com.] [Commercial Code] art. L225-102-4 (Fr.).
https://www.legifrance.gouv.fr/codes/article_lc/LEGIARTI000035181820/
Congressional Research Service. (2020). Worker Rights Provisions in Free Trade Agreements
(FTAs). https://crsreports.congress.gov
Congressional Research Service. (2021a). Section 307 and Imports Produced by Forced Labor.
https://crsreports.congress.gov/product/pdf/IF/IF11360
Congressional Research Service. (2021b). Section 307 and U.S. Imports of Products of Forced
Labor: Overview and Issues for Congress. https://crsreports.congress.gov
Connellan, C., Hussain, T., Barclay, D. A., Holland, E., Kepkay, A., & Toabe, A. (2019). US
Customs & Border Protection Enforces Forced Labor Prohibition in First Action Against
Vessel.
https://www.whitecase.com/sites/whitecase/files/files/download/publications/uscustoms-and-border-protection-enforces-forced-labor-prohibition-in-first-actionagainst-vessel.pdf
Consolidated version of the Treaty on European Union. OJ C 326, 26.10.2012. https://eurlex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=celex%3A12012M%2FTXT
Coppedge, M., Gerring, J., Knutsen, C. H., Lindberg, S. I., Teorell, J., Altman, D., Bernhard, M.,
Cornell, A., Fish, M. S., Gastaldi, L., Gjerløw, H., Glynn, A., Hicken, A., Lührmann, A.,
Maerz, S. F., Marquardt, K. M., McMann, K. M., Mechkova, V., Paxton, P., … Ziblatt, D.
(2021). V-Dem Codebook v11. SSRN Electronic Journal, 427.
https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3802627
Council Decision (CFSP) 2020/1999 of 7 December 2020 concerning restrictive measures
against serious human rights violations and abuses. OJ L 410I, 7.12.2020. https://eurlex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=OJ:L:2020:410I:TOC
Council of the European Union. (2021). EU imposes further sanctions over serious violations
of human rights around the world [Press release]. European Council.
https://www.consilium.europa.eu/en/press/press-releases/2021/03/22/eu-imposesfurther-sanctions-over-serious-violations-of-human-rights-around-the-world/
Council Regulation (EC) No 3281/94 of 19 December 1994 applying a four-year scheme of
generalized tariff preferences (1995 to 1998) in respect of certain industrial products
originating in developing countries. OJ L 348, 31.12.1994. https://eurlex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/ALL/?uri=OJ%3AL%3A1994%3A348%3ATOC
Council Regulation (EC) No 980/2005 of 27 June 2005 applying a scheme of generalised tariff
preferences. OJ L 169, 30.6.2005. https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/TXT/?uri=oj%3AJOL_2005_169_R_TOC
Council Regulation (EC) No 978/2012 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 25
October 2012 applying a scheme of generalised tariff preferences and repealing
Council Regulation (EC) No 732/2008. OJ L 303, 31.10.2012. https://eurlex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=OJ%3AL%3A2012%3A303%3ATOC
157
Council Regulation (EU) 2020/1998 of 7 December 2020 concerning restrictive measures
against serious human rights violations and abuses. OJ L 410I, 7.12.2020. https://eurlex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=OJ:L:2020:410I:TOC
Cour de cassation [Cass.], [supreme court for judicial matters] com., Sep. 15, 2009, Bull. IV,
n° 110, No. 08-19200 (Fr.).
https://www.legifrance.gouv.fr/juri/id/JURITEXT000021054038/
Damen, M., & Igler, W. (2020). Trade regimes applicable to developing countries. European
Parliament. https://www.europarl.europa.eu/ftu/pdf/en/FTU_5.2.3.pdf
Dammert, A. C., de Hoop, J., Mvukiyehe, E., & Rosati, F. C. (2018). Effects of public policy on
child labor: Current knowledge, gaps, and implications for program design. World
Development, 110, 104–123. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2018.05.001
Davies, R. B., & Voy, A. (2009). The effect of FDI on child labor. Journal of Development
Economics, 88(1), 59–66. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2008.02.001
de Buhr, E. (2019). Evaluation Youth Inclusive Community-Based Monitoring and
Remediation System on Child Labour (YICBMR) as implemented by Belize Sugar Cane
Farmers Association (BSCFA). In Fairtrade International.
https://files.fairtrade.net/publications/Fairtrade_Belize_Sugarcane_Report_FINAL2019-11-29.pdf
de Buhr, E. & Gordon, E. (2018). Bitter sweets: prevalence of forced labour and child labour
in the cocoa sectors of Côte d’Ivoire and Ghana. Tulane University & Walk Free
Foundation. https://cocoainitiative.org/wp-content/uploads/2018/10/CocoaReport_181004_V15-FNL_digital.pdf
Defending Public Safety Employees Act of 2015, Pub. L. 114-26, 129 Stat. 319 (2015).
https://www.congress.gov/114/plaws/publ26/PLAW-114publ26.pdf
DeGregori, T. R. (2002). Child Labor or Child Prostitution? Cato Institute.
https://www.cato.org/commentary/child-labor-or-childprostitution?queryID=8bce34f73bbd1f1fe7a269228e5ac9cd
Décision n° 2017-750 DC du 23 mars 2017 relative au devoir de vigilance des sociétés mères
et des entreprises donneuses d'ordre [Law on the duty of oversight of parent
companies and commissioning enterprises]. https://www.conseilconstitutionnel.fr/en/decision/2017/2017750DC.htm
Diallo, Y., Etienne, A., & Mehran, F. (2013). Global child labour trends 2008 to 2012. In
International Labour Office, International Programme on the Elimination of Child
Labour (IPEC).
https://www.ilo.org/ipec/Informationresources/WCMS_IPEC_PUB_23015/lang-en/index.htm
Diller, J. M., & Levy, D. A. (1997). Child Labor, Trade and Investment: Toward the
Harmonization of International Law. American Journal of International Law, 91(4),
663–696. https://doi.org/10.2307/2998099
Dimova, R., Epstein, G. S., & Gang, I. N. (2015). Migration, Transfers and Child Labor. Review
of Development Economics, 19(3), 735–747. https://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12156
158
Direction générale du Trésor. (2020). Non-paper from the Netherlands and France on trade,
social economic effects and sustainable development.
https://www.tresor.economie.gouv.fr/Articles/73ce0c5c-11ab-402d-95b15dbb8759d699/files/6b6ff3bf-e8fb-4de2-94f8-922eddd81d08
Doepke, M., & Zilibotti, F. (2005). The Macroeconomics of Child Labor Regulation. American
Economic Review, 95(5), 1492–1524. https://doi.org/10.1257/000282805775014425
Dou, E., Whalen, J., & Chen, A. (2021). U.S. ban on China’s Xinjiang cotton fractures fashion
industry supply chains. The Washington Post.
https://www.washingtonpost.com/world/asia_pacific/china-cotton-sanctionsxinjiang-uighurs/2021/02/21/a8a4b128-70ee-11eb-93be-c10813e358a2_story.html
Drèze, J., & Kingdon, G. G. (1999). School Participation in Rural India. LSE STICERD Research
Paper, No. DEDPS1. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1126987
Duflo, E. (2001). Schooling and labor market consequences of school construction in
Indonesia: Evidence from an unusual policy experiment. American Economic Review,
91(4), 795–813. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.91.4.795
Dufour, M., Labrie, V., & Tremblay-Pepin, S. (2021). Using the Market Basket Measure to
Discuss Income Inequality from the Perspective of Basic Needs. Social Indicators
Research, 1–24. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-020-02580-9
Duthilleul, A., & de Jouvenel, M. (2020). Evaluation de la Mise en Œuvre de la Loi n° 2017399 du 27 Mars 2017 Relative au Devoir de Vigilance des Sociétés Mères et des
Entreprises Donneuses d’Ordre [Evaluation of the Implementation of the Law n° 2017399 of 27 March 2017 on the Duty of Vigilance. In Conseil Général de l’Économie, de
l’Énergie et des Technologies. Ministère de l’Économie et des Finances.
https://www.economie.gouv.fr/files/files/directions_services/cge/devoirs-vigilancesentreprises.pdf
Ebert, F. C. (2013). Social dimensions of free trade agreements. In ILO.
https://labordoc.ilo.org/discovery/fulldisplay?vid=41ILO_INST:41ILO_V1&search_scop
e=ALL_ILO&tab=Everything&docid=alma994838513402676&lang=es&context=L&adap
tor=Local%20Search%20Engine&query=any,contains,Guide%20on%20employment%2
0policy%20and%20International%20Labour%20Stand
EDH. (2018). Application de la loi sur le devoir de vigilance: Plans de vigilance 2018-2019
[Application of the Duty of Vigilance Law: Vigilance Plans 2018-2019]. https://www.edh.org/userfiles/EDH%20-%20Etude%20plans%20de%20vigilance%202019.pdf
Edmonds, E. V. (2001). Will Child Labor Decline with Improvements in Living Standards? In
Dartmouth College, Department of Economics.
https://www.researchgate.net/publication/248449696_Will_Child_Labor_Decline_wit
h_Improvements_in_Living_Standards
Edmonds, E. V. (2005). Does Child Labor Decline with Improving Economic Status? Journal of
Human Resources, XL(1), 77–99. https://doi.org/10.3368/jhr.XL.1.77
Edmonds, E. V. (2006). Child labor and schooling responses to anticipated income in South
Africa. Journal of Development Economics, 81(2), 386–414.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2005.05.001
159
Edmonds, E. V. (2010). Trade, Child Labor, and Schooling in Poor Countries. In G. Porto & B.
M. Hoekman (Eds.), Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: Impacts,
determinants and policy responses. International Bank for Reconstruction and
Development / The World Bank.
http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/539321468331734401/Tradeadjustment-costs-in-developing-countries-impacts-determinants-and-policy-responses
Edmonds, E. V., & Pavcnik, N. (2004a). International Trade and Child Labor: Cross-Country
Evidence (10317).
Edmonds, E. V., & Pavcnik, N. (2004b). The effect of trade liberalization on child labor.
Journal of International Economics, Forthcoming.
Edmonds, E. V., & Pavcnik, N. (2005). Child labor in the global economy. Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 19(1), 199–220. https://doi.org/10.1257/0895330053147895
Edmonds, E. V., & Shrestha, M. (2012). The impact of minimum age of employment
regulation on child labor and schooling. IZA Journal of Labor Policy, 1(14), 2–28.
https://doi.org/10.1186/2193-9004-1-14
Elliott, K. A., & Freeman, R. B. (2003). Can Labor Standards Improve Under Globalization?
The Peterson Institute for International Economics.
https://www.piie.com/bookstore/can-labor-standards-improve-under-globalization
Enneking, L. (2020). The Netherlands Country Report. In European Commission (Ed.), Study
on due diligence requirements through the supply chain - Part III: country reports (p.
572). Publications Office of the European Union. https://doi.org/10.2838/703732
EU targets individuals, entities and bodies with new global human rights sanctions regime.
(2020). The UK Law Societies Joint Brussels Office.
https://www.lawsocieties.eu/news/eu-targets-individuals-entities-and-bodies-withnew-global-human-rights-sanctions-regime/6001547.article
European Commission. (2018a). Council Decision on the conclusion of the Economic
Partnership Agreement between the European Union and Japan COM(2018) 192 final.
https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/TXT/HTML/?uri=CELEX:52018PC0192&from=EN
European Commission. (2018b). Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and
of the Council establishing the Neighbourhood, Development and International
Cooperation Instrument. In European Commission.
https://www.europarl.europa.eu/RegData/docs_autres_institutions/commission_eur
opeenne/com/2018/0460/COM_COM(2018)0460_EN.pdf
European Commission. (2018c). Chapter 4: Institutional, General and Final Provisions. In EUVietnam Investment Protection Agreement.
https://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2018/september/tradoc_157395.pdf
European Commission. (2019). EU Aid for Trade. Progress Report 2019: Review of progress
on the implementation of the updated EU Aid for Trade Strategy of 2017.
https://doi.org/10.2841/81891
European Commission. (2020a). New Investment Protection Agreements: Better protection
for investors-and better protection for citizens International investment-a key driver for
160
growth and jobs.
https://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2020/july/tradoc_158908.pdf
European Commission. (2020b). Report from the Commission to the European Parliament,
the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and The Committee of the
Regions: on the Implementation of EU Trade Agreements COM(2020) 705 final.
https://ec.europa.eu/transparency/regdoc/rep/1/2020/EN/COM-2020-705-F1-ENMAIN-PART-1.PDF
European Commission. (2020c). Sustainable development.
https://ec.europa.eu/trade/policy/policy-making/sustainable-development/
European Commission. (2020d). Critical Raw Materials Resilience: Charting a Path towards
greater Security and Sustainability COM(2020) 474 final.
https://ec.europa.eu/docsroom/documents/42849
European Commission. (2020e, December 1). Chief Trade Enforcement Officer.
https://ec.europa.eu/trade/trade-policy-and-you/contacts/chief-trade-enforcementofficer/
European Commission. (2021a). Eurostat Comext - International Trade. EU trade since 1988
by HS2-4-6 and CN8 (DS-045409) [Data file].
http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/newxtweb/mainxtnet.do
European Commission. (2021b). Operating guidelines for the ‘Single Entry Point’ and
complaints mechanism for the enforcement of EU trade agreements and
arrangements.
https://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2020/november/tradoc_159074.pdf
European Commission. (2021c). Trade Policy Review: an Open, Sustainable and Assertive
Trade Policy. https://doi.org/10.2781/862105
European Commission. (2021d). Annex to the Communication from the Commission to the
European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and
the Committee of the Regions - Trade Policy Review - An Open, Sustainable and
Assertive Trade Policy.
https://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2021/february/tradoc_159439.pdf
European Commission. (2021e). Reforming the WTO: Towards a sustainable and effective
multilateral trading system. Publications Office of the European Union.
https://doi.org/10.2781/82603
European Commission Services. (2017). Non-paper of the Commission Services: Trade and
Sustainable Development chapters in EU Free Trade Agreements.
http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2006/december/tradoc_118238.pdf.
European Commission Services. (2018). Feedback and way forward on improving the
implementation and enforcement of Trade and Sustainable Development chapters in
EU Free Trade Agreements (Issue October 2015).
http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2018/february/tradoc_156618.pdf
European Parliament. (2015). Parliamentary questions. Question for written answer E008441-15: Concept of social dumping.
https://www.europarl.europa.eu/doceo/document/E-8-2015-008441_EN.html
161
European Parliament. (2020a). Resolution of 13 February 2020 on child labour in mines in
Madagascar (2020/2552(RSP)).
https://www.europarl.europa.eu/doceo/document/TA-9-2020-0037_EN.html
European Parliament. (2020b). Resolution of 7 October 2020 on the implementation of the
common commercial policy . https://www.europarl.europa.eu/doceo/document/TA-92020-0252_EN.html
European Parliament. (2021a). Opinion on the Committee on International Trade.
https://www.europarl.europa.eu/doceo/document/INTA-AD-663251_EN.pdf
European Parliament. (2021b). Provisional agreement resulting from interinstitutional
negotiations.
https://www.europarl.europa.eu/meetdocs/2014_2019/plmrep/COMMITTEES/CJ19/
AG/2021/03-17/1226377EN.pdf
European Parliament. (2021c). Global Europe: MEPs back new instrument for external EU
cooperation in 2021-2027 [Press release].
https://www.europarl.europa.eu/news/en/press-room/20210312IPR99818/globaleurope-meps-back-new-instrument-for-external-eu-cooperation-in-2021-2027
European Parliament resolution of 10 March 2021 with recommendations to the
Commission on corporate due diligence and corporate accountability (2020/2129(INL))
https://oeil.secure.europarl.europa.eu/oeil/popups/ficheprocedure.do?lang=en&refe
rence=2020/2129(INL)
European Trade Union Confederation. (2017). ETUC submission on the Non-paper of the
Commission services on Trade and Sustainable Development (TSD) chapters in EU Free
Trade Agreements (FTAs) . ETUC. https://www.etuc.org/en/document/etucsubmission-non-paper-commission-services-trade-and-sustainable-development-tsd
European Union. (2019). EU trade map: The state of EU trade.
https://www.consilium.europa.eu/en/infographics/eu-trade-map/
EU-Korea FTA (2010). OJ L 127, 14.052011. https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/ALL/?uri=OJ%3AL%3A2011%3A127%3ATOC
EU-Ukraine Association Agreement (2014). OJ L 161, 29.5.2014. https://eurlex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/ALL/?uri=CELEX%3A22014A0529%2801%29
EU-Vietnam FTA (2019). OJ L 186/3, 12.6.2020. https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/TXT/?uri=OJ%3AL%3A2020%3A186%3ATOC
EU-Singapore FTA (2018). OJ L 294, 14.11.2019. https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/GA/TXT/?uri=CELEX%3A22019A1114%2801%29
EU-Central America Association agreement (2012). OJ L 346, 15.12.2012. https://eurlex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/ALL/?uri=CELEX:22012A1215(01)
Ethics Information Committee. (2019). Report from the Ethics Information Committee,
appointed by the Norwegian Government on June 1, 2018 [Draft translation from
Norwegian of sections of Part I]. https://media.businesshumanrights.org/media/documents/files/documents/Norway_Draft_Transparency_Ac
t_-_draft_translation_0.pdf
162
Executive Order No. 13818, 82 F.R. 60839 (2017). Blocking the Property of Persons Involved
in Serious Human Rights Abuse or Corruption
https://www.federalregister.gov/documents/2017/12/26/2017-27925/blocking-theproperty-of-persons-involved-in-serious-human-rights-abuse-or-corruption
Executive Order No. 13126, 64 F.R. 32383 (1999). Prohibition of Acquisition of Products
Produced by Forced or Indentured Child Labor
https://www.federalregister.gov/documents/1999/06/16/99-15491/prohibition-ofacquisition-of-products-produced-by-forced-or-indentured-child-labor
Fatima, A. (2017). The effect of globalization and credit market imperfections on the
incidence of child labour. International Journal of Social Economics, 44(8), 998–1017.
https://doi.org/10.1108/IJSE-04-2015-0102
Foreign Affairs Council. (2016). Council Conclusions on Child Labour 20 June 2016, 10244/16.
European Union. https://data.consilium.europa.eu/doc/document/ST-10244-2016INIT/en/pdf
Gibson Dunn. (2020). The EU Adopts Magnitsky-Style Global Human Rights Sanctions
Regime. Gibson, Dunn & Crutcher LLP. https://www.gibsondunn.com/eu-adoptsmagnitsky-style-global-human-rights-sanctions-regime/
Global Living Wage Coalition. (n.d.). What is a living wage? Retrieved May 11, 2021, from
https://globallivingwage.org/
Global Magnitsky Human Rights Accountability Act, 22 U.S.C §§2656 (2016).
https://home.treasury.gov/policy-issues/financial-sanctions/sanctions-programs-andcountry-information/global-magnitsky-sanctions
Governance and Tripartism Department. (2019). Update on the Alliance 8.7 of the 2030
Agenda for Sustainable Development. International Labour Office.
https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---ed_norm/--relconf/documents/meetingdocument/wcms_670573.pdf
Government of Korea. (1997). Trade Union and Labor Relations Adjustment Act 1997, Act
No. 5310. https://www.ilo.org/dyn/natlex/natlex4.detail?p_isn=46398
GoodWeave. (2017). Closing the “Consumptive Demand Loophole”: Amendment to the Tariff
Act of 1930. GoodWeave. https://goodweave.org/closing-the-consumptive-demandloophole-amendment-to-the-tariff-act-of-1930/
Grabosch, R. (2021). The German Supply Chain Due Diligence Act in the Making – What to
Expect [Blog Post]. Nova BHRE Blog. https://novabhre.novalaw.unl.pt/german-supplychain-due-dligence-act-what-to-expect/
Grootaert, C. (1998). Child Labor in Cote dIvoire: Incidence and Determinants. Social
Development Department Environmentally and Socially Sustainable Development
Network The World Bank, 1–80.
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=569204
Grootaert, C., & Kanbur, R. (1995). Child Labor: An Economic-Perspective. International
Labour Review, 134(2).
163
Guarcello, L., Mealli, F., & Rosati, F. C. (2010). Household vulnerability and child labor: The
effect of shocks, credit rationing, and insurance. Journal of Population Economics, 23,
169–198. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-008-0233-4
Güvercin, D. (2020). Women in Politics and Child Labor: an Instrumental Variable Approach.
The European Journal of Development Research, 32, 873–888.
https://doi.org/10.1057/s41287-019-00243-1
Hanson, J., & Sigman, R. (2020). Leviathan’s Latent Dimensions: Measuring State Capacity
for Comparative Political Research. Journal of Politics, Forthcoming. http://wwwpersonal.umich.edu/~jkhanson/resources/hanson_sigman13.pdf
Harrison, J., Richardson, B., Campling, L., Smith, A., & Barbu, M. (2017). Taking Labour Rights
Seriously in Post-Brexit UK Trade Agreements Protect, Promote, Empower. In CSGR
Working Paper Series (284/17). http://wrap.warwick.ac.uk/90331/
Harvey, L., & Green, D. (1993). Defining Quality. Assessment & Evaluation in Higher
Education, 18(1), 9–34. https://doi.org/10.1080/0260293930180102
Hendrix, M. C. (2010). Enforcing the U.S. trafficking victims protection act in emerging
markets: The challenge of affecting change in India and China. Cornell International
Law Journal, 43, 173–206.
https://ww3.lawschool.cornell.edu/research/ILJ/upload/Hendrix.pdf
Hope and Homes for Children, Child’s i Foundation, & ACI Uganda. (2020). EU support for
care reform for children in Uganda in the 2021–2027 period.
https://www.hopeandhomes.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/12/2020-11-Uganda-EUfunds_LONG_FINAL.pdf
Human Rights Watch. (2017a). “We can’t refuse to pick cotton”: Forced and Child Labor
linked to World Bank Group investments in Uzbekistan.
https://www.hrw.org/report/2017/06/27/we-cant-refuse-pick-cotton/forced-andchild-labor-linked-world-bank-group
Human Rights Watch. (2017b). The US Global Magnitsky Act: Questions and answers.
https://www.hrw.org/news/2017/09/13/us-global-magnitsky-act
Hurst, D. (2021a). US moves to support Australian push to tackle China’s “human and labour
rights abuses.” The Guardian. https://www.theguardian.com/australianews/2021/feb/23/us-moves-to-support-australian-push-to-tackle-chinas-humanand-labour-rights-abuses
Hurst, D. (2021b). Australia examines modern slavery laws amid concerns over products
linked to Uyghur abuse. The Guardian.
https://www.theguardian.com/law/2021/apr/27/australia-examines-modern-slaverylaws-amid-concerns-over-products-linked-to-uyghur-abuse
Ibañez, J. I., Bayer, C. N., Xu, J., & Cooper, A. (2020). Devoir de Vigilance: Reforming
Corporate Risk Engagement. In Development International e.V. https://www.ipointsystems.com/ddv-report-2020/
III Global Conference on Child Labour. (2013). The Brasilia Declaration on Child Labour
October 8th -10 th 2013 (p. 4).
http://www.ilo.org/ipecinfo/product/download.do?type=document&id=23480
164
IISD. (2021). EU Parliamentarians Analyze Options for Import Ban on Forced Labor and
Modern Slavery. IISD SDG Knowledge Hub. https://sdg.iisd.org/news/euparliamentarians-analyze-options-for-import-ban-on-forced-labor-and-modernslavery/
Immenkamp, B. (2021). A new neighbourhood, development and international cooperation
instrument – Global Europe. EPRS, European Parliamentary Research Service, PE
628.251(March).
https://www.europarl.europa.eu/RegData/etudes/BRIE/2018/628251/EPRS_BRI(2018
)628251_EN.pdf
International Labour Office. (2016). Assessment of labour provisions in trade and investment
arrangements. ILO Publications.
https://www.ilo.org/global/publications/books/WCMS_498944/lang--en/index.htm
International Labour Office. (2017a). Global estimates of child labour: Result and trends,
2012-2016. ILO Publications. https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/--dgreports/---dcomm/documents/publication/wcms_575499.pdf
International Labour Office. (2017b). Handbook on Assesment of Labour Provisions in Trade
and Investment Arrangements. ILO Publications.
https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---dgreports/--inst/documents/publication/wcms_564702.pdf
International Labour Office. (2018). 20th International Conference of Labour Statisticians Appendix: Revised draft guidelines concerning the measurement of forced labour. ILO
Publications. https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---dgreports/--stat/documents/meetingdocument/wcms_647379.pdf
International Labour Organization. (n.d.-a). Child Labour Platform (CLP). Retrieved March 28,
2021, from https://www.ilo.org/ipec/Action/CSR/clp/lang--en/index.htm
International Labour Organization. (n.d.-b). International Programme on the Elimination of
Child Labour and Forced Labour (IPEC+). https://www.ilo.org/ipec/lang--en/index.htm
International Labour Organization. (n.d.-c). Ratifications by Convention. Retrieved March 14,
2021, from https://www.ilo.org/dyn/normlex/en/f?p=1000:12001::::::
International Labour Organization. (n.d.-d). Trade for Decent Work Project. Retrieved May
25, 2021, from https://www.ilo.org/global/standards/WCMS_697996/lang-en/index.htm
International Labour Organization. (n.d.-e). UN Global Compact Labour Working Group Child
Labour Platform.
https://www.ilo.org/ipecinfo/product/download.do?type=document&id=21556
International Labour Organization. (1930). Forced Labour Convention (No. 29).
https://www.ilo.org/dyn/normlex/en/f?p=1000:12100:0::NO::P12100_ILO_CODE:C02
9
International Labour Organization. (1948). Freedom of Association and Protection of the
Right to Organise Convention (No. 87).
https://www.ilo.org/dyn/normlex/en/f?p=1000:12100:0::NO::P12100_INSTRUMENT_I
D:312232
165
International Labour Organization. (1949). Right to Organise and Collective Bargaining
Convention (No. 98).
https://www.ilo.org/dyn/normlex/en/f?p=NORMLEXPUB:12100:0::NO::P12100_ILO_C
ODE:C098
International Labour Organization. (1951). Equal Remuneration Convention, 1951 (No. 100).
https://www.ilo.org/dyn/normlex/en/f?p=NORMLEXPUB:12100:0::NO:12100:P12100_
INSTRUMENT_ID:312245:NO
International Labour Organization. (1957). Abolition of Forced Labour Convention (No. 105).
https://www.ilo.org/dyn/normlex/en/f?p=1000:12100:0::NO::P12100_INSTRUMENT_I
D,P12100_LANG_CODE:312250,es:NO
International Labour Organization. (1958). Discrimination (Employment and Occupation)
Convention, 1958 (No. 111).
https://www.ilo.org/dyn/normlex/en/f?p=NORMLEXPUB:12100:0::NO:12100:P12100_
INSTRUMENT_ID:312256:NO
International Labour Organization. (1973). Minimum Age Convention (No. 138).
https://www.ilo.org/dyn/normlex/en/f?p=NORMLEXPUB:12100:0::NO::P12100_ILO_C
ODE:C138
International Labour Organization. (1981). Workers with Family Responsibilities Convention,
1981 (No. 156).
https://www.ilo.org/dyn/normlex/en/f?p=NORMLEXPUB:12100:0::NO:12100:P12100_
INSTRUMENT_ID:312301:NO
International Labour Organization. (1998). ILO Declaration on Fundamental Principles and
Rights at Work. https://www.ilo.org/declaration/thedeclaration/textdeclaration/lang-en/index.htm
International Labour Organization. (1999). Worst Forms of Child Labour Convention (No.
182).
https://www.ilo.org/dyn/normlex/en/f?p=NORMLEXPUB:12100:::NO:12100:P12100_I
LO_CODE:C182:NO
International Labour Organization. (2001). Safety and Health in Agriculture Convention (No.
184).
https://www.ilo.org/dyn/normlex/en/f?p=NORMLEXPUB:12100:0::NO::P12100_ILO_C
ODE:C184
International Labour Organization. (2008). ILO Declaration on Social Justice for a Fair
Globalization. http://www.ilo.org/global/about-the-ilo/mission-andobjectives/WCMS_099766/lang--en/index.htm
International Labour Organization. (2009). United States Free Trade Agreements (FTAs).
https://www.ilo.org/global/standards/information-resources-and-publications/freetrade-agreements-and-labour-rights/WCMS_115531/lang--en/index.htm#P6_1463
International Labour Organization. (2011). Domestic Workers Convention, 2011 (No. 189).
https://www.ilo.org/dyn/normlex/en/f?p=NORMLEXPUB:12100:0::NO:12100:P12100_
INSTRUMENT_ID:2551460:NO
166
International Labour Organization. (2015). How to do business with respect for children’s
right to be free from child labour: ILO-IOE child labour guidance tool for business.
https://www.ilo.org/ipec/Informationresources/WCMS_IPEC_PUB_27555/lang-en/index.htm
International Labour Organization. (2017). ILO IPEC + Flagship Strategy. International
Programme on the Elimination of Child Labour and Forced Labour.
https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---ed_norm/--ipec/documents/publication/wcms_528938.pdf
International Labour Organization. (2018). Clear Cotton Project. www.ilo.org/clearcotton
International Labour Organization. (2019). Violence and Harassment Convention, 2019 (No.
190).
https://www.ilo.org/dyn/normlex/en/f?p=NORMLEXPUB:12100:0::NO:12100:P12100_
INSTRUMENT_ID:3999810:NO
International Labour Organization. (2020a). COVID-19 impact on child labour and forced
labour: The response of the IPEC+ Flagship Programme.
https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---ed_norm/--ipec/documents/publication/wcms_745287.pdf
International Labour Organization. (2020b). IPEC+ Global Flagship Programme
Implementation: Towards a world free from child labour and forced labour.
https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---ed_norm/--ipec/documents/publication/wcms_633435.pdf
International Labour Organization. (2020c). Staff list: Fundamentals Principles and Rights at
Work Branch (FUNDAMENTALS). http://www.ilo.org/global/about-the-ilo/how-the-iloworks/departments-and-offices/governance/fprw/WCMS_443534/lang--en/index.htm
International Labour Organization, & Fundamental Principles and Rights at Work Branch.
(2019). Tackling child labour: 100 years of action. ILO publications.
https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---ed_norm/--ipec/documents/publication/wcms_709665.pdf
International Labour Organization, & International Institute for Labour Studies. (2013). The
Social Dimensions of Free Trade Agreements (2015th ed.). ILO Publications.
https://www.ilo.org/global/research/publications/WCMS_228965/lang--en/index.htm
International Labour Organization, International Programme on the Elimination of Child
Labour, & Statistical Information and Monitoring Programme on Child Labour. (2007).
Comparison of survey instruments for collecting data on child labour.
https://www.ilo.org/ipecinfo/product/viewProduct.do?productId=7873
International Labour Organization, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development, Organization for Migration, & United Nations Children’s Fund. (2019).
Ending child labour, forced labour and human trafficking in global supply chains.
https://www.ilo.org/ipec/Informationresources/WCMS_716930/lang--en/index.htm
International Labour Organization, & U.S. Department of Labor. (2019). To eliminate child
labour and forced labour.
167
https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/@ed_norm/@ipec/documents/publicatio
n/wcms_710971.pdf
International Labour Organization, & United Nations Children’s Fund. (2020). COVID-19 and
Child Labour: A time of crisis, a time to act.
https://www.unicef.org/media/70261/file/COVID-19-and-Child-labour-2020.pdf
International Monetary Fund. (n.d.). Balance of Payments database, supplemented by data
from the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development and official national
sources. The World Bank. Retrieved May 16, 2021, from
https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/BM.KLT.DINV.CD.WD?end=2019&locations=EU
&start=1970&view=chart
International Partnerships. (2021). EU boosts sustainable cocoa production in Côte d’Ivoire,
Ghana and Cameroon. European Commission. https://ec.europa.eu/internationalpartnerships/news/eu-boosts-sustainable-cocoa-production-cote-divoire-ghana-andcameroon_en
International Programme on the Elimination of Child Labour. (2002). Every child counts:
New global estimates on child labour. In International Labour Office.
https://www.ilo.org/ipecinfo/product/download.do?type=document&id=742
Jill Murray, Laurence Boisson de Chazournes, Jaemin Lee, & Mr Rieu Kim. (2021). Panel Of
Experts Proceeding Constituted Under Article 13.15 Of The Eu-Korea Free Trade
Agreement: Report of The Panel Of Experts.
https://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2021/january/tradoc_159358.pdf
Joseph, S. (2011). Blame it on the WTO?: A Human Rights Critique. In Blame it on the WTO?:
A Human Rights Critique. Oxford University Press.
https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199565894.001.0001
Kaufmann, D., & Kraay, A. (2019). Worldwide Governance Indicators. World Bank.
https://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/
Kelleher, J. P. (1994). The Child Labor Deterrence Act: American Unilateralism and the GATT.
Minnesota Journal of Global Trade, 3(119), 161.
https://scholarship.law.umn.edu/mjilhttps://scholarship.law.umn.edu/mjil/119
Kis–Katos, K., & Schulze, G. G. (2006). Where child labor supply finds its demand? In
University of Freiburg: Institute for Economic Research (Vols. J8-I3). http://www.vwliwipol.uni-freiburg.de/iwipol//publications/kiskatos-schulze_childlaborindonesia_WP06.pdf
Kuplewatzky, N. (2016). An Appeal for Targeted Regulatory Protection of Human Rights in
the European Union’s External Trade Relations in Light of Front Polisario. Global Trade
and Customs Journal, 11(11/12), 568–579.
https://kluwerlawonline.com/journalarticle/Global+Trade+and+Customs+Journal/11.1
1/GTCJ2016072
Gesetz über die unternehmerischen Sorgfaltspflichten in Lieferketten 03. März 2021. [Law
on Corporate Due Diligence in Supply Chains March, 3, 2021].
https://www.bmas.de/SharedDocs/Downloads/DE/Gesetze/Regierungsentwuerfe/reg
-sorgfaltspflichtengesetz.pdf
168
L’Assemblée fédérale de la Confédération suisse [The Federal Assembly of the Swiss
Confederation]. (2020). Code des obligations: Contre-projet indirect à l’initiative
populaire «Entreprises responsables – pour protéger l’être humain et l’environnement»
[Code of Obligations: Indirect counter-proposal to the popular initiative "Responsible
Business - to protect people and the environment].
https://www.skmr.ch/cms/upload/pdf/2020/201217_Texte_contre-projet_IMR.pdf
Lavoie, M., & Stockhammer, E. (2013). Wage-Led Growth An Equitable Strategy for
Economic Recovery. In M. Lavoie & E. Stockhammer (Eds.), Wage-led Growth: An
Equitable Strategy for Economic Recovery. Palgrave Macmillan and the International
Labour Office. http://ilo.org/global/publications/books/forthcomingpublications/WCMS_218886/lang-en/index.htm#:~:text=This%20original%20and%20extensive%20study,aggregate%20d
emand%20and%20labour%20productivity.
Lee, L. (2020a). Amid virus crisis, U.S. bars imports of Malaysia’s Top Glove over labour
issues. Reuters. https://www.reuters.com/article/us-top-glove-usa/amid-virus-crisisus-bars-imports-of-malaysias-top-glove-over-labor-issues-idUSKCN24H0K2
Lee, L. (2020b). Racing to reverse U.S. ban, Malaysia’s Top Glove improves workers’ housing.
Reuters. https://www.reuters.com/article/us-topglove-labour/racing-to-reverse-u-sban-malaysias-top-glove-improves-workers-housing-idUSKCN2571ZL
Levy, V. (1985). Cropping Pattern, Mechanization, Child Labor, and Fertility Behavior in a
Farming Economy: Rural Egypt. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 33(4),
777–791. https://doi.org/10.1086/451494
Lewis, M. (2020). OPINION: Big brands have mistreated their workers throughout the
COVID-19 crisis. Thomson Reuters Foundation.
https://news.trust.org/item/20201113123916-2hj8y/
Littenberg, R., & Blinder, N. V. (2019). Dutch Child Labor Due Diligence Act Approved by
Senate – Implications for Global Companies. Ropes & Gray LLP
https://www.ropesgray.com/en/newsroom/alerts/2019/06/Dutch-Child-Labor-DueDiligence-Act-Approved-by-Senate-Implications-for-Global-Companies
LOI 2017-399 du 27 March 2017 relative au devoir de vigilance des sociétés mères et des
entreprises donneuses d’ordre [Law 2017-399 of March 27, 2017 on Duty of Vigilance
of Parent and Outsourcing Companies], Journal Officiel de la République Française
[J.O.] [Official Gazette of France], Mar. 27, 2017, ECFX1509096L.
https://www.legifrance.gouv.fr/loda/id/JORFTEXT000034290626/
Lowe, S. (2019). The EU should reconsider its approach to trade and sustainable
development. In Centre for European Reform.
https://www.cer.eu/sites/default/files/insight_SL_31.10.19.pdf
Luyten, A.-E. (2021). The EU-UK TCA: A Front-runner in Trade and Sustainable Development
[Blog post]. Trade Experettes. https://www.tradeexperettes.org/blog/articles/the-euuk-tca-a-front-runner-in-trade-and-sustainable-development
Maberry, J. S., & Torrico, M. (2021). Forced Labor and Supply Chains: A Complete Ban on
Goods from Xinjiang or Additional WROs on the Horizon? [Blog post]. Global Trade
169
Law Blog. https://www.globaltradelawblog.com/2021/03/19/forced-labor-supplychains-wros/#page=1
Mansoor, F. (2004). The WTO versus the ILO and the case of child labour. Web Journal of
Current Legal Issues, 2, 1–22.
https://www.peacepalacelibrary.nl/ebooks/files/WEBJCLI_MANSOOR_WTO-versusthe-ILO.pdf
Martin, W., & Maskus, K. E. (2001). Core labor standards and competitiveness: Implications
for global trade policy. Review of International Economics, 9(2), 317–328.
https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9396.00281
Martinez-Zarzoso, I., & Kruse, H. W. (2019). Are Labour Provisions in Free Trade Agreements
Improving Labour Conditions? Open Economies Review.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-019-09545-7
Marx, A., Bright, C., & Wouters, J. (2019). Access to legal remedies for victims of corporate
human rights abuses in third countries Policy Department for External Relations. Study
Requested by the DROI Committee, European Parliament, PE 603.475.
https://doi.org/10.2861/566720
Maskus, K. (1997). Should Core Labor Standards Be Imposed Through International Trade
Policy? In World Bank Working Paper (No. 1817).
https://documents.worldbank.org/en/publication/documentsreports/documentdetail/359161468766533116/should-core-labor-standards-beimposed-through-international-trade-policy
Millennium Challenge Corporation. (n.d.-a). About MCC. Retrieved March 28, 2021, from
https://www.mcc.gov/about
Millennium Challenge Corporation. (n.d.-b). Concurrent Compacts for Regional Investments .
Retrieved March 28, 2021, from https://www.mcc.gov/how-wework/program/concurrent-compact
Millennium Challenge Corporation. (2017). Improving Native Plant Harvesting and Sales in
Namibia . https://www.mcc.gov/resources/doc/evalbrief-060117-nam-indigenousproducts
Millennium Challenge Corporation. (2021). Country Scorecards. https://www.mcc.gov/whowe-select/scorecards
Mitro, M. T. (2002). Outlawing the Trade in Child Labor Products: Why the GATT Article XX
Health Exception Authorizes Unilateral Sanctions. American University Law Review,
51(6), 1223–1273.
https://digitalcommons.wcl.american.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?referer=&httpsredir=1
&article=1151&context=aulr
Moore, M., & Scherrer, C. (2017). Conditional or Promotional Trade Agreements-Is
Enforcement Possible? - How International Labour Standards Can Be Enforced through
US and EU Social Chapters. In Friedrich Ebert Stiftung. http://library.fes.de/pdffiles/bueros/singapur/13446.pdf
170
MVO Platform. (2019). Update: Frequently Asked Questions about the new Dutch Child
Labour Due Diligence Law. https://www.mvoplatform.nl/en/frequently-askedquestions-about-the-new-dutch-child-labour-due-diligence-law/
MVO Platform. (2021). Dutch bill on Responsible and Sustainable International Business
Conduct a major step towards protecting human rights and the environment
worldwide. https://www.mvoplatform.nl/en/dutch-bill-on-responsible-andsustainable-international-business-conduct-a-major-step-towards-protecting-humanrights-and-the-environment-worldwide/
Myers, L., & Theytaz-Bergman, L. (2017). The neglected link effects of llimate change and
rnvironmental fegradation on child labour content.
http://www.terredeshommes.org/wp-content/uploads/2017/06/CL-Report-2017engl.pdf
Nepal, A., & Nepal, M. (2012). Is child labour a substitute for adult labour? The relationship
between child labour and adult illness in Nepal. International Labour Review, 151(1–
2), 109–121. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1564-913X.2012.00137.x
Nestlé. (2019). Tackling Child Labour 2019 Report.
https://www.nestlecocoaplan.com/themes/custom/cocoa/dist/assets/nestle-tacklingchild-labor-2019.pdf
Neumayer, E., & De Soysa, I. (2005). Trade openness, Foreign Direct Investment and child
labor. World Development, 33(1), 43–63.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2004.06.014
New bill could force Dutch companies to be ethical, or face sanctions. (2021). NL Times.
https://nltimes.nl/2021/03/10/new-bill-force-dutch-companies-ethical-face-sanctions
Niava, L. F. B., & Bayer, C. N. (2018). Analyse sociologique de l’autonomisation des
producteurs de cacao dans l’ouest de la Côte d’Ivoire [Sociological analysis of the
empowerment of cocoa farmers in western Côte d’Ivoire]. In A. Loba & A. G. Bolou
(Eds.), La Problematique du Developpement dans L’ouest de la Cote D’ivoire: Eléments
de Diagnostic et de Réflexion [The Problem of Development in Western Cote D’Ivoire:
Elements of Diagnosis and Reflection] (pp. 163–176). Gcréa. https://28696c7d-66ef4bd0-86e3c319e9b535e4.filesusr.com/ugd/f0f801_b32ba4a7ea4941febd84d52fb80e220e.pdf
NORC at the University of Chicago. (2014). Evaluation of MCA Namibia’s Conservancy
Support and Indigenous Natural Products Activities. In Millennium Challenge
Corporation (Issue December).
https://data.mcc.gov/evaluations/index.php/catalog/152
OECD. (2016). OECD Due Diligence Guidance for Responsible Supply Chains of Minerals from
Conflict-Affected and High-Risk Areas: Third Edition. In OECD Publishing.
https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264252479-en
Office of Financial Sanctions Implementation HM Treasury. (2021). Consolidated List of
Financial Sanctions Targets in the UK.
https://ofsistorage.blob.core.windows.net/publishlive/ConList.html
171
Office of the High Commissioner for Human Rights. (2012). The Corporate Responsibility to
Respect Human Rights: An Interpretive Guide.
https://www.ohchr.org/documents/publications/hr.pub.12.2_en.pdf
Office of the High Commissioner for Human Rights. (2020). EU contribution to the upcoming
thematic report on the 10th anniversary of the UN Guiding Principles on Business and
Human Rights . https://op.europa.eu/en/publication-detail/-/publication/8ba0a8fd4c83-11ea-b8b7-01aa75ed71a1/language-en
Olarreaga, M., Saiovici, G., & Ugarte, C. (2020). Child Labour and Global Value Chains (No.
DP15426; CEPR Discussion Paper).
https://cepr.org/active/publications/discussion_papers/dp.php?dpno=15426#
Open letter: change course on the International Year for the Elimination of Child Labour.
(2021). Open Democracy. https://www.opendemocracy.net/en/beyond-traffickingand-slavery/open-letter-change-course-international-year-elimination-child-labour/
Orbie, J., Martens, D., Oehri, M., & Van den Putte, L. (2016). Promoting sustainable
development or legitimising free trade? Civil society mechanisms in EU trade
agreements. Third World Thematics: A TWQ Journal, 1(4).
https://doi.org/10.1080/23802014.2016.1294032
Orbie, J., Martens, D., & Van Den Putte, L. (2016). Civil society meetings in European Union
trade agreements: features, purposes, and evaluation. Centre For the Law of EU
External Relations (CLEER), 3. https://doi.org/10.13140/rg.2.2.18580.71042
Patel, S. K. (2016). Climate Change and Climate-Induced Disasters in Odisha, Eastern India:
Impacts, Adaptation and Future Policy Implications. International Journal of
Humanities and Social Science Invention, 5(8), 60–63.
http://www.ijhssi.org/papers/v5(8)/J050801060063.pdf
Peksen, D. (2019). When Do Economic Sanctions Work Best? Center for a New American
Security. https://www.cnas.org/publications/commentary/when-do-economicsanctions-work-best
Pinstrup-Andersen, P., Watson, D. D., Frandsen, S. E., Kuyvenhoven, A., & Braun, J. von.
(2011). Food Policy for Developing Countries: The Role of Government in Global,
National, and Local Food Systems. Cornell University Press.
https://doi.org/10.7591/j.ctt7v910
Postnikov, E., & Bastiaens, I. (2014). Does dialogue work? The effectiveness of labor
standards in EU preferential trade agreements. Journal of European Public Policy,
21(6), 923–940. https://doi.org/10.1080/13501763.2014.910869
Powell, B. (2014). A Case against Child Labor Prohibitions. Economic Development Bulletin,
21, 4. https://www.cato.org/economic-development-bulletin/case-against-child-laborprohibitions
PRS Group. (2018). ICRG Methodology. In International Country Risk Guide.
https://www.prsgroup.com/wp-content/uploads/2018/01/icrgmethodology.pdf
Raess, D. (2018). Labour (and environmental) provisions in FTAs: What do they do? In The
future of sustainable development chapters in EU free trade agreements (pp. 7–21).
European Union. https://doi.org/10.2861/653174
172
Rahman, M. M., & Khanam, R. (2012). Child labour: the effects of globalisation. The Journal
of Applied Business and Economics, 13(4), 59–71.
https://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/11049903.pdf
Rahman, M. M., Khanam, R., & Absar, N. U. (1999). Child Labor in Bangladesh: A Critical
Appraisal of Harkin’s Bill and the MOU-Type Schooling Program. Journal of Economic
Issues, 33(4), 985–1003. https://doi.org/10.1080/00213624.1999.11506225
Ram, R. (1982). Composite indices of physical quality of life, basic needs fulfilment, and
income. A “principal component” representation. Journal of Development Economics,
11(2), 227–247. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3878(82)90005-0
Regulation (EU) No 978/2012 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 25 October
2012 Applying a Scheme of Generalised Tariff Preferences and Repealing Council
Regulation (EC) No 732/2008. OJ L 303, 31.10.2012. https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/TXT/?uri=celex%3A32012R0978
Rebitzer, J. B. (1995). Is there a trade-off between supervision and wages? An empirical test
of efficiency wage theory. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 28(1), 107–
129. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-2681(95)00023-0
Reuters. (2021). U.S. Customs says forced labour used at Malaysia’s Top Glove, to seize
gloves. Reuters. https://www.reuters.com/world/asia-pacific/us-customs-seizesmalaysias-top-glove-shipment-following-forced-labour-finding-2021-05-05/
Rosenzweig, R. M. (1980). Household and Non-Household Activities of Youths: Issues of
Modelling, Data and Estimation Strategies. ILO Working Papers.
https://ideas.repec.org/p/ilo/ilowps/992032963402676.html
Ruggie, J. (2021). Letter from John Ruggie to German Ministers regarding alignment of draft
supply chain law with the UNGPs . Shift. https://shiftproject.org/ruggie-letter-germanlaw-supply-chain-law/
Russia and Moldova Jackson-Vanik Repeal and Sergei Magnitsky Rule of Law Accountability
Act of 2012, Pub. L. No. 112-208, 126 Stat. 1496 (2012).
https://home.treasury.gov/system/files/126/pl112_208.pdf
Sadhu, S., Kysia, K., Onyango, L., Zinnes, C., Lord, S., Monnard, A., & Arellano, I. R. (2020).
NORC Final Report: Assessing Progress in Reducing Child Labor in Cocoa Production in
Cocoa Growing Areas of Côte d’Ivoire and Ghana.
https://www.norc.org/Research/Projects/Pages/assessing-progress-in-reducing-childlabor-in-cocoa-growing-areas-of-c%C3%B4te-d%E2%80%99ivoire-and-ghana.aspx
Sakellariou, C., & Lall, A. (1998). Child Labor in the Philippines. In The Policy Analysis of Child
Labor: A Comparative Study. World Bank.
Sanctions and Anti-Money Laundering Act 2018, c.13 (UK),
https://www.legislation.gov.uk/ukpga/2018/13/contents/enacted
Schultz, T. W. (1960). Capital Formation by Education. Journal of Political Economy, 68(6),
571–583. https://doi.org/10.1086/258393
173
Shapiro, C., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1984). Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device.
The American Economic Review, 74(3), 433–444.
http://www.jstor.org/stable/1804018
Shenoy, R. (2021). US Customs and Border Protection monitors imports to curb products
made by forced labor. The World. https://www.pri.org/stories/2021-04-30/uscustoms-and-border-protection-monitors-imports-curb-products-made-forced-labor
Shift. (2018). Human Rights Reporting in France: A Baseline for Assessing the Duty of
Vigilance Law. https://shiftproject.org/wp-content/uploads/2018/09/Human-RightsReporting-in-France.pdf
Shift. (2019). Human Rights Reporting in France: Two Year In: Has the Duty of Vigilance Law
led to more Meaningful Disclosure? https://humanrights.wbcsd.org/project/humanrights-reporting-in-france-two-years-in-has-the-duty-of-vigilance-law-led-to-moremeaningful-disclosure/
Shift. (2021). Human Rights Due Diligence: the State of Play in Europe.
https://shiftproject.org/resource/mhrdd-europe-map/
Spaull, N., & Taylor, S. (2012). “Effective enrolment” - Creating a composite measure of
educational access and educational quality to accurately describe education system
performance in sub-Saharan Africa. In Working Papers (21/2012). Stellenbosch
University, Department of Economics. https://resep.sun.ac.za/wpcontent/uploads/2017/10/wp-21-2012.pdf
Srinivasan, T. N. (1998). Trade and Human Rights. In A. Deardorff & R. Stern (Eds.),
Constituent Interests and U.S. Trade Policies (pp. 225–253). University of Michigan
Press. https://doi.org/10.3998/mpub.15469
Standaert, M. (2021). Nike and H&M face backlash in China over Xinjiang statements. The
Guardian. https://www.theguardian.com/world/2021/mar/25/nike-and-hm-facebacklash-in-china-over-xinjiang-statements
Swanson, A. (2020). Nike and Coca-Cola Lobby Against Xinjiang Forced Labor Bill. The New
York Times. https://www.nytimes.com/2020/11/29/business/economy/nike-cocacola-xinjiang-forced-labor-bill.html
Tanaka, R. (2003). Inequality as a determinant of child labor. Economics Letters, 80(1), 93–
97. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0165-1765(03)00061-2
Tariff Act, 19 U.S.C. § 1202 (1935).
https://uscode.house.gov/view.xhtml?path=/prelim@title19/chapter4&edition=preli
m
The Dutch Child Labour Due Diligence Act 2019. Wet van 24 oktober 2019 n. 401 houdende
de invoering van een zorgplicht ter voorkoming van de levering van goederen en
diensten die met behulp van kinderarbeid tot stand zijn gekomen [Act of 24 October
2019 n. 401 introducing a due diligence to prevent the supply of goods and services
that have been produced using child labour.
https://www.eerstekamer.nl/behandeling/20170207/gewijzigd_voorstel_van_wet/do
cument3/f=/vkbkk8pud2zt.pdf
174
The Global Human Rights Sanctions Regulations 2020, UK Statutory Instruments 2020 No.
680, July 2020. https://www.legislation.gov.uk/uksi/2020/680/introduction/made
The Hague Global Child Labour Conference. (2010). Roadmap for achieving the elimination
of the Worst Forms of Child Labour by 2016, May 11th 2010.
https://www.ilo.org/ipec/Informationresources/WCMS_IPEC_PUB_13453/lang-en/index.htm
The World Bank. (2020). Data on Statistical Capacity.
https://datatopics.worldbank.org/statisticalcapacity/
The World Bank. (2021). DataBank: Metadata Glossary.
https://databank.worldbank.org/metadataglossary/genderstatistics/series/SL.TLF.0714.MA.ZS
Titievskaia, J., Zamfir, I., & Handeland, C. (2021). WTO rules: Compatibility with human and
labour rights. EPRS, European Parliamentary Research Service, PE 689.359.
https://www.europarl.europa.eu/RegData/etudes/BRIE/2021/689359/EPRS_BRI(2021
)689359_EN.pdf
Torres-Cortés, F., Salinier, C., Deringer, H., Bright, C., Baeza-Breinbauer, D., Smit, L., Tejero
Tobed, H., Bauer, M., Kara, S., Alleweldt, F., McCorquodale, R. (2020). Study on due
diligence requirements through the supply chain: Final report. European Commission.
https://doi.org/10.2838/39830
Trade Act, 19 U.S.C. ch. 12 (1974). https://www.govinfo.gov/content/pkg/PLAW107publ210/html/PLAW-107publ210.htm
Trade Act, 19 U.S.C § 3801 (2002). https://www.govinfo.gov/content/pkg/PLAW107publ210/pdf/PLAW-107publ210.pdf
Trade and Development Act of 2000, Pub. L. 106-200; 114 Stat 251 (2000).
https://www.congress.gov/bill/106th-congress/house-bill/434
Trade Facilitation and Trade Enforcement Act of 2015, Pub. L. 114-125, 130 Stat. 122 (2015),
codified at 19 U.S.C §§ 4301. https://www.congress.gov/114/bills/hr644/BILLS114hr644enr.pdf
Trade and Cooperation Agreement. (2020). Trade and cooperation agreement between the
European Union and the European Atomic Energy Community, of the one part, and
the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland, on the other part. Official
Journal of the European Union. https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legalcontent/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:22020A1231(01)&from=EN
Trade Promotion Authority Act, Pub. L. 114-26, 129 Stat. 319 (2015).
https://www.congress.gov/114/plaws/publ26/PLAW-114publ26.pdf
Trafficking Victims Protection Act, 22 U.S.C. §§ 7101-7110 (2000).
https://uscode.house.gov/view.xhtml?path=/prelim@title22/chapter78&edition=preli
m
Trafficking Victims Protection Act of 2003, Pub. L. No. 108-193, 117 Stat 2875 (2003),
amended 2005, 2008. 22 U.S.C §§ 7101-7110 (2000)
https://www.congress.gov/bill/108th-congress/house-bill/2620
175
Trafficking Victims Protection Reauthorization Act of 2005, Pub. L. No. 169-164, 199 Stat
3558 (2006). https://www.dol.gov/agencies/ilab/about/laws
Trafficking Victims Protection Act of 2008, Pub. L. No. 110-457, 122 Stat 5044 (2008) 22
U.S.C §§ 7101-7110 (2000) https://www.congress.gov/bill/110th-congress/housebill/7311/text
Trafficking Victims Protection Act of 2013, H.R. 898 113th Cong. 2013-2014 (2013)
https://www.congress.gov/bill/113th-congress/house-bill/898
Trafficking Victims Protection Reauthorization Act of 2005, Pub. L. No. 109-164, 119 Stat
3558 (2006) 22 U.S.C §§ 7101-7110 (2000) https://www.congress.gov/bill/109thcongress/house-bill/972 P.L.109-164
Transparency International. (2020). Corruption Perceptions Index 2020. Transparency
International. https://www.transparency.org/en/cpi/2020/index/nzl
Trans-Pacific Partnership Agreement, January 28, 2016, 162 Cong. Rec. S334, Issue 17
https://www.congress.gov/congressional-record/2016/01/28/senate-section
Treasury and General Government Appropriations Act of 1997, Pub. L. No. 105-61, § 634,
111 Stat. 1272, 1316 https://www.congress.gov/bill/105th-congress/senate-bill/1023
Trebilcock, M. J., & Howse, R. (1995). The Regulation of International Trade. Routledge.
https://books.google.com.ar/books/about/The_Regulation_of_International_Trade.ht
ml?id=EXK2QgAACAAJ&redir_esc=y
U.K. Government. (2021). UK Government announces business measures over Xinjiang
human rights abuses [Press release]. https://www.gov.uk/government/news/ukgovernment-announces-business-measures-over-xinjiang-human-rights-abuses
U.S. Customs and Border Protection. (n.d.). Withhold Release Orders and Findings. Retrieved
May 12, 2021, from https://www.cbp.gov/trade/programs-administration/forcedlabor/withhold-release-orders-and-findings
U.S. Customs and Border Protection. (2016a). Trade Facilitation and Trade Enforcement Act
of 2015: Repeal of the Consumptive Demand Clause. http://www.cbp.gov/trade/tradecommunity/programsU.S. Customs and Border Protection. (2016b). Trade Facilitation and Trade Enforcement Act
of 2015: Repeal of the Consumptive Demand Clause - Frequently Asked Questions. In
CBP Publication # 2133-0416.
https://www.cbp.gov/sites/default/files/assets/documents/2016-Apr/tftea-repealconsumptive-demand-clause-faqs.pdf
U.S. Customs and Border Protection. (2017). What Every Member of the Trade Community
Should Know: Reasonable Care. An Informed Compliance Publication.
https://www.cbp.gov
U.S. Customs and Border Protection. (2019a). Forced Labour Process. CBP Publication #08470219. https://www.cbp.gov/sites/default/files/assets/documents/2019Feb/Forced_Labor_Process_Map_PBRB.pdf
176
U.S. Customs and Border Protection. (2019b). CBP Issues Withhold Release Order on
Tobacco from Malawi [Press release]. https://www.cbp.gov/newsroom/nationalmedia-release/cbp-issues-withhold-release-order-tobacco-malawi
U.S. Customs and Border Protection. (2021). Forced Labor.
https://www.cbp.gov/trade/programs-administration/forced-labor
U.S. Department of Labor. (n.d.-a). List of Goods Produced by Child Labor or Forced Labor.
The Bureau of International Labor Affairs. Retrieved March 14, 2021, from
https://www.dol.gov/agencies/ilab/reports/child-labor/list-of-goods
U.S. Department of Labor. (n.d.-b). List of Goods Produced by Child Labor or Forced Labor Electronics. The Bureau of International Labor Affairs. Retrieved May 11, 2021, from
https://www.dol.gov/agencies/ilab/reports/child-labor/list-ofgoods?tid=All&field_exp_good_target_id=5784&field_exp_exploitation_type_target_i
d_1=15413&items_per_page=10
U.S. Department of Labor. (n.d.-c). List of Products Produced by Forced or Indentured Child
Labor. The Bureau of International Labor Affairs. Retrieved March 14, 2021, from
https://www.dol.gov/agencies/ilab/reports/child-labor/list-ofproducts?combine=&tid=All&field_exp_good_target_id=All&items_per_page=10&pag
e=1
U.S. Department of Labor. (2018). ILAB: Bureau of International Labor Affairs.
https://www.dol.gov/sites/dolgov/files/ILAB/images/ILAB%20Fact%20Sheet%20%20FINAL%20FY18_0.pdf
U.S. Department of Labor. (2020a). 2020 List of Goods Produced by Child Labor or Forced
Labor.
https://www.dol.gov/sites/dolgov/files/ILAB/child_labor_reports/tda2019/2020_TVP
RA_List_Online_Final.pdf
U.S. Department of Labor. (2020b). FY 2020 - Congressional Budget Justification:
Departamental Management.
https://www.dol.gov/sites/dolgov/files/general/budget/2020/CBJ-2020-V3-02.pdf
U.S. Department of Labor. (2021). FY 2021 - Department of Labor: Budget in Brief.
https://www.dol.gov/sites/dolgov/files/general/budget/2021/FY2021BIB.pdf
U.S. Department of State. (2021). Letter to Senator the Honorable Eric Abetz- Custom
Amendment (Banning Goods Produced by Uyghur Forced Labour) Bill 2020 Submission
38.
U.S. Department of the Treasury. (2020). Treasury Sanctions Chinese Entity and Officials
Pursuant to Global Magnitsky Human Rights Executive Order [Press release].
https://home.treasury.gov/news/press-releases/sm1073
U.S. Immigration and Customs Enforcement. (2018). Forced Labor and Forced Child Labor:
Fiscal Year 2017 Report to Congress.
https://www.dhs.gov/sites/default/files/publications/ICE%20%20Forced%20Labor%20and%20Forced%20Child%20Labor.pdf
177
Ul-Haq, J., Khanum, S., & Raza Cheema, A. (2020). The impact of trade liberalization on child
labor in Pakistan. International Review of Applied Economics, 34(6), 769–784.
https://doi.org/10.1080/02692171.2020.1782853
Understanding Children’s Work project, based on data from ILO UNICEF and the World
Bank. (n.d.). Children in employment, total (% of children ages 7-14). Retrieved May
24, 2021, from
https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SL.TLF.0714.ZS?end=2016&name_desc=false&st
art=1994&view=chart
UNESCO Institute for Statistics. (n.d.). UIS Statistics database. Retrieved March 28, 2021,
from http://data.uis.unesco.org/
United Nations. (n.d.). Goal 17: Revitalize the global partnership for sustainable
development. Retrieved May 23, 2021, from
https://www.un.org/sustainabledevelopment/globalpartnerships/
United Nations. (1969). Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties 1969. Done at Vienna on
23 May 1969. Entered into force on 27 January 1980. Treaty Series, 1155, 331.
https://legal.un.org/ilc/texts/instruments/english/conventions/1_1_1969.pdf
United Nations. (2011). Guiding Principles on business and human rights. Implementing the
United Nations “Protect, Respect and Remedy” Framework. In United Nations.
https://www.ohchr.org/documents/publications/guidingprinciplesbusinesshr_en.pdf
United Nations. (2014). Country classification: Data sources, country classifications and
aggregation methodology. In World Economic Situation and Prospects 2014 (p. 198).
https://doi.org/10.18356/ad0c5772-en
United Nations. (2015). Transforming our world: the 2030 Agenda for Sustainable
Development (A/RES/70/1). In resolution adopted at the Seventieth Session, 25
September by the UN General Assembly.
https://doi.org/10.1163/157180910X12665776638740
United Nations. (2020). Methodology - standard country or area codes for statistical use
(M49). https://unstats.un.org/unsd/methodology/m49/#geo-regions
United Nations. (2021a). United Nations Treaty Collection: 11. Convention of the Rights of
the Child.
United Nations. (2021b). United Nations Treaty Collection: 1. Vienna Convention on the Law
of Treaties.
https://treaties.un.org/pages/ViewDetailsIII.aspx?src=TREATY&mtdsg_no=XXIII1&chapter=23&Temp=mtdsg3&clang=_en
United Nations Children’s Fund. (n.d.). Orphans. Retrieved May 11, 2021, from
https://www.unicef.org/media/orphans
United Nations Children’s Fund. (1997). The state of the world ’s children 1997. In Oxford
University Press. https://www.unicef.org/reports/state-worlds-children-1997
United Nations Children’s Fund. (2015). Unless we act now: The impact of climate change on
children. https://www.unicef.org/media/60111/file
178
United Nations Children’s Fund. (2020). Children in monetary poor households and COVID19: Technical note. https://www.unicef.org/documents/children-monetary-poorhouseholds-and-covid-19
United Nations Children’s Fund, Save the Children Europe, Missing Children Europe, SOS
Children’s Villages International, PICUM, Eurochild, Terre des Hommes, Plan
International, & ChildFund Alliance. (2020). Joint Position Paper on a Comprehensive
Child Rights Strategy*. https://ec.europa.eu/international-partnerships/europeanconsensus-development_en
United Nations Children’s Fund, The UN Global Compact, & Save the Children. (2012).
Children’s Rights and Business Principles.
https://resourcecentre.savethechildren.net/node/5717/pdf/5717.pdf
United Nations Development, & Programme and Oxford Poverty and Human Development
Initiative. (2020). Global Multidimensional Poverty index 2020 – Charting Pathways out
of Multidimensional Poverty: Achieving the SDGs. https://ophi.org.uk/global-mpireport-2020/
United Nations General Assembly. (1989). Convention on the Rights of the Child (p. 15).
https://www.unicef.org/child-rights-convention/convention-text
United States – Mexico – Canada Agreement Implementation Act of 2020. Pub Law 116-113,
134 Stat. 11 (2020). https://www.congress.gov/116/plaws/publ113/PLAW116publ113.pdf
United States Trade Representative. (n.d.-a). Enforcement. Retrieved May 13, 2021, from
https://ustr.gov/issue-areas/enforcement
United States Trade Representative. (n.d.-b). Labor Reports. Retrieved May 13, 2021, from
https://ustr.gov/issue-areas/labor/labor-reports
Unofficial English translation of the act, commissioned by the law firm of Ropes & Gray.
Retrieved May 15, 2021, from
https://www.ropesgray.com/en/newsroom/alerts/2019/06/Dutch-Child-Labor-DueDiligence-Act-Approvedby-Senate-Implications-for-Global-Companies
Unofficial Translation of Dutch Bill for Responsible and Sustainable International Business
Conduct, Section 1.2. Duty of care for every enterprise (n.d.)
https://www.mvoplatform.nl/en/wp-content/uploads/sites/6/2021/03/Bill-forResponsible-and-Sustainable-International-Business-Conduct-unofficial-translationMVO-Platform.pdf
Uyghur Forced Labor Prevention Act of 2020, H.R. 6210, 116th Congress.
https://www.congress.gov/bill/116th-congress/house-bill/6210
Van Den Putte, L., Orbie, J., Bossuyt, F., Martens, D., & de Ville, F. (2015). What social face of
the new EU trade agreements? Beyond the ‘soft’ approach. ETUI Policy Briefs, 13, 1–5.
https://www.etui.org/fr/publications/policy-briefs/european-economic-employmentand-social-policy/what-social-face-of-the-new-eu-trade-agreements-beyond-the-softapproach
179
Vanpeperstraete, B. (2021). Towards an EU import ban on forced labour and modern
slavery-February 2021 Executive Summary (Discussion Paper).
https://www.europarl.europa.eu/doceo/document/E-7-2013-002019_EN.html
Verisk Maplecroft. (2019). Child labour index 2019: Overview and findings.
https://humanrights.wbcsd.org/project/child-labour-index-2019/
Victims of Trafficking and Violence Protection Act of 2000, Pub. L. No. 106-386 §§ 106-108,
114 Stat. 1464, 1466. https://www.govinfo.gov/content/pkg/PLAW106publ386/pdf/PLAW-106publ386.pdf
von der Leyen, U. (2019). A Union that strives for more. My agenda for Europe: Political
Guidelines for the next European Commission 2019-2024. In European Commission.
https://ec.europa.eu/info/sites/info/files/political-guidelines-nextcommission_en_0.pdf
Watson, D. I. (2014). Poverty and Basic Needs. Encyclopedia of Food and Agricultural Ethics,
February, 1529–1535. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-6167-4
Weil, D. (2018). Creating a strategic enforcement approach to address wage theft: One
academic’s journey in organizational change. Journal of Industrial Relations, 60(3),
438–460. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022185618765551
Wilde-Ramsing, J., Wolfkamp, M., & de Leth, D. O. (2021). The next step for corporate
accountability in the Netherlands: the new Bill for Responsible and Sustainable
International Business Conduct [Blog post]. Nova BHRE.
https://novabhre.novalaw.unl.pt/new-bill-for-responsible-sustainable-internationalbusiness-conduct-netherlands/
Worker-Driven Social Responsibility Network. (n.d.). Statement of Principles. Retrieved
March 28, 2021, from https://wsr-network.org/what-is-wsr/statement-of-principles/
World Bank Blogs. (2021). Updated estimates of the impact of COVID-19 on global poverty:
Looking back at 2020 and the outlook for 2021 [Blog post].
https://blogs.worldbank.org/opendata/updated-estimates-impact-covid-19-globalpoverty-looking-back-2020-and-outlook-2021?cid=pov_tt_poverty_en_ext
World Economic Forum. (2020). The Global Competitiveness Report: How Countries are
Performing on the Road to Recovery (K. Schwab & S. Zahidi (Eds.)).
http://www3.weforum.org/docs/WEF_TheGlobalCompetitivenessReport2020.pdf
World Trade Organization. (n.d.-a). Agreement on Implementation of Article VI (Antidumping). Retrieved May 16, 2021, from
https://www.wto.org/english/docs_e/legal_e/ursum_e.htm#fAgreement
World Trade Organization. (n.d.-b). Aid for trade. Retrieved March 28, 2021, from
https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/devel_e/a4t_e/aid4trade_e.htm
World Trade Organization. (n.d.-c). Understanding the WTO - Anti-dumping, subsidies,
safeguards: contingencies, etc. Retrieved May 16, 2021, from
https://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/whatis_e/tif_e/agrm8_e.htm
180
World Trade Organization. (1994a). GATT 1994. Article II: Determination of Dumping (p. 4).
https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/publications_e/ai17_e/anti_dumping_art2_oth.p
df
World Trade Organization. (1994b). GATT 1994. Article VI: Anti-Dumping and Countervailing
Duties. https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/gatt_ai_e/art6_e.pdf
World Trade Organization. (1994c). GATT 1994. Article XX: General Exceptions (p. 37).
https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/gatt_ai_e/art20_e.pdf
World Trade Organization. (1996). Singapore Ministerial Declaration WT/MIN(96)/DEC.
https://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/minist_e/min96_e/wtodec_e.htm
World Trade Organization. (2015). Nairobi Ministerial Declaration WT/MIN(15)/DEC. Tenth
Ministerial Conference in Nairobi.
https://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/minist_e/mc10_e/mindecision_e.htm
World Trade Organization. (2016). Members and Observers.
https://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/whatis_e/tif_e/org6_e.htm
Wu, M. (2008). Free Trade and the Protection of Public Morals: An Analysis of the Newly
Emerging Public Morals Clause Doctrine. Yale J. Int’l L., 33(1), 215–248.
https://digitalcommons.law.yale.edu/yjil/vol33/iss1/6
Zamfir, I. (2019a). Human rights in EU trade agreements: The human rights clause and its
application. EPRS, European Parliamentary Research Service, PE 637.975(July).
https://www.europarl.europa.eu/thinktank/en/document.html?reference=EPRS_BRI(
2019)637975
Zamfir, I. (2019b). Child labour: A priority for EU human rights action. EPRS, European
Parliamentary Research Service, PE 633.142(January).
https://www.europarl.europa.eu/RegData/etudes/BRIE/2019/633142/EPRS_BRI(2019
)633142_EN.pdf?
Zhao, L., Wang, F., & Zhao, Z. (2016). Trade liberalization and child labor. IZA Discussion
Papers No. 10295. http://ftp.iza.org/dp10295.pdf
19 U.S.C. § 1307, Convict-made goods; importation prohibited, June 17, 1930, ch. 497, title
III, §307, 46 Stat. 689 ; Pub. L. 106–200, title IV, §411(a), May 18, 2000, 114 Stat. 298
https://www.govinfo.gov/content/pkg/USCODE-2011-title19/html/USCODE-2011title19-chap4-subtitleII-partI-sec1307.htm
19 U.S.C. § 2497 (4), Supplemental agricultural disaster assistance, October 21, 2009, Pub. L.
111-80, title VII, §745(b), Oct. 21, 2009, 123 Stat. 2130.298
https://www.govinfo.gov/app/details/USCODE-2009-title19/USCODE-2009-title19chap12-subchapVIII-sec2497
19 C.F.R. § 12.42, Findings of Commissioner of CBP. https://www.ecfr.gov/cgi-bin/textidx?SID=a4481bd333acdfc4f534f3d73993b732&mc=true&node=sg19.1.12_141.sg16&
rgn=div7
48 C.F.R. § 22.1504, Violations and remedies.
https://www.law.cornell.edu/cfr/text/48/22.1504
181
Development International e.V.