PA P ER SERI ES
D I SCU SSI O N
IZA DP No. 470
Does Globalisation Increase Child Labour?
Alessandro Cigno
Furio C. Rosat i
Lorenzo Guarcello
April 2002
Forschungsinst it ut
zur Zukunf t der Arbeit
Inst it ut e f or t he St udy
of Labor
Does Globalisation Increase Child Labour?
Alessandro Cigno
University of Florence, CESifo, CHILD and IZA, Bonn
Furio C. Rosati
University of Sassari, University of Rome “Tor Vergata” and UNICEF
Lorenzo Guarcello
UNICEF
Discussion Paper No. 470
April 2002
IZA
P.O. Box 7240
D-53072 Bonn
Germany
Tel.: +49-228-3894-0
Fax: +49-228-3894-210
Email:
[email protected]
This Discussion Paper is issued within the framework of IZA’s research area
Internationalization of Labor Markets. Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s)
and not those of the institute. Research disseminated by IZA may include views on policy, but
the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions.
The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research
center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an
independent, nonprofit limited liability company (Gesellschaft mit beschränkter Haftung)
supported by the Deutsche Post AG. The center is associated with the University of Bonn
and offers a stimulating research environment through its research networks, research
support, and visitors and doctoral programs. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally
competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and
(iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. The current
research program deals with (1) mobility and flexibility of labor, (2) internationalization of
labor markets, (3) welfare state and labor markets, (4) labor markets in transition countries,
(5) the future of labor, (6) evaluation of labor market policies and projects and (7) general
labor economics.
IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage
discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised
version may be available on the IZA website (www.iza.org) or directly from the author.
IZA Discussion Paper No. 470
April 2002
ABSTRACT
Does Globalisation Increase Child Labour?
There is no empirical evidence that trade exposure per se increases child labour. As trade
theory and household economics lead us to expect, the cross-country evidence seems to
indicate that trade reduces or, at worst, has no significant effect on child labour. Consistently
with the theory, a comparatively well educated labour force, and active social policies, appear
to be conducive to a reduction in child labour. For countries with a largely uneducated
workforce, the problem is not so much globalisation, as being allowed to take part in it.
JEL Classification:
Keywords:
D13, F12, I20, J13, J24, O15
child labour, globalisation, education, health, skill premium, trade
Alessandro Cigno
Università di Firenze
Dipartimento di Studi sullo Stato
Via S. Caterina d’Alessandria 3
I-50129 Firenze
Italy
Tel.: +39 055-4622922
Fax: +39 055-472102
Email:
[email protected]
1. Introduction
Globalisation, the process by which an increasing share of world production is traded
internationally, and the productive systems of different countries become increasingly
integrated, is credited with many merits and held responsible for many evils. The
present paper attempts to answer the following question: given that international trade
has major allocative and distributive implications, are children likely to be among the
losers? More specifically, given that child labour appears to be on the increase
worldwide, could this be a consequence of globalisation?
The current wave of globalisation started soon after the end of the second
world war, but got in its stride in the 1980s, as rapid progress in information and
transport technology compounded the effects of trade liberalisation (Krugman, 1995).
To try and understand the consequences of globalisation it thus seems reasonable to
look at what has happened over the last couple of decades. Much of the existing
literature on the subject is concerned with the consequences of globalisation for wages
and employment in the developed world (Wood, 1998). Since our concern is child
labour, and child labour is concentrated mainly in the developing world,2 we shall
focus on developing countries.
A useful source of cross-country information on child labour and international
trade are the World Bank’s Development Indicators. Another valuable source of
information on trade openness is Sachs and Warner (1995), which classifies a country
as “open” if free from a number of obstacles to trade, from non-tariff barriers to state
monopoly on major exports. Combining these two sources of information, we
assembled a set of relevant data on all developing countries for the relevant years
available, namely 1980, 1990, 1995 and 1998.
The measure of child labour that figures in the Development Indicators is the
participation rate of persons aged 10 to 14. That is an important indicator of early
involvement in work activities, but presents two lacunae. The first is that, by
excluding children younger than 10, it leaves out a large, arguably the most
worrisome, part of the phenomenon in question. A substantial number of children in
that age group is working either part or full time. According to the 1999 National
2
Though not on a comparable scale, child labour is becoming a problem also in developed countries.
There, however, it is largely connected with clandestine immigration. One way or another, the main
source of child workers is thus the developing world.
2
Council of Applied Economic Research survey of rural Indian households, for
example, around 10 percent of children aged 6 to 10 were reported by their parents as
working in one way or another.3 The second lacuna is that this measure of child
labour does not include children working within the household, and does not account
for children engaged in unofficial, especially if illegal, work activities. We know from
other sources, however, that children are extensively engaged in domestic activities,
and that many children reportedly doing nothing could be actually working. For
example, in the already mentioned Indian survey, the place where children are most
commonly reported to be working is the household. In the same survey, as much as a
quarter of children between the ages of 6 and 14 is reported as neither working nor
attending school, but there are reasons to suspect that a sizeable proportion of them
works (Cigno and Rosati, 2002).
As an alternative to this measure of child labour, we shall use also the primary
school non-attendance rate (the complement to unity of the primary school net
enrolment rate reported in the Development Indicators). The shortcoming of this
alternative measure is that a child not attending school is not necessarily working. On
the other hand, however, children not reporting for school are more difficult to
monitor, and thus more at risk of exposure to the worst forms of abuse - from
hazardous or very hard work, to soldiering and prostitution - than children regularly
available for inspection by the school authorities (Cigno, Rosati and Tzannatos,
2002). Therefore, the non-attendance rate is not only a correlate of child labour at
very young ages, but also a valuable danger signal. The 10-14 labour participation
rate and the primary school non-attendance rate are positively correlated with each
other across countries and years of observation, but the coefficient of correlation is
much less than unity.
3
Detailed information for about 40 countries can be found at www.ucw-project.org.
3
Figure 1.Correlation between Child Labour and Trade
60
Child Labour 10-14 (% of age group)
50
40
30
20
10
0
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
Trade, (% of GDP, PPP)
Figures 1 and 2 show that both measures of child labour are negatively
correlated with trade openness as conventionally measured (imports plus exports,
divided by GDP). The interpolating line is shown just as a guide to the eye, and
should not be interpreted as a causal relationship. It is interesting to note, however,
that the dispersion around this interpolating line tends to decrease as trade increases.
In other words, countries with little international exposure differ more widely with
regard to child labour than countries well integrated in the global economy. Those
with trade up to 20 percent of GDP, for example, have labour participation rates for
10-14 year olds ranging from little over zero to more than 55 percent, and primary
school non-attendance rates ranging between zero and 80 percent. By contrast, in
countries with trade equal to more than 40 percent of GDP, both measures of child
labour range between little over zero and little over a quarter of the relevant age
group.
4
Figure 2. Correlation between Primary School Non –Attendance rate and Trade
80
70
100-Enrollment rates
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
0
20
40
60
80
100
Trade (% of GDP, PPP)
The finding that trade makes countries more alike is hardly surprising. The
finding that trading countries tend to have less child labour than autarchic ones is less
obvious. Let us see what economic theory has to say on the matter.
2. Household decisions
The first thing to be kept in mind is that children do not normally choose to work.
Most have that decision taken for them, mainly by their parents. Even in the case of a
child who was expelled or run away from home, the reasons for his or her
predicament can be traced back to parental actions.4 The second is that the great
majority of working children is employed in the family business, most often a farm, or
in the household itself (looking after younger siblings, and generally substituting for
adult members in the performance of domestic chores).5 Therefore, the first piece of
economic theory to be looked at is household economics, which describes the
4
The only exception are children who lost their family of origin because of some catastrophic event
(war, natural disaster), and those who were abducted; see Cigno, Rosati and Tzannatos (2002).
5
See Cigno, Rosati and Tzannatos (2001).
5
household as a “small open economy” immersed in a wider market economy (Cigno,
1991).
Much of this literature is based on the assumption that a parent, or parents
jointly, act as a kind of benevolent dictator. Except in extreme cases,6 however, many
of the theoretical predictions are qualitatively the same whether one assumes that
parents are altruistically inclined towards their offspring (Becker, 1981) or ultimately
self-interested (Cigno 1993; Rosati 1996). So long as parents care about their own as
well as their children’s consumption, the decision whether to send a child to work or
to school does in fact depend on essentially three things: the cost (including the
opportunity-cost) of education, the expected return to education, an the extent to
which parents are able to finance educational investments.7
Three types of outcome are possible (Cigno and Rosati, 2002). If the marginal
cost of education (say, the cost of increasing the child’s future earning ability by one
dollar) is everywhere higher than the maximum that parents are willing to pay for it,
we have a corner solution with the child working full time. Another corner solution
arises if the marginal cost of education for a child studying full time is lower than the
minimum at which parents are willing to forgo their children’s earnings altogether. If
that is the case, the child studies full time. If the marginal cost of education falls
between those two limits, we have an interior solution, with the child working and
attending school at the same time. How much parents are willing to pay, at the
margin, for a child’s education depends not only on preferences, but also on the
expected return to education (Rosenzweig, 1995). If parental preferences are nonaltruistic, it will depend also on how much of that return can be appropriated by
parents (Cigno, 1993; Rosati, 1996).
An important role in determining whether a child will work or go to school is
played by the capital market. Suppose that a child’s future earnings could be
substantially enhanced by education. Were it possible to borrow against those
expected future earnings, parents could use the amount borrowed to finance the
child’s education and current consumption. If that is not possible, however, the child’s
education will have to be financed out of the household’s current earnings and assets.
6
Basu and Van (1998), for example, assume that parents will make their children work only if the
alternative is starvation.
7
See Cigno and Rosati (2002), Grootaert and Kanbur (1995), Rosati (2000).
6
2.1 The effects of wage rate changes
If the time-allocation problem has an interior solution, wage rate changes have
substitution-effects. In the absence of a liquidity constraint, any wage increase will
have also an income-effect on the demand for education, positive if we assume that
human capital (the child’s future skill level) is a normal good,8. In the presence of a
binding liquidity constraint, however, there can be income-effects only if the change
concerns current wage rates.
Consider first the case of an increase in the wage rate for uneducated workers,
holding other wage rates constant. As the expected return to education falls, there is a
substitution away from education. There is, on the other hand, a positive incomeeffect, stronger in households where the parents are themselves uneducated.. The net
effect on the supply of child labour is thus ambiguous.
The picture is somewhat different if there is an increase in the wage rate for
educated workers. As the expected return to education increases, the substitution is
now away from child labour. In households where the adults are educated, the
substitution-effect will be reinforced by an income-effect. Where the adults are
uneducated, there will be an income-effect only if the liquidity constraint is not
binding. The supply of child labour will fall anyway.
If the household is initially at a corner, with the child either working full time
or studying full time, there will obviously be no substitution effects. But a large
enough increase in the wage rate for educated workers will (and an increase in the
wage rate for uneducated workers may) reduce child labour.
2.2 The effects of policy
We have seen that capital market imperfection establishes a link between child labour
participation, and current income (Balland and Robinson, 2000, Rosati 1999).
Whether this household-level link will translate into an aggregate-level relationship
between child labour and per-capita income depends on income distribution and
educational policies. Other things being equal, the more successful a government is in
re-distributing income through the tax system, or in directly subsidising education, the
lower the child labour rate associated with any given level of per-capita income.
8
Either in the sense that higher future earnings translate into higher future consumption for the child
(Becker, 1981), and that this is a normal good, or in the sense that they translate into higher future
consumption for the parents themselves (Cigno, 1993), and that this is a normal good.
7
Parents determine the household’s supply of child labour (to itself or to the
market) not only by disposing of the time of existing children, but also by determining
how many children there are. Parental actions, such as frequency of intercourse and
use of contraception, do in fact condition the probability distribution of a birth. Once a
child is born, parental actions, such as expenditure for the child’s nutrition and health
care,9 condition the child’s probability of survival to an age where he or she can be
made to work (Cigno, 1998). This last aspect is particularly relevant for developing
countries, where infant mortality is counted per hundred rather than thousand live
births.
Of course, the probability that a child will survive to school age depends not
only on parental actions, but also on external causes, such as climate and genetic
factors. It depends also on government expenditure for health and sanitation. The
higher this expenditure, the higher, other things being equal, the probability that a
child will survive to school age, and later to adulthood; the higher, consequently, the
return to investing in a child’s education. Other things, however, are not equal.
If public health expenditure is a complement for private (parental) expenditure
on a child’s health and nutrition, in the sense that the former raises the expected
marginal utility of the latter, then an increase in public expenditure will induce parents
to raise their contribution. If the two are substitutes, in the sense that public
expenditure lowers the expected marginal utility of private expenditure, the effect may
be the opposite. May, not will, because there is a income and a substitution effect. The
latter is definitely negative, but the former is positive because parents can now
procure the same number of surviving children at lower cost, and it is thus as if they
had become richer (Cigno, 1998). In the first case, public expenditure crowds in
private expenditure, in the second it crowds it out.
Even if there is crowding out, however, it is unlikely that this will be total. We
may thus expect an increase in public expenditure for health or sanitation to reduce
the incidence of child labour by inducing parents to switch from a high-fertility, lowsurvival, low-education to a low-fertility, high-survival, high-education strategy.10
Micro-econometric evidence of interactions between public health provision and
9
Expenditures on nutrition and health reduce not only mortality, but also morbidity. Since the two are
positively correlated, everything we say about the effects of parental and government actions on the
probability premature death applies also to the probability of illness (and thus to a child’s future ability
to work or study with profit).
8
educational policies is reported in Cigno and Rosati (2002) and Rosenzweig and
Wolpin (1982).
3. The effect of trade
The second relevant piece of economics is trade theory. We know from David
Ricardo that a country enjoys higher welfare if, instead of directly producing all the
goods its members wish to consume, it specializes in the production of goods it can
produce at comparatively lower cost, and exchanges the surplus for those it does not
produce in sufficient quantity. The same may be said about households, and about
individuals within households Cigno (1991, 2001).
Since the cost of a good depends on the prices of the factors used for its
production, and the prices of traded factors are the same everywhere, differences in
the relative costs of traded goods reflect differences in the relative prices of nontradeables used as factors of production. In turn, the relative prices of these immobile
factors reflect differences in endowments. Heckscher-Ohlin theory predicts that
countries will specialize in the production of those traded goods that make more
intensive use of the non-traded factor of which they have relative abundance. It also
predicts that the benefits of trade will accrue to the comparatively more abundant
factor; in other words, that the rental price of the comparatively more abundant factor
will rise relative to that of the less abundant one.
What are these, all-important, non-traded factors? In traditional classroom
accounts, they are capital and labour. Countries with a relative abundance of capital
(developed countries, the so-called North) will thus export capital-intensive products.
Countries with a relative abundance of labour (developing countries, the so-called
South) will export labour-intensive products. Since, within each country, an increase
in trade raises the price of the abundant factor relative to that of the scarce one, an
implication of this vision of the world is that globalisation will make workers worseoff (relative to capitalists) in the North, better-off in the South. This, incidentally,
justifies the alarm of trade unions in the North, but not the opposition of so many
paladins of the underprivileged in the South.
10
In Becker’s terminology, public expenditure thus triggers a substitution of quality for quantity (of
children).
9
3.1 Heckscher-Ohlin reconsidered
This vision of the world has somewhat changed over the last couple of decades.
Partly, this is a reflection of a general re-thinking of the development process. While
early growth theory equated economic growth with the accumulation of physical
capital (buildings and machinery) per head of population, modern theory does in fact
attach much greater importance to the accumulation of human capital.11 Partly,
however, the change of emphasis comes also from a recognition that physical capital
is anything but immobile. Machinery can be moved around, and buildings can be
taken down and rebuilt elsewhere. Since the financial capital (equity or debt
instruments) needed to pay for plants and machinery is highly mobile, physical capital
is then mobile too.
Human capital, by contrast, is embodied in skilled workers. These are more
mobile than their unskilled brethren, but they, too, have their international mobility
restricted by immigration rules and personal ties. As a broad generalization, one might
then say that the fixed factors determining the comparative advantages of different
countries are predominantly their different skill endowments. Of course, in the same
way as capital endowments can be modified by investment, so skill endowments can
be modified by education, but education takes much longer than the purchase of a
new machine, or the construction of a plant, and workers are by-and-large more
durable than physical capital. Starting from these premises, Adrian Wood has reformulated the theory of comparative advantage in terms of skill endowments: trading
countries make and export the goods that make greater use of their comparatively
more abundant skill level. Within each trading country, the benefit of increased world
trade will then accrue to members of the relatively larger skill group (Wood, 1994). In
other words, the wage rate of the comparatively larger group will rise relative to those
of the others. Without special assumptions, however, the theory does not tell us
whether the wage rates of the comparatively smaller groups will fall in absolute
terms. As we will see, this is of some relevance.
For our purposes, the relevant skill categorization is into workers with less
than completed primary education, workers with completed primary education, and
workers with secondary or higher education. In developed countries, the proportion of
11
Growth theorists have always been aware that both kinds of capital matter. If a simplification was
required for analytical tractability, however, the variable left out used to be human capital. Starting
with Becker, Murphy and Tamura (1990), the omitted variable now tends to be physical capital;.
10
workers with less than completed primary education is negligible, and there are
comparatively many workers with secondary or higher education. In those countries,
globalization can thus be expected to raise the wage differential between more and
less educated workers. In developing countries, by contrast, the proportion of workers
with secondary or higher education is generally very small.12 In some of these
countries, the comparatively larger group is that of workers who have not even
completed primary education.13 There, globalization will raise the skill premium as in
developed countries. In other developing countries, however, the comparatively larger
group is that of workers with completed primary education.14 Here, globalization will
reduce the skill premium.
Table 1
Descriptive Statistics for the Variables Employed in the Regressions
Variable
Child Labour
Trade
Open
Gdp
Health Expenditure
100-Enrollment rate
Primary
Secondary
Mean Std. Dev.
18.567
32.200
0.426
3361.12
2.409
22.257
0.179
0.108
16.180
48.685
0.495
3594.67
1.437
22.289
0.153
0.115
Min
Max
0
0
0
343.7
0.0001
0.100
0.009
0.001
70.89
570.87
1
24200
7.76
85.5
0.918
0.589
Where there is a comparative abundance of workers with completed primary
education, globalization may thus be expected to raise the wage rate of this group
relative to that of less educated workers. As we saw in the last section, that will
reduce child labour, and the effect will be larger if the wage rates of educated workers
increase in absolute, as well as relative terms. A micro-econometric analysis of panel
data for Vietnam15, a country with a comparative abundance of educated workers,
finds a negative effect of international integration on child labour. By contrast, where
there is a comparative abundance of workers who have not even completed primary
education, child labour may rise or fall. It will definitely rise if the wage rates of the
educated workers fall in absolute, as well as in relative terms.
12
Less than 11 percent, on average, over the 1980-98 period; but it can go as low as 0.1, or as high as
59 percent (see Table 1).
13
The average of all developing countries for the 1980-98 period is nearly 70 percent (see Table 1).
14
The average is 18 percent, but the largest share, 92 percent, is a hundred times the smallest (see
Table 1).
11
3.2 Intra-industry trade
Globalization does not just mean more trade. It means also more trade in intermediate
goods. By facilitating the coordination of dispersed production activities, falling
transport costs and advances in information technology in fact favour the
segmentation of production processes, and the location of different segments of the
same process in different countries. The growing literature on this new aspect of
international trade16 emphasizes the effects of market size on the international
division of labour.
Gilles Duranton adds an extra dimension to this new trade theory by pointing
out that, since the output of different segments of the same production process must
be ultimately combined into a final good, the extent to which these different segments
can be carried out in different countries is limited by the ability of different work
forces to produce intermediate goods that will prove mutually compatible. As this
means, in large measure, ability to deliver goods in time, and of the right quality,
satisfying the compatibility requirement is clearly facilitated by the existence of work
forces with similar characteristics. That is consistent with the observation that intraindustry trade has so far occurred mainly among countries at the same stage of
development.
This argument points to a trade-off between comparative advantage, which
privileges trade with unequals, and compatibility, which favours trade with equals.
Tension between these two considerations may lead to complex dynamics, with a
phase in which international trade is driven primarily by differences in relative factor
endowments, and one in which work forces with similar characteristics form
integrated production systems - coalitions of individuals, better-off trading with one
another than with the world at large - that will uncouple from the rest of the world
economy (Duranton, 1998). Instead of increasing wage inequalities within countries,
international trade could thus end up increasing inequalities between countries
(Krugman and Venables, 1995).
Acceptance into these clubs of countries, the members of which speak only to
one another, is thus associated with the availability of educated workers in sufficient
numbers. The countries more likely to be left out are the same ones where, according
to Heckscher-Ohlin theory, exposure to international trade is most likely to reduce the
15
16
The Vietnam Living Standards Survey, complemented by a survey of community-level prices.
For a survey, see Ottaviano and Puga (1997).
12
incentive for parents to educate their children. According to “old” trade theory, the
danger for these countries is to become more backward through trade. According to
“new” trade theory, the danger is that these countries will be excluded from economic
integration with the more developed ones. Either way, children will suffer.
4. Cross-country evidence
Combined with household economics, trade theory thus tells us that exposure to
international trade may or may not increase child labour. As we have seen, a
necessary condition for this to be the case is that the country opening itself to
international competition should have a comparatively large share of educated
workers. Household economics on its own further tells us that policies aimed at
lowering mortality are likely to reduce also child labour.
To test these propositions on the cross-country data mentioned in the
Introduction, we regressed child labour on trade openness, real per-capita income,
health policy, and skill composition. Child labour is alternatively measured by the 1014 labour participation rate, or by the primary school non-attendance rate. Trade
openness is alternatively represented by the trade ratio (exports plus imports, divided
by GDP) or by a dummy taking value one if the country is open according to the
Sachs-Warner definition, zero otherwise. Real per-capita income is measured as GDP
in constant PPP units per head of population. Health policy is represented by the share
of public health expenditure in GDP. Skill composition is represented by the share of
the workforce aged 25 or over which completed only primary education, and by that
which attained secondary or higher education (the reference group is that without
completed primary education). Descriptive statistics are reported in Table 1.
Skill composition is a stock concept, reflecting the cumulated effects of past
educational policies. In view of the fact that current educational policies affect the
incentive to send children to school, it would have been desirable to control for these
policies too. Since child labour is a close correlate of school attendance,17 however,
there is no way we could do that with our data. It would have also been desirable to
control for differences in income distribution as a way of capturing the proportion of
households subject to a binding liquidity constraint, but the information is not
17
Where child labour is measured by the primary non-attendance rate, the correlation coefficient is –1.
13
comparable across countries and dates of observation. To the extent that public health
expenditure and the share of educated workers in the total workforce are symptoms of
government activism, however, these variables may be thought to act as proxies for
income distribution.
Table 2a reports fixed-effect18 OLS estimates of the effects of trade on our two
measures of child labour. If skill composition is not controlled for, trade raises the 1014 labour participation rate, but has no significant effect on the primary school nonattendance rate. If skill composition is controlled for, trade has no significant effect on
either measure of child labour. The picture is somewhat more favourable to
globalisation when trade is replaced by a dummy taking value 1 if the country is open
in the Sachs-Warner sense, 0 otherwise. (Table 2b). Openness then reduces child
labour, no matter how measured, even if we do not control for skill composition.19
Income, and public health expenditure, reduce both measures of child labour.
The effects of skill composition have the expected sign. The proportion of
workers with completed primary education has a negative effect on child labour, and
so does the share of workers with secondary or higher education (but takes
significance away from the share of workers with completed primary education).
These findings are consistent with the theoretical considerations of the last
section. What the data tell us in essence is that, other things being equal, international
competition reduces or, at worst, has no significant effect on child labour.
Interestingly, the more optimistic scenario is associated with the more stringent
definition of trade openness, the one that takes into account the conditions under
which trade takes place, rather than the actual volume of trade. Since the beneficial
effects of international exposure come through relative price changes, it is in fact not
irrelevant whether internal prices are subject to government control or free to adjust to
international prices, and whether or not foreign trade is distorted by quotas and state
monopoly.
18
To account for unobserved heterogeneity
This is consistent with already mentioned longitudinal evidence from Vietnam; see Edmonds and
Pavcnik (2001).
19
14
Table 2a Estimates using the trade ratio as a measure of openness
Dependent Variable Child Labour
0.065
(2.34)*
-0.003
(8.57)**
-3.202
(5.05)**
Trade
Gdp
Health
expend.
Primary
0.05
(1.65)
-0.002
(4.71)**
-2.036
(2.60)*
-17.775
(2.57)*
Secondary
Constant
31.441
(17.67)**
28.581
(13.78)**
Dependent Variable 100-Enrollment rate
0.031
(1.1)
-0.001
(2.89)**
-2.136
(2.92)**
-8.004
-1.18
-43.291
(4.75)**
29.735
(15.28)**
Obs.
211
147
147
R-squared
0.41
0.41
0.49
Absolute value of t-statistics in parentheses
* significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%
Trade
Gdp
Health
expend.
0.063
(1.37)
-0.003
(5.05)**
-3.882
(2.95)**
0.037
(0.78)
-0.001
(2.01)*
-1
-0.74
-42.77
(3.83)**
36.286
(10.68)**
30.95
(8.89)**
Primary
Secondary
Constant
Obs.
R-squared
142
0.26
102
0.33
0.02
(0.42)
-0.001
(0.86)
-1.214
(0.91)
-34.788
(3.00)**
-37.173
(2.09)*
31.591
(9.19)**
102
0.36
The coefficients of the skill composition variables measure the effects of
increasing the proportion of the total workforce that ha achieved a certain educational
level (primary only, secondary or higher), holding all the other variables (openness
included) constant at their mean values. Given that openness is quite high on average
(43.35 percent of the sample is “open” by the Sachs-Warner definition, trade is on
average 32.25 percent of GDP), these findings are compatible with the proposition
that (a) trade increases the skill premium in countries with a comparative abundance
of educated workers, and (b) only countries with a sufficiently educated workforce are
able to integrate in the emerging global economy. However, if we try to interact
openness with skill composition, all variables other than the interaction terms lose
significance. Clearly, therefore, our data do not allow us to disentangle the effect of
skill composition per se, from the combined effect of skill composition and trade
openness.
15
Table 2b Estimates using Sachs-Warner measure of openness
Dependent Variable Child Labour
-10.243
(5.47)**
-0.002
(7.39)**
-2.881
(4.03)**
Open
Gdp
Health
expend
Primary
-7.664
(3.74)**
-0.001
(5.22)**
-2.198
(2.80)**
-13.049
(1.87)
Secondary
Constant
35.955
(18.36)**
32.165
(14.37)**
-6.999
(3.64)**
-0.001
(2.89)**
-2.474
(3.35)**
-3.086
(0.45)
-43.505
(4.35)**
33.307
(15.75)**
Obs.
166
136
136
R-squared
0.49
0.44
0.51
Absolute value of t-statistics in parentheses
* significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%
Dependent Variable 100-Enrollment rate
Open
Gdp
Health
expend
-7.128
(1.86)
-0.002
(4.28)**
-4.436
(2.94)**
-2.077
(0.58)
-0.001
(2.04)*
-1.315
(0.95)
-43.612
(3.73)**
41.921
(10.58)**
32.225
(8.46)**
Primary
Secondary
Constant
Obs.
R-squared
116
0.3
94
0.31
-1.293
(0.37)
-0.0003
(0.63)
-1.389
(1.02)
-35.673
(2.96)**
-40.63
(2.16)*
32.64
(8.74)**
94
0.35
The share of public health expenditure in GDP significantly reduces the 10-14
labour participation rate whether or not we control for skill composition, but its effect
on the primary school non-attendance rate is insignificant if skill composition is
controlled for. This finding is coherent with the theoretical argument and microeconometric evidence mentioned in section 3, that health and educational outcomes
are jointly determined by health and education policies. But, again, we are unable to
capture these complex interactions with our cross-country data.
5. Conclusion
There is no empirical evidence that exposure to international trade, and economic
integration across national borders, raise the incidence of child labour. If anything, the
evidence points the other way. The theoretical explanation runs as follows. Parental
decisions whether a child should work or go to school depend on the costs and
benefits of education. Due to capital market imperfections, however, educational
investments may be limited by household liquidity constraints.
In a country that starts out with a largely uneducated workforce, globalisation
raises the wage rates of uneducated, relative to educated workers. That reduces the
incentive to educate a child, and raises the incentive to make the child work at the
earliest opportunity. On the other hand, if the wage rate of uneducated workers rises
16
in absolute as well as relative terms, this will have a positive income-effect on the
demand for education The net effects of globalisation are thus ambiguous.
Where the countries at the bottom of the pile are concerned, there is also
another problem. According to a variant of new trade theory, a country that starts out
with a largely uneducated workforce risks being excluded from trade in intermediate
goods with the more developed countries as the latter form exclusive clubs.
Globalisation could thus further impoverish countries with particularly unfavourable
initial conditions. For all these reasons, child labour is likely to rise where the share of
educated workers is very low.
By contrast, in a country that starts out with a comparatively large share of
educated workers, globalisation will raise the wage rates of these workers relative to
those of uneducated ones. Very few developing countries have a sizeable proportion
of the workforce educated to secondary or higher level, but some have a comparative
abundance of workers with completed primary education. For this elite of the
developing world, exposure to trade raises the incentive for parents to send their
children to school. However, if the wage rates of uneducated workers fall in absolute
terms, as well as relative to those of educated workers, there will be a negative
income-effect on the demand for education by households where the parents are
themselves uneducated, and this effect will be stronger in the presence of a the
liquidity constraint. The net effects of globalisation are thus ambiguous for this
category of developing countries too, but child labour is more likely to fall.
The role of national policy in the face of increasing international integration is
different for the two categories of countries. For those with a relative abundance of
uneducated workers, the primary aim is to restore (or create) the incentive for parents
to send their children to school. In countries with a relative abundance of educated
workers, by contrast, the problem is rather that of relaxing the liquidity constraint for
households where the parents are illiterate.
For all its limitations,20 the available cross-country evidence appears to bear
out these theoretical considerations. Controlling for GDP, skill composition of the
adult workforce, and weight of public health expenditure in GDP, trade openness is
found to have a negative effect on child labour (the ratio of trade to GDP has no
significant effect). The existence of an educated workforce (not the number of
20
But single-country evidence based on micro-data, to which we have referred in the body of the paper,
points in the same direction.
17
children currently going to school) is associated with a low incidence of child labour.
The share of public health expenditure in GDP tends to reduce child labour.
Concern that trade exposure per se could be a cause a rise in child labour does
not appear to be well founded, except insofar as countries with a largely uneducated
workforce could be left out of the globalisation process, and become poorer as a
result. There, however, the problem is not so much globalisation, as the ability to take
part in it.
References
Balland, J.M. and A. Robinson (2000), “Is Child Labor Inefficient?”, Journal of
Political Economy 108, 663-679
Basu, K. and P.H. Van (1998), “The Economics of Child Labor”, American Economic
Review 88, 412-427
Becker, G.S. (1981), A Treatise on the Family, Harvard University Press, Cambridge,
Mass.
Becker, G.S., Murphy, K.M. and R.F. Tamura (1990), “Human Capital, Fertility and
Economic Growth”, Journal of Political Economy 98, S12-S37
Cigno, A. (1991), Economics of the Family. Clarendon Press and Oxford University
Press, Oxford and New York
Cigno, A. (1993), “Intergenerational Transfers without Altruism: Family, Market and
State”, European Journal of Political Economy 7, 505-518
Cigno, A. (1998), “Fertility Decisions When Infant Survival Is Endogenous”, Journal
of Population Economics 11, 21-28
Cigno, A. (2001), “Comparative Advantage, Observability, and the Optimal Tax
Treatment of Families with Children”, International Tax and Public Finance 8, 455470
Cigno, A. and F.C. Rosati (2002), “Child Labour, Education and Nutrition in Rural
India”, Pacific Economic Review 7, 1-19.
Cigno, A., Rosati, F.C. and Z. Tzannatos (2002), Handbook of Child Labor, The
World Bank , Washington D.C.
Duranton, G. (1998), Globalisation, Productive Systems and Inequalities, Centre for
Economic Performance, London
Edmonds, E. and N. Pavcnik (2001), Does Globalisation Increase Child Work?,
Dartmouth College and NBER, mimeo
18
Grootaert, C. and R. Kanbur (1995), "Child Labor: An Economic Perspective",
International Labor Review 134, 187-203
Krugman, P. (1995), “Growing World Trade: Causes and Consequences”, Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity 1, 327-377
Krugman, P. and A. Venables (1995), “Globalisation and the Inequality of Nations”,
Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 857-880
Ottaviano, G. and D. Puga (1997), Agglomeration in the Global Economy: A Survey
of the New Economic Geography, CEPR W.P. N° 1699
Ray, R. (2000), “Analysis of Child Labour in Peru and Pakistan: a Comparative
Study”, Journal of Population Economics 13, 3-20
Rosati, F.C. (1996), "Social Security in a Non-Altruistic Model with Uncertainty and
Endogenous Fertility", Journal of Public Economics 60, 283-294
Rosati, F.C. (1999), "Child Work", World Bank D.P.
Rosati, F.C. (2000), Morocco: Reducing Child Labor by Increasing School
Availability. World Bank WP
Rosenzweig. M.R. (1995), “Why Are there Returns to Schooling?”, American
Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 85, 153-158
Rosenzweig. M.R. and K.J. Wolpin (1982), “Governmental Interventions and
Household Behavior in a Developing Country”, Journal of Development Economics
10, 209-225
Sachs, J.D. and A. Warner (1995), “Economic Reform and the Process of Global
Integration”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1
.
Wood, A. (1994), North-South Trade, Employment and Inequality, Clarendon Press,
Oxford
Wood, A. (1998), “Globalisation and the Rise in Labour Market Inequalities”,
Economic Journal 108, 1463-1482
19
IZA Discussion Papers
No.
Author(s)
Title
Area
455
J. T. Addison
C. R. Belfield
Unions and Establishment Performance:
Evidence from the British Workplace Industrial/
Employee Relations Surveys
3
03/02
456
T. M. Andersen
International Integration, Risk and the Welfare
State
2
03/02
457
M. Lindeboom
M. Kerkhofs
Health and Work of the Elderly: Subjective
Health Measures, Reporting Errors and the
Endogenous Relationship between Health and
Work
3
03/02
458
M. Galeotti
L. J. Maccini
F. Schiantarelli
Inventories, Employment and Hours
5
03/02
459
M. Biewen
The Covariance Structure of East and West
German Incomes and its Implications for the
Persistence of Poverty and Inequality
3
03/02
460
B. R. Chiswick
Y. Liang Lee
P. W. Miller
Family Matter: The Role of the Family in
Immigrants’ Destination Language Acquisition
2
03/02
461
M. Gurgand
D. N. Margolis
Welfare and Labor Earnings:
An Evaluation of the Financial Gains to Work
3
03/02
462
B. R. Chiswick
Y. Liang Lee
P. W. Miller
The Determinants of the Geographic
Concentration among Immigrants: Application to
Australia
2
03/02
463
E. Wasmer
Labor Supply Dynamics, Unemployment and
Human Capital Investments
5
03/02
464
W. Schnedler
U. Sunde
The Hold-Down Problem and the Boundaries of
the Firm: Lessons from a Hidden Action Model
with Endogenous Outside Option
1
03/02
465
J. Ermisch
M. Francesconi
Intergenerational Social Mobility and Assortative
Mating in Britain
1
04/02
466
J. E. Askildsen
E. Bratberg
Ø. A. Nilsen
Unemployment, Labour Force Composition and
Sickness Absence: A Panel Data Study
1
04/02
467
A. Venturini
C. Villosio
Are Immigrants Competing with Natives in the
Italian Labour Market? The Employment Effect
1
04/02
468
J. Wagner
The Impact of Risk Aversion, Role Models, and
the Regional Milieu on the Transition from
Unemployment to Self-Employment: Empirical
Evidence for Germany
1
04/02
469
R. Lalive
J. C. van Ours
J. Zweimüller
The Effect of Benefit Sanctions on the Duration
of Unemployment
3
04/02
470
A. Cigno
F. C. Rosati
L. Guarcello
Does Globalisation Increase Child Labour?
2
04/02
An updated list of IZA Discussion Papers is available on the center‘s homepage www.iza.org.
Date