Marcelo Bucheli and Erica Salvaj
Reputation and Political Legitimacy:
ITT in Chile, 1927-1972
The literature on multinational corporations argues that a foreign firm can legitimize its activities, improve its reputation in
a host country, and reduce the risk of hostile actions by the
host government (including expropriation) by approaching
and incorporating influential members of the domestic elite in
its business. By using the concept of obsolescing political legitimacy, we argue that this legitimating strategy can lead to a
loss of reputation and eventual illegitimacy when the host
country undergoes significant social and institutional changes.
When these changes take place, the domestic society can perceive that the multinational benefited from a previous social
and institutional order increasingly considered as illegitimate.
Under these circumstances, the new order will question the
legitimacy of the multinational's operations, increasing the risk
of expropriation. We illustrate our hypothesis with the case
of the political strategies of the International Telephone and
Telegraph Company (ITT) in Chile in the twentieth century.
T
his article studies the relationship between political legitimacy,
corporate reputation, and the risk of expropriation for a multinational corporation. Organizations try to legitimize their operations and
establish their reputations before a particular set of stakeholders. However, when stakeholders change and new stakeholders have new views
of legitimate activities, the new institutional environment can aftect the
firm's reputation before domestic society and the very legitimacy of its
operations.^ The loss of legitimacy of a foreign firm before the host society can lead to the expropriation of assets by the host government.
The authors wish to thank the Chilean government for generous funding of this research
provided through the Fondecyt grant no. 11085048. We also thank Adoración Alvaro-Moya
and Alfredo Enrione for their comments on previous versions of this article.
'Mark Sucbman, "Managing Legitimacy: Strategic and Institutional Approaches," Academy of Management Review 20, no. 3 (1995): 571-610.
Business History Review 87 (Winter 2013): 729-755. doi:io.ioi7/Sooo768o5i3OOiu6
© 2013 The President and Fellows of Harvard College. ISSN 0007-6805; 2044-768X (Web),
Marcelo Bucheli and Erica Salvaj / 730
The expropriation of foreign properfy by local governments peaked
in the 1960s and 1970s, when governments of many less-developed
countries took over the properties of multinational corporations, particularly in utilify and natural resource sectors.^ After a pause of almost
two decades, the early twenfy-first century witnessed the return of expropriation in some countries, requiring the review of this issue in a
historical perspective.
The literature on expropriation of foreign private properfy by domestic governments has analyzed this phenomenon through two main
theoretical approaches. The first one is the so-called obsolescing bargaining power theory, which argues roughly that the more a multinational has invested in a large amount of fixed assets, the easier it is
for the local government to change the rules (which can go from higher
taxation, royalties, or domestic-worker wages to outright expropriation).
With the investment already committed, the multinational cannot just
pack up and leave; it therefore is forced to renegotiate with the government from a weaker position than before.^ Moreover, the more knowledge a domestic sociefy has accumulated on how to run the business
owned by the multinational, the easier it will be for the domestic government to expropriate."* Neoinstitutional theory informs the second approach and explains the likelihood of expropriation based on the domestic country's institutional framework. Neoinstitutional theorists argue
that, in countries where the executive has limited constraints—mainly
dictatorial regimes—the risks of expropriation or arbitrary changes
in the rules regulating foreign investors' operations are higher than in
countries where the executive cannot change the rules at will, such as
in liberal democracies.^ These scholars agree with the obsolescing
^Stephen Kobrin, "Foreign Enterprise and Forced Divestment in LDCs," International
Organization 34, no. 1 (1980): 65-88; Mira Wilkins, The Matiiring of Multinational Enterprise: American Business Abroad fi-om 1914 to 1970 (Cambridge, Mass., 1974), 350-71.
3 Raymond Vernon, Sovereignty at Bay (New York, 1971); Louis Wells and David Smith,
"Mineral Agreements in Developing Countries: Stnicture and Substance," American Journal
oflnternational Law 69, no. 3 (1975): 560-90; Louis Wells, "Negotiating with Third World
Governments," Harvard Business Review 55, no. 1 (1977): 52-80; Nathan Fagre and Louis
Wells, "Bargaining Power of Multinationals and Host Governments," Journal of International Business Studies 13, no. 2 (1982): 9-23.
"• Stephen Kobrin, "Foreign Enterprise and Forced Divestment in LDCs."
^Witold Henisz, "The Institutional Environment for Economic Growth," Economics and
Politics 12, no. 1 (2000): 1-31; Witold Henisz, "Political Institutions and Policy Volatility,"
Economics and Politics 16, no. 1 (2004): 1-27; Yi Feng, "Political Freedom, Political Instability, and Pohcy Uncertainty: A Study of Political Institutions and Private Investment in Developing Countries," International Studies Quarterly 45, no. 2 (2001): 271-94; Nathan Jensen,
"Political Risk, Democratic Institutions, and Foreign Direct Investment," Journal of Politics
70, no. 4 (2008): 1040-52; Nathan Jensen, "Democratic Governance and Multinational Corporations: Political Regimes and Infiows of Foreign Direct Investment," International Organization 57, no. 3 (2003): 587-616; Nathan Jensen, Nation States and the Multinational
Corporation: A Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment (Princeton, 2006).
Reputation and Political Legitimacy / 731
bargaining scholars that utilify and natural resource sectors are more
vulnerable to expropriation than service industries.
We contribute to the scholarship on corporate reputation by suggesting links with the expropriation of foreign properfy, in particular by
proposing the concept of obsolescing political legitimacy. We define
this concept as a foreign firm's gradual loss of legitimacy before the
local sociefy, resulting from the identification of this firm with a previous social and/or political regime increasingly perceived as illegitimate
or archaic. We develop this concept using Daron Acemoglu and James
Robinson's conceptual framework developed in Economic Origins of
Dictatorship and Democracy as our starting point. According to these
scholars, the political status quo in a sociefy results from a history of
previous conflicts between difterent groups or social classes over economic resources. Each of these conflicting groups has an ideal set of political institutions from which they will obtain economic benefit, and at
the moment when a conflict is settled those with greater political power
define the final institutional outcome. The political institutions created
by the winners determine how the political power and economic resources are distributed.^ As long as a new institutional framework is
consolidated, the system preceding it wifl be considered and represented as illegitimate by those benefiting from the newly triumphant
system.^ We maintain that, if winners increasingly perceive an organization (a foreign private firm, in this case) as linked or (even worse)
having benefited from the previous institutional order, the winners will
increasingly question its legitimacy. The less legitimate they perceive
the firm's operations, the less protected its properfy rights will be. Neither corporate reputation nor political legitimacy is stable or eternal
and their decay is often as important as their initial construction.
A firm's loss of legitimacy can be sudden or gradual. In countries
with dramatic and rapid institutional changes (e.g., revolutions or decolonization), the challenges to the legitimacy of a foreign firm's operations wifl be fast and radical. Other countries, however, experience
gradual institutional changes that can be harder to perceive by foreign
firms. Sociologist Guillermo O'Donnell argues that gradual political
changes that benefit traditionally oppressed groups should allow firms
to adapt their strategy gradually to the new environment and not lose
legitimacy.^ In this article, we show that gradual and relatively slow
changes can lead some firms to remain in a comfort zone for too long
* Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson, Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy (Cambridge, U.K., 2006); Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson, "On the Economic Origins of Democracy," Daedalus 136, no. 1 (2007): 160-62.
'Guillermo O'Donnell, El estado burocrático autoritario (Buenos Aires, 1982)
«Ibid.
Marcelo Bucheli and Erica Salvaj / 732
and face challenges to their legitimacy in the long term when it is too
late to change. In this article we focus on a gradual change rather than
on a sudden one, which allows us to see a long-term process of loss of
political legitimacy. Our concept is relevant for the analysis of corporate
reputation. We follow other scholars who argue that general changes
in the standards on which reputation is based have consequent effects
on the firm's legitimacy.^ In our approach, we assume these general
changes in standards as resulting from social and institutional changes
in the society where the firm is operating.
Some scholars posit that a multinational can gain political legitimacy, reputation, knowledge of domestic politics, and resources from
other sectors by creating ties with the local elite (often done by appointing them to their boards).'" The concept of obsolescing political
legitimacy serves to show the limits of this particular strategy. If the
host country goes through a series of institutional changes affecting
domestic polities but the board composition does not change and remains tied to the previously existing order, domestic actors can question the legitimacy ofthe multinational's operations. The decision of a
firm to keep itself allied to the elite ruling the country prior to the social and institutional changes can be due to two causes. First, and in
opposition to what O'Donnell argues, this may result from the firm's
lack of perception of changes taking place in the host country. Or, second, the firm might be trying to legitimize its operations and maintain
a good reputation before particular stakeholders, while neglecting others. Corporate reputation has different dimensions, and a firm that
only focuses on one might be dangerously hurting others." We show
^Brayde
•
n King and David Whetten, "Rethinking the Relationship between Reputation
and Legitimacy: A Social Actor Conceptualization," Corporate Reputation Review li, no. 3
(2008): 192-207.
'"Tatiana Kostova and Srilata Zaheer, "Organizational Legitimacy under Conditions of
Complexity: The Case of the Multinational Enterprise," Academy of Management Review
24, no. 1 (1999): 64-81; Tatiana Kostova, Kendall Roth, and Tina Dacin, "Institutional Theory in the Study of Multinational Corporations: A Critique and New Directions," Academy of
Management Review 33, no. 4 (2008): 994-1006; Amy Hillman and William Wan, "The Determinants of MNE's Subsidiaries Political Strategies: Evidence of Institutional Duality,"
Journal of International Business Studies 36, no. 3 (2005): 322-40; Mark Mizruchi, "ViTiat
Do Interlocks Do? An Analysis, Critique, and Assessment of Research on Interlocking Directorates," j4;iniiaZ ÄeDieit) 0}Sociology 22, no. 1 (1996): 271-98; Joel Podolny, "Networks as
the Pipes and Prisms ofthe Market," American Journal of Sociology 107, no. 1 (2001): 3 3 60; Jean Boddewyn and Thomas Brewer, "International Business-Political Behavior: New
Theoretical Directions," Academy of Management Review 19, no. 1 (i994): 119-43; Joel Podolny, "A Status Based Model of Market Competition," American Journal of Sociology 98,
no. 4 (1993): 829-72.
" Mooweon Rhee and Michael Valdéz, "Contextual Factors Surrounding Reputation Damage with Potential Implications for Reputation Repair," Academy of Management Review
34, no. 1 (2009): 146-68.
Reputation and Political Legitimacy / 733
that afirmthat focuses on a legitimating strategy consisting of having
a board composed of the host country's traditional elite can gain reputation in just one dimension but lose it in another one. By analyzing
how a strategy to gain legitimacy and reputation before one social
group generated reputational problems before other social groups
(eventually ending in expropriation), we respond to recent calls to do
historical studies on corporate reputation that include the role of different stakeholders.'^
We illustrate our hypothesis by studying the operations of the U.S.based multinational telecommunications firm International Telephone
and Telegraph Company (ITT) in Chile between 1927 and 1972. Few
multinational corporations have a more negative reputation worldwide
than ITT. A recent informal poll among business historians ranked ITT
as the fifth most hated corporation in history. ^3 JXT owes part of its terrible reputation to its operations in Chile, where in 1972 some of ITT's
internal documents leaked to the media showed the company conspiring with the CIA to overthrow Chile's left-wing president Salvador Allende. This leak created an international scandal that tainted ITT's reputation for decades.'4 Unsurprisingly, the literature on ITT in Chile
foeuses overwhelmingly on the Allende affair. ^^ Y^Q show that the Allende affair was just the culmination of a decades-long loss of legitimacy and reputation before Chilean society, resulting from ITT's
expensive and poor service and its determination to keep a board of directors composed of Chilean traditional right, even when the rise of
more working- and middle-class political parties had eclipsed this group.
The board composition had allowed the firm to have important connections with Chile's corporate elite. However, in a country where average
citizens increasingly considered telephone service a necessity, the new
political parties attacked ITT and used the multinational's political
'^Christopher McKenna and Rowena Olegario, "Corporate Reputation and Regulation in
Historical Perspective," in Handbook of Corporate Reputation, ed. Michael Barnett and Tim
Pollock (Oxford, 2012), 260-77.
'3 "History's Thirteen Most Hated Companies," Daily Beast, last modified 22 June 2010,
http://vkww.dailybeast.com/.
"* Brent Fisse and John Braithwaite, The Impact of Publicity on Corporate Offenders (Al-
bany, 1983), 124-35.
"'Kristian Gustafson, Hostile Intent: U.S. Covert Operations in Chile, 1964-1974 (Washington, D.C, 2007); Peter Kornbluh, The Pinochet File (Washington, D.C, 2003); Lubna
Qureshi, Nixon, Kissinger, and Allende: U.S. Involvement in the 1973 Coup in Chile (Lanham, Md., 2009); Anthony Sampson, The Sovereign State o//7"r(New York, 1973); Paul Sigmund, The Overthrow of Allende and the Politics of Chile (Pittsburgh, 1977); Paul Sigmund,
Multinationals in Latin America: The Politics of Nationalization (Madison, Wise, 1980).
For an analysis of the post-1980s period, see Fernando Coloma and Luis Herrera, "Análisis
institucional y económico del sector de telecomunicaciones en Chile," Cuadernos de Economia 27, no. 125 (1990): 429-72.
Marcelo Bucheli and Erica Salvaj / 734
board composition to portray the firm as a relic of a less egalitarian past
and to question the legitimacy of its operations. Therefore, during the
half-century period we study, the company sought to legitimize itself
before a social group that was losing legitimacy, harming both the firm's
reputation and legitimacy, facilitating and legitimizing the eventual expropriation of its assets by the Chilean government.
We contribute to the literature on obsolescing bargaining power by
including the changing perceived legitimacy of foreign firms' operations. We study the relationship between political regimes and security
of foreign investors' property rights and show that a more democratic
regime can secure foreign firms' property rights better than a more autocratic regime, as long as the multinationals did not benefit from a
previous less democratic regime.'^ As wefl, we expand the understanding of corporate reputation by doing a historical analysis of the different dimensions of reputation of a particular firm. Finally, we contribute
to Latin American history by showing ITT's expropriation in Chile as
the last stage of a long process of loss of legitimacy.
We analyze the political composition of the board of directors of
ITT's Chilean subsidiary. Compañía de Teléfonos de Chile, by researching the political biographies of each member between 1950 and 1970.
As wefl, we perform a network analysis for 1969. Our primary sources
include the Chilean congressional debates, corporate reports, U.S. Senate hearings on ITT, declassified documents from the U.S. Central Intelligence Agency (CIA), Chilean government reports, and Chilean and
American media.
Political Environment and Early ITT Investments in Chile
ITT experienced spectacular growth becoming a major telecommunications multinational just one decade after its establishment in 1920.
By 1929, "no other American (or foreign) corporation had such huge investments abroad in communications [and] no other U.S. corporation
had so many employees in foreign lands."^'' During this growth, ITT
used, as one of its political strategies, the appointment of influential
'^A further theoretical discussion on how long-term and gradual institutional changes
can affect a corporation's legitimacy is found in Marcelo Bucheli and Jin-Uk Kim, "The State
as a Historical Construct in Organization Studies," in Organizations in Time, ed. Marcelo
Bucheli and R. Daniel Wadhwani (Oxford, 2014), 241-62. An application of this concept for
the case of multinationals operating in the agricultural sector can be found in Marcelo Bucheli and Min-Young Kim, "Political Institutional Change, Obsolescing Legitimacy, and Multinational Corporations," Management International Review 52, no. 6 (2012): 847-77.
''Wilkins, Maturing, 130-31.
Reputation and Political Legitimacy / 735
people of the local elite to its boards.^^ They started this practice in
Spain and later applied it to other countries.'^
ITT started operations in Chile in 1927, after acquiring the British
firm Chili Telephone Company, which controlled 78 percent of the Chilean market and had been criticized for its high rates and bad service.^°
In 1924, the government had extended Chili Telephone's concession
subject to the firm's commitment to expand the system and accept government's intervention determining telephone rates. The government
reserved the right to expropriate the firm after the end of the fifty-year
concession. Dissatisfied with the new contractual terms. Chili Telephone
Company sold its operations to ITT, which created a new firm under
the name of Compañía de Teléfonos de Chile (hereafter, ITT-CTC).^'
The timing of ITT's arrival in Chile determined its political future.
The firm started operations during the semi-autocratic regime of Carlos
Ibáñez del Campo, a president who took advantage of a booming economy to embark on an ambitious economic program that included soft
loans to manufacturing, government investment in infrastructure and
social welfare, and an open-door policy to foreign investors.^^ By 1929,
U.S. investments in Chile had grown to $625 million from just one million in 1900, most of them arriving during the Ibáñez regime.^^
As a means to encourage investments in telephone infrastructure,
Ibáñez reformed the law so that the telephone system would be independent of the restrictions present in the existing electrical-services
legislation. In 1929, the government-controlled senate approved a law
permitting fifty-year telephone concessions (which could be extended
'^Robert Sobel, TTT: The Management of Opportunity (New York, 1982), 14-40; Angel
Calvo, "State, Firms, and Technology: The Rise of Multinational Telecommunications Companies—ITT and the Compañia Telefónica Nacional de España, 1924-1945," Business History 50, no. 4 (2008): 455-59; Antonio Pérez Yustle, "La Compañia Telefónica Nacional de
España en la Dictadura de Primo de Rivera, 1923-1930," Ph.D. diss.. Universidad Politécnica
de Madrid, 2004, 72-83, 150-74, 271-72; Adoración Alvaro-Moya, "Redes empresariales,
inversión directa extranjera y monopolio: El caso de Telefónica, 1924-1965," Revista de Historia Industrial 16, no. 34 (2007): 65-96; Adoración Álvaro-Moya, "Inversión directa extranjera y formación de capacidades organizativas locales: Un análisis del impacto de Estados Unidos en la empresa española, 1918-1975," Ph.D. diss.. Universidad Complutense de
Madrid, 2010, 163-64; Ángel Calvo, Historia de Telefónica, 1924-1975 (Madrid, 2010);
Wilkins, Maturing, 71-72.
'^Gabriela Martinez, Latin American Telecommunications: Telefonica's Conquest (New
York, 2008), 20.
=° Julio Covarrubias, Un cable al cielo: Telefónica CTC Chile, 1880-2005 (Santiago,
2005), 68.
^' Carlos Donoso, "De la Compañía Chilena de Teléfonos de Edison a la Compañia de Teléfonos de Chile: Los primeros 50 años de la telefonía nacional, 1880-1930," Historia (Santiago) 33 (2000): 101-39.
^^ Mariana Aylvdn et al., Chile en el siglo XX (Santiago, 1983), 122.
-3 Harold Blakemore, "From the War of the Pacific to 1930," in Chile since Independence,
ed. Leslie Bethell (Cambridge, U.K., 1993), 82-83.
Marcelo Bucheli and Erica Salvaj / 736
Table 1
ITT-CTC, Profitability on Net Investments, 1950-1958
Year
Profit Rate
1950
1951
1952
1953
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
1.11
4.63
4.47
4.60
2.93
2.66
3.91
2.91
7.69
Source: ITT-CTC, Memoria Anual, various years.
to ninefy years). For the first time, the concessions were to be awarded
for the whole country (instead of the untfl-then existing regional concessions). Under the new law, the government abandoned its right to
nationalize the concessions before fifty years, but had the right to appoint three board members. Phone rates required the president's final
approval, but would be calculated to guarantee a profit rate of 10 percent of the firm's net investment.^'* In 1930, ITT-CTC signed a thirfyyear concession agreement under these terms and committed to modernize and expand the service.^^
Ibáñez's economic plans came to a sudden halt with the worldwide
Great Depression, which had devastating eftects on the Chilean economy. ^^ The crisis led to popular unrest forcing Ibáñez to resign in June
1931. As a result of the crisis, the government could not assure ITT-CTC
afixedprofit rate of 10 percent. During the 1931-1958 period, the company constantly complained about its inabflify to raise rates and achieve
the 10-percent profit rate (see Table 1).^^
Urbanization, Industrialization, and Political Change
In 1932, Chile started a long-term period of political stabilify after
the election of center-right candidate, Arturo Alessandri. These elections determined Chile's political map for the next decade, with the
^•^ Covarrubias, Un cable, 67-72; Donoso, "De la Compañía Chilena."
^'Donoso, "De la Compañia Chilena."
^*Aníbal Pinto, Chile, un caso de desarrollo frustrado (Santiago, 1973), 168; Ricardo
Ffrench-Davis and Osear Muñoz, "Desarrollo económico, inestabilidad y desequilibrios
políticos en Chile," Estudios deplan 28 (June 1990): 127.
'''m-CYC,
•
Memoria Anual, 1950-1958; Covarrubias, Uncable,78.
Reputation and Political Legitimacy / 737
right represented by the two traditional Liberal and Conservative parties (representing the secular and Catholic factions of the Chflean right,
respectively), the center by the middle-class oriented Radical Party, and
the left by the rising Socialist and Communist parties.^^ After 1932,
Chile also began a period of consensus in terms of economic policy, in
which the major political and economic forces agreed that economic
prosperity could only be achieved through protectionism, state-led import substitution industrialization (ISI), and heavy government investment in social welfare. The following decades witnessed an enlargement
ofthe urban middle class and the organization ofthe ever more militant
industrial working class. The political changes resulting from this social
transformation sowed the seeds for future challenges to the legitimacy
of ITT's operations.
The ISI consolidated through an alliance between the government
and the private sector and the creation of government agencies in charge
of channeling funds to domestic industry.^^ This economic model thrived
even during the rule of a center-left coalition known as the Popular Front
(1938-1941), led by the Radicals and supported by the Socialist and Communist parties.^" In the 1930s, the government purchased 12.5 percent
of ITT-CTC shares through Corporación de Fomento (CORFO), the government's main development agency. The number of government directors on the ITT-CTC board remained at two individuals.-''
A larger middle-class urban population meant higher demand and
consumption of telephone service. Between 1925 and 1950, Chfle's percapita GDP increased from $3,285 to $3,943, with the number of telephones increasing from 33,249 in 1927 (8 telephones per thousand
people) to 127,344 in 195O (20.9 telephones per thousand people) (see
Figure 1); by 1947, Chile was ITT's largest consumer of telephones in the
world.3^ According to ITT, the company could not satisfy Chile's rapid
rise in demand because ofthe increasing costs of materials due to inflation and mandatory wage increases.-'^ In 1950, the Chilean government
^^ Michael Monteón, Chile and the Great Depression: The Politics of Underdevelopment,
1927-1948 (Tempe, Ariz., 1998), 73-75°'Ben R. Schneider, Business, Politics, and the State in Twentieth Century Latin America (Cambridge, U.K., 2004), 155.
^"Ricardo Ffrench-Davis et al., "The Industrialization of Chile, 1940-82," An Economic
History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, vol. 3, ed. Enrique Cárdenas, José Antonio
Ocampo, and Rosemary Thorp (New York, 2000), 130-32; Guy Douyon, "Chilean Industrialization since CORFO," Ph.D. diss., American University, 1972, 87—89.
31 ITT-CTC, Memoria Anual, various years.
3-Measured in 1995 dollars by purchasing power parity. See Juan Bräunet et al.,
Economia Chilena, 1810-1995 (Santiago, 2000), 310. Before 1945, the largest market was
Argentina, but ITT sold its interests there that year. See, ITT, Annual Report (1945), 32; ITT,
Annual Report (1946), 33; Wilkins, Maturing, 304.
33 ITT, Annual Report (1947), 34; ITT, Annual Report (1949), 15.
Marcelo Bucheli and Erica Salvaj / 738
-Telephones per 1000 people
45
40
y
35
30
25
20
15 -I
10
5
O
O^
^^
O^
O^
ON
O^
ON
ON
ON
ON
ON
ON
ON
ON
ON
<^^
ON
ON
ON
Figure 1. Telephone coverage in Chile: Number of telepbones per looo people. (Source: Calculations vrith information from the Oxford Latin American Economic History Database,
http://oxlad.qeh.ox.ac.uk/, accessed 28 Feb. 2011.)
compensated the firm by allowing it to increase telephone rates by
60 percent, which the company considered to barely cover wage increases.'^'* The measure was highly unpopular because it took place in
times of rising infiation. In 1945, the inflation rate in Chile was 7.7 percent, jumped to 30 percent in 1946, and was 23 percent in 1947.^5 In
1956, concerned about ITT-CTC's seeming lack of capacity to satisfy
domestic demand, some members of the country's technocratic elite
proposed the creation of a state-owned corporation, an idea that ITTCTC
ö
Exhaustion of the ISI Model and New Political Alternatives
During the 1950s, Chile went through several changes relevant for
ITT's operations. First, infiation led many politicians of different colors
to question the ISI model. Second, economic conditions decreased support for the Radicals, who were replaced by the Christian Democrats as
the main center middle-class-oriented political party. And, third, the
political left became more powerful.
3'' ITT, Annual Reports (1950,1951).
35 Braun et al., Economia, 336.
3* Guillermo Guajardo, "Nacionahsmo económico y tecnología internacional: Estados
Unidos y la industrialización de México y Chile," in Ni éxito, ni fracaso: Ideas, recursos y actores en las politicas económicas latinoamericanas del siglo XX, ed. Guillermo Guajardo
(Mexico City, 2005), 104.
Reputation and Political Legitimacy / 739
In 1952, Chile reelected former president Ibáñez, who came to
power with the strong support of the left. To fight an inflation rate of
71 percent in 1954 and 83 percent in 1955, he cut spending and subsidies, and approved increasing telephone rates; his strategy quickly
sparked strikes and demonstrations and broke his alliance with the
left.3'' By the end of his administration, an unpopular Ibáñez desperately reapproached the left by legalizing the Communist Party (banned
in 1948) and worked wdth the left in an electoral reform that increased
mass participation in politics and reduced the power the right had in
the countryside, benefiting nontraditional parties. Nevertheless, the
economic crisis continued.-^^
Shortly before leaving power in January 1958, Ibáñez revised the
existing concession that Chile had awarded to ITT-CTC in 1927. Under
the new contract, ITT-CTC committed itself to expand coverage to
84,000 more telephones, while the government assured the firm a minimum 10 percent return on assets, for which it authorized rate hikes up
to 94 percent that year.'^' The company reported this measure, as well
as the previous unpopular Ibáñez austerity measures, as highly positive
and did not complain again about low profits in its reports.'*"
An earthquake in southern Chile in i960 complicated ITT-CTC's
technical and political conditions. The destruction of a good part of the
telecommunications infrastructure left most of southern Chile incommunicado, leading influential engineers to advocate for the creation of a
state-owned telecommunications company, a proposal rejected by both
ITT-CTC and the U.S. embassy.^'
The 1950s economic crisis led to a lack of credibility among the
constituencies of the parties holding power until then. The middle class
was disappointed with the Radicals while the urban working class,
many of them living in the progressively larger shantytowns surrounding Santiago, felt that the existing economic model was not benefiting
them. Two political movements capitalized on this discontent. The first
one was the Christian Democratic Party (hereafter DC, in its Spanish
acronym), created in 1957, which questioned capitalism and considered
T, Annual Report (1953), 28; ITT, Annual Report (1954), 31; Aylwin et al., Chile,
235; Braun, et al., Economia, 336.
^^Tomá
•
s Moulian, Fracturas: De Pedro Aguirre Cerda a Salvador Allende, 1938—1973
(Santiago, 2006), 168-69.
^'"Fórmula para la ampliación del servicio telefónico," El Mercurio, 3 Jan. 1958; "40 millones de dólares serán invertidos en ampliación de servicio telefónico en Chile," El Mercurio,
6 Feb. 1958.
t • " ITT justified this increase, arguing tbat Chilean rates were still relatively cheap for international standards; see ITT-CTC, Memoria Anual (1957), 11; ITT, Annual Report (1956),
43; ITT,ylnnua/ßeport (1958), 43-44.
"*'Covarrubias, Un cable, 100-108.
Marcelo Bucheli and Erica Salvaj / 740
the fight against poverfy as a Catholic moral dufy, even through wealth
redistribution if necessary."*^ The second political movement was the
Frente de Acción Popular (FRAP), created in 1956 by the Socialist and
Communist parties.**^
The two new political organizations argued that the economic crisis
resulted from the exhaustion of the ISI model. For the DC, ISI had been
too oriented toward big business and needed to be reformed so that
wealth was more equally distributed under government leadership. The
parfy advocated for a redistribution of land in the agrarian sector, the
participation of the Chilean government in the foreign-controlled mining sector, and policies of political empowerment of the lower classes.
The FRAP agreed that ISI had not benefited the lower classes, but proposed as an alternative the expropriation of foreign properfy and state
control of monopolies, banking, and foreign trade. The Liberals and
Conservatives also believed that ISI was reaching its limits, but believed
the solution consisted of policies of privatization and opening of the
economy.44 These three economic proposals dominated the political
debate and aftected the perception of ITT's operations.
ITT's Link to the Past as Political Liability
The Chilean political right had the opportunify to test its economic
formula after Jorge Alessandri's triumph in the 1958 elections. Alessandri's was a bittersweet victory for the Conservative-Liberal coalition
that brought him to power: He narrowly won with just 31.6 percent of
the votes against 28.5 percent for FRAP's candidate. DC candidate Eduardo Frei Montalva finished third with 20.5 percent replacing the Radicals as the main center political party.^s
Aware of the decreasing popularify of his Conservative and Liberal
backers, Alessandri made big efforts to show himself as a postpartisan
technocrat, rather than a parfy ideologue.'*^ The DC and left-wing opposition, however, constantly portrayed him as a representative of the oligarchy, foreign interests, and the increasingly unpopular political right.
The outcome of Alessandri's policies did not help him. After liberalizing
''^Bernardo Navarrete, "Un centro excéntrico: Cambio y continuidad en la Democracia
Cristiana, 1957-2005," Política 45, no. 1 (2005): 117; Luis Moulian and Gloria Guerra,
Eduardo Frei M. Biografia de un estadista utópico (Santiago, 2000), 47-55.
"•
3Albert o Cardemil, El camino de la utopia: Alessandri, Frei, Allende (Santiago, 1997),
133''Lui
'•
s Corvalán Marquez, Del anticapitalismo al neoliberalismo en Chile: Izquierda,
centro y derecha en la lucha entre los proyectos globales, 1950-2000 (Santiago, 2001), 1718; Cardemil, El camino, 133; Navarrete, "Un centro excéntrico," 118.
''^Paul Drake, "Chile, 1930-1958," in Chile since Independence, ed. Lt^slie Bethell (Cambridge, U.K., 1993), 128; Aylwin et al., Chile, 245-47.
'Cardemil
••
, El camino, 26-29; Drake, "Chile," 142.
Reputation and Political Legitimacy / 741
the economy, imports skyrocketed, exports stagnated, and inflation remained high.47 Lack of confidence and an artificially strong exchange
rate encouraged capital flight, against which the President desperately
fought in December 1961 by restricting operations in foreign currency."*^
Unable to keep the currency's value, in January 1962 Alessandri devalued the Chflean currency 30 percent, which was interpreted as a signal
of a fafled economic policy.'*^
The repetitive government approval to increase telephone rates and
the pressures this generated in the budget of a middle class already
struggling with the apparently out-of-control inflation became a political issue. Earlier, in 1957, Federico Duncker, an ITT-CTC lawyer, warned
that the firm had to make extra eftorts to explain to the public the technical reasons for the constant rate increases in order to avoid a political
backlash.^" In contrast, in most of its post-1958 reports, the company
expressed its satisfaction with the new government policy.^^ Duncker's
warning proved prophetic: On July 17, 1962, a heated and lengthy debate took place in the Chilean Congress regarding ITT-CTC's operations
in which the company was attacked from many fronts.
The 1962 congressional debates on ITT-CTC showed some consensus on what the problems were, but big difterences on how to solve
them. The consensus shared by the left, center, and right was that ITTCTC's original concession contracts had been too generous for the multinational, that phone rates were expensive, and that the qualify of the
service was bad. With people of afl social backgrounds complaining
about these issues, no politician could aftord to alienate their constituencies by disagreeing with these basic points. The disagreements, however, were strong. The DC blamed the right for not opposing earlier a
contract granting monopolistic powers to a foreign firm. The company
was so corrupt, they argued, that it did not even comply with the already
generous contract because it was not extending the telephone lines as
required. They added that the government had created several commissions in the past to investigate these irregularities, but they never prospered because of the Liberals' and Conservatives' systematic opposition.
For the Liberals, the main problem was the existence of a monopoly. Jorge Hübner, a Liberal congressman, said that his parfy opposed
"any kind of monopoly, whether it is private or state-owned." He added
'''Ffrench-Davis, et al., "The Industrialization of Chile," 133.
''^"Chile Forbids Dollar Payments for Foreign Products until Jan. 6," Wall Street Journal, 29 Dec. 1961, 4.
''^ "Value of Cbilean Escudo Drops as Much as 30 Percent after Exchange Ban Ends," Wall
Street Journal, 17 Jan. 1962, 4; "Chile's New Dual Rate Foreign Exchange Plan Clouds Trade
Picture," Wall Street Journal, 22 Jan. 1962,12.
^""Interesantes observaciones en la junta de accionistas de la Compañía Chilena de Teléfonos," El Mercurio, 2 Apr. 1957.
51 ITT-CTC, Memoria Anual, various years.
Marcelo Bucheli and Erica Salvaj / 742
that things would work better if the directors appointed by the government were controlling the company's actions, which in his view they
apparently did not do. He also defended his party's previous authorizations for telephone rate hikes arguing that the company needed a
minimum to survive. The Liberal solution was to open the market to
other private firms to compete against ITT. On the other hand, the
Communists and Socialists argued that by its very nature, if left alone, a
multinational corporation would try to abuse its customers, the only solution being a statization ofthe industry. They added that not only were
the company's rates outrageously high, but also ITT-CTC underpaid its
workers. For the left, as long as they had a right-wing government, there
was not much to do about the company's abuses.^^ The company did not
mention the debates in its 1962 or 1963 reports, but emphasized how,
thanks to government support, they were making big strides to extend
telephone coverage as promised.^^ j ^ the meantime, CORFO continued
studying the feasibility of a national telecommunications company.^^*
The tone of the debate became more extreme on August 28, 1963.
This time, the DC openly advocated for outright expropriation of ITTCTC. In a very dramatic intervention, DC Congressman Mario Hamuy
defended this proposal arguing that ITT-CTC had repeatedly ignored
any plea to stop raising rates. He added that the 10-percent profit on
net investments rate assured by the government included loans acquired by the company, meaning the Chilean taxpayers were subsidizing
the multinational's loans. Hamuy added that the 39 percent increase in
rates in 1962 and the 49 percent already accumulated in 1963 were simply unsustainable for Chilean consumers. Hamuy emphasized that the
problem with ITT-CTC was not an isolated one, but was a reflection of
the structural economic problems generated by the pro-big-business
Alessandri administration. The Socialist congressmen agreed with the
DC on the latter point, but added that the structural problems were not
just internal but global and ITT represented the United States' imperialism, whose actions needed to be resisted not simply because of a
problem of phone rates, but also of sovereignty and exploitation. In
this debate, the formerly popular Radicals sided with the Liberals in
their opposition to the expropriation proposed by the DC, arguing that
Chile was a country with rule of law and that contracts (no matter how
badly they had been written) needed to be honored. The DC and the left
counterargued that because the contract had been signed under a less
democratic regime it lacked legitimacy. They had a similar argument to
question the validity ofthe 10 percent secured-profit
^^ chile. Cámara de Diputados, Boletín de Sesiones, 17 July 1962.
53 ITT-CTC, Memoria Anual (1962,1963).
^''Guajardo, "Nacionalismo económico," 105.
^^ Chile, Cámara de Diputados, Boletin de Sesiones, 28 Aug. 1963.
Reputation and Political Legitimacy / 743
Table 2
ITT-CTC Board of Directors According to Political Affiliation
and/or Whether or Not They Were
ITT Executives, 1950-1970
ITTExecutive
Political Affiliation
Christian Democrat (or highly likely)
Conservative or Liberal (or highly likely)
No Information
Total
No
No
Fes
Yes
Total
4
16
5
0
0
11
4
16
16
25
11
36
Source: Appendix.
Board Composition and Legitimacy
The first congressional criticisms against ITT-CTC's board composition came on August 28, 1963. Communist Congressman Carlos Rosales said that the company's power resided in its board of directors,
arguing that ITT-CTC strategically chose people with good political
connections. Rosales used as example the company's president, Ernesto
Barros Jarpa, former Vice President of the Liberal Party and former
Minister of Interior and Foreign Relations. Barros Jarpa also sat on the
boards of several of Chile's main corporations in construction, finance,
and manufacturing (see Appendix). After highlighting Barros Jarpa's
importance. Rosales proceeded to read the list of ITT-CTC directors
showing how most of them belonged to the Liberal and Conservative
parties. The government directors. Rosales added, were overtly working for the company and received compensation for this. He concluded
that because of this composition and their connections to Alessandri's
government the company had been safe in its abusive behavior. ^^
The argument about ITT-CTC's board being dominated by the Liberals and Conservatives was not unsubstantiated. Although the company's annual reports do not mention the directors' political affiliations,
the facf that most of them are prominent members of society allows us
to research the biography of each one of them and determine their affiliation. The Appendix shows the directors' biographies and political affiliations, and in Table 2 we display the summary of that information:
Between 1950 and 1970, individuals belonging to the Liberal and Conservative parties did dominate the ITT-CTC board. As some congressmen argued, we show that those belonging to the political right were
s*-Ibid., 3817.
Marcelo Bucheli and Erica Salvaj / 744
Table 3
ITT-CTC Board of Directors According to Political Affiliation
and Executive Position for Individuals Working for the
Company for More than Four Years, 1950-1970
ITTExecutive
Political Affiliation
No
Christian Democrat
Conservative or Liberal
No Information
1
10
3
Total
Yes
Total
0
14
0
3
1
10
6
3
17
Source: Appendix.
not even executives of this firm. Moreover, the DC or Radical directors
were those appointed by the government.
In order to consider the directors who stayed on the board for a
longer period of time (who, we assume, will be the most influential in
the company). Table 3 displays the results only for directors sitting on
the board for more than four years. It shows that the board was very
stable with not much rotation (which is also evident in the Appendix)
and that the longest-serving directors belonged to or sympathized with
the Liberal and Conservative parties.
Table 4 shows how during this period, mostly people who belonged
to or sympathized with the Liberal and Conservative parties held the
positions of president or vice president. The individuals for whom we
did not find any information were either foreigners (mostly American) or government representatives. In short, the three tables show a
Table 4
ITT-CTC Board of Directors According to Pohtical Affiliation
and/or Whether or Not They Were Presidents or
Vice Presidents of the Board, 1950-1970
Political Affiliation
President or
Vice President
No
Yes
Christian Democrat (or highly likely)
Liberal or Conservative (or highly likely)
4
10
0
6
14
2
16
28
S
36
No information
Total
Source: Appendix.
Total
4
16
Reputation and Political Legitimacy / 745
company that, during the period we study, remained with a board composed of the traditional right, which explains why it was such an easy
target for Christian Democrats, Socialists, and Communists.
Political acceptance of ITT was turning on several fronts. In August
1963, weekly magazine Vistazo published a long article showing how
the presence of politicians in corporate boards benefited these companies. According to the article, the presence of Barros Jarpa on ITTCTC's board and on the board of Banco de Crédito e Inversiones made
it possible for the company to receive cheap loans.^^ The article also
pointed out the benefits that other large corporations, such as privately
owned oilfirmCompañia de Petróleos de Chile (COPEC), obtained from
these political relations.
A network analysis shows that ITT-CTC's board was even more interconnected with Chile's main corporations than the Vistazo article
claimed.5^ Although we do not have the information to do network
analysis for the pre-1969 period, the fact that the board barely changed
between the 1920s and 1960s allows us to assume that the firm had
strong connections in the previous years.^^ Also, we find a strong connection with a state-owned firm (the Empresa Nacional de Electricidad). However, two of the three directors both firms shared were appointed by the state.
^'"Ocho sociedades con cuñas en diez poderosos bancos," Vistazo 569 (1963): 11. The information from the firm's corporate reports do not show a clear benefit in cheap loans from
the financial sector (see, ITT-CTC, Memoria Anual, various years). The Vistazo article, however, added more questions about the firm's board's legitimacy.
''" ITT-CTC created links through its board of directors vrith several corporations. Its
strongest links were with Empresa Nacional de Electricidad, with which it shared three directors and vvith Cementos Bio Bio, with which it shared two. ITT-CTC also shared one director
with Compañia Chilena de Fósforos, Compañia General de Electricidad, Empresas COPEC,
Empresa Nacional de Telecomunicaciones, Empresas CMPC, Banco Continental, Gildemeister. Empresa Pesquera Eperva, Philips Chile, Cementos Polpaico, Banco de Crédito e Inversiones, Plásticos Nacionales, Compañía de Seguros Francisco de Aguirre, Tejidos Caupolicán,
Agencia Graham, Chilena Consolidada Seguros de Vida, Banco de Chile, Compañía de Cervecerías Unidas, and Industria Nacional del Rayón. Those firms with links to ITT-CTC also
had links vrith each other. The ones sharing one director were Agencia Graham, Banco Continental, Banco de Chile, Banco de Crédito e Inversiones, Cementos Bio Bio, Cementos Polpaico, Chilena Consolidada de Seguros de Vida, Compañía Chilena de Fósforos, Compañia de
Cervecerias Unidas, Compañía de Seguros Francisco de Aguirre, Compañia General de Electricidad, Empresa Pesquera Eperva, Empresa Nacional de Electricidad, Empresas CMPC,
Empresas COPEC, Gildemeister, Industria Nacional del Rayón, Philips Chile, Plásticos Nacionales and Tejidos Caupolicán. Those sharing two directors included Agencia Graham,
Banco de Chile, Banco de Crédito e Inversiones, Cementos Bio Bio, Chilena Consolidada
de Seguros de Vida, Compañía de Cervecerias Unidas, Compañía de Seguros Francisco de
Aguirre, Empresa Nacional de Electricidad, Empresa Nacional de Telecomunicaciones, Empresas CMPC, Industria Nacional del Rayón, Plásticos Nacionales and Tejidos Caupolicán.
Corporations sharing three directors included Compañia de Cervecerias Unidas, Banco de
Chile, Chilena Consolidada de Seguros de Vida, and Agencia Graham.
5'For a detailed study explaining the position of ITT-CTC in Chile's corporate world, see
Erica Salvaj and Andrea Lluch, "Estudio comparativo del capitalismo argentino y chileno:
Un análisis desde las redes de directorio a fines del modelo sustitutivo de importaciones,"
REDES: Revista hispana para el análisis de redes sociales 23, no. 3 (2012): 43-79.
Marcelo Bucheli and Erica Salvaj / 746
Criticisms in the Chflean Congress against ITT-CTC's board composition continued in November 1963. DCs criticisms were harsher
than before when its members said that ITT-CTC's board was composed of "the most reactionary elements in the country" and existed to
oppose the workers.^" DC Congressman Luis Musalem said that President Alessandri himself was a former director of several boards composed of some ITT-CTC directors, which created a collusion of interests. For Hamuy, all these examples showed that the only option was
expropriation, something he and his parfymen promised they would do
if their candidate, Eduardo Frei, won the 1964 elections.^^ According to
the original contract, the Socialists added that the Supreme Court was
to resolve afl problems with the company, which provided ITT-CTC an
unfair advantage because one former director of the company, Pedro
Sflva Fernández, was then the Supreme Court President.^^
The DC and FRAP had good reasons to feel emboldened in the debates. In the 1963 municipal elections, the DC became the country's
largest political force with 22.7 percent of the votes, while the Liberals'
and Conservatives' shares fell from 16.5 percent to 13.2 and ftom 14.7 to
11.4, respectively. In the traditionally conservative region of Curicó,
FRAP surprised the country by winning with 39.2 percent of the vote.
After this humiliating defeat, demoralized Liberals and Conservatives
decided not to nominate any candidate for the 1964 presidential elections and reluctantly supported DCs
ITT's Last Political Strategies under a New Political Order
The 1964 presidential elections changed the Chflean political landscape. DCs Frei won with 56 percent of the vote, followed by FRAP's
Allende with 38.9 percent, and the Radical candidate with a mere 5 percent.^'' The right-wing Liberal and Conservative parties had clearly lost
relevance, and the two harshest critics of ITT-CTC's operations then
dominated the political arena.
Allende's rising popularify panicked the Chilean right, the U.S. government, and ITT. The right-wing parties did not like Frei, who as a candidate in 1962 said, "Capitalism has been incapable of solving our social
and economic problems."^^ In 1964, Frei advocated nationalization of
the copper industry and redistribution of land among poor peasants,
^° Chile, Cámara de Diputados, Boletín de Sesiones, 13 Nov. 1963,1330.
*'Ibid.
" Ibid., 1337y
l., Chile, 255-57.
'"Ibid., 258.
*5Cardemil, El camino, 190.
Reputation and Political Legitimacy / 747
but the right-wing party considered him the "lesser evil" compared to
Allende.^^ For Washington, Frei's movement represented a promising
alternative between the reactionary right and Cuba's Communist model.''^
Worried about Allende's potential triumph, the U.S. government secretly supported Frei's candidacy and anti-Communist media outlets by
channeling $2.6 million funding through the CIA.^^ Once Frei was in
power, the CIA provided funds to the DC candidates for the 1965 congressional elections. During the 1963 campaign, ITT approached the CIA
and offered its financial support to operations, aiming to assure Frei's
victory, but the CIA rejected the offer.^^
The DC government did not expropriate ITT's properties in Chile
as promised, but it intervened in the industry. In 1964, resulting from
the post-1960 earthquake studies, the government created Entel, a
government-owned long-distance phone company to supply segments
of the market neglected by ITT and therefore not originally created to
compete against ITT.^° In 1967, new regulations gave the government
the power to control basic telephone networks and to supply service to
poor areas and authorized CORFO to purchase up to 49 percent of ITTCTC shares.^^ Although the latter did not happen under Frei, the new
legal framework permitted a gradual transfer of this service to the state.
In addition, new automated technology became avaflable to the Chilean
firm, allowing it to rapidly expand its services without needing to depend on ITT-CTC.7^
Frei lost the support of the Chilean right soon after taking power.
Higher taxation, political empowerment of the lower classes, and expropriation of land to the traditional rural elite alienated the right, who
said that Frei was simply "paving the road to Communism in Chile."''^
His social policies did not make him popular among the left, either. Allende accused Frei of being the "candidate of imperialism" and promised total opposition from day one.^'* In spite of these challenges, the
Lundahl, "El camino a la dictadura: Desarrollo politico y económico en Chile,
1952-73," in Economia y politico durante el gobierno militar en Chile, 1973-1987, ed. Roberto Garcia (Mexico City, 1989), 27-29; Patricio Dooner, Cambios sociales y conflicto politico: El conflicto politico nacional durante el gobierno de Eduardo Frei (1964-1970) (Santiago, 1983), 27; Moulian and Guerra, Eduardo Frei, 129-30.
*'Leonard Gross, The Last Best Hope: Eduardo Frei and Chilean Democracy (New York,
1967).
• • ^ United States Senate, Select Committee to Study Governmental Operations with Respect to Intelligence Activities, Covert Action in Chile (Washington, D.C., 1975), 9.
• •^ United States Senate, Covert Action, 11-12.
''"Covarrubias, Un cable, 108-10.
"Ahmed Galal, "Chile: Regulatory Specificity, Credibility of Commitment, and Distributional Demands," in Regulations, Institutions, and Commitment: Comparative Studies of
Telecommunications, ed. Brian Levy and Pablo Spiller (Cambridge, U.K., 1996), 122-24.
"^Guajardo
•
, "Nacionalismo económico," 106.
'•' Corvalán, Del anticapitalismo, 103.
^'' Dooner, Cambios, 35-36.
Marcelo Bucheli and Erica Salvaj / 748
DC enjoyed an overwhelming 43.6 percent triumph in the 1965 congressional elections. Allende's FRAP came in second with 26.2 percent
of the votes, while the Liberals and Conservatives obtained 3.15 and
1.9 percent, respectively.^^ Frei changed the constitution modifying
the definition of private property, which allowed him to go ahead with
the agrarian reform and partial government acquisition of the copper
industry.''^ By 1967, the right reinvented itself, creating the National
Party, and continued their opposition to Frei.''^
Criticisms against ITT-CTC continued in Congress after Frei's election. The DC accused ITT-CTC of committing abuses with total impunity and proposed a fixed phone rate for all users to relieve families
from the ever-increasing costs of this service.''^ Criticisms from the
Socialist Party focused on labor abuses and low wages.''^ ITT-CTC responded to these accusations in Congress arguing that a fixed rate would
benefit large companies to the detriment of families and added that the
existing rate system encouraged excessive telephone usage, which forced
the firm to invest more than expected.^" During the whole Frei administration, ITT's board remained dominated by Liberals and Conservatives (see Appendix).
As the 1970 presidential elections approached, Chilean politics
became increasingly polarized. In 1967, the Socialist Party openly declared the legitimacy of armed struggle, and in 1968, the left wing
created a new clandestine group (the Movimiento de Izquierda Revolucionaria or Revolutionary Left Movement [MIR]) to promote a
Cuban-style revolution.^^ In 1969, radical left-wing groups put bombs
in the American Cultural Institute and in the El Mercurio newspaper
building, and a group of right-wing army officers unsuccessfully rebelled against the government. The National Party justified the army
rebellion as the inevitable outcome of the chaos generated by government policies. Internally, the DC faced problems too when in 1969
some of its left-wing members created their own movement knovm as
MAPU and joined the Allende coalition. To make things worse, the
right surprised the country with a revival when the National Party obtained 20 percent of the votes in the 1969 congressional elections. The
right interpreted this success as a vote of a frustrated population longing for
^
l., Chile, 261.
d., 263-70.
^Corvalán, Del anticapitalismo, 101.
^*Chile, Cámara de Diputados, Boletín de Sesiones, 11 May 1966, 8174.
™ Chile, Cámara de Diputados, Boletín de Sesiones, 12 July 1966.
'"Chile, Cámara de Diputados, Boletín de Sesiones, 11 May 1966.
^'Corvalán, Del antícapitalismo, 108.
^
l , Chile, 276-82.
Reputation and Political Legitimacy / 74g
The constitution did not allow Frei to run for a second term, so the
DC chose Radomiro Tomic as their presidential candidate. Tomic, a
member of the party's left, accepted the nomination under the condition that his party declare itself "anti-capitalist... socialist, and revolutionary."^^ Tomic also proposed an alliance with the left, which the
party rejected.^"* The National Party nominated former president Jorge
Alessandri, while the left (now under the umbrella of the Unidad Popular or Popular Unity [UP]) nominated Allende.
The U.S. government and ITT did not passively wait for the results.
The CIA engaged in a complex scheme to avoid the triumph of Allende
in the elections and prevent him from taking power after his electoral
victory.^s The plan included providing funding to both the DC and
National Party campaigns and anti-Allende media outlets worldwide,
instigating a coup after the elections if Allende won, and encouraging
congressmen to deny Allende's accession to power due to constitutional
technicalities. ITT enthusiastically oftered its support to conspire against
Allende and oftered funding for the operation to the CIA. The CIA rejected ITT's money, but advised the company on how to channel money
secretly to Alessandri's campaign.^^ Once Allende took power, the CIA
sought to undermine his administration through economic warfare, for
which it sought an alliance with ITT.^^ There is no evidence, however,
that ITT participated in economic warfare.^^
In 1971, Allende took over part of ITT-CTC's management control.
On August 30,1972, in the midst of an economic crisis and fierce opposition from the right, the government proposed a constitutional reform
that would aflow it to expropriate ITT-CTC's assets. By then, the Washington Post had made public ITT internal documents showing the company's collusion with the CIA to conspire against Allende, and the Chilean government lost no time in capitalizing on this scandal by rapidly
translating and pubhshing the documents into Spanish.^^ Appearing as
a foreign conspirator against the Chilean government delegitimized ITT
even more, making it hard for Allende's opposition to defend it. In fact,
^3 Ibid., 280-81.
^"•
Corvalán , Del andcapitalismo, 78.
^5 United States Senate, Select Committee on Foreign Relations, The International Telephone and Telegraph Company and Chile, 1970-71 (Washington, D.C., 1973); Jack Anderson, The Anderson Papers (New York, 1974); Edward Korry, "The U.S.A. in Chile, Chile in
the U.S.A.: A Full Retrospective Political and Economic View (1963-1975)," Estudios Públicos 72 (Spring 1998): 1-48; Kornbluh, Pinochet; Qureshi, Nixon.
"*'United States Senate, Covert Action, 16.
^^"From Korry to Kissinger and Johnson, 5 Oct. 1970," United States Department of
State, CIA Chile Declassification Project Tranche III (1979-1991) (Washington, D.C., 1991).
^^ United States Senate, Covert Action, 13.
^'Chile, Secretaria General de Gobierno, Documentos Secretos de la ITT (Santiago,
1972); Antonio Vargas MacDonald, ITT: Documentos de una agresión (Mexico City, 1973).
Marcelo Bucheli and Erica Salvaj / 750
despite the hostilify against Allende in Congress and the openly expropriatory nature of this proposal, there is no record of any congressman
defending the company. The DC congressmen said that it was probably
better to wait until the concession expired, but gave their approval, as
did the Radicals. No one argued that a new Chilean firm was incapable
of running the industry without the multinational, because by then
Entel had mastered the new automated technology.^" In the same session, the Socialists reminded Congress of what everybody had complained of before (bad and expensive service) and added the element of
violation of national sovereignfy. That day. Congress approved the law
permitting the expropriation of ITT's properties in Chile.^^ The worldwide damage to ITT's reputation worsened on December 4,1972, when
Allende gave a dramatic speech at the General Assembly of the United
Nations, accusing ITT and the CIA of conspiring against his government.^^ This happened at a moment when ITT was already dealing with
a bribery scandal in the U.S.'^
The role of the CIA and ITT in the 1973 coup is still a matter of debate. While some authors argue that both ITT and the CIA played a crucial role in overthrowing Allende, others claim that, even though both
wanted Allende out of power, the coup was mainly a Chilean internal
affair.^"* Regardless of the role ITT played, the leaked documents had a
terrible eftect on the firm's reputation and left its legitimacy in shambles.
Conclusion
As a way to understand hostile actions by domestic governments
(which can include expropriation) against foreign firms, this article studies the gradual loss of political legitimacy of a multinational corporation before the host country's sociefy. We propose the concept of obsolescing political legitimacy, which we define as a foreign firm's gradual
loss of legitimacy before the local sociefy, resulting from the identification of this firm with a previous social and/or political regime increasingly perceived as illegitimate or archaic. Following Brayden King
and David Whetten, we assume that institutional changes in the host
'"Guajardo, "Nacionalismo económico," 106.
''Chile, Cámara de Diputados, Boletin de Sesiones, 30 Aug. 1972.
'^Salvador Allende, "Address to the United Nations General Assembly, 4 Dec. 1972," in
Salvador Allende Reader: Chile's Voice of Democracy, ed. James Cockcroft (Melbourne,
2000), 200-221.
'3 "O'Brien and GOP Clash Over IT&T," New York Times, 14 Dec. 1971, 36.
Kornbluh
•'•
, Pinochet; Qureshi, Nixon; Jonathan Haslam, The Nixon Administration and
the Death ofAUende's Chile: A Case of Assisted Suicide (London, 2005); Sampson, Sovereign State; Corvalán, Del anticapitalismo, 217—33; Gustafson, Hostile. 179—201; Monica
González, Chile la conjura: Los mil y un días del golpe (Santiago, 2005).
Reputation and Political Legitimacy / 751
country will also change the legitimacy standards used by the host sociefy, eventually aftecting the firm's reputation before the same sociefy.^^
The concept of obsolescing political legitimacy allows us to contribute
to the extant interpretations on expropriations coming from the literatures of obsolescing bargaining power and neoinstitutional political
economy. The first body of scholarship argues that the likelihood of expropriation of a multinational increases the more the company has invested sunk assets in the domestic country. The second school argues
that the likelihood of expropriation increases with more authoritarian
regimes and decreases with more democratic regimes. By putting the
element of perceived legitimacy and reputation of the firm at the center
of the analysis, we show that in certain circumstances the arrival of a
more democratic regime can generate more chaflenges for a multinational corporation's properfy rights. If the local sociefy perceives a multinational to have benefited in the past from a social and/or political
order increasingly considered illegitimate, a government can assume
that it does not need to honor any contract signed by that multinational
with the previous regime.
We illustrate our point with the case of the U.S. multinational ITT
in Chile. Since its arrival, the company opted for a legitimization strategy of appointing influential members of the Chilean elite to its subsidiary's board of directors. The problem with this strategy is the dynamic
nature of politics. During the period we study, Chile went through social and political changes that increased the political and economic
power of previously excluded social groups (mainly the middle and the
working class), for whom telephone service was not considered a luxury
anymore. The new political parties that questioned ITT's corporate
power and the very legitimacy of its operations capitalized on the firm's
increasingly poor reputation due to deficient and expensive service.
One of the ways they delegitimized ITT was by portraying its board of
directors as a relic of Chile's less democratic political past. They used
this argument to justify the expropriation of ITT's assets in Chfle. When
the company was discovered conspiring against the government, it lost
what remained of its reputation and legitimacy, making the expropriation even easier.
The concept of obsolescing legitimacy provides us with a new analytical tool to understand the relationship between multinationals and
governments. The concept is particularly useful in the presence of institutional changes. These changes can be the result of gradual changes
or of sudden and violent events—such as mflitary coups, revolutions, or
independence wars. We focus on gradual institutional changes where a
"King and Whetten, "Rethinking."
Marcelo Bucheli and Erica Salvaj / 752
corporation (or any other kind of organization) can adapt by aligning itself with those replacing the groups previously in power. By doing this,
the firm can keep its legitimacy before the domestic society. However, if
the firm remains allied to those losing political power and representing
a gradually disappearing social and political past, the firm can lose legitimacy and risk losing its property rights.
Other cases of gradual institutional and social changes have shown
how the multinationals have successfully adapted. During the 1940s
and 1950s, foreign oil companies operating in Venezuela were aware
that many considered them allied to the previous dictatorial regimes, so
these multinationals sought to legitimize their operations by embracing
Venezuelan nationalism and investing in social welfare.^^ Several U.S.
multinationals also adopted a Mexican nationalistic discourse after the
1938 expropriation of foreign oil companies.^'' In the 1960s, some British companies operating in Africa did the same when facing the inevitable collapse ofthe British Empire.^^
We can also see cases of obsolescing legitimacy v«th rapid institutional changes. For instance, local rulers used the new institutional environment in Africa in the years following decolonization to argue that
previously existing or international legislation protecting the property
of multinational corporations was illegitimate because colonial powers
had imposed it.'' After the 1959 revolution, the Cuban government justified expropriations, arguing that foreign firms had previously benefited from a dictatorship or foreign occupation. ^°° With the end of the
Apartheid regime in South Africa, many members of the African National Congress (ANC) advocated (unsuccessfully) for mass expropriations of private property arguing that those firms had benefited from
the previous racist regime.'"^ More recently, in 2008, the Argentinean
government expropriated privately owned pension-fund companies, arguing that these companies benefited from the previously (and highly
'^Miguel Tinker-Salas, The Enduring Legacy: Oil, Culture, and Society in Venezuela
(Durham, N.C., 2009), 171-203.
'^ Julio Moreno, Yankee Don't Go Home: Mexican Nationalism, American Business Culture, and the Shaping of Modern Mexico, 1920-1950 (Chapel Hill, N.C., 2003).
'* Stephanie Decker, "Corporate Legitimacy and Advertising: British Companies and the
Rhetoric of Development in West Africa, 1950—1970," Business History Review 81, no. 1
(2007): 59-86.
''Leshe Rood, "Nationalization and Indigenization in Africa," Journal of Modern African Studies 14, no. 3 (1976): 427-47; Adeoye Akinsanya, "Host Governments' Responses to
Foreign Economic Control: The Experiences of Selected African Countries," International
and Comparative Law Quarterly 30, no. 4 (1981): 769-90.
'"^ Louis Pérez, Cuba and the United States: Ties of Singular Intimacy (Athens, Ga.,
2003), 242-52.
'"'Patrick Bond and Khadija Sharife, "Apartheid Reparations and the Contestation of
Corporate Power in Africa," Review of African Political Economy 36, no. 119 (2009):
115-37-
Reputation and Political Legitimacy / 753
delegitimized) free market system ruling that country before the 2001
economic collapse.^°^ A similar sudden loss of legitimacy of multinational
corporations resulting from regime change also occurred in 2011 during
the prodemocracy popular rebellions taking place in the Middle East
and North Africa.
The fall of highly unpopular foreign business-friendly dictatorial
regimes led some analysts to express concern for the fate of the investments of the multinational corporations that benefited from the crumbling or fallen dictatorships.^"^ These concerns were clearly related to
the fear that once a democratic regime replaced a business-friendly dictator, the political legitimacy of the multinationals operating there
would be in danger. ^°4 The fast pace of these political changes led the
multinationals to face a sudden problem of reputation and legitimacy.
Several of these eases cannot be explained by equating democracy with
security of property rights or by the concept of obsolescing bargaining
power alone. We hope an analysis focused on the perceived legitimacy
and long-term reputation of the operations of foreign firms can provide
scholars with a tool for deeper understanding of the changing dynamics
between multinationals and host societies.
'"^"Argentina ehmina el sistema privado de pensiones," El Mundo (Spain), 21 Oct. 2008;
"Con críticas a las AFJP Cristina Kirchner firmó el proyecto para poner fin a la jubilación
privada," La Nación (Argentina), 21 Oct. 2008.
103 »Oil Pressure Rising," Economist, 26 Feb. 2011, 79-80.
'"''"Arab Unrest Put Their Lobbyists in Uneasy Spot," New York Times, 2 Mar. 2011, Al.
Marcelo Bucheli and Erica Salvaj / 754
o
c
o
o
I
I
'S
^ §
2 O
o
§1
to o
—I
.-H
.—I
CN] CM
CO
O
O O
tr- t >
02 en
.0
I
ii
S
I
o
o
S
O2
"T
CO
CD
-19
H
H
g
CO
O2
s
Si
o
I
ñ
Reputation and Political Legitimacy / 755
m
.'S "íí
o
a
'c
c
~—
!•
§<:; :
ni
I s <i i •
^
c s .iä
05
loe'
.v
;-
r^
-
M) o . 2 Q
b ra ^-H
3 .. o o 2
<^.2
5 .a Ï
M o
U
^
1
S
; « .
^
e-.si
Ol
2 1
o
1 Á
,—i
195(
2Ö4
§ ^ 2 § S
S
œ
i -x¡c -a0)
Ol
! - S ^ Tr
S
•a
es:
esi
esi
•a
•a . 3 . ^ 4 .
>>
sg¡
e H
o
o
i
o
I
o
S
SS---'
O
-S
1 '53 o
N 00
Marcelo Bucheli and Erica Salvaj / 756
MARCELO BUCHELI is associate professor of historj' and business administration at the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign. He has published several articles on the operations of multinationals in Latin America in
management and history journals. He is the author oí Bananas and Business
(New York, 2005) and coeditor of Organizations in Time (Oxford, 2014) with
R. Daniel Wadhwani. He earned his Ph.D. at Stanford, v^^as the 2004-2005
Harvard-Newcomen fellow, and a visiting scholar at the École Polytechnique
(Paris) in 2013.
ERICA SALVAJ is professor of management and strategy at Universidad
del Desarrollo (Chile). She earned an MA at Universidad Carlos III (Spain)
and a Ph.D. at IESE Business School (Spain). Her research has been funded
by those two institutions and the Comisión Nacional de Investigación Científica y Tecnológica de Chile (CONICYT). She has published several articles and
chapters on corporate governance, strategy, and social networks, was the
GCEE Fellow at Babson College (2012), and has been a visiting professor at
Universidad Torcuato Di Telia (Buenos Aires) since 2009.
Copyright of Business History Review is the property of President & Fellows of Harvard
College and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv
without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print,
download, or email articles for individual use.