International Journal of Public Administration
ISSN: 0190-0692 (Print) 1532-4265 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/lpad20
Gift Giving and Corruption
Adam Graycar & David Jancsics
To cite this article: Adam Graycar & David Jancsics (2017) Gift Giving and
Corruption, International Journal of Public Administration, 40:12, 1013-1023, DOI:
10.1080/01900692.2016.1177833
To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/01900692.2016.1177833
Published online: 07 Jun 2016.
Submit your article to this journal
Article views: 294
View related articles
View Crossmark data
Citing articles: 4 View citing articles
Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at
http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=lpad20
Download by: [Professor Adam Graycar]
Date: 22 September 2017, At: 06:39
INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION
2017, VOL. 40, NO. 12, 1013–1023
https://doi.org/10.1080/01900692.2016.1177833
Gift Giving and Corruption
Adam Graycara and David Jancsicsb
School of Social and Policy Studies, Flinders University, Flinders, Australia; bSchool of Public Affairs and Administration, Rutgers, The State
University of New Jersey-Newark, Newark, USA
Downloaded by [Professor Adam Graycar] at 06:39 22 September 2017
a
ABSTRACT
KEYWORDS
When individuals exchange gifts, social bonds are strengthened and reciprocity is created. If the
gift and the reciprocation both come from private resources, it is clearly a gift. If what is
reciprocated after a gift is given comes from an organization, or is a government resource rather
than from “one’s own pocket” then it is most likely a bribe. This study reviews the anthropological
literature on gift giving and constructs a typology for examining the gift/bribe distinction in
public administration. This classification helps distinguish analytically among different gift practices and clarify conceptual ambiguity of the terms gift and bribe.
Anthropology; corruption;
gift giving; public
administration
Introduction
Public administration involves the implementation of
policies and the use of discretion in that implementation. Gift giving is a universal phenomenon. When gifts
are given in a social situation what is expected in
return? When gifts are given in a public sector activity
what is expected in return? When is a gift a bribe?
These are the questions that this study seeks to address.
In so doing, it explores the literature around gift giving,
develops a typology for gifts and bribes, and applies it
to a public administration context.
The Weberian concept of bureaucracy places the office
at the heart of legal-rational activity. Civil servants occupy
an office and perform duties commensurate with that
office. There are delegations attached to each office, and
civil servants receive a salary for exercising these delegations. They should receive no more than their salary. In
some countries, salaries for civil servants are so low that
the proceeds of bribery and extortion supplement the
meager wages. In developed countries, many civil servants’ salaries are comparatively low, and the judgments
they make create wealth and opportunity for stakeholders
who generally have more than the civil servants with
whom they deal. The low paid civil servants however
can exercise considerable discretion which can provide
opportunity for bribe taking or extortion.
When civil servants control scarce resources such as
the issuing of a license, which they might not issue
without a bribe, we have a situation of rent seeking.
They have or they create a monopoly. Seeking a bribe
CONTACT Adam Graycar
Flinders, South Australia.
[email protected]
© 2017 Taylor & Francis Group, LLC
in addition to their salary does not add value, or add to
productivity. Speed money, by which civil servants
speed up a process, has often led government officials
to extort payments for the provision of any service at
all. This rent seeking behavior then becomes the standard for required payments, and this leads to significant inefficiencies (Klitgaard, 1988), not to mention the
undermining of confidence. Rent seeking is not the
focus of this article.
Under Weber’s rational legal system, all officials
follow rules and fit into formal roles that are different from the personal, family, and friendship roles
that shape the society. They are supposed to treat
each client impartially and equally, ignoring social
issues and personal ties. As Felson (2011) pointed
out, in Weber’s terms, bureaucracy is like a
machine, since it separates personal interests
(including family and friend commitments) from
larger interests and facilitates the latter.
All social systems involve looking after one’s personal interests and meeting social commitments to relatives and friends. Felson (2011) further noted that
corruption is the interplay between these primary
human imperatives and the imperatives of the bureaucratic systems that channel human interests. A tension
therefore is apparent between human activities and
aspirations and the imperatives of the larger social
and economic system. This is played out at the margins
of what might be deemed corruption in bureaucracies,
and the lubricant is often the gifts that are exchanged,
and the nature of those exchanges.
School of Social and Policy Studies, Flinders University, GPO Box 2100, Adelaide 5001,
Downloaded by [Professor Adam Graycar] at 06:39 22 September 2017
1014
A. GRAYCAR AND D. JANCSICS
Generally, people see no harm in giving gifts. Gifts
are usually exchanged as part of a regular social
relationship. On the other hand, people almost universally condemn bribes, viewing them as undesirable, harmful, and destructive. Bribes are given to
influence the outcome of a political, bureaucratic,
business or professional decision or relationship.
Gifts are legal, while bribes are illegal. If only it
were so clear-cut and unambiguous!
This article examines gift giving in public life and
notes that while the line between a gift and a bribe
is contestable, acceptance of and reliance on gifts
harms public policy and the delivery of services. Let
us list a dozen examples from our research. The first
and last examples are clear-cut and unambiguously a
gift and a bribe, respectively. Each of the examples
in between would have advocates arguing about the
extent to which they are acceptable or unacceptable
behaviors, and how they affect an outcome. The first
few examples are clear social and private examples,
the latter group are examples of public policy and
public service.
(8) A city official in New Zealand who is responsible for approving construction permits is
taken to a lavish lunch by a property developer, and then to a football match where he
sits in a corporate box.
(9) By giving small gifts, citizens in Benin try to
“personalize” their relationship with government officers otherwise they face negligent or
harsh treatment.
(10) In rural Mexico, corrupt government officials
share some of their illegally accumulated
wealth throughout the local community by
financing carnivals and fiestas with free food
and alcohol.
(11) A government minister for public works in
Queensland Australia accepts heavily discounted shares in a mining company, which
is planning a new mine and other infrastructure investments.
(12) A driving license tester in India is offered
money to issue a driver’s license without the
applicant taking a test.
(1) A neighbor in America brings a new resident
to the neighborhood home baked cakes and
cookies and a casserole.
(2) In Japan, new business partners often
exchange beautifully wrapped quality gifts at
the end of their first meeting.
(3) An employee electrician in Poland installs an
alarm and surveillance system in his daughter’s kindergarten for free (in work time, and
using his employer’s equipment).
(4) A multinational company in Europe rents out
two elegant resorts, a ski house in Austria and
a seaside villa in Croatia. The company gives
its VIP suppliers and clients in different countries the opportunity to spend some time in
the resorts for free whenever they want.
(5) An employee motor mechanic in Hungary
works on a car that has been brought in for
service and fixes (without charge) on his
friend’s car, things over and above what is
being paid for.
(6) In many post-socialist Central and Eastern
European countries, people give unofficial
payments in white envelopes to doctors to
show their “gratitude” (otherwise they may
not be attended to).
(7) Before a wedding Kazakh families organize
“in-law parties” in which they invite a powerful government official who receives expensive gifts from the parents of the couple.
These examples can be discussed and debated to
identify social exchanges, bribes, rent seeking, and
various arrangements that could distort policy and
services. Noting the conceptual ambiguity of the
terms gift and bribe, this article is divided into
three parts. The first part provides a working definition of gift giving and discusses several forms of
goods that can be exchanged as a gift, and discusses
similarities between gifts and bribes. We show that
many informal practices that are defined legally as
bribes have the same context and characteristics as
do gifts. In the second part, we note that when
transactions take place in organizations a distinction
is made between normal gift giving and bribery. In
the third part, we construct a framework for the
analysis of gifts and bribes in the public sector. We
conclude with applications of the framework and
suggestions for future studies.
Lines are often rigidly drawn. Bribery or corruption is typically associated with immorality and evil,
and gift giving is linked to goodness and self-sacrifice
(Rose-Ackerman, 1998). Economists, legal scholars,
political scientists, and international NGOs categorically take the view that bribes are illegal acts, prohibited by law, and understood as such in many
societies. However, this approach falls short of
explaining why otherwise normal individuals all
around the world routinely break the rules and
engage in informal exchanges that are defined as
bribery by law. Answers can be found in the work
INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION
of anthropologists, who provide the most comprehensive scholarship on this topic, and the task is to
apply these to public administration.
Anthropological concepts of gift and bribe
Downloaded by [Professor Adam Graycar] at 06:39 22 September 2017
What is gift giving?
Rather than crisply defining “gift”, anthropologists consider gift giving and bribing as “emic” concepts that
should not be defined by the observer scientist but rather
ought to be examined from the perspective of local
people (Torsello & Venard, 2015). Gift and bribe are
what local actors believe that they are (Werner, 2000).
Instead of defining the gift/bribe divided strictly in legal
terms, scholars in anthropology introduce a second
dimension and discuss the topic in terms of law and
morality at the same time (Anders & Nuijten, 2008).
According to this view, what is defined as corrupt and
illegal by the authorities, is often regarded as gift giving,
a morally justifiable act by local population (Torsello &
Venard, 2015). The legal system should not be the primary standard against which practices are judged as
either gift giving or bribes (Smart & Hsu, 2008).
According to the Encyclopedia Britannica, “gift
exchange is the transfer of goods or services that,
although regarded as voluntary by the people
involved, is part of the expected social behavior.”
This views gift as an exchange process that transfers
resources between actors. Exchange means “the giving
up of something in return for receiving something
else” (Macneil, 1986, p. 567). The definition also suggests that gift is subject to social expectations (rules),
even if the participants are not aware.
Almost anything of value can be given as a gift.
Nevertheless, gift does not need to be an object with
physical properties (Larsen & Watson, 2001). It may
come in different forms of labor; for example, cooking
for someone (Carrier, 1991; Murcott, 1983). Mutual
favors (including sex) can also serve as a gift.
Nonmaterial gifts or counter gifts do not always come
from an individual. They can be initiated by a community
or family, in the form of symbolic capital such as recognition, honor, prestige, or nobility (Bourdieu, 1997). For
example, unconditional hospitality to total strangers was
the norm in Arabian, Iranian, and Indian cultures where
the indirect reciprocity came as credit from the community (Offer, 1997).
Anthropologists originally studied gift in ancient or
“primitive” cultures, but they also confirm that gift
giving is a fundamental informal institution in contemporary societies (Lemmergaard & Sara Louise, 2011).
Beyond the typical and pure gift situations such as
1015
birthday, wedding or Christmas gifts, our modern
social life is full of symbolic and materialistic exchanges
of favors. For example, when our neighbors are busy we
pick up their children from school, and in return, they
walk our dog when we have to work late. Gifts have a
clear complementary role in areas where market solutions are scarce or imperfect. There are obvious instrumental benefits of such informal quid pro quo because
we can obtain resources that are rare or more expensive
if purchased in a commercial market. Through gift-type
exchanges, we can also receive services that require
more trust between the partners than impersonal economic transactions normally offer.
Similarities between gifts and bribes
Gifts and bribes are both socially functional institutions, and operate as complex rule systems. According
to anthropologists, both gifts and bribes are informal
exchange processes regulated by multiple (formal and
informal) rule systems (Anders & Nuijten, 2008).
Beyond their instrumental advantages, both have
important social functions which keep together social
groups at different levels of society. The universal
norms of gift giving and bribery (1) trigger reciprocity,
(2) regulate the (gift/bribe) exchange process, and (3)
enforce a quid pro quo. According to anthropologists
this normative similarity suggests that gift and bribe
constitute the same type of social behavior (Shore &
Haller, 2005; Smart & Hsu, 2008).
Gifts and bribes as multiple rule systems
Simmel (1950, p. 387) claimed that “all contacts among
men rest on the schema of giving and returning the
equivalence.” The most powerful driver of gift
exchanges is reciprocity, a universal norm that can be
found in almost all cultures. The origin of the universal
norm of reciprocity can be tracked back to ancient
religious rituals, when people offered sacrifices to the
gods as an act that should have been necessarily reciprocated (Mauss, 2002). Forms of reciprocity exist in all
societies to this day.
Although the economics literature claims that
altruistic giving exists when giving is not followed
by a return from the recipient (Rose-Ackerman,
1998), anthropologists believe that gifts always trigger
a return or at minimum, a feeling of obligation to
repay favors on the receiver side (Douglas, 2002).
The unreciprocated gift makes the person who has
accepted it feel inferior because of the sense of
indebtedness and the receiver will seek to get rid of
such obligation by reciprocating (Ferraro, 2004;
Malinowski, 1922; Mauss, 2002; Strathern, 2012).
Downloaded by [Professor Adam Graycar] at 06:39 22 September 2017
1016
A. GRAYCAR AND D. JANCSICS
Reciprocity means lending resources to someone in
the present and demanding (or at least hoping for) a
return in the future (Peebles, 2010).
Beyond the strong obligation to reciprocate, informal norms also shape other parts in the exchange of
giving and accepting gifts (Mauss, 2002). Some gifts are
regulated by society wide, almost universalistic norms.
For example, Christmas, birthday or baby shower gifts
and the related informal codes can be found in most
countries. Some gift-related norms are more culture
specific. In many Latin American countries, giving a
knife as a gift is taboo because it means ending a
relationship (Arunthanes, Tansuhaj, & Lemak, 1994).
In China, giving a clock as a gift is associated with bad
luck (Reardon, 1984).
Anthropologists argue that the phenomenon defined
as bribery by authorities is regulated by informal rules
simultaneously with formal criminal codes. Such legal
plurality makes the boundaries between gift and bribe
especially blurry (Polese, 2008). From this anthropological view, gift and bribe refer to the same type of social
behavior because both are subject of diverse and often
contradictory rule systems, and formal law is just one
of them. Informal norms are often so powerful indicating that people should share limited resources in a
particular way, very often with their closest friends,
kin, classmates, colleagues, ethnic groups, local communities or other informal networks, and not with
outsiders, as we saw in example 5 (the Hungarian
motor mechanic).
Universal informal norms can facilitate bribery. For
example, it was a common aphorism in many socialist
countries the “those who do not steal from the state steal
from their families” (Misangyi, Weaver, & Elms, 2008,
p. 753). Such general “Robin Hood” attitudes still exist in
the post-communist period and makes “stealing back”
from the state perfectly legitimate or even obligatory for
major part of society (Jancsics, 2015). Furthermore, paying physicians unofficially in post-communist Russia or
Hungary is not just morally accepted but an almost obligatory universal norm (Gaál, 2006; Rivkin-Fish, 2005).
Despite this practice being illegal in both countries,
those who do not express such appreciation could expect
a lower quality physician service. In Kazakhstan, officials
only accept bribes from people they know, and the handing over a secret envelope is stated as “this is for your
children”. (Werner, 2000, p. 19).
Gifts and bribes as socially functional institutions
Gifts and bribes both have important social functions as we discuss below when describing compadrazgo, blat, and guanxi. They keep social groups
together and help them survive by reducing risk and
uncertainty derived from inadequate formal institutional structures. A gift represents something substantially social beyond its pure instrumental value
(Alexander, 2001; Carrier, 1991).
A gift always refers to its symbolic meaning
related to the social bond between the partners
and the giver’s self-identity (Betteridge, 1985;
Sherry, 1983) and as rituals, gifts shape the participants’ recent and future expectations and behavior
(Komter, 2007). Thus gift has a crucial communicative function (Schieffelin, 1980). It sends symbolic
messages from the giver, which are interpreted by
the receiver (Wooten, 2000). Gifts can be strategically used as signals of the intention to establish
relationship and shorten social distance (Camerer,
1988; Otnes & Beltramini, 1996; Sahlins, 1965). For
example, giving home baked cakes and cookies to
new neighbors, a widespread custom in US suburbs,
is one way to make the newcomers members of the
local community. Signaling that a gift is required for
the issue of a license however, is rent seeking. While
this is a distortion of public policy this phenomenon
is not the main theme of this article.
When applied to a bureaucratic situation, ingroup
and outgroup operate differently. Corrupt exchanges
within a bureaucracy are risky, if trust is not strong.
Trust is a typical solution for risk because it provides a framework of social arrangements by serving
as a buffer against uncertainty (Luhmann, 1988).
There is the functional aspect of the gift-briber
dilemma. Transactions that look like deviant and
socially harmful behavior to outside observers
might be seen as a gift practice with crucial social
and symbolic functions by the local population
(Smith, 2007). Trust-based informal exchange systems that are often labeled as corrupt by outside
observers or authorities often function as survival
kits to deal with the inadequacies of formal institutional structures, shortage, insufficient formal rights,
harsh uncertain environment, or rigid authoritarian
systems.
They exist in many countries but probably the most
well-known examples are compadrazgo in Latin
America, blat in Russia, and guanxi in China
(Lomnitz, 1988). All of them are based on delayed
reciprocity. Although some scholars link these systems
to corruption, the anthropological literature stresses
their positive role in compensating for the imperfections of government and other formal institutions.
In Latin America, the relationship known as “compadrazgo” (co-parent or godparent) has become a
tool that allows poor social groups to survive physically and lets middle and upper classes maintain their
Downloaded by [Professor Adam Graycar] at 06:39 22 September 2017
INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION
social status and privileges (Lomnitz, 1988). For
example, using compadrazgo, individuals in the
urban middle class in Chile circulate resources such
as political support, school admission, jobs, and bank
loans (Lomnitz & Sheinbaum, 2004). Blat was an
informal tool in Russia that helped reduce uncertainty in conditions of shortage during communist
rule (Ledeneva, 1998). Russian people used blat as a
special form of barter, a non-monetary exchange,
because in the socialist planned economy money
was not necessarily the main tool of economic
transactions.
The continuous reciprocal exchange system in China
is known as guanxi. Its positive function is that it builds
trust in the absence of adequate formal legal and financial institutions (Smart & Hsu, 2008). In order to
reduce uncertainties in a fraught bureaucratic, legal,
and entrepreneurial system, Chinese people often use
gift-based guanxi “friendship” to obtain licenses, cheap
loans, retail space or introduce potential clients. Similar
systems operate in other cultures.
Not all bribery is gift related. Sometimes bribery
is a more instrumental transaction with the primary
function being to obtain direct and one-time benefit
for the participants. The most typical examples of
such non-gift-type corrupt transactions are bribing
traffic police, parking attendants, custom officers, or
other street-level bureaucrats. They usually happen
“on the spot” when the actors do not know each
other and there is a little chance that they will meet
again in the future (Jancsics, 2013). Here, cash-bribe
and instant responses dominate the transaction.
They are less personal and more economic-type
exchanges when parties have distinct economic and
social interest (Gregory, 1982; Sahlins, 1965).
Since informal norms rarely provide guidelines,
actors are on their own during these exchanges. They
must improvise and communicate effectively in order
to successfully make a corrupt deal on the spot.
However, if the actors are interested in repeating a
corrupt deal with the same partner, they will likely to
turn their exchange into a gift-type bribe based on
mutual trust and delayed reciprocity, features that
reduce the risks of detection and blur the corrupt
nature of the exchange (Lawler & Hipp, 2010).
Organizational dimension
People exchange gifts in various social and familial
and clan arrangements as discussed above. When we
turn to corruption, we can identify corrupt individuals, corrupt groups and corrupt organizations
(Graycar & Prenzler, 2013). When gifts are exchanged
1017
in a way that affects public policy or public administration we need to focus on an organizational dimension. At least one corrupt actor is invariably an
occupant of a public or private office. Corruption
and bribery are acts that often involve public servants
(Friedrich, 1993; Rose-Ackerman, 1996; Shleifer &
Vishny, 1993; World Bank, 1997), though corruption
can be found in any formally organized context in
governments and in private firms or in NGOs
(Aguilera & Vadera, 2008; Argandona, 2003;
Ashforth & Anand, 2003; Pellegrini, 2011).
Social/organizational exchanges
Including the organizational dimension in the analysis of the gift-bribe dilemma helps distinguish
between seemingly similar activities. A society-tosociety transaction involves gifts where the organizational affiliation of the partners is irrelevant. The
giver who initiates the transaction, and the receiver
who later reciprocates, bring their own or their
social groups’ resources in the transaction. When a
new resident moves into a neighborhood and a
neighbor brings them home baked cakes, and the
new resident in return invites the neighbor for a
lunch, it is a typical case of a society-to-society gift
transaction.
In contrast to this pattern, where there is a
society-to-bureaucracy transaction, someone gives a
gift to an organizational member but the counter
gift “does not come from one’s own pocket”
(Ledeneva, 2014, p. 21), but from public or private
organizational resources, then there is a bribe. For
example, if a government official in Kazakhstan
receives an expensive gift at an “in-law party” it
may not be seen culturally as a bribe, although it
may be against the code of conduct of his organization (Werner, 2000). However, if a few months later
he reciprocates this gift to the family with, say, a
governmental license he will turn organizational
resources into private ones. He will be trading his
entrusted authority.
The employee electrician who installs an alarm and
surveillance system in his daughter’s kindergarten for
free in work time, and using his employer’s resources
also falls into society-to-bureaucracy category. This is
“corruption with theft” (Shleifer & Vishny, 1993,
p. 601), an exchange when the actors steal the goods
of their organization and, by following the informal
norms of their social group, turn them into gifts and
transfer them to informal group members.
The value of the exchange is not always material,
and as such where there is low value people often do
Downloaded by [Professor Adam Graycar] at 06:39 22 September 2017
1018
A. GRAYCAR AND D. JANCSICS
not perceive it as a bribe. An employee hairdresser
might spend more time on a friends’ hair than normally; a car mechanic may fix some extra issues on a
neighbor’s car and not include them on the bill; a
school teacher who is a patient may receive special
care from a heart specialist whose child is a student in
the teacher’s class (Patico, 2002).
However, in many cases the stakes can be much
higher (Graycar & Prenzler, 2013: 4). For example,
giving a license to somebody without the necessary
skills to use equipment could cause serious accidents
and harm people. Regardless of the value of the
exchanged gift, these practices channel organizational
(or public) resources into private hands (RoseAckerman, 1998).
Sometimes, the counter transfer is not a “stolen”
organizational resource but just the normal treatment
of a client. In many African countries, people who want
to deal with public agencies must initiate a personal
relation and build trust with civil servants by giving
gifts in advance of the official transaction (Blundo &
Olivier De Sardan, 2006). Clients of the public service
who do not establish such social bonds can expect
poorer treatment from the officials.
Informal exchange systems such as compadrazgo,
blat, or guanxi simultaneously transfer private/community as well as organizational resources. For example,
when guanxi partners provide informal loans to each
other, the transaction involves only their private
resources while in many other cases bureaucratic permits and licenses serve as counter gift from a guanxi
network member.
Gift giving in the organizational circumstances
described above can result in a loss in revenue and an
undermining of bureaucratic processes and confidence
in those processes. Organizational affiliation is important. Where it is irrelevant to the transaction, the
exchange is a gift. Where one’s affiliation is central to
the transaction, the gift may well be a bribe.
and increases the chances of sales and business deals
(Arunthanes et al., 1994). Moreover, the total denial of
corporate gift exchange may well be an insult in many
parts of the world. In Japan, not giving a new business
partner wrapped quality gifts at the end of their first
meeting may prevent future deals. Gift giving can also
be an integral part of an organization’s marketing and
communication strategy. A nice pen with the firm’s
name on it can remind former or current business
partners of the firm’s products (Fan, 2006).
Exchanging bureaucratic gifts has the same functions
as gift giving between relatives, friends or acquaintances. It sends symbolic messages, creates goodwill,
develops social bonds and reduces transaction costs,
risks and uncertainties, derived from dealing with
strangers (Gordon & Miyake, 2001). Importantly, business gifts also have reciprocal effects and just like regular gifts they build social cohesion by simulating the
informal institution of gift within a controlled formal
environment (Arunthanes et al., 1994). They aim to
trigger positive discrimination by the other party to
get a discount, a lower price, longer delay in payment
and so on.
Bureaucratic gift giving is a bureaucracy-tobureaucracy transaction, regulated by organizational
codes of conduct which provide guidelines about the
form, the value and other conditions of the accepted
gifts (Irwin, 2013). For example, giving or receiving
gifts before a large deal or during a tendering process
is prohibited. Organizations usually limit the maximum value of the given or received gift and require
official records about gift transactions. Nevertheless,
most codes offer some discretionary freedom to the
employees to judge what is acceptable within cultural
considerations (Gordon & Miyake, 2001).
The key here is transparency, and an assessment of
whether there is an expected and distorting quid pro
quo for something like a cup of coffee, a meal, or a pen,
or some larger gift.
Benign? Gifts and bribes
Bribery as policy
In the case of normal gift exchange, participants bring
their own, family or community resources, in the transaction. When they exchange something that belongs to
an organization, normal gift exchange becomes a bribe,
unless there are clear guidelines and transparency.
There are times when a “bureaucratic bribe” is against
the organization’s formal rules, yet supported by informal organizational expectations.
Giving and accepting of gifts and hospitality has an
essential role in facilitating long-term business relationships. It enhances the company’s image
We cross into different territory when organizational
resources are traded for gifts or benefits, and when this
is done in secret or with no transparency. Although
such exchanges are still bureaucracy-to-bureaucracy
transactions, they fall into the category of bribery.
Sometimes, this can be a formal policy in an organization, and sometimes it can be informal practice when
the policy forbids it.
Gift and bribe reallocate organizational resources in
order to serve organizations goal, enhance business and
guarantee the organizations’ survival for a long term.
Downloaded by [Professor Adam Graycar] at 06:39 22 September 2017
INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION
Pharmaceutical companies for example sponsor for
physicians, all-expenses-paid “conference trips” to
attractive resort. These practices it is argued significantly increase the prescribing of the promoted drugs
(Orlowski & Wateska, 1992). A company that maintains ski lodges and seaside villas for VIP suppliers and
clients, or a property developer who invites officials
responsible for approving construction, to a lavish
lunch follow the very similar pattern.
Facilitation payments involve gifts to officials to
make happen things that should happen as a matter
of administrative or bureaucratic course. Without such
a payment an enterprise may face serious difficulties in
securing normal business activity. A company’s product
might lie on the dock of a foreign port, and to avoid
spoilage of the whole cargo the manager makes a choice
between a large company loss or a small payment/gift
to facilitate the business at hand (Fadiman, 1986). Does
it happen just once, or is it endemic? Such settings
easily trigger a bureaucratic bribe. These patterns
involve gifts in which group of employees carry out
corrupt action on behalf of the organization (Pinto,
Leana, & Pil, 2008).
Between 2001 and 2007, Siemens, the German multinational with a wide range of businesses across the
globe, made some 4,283 corrupt payments to foreign
officials totaling over $US 1.4 billion. Up until 1999 in
Germany corrupt payments to foreign officials were
tax-deductible expenses. This led to the systematic
embedding of a bribery culture within the organization,
which included management instructions on how to set
up shell companies in order to funnel illicit payments
to foreign officials. As a corrupt organization, Siemens
was indicted and prosecuted in Germany, the USA and
Italy.1 Overall, their breaches of procurement policies
cost the company $2.6 billion—$1.6 billion in fines in
Germany and the USA, and $1 billion in self-initiated
corporate reforms.
Crossing the line between bureaucratic gift and bribe is
often authorized by managers (Misangyi et al., 2008).
Here, the formal organizational rule bans the exchange
while informal norms legitimated by authorities allow it.
Managers usually do not directly permit rule breaking but
create a permissive ethical climate and organizational
culture (Martin, Lopez, Roscigno, & Hodson, 2013).
Setting up unrealistic service and financial targets and
turning a blind eye to the tools employees use to make
deals is a typical means of facilitating bureaucratic bribe
(Ashforth & Anand, 2003; Vaughan, 1982). Emphasis on
ends rather than means, supported by strong incentives
for attaining may be a clear signal of an unethical climate
(Brief, Buttram, & Dukerich, 2001; Misangyi et al., 2008).
When bribery is an unofficial organizational policy, the
1019
practice may become routinized and embedded into the
organization’s normal procedures. An organization’s
informal norm system helps to hide such practices.
Organizations have a natural tendency to create a culture
of silence and cover-up against the outside world where
even honest members show solidarity with their deviant
and corrupt colleagues (Katz, 1977).
Gifts and bribes in public sector settings
We have a situation where people have always
exchanged gifts, and incurred obligations. We have a
formal rational-legal bureaucratic system where the
office is the unit of analysis, but the office holder has
discretion and accountability and if these are out of
balance, a corrupt situation exists. We have expectations of transparency in dealings, especially those that
involve exchanges. All deplore bribery and corruption,
yet we find many examples of officials receiving gifts
that they thought were perfectly acceptable, and perhaps sometimes they were.
Our political and administrative history is replete
with examples of officials who have taken gifts and
denied that there was a quid pro quo. We have blatant
examples of bribes where a rent seeking bureaucrat
would not perform a required task without a “gift”.
How do we start to draw up the categories of what is
acceptable and what is not? Most bureaucratic systems
have rules about the value of the gifts that officials can
receive, and still there is confusion. Most systems have
“gift registers” which document gifts received, yet these
are often not complete, or once completed, rarely
scrutinized.
As noted above, bribes can take many forms and
can do damage of great magnitude. The damage is not
always financial. One study in New York found that
the dollar value of bribes paid to New York City
officials was very small (bribes of less than a few
hundred dollars) yet the damage was to reputation,
confidence, and most of all to the governance capacity
of the city itself (Graycar & Villa, 2011).
All of this has relevance for public administration. Officials need to have discretion and need to
engage with stakeholders. To refuse a cup of coffee
purchased by a stakeholder does not make sense,
nor does the refusal to accept a sandwich lunch, or
a bunch of flowers, or a box of chocolates. Yet, so
many training courses in organizational integrity
focus on these types of events and discuss them in
great detail. If an official could be “bought” for a
cup of coffee, and misuse discretion, then s/he
would not benefit from more rules or more restrictions. The real challenge is knowing when to draw
Downloaded by [Professor Adam Graycar] at 06:39 22 September 2017
1020
A. GRAYCAR AND D. JANCSICS
the line—modest lunch, less modest dinner, premium box at the football, trip to Las Vegas, with
perhaps the services of a hooker. Most officials
know where to draw the line. The key is to be
open and transparent about any gift.
In essence, we have four situations which we call,
social gift, social bribe, bureaucratic gift, and bureaucratic bribe. These four categories all involve some
element of gift, and therefore are distinct from our
example 12 above (driving license inspector) which is
unambiguously a bribe—a non-gift bribe. Our typology below does not cover the common phenomenon
of a non-gift bribe. Our other examples are assigned
to the various categories, though this assignment
could be the subject of debate.
Table 1 shows these main types of exchanges that
involve gift. The variables that we would consider
for each of these are: what is the primary function
of the exchange; what is it that is being transacted;
what is expected in return; does the organizational
affiliation of the participants matter; are they
exchanging their own resources, or somebody else’s
(the organization’s); is there transparency in the
transaction; who are the winners and who are the
losers; what is the primary means of regulation of
the transaction.
Social gift is an exchange of private resources
between individuals or members of a social group
with the primary function of facilitating (maintaining,
creating, negotiating or breaking) social relationships
and reinforce social bonds. Here, the participants’ formal organizational affiliation is irrelevant. Although
social gifting is facilitated by informal norms, it is a
relatively transparent act, visible to other group
Table 1. Types of gift exchange.
Social gift
Primary function, social
Individual or societal transaction
Private goods exchanged
Community/individual benefits by
strengthening social bonds
Nobody loses
Governed by informal norms
Transparent
Bureaucratic gift
Primary function, instrumental
Organizational transaction
Organizational goods exchanged
Organization benefits
Nobody loses
Governed by formal rules
Transparent
Social bribe
Primary function, social
Individual or societal vs.
organizational transaction
Private and organizational goods
exchanged
Community/individual benefits by
strengthening social bonds
Organization loses
Governed by informal norms
Non-transparent
Bureaucratic bribe
Primary function, instrumental
Organizational transaction
Organizational goods exchanged
Organization benefits
Competition or general public loses
Governed by informal
organizational norms
Non-transparent
members and outsiders. There are usually no losers of
this type of gift giving. Example 1 above fits here.
Social bribe is very similar to social gift practices
except that here at least one actor brings into the
transaction goods that belong to an organization.
The primary function of this exchange type is still
social. In this case, the obligations and informal
norms derived from one’s social membership are
more powerful than the organizational rules and
are related to the person’s formal bureaucratic role.
Therefore, participants view “stealing” from their
organization as acceptable or even desirable. While
the community and individuals benefit by strengthening social bonds the organization loses its
resources. Social bribe is not transparent, since
actors try to hide the exchange from the organization. Examples 3, 5, 6, 7, 9, and 10 fit here.
Bureaucratic gift is a transparent and formally
regulated gift form that allocates organizational
resources. It tries to simulate social gifting by creating goodwill and triggering reciprocal effects between
office holders in different bureaucracies. The primary
instrumental function of this type is to benefit the
organization by facilitating smoother transactions
with other organizations. However, the norm of reciprocity is usually weaker in organizational contexts
than in society because people often feel that the
favor they receive is driven by calculative motivation
rather than genuine help (Belmi & Pfeffer, 2015).
Example 2 fits here.
Bureaucratic bribe involves gift-type transactions in
which the main beneficiary, as in the case of bureaucratic gift, is the organization. Here, formal rule breaking is facilitated by informal norms, the organization’s
corrupt culture. Although individuals may also profit
from a bureaucratic bribe the primary function of such
non-transparent transactions is to ensure the organization’s survival. Defense contractors who have former
senior military officers in the top echelons may exhibit
bureaucratic bribery, for in winning large contracts
through their contacts, the organization wins and the
community loses as public spending on weapons goes
up without real competition (Perrow, 2007). Similarly,
a company which might provide a gift to the police
retirement foundation could get its security protection
from the city’s police department on very favorable
terms. Or a company which finances an urban renewal
project would be so much in favor with the city government which could limit development applications by
competitors, whose entry could increase the demand
for skilled labor in the area. In these examples of
bureaucratic bribe, the organization wins and the community loses. Examples 4, 8, and 11 fit here.
INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION
Downloaded by [Professor Adam Graycar] at 06:39 22 September 2017
Conclusions
Gift and bribe practices are similar phenomena that can
be found all around the world. People have always circulated resources through gift exchanges in order to keep
their social group together. These trust-based relationship structures help reduce risk and uncertainty and offer
safety networks, stability and meaning in many situations
of social life. Anthropologists reveal shared features and
important social and cultural aspects of the gift-bribe
divide. Gift and bribe are relative; they may look totally
different from the perspective of authorities than from
the viewpoint of local actors.
However, there is a tipping point where a normal
gift turns into a bribe. The typology we offer here
suggests that the organizational dimension is an important explanatory factor in the analysis of gift-bribe
practices in two ways. It helps clarify the difference
between gift and bribe. It is also a sufficient tool to
detect additional gift-type exchanges that occur only
between organizational actors. The presence of organizational resources in an informal transaction is a distinguishing criterion between gift and bribe. Moreover,
a bribe is always a hidden non-transparent exchange.
Sharing bureaucratic resources with favored outsiders
is clearly against the interest of the organization and it is
likely that organizational control mechanisms will seek
and detect such “leaks.” However, in the case of bureaucratic gift and bribe practices, the organization may not
detect the transfer as a resource loss. Some organizations
turn a blind eye to the move from gift to bribe as they view
it as an investment in the organization’s future. Other
organizations build integrity, so that they can adhere as
much as possible to the Weberian bureaucratic model and
invest in their staff to build integrity and handle gift/bribe
issues in an ethical and transparent manner.
Note
1. See http://www.fcpablog.com/blog/tag/siemens?
currentPage=8
References
Aguilera, R. V., & Vadera, A. K. (2008). The dark side of
authority: Antecedents, mechanisms, and outcomes of
organizational corruption. Journal of Business Ethics, 77,
431–449. doi:10.1007/s10551-007-9358-8
Alexander, C. (2001). Legal and binding: Time, change and
long-term
transactions.
Journal
of
the
Royal
Anthropological Institute, 7, 467–485. doi:10.1111/14679655.00073
Anders, G., & Nuijten, M. (2008). Corruption and the secret of
law: An introduction. In M. Nuijten, & G. Anders (Ed.),
1021
Corruption and the secret of law: A legal anthropological
perspective (pp. 1–26). Abingdon, UK: Ashgate Publishing
Group.
Argandona, A. (2003). Private-to-private corruption. Journal
of Business Ethics, 47, 253–267. doi:10.1023/
A:1026266219609
Arunthanes, W., Tansuhaj, P., & Lemak, D. J. (1994). Crosscultural business gift giving. International Marketing
Review, 11, 44–55. doi:10.1108/02651339410069245
Ashforth, B. E., & Anand, V. (2003). The normalization of
corruption in organizations. Research in Organizational
Behavior, 25, 1–52. doi:10.1016/S0191-3085(03)25001-2
Belmi, P., & Pfeffer, J. (2015). How “organization” can
weaken the norm of reciprocity: The effects of attributions
for favors and a calculative mindset. Academy of
Management Discoveries, 1, 36–57. doi:10.5465/
amd.2014.0015
Betteridge, A. H. (1985). Gift exchange in Iran: The locus of
self-identity in social interaction. Anthropological
Quarterly, 58, 190–202. doi:10.2307/3318149
Blundo, G., & Olivier De Sardan, J. (2006). Everyday corruption and the state: Citizens & public officials in Africa. New
York, NY: Zed Books.
Bourdieu, P. (1997). Marginalia—Some additional notes of
the gift. In Schrift (Ed.), The logic of the gift (pp. 231–241).
New York, NY: Routledge.
Brief, A. P., Buttram, R. T., & Dukerich, J. M. (2001).
Collective corruption in the corporate world: Toward a
process model. Mahwah, NJ: Erlbaum.
Camerer, C. (1988). Gifts as economic signals and social
symbols. The American Journal of Sociology, 94(Suppl),
S180–S214. doi:10.1086/228946
Carrier, J. (1991). Gifts, commodities, and social relations: A
Maussian view of exchange. Sociological Forum, 6, 119–
136. doi:10.1007/BF01112730
Douglas, M. (2002). Foreword: No free gifts. In M. Mauss
(Ed.), The gift: The form and reason for exchange in archaic
societies. London, UK: Routledge Classics.
Fadiman, J. A. (1986). A traveller’s guide to gifts and bribes.
Harvard Business Review (July-August), 122–136.
Fan, Y. (2006). Promoting business with corporate gifts –
Major issues and empirical evidence. Corporate
Communications: An International Journal, 11, 43–55.
doi:10.1108/13563280610643543
Felson, M. (2011). Corruption in the broad sweep of history.
In A. Graycar, & R. G. Smith (Ed.), Handbook of global
research and practice in corruption (pp. 12–17).
Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
Ferraro, E. (2004). Owing and being in debt. A contribution
from the Northern Andes of Ecuador. Social Anthropology,
12, 77–94. doi:10.1017/S0964028204000060
Friedrich, C. J. (1993). Corruption concepts in historical
perspective. In A. J. Heidenheimer, M. Johnston, & V.
T. LeVine (Ed.), Political Corruption: A Handbook (pp.
15–24). London, UK: Transaction Publishers.
Gaál, P. (2006). Gift, fee or bribe? Informal payments in
Hungary. In J. Kotalik & D. Rodriguez (Ed.), Global
Corruption Report 2006 (pp. 71–74). Berlin, Germany:
Transparency International.
Gordon, K., & Miyake, M. (2001). Business approaches to
combating bribery: A study of codes of conduct. Journal of
Business Ethics, 34, 161–173. doi:10.1023/A:1012517622479
Downloaded by [Professor Adam Graycar] at 06:39 22 September 2017
1022
A. GRAYCAR AND D. JANCSICS
Graycar, A., & Prenzler, T. (2013). Understanding and preventing corruption. New York, NY: Palgrave.
Graycar, A., & Villa, D. (2011). The loss of governance
capacity through corruption. Governance, 24, 419–438.
doi:10.1111/gove.2011.24.issue-3
Gregory, C. A. (1982). Gifts and commodities. London and
New York, NY: Academic Press.
Irwin, J. (2013). How corporate gift-giving can be ethical.
Ethical Corporation. Retrieved from http://www.ethical
corp.com/business-strategy/how-corporate-gift-givingcan-be-ethical
Jancsics, D. (2013). Petty corruption in Central and Eastern
Europe: The client’s perspective. Crime, Law and Social
Change, 60, 319–341. doi:10.1007/s10611-013-9451-0
Jancsics, D. (2015). Imperatives in informal organizational
resource exchange in Central Europe. Journal of Eurasian
Studies, 6, 59–68. doi:10.1016/j.euras.2014.10.001
Katz, J. (1977). Cover-up and collective integrity: On the natural
antagonisms of authority internal and external to organizations. Social Problems, 25, 3–17. doi:10.2307/800463
Klitgaard, R. (1988). Controlling corruption. Berkeley, CA:
University of California Press.
Komter, A. (2007). Gifts and social relations: The mechanisms of reciprocity. International Sociology, 22, 93–107.
doi:10.1177/0268580907070127
Larsen, D., & Watson, J. J. (2001). A guide map to the terrain
of gift value. Psychology & Marketing, 18, 889–906.
doi:10.1002/(ISSN)1520-6793
Lawler, E. J., & Hipp, L. (2010). Corruption as social
exchange. In S. R. Thye, & E. J. Lawler (Ed.), Advances in
group processes (Vol. 27, pp. 269–296). Bingley, UK:
Emerald Group Publishing Limited.
Ledeneva, A. V. (1998). Russia’s economy of favours: Blat,
networking and informal exchange. Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press.
Ledeneva, A. V. (2014). The ambivalence of blurred boundaries: Where informality stops and corruption begins?
Perspectives, 12, 19–22.
Lemmergaard, J., & Sara Louise, M. (2011). Regarding gifts On Christmas gift exchange and asymmetrical business
relations. Organization, 18, 763–777. doi:10.1177/
1350508411416402
Lomnitz, L. A. (1988). Informal exchange networks in formal
systems: A theoretical model. American Anthropologist, 90,
42–55. doi:10.1525/aa.1988.90.issue-1
Lomnitz, L. A., & Sheinbaum, D. (2004). Trust, social networks and the informal economy: A comparative analysis.
Review
of
Sociology,
10,
5–26.
doi:10.1556/
RevSoc.10.2004.1.1
Luhmann, N. (1988). Familiarity, confidence, trust: Problems
and alternatives. In D. Gambetta (Ed.), Trust: Making and
breaking cooperative relations (pp. 94–107). New York,
NY: Basil Blackwell.
Macneil, I. R. (1986). Exchange revisited. Ethics, 96, 567–593.
doi:10.1086/292776
Malinowski, B. (1961) [1922]. Argonauts of the Western Pacific:
An account of native enterprise and adventure in the archipelagoes of Melanesian New Guinea. New York, NY: Dutton.
Martin, A. W., Lopez, S. H., Roscigno, V. J., & Hodson, R.
(2013). Against the rules: Synthesizing types and processes
of bureaucratic rulebreaking. Academy of Management
Review, 38, 550–574. doi:10.5465/amr.2011.0223
Mauss, M. (2002) [1954]. The gift: The form and reason for
exchange in archaic societies. London, UK: Routledge.
Misangyi, V. F., Weaver, G. R., & Elms, H. (2008). Ending
corruption: The interplay among institutional logics,
resources, and institutional entrepreneurs. Academy of
Management Review, 33, 750–770. doi:10.5465/
AMR.2008.32465769
Murcott, A. (1983). It’s a pleasure to cook for him. In E.
Gamarnikov, D. Morgan, J. Purvis, & D. Taylorson (Eds.),
The Public and the Private (pp. 78–90). London, UK:
Heinemann.
Offer, A. (1997). Between the gift and the market: The economy of regard. The Economic History Review, 50, 450–476.
doi:10.1111/ehr.1997.50.issue-3
Orlowski, J. P., & Wateska, L. (1992). The effects of pharmaceutical firm enticements on physician prescribing patterns. There’s no such thing as a free lunch. Chest, 102,
270–273. doi:10.1378/chest.102.1.270
Otnes, C., & Beltramini, R. F. (1996). Gift giving: An overview. In C. Otnes, & R. F. Beltramini (Ed.), Gift giving: A
research anthology (pp. 30–15). Bowling Green, OH:
Bowling Green State University Popular Press.
Patico, J. (2002). Chocolate and cognac: Gifts and the recognition of social worlds in post-Soviet Russia. Ethnos, 67,
345–368. doi:10.1080/0014184022000031202
Peebles, G. (2010). The anthropology of credit and debt.
Annual Review of Anthropology, 39, 225–240.
doi:10.1146/annurev-anthro-090109-133856
Pellegrini, L. (2011). Corruption, development and the environment. New York, NY: Springer.
Perrow, C. (2007). Why bureaucracy? In A. S. Wharton (Ed.),
The sociology of organizations (pp. 23–51). Los Angeles,
CA: Roxbury P. C.
Pinto, J., Leana, C. R., & Pil, F. K. (2008). Corrupt organizations or organizations of corrupt individuals? Two types of
organization-level corruption. Academy of Management
Review, 33, 685–709. doi:10.5465/AMR.2008.32465726
Polese, A. (2008). If I receive it, it is a gift; If I demand it, then
it is a bribe. Anthropology in Action, 15, 47–60.
doi:10.3167/aia.2008.150305
Reardon, K. K. (1984). It’s the thought that counts. Harvard
Business Review, 62, 136–141.
Rivkin-Fish, D. (2005). Bribes, gifts and unofficial payments:
Rethinking corruption in post-Soviet Russian health care.
In D. Haller, & C. Shore (Ed.), Corruption: Anthropological
perspectives (pp. 47–64). London, UK: Pluto Press.
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1996). Democracy and `Grand’
Corruption’. International Social Science Journal, 48, 365–
380. doi:10.1111/1468-2451.00038
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1998). Bribes and gifts. In A. Ben-Ner, &
L. Putterman (Ed.), Economics, values, and organization
(pp. 296–328). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University
Press.
Sahlins, M. D. (1965). On the sociology of primitive
exchange. In M. Banton (Ed.), The relevance of models
for social anthropology (pp. 139–236). New York, NY:
Praeger.
Schieffelin, E. L. (1980). Reciprocity and the construction of
reality. Man, 15, 502–517. doi:10.2307/2801347
Sherry Jr., J. F. (1983). Gift giving in anthropological perspective. Journal of Consumer Research, 10, 157–168.
doi:10.1086/jcr.1983.10.issue-2
INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION
Downloaded by [Professor Adam Graycar] at 06:39 22 September 2017
Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1993). Corruption. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 599–617.
doi:10.2307/2118402
Shore, C., & Haller, D. (2005). Introduction - Sharp practice:
Anthropology and the study of corruption. In D. Haller, &
C. Shore (Ed.), Corruption: Anthropological perspectives
(pp. 1–26). London, UK: Pluto Press.
Simmel, G. (1950). The sociology of Georg Simmel. New York:
The Free Press.
Smart, A., & Hsu, C. L. (2008). Corruption or social capital?
Tact and the performance of guanxi in market socialist
China. In M. Nuijten, & G. Anders (Ed.), Corruption and
the secret of law: A legal anthropological perspective (pp.
167–191). Abingdon, UK: Ashgate Publishing Group.
Smith, D. J. (2007). A culture of corruption: Everyday deception and popular discontent in Nigeria. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
1023
Strathern, M. (2012). Gifts money cannot buy. Social
Anthropology,
20,
397–410.
doi:10.1111/j.14698676.2012.00224.x
Torsello, D., & Venard, B. (2015). The anthropology of corruption. Journal of Management Inquiry Published electronically on April 5 doi:10.1177/1056492615579081.
Vaughan, D. (1982). Toward understanding unlawful organizational behavior. Michigan Law Review, 80, 1377–1402.
doi:10.2307/1288553
Werner, C. (2000). Gifts, bribes, and development in postsoviet Kazakstan. Human Organization, 59, 11–22.
doi:10.17730/humo.59.1.w2582tqj18v3880p
Wooten, D. B. (2000). Qualitative steps toward an expanded
model of anxiety of gift-giving. Journal of Consumer
Research, 27, 84–95. doi:10.1086/314310
World Bank. (1997). Helping countries combat corruption.
Washington, CD: World Bank.