PORTS IN THE FRAMEWORK OF EU TRANSPORT POLICY
Introduction1
This is an earlier and substantially lengthier version of the European Commission’s
Green Paper on Ports and Maritime Infrastructure, which I had prepared as a
member of Commissioner Neil Kinnock’s wise men group. The Green Paper has
often been described as the most influential port policy document ever produced by
the EC. The current version does not in any way commit the European Commission
and interested readers are advised to refer to the final version of the Green Paper as
published by the EC.
The present work requires careful and persistent reading so that the reader bypasses
the necessary bureaucratic superficiality and identifies my core arguments which, I
am happy to say, have not changed to the slightest in the 15 years since its
publication. Many of these arguments had been described as ‘politically dangerous’
and, consequently, did not find their way into the Green Paper. I quote one of them in
p.7 (emphasis added):
…The Commission’s White Paper on the future development of the common
transport policy2 laid down a new vision for transport policy, following the principle
of sustainable mobility; i.e. a strategy that acknowledges the need for a more balanced
transport system that would fulfill its economic and social role while, at the same
time, containing its effects on the environment. The overall objective of such an
approach, as clearly described by the European Parliament3, is to …promote
sustainable, efficient transport systems which meet the economic, social,
environmental and safety needs of European citizens; help reduce regional
disparities; and enable European business to compete effectively in world markets…
Again, the ‘challenge’ is apparent: a more balanced pan-European transport system
with the above objectives is in stark contrast with hub-porting; concentration of traffic
to selected ports; longer distances; and consequent transport externalities. It is thus
increasingly felt that the European Commission needs to depart from its all-pleasing
‘statements’ and make hard-nosed decisions in order to effectuate its cohesion and
regional development objectives which are the overarching ones…(unquote).
A closing note of caution on my use of the word superficiality: With remarkable
consistency, European institutions involved in the maritime sector have been focusing
all along on issues such as safety and environmental protection; issues which, among
others, have allowed the proliferation of various monopolies in the port sector. I
believe this has not happened accidentally. I believe instead that the focus on the
‘secondary’ has diverted attention from the ‘primary’ which comprises the ‘politically
sensitive’ issues of port pricing; infrastructure financing; state aids; transparency of
port accounts; and, finally, a European ‘port governance’ model.
1
This introduction was written in 2012, i.e. 15 years since the original publication.
op. cit. 5
3
Towards a European Wide Transport Policy; A Set of Common Principles. European Parliament, Third PanEuropean Transport Conference, Helsinki, 23-25 June 1997, p.5 (Annex).
2
General
European ports, with the overwhelming predominance of those located in the North Sea area,
handle approximately 2.5 billion tons of cargo per year. Around 70% of this consists of deepsea traffic and 30% of intra-European trade. In addition, ferries carry more than 100 million
passengers each year4, providing essential connections to peripheral countries and islands, and
contributing to the development of Europe’s tourism industry.
Table 1: Port Traffic and Short Sea Shipping in the EU (million tons)
Goods Loaded
Intra-EU
Total
1985
1990
1992
203.8
517.6
230.3
536.3
241.8
564.8
Goods Unloaded
Intra-EU
209.9
233.1
272.2
Total
1,131.4
1,316.1 1,360.9
1,852.4 1,925.7
Total
1,649.0
Source: Erasmus University Rotterdam
Profound trends in trade liberalisation and the globalisation of the world economy are having
significant impacts on international seaborne transport and ports, with long term effects not
easily predictable. These trends have drastically weakened the link between manufacturing and
the location of factors of production, and have stimulated a most noticeable shift of
manufacturing activities towards countries with a comparative advantage.
In their turn too, developments in international transport and communications technologies have
been instrumental in shaping manufacturing processes. Containerisation and advances in global
supply chain management have revolutionized the trading arrangements of value-added goods
and have given manufacturers and shippers more control and choice over the productiontransport-distribution chain. In addition, the increased reliability and accuracy of international
transport now allows manufacturing industries to adopt flexible Just-in-Time and Make-to-Order
production technologies that inter alia, allow them to cope with the vagaries and unpredictability
of the seasonal, business and trade cycles, as well as plan business development in a more
efficient and cost effective way. Transport efficiency has become also necessary due to the
very same nature of value-added goods whose increasing sophistication requires fast transit
times from origin to destination in order to increase traders’ turnover and minimise holding-,
pipeline-, and inventory costs.
Competition is forcing carriers to continuously strive to lower their unit costs, mainly through
the construction of increasingly larger vessels. Shippers, on their side, require frequent
services and more port calls, in order to reduce their inventory costs. The combination of
larger vessels and frequent services leads to low ship capacity utilisation. To cope with this,
carriers integrate horizontally by forming strategic alliances. By means of this, and by
dovetailing their networks, they exercise better control on their joint capacities, achieve better
4
According to estimates of the European Community Shipowners’ Associations
2
asset utilisation and lower average costs. At the same time, and in order to differentiate from
the homogeneous and highly competitive port-to-port service, carriers also integrate vertically
with terminals, warehousing and distribution systems in an effort to offer premium, tailormade, door-to-door solutions.
Economies of scale at sea (larger vessels) and horizontal and vertical integration require
carriers to limit their ports of call at a few large hubs. However, concentration of cargo in a
limited number of mega-ports entails loss of flexibility and competition while, at the same
time, it leads to longer land transport distances and to an increase in the use of road transport.
Mega ships and hub-porting are thus counterproductive to a policy of shifting freight from
road to sea and are, in general, disliked by shippers, who favour less transhipment and goods
landing as close to them as possible.
Undoubtedly, further trade liberalisation will create new and stronger trade flows and demand
for shipping services. The type of shipping that will emerge, however, is not unambiguously
foreseen by industry observers. Despite conventional wisdom that wants a continuing
increase in ship sizes, a number of external long term trends point to the direction of a
possible increase in the market share of smaller ships, targeting more immediate hinterlands.
These trends include world-wide port development (making multi-porting economically
attractive); regionalisation of trade (involving shorter distances); and diseconomies of scale in
major ports. Two additional trends pointing to this direction are the development of transport
infrastructure in peripheral Europe, and a future road pricing policy not favouring longdistance haulage. Their effect could be more balanced traffic flows and port development in
Europe.
Whatever the likely future scenario, one thing remains: Europe’s export competitiveness in a
global economy depends increasingly on efficient and cost effective transport and port
systems. Furthermore, the substantial emphasis the Union attributes to the development of
trans-European transport networks, aiming at closer economic and social integration;
creation of employment; growth; and sustainable mobility, charges ports with an additional
role and responsibility. Indeed, the development of the Union’s multimodal transport network
would be incomplete without including ports; i.e. its interconnection points.
The European Union has certain obligations under the Treaties, which have special relevance
to the port sector. Firstly, the Treaty of Rome determines the rules governing competition;
State aid; freedom to provide services; and the right of establishment. Furthermore, the
Maastricht Treaty has laid down the rules governing the development of a Trans-European
Transport Network, aimed at serving the objectives of the single market, i.e. to strengthen
economic and social cohesion and to link island; landlocked; and peripheral regions of the
Union with its more central areas.
The Commission, therefore, finds it important to promote the port sector through a number of
positive measures and actions aimed at improving its overall performance. These include
actions to improve port efficiency; remove harmful obstacles to trade; and promote
improvements in port and related infrastructure so that port efficiency reaches higher
standards throughout the Community.
The Role of Ports in Trans-European Transport Networks
The Treaty of the European Union governs the EU’s work in developing the trans-European
transport networks. It requires the EU to promote the interconnection and interoperability of
national networks -and access to them-, taking into account the need to link island;
landlocked; and peripheral regions of the Union with its more central areas. The aim is to
3
enable citizens of the Union, economic operators and regional and local communities to
derive full benefit from the internal market.
However, interconnection, interoperability and TEN optimisation in general cannot be
achieved if ports are not included in the equation as the crucial links of a closed (i.e. total)
European transport system. Considering European ports as a whole and as the international
interface of the European logistical network is consistent with the approach taken by the
Commission in its White Book on the future development of the common transport policy.5 In
fact, while taking note of existing inefficiencies and discordances, the White Book provides
for a global approach to the problem; it aims at a more balanced modal development of
transport, allowing users greater freedom of choice; at a more balanced distribution among
regions of benefits resulting from infrastructure development; at improving the efficiency of
companies operating in this sector; and at increased safety and attention to the problems of
environmental protection. All this, while taking social problems related to the sector’s
employment levels into account.
In brief, the objectives of including ports in the TENs strategy can be summarized as follows:
Encourage growth of inter/intra EU trade and more specifically trade with the
Community’s nearest neighbours (EFTA, Central and Eastern Europe, Mediterranean and
North Africa);
Overcome congestion of the main land-corridors and minimise the external costs of
European transport by contributing to the development of combined transport;
Improve the accessibility of peripheral regions and strengthen the economic and social
cohesion within the Community by enhancing the Community’s internal maritime links,
paying particular attention to island and peripheral regions.
Connections to neighbouring third countries
The Treaty and the TEN Guidelines permit cooperation with neighbouring countries in order
to promote projects of mutual interest and ensure the interoperability of networks at a panEuropean level. One of the aims is to connect TENs with networks outside the Union,
particularly with Central and Eastern Europe and the Mediterranean area.
Given the opportunities and initiatives for increased trade between the EU and neighbouring
third countries, it is a desirable objective to seek standards in these ports -particularly those
involved in major trade flows with the EU- which are comparable to standards found in the
Union. In general, this means continuing the processes of rehabilitation and modernisation;
implementing basic standards concerning safety and environmental protection; and, where
necessary, improving security, monitoring and registration arrangements for cargo.
The EU has also been trying to ensure that the increased trade prospects with the Baltic Sea
countries would not be hampered by logistical restrictions in ports. The Union is thus
cooperating with these countries in maritime and port projects, and it is actively encouraging
cooperation between those countries themselves. A specialised working group meets
regularly to monitor progress. Equally, the MEDA programme recently adopted by the EU
allows for cooperation and project financing in Mediterranean countries. Practical work has
already started with maritime issues being at the forefront of cooperation.
Furthermore, in the framework of the Uruguay Round, the Community has been instrumental,
at an early stage of the negotiations, in ensuring that talks on the liberalisation of maritime
transport services included, as an integral part, rules on the use of ports.
5
The Future Development of the Common Transport Policy: A Global Approach to the Construction of the
Community Framework for Sustainable Mobility. COM(92)494 final.
4
The GATS negotiations were suspended without conclusion,6 to be resumed in the year 2000.
However, it is now accepted that a liberalised maritime transport régime will have to
guarantee national treatment of non-national operators in ports, in particular with regard to
the use of port infrastructure; fees and charges; use of facilities; the assignment of berths; as
well as the non-discriminatory use of auxiliary services.
Although the EU will continue to seek agreement on further liberalisation in the framework
of the WTO, it must in the meantime pursue its own interests, where necessary. It may thus
prove appropriate to do so bilaterally in contacts with third countries, as was done in the past
where bilateral contacts resulted in a number of changes in third countries' port practices.
The Nodes of Intermodality
Intermodality is an essential component of the European Union’s Common Transport Policy
for sustainable mobility. Its objective is to develop a framework for an optimal integration of
different modes and utilisation of their capacities, so as to enable an efficient and costeffective use of the transport system through seamless, customer-oriented door-to-door
services whilst favouring innovation and competition between transport operators.7
Ports are crucial connecting points in intermodal transport, transferring goods and passengers
between maritime and land-based modes of transport. Higher port efficiency thus contributes to
the integration of modes in a single system, allowing better use of rail, inland and sea
transport; modes that, by their nature, do not always allow door-to-door delivery.
Seamless transport systems necessitate open access to (port) infrastructure to all licensed
operators. The Commission has proposed the creation of Trans-European Rail Freight
Freeways, characterised by open access, and by the removal of a wide range of obstacles to
international traffic.8 The idea is being implemented by railway companies, Member States
and shippers and the first freeways are expected to become operational before the end of
1997. As the freeways are likely to become an important element in intermodal transport, the
Commission will give priority to their development.9
One of the main requirements of intermodality, as well as an objective in the development of
the TENs, is that transport modes are physically linked. However, successful intermodality is
dependent on a number of equally important factors and difficulties that have to be identified
and addressed in the near future. For example, the use of more than one transport modes can
result in additional transfer costs, reduced reliability and more complex administrative
procedures. The use of modern information systems is crucial in this respect. Such systems are
already in use in the larger European ports but are still important missing links in other parts of
the Union. The Commission is supporting the development of such systems in the framework of
its Research and Development Programme (MARTRANS, BOPCOM). The aim of future
projects in this field will be to ensure interoperability and interconnectivity between such
systems. There might also be a need to integrate EDI (electronic data interchange), AEI
(automatic equipment identification) and a terminal monitoring and guiding systems in one
common information system in order to optimise communication between the port and its
customers, reduce paper requirements and improve the service and management of ports.
6
The WTO Negotiating Group on Maritime Transport Services suspended its work on 28/6/1996. It nevertheless
adopted a so-called peace clause under which countries agree not to apply any measures affecting trade in
maritime transport services except in response to measures applied by other countries. The clause covers maritime
transport as it was negotiated; it therefore covers access to and use of port and auxiliary services.
7
Intermodality and Intermodal Freight Transport in the European Union; A Systems Approach to Freight
Transport. Commission Communication, COM(97)243 final. Brussels, 29.05.97.
8
A Strategy for Revitalising the Community’s Railways. European Commission White Paper, COM(96)421 final,
30.07.96 and COM(96)421/2 final, June 1996.
9
Trans-European Rail Freight Freeways, Commission Communication, COM(97)242 final, 29.05.97.
5
Ports and Development of Short Sea Shipping in Europe
The promotion of environmentally friendly modes of transport –Short Sea Shipping (SSS) in
particular- and their effective integration in multimodal transport chains and networks is a
central objective in the Union’s transport policy. However, despite the increasing turnover of
European ports, intra-European maritime traffic has not as yet been able to demonstrate a
distinctive increase in the market share of SSS, vis à vis that of the road transport sector. A
number of factors can account for this, including terminal costs and turnaround times; lack of
appropriate infrastructure; institutional rigidities in ports; adaptability to multimodal transport
systems; and lack of information to shippers.
In its Communication on Short Sea Shipping10, the Commission set out a framework of
initiatives necessary to promote short sea services in Europe, stressing the need for improved
port efficiency. An important issue in this respect has been the complexity of documentary
and procedural requirements in ports, given that a number of cumbersome procedures and
practices still exist, mostly beyond the port’s own control, that impose significant costs on
commercial operators and put maritime transport at a disadvantage compared to other modes.
The Commission is currently undertaking a fact-finding study to identify requirements in
ports that affect maritime trade in Europe and compare them with those prevailing in inland
transport. Customs requirements and the efficiency of customs authorities in processing
documentation are particularly being addressed. In this context, implementation of EDI is
seen as an important tool to improve the flow of information between customs authorities and
other parties in the transport chain. If needed, the Commission will recommend actions aimed
at the streamlining of procedures in maritime transport.
To evaluate the market potential and competitiveness of Short Sea Shipping in certain
specific trade corridors, the Commission is considering ways of compiling relevant
information; something that will also be to the benefit of ports and maritime industries in
general. Action in this area is already being undertaken in the framework of the concerted
action on Short Sea Shipping R&D programme, sponsored by the Commission, and it is also
the basis of the PACT projects currently underway.
Co-operation among all parties in the transport chain is necessary if short sea operators are to
be effectively and competitively engaged in door-to-door transport solutions.
Notwithstanding commercial considerations, co-operation among ports should be encouraged,
particularly in the area of telematics, the streamlining of procedures and the exchange of
know-how. For this reason, and in the context of TENs, priority will be given to projects
which entail co-operation between two or more ports.
Ports should also be encouraged to play an active role in the promotion of Short Sea Shipping
and participate actively in maritime roundtables, such as those established under the umbrella
of the Maritime Industries Forum.
Moreover, as port costs are essential to the development of Short Sea Shipping, port
authorities should be encouraged to consider the granting of rebates to vessels according to
frequency, volume of cargo, and type of service rendered. In a similar manner, and to the
extent possible, charges for port services should be in principle open to negotiation at a local
level.
However, a factor that could be instrumental in boosting Short Sea Shipping in Europe is a
cost-recovery pricing policy in road transport, which would inter alia internalize this mode’s
10
The Development of Short Sea Shipping in Europe: Prospects and Challenges. COM(95)317, 05.06.95.
6
substantial external costs. Such a policy, already suggested by the Commission in its Green
Paper Towards a Fair and Efficient Pricing in Transport,11 is expected to make competition
among ports and transport systems fairer and more efficient, leading to a more balanced
distribution of traffic across Europe. However, the Green Paper takes a cautious approach to
road-pricing in peripheral regions, as road haulage there is still a public good and the
predominant mode of transport. Therefore, pricing policies aimed at shifting cargo from roads
may have adverse effects on those regions’ economic development prospects.12
The EU Regional and Cohesion Policies with Respect to Ports
The Commission’s White Paper on the future development of the common transport policy13
laid down a new vision for transport policy, following the principle of sustainable mobility;
i.e. a strategy that acknowledges the need for a more balanced transport system that would
fulfill its economic and social role while, at the same time, containing its effects on the
environment. The overall objective of such an approach, as clearly described by the European
Parliament14, is to …promote sustainable, efficient transport systems which meet the
economic, social, environmental and safety needs of European citizens; help reduce regional
disparities; and enable European business to compete effectively in world markets… Again,
the ‘challenge’ is apparent: a more balanced pan-European transport system with the above
objectives is in stark contrast with hub-porting; concentration of traffic to selected ports;
longer distances; and consequent transport externalities. It is thus increasingly felt that the
European Commission needs to depart from its all-pleasing ‘statements’ and make hardnosed decisions in order to effectuate its cohesion and regional development objectives which
are the overarching ones.
Article 130 of the Treaty discusses the role of networks in promoting harmonious
development and in strengthening economic and social cohesion. This is so, as optimisation
of TENs is likely to reduce transport costs and the “perception of distance”, at least in the
long-run, and thus lead to important locational decisions causing production to relocate to
peripheral regions.15 For those reasons, the Treaty provides for the establishment of a
Cohesion Fund, to support transport and environmental projects in Member States that
qualify. In addition, as all Cohesion Fund countries, and virtually all areas covered by the
Structural Fund provisions, are on the periphery of the EU, having substantial coastlines and
often many islands, a well-integrated maritime sector would fully contribute to the
development of the single market and those further steps envisaged by the Treaty.
Ports in these regions have to be adequately prepared to take on the challenge. Otherwise, the
economic and social benefits of greater cohesion can be easily withered away by peripheral
ports that are generally characterised by lower levels of efficiency, mainly as a result of
under-investment. Efficiency improvements will be necessary to ensure that existing and
future facilities are used as effectively as possible; to enable ports take their share in the
increased traffic of the single market; and to allow ports to play their proper part in a more
balanced distribution of traffic. It should be kept in mind that the lack of facilities at one part of
the maritime chain can eventually damage the overall efficiency and image of maritime
transport. The aim is thus to bring ports at both ends up to the highest possible standards, to the
benefit of the overall transport system.
11
Towards Fair and Efficient Pricing in Transport: Policy Options for Internalising the External Costs of
Transport in the European Union. COM(95)691, final.
12
see also First Report on Economic and Social Cohesion. European Commission, Luxembourg, 1996
(Preliminary Edition).
13
op. cit. 5
14
Towards a European Wide Transport Policy; A Set of Common Principles. European Parliament, Third PanEuropean Transport Conference, Helsinki, 23-25 June 1997, p.5 (Annex).
15
op. cit. 12
7
The Community has provided considerable support to port development in the form of grants
from Community funds, especially through the Cohesion and Structural funds. In the case of
Structural Funds, the relevant instrument for ports is the European Regional Development
Fund (ERDF). A number of objectives have been established for purposes of fund
distribution: Those pertinent to transport infrastructure development are the structural
adjustment of less developed regions (Objective I); development of regions affected by
industrial decline (Objective 2); and development of rural areas (Objective 5b). The transport
related resources of the ERDF are substantial in the current programming period (1994-99),
while the Objective 1 areas are the most significant recipients of funds as regards ports. In
addition to the ERDF, structural funds are also available to ports in eligible areas under
INTERREG II C, which promotes cooperation between and within EU regions.
The second major funding instrument of the Community is the Cohesion Fund. In the period
1993-96, a total of 2.1 billion ECU was allocated to the transport sector, 3.4% (74.4 million
ECU) of which funded port infrastructure projects. Finally, the European Investment Bank
provides loans to finance infrastructure that contributes to regional development; the bulk of
its lending activity in the 1991-95 period –i.e. 44 billion ECU- went to the eligible areas
(Objectives I, 2 and 5b). Most of the loans from the EIB have been allocated to infrastructure
projects, including trans-European Transport Networks.
From a transport perspective, these funds should serve such priorities as: better integration of
ports into TENs; improving access to port hinterland; and refurbishing the infrastructure inside
the port area. Exceptionally, projects may include investment in superstructure and mobile assets
(e.g. terminal buildings, cranes), provided these remain an integral part of a larger infrastructure
project and they increase the overall benefits of the investment.
The Role of Ports in Maritime Safety and the Protection of the Environment
Ports are the most obvious points where compliance to international or EC maritime safety
regulations can best be checked and uniformly enforced. The Community’s maritime safety
policy, aimed at the elimination of sub-standard shipping through the proper enforcement of
international legislation, is primarily focused on ships. However, the policy has also a direct
impact on ports, as it requires them to co-operate in the implementation or enforcement of the
legislation16 and ensure a high level of port services (such as pilotage, mooring and towage) that
are intrinsically related to the safety of ships. Equally importantly, the absence of uniform
application of safety rules among ports can lead to distortions of competition and this is an
important consideration to be taken into account when examining possible new initiatives in the
field of maritime safety.
In the area of environmental protection, and in addition to the requirements of international
Conventions (particularly MARPOL 73/78), a number of non-mandatory Codes and Resolutions
have been issued by IMO. The Community has already started to take measures towards the
convergent implementation of these international rules and legislation17 and port authorities will
have to play an essential role.
Environmental impact of port development and operations
Infrastructure projects have a negative impact on the environment that has always to be
considered through appropriate environmental impact assessments. Ports are often in
16
The uniform enforcement of international rules to all ships operating in Community waters is the purpose of
Directive 95/21/EC on Port State Control (PSC). The Directive requests port authorities and pilotage services to
co-operate by providing relevant information and assist PSC inspectors in detecting and targeting sub-standard
ships for priority inspections.
17
Legislation has been adopted for notification requirements for ships carrying dangerous or polluting goods, (ii)
promotion of environmentally friendly oil tankers (SBT Regulation) and (iii) the Commission services are
developing a draft Directive on the use of reception facilities in European ports.
8
proximity to populated areas, or areas where particular attention must be given to endangered
species. As a result, port development, particularly in densely populated areas, is confronted
with special circumstances and constraints. Several Directives are already in place to address
this problem and promote environmentally friendly solutions. Among them are Directives on
environmental impact assessment and the Wild Birds and Habitats Directive. With assistance
from the Commission, the European Seaports Organisation (ESPO) has published a Code of
Conduct, providing a quality framework for programming action with respect to the
protection of the environment within port areas.
FINANCING OF INFRASTRUCTURE AND COST RECOVERY IN PORTS
General
The administration and financing of ports in Europe -as of course in other parts of the worldprincipally falls under two philosophies: that which sees ports indiscriminately as business
undertakings that ought to recover their costs from port users that benefit directly, and the
philosophy that sees ports as trade facilitators and growth-poles to regional and national
development, and thus as sectors producing a service of general economic interest that ought
to be provided by the public sector and principally paid for by the general taxpayer. The
arguments for and against each approach abound, often giving ground to intensive debate,
while the overall picture is far from being conclusive.
Furthermore, certain port infrastructures, such as for example breakwaters and navigational
aids, have traditionally been regarded as public goods18, while a number of port services
(mainly the nautical-technical ones described below) may carry important public service
obligations, due to their relation with the safety of ports.
Thus, as regards ownership and organisation, ports may be state-owned, municipal, private or
owned and run in some other way; they may be government bodies, have close links with the
local public authorities or be autonomous. Whatever the case, however, ports are subject to
considerable regulation and supervision by either national or local authorities.
The same diversity of norms exists, as a result, with regard to the financing of port
infrastructure: this can be wholly funded by the State, the private sector or by a mix of both
sources of finance at varying degrees of participation. A distinctive trend, however, has
emerged whereby port activities of a predominantly commercial nature –such as cargo
handling and the financing of port superstructure- are increasingly becoming the concern of
the private sector, while ports tend to restrict themselves to their “landlord” role and be
involved in the operation and finance of those facilities and services that are essential for the
safe and efficient operation of the port. The “comprehensive” or “service” model of port
organisation, where the port authority functions also as port operator and employer of port
workers, is increasingly becoming a thing of the past (Figure 1).
18
A public good is one for which: (i) no particular user can be excluded from its use if he is not prepared to share
in the costs of its production; (ii) the consumption of user A does not affect that of user B; and (iii) the cost of i
production does not vary with use.
9
Figure 1: Port operating systems
A Historical Perspective on the Changing Role of Ports
In Europe, as in many other parts in the world, ports have traditionally been seen by
governments as growth-poles and fulcra of national and regional development.19 As a matter
of fact, ports have often been used as instruments of regional planning. Many Member States
have done so by steering state investment, through regional policies, towards ports and portrelated infrastructure, in order to stimulate national economic development.20 In this role,
ports are expected to generate substantial employment and numerous benefits, for the country as
a whole, some of which not necessarily producing tangible financial rewards for the ports
concerned. As government policies usually go beyond considerations of short-term financial
profitability and towards the maximisation of long-term economic benefit and general welfare,
state intervention has often been justified on grounds of these “not solely commercial” objectives
of ports.
Port capacity and its spatial characteristics are often determined by national priorities aiming at
the spatial reorganisation of national economic activity. Investments in port and port-related
infrastructure, such as new terminals; docks; deep-water quays; major locks; access channels;
etc. are thus still centrally funded in many Member States, considered to be serving the collective
benefit of the nation. It is perhaps worth mentioning at this point that, for instance in Japan,
apart from the direct financial returns of port operations, port development is appraised on the
basis of its contribution to the social and economic development of the region and the nation.
Port master plans are thus adjusted to, and included in, the country's regional development plans,
while ports are managed and administered by public sector bodies.
19
characteristic examples of this approach can be found in the Maritime Industrial Development Areas (MIDA) of
Rotterdam and Antwerp.
20
A classic example of such as policy was the Mezzogiorno in Italy, considered by many as a model of spatial
reorganisation of economic development. In the United Kingdom, this task was the responsibility of the National
Ports Council, established in 1964 and abolished in 1981.
10
Table 2: Direct and indirect employment in selected ports in the EU
(Number of employees)
Direct
Indirect
Total
Hamburg
95,100
47,500
142,600
Flemish Ports
22,300
22,500
44,800
Rotterdam
63,000
35,000
98,000
Source: Erasmus University Rotterdam
Port Competition
However relevant such a national approach to port development may have been in the earlier
stages of economic development in Europe –or for some Member States even now–
continuing adherence to it nowadays may give rise to legitimate concerns.
Indeed, in earlier periods, general cargo traffic was less containerized, regional port
competition less of an issue, and ports comprised a lot of labour intensive activities,
generating considerable direct and indirect added-value. However, the completion of the
internal market and the existence and further development of superior inland transport
networks across Europe has significantly intensified competition among ports, particularly
competition aimed at attracting unitised transshipment cargo. Especially the latter type of
competition, combined with automated labour-saving cargo handling systems, reduces the
direct added-value of port activities, while the benefits of port investments and their impacts
can be easily dissipated from the country in question to the final consignor/consignee. This
issue causes considerable concern to governments contemplating the continuation of public
funding of port projects, as it deprives them of the basic rationale of doing so, namely, that
the port provides a service of general economic interest.
At the same time, disappearing national (captive) hinterlands mean that the pricing, port
development and financing decisions of a particular port may have marked effects on its
neighbours, nationally and internationally. This raises the relevance and desirability of a more
coordinated approach to port development at pan-European level aimed, inter alia, at
ensuring that ports compete fairly, on sound economic principles, both for existing and new
trade, and at the same time highlighting the crucial role of ports in the optimisation of transEuropean transport networks.
However, as ports are nodes in an increasingly door-to-door managed logistics system,
competition and the desirability of a more coordinated approach to port development at a panEuropean level21 cannot be ascertained a priori, without due regard to the investments in, and
pricing policies of, other modes and infrastructure, particularly those of direct impact on the
operation of ports. For example, presently, inter-port competition is affected by road transport
pricing policies favouring long-hauls, without internalising the external (social) costs of
transport. A user pays policy for road transport, as suggested by the Commission22, could redirect traffic and lead to a different distribution of cargo flows among European ports. Such
considerations necessitate a phased, step-by-step, approach to policy, taking into account
existing ‘equilibria’.
21
22
e.g. through the identification and funding of projects of common interest.
op. cit. 11
11
Identification of Projects of Common Interest and Maps of Ports
Among others, the Treaty of the European Union requires the establishment of guidelines
which cover objectives and broad lines of measures and which identify “projects of common
interest”. The EU may provide support to such projects from the TEN budget line (mainly for
feasibility studies) and from the Cohesion Fund (to countries that are eligible). The
underlying philosophy of TENs is to provide the framework of an optimized pan-European
transport system to be used by Member States as a guide for the development of their
infrastructure. Funding for the latter, however, has to be found by Member States themselves,
either centrally or through public/private partnerships.
The Commission is well aware of the fact that port development in many Member States is
driven by demand and the whatever assistance it thus provides in the framework of TENs is
by no means meant to superimpose a centrally determined system of port development in
Europe, or allocate roles to specific ports. Such assistance is only meant to ensure a “natural”
flow of traffic across Europe –to the benefit of the consumer- and to contribute so that the
present situation in European transport, largely the result of past investments that were not
market driven, does not continue to proliferate road transport congestion. The aim is to
promote physical and managerial improvements, so that transfers between land and maritime
transport are seamless, and to establish efficient intermodal transport chains which facilitate
trade, promote Short Sea Shipping and strengthen economic and social cohesion. Thus,
projects enhancing the functionality and optimisation of TENs, as well as ones aiming at
diverting traffic from road to sea, and thus remove bottlenecks and provide missing links,
could be considered as serving the “common (European) interest”.
The same philosophy applies to the requirement for the preparation of a map of ports. The
Guidelines for the development of TENs, setting out the priorities of the EU’s transport
infrastructure policy, did not, in the first place, include a map of ports. However, the port
element is now being revised, following a request from the Parliament and the Council, in
order to include a map of ports and a revision of the criteria for identifying projects of
common interest.
Again, the aim of a map of ports is by no means to allocate roles among ports, but to present
port traffic in relation to the served industrial, consumption and population centres.
Something like this would undoubtedly demonstrate the significant gains and rewards of
extended hinterlands for ports that have achieved a high level of efficiency. This can
definitely set an effective example for others to follow (The success of the Port of Rotterdam,
not an uncharacteristic one in this respect among North Sea ports, can be evidenced from
Table 3).
Table 3: Road freight traffic from/to the Port of Rotterdam
(selected countries, in 1000 tons, 1995)
A
DK
E
GR
I
Incoming
71
11
52
1
147
Outgoing
117
26
130
18
184
Source: Erasmus University Rotterdam
S
35
58
When drawing up a map of ports, special attention should be given to possible distortion of
competition between ports. A map of ports should therefore be based on objective criteria.
Furthermore, the map must take into account that one of the aims of EU transport policy is to
promote Short Sea Shipping and that the maritime element of the network often ensures
important links to peripheral areas and islands. This would imply including a wide range of
ports in all parts of the Union. Additionally, it is important to ensure that justified port
12
projects, even in smaller ports in remote areas of the Union, not identified in the maps, are not
excluded from funding. In the future, the Commission will consider if it would be appropriate
to introduce additional criteria for the identification of ports, such as a classification of ports
that could add value to the multimodal approach.
Financing and Charging of Port Infrastructure
The trend towards greater private sector participation in ports can be explained by both actual
economic considerations and by a noticeable shift in attitude regarding the function and role
of ports. Firstly, the need for projects to be economically viable is seen as a necessary
discipline in circumstances where resources for infrastructure development are limited, and
when the involvement of the private sector, either on its own or in the form of public-private
partnerships, is accepted as a growing and desirable development, recognised also in the TEN
Guidelines.
Second, the fact that ports –especially container terminals- are used mostly for commercial
ends; the often scant diversification of users they serve; and the typically private
organisational structures they adopt, differentiates them from the pure public goods to which
they had often been likened. 23 Thus, the port industry is increasingly viewed as one moving
from a situation where predominantly public capital was used to provide common user
facilities, to one where capital is being used to provide terminals which are designed to serve
the logistics requirements of more narrowly defined groups of users. Indeed, they may be
designed to serve the needs of a few firms or even just one. In such a way, the “general
economic interest” argument loses weight, leading to a more commercial, user-pay, attitude
towards pricing and infrastructure funding.
These pragmatic developments have also led the European Parliament to assert that, while
acknowledging that there are different financing arrangements (i.e. public/private, to varying
degrees) in individual ports which need to be respected, there is no substantial difference
between investments in port infrastructure and other capital intensive investments in
industrial complexes. Therefore, there is no reason for adopting a completely different
approach to port investments and consequently no justification why the direct users should
not bear the costs of such investments.24 As a matter of fact, the European Parliament goes
even further to point out that the introduction of market principles in infrastructure works
would be the most effective remedy to the risk of creating wasteful overcapacity and possible
distortions of trade flows between Member States.
The general view of the Commission in the past has been that public investment in port
infrastructure, including land and maritime access, does not normally constitute State aid in
the meaning of Article 92 of the Treaty, in so far as the infrastructure is accessible to all users
on a normal, non-discriminatory basis.25 Such investments have been considered by the
Commission as comprising general measures and expenses incurred by the State in the
framework of its responsibilities in physical planning that favour the nation by and large.
However, European integration and the resulting intensified competition among ports in
different Member States do not always allow this view to be unquestionably accepted as a
universal truth. This is the more so given that the public funding of port infrastructure and the
cost recovery of port services are two different things. Although in certain instances
infrastructure can and perhaps should be funded by public money due to a variety of legal,
economic and administrative reasons, this does not mean that this investment should be
23
such as defence, education, justice, environmental protection, etc.
European Sea Port Policy. European Parliament, Directorate General for Research, Transport Series E-1, 1993.
25
However, also in cases where particular investments may benefit only certain users, exemptions are possible,
e.g. for regional development purposes under Article 92.3 of the EC Treaty.
24
13
forgiven and not attempted to be at least partially recovered from users who directly benefit,
regardless of how the investment was funded.
In this respect, reference can be made to the EC’s position that, as a general rule and in order
to avoid distortions of competition and choice within and between modes, … all transport
users should pay the full cost, internal and external, of the transport services they consume,
even if these costs are in some cases paid by society to assist those in need…This, in addition
to the above views of the European Parliament, reaffirms the Commission’s earlier assertion26
that … it would be desirable port charges to reflect the commercial cost of capital invested in
infrastructure in order to approximate the competition conditions of ports…Finally, the
Commission’s Green Paper on Fair and Efficient Pricing27 maintained that infrastructure
charges should (i) be linked as much as possible to actual costs at the level of the individual
user; (ii) be recovered in full; and (iii) be transparent.
All the above tendencies in Community thinking point to the emergence of a new approach
for the pricing of port infrastructure. Broadly speaking, port infrastructure should be priced in
such a way as to make investments economically viable and, implicit to this, users should
bear the real costs of the port services they consume. Economic viability is, however, to be
distinguished from financial viability of private investment, as the former usually entails
considerations such as creation of employment; income distribution; regional disparities, etc.
Given the diversity of port financing regimes across the Union, as well as the different
perceptions as regards the role, functions and the institutional framework of ports, the future
development of a consistent set of criteria for the evaluation of the economic viability of port
investments would be desirable.
Although the application of this principle to the port industry is of particular significance in
terms of higher efficiency; rationalisation of investments; and examination of State aid
measures, it may at the same time have a number of far-reaching ramifications that have to be
carefully studied and monitored. These may include such issues as the effect of the policy on
port charges and final consumer prices; ocean freight rates and short-sea-shipping; spatial
decisions of companies; re-distribution of existing traffic among ports, etc.
In addition, it should also be kept in mind that a great number of European ports are located
in less developed and peripheral areas, or in islands. Often, these ports represent the only link
to the rest of the Union and constitute the fulcrum of significant economic activity in their
region. They may thus be important parameters in the Union’s Cohesion policies and the
application of the cost recovery principle in such cases, if at all desirable, could create
considerable difficulties.
In any case, the interdependence of transport modes and related infrastructure–some of them
falling under their own legal regimes and policies- necessitates not only a consistent step-bystep approach to the pricing of port infrastructure – starting from investments within the portbut also to the provision of ample time for ports to adjust. The method of cost recovery, in
that case, should be left to Member States, on the basis of the principle of subsidiarity. The
effect of this charging regime on two specific types of port infrastructure –maritime access
and navigational aids- is of particular interest in this context and it is thus briefly discussed in
the following paragraphs.
Maritime access
A number of European ports, mainly those of the North Sea, are located on river estuaries or
they are river ports subject to considerable siltation. The provision of adequate maritime
access in these ports requires substantial yearly outlays for dredging, which presently are in
26
27
General Study of State aid in the Port Sector. No VII/103/89.
Op. cit. 11
14
most cases publicly funded. However, there is no a priori reason why maritime access should
be treated differently from other types of port infrastructure, particularly when approach
channels are provided at such water depth that, although open to all, are really meant for a
small number of easily identifiable users.
Navigational Aids
Aids to navigation have traditionally been used in economic theory as the most characteristic
examples of a public good.28 Apart from the typical lighthouses, buoys, etc., modern
navigational aids in busy seaways and along dangerous or environmentally sensitive coasts
include the development of radio-navigation systems (e.g. LORAN-C, GNSS); the physical
infrastructure needed to support VTS or VTMIS; and systems of mandatory ship-routing and
ship-reporting (e.g. EUROREP Directive).
In several cases, the safety of commercial interests of both local and transiting traffic are
better served by systems that transcend national boundaries and, ideally, could be developed
on a regional basis.29 This is the more so when the importance of several European seaways
to world trade, and the increasing sophistication and capital intensity of such systems, would
make it unfair to leave the expense of their implementation solely to the coastal states
concerned, since all transiting traffic and regional users (e.g. fishing vessels) would
eventually benefit. The risk of doing so is that some necessary aids might not be provided, or
that states providing them may try to recover costs in a non-optimal way. Obviously, coastal
aids to navigation benefit a traffic which, for cost recovery purposes, is “captive” only if
systems are viewed on a large regional (e.g. European) basis.
The need for the development of a Commission proposal laying down both the principles for
a charging system(s), aimed at the recovery of the development and investment costs of such
aids, and a mechanism to equitably share the financial burden with users, was clearly
identified in the Commission Communication “A common Policy on safe seas” (points 101 to
114).
As far as local aids to navigation are concerned, particularly those associated with the
approaches to ports, the principal beneficiaries are local port users. The development and
implementation of navigational aids in port areas is therefore closely related to investments in
or near the port and, to a large extent, they may be regarded as the responsibility of the
competent (port) authority. Cost recovery of such infrastructure could thus continue to be
dealt with by national or local bodies, viewed either as a charge to be fully met by the
competent authority or, as in most Member States, to be included in port dues. At any rate,
here too, the “user-pays” principle will have to be considered in the framework of EC
legislation.
28
for the definition of a public good, see footnote 18.
in the context of the development of a trans-European network of vessel traffic management and information
system (VTMIS), the Community has already granted financial support to a number of port or coastal vessel traffic
services in the peripheral regions of the Community. In addition, with the European Permanent Traffic
Observatory (EPTO) project, a tool has been made available by the Commission to any port or VTS in the
Community for the systematic analysis of local traffic conditions in the port area and their improvement. The
extension of EPTO to a larger number of ports would greatly enhance its potential positive effects. Finally, the
Commission is examining harmonisation measures for VTSs, concentrating on minimum performance
requirements for VTS equipment (interfaces between VTS) and harmonised procedures to improve ship-shore
communication.
29
15
Application of the State Aid Provisions of the EC Treaty to the Port Sector
In the highly competitive environment of an integrated Europe, state-aids can have farreaching ramifications and are increasingly becoming one of the central issues in the
industrial and competition policies of the EU. Among others, the issue has also been
addressed in the White Book on the future development of the common transport policy30,
according to which …the opening up of transport markets to more competition as a result of
the 1992 programme means that greater attention has to be paid to subsidies which could
unfairly advantage particular operators…
Obviously, if a port receives public financial support, in a competitive environment, it might
be in a position to offer actual or potential users more favourable conditions than its
competitors, thus leading to a situation where the natural flow of trade is distorted. As ports
play a vital linking role between land and maritime transport, the effect of such a distortion
may be very far-reaching.
State aid to ports can take different forms, some of them easily recognizable, some not. State
aid is easily recognizable when granted as direct subsidies, such as the offsetting of operating
losses, but it may also be indirect, and thus less explicit, when, for example, it takes the form
of leasing land areas or provision of government loans, or loan guarantees, under special
conditions.
Article 92.1 of the EC Treaty provides that aid granted by a Member State or through State
resources in any form whatsoever which distorts or threatens to distort competition, by
favouring certain undertakings, or the production of certain goods, is incompatible with the
common market in so far as it affects trade between Member States.
In order to assess whether a State measure involves aid elements in general, the Commission
has established, inter alia, the principle that no State aid is involved when the public sector
contributes to a (port) company on a basis that would be acceptable to a private investor
operating under normal market economy conditions.31 If the private market investor principle
is not applied, the measure may be considered as aid and its compatibility with Article 92.2 or
92.3 of the Treaty has to be examined by the Commission. At first sight, the assessment of aid
in the port sector appears to present no particular difficulty as far as social, restructuring,
operating and rescue aids are concerned. However, given the widespread practices of State
involvement in the sector and the sometimes unclear allocation of responsibilities therein, the
assessment of State measures, in the light of the State aid provisions of the Treaty, is not
always without problems.
A good example of such a problem is the public financing of superstructure, intended to be
operated by private companies. In such cases, i.e. when a public (port) authority decides to
contract out the operation of public investments to private companies, the process should be
based on open and transparent public tendering procedures, with the successful bidder
obliged to maintain independent accounts separate from those of the port. This seems to be
the current practice in a number of ports.
If a cost recovery approach becomes a generally accepted principle, and in the sake of
ensuring transparency and fair competition among ports, the market investor principle could
eventually be extended to include investments in infrastructure. Inter alia, something like this
30
op. cit. 5, paragraph 351.
Commission, Application of Articles 92 and 93 of the EEC Treaty to public authorities’ holdings, Bulletin EC 91984.
31
16
would eliminate the often complex and confusing need to distinguish between public
investments in infrastructure and superstructure.
Transparency of Port Accounts
An effective and fair implementation of the cost recovery approach; the evaluation of State
aid measures; and meaningful comparisons among ports undoubtedly require the transparency
of port financial accounts. This is the more so when ports include a number of commercial
activities, carried out by private operators, that should, according to Community law, be seen
as separate undertakings with separate accounts. Currently, however, due to differences in the
institutional framework and in the financing and charging regimes in ports and related
infrastructure in Europe, the financial relationships between the public sector and the ports
are often unclear.
The Commission Directive 80/723 on the transparency of financial relations between
Member States and public undertakings32 applies in principle also to the port sector. In
general, the Directive applies to public undertakings whose turnover is at least 40 MECU
during the two financial years preceding that in which public funds are made available.
Member States are obliged to provide information at the request of the Commission,
notwithstanding the fact that, occasionally, economic activities of an industrial or commercial
nature may be integrated into the State administration.
PORT SERVICES – MARKET ACCESS AND ORGANISATION
General
Ports are principally service industries having as their main function the transfer of
passengers and cargo from sea to land transport and vice versa. To achieve this, the port
provides a miscellany of services and facilities, often distinguished between those pertaining
to the ship (such as pilotage, towage and mooring) and those related to cargo (mainly cargohandling and storage). In addition, a number of ancillary services are also provided by the
port, facilitating its orderly operation. The latter include communications, port security, firefighting, bunkering, water supply and waste reception facilities. Depending on the
organisation, legal status and objectives of a port, port services can be provided either as a
comprehensive package, or separately, and on a compulsory or voluntary basis.
The efficiency, cost effectiveness and quality of a service are, in general, concepts more
difficult to establish and value than in the case of merchandised goods. Port services are no
exemption to this. However, their smooth and coordinated functioning remains crucial in
determining overall port performance and competitiveness, as well as the efficiency of
investments in port infrastructure and superstructure.
In several cases, the port services sector still maintains significant rigidities and restrictive
practices, often in variance with the economic and structural evolutions sweeping across
Europe. It is true that as a result of new technologies, port services require a high level of
professional competency in order to avoid accidents in the port area. To this end, and also to
prevent possible detrimental effects of liberalisation on the level of safety, the establishment
of minimum qualification requirements for pilots, mooring personnel and VTS operators is
being examined. However, exclusive rights and legal or de facto monopolies are often
32
Commission Directive 80/723/EEC (OJ L 195 of 29 July 1980), as amended by Directive 85/413/EEC (OJ L 229
of 28 August 1985) in order to cover, inter alia, the transport sector.
17
unconvincingly (let alone unnecessarily) explained on grounds of safety, public service
obligations, minimum company size, historical factors and local particularities.
Services Related to the Cargo
These services consist of stevedoring, i.e. the loading, stowage and discharging of cargo,
storage (short term), warehousing (long term – open, closed or refrigerated) and, possibly,
cargo-processing, customs clearance, etc.
Among all port services, cargo-handling has been the one most profoundly affected by
technological development and intensified inter-port competition, the latter mainly as a result
of the completion of the internal market. Containerisation and the capital-intensive nature of
shipping have increased pressures on ports for further improvements in labour productivity and
operational efficiency. In its efforts to adjust to the new demand requirements, the port industry
itself has also been progressively transformed into a capital-intensive one, requiring massive
investments in sophisticated cargo-handling equipment and commensurate reductions in direct
port employment (again, the not untypical example of Rotterdam is shown in Table 4). These
developments are shaping new trends in the market, characterised by capital concentration,
specialisation and vertical integration.
Table 4: General Cargo Productivity at the Port of Rotterdam
Cargo Handling
General Cargo
Employees (x 1000)
(million tons)
1985
14
49
1990
11
58
1995
9
71
Source: Erasmus University Rotterdam
In the majority of Member States no formal restrictions exist for firms wishing to establish
themselves as stevedoring companies in an EU port. However, the particular market structure
of the stevedoring industry; the size of required investments; lease contracts; minimum
company size; and scarcity of land may pose effective barriers-to-entry to new entrants and
offer significant advantages to incumbent operators. In addition, although stevedoring
companies are in principle free to apply for port sites, such applications may be subject to
different, and often obscure, evaluation criteria, applied by the competent port authorities,
such as economic and environmental impact, job creation, etc.
At the same time, inflexibility in the supply of port labour has often been contested as not
corresponding to the new technological requirements of modern port operations. Several
Member States have thus recently introduced legislative reforms aimed at adjusting the
structure of the port labour market to technological and structural changes, while at the same
time taking into account the associated social problems.
Port labour rigidities are mainly attributable to the registration of port workers and the
existence of labour pools. In several Member States port work is restricted to registered port
workers; a practice encouraged by ILO Dock Work Convention of 1973. The underlying
principle behind this practice is to limit casual work and the degradation of social protection
standards this sometimes entails, and to ensure that only properly trained and qualified
workers are given the responsibility to operate advanced and expensive equipment.
18
However, limitations in the supply of labour can be a hindrance to new investment in the port
area and can severely affect port efficiency and competitiveness. Furthermore, in some
Member States, registers are kept at unjustifiably high levels, while the relatively protected
position of port workers enables them to enjoy salaries and other conditions of employment
that are considerably higher than those paid for comparable jobs elsewhere in the economy.
Some observers33 argue that this privileged position has finally resulted in a negative attitude
of the general public, and other unions, towards port workers.
Labour pools exist in a number of EU ports. They have their origin in the past, at times when
port work was highly irregular, mainly due to the (then) erratic and unpredictable pattern of
ship arrivals. Their aim was to enable port workers share, as equitably as possible, the “peaks
and troughs” of port work. Among others, this had helped to de-casualise labour and provide
some form of income and employment stability to port workers.
Nowadays, pools constitute the bridge between the former labour-oriented type of port
organisation, based on casual employment, and the present capital-intensive one where a
direct and long-term employment relationship with the operator becomes the rule. Thus, for
the industry, pools constitute a practical solution to work irregularity, worth participatory
financing by operators in the port. Pools may be founded on a legal provision, imposing the
participation or control of public Authorities, or on a voluntary basis following agreements
between employers and the workforce. They may take the form of a public or commercial
enterprise, State agency or cooperative.
Services Related to the Ship
In general, public sector involvement in the provision of such services is considerable in most
EU ports. The nature of ship-related port services is considered by several Member States to
be intrinsically related to the safety of vessels, people, cargo and the port community by and
large. Thus, the service is often modeled around the public service concept, enjoying
considerable immunity from competition law,34 with dues determined or controlled by the
competent national administration. Of all ship-related services, pilotage, towage and mooring
are considered to be the most important.
Pilotage
Pilotage is the act, carried out by a qualified person known as a pilot, of assisting the master
of a ship in navigation when entering or leaving a port or an area of confined waters. It is a
characteristic example of a compulsory nautical service, particularly for vessels exceeding a
certain tonnage or length and for vessels carrying dangerous goods. Exemption certificates
for frequently calling masters and vessels (usually ferries) may be issued, albeit on the basis
of complex and diversified rules. Exemptions from mandatory- as well as greater use of
shore-based pilotage assistance are practices that should be encouraged, particularly in so far
as they contribute to the EU’s objective of promoting Short Sea Shipping. Such practices
should, however, be adopted as long as they do not jeopardize the safety of navigation or the
discharge of entrusted public service obligations, something largely depending on local
circumstances.
The degree of public sector involvement in the provision of the service varies widely across
Europe. In some Member States, the service is entrusted to national- or port authorities and
pilots are, in this case, civil servants. In other Member States, pilots are self-employed in
33
see A.S. Harding (1990) Restrictive labour practices in seaports. The World Bank, Washington (WPS 514).
The Court has recently held in the “Calì case” (CJEC 18/3/97, aff. C-343/95, Diego Calì & Figli Srl/ Servici
ecologici porto di Genova SpA (SPEG), unpublished), that article 86 of the Treaty does not apply to the legal
monopoly of anti-pollution control on the ground that this activity is inherent to the essential prerogatives of the
State responsible for the protection of the marine environment.
34
19
partnership associations or collectives, which can be financially or operationally autonomous.
Even in this case, however, public sector involvement still remains predominant: pilot
associations are appointed by the competent Authority who holds the overall control and
responsibility for pilots’ licenses, training, tariffs and quality. The regulatory framework that
governs the provision of the service affords pilot associations de jure exclusive rights, often
associated with public service obligations, and it limits pilot liability in case of accident.
Exclusive rights are usually limited to a single port.
Towage
The service consists of towing or pushing ships with small powerful vessels (tugs) and in
particular of assisting ships’ maneuvres in port or in access channels, as well as of providing
assistance in mooring, docking, lightening and bunkering operations.
Although information at the disposal of the Commission is fragmented and rudimentary, it
seems that a significant diversity of organisational structures exists across Europe. Here, too,
the service is provided either by the public or private sector, on a voluntary or mandatory
basis. Public sector provision may involve the local port authority or licensed operators under
exclusive rights. In this case, rates are fixed and controlled by the competent national, local or
port authority. Where the service is provided by private operators, no formal restrictions to
market access exist and public sector involvement is generally limited to ensuring
compliance to safety and environmental standards. Rates are in principle freely negotiated.
Mooring
Berthing, unberthing and mooring refer to the service of securing the ship at berth by ropes. A
similar lack of systematic information exists and the same variety of legal regimes seems to
prevail: the service is provided directly by port authorities, by licensed companies or
cooperatives operating under exclusive rights, or by a number of private companies. In
certain cases, licensed operators are charged legally or contractually with public service
obligations, ensuring their participation in emergency situations. The licensing system implies
also the involvement of port authorities, and eventually of professional organisations, in the
fixing of rates.
Port Services under the Rules of the Treaty
It appears that in spite of structural and economic evolution and trends towards new
organisational forms, the port services sector in Europe continues to adopt (by choice or
necessity) institutional rigidities often not conducive to greater port efficiency and
competitiveness. By and large, restrictive practices in the sector usually derive from
employment conditions, due to historical, political and economic factors, that several Member
States have recently undertaken to remedy.
According to the principle of neutrality, guaranteed by art. 222 of the EC Treaty, the
Commission is neutral with regard to the private or public status of port operators. Moreover,
the Commission respects, on the basis of the subsidiarity, the right of Member States to
define the regimes of the services provided in their ports according to their particular
geographical, administrative, social, technical and historical circumstances.
However, and although ports have remained for more than thirty years outside Community
action, as a gray-area between sea and land transport, the European Court and the European
Commission have repeatedly made it clear that the rules of the Treaty, mainly those
pertaining to competition, also apply to ports. This legal tendency is consistent with the
European Union’s policy to encourage modernisation and efficiency, taking into account
structural developments in worldwide competition and the need of companies to seek out
better quality at reasonable prices.
20
The legal context of the application of the rules of the Treaty to the port services sector has
recently become clearer on the basis of the principles confirmed by Court jurisprudence and
the Commission’s decisions. At a first instance, the Court of Justice has condemned a
particular case of a regime of stevedoring services, based on the dual monopoly of port
operators and dock work companies, purported to have led to abuse of dominant position.
Subsequently, the discriminatory tariffs charged by pilot corporations in a certain port were
held to be incompatible with EC competition rules.35 In addition, the Commission has also
adopted Decisions applying competition rules to the port sector, condemning port
undertakings, acting both as port Authorities and shipping companies, for having refused their
competitors access to essential port facilities.36
In enforcing the Treaty rules to the port services sector, the Commission examines each
complaint on a case by case basis, giving due regard to the following considerations:
In principle, the general rules of the Treaty with respect to competition and discrimination on
grounds of nationality also apply to port services, as long as this does not obstruct, in law or
in fact, the execution of the assigned tasks. The European Union is particularly sensitive to
the issue of safety of maritime transport and well aware of the fact that safety considerations
often bring some port services under the ambit of Article 90 of the Treaty, which can restrict
market access by legitimizing exclusive rights of public undertakings entrusted with the
operation of services of general economic interest, or with public service obligations.
In this context, however, the Commission has to examine, on the basis of the principle of
proportionality, if the same objectives could not be achieved by less restrictive practices or
even without restrictions at all. The challenge, therefore, is to combine safety imperatives
with a structure compatible with competitive patterns. This is of particular relevance in cases
where a single undertaking is operating both services falling under the scope of Article 90,
and ones of purely commercial nature.37 In such a situation, and also in the sake of fair and
transparent pricing, port operators should be encouraged to maintain separate accounts.
In some ports and under certain conditions of demand, exclusive rights can be justified by the
fact that only one operator can economically provide the service. However, when the national
system is based on a concession or a license, it would be desirable to effectuate the selection
of the supplier(s) on the basis of a transparent, objective and non-discriminatory public tender
procedure, granting exploitation rights for a (limited) period that would, inter alia, allow
normal recovery of investments. This last point emphasizes the significance of adequate
monitoring by the national authorities responsible for the approval or fixing of prices, aimed
at ensuring that prices are fair, transparent and reflect the costs incurred in the provision of the
service.
35
CJEC 17/5/94, aff. C-18/93, Corsica Ferries Italia Srl/Corpo dei piloti del porto di Genova, [1994] ECR-I1824. Actually the Court is considering a recent preliminary issue concerning the legality of the compulsory
provision of mooring services in two ports and of the tariffs applied, alleged not to reflect the real cost (aff. C266/96, Corsica Ferries France S.A./ Ormeggiatori).
36
i.e. Decision 21/12/93, Port de Rødby, 94/119/EC, OJEC L 55/52, 26-2-94; Decision 21/12/93, IV/34.689, Sea
Containers/Sealink, OJEC L 15/8, 18-1-94
37
in case 179/90 Merci Convenzionali di Porto di Genova v. Gabrielli [1991] ECR-I-5923, CJEC 10/12/91 the
Court explicitly held that the stevedoring services could not qualify as services of general economic interest.
21