Public Disclosure Authorized
Public Disclosure Authorized
Public Disclosure Authorized
Public Disclosure Authorized
45624 V2
ARCTIC OCEAN
Bermg
s..
"'"
PACI FI C
OCEAN
.I
f\
This report is part of a series undertaken by the Europe and Central Asia Region of the World Bank .
Earlier reports have investigated poverty, jobs, trade , m igration , and demography. The series covers
the following countries:
Albania
Armenia
Azerbaijan
Belarus
Bosnia and Herzegovina
Bulgaria
Croatia
Czech Republic
Estonia
FYR Macedonia
Georgia
Hungary
Kazakhstan
Kyrgyz Republic
Latvia
Lithuania
Moldova
Montenegro
Poland
Romania
Russian Federation
Serbia
Slovak Republic
Slovenia
Taj ikistan
Turkey
Turkmenistan
Ukraine
Uzbekistan
.,,,.
l.uw1,e1160"N)
ISRD34
;~
Af>Rll.2007
OVERVIEW
UNLEASHING PROSPERITY
OVERVIEW
UNLEASHING PROSPERITY
Productivity Growth in Eastern Europe
and the Former Soviet Union
Asad Alam, Paloma Anos Casero,
Faruk Khan, and Charles Udomsaph
THE WORLD BANK
Washington, D.C.
© 2008 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank
1818 H Street, NW
Washington, DC 20433
Telephone: 202-473-1000
Internet: www.worldbank.org
E-ma il :
[email protected]
All rights reserved
1 2 3 4 11 10 09 08
This volume is a product of the staff of the Internationa l Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The
World Bank. The findin gs, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this volume do not necessarily
reflect the views of the Executive Directors of The World Bank or the governments they represent.
The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries,
colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do n ot imply any judgement on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or
acceptance of such boundaries.
Rights and Permissions
The material in this publication is copyrighted. Copying and/or transmitting portions or all of this work
without permission may be a violation of applicable law. The International Bank for Reconstruction and
Development/The World Bank encourages dissemination of its work and will normally grant permission
to reproduce portions of the work promptly.
For permission to photocopy or reprint any part of this work, please send a request with complete
information to the Copyright Clearance Center Inc., 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923 , USA;
telephone: 978-750-8400; fax: 978-750-4470; Internet: www.copyright.com.
All other queries on rights and licenses, including subsidiary rights, should be addressed to the Office
of the Publisher, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-522-2422;
e-mail:
[email protected].
Cover photo by: Mikhail Malyshev/iStockphoto.
Cover design: Naylor Design, Inc.
This booklet conta in s the Overview, along with a list of contents, from the forthcoming book,
Unleashing Prosperity: Productivity Growth in Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union. To order copies
of the full-length book, published by the World Bank, please use the form provided at the back of
this booklet.
Contents
Overview
1. Patterns of Aggregate Productivity Growth
2. Sectoral Patterns of Productivity Growth
3. Firm Productivity Growth
4. The Future Role of Public Policy
Bibliography
v
.·.
Overview
Productivity isn't everything, but in the long run it is almost everything.
-Paul Krugman
Introduction
The countries of Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union
(the Region, hereafter) experienced a productivity surge over
1999-2005 that drove up living standards and reduced poverty. Productivity growth is probably the single most important indicator of
a country's economic progress. It is only through increases in productivity that firms may enjoy good prospects for higher profits so
they may invest in new technologies, create jobs, pay more in
wages and dividends, and apportion wealth. The efficiency of labor
and capital rose rapidly in the Region, especially in the middle income countries of the Former Soviet Union (averaging 6 percent
during 1999-2005). Output growth during this period was mainly
driven by increased productivity, whereas the accumulation of labor
and capital played a small role. The surge in productivity drove up
living standards. The Region's real income per capita (in constant
dollar equivalents of purchasing power parity [PPP]) rose from
2
Unleashing Prosperity
US$5, 903 in 1998 to US$8,41 l in 2005, lifting about 50 million
people out of poverty.
Part of the productivity gains derived from increased capacity utilization, especially in the Commonwealth of Independent States
(CIS- Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Georgia, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyz
Republic, Moldova , Russian Federation, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan,
Ukraine, and Uzbekistan). After a deep fall in output in the early
phase of the transition, output per capita recovered in many countries. As firms began using their excess labor and capital, which had
become idle during the deep transitional recession, output increased,
and this is captured in TFP estimates.
Part of the productivity gains also derived from major structural
changes in the economies of the Region, as resources were progres sively shifted to higher-productivity uses in response to changed
economic and institutional incentives. The transition to a market
economy involved a substantial reallocation of factors (labor and
capital) across sectors. Many workers moved out of manufacturing
and into services, a sector that had been underdeveloped under central planning. In the low income CIS countries, however, labor
shifted out of manufacturing into agriculture and there was little
progress in the development of a modern service sector. 1
But most of the productivity surge was driven by firm dynamics.
From a microeconomic perspective, productivity growth may be
decomposed into three main sources: productivity gains within existing
firms, the reallocation of resources across existing firms, and firm
turnover (the entry of new, more-productive firms and the exit of obsolete firms) . Faced with radical changes in the Region's economies, firms
were forced to adapt their behavior. Some seized new opportunities,
occupying new market niches that had not been available during central planning. Many obsolete firms that were supported by state subsidies were restructured or closed down. Firms that survived managed to
enhance productivity by investing in worker skills and adopting new
technologies, abandoning old production lines and introducing new
ones, producing new products, and accessing new markets.
Domestic reforms and external factors contributed to the productivity surge. Macroeconomic stability, a better governance and business environment, stronger competition, skill development, financial
deepening, and investments in infrastructure, particularly in information and communication technology (ICT) , were key drivers of
productivity growth. Globalizing factors also contributed to the
increase in productivity, especially in the new European Union (EU)
member states (the EU - 10: Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Estonia,
Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Romania , the Slovak Republic,
Overview
3
and Slovenia). In these countries, trade and foreign investment
played a significant role in productivity growth by stimulating tech nological transfers and innovation.
Notwithstanding the recent gains, significant challenges remain in
sustaining productivity growth. This is especially evident in the wide
disparities in annual per capita income in the Region, ranging from
US$300 in Tajikistan to US$8,000 in Poland, as well as the disparities
in income per capita between the early reformers-the EU-10-and
the EU-15 (Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany,
Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain,
Sweden, and the United Kingdom, see figure 1). Narrowing these
income gaps calls for more rapid productivity growth.
But the room for more rapid productivity growth may be constrained by the limited ability of firms to adopt new technologies
(driven by deficiencies in the education system, labor market rigidities,
skill shortages, weak private sector involvement in research and development (R&D), and shallow financial markets) , the out-migration of
labor, and declining populations in many countries (World Bank
2007b). In addition, while investment rates are comparable with those
in advanced market economies, the countries of the Region lag in
the quality of infrastructure. New vintages of capital are needed to
expand the Region's technological frontier. Policy shortcomingsparticularly with respect to macroeconomic management (to cope
with volatility, real exchange appreciation, and inflationary pressures) ,
the weak investment climate, and the inadequacy of social safety nets
FIGURE 1
A Large Income Gap Divides the Region, Which Also Lags
Behind the EU-15
12.000
50
c
11,000
"'~ -
45
10,000
40
Ci)
~ - ~ 9,000
-g ~ 8.000
"'
.,g5- E.
7.ooo
35
·'"'°
30
E
~
25
"'
.,.
~
6.000
20 ::::)
"'0
~
·~
3.000
u
2,000
a.
1.000
c
co ·-
a;
UJ
4.000
s
a.
o
"'t:'
"'a.
Lii
.g
ro 5.ooo
"'c
.~
E.
15 B
0
·;::;
+-
10
_m,;"'
-~
CIS-low
-'
CIS-mid
Southeastern
Europe
Turkey
Sources: World Bank staff calculations; World Development Indicators Database 2007.
EU-10
~
4
Unleashing Prosperity
to protect and train workers adversely affected by firm restructuring
and closures-may also limit the ability of policy makers to sustain
productivity growth.
Addressing these challenges will require sustained, even accelerated policy and institutional reforms. The heterogeneity of the
Region means that the specific mix of policy reforms needed to sustain productivity growth varies across countries. This report argues
that, for the late reformers (most of Southeastern Europe [SEE:
Albania , Bosnia and Herzegovina , Croatia, the former Yugoslav
Republic of Macedonia, Serbia and Montenegro (now separate and
independent)] and the CIS), policy reforms aimed at accelerating
reallocation are a top priority, whereas, for the early reformers (most
of the EU-10, plus Turkey) , policy reforms aimed at improving the
ability of firms to innovate and compete in global markets are a top
priority. Though reform priorities vary significantly even within the
two broad groups of countries, the evidence is clear: the intensity
and speed of reforms matter for productivity growth.
Measuring productivity growth is difficult. The measure most commonly used is labor productivity because it is easy to calculate and
interpret. It captures how much output is produced, on average, by
each unit of labor employed in production. Labor productivity growth
thus gauges the increase in the amount (or value) of output generated per worker. Another measure is total factor productivity (TFP)
growth, which refers to increases in output not attributable to
increases in labor or capita l inputs. TFP growth captures efficiency
gains from the technological progress embodied in firm -level
improvements, such as better production management methods,
better customer support, and better distribution channels for the
delivery of goods and services. Both labor and TFP growth may be
estimated for the economy as a whole, for a sector of the economy, or
for an individual firm.
This report integrates an impressive array of data sets to assess the
macro, sectoral, and micro underpinnings of productivity growth in
the Region . It builds on aggregate estimates of productivity comparable across countries and over time. It then explores industry and
firm-level heterogeneity to understand more clearly the roots of
observed aggregate economic performance. Its creative use of new
firm -level data sets provides fresh insights into the policy an d
microeconomic foundations of growth in the Region. The new data
include corporate financial data on more than 60,000 firms in 14
countries of the Region (the Amadeus Database) and a harmonized
firm-level database drawing on a manufacturing census for 8 countries. 2 These microeconomic data sets permit productivity dynamics
Overview
to be studied through a decomposition of aggregate productivity
growth into the reallocation of labor across firms, firm turnover, and
internal firm efficiency. They also permit the evolution of firm demographics to be examined over time, such as firm survival rates,
average firm size among entering firms, and the rates of the creation
and destruction of firms and jobs. Other data derived from international reviews of policy reforms (the Doing Business Database, the
Economic Freedom of the World Database, the European Bank for
Reconstruction and Development [EBRD] transition indicators)
and from enterprise surveys (the Business Environment and
Enterprise Performance Survey [B EEPS] Database) shed light on
the policy and regulatory constraints to rea llocation and firm productivity growth.
The analysis in this report exploits these data to answer the
following questions:
• What can we learn from the productivity patterns in the Region? What
are the roles of capital accumulation and labor participation and
the combined efficiency of these factors in driving output growth?
• What are the sources of productivity growth in the Region? How important has the rea llocation of resources across and w ithin sectors
been in explaining the productivity surge in the Region?
• Is the transition process over in some countries? Are countries still struggling to restructure their economies?
• What is the role of policy reforms in productivity growth? How do policy
drivers influence the pace of reallocation and firm productivity
growth? What are the remaining barriers to sustained productivity growth? Which policy reforms w ill be needed to sustain productivity growth?
The Region shows great diversity in productivity performance and
progress in reform (figure 2). Two broad groups of countries emerge
from the analysis: the more productive, early reformers (the EU-10
and Turkey) and the less productive, late reformers (most of the CIS
and the SEE). The main challenge in the EU-10 and Turkey is to
boost innovation to compete successfully in global markets, while
the primary challenge in the CIS and SEE is to accelerate reallocation
to address the legacy of the transition.
The more-productive early reformers: the EU-10 and Turkey. The EU-10
recovered earlier from the initial economic collapse and pursued
deep and pervasive structural reforms. Most of these countries display
higher productivity levels and are now well-functioning market
economies. In these early reformers, the role of firm turnover and
5
Unleashing Prosperity
6
FIGURE 2
Productivity and Progress in Reform in the Region
a. Progress, 1999-2005
7-
high productivity,
early reformers
6-
"'
a;
>
2
~-
SEE 1999
•
"'u...
>-C>
E
- 1025
•
•SEE 2005
CIS-low 2005
CIS-mid 1999
5-
~EU
EU-101999
CIS-mid 2005
CIS-low 1999 . /
low productivity,
late reformers
4
+-~
~
-+~
~
~-,
4
3
EBRO transition index
b. Levels, 2005
Russian Federation
~
s- 1-~
B~e a ~l _ ru _ s ~ . ~ S - e b -r - ia - a - nd _ M _ o_ n - te - ne ~ ~ ~ ~ - ! ~ - ~ ~ ~n - n~.,
on
g!
MacE~on1.
Azerbaijan
~i ~ ~ a-rn .,- ~
FYR
Georgia
Kyrgyz Republic •
f-
0>
a -r ~ in 4.e - A ~ rm~e
•
2
"'u...
E
e
Slovenia
Czech
•
Republic •Hungary
L ithuan~
" • • " Estonia
Croatia Latvia Poland
Bulgaria• Slovak Republic
Uzbekistan •
5-
•Tajikistan
••
Moldova
4
EBRO transition index. 2005
Sources. EBRO 2006; Amadeus Database 2006.
reallocation in productivity growth has declined. The productivity
surge is now mainly driven by firm efficiency gains stemming from
technological innovation, robust competition, and the penetration
of new export markets. After more than a decade of sustained policy
reforms, resources have shifted from lower- to higher-productivity
u ses. Existing firms hav e been restructured, shed excess labor,
and acquired foreign techno logies. New productive firms have
Overview
emerged, and obsolete firms hav e closed down. Turkey, the only
nontransition country in the Region, is in a gro up by itself, but it
reflects many of the productivity trends shown by the EU -10 .
Since th e 2001 financial crisis, Turkey has been going through its
own economic transformation and has undertaken bold reforms
to stimulate productivity growth and integrate with the globa l
economy. As in the EU- 10, domestic and imp ort competition,
export penetration in new markets, and innovation have spurred
increases in firm efficiency.
The less-productive late reformers: SEE, CIS-mid, and CIS-low. These
countries sh ow lower levels of productivity; most of them undertook
reforms in the late 1990s and are still dealing with the substantial
misallocation of resources inherited from central planning. Among
the late reformers, the contributions of firm turnover and reallocation
to productivity growth are increasing. Firm efficiency is also playing
an important role in aggregate productivity growth, but is mainly
driven by transitory factors, especially the utilization of excess capacity and labor shedding. Most CIS and SEE countries continue to face
significant resource misallocation and are still some way from the end
of the transition. Rapid productivity gains were fairly easy to achieve
during the first years of recovery from the deep transitional recession.
The scope for productivity-enhancing reallocation was then large. In
addition, firms in these countries were so far from the technology
frontier that the acquisition of foreign machinery and equipment,
combined with favorable terms of trade and the utilization of excess
capacity, made extremely large productivity gains possible within a
short time. Sustained and strong productivity growth over the longer
term will prove more difficult as excess capacity is used up. Recent
efforts to promote privatization and firm restructuring are steps in the
right direction.
Three central messages emerge from our ana lysis:
• For some countries in the Region, recognizing that the transition is over is
now important. As markets develop and resources are allowed to
flow to more productive uses, the legacy of transition progressively
weakens. This is reflected in the productivity patterns in countries.
In most of the EU-10, the contributions of reallocation and firm
turnover to aggregate productivity growth have declined. Productivity is mainly driven by efficiency ga ins within individual firms.
The productivity patterns in these countries resemble those of
advanced market economies. This is not to suggest that differences
in productivity across firms disappear altogether as countries move
out of transition. These differences will always exist as a result of
technological innovation, the penetration of new export markets,
7
8
Unleashing Prosperity
and other factors. But the drivers of firm productivity growth will
no longer be specific to the transition. Reallocation and firm
turnover will continue to play a role, but they will tend to be asso ciated with the business cycle as in advanced market economies.
• Accelerating reallocation and removing barriers to firm entry and exit are
top priorities among the late reformers in sustaining strong productivity
growth. In most of the CIS and SEE, but also in some EU-10 countries,
such as Romania, the contributions of the reallocation of resources
and of firm turnover (or net entry) to productivity growth are quite
substantial; they are larger than those in advanced market
econorrues. The fact that productivity dispersion across firms is still
higher in these countries than in advanced market economies suggests that there is ample room for productivity gains derived from
reallocation and firm turnover. But reallocation does not occur
automatically. Its nature and speed depend on factor mobility, which,
in turn, is affected by the policy environment. Trade openness may
facilitate shifts of labor from agriculture toward higher-productivity
activities in the manufacturing and service sectors. Greater access to
finance may also promote the movement of labor toward industry
and services by alleviating liquidity constraints in firms that are hiring. Investments in human capital and greater labor market flexibility may accelerate the reallocation process by increasing worker
mobility. Such a set of policies, combined with streamlined regulations for start-ups to encourage the entry of new, more-productive
firms and stronger product market competition to spur the exit of
obsolete firms, may also contribute to sustaining productivity
growth. These efforts to improve firm-level efficiency should be
complemented by adequate social safety nets to help mitigate the
short-term costs of reallocation among workers who are displaced
or pushed out of the workforce.
• Fostering innovation and international competitiveness is a top priority
among early reformers in sustaining productivity growth. Turkey and
most of the EU-10 have achieved impressive results in economic
liberalization, the privatization of state-owned enterprises, and
opening up their economies to international trade and capital flows .
But the integration of goods, services, and capital markets into the
world economy is only a first step. Globalization calls for new forms
of organization in production to compete in international markets.
Innovation, a key driver of productivity growth, requires firms that
are less vertically integrated, as well as greater integration into
global production chains. It requires grea ter mobility within and
Overview
across firms and more flexible labor markets. And it requires greater
reliance on market finance and higher investment in R&D and in
tertiary education. Innovation-led productivity growth thus calls
for policies that increase private sector participation in R&D so as
to support skill-based industries and move up the value chain in
exports. It also calls for deeper financial sectors that are able to
facilitate the financing of new capital. Service sector regulations
that facilitate the entry of new players, particularly in services
and network industries, will prove important in fostering inno vation. Promoting greater competition in financial services and
infrastructure -related services, such as telecommunications and
transport, will also be important.
What Are the Patterns of Productivity Growth?
Although output, productivity, and prosperity have all risen significantly in the Region since 1999, large gaps remain among countries
and sectors. Rapid productivity gains have driven economic growth
and helped eliminate some disparities across the Region . But productivity still varies from country to country because of differences in
production structures and firm strategies.
Productivity-Driven Output Growth Has Brought
Unprecedented Prosperity
Across the Region, strong output growth since 1999 has reversed
much of the economic decline that occurred during the early days of
the transition. The transition started in the early 1990s with a dra matic recession; the deeper contractions occurred in the CIS and SEE
(figure 3). Output declined in virtually all transition economies in the
initial years. Output fe ll by about 15 percent in the EU - 10 and by
35-40 percent in the CIS. The speed and extent of the economic
recovery that followed varied widely across the Region. The CIS
reached the nadir in 1998 when the financia l crisis unfolded in th e
Russian Federation.
Brisk growth, particularly in the CIS, led to a rapid increase in living
standards. By the end of 2005 , the per capita gross domestic product
(GDP) in the CIS was about 50 percent higher than it had been in
1998, though some of the countries had not yet reached pretransition
income levels (figure 3). In the EU- 10, GDP was about 15 percent
higher than the level in 1993. Annual income per capita in the
9
Unleash ing Prosperity
10
Region, in constant PPP dollars, went from US$5,807 in 1998 to
US$8,398 in 2005. By this measure, the Region is now richer than
Latin America. This strong growth lifted about 50 million people out
of absolute poverty (defined as US$2.15 a day in 2000 PPP dollars)
within a population of nearly 400 million (figure 3).
Economic growth was mostly driven by productivity gains; TFP
growth accounted for over 80 percent of total output growth in the
Region over 1999- 2005, m u ch higher than other regions (figure 4) .3
In some countries, but particu larly in the CIS, part of the productivity
gains derived from the utilization of excess capacity, which is normal
during a recovery. Since 1990, TFP growth has surged, particularly in
the CIS (figure 5) . This is mainly a reflection of the growth rebound in
these countries from the deep contractions of the 1990s. In most of
the EU-10, in contrast, productivity growth has been steady since the
mid-l 990s. These countries were early reformers and made the
strongest strides in building the institutional foundations of a market
economy, developing a vibrant private sector, and opening up to international trade and foreign finance .
However, the contribution of capital and labor accumulation to the
Region's growth performance has been disappointing. The small role
of capital stock accumulation and employment growth in the Region's
growth performance contrasts with the experience of rapidly growing
economies in East Asia, where factor accumulation is the main driver
of output growth (figure 4). A similar message emerges from the
FIGURE 3
Gross Domestic Product Rose, and Poverty Fell Dramatically
b. Population by poverty status
a. Index of gross domestic product
100
180
0
0
II
en
90
80
Turkey
160
en
~
140
214.7
247.4
70
311 .0
c: 60
~
Q;
Cl.
50
40
160.7
158.3
30
20
10
04-
#~
-"'._
~_.
1998- 99
year
......,._
2002--03
~
-
2005--06
millions
D
nonpoor: above US$4.30 a day
D
vulnerable below US$4.30 a day.
above US$2. 15
poor: below US$2. 15 a day
Sources:World Bank staff calculations; World Development Indicators Database 2007; household budget surveys; poverty lines in 2000 PPPs.
Overview
11
FIGURE 4
TFP, More Than Labor or Capital, Has Boosted Growth
.r:"
~0
3
0,
cfi 1
0
~
TFP
D labor force
capital stock
Source: World Bank staff calculations (see appendix 1A)
Note: CIS = Commonwealth of Independent States; EU = European Union; LAC = Latin America and the Caribbean;
SEE= Southeastern Europe.
FIGURE 5
TFP Has Rebounded across the Region Since 1990
4
~
<:
~
Q +-.f>",
-
-J>'L,.t=
~
.1-"'r
-"'
~
-2
-4
-6
-8
CIS-low
CIS-mid
1990-94
EU-10
0 1995-98
SEE
Turkey
SI 1999-2005
Source: World Bank staff calculations (see appendix 1A for data sources).
decomposition of th e growth of GDP per capita. Growth in income
per capita from 1999 to 2004, (figure 6) owes more to growth in labor
productivity than to employment growth (the share of the working age population to total population) or favorabl e demography (the
employment share of the total population).
Labor supply and demand factors explain the small contribution
of labor input to total output growth. A shrinking working-age population, out-migration, declines in labor participation, and high
unemployment rates stifled labor supply, thereby contributing to
disappointing labor outcomes . Indeed , the employment rate has
continued to fall in many countries since 1998 (figure 7). While the
employment rate is genera lly higher in the CIS (relative to the
Unleashing Prosperity
12
FIGURE 6
Labor Productivity, More Than Employment or Population Growth, Raised per Capita Income,
1999-2004
10
17.31
(6 5)
(40)
~
0
0,
cfi -2
(26)
I
(31)
i
-4
~
(-28)
--{)
-8
II
(37)
(14)
i
(-32)
(-59)
1993- 98
1999--2004
1990--98
EU-10
1999--2004
Turkey
1993-98
1999-2004
1993- 98
CIS-mid
• output per worker
1999-2004
1996-98
CIS-low
1999- 2004
SEE
Cl employment to working population
D working population to total population
output per capita growth in brackets
Source: World Bank sta ff calculations.
FIGURE 7
The Share of Workers in the Working-Age Population Has Fallen
80
'° .g
10
60
.e. g_
50
ai
c:
~
§
·.;::;
~
C'O
u
0
.::- 40
l!l
0.
B 30
ai
~-
~
0
0
:!§
"#.
0
20
10
EU-10
Turkey
SEE
D 1990--98
CIS-mid
CIS-low
1999--2005
Sources: World Bank staff calculations; World Development Indicators Database 2007.
EU-10, where the rate is short of the Lisbon target of 70 percent) ,
many jobs in the CIS are in low-productivity occupations. These
constraints are compounded by deficiencies in the higher education
system, which worsen skill mismatches, and rigidities in labor market regulations, which make it difficult for firms to hire workers and
slow the pace of the reallocation of workers.
The small role of capita l accumulation in the Region's growth
partly reflects inefficiencies and low investments in new vintages of
capital. In the context of a declining labor force, sustaining per capita
income growth will depend on capital deepening (increasing the
physical capital per worker) and on additional productivity gains. The
small impact of capital accumula tion on output growth, particularly
Overview
13
in the CIS, also reflects adjustments in the corporate sector that have
delayed new investments and Jed to the disposa l of old capital stock.
In the EU-10, investment rates have not been low, but depreciation
rates are high, and infrastructure provision still lags considerably
relative to the EU-15. Even more critical than the quantity of capital
investments is the quality of the investments . The EU -10 countries
have invested the most in ICT. The use and production of ICT have
propelled labor productivity growth (figure 8) .
A Substantial Gap in Productivity Remains
across the Region
Despite the productivity surge, wide gaps in productivity still divide
the Region. Productivity levels in the EU-10 in 200 5 were more than
twice those in poorer CIS countries (figure 9). Narrowing this gap in
productivity calls for sustained productivity growth in these countries.
What Are the Sources of Productivity Growth?
The economic transition from central planning brought gains in efficiency throughout the Region. Many countries saw a dramatic shift of
resources toward the service sector, which was underdeveloped under
centralized regimes. This shift increased labor productivity in agriculture and manufacturing partly because of labor shedding. While these
structural changes contributed to increased productivity growth, firm
efficiency gains accounted for most of the surge in productivity and
FIGURE 8
Investments in ICT Contributed to Labor Productivity Growth, 1995--2004
0.8
0.7
Source. Piatkowski and van Ark 2007.
Unleashing Prosperity
14
FIGURE 9
TFP in the Poorest Countries in the Region Is Only Half the Level in the EU-10
a. In ITFP)
b. TFP in the Region and in comparators
6.5
7.0
-
6.0
c:::-
t=.
.!:
5.5
5.0
4.5
t
CIS-low
-
-
-
- -
-
6.5
-
c:::- 6.0
u...
t-
:E" 5.5
5.0
4.5
CIS-mid
SEE
Turkey
1992 0 1998 0 2005
EU-10
-
J
China
-
f-
-
East Asia
Industrial
LAC
the Region
1990 01 998 0 2005
Source: World Bank staff calculations.
brought about a remarkable boost in job flows, although the net
employment impact varied across countries, subregions, and industries.
The Reallocation of Resources toward Services Has
Boosted Aggregate Productivity
There has been substantial resource reallocation toward services
(figure 10). The economies of the Region faced significant challenges in resource allocation at the start of the transition because
of serious structural distortions inherited from central planning,
namely, an oversized manufacturing sector and an underdeveloped
service sector. The service sector has grown relative to agriculture
and industry across the Region. In the EU-10, the share of services
in total value added rose dramatically, from 40 percent in 1999 to
60 percent in 2005. Labor also shifted toward services.
These sectoral shifts were related to the overindustrialization of
the economies, especially in the CIS , although the magnitude of
labor reallocation differed across countries. First, many workers
moved out of manufacturing as industries adjusted to market forces .
This is reflected in significant declines in the share of employment in
industry, especially in the CIS, where it fell by around 13 percentage
points. Second, workers shifted to market -based services in both
the EU-10 and the CIS. At the beginning of the transition, these
economies had small service sectors. These sectors grew in response
to demand and increased their share in employment by around 16
and 9 percentage points in the EU - 10 and the CIS, respectively,
moving closer to the patterns observed in advanced market
economies. Third, labor in the low income CIS countries shifted
15
Overview
to agriculture, which increased its emp loyment share by around
20 percentage points. This occurred because agricu lture p layed
the ro le of a social safety net and absorbed disp laced labor from
urban industries .
The broad shift to services drove up overa ll productivity leve ls.
Since va lue added per worker is the lowest in agriculture and the
highest in services in most countries (th e exception is the CIS), the
shift in employment away from agriculture and manufacturing into
services raised labor productivity (figure 11) .
FIGURE 10
The Share of Services in Value Added and Employment Has Risen
a. Sectoral shares of total value added
b. Sectoral shares of total employment
100
90
100
90
80
80
70
70
E 60
~ 50
~ 40
E 60
~ 50
~ 40
30
20
10
0 .µ...-=.,c-"-"'-.,-J""-'-r"'"""-r
30
20
10
0 -l-"--".,,.L-..L.,..J"-J.,..L-L,.L-......................................................"-,-1...........
agriculture
D
industry
~
servic
agriculture
D
industry
1§::1 services
Sources.· World Bank staff calculations; World Development Indicators Database 2007.
Note: Employment is proxied by labor force participation. The definition of services in the World Development Indicators Database includes government services and
market services. The definition of industry covers manufacturing. construction. electricity, gas. and water.
FIGURE 11
Higher Value Added per Worker in Services Raised Overall Labor
Productivity in Most Countries, 1999-2004
30
0
0
0
25
N
E
~"' "'-.::> 20
c: c:
0
rn
'-'"'
z: 6
·-
>
."B
..c:
15
-
~
:::> (/)
1l
::::J
10
0.
Ci
..c
~
CIS-low
CIS-mid
agriculture
Turkey
SEE
subregion
D
industry
~
services
Sources: World Bank staff calculations; World Development Indicators Database 2007.
EU-10
16
Unleashing Prosperity
Efficiency Gains within Sectors Have Been More Important
Than Cross-Sectoral Shifts
The sources of aggregate productivity growth may be divided into
three components, as follows:
• The within effect captures the impact of productivity growth in
individual sectors on aggregate productivity in the economy.
• The between effect captures the impact of the reallocation of
employment across sectors. A positive between effect means that
aggregate productivity rises because the sector displays higher than
average productivity and labor is moving into the sector or because
the sector has lower than average productivity and labor is leaving
the sector.
• The cross effect captures the impact of the reallocation of employment into sectors exhibiting growing productivity. A positive cross
effect means that aggregate productivity increases because employment has moved to sectors showing positive productivity growth
(or out of sectors with negative productivity growth).
The sectoral reallocation effects have been substantial in the
Region, but they tend to cancel each other out. Labor is generally
moving to sectors with high productivity levels (services) and out of
sectors with low productivity levels (agriculture). This is reflected in a
positive between term. At the same time, labor is moving out of sectors with increasing productivity growth (agriculture, manufacturing) and into sectors with decreasing productivity growth (services).
This is reflected in a negative cross term.
Productivity growth in manufacturing and agriculture exceeded productivity growth in services, although the patterns varied across countries. In Turkey and the SEE, agricultural productivity growth exceeded
productivity growth in manufacturing and services (figure 12). In
the EU-10, productivity grew more rapidly in manufacturing and
agriculture than in services. Productivity growth in the CIS has been
the highest in the Region, particularly more recently, and has
followed a similar pattern across all three sectors, reflecting a broadbased economic recovery after the deep recession.
In agriculture, labor shedding seems to be the main driving force
behind the strong productivity surge in the Region. In labor-intensive
regions (typica lly in countries such as Albania, Armenia, Georgia, and
the Kyrgyz Republic), a shift from large-sca le collective farming to
small-scale individual farming caused dramatic gains in techn ical efficiency, but relatively small losses in scale efficiency. In capital- and
land-intensive regions (in countries such as the Czech Republic,
17
Overview
FIGURE 12
Labor Productivity Growth Was High, Particularly in the CIS, 1999-2004
a. Labor productivity growth
b. Labor productivity levels
60
10
ro
2i
·.;::;
ro
c
~
6
c.
4
:;;
(/)
50
"O
:53 ~
40
8 £
30
.S 5
C>
N
~
~
~
ui
.!:? 20
~
:g
0
10
u
CIS-low CIS- mid
agriculture
SEE
D
Turkey
industry
~
EU-10
EU-15
services
CIS-low
CIS-mid
agriculture
SEE
D
Sources: World Bank staff calculations; World Development Indicators Database 2007.
Hungary, and the Slovak Republic), gains in labor productivity arose
primarily because large farms shed labor as they were privatized and
because of intersectoral labor reallocation as workers moved away
from agriculture to more rapidly growing industries in manufacturing and services. In countries in which neither type of reform was
implem ented vigorously, productivity gains were genera ll y modest.
During the first stage of transition, trade liberalization, the elimination of subsidies, price liberalization, and land reforms were required
to accelerate farm restructuring and facilitate the sectoral realloca tion of labor. As countries progress along the transition path, an
improved investment climate and stronger competition in services
are needed to improve within -farm productivity growth and provide
off-farm job opportunities.
Productivity growth in manufacturing has been driven by efficiency
ga ins in industries with higher capacity for innovation.4 High-technology manufacturing industries led the productivity growth in the
manufacturing sector, exhibiting the highest annual average productivity growth rates. This group of manufacturing industries employs a
large share of highly skilled workers, produces ICT goods, or uses a relatively large amount of ICT capital. The high -technology group
includes manufacturers of office machinery, electrical and electronic
equipment, and optical instruments. Low-technology manufacturing
industries, such as traditional consumer goods manufacturing, posted
a lower average productivity growth. Not surprisingly, high-technology
industries display higher TFP growth in countries showing more
progress in the liberalization of key service industries, deeper financial
markets, a more highly skilled workforce, more flexible labor markets,
and more R&D investments by the private sector.
Turkey
industry
~
EU-10
services
EU-15
18
Unleashing Prosperity
Productivity growth in services has been driven by backbone
industries such as transport, telecommunications, and financial
intermediation. These industries have shown higher productivity
levels and a greater propensity to use or produce ICT such as retai l
trade, transport, telecommunications, and financial intermediation
services. The productivity growth in these sectors during 1997-2004
surpassed the average productivity growth achieved among the
EU-15. Nevertheless, a substantial gap remains in productivity levels.
The strong performance of these service industries suggests that
there is a potential for growth driven by services. The efficiency of
backbone services is crucial to the productivity of other sectors in the
economy and for integration into global markets. It also enables firms
to participate in the global fragmentation of the production of services, which leads to increased service exports .
The potential gains will not be achieved automatically, however. The
penetration and efficient use of ICT in services are still limited. Investments in ICT in services will bring about large productivity gains. Policy
makers in the Region can pla y a major role in sustaining the momentum of growth in the service sector by pursuing service liberalization
across the board, removing regulatory barriers that limit competition in
various service industries, and attracting more foreign direct investment (FDI) and greater trade flows.
Firm Dynamics Contributed to Productivity Growth
More Than Sectoral Changes Did
The analysis of cross-sectoral shifts hides substantial firm dynamism
within indu stries . The reallocation of workers and firms from lessproductive activities to more-productive activities is important in promoting productivity growth in any market economy, but it assumed a
greater role in transition economies because of the highly distorted
industrial structures inherited from central planning. Faced with the
radical transformation of the economy, firms in all countries were
forced to adapt their behavior. Some firms increased productivity
through defensive restructuring (labor shedding), while others did so
through strategic restructuring (the adoption of new technologies). New
firms entered the market, occupied emerging niches and displaced
obsolete firms that had been forced to exit the market.
Evidence at the firm level reveals how individua l enterprises
managed to reallocate resources, improve efficiency, and enter or
exit business operations. It also sheds light on the obstacles that
firms face in these tasks. Drawing on firm-level data, one may
Overview
decompose aggregate productivity growth into three main compo nents, as follows:
• The within component accounts for the productivity growth taking
place within firms .
• The reallocation component captures the productivity gains derived
from the reallocation of labor across firms . It is the sum of two
terms: between and cross. The between component reflects gains
that arise as high-productivity firms acquire greater market share
or as low -productivity firms lose market share. The cross component reflects increases in aggregate productivity that arise as firms
showing high productivity growth gain market share (or as firms
showing low productivity growth lose market share) .
• The net entry component (also known as firm turnover or firm
churning) reflects the productivity gains resulting from the creation of new, more productive firms and the exit of obsolete firms .
This component is calculated as the sum of two terms: firm entry
and firm exit.
This decomposition of labor manufacturing productivity growth draws
on empirical work carried out by Bartelsman and Scarpetta (2007) and
Brown and Earle (2007). Their findings suggest the following: 5
• Productivity gains within existing firms account for the bulk of productivity
growth, especially in early reformers . In some early reformers, withinfirm productivity growth accounts for more than 80 percent of total
manufacturing productivity growth. In late reformers, it accounts
for between 30 and 60 percent of overall manufacturing productivity growth.
• The reallocation of labor across existing firms plays a significant role in
productivity growth, especially in late reformers. Reallocation rates are
particularly large in countries that are still addressing the resource
misallocations inherited from centra l planning . Reallocation
amounts to 15-20 percent of total manufacturing productivity
growth in early reformers, but may account for up to 70 percent
of total manufacturing productivity growth in some late
reformers. Reallocation rates are higher in the latter group of
countries, ranging from 15 to 30 percentage points. In early
reformers, reallocation rates are only about 6 percentage points .
In late reformers, the cross term tends to be negative . This implies
that firms experiencing an increase in productivity have also lost
employment share (that is, the productivity growth of these firms
19
Unleashing Prosperity
20
has been associated with restructuring and downsizing rather
than expansion) .
• Firm churning is also an important driver of productivity growth in transition economies, especially among the late reformers. Firm turnover is
also an important driver of total productivity growth in advanced
market economies, accounting for 20-50 percent of total productivity growth. In these countries, the exit effect is positive (that is,
the least productive firms exit the market, thereby helping to raise
the average productivity of firms that survive), whereas the entry
term has tended to be negative.6 In late reformers, in contrast, the
entry term tends to be positive and contributes about 10 percent to
aggregate manufacturing productivity growth.
Efficiency Gains within Firms Drive the Bulk
of Productivity Growth
The bulk of productivity growth arises from efficiency gains within
existing firms . This is axiomatic in regard to healthy market economies,
but it is also true in transition economies. Nonetheless, firms improve
their productivity in different ways, reflecting variations in the broader
country business environment in which they operate. In late reformers, within-firm productivity growth is mostly driven by the utilization
· of excess capacity and by defensive restructuring (shedding labor and
adopting other cost-cutting strategies). In Russia, the available survey
data suggest that capacity utilization rates in manufacturing industries
have increased appreciably since 1999. In contrast, in early reformers,
firms improve their productivity through strategic restructuring, that is,
by investing in new technologies and improving the value added content of products and exports. Figure 13 compares the contributions to
manufacturing productivity growth (expressed in percentage points) in
Hungary and Ukraine.
The available empirical evidence shows a great deal of firm heterogeneity. Firm manufacturing productivity patterns vary according to
several factors, including location, firm size, ownership, and industry.
• Location. Firms located in rapidly reforming areas enjoy higher
productivity growth than those located in laggard areas reforming
slowly. This is the case in Ukraine. Similarly, firms located in areas
with better transport infrastructure tend to exhibit higher productivity growth relative to firms located in areas with greater
transport deficiencies.
• Firm size. Among large firms (250 or more employees), withinfirm productivity gains are larger relative to small firms (less than
I
21
Overview
FIGURE 13
As Transition Proceeds, Productivity Growth Is Driven Mainly by
Efficiency Gains within Firms
within
D net entry
D reallocation
Sourcf!. Brown and Earle 2007.
50 employees) and medium firms (50 to 249 employees) , although
the reallocation effects are larger among small firms. Among large
firms, the net entry contribution to total productivity growth is
often negative.
• Firm ownership. In the new private sector (private firms established
since the beginning of transition) , manu facturing produ ctivity
growth is higher relative to the old private sector (firms established
prior to the transition). Within-firm productivity growth is nearly
twice as high in the new firms relative to the old firms in Hungary
and Russia . In Russia and Ukraine, the reallocation effects are
larger among the new firms relative to the old firms . There are also
different productivity patterns among state-owned firms and private firms . Reallocation tends to contribute more to productivity
growth among private firms relative to state-owned firms . This is
the case in Hungary and Romania. However, in Russia and Ukraine,
private firms are still less productive, on average, than state-owned
firms. The contribution of the rea llocation of resources among
mcumbent firms is also much greater among private firms in Hungary and Romania than among private firms in Russia and
Ukraine. These differences are related to the modes of privatization
and the degree of market competition (see the next section).
Foreign-owned firms tend to show higher productivity growth
than domestic private or state firms, except in Russia . The large
productivity growth enjoyed by foreign firms is driven mainly by
within-firm productivity growth.
• Industry. Firms operating in !CT-related industries display higher
productivity growth. Firms operating in !CT-related industries rely
on strategic restructuring, thereby improving their productivity by
22
Unleashing Prosperity
adopting new and better ways to produce goods. In contrast, firms
in non-ICT industries tend to engage in defensive restructuring to
increase productivity, mostly by shedding labor. Overall, firms in
non -ICT industries tend to show lower productivity growth than
firms operating in ICT industries. Firm entry also plays an important role in boosting productivity in !CT-related industries, whereas
the contribution of new firms to productivity growth is negative in
non-ICT industries. This is particularly the case in the early reformers,
where a large number of new firms emerged in industries with
greater opportunities for innovation. The better performance of
companies operating in !CT-intensive sectors may be considered
evidence of the presence of technological spillovers. If a firm operates in a high-technology environment, it is more likely to absorb
new developments quickly and to boost productivity more extensively. Similarly, firms in industries that depend on external financing tend to enjoy higher productivity growth, particularly in
countries with deeper financial markets. In late reformers, there is
also a productivity growth gap between industries that are highly
reliant on external financing and those that depend little on external
financing, although the gap is similar across countries.
Firm Churning Contributes to Productivity Growth
The process of creative destruction, whereby a significant number of
businesses start up or close their operations, encourages firms to
experiment and learn. It rewards success, and it punishes failure.
Healthy market economies exhibit fairly high rates of firm entry and
exit; from 5 to 20 percent of firms enter or exit the market every year.
In the Region, about 20 percent of firms have been created or
destroyed during the past decade (figure 14).
Firm turnover is an important driver of productivity growth in transition economies, especially in late reformers. In early reformers at the
start of the transition, the contribution of net entry was large and
accounted for between 20 and 40 percent of total productivity growth.
Over time, the relative contribution of net entry declined and converged
to levels similar to those observed in advanced market economies. In
late reformers, the contribution of firm churning to total productivity
growth is still substantial and has been increasing in recent years. In
Russia, net entry accounted for over 17 percent of total manufacturing
productivity growth in 1998-2001 and increased to 46 percent in
2001-04. In most late reformers, where low-productivity firmsbecause they are sheltered from competitive pressures-have managed
to contain job destruction, the effect of firm entry also tends to be larger
23
Overview
FIGURE 14
Business Start-Ups Have Exceeded Business Exits in Most Countries
60
50
40
the Region
0 firm entry rates D firm exit rates
Sources. Bartelsman and Scarpetta 2007; Brown and Earle 2007.
than the effect of firm exit. This suggests that entering firms may still
have to undergo downsizing and restructuring.
The size and timing of firm churning vary across countries . In
Hungary, at the onset of the transition, a large share of firms closed
down and were replaced by new, small ventures, largely as a response
to privatization reforms (figure 15). Over time, net firm flows
declined to values fairly close to those observed in advanced market
economies. In late reformers, such as Russia, firm turnover flows
were remarkably low, and, during the second half of the 1990s, firm
exit rates exceeded firm entry rates . After the 1998 crisis, this trend
was reversed, and the number of new firms exceeded the number of
firms that disappeared. The size of firm churning also varies across
industries . Firm turnover rates (especially if they are weighted by
employment) are higher in service industries (especially in trade)
than in manufacturing industries. However, in most countries, some
high -technology industries experiencing rapid technological change
and market experimentation showed relatively high entry rates in
the 1990s (for example, office computing and office equipment, as
well as radio, television, and communications) .
The productivity performance of entrants relative to incumbents
varies across countries:
• Entrants tend to show higher productivity than incumbents in countries
where reforms are lagging, while, in early reformers, the relative
productivity is lower among entrants than among incumbents,
though it tends to rise among entrants as they age. In Hungary and
Unleashing Prosperity
24
FIGURE 15
Hungary's Reforms Led to Increased Firm Entry, While the 1998 Crisis
Prompted Firm Exit in the Russian Federation
a. Hungary, 1987-2003
50
45
40
~
35
.§
30
§
25
0 20
#-
15
10
1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
year
a firm entry II firm exit
b. Russian Federation. 1996--2004
50
45
40
~
35
.§
30
§
25
0 20
"#- 15
10
year
o firm entry
firm exit
Source: Brown and Earle 2007.
Note: Firm flow data in the early years of the transition may be affected by data quality issues.
Romania, entrants are less productive than the average incumbent, which might signal that they are experimenting more. This
pattern is similar to the one observed in the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) , where entrants
often lack experience, and small size often makes new firms less
productive. In contrast, in Georgia, Russia, and Ukraine, entrants
are (on average) more productive than incumbents. They have
been able to fill niches, mostly in market services, that were underdeveloped or nonexistent during central planning (figure 16).
• Entrants tend to be small relative to incumbents in most countries. Under
the centrally planned system, there were relatively few small firms,
but, during the transition, the number of small firms shot up, particularly in business service activities. At the same time, many of the
entrants that failed during the initial years were also relatively small.
25
Overview
FIGURE 16
In Slovenia, the Largest Manufacturing Firms Have Shrunk, While, in Mexico, They Have
Expanded
b. Mexico
a. Sloveni a
¥1 .000
~
900
c.
E 800
0"' 700
Ci; 600
~ 500
.s 400
·~ 300
200
~
100
~
o -1~=
ii;
1985
.§
:=r
1990
1995
~=r
=-,
2000
2005
year
3rd quartile
-
2nd quartile
year
-
top quartile
3rd quartile
-
2nd quartile
Source: Bartelsman and Scarpetta 2007.
• Entrants tended to exhibit high survival rates at the beginning of the
transition . An understanding of post-entry performance sheds light
on the market selection process, which separates successful entrant
firms that survive and prosper from entrant firms that stagnate
and eventually exit. Survival rates after entry are higher in Russia
and Ukraine. In Estonia, Latvia, and Slovenia, but also in Romania
and Hungary, around 70 percent of entering firms survive at least
four years. In contrast, in Mexico, firm survival rates are much
lower, pointing to harsher market selection or higher variance in
the quality of entrants. It may also be that entrants in the transition economies were actually restructured firms that reentered the
market with employees who possessed experience and with established connections with customers and suppliers. Such an advantage is likely to diminish over time (figure 17).
• As countries progress along the transition path, the market becomes
harsher and the survival rate of entrants drops. Entrants show rapidly
declining probabilities of survival (especially in Russia, where less
than 10 percent of entrants are still in business after seven years).
In Hungary, 25 percent of entrant firms are no longer active in the
market after two years; the figure is 50 percent after five years,
and, after seven years, about 70 percent of new firms have exited .
Failure rates among young businesses are high in all market
economies, but, in industrial countries, about 50-60 percent of new
firms are still in business after seven years. In the Baltic states
(Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania), entrants face an environment
that is slightly less harsh than the environment in the EU; about
-
top quartile
Unleashing Prosperity
26
FIGURE 17
Entrants Survival Rates Are Higher In The Region Than In Advanced In Economies
a. Transition Economies Show Higher Survival Rates Than Many Advanced Economies
country
2 year
D 4 year
D 7 year
b. As the Transition Matures, Markets Grow Harsh, and Entrant Survival Rates Drop
90
70
;,'<
60
Jii
50
["
·~
'°
>
40
~-
,__
30
-
20
I<
"1:.1
.~
-
10
0
f~
1--
':
-
....,..,
-
-
80
'.
,__
I
~\,
-
..
''
~
'X ...
,
-
~i
-
1:.
r:
t·.1
tr
I~
Hungary
Russian Federation Russian Federation
Ukraine
Ukraine
Hungary
1991- 95 cohorts 1996-2001 cohorts 1993- 97 cohorts 1998-2002 cohorts 1993- 96 cohorts 1997- 2003 cohorts
two-year survival
o four-year surviva l
o seven-yea r survival
Source: Brown and Earle 2007.
70 percent of entrants survive at least four years, and 50- 60 percent
survive at least seven years.
• Successful entrants that exhibited higher initial productivity tend to create more jobs. The probability of employment growth is strongly
associated with a firm's in itial productivity performan ce. In many
countries in the Region, the most productive entrants provided
the most stable employment over the fi rst three years of firm
operations (figure 18).
• But, even successful entrants have not expanded significantly in the Region;
th is is especially true of large firms in manufacturing. At the start of the
transition, firms in Estonia, Latvia, and Slovenia exhibited sub stantial declines in size, especially in manufacturing. The largest
27
Overview
FIGURE 18
Entrants with Higher Labor Productivity Are More Successful at
Maintaining the Workforce
deviation from sectoral average labor productivity at start-up, %
-
Georgia
Hungary -
Romania
-
Russian Federation -
Ukraine
Source: Brown and Earle 2007.
quartile of firms in manufacturing was particularly affected. In
Slovenia, the average size among firms in the largest quartile had
dropped from more than 800 to 200 employees by the early 2000s.
In the Baltic states, no sign of an increase in firm size has been
apparent. Indeed, the size of the largest firms in Estonia, Latvia,
and Slovenia declined during the transition. The question remains
whether firms in these countries are able to benefit fully from the
opportunities of economic integration into the EU and an enlarged
market. The lack of growth in large manufacturing firms contrasts
with the case of Mexico. In Mexico, there has been a rapid expansion in the mean size of manufacturing firms in the largest quartile
from 80 to 120 employees per firm (figure 16), and the average
size of the largest firms grew rapidly during the first years following
the adoption of the North American Free Trade Agreement.
Resource Reallocation across Existing Firms Contributes
to Productivity Growth
The reallocation of labor across existing firms also contributed to productivity growth, and its role was particularly large at the start of the
transition. In countries at the early stages of transition, the between
term tended to be large and positive, indicating that firms with rugher
than average productivity levels were gaining market share. At the
same time, the contribution to total productivity growth of the cross
term (shifts of resources toward firms with rugher than average productivity growth) is negative. This suggests that firms experiencing
an increase in productivity were also losing employment shares, that
Unleashing Prosperity
28
is, their productivity growth was associated with restructuring and
downsizing rather than with expansion.
The rapid pace of restructuring in transition economies is not evidence of the competitive conditions observed in healthy market
economies. The pace of entry and exit and the contribution of reallocation to productivity in mature economies point to an ongoing, steadystate process that exerts pressure on incumbents to perform well. In
late reformers, which are not so far along in the transition process,
reallocation is less an indicator of the overall state of competitiveness
of the market and more a reflection of a major change in the supply
side of the economy. In early reformers, the pattern is different. Once
the net entry rate has become settled, a lack of correlation between the
net entry component of growth and incumbent growth may be more
indicative of problems in competition.
As the transition matures, the role of reallocation and firm
turnover in aggregate productivity growth declines, converging
toward the patterns observed in advanced market economies. Not
surprisingly, the contributions of reallocation and net entry (or firm
churning) to overall productivity growth decrease as countries move
along the transition path . After the major distortions inherited from
the central planning period have been addressed and after the pretransition void in certain activities has been filled , productivity
decompositions in advanced reformers tend to converge toward
those observed in advanced market economies (figure 19).
Reallocation, Firm Turnover, and Within-Firm
Productivity Growth Reinforce Each Other
The analysis above focuses on the direct contributions of firm pro ductivity gains within existing firms, labor reallocation across existing
FIGURE 19
The Role of Reallocation and Firm Turnover in Productivity Growth in Early Reformers Is Now
Similar to That in Advanced Market Economies
within
D reallocation D net entry
Sources:Bartelsman and Scarpetta 2007; Brown and Earle 2007.
within
D reallocation D net entry
Overview
firms, and firm churning to overall productivity growth. The contributions of labor reallocation and firm turnover are often interpreted
in the literature as a reflection of a process of creative destruction,
while the within-firm contribution is interpreted as a reflection of
more traditional sources of productivity growth (the average firm
becomes more productive with advancing technology). But, rather
than alternatives, these effects (within-firm productivity growth,
labor reallocations, and firm churning) may be closely related. A
stronger pace in firm creation and destruction may also influence the
decisions of domestic firms about efficiency-enhancing investments.
The entry of productive firms may increase the contestability of the
market, forcing some firms to exit, but also raising the pressure on
incumbents to perform more effectively.
Notwithstanding the observed decline in the role of labor reallocation and firm turnover among early reformers, the process of creative
destruction is still active in the Region. Among the early reformers, the
transition is over, but the Schumpeterian process of creative destruction is not. The large contributions of reallocation across sectors and
firm turnover have now declined to the levels observed in advanced
market economies. But this does not mean that reallocation and firm
turnover will be unimportant for productivity growth. In advanced
market economies, these factors tend to be correlated with the business cycle, and this is likely to be the case in the early reformers as
well. The fact that productivity dispersion in the Region is still greater
than it is in the United States suggests that there is plenty of room in
the Region for significant productivity growth via reallocation and
firm turnover.
While, in advanced market economies, new entrants exert pressure on incumbents to perform more efficiently, this is not the case in
the Region. This is so for the following reasons:
• In advanced market economies, the greater competitive pressure
exerted by entrants induces incumbents to perform more efficiently.
In the OECD, there is a strong, positive, and statistically significant
correlation between the contribution of net entry and the productivity growth of incumbents (Bartelsman and Scarpetta 2007) . There
is also evidence that sectors with many entrants push incumbents
in these sectors to increase their productivity. But, even in the
OECD , the impact of entry on the productivity of incumbents
varies across industries. Based on data on firms in the United
Kingdom over 1987-93, a study by Aghion (2006) finds that the
effect of entry on productivity growth is more positive in industries
that are close to the technological frontier than in industries that are
not close to the frontier.
29
Unl eashing Prosperity
30
• In the Region, firm churning does not exert pressure on incumbents to improve productivity. Particularly among late reformers,
the relationship between the performance of incumbents and net
entry is weaker (figure 20). The lack of pressure from new firms on
incumbents reflects weaker market competition. It may also be
partly caused by the high failure rates among new businesses.
Distortions in market structure and institutions also affect productivity growth. Allocative efficiency has improved in the
Region, although it remains low by international standards. Early
in the trans ition, resources were locked in lower-productivity
firms, on average, but the allocation rapidly improved over time
with the exit of poor firms and the movement of resources toward
more-productive firms. But even early reformers- the EU 10still disp lay lower allocative efficiency than the EU-15 and the
United States, suggesting that there is room for additional adjust ments (figure 21).
Firm Dynamics Have Brought About a Remarkable
Surge in Job Flows
At the beginning of the transition, gross and net firm flows were large
relative to industrial and other emerging economies. Firm-level data on
a sample of countries in the Region and a number of comparator countries provide insights on the size of firms and job dynamics. In modem
economies, gross rates of job creation and destruction range between
5 and 20 percent, adding up to job turnover of up to 40 percent. A
significant part of this job turnover (often 30-50 percent) is due to
the entry and exit of firms. In the Region , job reallocation rates across
FIGURE 20
In Late Reformers, Firm Turnover Has Not Spurred Productivity Gains in Existing Firms
b. Georgia, Russian Fed., Ukraine
a. Slovenia
~
.<::
0.6
j';
04
c,
.-B
i"
~
~s
150
~
0.8
~0
·:;;
~
0.2
--0.2
•
2
c::n
j';
•
• ••
•
•
•• •
.
• •
+--------------- 1.0
0.2
04
0.6
0
0.8
--04
--0.2
net entry contribution 1%1
Sources: Bartelsman and Scarpetta 2007; Brown and Earle 2007.
·:;;
·~
-g
Ci
100
50
•
0
·~,:.
.. •
•• • •• •
"
.0 -50
Q)
§
s - 100
-40
-20
20
40
60
net entry contribution 1%1
80
100
31
Overview
FIGURE 21
Allocative Efficiency Remains Low in the Region
-0
40
c::
ro ~
~
:~
35
-<::: '-'
en::>
·-
Q)
3:
c::
Q)
Q)
3:
~
Q)
'-'
-0
0
a.
~
'O
25
0 20
.0
..§!
-<:::
en
c:: ·-
~~
Q)
30
15
10
c::
::>
United States
EU-15
EU-10
Source: Bartelsman and Scarpetta 2007.
Note: The figure shows the average Olley-Pakes cross term in manufacturing.
firms surged rapidly in response to transition. Job reallocation (the
sum of job creation and destruction) increased dramatically, from
less than 10 percent of the workforce before the transition to about
20 percent in the 1990s. As the transition moved forward, net firm
flows declined and , at the end of the 1990s, had reached values fairly
close to those observed in other countries.
Firm turnover contributed substantially to overall job creation
during the earlier stages of the transition, but the contribution
declined over time. Firm entry outpaced firm exit at the start of the
transition, contributing significantly to job creation (25 to 50 percent).
New firms not only displaced obsolete incumbents during the transi tion phase, but also filled markets that had previously been either
nonexistent or poorly populated. After firms had filled these pretransition voids, job creation arose increasingly from the expansion
of surviving firms .
The contribution of firm exit to job destruction followed different
trends across countries. In the OECD, firm exit is strongly correlated
with job destruction. This is not the case in the Region, particu larly
among the late reformers. In these countries, the share of job destruction by continuing firms is much larger than the share of job destruction resu lting from firm exit (figure 22) . These patterns confirm
earlier findings that existing firms in late-reforming countries resorted
to defensive restructuring to improve productivity by downsizing and
shedding redundant labor.
In countries where job flows were not synchronized, job creation
lagged behind job destruction. Job destruction generally surged first,
but the response of job creation varied across countries; it caught up
rapidly with job destruction in the leading reformers, but remained
Unleashing Prosperity
32
FIGURE 22
Labor Shedding at Existing Firms Was the Main Source of Job Destruction
20
15
10
.,"
E
~
l
"!§
B
-5
0 - 10
<fl-
- 15
- 20
- 25
Slovenia
Estonia
D job creation : firm entry
Latvia
Hungary
Romania
job creation: existing firms
Russian
Federation
Ukraine
Georgia
developed developing
countries countries
D job destruction : fi rm exit D job destruction: existing firms
Sources: Bartelsman and Scarpetta 2007; Brown and Earle 2007.
less consistent than job destruction for prolonged periods in the
lagging reformers. In countries lagging in market-oriented reforms,
such as Russia, stringent labor market regulations discouraged job
creation, and as a result, job destruction rates exceeded job creation.
In some instances, these unsynchron ized job flows gave rise to
unemployment (or underemployment, that is, low-productive
employment in the informal sector) . In contrast, in early reformers,
such as Hungary, job creation rapidly caught up with job destruction,
giving rise to synchronized job flows (figure 23) .
In services, job creation exceeded job destruction owing to the
growing role of services in the Region. The service sector, underde veloped during the central planning period, grew and gained shares
in value added and employment. The growth in the sector also
reflected an explosive expansion in new firms in markets that had
previously been nonexistent or poorly populated. As a result, there
were net employment gains in most countries (figure 24).
In Sum, Policy Reforms Should Stimulate Productivity and
Remove Barriers to Firm Expansion
In late reformers, there is still a large misallocation of resources across
firms , industries, and locations . This ongoing economic distortion
calls for policy reforms to accelerate the pace of reallocation so that
resources flow from less- to more-productive uses. The process of
creative destruction (that is, the exit of unprofitable firms and the
Overview
33
FIGURE 23
Sometimes Unsynchronized Job Flows Gave Rise to Net Employment
Losses
a. Hungary, manufacturing
50
45
40
c
~
Q)
~
35
30
25
ro
§ 20
#. 15
10
1989
1991
1993
1995
1997
1999
2001
2003
year
=
net employment losses =net employment gains -
job creation -
job destruction
b. Russian Federation, manufacturing
50
45
40
c
Q)
~
35
30
Ci
iij 25
"§
B 20
#. 15
10
at:=~
1986
1988
=-.
1990
~
1992
1994
~.-:;_,
1996
year
net employment losses =net employment gai ns -
~
1998
~
2000
job creation -
2002
2004
job destruction
Source: Brown and Earle 2007.
entry of more -productive ones) needs to be invigorated through
privatization and stronger market competition.
Although productivity increases are largely driven by within-firm
adjustments, firm entry and exit should play an important role in
sustaining produ ctivity growth in the years to come . By continu ing
to protect ailing firms and contain firm exit, the late reformers have
not been able to free resources from less-productive uses for moreproductive uses . Similarly, restrictive product land factor markets
and the uncertain business environment discourage firm entry and
Unleashing Prosperity
34
FIGURE 24
In Services, Job Creation Outpaced Job Losses
a. Hungary, services
50
45
40
c:
E 35
.2 30
Cl.
E
Q)
-ro
25
s 20
cfi 15
10
1989
1991
1993
1995
1997
1999
2001
2003
year
net employment losses
= net employment gains -
job creation -
job destruction
b. Romania, services
50
45
c:
40
E
35
Q)
>-
0
a.
E
30
Q)
}§ 25
B
0 20
""
15
10
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005
year
net employment losses
= net employment gains -
job creation -
job destruction
Source: Brown and Earle 2007.
the adoption of better technologies. To foster labor reallocation
acros s and within sectors and firm s, policies need to encourage
workers to adapt to changing demands for labor and skills, for
instance through reforms in the education sector.
In the early reformers, the main challenges revolve around stimulating innovation within firms and encouraging the expansion of successful firm s. These countries also ne ed to focus on reducing any
remaining barriers to firm entry. In this regard, credit constraints, labor
market rigidities, and deficiencies in tertiary and vocational education
are likely to act as barriers to entry and innovation. Restrictive product, labor, and service markets may discourage the entry and growth
Overview
of new firms and may reduce innovative efforts and technology
spillovers, and this negatively affects productivity growth.
While entry may be relatively easy for small businesses, firm survival seems to be more difficult. In addition, even though rea lloca tion may enhance productivity in the economy as a whole, there
are losers in the process. The losers include owners of obsolete bu sinesses and displaced workers . The high incidence of business failures and job losses in some countries, such as Romania, is a clear
source of concern.
The net employment losses observed in some countries of the
Region are also the result of policy barriers that slow the pace of the
reallocation of resources. The barriers include limited factor mobility
(credit market frictions and rigidities in labor markets) and other
regulatory constraints affecting firm entry and firm performance. It
is, therefore, not surprising to observe that, in these countries, the
informal economy still plays an important role as a temporary buffer
by creating (less-productive) jobs.
Which Policies Drive Productivity Growth?
The decisions of firms to improve productivity are influenced by the
incentive framework in which the firms operate, and the incentives
are created or reinforced through government policies and institutions.
The strong productivity performance in the Region has been a reflection of improvements in individual sectors and firms. Moreover, firms
that have performed well in a particular sector tend to be located in
countries that have made the most progress in reforming the policy
and regulatory environment. Differences in the productivity performance across firms within the same industries, even during the growth
episode in the late 1990s, have revived the debate over which policies
drive productivity growth in the Region. What effect has globalization
had on productivity? How do government policies and other features
of the business environment contribute to firm and industry productivity growth? Which policies should be advocated?
Policy Reforms Boost Firm Productivity
Evidence shows that firm productivity growth is associated with
infrastructure quality, financial development, labor market flexibil ity, the quality of labor, good governance, and market competition
(figure 25). The findings presented in this study are consistent with
the findings of the large, cross-country empirical literature. Aggregate
35
36
Unleashing Prosperity
FIGURE 25
Policy Reforms Boost Firm Productivity
a. Infrastructure quality indicator
1.2
"'aI"
0.4
"'I"
a
N
0.8
N
0.3
N
0.6
N
0.2
a
a
au.....:
I-
c:n
0.4
.!:
0.2
a
a
8::-
•
I-
••
E
<O
--0.2
a
a
N
8::"
I-
d. Labor market flexibil ity indicator
0.2
E
--0.2
0.8
a
a
0.6
N
•
•
o...." 0.4
u...
•
•
I-
c:n
• •
••
<O
.<:::
"'aI"
N
0.6
.!:
Q)
c:n
c
•
change in indicator. 2001--03
c. Governance indicator
0.8
0.4
--0.2
--0.3
•
c:n
(..)
-5
•
E
0.2
.!:
Q)
c:n
c
•
•
••••
•
<O
.<:::
(..) --0.2
•
e. Labor quality indicator
a
a
0.6
a.:
0.4
N
u...
I-
c:n
"'aI"
E
s
Q)
c:n
c
0.2
0
(..)
--0.2
--0.4
•
•
0
--1
<O
.<:::
..
•
•
•
.•,.. .
•
•
change in indicator. 2001--03
•
0.2
N
0.15
N
0.1
•
c:n 0.05
•
a
a
•
•
f. Competition indicator
0.25
•
N
0
change in indicator. 2001--03
change in indicator. 2001--03
0.8
•
•
--0.4
--0.4
"'"
l'
•
•
•
<O
change in indicator. 2001 --03
a
•
--1
Q)
•
1.2
N
0.1
g' --0.1
•2
--0.4
"'I"
c:n
E
.!:
• •
•
Q)
c:n
c
.<:::
(..)
b. Financial development indicator
0.5
a.:
u...
I-
E
.!:
Q)
g'
--0.05
<O
.3
--0.2
•
...
•
• • •
• •
•
--0.1
•
0•
0.1
0.2
.<:::
(..)
--0.1
--0.15
•
change in indicator. 2001--03
Sources:Amadeus Database 2006; BEEPS 2002. 2005.
Note: The dependent variable is the change in log TFP from 2002 to 2004, subtracting the effects of all other regressors in the full model. See appendix 3 for the estimation methodology and model specification.
cross-country regressions, while generating useful insights, only provide
crude indicators of the factors behind the productivity performance of
individual countries. This analysis is bound to mask substantial variations within countries and within sectors because of the heterogeneity
of firm responses to the policy and business environment in which
the firms operate.
Overview
The empirical evidence suggests five areas for policy action: promoting good governance and macro stability, strengthening competition,
investing in labor and technology, investing in infrastructure, and
deepening the financial sector.
Ensuring Good Governance and Macroeconomic Stability
Improvements in governance lower transaction costs among firms
by protecting and enforcing property rights, curbing burdensome
administrative and judicia l rulings, and ensuring good regulatory
quality. Sound macroeconomic management holds inflation and fiscal
deficits in check to maintain a stable economic environment. More
broadly, good governance and macroeconomic management increase
predictability and reduce risk in the business environment, which
facilitates investment decisions by entrepreneurs. Improvements in
corporate governance also contribute to firm productivity growth by
increasing the accountability for poor performance.
The transition economies, especially the middle -income ones, must
address their remaining macroeconomic vulnerabilities so as to sustain
growth momentum. Notwithstanding recent gains in the acceleration
of growth, some risks have re -emerged and grown in the light of the
recent global credit crunch. Recent rapid growth may slow down .
Inflationary and external pressures are building again as a result of the
past few years of rapid growth, the quick expansion of credit, and
rising food and energy import prices. Current account and budget
deficits have grown in some countries. These excess demand pressures
have generated concern over macroeconomic vulnerabilities and need
to be addressed to provide the necessary, basic macroeconomic stability
and governance. Toward this end, prudent fiscal and monetary policies
must be maintained to reach stable inflation at low levels, a balance in
banking and corporate sector governance regulations, effective supervision, sound competition policies that encourage efficiency, and the
development of institutional structures and economic policy processes
that permit rapid policy adjustments in response to shocks.
Strengthening Competition
Competition has a pervasive and long- lasting impact on economic
performance because it affects the incentive structure among economic actors by encouraging innovative activities and by selecting
more-efficient activities over less-efficient activities. At the start of the
transition to a competitive market economy, the pressure to increase
capacity utilization and institute privatization was the main trigger
37
38
Unleashing Prosperity
of firm restructuring and productivity growth . In the longer term,
however, productivity improvements need to be sustained through
policies aimed at accelerating the rea llocation of resources and
promoting the introduction of new technologies. The contribution of
entrants to productivity growth is thus critical, and it is particularly
strong in higher-technology sectors.
Competition is needed in both product and service markets to
foster productivity growth. Dynamic efficiency gains from product
market competition, however, are unlikely to be achieved without
well-functioning service markets. Service liberalization enhances the
quality and availability of services through competition and economies
of scale. The benefits of service liberalization are not limited to the
service sector; they affect all economic activities. Given that services
contribute an average of around 10-20 percent to the production cost
of products and account for all trading costs (transport, trade finance,
insurance, communications, and distribution services) , the savings
from stronger competition by foreign providers and the gains in competitiveness on international markets among services and goods may
be substantial.
Privatization may also play an important role in productivity
growth. Privatization reforms have been the main trigger of firm
churning and restructuring in transition economies. The net impact
of privatization on productivity growth has varied from country to
country because transition countries have relied on different methods
of privatization and have transferred ownership at a varying pace
(figure 26) . FDI may also provide domestic firms with access to more
efficient technologies and open opportunities for entrants as suppliers,
users, or service providers to foreign affiliates.
Policies to strengthen domestic competition are working but need
to be reinforced. Since the start of the transition, the promotion of
the entry of more-productive firms and the exit of old, less-productive
firms has been a focus of public policy and has been seen as a key
driver of economic transformation. Entry has best been promoted
through the development of a positive investment climate, while the
exit of old firms has best been accomplished through the imposition
of market discipline. The imposition of market discipline-for
example, through the hardening of budget constraints, the intro duction of market competition, the enforcement of bankruptcy
procedures, and better performance measurement-forces older
firms to restructure and become more productive and compete or
else face closure. But these policies primarily target reallocation
and firm turnover, not within -firm productivity growth. For the
latter, competition policies must facilitate integration with global
I
Overview
39
FIGURE 26
Privatization Has Raised TFP Especially in Countries That Attracted FDI
a. Domestic privatization
-8 - 7 --6 - 5 -4 -3 - 2 - 1 0
1
yea rs before privatizati on
-Romania
Hungary
2
3
4
5
6
7
years after privatization
-
Ukraine -
Russian Federation
b. Firms that become foreign-owned
"'
· "'
~ .~
c::
Cl_
§
u
~
1.8
:g_
E
8 1.3
N
""0
·.;::;
Q)
ro c::
§_ ~
0.8
..c .2:1
~
ec:n
0...
19
~
:::> 0.3
~
u... "'>
>-8 -7 --6 - 5 -4 -3 -2 - 1 0
years before privatization
-
Romania
Hungary
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
years after privatization
-
Ukraine -
Russian Federation
Source: Brown and Earle 2007.
production networks, integrate domestic factor and product markets,
and strengthen the regulatory framework for service sector competition. An important new aspect of policies aimed at promoting
within-firm productivity growth is the establi shment of links
between upstream production and downstream services.
Investing in Labor and Technology
A skilled workforce is essential for firm productivity growth because
it enables firms to adopt new, better technologies. It also helps in
accelerating the reallocation of resources. Skilled workers are more
proficient at dealing with rapid change and are more flexible in moving
across jobs. In the Region, high-technology sectors are absorbing
younger and more highly skilled workers than are low-technology
sectors, but many firms are facing increasing shortages in skills. A recent
Unleashing Prosperity
40
I
World Bank report (Desai and Goldberg 2007) on the investment
climate in Russia finds that shortages of management and technical
skills in Russia have originated in deficiencies in the higher education
and public research system and underinvestment in training at the
firm level, which are common deficiencies in the Region. Training
policies may help improve the productivity of labor across the
Region. In some countries (the Czech Republic and Poland, for
example) , training policies have evolved to accommodate the
increased demand for skills. In particu lar, they have focused on
involving private training suppliers and on giving incentives for firms
to provide formal training, although evidence on the effectiveness of
such programs is patchy.
Countries need to exploit fully their fairly high human capital
stock, solid scientific base, and well-developed research institutions to
absorb and diffuse new technologies from abroad. Investing more and
more effectively in higher education and promoting technological
adoption and adaptation are key to catching up with the technological
frontier, expediting growth, and accelerating convergence. Globalizing
forces provide a substantial opportunity for countries to acquire labor
skills and technology though FDI, licensing, and imports of capital
goods. The low spending on R&D in the Region- at less than 1 percent
of GDP compared with the EU's target of 3 percent-limits the potential for technology development, while the public nature of the spending restricts efficient application. Bringing in more private partnerships
in R&D, as is the practice in more advanced countries, may help relieve
financing constraints on the absorption and dHfusion of new technologies and help any such investment generate higher returns.
Investing in Infrastructure
Improved infrastructure is important for firm productivity growth.
Training alone will not suffice to enhance the capacity of firms to
innovate. Firms in countries with access to modern telecommunica tions services, reliable electricity supply, and efficient transport links
are more productive that those operating in countries without these
advantages . In many countries in the Region, infrastructure defi ciencies negatively affect firm productivity growth. Building and
maintaining roads, ports, electricity grids, and telecommunications
networks are expensive; so, it is not surprising that poor countries
in the Region have more problems with infrastructure. Nonetheless, the challenge of modernizing infrastructure is not merely an
issue of finding financing. The origin of the difficulties in infrastructure provision in the Region is weak competition, insufficient
Overview
investments in operations and maintenance, and an inadequate
regulatory framework.
Deepening the Financial Sector
Greater financial market sophistication a ll ows firms to take on
more innovative and risky projects by offering payment services,
mob ilizing savings, and allocating financing to firms wishing to
invest. If these markets work well, they give firms of all types the
ability to seize promising investment opportunities. They reduce
the reliance of firms on internally generated cash flows and money
from informal sources, such as family and friends, giving the firms
access to external equity and facilitating entry into product markets.
Constraints to the development of the financial sector-such as entry
barriers, restrictions on foreign banks, and state ownership of
banks-hurt the financial system and its ability to increase firm productivity growth. Empirical analysis in the Region has shown that
firm productivity growth is associated with deeper financia l markets
and better access to credit from foreign and private banks.
A mu ltipronged financia l sector agenda needs to be followed to
deepen financial intermediation, promote post-entry firm growth,
and strengthen the impact of financial markets on productiv ity
growth generally. Such an agenda, which needs to be tai lored to
specific country situations, should cover the comp letion of the
privatization of state banks, the strengthening of the prudential
framework for bank and nonbank intermediation, the improvement of bank supervision, the strengthening of financial reporting
and transparency requirements for bank ownership, and the
improvement of credit information systems and collateral regimes.
Transition countries have achieved a great deal in the establish ment of banks and capital markets, but the contribution of the
financial sector to productivity and growth has been uneven. The financial sector in many countries in the Region remains underdeveloped
relative to that in other countries at the same level of income. More
recently, across the Region, there has been rapid growth in bank credit,
much of which is highly skewed toward consumer lending. Whatever
firm lending takes place is primarily concentrated in large firms. Indeed,
little credit has flowed to new or existing small and medium-sized private enterprises, even though the experience of the EU-10 and Turkey
suggests that financial deepening and the development of credit sources
located outside firms are essential in promoting expansion and
economies of scale within firms after start-up. Financial credit for rural
enterprises and farm growth is even scarcer.
41
42
Unleashing Prosperity
Going Forward: Productivity Growth Requires a
Differentiated Policy Agenda across Countries
Although all countries in the Region need to continue their reform
efforts, their priorities in public policy will depend on their development path. Thus, the primary challenge for the CIS and SEE remains
the need to address the transition legacy, while the main challenge for
the EU-10 and for Turkey is to boost innovation and productivity
growth so as to catch up with the income levels of the EU-15 (table 1).
For the CIS and SEE, the greater initial misallocation of resources
and the slower path of transition suggest that productivity gains may
still be tapped by facilitating firm restructuring, promoting the net
entry of firms, easing access to credit, and simplifying trade practices
to capture advantages from trade and greater openness.
For the EU-10, which have largely addressed the legacy of transition, the transition is over. Gains will still accrue from efficient reallocation and churning, as in even the most advanced economies.
But the bulk of productivity gains are likely to be tapped through
within-firm productivity growth by way of greater competition,
more technological imitation and innovation, better absorption of
new skills and technology, and additional development of new
products and markets. These countries are now competing in the
same markets as the more advanced European economies and are
catching up with the technological frontier. The success of the EU10 and of Turkey in moving ever closer to the income levels of the
EU -15 largely depends on how well firms and workers are able to
move rapidly into new products and markets and make production
processes more efficient.
Priorities need to be set in each country based on the relative
importance of the three channels of productivity growth at the firm
level: within-firm productivity growth, reallocation across firms and
sectors, and net entry. Increasing competition, opening the economy
to trade, and hardening budget constraints on state enterprises will
strengthen the ability of firms to take advantage of each of these
channels. But policies may be differentiated across these channels.
For instance, financial deepening and the development of sources of
credit outside firms are essential in promoting within-firm growth, as
the evidence on Turkey suggests.
However, enterprise restructuring and labor reallocation processes
might generate some labor costs. This may be mitigated through
adequate social safety nets to support workers who have been laid
off during firm restructuring (World Bank 2002; Alam et al. 2005;
Chawla , Betcherman, and Banerji 2007). In the CIS, where the
1
'
I
43
Overview
TABLE 1
Late Reformers Must Complete the Transition; Early Reformers Must Foster Innovation
Stage
Reforms
First phase of convergence: late reformers in which the initial
level of misallocation was greater and transition
reforms proceeded slowly
Address the transition legacy:
• Facilitate firm entry, restructuring, and exit by
- improving the business environment, particularly business
licensing, taxation, and legal and judicial reform
- hardening the budget constraints to close or
privatize loss-making public enterprises
• Lower the cost of, and improve access to, credit
• Accelerate the behind-the-border agenda to deepen the gains from
trade openness. particularly the liberalization of services
and the improvement of trade facilitation and logistics such as
information technology, infrastructure, port efficiency, and
customs regimes
Second phase of convergence: early reformers in which the
misallocation of resources has been substantially corrected
relative to their peers, but which are still lagging the EU-15
The second- or third-generation reform agenda: sustain productivity gains
and foster innovation as a source of growth by
• deepening bank and nonbank financial intermediation
• adopting competitive product and labor market regulations
• improving the quality of human capital (tertiary education)
• investing in knowledge (R&D) and new technologies (ICT)
'
Source: Compiled by the authors.
challenge of restructuring is still relevant and poverty and inequality
remain concerns, providing adequate levels of socia l assistance must
be a policy priority. In the EU-10, which can afford more generous
safety nets, formal unemployment insurance schemes are being
expanded and provide the best way to protect workers displaced by
enterprise restructuring. The guaranteed employment, retirement
security, and consumer subsidies of the former socialist systems
have become obsolete. In many instances, these were fiscally unaffordable, as countries sought to balance expenditure demands with
revenues . The best method for protecting the most vulnerable
workers involves two steps: removal of the barriers to the entry of
new enterprises, thereby creating additional employment opportunities, and the targeting of social assistance on those workers whose
skills and experience mean that they are less likely to be employed
in the new enterprises.
Conclusion
The countries of the Region have shown strong productivity growth
during 1999-2005 that has driven up living standards and reduced
poverty. Both domestic and globalizing factors have contributed to
this, but significant challenges remain in sustaining productivity
I
Unleashing Prosperity
44
growth. Public policies can play an important role but they need to be
carefully tailored to each country's situation.
Notes
The bibliography is in the report, Unleashing Prosperity (forthcoming) .
1. The low income CIS countries (low-CIS or CIS-low) are Armenia,
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
Azerbaijan, Georgia, the Kyrgyz Republic, Moldova, Tajikistan, and
Uzbekistan.
These data have been collected by independent researchers Eric
J. Bartelsman, David J. Brown, John S. Earle, and Stefano Scarpetta.
Earlier sets of the data have been used by these researchers in analyses in published papers.
The TFP estimates tend to be controversial because of measurement
errors. This is particularly true in transition economies, where the
quality of the capital stock series remains problematic. Nevertheless,
robustness tests applied to the capital stock series ensure that the relative changes indicated in productivity patterns across countries and
over time are reliable .
The analysis of productivity patterns in manufacturing and service
industries focuses on a group of countries (the Czech Republic, Estonia,
Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, the Slovak Republic, and Slovenia)
for which harmonized industry-level deflators are available.
A cautionary note is in order on comparisons between productivity
growth decompositions across countries. The decomposition of aggregate
productivity growth might yield somewhat different results depending on
the time horizon (three-year rolling periods or five-year rolling periods) .
The entry component tends to be larger over longer horizons because
more of the entry effect is a within effect over time. Also, the within and
entry terms may be influenced by noise and imperfect deflators that might
lead to an upward bias in absolute magnitudes. Nevertheless, the broad
trends across countries are maintained. Brown, Earle, and Telegdy (2007)
correct for this last problem by comparing the productivity of entrants
with the sectoral weighted average for the same year.
A negative entry effect results if the entrants are less productive than the
average incumbents; this does not necessarily point to a lack of
dynamism. In vibrant and technologically advanced sectors, many highrisk entrants may exhibit low average productivity, and market selection
weeds out all but the most productive entrants, which will eventually
overtake incumbents.
UNLEASHING PROSPERITY
PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH IN EASTERN EUROPE AND THE FORMER SOVIET UNION
Many countries of Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union have seen an economic resurgence
over the past five years, especially in the Com monwealth of Independent States. Both domestic
and global factors have contributed to the productivity su rg e and helped to narrow the productivity
gap between lower and higher income countries. This report analyzes the policy-driven
improvements in prod uctivity in the reg ion , usi ng multiple data sets and econometric techn iques.
PRODUCT
Unleashing Prosperity: Productivity
Growth in Eastern Europe and Former
Soviet Union {ISBN: 978-0-8213-7279-1)
STOCK#
PRICE
017279
US$35
QTY
SUBTOTAL
Subtotal
• Geographic discounts apply- up to 75% depending on ship-to
country. See http://publications.worldbank.org/discounts.
Geographic discount*
••Within the US, charges on prepaid orders are $8.00 per order.
Institutional customers using a purchase order will be charged actual
shipping costs. Outside of the US, customers have the option to
choose between non-trackable airmail delivery (US$7 per order plus
US$6 per item) and trackable couriered airmail delivery (US$16. 50
per order plus US$8 per item). Non-trackable delivery may take 4-6
weeks, trackable delivery takes about 2 weeks.
Shipping and Handling**
Total US$
ORDER ONLINE AT www.worldbank.org/publications
Customers in the Un ited States
Complete this form and mail it to World Bank
Publications, P.O. Box 960, Herndon VA 20172-0969 or
fax it to 703-661-1501 . To charge by credit card , either
order online or call 800-645-724 7 or 703-661-1580.
Customers outside the Un ited States
Contact you r loca l distributor fo r information on prices in
local currency and payment terms (http://publications.
worldbank.org/booksellers) . If you do not have a distributor,
order online or fax th is form to +1 -703-661 -1501 or mail it to
World Bank Publications, P.O. Box 960, Herndon VA 201720969, USA.
MAILING ADDRESS
METHOD OF PAYMENT
Name ________________
D
Charge my:
D
Organization _______ _ __ _ _ _
Address ________ _______
City _ _ _ ____ State_ Zip _ __
Visa
D
Mastercard
D American Express
Name ______________
Card# _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ __
Signature ______________
Exp. Date_ _ _ _ _ __ _ _ _ _ _ __
Country _ _ _ _ _ _ _ __ _ _ _ __
Phone _ _ _ _ _ _ _ Fax ______
Email _____________ _ __
D Enclosed is my check in US$ drawn on a U.S. bank and
made payable to the World Bank.
TO ORDER
World Bank Publications
www.wo rldbank.org/publications
By phone : +1-703-661-1580 or 800-645-7247 •
By fax: +1-703-661 -1 501 •
By mail: P.O. Box 960, Herndon, VA 20172-0960, USA
Questions? E-mail us at
[email protected]
AVAILABLE AT BETTER BOOKSTORES
~~
THANK YOU FOR YOUR ORDER
WORLD BANK
Publications
I
The reference of choice on development
I
Errata
The following are corrections in the Overview.
p. 3, line 7: "US$300 in Tajikistan" should read "US$950 in Tajikistan."
p. 3, lines 7-8: "US$8 ,000 in Poland" should read "US$ 17,991 in
Slovenia over 1999-2005 (international US$) ."
p . 10, line L "from US$5 ,807" should read "from US$5,903 ."
p. 10, line 2, "US$8,398" should read "US$8,4 ll."
p. 10, line 5, "nearly 400 milUon" should read "ove r 400 million."