Shared Prosperity: Paving the
Way in Europe and Central Asia
EUROPE AND CENTRAL ASIA STUDIES
Europe and Central Asia Studies feature analytical reports on main challenges
and opportunities faced by countries in the region, with the aim to inform a
broad policy debate. Titles in this regional flagship series undergo extensive
internal and external review prior to publication.
Shared Prosperity: Paving the
Way in Europe and Central Asia
Maurizio Bussolo and Luis F. Lopez-Calva
© 2014 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank
1818 H Street NW
Washington, DC 20433
Telephone: 202-473-1000
Internet: www.worldbank.org
Some rights reserved.
1234
17 16 15 14
This work is a product of the staff of The World Bank with external contributions. The findings,
interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this work do not necessarily reflect the views of The World
Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not
guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and
other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World
Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.
Nothing herein shall constitute or be considered to be a limitation upon or waiver of the privileges and
immunities of The World Bank, all of which are specifically reserved.
Rights and Permissions
This work is available under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 IGO license (CC BY 3.0 IGO) http://
creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/IGO. Under the Creative Commons Attribution license, you are
free to copy, distribute, transmit, and adapt this work, including for commercial purposes, under the
following conditions:
Attribution—Please cite the work as follows: Bussolo, Maurizio, and Luis F. Lopez-Calva.
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia. Washington, DC: World Bank.
doi:10.1596/978-1-4648-0230-0. License: Creative Commons Attribution CC BY 3.0 IGO
Translations—If you create a translation of this work, please add the following disclaimer along with the
attribution: This translation was not created by The World Bank and should not be considered an official
World Bank translation. The World Bank shall not be liable for any content or error in this translation.
Adaptations—If you create an adaptation of this work, please add the following disclaimer along with
the attribution: This is an adaptation of an original work by The World Bank. Responsibility for the views
and opinions expressed in the adaptation rests solely with the author or authors of the adaptation and
are not endorsed by The World Bank.
Third-party content—The World Bank does not necessarily own each component of the content
contained within the work. The World Bank therefore does not warrant that the use of any third-partyowned individual component or part contained in the work will not infringe on the rights of those third
parties. The risk of claims resulting from such infringement rests solely with you. If you wish to reuse
a component of the work, it is your responsibility to determine whether permission is needed for that
reuse and to obtain permission from the copyright owner. Examples of components can include, but
are not limited to, tables, figures, or images.
All queries on rights and licenses should be addressed to the Publishing and Knowledge Division,
The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-522-2625; e-mail: pubrights
@worldbank.org.
ISBN (paper): 978-1-4648-0230-0
ISBN (electronic): 978-1-4648-0267-6
DOI: 10.1596/978-1-4648-0230-0
Cover and interior design: Debra Naylor, Naylor Design, Inc.
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication data has been requested.
Contents
Foreword . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
ix
Acknowledgments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
xi
Abbreviations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
xiii
Executive Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
1
What Is the Trend in Shared Prosperity in the Region? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
How Is Shared Prosperity Achieved? What Are Its Determinants? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Who Are the People in the Bottom 40 in the Region?. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
What Can We Do to Boost Shared Prosperity? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
References. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
2
3
4
4
5
1. Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
7
Notes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
References. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
10
10
2. Shared Prosperity in Europe and Central Asia:
Recent Trends . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
Note . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
References. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
19
19
3. The Drivers of Shared Prosperity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
An Asset-Based Framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Labor Market Income, Nonmarket Income, and Growth Incidence . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Notes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
References. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
21
27
38
39
4. Structural and Cyclical Variables within the Framework . . . . . . . . 41
Periods of Steady Growth and Periods of Economic Cycles . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Economic Structure and Growth Opportunities among the Bottom 40 . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Annex 4A. Income Growth Rates, the Bottom 40 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Annex 4B. The Social Accounting Matrix Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Notes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
References. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
42
50
61
62
63
63
v
vi ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
5. The Sustainability Dimension . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65
Economic Sustainability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Social Sustainability. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Environmental Sustainability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Note . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
References. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
65
68
69
73
73
6. Policy Links . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
75
Macroeconomic Management . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Tax Structure and Fiscal Spending . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Government Institutional Capacity for Efficient Service Delivery. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Risk Management . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Enabling Well-Functioning Markets and a Favorable Business Environment . . . . . . . . . .
Using the Policy Matrix to Design Policies in a Different Way . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Notes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
78
79
81
83
84
86
87
References. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
87
7. Concluding Remarks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89
Appendix The Bottom 40 Indicator in Context . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91
References. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
93
Boxes
2.1
3.1
3.2
5.1
5.2
5.3
6.1
Comparing the Bottom 40 and the Top 60 in the Microdata . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
The Asset-Based Approach: The Stories of Mariam and Emre . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Constrained Social Capital and the Bottom 40: The Case of Displaced
Persons . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
The Concentration of Wealth in Europe and Central Asia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
The Sustainability of Shared Prosperity: The Roma and Gender Equality. . . . . . .
Converting Natural Assets into Bottom 40 Income: The Environmental
Services Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Shared Prosperity, Anonymity, and Mobility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
16
24
26
66
70
72
83
Figures
2.1
2.2
2.3
2.4
2.5
Rates of Growth of the Bottom 40 Were Heterogeneous, but, on Average,
Good across Europe and Central Asia in 2005–10 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Shared Prosperity in Europe and Central Asia Has Achieved Results Close
to Those of the Top Performers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
In Terms of Shared Prosperity, the Largest Countries Have Performed
Particularly Well in Europe and Central Asia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
In Latin America and the Caribbean, Europe and Central Asia, and East Asia
and the Pacific, Income Growth among the Bottom 40 Has Been Stronger
Than Mean Income Growth . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Growth of GDP Alone Does Not Explain the Growth in Bottom 40 Incomes . . . .
12
13
13
14
15
●
Contents
B2.1.1 Bottom 40 versus Top 60: During the Steady Growth Period, Growth Rates
Were Similar for the Two Groups . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
B2.1.2 Bottom 40 versus Top 60: During the Cyclical Period, the Bottom 40
Outperformed the Top 60 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
2.6
Growth Incidence Curves Show the Diverse Growth Patterns in Europe and
Central Asia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
2.7
Some Countries Face a Greater Challenge in Closing the Income Gap
between the Bottom 40 and the Top 60 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
3.1
The Asset-Based Approach and the Joint Determination of Growth and
Distribution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
3.2
Human Capital Is a Key Asset in Income Generation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
3.3
Household Dependency on Pensions Tends to Be High in the Region . . . . . . . .
3.4
Social Assistance Is an Important Source of Income for the Bottom 40 in
Selected Countries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
3.5
The Tertiary Education Gap between the Top 60 and the Bottom 40 Is Large
in All Countries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
3.6
Fewer People in the Top 60 Relative to the Bottom 40 Have Only Primary
Education . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
3.7
People in the Bottom 40 Are More Likely Than People in the Top 60 to
Be Unemployed . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
3.8
Households in the Bottom 40 Have More Dependents . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
3.9
Better Asset Holdings and More Intense Use of Assets Are Associated
with Stronger Growth among the Bottom 40 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
3.10 The Aged Dependency Ratio and Income Growth among the Bottom 40
Show a Negative Relation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
3.11 Differences in Asset Holdings and in Asset Use Help Explain Differences in
Bottom 40 Performance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
3.12 The High Dependency on Transfers of the Bottom 40 in Romania, 2007–10 . . . .
3.13 Income Growth among the Bottom 40 in Tajikistan in 2005–10 Was Driven
by Market Incomes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
4.1
Different Drivers Are Affecting Income Growth among the Bottom 40 in
Periods of Steady Growth and Periods of Economic Cycles . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
4.2
In Periods of Steady Growth, Structural Variables, Such as Demography,
Are Important for Shared Prosperity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
4.3
The Baltic States Were More Affected by the 2008–09 Global Financial Crisis . .
4.4
Large Adjustments in Tradable Sectors Accompany Crises and Economic
Cycles . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
4.5
Countercyclical Policies Can Potentially Protect Incomes among the
Bottom 40 during a Crisis. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
4.6
Shifts toward Manufacturing (and Services) and Increases in Participation
Are Associated with Stronger Growth among the Bottom 40. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
4.7
GDP Growth and Income Growth of the Bottom 40 Are More Strongly
Associated during Steady Growth Than during Cyclical Periods . . . . . . . . . . . . .
4.8
Income Multipliers Highlight the Wide Range in Structure in the Economies
of Europe and Central Asia, Part 1 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
4.9
Income Multipliers Highlight the Wide Range in Structure in the Economies
of Europe and Central Asia, Part 2 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
16
17
18
19
22
28
29
30
30
31
32
33
35
36
36
37
38
43
44
47
48
49
49
50
54
55
vii
viii ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
4.10
Backward and Forward Links, Selected Countries, Europe and
Central Asia, 2007 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
B5.1.1 Average Age of Billionaires, by World Region, 2005–13. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
5.1
Most Important Factor in Succeeding in Life, Europe and Central Asia, 2010 . . .
5.2
CO2 Emissions, Europe and Central Asia versus Rest of the World, 2009 . . . . . .
6.1
Labor Market Incentives Can Be Curbed by Taxation and Benefits . . . . . . . . . . .
6.2
The Bottom 40 Gap in Accessing Financial Assets Relative to the Top 60 . . . . . .
58
67
69
71
80
86
Map
B5.1.1 Average Net Worth per Billionaire, World, 2013, U.S. dollars. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
67
Tables
B3.1.1 The Asset-Based Approach: The Stories of Mariam and Emre . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
4.1
Different Bottom 40 Income Growth, Similar GDP Growth: Czech Republic
and Lithuania, 2004–08 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
4.2
Similar Bottom 40 Income Growth, Different GDP Growth: Kazakhstan
and Kyrgyz Republic, circa 2000–08 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
4.3
Similar Bottom 40 Income Growth, Different GDP Growth: Selected Countries,
2005–10 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
4.4
Economic Structure, Selected Countries, Europe and Central Asia, 2007 . . . . . .
4A.1 Income Growth Rates among the Bottom 40, circa 2004–08 and 2005–10 . . . . .
4B.1 The Schematic Social Accounting Matrix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
B5.1.1 Number of Billionaires, by World Region, 2005–13 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
6.1
Policy Matrix for Implementing the Asset-Based Approach within a Shared
Prosperity Framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
6.2
The Asset-Based Approach and Macroeconomic Management:
Macroeconomic Fundamentals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
6.3
The Asset-Based Approach and Fiscal Systems: Social Assistance Policies . . . . .
6.4
The Asset-Based Approach and Institutional Capacity: Service Delivery . . . . . . .
6.5
The Asset-Based Approach and Risk-Coping Mechanisms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
6.6
The Asset-Based Approach, Well-Functioning Markets, and the Business
Climate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
25
44
45
46
52
61
62
66
76
78
80
82
84
87
Foreword
The world has come a long way in its fight against extreme poverty. In low-income
and middle-income countries, the proportion of people living in extreme poverty
has declined by more than half in two decades, from 43 percent in 1990
to 21 percent in 2010. At the same time, increased income levels have enabled
millions of people to join the middle class, particularly in Southeast Asia and Latin
America. In 1970, developing economies accounted for 20 percent of world gross
domestic product (GDP), whereas in 2014 they account for 34 percent. Many economists foresee this positive trajectory continuing unabated, bringing developing
economies’ share of global GDP growth close to 50 percent within a generation.
Economic prosperity has never been more evenly distributed across the globe
than it is today.
Yet, economic prosperity has not been shared with everyone. Within countries,
millions of people have been left behind as their incomes grow slowly, stagnate,
or, in some cases, decline—while the prosperity gap between the wealthiest and
the poorest continues to expand.
Most countries in Europe and Central Asia have done well at increasing the
incomes of the bottom 40 percent, which grew by an average of 3.8 percent from
2005 to 2010, faster than the income growth for the population overall. Even
though these gains proved resilient to the 2008–09 global financial crisis, the
region now stands at a crossroads. The crisis that abruptly halted a prolonged
period of strong economic growth in the first decade of the 21st century has been
followed by a tepid recovery, leaving many ECA economies at risk of economic
stagnation. Short- to medium-term growth forecasts remain grim, with fiscal
austerity measures and stifled investment fueling growing frustration and social
unrest—particularly among the young, unemployed, and socially excluded. To
prevent the past economic gains from being reversed, a better understanding of
the interplay between equity and growth is essential for development practitioners, policy makers, and governments.
The World Bank has recently renewed its strategy, establishing two overarching
goals: eliminating extreme poverty and boosting shared prosperity. The latter
objective, which is the focus of this report, aims to increase the welfare of the
bottom 40 percent of the distribution in every country. Long-term sustainability of
social progress is also an important consideration in pursuing both of these
overarching goals. This commitment of the World Bank to the advancement of the
ix
x
●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
least well off is not new. The Bank has consistently worked to ensure that economic
growth is shared widely, and that benefits the lower-income groups.
Forty years ago, a group of World Bank economists first highlighted the need
to view distributional objectives jointly with growth objectives and indeed to
express these objectives “dynamically in terms of desired rates of growth of
income of different groups” (Chenery et al. 1974, 38). Their quest reflected an
early vision of what would eventually become an integral part of the World Bank
Group’s strategy: fostering income growth of the bottom 40 percent of the population in every country.
The information and data available in 1974 were far less comprehensive and
advanced than what we have at our disposal today, which currently include more
than 4,000 surveys of households and firms across 192 countries. We now have
data on a wide range of topics such as living standards, demographic characteristics and health conditions, financial situations, constraints to growth, and investment environments. This wealth of data helps to advance economic theory and to
better identify and evaluate the impact of economic shocks and policies.
This report aims to propose a way to think and structure a debate about shared
prosperity in Europe and Central Asia. It is about better understanding the conditions and policies that lead to more systematic income growth for the bottom
40 percent and identifying policies and investments that can help countries
accelerate income growth for the bottom 40 percent. In this endeavor, the report
seeks to provide a view of shared prosperity that reconciles equity and growth,
while building a bridge between macroeconomic and microeconomic drivers of
income growth among the bottom 40 percent in different parts of the region.
Achieving shared prosperity may be an enormous challenge, but it is one that we
are determined to meet. We hope this report can help pave the way forward.
Laura Tuck
Vice President, Europe and Central Asia Region
The World Bank
Reference
Chenery, Hollis Burnley, Richard Jolly, Montek S. Ahluwalia, C. L. Bell, and John H. Duloy.
1974. Redistribution with Growth: Policies to Improve Income Distribution in Developing Countries in the Context of Economic Growth. World Bank Research Series. Washington, DC: World Bank; New York: Oxford University Press.
Acknowledgments
This report has been written by a team led by Maurizio Bussolo and Luis F. LopezCalva. The core team members are Joâo Pedro Azevedo, Lidia Ceriani, Giorgia
Demarchi, Dobrina Gogova, Mariam Lomaia, José Montes, Georgi Lyudmilov
Panterov, and Sara Signorelli. Robert Zimmermann edited the report. Invaluable
data analysis and support were provided by the Europe and Central Asia Team for
Statistical Development, led by Joâo Pedro Azevedo.
The team benefited from comments and inputs prepared by a support team
and sector focal points, a group comprising Omar Arias, David Bernstein,
Joanna P. de Berry, Zeljko Bogetic, Kimberly Blair Bolch, Joanne Catherine Gaskell,
Alvaro Gonzalez, Kseniya Lvovsky, Grzegorz Peszko, and Siddharth Sharma.
The work has been conducted under the direction of Hans Timmer and
Carolina Sanchez-Paramo.
The peer reviewers were James Foster, Martin Raiser, and Ana Revenga, who
provided excellent comments to improve the report. The team received useful
comments from Kulsum Ahmed, Paloma Anos-Casero, Gerardo Corrochano,
Kirsten Hommann, Elisabeth Huybens, Roumeen Islam, Henry Kerali, Andrew C.
Kircher, Craig Meisner, Alberto Rodriguez, Pedro Rodriguez, Indhira Santos, Carlos
Silva-Jauregui, and Marina Wes. The team also benefited from internal discussions
with the members of the poverty team at the Poverty Reduction and
Economic Management Sector in the Europe and Central Asia Vice Presidency, as
well as with many colleagues during the presentations at the “Shared Prosperity
Clinics,” which were held while this report was being prepared.
xi
Abbreviations
EU
GDP
GIC
SAM
European Union
gross domestic product
growth incidence curve
social accounting matrix
Country Codes
ALB
ARM
BGR
BLR
CZE
EST
GEO
HRV
HUN
KAZ
KGZ
KSV
LTU
LVA
MDA
MKD
MNE
POL
ROM
RUS
SRB
SVK
SVN
TJK
TUR
UKR
Albania
Armenia
Bulgaria
Belarus
Czech Republic
Estonia
Georgia
Croatia
Hungary
Kazakhstan
Kyrgyz Republic
Kosovo
Lithuania
Latvia
Moldova
Macedonia, former Yugoslav Republic of
Montenegro
Poland
Romania
Russian Federation
Serbia
Slovak Republic
Slovenia
Tajikistan
Turkey
Ukraine
Note: All dollar amounts are U.S. dollars ($) unless otherwise indicated.
xiii
Executive Summary
The World Bank has recently identified two strategic goals: ending extreme poverty and boosting shared prosperity. The two goals should be achieved in a sustainable way. Here, sustainability is meant in a broad sense, that is, the economic,
social, and environmental dimensions are to be considered together.
The present report focuses on the second goal: shared prosperity. Boosting
shared prosperity has been defined as “expanding the size of the pie continuously
and sharing it in such a way that the welfare of those at the lower end of the income
distribution rises as quickly as possible” (World Bank 2013, 21). Income growth
among the bottom 40 percent of the income distribution in the population (the
bottom 40) is the indicator used to measure shared prosperity.
The report focuses on the bottom 40 in the Europe and Central Asia region and
addresses the following key questions:
1. What has been the trend in shared prosperity in the region? The answer is fairly
positive, on average. However, the outcomes have also been heterogeneous,
and the sustainability is uncertain.
2. What are the determinants of shared prosperity, and how is shared prosperity
achieved? This report proposes a framework to answer this two-part question.
Within the framework, macroeconomic drivers (aggregate growth, factor
returns, and relative prices) and microeconomic characteristics (particularly
assets owned by individuals) matter.
1
2 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
3. Who are the people in the bottom 40 in the region? The answer varies by
country and by period. A preliminary finding is that the working-age population among the bottom 40 in the majority of countries has accumulated relatively less human capital. Additionally, because of lower labor force participation rates and higher unemployment rates, the bottom 40 uses its human
capital less intensively.
4. What can we do to boost shared prosperity, and what does a shared prosperity
focus mean for the disparate operations and advisory activities carried out by
the World Bank or the policy reforms adopted by governments? This is a challenge reserved for the specific application of the framework within countries.
It seems clear, however, that the application of the framework will encourage
a more balanced approach to development policy. This new approach will
combine the quest for economic growth with a concern for equity because it
recognizes that, at least in the long run, these reinforce each other.
Let’s consider these questions in more detail.
What Is the Trend in Shared Prosperity in the Region?
The substantial economic growth experienced in Europe and Central Asia appears
to have been accompanied by positive performance in shared prosperity in recent
years. The incomes of households in the bottom 40 have expanded 20 percent
more rapidly than national average incomes. In the region during the period from
about 2005 to 2010, the average income among the bottom 40 increased by
3.8 percent. This is a good performance relative to other regions at a similar level
of income, such as Latin America and the Caribbean, which achieved a rate of
4.9 percent.
Nonetheless, behind the regional average, there is a large heterogeneity.
Between 2005 and 2010, a Belarussian, Polish, Russian, or Slovak household in the
lower segment of the income distribution enjoyed an income growth rate of
around 8 percent or more a year. At an annual average growth of over 11 percent,
the incomes of the Slovaks in the bottom 40 rose by 70 percent during these five
years. However, less well off people in Latvia, Turkey, and Ukraine experienced an
average yearly increase of only 5 percent or less, almost half the rate of the same
group among the best performers. Meanwhile, people in Croatia, Georgia, the
former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, and Serbia sustained losses of 1 percent
or more annually.
The sustainability of this recent income growth among the bottom 40 is unclear
given that it appears to have been driven by transfers, not by an expansion in factor accumulation, returns, or productivity. In 2010, households in the bottom 40 in
Croatia, Moldova, Serbia, and Ukraine were receiving, on average, 30 percent or
more of their incomes in the form of pensions, while, among corresponding households, the average income share accounted for by social assistance was around
10 percent in Albania, Croatia, Kosovo, FYR Macedonia, Moldova, and Turkey.
Executive Summary
How Is Shared Prosperity Achieved? What Are Its
Determinants?
One way of answering these questions is by seeking to explain the uneven performance across the region. Clearly, overall economic growth is an important determinant, but what is behind the differences in income growth among the bottom
40 even in countries with similar rates of growth in gross domestic product (GDP)?
This is the case, for example, of Georgia and Poland, each with GDP growth of
about 5 percent, but with the bottom 40 experiencing a contraction in incomes in
Georgia and a strong expansion in Poland. Do the characteristics of individuals
and households in the bottom 40 determine their capacity to benefit from and
participate in overall growth? Or do macroeconomic drivers, such as the terms of
trade, skill premiums, or overall shifts in productivity, shape a specific pattern of
growth and growth incidence in favor of or against the bottom 40? An initial
answer to these questions is that both the level of growth and the incidence of
growth—that is, the income growth at each percentile of the distribution—matter
for shared prosperity.
This report proposes an analytical framework to help us understand how micro
characteristics and macro drivers affect shared prosperity jointly. The cornerstone
of the framework is an asset-based approach. The level and accumulation of
the assets people own—human capital, physical and financial assets, and social and
natural capital—influence income generation as does the intensity with which these
assets are used and the returns associated with the assets. In addition to market
income, public and private transfers can account for a significant share of the total
income of individuals. Households (and firms) make many important economic
decisions affecting the accumulation and the use of the assets of their members.
But, most of the time, variables outside the control of households govern the
income generated from these assets. For example, the returns to education—a key
variable affecting the investment in and income from human capital—result from
the interaction of both the supply of and the demand for skilled workers. And the
demand for the labor of these workers depends on technology and the availability
of other factors. All these variables are determined at the macro level and are taken
as a given by individual households (and firms). Our proposed framework combines
both (1) microeconomic decisions and the resulting endowments of the various
types of assets at the individual level and (2) macroeconomic variables, such as the
returns to assets. These two sets of variables jointly determine shared prosperity.
The framework constitutes the report’s most important contribution because it
overcomes the disadvantages of two narrower approaches frequently followed in
the past. The first narrower approach is a standard macro top-down approach that
assumes growth is fundamentally determined by aggregate variables and that,
once growth has been activated, everybody will be lifted or everybody can be lifted
through redistribution. The second is the bottom-up microeconomic approach
according to which aggregate growth is the weighted average of the productive
efforts of micro units such as households and firms.
The framework can accommodate a variety of assets. For illustrative purposes,
this report describes how natural capital and social capital might be included.
● 3
4 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
Standard markets do not exist for these types of assets; so, the channels through
which these assets influence shared prosperity do not encompass prices. For
example, through social norms or the incidence of discrimination, social capital
can impact income generation by affecting the way individuals use their assets. An
example is the gap between male and female labor force participation: although
improving, female labor force participation is lagging among the bottom 40 in
many countries of the region.
Who Are the People in the Bottom 40 in the Region?
The evidence available on Europe and Central Asia confirms that households in
the bottom 40 tend to have a smaller stock of human capital as measured by educational attainment. In addition, the returns to education tend to be lower among
the bottom 40 with respect to the top 60 percent of the income distribution (the
top 60), indicating differences in productivity that may be related to the quality of
education received by the two groups. Market segmentation may also account for
this difference. There is evidence that workers in the bottom 40 have fewer employment opportunities outside agriculture, but this varies across countries. People in
the bottom 40 are also affected by lower rates of labor force participation and
higher levels of unemployment. On average, households in the poorer segment
of the distribution depend more heavily on nonmarket income flows, especially
public transfers.
In terms of demographic characteristics, each employed member of households in the bottom 40 in Europe and Central Asia must provide for six other
individuals on average; the corresponding number of individuals in the top 60 is
four. There is evidence that ethnic minorities, such as the Roma, tend to be overrepresented in the bottom 40.
What Can We Do to Boost Shared Prosperity?
This is the most difficult question. The answer is beyond the scope of this report,
but the report suggests a path to the answer. In the policy realm, it highlights three
main issues. First, among policy makers, adopting the goal of shared prosperity
implies a major shift toward the simultaneous pursuit of economic growth and
equity. Likewise, it implies a shift away from an agenda of maximizing growth without attention to who contributes to it or who benefits from it and also away from a
program of redistribution that overlooks incentives. Policy makers are becoming
aware that, despite a positive effect on the average income of their citizens, many
macro policies sometimes produce such a deterioration in the welfare of specific
groups that the policies become socially undesirable and politically untenable.
Similarly, poverty reduction policies designed to target specific individuals and
households may have macroeconomic (mostly fiscal) consequences. Thus, the
selection and implementation of economic policies require a careful assessment
of the effects both on aggregate economy-wide variables—such as employment,
inflation, or aggregate growth—and on income distribution and poverty.
Executive Summary
Second, the time frame for implementing and evaluating policies is crucial. In
the short run, policy can influence the intensity of the use of assets, transfers, and
prices, which are also affected by cyclical conditions, such as unemployment, inflation, and the fiscal capacity of governments to respond to shocks. But only in the
long run can asset accumulation be significantly altered. The policies that can help
sustain the long-term drivers of income growth among the bottom 40 are therefore different from the interventions that provide a buffer from an economic crisis
or other type of short-term shock.
Third, a great challenge in building an integrated macro-micro growth-cumequity set of policies is the reconciliation of macro- and microdata. Standard macrodata sets, such as those supplied by a central bank or national income accounts,
can sometimes provide assessments on economic progress that are opposed to
the assessments produced on the basis of microdata sets, such as household surveys, labor force surveys, population censuses, and community-level surveys. Differences in the levels of economic variables—for example, between consumption
or income per capita measured through household surveys or national accounts—
can still be explained; however, if the trends differ across countries or groups, the
issue becomes more complicated.
Shared prosperity is not a new area of attention for the World Bank. (Indeed, in
the mid-1970s, Chenery et al. [1974, 38] were already talking about “desired rates
of growth of income of different groups” and were referring specifically to the
poorest 40 percent.) But achieving this goal sustainably requires changing the way
we think about and support development in terms of analysis, measurement, data,
and policies. The task ahead is challenging, but it is within reach.
References
Chenery, Hollis Burnley, Richard Jolly, Montek S. Ahluwalia, C. L. Bell, and John H. Duloy.
1974. Redistribution with Growth: Policies to Improve Income Distribution in Developing Countries in the Context of Economic Growth. World Bank Research Series. Washington, DC: World Bank; New York: Oxford University Press.
World Bank. 2013. “The World Bank Group Goals: End Extreme Poverty and Promote
Shared Prosperity.” World Bank, Washington, DC. http://www.worldbank.org/content
/dam/Worldbank/document/WB-goals2013.pdf.
● 5
Introduction
In line with a long tradition of commitment to inclusive and sustainable development, the World Bank has recently renewed its strategy to help countries sustainably raise the living standards of their citizens at the lower end of the income distribution. During the 2013 Bank-Fund Annual Meetings, the Bank announced the
twin goals of ending extreme poverty and boosting shared prosperity. The first
goal is to reduce the share of people living on less than $1.25 a day to fewer than
3 percent globally by 2030. The developing world has cut this extreme poverty
rate in half since 1990, and the goal of eradicating poverty is now within reach. The
second goal is to foster income growth within every country among the bottom
40 percent of the population (the bottom 40). Developing countries have also
been remarkably successful in accelerating overall growth over the last two decades. Average structural growth in gross domestic product (GDP) has doubled,
from 3 percent annually in the beginning of the 1990s to more than 6 percent in
2014. It is paramount that people at the lower end of the income distribution participate in and benefit from continued strong economic progress.
This report focuses on the second goal—boosting shared prosperity—because
it is especially relevant for Europe and Central Asia. Many middle-income countries in the region have been successful in the past, but are struggling to maintain
a rapid pace of equitable growth. The second goal also deserves special attention
because there is little understanding of or experience in influencing the growth
prospects of the bottom 40 within countries, even if income growth among the
bottom 40 is not a completely new area of attention for the Bank. Indeed, in the
mid-1970s, Chenery et al. (1974, 38) were already writing about “desired rates of
7
8 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
growth of income of different groups” in reference specifically to the bottom 40.
The current renewed focus, however, provides the opportunity to develop a more
comprehensive and more empirical understanding of the drivers of income growth
among the bottom 40 and to unveil new policy options. We are still at the start of
this fresh agenda: we require more and better data, deeper analysis, and extensive
policy discussions. This report is meant to jump-start that work in the Europe and
Central Asia region.1
A first important observation is that overall GDP growth is not necessarily a
good proxy for income growth among the bottom 40 and that a favorable macroeconomic environment does not automatically translate into good growth prospects for people at the lower end of the income distribution. Recent developments in Georgia are a case in point. The Georgian economy grew at an
A focus
average 5 percent a year or more during the first decade of this century,
accompanied by important reforms and the promotion of private sector
on shared prosperity
investment. The country continues to grow steadily even in the aftercan unveil new
math of the 2008–09 global financial crisis, after recovering from a year
of economic contraction. Foreign investment flows regularly into the
policy options for
economy, attracted by a healthy business climate and an extraordinary
inclusive and
record in the doing business indicators.2 However, people in the bottom
sustainable
40 in Georgia have experienced limited and even negative growth
throughout
most of this same period. To address this problem, the governgrowth.
ment and civil society in the country are engaged in rethinking the growth
model to make it more inclusive in a productive way.
However, there are also many examples of more rapid income growth among
the bottom 40 than among the top 60 percent of the income distribution in the
population (the top 60). In the whole of Europe and Central Asia in 2005–10,
income growth among the bottom 40 outpaced income growth among the top 60
by an average of 0.8 percentage points annually. As a result, the bottom 40 in
Europe and Central Asia generally did quite well during the period, compared with
corresponding groups in other regions.
A second key observation is that income growth among the bottom 40 cannot
be understood in isolation from macroeconomic developments. Though there are
differences across countries, the correlation between income growth among the
bottom 40 and macroeconomic variables is significant and positive. This was apparent during the long boom before the 2008 crisis, and it also emerged during the
cyclical developments surrounding the crisis. During boom periods, the bottom 40
benefits from macroeconomic drivers as employment opportunities expand and
overall increases in productivity translate into rising wages. During recessions,
income growth among the bottom 40 drops as unemployment increases and
wages soften, while social safety nets and policy responses determine the degree
of mitigation. The terms of trade and, in general, relative prices are, apart from
wages and social transfers, major macroeconomic transmission channels.
On the basis of these two observations, this report proposes a framework that
combines macroeconomic drivers and microeconomic characteristics. The framework enables us to analyze the components of income growth among the bottom
40. The framework goes beyond the standard macro approach and micro tools. A
standard macro approach takes a top-down view of the growth process. This view
Introduction
● 9
assumes that growth is fundamentally determined by aggregate variables and that,
once growth has been activated, everybody will be lifted or everybody can be lifted
through redistribution. The microeconomic tools, on the other hand, follow a purely
bottom-up approach. This approach postulates that macro growth is the weighted
average of the productive efforts of micro units (households and firms). In reality,
income growth among specific groups is simultaneously driven by individual characteristics (schooling, location, employment, access to financial systems, the productivity of natural resources) and macroeconomic drivers (wage growth, skill premiums, the business cycle). Our framework reveals large differences between the
characteristics of individuals in the bottom 40 and the characteristics of individuals
in the top 60 within the countries of Europe and Central Asia, while also acknowledging the key role of variables outside the control of individuals.
A great challenge in building this integrated macro-micro framework is the
reconciliation of macro- and microdata. Standard macrodata sets—including those
from a central bank or national income accounts—can, at times, provide assessments of economic progress that contrast with assessments gauged on the basis
of microdata sets, such as household surveys, labor force surveys, population censuses, and community-level surveys. Differences in economic variables—for instance, between consumption or income per capita as measured in household
surveys or in national accounts—can be explained, and simple methods to
This report
reconcile them are available. However, the situation becomes more comproposes a
plicated if trends differ. The case of India is a well-known example: consumption growth and poverty reduction rates calculated on the basis of
framework
surveys appear to be much slower than the corresponding rates estithat combines
mated on the basis of national accounts. And, so, supporters of additional market-friendly reforms of the Indian economy appeal to the
macroeconomic drivers
positive results from the national accounts, whereas opponents of the
and microeconomic
reforms use the sluggish poverty reduction shown in the surveys as evicharacteristics.
dence against recent or future liberalizations. Great gains can be obtained
by using and comparing macro- and microdata sets, and considering them
together is the only way to “look behind the averages” in the analysis of the
growth-distribution nexus (Ravallion 2001, 10).
Finally, the shared prosperity goal urges a revisiting of policy choices and the
implementation or, at least, the devising of fresh interventions. Policy makers are
becoming aware that, despite a positive effect on the average income of their citizens, many macro policies can produce such deterioration in the welfare of specific
groups that the policies become socially undesirable and politically unsustainable.
Similarly, poverty reduction policies designed to target specific individuals or specific households may end up generating macroeconomic (mainly fiscal) consequences. Thus, the selection and implementation of economic policies require a
careful assessment of the effects on aggregate economy-wide variables—such as
employment, inflation, or aggregate growth—as well as on income distribution
and poverty. Another effect to consider is the effect on environmental quality and
natural resources, which often involves health, productivity, and income issues that
implicate the bottom 40 more relative to the overall population.
The countries of Europe and Central Asia display great heterogeneity in terms
of the links between aggregate economic growth and the growth of income at the
10 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
bottom of the distribution. Identifying effective and feasible policies that ensure
that the welfare of those at the lower end of the income distribution rises as quickly
as possible thus requires us to zoom in on the bottom 40 at the country level and
explain the potential determinants of this diversity. Placing all these associated
factors in a unifying framework is the purpose of this report. By fostering an understanding of the heterogeneity among countries and encouraging policy proposals
for boosting growth at the bottom, the shared prosperity discussion can facilitate
a fresh perspective on evaluation and renewed action aimed at achieving social
progress.
Notes
1. A more detailed discussion of the bottom 40 indicator is presented in the appendix.
2. See Doing Business (database), International Finance Corporation and World Bank,
Washington, DC, http://www.doingbusiness.org/data.
References
Chenery, Hollis Burnley, Richard Jolly, Montek S. Ahluwalia, C. L. Bell, and John H. Duloy.
1974. Redistribution with Growth: Policies to Improve Income Distribution in Developing Countries in the Context of Economic Growth. World Bank Research Series. Washington, DC: World Bank; New York: Oxford University Press.
Ravallion, Martin. 2001. “Growth, Inequality, and Poverty: Looking beyond Averages.”
Policy Research Working Paper 2558, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Shared Prosperity in Europe and
Central Asia: Recent Trends
The first years of the new millennium marked a period of strong economic performance in Europe and Central Asia. The data show substantial growth, accompanied by significant poverty reduction through most of the last decade, despite the
global financial crisis of 2008, which slowed the trend. Between 2000 and the 2008
crisis, the unweighted average per capita growth rate in the transition countries in
the region was 6 percent a year.
How did the countries of Europe and Central Asia fare if they are viewed
through the new shared prosperity lens? Figure 2.1 shows the income growth
among the population in the bottom 40 percent of the distribution between 2005
and 2010. The data suggest that the strong economic growth and poverty reduction experienced in the region were matched by an overall positive record in
shared prosperity in the latter part of the first decade of the 2000s. In all but a
handful of countries, household incomes among the bottom 40 grew at relatively
high annual rates: the regional average was around 3.8 percent.
A few qualifications are in order. First, the time period examined in figure 2.1
(2005–10) is relatively short. Cyclical fluctuations—for instance, swings in commodity prices—could be driving performance during such a short time span,
whereas more profound structural changes, such as the upgrading of an education
system or demographic shifts, take longer to become visible. Second, this period
includes large fluctuations: the boom period up to 2008, the sizable shock of the
global financial crisis of 2008–09, and the rebound in 2010. This five-year period
is thus not necessarily representative of the steady-state behavior of these economies. These qualifications notwithstanding (they are dealt with in more detail
11
12 ●
FIGURE 2.1
Rates of Growth of
the Bottom 40 Were
Heterogeneous, but, on
Average, Good across
Europe and Central Asia
in 2005–10
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
Croatia
–1.8
Serbia
–1.8
Macedonia, FYR
–1.5
Albania
–1.2
Georgia
–0.9
Armenia
1.0
Hungary
1.6
Slovenia
2.3
Montenegro
2.5
Bulgaria
2.9
Czech Republic
3.0
Lithuania
3.5
Kosovo
3.9
Estonia
4.1
Latvia
4.7
Ukraine
4.7
Turkey
5.0
Moldova
5.7
Kyrgyz Republic
5.8
Tajikistan
6.1
Kazakhstan
6.2
Romania
6.2
Poland
8.0
Belarus
9.1
Russian Federation
9.6
Slovak Republic
11.3
–2
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
Average annualized per capita income growth, bottom 40, %
Sources: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team
for Statistical Development, World Bank, Washington, DC; EU-SILC (European Union Statistics on
Income and Living Conditions), Eurostat, Luxembourg, http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal
/page/portal/microdata/eu_silc.
Note: The years in the figure have been chosen because data have been harmonized and are
comparable in the countries of Europe and Central Asia circa 2005–10.
later), is there a yardstick for judging the quality of the observed income growth
among the bottom 40 in Europe and Central Asia?
One way to answer this question is to benchmark the performance of the region
to that of other regions. Within the global context and during the same period,
around 2005–10, Europe and Central Asia did quite well. In simple average terms
(namely, calculating the mean of the growth rates for all the countries in each region),
the growth in income among the bottom 40 in Europe and Central Asia (3.8 percent,
on average) was close to that in South Asia and not so distant from that in Latin
America and the Caribbean and in East Asia and the Pacific, the top performers,
which achieved rates of 4.9 percent and 5.2 percent, respectively (figure 2.2). If we
weight the averages by the population in each country, Europe and Central Asia
climb to the first position, reaching a weighted growth rate of 6.5 percent (figure 2.3).
In Europe and Central Asia, more populous countries appear to have outperformed the smaller ones. For these comparisons, some regions and some
● 13
Shared Prosperity in Europe and Central Asia: Recent Trends
FIGURE 2.2
Shared Prosperity in
Europe and Central Asia
Has Achieved Results
Close to Those of the
Top Performers
6
5.2
4.9
Simple regional averages, bottom 40
income growth, circa 2005–10, %
5
4.2
3.8
4
3
2.4
2.2
2
1
0
East Asia & Latin America &
Caribbean
Pacific
(all income
(all income
levels)
levels)
South Asia
Europe &
Central Asia
(all income
levels)
Middle East &
North Africa
(all income
levels)
Sub-Saharan
Africa
(all income
levels)
Region
Source: Household budget surveys.
FIGURE 2.3
In Terms of Shared
Prosperity, the Largest
Countries Have Performed
Particularly Well in Europe
and Central Asia
Population-weighted regional averages, bottom 40
income growth, circa 2005–10, %
8
7
6.5
5.9
6
5
4.7
4
2.8
3
2.4
2
1.6
1
0
Europe &
Central Asia
(all income
levels)
East Asia & Latin America & Sub-Saharan
Pacific
Caribbean
Africa
(all income
(all income
(all income
levels)
levels)
levels)
Region
Source: Household budget surveys.
South Asia
Middle East &
North Africa
(all income
levels)
14 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
1.8
1.7
1.6
Ratio of bottom 40 growth to mean growth
FIGURE 2.4
In Latin America and the
Caribbean, Europe and
Central Asia, and East Asia
and the Pacific, Income
Growth among the Bottom
40 Has Been Stronger Than
Mean Income Growth
1.4
1.2
1.2
1.1
1.0
0.9
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
Latin America & Europe &
Caribbean
Central Asia
(all income
(all income
levels)
levels)
East Asia &
Pacific
(all income
levels)
South Asia
Sub-Saharan
Africa
(all income
levels)
Middle East &
North Africa
(all income
levels)
Region
Source: Household budget surveys.
countries within regions provide information about income and consumption
variables, while others offer information on only one of these welfare indicators.
Azevedo (2014) explains the constraints in terms of sources of data, differences
between income and consumption measurement, and consistency between macrodata and microdata. We perform robustness checks in the analysis whenever
possible to verify the validity of our conclusions despite the data comparability
limitations.
Finally, if the assessment is based on the growth in income among the bottom 40 with respect to mean income growth, the region also performs relatively well: income among the bottom 40 in Europe and Central Asia grew
The positive
by 20 percent more than the mean. This is below only the performance
performance hides
in Latin America, where income among the bottom 40 grew 70 percent
more relative to the mean in circa 2005–10 (figure 2.4).
considerable
Despite the positive relative performance, there is extensive heteroheterogeneity
geneity across the countries of Europe and Central Asia. Between
within the region.
around 2005 and 2010, a Belarussian, Polish, Russian, or Slovak household in the lower segment of the income distribution enjoyed a growth
rate of around 8 percent or more a year. With a yearly growth rate of over 11
percent, the incomes of the Slovaks in the bottom 40 rose by 70 percent during
these five years. However, less well off people living in Latvia, Turkey, and Ukraine
experienced a yearly increase of only 5 percent or less, almost half the rate of
the same group among the best performers. On the other hand, people in
Croatia, Georgia, the former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, and Serbia sustained losses of 1 percent or more annually. In addition to the issue of establishing
● 15
Average annualized income growth, bottom 40, circa 2005–10, %
Shared Prosperity in Europe and Central Asia: Recent Trends
FIGURE 2.5
Growth of GDP Alone Does
Not Explain the Growth in
Bottom 40 Incomes
12
SVK
10
RUS
BLR
8
45° line
POL
6
4
ROM
LVA
UKR
EST
KSV
KAZ
TJK
MDA KGZ
TUR
LTU
CZE
BGR
SVN
2
MNE
HUN
ARM
0
–2
–1
GEO
MKD
HRV
SRB
0
1
2
3
4
5
ALB
6
7
8
Average annual per capita GDP growth, circa 2005–10, %
Sources: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team
for Statistical Development, World Bank, Washington, DC; EU-SILC (European Union Statistics on
Income and Living Conditions), Eurostat, Luxembourg, http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal
/page/portal/microdata/eu_silc; World Development Indicators (database), World Bank, Washington, DC, http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators; national
accounts.
Note: Data are calculated at constant purchasing power parity prices.
what constitutes good performance, these uneven growth rates point to the need
to understand the determinants of the heterogeneity to be able to shed light on
whether the region is on the path to shared prosperity and on ways to foster shared
prosperity.
As a first element, gross domestic product (GDP) growth is clearly essential in
achieving positive results. In Europe and Central Asia, the relationship between
GDP growth and income growth among the bottom 40, though positive, is far
from perfectly direct (figure 2.5). Rather than being neatly aligned close to the 45
degree line (which would occur if income growth among the bottom 40 were
mainly associated with the growth of GDP), the data points are considerably dispersed. This indicates that, although growth matters, there are other elements that
matter, too, and—as we argue—a key element is the pattern in this growth. GDP
growth alone may not suffice to ensure strong performance in shared prosperity.
Group averages also hide the high degree of heterogeneity within the region,
and there may likewise be large variations in income growth across households
in each income group. Three key features should therefore be considered in
attempting to unpack the heterogeneity: (1) the level of overall growth; (2) the
incidence of the growth, that is, the income growth at each percentile of the distribution; and (3) the initial share of income that goes to the bottom 40 versus the
top 60 (box 2.1).1
Growth incidence curves (GICs) indicate the growth of incomes along the
income distribution from the poorest to the richest individual. In general, all else
16 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
BOX 2.1
Comparing the Bottom 40 and the Top 60 in the Microdata
Figures B2.1.1 and B2.1.2 show the growth in
income among the bottom 40 versus the growth
in income among the top 60 during two different periods. The first period is from early 2000
until 2008, before the onset of the global crisis,
a period of steady growth in the region (figure
B2.1.1). Figure B2.1.2 shows the same information
for the period 2005–10, during which there was
growth, contraction, and then recovery.
Average annual per capita income growth, bottom 40, %
FIGURE B2.1.1
Bottom 40 versus Top 60: During the Steady Growth Period, Growth Rates Were Similar
for the Two Groups
45° line
23
SVK
LTU
18
EST
LVA
13
KAZ
8
3
CZE
SVN
HUN
TUR
SRB
GEO
0
UKR
BLR
ARM
MNE
ROM
TJK
KGZ
POL
KSV
–2
0
3
8
13
18
23
Average annual per capita income growth, top 60, %
Sources: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team for Statistical Development,
World Bank, Washington, DC; EU-SILC (European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions), Eurostat, Luxembourg,
http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/microdata/eu_silc.
Note: Data are calculated at constant purchasing power parity prices.
(Continued)
held constant, the higher the overall rate of growth, the higher the growth of the
incomes of the bottom 40. Figure 2.6 illustrates an example of GICs comparing
pairs of countries that had (1) similar GDP growth, but contrasting growth among
the bottom 40 (Georgia and Kazakhstan, panels a and b) and (2) contrasting overall growth, but similar growth among the bottom 40 (Ukraine and Tajikistan,
panels c and d). The four patterns are considerably different, illustrating the following points:
• Incomes grew more quickly at the bottom in Kazakhstan and Ukraine and less
quickly in Georgia and Tajikistan. The growth incidence in Georgia is even
slightly regressive; thus, while both Georgia and Kazakhstan register GDP
● 17
Shared Prosperity in Europe and Central Asia: Recent Trends
BOX 2.1
(continued)
In both periods, bottom 40 income growth is
greater in most countries, though the pattern is
more pronounced during the cyclical period. One
potential explanation is the nature of the global
crisis, which was triggered by a financial collapse,
thereby affecting the top 60 relatively more than
the bottom 40. In addition, in many countries, the
fiscal response through transfers and public investments tended to favor the bottom 40 to a larger
extent.
Average annual per capita income growth, bottom 40, %
FIGURE B2.1.2
Bottom 40 versus Top 60: During the Cyclical Period, the Bottom 40 Outperformed the Top 60
14
45° line
12
SVK
10
RUS
BLR
8
POL
ROM
KGZ MDA
LVA
UKR
LTU
KSV EST
CZE
MNE
SVN BGR
6
4
2
HUN
TJK KAZ
TUR
ARM
0
ALB
SRB
–2
GEO
0
MKD
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
Average annual per capita income growth, top 60, %
Sources: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team for Statistical Development,
World Bank, Washington, DC; EU-SILC (European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions), Eurostat, Luxembourg,
http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/microdata/eu_silc; World Development Indicators (database), World
Bank, Washington, DC, http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators; national accounts.
Note: Data are calculated at constant purchasing power parity prices.
growth of about 4 percent, they show different rates of growth among the bottom 40 (−1 percent and 6 percent, respectively).
• A direct comparison of the GICs for Tajikistan and Ukraine highlights the fact
that, even in a context of quite different macro performance, the bottom 40 in
each country was able to grow relatively more strongly than the respective top
60. Tajikistan, however, constitutes a case in which the overall growth rate is
such that growth among the bottom 40 is high, although the growth incidence
is not particularly progressive.
• The average growth of both the bottom 40 and the top 60 hides a good deal
of heterogeneity within these groups. In the case of Tajikistan, for example, the
18 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
FIGURE 2.6
Growth Incidence Curves Show the Diverse Growth Patterns in Europe and Central Asia
a. Georgia, 2006−11
b. Kazakhstan, 2006−10
10
Average
top 60
5
Average annual per capita
income growth, %
Average annual per capita
income growth, %
10
Average population
0
Average
bottom 40
−5
Average
bottom 40
5
Average population
0
−10
0
20
40
60
80
100
0
Income population percentile
from poorest (0) to richest (100)
20
40
60
80
100
Income population percentile
from poorest (0) to richest (100)
c. Ukraine, 2005−10
d. Tajikistan, 2004−09
15
10
Average
bottom 40
Average annual per capita
income growth, %
Average annual per capita
income growth, %
Average
top 60
5
Average population
0
Average
top 60
Average
bottom 40
10
5
Average population
Average
top 60
0
−5
−5
0
20
40
60
80
Income population percentile
from poorest (0) to richest (100)
100
0
20
40
60
80
100
Income population percentile
from poorest (0) to richest (100)
Source: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team for Statistical Development, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Note: The solid horizontal lines in the panels show the average levels of growth for the whole economy, for the bottom 40, and for the top 60 in
each case.
average of the top 60 has been affected by a fall in the incomes among a group
within the top decile.
Finally, in addition to the level of aggregate growth and the incidence of growth
across different income groups, a key element that helps to understand the contribution of the bottom 40 to overall growth is the initial share of income represented by this group. There is a positive correlation between the initial share of
total income that goes to the bottom 40 and the contribution of the bottom 40 to
overall growth. This indicator also shows a large variation across countries (figure
2.7). The initial share of income held by the bottom 40 is, in turn, associated
inversely with the initial level of income inequality.
If one focuses on the performance of the bottom 40, it is helpful to think of
growth and distribution as codetermined, as Chenery et al. (1974) suggest one
should do. The associations reviewed so far have no causal implication; though
helpful as a first instance, they describe the process without providing sufficient
elements for us to understand fully the heterogeneity in the performance of the
bottom 40. The framework proposed in the next chapter represents an attempt to
view the heterogeneity at a deeper level.
● 19
Shared Prosperity in Europe and Central Asia: Recent Trends
Slovenia
24.5
Czech Republic
23.7
Slovak Republic
22.6
Kazakhstan
22.4
Belarus
22.4
Ukraine
22.1
Serbia
21.9
Armenia
21.9
Montenegro
21.7
Kosovo
21.5
Croatia
21.4
Albania
20.7
Estonia
20.0
Tajikistan
19.8
19.2
Hungary
18.9
Lithuania
18.7
Moldova
18.4
Bulgaria
18.1
Poland
Kyrgyz Republic
17.0
Macedonia, FYR
16.9
16.9
Latvia
16.3
Georgia
16.2
Romania
16.0
Russian Federation
15.9
Turkey
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
Share in total income, bottom 40, circa 2005, %
Sources: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team for
Statistical Development, World Bank, Washington, DC; EU-SILC (European Union Statistics on Income
and Living Conditions), Eurostat, Luxembourg, http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal
/microdata/eu_silc.
Note
1. This pattern remains—though the dispersion is reduced—if, instead of GDP, the comparison relies on the mean income growth shown in survey data. Using GDP is desirable
because, whenever we measure overall growth, we do so in terms of GDP, not in terms
of household income or consumption as measured in surveys (Azevedo 2014).
References
Azevedo, Joâo Pedro. 2014. “A New Impetus to an Old Debate: When and Why Do Macro
and Micro Numbers Diverge?” ECA PREM Technical Background Note, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Chenery, Hollis Burnley, Richard Jolly, Montek S. Ahluwalia, C. L. Bell, and John H. Duloy.
1974. Redistribution with Growth: Policies to Improve Income Distribution in Developing Countries in the Context of Economic Growth. World Bank Research Series. Washington, DC: World Bank; New York: Oxford University Press.
FIGURE 2.7
Some Countries Face
a Greater Challenge in
Closing the Income Gap
between the Bottom 40
and the Top 60
The Drivers of Shared Prosperity
An Asset-Based Framework
Our proposed framework relies on an asset-based approach as a building block.
This approach incorporates the relevance of the long-term productive capacity of
households to contribute to growth as well as the relevance of macroeconomic
variables that affect, for example, the demand for labor across sectors, relative
prices (returns), and the intensity of the use of assets over the economic cycle. This
perspective permits an enhanced understanding of growth incidence (Attanasio
and Székely 1999; Carter and Barrett 2006). The main elements of the framework
are the following:
• At the macroeconomic level, the scheme includes variables such as commodity
prices, external conditions, the importance of trade in the economy, the sectoral composition of growth, and fiscal structure and capacity. Looking forward,
measures of national wealth accounting and the carbon (CO2) intensity of
growth can also be added because it is anticipated that these will affect commodity prices and other macro variables in the future (for example, after 2020).
• At the microeconomic level, the capacity of households to contribute productively to overall growth depends on the assets they own or have access to, the
existing returns to these assets, and how intensively the assets can be used. The
assets may include human capital, financial capital, social capital, and natural
capital, such as land, soil, forests, and water.1
21
22 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
• Finally, the income generation capacity of households is complemented
by nonmarket income, that is, transfers from private sources (remittances, for
instance) and public sources (social assistance, for example).
Traditionally, a top-down approach would emphasize the macroeconomic drivers (the first bullet point in the preceding list) and view the resulting distribution as
a separate element. A purely bottom-up approach would emphasize the longterm determinants of growth as a function of the productive capacity of the economy and the efficient allocation of household assets to the most productive use.
Our proposed framework considers that, in the short run, the distribution of
assets is a given, and variables such as prices, growth composition, and
The asset-based
fiscal transfers will play a bigger role (emphasizing the demand side). In
framework looks
the medium and long term, however, the level and distribution of assets
and the returns on the assets, which reflect their productivity, will be the
at the joint determination
main drivers. In this sense, if the bottom 40 possesses a lower producof growth and the
tive capacity, there will be an upper bound to the potential for growth
(figure 3.1). Clearly, elements such as prices and the intensity of asset use
distribution of growth.
may be affected by cyclical conditions: unemployment would prevent
individuals from generating income from labor; inflation may distort the
relative returns to assets and induce misallocations; and the fiscal capacity of
governments to respond to shocks could limit the countercyclical role of transfers,
while households may rely more on private transfers during difficult times.
For instance, if we assume that one of the main assets owned by households is
human capital, which represents a principal source of household income, whether
the bottom 40 is different from the top 60 in this dimension becomes an important
question. Analyses of the determinants of growth demonstrate that an income
group characterized by lower human capital accumulation is more limited in growth
FIGURE 3.1
The Asset-Based Approach
and the Joint Determination
of Growth and Distribution
Net
assets
×
Intensity
of use
×
Prices
+
Distribution
Change in income
generation capacity
Transfers
=
Income
generation
capacity
Sustainability
Sustainability
Growth
External conditions
Sector composition
Key prices
The Drivers of Shared Prosperity
● 23
potential. The evidence on Europe and Central Asia confirms that households in the
bottom 40 tend to have a smaller stock of human capital as measured by educational attainment. Similarly, it is important to understand whether there is a special
relationship between households in the bottom 40 (particularly in rural areas) and
reliance on, access to, and the quality and value of productive natural assets. Such
an analysis is envisaged for the next stage of the development of the framework.
In terms of returns, although it is more difficult to show a systematic pattern
across a large sample of countries because of data limitations, we find that, after
we control for observable characteristics, hourly earnings tend to be lower among
households at the bottom of the distribution. This may reflect differences in productivity, issues related to market segmentation, and heterogeneity in the quality
of education, the variable used to approximate human capital. (Thus, the intensity
of the use of human capital measured by the number of hours of work is lower
among the bottom 40.) There may also be reasons for differences in returns that
are not related to markets, but to social norms, institutions, and culture; an example is offered by discrimination in the labor market.
Assets can be grouped into human capital, physical assets, financial assets,
social capital, and natural capital. Policies have an effect on the decisions of agents
with respect to these types of assets by influencing relative returns, by removing
access barriers, and by providing information about asset use and returns. Interventions to foster growth among the bottom 40 can be understood coherently from
this asset-based perspective (see chapter 6). Investments in education and health
are the most obvious policies regarding human capital accumulation. Investments in infrastructure can improve accessibility and connect markets, reduce
A household’s income
transport or communication costs, and impact relative returns to investment in certain assets. Policies that solve market failures in credit or insurgeneration capacity is
ance markets also have an impact on the portfolio decisions of economic
determined by its net
agents. Legal and administrative reforms such as the transfer of ownerassets, the intensity of use
ship to local governments and communities, land titling, or the regularof these assets, the
ization of property rights tend to improve the capacity of households to
use their assets more intensively, thereby enhancing their potential to
returns on the assets, and
contribute to economic growth. The functioning of markets and the role
private and public
of regulatory institutions allow agents to access markets, accumulate assets,
transfers.
and use assets more intensively. The impact of addressing gender disparities
in access to production assets such as land is another policy-relevant area worth
further study and documentation. Through the story of two individuals, box 3.1
illustrates how the asset-based approach can be understood in simple terms.
This report uses data to analyze in more detail the case of human capital and
income generation through the labor market because, according to surveys, this
source of income represents the largest share of income among most households
in the region. However, other types of assets are also important, and there are also
interactions and complementarities (box 3.2).
Because the variable of interest is income growth among the bottom 40, the
framework must be understood in terms of the dynamics: how net assets, returns,
intensity, and net market income change over time, resulting in a change in
the income generated by households. The basic notion must be complemented
by equations or simple rules that describe the accumulation of each asset.
24 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
BOX 3.1
The Asset-Based Approach: The Stories of Mariam and Emre
Let us illustrate the asset-based approach by
using the example of two individuals, Mariam in
rural Georgia and Emre in urban Turkey.
Mariam has a small plot of land inherited from
her parents. Along with her children, she uses the
land to produce small amounts of agricultural
goods to sell in the local market. She holds traditional rights over her land that have been
respected for generations, though there are no
legal documents backing up these rights. She
completed primary school and works for a relatively low salary, three or four months a year, in a
small grocery store owned by a good friend of her
late father. She also receives social assistance
from the government, mainly because she is a
woman head of household. As is customary in her
community, Mariam keeps cash savings at home
to solve the needs of the household throughout
the year. She has managed to accumulate some
surpluses, hoping that, one day, she will have
enough savings to open her own grocery store
and diversify the sources of income in her
household.
Emre went to school in Turkey, where he finished high school. He has a job in a local manufacturing plant. Using some savings and money
he inherited from his father, he bought a small
apartment, where he lives and where he also rents
one room to a work colleague, who lives there
during the weekdays and goes back to his hometown during the weekends. Emre manages to
save part of his salary regularly. (His salary has
increased recently because of an active government minimum wage policy that has had an
impact on wage negotiations throughout the
country.) He plans to buy a new apartment, move
into it, and rent out the entire apartment where he
currently lives. He is also attending training
courses offered by a private provider; he uses a
public cash voucher to pay for the course. This
training will allow him to become certified in spe-
cific processes related to his work, and it could
even open up new job opportunities in the future.
Moreover, in these training courses, he is meeting
other people working in areas and firms related to
his own.
The Market and Nonmarket Incomes of
Mariam and Emre
Mariam and Emre generate income from a different combination of assets, intensity of asset use,
and nonmarket income sources (table B3.1.1).
Not only has Emre accumulated a higher level of
human capital, but also he uses it more intensely
and obtains a higher return, which has increased
because of the active wage policies in his country.
Mariam uses her lower human capital to work her
own land and, in return, is able to make extra savings by avoiding the need to hire an additional
worker. At the grocery store, she also receives a
salary that is high relative to her skills because her
father’s friend trusts her to carry out cash transactions in the store and manage the inventory.
Both Mariam and Emre also possess physical
capital: land and real estate, respectively. Mariam
exploits her land and obtains a return by selling
the produce at the market. However, she could
use it more intensively if the legal property documents were available, which would give her the
chance to use the land as collateral to access
credit and start a business to diversify her sources
of income. Emre obtains an inflow of income
through the rent of a second room in the apartment. He can accomplish this also by exploiting
his social capital: renting to a person from his job
network, someone he can trust who is available to
carry out such an informal transaction.
In terms of financial capital, Mariam does have
savings, but she does not use them intensively;
she keeps them in cash at home, thereby forgoing potential returns from saving in the formal
banking sector. Emre has financial capital—his
(Continued)
● 25
The Drivers of Shared Prosperity
BOX 3.1
(continued)
TABLE B3.1.1 The Asset-Based Approach: The Stories of Mariam and Emre
Story
Mariam
Asset
Intensity
Accumulation
Works her own land;
works at a grocery
store four months a
year
Equivalent salary
she would have paid
if hiring; salary for
grocery store work
None
Physical: land
Uses land to produce;
cannot use it as
collateral (absence of
legal documents)
Profit from agricultural
production
None
Financial
Low; savings are
kept at home
None, or negative
because of inflation
Surpluses added
every year; hopes
to invest in business
Social: social and
family networks
Used to obtain a job
in a grocery store
every year
Differential salary
from job compared
with other options
Reinforces
networks
Natural: the
land itself
Land is kept arable;
no improvements
None
None
Nonmarket income
Emre
Returns
Human: primary
school; knowledge
of agricultural work
Monthly government transfers
Human: secondary
education
Full-time job
Wages received
Training for
certification
Physical: apartment
ownership
High; lives there and
rents
Imputed rent (lives
there); income from
rental of extra room
Potential
increase in
property value
Financial: bank
savings
High; through the
financial sector
Interest
Adds to savings
systematically
Social: work-related
social network
High; rents extra room
to colleague
Rent
Strengthens
networks at work
Natural: none
None
None
None
Nonmarket
Subsidy to pay for training
savings—and is using them more intensively by
obtaining a return and accumulating savings to
invest in a new apartment.
Mariam is also receiving nonmarket income
through public social assistance transfers. Emre
receives a voucher to pay for his training, and the
voucher represents part of his overall income.
invest in a business in the future. Formalizing the
Asset Accumulation
Mariam attempts to accumulate assets through
savings she keeps at home; she would like to
the same area of activity. Moreover, he is saving in
property rights over her land could accelerate this
process because she would be able to use her land
more intensively, as collateral for a loan. Emre is
investing in his skills, trying to obtain the certification that will enhance his employability in the near
future, while also strengthening his networks within
the bank to accumulate physical assets by, eventually, acquiring another property where he can live.
(Continued)
26 ●
BOX 3.1
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
The Asset-Based Approach: The Stories of Mariam and Emre (continued)
Mariam and Emre Contribute to
Overall Growth
There are variables that Mariam and Emre cannot
control, including the existing level of wages, the
level of the demand for their skills, and the price of
the goods they produce. These are determined by
overall macroeconomic performance and may
depend on cyclical factors. (If the sector in which
Emre works faces lower demand for its products,
his situation can change for him, and his plans may
be thwarted.) Within this context, however, Mariam and Emre make decisions that allow them to
be productive and contribute to overall growth in
BOX 3.2
their countries. To understand how they can contribute more, become more productive, and
achieve the goals they have established for themselves, we need to examine the microeconomic
dynamics in terms of their assets, the intensity of
the use of their assets, and their returns. But public
decisions also matter through a component of
nonmarket income—transfers—that is an important complement in providing income support and
thereby also influences their economic decisions.
Policies can play a key role in these dynamics.
The channels through which this occurs are discussed in chapter 6.
Constrained Social Capital and the Bottom 40: The Case of
Displaced Persons
There are approximately 2.5 million individuals in
Europe and Central Asia who have been forcibly
displaced as a result of conflict or violence. Where
statistics exist, there is evidence that displaced
persons are more likely to be poor and more likely
to be in the bottom 40 than the nondisplaced.
In Azerbaijan, for example, poverty rates among
the displaced are at 25 percent, compared with
20 percent among the nondisplaced (World Bank
2011). Employment rates among the displaced are
40 percent compared with 57 percent among the
nondisplaced. Research undertaken by the World
Bank has shown that constrained social capital is
an important factor in the increased likelihood
of a displaced person being poor in Azerbaijan.
Displaced persons tend to live in socially and
geographically isolated settlements with limited
chances to make contact and connect with nondisplaced persons who could offer them livelihood opportunities. The displaced suffer from
social stigma and derogatory attitudes, which
further marginalize them. In addition, there are
high levels of mental health challenges among the
displaced, such as depression and hopelessness,
which render it more difficult for them to be economically active. These social capital constraints
compound many other asset deficiencies, such as
the loss of physical assets these individuals experienced when they fled their places of origin, the
irrelevance of their human capital assets (education and skills) in the labor markets of the places
where they settle, and their poor living conditions
and limited fi nancial assets, which reinforce the
propensity to poverty.
Marginalization and discrimination based
on ethnicity, which affect household economic
opportunities, are common among displaced persons across Europe and Central Asia. In Croatia,
for example, the difficulty faced by the Serbian
minority in gaining access to employment is recognized as an area requiring additional redress
(European Commission 2010). In all these cases,
it is the group identity and the relative position
of the group in the wider society that affects the
social capital of a household and the chances to
move out of the bottom 40.
The Drivers of Shared Prosperity
● 27
Such accumulation rules are asset specific (Attanasio and Székely 1999). A child’s
human capital accumulation, for example, depends on the human capital of the
parents, the accessibility and quality of educational supply, the access to credit,
and so on. Accumulation will also be a negative function of exposure to negative
shocks that destroy existing assets in the absence of coping mechanisms. Finally,
accumulation is related to the incentive structure implied by existing fiscal systems.
All these elements are relevant if the framework is applied in the policy realm.
The potential trade-offs between growth and redistribution have been widely
discussed in the literature. (The impossibility of lump-sum redistribution leads to
interventions that alter relative prices and imply departures from first-best allocations.) Research has emphasized that these short-term trade-offs should not
necessarily guide policy making (for example, see Bourguignon 2001). PolTrade-offs
icy choices should be made within a dynamic long-term framework
between equity and
whereby both efficiency and equity are potentially enhanced. Thus,
efficiency can be avoided
equity-efficiency trade-offs may be avoided if redistribution involves an
increase in the productive capacity of the households at the bottom. In
if redistribution involves
the long run, productivity will determine the capacity of the economy
an increase in the
to grow. Productivity is linked to the capacity of people to contribute to
growth by using the assets they own, such as human, physical, and finanproductive capacity
cial capital as well as intangible capital, including entrepreneurship and
of households.
innovative capacity. The introduction of dynamics changes the nature of the
potential trade-offs.
The time dimension plays, in this way, a crucial role. It is clear that the policy
options are limited in any attempt to influence the microeconomic determinants
of growth in the short run, while macroeconomic variables are the primary factors.
The application of policy instruments to guarantee access to opportunities must
be viewed through a long-term focus on growth. Transfers for social assistance, for
example, may be useful as income support, but do not necessarily increase productive capacities and may even deter asset accumulation and labor force participation.2 On the other hand, investments in education and health, in connectivity
and infrastructure, or in the enhancement of the capacity of the government to
provide services to everyone are all policies that—if properly assessed ex ante—
could impact productivity and thus the capacity of the bottom 40 to contribute to
growth in the medium term and help overcome the static trade-offs.
Labor Market Income, Nonmarket Income,
and Growth Incidence
The asset-based approach allows us to analyze income growth among the bottom
40 by addressing two fundamental questions simultaneously:
• Is the capacity to accumulate assets, use them intensively, and obtain returns
that are consistent with the associated productivity different among households
in the bottom 40 and households in the top 60?
• Are macro variables—variables that affect household behavior, but are not
under the control of households, such as the returns to education, the real
28 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
exchange rate, and initial production or occupational structures—affecting
poorer and richer households differently?
(Note that the framework also includes transfers. In the short run, or during a
crisis, these may play an important buffer role, but it is difficult to envisage transfers, either private or public, as a sustainable source of income growth.)
Starting from the first question, the remainder of this chapter presents empirical
evidence on the gaps between the bottom 40 and the top 60 across the various
dimensions of assets, intensity of use, and returns.
In most countries, income derived from labor market participation represents
the most important component in total income: on average, it accounts for 60
percent of incomes in Europe and Central Asia. There is, however, heterogeneity
across countries (see figure 3.2 for a sample of countries). Given the significance
of human capital as a source of income generation, it is a key asset in the analysis.
In terms of nonmarket income, the share of public transfers from pensions and
social assistance is particularly high compared with the average in other regions
(about 20 percent in Latin America and the Caribbean, for example) (figures 3.3
and 3.4). A strong emerging finding is the high dependency of households in
Europe and Central Asia on generous systems of public transfers, which may
threaten fiscal sustainability and create disincentives for labor force participation.3
FIGURE 3.2
Human Capital Is a Key
Asset in Income Generation
Albania
Armenia
Bottom 40
Top 60
Croatia
Georgia
Kazakhstan
Kosovo
Macedonia, FYR
Moldova
Serbia
Tajikistan
Turkey
Ukraine
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
Share of wage income in total income, circa 2010, %
Source: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team for
Statistical Development, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Note: Wage income includes both employee and self-employed earned income.
● 29
The Drivers of Shared Prosperity
FIGURE 3.3
Household Dependency on Pensions Tends to Be High in the Region
a. All households
b. Excluding households with pension income only
Albania
Albania
Armenia
Armenia
Croatia
Croatia
Kazakhstan
Kazakhstan
Kosovo
Kosovo
Macedonia, FYR
Macedonia, FYR
Moldova
Moldova
Serbia
Serbia
Tajikistan
Tajikistan
Turkey
Turkey
Ukraine
Ukraine
0
10
20
30
40
50
Share of pensions in total income, circa 2010, %
Bottom 40
Top 60
60
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
Share of pensions in total income, circa 2010, %
Bottom 40
Top 60
Source: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team for Statistical Development, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
In Serbia, for example, the bottom 40 receives more than 40 percent of their total
income from pensions (figure 3.3). Social assistance also plays a major role in some
countries, such as Bosnia and Herzegovina as well as Kosovo. In Georgia, which is
not included in figures 3.3 and 3.4 because of the difficulty of separating pensions
from social assistance in the total nonmarket income from public sources, the
bottom 40 receives more than 40 percent of their total income from nonmarket sources linked to public funding.
Income from
Two main messages can be derived from these numbers. First, public
public transfers
nonmarket income plays a key role as an income source in Europe and
among the bottom 40
Central Asia. Second, in general, the bottom 40 tends to depend more
on these sources.
is particularly high
For the analysis of the generation of market income, figures 3.5 and
in the region.
3.6 provide an indicator of one type of asset, human capital, which is
measured using the data available from a large set of countries based on
the working-age population that has completed tertiary education (figure
3.5) and on the working-age population that has completed, at most, primary
education (figure 3.6). The intensity in the use of the asset—human capital—is
represented by labor force participation.
There is a systematic gap between these two groups that implies the bottom
40 possesses lesser capacity to generate income, all else held constant. Among
the working-age population, the top 60 in the vast majority of these countries has
accumulated higher levels of human capital, while the bottom 40 uses human
30 ●
FIGURE 3.4
Social Assistance Is an
Important Source of Income
for the Bottom 40 in Selected
Countries
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
Albania
Armenia
Croatia
Kazakhstan
Bottom 40
Top 60
Kosovo
Macedonia, FYR
Moldova
Serbia
Tajikistan
Turkey
Ukraine
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
Share of social assistance in total income, circa 2010, %
Source: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team for
Statistical Development, World Bank, Washington, DC.
FIGURE 3.5
The Tertiary Education Gap
between the Top 60 and the
Bottom 40 Is Large in All
Countries
Turkey
Romania
Macedonia, FYR
Albania
Serbia
Bottom 40
Top 60
Moldova
Kosovo
Bulgaria
Tajikistan
Montenegro
Slovenia
Czech Republic
Poland
Hungary
Kyrgyz Republic
Croatia
Armenia
Slovak Republic
Ukraine
Georgia
Kazakhstan
Latvia
Russian Federation
Estonia
Lithuania
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
Share of working-age population aged 25+ years
with tertiary education, circa 2010, %
Sources: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team for
Statistical Development, World Bank, Washington, DC; EU-SILC (European Union Statistics on Income
and Living Conditions), Eurostat, Luxembourg, http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal
/microdata/eu_silc.
● 31
The Drivers of Shared Prosperity
FIGURE 3.6
Fewer People in the
Top 60 Relative to the
Bottom 40 Have Only
Primary Education
Turkey
Kosovo
Albania
Macedonia, FYR
Serbia
Bottom 40
Moldova
Top 60
Croatia
Poland
Tajikistan
Ukraine
Bulgaria
Romania
Montenegro
Kyrgyz Republic
Russian Federation
Georgia
Lithuania
Kazakhstan
Hungary
Slovenia
Armenia
Estonia
Latvia
Slovak Republic
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
Share of working-age population aged 25+ years
with, at most, primary education, circa 2010, %
Sources: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team for
Statistical Development, World Bank, Washington, DC; EU-SILC (European Union Statistics on Income
and Living Conditions), Eurostat, Luxembourg, http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal
/microdata/eu_silc.
capital less intensively by exhibiting not only lower rates of labor force participation, but also, as figure 3.7 shows, higher unemployment rates.
Our findings highlight two patterns that sketch a portrait of households in the
bottom 40 across countries and can help guide policy actions, that is, these households (1) have fewer assets and (2) use their fewer assets less intensively. A third
element, the returns to these assets (or factor prices), is also important. Even if
these prices are determined at the macro level, they may differ across households
in the bottom and top portions of the distribution.
The systematic analysis of returns faces limitations in some countries. However,
in countries in which the analysis is feasible, the returns to education are lower
among individuals in the lowest two quintiles. For example, in the case of the Russian Federation, the returns to education seem to be greater in the upper part of
the distribution.4 In 2000, the wage premium of a university degree compared with
the wage premium of less than a high school diploma among individuals in the top
32 ●
FIGURE 3.7
People in the Bottom 40
Are More Likely Than
People in the Top 60 to
Be Unemployed
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
Russian Federation
Moldova
Kyrgyz Republic
Kazakhstan
Bottom 40
Top 60
Turkey
Romania
Tajikistan
Albania
Czech Republic
Georgia
Poland
Armenia
Macedonia, FYR
Estonia
Slovenia
Slovak Republic
Hungary
Ukraine
Bulgaria
Lithuania
Latvia
Serbia
Montenegro
Croatia
Kosovo
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
Unemployment as a share of the working-age population
aged 25+ years, circa 2010, %
Sources: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team for
Statistical Development, World Bank, Washington, DC; EU-SILC (European Union Statistics on Income
and Living Conditions), Eurostat, Luxembourg, http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal
/microdata/eu_silc.
60 relative to the bottom 40 was plus 30 percent; the gap was even wider among
individuals at higher levels of educational attainment. In 2005, people at most
levels of educational attainment in the top 60 outperformed the most well educated people in the bottom 40. By 2010, people at all levels of educational attainment in the top 60 were outperforming the most well educated in the bottom 40.
The household per capita availability of income generating assets is associated
with dependency ratios as well. Thus, the dependency of households on employed
members is high among the bottom 40. On average in Europe and Central Asia,
each employed member of households in the bottom 40 must provide for six other
individuals; the corresponding number of individuals in the top 60 is four (figure
3.8). In Kosovo, the difference between the bottom 40 and the top 60 in this indicator is not two, but four individuals. This pattern in Kosovo is the result of both
● 33
The Drivers of Shared Prosperity
FIGURE 3.8
Households in the Bottom
40 Have More Dependents
Russian Federation
Slovak Republic
Armenia
Bottom 40
Top 60
Macedonia, FYR
Montenegro
Kazakhstan
Ukraine
Georgia
Romania
Lithuania
Poland
Estonia
Hungary
Czech Republic
Serbia
Latvia
Slovenia
Bulgaria
Moldova
Albania
Kyrgyz Republic
Kosovo
Tajikistan
Turkey
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
Ratio of dependents to the productive population, circa 2010, %
Sources: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team for
Statistical Development, World Bank, Washington, DC; EU-SILC (European Union Statistics on Income
and Living Conditions), Eurostat, Luxembourg, http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal
/microdata/eu_silc.
a higher child dependency ratio and lower employment rates among working-age
individuals at the bottom of the distribution. The higher dependency ratio means
the earnings of relatively fewer employed household members must support relatively more people, but also that households are relatively more vulnerable to job
loss, illness, or other shocks affecting income earners. Generally, the more limited
capacity of households among the bottom 40 to use human capital intensively and
the higher unemployment rates among this group represent substantial barriers to
sharing prosperity efficiently across the entire income distribution.
All these elements—level of asset holdings, intensity of asset use, and returns
to assets—are useful in determining the capacity of households at the bottom to
generate income and contribute to growth. Likewise, gaps in these areas between
the bottom 40 and the top 60 help explain the differential capacity of these groups
34 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
to contribute to overall growth. In principle, these elements are associated with
growth incidence: if the bottom 40 has less human capital, it will have less income
growth potential, though the structure of the economy matters. For example, if the
engine of growth in an economy is a sector intensive in low skills, this would be
reflected in the relative returns to low skills, and the incidence of growth could be
progressive.
The heterogeneity we seek to explain, however, is the heterogeneity across
countries. In this sense, rather than the gap between the bottom 40 and the top
60 within a country, we would like to be able to compare credibly the levels of
household asset holdings, intensity of asset use, and prices (returns to assets)
between two countries. Across countries, are the differential levels of, for example, human capital in the bottom 40 associated with the heterogeneity in the
The levels of
shared prosperity indicator? Without any implication of causality, we use
asset holdings,
multivariate regression analysis based on data for the entire Europe and
Central Asia region to respond to this question more systematically. Figintensity of asset use,
ure 3.9 shows that the higher the value of the indicator of human capital
and returns to assets
among the bottom 40 by country, the higher the income growth of the
within the bottom 40
bottom 40 in the periods before and after crisis (after one has controlled
vary across countries
for other characteristics). If more people of working age in the bottom
40
leave or do not enter the labor force (meaning that the productive
in the region.
capacity embedded in their human capital is not used), then income growth
within the bottom 40 slows.
Demographic factors also help explain the heterogeneity in the performance in
income growth among the bottom 40 in Europe and Central Asia. One element
worth highlighting is demographic composition as captured by the aged dependency ratio. Households in the bottom 40 tend to have lower aged dependency
ratios, which tend to be associated with higher income growth (figure 3.10).
A detailed analysis of the specific context is crucial to understanding patterns
within countries to help us explain the heterogeneity across countries. For instance,
Georgia, Kazakhstan, and Poland exhibited similar GDP growth rates, but different
rates of income growth among the bottom 40 during 2005–10. Kazakhstan and
Poland performed much better in this indicator. Georgia grew at an average 4.3
percent a year, close to Kazakhstan’s 3.5 percent and Poland’s 4.7 percent. In contrast, the bottom 40 experienced a decline in consumption in Georgia (−0.9 percent a year), while the bottom 40 in Kazakhstan experienced a sharp increase, 6.2
percent annually, which was above the country’s average, and the bottom 40 in
Poland showed an impressive 8.0 percent increase for the same indicator. It is
worth noticing that Kazakhstan has a greater dependence on earnings from natural
resources, and Poland has a more important manufacturing sector.
Why do countries growing at a similar pace present such diverging performance in shared prosperity? One way to explore the potential causes requires
taking a closer look at the characteristics of the bottom 40 in each country. The
bottom 40 is quite different in Georgia and Kazakhstan. Compared with the bottom 40 in Kazakhstan, the least well off in Georgia live in households with heads
who are slightly less well educated, who are less likely overall to be employed, and
who are three times more likely not to be participating in the labor force. Households in Georgia are headed by individuals who are twice as likely to have
● 35
The Drivers of Shared Prosperity
a. Bottom 40 growth and share of the population aged 25+ years with tertiary education
10
SVK, 2004
LTU, 2004
BLR, 2006
Income growth, %
5
EST, 2004
LVA, 2004
RUS, 2004
BLR, 1999
TJK, 2004
ARM, 2001
SVK, 2005
KSV, 2006
UKR, 2002
0
−5
MDA, 2006
TJK, 1999
KAZ, 2001
ALB, 2005 SRB, 2003
HUN, 2005
TUR, 2002
SRB, 2007
MNE, 2005
KAZ, 2006
ROM, 1999 SVN, 2005 MKD, KSV,
2003 2003
HRV, 2004
MNE, 2006
CZE, 2005
CZE, 2004
HUN, 2004
SVN, 2004
GEO, 2006
LVA, 2005
EST, 2005
POL, 1999
LTU, 2005
GEO, 1999
−10
−10
0
10
20
Share of population aged 25+ years with tertiary education
b. Bottom 40 growth and share of the population aged 25+ years out of the labor force
SVK, 2004
10
BLR, 2006
Income growth, %
SVK, 2005
5
0
−5
RUS, 2004
LVA, 2004
EST, 2004
BLR, 1999
MDA, 2006
UKR, 2002
LTU, 2004
KAZ, 2001 ARM, 2001
MNE, 2005
ALB, 2005
SRB, 2007
LVA, 2005
ROM,
SVN, 2005
SRB,1999
2003 HUN, 2005
HRV, 2004
MNE, 2006
KAZ, 2006
CZE, 2005
POL, 1999
CZE, 2004
EST, 2005
SVN, 2004
HUN, 2004
KSV, 2006
TJK, 2004
TJK, 1999
TUR, 2002
MKD, 2003
LTU, 2005
GEO, 2006
KSV, 2003
GEO, 1999
−10
−20
0
20
40
Share of population aged 25+ years out of the labor force
Sources: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team for
Statistical Development, World Bank, Washington, DC; EU-SILC (European Union Statistics on Income
and Living Conditions), Eurostat, Luxembourg, http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal
/microdata/eu_silc.
completed only primary education relative to the comparison group in Kazakhstan. Finally, a higher proportion of household heads are self-employed in Georgia
compared with Kazakhstan, where more people appear to be working as employees (figure 3.11). Educational attainment at the bottom is also at a considerably
higher level in Poland than in Georgia, and, among these countries, Poland has
the largest share of household heads working as employees rather than selfemployed. Poland, however, differs because around 24 percent of its labor force
is employed in the public sector, against only 9 percent in Georgia and around 20
percent in Kazakhstan.
Under these conditions, our framework implies that, if incomes among the
bottom 40 are to grow as quickly as incomes among the top 60, some offsetting
elements must be in place. Thus, for instance, the returns to relatively unskilled
FIGURE 3.9
Better Asset Holdings
and More Intense Use of
Assets Are Associated with
Stronger Growth among
the Bottom 40
36 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
FIGURE 3.10
The Aged Dependency
Ratio and Income Growth
among the Bottom 40
Show a Negative Relation
15
SVK, 2004
10
Income growth, %
SVK, 2005
5
BLR, 2006
LTU, 2004
RUS, 2004
TJK, 1999
EST, 2004
LVA, 2004
KAZ, 2001
BLR, 1999
ALB, 2005
HUN, 2005
ARM, 2001
MDA, 2006
UKR, 2002
TUR, 2002
ROM, 1999 LVA, 2005
CZE, 2005 KAZ, 2006
MKD,
2003
CZE, 2004
SVN, 2005 MNE, 2005
GEO, 2006
EST, 2005 POL, 1999
HUN, 2004
MNE, 2006
KSV, 2003
SVN, 2004
LTU, 2005
TJK, 2004
0
−5
KSV, 2006
SRB, 2007
SRB, 2003
HRV, 2004
−10
GEO, 1999
−10
−5
0
5
10
15
20
Aged dependency ratio (population aged 65+/population aged 15–64)
Sources: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team for
Statistical Development, World Bank, Washington, DC; EU-SILC (European Union Statistics on Income
and Living Conditions), Eurostat, Luxembourg, http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal
/microdata/eu_silc.
FIGURE 3.11
Differences in Asset Holdings and in Asset Use Help Explain Differences in Bottom 40 Performance
Ratios or percent of household heads
0.6
0.57
0.5
0.44
0.4
0.3
0.38
0.31
0.2
0.2
0.18
0.13
0.1
0.2
0.2
0.16 0.15
0.12
0.07
0.06
0.05
0.02
0
Child
dependency
Elderly
dependency
Demographic
Household
head with
postsecondary
education
Household
head with
tertiary
education
Household head: Household head: Household head: Household head:
employee
self-employed
unemployed
out of labor
force
Education
Labor market
Georgia
Kazakhstan
Source: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team for Statistical Development, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
● 37
The Drivers of Shared Prosperity
FIGURE 3.12
The High Dependency on
Transfers of the Bottom 40
in Romania, 2007–10
5.05
Non–labor income per adult
1.66
Average earnings of economically active adults
Share of adults
0.14
Share of economically active adults
−0.38
Taxes
−1.06
−2
−1
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Share of income growth, %
Source: Azevedo and Nguyen 2014.
Note: Shapley decomposition of income growth among the bottom 40 using income per capita
(2005 purchasing power parity U.S. dollars).
people must be higher, or social transfers must play a compensating role. Otherwise, the bottom 40 in Georgia would continue to be systematically less able to
contribute to growth by exploiting productively the assets they possess.
Conversely, we can learn from the case of countries with similar bottom 40
growth, but appreciably different levels of GDP growth. For example, although
Romania and Tajikistan enjoyed similar GDP growth before 2005 (around 6 percent annually), GDP responded differently in each country during the period that
encompasses the global crisis of 2008–09 (that is, 2005 to 2010). During the latter
period, Tajikistan continued to grow at over 4 percent, while GDP growth in
Romania averaged between 1 percent and 2 percent a year. Nonetheless, incomes
among the bottom 40 in these two countries grew at a similar pace, slightly above
6 percent a year. A decomposition of the sources of this income growth in these
countries shows, however, that in Tajikistan, labor market earnings and remittances explain about 40 percent and 12 percent of total income growth, respectively, whereas, in Romania, transfers explain close to 90 percent of the income
change among the bottom 40 between 2007 and 2010 (Azevedo and Nguyen
2014; figure 3.12).
Given that labor income is the main driver behind income growth among the
bottom 40 in Tajikistan, it would seem that this country would show a more sustainable growth pattern. Nonetheless, most of the growth in earnings has been
derived from wages, not from an increase in the share of economically active
adults, which increased, but only slightly (figure 3.13). Our framework allows us to
disentangle the various elements and understand the implications of these patterns for the sustainability of the observed rate of income growth among the bottom 40. The patterns seem more favorable to Tajikistan given the increasingly
limited fiscal space in Romania to sustain income growth via social assistance and
pensions. In Romania, going forward, sustaining growth among the bottom 40 will
depend on greater labor productivity and a higher employment rate.
38 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
FIGURE 3.13
Income Growth among the
Bottom 40 in Tajikistan in
2005–10 Was Driven by
Market Incomes
Other income per adult
4.9
Remittances per adult
4.7
Social assistance per adult
1.5
Pensions per adult
4.2
Average earnings per economically active adult
15.8
Share of economically active adults
3.0
Share of adults
2.2
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Share of income growth, %
Source: Azevedo, Atamanov, and Rajabov 2014.
As reflected in these country examples and looking at the regional averages,
the framework represents a useful way to approximate the heterogeneity in the
growth of the bottom 40. The specifics, however, rely fundamentally on context.
There may be different combinations of elements on the supply and demand side
that explain the observed outcomes.
Notes
1. Social capital refers to the preferential treatment and social cooperation among individuals and groups that can contribute to the economic gains of these individuals and
groups.
2. In some countries, there has been an effort to link (or condition) social assistance programs, investments in human capital, and the health of the next generation (through
conditional cash transfer programs). This has been considered a way to maximize the
productive impact of social assistance.
3. Schwarz et al. (2014) have analyzed the impact of demographic dynamics on the sustainability of the region’s pension systems, raising concerns about the efficiency and fiscal
implications of generous pension systems in countries such as Bosnia and Herzegovina,
the former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, Montenegro, Serbia, and Ukraine (labeled
high-spending transition economies by Schwarz et al.).
4. Returns to education are estimated using a regression model with data from the RLMSHSE (Russia Longitudinal Monitoring Survey–Higher School of Economics), National
Research University Higher School of Economics; ZAO Demoscope; Carolina Population
Center, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill; and Institute of Sociology RAS,
http://www.cpc.unc.edu/projects/rlms-hse. The analysis follows Mincer (1974): an
econometric equation relating hourly wages to age and education levels is defined and
estimated for the years 2000, 2005, and 2010, and a second series of equations allows
the relationship between education and wages to differ between individuals in the bottom 40 and individuals in the top 60.
The Drivers of Shared Prosperity
References
Attanasio, Orazio P., and Miguel Székely. 1999. “An Asset-Based Approach to the Analysis
of Poverty in Latin America.” Working Paper R-376, Inter-American Development Bank,
Washington, DC.
Azevedo, Joâo Pedro, Aziz Atamanov, and Alisher Rajabov. 2014. “Poverty Reduction and
Shared Prosperity in Tajikistan: A Diagnostic.” Poverty Reduction and Economic Management, Europe and Central Asia Region, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Azevedo, Joâo Pedro, and Minh Cong Nguyen. 2014. “Understanding Shared Prosperity:
A Decomposition.” World Bank, Washington, DC.
Bourguignon, François. 2001. “The Pace of Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction.”
Paper presented at CESifo Group’s Conference “Growth and Inequality: Issues and
Policy Implications,” Munich, May 18–20.
Carter, Michael R., and Christopher B. Barrett. 2006. “The Economics of Poverty Traps and
Persistent Poverty: An Asset-Based Approach.” Journal of Development Studies 42 (2):
178–99.
ECATSD (Europe and Central Asia Team for Statistical Development). 2014. ECAPOV
Harmonization Guidelines. March. Washington, DC: World Bank.
European Commission. 2010. “Croatia 2010 Progress Report.” Commission Staff Working
Document SEC (2010) 1326 (November 9), European Commission, Brussels.
Eurostat. 2012. “European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (EU-SILC),
2005–11.” Eurostat, Luxembourg. http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page
/portal/microdata/eu_silc.
Mincer, Jacob A. 1974. Schooling, Experience, and Earnings. Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Schwarz, Anita M., Omar S. Arias, Asta Zviniene, Heinz P. Rudolph, Sebastian Eckardt,
Johannes Koettl, Herwig Immervoll, and Miglena Abels. 2014. The Inverting Pyramid:
Pension Systems Facing Demographic Challenges in Europe and Central Asia. Washington, DC: World Bank.
World Bank. 2011. “Azerbaijan, Building Assets and Promoting Self Reliance: The Livelihoods of Internally Displaced Persons.” Report AAA64–AZ (October), World Bank,
Washington, DC. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/2794.
● 39
Structural and Cyclical Variables
within the Framework
Several variables in the framework introduced in the previous chapter are outside
the control of individuals; instead, they are determined by macroeconomic forces.
Thus, increases in wage rates follow economy-wide productivity trends, and skill
premiums are determined by the overall demand and supply of skilled labor. Similarly, other asset prices result from general market forces; the intensity of the use
of endowments is largely affected by the macroeconomic business cycle; and
transfers are supplied because of the social security system that has been established. All individuals in a country face the same macroeconomic environment, but
this environment will affect individuals differently, depending on the characteristics of the individuals and on the moment in time. During recessions, incomes
among certain groups may be protected more than incomes among other groups.
During economic booms, people with substantial assets will benefit more than
other people. This all means that macroeconomic forces, in combination with
individual characteristics, might explain the differences between the growth in
income among the bottom 40 and overall income growth in an economy. Ultimately, our framework will allow us to analyze specific macroeconomic drivers and
the impact of these drivers on income growth among the bottom 40 in a particular
period. Such an application of the framework requires the collection of additional
relevant data.
This chapter illustrates how macroeconomic forces influence incomes among
the bottom 40 heterogeneously. We examine cases of economies in which the
performance in overall growth is similar, but in which the performance in shared
prosperity differs. Conversely, we also examine countries with similar performance
41
42 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
in shared prosperity, but different overall growth outcomes. This analysis is carried
out separately for a period of steady economic growth (broadly, the decade before
2008) and for a period that includes a full cycle, the 2005–10 interval. This allows
us to identify a series of aggregate macroeconomic variables—GDP growth, shifts
in the real exchange rate, demographic trends, employment, macro balances—
and how these variables are linked to the performance of the bottom 40.
The structure of an economy in terms of sectoral production and employment
is also a variable beyond the control of individuals. The Europe and Central Asia
region exhibits a wide array of economic structures, including countries relying
predominantly on agriculture for employment and value added growth, countries
with a stronger manufacturing sector that is integrated with Western Europe, and
countries dependent on commodity exports. How do the initial economic structures or shifts in these structures affect the bottom 40? Once again, the framework
can help us address this question; the second section of this chapter contains a few
specific examples.
Periods of Steady Growth and Periods of
Economic Cycles
In the long run, asset accumulation, technological progress, and productivity, as
well as changes in the key structural features of an economy, for example, urbanization, dependency ratios, and openness, are the relevant macroeconomic drivers
of sustained growth. In the short run, business cycle fluctuations in prices, employment, the current account, and government balances are among the major determinants of changes in incomes.
Ideally, we would like to analyze changes in the economic fortune of the bottom
40 in both sets of circumstances. This is because the policies needed to support
the long-term drivers of sustainable growth among the bottom 40 are different
relative to the interventions required to protect the bottom 40 from an economic
crisis, such as the 2008–09 financial crisis, or other short-term shocks. Data availability and comparability are the main challenges to a detailed investigation
of this issue. Household surveys have been conducted in many countries
All individuals
of Europe and Central Asia since the mid-1990s, but comparisons of per
in a country face the
capita income (or consumption) levels among the bottom 40 between
same macroeconomic
those earlier years and the recent crisis years present difficulties.1 Dealing with these challenges in the best way possible, figure 4.1 provides a
environment, but they
comparison of the growth rates in income (or consumption) among the
are affected by it
bottom 40 in 2005–10 with the same indicator during a longer period
differently.
before 2008 (for most countries).2 Note that we intentionally include an
overlap in the two periods. The longer period covers, data permitting, the
full decade before 2008, a time of relatively sustained rapid or even accelerating growth; we thus label it the steady growth period. By overlapping with the later
part of the steady growth period, 2005–10 includes three years of strong growth
up to 2008, the contraction of 2008–09, and the rebound after the crisis, a full,
pronounced cycle; we therefore label this period the cyclical period.
Figure 4.1 shows that the bottom 40 in the countries of Europe and Central Asia
experienced a sharp decline in incomes during the crisis. Because of the crisis,
● 43
Structural and Cyclical Variables within the Framework
Income growth, bottom 40, before 2008, %
SVK
45° line
LTU
18
EST
LVA
13
UKR
ARM
8
3
MNE
CZE
HUN SVN
KAZ
KGZ
TJK
BLR
FIGURE 4.1
Different Drivers Are
Affecting Income Growth
among the Bottom 40 in
Periods of Steady Growth
and Periods of Economic
Cycles
TUR
SRB
GEO
0
KSV
−2
–2
0
3
8
13
18
Income growth, bottom 40, circa 2005–10, %
Sources: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team
for Statistical Development, World Bank, Washington, DC; EU-SILC (European Union Statistics on
Income and Living Conditions), Eurostat, Luxembourg, http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal
/page/portal/microdata/eu_silc.
Note: Especially in the countries in the oval, income growth among the bottom 40 was much more
heterogeneous during the steady growth period than during the cyclical period.
growth in average incomes during the cyclical period (2005–10) was rather limited,
far below the spectacular income growth during the precrisis steady growth period
(before 2008).3 A more surprising observation is that income growth among the
bottom 40 was much more heterogeneous across countries during the steady
growth period than during the cyclical period (especially among those countries in the oval in figure 4.1). It seems that the heterogeneity before 2008
Bottom 40
reflects structural factors, while cyclical factors dominated during the
growth was more
more recent, volatile period (2005–10) and caused income growth to
heterogeneous across
become more homogeneous.
countries during the
Some of the vastly different performance of the bottom 40 across
countries during the steady growth period occurred while GDP
steady growth period
expanded at rather similar rates. For example, during 2004–08, per
(pre-2008) than during
capita GDP grew at an annual rate of 7.7 percent in Lithuania, but at a
the cyclical period.
slightly lower rate, 5.2 percent, in the Czech Republic (table 4.1). However,
the per capita income of the bottom 40 increased by more than 18 percent
annually in Lithuania, compared with only 6 percent in the Czech Republic.
What is behind the difference in performance of the bottom 40 in the Czech
Republic and Lithuania? Both countries joined the European Union (EU) in 2004
and experienced sustained GDP growth before the 2008–09 crisis. However, the
evolution of structural factors—such as demographics, sectoral production shifts
(away from agriculture and toward manufacturing and services), and labor productivity—displays noticeable differences in the two economies.
Lithuania experienced a large rise in labor productivity, coupled with growth in
total employment. Because labor earnings constitute the chief source of income
among the bottom 40, these positive changes are likely associated with improvements in the welfare of this poorer segment of the population. The indicators of
sectoral activity underline that Lithuania experienced swifter shifts that moved the
44 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
TABLE 4.1 Different Bottom 40 Income Growth, Similar GDP Growth:
Czech Republic and Lithuania, 2004–08
Percent
Variable
GDP growth
Bottom 40 income growth
Labor productivity growth
Total employment growth
Change in exports as a share of GDP
Change in industry as a share of GDP
Change in services as a share of GDP
Change in industry as a share of employment
Change in services as a share of employment
Change in remittances as a share of GDP
Change in government expenditures on social
protection as a share of GDP
Czech Republic
Lithuania
5.2
6.3
3.9
1.6
11.0
3.3
−2.4
1.3
−0.2
−0.1
1.3
7.7
18.7
5.9
1.1
8.2
−0.3
1.3
2.2
5.2
2.6
5.1
Source: World Development Indicators (database), World Bank, Washington, DC, http://data
.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators.
economy toward an employment structure in which manufacturing and services—
usually accompanied by higher value added than agriculture—account for a large
share of the total.
In contrast, labor productivity in the Czech Republic increased by a much lesser
extent, but to a similar level of total employment growth. Services shrank both in
the contribution to GDP and in relation to job creation. This may indicate that GDP
growth was being led by the expansion of other sectors, possibly less labor intensive. (See the next section for more details about the links between the structure
of the economy and income growth among the bottom 40.) Demographic trends
show another striking difference between these two countries. Even if, in levels, the
ratio of the working to the nonworking population is slightly higher in the Czech
Republic than in Lithuania, as illustrated in figure 4.2, the change in the ratio, which
matters for growth, is supportive only in the latter country.
FIGURE 4.2
In Periods of Steady Growth, Structural Variables, Such as Demography, Are Important for Shared Prosperity
a. Czech Republic
b. Lithuania
2.6
Ratio of working population to
nonworking population, 2000–10, %
Ratio of working population to
nonworking population, 2000–10, %
2.6
2.4
2.2
2.0
2.4
2.2
2.0
2000
2005
2010
2000
2005
2010
Source: World Population Prospects: The 2012 Revision (database), Population Division, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, United
Nations, http://esa.un.org/unpd/wpp/unpp/panel_population.htm.
● 45
Structural and Cyclical Variables within the Framework
TABLE 4.2 Similar Bottom 40 Income Growth, Different GDP Growth:
Kazakhstan and Kyrgyz Republic, circa 2000–08
Percent
Variable
GDP growth
Bottom 40 income growth
Labor productivity growth
Total employment growth
Change in the female labor participation rate
Change in exports as a share of GDP
Change in industry as a share of GDP
Change in services as a share of GDP
Change in industry as a share of employment
Change in services as a share of employment
Change in remittances as a share of GDP
Kazakhstan
Kyrgyz Republic
7.9
11.4
6.6
2.0
6.0
−9.5
2.3
0.5
2.6
2.8
0.1
3.8
9.8
2.8
2.0
10.0
0.3
−4.3
18.4
10.1
8.8
10.9
Source: World Development Indicators (database), World Bank, Washington, DC, http://data
.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators.
Transfers seem to play a key role in boosting the income of the bottom 40. We
observe that, in Lithuania, remittances and government expenditures on social
protection have risen, while remittances have declined in the Czech Republic.
These flows—if they have a progressive incidence—could explain a significant part
of the difference in income growth among the bottom 40 in the two countries.
On the other side of the coin, consider the case of Kazakhstan and the Kyrgyz
Republic, which have experienced almost identical income growth among the
bottom 40 despite the differences in macro performance. The patterns that
The diverse
have arisen are consistent with the previous example (table 4.2). Despite
pattern of aggregate
a lower GDP growth rate, the Kyrgyz Republic showed a substantial
growth helps explain
increase in the share of services in total value added, mirroring part of
the structural change observed in Lithuania. Driven mainly by an
the heterogeneity in
upsurge of 4.8 percent in mining activity, sectoral shifts in Kazakhstan
growth of the bottom
led to a boost in the importance of the industrial sector. The contribution of mining to overall growth in Kazakhstan was 34.3 percent, likely
40 across the region.
associated with a shift in the factorial distribution of income that favored
natural resources and capital versus labor. Other differences include the fact
that the Kyrgyz Republic widened trade openness considerably, generating a
rise in exports, while, in contrast, Kazakhstan tightened trade.
Similar to Lithuania, the importance of industry and services as a share of total
employment rose considerably in the Kyrgyz Republic, which might have increased
the average wage of the bottom 40. Meanwhile, in Kazakhstan, the average wage
and the employment shares remained fairly stable. Finally, we observe a boost in
remittances of 11 percent in the Kyrgyz Republic, which represented, potentially,
a major contribution to the welfare of the bottom 40.
In summary, the same labor market changes, structural factors, and variations
in transfers that boosted shared prosperity in Lithuania and helped in the Kyrgyz
Republic, slowed progress in the Czech Republic and Kazakhstan.
As these examples show, by affecting returns and the intensity of the use of
assets in a way that is not uniform (see above), the nature and composition of
aggregate growth matter perhaps even more than the actual growth rate. During
the period of rapid growth and few cyclical fluctuations that we consider here,
46 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
TABLE 4.3 Similar Bottom 40 Income Growth, Different GDP Growth:
Selected Countries, 2005–10
Percent
Country
Kazakhstan
Tajikistan
Kyrgyz Republic
Latvia
Estonia
Hungary
GDP growth
Bottom 40 income growth
Good
3.5
4.3
3.9
Inferior
−0.1
0.1
0
Good
6.1
6.1
5.8
Good
4.7
4.1
1.6
Sources: ECAPOV database harmonization as of February 2014, Europe and Central Asia Team
for Statistical Development, World Bank, Washington, DC; EU-SILC (European Union Statistics on
Income and Living Conditions), Eurostat, Luxembourg, http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal
/page/portal/microdata/eu_silc; World Development Indicators (database), World Bank,
Washington, DC, http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators.
there was an association—note we make no claim of causality—between improvements in the welfare of the bottom 40 and job creation, participation rates, and
productivity growth. A structural transition toward a service economy, coupled
with supportive population trends, also seems to be accompanied by more inclusive growth patterns.
Are these conjectures still valid if we analyze the 2005–10 cyclical period? Once
again, it is helpful to start by contrasting countries showing variations in performance in the aggregate and in income growth among the bottom 40. Consider,
for example, the set of countries in table 4.3. These countries have a relatively
good record in shared prosperity even if some enjoyed positive GDP growth, while
others were caught up in recession or stagnation during the period.
The Baltic economies were the most overheated in Europe and Central Asia on
the eve of the financial crisis. Two of them, Latvia and Estonia, together with Hungary, represent the subgroup with relatively high-income growth among the bottom 40, but low GDP growth. Unlike these three EU member countries, the Central
Asian countries (and Moldova)—the contrasting subgroup in table 4.3—were
much less affected by the 2008–09 global financial crisis and thus did not experience a severe economic contraction. Mainly because of their less-open economies
and minimal exposure to global capital markets, Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic,
Moldova, and Tajikistan limited the negative impact of the global crisis on the
domestic market (figure 4.3).
Current account imbalances in the three EU countries were caused by a large
influx of foreign capital, mainly directed toward the nontradable sector. These
countries experienced price and wage inflation as a consequence of the inflows,
which also triggered a domestic demand and credit boom. The crisis-mandated
adjustment in these countries is especially visible in the change in current accounts
(or the net trade positions depicted in figure 4.4). Estonia and Latvia—because of
the drop in domestic demand and a boost in exports triggered by depreciated real
exchange rates—experienced 11 and 13 GDP percentage point improvements in
their net trade balance, respectively.4
It is likely that the change in the real exchange rate affected people differently
across sectors, benefiting those in exportable and import-substituting industries,
while hurting those employed in nontradable sectors. Using the framework,
● 47
Structural and Cyclical Variables within the Framework
FIGURE 4.3
The Baltic States Were
More Affected by the
2008–09 Global Financial
Crisis
20
Per capita GDP growth, 2006–12, %
15
10
2006
5
2007
2008
0
2009
2010
–5
2011
2012
–10
–15
–20
Latvia
Estonia
Hungary
Kyrgyz
Republic
Kazakhstan
Tajikistan
Source: World Development Indicators (database), World Bank, Washington, DC, http://data
.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators.
we should then be able to trace these macro shocks to the income of individuals
and, specifically, to individuals in the bottom 40.
The framework also identifies transfers as one of the sources of household
incomes. During the cyclical period, public transfers appear to have played a quite
important role. The fiscal adjustment imposed by the crisis was mitigated by the
greater use of EU funds and, in the case of Latvia, of financial assistance from the
International Monetary Fund. Government spending rose by 7.1 percent in Estonia and 7.6 percent in Latvia and remained high, at 50 percent of GDP, in
Shared
Hungary. More government expenditure on social security helped cushion
poverty impacts by protecting the incomes of existing beneficiaries and
prosperity is linked to
expanding the coverage to new ones (Williams et al. 2012). Governmacroeconomic growth,
ment expenditure in Kazakhstan changed only marginally (by 1.8 perbut also to changes in the
cent), whereas, in the Kyrgyz Republic and Tajikistan, it rose by 8.3 perlabor market, structural
cent and 7.4 percent, respectively (figure 4.5).
These examples indicate that there are links between shared prosshifts, and policy
perity and macroeconomic growth, changes in the labor market, strucinterventions.
tural shifts, and policy interventions. However, we have explored these
associations in an ad hoc fashion, with no attempt at controlling for potential
cross effects. Up to this point, we have not gauged the strength of the relationship between shared prosperity and any of these specific variables in a setting that
keeps the others constant. A multivariate approach is needed to isolate the effect
of an individual variable if nothing else changes; the simplest method is a regression analysis.
Continuing with the distinction between the steady growth period and the
cyclical period, we carry out our analysis in two steps: one dealing with the longer
period before 2008 and one dealing with the 2005–10 interval, which includes the
2008–09 crisis.5
48 ●
FIGURE 4.4
Large Adjustments in
Tradable Sectors Accompany
Crises and Economic Cycles
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
Bulgaria
15.8
Latvia
13.0
Moldova
11.5
Romania
11.4
Estonia
11.3
Hungary
10.4
9.4
Serbia
8.1
Slovak Republic
Kyrgyz Republic
7.6
6.2
Lithuania
4.2
Armenia
3.3
Czech Republic
1.5
Slovenia
Georgia
0
Kosovo
0
Montenegro
0
–0.6
Kazakhstan
–1.0
Turkey
–1.7
Poland
–3.5
Croatia
Belarus
–7.4
Ukraine
–8.3
Russian Federation
–8.6
Macedonia, FYR
Tajikistan
–8.7
–10.0
Albania –52.6
–30 –25 –20 –15 –10 –5
0
5
10
15
20
Changes in the balance of trade, circa 2005–10, % of GDP
Source: World Development Indicators (database), World Bank, Washington, DC, http://data
.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators.
The results confirm—in a context in which there is no other change—some
of our previous observations.6 For instance, they suggest that there is a significant
positive relationship between the level of industrialization, any change in this
level, and income growth among the bottom 40. A graphical representation of this
relationship and of that with the change in the labor market participation rate is
shown in figure 4.6. Using the case of the Kyrgyz Republic as an example may
clarify how these results can be read. The slope of the line in panel a, figure 4.6 is
about 4, meaning that every 1 percent change in the industrial employment share
is associated with a 4 percentage point change in income growth among the
bottom 40 (if we hold constant all other factors linked to this growth). During
2000–04, the first part of the steady growth period, the income of the bottom 40
● 49
Structural and Cyclical Variables within the Framework
FIGURE 4.5
Countercyclical Policies Can
Potentially Protect Incomes
among the Bottom 40 during
a Crisis
Hungary
Latvia
Government expenditure, % of GDP, initial year
Government expenditure, % of GDP, final year
Estonia
Kyrgyz Republic
Tajikistan
Kazakhstan
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
Government expenditures, circa 2005–10, % of GDP
Source: World Development Indicators (database), World Bank,
Washington, DC, http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world
-development-indicators.
Note: Along the x-axis, the initial year is, broadly, 2005, but not always,
while the final year is, broadly, but not always 2010.
FIGURE 4.6
Shifts toward Manufacturing (and Services) and Increases in Participation Are Associated with Stronger
Growth among the Bottom 40
a. Change in industrial share in employment, steady growth period
b. Change in labor participation, steady growth period
10
Income growth, bottom 40, %
Income growth, bottom 40, %
10
5
0
–5
–10
5
0
–5
–10
−1
−0.5
0
0.5
1
Change in industrial share in employment, %
−2
−1
0
1
Change in labor participation rate, %
Note: The panels are partial regression plots or added variable plots, which are often used to illustrate graphically the relationship between
the dependent variable and one of the independent variables from a multivariate regression model. Plots of this type often have a ceteris
paribus interpretation because they capture the relationship between the two variables, while the effects of the remaining independent
variables are taken out. The horizontal axis in a partial regression plot represents the residuals from regressing one independent variable on
all the other independent variables from the original regression. The vertical axis represents the residuals from regressing the dependent
variable on the original set of independent variables, with the variable plotted on the horizontal axis omitted from the regression. Panel a:
coef. = 4.0422007, se = 1.932234, t = 2.09; panel b: coef. = 3.668389, se = 1.4054773, t = 2.61.
50 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
FIGURE 4.7
GDP Growth and Income Growth of the Bottom 40 Are More Strongly Associated during Steady Growth
Than during Cyclical Periods
a. Steady growth period
b. Cyclical period
10
Income growth, bottom 40, %
Income growth, bottom 40, %
10
5
0
–5
–10
5
0
–5
–10
−4
−2
0
2
4
Per capita GDP growth, % (constant local currency units)
−4
−2
0
2
4
Per capita GDP growth, % (constant local currency units)
Note: Partial regression plots; see the note to figure 4.6 for a detailed explanation. Panel a: coef. = 2.2179138, se = .52473303, t = 4.23;
panel b: coef. = .86063292, se = .4951238, t = 1.74.
expanded at a yearly rate of 11.5 percent in the Kyrgyz Republic. During this same
period, the share of employment in the industrial sectors in the Kyrgyz Republic
rose by 1.7 percentage points. In terms of the relationship shown in figure 4.6,
about 7 percentage points of the 11.5 percent income growth among the bottom
40 are associated with the industrialization of employment, while other factors
contributed to the remaining 4 points.7
We replicate the analysis for the 2005–10 cyclical period. Some interesting results emerge. The correlation between overall growth and income
Overall growth
growth among the bottom 40, which was strong and statistically signifiand growth of the
cant during the steady growth period, becomes insignificant during the
bottom 40 were more
cyclical period (figure 4.7). What might explain the less significant association in the short-term cyclical period? One factor may be related to
strongly correlated in the
profits. Profits tend to be the most volatile component of added value,
steady growth period
much more than labor earnings, which may clarify why GDP growth and
(pre-2008).
income growth among the bottom 40 (which mainly consists of growth in
labor income) are disconnected in 2005–10.8
This confirms a result highlighted earlier: the pattern of economic growth,
perhaps even more than the magnitude, affects the opportunities of people at the
lower end of the income distribution. However, this link is much clearer in periods
with relatively steady growth than in more cyclical periods.
Economic Structure and Growth Opportunities among
the Bottom 40
Interindustry links, production, export specialization, and the relative abundance
of factors, as well as import dependency, are some of the relevant structural
Structural and Cyclical Variables within the Framework
● 51
features influencing growth and the incidence of growth. The links between the
structure of the economy and income growth among the bottom 40 are highlighted using a simple linear multiplier model based on a recent social accounting
matrix (SAM) (see annex 4B for details). In nontechnical terms, a multiplier indicates the amount of the rise in the income for a certain factor, for example unskilled
labor, in response to a rise in the demand for a specific product, for example bread.
It is known as a multiplier because it accounts not only for the direct demand for
the unskilled labor needed to produce the additional bread, but also for the indirect effects associated with the demand for the intermediates (flour, water, electricity, and so on) that are included in the production. To supply additional intermediates, further demands of unskilled labor arise, and so on. The size of the multipliers
depends on the structure of the economy. Looking at the multipliers for unskilled
labor relative to those for skilled labor or capital can thus provide a quick summary
of how the structure of the economy affects income growth among the bottom 40
(assuming that unskilled labor is the main source of income among this group).
Table 4.4 offers a snapshot of the economic structure in the region. The table
collects simple country-specific and regional averages for the sectoral structures of
GDP and employment by skill level. Europe and Central Asia is a heterogeneous
region. On average, agriculture accounts for about 10 percent of GDP, but the
share varies from a high of 20 percent in the Kyrgyz Republic and 18 percent in
Georgia to a low of 3 percent in Hungary. In the mining sector, a coefficient
Structural economic
of variation of almost 200 percent signals much larger variations around
the regional mean of 10 percent: from 60.0 percent in Azerbaijan to 0.4
features, such as
percent in the Kyrgyz Republic. Finally, the wide range in the share of
production specialization
GDP generated by utilities—a composite sector including energy,
water, telecommunications, and other infrastructure services—potenand sectoral employment,
tially indicates how countries in the region have organized production
can influence the
in these crucial infrastructure sectors differently.
incidence of growth.
We observe a similar heterogeneity in employment structures. However, the most striking regional features are the concentration of unskilled
employment in agriculture and food production and the concentration of
skilled employment in services. About one-third of unskilled workers are employed
in agriculture and food production, whereas more than half of skilled individuals
are working in services.
Table 4.4 also reports on labor inputs, which are expressed as the number of
workers needed to produce output valued at $1 million given the current (static)
structure of production in these countries. The inputs illustrate the extensive diversity across these economies: on average about 50 workers—12 unskilled and 36
skilled—are employed for every $1 million in output. Across the region, the ratio
varies from 12 workers to 177 workers; for reference, in China and the United
States, 50 and 5 workers, respectively, are used to produce $1 million in output.
Using input-output tables embedded in the SAM, we may estimate the income
multiplier effects associated with a change in demand. The SAM multipliers can be
seen as a first approximation of the full general equilibrium effects that derive from
an increase in demand. These multipliers do not merely cover the direct increase
in the use of the factor (and thus in the associated income) that is needed to satisfy
the additional final demand (as in the last two rows of table 4.4), but also the indirect effect derived from the interindustry links in the economy.
52 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
TABLE 4.4 Economic Structure, Selected Countries, Europe and Central Asia, 2007
Indicator
Albania
Armenia
Azerbaijan
Belarus
Bulgaria
Structure of GDP, by sector, %
Agriculture
13
11
6
5
4
Food products
3
9
1
3
5
Mining
4
3
60
4
3
Manufacturing
8
8
2
17
15
Utilities
2
9
5
12
11
Construction
8
34
7
12
8
Firm services
14
2
3
7
22
Other services
49
25
18
40
32
Structure of unskilled employment, by sector, %
Agriculture
36
36
36
36
0
Food products
1
13
1
2
5
Mining
1
2
17
1
6
Manufacturing
10
9
3
17
28
Utilities
1
5
11
7
7
Construction
8
15
6
7
8
Firm services
9
1
3
3
8
Other services
33
18
22
25
37
Structure of skilled employment, by sector, %
Agriculture
8
8
8
8
5
Food products
1
12
1
2
4
Mining
1
3
23
2
2
Manufacturing
9
9
2
15
21
Utilities
2
9
17
12
8
Construction
13
25
9
12
9
Firm services
14
3
5
6
9
Other services
52
31
34
43
42
Labor multiplier: how many workers are needed to produce one unit of output, that is, $1 million
All
50
61
50
28
31
Unskilled
16
20
16
9
5
Skilled
34
41
34
19
26
Georgia
Hungary
18
3
2
6
3
6
6
57
3
5
1
27
4
8
24
28
25
2
27
3
2
3
2
36
12
8
3
43
2
4
8
19
3
4
1
8
5
5
5
69
4
6
1
29
4
7
15
35
76
1
75
12
2
11
Sources: Household surveys; GTAP Data Base, Global Trade Analysis Project, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Department of Agricultural
Economics, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN, https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/databases/default.asp.
Note: n.a. = not applicable.
We present two relevant sets of figures. In the first set, the multipliers are shown
for the incomes of unskilled labor, skilled labor, natural resources (which are considered a factor of production), and capital that are associated with an increase in
the demand for agricultural, mining, and manufacturing products (figures 4.8 and
4.9). The countries in the figures are ranked according to the size of the multipliers,
from the largest, at the top, to the smallest, at the bottom. Thus, for example, for
every dollar of additional demand for agricultural products, unskilled workers
enjoy an increase of $0.52 in income in Turkey (figure 4.8, panel a). In the case of
an increase of $1.00 in the demand for mining products, the incomes of unskilled
workers in Kazakhstan go up by $0.17 (figure 4.8, panel b), and so on.
Figure 4.8 shows that the intersectoral links as well as the household consumption loops—that is, the feedback effects from the initial increase in demand,
through the additional demand for intermediate goods, and through the increase
in final demand—can be substantial. The direct increase in the demand for
unskilled labor (also called the technical coefficient) because of a rise in the
● 53
Structural and Cyclical Variables within the Framework
Kazakhstan
Kyrgyz Republic
Romania
Russian
Federation
Turkey
Ukraine
Simple average
5
3
19
11
4
8
13
37
20
1
0
8
42
4
2
24
8
12
3
20
5
11
17
25
6
2
16
10
5
9
10
43
7
5
2
18
2
7
10
48
9
2
4
7
19
5
12
41
9
4
9
12
9
10
11
36
36
2
6
12
3
5
7
29
36
1
0
10
27
3
2
20
40
4
6
17
3
6
5
20
12
3
5
20
6
8
8
38
36
3
1
9
1
7
6
36
32
2
2
7
16
4
7
30
29
4
6
15
7
6
5
28
8
2
8
10
5
8
12
48
8
1
0
8
43
5
3
32
8
6
2
26
5
10
8
35
4
2
5
14
7
10
10
47
7
2
2
7
2
11
10
59
9
2
3
8
21
6
9
40
7
4
4
13
11
10
8
43
19
6
13
177
58
119
24
4
20
27
5
22
21
12
9
47
1
46
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
demand for agricultural products is 0.3 in Turkey (that is, $0.30 per $1.00 increase
in the demand for agricultural products), whereas the full multiplier effect is 0.5.
The impact of the same unitary increase in the demand for agricultural, mining,
and manufacturing products is quite different if the incomes of skilled labor, capital, or natural resources are considered (figure 4.9). The multipliers for the incomes
of skilled workers tend to be higher than those for unskilled workers, and they
benefit from increases in the demand for any of the three products we consider
here. In Russia, for example, an increase in the demand for agricultural, mining,
and manufacturing products of a dollar generates an increase of $0.56, $0.34, and
$0.32, respectively, in the incomes of skilled workers; whereas it produces an
impact of $0.20, $0.06, and $0.07, respectively, in the incomes of the relevant
unskilled workers. Unskilled workers are earning most of their incomes from primary activities and tend to be less interconnected with the rest of the economy.
Perhaps not surprisingly, natural resources, panels d–f in figure 4.9, show an even
larger concentration of income multipliers. These are above $0.10 in only three
54 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
FIGURE 4.8
Income Multipliers Highlight the Wide Range in Structure in the Economies of Europe and Central Asia, Part 1
a. Change in unskilled labor income arising from a $1.00 increase
in the demand for agricultural products
b. Change in unskilled labor income arising from a $1.00 increase
in the demand for mining products
0.52
Turkey
0.28
Belarus
0.22
0.20
0.10
0.02
0.02
0.02
0.02
Hungary
0.09
0
Ukraine
0.04
0
0.03
Belarus
0.10
Ukraine
0.06
0.06
Bulgaria
Kyrgyz
Republic
Georgia
0.20
Hungary
0.07
Romania
Russian
Federation
Azerbaijan
0.24
Bulgaria
Russian
Federation
Georgia
0.09
Armenia
0.35
Romania
0.11
Albania
0.33
Kazakhstan
0.12
Turkey
0.37
Azerbaijan
0.17
Kazakhstan
0.43
Albania
Kyrgyz
Republic
Armenia
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.50
0.60
0.05
0
0.10
0.15
0.20
Income multipliers, U.S. dollars
Income multipliers, U.S. dollars
c. Change in unskilled labor income arising from a $1.00 increase
in the demand for manufacturing products
0.17
Turkey
Armenia
0.14
0.12
Kazakhstan
Albania
0.11
Belarus
0.10
Kyrgyz Republic
Russian
Federation
Romania
0.10
0.07
0.06
Bulgaria
0.04
Hungary
0.03
Azerbaijan
0.03
0.02
Georgia
0.01
Ukraine
0
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
Income multipliers, U.S. dollars
Source: GTAP Data Base, Global Trade Analysis Project, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Department of Agricultural Economics, Purdue
University, West Lafayette, IN, https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/databases/default.asp.
Note: Some multipliers have been rounded.
countries—Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, and Russia—and only with respect to increases
in the demand for mining products.
The second set of graphical representations of the economic structure of these
countries, shown in figure 4.10, depicts the forward and backward links across the
eight production sectors considered here. A backward link measures the strength
(in percentage terms) of a sector’s interindustry links if we are considering the
● 55
Structural and Cyclical Variables within the Framework
FIGURE 4.9
Income Multipliers Highlight the Wide Range in Structure in the Economies of Europe and Central Asia, Part 2
a. Change in skilled labor income arising from a $1.00 increase
in the demand for agricultural products
Georgia
b. Change in skilled labor income arising from a $1.00 increase in
the demand for mining products
0.80
Ukraine
Romania
Russian
Federation
Hungary
0.66
0.56
0.41
Turkey
Turkey
Kyrgyz
Republic
Kazakhstan
0.41
Georgia
0.35
0.32
0.23
0.20
0.15
0.10
Bulgaria
0.10
Hungary
0.10
0.07
Belarus
Kyrgyz
Republic
0.18
0
0.19
0.17
Azerbaijan
0.30
Belarus
0.24
0.19
Armenia
0.33
Azerbaijan
0.31
Albania
Albania
Bulgaria
0.34
Ukraine
0.52
Armenia
0.37
Kazakhstan
Russian
Federation
Romania
0.76
0.40
0.60
0.80
1.00
0.04
0
0.05
Income multipliers, U.S. dollars
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
0.30
0.35
0.40
Income multipliers, U.S. dollars
c. Change in skilled labor income arising from a $1.00 increase
in the demand for manufacturing products
Romania
Russian
Federation
Ukraine
0.40
0.32
0.31
Georgia
0.27
Turkey
0.26
Hungary
0.25
Kazakhstan
0.22
Bulgaria
0.20
Armenia
0.20
Belarus
0.18
Albania
Kyrgyz
Republic
Azerbaijan
0.17
0.14
0.04
0
0.10
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.50
Income multipliers, U.S. dollars
(Continued)
sector’s demand for intermediate goods; a forward link measures the sector’s
deliveries of output (as intermediate goods) to the rest of the economy (see
Azevedo 2014).
We then classify sectors as weak if both the forward and the backward links are
less than 1, key if they are both above 1, and forward or backward oriented if one
link, but not the other, is above 1. In eight of the countries we consider, the mining
sector is weak: it tends to be an enclave sector the expansion of which does not
56 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
FIGURE 4.9
Income Multipliers Highlight the Wide Range in Structure in the Economies of Europe and Central Asia, Part 2
(continued)
d. Change in natural resources income arising from a $1.00
increase in the demand for agricultural products
e. Change in natural resources income arising from a $1.00
increase in the demand for mining products
Azerbaijan
0.03
Kazakhstan
Azerbaijan
Russian
Federation
Albania
0.03
0.01
Ukraine
Turkey
Georgia
0.06
Ukraine
0.05
0.01
Turkey
0.05
0.01
Armenia
0.01
Romania
0.19
0.08
Romania
0.01
Belarus
0.27
0.20
Kazakhstan
Russian
Federation
Albania
0.03
0.03
Georgia
0
0.02
Armenia
0
Bulgaria
0.02
Bulgaria
Kyrgyz
Republic
Hungary
0
Belarus
0.02
Hungary
Kyrgyz
Republic
0
0
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.01
0.01
0.05
0
Income multipliers, U.S. dollars
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
0.30
Income multipliers, U.S. dollars
f. Change in natural resources income arising from a $1.00 increase
in the demand for manufacturing products
0.03
Kazakhstan
Russian
Federation
Azerbaijan
0.03
0.02
Ukraine
0.01
0.01
Albania
Romania
0.01
Armenia
0
Turkey
0
Bulgaria
0
Belarus
0
Georgia
Kyrgyz
Republic
Hungary
0
0
0
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
Income multipliers, U.S. dollars
(Continued)
generate significant beneficial effects for the rest of the economy by stimulating
demand for inputs or efficiently delivering inputs to other sectors. We also find the
utility or infrastructure sectors located across the four quadrants, which points to
the diversity across the region and the possibility, for a number of countries, of
improvements in the physical infrastructure connections with the rest of the econ-
● 57
Structural and Cyclical Variables within the Framework
FIGURE 4.9
Income Multipliers Highlight the Wide Range in Structure in the Economies of Europe and Central Asia, Part 2
(continued)
g. Change in capital income arising from a $1.00 increase in the
demand for agricultural products
Turkey
Kyrgyz
Republic
Albania
h. Change in capital income arising from a $1.00 increase in
the demand for mining products
Azerbaijan
Russian
Federation
Albania
0.94
0.69
0.65
Romania
Bulgaria
Russian
Federation
Hungary
0.44
Armenia
Georgia
0.44
Ukraine
0.21
0.20
0.16
0.15
Hungary
Kyrgyz
Republic
Belarus
0.30
0
0.19
0.17
Georgia
0.22
Belarus
0.31
Bulgaria
0.37
Azerbaijan
0.41
Romania
0.33
Kazakhstan
0.43
Turkey
0.56
0.48
Ukraine
0.52
Kazakhstan
0.58
Armenia
0.68
0.63
0.40
0.60
0.80
1.00
0.12
0.09
0.09
0.10
0
Income multipliers, U.S. dollars
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.50
0.60
0.70
0.80
Income multipliers, U.S. dollars
i. Change in capital income arising from a $1.00 increase in the demand
for manufacturing products
Turkey
0.71
Russian Federation
0.38
Kyrgyz Republic
0.35
Romania
0.34
Albania
0.30
Hungary
0.29
Armenia
0.26
Bulgaria
0.26
Ukraine
0.22
Kazakhstan
0.22
Georgia
0.18
Belarus
0.17
Azerbaijan
0.11
0
0.10
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.50
0.60
0.70
0.80
Income multipliers, U.S. dollars
Source: GTAP Data Base, Global Trade Analysis Project, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Department of Agricultural Economics, Purdue
University, West Lafayette, IN, https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/databases/default.asp.
Note: Some multipliers have been rounded.
omy. Finally, manufacturing prominently figures as the most crucial forwardoriented sector, while agriculture is the most common backward-oriented sector.
A first conclusion based on these calculations is that economic structures vastly
differ across the countries of the region. In economies in which agriculture still
58 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
FIGURE 4.10
Backward and Forward Links, Selected Countries, Europe and Central Asia, 2007
a. Albania
2.55
b. Armenia
Forward oriented
Forward oriented
Key
Other services
Agriculture
1.55
Agriculture
Manufacturing
1.05
Firm services
Food products
Manufacturing
0.76
Utilities
Mining
0.56
Weak
0.05
0.40 0.50
Construction
0.60
0.70
0.80
0.90
1.00
1.10
1.20
Backward links
c. Azerbaijan
d. Belarus
1.92
0.96
Agriculture
Mining
Forward oriented
1.72
Utilities
Food products
0.56
Key
Manufacturing
1.52
Mining
0.76
1.32
Other services
1.12
Utilities
0.36
Backward
oriented
Construction
0.81
1.01
1.21
Backward links
1.41
1.61
Agriculture
0.92
Food products
0.72
Firm services
0.61
2.12
Key
Other services
0.16
0.41
Weak
Backward oriented
Firm services
0.16
0.38 0.48 0.58 0.68 0.78 0.88 0.98 1.08 1.18 1.28 1.38
Backward links
Forward oriented
Manufacturing
Weak
Construction
0.36
Backward
oriented
Utilities
Other services
Food products
0.96
Mining
0.55
Forward links
Forward links
1.16
Forward links
Forward links
2.05
1.16
Key
1.36
0.52
Backward
Firm services
Construction oriented
0.32
Weak
0.12
0.48 0.58
0.68
0.78
0.88
0.98
1.08
1.18
1.28
Backward links
(Continued)
accounts for a large share, the incomes of unskilled workers, many of whom are
among the bottom 40, will be strongly affected by changes in agricultural revenues.
In these countries, workers who are able to move out of agriculture into manufacturing or services have a huge potential for realizing gains. In other countries, the
share of agriculture is small, and these gains have already been realized.
A second conclusion is that transmission channels may be quite different in the
same sectors in different countries. For instance, in some countries, the utilities
sector shows almost no forward or backward links and is remarkably isolated,
while, in other countries, the same sector is much more integrated and has a much
clearer impact on income growth among the bottom 40.
● 59
Structural and Cyclical Variables within the Framework
FIGURE 4.10
Backward and Forward Links, Selected Countries, Europe and Central Asia, 2007 (continued)
f. Georgia
e. Bulgaria
1.79
Forward
oriented
1.59
Key
Other services
Manufacturing
Forward oriented
Other services Key
2.05
Firm services
1.19
Mining
0.99
Food products
0.79
Forward links
Forward links
1.39
Agriculture
Manufacturing
1.05
Weak
0.19
0.41
0.51
0.61
Forward oriented
0.71
0.81
0.91
1.01
1.11
Utilities
0.55
Agriculture
Backward
Construction
oriented
0.39
Food products
Mining
Utilities
0.59
Firm services
Construction
Weak
Backward links
Backward links
g. Hungary
h. Kazakhstan
Manufacturing
Backward
oriented
0.05
0.32 0.42 0.52 0.62 0.72 0.82 0.92 1.02 1.12 1.22 1.32
1.21
1.97
Key
2.10
Forward oriented
Other services
Key
1.77
1.57
1.60
Firm services
1.10
Food products
Backward
oriented
Utilities
Mining
0.60
Weak
0.10
0.42 0.52
0.72
0.82
0.92
1.02
1.12
Manufacturing
1.37
1.17
0.97
0.77
Mining
Agriculture
Backward
Food products
oriented
Construction
Utilities
Firm services
0.57
Agriculture
Construction
0.62
Forward links
Other services
Forward links
1.55
1.22
Weak
0.37
0.60
0.70
0.80
Backward links
0.90
1.00
1.10
1.20
1.30
Backward links
(Continued)
There are, however, many caveats: our input-output analysis has severe limitations. For example, the mining of natural resources may have few direct links to
other parts of an economy, but real incomes may still rapidly rise because, as a
result of a commodity price boom, surplus profits are being spent, and the currency is experiencing a real appreciation. More research is needed to assess the
full impact of macroeconomic developments on income growth. Because of these
differences, infrastructure investments may have quite different impacts on the
welfare of the bottom 40.
60 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
FIGURE 4.10
Backward and Forward Links, Selected Countries, Europe and Central Asia, 2007 (continued)
i. Kyrgyz Republic
Utilities
Forward oriented
Manufacturing
Other services
1.51
Forward links
1.91
Key
1.71
1.71
Agriculture
1.31
1.11
0.91
Mining
0.71
Food products
0.51
0.31
Manufacturing
Forward oriented
Other services
1.31
1.11
Food products
Firm services
0.91
Mining
0.71
Agriculture
Utilities
Construction Backward
oriented
0.51
Firm services
Weak
0.11
0.15
Backward
oriented
Construction
0.35
0.55
0.75
0.95
1.15
0.31
Weak
0.11
0.58
0.68
1.35
0.78
0.88
Backward links
Forward oriented
0.98
2.02
Key
Other services
1.28
Forward oriented
Key
Other services
Manufacturing
1.53
1.52
1.33
Manufacturing
Forward links
Forward links
1.18
l. Turkey
1.73
1.13
0.93
Mining
Food products
0.73
Weak
0.13
0.71
0.91
1.01
1.02
1.11
Firm services
Food products
Agriculture
Mining
0.52
Backward
oriented
Construction
0.81
Agriculture
Utilities
Firm services
0.53
0.33
1.08
Backward links
k. Russian Federation
1.93
Key
1.51
Forward links
1.91
j. Romania
Utilities
Weak
0.02
0.46
1.21
0.56
0.66
0.76
0.86
Construction
0.96
1.06
Backward
oriented
1.16
1.26
Backward links
Backward links
m. Ukraine
1.64
1.44
Forward oriented
Manufacturing
Mining
1.24
Forward links
Key
Other services
Utilities
1.04
Agriculture
0.84
Firm services
Food products
0.64
0.44
Construction Backward
oriented
0.24
Weak
0.04
0.54
0.64
0.74
0.84
0.94
1.04
1.14
1.24
1.34
Backward links
Source: GTAP Data Base, Global Trade Analysis Project, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Department of Agricultural Economics, Purdue
University, West Lafayette, IN, https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/databases/default.asp.
Note: The axes, that is, backward and forward links, are expressed as the ratio of the type of link with the average change in the economy
arising from a shock. For example, if the ratio is higher than 1 for a forward link, then the change in sector j ’s income is higher than the
average income change in the economy after a unitary injection in all sectors.
● 61
Structural and Cyclical Variables within the Framework
Annex 4A Income Growth Rates, the Bottom 40
TABLE 4A.1 Income Growth Rates among the Bottom 40, circa 2004–08 and 2005–10
Country
Slovak Republic
Russian Federation
Belarus
Poland
Romania
Kazakhstan
Tajikistan
Kyrgyz Republic
Moldova
Turkey
Latvia
Ukraine
Estonia
Kosovo
Lithuania
Czech Republic
Bulgaria
Montenegro
Slovenia
Hungary
Armenia
Georgia
Albania
Macedonia, FYR
Croatia
Serbia
Maximum
Minimum
Bottom 40, yearly
growth rate, %
Survey type
Circa 2005–10
2004–08
20.3
Income
Expenditure
Expenditure
Expenditure
Expenditure
Expenditure
Expenditure
1999–2008
1999–2008
1999–2008
2001–08
1999–2007
2000–08
10.0
2.2
6.7
11.4
8.9
9.8
Expenditure
Income
Expenditure
Income
Expenditure
Income
Income
2002–08
2004–08
2002–08
2004–08
2003–06
2004–08
2004–08
4.8
13.9
10.9
14.9
−0.7
18.7
6.3
Expenditure
Income
Income
Expenditure
Expenditure
Expenditure
Expenditure
Expenditure
Income
Expenditure
Income
Expenditure
Income
Income
Expenditure
Income
Income
Expenditure
Expenditure
2005–08
2004–08
2004–08
2001–08
1999–08
7.5
5.9
5.4
9.0
1.2
Expenditure
2003–08
3.8
20.3
−0.7
2005–10
2004–09
2006–11
2005–10
2006–10
2006–10
2004–09
2006–11
2006–11
2006–11
2005–10
2005–10
2005–10
2006–11
2005–10
2005–10
2007–10
2006–11
2005–10
2005–10
2007–11
2006–11
2005–08
2003–08
2004–08
2007–10
Survey type
Income
Before crisis
Expenditure
Income
Income
Expenditure
Expenditure
Expenditure
Expenditure
Expenditure
Expenditure
Bottom 40, yearly
growth rate, %
11.3
9.6
9.1
8.0
6.2
6.2
6.1
5.8
5.7
5.0
4.7
4.7
4.1
3.9
3.5
3.0
2.9
2.5
2.3
1.6
1.0
–0.9
–1.2
−1.5
−1.8
−1.8
11.3
−1.8
62 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
Annex 4B The Social Accounting Matrix Model9
In technical terms, the social accounting matrices (SAMs) represent the circular
flow of income in an economy between sectors or activities, as well as between
sectors, the government, households, and the rest of the world. Each cell in a
SAM, denoted by SAMij, represents payments from an account j to another account
i. In using a SAM for analysis, one must set some accounts as endogenous (meaning that they can react to a shock in the economy) and the rest of the accounts as
exogenous (no change in the account following a shock). In the exercise we
describe in this report, we set the government, capital, and rest of the world
accounts as exogenous, but this choice can be changed according to the type of
analysis. Mathematically, the structure of the simulations can be presented using a
simple representation of a SAM (table 4B.1).
TABLE 4B.1 The Schematic Social Accounting Matrix
Income/expenditure
Endogenous accounts
Exogenous accounts
Total
Endogenous accounts
Exogenous accounts
Total
T
L
Y
X
T
Yx
Y
Yx
Source: Adapted from Defourny and Thorbecke 1984.
The core of the SAM analysis is the multiplier model. Assume there are n
endogenous accounts. Let Anxn denote the matrix of technical coefficients, that is,
the matrix resulting from dividing every cell Tij in Tnxn by the respective column
sum Yj. Let Ynx1, Nnx1, and Xnx1 denote column vectors with the sums of the total
expenditures for the endogenous accounts, the endogenous component of these
expenditures, and the exogenous component, respectively. Then, by construction,
the following two equations hold:
Y=N+X
(4B.1)
N = AY.
(4B.2)
Y = AY + X,
(4B.3)
Y = (I − A)−1 X = MX,
(4B.4)
and
Combining these equations yields
which may be rewritten as follows:
where I is the n x n identity matrix. The matrix M = (I − A)−1 is known as the accounting multiplier matrix, the Leontief inverse matrix, or simply the inverse matrix. Each
cell, mij, of M quantifies the change in total income of account i as a result of a
unitary increase in the exogenous component of account j. This change takes into
account all the interactions in the economy that follow from an initial shock, so that
SAMs are general equilibrium models.
In using SAMs in simulations of standard demand shocks (for example, an
increase in the demand of tourism from the rest of the world), one must realize that
a number of assumptions are implicit in the framework. The two main assumptions
Structural and Cyclical Variables within the Framework
are that all prices remain fixed, as do all expenditure propensities, whether one
considers productive activities or the commodities purchased by households.
Thus, a SAM is essentially a picture at one point in time of the economy and of the
relations between different sectors as well as institutions or groups of agents. In
using the SAM for simulations, we assume that the structural relations observed in
the economy do not change, which is to say that there are no behavioral adjustments by agents following a shock. This is a strong assumption, which implies that
the analysis obtained from a SAM is often tentative and indicative only and may
lead to an overestimation of the impact of a shock.
Notes
1. Even if annual surveys are available for a subset of countries, there are cases in which
surveys were not conducted during 2008 and 2009, thus rendering observation of the
crisis in the microdata quite difficult.
2. Annex 4A, table 4A.1 provides more information on the data underpinning figure 4.1.
This includes the specific time periods considered for each country and the welfare
measure used to calculate the shared prosperity indicator.
3. This is particularly noteworthy given that the two periods overlap; see the details in
annex 4A, table 4A.1.
4. The changes in net trade are large and imply that Latvia moved from a deficit of 15
percent of GDP in 2005 to a deficit of 2 percent in 2010, whereas Estonia moved from a
deficit of 7 percent to a surplus of 4 percent in the same period.
5. This analysis is merely descriptive; no causality can be inferred from these results, which
merely constitute suggestive associations.
6. Note that the regression analysis carried out on data on the steady growth period identifies the following as the variables with the strongest link to shared prosperity: (a) the
growth of GDP per capita, (b) a change in the labor participation rate, (c) a change in the
employment share of industrial sectors (that is, mining and manufacturing), (d) the initial
share of employment in the industrial sectors, (e) the initial labor participation rate, and
(f) the change in the mortality rate.
7. The total effect of the change in the employment share of industry (independent variable) on the growth of the bottom 40 (the dependent variable) in the case of the Kyrgyz
Republic varies between 1.19 percent and 13.16 percent. This range is calculated by
using the 90 percent confidence interval bounds of the coefficient estimate in the model.
The wide range derives from the large standard error in the estimation, which, in turn,
depends on the limited number of observations used in the regression: one additional
warning sign that the results are to be taken with a grain of salt.
8. Similarly, among the demand components of GDP, investments are much more cyclical
than consumption.
9. The SAM multiplier estimation has been carried out using SimSIP SAM, a Microsoft
Excel–based tool for the analysis of input-output tables and SAMs. For documentation
on the tool, see “SimSIP: Simulations for Social Indicators and Poverty,” SimSIP, World
Bank, Washington, DC, http://www.simsip.org/.
References
Azevedo, Joâo Pedro. 2014. “A New Impetus to an Old Debate: When and Why Do Macro
and Micro Numbers Diverge?” ECA PREM Technical Background Note, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
● 63
64 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
Defourny, Jacques, and Erik Thorbecke. 1984. “Structural Path Analysis and Multiplier
Decomposition within a Social Accounting Matrix Framework.” Economic Journal 94
(373): 111–36.
Williams, Penny, Jennica Larrison, Victoria Strokova, and Kathy Lindert. 2012. “Social
Safety Nets in Europe and Central Asia: Preparing for Crisis, Adapting to Demographic
Change, and Promoting Employability.” Europe and Central Asia Knowledge Brief 48
(69096), World Bank, Washington, DC. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org
/handle/10986/10049.
The Sustainability Dimension
At the core of the two World Bank goals of ending extreme poverty and boosting
shared prosperity is an overarching concern for sustainability. The World Bank’s
strategy establishes explicitly that the pursuit of shared prosperity, measured
through income growth among the bottom 40, must be economically, environmentally, and socially sustainable. Shared prosperity cannot be achieved, for
instance, through approaches that are self-defeating over time. Thus, an imprudent fiscal policy that involves redistribution to the bottom 40, but undermines
future financial solvency; a growth model that relies on the overexploitation of
natural resources without a corresponding investment in the productive capacity
of the economy through a strategy of diversification; and a social contract that
systematically excludes some groups, inducing polarization and weakening social
cohesion: all these would have to be ruled out. Sustainability is therefore understood broadly to include, but not be limited to, one-dimensional notions that are
focused only on fiscal or environmental concerns.
Economic Sustainability
Economically, a path to development is sustainable if it promotes fiscally responsible financial management. In several countries following the crisis in 2008–09,
including Georgia and Romania, growth was led by public investment and substantial expansion in social assistance programs, which resulted in a partial recovery in the incomes of the bottom 40. However, this growth pattern may not be
65
66 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
fiscally sustainable, and an effort must be made to reorient growth so that it is
driven by the private sector.
Additionally, an important obstacle in the pursuit of sustained shared prosperity is the unequal distribution of power and influence, which may result because
of substantial income inequality, particularly if income and wealth are highly
concentrated at the top (box 5.1). A system in which a more well off minority at the top of the distribution has disproportionate power to lobby and
The pursuit
to influence the distribution of resources through the political process
of shared prosperity
can distort policy making and slow growth (Robinson 2010; Saint-Paul
must be economically,
and Verdier 1996). Under such conditions of inequitable access to
influence, policies and institutional designs can easily emerge that
environmentally, and
favor anticompetitive rent seeking, thereby negatively affecting the
socially sustainable.
potential for growth (Guerrero, Lopez-Calva, and Walton 2009).1 How
do these distortions in policy making affect the bottom 40 in particular?
To name but one example, powerful interests may effectively veto measures to boost market access among small entrepreneurs in the bottom 40,
BOX 5.1
The Concentration of Wealth in Europe and Central Asia
According to Forbes, Europe and Central Asia
had 181 billionaires in 2013, 110 of whom were in
Russia, 43 in Turkey, 10 in Ukraine, and the others
in Kazakhstan (5), the Czech Republic and Poland
(4 each), Cyprus (3), and Georgia and Romania
(1 each) (table B5.1.1).
Hosting 13 percent of the billionaires in the
world, Europe and Central Asia is the fourth most
affluent region after North America (Canada and
the United States), Asia, and the EU15 (map B5.1.1).
However, unlike the EU15 and North America,
where the share of billionaires has decreased dra-
matically over the last decade, it doubled in Europe
and Central Asia (as well as in Asia), moving up from
6 percent to 13 percent. Although the average per
capita net worth of the billionaires in Europe and
Central Asia ($3.09 billion) is the third lowest after
North Africa and the Middle East, as well as Asia
(respectively, $2.93 billion and $2.90 billion), billionaires have increased their wealth more quickly in
Europe and Central Asia than anywhere else.
The Europe and Central Asia region also holds
another record: the billionaires are the youngest
in the world, with an average age of 54 years in
TABLE B5.1.1 Number of Billionaires, by World Region, 2005–13
Region
2005
Europe and Central Asia
Sub-Saharan Africa
Asia
Australia and Zealand
EU15
Latin America and Caribbean
North Africa and Middle East
North America
Total
43
3
81
6
156
26
18
358
691
2008
2013
146
5
187
18
193
38
44
494
1,125
181
10
356
25
233
100
50
471
1,426
Sources: World Bank staff analysis; “The World’s Billionaires,” Forbes, New York, March 25, 2013.
Note: EU15 = Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy,
Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom.
(Continued)
● 67
The Sustainability Dimension
BOX 5.1
(continued)
2013, while, in all other regions, the average is 60
or above; in North America, it is 68 (figure B5.1.1).
The source of wealth in Europe and Central
Asia varies, from natural resources (oil, natural
gas, mining) to agriculture and food, and services
(construction, insurance, banking, and telecommunications). Many of the billionaires have diversified their fortunes across numerous activities.
MAP B5.1.1
Average Net Worth per Billionaire, World, 2013, U.S. dollars
5.00 billion or more
4.00–4.99 billion
3.50–3.99 billion
3.00–3.49 billion
2.50–2.99 billion
1.50–2.49 billion
1.00–1.49 billion
No data
Sources: World Bank staff analysis; “The World’s Billionaires,” Forbes, New York, March 25, 2013.
FIGURE B5.1.1
Average Age of Billionaires, by World Region, 2005–13
80
Europe and Central Asia
North America
Age, years
EU15
64 64
50
63
61
60
Asia
Middle East and North Africa
62
62
Australia and New Zealand
Latin America and Caribbean
69 68 67
70
Sub-Saharan Africa
66
65 64
66 68
54
51
50
60
60
56
63 63 63 63
40
30
20
10
0
2005
2008
2013
Sources: World Bank staff analysis; “The World’s Billionaires,” Forbes, New York, March 25, 2013.
Note: EU15 = Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands,
Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom.
68 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
thus preventing them from contributing to growth. As box 5.1 shows, there has
been a large concentration of wealth at the top in the countries of Europe and
Central Asia.
Social Sustainability
Images of social unrest, protests against political and economic elites, and discontent among disenfranchised or vulnerable groups have been common in Europe
and Central Asia in recent years. Studies on subjective indicators of social
A concern
advancement report that populations have a systematic perception of
with social sustainability
deterioration in economic conditions, contrary to conclusions drawn from
objective indicators. According to qualitative and quantitative studies,
means ensuring equality
the rise in average incomes and in living standards is not reflected in a
of opportunities, thereby
widespread perception that society is more inclusive and fair; there is
allowing all citizens
consequently a clear risk of societal fragmentation, which could significantly
affect the process of economic development. More than 15 perto contribute
cent of the people in 25 countries in Europe and Central Asia say that
to growth.
political connections or breaking the law are the main elements of achieving
success in life; the only country in Western Europe in this group is Italy. In
Croatia, FYR Macedonia, and Serbia, the share of people responding this way is
greater than 50 percent. Conversely, fewer than 6 percent of the population believe
so in Sweden and the United Kingdom (figure 5.1).
Such concerns about social sustainability should also be taken into consideration. By excluding groups—such as the Roma, youth, women, the rural poor, and
so on—from participation in certain markets and from benefiting from social
investments, society also prevents these groups from contributing to growth and
alienates them from the social contract. Poverty rates among the Roma, for example, are systematically high (box 5.2).
In chapter 3, which introduces the asset-based approach, we emphasize the
relevance of considering other assets besides traditional human and financial capital. Indeed, a key asset among households is social capital, the extent and power
of the household’s social connections, networks, and other such nonmarket factors
that may be used to increase economic gains. In Europe and Central Asia, household social capital can be constrained by the existence of historic patterns of exclusion, discrimination, absence of voice and civic participation, low political representation, and barriers of entry or access to employment and entrepreneurship
affecting certain groups based on their social status. Groups affected by these
dimensions have a smaller stock of social capital to apply toward realizing economic gains, and this may make them more likely to be counted among the bottom 40. Assessing how the bottom 40 differs from the top 60 in the strength of
social capital and who is disadvantaged is important because it leads to the formation of policies that are socially as well as economically targeted.
The concern with social sustainability and overall governance in the context of
the growth process should translate into ensuring equality of opportunity among
all citizens so that socioeconomic achievement is not associated with specific circumstances or particular social identities.
● 69
The Sustainability Dimension
FIGURE 5.1
Most Important Factor in
Succeeding in Life, Europe
and Central Asia, 2010
Sweden
United Kingdom
Tajikistan
Uzbekistan
Germany
Effort or skills
Azerbaijan
Political connections or breaking the law
Mongolia
Kyrgyz Republic
Moldova
France
Georgia
Belarus
Poland
Estonia
Kazakhstan
Turkey
Latvia
Russian Federation
Italy
Romania
Ukraine
Czech Republic
Lithuania
Albania
Hungary
Montenegro
Armenia
Slovak Republic
Slovenia
Bosnia and Herzegovina
Bulgaria
Kosovo
Serbia
Croatia
Macedonia, FYR
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90 100
Percent of respondents
Source: LITS (Life in Transition Survey database), European Bank for Reconstruction and
Development, London, http://www.ebrd.com/pages/research/economics/data/lits.shtml.
Environmental Sustainability
Policies to promote economic growth should reflect the limited nature of nonrenewable resources, as well as the impact of economic activity on the
environment—with special emphasis on climate change—and the need to protect
biodiversity. Environmentally sustainable policies are essential for economic growth
in general and for income growth among the bottom 40 in particular. Multiple
two-way links that are relevant in this area will be analyzed and articulated as the
70 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
BOX 5.2
The Sustainability of Shared Prosperity: The Roma and
Gender Equality
More workers are needed to ensure that dependency ratios and the fiscal burden do not become
unsustainable. New entrants to the labor market
play a large role in paying the taxes that provide pensions, health care, infrastructure, and
other benefi ts. A broad view of social and economic sustainability must therefore account for
the productive potential of excluded groups that
could contribute significantly to the income of
their households and GDP growth. The populations of Eastern Europe are rapidly aging, and
inclusive labor markets have become a pressing
economic necessity. The conditions among the
Roma and the consequences of gender inequality
are two areas that highlight the potential cost of
exclusion.
Boosting employment among the Roma, the
largest, poorest minority in Europe and one of
the continent’s most rapidly growing populations, would have economic and fiscal benefits
in several countries. Thus, for instance, government social assistance payments would decline
as a result, and income tax revenue would rise.
The Roma are now less likely to be employed
than their non-Roma peers and earn considerably
less if they are employed. A World Bank study
(2010) estimates that closing the labor market gap
between the Roma and non-Roma in Bulgaria, the
Czech Republic, Romania, and Serbia, where the
employment gap is 26 percentage points, and
the average wage gap is 50 percent, would lead
to €2 billion to €5.5 billion in economic benefits
and €0.7 million to €1.8 million in fiscal benefits
(depending on the population estimates). Up to
10–20 percent of new labor market entrants in
Eastern Europe are young Roma, meaning that
addressing the persistent inequalities behind the
low productivity among the Roma is all the more
urgent. Investing in this group’s human capital
assets from an early age by improving the access
of the Roma to education and greater educational
attainment is a prerequisite for bridging the labor
market gap, which would allow more Roma to use
their assets intensively and for higher returns.
Similarly, the countries of Europe and Central Asia have not yet taken advantage of the full
productive potential of women, who represent
over half the population. The female labor force
participation rate, 52 percent in the region, is 23
percentage points lower than the corresponding
rate among men. Increasing women’s inclusion
in labor markets would allow women to maximize the returns on their human capital assets,
thereby generating productivity gains that would
have a direct impact on GDP (World Bank 2014).
According to Booz & Company research, raising
employment among women to the levels among
men could boost GDP by up to 19 percent in
Italy, which has labor force participation rates
similar to the average in Europe and Central Asia
(Aguirre et al. 2012). The potential gains may be
highest where female labor force participation
rates are relatively low and women are relatively
well educated, which is the case in most countries of Europe and Central Asia, where women
account for over half of university students.
framework is developed. Countries relying extensively on nonrenewable natural
resources as a source of growth (minerals, hydrocarbons, and so on), as is the
case in many countries in Europe and Central Asia, should be managing the revenues derived from this growth wisely, thereby laying the foundation for efficient
long-term development and ensuring that the communities living where these
resources are located obtain a fair share of the benefits. The mismanagement of
renewable resources (water, fertile soil, forest), leading to their degradation and
depletion, may have a serious adverse impact on the productivity and well-being
● 71
The Sustainability Dimension
FIGURE 5.2
CO2 Emissions, Europe and
Central Asia versus Rest of
the World, 2009
0.9
CO2 intensity, kilograms per 2005 purchasing
power parity U.S. dollars of GDP
East Asia & Pacific
0.8
0.7
0.6
High-income Europe & Central Asia
Middle East & North Africa
Developing Europe & Central Asia
South Asia
0.5
Sub-Saharan Africa
Latin America & Caribbean
Other high-income areas
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
25,000
50,000
Cumulative income, constant 2005 international U.S. dollars, billions
Source: World Bank calculations.
Note: Excludes land use.
of households, and the poor are the least able to cope. Recall the effects of the
shrinking of the Aral Sea, which has devastated the livelihoods of nearby communities, many of which were traditionally inhabited by poorer ethnic minorities. Environmental pollution negatively impacts human capital (mainly through poor health),
productivity (through both poor health and the poor quality of inputs), and competiveness. In Kosovo, the economic cost of environmental degradation was
equivalent to 5 percent of the country’s GDP in 2010 (World Bank 2013a).
Policies
Meanwhile, the more efficient and sustainable use of natural resources
promoting growth
increases competiveness, reduces the cost of degradation, and has the
potential to raise the incomes of the bottom 40 (box 5.3). Furthermore,
should account for the
the countries of Europe and Central Asia also face important challenges
impact of economic
because of their vulnerability to climate change and the need to become
activity on limited natural
more energy efficient and less CO2 emission intensive (figure 5.2).
resources and the
Recognizing the importance of achieving growth and shared prosperity through sustainable policies, the World Bank has helped countries
environment.
apply a number of analytical tools, such as the inclusion of natural and
social capital in national accounting (currently being undertaken in Turkey),
assessing the costs of environmental degradation and priority measures to reduce
these (country environmental analysis has been carried out in Kosovo and is now
ongoing in Armenia), and, most recently, green growth low carbon studies (completed in Poland and the former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, and initiated in
Romania). As a next step, it would be useful to add to these tools a capacity to
measure the relevant impacts on the bottom 40.
Integrating the sustainability dimension into efforts to boost growth and shared
prosperity successfully would “ensure better balance between natural resources,
physical and human capital, and economic institutions” (Gill et al. 2014, xvii).
72 ●
BOX 5.3
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
Converting Natural Assets into Bottom 40 Income:
The Environmental Services Approach
Low income generation capacity is most prevalent in Albania’s northern upland county of Kukes,
which is characterized by sloped, heavily eroded
terrain. Historic underinvestment in forestry and
rural land management means that the returns to
these investments are high, particularly for the
bottom 40, among which income growth lags
behind per capita GDP growth. The Environmental Services Project supports a package of interventions designed to boost income from natural
capital in upland rural areas (World Bank 2013b).
The project aims to reverse trends in land degradation and improve forest health, thereby increasing the stock of natural assets; promote the intensive, sustainable use of rural landscapes through
management planning; raise the farmgate prices
of environmental goods through payments for
environmental ser vices; and provide income
transfers that will simultaneously target the poor
and enhance environmental service flows.
Assets
Land is a critical asset for Albania’s rural poor. The
predominant agricultural activity in upland Albania
is livestock cultivation, which puts considerable
pressure on the productive value of land. Overgrazing leads to erosion, which has both in-place
and downstream productivity costs. Investing in
fences, remote water points, and reforestation can
restore the value of land assets. Furthermore, the
project has a property registration component
that, in the long run, should secure the access of
rural communities to forests and pastures.
Promoting Intensive, Sustainable Use
The key to sustainable forestry management is
thinning, which supplies fuelwood in the short
run, while increasing the long-run supply of harvestable timber. Investments in the capacity of
the district forest service and local communities
to manage forest data and execute management
plans can lift timber extraction rates, while simultaneously boosting sustainable yields.
Prices
Rural land management practices that reduce
overgrazing, expand vegetative cover, and
improve forest health will simultaneously sequester carbon and improve downstream water services (both water flows and water quality), environmental services that typically go uncompensated.
The project supplies financing through carbon
markets and other public or private sources so
that rural land managers can increase the prices
they receive for managing their land.
Transfers
Payments for environmental services can be considered as getting the prices right for nonmarketed goods, or the payments can be considered
as income transfers. In Albania, monetary rewards
for land management practices that generate
ecosystem services have the dual benefit of augmenting the incomes of the rural poor, while providing benefits to downstream users such as water
utilities and hydropower plants.
Through this combination of interventions, the
Environmental Services Project in Albania harnesses the power of the access to natural assets,
the sustainable, intensive use of these resources,
more accurate pricing, and conditional transfers
to raise the incomes and well-being of Albania’s
bottom 40.
Special attention should be paid to identifying pro-growth policies that promote
all three dimensions of sustainability at once; for example, reducing energy subsidies through a more targeted design can support fiscal, social, and environmental
objectives.
The Sustainability Dimension
Note
1. For an in-depth discussion on inequality, lobbying, and resource misallocation, see
Esteban and Ray (2006).
References
Aguirre, DeAnne, Leila Hoteit, Christine Rupp, and Karim Sabbagh. 2012. “Empowering
the Third Billion: Women and the World of Work in 2012.” Booz & Company, New York.
Esteban, Joan, and Debraj Ray. 2006. “Inequality, Lobbying, and Resource Allocation.”
American Economic Review 96 (1): 257–79.
Gill, Indermit S., Ivailo Izvorski, Willem van Eeghen, and Donato De Rosa. 2014. Diversified
Development: Making the Most of Natural Resources in Eurasia. With Mariana Iootty
De Paiva Dias, Naoko Kojo, Kazi M. Matin, Vilas Pathikonda, and Naotaka Sugawara.
Washington, DC: World Bank.
Guerrero, Isabel, Luis F. Lopez-Calva, and Michael Walton. 2009. “The Inequality Trap and
Its Links to Low Growth in Mexico.” In No Growth without Equity? Inequality, Interests,
and Competition in Mexico, edited by Santiago Levy and Michael Walton, 111–56.
Washington, DC: World Bank; New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Robinson, James A. 2010. “The Political Economy of Redistributive Policies.” In Declining
Inequality in Latin America: A Decade of Progress?, edited by Luis F. Lopez-Calva and
Nora Lustig, 39–71. New York: United Nations Development Programme; Baltimore:
Brookings Institution Press.
Saint-Paul, Gilles, and Thierry Verdier. 1996. “Inequality, Redistribution, and Growth:
A Challenge to the Conventional Political Economy Approach.” European Economic
Review 40 (3–5): 719–28.
World Bank. 2010. “Roma Inclusion: An Economic Opportunity for Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Romania and Serbia.” Policy Note (September 30), World Bank, Washington, DC.
———. 2013a. “Kosovo: Country Environmental Analysis.” Report 75029-XK (January),
World Bank, Washington, DC.
———. 2013b. “Albania: Environmental Services Project.” Report E4423 (November 10),
World Bank, Washington, DC.
———. 2014. “Gender at Work: A Companion to the World Development Report on
Jobs.” World Bank, Washington, DC.
● 73
Policy Links
Applying the framework to the analysis of specific policies will bring a new perspective to policy design, one that allows the incorporation of a shared prosperity
focus. The first added value of looking at policies through a shared prosperity lens
is that it helps debunk common misconceptions about two widely accepted, but
false, dichotomies.
The first dichotomy is the one between macro- and microeconomic approaches
to income growth at the bottom of the distribution. The purely macro view implies
that getting the macro fundamentals right and creating the conditions for growth
would be enough to expect income growth at the bottom (Dollar, Kleineberg, and
Kraay 2013). In this sense, a strictly macroeconomic approach, basically focused
on overall growth, could explain the heterogeneity of performance in a shared
prosperity indicator. On the other hand, a microeconomic perspective by itself
would tell us that the heterogeneity can be fully explained by looking at the characteristics of those at the bottom and then seeing overall performance exclusively
as the addition of the individual trajectories. This framework integrates both the
macroeconomic and microeconomic elements, explaining how the macro variables affect income growth differentially along the income distribution, for example, through relative prices and the composition of growth, but also how the distribution of assets at the bottom will determine the capacity of each group to
contribute to overall growth. Growth and the incidence of growth can be understood as jointly determined processes.
The second false dichotomy, better defined as a false trade-off, is between
growth and redistribution. As explained above, growth and distribution are jointly
75
76 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
determined (Ferreira 2010). More importantly, redistribution policies that increase
the productive capacity of the poor through, for example, the provision of education and health or investments in connectivity will pay off and enhance the overall
growth potential of the economy. Then, by adding the temporal dimension and
differentiating among the short, medium, and long terms, the equity-efficiency
The framework
trade-off can be overcome. A recent review of the evidence has shown that
the trade-off between fiscal redistribution and growth cannot be empiriallows the analysis of
cally validated (Ostry, Berg, and Tsangarides 2014).
the transmission
The second added value of the shared prosperity framework promechanism between
posed in this report is that it offers a new and concrete way to analyze
policy interventions
the transmission mechanisms between policy interventions and the susand income growth
tainable growth of the bottom 40. Interventions in specific policy areas
could be assessed for their potential impact on the income generating
among the bottom 40.
capacity of the bottom 40—and, therefore, their capacity to contribute to
growth—through asset holdings and accumulation, the intensity of asset use,
the impact on the returns to assets, and the implications of nonmarket income
(public and private transfers) for equity and efficiency. The shared prosperity
approach, using the proposed framework, can provide guidance to policy makers
on key questions to be considered in the formulation of interventions.
TABLE 6.1 Policy Matrix for Implementing the Asset-Based Approach within a Shared Prosperity
Framework
Policy area
Assets
Intensity of use
1. Macroeconomic
fundamentals
Is the macro
environment
inducing
investments in
asset accumulation
by the bottom 40?
Is unemployment
affecting the
bottom 40
disproportionally?
Is this because
of the sector
composition of
GDP growth? What
can be done to
boost employment
at the bottom?
Is inflation
distorting
relative prices
and inducing the
misallocation
of resources? Is
it affecting net
borrowers in
the economy,
typically the
bottom 40?
Prices
2. Fiscal systems
Are in-kind
transfers sufficient
to guarantee asset
accumulation by
the bottom 40
(human capital
and health, for
instance)?
Does the tax
structure affect
work incentives
among individuals?
The decisions
of firms to hire
and invest? Are
countercyclical
components in
the fiscal system
being adequately
targeted and
financed? Are
public investments
following correct
evaluations of longterm productive
impacts?
Are fiscal
systems inducing
inefficiencies
through their
effects on prices?
Are fiscal systems
progressive
in providing
investment space
to the bottom
40?
Transfers
Sustainability
Is the macro
environment
allowing the
bottom 40 to save
and accumulate
assets?
Are transfers
for social
assistance
well targeted?
Do they
distinguish
between the
chronic and
transitory
poor?
Is a prudent
fiscal policy
ensuring that
the fiscal burden
does not fall
disproportionately
on future
generations? Is it
crowding out the
private sector,
particularly small
and medium
enterprises, by
distorting the
portfolio decisions
of banks?
(Continued)
● 77
Policy Links
TABLE 6.1 (continued)
Policy area
Intensity of use
Prices
Transfers
3. Institutional
capacity, service
delivery
Are the goodquality services
provided to
the bottom 40
sufficient to
guarantee access
to economic
opportunities?
Are institutional
conditions
appropriate for
the protection of
social and natural
capital?
Assets
Does infrastructure,
transport, or
connectivity
enhance the
capacity to use
assets more
intensively? Have
markets been
established for the
sustainable use of
natural capital?
Do prices reflect
the relative
scarcity of
resources? Are
the returns to
assets affected
by the quality of
publicly provided
complementary
inputs?
Is there
sufficient
institutional
capacity
to manage
transfer
programs in
a transparent
way?
Are systems in
place to ensure
monitoring
and evaluation
and systematic
improvements
in the services
delivered to the
bottom 40? Are
certain groups
systematically
excluded from
services? Why?
4. Risk
management
Are the assets of
the bottom 40
being destroyed
by shocks or
overexposed to
shocks? Are the
portfolio decisions
of the bottom 40
being affected by
exposure to risks?
Are extensive and
intensive risks
leading to an
inefficiently low use
of specific assets,
particularly those
of the bottom 40?
Do prices
or returns
appropriately
reflect risk, or
are they inducing
inefficient risk
taking?
Are transfers
or public
insurance
mechanisms
inducing
moral hazard
by, for example, providing
commercial
risk guarantees to investors at the
expense of
taxpayers?
Is exposure to risk
threatening the
capacity of the
system to survive
in the long term?
5. Well-functioning
markets,
business
environment
Are markets
excluding the
bottom 40 from
access to financing
or access to
investments in
specific assets?
Is market power
preventing the
operation or
growth of small
and medium
enterprises
through high
costs for adopting
new technology
and undertaking
new investments
among the
bottom 40?
Do markets
allocate resources
for the most
efficient and
equitable use?
Do markets
provide incentives
for economic
participation
among lessprivileged
households? How
do the rule of law,
regulations, and
the availability and
quality of public
goods induce
higher intensity
in the use of
household assets?
Do price
and factor
rewards reflect
undistorted
conditions?
Are there gaps
in the returns
for the bottom
40 that could
be corrected if
markets were
functioning more
adequately?
Are fiscal
transfers and
subsidies
distorting
competitive
conditions? Is
market power
reflected in
the allocation
of fiscal
subsidies?
Are market
imperfections
generating
inequality traps
and threatening
social cohesion in
the long term? Are
key regulations
being captured by
powerful actors,
distorting the
regulatory capacity
of the state
and negatively
affecting investors
and consumers?
As a proposed tool, this report provides a matrix (table 6.1) that outlines the
transmission channels through which interventions in five broad policy areas can
affect the capacity of the bottom 40 to contribute to growth by influencing their
asset accumulation, asset use, and returns to assets. These five policy channels
may contain many specific policy interventions. The matrix represents an attempt
to structure the conversation around the elements of the proposed framework,
and it does this by providing questions rather than answers in each cell. The main
Sustainability
78 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
reason why the different cells are presented as questions is because the answers
are necessarily context specific and require analysis of the specific interventions
under consideration. Responding to these questions may also be demanding in
terms of data requirements.
The five policy areas we review here are (1) macroeconomic management;
(2) fiscal policies, including tax structure and spending; (3) the institutional capacity
at various levels of government to deliver good-quality services efficiently;
(4) effective risk management instruments and systems; and (5) the capacity to
enable well-functioning markets and a favorable business environment. The next
section discusses concrete examples of policy interventions in Europe and Central
Asia to illustrate how the matrix for implementing the shared prosperity framework
can be applied in these five areas.
Macroeconomic Management
Responsible macroeconomic policy is crucial to sustaining any growth strategy by
providing certainty and avoiding the distortions in relative prices and the returns
to assets that induce major misallocations and regressive redistribution (table 6.2).
Inflationary environments, for example, redistribute to net savers from net borrowers, who are typically among the bottom 40. The literature has shown that inflationary environments and exchange rate misalignment do have distributional
implications and, particularly inflation, tend to affect the bottom of the disResponsible
tribution (Bulíř 2001; Li and Zou 2002). Exchange rate volatility has an
macroeconomic
effect on investment decisions, productivity, and the accumulation of
assets, thereby distorting portfolio decisions (Aghion et al. 2006). Macpolicy can prevent
roeconomic stability and prudent monetary and fiscal policies are thus
misallocations and
a necessary condition for a sustainable growth model and, consequently,
for shared prosperity.
regressive redistribution.
For example, natural resource–rich countries in Eurasia are confronted by these macroeconomic and fiscal challenges because extensive
reliance on revenues from natural resources can result in volatility in GDP,
government outlays, and the real exchange rate. In the face of this, countries
such as Kazakhstan or the Russian Federation tend to filter inflows from resource
revenues into oil or stabilization funds. These can be accessed to help manage
macroeconomic volatility and can guarantee that revenues from natural resources
also benefit future generations, rather than increasing government expenditures
TABLE 6.2 The Asset-Based Approach and Macroeconomic Management: Macroeconomic Fundamentals
Assets
Is the macro environment inducing investment in asset accumulation by the bottom 40?
Intensity of use
Is unemployment affecting the bottom 40 disproportionately? What can be done to boost
employment at the bottom?
Prices
Is inflation distorting relative prices and inducing the misallocation of resources? Is it affecting
net borrowers in the economy, typically the bottom 40?
Transfers
Is the structure of transfers threatening fiscal sustainability?
Sustainability
Is the macro environment allowing the bottom 40 to save and accumulate assets?
Policy Links
● 79
for immediate political gains. But a recent World Bank study finds that Eurasian
countries should do more to diversify their asset portfolio not least by investing
more of their revenues from natural resources into human capital and quality
services (Gill et al. 2014). This will ultimately ensure that assets beyond land and
natural assets are employed to generate greater returns.
Tax Structure and Fiscal Spending
Through the use of taxes and transfers, fiscal policies have efficiency and equity
implications. In the short run, the net system of fiscal incentives either reinforces or
offsets the patterns determined by market income. These policies, however, have
a medium- and long-term impact as well because they prompt behavioral
responses in asset accumulation and use—as in the case of labor force participation or hiring decisions by firms—and may induce factor misallocations or affect
the size distribution of firms. Additionally, policies related to tax structure and
spending have important implications for fiscal sustainability in the long term. This
will be exacerbated in most parts of Europe and Central Asia by the changing
demographic structure: aged dependency ratios are increasing at a more
rapid rate than the share of the population contributing to the fiscal system
through labor taxation.
Fiscal policies,
For instance, social assistance and pensions play a major role in the
through the use of
income generation pattern of the bottom 40 in Europe and Central
taxes and transfers, have
Asia. On the positive side, social assistance and pensions provided the
necessary protection from the shocks generated by the 2008–09 crisis
efficiency and equity
to a large part of the bottom 40 in several countries. Indeed, through
implications.
income support, social assistance programs are aimed also at preventing
temporary shocks from having permanent effects on household welfare.
They might impede, for example, households from divesting assets during
downturns, thereby lowering the capacity to recover and to contribute to growth
productively after a shock. On the other hand, transfers can distort the incentives
for labor force participation and can become a threat to fiscal sustainability.
Thus, in the western Balkans, the structure of taxes and social protection systems
distorts the returns to participation in formal employment, particularly among lowwage earners. People in the bottom 40 are overrepresented among low-wage earners, who tend to rely more heavily on transfers. The cost of moving out of social
assistance in these countries—measured by an implicit tax rate that captures social
assistance benefits and labor taxes (labeled the inactivity trap)—is likely to be more
onerous among the bottom 40 (figure 6.1, panel a). Disincentives to work are particularly substantial in the former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, Montenegro,
and Serbia, where tax rates are above 70 percent among low-wage earners: in other
words, taking a (formal) job increases a household’s total income by a mere 30 percent of the low-wage earner’s potential new salary (Ceriani and Davalos 2014). Moving out of unemployment is also discouraged through the fiscal system via generous
unemployment benefits (labeled the unemployment trap) (figure 6.1, panel b).
Through the fiscal channel, policy appears to distort relative prices and the
returns to assets in favor of lower labor force participation, thus affecting the
80 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
FIGURE 6.1
Labor Market Incentives Can Be Curbed by Taxation and Benefits
a. Implicit tax rate that captures social assistance benefits
and labor taxes
b. Moving out of unemployment, losing unemployment benefits,
and paying income taxes
Bosnia and Herzegovina,
Federation
Bosnia and Herzegovina,
Rep. Srpska
Montenegro
OECD, non-Europe
Southeast Europe
Location
Location
Montenegro
Macedonia, FYR
Bosnia and Herzegovina,
Rep. Srpska
Bosnia and Herzegovina,
Federation
EU11
EU11
Southeast Europe
Serbia
Macedonia, FYR
OECD, non-Europe
OECD, Europe (non-ECA)
Serbia
OECD, Europe (non-ECA)
15
25
35
45
55
65
75
85
95
Tax rate, 2009, %
Average wage
earner
Low-wage/part-time
earner
15
25
35
45
55
65
75
85
95
Population share, 2009, %
Average wage
earner
Low-wage/part-time
earner
Source: Ceriani and Davalos 2014.
Note: Calculations are based on one-earner couples with two children. They measure the share of gross income of the accepted formal
job—including in-work benefits—that is taxed away through personal income tax, social security contributions, and lost benefits (for the
inactivity trap, this refers to social assistance, family, and housing benefits; for the unemployment trap, this refers to unemployment, family,
and housing benefits). Children are assumed to be ages 4 and 6. The data for Montenegro are from 2011. Low-wage earner refers to those
earning 50 percent of the average wage. ECA = Europe and Central Asia; EU11 = Bulgaria, Croatia, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary,
Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Romania, the Slovak Republic, and Slovenia; OECD = Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.
TABLE 6.3 The Asset-Based Approach and Fiscal Systems: Social Assistance Policies
Assets
Are transfers sufficient to guarantee asset accumulation or prevent disinvestment in human capital
among the bottom 40 during shocks?
Intensity of use
Do the tax structure and its interaction with social protection systems affect the incentives of
individuals in the bottom 40 to work?
Prices
Do the tax system and the generosity of social assistance distort the returns to assets in favor of
lower labor force participation for those at the bottom?
Transfers
Are social assistance programs well targeted? Do social assistance programs distinguish between
the chronic poor and the transitory poor in the bottom 40?
Sustainability
Is the size of total social assistance transfers fiscally sustainable? Or will the fiscal burden to
which transfers contribute fall disproportionately on future generations? Will the demographic
composition of the country (for example, high aged dependency ratios) generate additional fiscal
concerns?
intensity of the use of the human capital endowment and, ultimately, the contribution of the bottom 40 to overall growth. Decisions regarding fiscal incentives
through taxes and transfers should thus be analyzed in terms of their impact on
the structure of household income generation (table 6.3).
Along similar lines, several other measures may affect the way fiscal policy
impacts the accumulation, use, and returns to assets among the bottom 40.
Policy Links
● 81
This might include, for example, tax structures and incentives for firms to hire and
invest, thus creating jobs for the bottom 40, or to government transfers beyond
social assistance (for example, energy subsidies).
Government Institutional Capacity for Efficient Service
Delivery
The institutional capacity to deliver good-quality services enhances overall productivity and supports equality in opportunities. Access to good-quality services
such as education and health, which can equip the least well off in society with the
human capital assets necessary to participate in the labor market, for example,
should be a priority in the shared prosperity agenda. Furthermore, infrastructure
services, connectivity, and the provision of key inputs such as energy must be in
place to ensure that the assets of the bottom 40, such as human capital, physical
assets such as land, or financial assets, can be used intensively. The adequate
delivery of these services for asset accumulation and use requires good governance and strong institutional capacity.
Increasing the efficiency and sustainability of infrastructure services such as electricity and water utilities and improving connectivity and the transport infrastructure
are important challenges in many countries of Europe and Central Asia. The rapid
growth many countries experienced during the first decade of the 2000s brought
to the fore the need to improve service quality in utilities by, for example,
The institutional
upgrading dilapidated infrastructure and addressing rapidly growing
demand. If we look at energy sector reforms from the angle of shared
capacity to deliver
prosperity, two sets of issues arise (table 6.4). The first relates to service
good-quality services
delivery and how service delivery might translate into the accumulation,
enhances overall
use, and sustainability of assets highlighted in the matrix. Are utility services accessible to all, including the bottom 40? Or do the poorest segproductivity and
ments of the population have less access to utility networks or goodsupports equality
quality services? The level of access of the bottom 40 to good-quality
of opportunity.
services may determine their ability to accumulate assets, for example, in
health care, which is a prerequisite for subsequent human capital accumulation and use through the labor market. Inadequate service delivery among the
poorest may incur a cost in poor financial and environmental sustainability. As
recent analyses of the electricity sector in western Balkan countries such as Albania
show, the lack of adequate services can contribute to the unwillingness to pay and
to poor collection rates (electricity sector), in addition to the incidence of illegal
connections (water). Environmental sustainability is threatened if households in the
bottom 40 cannot afford to use utility services and resort to more highly polluting
methods to generate heat.
The second set of issues linking energy sector reforms and the bottom 40 within
our framework relates to fiscal systems. As fiscal pressures increase, especially in
the aftermath of shocks, subsidies to maintain affordable prices may become less
viable. The poorest households, already seeking to minimize energy consumption,
are at greater risk of abandoning basic services. Policy makers may be called upon
to ensure that transfers, through efficient and effective social protection mechanisms, reach those at the bottom of the income distribution so that these people
82 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
TABLE 6.4 The Asset-Based Approach and Institutional Capacity: Service Delivery
Assets
Is energy accessible and affordable to the bottom 40 so they are guaranteed human capital
accumulation? Is connectivity a constraint to asset accumulation? Are the energy services used by
the bottom 40 of adequate quality? Are the energy sources they use more polluting or dangerous
than those used by the rest of the population?
Intensity of use
Are energy services enabling the more effective use of assets and access to economic
opportunities? Is connectivity favoring the most productive use of assets among the bottom 40?
Prices
Is connectivity fostering prices that reflect the actual productivity of assets across different uses?
Transfers
Do public transfers ensure the affordability of good-quality energy services among the bottom
40? Do subsidies for energy producers distort competitive conditions? Are they effective in
trickling down to users in the bottom 40, resulting in lower prices and greater affordability among
this group?
Sustainability
Are energy services being provided at high environmental cost? Will the cost be passed on to
future generations? Is the political economy such that, in periods of austerity, the bottom 40 is
most affected?
are guaranteed access to basic services. Romania, which, in recent years, has
replaced a central subsidy for district heating with the extended coverage of a
benefit targeting low-income users, presents an example of the implementation of
this type of reform.
Transport and connectivity reforms provide another opportunity to reflect upon
the link between good-quality services and institutional capacity on the one hand
and the accumulation and use of assets by the bottom 40 on the other. Improving
land, air, and information and communications technology connectivity tends to
have a positive impact on competitiveness and, ultimately, job creation and income
growth. By reducing the cost of doing business and creating job opportunities
through trade and links with external markets, enhancing transport routes and connectivity can lead to asset accumulation and greater intensity in the use of assets.
Armenia, a landlocked economy, has recently been experiencing the benefits of
enhanced connectivity with world markets, not least because of aviation sector liberalization. The expected drop in the cost of traveling to and from the country will
improve opportunities for trade and the movement of people. This will likely generate jobs and greater returns on assets and decrease the prices of the imported
goods consumed by the bottom 40, thus allowing for greater investment in asset
accumulation.
Another natural candidate to highlight the link between service delivery and
asset accumulation among individuals in the bottom 40 is education. The delivery
of low-quality education services can hinder the chances of the least well off to
accumulate the human capital necessary to access employment opportunities and
maximize the returns to assets. This limits upward mobility and may perpetuate the
systematic exclusion of certain groups concentrated among the bottom 40 from
economic opportunities. Roma children, for example, are particularly vulnerable to
exclusion from good-quality education because of their high drop-out rates or
because of their segregation from the school system in special schools for children
with disabilities. A 2010 four-country study shows that low levels of employment
and low wages among the Roma translate into economy-wide productivity losses
of hundreds of millions of euros (estimated at as much as €5.7 billion annually) and
annual fiscal losses of €2 billion (World Bank 2010).
● 83
Policy Links
Risk Management
There is vast evidence showing that transitory shocks can have permanent effects
on household welfare. Assets can be destroyed, and shocks can induce agents to
divest in inefficient ways. Catastrophic shocks, such as health crises among
income earners who do not have insurance, can cause households to lose sufficient asset holdings so that they become caught in poverty traps, that is, a new,
low level of steady-state welfare (Carter and Barrett 2006). Understanding the
correlates of household entries into and exits from the bottom 40 is relevant not
for the purpose of identifying the individuals in this situation to target them, but
to understand the channels through which this occurs and manage these channels through policy (box 6.1).
In the Europe and Central Asia region, as in other regions, net changes in
poverty mask the mobility of people in and out of poverty. The churning associated with the vulnerability to shocks among individuals and households close
to the poverty line and the need these people feel to protect themselves from
the shocks can affect their asset portfolio decisions and induce more asset
accumulation.
Shocks such as those generated by the 2008–09 crisis are transmitted to households and social spending programs through several channels that affect the
BOX 6.1
Shared Prosperity, Anonymity, and Mobility
One of the characteristics of the shared prosperity
indicator—average income growth among the
bottom 40—is anonymity, that is, the indicator
does not consider the identity of people at the
bottom of the income distribution, unlike mobility
measures, which are aimed at following the welfare of a single set of individuals. Thus, the people
who are at the bottom may be completely different individuals in two different periods.
Nonetheless, though it is not explicit in the
bottom 40 indicator, mobility is a policy concern.
The underlying interest in equity and access to
opportunities means that inter- and intragenerational mobility is an important aspect of the
shared prosperity–focused policy discussion. The
nonanonymous mobility analysis supplies important insights. First, it provides key details about
the assets and pathways that may allow individuals and households to escape the bottom 40 and
the factors that may cause others to remain in this
population group. Second, beyond this betweengroup analysis, a mobility approach also sheds
light on intergenerational change: Is the inequality in the distribution of assets maintained across
younger or older cohorts? Does the presence of
well-educated parents in a household significantly determine the educational attainment and
thus the income generation potential of other
household members?
To understand the factors associated with mobility, the analysis should maintain non-anonymity
and use panel data or alternative techniques. This
would allow researchers to explore (a) the factors
associated with the vulnerability to poverty, the
mobility out of poverty, and entry into the middle
class; (b) changes in the asset composition of
groups over time; and (c) the effects of systemic
and idiosyncratic risks and shocks on mobility patterns, including potential traps (threshold effects)
and the permanent effects of transitory shocks.
84 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
TABLE 6.5 The Asset-Based Approach and Risk-Coping Mechanisms
Assets
Are shocks inducing inefficient portfolio reallocation—divesting in productive assets, destruction
of assets—because of the lower access of the bottom 40 to formal insurance mechanisms? Are
the shocks reducing assets beyond a threshold that may create low income generation traps?
Intensity of use
Are shocks affecting the capacity of the bottom 40 to use their assets more intensely (for
example, by increasing unemployment)? Are shocks inducing an overuse of assets—for example,
natural assets—that affects sustainability?
Prices
Do price and factor rewards reflect undistorted conditions? Are there gaps in the returns for the
bottom 40 that could be corrected if markets were functioning more adequately?
Transfers
Are transfers responding effectively to provide income support to the bottom 40? Do transfer
systems reflect the transitory nature of shocks, or do they induce dependency on social
assistance?
Sustainability
Are shocks inducing the depletion of natural capital? Are fiscal responses sustainable, or are they
creating a disproportionate fiscal burden?
vulnerability to risks at both the micro and macro levels. Because of reductions in
credit access, declines in savings, and losses in the value of assets, financial markets
represent a first transmission channel. Shocks are also channeled through product
markets, which are characterized at times of crisis by slower growth, less production, and changes in relative prices. The third transmission channel through which
a crisis can affect households is labor markets, which exert their impact through
downturns in employment and income. These three channels of transmission—financial markets, product markets, and labor markets—affect the
Transitory shocks
market income component in the asset-based approach. Nonmarket
can have permanent
income may also be affected through a fiscal channel if the political
economy of adjustment implies that budget cuts affect the transfers and
effects on welfare
service provision to individuals at the bottom.
among the bottom 40.
Indeed, not only the levels, but also the composition of social expenditure may change. Lower revenues impose stronger fiscal constraints on
governments, which face pressures to reduce the social spending that
would allow asset accumulation (for example, spending on education and
health), while the demand rises for unemployment spending and social assistance spending. If the instruments to respond are not well designed, transfers may
be difficult to withdraw after the shock, affecting permanently the capacity to provide higher-quality in-kind services, endangering fiscal sustainability, and potentially creating distorted incentives (table 6.5).
Enabling Well-Functioning Markets and a Favorable
Business Environment
Well-functioning markets have the effect of allowing resources—assets—to be allocated to the most productive use. Exclusion and barriers to access imply, therefore,
an increase in the inefficiencies that affect the capacity of the bottom 40 to contribute to overall growth. If bottom 40 households are excluded from specific markets,
they are prevented from accumulating assets or using assets more intensively and
effectively. One dimension of these market inefficiencies is labor mobility. Shared
Policy Links
● 85
prosperity will become more difficult to attain if people in the bottom 40 are stuck
in firms exhibiting slower productivity growth. Not only the level of skills matter, but
also how skills are allocated. Workers who appear to have similar skills may be
employed in different firms and earn different wages. Such wage gaps have been
observed, for instance, between large and small firms and between stateIf the bottom 40
owned enterprises and private firms. A market imperfection, policy, or
faces relatively greater
regulation may be segmenting workers, thereby preventing them from
sharing equally in growth. The exact nature and cause of such segmentabarriers in the access
tion may vary; several economic models explain how specific market
to markets, they are
failures, policies, or regulations may cause the segmentation. Informalprevented from
ity is also widespread in many countries of Europe and Central Asia.
accumulating and
Evidence exists that excessive regulation may create incentives to remain
informal, even though, relative to formal firms, informal firms offer only
using their assets
limited opportunities for income growth. The bottom 40 in the countries of
effectively.
Europe and Central Asia are likely to be disproportionately employed in lowgrowth areas. The differences we observe in employment and wages across the
region may be the result of a policy or market failure that prevents low-wage workers in the bottom 40 from finding more well paying jobs.
Constraints that inhibit the poor from engaging in entrepreneurial activities
generate high efficiency costs. Poorly functioning financial markets may distort the
allocation of capital in ways that affect the bottom 40 more adversely than the rest
of the population. For instance, such markets could disproportionally restrict the
opportunities for entrepreneurship and innovation among the bottom 40. Like the
rest of the population, many people in the bottom 40 possess entrepreneurial
ability and good business skills and want to start businesses or invest in improving
their enterprises. But, because of poorly functioning financial markets, access to
finance is more constrained among the bottom 40, irrespective of the potential for
growth, because the bottom 40 is characterized by a shortage of collateral.
The Life in Transition Survey provides evidence that the access of the bottom
40 to financial services is relatively more restricted and that the bottom 40 must
rely more on informal sources of credit (figure 6.2). In all countries, the majority of
households seeking to borrow money reported that they approached relatives or
friends.1 The share of households that try to borrow from banks is systematically
higher in the top 60 than in the bottom 40. In Albania, Azerbaijan, Bulgaria,
Croatia, Georgia, Lithuania, Slovenia, and Turkey, the gap in access to credit
through banks between the top 60 and the bottom 40 is at least 10 percentage
points and, in FYR Macedonia, reaches 25 percentage points.
The excessive regulation of business entry may also be a serious constraint
because of the resulting high costs associated with establishing a business that are
particularly prohibitive for poorer would-be entrepreneurs. Likewise, financially
underdeveloped countries characterized by difficult business entry requirements
are plagued by lower start-up rates among formal sector businesses. Moreover, to
the extent that new businesses are more likely to employ young, relatively lessskilled workers from the bottom 40, this constraint also affects people in the bottom 40 who might otherwise find higher-paying jobs in new firms.
Such distortions restrict overall productivity growth by misallocating capital and
may inordinately burden the relatively less well skilled in the bottom 40. If people
86 ●
FIGURE 6.2
The Bottom 40 Gap in
Accessing Financial Assets
Relative to the Top 60
Bottom 40
Top 60
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
Uzbekistan
Kyrgyz Republic
Albania
Moldova
Ukraine
Lithuania
Latvia
Kazakhstan
Macedonia, FYR
Tajikistan
Georgia
Estonia
Poland
Azerbaijan
Belarus
Armenia
Turkey
Russian Federation
Serbia
Kosovo
Bosnia and Herzegovina
Czech Republic
Slovak Republic
Romania
Croatia
Bulgaria
Hungary
Slovenia
Montenegro
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
Share of population borrowing from banks, %
Source: LITS (Life in Transition Survey database), European Bank for Reconstruction and
Development, London, http://www.ebrd.com/pages/research/economics/data/lits.shtml.
in the bottom 40 are more likely to be working in firms that are relatively more
constrained by a poor business environment, then they would bear a disproportionate share of the incidence of the constraints on doing business (table 6.6).
Using the Policy Matrix to Design Policies in a
Different Way
The proposed matrix is a tool that provides a well-structured set of questions to be
addressed during the design of policies in a way that is consistent with the approach
● 87
Policy Links
TABLE 6.6 The Asset-Based Approach, Well-Functioning Markets, and the Business Climate
Assets
Are markets excluding the bottom 40 from access to financing or access to investments in specific
assets? Is market power preventing the operation or growth of small and medium enterprises
through the high costs for adopting new technology and undertaking new investments among the
bottom 40?
Intensity of use
Do markets allocate resources for the most efficient and equitable use? Do markets provide
incentives for economic participation among bottom 40 households? How do the rule of law,
regulations, and the availability and quality of public goods induce higher intensity in the use of
household assets for the bottom 40?
Prices
Is connectivity fostering prices that reflect the actual productivity of assets across different uses?
Transfers
Are fiscal transfers and subsidies distorting competitive conditions? Is market power reflected in
the allocation of fiscal subsidies?
Sustainability
Are market imperfections generating inequality traps and threatening social cohesion in the long
term? Are key regulations being captured by powerful actors, distorting the regulatory capacity
of the state, and negatively affecting investors and consumers?
proposed in this report. The answers to these questions are necessarily context
specific and, as we have explained, may be demanding in terms of the data required
to respond to them. The fundamental issue, however, is that answering such questions within a shared prosperity lens will lead to a policy design that is different from
traditional approaches. Aspects related to targeting, which imply a specific answer
if policies are discussed in terms of extreme poverty reduction, may elicit different
answers if they are viewed through this lens. Unlike the concern with poverty, the
concern about the bottom 40 is anonymous: instruments should not be designed
to reach a specific individual with particular characteristics.2 Policies, in this case,
should be designed to affect the channels through which individuals accumulate
assets, use them productively, and respond to the incentives established by transfers, but independently of who the individuals are. The matrix is an attempt to pose
the appropriate questions in the direction of creating those policies that generate
a dynamic whereby the bottom 40 becomes more productive, contributes more
actively to economic growth, and improves its standard of living.
Notes
1. Except among the top 60 in Bulgaria, while, in Slovenia, banks were the first choice.
2. One of the main achievements of recent poverty reduction strategies, such as conditional cash transfers, is the creation of large databases with information whereby
specific individuals can be qualified and admitted into the specific components of the
intervention.
References
Aghion, Philippe, Philippe Bacchetta, Romain Ranciere, and Kenneth Rogoff. 2006. “Exchange Rate Volatility and Productivity Growth: The Role of Financial Development.”
NBER Working Paper 12117, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Bulíř, Aleš. 2001. “Income Inequality: Does Inflation Matter?” IMF Staff Papers 48 (1):
139–59.
88 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
Carter, Michael R., and Christopher B. Barrett. 2006. “The Economics of Poverty Traps and
Persistent Poverty: An Asset-Based Approach.” Journal of Development Studies 42 (2):
178–99.
Ceriani, Lidia, and Maria Eugenia Davalos. 2014. “First Insights into Promoting Shared
Prosperity in South East Europe.” World Bank, Washington, DC.
Dollar, David, Tatjana Kleineberg, and Aart Kraay. 2013. “Growth Still Is Good for the
Poor.” Policy Research Working Paper 6568, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Ferreira, Francisco H. G. 2010. “Distributions in Motion: Economic Growth, Inequality,
and Poverty Dynamics.” Policy Research Working Paper 5424, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Gill, Indermit S., Ivailo Izvorski, Willem van Eeghen, and Donato De Rosa. 2014. Diversified
Development: Making the Most of Natural Resources in Eurasia. With Mariana Iootty
De Paiva Dias, Naoko Kojo, Kazi M. Matin, Vilas Pathikonda, and Naotaka Sugawara.
Washington, DC: World Bank.
Li, Hongyi, and Heng-fu Zou. 2002. “Inflation, Growth, and Income Distribution: A CrossCountry Study.” Annals of Economics and Finance 3 (1): 85–101.
Ostry, Jonathan D., Andrew Berg, and Charalambos G. Tsangarides. 2014. “Redistribution,
Inequality, and Growth.” IMF Staff Discussion Note SDN/14.02 (February), International
Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
World Bank. 2010. “Roma Inclusion: An Economic Opportunity for Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Romania, and Serbia.” Policy Note (September 30), World Bank, Washington, DC.
Concluding Remarks
The recent adoption of the twin goals—ending extreme poverty and promoting
shared prosperity—has renewed the World Bank’s commitment to helping countries raise the living standards of their citizens at the lower end of the income distribution in a sustainable way. This report proposes an integrated framework for
understanding the heterogenous performance within Europe and Central Asia in
terms of the shared prosperity goal: fostering income growth among the bottom
40. Understanding the determinants of income growth among the bottom 40 can
assist in the design of better policies, which can lead to sustainable growth.
In its analysis, the approach combines macroeconomic drivers and microeconomic characteristics to explain growth at the bottom end of the distribution. It
considers growth and the incidence of growth as jointly determined. To explain
how they are jointly determined, the report proposes a framework that builds on
an asset-based approach, and it highlights the importance of the time horizon to
overcome potential equity-efficiency trade-offs. The trade-offs are, in any case,
only apparent: the redistribution of productive capacities feeds back into longterm growth.
The cornerstone of the framework is the asset-based approach.The level and
accumulation of assets that people own (human capital, financial capital, physical
assets, natural capital, and social capital) matter for income generation, as do the
intensity with which they are used and the existing returns to these assets. In addition to market income, transfers (both public and private) either reinforce or offset
the patterns determined by the market. In the medium and long term, the level
89
90 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
and distribution of assets and their returns become key drivers behind growth and
the incidence of growth.
The analysis includes comparisons of countries with a similar profile of aggregate economic expansion, but different income growth rates among the bottom
40. The report finds that, overall, the long-run determinants of income growth
among the bottom 40 are quite different from performance in the short term,
when cyclical fluctuations dominate, such as during the 2008–09 financial crisis.
A variety of examples are used in the report to illustrate how the framework can
be applied to approximate the heterogeneity in the growth of the bottom 40,
although the specifics depend on the context. Relying on the shared prosperity
lens, the report proposes five main areas of policy that can affect how the bottom
40 accumulates assets and uses these assets productively and how the returns are
accrued from the use of the assets, as well as how nonmarket income complements income generation capacity. These areas are (1) macroeconomic management; (2) fiscal policies, including tax structure and spending; (3) institutional
capacity for efficacy in quality service delivery at various government levels;
(4) instruments and systems for risk management; and (5) capacity to enable wellfunctioning markets and a favorable business environment.
Applying the framework to the analysis of specific policies will bring a new
perspective to policy design. Thus, looking at policies through a shared prosperity
lens helps debunk common misconceptions about two commonly accepted, but
false, dichotomies. The first dichotomy is between macro- and microeconomic
approaches to income growth at the bottom of the distribution. The framework
integrates both the macroeconomic and microeconomic elements, explaining
how the macro variables affect income growth differentially along the income distribution, for example, through relative prices and the composition of growth, but
also how the distribution of assets at the bottom will determine the capacity of
each group to contribute to overall growth. The second false dichotomy is between
growth and redistribution. By adding the temporal dimension and differentiating
among the short, medium, and long terms, the equity-efficiency trade-off can be
overcome. If this more comprehensive view is installed in the policy discussion,
and we are able to change the way in which we think about the design of specific
interventions, our report will have achieved its objectives.
Appendix
The Bottom 40 Indicator in Context
The focus on growth at the bottom of the income distribution is not without precedent. Recently, Basu (2011) has proposed the quintile axiom, which states that, in
evaluating a country’s performance, one should focus on the incomes of the bottom 20 percent of the population’s income distribution (the bottom quintile). Much
earlier, in their Redistribution with Growth, Chenery et al. (1974, 38) stated that a
“concern with income distribution is not simply a concern with income shares but
rather with the level and growth of income in lower-income groups.” For at least
40 years, this debate has been accompanied by a discussion about which measure
can best capture these concepts. Income growth among the bottom 40 has often
been considered a candidate indicator.
The point of departure in the framework of Chenery et al. (1974) is the understanding that growth in social welfare can be defined as the weighted sum of the
growth in the incomes of all income groups (for example, income quintiles) in a
society:
G t,t+1 = g1 t,t+1w1+ g2 t,t+1w2+…+ gn t,t+1 wn
(1)
where g1, . . . gn = the income growth rate for each of the n income groups
between periods t and t+1; and w1, . . . wn = the weight for each of the n income
groups (which is the share of income of that group in the initial period t).
Choosing the weight of each income group or quintile implies a normative
choice and “reflects the social premium on generating growth at each income
level” (Chenery et al. 1974, 39). As Ferreira (2010, 4) puts it, “average income,
91
92 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
poverty, and inequality are all aggregate concepts: averages of incomes or income
gaps, measured in different ways, and with different weights along the distribution.
Their evolution over time—economic growth, changes in poverty, and changes in
inequality—are all jointly determined by the individual income dynamics in that
distribution.”
If overall growth is taken as the only measure of progress, then the initial income
share of each income group determines the relative weight of that group. As a
result, those people with initially larger income shares would continue to be
weighted more than others. By focusing on overall growth, one would therefore
promote greater growth among those people with initially larger income shares.
Maximizing overall growth is thus not a distributionally neutral objective.
Instead, if the progressivity of growth is a concern, then the distributional
weights must be redefined to account for the dynamics at the bottom of the distribution. This is consistent with the Rawlsian view that greater weight should be
placed on the disadvantaged. The question of how this should be done, however,
has triggered an important debate in the academic and policy realms.
The implicit issue of the weighting of different groups in terms of welfare is
addressed in the work of Foster and Székely (2008). Concerned with the progressivity of growth and the redefinition of distributional weights, the authors propose
a general framework to assess whether economic expansion is felt by the more
well off, with little if any benefits trickling down to poorer income groups. They set
forth a new way to aggregate growth among various groups, considering GDP
growth as a special case in which inequality is not a concern. In contrast to standard approaches, their methodology does not employ an arbitrary income threshold, which would ignore the incomes only a little above the threshold by giving
these incomes a weight of zero. Instead, they provide a method to track low
incomes that builds on Atkinson’s (1970) parametric family of equally distributed
equivalent income (general means), while allowing for subgroup consistency. They
outline a parameter range that is bottom sensitive and select different low-income
standards from this range, which they verify empirically. Thus, their low-income
standards assign progressively less weight to the incomes that are higher up the
distribution, so that their overall welfare measure is less sensitive to income growth
at the top of the distribution.
Such a reweighted welfare measure is, however, not easy to apply in practical
economic policy. Basu (2013), for instance, points out that the use of the bottom
40 indicator is a practical and easily understood tool so that policy makers can
measure shared prosperity. Because countries already track aggregate growth,
one might also simply compare these data with data on the income growth among
the bottom 40 to assess the degree of inequality. He argues that, obviously, there
is also an important weakness of the bottom 40 indicator: two countries with the
same level of per capita income and Lorenz curves that cross at the 40 percent
population mark will be viewed the same, even if, elsewhere in the distribution,
incomes are different. However, the advantage of the simplicity of the indicator
outweighs the disadvantages.
Boosting income growth among the bottom 40 is not a specific goal that can
be met. There is no maximum growth that can be achieved. However, a temporary
Appendix The Bottom 40 Indicator in Context
growth spurt that cannot be sustained would backfire in the long run. This is why
the sustainability of the growth is crucial. As Basu (2013, 3) notes, pursuing the
goal should “not create a liability for future generations.” Shared prosperity should
therefore be achieved in a way that: (1) manages the resources of the planet for
future generations, (2) ensures social inclusion and thus minimizes social strife, and
(3) adopts fiscally responsible policies that limit future debt burden (World Bank
2013).
Poverty eradication and fostering shared prosperity are complementary
endeavors, as are the two indicators proposed for monitoring their pursuit, which
have substantially different properties. The poverty measure is absolute in nature:
it accounts for the share of the population living below a fixed monetary threshold,
be it country specific (a national poverty line), international (the $1.25-a-day line),
or established according to regional parameters (for Europe and Central Asia,
$2.50 a day or $5.00 a day). Shared prosperity, on the other hand, is a relative
measure that looks at income (or consumption) growth among the poorest 40
percent in a country’s population over time. The shared prosperity indicator is not
an inequality measure, although it can be extended to become one, for example
by looking at the share of national income owned by the bottom 40 or by comparing growth among the bottom 40 with the mean growth in the distribution. Regardless of the income level of the country and even in situations of close-to-negligible
poverty levels, the shared prosperity goal will always be relevant: there is always a
bottom 40 that represents a group of concern.
Like GDP growth and changes in the poverty rate, income growth among the
bottom 40 is anonymous. The people at the bottom of the income distribution in
the beginning of a period are not necessarily the same as the people at the bottom
of the income distribution at the end of that period.
While the focus on income growth among the bottom 40 is an old concept and
builds on a long history of debates about how best to measure welfare, there are
not many examples of thorough empirical analyses. One problem is the lack of
consistent long time series.
References
Atkinson, Anthony B. 1970. “On the Measurement of Inequality.” Journal of Economic
Theory 2 (3): 244–63.
Basu, Kaushik. 2011. Beyond the Invisible Hand: Groundwork for a New Economics.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
———. 2013. “Shared Prosperity and the Mitigation of Poverty: In Practice and in Precept.” Policy Research Working Paper 6700, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Chenery, Hollis Burnley, Richard Jolly, Montek S. Ahluwalia, C. L. Bell, and John H. Duloy.
1974. Redistribution with Growth: Policies to Improve Income Distribution in Developing Countries in the Context of Economic Growth. World Bank Research Series. Washington, DC: World Bank; New York: Oxford University Press.
Ferreira, Francisco H. G. 2010. “Distributions in Motion: Economic Growth, Inequality,
and Poverty Dynamics.” Policy Research Working Paper 5424, World Bank, Washington, DC.
● 93
94 ●
Shared Prosperity: Paving the Way in Europe and Central Asia
Foster, James E., and Miguel Székely. 2008. “Is Economic Growth Good for the Poor?
Tracking Low Incomes Using General Means.” International Economic Review 49 (4):
1143–72.
World Bank. 2013. “The World Bank Group Goals: End Extreme Poverty and Promote
Shared Prosperity.” World Bank, Washington, DC. http://www.worldbank.org/content
/dam/Worldbank/document/WB-goals2013.pdf.