A Study of Working-Class in Korea 497
summary
A Study of Working-Class in Korea
Kim Dong-Choon
1. Preface
Korea’s labor movement since the late 1980s in often brought to discussion as an
exceptional case in comparison with those of advanced countries, because it showed
uncommon energetic appearance in the trends of world-wide decline of organized
labor. Like the cases of late developing countries such as Brazil, Philippines and South
Africa, labor protest in Korea developed its vitality in the context of breakdown of the
authoritarian regime, the Fifth Republic(1980∼1987). After the massive labor
mobilization which continued for three months in the summer of 1987. some four
thousand unions were newly organized initiating collective-bargaining at company
level. Workers’ growing concern about their rights and active participation in union
activity was noteworthy.
However, it is still difficult to conclude Korea as that working-class power in
Korea is gaining strength. Workers in Korea are in a weak power that they are still
constrained by the existing fragmented system of union organization, continue to have
serious difficulty in effectively defending their job security, in failing to dispatch their
members to the National Assembly. The number of strikes and union density curved
downward from 1990. Workers have failed in urging to build an effective institutional
apparatus to defend their interests, while continuing to pronounce a need to find an
alternative to the existing company-level bargaining system.
The state-sponsored official union(Federation of Korean Trade Unions), which has
been criticized and attacked as a traitor to the workers’ interest since 1970s, has not
receded its exclusive status to newly constructed labor organization(The Korean
498
Trade Union Congress). The authorities not denied the legal status of this ’New
Union’, but also have severely oppressed it by defining it illegal, or destructive and by
regarding it an enemy of industrial peace.
Some analysts have characterized this situation of Korea’s labor unions as "early
decline just after late development", that have bypassed the period of class-oriented
labor movement. Although I do not agree with this assessment wholeheartedly, I think
it is an urgent task to explain the failure the Korea’s organized labor to build an
effective institutional power base on the basis of its movements since 1987. Such an
explanation is necessary to identify the implications for future of the labor relations
and labor movements in Korea.
This study focuses on the internal, or subjective base of union activity as the way
of explaining the union weakness.
2. The Rise and Decline of Union Density
The union membership in Korea has, in the process of industrialization, slowly
increased. But union density in Korea has never reached 20% since the start of
state-led industrialization in the early 1960s. Since ’the 1987 great strikes’, some four
thousand of new unions have been organized and over sixty thousand workers were
unionized. Most of them are employees of small and medium size companies. The rise
in union membership was made possible by the revision of labor law undertaked
passively by the ruling class directly after ’the strikes’, which has enlarged the space
of union organization and the formation of workers’ solidarity. But these rising trends
began to stall in 1990, when political and economic atmosphere transformed adversely
for workers. Many unions with small membership found it difficult to survive under
the changed condition. Accordingly union membership fell below the 17% of the total
workforce in 1992.
It may be assumed that the decline of union density was related to the sudden
development of hard circumstances for union activity after 1990. But the decline of
union density cannot be attributed wholly to the toughness of political circumstances
and the end of economic boom after 1989. An examination of the composition of union
membership and the tendency of decline by industry, region, company size, and sex
has revealed that legislative and institutional hurdles were the major factors in the
A Study of Working-Class in Korea 499
slowdown and decrease in the union density. Contrary to the popular belief, union
decline in Korea was not mainly due to the changing composition of labor
force(increased proportion of service workers) or the fundamental transformation of
labor process and rationalization of managerial strategy. These factors had some
influence on the union decline in some cases, but on the whole their contribution has
been negligible until now.
It can be conclude that some structural and institutional setting continue to be
crucial factors in determining the low union density in Korea. The current labor law,
which permits only company-level union organization, prevents large numbers of
workers employed at small to medium size companies from organizing unions in the
face of hostile attitudes of employers and threaten of dismissal. It is nearly impossible
for workers in small size companies to organize union, because workers cannot
effectively overcome the paternalistic or despotic control of the management. It would
be difficult to expect a growth in the union density as long as workers efforts to
organize union beyond the company level continue to be frustrated by labor law and
the hostility of employers.
3. Worker’s Orientation and Union Solidarity
Worker’s orientation or consciousness toward work, labor union and company is
very important in understanding the pattern and character of union activity. Whether
workers have a "instrumental orientation" or "socialistic orientation" toward their
company and union may determine the strength of labor union as well as the general
character and strategy of unions. But this orientation or consciousness must not be
regarded as originating directly the intrinsic and psychological state of workers.
Generally speaking. worker’s orientation toward work and union tends to be
conditioned by social relations, distribution of power between "capital" and "labor" on
the shop-floor and in the society and nation as a whole.
Privatized and individualized workers would not have any concern about workplace
problems, and committed workers would devote their energy to the company
regarding it as a path to self-development like as in the cas of Japanese workers. So
some hypotheses could be formulated on the question of the causal relationship
between the decline of union density, maintenance of enterprise unionism and the
500
meaningful transformation of worker’s consciousness after 1987.
It has been ofter assumed that a larger part of the Korean workers began to
relinquish their loyalty to employers after the 1987’s "great striker". After the
heavy-chemical industrialization of 1970s, highly educated workers became the major
segment of the working class. They are usually firmly anchored in the life of working
class, making them more sensitive to and critical of their existing working conditions
and wage. Moreover, their bitter past experience of inhumane treatment by employers
became an important catalyst for the development solidarity among themselves. Labor
militancy that manifested in 1987-1989 period, could be attributed to their internal
solidarity. But the rise of workers’ class-orientation did not curtail their attachment to
company and loyalty to employers. How can this phenomena be explained?
Workers’ major motivating for working in Korea is, as is the case of in other
capitalist societies, the pursuit of economic well-fulfillment or career accumulation but
a tool for a comfortable life. But their "instrumental orientation" to work is
accompanied by high solidarity-orientation to union. It appears that instrumentalism
to work and solidarity to union may not be mutually exclusive. It can be interpreted
that instrumentalism and solidarity orientation have a contradictorily co-existence in
workers’ mind. The appearance of instrumentalism may reflect their disadvantageous
market situation. In some respects, their obedience to the superiors before 1987 may
not have been based on an acceptance of the legitimacy of the existing labor regime
or a voluntary reverence of capitalist, but inevitable compulsion of the ’bread and
butter’ logic. So their abrupt discoloration was not far from understandable.
Based on existing research data, it can be argued that important transformation in
workers’ consciousness did not took place as it has been supposed, It is undeniable
that class solidarity has progressed greatly, but it does to generally go beyond the
boundary of the company. Loyalties both to the company and to the union still coexist
in the minds of workers. We may characterize this phenomenon as the "dual loyalty
of workers", similar to that found among the Japanese militant workers in the 1950s
and 1960s. If we take into account of social conditions of Korean workers, it is not
difficult to understand why they have a "dual loyalty".
For several decades, most workers in Korea had no idea what unions was, or what
rights workers could had. Workers are still unwilling to risk the wrath of their
employers. So workers’ attachment to firm may not be due to their sincere devotion
to work or employers, but due to the cost of "exit’ and "voice" which forbid them from
A Study of Working-Class in Korea 501
taking risky actions. This situation makes it possible that "conflict consciousness" or
hostility to hand in hand with cooperative attitudes to them.
Worker’s passivity to union activity at the risk of employers’ denials can be
attributed to the powerlessness of union, not due to their intrinsic personality, cultural
tradition, or ignorance. Company-orientation of Korean labor leaders and rank-and
files can be accountable in this respect. Both employers and employees acknowledge
the social distance between them is too large to permit a mutual trust. From the
workers’ standpoint, the fact that they have a sense of distance with regard to
employers is equal to have a firm solidarity toward their fellow workers. So this
strong solidarity among workers can go hand in hand with their ’loyalty’ to the
employers. Thus, the maintenance of a company-union system can be explained when
we take into consideration all of these facts. Labor relations at company level is very
conflictual, or even antagonistic, but it can be sustained under the extreme
depoliticalization of workers.
4. The Internal Politics and The Strategy of Enterprise Union.
In order to understand the strategy of unions, it is necessary to take objective
circumstances and organizational logic of unions into consideration. Economic and
political circumstances constrain the range of negotiation between employees and
employers. And internal logic of formal organization provides the initial setting in
which important actors decide on some strategies.
Korean labor unions, whose overall environment is shaped by the concrete
politico-economic conditions of Korea, are constrained by the specific system of
organization, company union. And developing countries like Korea always put more
emphasis on ’goal of state’ than worker’s needs. In this situation, strikes have always
been attacked as "selfish action" without a consideration for the hardship of the
national economy. Authorities forbid workers from participating in political
organization. Given such a situation, workers have choice but to attempt to extract
’cash wage’ as much as possible. It would, then, be reasonable to assume that
economic militancy at company level stems from this unique circumstance. In spite of
repeated emphasis on labor solidarity, labor leaders always put their priority on
shop-floor collective negotiation and stabilization of company union. This strategy
502
may reflect a realistic and "rational choice" on the part of the union leaders.
Of course, it is understandable that, under the existing system of
interest-representation, enterprise collective bargaining, the labor leaders focus their
efforts on the owners or managers of the firms. But, then, it is reasonable to assume
that a severe limitation lies ahead of a successful shop-floor employer/employee
negotiation. Workers would not be able to achieve anything other than what
employers would be willing or can permit. Overemphasis on company-level
negotiation and labor militancy on the wage issue may be repeated over and over
again, at the great detriment to the long-term labor strength. Thus, it can be
concluded that such a situation, in which union solidarity and political action require
a high participation cast, it would be natural to expect the labor leaders to opt for a
possible and attainable path instead of pursuing "idealistic goals".
Strategies adopted by union leaders cannot be regarded as having designed with a
consideration for the prospect of national labor relations or the future effects. The
pioneering strike efforts by the large-company workers may give confidence to
small-medium scale company workers. But on the other hand, labor militancy at
company level may widen the wage gap between the large and small companied,
raising a barrier for the formation of a joint action by all workers and eventually
weakening the class solidarity. the growth of organizational capacity of large company
unions may give rises to an unintended consequence for the nation-wide labor
movements, because it may accelerate the differentiation of wage levels and working
conditions of workers.
Under a regime of enterprise unionism, marrowness of leader’s vision and
segmentation of workers may be inevitable. These are the paradoxical effect of
economic militancy at company.
5. Limitation of Union Solidarity
New labor leaders have made every effort to strengthen union solidarity. Their
concern focused on the question of the ways to overcome the constraints of the
enterprise unionsim. Union leaders are convinced that the very form of organization
constrain the development of consciousness and class capacity of workers.
Union leaders since 1988, confronted with the hostile attitude and reaction of
A Study of Working-Class in Korea 503
employers and government. instinctively searched for help from other neighboring
unions. These "first-stand solidarity" among unit unions led to the establishment of
several ’Association of Regional Unions’ from 1987 to 1989, in various industrial cities
in Korea. The members of these organizations were new unions organized following
’th 1987’s great strikes’. They adopted ’autonomous, democratic unionism’ as their
strategy for future movement. Chonnohyup (Korean Trade Union Congress), which
declared the transformation of labor movement from cooperative unionism to
"democratic unionsim", was built on the basis of these Associations of Regional
Unions.
Chonnohyup identifies itself as the transitional organization to the way of
centralized industrial-level union. But hurdles of labor law and differentiation in the
working conditions among the companies, and the ’free rider’ strategy of large
company unions have been the main barrier to their efforts.
6. Conclusion.
It can be concluded that the power imbalance between workers and employers,
initiated in the building of the "divided-state" and state-led industrialization in the
1960s, is still the most crucial barrier for the growth of the union organization.
Disadvantageous institutional settings, such as the existing power relations and labor
law, have given rise to a "culture of submission" among workers. On the other side,
it conditions union leaders to adopt uncompromising strategy.
The existing labor law, the form of union organization, the structure of collective
bargaining, the current form of wage, the levels of social welfare and party system
constitute the institutional factors. This leads to a conclusion that Korean workers
have very a very narrow space, within the given institutional constraints, to pursue
their goals independent of the benevolence of the employers.
1) The worker’s role in the 1987’s liberalization and the pattern of their opposition
against the old labor relations is a very important in understanding the development
of the labor movement thereafter. Their initial action during the process of political
liberalization was nothing more than the effect of the past history of industrialization
and the systems of labor relations. The very fact that workers did not take any active
504
role in the breakdown of the authoritarian rule and their massive protest movements
in 1987 was nothin but a loyal opposition within the space provided by the existing
labor laws greatly affected their ensuing action. This produced a vicious-cycle of
workplace labor disputes and constraint of worker’s need within the boundary of
company.
2) Korean working class has internalized the historical experience of "failed
revolution" of 1945-1953 as all other Koreans have. It was the result of this collective
acculturation that most of Korean workers accepted the unjust and harsh labor
situation under the Fifth republic, 1980-1987. We can understand the pattern of
worker’s adaptation, such as this, when we take into consideration their past
experience as ’the underprivileged’ and current socio-political situation which demands
high cost participating in any organized movements. The large portion of rewards
workers obtain is still cash wage provided by the employers. Under the circumstance,
their ’dual loyalty’ to union and company is unavoidable. And worker’s high
commitment to labor unions does not lead to the development of solidarity as s ’class’.
3) When we regard union as an actor, weakness of working-class solidarity can be
explained by strategies adopted by individual unions. It is necessary to analyze the
trajectory of the unions’ of large companies which led the national labor movements.
The unions have become overburdened, in such a situation, as all of workers’ needs
were centralized into the company union because of the absence of any other route for
the realization of their interests.
I would like to emphasize here that consolidation of union organization under the
system of enterprise unionism does not necessarily lead to the growth of
working-class strength at the national level. Though worker’s immediate interests can
be met by strengthening the company union, the varing level of union bargaining
power accelerates the wage differences between companies and deepens the labor
segmentation.
The low union density and the weakness of union cannot be attributed to the
sudden changes in the economic structure or the intensification of state repression
after 1987. It is rater the institutional settings established during the authoritarial rule
before 1987, which compel the workers or unions to submit and adapt to the existing
labor relations.