!"
#
$
& &
!"
#
&&
'
&&
*
'
+
%
# -.
%
%
( )
&
&
*
,
,
)
)
. 12
)
/0
3 &
45
6 )
Université Libre de Bruxelles - Solvay Brussels School of Economics and Management
Centre Emile Bernheim
ULB CP114/03 50, avenue F.D. Roosevelt 1050 Brussels BELGIUM
e-mail:
[email protected] Tel. : +32 (0)2/650.48.64 Fax : +32 (0)2/650.41.88
On the price elasticity of demand for
patents∗
GAETAN de RASSENFOSSE†
BRUNO van POTTELSBERGHE de la POTTERIE‡
A slightly modified version is forthcoming in
Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics. Please consult the
published paper.
Abstract
This paper provides an analysis of the impact of patent fees on the demand for patents. It presents a dataset of fees since 1980 at the European
(EPO), the U.S. and the Japanese patent offices. Descriptive statistics
show that fees have severely decreased at the EPO over the nineties, converging towards the level of fees in the U.S. and Japan. The estimation of
dynamic panel data models suggests that the price elasticity of demand
for patents is about -0.30. These results suggest that the laxity of fee
policy at the EPO has significantly contributed to the rising propensity
to patent.
Keywords: patent cost, patent fees, price elasticity, patent explosion,
propensity to patent.
JEL Classification: O30, O31, O38, O57
∗ The authors are grateful to Karin Hoisl, Paul Jensen, Keld Laursen, Laura Toschi, Nicolas van Zeebroeck and two anonymous referees as well as the Editor for useful comments.
This paper has benefited from comments of the audience of various seminars and conferences including the 4th EPIP conference (Bologna), the 98th AEA conference (Tokyo) and
the DRUID-DIME Winter 2009 PhD conference (Aalborg). Gaetan gratefully acknowledges
financial support from the FRS-FNRS.
† The University of Melbourne. Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, and Intellectual Property Research Institute of Australia. Level 7, Alan Gilbert Building, Victoria 3010, Australia. (email:
[email protected])
‡ Université libre de Bruxelles (Solvay Brussels School of Economics and Management,
ECARES). Bruegel, Brussels, and CEPR, London.
1
1
Introduction
In 2008 the total number of patent applications filed at the European Patent
Office (EPO) again reached a new record of 146,150.1 The United States Patent
and Trademark Office (USPTO) as well as the Japan Patent Office (JPO)
achieved a similar success, as illustrated by the spectacular 456,321 and 391,002
applications respectively filed that same year. The left-hand side of Figure 1
shows that increases in patent filings are common in patent offices. Constant
record breaking is, however, not praised by all observers of patent systems.
Many concerns are being raised, especially by economists, as witnessed by the
recent contributions of Jaffe and Lerner (2004) and Bessen and Meurer (2008)
for the U.S. patent system and Guellec and van Pottelsberghe (2007) for the
European patent system. The worries are related to the number and quality of
incoming patent applications as well as to the longer pendency of the substantive examination of patents which generate worrying backlogs, increasing the
level of uncertainty on the market.
Figure 1: Total patent applications and the apparent propensity to patent
5
x 10
4
350
US
JP
EP
300
Patents per R&D expenditure
4.5
3.5
Patent filings
3
2.5
2
1.5
1
US
JP
EP
250
200
150
100
0.5
0
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
50
1980
2005
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
Notes: Left panel: JP, US and EP indicate the total number of yearly patent applications
from 1980 to 2005 at the JPO, the USPTO and the EPO, respectively. Right panel: Total
patent applications divided by total internal R&D expenditures (1980 = 100).
Sources: See Table 8 in Appendix B. Own computation.
The right-hand side of Figure 1 suggests that the boom in patent filings in
the U.S. and in Europe is due to an increase in the number of patents filed
per unit of R&D expenditure, and particularly so in Europe. The drop in the
patents-to-R&D ratio at the JPO is partly due to a change in drafting practices
that resulted in an increase in the average number of claims per patent since
the late eighties.
Kortum and Lerner (1999) argue that the jump in patenting at the USPTO
1 This figure does not include the PCT-International filings for which the EPO must “only”
provide a search report. Had these filings been taken into account, the total number of
applications would have been higher than 200,000. PCT stands for “Patent Cooperation
Treaty”. It provides a unified procedure for filing patent applications worldwide.
2
reflects ‘an increase in US innovation spurred by changes in the management
of research’ and a shift towards more applied activities. Guellec and van Pottelsberghe (2007) provide additional reasons. According to the authors, several
factors explain the surge in patent filings observed since the mid-nineties in
major patent offices. First, new actors came to the fore in the most advanced
economies. IP awareness is rising amongst SMEs and the Bayh-Dole act regulation ratified in the U.S. in 1980 (or the like in Europe since the mid-1990s) fostered academic patenting. Second, the emergence of new fields of research, such
as nanotechnologies and biotechnologies, has opened new patenting domains.
Third, new countries such as China, Brazil and India have gradually entered
the world patent system, partly stimulated by the Trade-Related Intellectual
Property Rights (TRIPs) agreements. The fourth reason — and probably the
most important one — is related to the emergence of new patent strategies. The
use of patents is increasingly shifting from the traditional use of protecting one’s
own innovations to new types of uses (see e.g. Cohen et al., 2000; Guellec et al.,
2007; Hall and Ziedonis, 2001; Rivette and Kline, 2000) and there is evidence
of “excessive” patenting behavior adopted by a number of applicants.
Several factors have influenced applicants’ behavior. Among them, the laxity
of patent offices possibly plays a role. Encaoua et al. (2006, p. 1430) argue
that ‘the boom in patent applications [is concomitant with] a general sentiment
of relaxation of patentability requirements [...] in certain jurisdictions.’ The
argument is also echoed in Sanyal and Jaffe (2006) who show that the explosion
of patenting in the U.S. can partly be attributed to lower examination standards
at the USPTO. Inappropriate fee policies may as well have helped to push the
trend upward: if the patenting process becomes cheaper, one would logically
expect a higher demand for patents.
The objective of the present paper is to test this “fees” assumption. The
contribution to the literature is twofold. First, the paper provides an analysis
of patent fees since 1980 in three major patent offices: the EPO, the JPO and
the USPTO. Second, it presents a first panel data analysis of the impact of fees
on the demand for patents. Existing studies on the price elasticity of demand
for patents are mainly performed at the cross-sectional level.2 A limitation of
this approach is that it assumes low adjustment costs, such that a change in any
explanatory variable leads to an immediate adjustment in the number of patents
applied for. Given that the main explanatory variable, R&D expenditure, is
itself very stable, the output is relatively close to its long-run level with respect
to that variable. However, the estimate of the price elasticity is more sensitive
to this issue, as patenting fees are potentially more volatile. A key feature of
this paper is thus the use of dynamic panel data models of patent applications,
which allow to control for time invariant country characteristics and to estimate
both short and long-run elasticities. On a more practical level, understanding
the demand response for fee change is of interest to patent offices for operational
reasons. Most of the patent offices are self-financed (Gans et al., 2004) and the
2 See e.g. de Rassenfosse and van Pottelsberghe (2007) and Harhoff et al. (2009). A comprehensive literature review on the role of fees in patent systems is provided in de Rassenfosse
and van Pottelsberghe (2010).
3
precise estimation of price elasticities is particularly interesting in this respect.
The paper is structured as follows. The next section describes the complex
fee structure of patent offices and presents the working assumptions that are
used to compute absolute and relative fees for the three patent offices. Section
3 analyzes the evolution and growth rates of fees since 1980. The econometric
methodology is explained in Section 4, and the results are presented in Section
5. The last section concludes and puts forward policy implications.
The main findings are that relative patent fees (i.e. fees per claim per capita)
have actually plummeted over the years since the mid-nineties in the three regions. Entry fees and cumulated fees up to the grant at the EPO have declined
severely since the mid-1990s, which contributed to the boom in patenting observed in Europe. The quantitative analysis suggests that the fee elasticity of
demand for patents is about -0.30.
2
Methodological approach
The fee structure in patent systems is particularly complex. From the filing
of an application to the grant of a patent and its renewal, the assignee has
to pay various fees at different points in time. The structure of fees in terms
of schedule and scope varies substantially across patent offices, which makes
international comparisons complex to implement. For instance, filing fees at
the USPTO explicitly include the search and examination of the patent, and
the whole process up to the grant lasts about 35 months. At the EPO, filing
and search fees lead to a search report after 18 months. Then the applicant
may withdraw its application or opt for a substantive examination and pay
examination fees. The process up to the grant lasts about 5 years on average
(van Zeebroeck, 2008). In addition firms may choose between various routes to
reach a patent office (i.e. direct application, second filings or PCT applications),
which affects patenting costs. Fees also vary according to the filing strategy
adopted by firms: they may opt for an accelerated search request, send late
replies, inflate the number of claims and pages or adopt a low quality drafting
style.3
The patenting process can be summarized in four key steps, each being
associated with specific fees and a particular timing: filing, search, examination
and granting. The first step consists of the filing of a patent, which includes a
filing fee and a search fee. When the search for prior art is performed and the
search report published (in general 18 months after the filing of the patent), it is
followed by the examination fees if a request for substantive examination is filed.
Then, if the patent is granted, the assignee must pay granting and publication
fees.
Comparing fees across patent offices therefore requires a cumulative approach. In what follows, two fee indicators are computed. The first one, entry
fees, represents the short-term cost of entering the patenting process. It includes
3 See van Pottelsberghe and François (2009) and van Pottelsberghe and Mejer (2010) for
an in-depth comparison of the fee structure at the USPTO, the JPO and the EPO.
4
all the fees that must be paid during the first 18 months from the filing date
and is generally composed of filing fees and search fees. At the USPTO, the
examination is performed for all patents (except if the applicant pays a fee to
defer examination) and filing fees actually encompass examination fees. The
second indicator corresponds to the (cumulated) fees up to the grant. It represents the minimum level of fees to be borne by an applicant in order to have
its patent granted. It encompasses entry fees, examination and granting fees.
Table 1 summarizes the composition of the two indicators for the three patent
offices.
EPO
JPO
USPTO
Table 1: Composition of fees indicators
Filing > Search > Exam. > Granting
(*)
(*)
(*)
> Renewal
Notes: and indicate the fees that are included in the first indicator (entry fees) and the
second indicator (fees up to the grant), respectively. (*) indicates when claim-based fees
have to be paid. At the EPO, the applicant has a maximum of six months from the
publication of the search report (i.e. eighteen months after the priority date) to request a
substantive examination. At the JPO, an applicant is allowed to wait for three years after
the application date to request an examination.
Several working assumptions had to be used regarding the mode of interaction with the office and the drafting style; they are described in Appendix
A. Amongst these are the average number of claims included in a patent.4 As
indicated in Table 1, all patent offices rely on claim-based fees, which may constitute an important share of total fees. We use the average number of claims
per patent in each office to estimate claim-based fees. The fees are thus computed for a representative patent in each of the three offices. Fees are expressed
in 2000 constant USD PPPs. Detailed data on fees and claims were provided directly by the EPO, the JPO and the USPTO. Data on exchange rates are taken
from the International Monetary Fund’s World Economic Outlook Database.
Table 8 in Appendix B provides detailed information on the data sources.
The computations of entry fees and fees up to the grant are performed in
absolute and relative terms. The relative measure follows the methodology put
forward by van Pottelsberghe and François (2009). It consists of dividing the
absolute fees by the average number of claims included in patent applications
and the number of inhabitants in the geographical region covered by the patent
system. Since the three offices rely on claim-based fees, and given that the
4 Claims are the legal substance of a patent, the codified description of the invention that
constitutes the scope of protection in case of a grant.
5
average number of claims varies substantially across the three offices and over
time, it is appropriate to compute the fees per claim, the lowest common denominator of an invention. Similarly, a comprehensive international comparison
should take into consideration the size of the geographical scope (i.e. a measure
of the potential market covered by the patent office). From the point of view of
the applicant, a larger market induces a lower fee per market unit. Regarding
Europe, the size of the market has been limited to that of five countries (EPC5): Germany, France, the United Kingdom, the Netherlands and Italy, the most
frequently targeted countries (see van Pottelsberghe and van Zeebroeck, 2008).
Note that fees could as well be expressed relative to the regions’ GDP, but it
would make little difference as the three economies are at a similar level of
development.
Historical data on fees and claims are provided in Table 9 in Appendix
B. It is important to keep in mind that fee indicators at the EPO are lower
bounds of actual cumulated fees, as neither the fees requested by national patent
offices for priority filings nor the PCT fees are accounted for. Priority filing fees
vary substantially across countries, around a median of e 612 according to de
Rassenfosse and van Pottelsberghe (2007). It is also important to remind that
other costs are not considered in the present analysis, including the costs for
drafting and prosecuting patents and translation costs. It is nearly impossible
to provide reliable figures for this type of arms-length costs over a long period
of time in the three geographical areas.
3
Descriptive statistics
This section provides a thorough analysis of the evolution of patent fees at the
three offices. Figure 2 displays entry fees and total fees for the year 2007, in
absolute and relative terms.
Figure 2: Absolute and relative fees in 2007 in USD PPPs
7000
2.5
JPO
USPTO
EPO
Fees per claim per capita
Absolute fees
6000
5000
4000
3000
2000
1000
0
Entry
2
1.5
1
0.5
0
Up to grant
JPO
USPTO
EPO
Entry
Up to grant
Notes: Relative fees are fees per claim per million capita. The population in 2007 in EPC-5,
JP and the US are (in millions) 280, 128 and 302, respectively.
Sources: See Table 8 in Appendix B. Own computation.
The left-hand side of Figure 2, which presents the absolute level of fees,
shows that the EPO is the most expensive office, being two to three times more
6
expensive than the USPTO. Entry fees are particularly low at the JPO, whereas
the EPO has particularly high fees up to the grant.5 The picture looks quite
different if relative measures are considered (fees per claim per million capita,
presented in the right-hand side of Figure 2). In the short term, the average
European patent is still about three times more expensive than the average U.S.
or Japanese patent. However, as far as total fees are concerned, the combined
impact of a low number of claims and a smaller population size makes Japan the
most expensive market to protect, while the U.S. is by far the most affordable.
The evolution of absolute fees is depicted in Figure 3. A strong convergence
between EPO and USPTO entry fees occurred (left panel): while they have been
substantially decreasing since the mid-1990s at the EPO, they increased slightly
at the USPTO. Fees at the JPO have been increasing as well but they remain
low in absolute level. Fees up to the grant (right panel) have been increasing
in the three offices, in particular at the JPO, with a compound annual growth
rate (CAGR) of 8.4% since 1980. Japanese fees up to the grant have gradually
caught up with their U.S. counterparts. The EPO had the smallest increase
(with a CAGR of 1.3%), but still remains the most expensive office in absolute
terms.
Figure 3: Evolution of entry fees (left) and fees up to the grant (right)
4000
10000
US
JP
EP
3500
3000
8000
Fees
Fees
2500
2000
US
JP
EP
6000
4000
1500
1000
2000
500
0
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
0
1980
2005
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
Notes: Fees are expressed in constant 2000 US PPPs.
Sources: See Table 8 in Appendix B. Own computation.
In an apparent desire to make the patent system more affordable, the EPO
substantially decreased its patent fees at the end of the nineties, especially from
1997 to 1999. In 2000, Gert Kolle, Director for International Legal Affairs at
the EPO, commented on the recent changes: ‘Over the past three years we’ve
reduced patent office costs considerably. Between 1997 and 1999, for instance,
the filing fees for a European patent designating all 19 member states have fallen
[by approximately 80%][...]. Likewise, the fees paid up to the point of grant
during that period have fallen [by approximately 40%][...]. In total, EPO fees
have been reduced by around 41%, and I believe we have now reached the point
5 These cumulated fees for the EPO do not include the translation costs and the validation
fees that must be paid in each desired national patent office once the patent is granted by
the EPO. If these costs were taken into account, an EPO patent would be 5 to 10 times more
expensive than a USPTO patent, as shown by van Pottelsberghe and François (2009).
7
where the potential savings that can be made in patent office costs have been
exhausted.’6
Figure 4 displays the evolution of relative fees (fees per claim per million
inhabitants) over the whole period. Relative entry fees have been decreasing
over time at the EPO and the JPO, despite a sharp increase in the mid-1980s
in Europe. The differences in relative entry fees have been drastically reduced
over time, but Europe is still the most expensive region in relative terms. As far
as fees up to the grant are concerned, Japan remains the place with the most
expensive fees in relative terms, followed by Europe in an intermediate position
and the U.S. with the cheapest fees per claim per million capita.
Figure 4: Evolution of relative entry fees (left) and fees up to the grant (right)
5
US
JP
EP
1.2
Fees per claim per capita
Fees per claim per capita
1.4
1
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
3
2
1
0
1980
2005
US
JP
EP
4
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
Notes: Fees are expressed in constant 2000 US PPPs. Relative fees are fees per claim per
million capita.
Sources: See Table 8 in Appendix B. Own computation.
Table 2 presents the compound annual growth rates of both absolute and
relative fees in constant national currency, from 1980 to 1995 and from 1995
to 2007. It clearly shows that, since the mid-1990s, the EPO has achieved the
sharpest decrease in both entry fees and fees up to the grant, in both absolute
and relative terms. A particularly sharp decrease has occurred for EPO relative
entry fees, with a drop of about 8% a year between 1995 and 2007 (and about
6% in absolute terms).7
The next section presents the econometric methodology that will be used
to approximate the level and significance of the price elasticity of demand for
6 Interview with Richard Poynder for Thomson Scientific: “Discussion of European Patent
System”, May 2000, http://thomsonreuters.com/. Note that the sharp decrease in short-term
fees is exacerbated by the reallocation of designation fees from entry fees to fees up to the
grant in 1998.
7 It is important to keep in mind that the average growth rate of relative fees in Europe is
an upper bound estimate, because we have assumed that the market size was “only” related
to the 5 countries in which patents are validated after the grant by the EPO. However, it
could be argued that the whole geographical area covered by the EPO should be taken into
account, i.e. currently about 500 million inhabitants. Should this be the case, and given
the fast increase in the number of EPO Member States (from 11 in the early eighties to 36
nowadays — that is more than one additional country every year), one would have observed
a waterfall shape in the relative fees at the EPO over the past twenty years, which reinforces
the idea that relative fees severely plummeted in Europe.
8
Table 2: Compound annual growth rate (CAGR)
local currency
1980-1995
Absolute fees
JPO USPTO
EPO
Entry
2.04%
11.94%
1.38%
Up to grant
8.41%
10.84%
2.25%
Fees per claim per million capita
JPO* USPTO
EPO
Entry -8.47%
8.25% -0.20%
Up to grant -2.47%
7.18%
0.66%
of patent fees in constant 2000
1995-2007
JPO
5.46%
2.68%
USPTO
1.24%
-0.07%
EPO
-6.17%
-1.96%
JPO
1.21%
-1.46%
USPTO
-2.67%
-3.92%
EPO
-8.14%
-4.03%
Notes: (*) the CAGR prior to 1995 at the JPO has been computed for 7 years, from 1988 to
1995, due to the fact that only one claim per patent was allowed in Japan until 1988
(Kotabe, 1992).
patents.
4
Econometric methodology
The price elasticity of demand for patents can be estimated through a classical
patent production function. Research efforts (R) lead to inventions and inventions possibly lead to patent applications (P ∗ ) as a function of γ, which captures
the rate at which research efforts lead to patents. In this model, patent fees (F )
are a determinant of the propensity to patent and are thus included as such in
the model8
P ∗ = γRβ1 F β2
(1)
where β1 is the elasticity of patents with respect to R&D expenditures and β2
represents the price elasticity of demand for patents, which is expected to be
negative.9
Two assumptions are made regarding the relationship between the three
variables. First, it is assumed that fees are independent of the level of demand
for patents. This assumption is not obvious because many patent offices are
self-financed through fee income and could set a profit maximizing fee. However, application fees are only a fraction of total fees collected by patent offices;
8 The focus here is more on the elasticity of the fees up to the grant than on entry fees. This
assumption suggests that applicants are influenced more by the cumulated fees of the process
they start. It could, however, be argued that some applicants may be interested only in shortterm protection (i.e. a patent pending protection). Additional estimates of the elasticity of
entry fees are therefore also reported.
9 Patenting costs are not accounted for in R&D expenditures. There is thus no risk of
double-counting when fees and R&D outlays are simultaneously included as explanatory variables.
9
renewal fees generally account for a substantial share of their income. Figure 3
provides a first evidence that patent fees do not react to the number of patent
filings. It shows that patent fees stayed constant at the USPTO during the 90’s
whereas the demand increased substantially over the period. This assumption
will be explicitly validated in Section 5 with a Granger causality test. The second assumption is that there exists a long-run equilibrium between the number
of patents and R&D efforts. That is, we postulate that the variables are cointegrated. The extra-information provided by the cointegration between variables
will be used to refine the econometric analysis. Again, this assumption will be
formally validated in the next section.
In order to approximate the elasticities, two econometric models are used:
a partial adjustment model and an error correction model. While the former
is intuitive to differentiate between short- and long-run elasticities, the latter
takes advantage of the co-integration between variables. Existing studies on the
price elasticity of demand for patents are mainly performed on cross-sectional
datasets. A limitation of this approach is that it assumes low adjustment costs,
such that a change in any explanatory variable leads to an immediate adjustment
in the number of patents applied for. Given that the main explanatory variable,
R&D expenditure, is itself very stable, the output is relatively close to its longrun level with respect to that variable. However, the estimate of the price
elasticity is more sensitive to this issue, as patent fees are potentially more
volatile. It is therefore important to exploit the dynamic dimension of the
demand function.
Partial adjustment model
The logarithmic transformation of the patent production function (1) produces
the following additive model:
ln Pit∗ = γi + β1 ln Rit + β2 ln Fit + εit
(2)
Rit and Fit are both expressed in constant US PPPs of 2000. There are three
countries (i ∈ [1, 3]) and twenty-six years (t ∈ [1, 26]). γi is assimilated to the
country fixed effect in the regression and εit is the error term.
Equation (2) implicitly assumes that the demand for patents immediately
adjusts to its long-run level P ∗ . There are many reasons to challenge this assumption and to assume that adjustment to any new equilibrium level occurs
over several periods. First, the filing of patents is subject to a learning process:
the current level of patents is likely to affect next year patenting activity. Second, the sequential and cumulative aspects of research and development projects
imply that an invention patented in a given year may be improved and yield
further patentable improvements in the subsequent years.10 Dynamic models
10 It can be argued that the R&D expenditure variable should be lagged so as to take into
account the potential delay between the research activities and the occurrence of a patent.
However, there is a strong contemporaneous relationship between R&D expenditures and
patenting (Hall et al., 1986). In any case, the dynamic specification allows for a delayed
impact of R&D expenditures over time.
10
can easily be recovered from equation (2) if one introduces a dynamic partial
adjustment process of the form (see e.g. Nerlove, 1958):
λ
Pit∗
Pit
=
,0 < λ < 1
(3)
Pi,t−1
Pi,t−1
where λ measures the rate of adjustment (the higher λ, the faster the adjustment). Taking the expression to the log and substituting for ln P ∗ into equation
(2), we obtain the following partial adjustment equation:
ln Pit = γis + (1 − λ) ln Pi,t−1 + β1s ln Rit + β2s ln Fit + νit
(4)
s
where β /λ equals β in equation (2) and represents the long-run elasticity; β s
represents the short-term elasticity. The inclusion of the lagged dependent variable in the model may result in biased estimates (see, for instance, Nickel, 1981).
Therefore, three methods are used to correct for this source of bias. First, we
rely on instrumental variables for the lagged number of patents. The instruments are the total number of inhabitants and the GDP per capita (capturing
both the size and the level of technological development of the region). A second and alternative methodology consists of running a Kiviet-type regression
(Kiviet, 1995) that directly removes the bias for the lagged estimator. The estimation method is based on Bruno (2005) which is particularly suited for a small
number of individuals. The Arellano-Bond estimator is the third method used.
It consists in estimating equation (4) in first difference and using the lagged
dependent variable as an instrument.
Error correction model
An error correction model (ECM) can be used to exploit the cointegration between variables; it allows combining the long-run relationship and the short
run effect. The error correction term is the residual from the estimated longrun relationship, that is, the difference between the observed and the estimated
demand for patents in level:
eit = ln Pit∗ + γˆi − βˆ1 ln Rit − βˆ2 ln Fit
(5)
The correction term is then used as an adjustment process to capture long-run
dynamics. The ECM is defined as the first difference of equation (2) plus last
period’s error correction term:
∗
∆Pit∗ = ci +α1 ∆ ln Rit +α2 ∆ ln Fit −(α3 ln Pi,t−1
−α4 ln Ri,t−1 −α5 ln Fi,t−1 )+νit
(6)
where α3 may range from 0 (no adjustment) to -1 (full adjustment). Long-run
effects for, say, fees are recovered by dividing α5 by the adjustment coefficient α3
(see Alogoskoufis and Smith, 1991, for a discussion). The econometric method
used for the ECM is a Prais-Winsten regression, which corrects for the potential
contemporaneous correlation of residuals. Equation (6) is estimated for both
fees up to the grant and entry fees.
11
5
Empirical results
A first glimpse at the potential impact of changes in fees on the behavior of
applicants is illustrated in Figure 5. Each panel plots the difference in the
patent-to-R&D ratio (as a proxy for the propensity to patent) between two
countries and the difference in the level of fees. The values are normalized to 1
in 1980, so that a difference in, say, relative fees in countries i and j greater than
0 actually means that fees in country i grew faster than fees in country j. It
clearly appears that a negative trend in the difference in fees is associated with
a positive trend in the difference in the patent-to-R&D ratio, and vice versa.
In other words, countries in which patents became more expensive had a lower
increase in their propensity to patent. These long-term graphical illustrations
suggest that fees affect the behavior of applicants.
4
3
−1
2
−1.5
1
∆ Propensity
US − JP
1990
1995
2000
0
2005
4
0
2
−5
0
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
−10
2005
1
5
0
0
−1
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
∆ Fees
1985
∆ Fees
−2
1980
∆ Fees
0
−0.5
∆ Propensity
EP − JP
∆ Propensity
US − EP
Figure 5: Bilateral differences in the evolutions of the propensity to patent and
fees, 1980-2005
−5
2005
Notes: ∆ Propensity (solid line) is defined as the difference between the propensity to
patent in country i and the propensity to patent in country j, relative to the base year 1980
(=1) [e.g. propensity eu(t)/propensity eu(1) - propensity jp(t)/propensity jp(1)], reported
on the left-hand scale. ∆ Fees (dashed line), reported on the right-hand scale, are defined
similarly with fees up to the grant.
Before assessing the magnitude of applicants’ sensibility to fees, we formally
test the assumptions underlying the regression models. First, we investigate the
dynamics of price adjustment. The assumption that fees are independent from
the total number of patents processed is tested with a Granger causality test
between the level of fees and the number of patents applied for. The optimal
number of lags p for the unrestricted regression was determined for each patent
office using the Schwarz’ Bayesian Information Criterion. A Granger causality
test was then performed using a restricted regression with p lagged value of both
12
the fees up to the grant and the total number of patent applications. Results
are presented in Table 3.
Table 3: Granger causality test
Nb of lags (p) F-value p-value
JPO
1
2.71
0.11
USPTO
1
1.17
0.29
EPO
2
1.14
0.34
It appears that the past demand for patents does not help to predict the
level of patent fees in any of the three regions. The hypothesis that the level
of demand causes in the Granger sense the level of fees is rejected for all three
country-series. As a consequence, patent fees can fairly be treated as exogenously determined in the regressions.
The assumption that the variables are cointegrated is tested in two steps.
First, we test for the presence of homogeneous autoregressive roots. Second,
we perform panel cointegration tests. A large literature on unit roots in panel
data has recently emerged and several statistical tests have been proposed. We
implement three tests proposed by Levin et al. (2002), Im et al. (2003) and
Maddala and Wu (1999) which all assume independence across units. They are
denoted LLC, IPS and MW, respectively. The disturbances of autoregressive
models are assumed to have a zero mean, finite variance and might exhibit autocorrelation. In each case, the null hypothesis is that of a unit root for all
individuals. LLC is performed under the restrictive alternative of an homogeneous autoregressive root. IPS extends LLC in that the alternative allows both
for heterogeneous roots and for heterogeneous presence of a unit root (i.e. the
alternative is that there might be a unit root for some individuals, but not for
all). The test statistic is based on the ADF statistics averaged across the individuals. Finally, MW is closely related to IPS but relies on combining the level
of p-values of the independent unit root tests (see Hurlin and Mignon, 2006, for
an excellent overview of unit root tests for panel data). Table 4 summarizes the
various results.
LLC
IPS
MW
P*
Value
0.92
3.09
9.25
Table 4: Panel unit root tests
R
F
p-value Value p-value Value
0.82
0.03
0.51
0.16
0.99
2.23
0.99
0.13
0.16
0.89
0.99
5.00
p-value
0.56
0.55
0.54
Notes: Individual effects included. LLC: corrected t-stat reported. IPS: Wtbar reported.
MW: Fisher statistic based on individual ADF statistics and their associated p-value pooled
test statistic. A Matlab code is available from C. Hurlin.
13
None of the tests leads to a rejection of the null hypothesis of a homogeneous
autoregressive root; all the series are therefore non-stationary. Then, a potential
co-integration relationship between the variables was tested using the four paneldata tests proposed by Westerlund (2007). Two tests (labeled G) are performed
under the alternative that the panel is co-integrated as a whole, while the two
other tests (labeled P ) are designed under the alternative that there is at least
one individual that is co-integrated. In all cases, the null is of no co-integration.
The results are presented in Table 5.
Table 5: Panel co-integration tests
Value p-value ∗ p-value †
Gτ
-2.93
0.05
0.09
Gα -12.72
0.16
0.02
-3.42
0.33
0.27
Pτ
Pα -10.46
0.07
0.05
Notes: The tests are implemented with a constant. The lags in the error correction equation
are chosen according to the Akaike information criterion. (∗ ) p-values under the normal
distribution. († ) p-values based on the bootstrapped distribution (400 runs). τ and α
indicate different test statistics. See Persyn and Westerlund (2008) for further
methodological details.
The null hypothesis of no co-integration is rejected under the test α, and
the G values indicate that the panel is co-integrated as a whole. The result
bears an interesting insight into the R&D-patent relationship, as it suggests
that there is a long-run equilibrium level between the number of patents and
R&D efforts, taking into account other determinants of patent filings such as
the level of patent fees.
Table 6 presents the estimated parameters of both the partial adjustment
model and the error correction model.
14
Table 6: Estimates of the parameters of the patent production function
Model
Dep. Var.
Fees
Est. method
ln Pt−1
ln Pt
Grant
IFGLS
A
0.719***
(8.50)
Partial Adjustment
ln Pt
Grant
LSDV C.B.
B
∆ ln Pt
Grant
Prais-Winsten
D
∆ ln Pt
Entry
Prais-Winsten
E
-0.114**
(2.31)
-0.071*
(1.63)
0.413***
(4.06)
0.548***
(2.62)
0.189*
(1.79)
0.520*
(2.38)
0.068
(0.87)
-0.067***
(4.02)
-0.121***
(4.06)
-0.073***
(3.63)
-0.070***
(2.83)
-0.008
(0.56)
Yes
0.20
75
Yes
0.09
75
0.855***
(19.16)
0.568***
(9.75)
∆ ln Pt−1
ln Rt
ECM
∆ ln Pt
Grant
GMM
C
0.409***
(3.52)
0.283***
(3.29)
∆ ln Rt
15
ln Rt−1
ln Ft
-0.060***
(2.80)
-0.071***
(3.82)
∆ ln Ft
ln Ft−1
Country FE
AR(1)
AR(2)
Adj. R2
Observations
Yes
0.00
0.90
75
Yes
0.12
0.98
75
Yes
0.00
0.60
0.71
72
Notes: The dependent variable is the number of patents applied for at the JPO, the USPTO or the EPO, in level (ln Pt ) or in first difference
(∆ ln Pt ). The econometric methods are for column A: iterated FGLS to correct for autocorrelation of residuals and contemporaneous panel
correlation. The variables CAP IT A and GDP CAP are used as instrumental variables for the lagged number of patents; column B: least square
dummy variable correcting for bias (LSDV C.B.) with bootstrapped standard errors (Bruno, 2005); column C: Arellano-Bond difference GMM (one
step) with one lag of the dependent variable (p-value for the Sargan test = 1.00); columns D and E: Prais-Winsten regression, correcting for
contemporaneous correlation of residuals. AR(1) and AR(2) report the p-values for the null-hypothesis of no autocorrelation of order 1 and 2,
respectively. ***, ** and * indicate significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent probability threshold, respectively.
Estimations of the parameters of the partial adjustment model are presented
in columns A to C, and estimations of the parameters of the error correction
model are presented in columns D and E. The regressions are estimated with
(absolute) fees up to the grant (columns A to D). For completeness, column E
reports to elasticity of (absolute) entry fees.11 The estimated price elasticity is
always negative and significant and suggests short-term elasticities of fees up
to the grant that vary between -0.06 and -0.12. Long-run elasticities must be
computed from the estimated parameters and multipliers; they are displayed in
Table 7. They range from -0.15 to -0.49, with an average of about -0.30. The
results are in line with the price elasticities estimated by de Rassenfosse and
van Pottelsberghe (2007, 2009) with cross sections of countries. They report
elasticities that vary between -0.45 and -0.56, which is slightly higher than the
present long-run estimates. The results confirm that patents are an inelastic
good. The long-term patent elasticity of R&D expenditures is about 1.50. Yet,
one has to be cautious not the interpret this parameter at face value since the
variable captures the potential of a region both in terms of research output and
market attractiveness. If entry fees are taken into account, column E of Table 6
shows that the short term elasticity is -0.07. Interestingly, the long-term effect
of entry fees is not significant as indicated in Table 7.
Table 7: Long-term elasticities
R&D
Fees
A
1.45***
(0.28)
-0.21**
(-0.16)
B
1.96***
(0.26)
-0.49***
(-0.09)
C
0.95***
(0.19)
-0.15***
(-0.04)
D
1.65***
(0.37)
-0.36***
(-0.12)
Mean A to D
1.50
-0.30
E
0.95*
(0.59)
-0.12
(-0.18)
Notes: Elasticities estimated from the regression results of Table 6. Standard errors are in
parenthesis. ***, **, * indicate significance at the 1, 5 and 10 percent probability threshold,
respectively.
The models presented in Table 6 were also estimated with time dummies to
account for a change in the propensity to patent over time. Regressions were
run with time dummies of 3, 4 and 5 years interval. Only the 4 and 5-years time
dummies were significant for some models but the estimated price elasticities
were very robust to the inclusion of time effects. Fees were also interacted with
time dummies but the interaction term was not significant, suggesting that the
impact of fees have been roughly stable over time. Similarly, time dummies
were interacted with R&D expenditures but with no significant effect.
The results of Table 7 can be used to estimate the total impact that the
fee policy adopted by the EPO had on the overall propensity to patent. Given
a mean price elasticity of -0.30, roughly 20% of the increase in patent filings
11 Note that the econometric models are estimated with absolute fees and not relative fees.
Absolute fees are the fees that applicants have to pay.
16
over the period 1995 to 2001 can be attributed to the decrease in fees.12 This
estimate is more conservative than that of Eaton et al. (2004), who attribute
60% of the increase in the number of EPO patents over the nineties to the
decline in the overall cost of seeking protection at the EPO.
6
Concluding remarks
The main objective of this paper is to assess whether fees could be one factor
underlying the boom in patent applications observed over the past two decades.
The paper focuses on the demand for patent at the patent offices of three main
regions, namely Europe (EPO), the U.S. (USPTO) and Japan (JPO). Entry
fees and fees up to the grant have been computed for a period ranging from
1980 to 2007. This unique dataset clearly shows that the EPO has operated
the sharpest decrease in patent fees since the mid-1990s, in both absolute and
relative terms (fees per claim per capita), and for both entry fees and fees up to
grant. The USPTO has maintained nearly stable absolute fees since 1995, but
has experienced a slight drop in relative fees. Despite this convergence, the EPO
still charges fees that are two to three times higher than those of the USPTO
in 2007.
The second contribution to the literature is to test empirically the intuition
that fees affect the filing behavior of applicants. This is performed through an
in-depth quantitative analysis aiming at evaluating the amplitude and significance of the price elasticity of demand for patents. The estimation of dynamic
panel-data models of patent applications underlines the prime role of research
activities, and a significant price elasticity of demand for patents of about -0.30.
This result is in line with (albeit lower than) the few existing estimates based
on cross-sectional analyses.
The impact of fees is estimated from the aggregate demand for patents. Another approach would have consisted in estimating the elasticity at the firm
level, where individual characteristics may imply a large difference in the reaction to change in fees among firms. Yet, that approach would be restricted to
a very limited time range and would hide the aggregate effect. As the focus
on the present study is on the policy dimension, we believe that the aggregate
approach is the best suited. It is nevertheless important to keep in mind that
important behavioral differences might be observed across firms according to
their size, their wealth or their industry.
The empirical exercise confirms that fees can actually be taken as a factor
influencing the propensity to patent, and hence can be considered as an effective
policy leverage by policy makers. The sharp drop in fees orchestrated by the
EPO, in both absolute and relative terms, and the stable, though very inexpensive, fee policy of the USPTO, combined with the negative and significant
12 Fees decreased by 50% (from 8,025 USD PPP in 1995 to 3,942 USD PPP in 2001),
which implies a 15% increase of patent applications. Meanwhile, patent applications actually
increased by 80%, so that roughly one fifth (15/80) of the growth in patent applications can
be attributed to the decrease in patent fees.
17
price elasticity of demand for patents, certainly did contribute to the observed
increase in patent filings. About 20% of the growth of patent applications at
the EPO in the mid-nineties can be attributed to the fee policy adopted over
that period. Part of the solution to the current backlog crisis would therefore
be to adopt a more stringent fee policy. As the fee elasticity is much smaller
than unity such a policy would further reinforce the funding model of the EPO.
Whether an increase in fees is socially desirable remains an open question.
To the best of our knowledge, there exists no study that explicitly looks at
this issue. A useful extension to the present work would thus be to investigate
whether higher fees weed out low quality patents.
References
Alogoskoufis, G. and Smith, R. (1991). ‘On error correction models: Specification, interpretation, estimation’, Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 5, pp.
97-128.
Bessen, J. and Meurer, M. (2008). Patent failure: How judges, bureaucrats, and
lawyers put innovators at risk, Princeton University Press, New Jersey.
Bruno, G. (2005). ‘Approximating the bias of the LSDV estimator for dynamic
unbalanced panel data models’, Economic Letters, Vol. 87, pp. 361-366.
Cohen, W., Nelson, R. and Walsh, J. (2000). ‘Protecting their intellectual assets:
Appropriability conditions and why US manufacturing firms patent (or not)’,
NBER Working Paper 7553.
de Rassenfosse, G. and van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B. (2007). ‘Per un
pugno di dollari: A first look at the price elasticity of patents’, Oxford Review
of Economic Policy, Vol. 23, pp. 588-604.
de Rassenfosse, G. and van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B. (2009). ‘A policy
insight into the R&D-patent relationship’, Research Policy, Vol. 38, pp. 779792.
de Rassenfosse, G. and van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B. (2010). ‘The role of
fees in patent systems: Theory and evidence’, CEPR Discussion Paper 7879.
Eaton, J., Kortum, S. and Lerner, J. (2004). ‘International patenting and the
European Patent Office: A quantitative assessment’, Patents, Innovation and
Economic Performance: OECD Conference Proceedings, pp. 27-52.
Encaoua, D., Guellec, D. and Martinez, C. (2006). ‘Patent system for encouraging innovation: Lessons from economic analysis’, Research Policy, Vol. 35,
pp. 1423-1440.
Gans, J., King, S. and Lampe, R. (2004). ‘Patent renewal fees and self-funding
patent offices’, Topics in Theoretical Economics, Vol. 4, article 6.
18
Guellec, D. and van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B. (2007). The economics of
the European patent system, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Guellec, D., van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B. and van Zeebroeck, N. (2007).
‘Patent as a market instrument’, in D. Guellec and B. van Pottelsberghe de
la Potterie, The economics of the European patent system, Oxford University
Press, Oxford, pp. 85-113.
Hall, B., Griliches, Z. and Hausman, J. (1986). ‘Patents and R and D: Is There
a Lag?’, International Economic Review, Vol. 27, pp. 265-283.
Hall, B. and Ziedonis, R. (2001). ‘The patent paradox revisited: An empirical
study of patenting in the US semiconductor industry, 1979-95’, The RAND
Journal of Economics, Vol. 32, pp. 101-128.
Harhoff, D., Hoisl, K., Reichl, B. and van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B. (2009).
‘Patent validation at the country level - The role of fees and translation costs’,
Research Policy, Vol. 38, pp. 1423-1437.
Hurlin, C. and Mignon, V. (2006). ‘Une Synthèse des tests de racine unitaire
sur données de panel’, Economie et Prévision, Vol. 169, pp. 253-294.
Im, K., Pesaran, M. and Shin, Y. (2003). ‘Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous
panels’, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 115, pp. 53-74.
Jaffe, A. and Lerner, J. (2004). Innovation and its discontents: How our broken
patent system is endangering innovation and progress, and what to do about
it, Princeton University Press, New Jersey.
Kiviet, J. (1995). ‘On bias, inconsistency, and efficiency of various estimators in
dynamic panel data models’, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 68, pp. 53-78.
Kortum, S. and Lerner, J. (1999). ‘What is behind the recent surge in patenting?’, Research Policy, Vol. 28, pp. 1-22.
Kotabe, M. (1992). ‘A comparative study of U.S. and Japanese patent systems’,
Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 23, pp. 147-168.
Levin, A., Lin, C. and Chu, C. (2002). ‘Unit root tests in panel data: Asymptotic
and finite-sample properties’, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 108, pp. 1-24.
Maddala, G. and Wu, S. (1999). ‘A comparative study of unit root tests with
panel data and a new simple test’, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 61, pp. 631-652.
Nerlove, M. (1958). ‘Distributed lags and estimation of long-run supply and
demand elasticities: Theoretical considerations’, Journal of Farm Economics,
Vol. 40, pp. 301-311.
Nickel, S. (1981). ‘Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects’, Econometrica,
Vol. 49, pp. 1417-1426.
19
Persyn, D. and Westerlund, J. (2008). ‘Error correction based cointegration tests
for panel data’, Stata Journal, Vol. 8, pp. 232-241.
Rivette, K. and Kline, D. (2000). Rembrandts in the attic: Unlocking the hidden
value of patents, Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA.
Sanyal, P. and Jaffe, A. (2006). ‘Peanut butter versus the new economy: Does
the increased rate of patenting signal more inventions or just lower standards?’, Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, Special Issue in the memory
of Zvi Griliches.
van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B. and François, D. (2009). ‘The cost factor
in patent systems’, Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, Vol. 9, pp.
1573-7012.
van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B. and Mejer, M. (2010). ‘The London Agreement and the cost of patenting in Europe’, European Journal of Law and
Economics, Vol. 29, pp. 211-237.
van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B. and van Zeebroeck, N. (2008). ‘A brief
history of space and time: The scope-year index as a patent value indicator
based on families and renewals’, Scientometrics, Vol. 75, pp. 319-338.
van Zeebroeck, N. (2008). ‘Patents only live twice: A patent survival analysis
in Europe’, Working Paper 07/028, Centre Emile Bernheim, Université libre
de Bruxelles.
van Zeebroeck, N., van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B. and Guellec, D. (2009).
‘Claiming more: The increased voluminosity of patent applications and its
determinants’, Research Policy, Vol. 38, pp. 1006-1020.
Westerlund, J. (2007). ‘Testing for error correction in panel data’, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 69, pp. 709-748.
20
A
Working assumptions
Each patent office has its own fee structure, which makes international comparisons a difficult exercise. The assumptions made for the empirical analysis
seek to make the results reasonably comparable. The present appendix provides
the list of working assumptions that were made when measuring absolute and
relative fees, for both entry fees and fees up to the grant.
The applicant is assumed to be a large entity (SMEs have reduced fees in
the USA and Japan, but large firms still account for the most important
share of applications);
No late payments, paper filing (as opposed to electronic filings, which are
slightly less expensive);
A change in price during the year is assumed to be effective the next year
if it was implemented after June 30. If it was implemented on or before
June 30, it is assumed effective at the beginning of the year.
Modification in the timing of fees has been taken into account when the
information was provided by the patent office. Otherwise, it is assumed
not to have changed over time. At the EPO, designation fees were included
in entry fees before 1998, and in total cumulated fees up to the grant for
the subsequent years.
Other country-specific assumptions are:
1. USPTO-related assumptions:
Three independent claims have been considered
2. EPO-related assumptions:
Euro-direct fees have been considered (the PCT route generally induces slightly higher fees);
Use of European Search Report since 2005;
Five countries were taken into consideration to compute the relative
fees: Germany, France, the United Kingdom, Italy and the Netherlands.
Exchange rates and inflation for EPC countries are based on German
macroeconomic data and provided by Eurostat.
21
B
Data sources
Table 8: Data sources and variables description
Variable
P
R
F
22
CLAIM S
RAT ES
CAP IT A
GDP CAP
Description
Total number of yearly patent applications defined as
sum of resident and non-resident applications.
(EPO: Eurodirect + PCT regional filings)
Total internal R&D expenditures
(EPO: R&D expenditures are computed for each year as
the sum of R&D expenditures of the EPC Member States)
Fees for a representative patent. See main text and
Appendix A for methodological details
Average number of claims per patent
Exchange rates from (current) national currency to constant
national currency and constant US PPPs.
Million of inhabitants
GDP per capita
Source
Provided by patent offices (EPO, JPO, USPTO)
OECD Main Science and Technology Indicators
EPO, USPTO, JPO. US.. fees from 1980 to 1982 come from
House Report No. 96-1307, 96th Cong., 2d Sess. (1980)
EPO, USPTO, JPO
International Monetary Fund
World Economic Outlook (IMF-WEO)
IMF-WEO
OECD Statistical Portal
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
Entry
5,400
6,300
6,300
6,300
6,300
9,500
9,500
9,500
9,500
9,500
9,500
9,500
9,500
9,500
9,500
9,500
9,500
9,500
9,500
21,000
21,000
21,000
21,000
21,000
16,000
16,000
16,000
16,000
Table 9: Patent fees in current local currency
JPO ( )
USPTO (US )
EPO (e)
UTG Cl.* Entry UTG Cl. Entry UTP Cl.
45,400
1
79
243 12 1,288 2,407 10
52,300
1
81
245 13 1,293 2,417 10
52,300
1
81
245 13 1,368 2,557 10
52,300
1
300
800 14 1,453 2,698 11
52,300
1
300
800 14 1,474 2,737 11
78,800
1
300
800 14 1,839 3,479 11
78,800
1
340
900 15 1,924 3,639 11
78,800
1
340
900 15 2,112 3,874 11
127,000
3
340
900 15 2,109 3,869 11
127,000
3
340
900 16 2,113 3,877 11
127,000
3
370
990 17 2,132 3,911 11
127,000
3
630 1,680 17 2,453 5,013 11
127,000
3
690 1,820 17 2,490 5,088 11
133,300
4
710 1,880 17 2,639 5,350 12
198,100
5
710 1,880 18 2,655 5,383 12
198,100
5
730 1,940 17 2,727 5,796 12
198,100
5
750 2,000 18 2,676 5,687 12
207,100
6
770 2,060 20 2,642 5,569 13
207,100
6
812 2,132 21 1,391 5,556 13
212,900
7
796 2,006 22
938 4,414 13
212,900
7
762 1,972 24
978 4,454 14
219,800
8
818 2,058 26
978 4,454 14
219,800
8
866 2,146 27
975 4,430 14
219,800
8
876 2,176 27 1,015 4,470 15
242,100
8
896 2,226 27 1,015 4,470 15
242,100
8 1,200 2,600 24 1,320 4,775 15
242,100
8 1,100 2,500 24 1,395 5,020 15
242,100
8 1,100 2,500 24 1,395 5,020 15
Notes: UTG stands for “Up to grant” and Cl. for the number of claims. *: Prior to 1988,
there was only one claim per patent in Japan (Kotabe, 1992). Data on the number of claims
in 2006 and 2007 at the USPTO and from 2005 to 2007 at the EPO was missing and has
been set constant. See Appendix A for methodological details.
23