DOI: 10.1111/infi.12110
ARTICLE
The monetary policy origins of the eurozone crisis
David Beckworth
The Mercatus Center at George Mason
University, Arlington, Virginia
Correspondence
David Beckworth, The Mercatus Center
at George Mason University, 3434
Washington Blvd., Arlington,
VA 22201, USA.
Email:
[email protected]
Abstract
The eurozone crisis represents one of the greatest
economic tragedies of the past century. It has caused
immense human suffering, which continues to this day.
The standard view attributes the economic crisis to an
earlier buildup of public and private debt that was
augmented by the imposition of austerity during the crisis.
Although evidence exists of a relationship between the
debt buildup, austerity measures, and economic growth
during the crisis, that same evidence, on closer examination, points to eurozone countries’ common monetary
policy as the real culprit behind the area’s sharp decline in
economic activity. In particular, it seems that the
European Central Bank’s tightening of monetary policy
in 2008 and again in 2010–2011 not only caused two
recessions but also sparked the sovereign debt crisis and
gave teeth to the austerity programs. Such findings point
to the need for a new monetary policy regime in the
eurozone. The case is made for the new regime to be a
targeted growth path for total money spending.
1 | INTRODUCTION
Since 2008, one of the greatest economic tragedies of the past century has been unfolding in the
eurozone. As seen in Figure 1, the region has endured two sharp recessions and a consistently
underperforming economy during this period. The eurozone’s unemployment rate topped 12% at its
peak, and deflation buffeted the region twice. Reported levels of alcohol abuse, psychological stress,
and suicides soared over this period (Ellyatt, 2012). Many observers view this crisis as a full-blown
114
|
© 2017 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/infi
International Finance. 2017;20:114–134.
BECKWORTH
|
115
FIGURE 1
The eurozone crisis
Notes: Gray bars = GDP recession; core countries = Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, and the
Netherlands; periphery countries = Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, and Spain
Sources: Eurostat; author’s calculations
depression, and some even believe it matches the severity of Europe’s Great Depression of the 1930s
(Avent, 2012; Aziz, 2014; Crafts, 2013; O’Brien, 2014).
Though the pain caused by the eurozone’s economic crisis has been acute, it has not been evenly
distributed. The second and third columns of Figure 1 show that the core region of the eurozone saw its
economy decline 2% below its precrisis trend by the end of 2014, compared to a 25% decline for the
periphery.1 Similarly, the core region experienced a peak unemployment rate of approximately 8%,
compared to almost 18% for the periphery. Such disparate economic effects meant that the periphery
countries suffered far more fallout from the crisis than did their counterparts in the eurozone’s core
region. In particular, periphery countries faced rising public-debt burdens from bailing out the private
sector and from having less national income to service their debts. In turn, the mounting debt burden
raised the specter of sovereign default and sparked an outflow of capital from the periphery.
These divergent outcomes fuelled rising tensions among eurozone members. Core countries
insisted that any debt restructuring or bailout package for the periphery countries be conditional on
those countries adopting austerity measures to rein in government budgets.2 Unsurprisingly, periphery
countries were not thrilled about raising taxes and cutting government spending in the midst of a deep
recession. Tensions also rose among member countries over the extent to which monetary policy
should address the crisis. Though the European Central Bank (ECB) did take some action during the
crisis, the periphery countries wanted the ECB to more aggressively ease monetary policy. The core
countries, especially Germany, were against such actions, and because of their objections, the ECB
only began a quantitative easing (QE) program on March 9, 2015.
116
|
BECKWORTH
Growing tensions sparked fear that the currency union might break apart. Some members
wondered whether the periphery countries might be better served by having their own currency and
monetary policy rather than by being subject to the ECB’s one-size-fits-all policies.3 Before the
creation of the euro, numerous critics had warned that the eurozone was far from being an optimal
currency area and that introduction of the currency would likely end in disaster.4 These warnings
appeared to be coming to fruition during the crisis and, as one observer put it, placed the eurozone in a
‘full-fledged existential crisis’ (Shambaugh, 2012). Concerns over the crisis became such an issue that
even the head of the ECB, Mario Draghi, felt compelled to address them in 2011 (Atkins & Barber,
2011).
All these challenges point to the severity of the eurozone crisis over the past eight years. They also
raise an important question: Why did the crisis suddenly erupt in 2008 and then intensify in 2011? To
answer this question, this paper begins by reviewing the standard view of the crisis and then considers
an alternative perspective—that of monetary policy origins. Next, the paper takes an in-depth look at
the evidence behind these two differing views of the crisis.
2 | THE STANDARD VIEW
The standard answer to the earlier question centres around three key developments. First, financial
panic in the United States spread to the eurozone and triggered the initial recession (Mishkin, 2011).
Second, the periphery countries of Greece, Italy, and Portugal either accumulated too much public debt
or failed to reduce public debt during the years leading up to the crisis. Also during that time, the
periphery countries of Ireland, Spain, and Portugal accumulated too much private debt, which later
became public debt because of government bailouts. These two developments led to the emergence of
the sovereign debt crisis, which caused the second recession (Lane, 2012). The third development was
the imposition of fiscal austerity on the periphery countries without offsetting expansionary fiscal
policy in the core countries. This asymmetric approach meant that fiscal policy overall contracted in the
eurozone, further depressing total money spending in the currency union during the second recession
(De Grawe, 2012).
Though widely held, this understanding has some serious timing problems, which are visible in
Figure 2. This figure shows that economic activity, as measured by industrial production, peaked in
January 2008 in both the core and the periphery regions of the eurozone.5 The economic weakening
that followed preceded by approximately seven months both the financial panic and the first signs of
sovereign debt distress, as seen in panels B and C. The timing suggests, then, that the slowdown in
economic activity gave rise to financial panic and the sovereign debt crisis, rather than the other way
around.
Industrial production peaked again in February 2011 for both the core and the periphery regions,
ushering in a second recession. Although periphery sovereign spreads had been elevated in 2010, they
had begun to stabilize by later that same year. Core sovereign spreads at the time were also flat.6 A new
surge in spreads, however, began in mid-2011. Bank stress also started increasing in mid-2011 as
concerns about the solvency of banks in periphery countries sparked an exodus of depositors.7 As it had
in 2008, economic contraction in early 2011 preceded the new round of sovereign debt and bank stress
that began in mid-2011. This timing suggests, again, that the former caused the latter. But what caused
the initial economic slowdowns of 2008 and 2011? The standard view of the eurozone crisis has no
answer.
Another problem with the standard view of the eurozone crisis is that it implies that the periphery
region, where the excessive debt buildup occurred, should have been hit first and hardest by the crisis.
BECKWORTH
|
117
FIGURE 2
Problems with the standard view
Notes: Gray bars = industrial production recession. The European interbank offer rate (EURIBOR) is an unsecured
short-term lending rate for banks, whereas the euro overnight index average (EONIA) swap rate is a secured lending
rate. Put differently, this spread measures the difference between risky and safe short-term lending rates
Sources: Eurostat; ECB; author’s calculations
However, the first panel in Figure 2 shows that both the core and the periphery contracted at
approximately the same time and pace during the first recession. The standard view cannot explain this
pattern. During the second recession, the periphery experienced a sharper economic contraction than
did the core, but the timing was again the same for both regions.8
The standard view of the eurozone economic crisis is incomplete. It cannot explain what caused
economic activity to slow down before financial panic and the sovereign debt crisis ensued. It also
cannot explain why the recessions in the periphery and core countries shared the same timing and, at
least initially, the same pace of contraction.9
118
|
BECKWORTH
3 | THE MONETARY POLICY ORIGINS VIEW
There is an alternative view that can explain these developments: the ECB’s tightening of monetary
policy first in 2008 and again in 2010–2011. It is a simple but thorough explanation for the origins and
severity of the eurozone crisis.
As noted earlier, the economy began contracting in early 2008. The growth of total money
spending, a broad indicator of monetary conditions, had started declining even earlier.10 With
monetary conditions tightening and the economy slowing down, most central banks would have cut
interest rates. The ECB, however, did nothing and kept its target interest rate pegged at 4%. Thus began
the first tightening cycle of the ECB in early 2008. In the following months, the ECB intensified this
tightening cycle by signalling that it would raise its policy rate to ward off rising inflation.11 Finally, in
July 2008, the ECB raised its target interest rate to 4.25% and kept it there for three months. This
tightening cycle was arguably the shock that triggered the eurozone crisis.
The second monetary policy tightening cycle began in late 2010, when the ECB again signalled that
it would raise its policy rate to stem burgeoning inflation. The anticipation of the raised rate began
stemming the growth in total money spending in early 2011, and the ECB indeed raised its policy rate
from 1.00% to 1.25% in April and again to 1.50% in July, where it stayed for four months. This second
tightening cycle occurred even though the eurozone was still recovering from its first recession, and it
is arguably the shock that intensified the economic crisis in 2011.
The simplicity and thoroughness of this view makes its near absence from popular discussion rather
surprising. Only Hetzel (2013, 2016) and a small number of bloggers and journalists have discussed
this particular understanding of the eurozone crisis.12 Many observers are aware of the ECB’s policy
actions, but few seem to connect the timing of those actions to the two recessions in the eurozone.
Consequently, the standard view continues to dominate debates regarding the origins of the crisis.13
This paper attempts to broaden the conversation on the eurozone crisis by closely examining the
view of monetary policy origins. It does so by providing a wide range of evidence. The next section
reconsiders the evidence for the standard view, which is—at best—an incomplete understanding of the
crisis. Building on the implications of that section, the paper then delves into the evidence for the
monetary policy origin view of the eurozone crisis and demonstrates why this view provides a better
explanation for the crisis. On the basis of those findings, the paper then proposes a new monetary policy
regime for the ECB.
4 | ANOTHER LOOK AT THE STANDARD VIEW OF THE
CRISIS
As outlined earlier, the standard view of the eurozone crisis considers financial panic to have caused the
first recession and the sovereign debt crisis to have caused the second, which in turn was intensified by
the tightening of fiscal policy. Serious timing problems abound with this view, as already noted.
However, such timing problems do not necessarily suggest that the developments implicit in this view
of the eurozone crisis neither affected nor amplified the existing recessions. Some may argue, for
example, that the burgeoning level of public debt and the intense levels of austerity turned what
otherwise would have been an ordinary recession into a depression that plagued the eurozone.
An important question, then, is how important these developments were in intensifying the
eurozone crisis. Another is to what extent the effects of these developments were conditional on the
stance of ECB monetary policy. These questions are examined next in relation to public debt and
austerity.
BECKWORTH
|
119
4.1 | Public debt
To understand the role the public debt burden played in the eurozone crisis, consider public debt trends
before and after the first recession started in the first quarter of 2008. Figure 3 shows the public debt-toGDP trends for the 11 largest economies in the eurozone and the eurozone as a whole. While the figure
reveals that public debt burdens in Greece and Portugal grew and that Italy failed to lower its elevated
level of public debt before the crisis, it also shows that, in almost every case, the debt burdens soared
after the recession started.
Spain, for example, saw its debt-to-GDP ratio go from 62.2% in the first quarter of 1999 to 34.5% in
the first quarter of 2008. Spain, in other words, was actually running budget surpluses and paying down
its debt before 2008. Once the recession started, though, its debt burden started growing and reached
98.5% by the fourth quarter of 2014.
This common pattern of run-up in public debt after 2008 suggests that the soaring public debt burden
was more a consequence than a cause of the eurozone crisis. National income fell in many countries,
making it harder for these countries to service their public debts. In some countries, such as Ireland and
Spain, bailouts of private debt raised the level of public debt, whereas in other countries, the use of
automatic stabilizers during the recessions raised the level of public debt.14 In all cases, however, it was
the weakened economy that catalyzed the events that caused public debt burdens to soar.
The point here, though, is to assess the standard view of the role of public debt in the eurozone
economic crisis. Figure 4 does so by considering whether the accumulation of public debt before
FIGURE 3
Ratio of public debt to GDP in the eurozone
Note: Gray lines are all the other countries
Sources: Eurostat; author’s calculations
120
|
FIGURE 4
BECKWORTH
Public debt and economic growth in 29 European countries
2008 and afterward is related to the sovereign debt crisis. The figure plots the public debt-to-GDP
ratio for 2007 and 2011 against real GDP growth during the approximate time period of the
sovereign debt crisis. The figure plots this relationship for 29 European countries, of which 13 are
members of the eurozone.15 The debt-to-GDP ratio for 2007 captures the effect of public debt
acquired before the first recession, whereas the ratio for 2011 captures the added public debt from
the bailout of private sector debt as well as the decline in nominal income. If the standard view is
correct, then, there should be a negative relationship between the public debt-to-GDP ratio and
economic growth.
Panel A in Figure 4 shows that the precrisis public debt burden—public debt acquired before
2008—is negatively related to economic growth during the crisis. However, precrisis public debt
explains only about one-third of the variation in real GDP growth. Although one-third is by no means
trivial, two-thirds of the variation in real GDP growth must be explained by another phenomenon.
Thus, the precrisis debt burden explains only one-third of the slowdown in economic activity.
Panel C of Figure 4 shows that, among European countries, only eurozone countries maintain the
relationship between public debt and economic growth. That is, only in those countries constrained by
ECB monetary policy does the public debt burden before 2008 appear to matter to economic growth
during the crisis. Why is this? What is unique about the eurozone that is not true of other countries? The
most obvious answer is a shared currency and monetary policy.
Panels B and D of Figure 4 repeat this exercise, but they use the public debt-to-GDP ratio for 2011.
By 2011, as noted previously, the public debt burden had grown, because many countries chose to bail
out their private sectors. Nonetheless, the same pattern emerges here and is even stronger than in 2008.
BECKWORTH
|
121
That is, the public debt burden is closely tied to economic growth for those European countries using
the euro.16 Again, this raises the question as to whether the public debt burden or the ECB’s tightening
of monetary policy caused the slowdown in real GDP. The monetary policy origins view of the crisis
points to the latter.
4.2 | Austerity
The final component of the standard view is the claim that the tightening of fiscal policy—austerity—in
the eurozone further intensified the crisis. In particular, austerity was imposed on the periphery
countries as part of their bailout and debt-restructuring programs, but without a compensatory offset in
expansionary fiscal policy from the core countries. Thus, fiscal policy tightened overall and further
reduced total money spending for the eurozone (De Grawe, 2012). Echoing this point, Krugman (2015)
created a scatterplot like the one in panel A of Figure 5. With an R2 value of 63.97%, the plot shows a
strong positive relationship between government spending and economic growth for 32 European
countries, of which 16 are eurozone members. Another example is a graph created by the International
Monetary Fund (IMF), which plotted real GDP forecast errors against a more general fiscal
consolidation measure. Like Krugman, the IMF found a strong fit between government spending and
economic growth, with an R2 of 50.06% (IMF, 2012). Both of these scatterplots are interpreted by
proponents of the standard view as evidence for the claim that austerity measures intensified the
eurozone crisis.
Panel B of Figure 5, however, raises questions about the meaning of these relationships. As
before, the graph separates eurozone from non-eurozone countries and fits each group with a
regression line. Here, the relationship between government spending and economic growth in
eurozone countries strengthens to an R2 value of 80.70%, whereas in non-eurozone countries it falls
to 17.76%.17 Dividing the countries included in the IMF scatterplot mentioned earlier yields similar
results: the R2 value for eurozone countries rises to 78.20% and for non-eurozone countries falls to
23.43%.18
Once again, these scatterplots raise the question as to whether austerity or ECB monetary policy
was behind this relationship. The effect of fiscal policy is generally considered to depend on the stance
of monetary policy, at least outside the zero lower bound (ZLB) of interest rates. For most of the period
covered in the scatterplots, the ECB’s target interest rate was meaningfully higher than the ZLB. Only
in November 2013 did the ECB lower its policy rate to 0.25%. This observation points to the stance of
ECB monetary policy as the driving force behind the sovereign debt crisis. Moreover, as noted earlier,
the ECB tightened monetary policy well before the sovereign debt crisis and before austerity measures
were put in place.
This section has shown that only in the eurozone countries were public debt burdens and austerity
meaningfully related to economic growth during the crisis. That is, only those countries governed
by ECB monetary policy were affected. These findings suggest that ECB monetary policy ultimately
caused the sovereign debt crisis and gave teeth to the austerity measures imposed on periphery
countries. This understanding is further examined in the next section.
5 | THE ECB’S ROLE IN THE EUROZONE CRISIS
The introduction to this paper noted that changes in the stance of ECB monetary policy preceded the
2008 and 2011 eurozone recessions. Section 4 of the paper discussed how debt and austerity were
issues only for those countries that were subject to ECB monetary policy. Both of these observations
122
|
BECKWORTH
FIGURE 5
Government spending and economic growth in 32 European countries
Notes: The eurozone countries of Latvia and Lithuania are defined here as non-eurozone countries because they
only joined in 2014 and 2015, respectively. Denmark is counted as a eurozone country because its currency is
pegged to the euro
Sources: Eurostat; author’s calculations
point to a monetary policy origins view of the eurozone crisis. This section further examines this view
of the crisis in three steps. First, it looks at four standard indicators of monetary policy to assess the
ECB’s actions during this time. Second, it compares the ECB’s actions against the Taylor rule for the
eurozone as a whole and for individual countries. Third, it tests for causality between the stance of
monetary policy and the performance of the economy using a panel vector autoregression.
Collectively, the evidence presented in this section strongly suggests that the policy errors of the ECB
—compounded by the problems inherent in applying a ‘one-size-fits-all’ monetary policy to a
suboptimal currency area—caused the eurozone crisis.
BECKWORTH
|
123
5.1 | Standard indicators of ECB monetary policy
Earlier it was argued that the ECB was tightening monetary policy in early 2008. Figure 6 provides
evidence to support this claim. Panel A plots the ECB’s policy interest rate (the main refinancing
operation rate) alongside industrial production, which acts as a measure of economic activity.19 Panel
A shows that even as the economy began to contract in early 2008, the ECB kept its policy rate steady at
4%. Hetzel (2013) argues that this failure to act was contrary to the ECB’s earlier track record of
‘leaning against the wind’—that is, the traditional response of the ECB to lower rates in the event of
economic contraction. In the early days of the eurozone crisis, however, the ECB chose not to lower
rates, a decision that essentially amounted to a passive form of monetary policy tightening.20
Panel B of Figure 6 confirms the passive tightening cycle of early 2008 using another indicator of
monetary policy: the spread between the safe interest rate on a 12-month and a one-month interbank
loan. According to the expectations theory of interest rates, this spread indicates where the market
sees short-term interest rates in the eurozone heading across the next year. As can be seen in the
graph, the spread starts to rise in early 2008, indicating that the market was expecting rates to rise.
The only reason the market expected this outcome was because the ECB had signaled that it would
raise rates.
Panel C of Figure 6 shows that the expectation of ECB tightening coincided with a slowdown in the
growth of total money spending. Total money spending is the amount of money (e.g. euros) in
circulation times how often that money is spent. It provides a broad measure of monetary conditions
and therefore acts as another indicator of monetary policy. Thus, panel C shows that, by creating the
expectation of future monetary policy tightening, the ECB caused total money spending growth to
decline in the eurozone in early 2008.21 Panel D shows that a big part of the decline in total money
spending growth was a fall in the M3 money supply growth.
FIGURE 6
Monetary policy in the eurozone
Note: Total money spending is measured using nominal GDP
Sources: Eurostat; ECB database; Deutsche Bundesbank; author’s calculations
124
|
BECKWORTH
Finally, in July 2008, the ECB made expectations of a rate hike a reality; the bank raised its target
interest rate to 4.25% and kept it there for three months. At that point, what had been an economic
contraction began free-falling into a deep recession. The tightening cycle was thus arguably the shock
that triggered the beginning of the eurozone crisis.22
The ECB eventually cut its target interest rate and introduced innovations, which included
extending the maturity of its refinancing options, expanding its list of acceptable collateral, and
engaging in a securities market program in which it bought some periphery country sovereign bonds to
control their yields.23 These programs, however, were limited, and the securities market program was
sterilized.24 So the recovery was both weak and, as shown in panel A of Figure 2, uneven across the
eurozone.
The weak recovery was cut short in 2011, when another recession began. As in the case of the
recession of 2008, a tightening of monetary policy also preceded the 2011 recession. In the latter case,
the expected path of the ECB policy rate started rising sharply in late 2010. This expectation stalled the
growth of total money spending and pushed the economy back into recession. In 2011, the ECB
worsened the blow by raising its policy rate from 1.00% to 1.25% in April and to 1.50% in July, where it
stayed for four months. It should not come as a surprise to anyone that an economy not fully recovered
from a deep recession could easily fall into another one if monetary policy were to tighten. This is
indeed what appears to have happened to the eurozone in 2011.
5.2 | Taylor rule analysis of ECB monetary policy
A more systematic way to evaluate monetary policy during the eurozone crisis is to compare the ECB’s
target interest rate to the one prescribed by the Taylor rule. The Taylor rule tells a central bank how to
best set its target interest rate according to changes in the economy. Consequently, the rule is often used
as a benchmark against which the actual interest rate path set by a central bank is evaluated. If, for
example, the Taylor rule prescribed an increase in the ECB’s policy interest rate and the ECB did
nothing to act on that prescription, the resulting gap would indicate a loose monetary policy.
Conversely, if the Taylor rule prescribed a decrease in the ECB’s policy interest rate and the ECB did
nothing, the gap would indicate a tight monetary policy. The stance of monetary policy, then, can be
gauged by looking at the difference between the actual interest rate path and that prescribed by the
Taylor rule. In this section, the paper uses the Taylor rule to systematically assess the ECB’s actions
leading up to and during the eurozone crisis.
Under the original Taylor rule, the central bank adjusts the target interest rate to deviations of
inflation from its desired level and to deviations of real GDP from its potential level. Although
economists disagree about how much emphasis to place on each deviation, the basic Taylor rule
framework continues to be used by many economists—and policy makers—as a benchmark.25
Building on Koenig’s (2012) observation that a Taylor rule is just a special case of a nominal GDP
(NGDP) targeting rule, this paper follows Beckworth and Hendrickson (2016) and Selgin, Beckworth,
and Bahadir (2015) in applying a Taylor rule that responds to deviations of total money spending from a
targeted growth path. Using NGDP to measure total money spending, this Taylor rule takes the
following form:
Gap
12
þ
ϕ
Σ
NGDP
=12
it ¼ i*t þ ϕ1 NGDPGap
2
t i
t
i¼1
ð1Þ
where it is the target interest rate, i*t is the market-clearing or equilibrium nominal interest rate, and
is the percentage difference between the actual and the targeted growth rate of NGDP. The
NGDPGap
t
BECKWORTH
|
125
ϕ1 NGDPGap
term causes the central
bank to respond
to current money spending deviations from its
t
Gap
NGDP
=12
term causes the central bank to respond to the
targeted growth rate. The ϕ2 Σ12
i¼1
t i
average of past target NGDP growth-rate misses across the business cycle, which is assumed here to
last approximately three years (12 quarters). The idea behind the second term is to make up for past
misses during the course of the business cycle so that a steady growth path for total money spending
is maintained.26 This approach makes it possible to stabilize monetary conditions without knowing
the output gap or the proper inflation rate to use, questions that plagued the standard Taylor rule.27
To operationalize Eq. (1), this analysis sets ϕ1 to 1, ϕ2 to 0.5, i*t to 1 plus the ECB’s consensus
inflation forecast for the next year, and the NGDP target to 3.5%.28 The target value is set at 3.5%
because the ECB has approximately a 2.0% inflation target and has seen its potential real GDP grow, on
average, by roughly 1.5% a year between 1999 and 2014.29 This approach implies that a reasonable
growth path for total money spending in the eurozone should be approximately 3.5% a year.
The interest rate path from this Taylor rule, along with the ECB’s policy rate path, is plotted in panel
A of Figure 7. This graph shows that, although the ECB’s monetary policy for the eurozone was
relatively effective through 2003, it was looser through 2007. This easing, though, pales in comparison
with the tightening cycle that began in 2008 and continued through 2009. This cycle begins with the
ECB raising its policy rate just as the Taylor rule rate begins falling. The ECB continues to trail the
descending Taylor rule rate through mid-2009. The second tightening cycle is also evident in panel A
of Figure 7. The Taylor rule rate starts falling again in 2011, just as the ECB begins tightening monetary
policy. This tightening cycle is not as deep as the previous one, but it lingers longer and indicates that
monetary policy is still tight in the eurozone.
FIGURE 7
Taylor rule interest rates versus actual ECB interest rates
Sources: Eurostat; ECB database; Deutsche Bundesbank; author’s calculations
126
|
BECKWORTH
Panel B of Figure 7 applies the Taylor rule to the core and the periphery regions of the eurozone. It
shows that not only was ECB monetary policy often non-neutral for the eurozone as whole, it was often
non-neutral in differing degrees for the regional economies. Specifically, the core countries had
relatively neutral monetary policy outside that 2008–2009 period, whereas the periphery countries had
consistently non-neutral monetary policy.
The figure indicates that monetary policy for the periphery was too loose during the boom years and
was too tight during the crisis years. In other words, monetary policy has been consistently procyclical
or ‘leaning with the wind’ for the periphery. It should not be surprising, then, that the periphery grew
more rapidly prior to the crisis and suffered more economic pain afterward. It should also not come as a
surprise that the core economies have resisted calls for more aggressive easing by the ECB, primarily
because monetary policy, outside of 2008–2009, has been largely neutral for the core.
The distortionary effects of the ECB’s one-size-fits-all monetary policy can be seen in more detail
in Figure 8. Here, the Taylor rule is applied to the 11 largest economies in the eurozone and the
eurozone as a whole and is also compared to the ECB policy rate. The graphs in this figure reveal a
persistent pattern, with the ECB setting its target interest rate in a manner more consistent with the core
economies than with the periphery countries, which appear to be on a monetary policy roller coaster.30
On the upside of the roller-coaster ride, the periphery economies of Greece, Ireland, Portugal, and
Spain were exposed to very accommodative monetary policy. These countries were experiencing rapid
growth in total money spending relative to the cost of funding that spending during the eurozone boom
years. Ireland, for example, averaged 14.0% nominal GDP growth between 1999 and 2002 but faced an
average ECB policy rate of 3.5%. This large spread between the nominal growth of the periphery and its
low financing costs screamed leverage. It is not surprising, then, that these economies saw a buildup of
FIGURE 8
Regional Taylor rule interest rates
Sources: Eurostat; ECB database; Deutsche Bundesbank; author’s calculations
BECKWORTH
|
127
debt, soaring asset prices, and large current account deficits. On the downside of the ECB roller-coaster
ride, all periphery countries experienced persistently tight monetary policy.
The ECB, therefore, was effectively creating very different monetary conditions in the regional
economies through its one-size-fits-all monetary policy. The importance of these differing monetary
conditions can be seen in Figure 9. This figure plots real GDP growth against the average Taylor rule
gap—the deviation between the ECB policy rate and the regional Taylor rule rate—for the eight largest
eurozone economies across the two recession periods. For both recessions, a strong relationship exists
FIGURE 9 ECB monetary policy and the 2008–2009 and 2011–2013 recessions
Sources: Eurostat; ECB database; Deutsche Bundesbank; author’s calculations
128
|
BECKWORTH
between the stance of monetary policy and the depth of the recession.31 Specifically, the tighter the
stance of monetary policy was for the multiyear period shown in the graphs, the deeper was the
recession. Maintaining a tight monetary policy over many years is a drag on the economy.
This analsyis explains why the periphery countries have fared so poorly relative to the core since
the crisis started. They had persistently tighter monetary policy. Moreover, this analysis points to the
monetary policy origin view of the eurozone economic crisis.
5.3 | Panel vector autoregression analysis of ECB monetary policy
The previous section provided strong evidence that the ECB’s tightening cycles, combined with the
challenges of applying a one-size-fits-all monetary policy to different economies, were what sparked—
and later intensified—the eurozone crisis. Some observers, however, may question whether causality
went from the Taylor rule gap to changes in economic growth. It is possible that the sovereign debt
crisis and austerity measures weakened the eurozone economy and thus caused the Taylor rule
deviations to grow.
As noted earlier, however, these Taylor rule deviations lasted for many years and therefore had to
have been a drag on the economy. So regardless of what initially caused the deviations, monetary
policy was persistently tight, a fact that implies causality running from tight ECB policy to the
contraction in economic growth. Moreover, the timing of the ECB’s actions outlined earlier renders
this causal path very likely.32
This causal path can be further verified by estimating a panel vector autoregression (VAR) for 11
eurozone economies for the period between the first quarter of 1999 and the fourth quarter of 2014.
This model allows one to estimate the dynamic effect of a shock to one variable while controlling for
changes in other variables, including ones for austerity and the debt crisis. Here, the panel VAR was
estimated using the Taylor rule gap, real government spending, total debt-to-GDP ratio, real GDP, core
inflation, and long-term interest rates.33
The real government spending variable is the measure used for austerity and the total debt-to-GDP
variable is the measure used for the debt crisis. The former is not a perfect measure of austerity since it
excludes tax changes. It is, however, the same measure used in Figure 5 which has been used by
observers like Krugman (2015) as as indicator of eurozone austerity. The latter measure is the sum of
private and public debt as a percent of GDP. Since private debt often became public debt during the
eurozone crisis, this total measure of debt avoids the potential for underestimating the effect of debt in
the crisis if one were to look only at private debt or only at public debt.
The panel VAR’s estimated effects of a shock to the Taylor rule gap—the impulse response
functions (IRFs)—during this time are reported in Figure 10. These responses reveal what generally
happened to the variables given a one standard deviation shock to the Taylor rule gap. These responses,
therefore, show the typical consequences of a change in the stance of ECB monetary policy. The solid
black line shows the point estimate of the IRF in percentage point terms for each of these variables, and
the gray lines provide a 95% confidence interval. The dashed line shows average point IRF coming
from a Taylor rule gap shock under all the different orderings of the monetary shock, austerity, and debt
crisis variables. It is provided as a robustness check.
The responses reveal a story consistent with the monetary policy origins view of the eurozone
crisis. Specifically, a typical tightening of monetary policy—a positive shock to the Taylor rule gap—
causes real GDP and core inflation to decline for approximately one and half years before beginning a
slow return to normal levels.34 This decline in economic activity causes the total debt-to-GDP ratio to
surge for about the same time and then slowly decline. The shock also caused long-term interest rates to
BECKWORTH
|
129
FIGURE 10 Typical response to a shock of one standard deviation to the Taylor rule gap (Actual ECB rate
minus Taylor rate)
Note: The IRF is the point estimate, whereas the AIRF is the average IRF for the different orderings of the
competing theory variables (i.e. debt crisis and austerity variables)
Sources: Eurostat; ECB database; Deutsche Bundesbank; author’s calculations
rise for roughly two years before unwinding back down. Finally, real government spending is relatively
stable for a few quarters after the shock, but then begins a sharp decline that persists for some time.
The causal channel is clear here: tight monetary policy during the sample period led to weaker
economic growth, lower inflation, higher debt levels, and an increase in the risk premium. Austerity,
with a short delay, is imposed in response to these developments. These results support the monetary
policy origin view of the eurozone crisis.
Another way to assess the importance of the monetary policy origin view is to look at the forecast
error variance decomposition (VDC) of real GDP caused by the Taylor rule gap, real government
spending, and total debt shocks. The VDC shows how much of the forecast error generated in the panel
VAR for real GDP can be attributed to each of theses shocks. The Taylor rule gap shock explains about
55% of the forecast error of real GDP upon impact and and continues to explain roughly that much for
the first year and half. Thereafter, its settles down to about 40%. The real government spending shock—
or austerity shock—only explains 6% at most, whereas the debt shock accounts for about 2%. The VDC
analysis further supports the monetary policy origins view of the eurozone crisis.
As a final robustness check of the relative importance of monetary policy, austerity, and debt crisis
views of the eurozone crisis, a Granger causality test was run on the monetary policy gap, real
government spending, and total debt-to-GDP to see if they Granger-caused real GDP. The Granger
causality test was applied to the reduced-form panel VAR model. Consequently, there are no ordering
of variables or identification questions here. The p-values for real government spending (0.22) and total
debt-to-GDP (0.10) indicate they did not Granger-cause real GDP at a significant level during the
130
|
BECKWORTH
sample period. The p-value for the Taylor rule gap (0.00), on the other hand, reveals that it does
Granger-cause real GDP at a significant level.
These findings, then, provide strong evidence for the causal path posited by the monetary policy
origins view of the eurozone economic crisis.
6 | POLICY IMPLICATIONS FOR THE EUROZONE
This paper has argued that the ECB’s tightening of monetary policy in 2008 and again in 2010–2011
caused the eurozone economic crisis. This view, though, raises the question about why the ECB
tightened its policy during these times. Hetzel (2015, 2016) shows that, in both cases, the ECB was
mistakenly worried about the rise in headline inflation, which both times had been caused by a
temporary surge in commodity prices. This can be seen in panels G, H, and I of Figure 1, which show
that core inflation remained stable even as headline inflation temporarily grew in 2008 and again in
2010–2011.
The ECB’s big mistake was in responding to these changes in inflation as if they were symptoms of
a demand shock when, in fact, they were symptoms of a supply shock. The ECB’s confusion over
inflation is a common problem for inflation-targeting banks. The Federal Reserve (the Fed), for
example, treated the declining inflation of 2002–2004 as a symptom of weak demand rather than as a
symptom of the rapid productivity growth that occurred during this period. The Fed consequently kept
interest rates low despite the housing boom taking off (Selgin et al., 2015). Similarly, as the U.S.
economy was imploding in September 2008, Fed officials decided not to lower interest rates over
concern about rising headline inflation. The burgeoning inflation, however, was the result of a
temporary surge in commodity prices rather than excessive demand growth. Thus, distinguishing
demand-driven changes in inflation from those driven by supply shocks remains a key challenge for
inflation-targeting central banks.35
One way to get around this problem is to target the cause rather than the symptom. If central banks
should respond only to demand-driven changes in inflation, why not cut to the chase and target demand
directly? A straightforward way to do this is to target the growth path of total money spending. By
focusing solely on demand growth, the ECB would not be tempted to respond to supply shocks as it did
in 2008 and in 2010–2011. For example, if a positive supply shock—say, a new technology or
increased oil supply—lowered prices of a commodity, the ECB would do nothing beyond maintaining
stable money spending. The composition of the spending would change—more goods and services
would be purchased at lower prices—but the total amount of spending would not. Nor would total
money spending change because of a negative supply shock—such as a natural disaster or an oil
shortage—though the composition of the spending would change.36 In other words, the ECB would let
relative prices and markets sort out real shocks on their own while it maintained monetary stability.
A targeted growth path or level target for total money spending would commit the ECB to make up
for past misses both above and below the target so that the targeted growth path would be maintained.
This approach would create expectations of stable spending growth that would become self-fulfilling.
That is, households and firms would have less incentive to rapidly spend or hoard money if they
believed that the ECB would automatically make up for past misses in the growth path of total money
spending. This expectation would thus decrease the likelihood of total money spending deviating from
its targeted growth path in the first place.
Adopting this target would also allow the ECB to facilitate a more balanced recovery across the
eurozone. To understand this claim, imagine that the ECB made its quantitative easing program
conditional on the eurozone returning to its precrisis NGDP trend path. This approach would lead to a
BECKWORTH
|
131
temporary burst of catch-up growth in total money spending. As a result, prices of goods and services
would temporarily increase, and they would do so first in the region with the least excess capacity—the
core countries. Prices of goods and services in the periphery countries would then become relatively
cheaper. Consequently, even though the exchange rate between the regions would not change, there
would be a relative change in price levels between countries, which would make the periphery region
more competitive.37
Note that a total money spending target for the ECB would not solve all the deep structural
problems that currently plague the eurozone.38 However, it would provide a monetary policy that does
not push the currency union into another recession. It would also facilitate a more balanced recovery
across member countries. The eurozone sorely needs such a monetary policy regime.
7 | CONCLUSION
The eurozone crisis represents one of the greatest economic tragedies of the past century. It has caused
immense human suffering, which continues to this day. The standard view attributes the crisis to an
earlier buildup of public and private debt that was augmented by the imposition of austerity during the
crisis. The evidence supporting this standard view, on closer examination, points to eurozone
countries’ common monetary policy as the real culprit behind the area’s sharp decline in economic
activity. In particular, it seems that the ECB’s tightening of monetary policy in 2008 and again in 2010–
2011 not only caused two recessions but also sparked the sovereign debt crisis and gave teeth to the
austerity programs. Such findings point to the need for a new monetary policy regime in the eurozone.
This paper has made the case for the new regime to be a targeted growth path for total money spending.
ENDNOTES
1
The core countries are Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, and the Netherlands. The periphery countries are
Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, and Spain. This taxonomy follows Nechio (2011).
2
Periphery countries were also required to implement structural reforms to labor markets and public pensions.
3
See, for example, Pritchard (2011) and Ponnuru (2011).
4
For an extensive review of the eurozone critics, see Jonung and Drea (2010).
5
Industrial production rather than GDP is used here as a measure of economic activity because data on the former are
available on a monthly basis and are therefore a more precise indicator of turning points in economic activity.
6
For the core region, the spread is calculated as the difference between the average weighted yield on all the core
countries less Germany minus the German yield.
7
This flow of capital out of periphery country banks and into core country banks further intensified regional differences
in the eurozone. See Hetzel (2015) for more on this point.
8
According to the industrial production index, the recession in the periphery did last a few months longer than in the core.
9
The austerity portion of the standard view is also problematic. As discussed later in the paper, the effect of austerity is
conditional on the stance of the monetary policy.
10
As discussed later, total money spending is measured by nominal GDP. Its growth rate began declining in the second
quarter of 2007.
11
As discussed later, this implicit tightening, and that which occurred in 2010, can be seen in the slope of the yield curve.
12
Bloggers promoting this view include Scott Sumner at TheMoneyIllusion, Lars Christensen at the Market Monetarist,
Nick Rowe at Worthwhile Canadian Initiative, and Juan Castaneda of The Old Lady of Threadneedle Street. Journalists
include Ambrose Evans-Pritchard of the Daily Telegraph and Matt O’Brien of the The Washington Post.
13
For more on this point, see Sumner (2014).
132
|
BECKWORTH
14
Put differently, tax revenues fall and unemployment insurance rises during recessions. This effect automatically causes
deficits—and therefore public debt—to grow.
15
The scatterplots used for analysis in section 4.1 of the paper treat Denmark as a eurozone country because its currency
is pegged to the euro and therefore has its monetary policy set by the ECB.
16
Similar results are shown for private credit in the Online Appendix. Only in those European countries affected by ECB
monetary policy was private credit growth tied to the slowdown in economic growth.
17
Steil and Walker (2015) reach a similar conclusion.
18
Similar resuts are shown in the Online Appendix for the IMF’s overall budget balance as a percentage of potential
GDP. This measure accounts for the business cycle and both spending and tax changes.
19
Here industrial production is used as a measure of economic activity rather than GDP because the former is available
on a monthly basis and therefore allows for a more precise timing of events.
20
The ECB’s reason for not ‘leaning against the wind’ was concern about rising inflation. The concern was misplaced,
though, because the surge in inflation was caused by a temporary rise in commodity prices. See Hetzel (2015) for more
on this point.
21
Note that the market also expected the ECB to cut its policy rate beginning around mid-2007. This expectation
coincided with a moderate slowdown in total spending growth. That the ECB did not cut its policy rate as expected, but
kept it at 4%, can arguably be seen as the real beginning of the tightening cycle.
22
Ironically, the ECB second pillar of its monetary policy is to maintain monetary stability. The decline in the M3 money
supply indicates that it effectively abandoned this pillar at the worst possible time.
23
The securities market program was used intermittently until 2012, when it was replaced by the outright monetary
transactions program.
24
That is every euro of sovereign debt the program bought up was offset by a euro’s worth of short-term assets on its
balance sheet.
25
Formally, the Taylor rule can be stated as follows:
it ¼ i*t þ ϕπ π~ t þ ϕy~y t
where it is the prescribed Taylor rule interest rate, i*t is an equilibrium nominal interest rate that is usually set equal to
2+ the inflation rate, π~ t is the deviation of inflation from its target, and ~y t is the percentage of deviation of the economy
from its sustainable growth path (or the output gap). There is some debate over how big the response coefficients ϕπ
and ϕy should be as well as over how the correct measure for π~ t should be chosen. For a recent discussion of these
issues, see Yellen (2012).
26
In other words, this Taylor rule approximately follows an NGDP-level target. Responding to the average of past misses
gets around the thorny problem of constantly reestimating the trend growth path of NGDP.
27
For more on this point, see Beckworth and Hendrickson (2016).
28
Setting i*t equal to 1 plus the inflation forecast implies a real natural interest rate of 1%. This approach follows Nechio
(2011).
29
Potential real GDP growth was calculated using the IMF’s output gap estimate for the eurozone.
30
Germany, in particular, has faired relatively well under ECB monetary policy. It only had a contraction in real growth
in 2009. Outside of 2009, then, ECB monetary policy seems to have been roughly neutral for Germany.
31
If Greece is dropped from the graph in panel B, which shows the 2011–2013 recession, the R2 still remains high at 80%.
32
This observation does not suggest, however, that there was no feedback between the weakened economy and the stance
of monetary policy. Rather, the stance of monetary policy tightened further once the economy started free-falling
simply because the ECB did nothing.
33
The panel VAR was estimated using country fixed effects and a Cholesky decomposition with the variables in the same
order as listed above. Note that this order allows shocks to the Taylor rule gap to immediately affect the other variables
in the VAR. This is reasonable given the quarterly frequency of the data and the role expectations play in monetary
BECKWORTH
|
133
policy. Also, because the Taylor rule has real GDP and inflation embedded in it, these variables are also able to affect
the Taylor rule gap contemporaneously. This property is desirable because one wants to see the effect of a monetary
policy shock on the economy, regardless of whether the shock is active (an explicit changing of interest rates not
warranted by changes in the economy) or passive (a failure to change interest rates when warranted by changes in the
economy). Real government spending and real GDP were transformed into log form so that all the responses can be
interpreted as percentage changes. Eight lags were used since this is sufficient to eliminate serial correlation and
capture any lag effect of money policy.
34
Put differently, monetary policy shocks appear to have no permanent effect on real economic activity in the IRFs.
However, this is the response of a typical shock and, as noted earlier, the ECB has been buffeted with a number of bad
monetary policy shocks since 2008. Consequently, the ECB’s actual return to full employment may take longer than
seen in the IRFs.
35
Supply shocks come from changes to the productive capacity of an economy. For example, reduction of an important
input for production such as oil or labor would be a negative supply shock. An increase in these inputs or the
introduction of a new technology that increases productivity would be a positive supply shock. These shocks create
problems for monetary policy because they push real GDP and price levels in opposite directions. If a war caused the
supply of oil to decrease, production costs would rise and would result in a temporary surge in inflation. An inflationtargeting central bank might be tempted to respond by tightening monetary policy, but doing so would further constrict
an already weakened economy. This is effectively what the ECB did in 2008 and in 2010–2011. Monetary policy
makers, therefore, should avoid responding to changes in inflation created by supply shocks.
Demand shocks, conversely, are not caused by changes to the productive capacity of an economy but rather by
changes in monetary conditions. A sudden increase in desired money holdings by households that caused spending to
fall would be an example of a negative demand shock. A permanent ‘helicopter drop’ of money by the government to
households would be an example of a positive demand shock. These shocks push real GDP and price levels in the same
direction and therefore make them easier to handle. For example, if there were a sudden surge in consumer spending
that led to an unsustainable boom in economic activity and an above-target rate of inflation, a central bank could
respond to both by tightening monetary policy. There would be no trade-offs. Monetary policy, therefore, can and
should respond to changes in inflation created by demand shocks.
36
In this case, fewer goods and services would be available, and prices would be higher.
37
Put differently, an NGDP growth path target would help bring about a much-needed depreciation of the periphery’s
real exchange rate relative to the core.
38
As mentioned earlier, many critics recognized, before it even happened, that the creation of the eurozone was
inherently problematic because the region failed to meet optimal currency area criteria. The crisis, then, may have been
inevitable, and the ECB may have been bound to make mistakes. The solution proposed here does not solve these
deeper structural problems.
REFERENCES
Atkins, R., & Barber, L. (2011). Draghi warns on eurozone break-up. The Financial Times, December 18.
Avent, R. (2012). The eurozone crisis: Call it a depression. The Economist, May 2. Retrieved from http://www.
economist.com/blogs/freeexchange/2012/05/euro-zone-crisis-0
Aziz, J. (2014). Europe is in an epic depression and it is getting worse. The Week, August 15. Retrieved from http://
theweek.com/articles/444505/europe-epic-depression-getting-worse
Beckworth, D., & Hendrickson, J. (2016). Nominal GDP targeting and the Taylor rule on an even playing field. Mercatus
Center Working Paper.
Crafts, N. (2013). The eurozone: If only it were the 1930s. VoxEU.org, December 13. Retrieved from http://www.voxeu.
org/article/eurozone-if-only-it-were-1930s
De Grawe, P. (2012). The eurozone’s double-dip recession is entirely self made. London School of Economics European
Politics and Policy blog, November 28. Retrieved from http://blogs.lse.ac.uk/europpblog/2012/11/28/eurozonedouble-dip-recession/
Ellyatt, H. (2012). Depression, suicides rise as euro debt crisis intensifies. CNBC, September 4. Retrieved from http://
www.cnbc.com/id/48883704
134
|
BECKWORTH
Hetzel, R. (2013). A monetarist critique of ECB monetary policy in the great recession. Working Paper 3-07R. Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond.
Hetzel, R. (2015). Should Greece remain in the eurozone? Working Paper 15-04R. Richmond Federal Reserve.
Hetzel, R. (2016). What caused the great recession in the eurozone? Working Paper 16-10. Richmond Federal Reserve.
IMF. (2012). Are we underestimating short-term fiscal multipliers? World Economic Outlook, pp. 41–43.
Jonung, L., & Drea, E. (2010). It can’t happen, it’s a bad idea, it won’t last: US economists on the EMU and the euro,
1989–2002. Econ Journal Watch, 7(1), 4–52.
Koenig, E. (2012). All in the family: The close connection between nominal GDP targeting and the Taylor rule. Staff
Paper 17. Dallas Federal Reserve.
Krugman, P. (2015). The record of austerity. The conscience of a liberal (blog). The New York Times, January 6.
Retrieved from http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2015/01/06/the-record-of-austerity/
Lane, P. (2012). The European sovereign debt crisis. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26(3), 49–68.
Mishkin, F. (2011). Over the cliff: From the subprime to the global financial crisis. Journal of Economic Perspectives,
25(1), 49–70.
Nechio, F. (2011). Monetary policy when one size does not fit all. Economic Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco.
O’Brien, M. (2014). Worse than the 1930s: Europe’s recession is really a depression. The Washington Post, August 20.
Retrieved from http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/wonkblog/wp/2014/08/20/worse-than-the-1930s-europesrecession-is-really-a-depression/
Ponnuru, R. (2011). Strong countries, not Greece, should ditch Euro. Bloomberg Business, September 19. Retrieved
from http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2011-09-20/strong-nations-not-greece-should-exit-euro-commenta
ry-by-ramesh-ponnuru
Pritchard, A. (2011). Germany and Greece flirt with mutually assured destruction. The Telegraph, September 11.
Retrieved from http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/financialcrisis/8755881/Germany-and-Greece-flirt-with-mutualassured-destruction.html
Selgin, G., Beckworth, D., & Bahadir, B. (2015). The productivity gap: Monetary policy, the subprime boom, and the
post-2001 productivity surge. Journal of Policy Modeling, 37(2), 189–207.
Shambaugh, J. (2012). The euro’s three crises. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 43, 157–231.
Steil, B., & Walker, D. (2015). Correcting Paul Krugman’s austerity chart for monetary effects yields very different
results. Retrieved from http://blogs.cfr.org/geographics/2015/01/13/krugmanchart/
Sumner, S. (2014). Why are economists in denial about the eurozone? TheMoneyIllusion, October 14. Retrieved from
http://www.themoneyillusion.com/?p=27795
Yellen, J. (2012). The economic outlook and monetary policy. Speech at the money marketers of New York University,
April 11.
SUPPORTING INFORMATION
Additional Supporting Information may be found online in the supporting information tab for this
article.
How to cite this article: Beckworth D. The monetary policy origins of the eurozone crisis.
International Finance. 2017;20:114–134. https://doi.org/10.1111/infi.12110