10.22367 Jem.2019.35.03
10.22367 Jem.2019.35.03
10.22367 Jem.2019.35.03
Abstract
1. Introduction
“We believe that poverty does not belong in a civilised human society. It
belongs in museums. This [Microcredit] Summit is about creating a process
which will send poverty to the museum... sixty-five years after this Summit, we
will create a poverty-free world” (Microcredit Summit, 1997, p. 11). With that
enthusiasm, Muhammad Yunus, leader of microfinance and Nobel Prize laureate,
started the microcredit movement and remarkably participated in the universal
collective effort to eradicate poverty and inequality. Throughout the last dec-
ades, poverty has been a major concern of the world (Hermes, 2014). Particular-
ly, the universal effort to combat poverty has been clearly demonstrated with the
launch of the Millennium Project in 2000 that aimed at achieving the eight Mil-
lennium Development Goals (MDGs) by the year 2015; when the ‘Eradication
of Extreme Poverty’ was the first of the 8 goals. By the end of the year 2015, the
Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) replaced the Millennium Project with
17 new aims including the ‘Reduced Inequality’ goal as well as the ‘No Poverty’
goal coming, again, on the top of the list (United Nations, 2015).
In an attempt to actively contribute to the universal collective effort to erad-
icate poverty and inequality, the modern model of microfinance has emerged
and rapidly disseminated throughout the world representing an extremely power-
ful tool in the face of destitution and hence, gaining a lot of supporters among
the public and academics (Buera, Kaboski, & Shin, 2012; Littlefield, Morduch,
& Hashemi, 2003).
Although there are various success stories of microfinance, it has been sub-
ject to several critiques raising an important debate among academics and practi-
tioners about its impact and sustainability (Ghosh, 2013; Hermes, 2014; Sample,
2011; Săvescu, 2010). The lack of consensus about the impact of microfinance
has made it essential to explore that topic further. Therefore, the purpose of this
paper is to investigate the effect of microfinance activity on income inequality.
In an attempt to answer this research question, this paper will be organised
as follows: The first section will review the literature on microfinance, its defini-
tions, importance, emergence, development, critiques and challenges, as well as
the impact of microfinance on income inequality. The following section will
focus on the research methodology including the model and variables’ specifica-
tions to test for a main hypothesis: Microfinance has a negative impact on (re-
duces) income inequality. And finally, the main findings, interpretations, and
policy recommendations will be presented.
42 Israa Ali Mahmoud Ali, Hebatallah Ghoneim
2. Literature review
This part will review the definition and concept of microfinance, its im-
portance and main objectives, the emergence and development of microfinance
institutions (MFIs), some critique of microfinance, and finally some challenges
facing microfinance.
It has been argued in several studies that the lack of access to credit by
a country’s poor population is one of the most considerable obstacles that hinder
that country from reducing its level of poverty and income inequality. Conse-
quently, it can be argued that microfinance plays an utterly crucial role in
a country’s economic development (Hulme & Mosley, 1996; McKenzie & Wood-
ruff, 2008). Accordingly, microfinance is defined as the provision of small, free
of collateral loans as well as other financial assets and insurance services to the
poor segment of the society to enhance their standard of living. That poor popu-
lation could not otherwise get access to such small-scale loans and financial
services because of the lack of collateral (Chowdhury, Ghosh, & Wright, 2005;
Taiwo, Yewande, Edwin, & Benson, 2016).
Săvescu (2010) provides another definition that links microfinance to small
enterprises and entrepreneurship. It defines microfinance as a means of financial
security for small entrepreneurs, that allows them to access small loans and basic
financial services that help them develop small businesses and thus escape pov-
erty through generating income for themselves and their families. The link be-
tween microfinance and small entrepreneurs has been also incorporated in a more
comprehensive definition of microfinance by Electrin et al. (2013) who defined
microfinance as an empowerment tool for low-income populations that grants
them small loans without collateral and with relatively low interest rates. This
should enable them to engage in small entrepreneurial activities and will ulti-
mately increase their welfare through better access to the funds necessary for
their children’s education and for better houses. They can also benefit from other
financial services such as micro-insurance and micro-mortgage offered by the
MFIs that are tailored to perfectly suit the needs of the underprivileged.
The aforementioned definitions of microfinance can be complemented by
what is stated by Rahman & Nie (2011); they have indicated that microfinance
means granting remittance, savings, as well as opportunities for better education,
The effect of microfinance on income inequality… 43
healthcare, skill training and insurance services that help the underprivileged
reach a better social standard, and to escape their cruel social situations due to
the lack of access to credit.
It is utterly important while reviewing the literature to distinguish between
two terms: microfinance and microcredit since they are often used interchangea-
bly (Fishman, 2012). As stated earlier, microfinance is the provision of versatile
financial services including small loans, thrift, micro-insurance, micro-savings
deposits and others in order to boost the poor population’s well-being. This will
essentially help curtail poverty and lead to economic development. On the other
hand, microcredit can be defined as the provision of micro-loans to the poor or
micro-entrepreneurs. Accordingly, it can be concluded that the microfinance
term is a broader and a more inclusive term than microcredit (Electrin et al.,
2013; Sengupta & Aubuchon, 2008; Taiwo et al., 2016).
1
JEEViKA means livelihoods (Kumar, 2016).
44 Israa Ali Mahmoud Ali, Hebatallah Ghoneim
et al., 2012; Littlefield et al., 2003). The microfinance’s ability to promote the
social inclusion of the marginalised members of the society such as immigrants,
the poor, women, etc. … is the main determinant of its economic importance. It
can simply fill the gap of the demand on micro-loans that is generally in excess
of the supply of micro-loans. Accordingly, the poor’s living standards will defi-
nitely be enhanced in terms of employment and income, education, and social
empowerment which ultimately promote economic development (Hermes, 2014;
Săvescu, 2010).
2
Moral hazard is a problem caused by asymmetric information that involves the risk of having
the borrower use the borrowed money in un-preferred or ‘immoral’ activities from the lender’s
perspective. Since these activities increase the probability that the borrower may default and
therefore lenders may stop giving out loans to avoid that risk (Mankiw & Rashwan, 2012).
3
Adverse selection is another problem caused by asymmetric information that makes lenders
refrain from giving out loans as they lack information about the borrowers and whether they are
The effect of microfinance on income inequality… 45
Grameen Bank’s model because safe members who intend to repay their loans
will not enter in a solidarity group whose members are not safe. Besides, mem-
bers of a group will not accept un-safe peers who are likely to default. Once the
two aforementioned concerns are avoided, the risk is significantly transferred
from the lender to the borrowers. Hence, the need to charge high interest rates to
compensate the risk of defaulting members disappears, and the Grameen Bank
can, opposite to other banks, charge low interest rates on all members (Sengupta
& Aubuchon, 2008).
likely to repay their loans or to default; especially that borrowers who are likely to default –
generate bad credit risks – are the ones that most actively demand credit and are likely to be
selected. Therefore, although there may be good borrowers, lenders do not want to give out
loans (Mankiw & Rashwan, 2012).
46 Israa Ali Mahmoud Ali, Hebatallah Ghoneim
Income inequality has an adverse effect on human capital and labour produc-
tivity as it hinders the poor’s ability to attain the adequate education. Income ine-
quality also obstructs the economic growth from benefitting the poorest quintiles
of the population (Dabla-Norris, Kochhar, Suphaphiphat, Ricka, & Tsounta,
2015). Microfinance impacts income inequality indirectly by tapping on such
education, employment, and poverty problems and thus lifts up the poor in com-
parison with the richer segments so that the gap between them shrinks.
Baldi & Šipilova (2014), in a study conducted in Latvia, prove that there is
a positive impact of microfinance on participants’ employment level. It was con-
cluded that individuals who had access to loans supported micro-entrepreneurs to
develop their micro-enterprises and thus aided them to break their unemploy-
ment and poverty cycle which ultimately contributed to Latvia’s economic de-
velopment.
48 Israa Ali Mahmoud Ali, Hebatallah Ghoneim
Another social aspect that reflects the microfinance’s positive impact on in-
come inequality is its influence on education. Amin & Sheikh (2011) contended –
based on a study of ASA, BRAC, and Grameen – that access to micro-loans
remarkably contributed to the households’ affordability of educating their children.
Moreover, Bruhn, & Love (2014) in a study of the economic consequences
of opening a new microfinance bank in Mexico, pointed out that the introduction
of microcredit services has considerably impacted low-income individuals in
terms of incomes, savings, and poverty reduction by helping them develop their
informal micro businesses. It also helped existing micro-enterprises improve
their businesses and incomes. McKenzie & Woodruff (2008) provide an expla-
nation to that increase in income by pointing out that micro-entrepreneurs highly
benefit from microcredit because even small capital investments remarkably
improve their businesses and increase incomes as they have a relatively higher rate
of return on capital. Consistently, findings from Rahman, Luo, & Minjuan’s
(2015) study in China show that, as a result of the availability of microfinance
services in a Chinese poor county, asset ownership of microcredit households
was significantly enhanced. Considering all the aforementioned findings, it can
be argued that microfinance can contribute to the alleviation of income inequality
through its positive upward push for incomes of the population’s poorest quintiles.
After exploring the literature about microfinance and its effect on income
inequality, it has been noticed that there is a gap in exploring the effect of micro-
finance on income inequality in direct manners through the examination of the
Gini-coefficient or any other quantitative index of income inequality. The major-
ity of the existing research is focused on other factors such as poverty reduction,
income per capita growth, increase in savings, increase in education and em-
ployment that in turn may affect income inequality. The gap particularly exists
in examining the impact of microfinance on income inequality in the developing
countries. This topic is rarely undertaken and requires further research. There-
fore, the exact hypothesis that will be tackled in this paper is: microfinance has
a negative effect on (reduces) income inequality in developing countries.
Table 2 contains a list of countries included in the sample ordered alphabet-
ically. The sample consists of 30 developing countries from across Africa, Asia,
Latin America, and Europe.
The effect of microfinance on income inequality… 49
This paper pursues a methodology that follows the past literature investigat-
ing the relationship between microfinance and macro-economic variables such
as financial development, poverty, and income inequality. For example, Beck,
Demirgüç-Kunt, & Levine (2007) have examined the cross-sectional relation-
ship between income inequality (Gini) and financial development (private credit).
They also specified some control variables affecting income inequality including
inflation, education, and trade openness. Similarly, Clarke, Xu, & Zou (2006)
assessed the cross-sectional relationship between Gini and financial sector de-
velopment (credit by both private sector firms and non-financial domestic sector).
The control variables included the inflation rate, non-agricultural sector share of
GDP, and several others. Furthermore, Bangoura, Mbow, Lessoua, & Diaw
(2016) examined the relationship between poverty and microfinance measured
by either the share of active borrowers in total population or the value of micro-
finance loans as a percentage of the GDP. Moreover, Kai & Hamori (2009) stud-
ied the effect of microfinance on income inequality. They used the number of
MFIs and the number of borrowers to capture microfinance intensity and includ-
ed inflation rate, democracy, and trade openness as control variables. Whereas
Hermes (2014) used the number of active borrowers and the value of micro-
finance loans to capture microfinance intensity and included inflation rate, per-
centage of arable land and rural population, democracy, schooling, and others as
control variables.
Accordingly, this paper follows the most relevant comprehensive model in
the context of the research question, which is the model used by Hermes (2014).
However, unlike the model used by Hermes (2014), this paper’s model will use
a more equally divided sample among Africa, Asia, and Latin America with an
average of 9 countries from each; while taking only 2 countries from Europe
since it is the least continent of interest due to its relative better economic situa-
50 Israa Ali Mahmoud Ali, Hebatallah Ghoneim
where:
Gini is the Gini-coefficient of country i,
α is the intercept term,
MFi is the microfinance intensity measure,
CVi is a vector of control variables that affect income inequality other than mi-
crofinance, Ɛi is the error term.
Data for all control variables is obtained from the World Bank Develop-
ment Indicators (WBDI) website, except the democracy variable, it is obtained
from the Center for Systematic Peace website, the Integrated Network for Socie-
tal Conflict Research (INSCR) data page. All data is collected for a sample of 30
developing countries from Africa, Latin America, Europe, and Asia. Gini data is
one-year observation assumed to be for the year 2015. Microfinance data include
the most recent data available expressed as cumulative numbers from 2013-
2015. All control variables are average numbers for the data of the most recent
available five years.
It is hypothesised that microfinance affects the Gini index negatively, which
means that; as microfinance intensity increases, there should be more financial
inclusion of the lowest-income groups, hence, less income inequality. Inflation
rate is expected to have a positive relation with Gini, since it decreases the pur-
chasing power of the population’s income. Moreover, it is expected that human
capital reflected in the secondary enrollment ratio has a negative coefficient
since educational attainment helps create more employment and financial inclu-
sion opportunities. There is some uncertainty about the impact of trade openness.
The literature studying the effect of trade openness on Gini provides mixed re-
sults; indicating that the relationship varies according to the sample countries as
well as the type of exports and imports in each country (Calderon & Chong,
2001; Mahesh, 2016). Similarly, the expected effect of the ruralisation ratio,
percentage of arable land, cannot be decided as it depends greatly on the nature
of the sample countries; for example if a country has a high percentage of arable
land, then ruralisation ratio will be negatively related to Gini. Similarly, popula-
tion growth may be positively or negatively related to Gini depending on wheth-
er this growth is in rural or urban population, and whether the country’s income
depends on agricultural or urban activities. As for the democracy variable, it is
expected to have a negative impact on Gini as higher democracy means better
policies that ensure more equal distribution of income.
First, an analysis of the descriptive statistics for the dependent and all inde-
pendent variables is shown in Table 3. The analysis mainly helps evaluate the
skewness of the data in order to choose the correct functional form and to decide
whether it is more appropriate to log the variables or to use them directly in the
regression analysis.
52 Israa Ali Mahmoud Ali, Hebatallah Ghoneim
Results of the descriptive statistics shown in Table 3 indicate that the varia-
bles do not have remarkably high skewness values which indicate that data are
nearly normally distributed and hence, the unlogged data can be used in the re-
gression analysis.
Secondly, a correlation matrix, shown in Table 4, has been examined to
check for possible multicollinearity problems.
The correlation matrix in Table 4 indicates that only the two variables ‘en-
rollment’ and ‘rural population’ are significantly correlated with each other with
a P-value of 0.0001 and therefore, should not be included in the same regression.
As for the two microfinance measures, they are significantly correlated as they
both measure microfinance intensity, however, they are not essentially intended
to be used simultaneously. Thus, the regression will be run four times, two times
The effect of microfinance on income inequality… 53
including MF1 with either of enrollment and rural population; then, similarly for
MF2.
In order to decide on the best model that includes the most relevant varia-
bles with significant impact on income inequality, two simple regressions have
been run to test the direct and separate effect of microfinance on Gini. Then,
a series of seven multiple regressions have been run; each included Gini as de-
pendent variable with only two explanatory variables: microfinance and one of
the control variables. This process has been repeated twice for each of the micro-
finance measures ‘MF_1’ and ‘MF_2’ with a total of 14 regressions. After that,
the coefficients’ P-values and t-statistics for the involved variables in all the
previously mentioned regressions have been analysed. Variables that have been
proved insignificant, i.e. having a P-value less than 0.10, were decided to be
eliminated from the analysis. Using MF_1, all control variables were significant
except trade openness; however, using MF_2, all control variables were significant
except trade openness and population growth. Accordingly, a decision has been
made to run 4 final regressions considering the above significance results and
the multicollinearity between enrollment and rural population. The regressions
that yielded the most adequate results are as follows:
1) Regress Gini on MF_1, enrollment, inflation, democracy, arable land, and
population growth. Results are in Table 5.
2) Regress Gini on MF_1, rural population, inflation, democracy, arable land,
and population growth. Results are in Table 6.
3) Regress Gini on MF_2, enrollment, inflation, democracy, and arable land.
Results are in Table 7.
4) Regress Gini on MF_2, rural population, inflation, democracy, and arable
land. Results are in Table 8.
Table 5 cont.
1 2 3 4 5
Arable Land −0.269561 0.077368 −3.484163 0.0021
Population Growth −1.082912 0.487352 −2.222035 0.0369
R-squared 0.614452 Mean dependent var 42.95517
Adjusted R-squared 0.509303 S.D. dependent var 7.470207
S.E. of regression 5.232865 Akaike info criterion 6.354300
Sum squared resid 602.4233 Schwarz criterion 6.684337
Log likelihood –85.13735 Hannan-Quinn criter. 6.457664
F-statistic 5.843605 Durbin-Watson stat 2.834992
Prob(F-statistic) 0.000914
And finally, the regression results in Table 8 show that all coefficients are
significant except MF_2 and inflation.
56 Israa Ali Mahmoud Ali, Hebatallah Ghoneim
5. Discussion
come inequality. A potential reason for this relationship may be that the growth
in population mainly occurs among the high income segments, therefore, the
income accruing to this segment is divided on a larger number of people; i.e.
their income per capita decreases which helps reduce the gap between high and
low-income segments. Also, countries with higher population growth may be
more alert to the income inequality problem and thus direct more attention and
adopt more equality-oriented policies which help decrease their Gini index. Al-
ternatively, this relationship could simply mean that higher population growth
means an increasing population size and labour supply which raises the coun-
try’s production, income, and income per capita leading to lower income ine-
quality.
The enrollment coefficients are negative yet insignificant with both MF_2
and MF_2. This could be caused by the fact that the regression is for a cross-
-sectional sample, where the effect of secondary education attainment could not
be reflected in the Gini.
When running the regression, with rural population (without enrollment),
both MF_1 and MF_2 yielded very near results to those of the regressions that
included the enrollment variables regarding the R-squared, adjusted R-squared,
Coefficients, P-values, and the F-statistics P-values (Table 6 and 8).
Throughout the 4 regressions, microfinance has not been proved significant.
When observing the P-value for the estimated microfinance coefficients, we can
find that MF_1 has a positive coefficient indicating a direct relation with income
inequality, i.e. as microfinance intensity (measured as a country’s total value of
MF loans divided by the GDP) increases, income inequality increases. Neverthe-
less, this positive relationship is insignificant and holds whether the accompany-
ing control variables include enrollment or rural population. As for the alterna-
tive measure of microfinance, that is, MF_2 (Total number of a country’s
microfinance borrowers divided by the total population) has negative coefficient
indicating an inverse relation with income inequality, i.e. as microfinance inten-
sity increases, income inequality decreases which conforms to the theory’s ex-
pectations. Yet, this relationship holds insignificant whether the accompanying
control variables include enrollment or rural population.
The insignificance of the microfinance variable’s effect on income inequali-
ty was unexpected. Instead, microfinance was expected to act as a major devel-
opment tool that contributes in curtailing the reasons for income inequality be-
tween the high and low-income segment of the society. This may be the result of
the relatively small customers’ base of microfinance or that the microfinance
58 Israa Ali Mahmoud Ali, Hebatallah Ghoneim
loans do not reach the truly underprivileged deserving segments in the sample
countries. Moreover, the regression did not consider the effect of loan-swapping
and over-indebtedness that the micro-borrowers may have suffered from in the
sample countries; which may have worsened the borrowers’ situation leading to
a positive yet insignificant effect of microfinance on income inequality (Ghosh,
2013; Sample, 2011).
Therefore, it is recommended that the sample countries’ governments en-
hance their supervisory role by enforcing a set of clear regulations to organize
the microfinance activities, preserve its transparency and goal achievement, en-
sure an ethical competition which prevents unethical practices that lead to wors-
en the status of the low-income segments instead of improving it, and to make
sure that micro-loans and other microfinance services reach the truly low-
income deserving segments.
Furthermore, it is recommended that countries adopting the group-lending
model restructure their lending process to accommodate a larger customer base.
One of the crucial shortcomings of the group lending model is that borrowers
who have high probability to repay their loans tend to choose group members
with similar high repayment probability to avoid being deprived from future
credit; while potentially excluding some other needy people. Thus, this model
could have a reverse effect and lead to more financial exclusion of the poor
which widens the gap between the rich and the poor. A proposed restructuring
solution is to adopt a lending model similar to the Islamic banks’ musharakah
motanaqisa or ‘diminished partnership’ concept: MFIs can provide a type of
contracts that allows low-income candidates to take an interest-free loan on
a condition to use it in a micro-business. The MFI should have a set of loan ap-
proval restrictions and should review the candidates’ profiles to assess whether
they deserve the loan. Once the contract is concluded, the MFI (capital owner
and partner) should monitor, supervise, and guide the borrower (partner contrib-
uting with management efforts) to ensure the sustainability of his micro-business
and thus, ensuring loan repayments. Profits are shared between the MFI and the
borrower; however, the borrower should make periodical payments along with
periodical profits in order to gradually purchase the MFI’s share in equity until it
reaches zero (Hassan & Lewis, 2007; Iqbal & Mirakhor, 2011; Manan & Kama-
luddin, 2010). This way, the borrower is allowed to improve his income while
contributing to the whole economy’s development, and the MFI benefits from
the partnership by investing its savings deposits in income-generating activities.
Diminished partnerships may represent an efficient solution to avoid any poten-
The effect of microfinance on income inequality… 59
tial financial exclusion that may reverse the effect of microfinance on income
inequality from negative to positive; and it is also suitable for both Islamic and
non-Islamic countries.
6. Conclusions
References
Amin, R., & Sheikh, R. I. (2011). The impact of micro-finance program on the poor:
A comparative study of Grameen Bank, BRAC and ASA in some selected areas in
Bangladesh. European Journal of Business Management, 3(4), 346-364. Retrieved
from http://www.iiste.org/Journals/index.php/EJBM/article/view/320
60 Israa Ali Mahmoud Ali, Hebatallah Ghoneim
Baldi, G., & Šipilova, V. (2014). How big are the employment effects of microloans?
Evidence from a case study in Latvia. Theoretical and Practical Research in Eco-
nomic Field, 5(1), 17-31. doi: 10.14505/tpref.v5.1(9).02
Bangoura, L., Mbow, M. K., Lessoua, A., & Diaw, D. (2016). Impact of microfinance on
poverty and inequality: A heterogeneous panel causality analysis. Revue
d’Economie Politique, 126(5), 789-818. doi: 10.3917/redp.265.0789
Bateman, M., & Chang, H. (2012). Microfinance and the illusion of development: From
hubris to nemesis in thirty years. World Economic Review, 1, 13-36. Retrieved from
http://wer.worldeconomicsassociation.org/papers/microfinance-and-the-illusion-of-
development-from-hubris-to-nemesis-in-thirty-years/
Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2007). Finance, inequality and the poor.
Journal of Economic Growth, 12, 27-49. doi: 10.1007/s10887-007-9010-6
Bruhn, M., & Love, I. (2014). The real impact of improved access to finance: Evidence
from Mexico. The Journal of Finance, 69(3), 1347-1376. doi: 10.1111/jofi.12091
Buera, F. J., Kaboski, J. P., & Shin, Y. (2012). The macroeconomics of microfinance
(NBER Working Paper No. 17905). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Econom-
ic Research. Retrieved from http://www.nber.org/papers/w17905
Calderon, C., & Chong, A. (2001). External sector and income inequality in interde-
pendent economies using a dynamic panel data approach. Economics Letters, 71,
225-231. doi: 10.1016/s0165-1765(01)00374-3
Chowdhury, M. J. A., Ghosh, D., & Wright, R. E. (2005). The impact of microcredit on
poverty: Evidence from Bangladesh. Progress in Development Studies, 5(4), 298-309.
doi: 10.1191/1464993405ps116oa
Clarke, G. R. G., Xu, L. C., & Zou, H. F. (2006). Finance and income inequality: What
do the data tell us? Southern Economic Journal, 72(3), 578-596. doi: 10.2307/
20111834
Copestake, J. (2013). Research on microfinance in India: Combining impact assessment
with a broader development perspective. Oxford Development Studies, 41(suppl 1),
S17-S34. doi: 10.1080/13600818.2012.689818
Dabla-Norris, E., Kochhar, K., Suphaphiphat, N., Ricka, F., & Tsounta, E. (2015). Caus-
es and consequences of income inequality: A global perspective (IMF Staff Discus-
sion Note No. 15/13). Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Retrieved
from https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.aspx?sk=42986.0
Electrin, M., Mosoti, J. M., George, G. E., Mandere, E. N., Jonathan, F. M., Kagumba,
A. M., & Njenga, M. (2013). An evaluation of microfinance services on poverty al-
leviation in Kisii county, Kenya. Research Journal of Finance and Accounting,
4(10), 28-37. Retrieved from http://repository.mkurwanda.ac.rw/handle/123456
789/219
Fishman, J. (2012). Microfinance – is there a solution? A survey on the use of MFIs to
alleviate poverty in India. Denver Journal of International Law & Policy, 40(4),
588-619. Retrieved from http://djilp.org/wp-content/uploads/2014/04/Fishman-
macro-FINAL.pdf
The effect of microfinance on income inequality… 61
Ghosh, J. (2013). Microfinance and the challenge of financial inclusion for development.
Cambridge Journal of Economics, 37, 1203-1219. doi: 10.1093/cje/bet042
Hassan, M. K., & Lewis M. K. (2007). Handbook of Islamic banking. United Kingdom:
Edward Elgar Publishing.
Hermes, N. (2014). Does microfinance affect income inequality? Applied Economics,
46(9), 1021-1034. doi: 10.1080/00036846.2013.864039
Hulme, D. (2000). Is microdebt good for poor people? A note on the dark side of micro-
finance. Small Enterprise Development, 11(1), 26-28. doi: 10.3362/0957-1329.
2000.006
Hulme, D., & Mosley, P. (1996). Finance against poverty. London: Routledge.
Iqbal, Z., & Mirakhor, A. (2011). An introduction to Islamic finance: Theory and prac-
tice. Singapore: John Wiley & Sons (Asia) Pte.
Kabeer, N. (2005). Gender equality and women’s empowerment: A critical analysis of
the third millennium development goal. Gender & Development, 13(1), 13-24. doi:
10.1080/13552070512331332273
Kai, H., & Hamori, S. (2009). Microfinance and inequality. Research in Applied Eco-
nomics, 1(1), 1-12. doi: 10.5296/rae.v1i1.304
Kumar, A. (2016). Does microfinance redefine identity, income and insecurity among
rural women? A model of women’s empowerment. Enterprise Development and
Microfinance, 27(3), 192-203. doi: 10.3362/1755-1986.2016.016
Ladman, J. R., & Afcha, G. (1990). Group lending: Why it failed in Bolivia. Savings and
Development, 14(4), 353-369. Retrieved from https://www.cabdirect.org/cabdirect/
abstract/19906709673
Littlefield, E., Morduch, J., & Hashemi, S. (2003). Is microfinance an effective strategy
to reach the Millennium Development Goals? CGAP Focus Note, 24, 1-11. Re-
trieved from http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/982761468319745482/Is-
microfinance-an-effective-strategy-to-reach-the-Millennium-Development-Goals
Mahesh, M. (2016). The effects of trade openness on income inequality: Evidence from
BRIC countries. Economics Bulletin, 36(3), 1751-1761. doi: 10.2139/ssrn.2736721
Manan, S. K. A., & Kamaluddin, N. (2010). The underlying contracts of Islamic banking
(IB) products and some related issues in the current practice. Malaysian Accounting
Review, 9, 99-144. Retrieved from arionline.uitm.edu.my/ojs/index.php/MAR/
article/view/238/153
Mankiw, N. G., & Rashwan, M. H. (2012). Principles of economics (Middle East ed.).
Hampshire: Cengage Learning EMEA.
McKenzie, D., & Woodruff, C. (2008). Experimental evidence on returns to capital and
access to finance in Mexico. World Bank Economic Review, 22, 457-482. doi:
10.1093/wber/lhn017
The Microcredit Summit. (1997). Microcredit Summit Report. Retrieved from http://
www.microcreditsummit.org/resource/59/1997-microcredit-summit-report.html
62 Israa Ali Mahmoud Ali, Hebatallah Ghoneim
Rahman, R., & Nie, Q. (2011). The synthesis of Grameen Bank: Microfinance approach-
es in Bangladesh. International Journal of Economics and Finance, 3(6), 207-218.
doi: 10.5539/ijef.v3n6p207
Rahman, M. W., Luo, J., & Minjuan, Z. (2015). Welfare impacts of microcredit pro-
grammes: An empirical investigation in the state‐designated poor counties of
Shaanxi, China. Journal of International Development, 27, 1012-1026. doi:
10.1002/jid.3020
Sample, B. (2011). Moving 100 million families out of severe poverty: How can we do
it? Auxiliary Session paper presented at The 2011 Global Microcredit Summit.
Valladolid, Spain: Global Microcredit summit. Retrieved from http://
www.microcreditsummit.org/resource/19/moving-100-million-families-out.html
Săvescu, R. F. (2010). Microfinance and its role in economic development. Review of
Management & Economic Engineering, 9(3), 51-63. Retrieved from: http://www.rmee.
org/37engleza.htm
Sengupta, R., & Aubuchon, C. P. (2008). The microfinance revolution: An overview.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 90(1), 9-30. doi: 10.20955/r.90.9-30
Shakya, Y. B., & Rankin, K. N. (2008). The politics of subversion in development prac-
tice: An exploration of microfinance in Nepal and Vietnam. The Journal of Devel-
opment Studies, 44(8), 1214-1235. doi: 10.1080/00220380802242461
Taiwo, J. N., Yewande, O. A., Edwin, A. M., & Benson, K. N. (2016). The role of mi-
crofinance institutions in financing small businesses. Journal of Internet Banking
and Commerce, 21(1), 1-20. Retrieved from: http://www.icommercecentral.com/open
-access/the-role-of-microfinance-institutions-in-financing-small-businesses.php?
aid=70480
United Nations. (2015). Sustainable Development Goals to kick in with start of new year.
Retrieved from http://www.un.org/apps/news/story.asp?NewsID=52922#.WDSLrFy
E03f