The Market Makers
The Market Makers
The Market Makers
Edited by
Gary G. Hamilton, Misha Petrovic, and Benjamin Senauer
1
3
Great Clarendon Street, Oxford ox2 6dp
Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford.
It furthers the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship,
and education by publishing worldwide in
Oxford New York
Auckland Cape Town Dar es Salaam Hong Kong Karachi
Kuala Lumpur Madrid Melbourne Mexico City Nairobi
New Delhi Shanghai Taipei Toronto
With offices in
Argentina Austria Brazil Chile Czech Republic France Greece
Guatemala Hungary Italy Japan Poland Portugal Singapore
South Korea Switzerland Thailand Turkey Ukraine Vietnam
Oxford is a registered trade mark of Oxford University Press
in the UK and in certain other countries
Published in the United States
by Oxford University Press Inc., New York
# Oxford University Press 2011
The moral rights of the authors have been asserted
Database right Oxford University Press (maker)
First published 2011
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced,
stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means,
without the prior permission in writing of Oxford University Press,
or as expressly permitted by law, or under terms agreed with the appropriate
reprographics rights organization. Enquiries concerning reproduction
outside the scope of the above should be sent to the Rights Department,
Oxford University Press, at the address above
You must not circulate this book in any other binding or cover
and you must impose the same condition on any acquirer
British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data
Data available
Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data
Data available
Typeset by SPI Publisher Services, Pondicherry, India
Printed in Great Britain
on acid-free paper by
MPG Books Group, Bodmin and King’s Lynn
ISBN 978–0–19–959017–9
1 3 5 7 9 10 8 6 4 2
Acknowledgments
vi
Contents
List of Figures ix
List of Tables x
Abbreviations xi
Contributors xiii
Introduction 1
Gary G. Hamilton and Misha Petrovic
Notes 311
References 326
Index 351
viii
List of Figures
x
Abbreviations
xii
Contributors
International Trade in South Korea and Taiwan (with Robert Feenstra) (2006) and
Commerce and Capitalism in Chinese Societies (2006).
John Humphrey is a Professorial Fellow at the Institute of Development Studies,
University of Sussex. He has published widely on current trends in globalization and
has researched extensively on global value chains, economic governance, and
standards.
Cheng-shu Kao is Professor of Sociology at Tunghai University in Taiwan. He is also
Vice Chairman of the Board of Trustees at Feng-Chia University in Taiwan. He is the
founding director and a continuing associate of the Institute of East Asian Societies and
Economies at Tunghai University, which is the location of the world’s most extensive
archive of interviews with Taiwanese businesspeople. He is the author of many books
and articles, including most recently The Boss’s Wife (1999, in Chinese).
Suresh Kotha is Douglas E. Olesen/Battelle Excellence Chair in Entrepreneurship and
Professor of Management and Organization at the Michael G. Foster School of Business
at the University of Washington. He is a leading authority on e-commerce and the
author of many articles and book chapters on this and related topics.
Kenneth Kraemer is Research Professor in the Paul Merage School of Business. He is
also Associate Director of the Center for Research on Information Technology and
Organizations (CRITO), as well as Co-Director of the Personal Computing Industry
Center at the University of California, Irvine. He is the author and co-author of many
books, including Asia’s Computer Challenge: Threat or Opportunity for the United States and
the World? (1998), Global E-Commerce: Impacts of National Environment and Policy (2006),
and Computerization Movements (2008).
Misha Petrovic is an Assistant Professor of Sociology at the National University of
Singapore. His dissertation, “Market Makers and Market Making: The Evolution of
Consumer Goods Markets in the United States, 1870–2000” (University of
Washington, 2005), is a pioneering study of the market-making perspective applied to
the United States.
Thomas Reardon has been a Professor in the Department of Agricultural, Food, and
Resource Economics at Michigan State University since January 1992; from, 1984 to
1991 he was with the International Food Policy Research Institute. His research focuses
on links between agri-food industry transformation and food security in Asia. He has
worked extensively on the “supermarket revolution,” transforming horticultural and
dairy product supply chains, and novel development strategies to link small farmers to
dynamic markets. He was an invitee to the World Economic Forum (WEF) at Davos in
2009 and is a member of the WEF’s Global Alliance Council for Food Security, as well as
a member of the expert panel on food security and agricultural development for the
Chicago Council on Global Affairs.
Benjamin Senauer is a Professor of Applied Economics at the University of Minnesota
and a past Co-Director of the Food Industry Center with the Sloan Foundation
Industries Study Program. He is one of the foremost experts on food retailing and food
policy. His numerous publications include the books Food Trends and the Changing
xiv
Contributors
Consumer (1991) and Ending Hunger in Our Lifetime: Globalization and Food Security
(2003).
Timothy Sturgeon is Senior Research Affiliate at the Massachusetts Institute of
Technology’s Industrial Performance Center. He is a leading authority on global value
chains and on the evolution of global industries. He is the author of many articles on
the topic and co-editor (with Momoko Kawakami) of The Dynamics of Local Learning in
Global Value Chains: Experiences from East Asia (2010).
Anthony P. Volpe is a senior research associate at the Harvard Center for Textile and
Apparel Research. His latest work centers on the role of analytics in retail environments.
He is currently a Global Product Manager in the retail division of SAS institute, Inc.
Michael Wortmann is currently in the School of Management, University of Surrey,
UK. He is a researcher in the Social Science Research Center in Berlin and at FAST e.V.,
a research and consulting organization he co-founded in 1986. He is one of the
foremost specialists on the retail industry in Europe and has written many articles on
the topic.
xv
This page intentionally left blank
Introduction
Gary G. Hamilton and Misha Petrovic
2
Introduction
suppliers. Although these two types of marketing developed at the same time,
between 1890 and 1930 in the USA, and somewhat later in the leading
European economies, by the mid-twentieth century the one led by large
manufacturers became recognized everywhere as dominant. This was due
partly to the climate of economic planning and regulation that favored the
large producers, itself a consequence of the Great Depression and the war
effort, but also to the greater ease with which large manufacturers expanded
globally. Between the early 1950s and the late 1970s, domestically as well as
globally, large manufacturers were arguably the main driving force of the
rapidly globalizing economy.2
All that has now changed. By the end of the twentieth century, large
retailers had replaced large manufacturers as the key organizers of the world
economy. This transformation, we suggest, amounts to a retail revolution on
the global scale.
The expression “retail revolution” is certainly not new. It has been used many
times for everything from the introduction of the first department stores,
chain stores, and supermarkets, to the post-Second World War adoption of
US retail formats in Europe and Japan, to the more recent technological
advances in retailing and international expansion of large retailers. All of
these, however, saw the retail revolution as the process limited to the retail
“industry” itself. When Bluestone and his colleagues (1981), for instance,
titled their investigation of the transformation in the US department store
sector The Retail Revolution, they focused on the processes of the “industriali-
zation of retailing,” characterized by the adoption of new technologies and
corporate managerial hierarchies, the emergence of giant firms (such as Sears
and J. C. Penney’s) that were then “about to buy out or drive out their
competition” (Bluestone et al. 1981: 143) and the concomitant changes in
retail labor.3 The US retail sector, they emphasized, was about to catch up with
the developments that had been present in manufacturing for many decades.
In our view, the retail revolution should be understood as a more funda-
mental transformation in the organization of the overall global economy, the
transformation that continues to change not only the world of retailing, or
even the relative power between retailers and their suppliers, but also the
shape of international trade, economic development, product worlds, and
consumption practices.
The rest of this volume is dedicated to addressing various aspects of this
transformation. Here we summarize some of the main trends from the 1950s
to the first decades of the twenty-first century that helped propel what was
3
Gary G. Hamilton and Misha Petrovic
initially a limited change of the US retail landscape into a major force of the
global economy.
The first such trend, already indicated above, was the phenomenal growth
of large retailers. The growth has been predicated on the convergence of
major retail innovations—self-service, broad product mix, and chain-store
replication—toward a standard business model adopted by retailers in many
different sectors. The revolution started in the USA, in the late 1950s and
early 1960s, based on the application of the supermarket model to general
merchandise and specialty retailing and on the dramatic expansion of retail
space in shopping centers. Some of its protagonists and major beneficiaries
were already established operators, such as Sears and J. C. Penney’s, Wool-
worth’s and Kresge’s, A&P (Atlantic and Pacific), Safeway and Albertsons,
May and Federated department stores. But the change in retail formats also
created opportunities for new specialty stores, such as The Limited (founded
in 1963), CVS Caremark (1963), The Gap (1969), Best Buy (1977), Home
Depot (1978), Costco (1983), and Staples (1986). Wal-Mart, Kmart, and
Target, the big three of discount general merchandising, all started their
operations in 1962, as did Kohl’s. As the US retail formats spread abroad
(see Petrovic, Chapter 3 this volume), similar transformations occurred in
Western Europe and Japan, and then in a number of other economies,
bringing to the fore new efficient operators, such as Carrefour, Tesco,
Metro, and Aldi. This new generation of retailers would eventually converge
on a portfolio of standardized retail formats, and come to dominate global
retail markets.
The second major trend has been the blurring of boundaries between man-
ufacturers, brand-name merchandisers, and retailers, as all of them increas-
ingly saw marketing as their core organizational activity and competence.
Before the 1960s, most brand-name merchandisers were also manufacturers
who promoted, often through extensive advertising, the products that they
actually made. In the 1970s, however, this pattern gave way to brand-name
merchandisers that sourced from original equipment manufacturers (OEMs)
most if not all of the goods sold under their brand name. Nike (1972), Ralph
Lauren, and The Limited were amongst the first and most well-known mer-
chandisers to do so, but the list of these factory-less brand-name merchandi-
sers is now quite long. Most of them never had factories in the first place, while
some of them, such as Schwinn bicycles, Eddie Bauer clothes, RCA TVs, began
as manufacturers, but by the 1980s had closed all or most of their factories and
simply became designers and merchandisers of products made by contract
manufacturers. By the late 1980s, this same pattern of shifting from
manufacturing to merchandising also swept through consumer electronics.
Dell, a factory-less brand-name merchandiser and now one of the world’s
largest sellers of brand-name computers, established its business only in
4
Introduction
1984. Dell’s chief competitors in the area of personal computers, IBM, Hewlett
Packard, and Compaq, all began as PC manufacturers and ended as merchan-
disers relying on contract manufacturing.
The third major trend concerns various momentous changes in retail tech-
nology, what Abernathy and his colleagues (1999; Chapter 2 this volume)
refer to as “lean retailing.” At the core of this transformation is the application
of information technology to all aspects of selling products, from tracking
consumer purchases to managing inventories and supply chains. One of the
best examples of such technologies is the Universal Product Code (UPC).
Supermarkets and food firms jointly developed bar codes and scanning
devices in the mid-1970s. In the early 1980s, Wal-Mart and Kmart were
amongst the first retailers to expand UPC to include non-food items, which
enabled them to develop computerized inventory systems. Most other firms,
large and small, followed suit later in the decade, so that, by the 1990s, UPC
had become nearly universal. From the mid-1980s on, the spreading use of bar
codes allowed a transformation in logistics, including containerization,
shipping, warehousing, stocking, and tracking consumer choices from
point-of-sales information.
Technological changes pushed retailers into the front category of technology
adopters and users. By allowing them directly to access and track consumer
demand at the checkout counter, new information and communication tech-
nologies gave retailers the means to refashion the relations with their suppliers.
Before the 1980s, business practitioners conceptualized the distribution of
manufactured goods from the viewpoint of manufacturers, as “distribution
channels.” After the 1980s, they coined new terminology to conceptualize the
distribution of goods from the perspective of the retailer: “supply chains.” With
the help of information technology, retailers began to practice “supply-chain
management,” which is another way of saying that they created price-sensitive
networks of firms that turned manufacturing and logistics into organizational
extensions of retailing (Feenstra and Hamilton 2006: 233).
The increasing concentration at the retail end largely results from the
national and international proliferation of chain stores that sell more or less
the same set of products everywhere the companies establish their retail out-
lets. The proliferation of chain stores creates a tremendous intermediary
demand (that is, the demand generated by the big buyers) for logistical and
manufacturing solutions that can supply each outlet with exactly those goods
required to restock their inventories. This intermediary demand always
extends beyond the boundaries of individual firms to incorporate all other
firms with which the specific retail firms do business. The networks of firms
organized around the intermediary demand for products makes manufac-
turers and logistics providers into “vendors,” into mere suppliers of goods
and services that the “big-box” retailers “buy” for their customers.
5
Gary G. Hamilton and Misha Petrovic
The fourth and perhaps the most important aspect of the retail revolution
is the fact that the goods that American and European consumers buy have
been increasingly sourced from suppliers located outside the United States
and Europe, particularly from East Asia. As we describe in Part III (see espe-
cially Hamilton and Kao, Chapter 6 this volume), starting in the mid-1960s
there was a dramatic increase in US imports of select categories of consumer
goods. Before 1965, imported goods represented a negligible part of US
consumption, but by the late 1970s they came to dominate consumption
of many common categories of consumer goods, from apparel and toys to
electronics and, increasingly, motorcycles and cars. From the very first begin-
nings of this trend, these consumer goods came predominately from East
Asia. This trend, which continues today, has had dire consequences for US-
based manufacturing of non-durable consumer goods, but was at the same
time a major factor in the development of manufacturing competences of
Asian firms and, by implication, in the general economic growth of Asian
economies. The ability of US, and soon after also European, retailers to find
alternative sources of supply and weaken the competitive position of domes-
tic brands increased the relative power of retailers over manufacturers.
The final aspect of the global retail revolution is the transformation of
consumption.4 The role of large retailers in globalizing consumption patterns
has been largely ignored in favor of more striking references to McDonaldiza-
tion and other similar putative processes of the globalization of American
brands, products, and popular culture. We believe that the transformation of
consumption brought about by the large retailers has been both more subtle
and ultimately more consequential than what such examples centered on
particular companies and products suggest. The issue is one not of
homogeneity versue diversity, globalization and localization, but rather of
the global convergence toward certain types of retail markets, product worlds,
and expectations of choice.
This convergence has increasingly created new types of consumers, as well
as an array of new types of retailers that cater to these consumers. Retailers
have been able to create new consumer markets throughout the world, not
simply because they offer cheaper prices, for that is usually not the case, but
rather because they promise a new way of life for people who come to see
themselves in a new light.
Social scientists have known for a long time that people consume what they
do as a means of conveying to others a sense of who they are as individuals.
Thorstein Veblen, in The Theory of the Leisure Class (1899), was the first social
scientist to develop a demand-driven theory of the economy. He showed that
the logic of consumption was to convey a sense of self-worth to others by
means of making invidious distinctions. People who regard themselves as
privileged in one way or another will use status-marking objects and actions
6
Introduction
7
Gary G. Hamilton and Misha Petrovic
However anachronistic they may be, these lifestyles and identities are neces-
sarily contemporary ones. They are up to date precisely because retailers and
other purveyors provide the necessary accoutrements to establish a contem-
porary way of life. Without these retailers, a particular lifestyle might be
difficult if not impossible to establish: difficult to find the right stuff, difficult
to find others to associate with, difficult even to know about. Demand-driven
retailing helps define and fill out lifestyles that would hardly exist otherwise.
It is also clear that, outside Europe and the United States, the feedback loop
between retailers and the new consumers has helped to create new identities
out of the apparent convergence that so many people have observed. Music,
movies, the Internet, technology hardware and software, vacations and tour-
ism, strategic English, standardized national languages, houses that call for
interior decoration, cuisines that require specialized kitchenware, occupations
that necessitate a standardized education—the list of convergences go on and
on. But what this listing obscures is the fact that these are the very media of
differentiation.
Demand-driven retailing allows consumers to create distinct worlds out of
standardized points of entry. The youth of each country use cell phones to
text to their friends and create their own rap songs; in turn, both media relay
to the audience what it means to be young and in a particular place. Bolly-
wood helps Indians to understand who they are or might be, a fact that can be
shared with movie-goers around the world, who in turn can understand who
they are not. Google and other Internet search engines adapt to each locale, as
well as to differentiate amongst locales, and Google and the other search
engines are strictly speaking demand driven; they rely on information fed by
its users.
The standardization of entry points encourages cultural differentiation,
encourages the formation of new worlds filled with new identities to
explore. Mathews and Lui (2001) show, in their fine collection on consum-
erism in Hong Kong, that shopping in Hong Kong has become a way of life,
not a Western way of life, but a new Hong Konger way of life. Chua, in Life Is
Not Complete without Shopping (2003), makes the same argument for Singa-
pore. In both locations, a unique consumer culture has emerged, including
styles of clothing, home decor, movies, and food. Mona Abaza (2001) lets us
see that shopping malls in Cairo offer a new space for Egyptians, not as
Westerners, but as Egyptians forging new identities to fit the times, for
women who are finding a space away from Islamic restrictions, for couples
who can look into each other’s eyes longingly and without shame. In Golden
Arches East: McDonald’s in East Asia, James Watson and colleagues (2006)
look at variations in how customers in different Asian societies respond to
McDonald’s, and make it clear that there is nothing uniform in the diffusion
8
Introduction
The retail revolution today engulfs the world economy. Despite the obvious-
ness of this transformation, and despite the fact that consumers experience its
effects every day, there has been very little research and very little writing that
explore the dimensions and effects of global retailing. To be sure, Wal-Mart
has been in the news and under the pen of many writers, often bitterly
criticized for its employment practices and for its ability to drive out local
retailers from the communities in which it builds new stores, and occasionally
praised as a champion of efficiency and consumer well-being (Bianco 2006;
Fishman 2006; Lichtenstein 2006, 2009). While somewhat overshadowed by
this focus on Wal-Mart, other large US retailers—such as the rapidly growing
Costco, Target, Home Depot, Lowe’s, Walgreen’s, and Best Buy; e-commerce
leaders such as Amazon, eBay and Dell; even those less stellar performers such
as Sears and Kmart, and Federated and May Department Stores;5 and super-
market chains such as Kroger, Albertsons, and Safeway—have also contributed
to the recent wave of interest in retailing and retailers. In Europe, the spotlight
has been on European retail giants, such as Carrefour, Tesco, Metro, Schwarz,
and Aldi and their efforts to integrate the EU retail market, expand interna-
tionally, and meet the competitive challenge posed by the ultimately unsuc-
cessful entrance of Wal-Mart into Germany and its successful move into Great
Britain.
This reportage, however, addresses only a small piece of what is a much
larger and much more complex phenomenon, a veritable transformation of
global markets for consumer goods, and of the global economy as a whole.
Market making
The chapters in this book analyze the scope and effects of the world’s largest
retailers in terms of their market-making activities. By the term “market
making” we mean something that is often overlooked in economic analysis
but is very important for the analysis of economic development and
globalization: large retailers “make” the markets for those products that they
sell. Often in fierce competition with each other, retailers assiduously calcu-
late how to generate, channel, and capture consumers’ demand. They locate
store sites and establish websites, select the mix of goods and services, set
prices and plan promotions, advertise and manage manufacturers’ and their
own brands, process and facilitate thousands of consumer transactions. In
9
Gary G. Hamilton and Misha Petrovic
doing this, retailers create and expand consumer goods markets, and shape
consumers’ preferences and behavior.
Large retailers do not only make consumer markets; they also make “sup-
plier markets.” Capturing sizable shares of the actual consumer markets for
products, large retailers gain commanding positions to structure and organize
suppliers for the products they sell. Conventional thinking describes retailers
as middlemen, the passive conduit between manufacturers and consumers.
The retail revolution, however, has made retailers proactive agents in design-
ing products, organizing suppliers, and even shaping consumers’ behavior. As
brand-name merchandiser Apple Computers did for the iPod, retailers often
create whole new markets—on both the consumer and the supplier side.
Understanding this fact allows one to track the changing role that manufac-
turers have had in the emerging system of global markets. For most consumer
goods, the manufacturer has become a contingent supplier of the goods it
makes, one of many firms that could manufacture comparable goods. The
markets in final goods, in turn, structure the markets for intermediate and
primary goods.
By being able to establish markets for the final goods they sell directly to
consumers, large retailers also shape global markets for many other goods and
services as well. Their decisions on which manufacturers to select, where those
manufacturers are to be located, what exact products the manufacturers
should make, under what conditions the manufacturers will make and pack-
age and deliver these products, and what price retailers will pay the manufac-
turers for all these goods and services are amongst the most significant factors
that shape the contemporary global economy. The concentration of global
manufacturing in East Asia, the rise of huge contract manufacturers, the
development of global logistics—these are but a few of the cascading effects
of the retail revolution that we will explore in this book.
10
Introduction
Table 0.1. Retail concentration in grocery trade, select economies, 2005 (%)
Finland 90 Netherlands 62
Australia 83 United Kingdom 59
Ireland 80 Italy 35
Germany 70 United States 34
France 70 Japan 11
Spain 65 China 6
stores were small, locally owned shops, and large chain operators were more
an exception than the rule. More recently, with the phenomenal growth of
Wal-Mart and “category killers” in the USA, and with the consolidation of the
European retail market, mostly by German and French retailers, concentration
in global retailing has been rapidly increasing. In some smaller European
economies, a few major retailers came to dominate large parts of the overall
retail sector. Table 0.1 shows the proportion of the grocery trade, traditionally
the largest retail sector, controlled by the five largest firms in select developed
economies and China.
The absolute size of the US market has so far precluded the levels of concen-
tration reached in smaller economies. In the comparable-sized EU-15 market,
the concentration ratio is around 25 percent, while in the Asia-Oceania
region, it is no more than 13 percent. However, if the huge and diverse retail
sector is further divided into subsections, the concentration ratios are much
higher. In the United States, as Table 0.2 shows, some of the major retail
sectors, including the “general-merchandise” sector (corresponding to the
last two rows of Table 0.2), exhibit very high concentration ratios. In each of
these sectors, there are “category killers,” such as Home Depot and Lowe’s, or
CVS and Walgreen’s, which dominate the category. Moreover, the share of
general merchandisers, such as Wal-Mart and Costco, in the sales of apparel,
consumer electronics, and groceries is often higher than that of the major
specialty retailers.
This trend of increasing retail concentration is particularly significant in
some smaller economies around the world that have recently deregulated
their retail markets and opened them to foreign investment. These economies
have seen astonishing increases in retail concentration take place during a
very short period of time (Reardon et al. 2007; see also Chapter 10 this
volume). For instance, the market share of top-ten food retailers in Greece
grew from 18.5 percent in 1990 to 72 percent in 1999, and in the Czech
Republic, from less than 10 percent in 1993 to over 50 percent in 2005.
11
Gary G. Hamilton and Misha Petrovic
Table 0.2. Retail concentration, market share of top firms, United States, 2002
Total retail 11 23
Electronic shopping 29 51
Clothing stores 28 52
Grocery stores 31 55
Health and personal care 46 60
Electronics and appliance 44 61
Shoe stores 40 68
Book stores 66 74
Office supplies 78 81
Home improvement centers 91 93
Department stores 72 99
Discount stores, warehouse, supercenters 94 99
12
Introduction
Note: These numbers do not include gasoline stations and car dealerships.
Sources: Euromonitor (2002).
density of retail establishments, most retail firms operate only a single store.
In the US retail sector, arguably the most advanced in the world, almost
80 percent of retail establishments have fewer than ten employees, account-
ing for 15 percent of all firms of that size in the economy.
Small retailing businesses often serve as a substitute for social welfare
mechanisms, especially in developing countries, with a high proportion of
self-employed, underemployed, and part-time workers. In addition, the large
number of retail proprietors and entrepreneurs and their embeddedness in
local communities give small retailers a measure of social and political impor-
tance that often exceeds the lobbying power of the big retailers. Hence, in
most developed countries, the government regulation of retail competition
typically includes measures that specifically protect small retailers from the
competitive threat posed by the large retailers. These measures take the form
of price regulations, strict zoning and development laws, limits on operating
hours, and so on. Ostensibly, they sacrifice a degree of efficiency that comes
with the expansion of the big retailing business in favor of alternative goals
such as consumer convenience and equity, preservation of local communities,
and environmental protection. However, just as in developing countries
where similar measures are defended more directly in terms of the protection
of domestic retail sector against foreign corporations, the impact of these
regulations on consumers’ welfare is at best ambivalent, and often negative,
thus favoring the special interests of small retailers over those of the consumer
majority.
13
Gary G. Hamilton and Misha Petrovic
14
Introduction
15
Gary G. Hamilton and Misha Petrovic
By the 1990s, these new, “lean retailers” had already garnered enough size
and momentum for the productivity gains to become apparent at the aggre-
gate level of the retail industry, as well as in wholesaling and logistics. US
retailers led the way, a fact highlighted by a series of McKinsey Global Institute
studies on sector-level productivity in developed economies. These studies,
summarized by Lewis (2004), suggest that one of the main reasons behind
the robust productivity growth that the US economy has largely enjoyed since
the mid-1990s has been the ability of large US retailers, led by Wal-Mart, to
restructure the retail industry as well as a number of related sectors. Retailing
and wholesaling sectors contributed about half of the US productivity growth
acceleration in the second half of the 1990s; Wal-Mart alone was responsible
for 4 percent of this growth, and the competitive pressure it exerted on other
retailers, as well as on wholesalers and suppliers, accounted for about twice as
much.
Leading European retailers, such as Carrefour, Tesco, and Metro, have similar
levels of productivity as Wal-Mart and other large US retailers, and were also
amongst the early adopters of new technologies. Yet, hampered by restrictive
regulations, European retailers influenced their respective national retail sec-
tors less than did US retailers, and their recent expansion has been due mainly
to their aggressive pursuit of internationalization opportunities. As a result,
while the productivity growth in information- technology-intensive indus-
tries, such as automobiles, industrial machines, computers, and consumer
electronics, has been equal or higher in the EU than in the USA, the productiv-
ity growth rate of distributive trades remains much lower (Denis, McMorrow,
and Röger 2004).
The productivity-enhancing effects of large retailers’ drive for efficiency are
felt globally, even when those retailers themselves operate in only a handful of
countries. Most large retailers source their products globally, and so their
productivity gains create spillover effects in their supply chains. Global sour-
cing predates the globalization of retailing and has already played a major role
in the development of export-led, or, to use a more appropriate term intro-
duced by Feenstra and Hamilton (2006), “demand-responsive” economies.
The “Asian Miracle,” certainly the most striking example of economic success
in the twentieth century, was to a large extent induced and supported by the
efforts of US retailers to generate, channel, and organize “intermediate
demand,” thus creating global economic linkages between American consu-
mers and Asian manufacturers. This demand-responsive development did not,
of course, stay limited to the export-oriented consumer goods industries, as it
triggered a cascading series of changes through sectors producing intermediate
inputs, logistics, financial and business services, and so on.
The resulting transformation of the overall economy, including the pro-
cesses of industrial upgrading and the emergence of the elaborate division of
16
Introduction
labor between East Asian economies, has also changed the social fabric of
Asian societies and the geopolitical situation in the Pacific region. The Asian
Miracle also often served as a role model for development policies in other
parts of the world, although with much more modest results. As a conse-
quence, a country’s degree of economic development became almost synony-
mous with the ability of its export-oriented industries to produce
technologically sophisticated, high value-added goods.
17
Gary G. Hamilton and Misha Petrovic
As with market power and productivity, the impact of large retailers on labor
markets is not limited to the retail sector. While a part of the shift from
manufacturing to retail jobs may be attributed to expected, and perhaps
unavoidable, structural adjustments in a developed service economy, US re-
tailers are also playing a causal role in the decline of domestic manufacturing
employment by their relentless pursuit of cost reduction and their global
sourcing strategies. The outsourcing of manufacturing, and, increasingly, of
service-sector jobs, has played a prominent part in recent public debates about
competitiveness and the long-term prospects of the American economy. It is
evident that large retailers are amongst the drivers of this process, as their
relations with their suppliers provide a major mechanism through which the
forces of global competition induce structural changes in local economies.
Impact on consumers
As we mentioned above, the effect of large retailers on consumers and their
shopping and consumption patterns is quite obvious and quite pervasive; yet
it has attracted somewhat less attention than the other effects discussed so far.
The fact that large modern retailers bring lower prices to the consumer is well
established and separable from the concerns about anti-competitive practices
and local price discrimination. The role of large retailers in standardizing retail
formats, product assortments, and shopping experience is less well documen-
ted, partly because these effects are more difficult to measure. The global
diffusion of modern retailing formats is perhaps the most observable of
these effects. Supermarkets, convenience stores, and fast-food restaurants
have been successful in many different socio-cultural contexts and at various
levels of economic development. Large “combination stores” selling general
merchandise and groceries under the same roof, shopping malls, and big-box
specialty stores (“category killers”) are less universally adopted, but the main
reason for their slower diffusion seems to be restrictive regulation rather than
the lack of consumer acceptance.
The standardization and global diffusion of retail formats go hand in hand
with the standardization of products and product assortments. Even when
most products are sourced locally, as is generally the case in food retailing,
large global retailers are able to benefit from the procurement of global brands
and from the standardization of the merchandise mix. Outside the realm of
cars, consumer electronics, and a few luxury items, there are few brands that
are truly global, and this facilitates the attempts of large retailers to promote
globally their own store brands, and, even more importantly, to turn them-
selves into globally recognized brands.
All of this does not just standardize the ways of meeting the demand for
consumer goods, but also helps define and change this demand. It is
18
Introduction
19
Gary G. Hamilton and Misha Petrovic
20
Introduction
21
Gary G. Hamilton and Misha Petrovic
may affect how much consumers spend and on what types of goods. But it is
always the role of market makers to create and organize markets, on both the
consumer’s and the supplier’s side, and thus they play the decisive role in
organizing the global economy. Insofar as the most important of these market
makers today are to be found amongst the ranks of large retailers and mer-
chandisers, they are the key to understanding and perhaps also to resolving
the problems of imbalances in the global economy. Whether their actions will
lead to the decrease in trade imbalances, by, say, developing and expanding
domestic demand in China and other major developing economies, or will
continue to exacerbate the trends of the last couple of decades, remains to be
seen. What is certain is the fact that retailers will have a large and growing
impact on global development for a long time to come.
The four parts of this book survey the dimensions and effects of the rise of global
retailing. The two chapters in Part One provide the theoretical and historical
background to understand the ongoing global retail revolution. In Chapter 1,
Petrovic and Hamilton outline the market-making perspective. They argue that
conventional economic analysis routinely misses the importance of markets as
marketplaces, as institutionalized locations where transactions occur, and of
market making as an organized process of intermediation, a process linking
sellers of goods and services with buyers of the same. Without markets and
without firms whose specialty is creating and maintaining marketplaces, the
core feature of all capitalist economies—namely, the exchange of goods and
services—would seem difficult, if not impossible, to analyze, and yet modern
economic analysis pays scant attention to such phenomena and so pays little
attention to retailing as an important economic activity. This chapter corrects
this deficiency by providing the conceptual dimensions of the market-making
perceptive.
In Chapter 2, Abernathy and Volpe demonstrate the impact of technologi-
cal innovations, both as they enable retailing, such as the effect of contain-
erized shipping on global sourcing, and as transforming factors, such as the
impact of information technology in the development of lean retailing tech-
niques. These technological innovations have had profound effects on many
dimensions of retailing, including merchandising (that is, product mix and
variety), retail formats, services offered (including payment), and supply-
chain management and sourcing strategies. Most of these major technological
innovations have generally occurred in other sectors of the economy, but
retailers have been able to utilize them for their own advantage, either directly
or indirectly, in selling products. Some examples include the development of
22
Introduction
23
Gary G. Hamilton and Misha Petrovic
many respects. The national retail systems in Europe are significantly different
from one another, not only because of differences in consumer preferences,
but also because of variations in regulations affecting retailing. The most rapid
transformation in retailing in the opening decade of the twenty-first century
has occurred in Eastern Europe, in many cases with West European retailers
playing a leading role. Many of the changes in Europe mirror those in the USA,
with the development of self-service, larger store-size formats, horizontal
expansion, and retailer-led efficiency gains in the supply chain. However, in
no European country are these changes as advanced as in the USA. The higher
level of regulation not only hampers these changes, but modifies them, lead-
ing to new innovations and dynamics in some cases.
Wortmann focuses on retailing in four major countries. In France and Great
Britain retailing regulation has been relatively weak, so many of the trends
have materialized to a much greater extent than in Italy, which has very rigid
regulations. Germany is somewhere in between, attempting to limit store size,
but not merchandising practices, which has led to the growth of small-store
hard discounters, such as Aldi. In part because of the limited opportunities to
expand domestically, some of the major European retailers have been leaders
in the global expansion of retailing. The chapter includes case studies of some
of the major European retail innovators, such as Carrefour, Aldi, Metro, and
Tesco, as well as a general overview of the internationalization efforts of
European retailers.
The effects of the more recent technological changes, the development of
the Internet and of overnight delivery services, are described by Kotha and
Basu in Chapter 5. The Internet and online retailing have given rise to new
retailing formats for selling traditional products, such as in the case of books
and Amazon.com. In addition, these new technologies have generated new
forms of market making. Perhaps the best and most successful example is
eBay.com, which brings together millions of buyers and sellers in a cyber
marketplace. Online shopping has also impacted incumbent retailers,
whether they see the Internet as just another marketing channel or a new
approach to retailing. Some existing retailers, such as Wal-Mart, are trying
largely to use an online presence to leverage their physical assets, but that
could change in the future. Online retailers are still in the process of discover-
ing what works and what does not. Broadband connectivity has given a major
boost to online retailing. The next stage, just beginning to emerge, may be
global online retailing. Finally, the easy availability of information on the
Internet, especially with the development of sophisticated search engines,
such as Google, has helped create more knowledgeable consumers. Even if
they do not buy online, by using the Internet, many consumers are now much
better informed than in the past. When potential customers who have
24
Introduction
searched on the Internet come into automobile dealerships, they may literally
know as much about the car models and pricing as the salesperson.
The four chapters in Part Three examine the continuing development of
global supplier markets and the formation of global retail supply chains led by
large retailers and brand-name merchandisers. In the first chapter in the part,
Chapter 6, “Supplier Markets and the Asian Miracle: The Rise of Demand-
Responsive Economies,” Hamilton and Kao demonstrate that the industriali-
zation of East Asia that started in the late 1960s and that is known as the
“Asian Miracle” is most accurately seen as the widespread development of
supplier markets for mostly American brand-name merchandisers and retail-
ers. Asia’s export-driven industrialization quickly led to the development of
“demand-responsive economies.” Using Taiwan as an example, the authors
show, step by step and industry by industry, how, through the actions of big
buyers, Asian economies in the 1970s and 1980s became organized backwards
from the development of consumer markets in the USA to the creation of
supplier markets for consumer goods in East Asia. Using extensive interview
data from Taiwanese business people, the authors present a number of case
studies showing the process of economic integration (and disintegration)
around the development of supplier markets. Such supply-chain-driven
economies are the essence of the demand-responsive economies that emerged
in East Asia in the second half of the twentieth century and that are charac-
teristic of economies around the world today.
In Chapter 7, “Global Logistics, Global Labor,” Bonacich and Hamilton
explain the crucial role played by logistics providers in creating the supply
chains of global retailers. Goods produced in Asia and elsewhere via global
sourcing must be moved to the United States in a timely manner. To meet this
need, a complex logistics system has developed, which includes everything
from infrastructure to logistics management. Some retailers have large inter-
nal logistics management departments. Others rely on third-party companies
that specialize in logistics. Global sourcing has been dependent on the simul-
taneous development of crucial supporting actors, including ocean shipping,
railroads, the trucking industry, air freight companies, and warehousing op-
erations. A key factor has been the evolution of inter-modal transportation
systems that can move containerized shipments quickly from Asia and else-
where to points throughout the USA and Europe.
The development of a global logistics infrastructure has made retailers’
management of their supply chains a global reality. Because of their tremen-
dous volume, and concomitant power, large retailers have played a major role
in shaping the development of global economies, including, most impor-
tantly, China, which has become the world’s leading exporter of consumer
goods. Through their management of supply chains, retailers are able to put
tremendous pressure on their suppliers to achieve flexible production and cost
25
Gary G. Hamilton and Misha Petrovic
26
Introduction
Taiwan, Mexico, Nicaragua, and Lesotho. Yue Yuen/Pou Chen, based in Hong
Kong and Taiwan, with a global workforce of 242,000 employees, is the
world’s largest maker of branded athletic and casual footwear. Its dominance
shapes the relative bargaining power it has with such major brand-name
merchandisers as Nike and Reebok. Increasingly, large contractors, and not
the retailers, manage the supply chain. Their emergence, along with the
pressure of lean retailing for cost cutting and quick response, is also compel-
ling retailers to shift critical functions such as inventory management to these
giant contract suppliers. China’s rise as an industrial power may further
change global supply-chain dynamics, with synergies arising from its supplier
clusters, investment in the next generation of technologies, and the rapid
growth of its domestic retail chains.
The two chapters in Part Four detail the multiple linkages between retailing
and manufacturing for two very different industries. In Chapter 9, “The
Global Spread of Modern Food Retailing,” Senauer and Reardon examine the
global transformation in the food industries and grocery retailing. Histori-
cally, some of the original global market makers were merchants trading
agricultural commodities, and such companies remained dominant until the
mid-twentieth century. In the period after the Second World War, major food
manufacturers, such as Coca Cola, Kellogg, and Nestle, became leaders in the
creation of multinational consumer markets for their products. In the last
quarter of the twentieth century, food retailers, including food service opera-
tors, began to play a major role in creating global consumer and supplier
markets. The fast-food companies, a uniquely American format, led the global
market making. McDonald’s, which in 2010 operates in some 120 countries,
excels at the creation of consumer markets for its format, offering a mix of
products and service, which in many of the countries it has entered literally
did not exist previously. At the same time, it has created a supplier base in
many of these countries.
Consumers have now become accustomed to having fresh fruits and vege-
tables year around and exotic food products from abroad, thanks to global
sourcing. A small number of European companies, including Carrefour,
Ahold, and Metro, along with Wal-Mart, are dominating the international
expansion of food retailers. The spread of supermarkets in developing
countries, typically regional chains, but also major global retailers, is having
a profound impact on their agricultural systems. It is reshaping the supply
chain for locally sourced products, all the way back to the farm level. Super-
market chains want to deal with a small number of reliable suppliers, not
hundreds of small peasant farmers. A contractual arrangement is frequently
established with a few “preferred suppliers” who can meet their standards.
In Chapter 10, “Market Making in the Personal-Computer Industry,” Kraemer
and Dedrick analyze a similar transformation in the personal-computer (PC)
27
Gary G. Hamilton and Misha Petrovic
28
Part One
The Market Makers:
A General Perspective
This page intentionally left blank
1
Introduction
other, with the market derived from Adam Smith’s conception of the “invisi-
ble hand,” and with organization cast as the “visible hand” (A. D. Chandler
1977) by which the wills of owners and managers are exercised.
In these and many other examples, the term “market organization” is an
oxymoron, a situation where more of one leads to less of the other. The subject
matter of industrial organization, a subfield in economics, is a good example
of how these two words do not get along. The primary topics of interest in this
subfield are actions of organizations, states, and firms that impede or other-
wise corrupt the “normal” operations of self-organizing markets. The result is
the economics of “imperfect competition” whereby strategic organizational
action leads to “market failure.” Organizations’ attempts to act on, rather than
strictly within, self-organizing, competitive markets naturally lead to pro-
blems, inefficiencies, and suboptimal outcomes.
The market-making perspective introduced in this volume seeks to elimi-
nate this artificial opposition between organization and market, by bringing
in the ideas of market making and market makers. In this perspective, markets
are not simple, spontaneously occurring, self-organizing structures. Rather,
they are made, maintained, and reproduced by economic actors, typically
large firms, that act as market makers. The results of their actions are the
markets of the modern economy—institutionally complex, consciously gen-
erated structures that enable and facilitate large numbers of transactions
between large numbers of diverse trading partners.
Our perspective thus shifts from abstract, purely conceptual markets of
standard economic theory, depicted by hypothetical supply-and-demand
curves, to retail stores, stock exchanges, trading companies, showroom floors,
all places where transactions occur, and to the institutional arrangements that
facilitate those transactions. It also shifts from looking at organizations as
either irrelevant for or detrimental to the functioning of the market, to under-
standing their crucial role in making market transactions possible.
Economic theorists, of one type or another, have been little interested in
market making and market makers. This disinterest is a result of two deeply
ingrained habits of thought in economic analysis. The first one, the equilib-
rium bias, we have already hinted at above. It treats markets as simple,
spontaneously emerging mechanisms of exchange and thus does not allow
for the ideas that markets could be institutionally complex and need to be
consciously created and maintained. In fact, markets are treated as non-
institutions, as paradigmatic examples of the celebrated “invisible hand”
that operates automatically and should be protected from being tampered
with. In such a perspective, market making can refer to little more than
guaranteeing the rules of the game, by the exchange parties themselves or by
an external legal–political authority, and perhaps regulating certain irration-
al behaviors of economic actors.
32
Retailers as Market Makers
The equilibrium bias has often been identified and criticized for its theoreti-
cal shortcomings and policy implications. The other type of bias, although as
commonly espoused in economic analysis and no less detrimental to the
understanding of markets, is less well recognized.1 We refer to it as the
“productionist” bias, since it is based on the belief that markets are a some-
what epiphenomenal aspect of the economy when compared to the funda-
mental economic reality of production. The productionist bias does not deny
the possibility of market making in general, but rather deprives it of economic
significance. The main activity of firms, it contends, is to produce valuable
goods and services. The way those are procured in the market, and the activ-
ities involved in such a procurement, are peripheral and incidental to what the
“real” economy is about.
The two types of bias may seem barely related, or even opposed to each
other. However, in the history of economic analysis they have often gone
hand in hand, partly because they have both chosen to ignore the institu-
tional aspects of markets and market making. Ever since Adam Smith wrote
about the pin factory and about the natural laws of supply and demand in The
Wealth of Nations (1977 [1776]), most economists have assumed that firms are
about the organization of production and that markets, for better or worse, are
self-organizing. The coexistence of the two biases was predicated on the
division of labor that produced a mutual lack of interest in each other’s
models. A theorist enthralled by the idea of spontaneous, automatic competi-
tive markets will in principle have little interest in the specifics of organiza-
tional activity, yet would still be likely to see production as the core concern of
the firm and market making as at best an imperfection and at worst an attempt
to tamper with the invisible hand of the market.2 Similarly, a theorist who
sees the economy as a system of production will have little interest in explor-
ing the details of the “distribution realm” and will probably accept that in
complex modern economies markets are effective, if not necessarily perfect,
mechanisms for the distribution of goods and services.3
Even when the two biases were at odds with each other, this only strength-
ened their prejudice against market making. For instance, a relatively strong
belief by some productionist theorists that the market system is an inefficient
mechanism of distribution, to be supplanted by some version of a “planned”
economy, zeroes in on market-making activities such as pricing and advertis-
ing as the best example of everything that is wrong with markets. On the
equilibrium side, transaction-cost theorists reject the view of the firm as a
production function, preferring to represent it instead as an alternative and
complement to the market system; yet this market-and-hierarchy approach
never broaches the issue of firms as market makers.
Both types of bias, thus, render market making irrelevant if not outright
harmful: a market imperfection or market tampering in equilibrium theories;
33
Misha Petrovic and Gary G. Hamilton
It is an open question which of the two aspects of the creation of the modern
economy is more important: mass production or mass selling.5 One thing is
certain, however; each depends on the existence of the other, and for this
reason, they both developed concurrently. However, a lot more has been
written about mass production than about mass selling. In the initial burst
of industrialization in the nineteenth century, the factory system was so new
and so instrumental in changing the organization of work that mass produc-
tion got the lion’s share of the attention. When Karl Marx joined Friedrich
Engels to write The Communist Manifesto (1849), the smoke stacks of England’s
factories were what seemed to be the most important part of capitalism, and so
they wrote about the emergence of new forms of production and labor, which
resulted, they believed, in vastly cheaper prices of goods that people every-
where, if they had those products in front of them, would obviously want to
buy. But Marx and Engels did not discuss the selling part of the equation; that
was assumed to be unproblematic. Later, when Marx wrote his tome Das
Kapital (1867), he did not talk about selling there either. In the “Preface” to
the first German edition, Marx said he studied the factory system in England
because that is where the “iron laws” of capitalism were being worked out, but
he did not go to Latin America or India or South East Asia to see how English
textiles were being peddled aggressively by British, Indian, and Chinese mer-
chants. Obviously, for Marx the laws of capitalism were laws about the orga-
nization of mass production and not of mass selling.
Marx and Engels were not the only ones to concentrate on making rather
than selling goods, for most other writers have done the same. Factory pro-
duction, however, was only half of the matter. With new forms of production
in the nineteenth century came the necessity to remake existing markets and
to find new markets, both of which in turn fostered more production. But
which came first, markets or factories? This is a chicken-and-egg question. It is
clear, however, that British colonialism was in full bloom before the textile
factories in England’s heartland reinvented themselves through mechaniza-
tion and expanded their production to meet the merchants’ demand for more
and more goods. And for many years, well into the nineteenth century,
the markets for English textiles and other English products expanded. From
the very beginning, the markets for selling those products were vastly more
34
Retailers as Market Makers
developed and more complexly organized than the factories making them,6
but, in the eyes of nineteenth-century observers, the more tangible factory
production seemed far more amazing and more revolutionary in every way
than selling goods.
The productionist view of the economy became even more dominant by the
end of the nineteenth century.7 In the second half of the nineteenth century,
large industrial enterprises emerged in nearly every sector of production and
played a central role in the expansion of national economies. These enter-
prises were at the forefront of capital formation and productivity growth. They
were the leaders in the utilization of science and technology, and the electrical
and internal-combustion machines that these firms invented, used, and sold
captured people’s imagination. These machines, marveled worldly wise Henry
Adams (1973 [1918]) in the opening years of the twentieth century, were
“dynamos,” “symbols of infinity,” signs of a limitless future.
To be sure, the techniques employed in mass selling even if less dramatic
were no less elaborate. Most of the selling that occurred in the early years of
European and American capitalism made use of organizational forms that
preceded the development of large mechanized factories. English and Scottish
trading companies and merchant houses (Chapman 1992; Jones 2000), ethnic
merchant groups (such as those organized by Chinese (Hao 1986; Suehiro
1989) and Indians (Markovits 2000, 2008), who followed British colonialism
around the world), and various types of specialized wholesalers organized
much of the selling to general stores and specialty shops, which in turn sold
to final consumers.
In the second half of the nineteenth century, a major new market format,
the department store, emerged in the European and American urban centers,
attracting enormous crowds and capturing the imagination of that genera-
tion of urban dwellers, many of them recent migrants from the countryside
(see Petrovic, Chapter 3 this volume). For those who could not access depart-
ment stores on a regular basis, mail-order businesses, some operated by
department stores, and some, especially in the United States, as independent
operations, brought the new world of modern, mass-produced consumer
goods straight to the home through their detailed, lavishly illustrated cata-
logs. By the early twentieth century, department stores such as Bon Marché,
Macy’s, and Harrods, and mail-order catalogs such as those for Sears and
Montgomery Ward’s, rivaled in size and organizational complexity the big-
gest manufacturing operations of the time, and were certainly more visible to
the masses of urban residents. The pervasive productionist bias, however,
made most economic observers of the time downplay the innovativeness
and importance of these mass retailers. The selling activities of mass manu-
facturers, and their innovations in advertising, marketing, pricing, franchis-
ing, and so on, also received little attention.
35
Misha Petrovic and Gary G. Hamilton
36
Retailers as Market Makers
find and encourage buyers, select buy and sell prices, define the terms of
transactions, manage the payments and record keeping for transactions and
hold inventories to provide liquidity or availability of goods and services”
(Spulber 1996: 135).
According to Spulber, intermediation encompasses most activities in retail-
ing, wholesaling, and financial sectors, as well as a substantial proportion of
those in business service and manufacturing sectors. He calculates that inter-
mediation accounts for somewhere between one-quarter and one-third of the
US gross domestic product.9
Clower and Howitt (1996: 24), approaching the issue from a post-Keynesian
perspective, describe market making in even broader terms:10
Trading opportunities are given not randomly by nature, or forced upon agents by
“authority,” but are given instead by business firms: wholesalers, retailers, brokers,
jobbers, manufacturers, banks, commodity exchanges, auction houses, employ-
ment agencies, mail order businesses, shopping malls, newspaper publishers,
accountants, doctors, lawyers . . . [These types of firms] find it profitable to organize
markets in such a way as to make trading relatively convenient and inexpensive
for other transactors.
37
Misha Petrovic and Gary G. Hamilton
Although highly stylized, this depiction captures the essence of the conven-
tional view of retailers. The retailers’ position in this linear progression always
comes later in time and in importance to the “fundamental” process of
actually making goods. More importantly, in this orderly flow of goods,
there is an implicit theory of markets as being functional to the operation of
the chain, with markets occurring at points where goods supposedly change
hands. Manufacturers buy inputs, make a product, and sell that product to
wholesalers, who in turn sell the product to retailers, who then “clear” the
channel when they sell those products to final consumers. In this portrayal,
manufacturers play the pivotal role of being the buyers of inputs who crea-
tively combine those inputs to make a product that is in turn sold to final
consumers. Market making is an unimportant activity along the chain, and
38
Retailers as Market Makers
instead represents primarily the final consumers’ demand for the manufac-
turers’ products.
If we conceptualize the economy in this fashion, then marketing and
market making become synonymous and largely the responsibility of manu-
facturers who make products and of brand-name merchandisers (for example,
Nike) who promote them.12 Distribution channels and supply chains become,
conceptually, the same thing. The role of retailer is reduced to that of service
provider, the supplier of locations where particular goods can be purchased,
the last link in a long chain of transfers that ends with the final buyer. This
portrayal assumes that the primary transaction in this lineal chain continues
to be the exchange between manufacturer and final consumer; all the rest are
merely transfers with a suitable mark-up for costs incurred (for example,
transportation costs) plus a suitable profit. This assumption maintains the
fiction that the overall chain can be represented conceptually and parsimoni-
ously by a supply and demand curve.
This is a productionist narrative of how economies work. Within this narra-
tive, there is an implicit critique of merchants and retailers as sometimes less
than honest and often greedy purveyors of products. This characterization
suggests that retailers’ organizations are less than efficient and, at times,
obstruct “normal” market forces through promoting cut-throat competition
and then selling goods at levels above or even below their “true price” merely
to drive out competition.13 Considering the pervasiveness of this account and
of the distrust of retailers implicit in it, we should not be surprised that
retailing has received scant interest from most economic observers of what-
ever discipline who are interested only in the “real” foundations of the
economy.
The market-making perspective provides another account of the same set of
activities told from the point of view of selling rather than making products.
The productionist version divides market players into singular functional roles
that efficiently link the supply (that is, the manufacturer) with the demand
(that is, the final consumer) for a good. By contrast, the market-making
perspective recognizes that markets and market making come in a remarkable
variety of types and levels of complexity; that market-making activities occur
at numerous points along the chain; that nearly every market player engages
in multiple roles; and that the link between supply and demand is a function
of market making and market makers, a link that is not well represented by a
supply and demand curve and equilibrating markets.
39
Misha Petrovic and Gary G. Hamilton
advertising and other sales promotions, and most of them have marketing
departments. Most large retailers typically engage in wholesaling activities,
and occasionally also in product development and manufacturing. Brand-
name merchandisers (for example, Nike) are typically listed as manufacturers
when what they do is to specialize in product development and marketing,
but not in manufacturing or retailing. Other firms develop core competence in
managing and marketing portfolios of brands, without entering product
development and manufacturing activities. Still others, such as McDonald’s
and Starbucks, operate primarily as “replicators” of business formats (Winter
and Szulanski 2001). In order to analyze market making, therefore, we must
replace the standard distinction between manufacturing, wholesale, and retail
firms by a series of distinctions based on the complexity of markets in which
firms sell their products, as well as on their specific capacities and competences
in making those markets.
The first, and most basic, distinction is between two types of markets in
which firms buy and sell. On the one hand, there are inter-firm markets, often
called supplier or industrial markets, in which firms (for example, DuPont) sell
goods or services only to other firms, but not to individual consumers. On the
other hand, there are consumer markets in which firms also, or exclusively,
sell directly to final consumers (for example, Wal-Mart). The latter category,
which includes retailing firms, deals on average with more complex markets,
since consumer markets involve a larger number of trading partners (their
customers) whose demand is less rationalized, less predictable, and harder to
ascertain.
The second distinction is between firms that market their products to final
consumers only in limited ways—for instance, through media advertising and
sales promotions—and those firms that mount “full package” selling opera-
tions in consumer markets, such as retail stores, restaurants, and hotels. There
are many examples of firms (for example, Intel, Kraft Foods) in the former
category that are able to create and maintain consumer markets, even though
they do not sell directly to consumers.
The third distinction refers to the breadth of products sold, separating firms
that sell only a limited range of products defined by production or consump-
tion complementarities, from those that sell a broad range and variety of
products. The former category includes some specialty retailers, but also
firms such as Microsoft, Dell, and Nike, as well as car dealerships, gasoline
stations, retail banks, personal service providers, and so on. The latter category
contains general retailers, such as supermarkets, hypermarkets, and depart-
ment stores, but also many “category killers” whose merchandise assortment,
although somewhat specialized, still typically includes thousands of different
products (e.g., Best Buy).
40
Retailers as Market Makers
Finally, a distinction can be made between firms that buy from few suppli-
ers, typically from large wholesalers, and those that deal with a large number
and variety of suppliers. Unlike the previous distinctions, this last one refers
strictly to inter-firm (supplier) markets, rather than consumer markets, and
captures the tendency of large general retailers to bypass traditional whole-
salers in favor of dealing directly with other types of suppliers.
41
Misha Petrovic and Gary G. Hamilton
used to pass goods along to consumers. They are, instead, the main players in
the game, several times larger than any consumer goods manufacturers, and
they earn their prominence by being specialists in connecting supplier and
consumer markets. These mass retailers use their leverage (that is, market
power) in one market to enhance their leverage in other markets. They use
their connections with suppliers to deliver just the right products at the right
price for their customers. They use their access to a huge number of customers
and potential customers to select and specify the products they sell and to
extract the best deals from the suppliers of those products. This leverage from
intermediation and market integration augments their capacity to make both
consumer and supplier markets. However, the ability to make these two types
of markets calls for very different market-making strategies in each market.
Consumer markets
Retailers of all types compete for consumers, and one of the ways that they
compete is in their ability to create a particular kind of marketplace where
particular kinds of products are sold. Retailers offer consumers ready-made
market mechanisms that facilitate exchange. These mechanisms come in
bundles or packages or formats that represent institutionalized market struc-
tures. A supermarket, a fast-food restaurant, a warehouse club, and a conve-
nience store are all examples of such standardized formats for obtaining food.
Retailers in each of these categories are market makers who assemble together
market mechanisms (pricing, advertising, product assortment) that match
their own competences with a perceived consumer environment.
In consumer markets, market making is, in the first instance, a competition
amongst and within market formats. Such market-making activities may include
competition within a well-recognized market category, such as price or service
competition between two supermarkets, or competition between different
market formats, such as the competition between, say, supermarkets, ware-
house clubs, and convenience stores. As Schumpeter (1950: 85) put it, refer-
ring to early twentieth-century retailing: “In the case of retail trade the
competition that matters arises not from additional shops of the same type,
but from the department stores, the chain store, the mail order house and the
supermarket.”
The competition “that matters,” then, is not about varying a few attributes
at the time, but rather is about devising “new ways of organizing things, new
sales–cost relationships, new methods of selling” (Bliss 1960: 72). This variety
of competing marketplace formats has resulted in big waves of innovation and
“creative destruction,” but, at any one point in time, multiple competing
formats coexist simply because the basis of competition is not, strictly
speaking, just about price. Warehouse clubs (Costco, Sam’s Club) and
42
Retailers as Market Makers
convenience stores (7-Eleven, AmPm) sell some of the same products, but do
not compete with each other in terms of price for those products. 7-Eleven, for
example, taps a market of people looking for convenience or, perhaps, of
people needing a place to “hang out.”
Price competition is less important between than within formats. But, even
within formats, competition is primarily between retailers (that is, market
makers) and not products. For example, price competition between super-
markets commonly takes the form of some offering “everyday low price”
and others subscribing to a “hi–low” pricing strategy involving low margins
on sales items and high margins on other goods.15 Although couched in terms
of prices, this, in reality, is a competition that applies less to products individ-
ually than to the retailers themselves.
The competition within market formats may also emphasize the range of
products being sold, or the level of service, rather than price, as the main
competitive tool. This kind of “horizontal” competition also exists between
very different types of markets. For example, a large supermarket, such as
Whole Foods, which offers a wide selection of organic products, may be
competing with a small grocery store, with a large chain like Wal-Mart, but
also with a neighborhood restaurant or an antique shop. Although it does not
sell similar products and services as the latter two, Whole Foods may, for
example, draw consumers away from other locations, or it may even capture
a larger portion of the consumer’s budget, thus shifting the structure of
preferences for specific goods and services.
Another very significant strategy in making consumer markets arises
between manufacturers (or merchandisers) of branded consumer goods and
retailers who sell these goods. The former typically advertise their goods
directly to the consumer and thus engage in market-making activities in
consumer markets. The latter may prefer to stock a different brand, including
their own store brand,16 but are compelled, at the same time, to offer those
brands for which consumers may have developed preferences based on mer-
chandisers’ advertisements. By offering their private-label goods at a slightly
lower price, retailers hope to create a multiple-product market for their own
brand, as well as to place a ceiling on the price that manufacturers and
merchandisers want for the brand-name goods that they sell to retailers.
While retailers try to create a marketplace that is in some sense unique, they
also share many market mechanisms that retailers commonly use. This mix of
unique and common elements is what creates the condition for competition.
Each seller tries to persuade consumers—by its pricing, product assortment,
store location, service, and many other elements—to shop in a specific way
that best suits the seller’s competence in selling. Because sellers are likely to
adopt organizational innovations from each other, they are also likely to
emulate each other’s market-making strategies. The most common forms of
43
Misha Petrovic and Gary G. Hamilton
Supplier markets
Unlike the horizontal competition in consumer markets, the competition in
supplier markets is typically referred to as being “vertical.” Competition in
supplier markets is a struggle amongst trading partners to define a market
structure for mutual exchange, a struggle to locate and refine the terms for
cooperation. This is competition amongst firms having different positions in a
supply chain, between, say, a manufacturer, a trading company, and a retailer.
The idea of verticality (for example, upstream and downstream) derives from a
production-centered image of the economy and does not capture the complex
firm and inter-firm structures that emerge in supplier markets and that we
discuss in Part Three of this book. Although rejecting the specific notion of
verticality, we shall nonetheless retain the label of vertical competition in
order to emphasize that such competitive relations often generate power
inequality amongst trading partners. In horizontal competition, since they
do not interact directly with each other, competitors do not have a position of
authority in relation to each other. In vertical competition between, for
instance, a retailer and its suppliers, one party in an exchange can directly
assert its market power to define the contractual foundations for exchange.
Economists conventionally define market power in terms of the firm’s
relative share of the market and its concomitant ability to influence the
market price for the product it is buying or selling. As noted above, this
definition makes market power into a market imperfection, a distortion from
the ideal type of perfectly competitive market where no market player, by
definition, can have (more than an infinitesimally small amount of ) market
power. In distorted markets, firms having high market power can exert various
types of price and non-price pressures on their suppliers and customers, and
44
Retailers as Market Makers
can also easily enter collusive agreements, tacit or explicit, with other such
firms, thus forming a cartel.
Such a definition not only presumes that, in the absence of market power,
markets would be “naturally” balanced between manufacturer’s supply and
consumer’s demand, but also misses the type of market power intrinsic in
market making. Only when market power is defined more broadly as the
ability to shape the exchange structure—that is, as market-making power—
does the notion of vertical competition become subsumed under a more
coherent framework of market-making competition. The competition within
supply chains is rarely limited to bargaining over the price of a predefined
homogenous good. In fact, price may be relatively unimportant. The struggle
also typically involves bargaining over issues such as how and when the
product will be delivered, who will take the responsibility for packaging and
presentation, advertising and warranty provisions, and even what the product
itself should consist of. Given this complexity, it should not be surprising that
trading partners compete not only to determine the outcomes of market
negotiations, but also over the right to set the rules and mechanisms by
which these outcomes are typically determined.
Market-making power, then, can be defined as the power to impose organi-
zation on the market, the power to define the shape of the market for oneself
and one’s trading partners. This outcome of market making can be thought of
more generally as “market organization.” Market organization is typically
more complex than simply the organization of one’s supply or distribution
channels. Even in the same industry, supply chains vary in many ways, and at
each link there are usually multiple players that can deliver comparable goods
or services. For instance, on the one hand, large retailers, as well as brand-
name merchandisers, typically line up many manufacturers to make such
products as apparel or footwear. By being able to pick and choose amongst a
number of manufacturers, trading companies, and logistic firms for particular
goods or services, large retailers and merchandisers are able to influence, if not
set, the terms (including price) for market exchanges, not only for themselves,
but also potentially for other players in the market as well. On the other hand,
manufacturers typically try to negotiate with multiple retailers, thereby diver-
sifying market outlets for their products.
Market institutions
Competition and cooperation between various firms in inter-firm markets, as
well as between retailers in consumer markets, result in the creation of a
highly sophisticated and complex institutional framework within which buy-
ing and selling of consumer goods occurs in the modern economy. Various
elements of such an institutional framework define and stabilize expectations
45
Misha Petrovic and Gary G. Hamilton
46
Retailers as Market Makers
47
Misha Petrovic and Gary G. Hamilton
state’s power to make markets and influence market makers is always limited by
the institutional complexity of markets and the degree of entrepreneurship and
competence needed for market-making success. The more complex the mar-
kets, the more limited the state capacity to make them “from above.” This
complexity is why direct state control or ownership of the retail sector almost
always fails to deliver, especially when compared to the state’s role in purely
“industrial” sectors such as resource extraction (oil, mining) or the provision of
basic infrastructure (power, telecommunications).
As they create market institutions out of the tools available to them in their
time and place, and in order to suit their organizational capacities, market
makers impose new organization on markets. The development and spread of
market institutions continually reconstruct the relationship between buyers
and sellers and thereby redefine the extent of the market.
In the following chapters, we examine such a co-evolution of market in-
stitutions, marketable products, market participants and market-making stra-
tegies. In Part Two, we address the evolution of consumer markets; in Part
Three, we trace the evolution of supplier markets; and in Part Four, we present
case studies combining both types of markets. By co-evolution, we mean that
institutions, products, participants, and strategies are all linked in a framework
of mutual causation. This framework of mutual causation is not obvious in the
abstract world of modern equilibrium economics, where homo economicus has
a constant presence across time and space, where firms are seen as production
functions or contract structures and not as actors, and where all markets,
whenever and wherever found, differ only in how close they approach the
“perfect” model of pure competition. Nor is this framework of mutual causa-
tion relevant for the productionist narratives, where production, and the
forces that shape production, are the only true factors in the evolution of
the economy. In contrast to these conventional approaches, we view all these
aspects of markets and market making as being in a constant process of
invention and re-invention.
For example, as Petrovic makes clear in Chapter 3, the institutionalization of
the supermarket format in the first half of the twentieth century necessitated
that manufacturers and retailers alike develop new strategies for selling pro-
ducts, that these products be reimagined and redesigned, and that consumers
start seeing themselves and the act of shopping in a different light. The co-
evolution of all these aspects of self-service shopping created an institution-
alized package that entrepreneurs could move across the retailing spectrum,
48
Retailers as Market Makers
49
2
Introduction
Many people living in Boston, Massachusetts, visit the Mall at Chestnut Hill
for their upmarket shopping. The Mall is located at the crossroads of Route 9
and Hammond Pond Parkway in Newton, one of the many upscale western
suburbs of Boston. The Mall follows the merchants’ dictum of locating stores
where it is easy for customers to drive to and park, with attractive merchandise
to make their visit a pleasant experience.
The Mall at Chestnut Hill is the present-day embodiment of the nineteenth
and early twentieth-century department store updated with ample parking for
today’s suburban shoppers. Richard Woodward (2007) of the New York Times
suggests that the present-day mall is but a modernized version of the Paris
arcades of the 1820s and 1830s, which he describes as follows:
The Mall at Chestnut Hill has the conventional two large anchor stores at
either end; in this case both anchors are Bloomingdale’s stores specializing in
different products at opposite ends of the two-storey enclosed atrium. Parking
spaces surround the Mall, and additional spaces are provided in a multi-storey
parking structure with a convenient covered bridge to the Mall. Beyond the
Bloomingdale anchors there are fifty-five other individual stores ranging from
Technology and Public Policy
Brooks Brothers, Coach, Ann Taylor, Barneys New York, Sur La Table, and
Apple Inc., to banks, three restaurants, and many small specialty shops.
Shoppers might have done pre-shopping on the Internet before coming to
the mall, some might have come in response to an advertisement sent to them
by mail, while others come just to have a good time enjoying the eye candy
and having lunch with a friend to cap off the outing. A few simply come and
sit in the overstuffed chairs in the lobby and watch the other shoppers.
Almost all shoppers come to the Mall with just a credit card—avoiding
carrying large amounts of cash—so that they can purchase whatever they
fancy, provided it is within their credit limit. When they enter the Mall,
they are probably unaware of the amount of technology and its sophistication
needed to keep the Mall and the stores running. Most of the technology is
hidden from view by careful design—the stores are providing an enticing
atmosphere with attractively displayed merchandise, not their back-office
technology. Technology is certainly visible in the Apple store, selling Apple
computers, iPhones, and iPods, along with the peripherals that make the iPod
the world’s most widely used MP3 player. But even here the WiFi system
connecting the displayed items to the Internet is happily running quietly in
the background throughout the store. Almost all of the technology necessary
for modern retailing was invented or developed outside the retail industry for
other applications or purposes. Over time, forward-looking merchants saw in
various technological advances an opportunity to enhance the retail shopping
experience, create new retail channels, and provide efficiently new and more
varied products. They adapted these technologies for use in their stores and
operations, forever altering the retail environment. In this way, technology
has become critical to modern retail market making.
Retail market makers who have exploited technology have done so in two
distinct ways. First, technology has been the basis for developing new retail
channels that are both pleasing and convenient for customers. This includes
enhancing traditional brick-and-mortar stores, as well as new channels such as
e-commerce, and Internet boutiques. Second, market makers have used new
technology to create more efficient supply channels expanding products for
retail selections, and to improve their organizational function. The technol-
ogy has put new products from around the world into retail stores and
expanded consumer choices at reasonable prices. This chapter will examine
the most prominent technologies responsible for today’s retail marketplace.
In later sections of this chapter we will trace the development of several
early disruptive technologies that have changed the face of American retailing
and manufacturing. We will start with the push of the railroad into the West
in the 1860s and the birth of mail-order market making by Montgomery
Ward’s in 1872. Then we will look at the effect of that most disruptive
transportation technology—the automobile—on big city retailing and the
51
Frederick H. Abernathy and Anthony P. Volpe
beginning of suburban shopping, lead first by Sears, Roebuck and Co. in the
1920s. In 1956 two other important disruptive technologies were introduced,
one quietly and the other with all of the fanfare of an Act of Congress pushed
by the then President Dwight Eisenhower. The first of these two technologies
was the shipping container, as well as the container ships that transport
material around the world very economically; the other is the US interstate
highway system, which was so important in providing Wal-Mart, as well as
other big-box retailers, with locations for stores during their rapid expansion
during the 1960s and 1970s. By being amongst the first in the 1980s to use bar-
code identifiers and the Internet for ordering, Wal-Mart revolutionized supply
chains and subsequently expanded its stores to become the world largest
retailer. Ports for container ships, railroads, and interstate highway connec-
tions are the basic triad of modern intermodal transportation of global com-
merce. But first we will review some of the important contemporary
technologies, working partially in the background, that make modern retail
shopping so attractive to customers and so transformative to the global
economy.
52
Technology and Public Policy
would all be shocked if we were to go into a store in the summertime and find
there was no air conditioning; it would probably be our last visit. In fifty or
sixty years the disruptive technology of air conditioning has gone from a
memorable experience to ubiquity. And that is the nature of most disruptive
technologies that are part of the standard retail environment.
Some technologies diffuse more rapidly—electric lighting, for example.
Edison first commercialized distributed electrical lighting in 1882. Less than
fifty years later, the construction of new power plants, fixtures, and bulbs had
led to electricity replacing gas and oil lighting in US cities and suburbs. John
Wanamaker, an important market-maker innovator in US retailing, installed
electrical lighting in his department store in Philadelphia in 1879 (Gibbons
1926: i. 218–19), having already installed arc lighting in outside window
displays in 1878. Soon after Edison’s demonstration of the system of electrical
lighting, Wanamaker went to Menlo Park, New Jersey, to visit Edison at his
research and development laboratory, and arranged for DC motors to power
ventilation fans in his stores, long before air was “conditioned.”
Along the way, it was necessary for public policy to provide enabling
legislation creating local and state building codes to ensure human safety
when electrical power was installed and used. We will see this time and time
again: public policy—national, local, or both—is necessary for the broad
diffusion of a new technology. We allow one electric power company to
have a monopoly of the means of distributing power to our homes. Imagine
the mess if there were multiple sets of power poles belonging to different
companies competing for our business. Some standards are set by an industry;
the typical standard screw base of an incandescent bulb—called the Edison
base—is just one example. It is true that there are several different light-bulb
bases, but most are for special lighting fixtures. It would be a household
nightmare if every manufacturer of lighting fixtures required a special bulb
base.1
In addition to lighting and air conditioning the elevator and the escalator
are two other common electrical devices in every modern multi-storey retail
building. Both were invented for other purposes: Elisha Otis invented a steam-
powered elevator with safety features in 1853 to move freight; modern eleva-
tors are now powered by electricity and controlled by elaborate computer
systems along with greatly enhanced safety features from those possible in
the 1853 patent for the elevator.2
Jesse Reno invented the escalator in 1892 as an electrically powered con-
veyor belt for moving people at Coney Island, New York. Harrods installed an
escalator in their already famous store in London amid great fanfare just two
years later. People movers were and are always important for retailers trying to
make it as painless as possible for customers to reach the upper floors without
the arduous climb of stairs. By 1900, department stores of ten storeys became
53
Frederick H. Abernathy and Anthony P. Volpe
common in the big cities of the USA, because growing land prices and increas-
ing population made large vertical retail spaces economically viable. Structural
steel, electric lighting, electric elevators, and electrically powered ventilation
made tall buildings possible. John Wanamaker, the famous merchant of the
nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, had a three-storey auditorium seat-
ing 1,300 people built into his new New York store in 1907 (Gibbons 1926:
ii. 109–10). In 1911 he topped all that had gone before by installing the
world’s “finest organ in the world” in the lavishly decorated marble-clad
149-foot-high Grand Court of his new 1911 building in Center City, Philadel-
phia. Macy’s now owns the store, and the organ has been refurbished and
expanded to 28,543 tubes (Whitney 2007). The store manager, James Kenny,
reports: “Every lunch time, people hear the organ and feel good—and people
are in a mind to shop when they’re feeling good. It is the ultimate feel-good
experience.” Visionary merchants such as Wanamaker quickly adopted new
technology to make the shopping experience inviting: concerts, restaurants,
and tearooms were added for shoppers’ convenience and enjoyment.
54
Technology and Public Policy
55
Frederick H. Abernathy and Anthony P. Volpe
modems” could transmit at 300 digital bits per second, and for the first time
serve as a dialer by translating digital computer commands directly into the
analog telephone network. It should be noted that the adoption of interna-
tional standards to ensure accurate data exchange between modems was
crucial in advancing this technology.
The credit industry, led by National BankAmericard, Inc. (NBI),3 leveraged
these technologies to automate the data-exchange process by developing a
fully electronic authorization system, which they called Base I (Mandell
1990: 62). An electronic card reader/dial terminal at the point of sale (POS)
could pull critical information from the “Magstripe,” including the issuing
bank’s phone number, the account number, and the expiration date; then
place a call answered by a computer; pass purchase information via touch
tone; and accept an authorization code—all in less than a minute. On the
receiving end, increasingly efficient databases could compare the queried
purchase amount to the customer’s available credit balance, and, if the
charge was approved, place immediate holds on the account. NBI’s success
with Base I in automating the authorization process led to the development
of Base II. This complementary touch-tone system allowed merchants to
capture sales electronically at the day’s end, eliminating the need to deposit
mountains of paper for processing at the acquiring bank. Acquiring fees were
reduced and accuracy was improved throughout the credit system. As a
result, merchant acceptance of credit cards continued to grow.
Beyond these benefits, electronic transaction networks also opened the door
to 24/7 credit-card use and Internet retailing. No longer constrained by bank-
ing hours, merchants were able to secure authorizations around the clock.
From the consumer’s perspective, plastic became a preferred substitute for
cash, day and night, on both weekdays and weekends. Encryption techniques
allow secure credit-card transactions online, and electronic signature has
become widely accepted. The result has been exciting new markets and retail
channels.
Next-generation POS systems are already being used in novel retail applica-
tions. Broadband lines and the Internet are permitting more real-time fraud
detection routines at the POS, without a noticeable increase in transaction
time. A growing number of chains use electronic signature pads to facilitate
credit-card use, eliminating the need for cashier identification. These rely on
LCD touch-screen technology. Symbol Technologies, now a subsidiary of
Motorola, is well known for its handheld POS terminals. Associates at Apple
Stores use these wireless devices to process customer credit-card purchases on
the spot, using IEEE 802.11 wireless protocols for speed and security. Never
needing to enter a checkout line enhances shoppers’ overall store experience.
Rental car companies use the same technology to close agreements within
56
Technology and Public Policy
57
Frederick H. Abernathy and Anthony P. Volpe
being made to solve this recognition problem. The researchers had selected a
box of cornflakes of a particular size as a representative target object. By
scanning laser beams onto the box in several directions and looking at the
scattered signal, they hoped to determine the size of the box. Other techni-
ques were being explored to recognize the name of the manufacturer; in this
case it was Kellogg. It is not easy to teach a computer system to find the name
of the manufacturer amongst all the writing on a breakfast food carton. So
their first attempts were just to recognize the K of the name, which is always
positioned prominently on the carton.
At the time, no one on the review panel was aware that the food market
retailers and their suppliers were already solving this problem in a beautifully
simple way, and without direct help from government of any level. Their work
resulted in the Universal Product Code (UPC), and its twelve numerical digit
bar code symbol that identifies the manufacturer and allows an exact descrip-
tion of the item. The focus of the group was solely on improving the efficiency
of supermarket checkout. It did not anticipate that it was about to create the
tool that would allow the entire retail supply chain to be rationalized. Alfred
D. Chandler Jr, writing on the jacket of the definitive book on the history of
the development of the bar code and the supermarket scanners systems,
Revolution at the Checkout Counter: The Explosion of the Bar Code, said:
This book tells in intriguing detail the almost unknown history of the coming of
the Universal Product Code (UPC)—an innovation that has transformed the
process of distribution and production as profoundly as the coming of the railroad
and the telegraph did more than a century ago. The book is essential reading for an
understanding of the evolution and impact of today’s information revolution.
(Brown 1997)
The bar code in the form that we all know, and the Universal Code Council
that administers the allocation of codes to manufacturers, were the product of
an initial meeting in 1969 of the Administrative Systems Committee of the
Grocery Manufacturers of America (GMA) and their counterparts in the food
market industry, the National Association of Food Chains (NAFC), to discuss a
product code for the food market industries. There was a general belief that a
machine-readable product code would increase substantially the productivity
of the front end of supermarkets. It was envisioned that each item offered for
sale would be marked with a code identifying the manufacturer and uniquely
describing the product. The code would be read by a scan system at the
checkout; the computer system would then rapidly look up from internal
files the name of the manufacturer, the product description, and the price.
Individual tagging of each item (item pricing) would no longer be needed for
checkout, and the labor cost saving from eliminating item pricing would be
available to finance the scanning equipment.
58
Technology and Public Policy
The motivation of grocery firms for such a system is obvious, while that of
the grocery manufacturers was equally pressing, if not as direct. There was talk
in Europe and in the USA that several high-tech firms were developing prod-
uct codes and scanning systems. The grocery manufacturers were worried that,
if a “universal code” were not developed and implemented across the indus-
try, some of the larger chains would select an identification code for their
products and then pressure their suppliers to use it on all the products shipped
to their stores. Such requirements would introduce huge inefficiencies in
suppliers’ product inventories and might result in Federal Trade Commission
objections that a manufacturer was providing services to one retailer not
available to others—something not allowed under the law.5 The way forward
then was clear: develop one product identification symbol and encourage all
food product manufacturers to provide it on their products. A reasonable code
for the retailer was one that could be scanned at the checkout counter or read
by a wand or entered in a register system by a clerk at a store without the
necessary technology. Naturally the scanning equipment would have to be
priced so that the hard saving from using the system would pay for the
equipment in a few years.
John T. Dunlop and Jan Rivkin (1997) describe the general economic and
technology conditions in the USA when the Universal Product Code (UPC)
was being developed. During the time of the UPC development, Dunlop had
been the Director of the Cost of Living Council appointed by President Nixon
to attempt to rein in the then raging national inflationary increases in the cost
of living. At that time the food industry was anxious to gain control of costs,
and product codes were one step in that direction. Their book also documents
the penetration of UPC bar codes into almost every product category in the
retail sector. By 1994, Food & Beverage had gone from being 100 percent of
all registrations to only about 28 percent of registrations; the remaining
registrations were in twenty-one different sectors, from Audio & Video to
Health & Beauty Aids. This diffusion into the overall retail sector was not
anticipated in 1969 at the first meeting of the principals of food manufacturers
and chain-store grocery operators; nor was it foreseen as late as June 1974,
when the first item bearing the UPC code, a package of Wrigley’s gum, passed
through the checkout scanner of the Marsh’s Supermarket in Troy, Ohio.
From the beginning the groups sponsoring the development of the UPC
aimed for a symbol code that would be in the public domain. They finally came
up with a twelve-digit bar code, which grew to fourteen digits in 2005 and can
now be found on virtually everything that we buy. Today the decision to
choose a series of bars surrounded by a white border to represent a series of
digits may seem an obvious one—obvious because it is simple and has been so
successful. Frozen-food products with small ice crystals on the package can be
scanned as well as a crumpled bag of pretzels or potato chips. We see how
59
Frederick H. Abernathy and Anthony P. Volpe
easily the bar symbols can be machine scanned when we do it ourselves at the
self-checkout counters at the local food and home improvement stores.
Clerks at big-box stores can now easily scan bags of lawn fertilizer with
portable wands that automatically sweep a red laser diode light beam across
the bars. The light reflected back to the wand creates a corresponding bright
and dark pattern on its receiver element, allowing internal deduction of the
numerical code that is printed on the base of the symbol. From the sophisti-
cated fundamental structure of the light and dark bars of the code, it is possible
for scan systems to distinguish the first digits—the manufacturer code—from
the last digits allocated to the item description, even when the code is scanned
backwards.
We have to admire the courage of the group from the GMA and NAFC
meeting in 1969: they set out to devise a product code and scanning system
for the food market industry by engaging the attention of the US electronic
industry. At the time they must have been encouraged by the 1969 moon
landing to believe that something seemingly as simple as codes and scanning
systems could be developed. The 1960s was after all the era of the laser, the
third generation of computers, and integrated circuits (H. B. O. Davis 1985:
140–5). The committee used its knowledge of the food industry wisely to insist
that detailed requirements for printing code labels be drawn up and tested on
actual products. Scanning trials were insisted on for assurance that the codes
could be successfully read 999 times out of 1,000 under normal conditions at
food markets. In the competition between the bull’s eye code of RCA and the
rectangular code of IBM, the winner was the latter’s rectangular bar code with
its specified clear surround.
It is hard to imagine now that the adoption of UPC at the checkout counter
was initially rather slow. The necessary scanning and computer equipment
then available was deemed very costly. Some food chains were worried that
not all food store product manufacturers would voluntarily adopt the UPC
code, making some item pricing of products necessary and thereby diminish-
ing labor cost saving and making scanning systems uneconomical. In fact
some states had consumer laws requiring individual price markings on each
item in the store, as Massachusetts still does.
By 1984, ten years after the first package of gum had passed a scanner in
March’s supermarket, only 33 percent of supermarkets had scanners (Haber-
man 2001: 27). But a tipping point was soon reached, and bar-code scanners
appeared in nearly every store. In the 1992 presidential campaign, the New
York Times, the Washington Post, and many other national publications ran
stories about President George H. W. Bush’s apparent wonderment upon
seeing a new supermarket scanner operating at a National Grocers’ Association
convention in Orlando, Florida (Brinkley 1992). Whether the President was
really seeing a scanner for the first time is not the point of the story for us now.
60
Technology and Public Policy
It is, rather, that by 1992 almost all newspaper readers were familiar with bar
codes and scanners in food stores; hence the President’s reaction suggested
that he was out of touch with everyday life in the country. Today bar codes
and scanners are near universal in mass retailing, not only in the USA, but
around the world. As consumers, we typically see only a few aspects of the use
of bar codes. For example, the item description that accompanies the sales
price on the printed sales receipts for every retail purchase comes from bar-
code look-up tables. Later in this chapter we will address the role of bar codes
in improving the efficiency of product supply chains and the prominent role
Wal-Mart has played in driving this process.
A succession of disruptive technologies has transformed retailing from the
general stores away from the city supplied by manufacturers in the cities to the
multiple overlapping forms of retailing we have today. First we begin by
visiting the history of early disruptive technologies, the railroad that gave us
mail-order retailing, and then the automobile that led to suburban mall
retailing. We will then explain how the disruptive technologies of bar codes
and the Internet, coupled with containers and container shipping, railroads,
and trucking, have helped to revolutionize worldwide product sourcing. In
1956, when container shipping started and Congress passed and President
Eisenhower signed the bill starting the Interstate highway system, no one saw
how these two events would change where goods would be manufactured.
These events allowed electronic and other manufacturers to create new mar-
kets for parts and assembly that would never have existed without these
disruptive shipping technologies.
61
Frederick H. Abernathy and Anthony P. Volpe
Illinois, Ohio, and further west (Soloman 2001: 40). Because of the railroad
and the corresponding westward expansion of the US population, Chicago
became a dynamic and important city, growing from an estimated population
of only 100 in 1830, to 29,963 in 1850, to 298, 977 in 1870, to 503,185 in
1880, and to 1,099,850 in 1890.6 By 1872, Chicago had many retail establish-
ments catering to the local demand for clothing and practical items of every-
day use. In 1872, a young clerk with an entrepreneurial spirit named
Montgomery Ward was working for the prominent and expanding store
Field, Palmer, and Leiter (FPL). The “Field” partner of FPL was the Marshall
Field whose fame in Chicago as a merchant grew to allow him to open the
then largest department store in the world on State Street in Chicago in 1907.
As a clerk for FPL, Montgomery Ward traveled by train and horse and buggy to
service the country stores that were the major clients of FPL.
He found that the country store, with its pot-bellied stove and cracker barrel, was a
snug place for farmers to sit and swap gossip on stormy days. But it was not so
comfortable for the farmer when he went to the counter to buy goods. Prices were
high and the choice of goods small. When the farmer complained, the storekeeper
pointed out that he had to buy what the wholesaler offered at the prices set by the
wholesaler. The farmer could take it or leave it and, since the storekeeper usually
was the only merchant in the area, the farmer had to take it. (Latham 1972: 3)
Ward understood the farmers’ and the shop owners’ dilemma. The long
chain from manufacturer to wholesaler, to jobber, and finally to the retailer at
the crossroad store had too many steps in the supply chain, each step marking
up the product to cover its costs. He conceived of direct mail-order sales. He
would be located in Chicago close to manufacturers and wholesalers; and by
combining many mail orders together he could buy in bulk at a discount and
sell directly to the farmers. He would write a catalog with detailed listing of the
items for sale, at a fixed price, with a money-back guarantee if the customers
were not satisfied with the merchandise. Ward began with two partners and
just $1,600 in August 1872. An early catalog listed 163 items, ranging from
yard goods of flannel and jeans fabric to an ostrich plume. In time, the
catalogue expanded to contain more than 130,000 items in 1967 (Latham
1972: 91).
There is always a problem of locating potential customers, and the early
mail-order company was no exception. There was certainly no easy way to
find listings of people in the farming communities in the rural west. Ward
solved this problem by sending his catalog—in the beginning really just a list
of items offered with their price—to the local Granges. The first local Granges,
founded as the National Grange of the Patrons of Husbandry in 1867, were
established as social and educational organizations but rapidly became politi-
cal organizations for the voice of the Western farmers to protest against the
62
Technology and Public Policy
abuses of the day. Ward was familiar with Granges from his sales trips in the
farm communities for FLT. Ward encouraged the local Granges to aggregate
their members’ orders and send a single order to Montgomery Ward, who
would ship the order to the nearest rail station c/o the Grange. Since the
minimum rail shipping order then was 100 pounds, this aggregation of indi-
vidual orders minimized the shipping cost to the farmers. The high cost of rail
shipments was always a concern to the farmers, both for the things they
purchased and for shipping their farm products to markets. The railroads at
this time had monopoly control of shipping to and from the rural farms. The
farmers, through their Granges, lobbied successfully in 1887 for a federal law
establishing the Interstate Commerce Commission (ICC) to regulate railroad
shipping rates.
At that time postal mail was delivered only to the nearest post office.
Direct rural delivery to the home was years off; free city delivery of mail
would come only in 1863. The consumers’ cost of mail-ordered items is the
sum of the merchants’ selling price and the cost of delivery. Even after the
ICC had regulated freight rates, farmers complained that they were poorly
and expensively served. Merchandise could be shipped by freight at a cost by
weight and distance, with a 100-pound minimum charge; by express with
one of the many express companies with unregulated rates; and by US Post,
with a 4-pound limit. Post was by far the cheapest, but not many orders
could meet the low weight limit. And for all three modes of shipment the
package was delivered only to the post office or train station. In many
communities the rail station was the post office and often the general store
as well. If a farmer bought from Ward’s, his local merchant and postmaster
would know. But farmers often needed credit at the general store to buy
essential items before the harvest, and they had reason to worry that buying
from Ward’s might jeopardize their credit.
The local merchants in the rural communities did not take kindly to their
customers going around them to Ward’s for dry goods and other staples of
farm life, but they could not match the prices offered by Ward. As Ward’s
volume of business expanded, prices would fall because of Ward’s volume
discounts from manufacturers. Ward’s prices in 1878 were lower than they
had been in 1872 (Latham 1972: 10). Every few years the volume of business
expanded, forcing Ward to move to ever-larger quarters along with expanded
catalog offerings. Ward offered almost everything: from farm machinery,
saddles and harnesses, to fine fashions for the ladies. Business grew, and by
1908 Ward’s mail-order house in Chicago contained more than 2 million
square feet of space, with other service centers in other Western cities.
While Ward’s was expanding, competition grew. Sears, Roebuck and Co.
grew from Richard Sears’s small operation of selling watches to other rail
station agents in 1886 into a firm with a large general catalog in 1896. This
63
Frederick H. Abernathy and Anthony P. Volpe
was also the year that rural free delivery (RFD) was first tried in a few regions of
the country on a very limited experimental basis. The sales of both Ward’s
and Sears were constrained because of the inflated expense of shipping orders
to rural customers. John Wanamaker, the famous Philadelphia merchant,
appointed Post Master General in 1889 in the Benjamin Harrison administra-
tion, tried without success to obtain Congress’s approval in 1891 for an
expanded RFD. In 1890, 1891, and 1892 Wanamaker (Gibbons 1926:
i. 282–3) also sought permission for the Postal Service to offer parcel post,
without success.7 When he was asked: “Mr. Wanamaker, why can you not
inaugurate parcels post?” He answered: “There are five insurmountable ob-
stacles: first is the American Express Company; second, the United States
Express Company; third, the Adams Express Company; fourth, the Wells-
Fargo Express Company; fifth, the Southern Express Company” (Gibbons
1926: i. 283).
Parcels Post became an official activity of the Postal Service only in 1913,
with approximately 300 million parcels handled in the first six months. The
weight limit was upped from the original 4 to 11 pounds, with increases to
20 pounds soon after (National Postal Museum 2008). The Parcel Post weight
limit in 2010 is 70 pounds, but other delivery systems such as UPS allow
heavier and larger packages.
64
Technology and Public Policy
store they could actually touch the fabric and try on apparel before purchas-
ing, or get the feel of a hammer or wrench. This was not possible in a mail-
order-only business.
General Wood was unable to convince Ward’s management of the validity
of his vision for retail merchandising—Ward’s probably believed that it
should stick to its core competencies—mail-order retailing. Wood left Ward’s
in 1924 and went to Sears, first as head of factory operations. Sears’s first retail
store experiment followed in 1925 and was a huge success, leading to a
dramatic expansion of retail stores. By 1928 Sears had opened 192 retail stores,
and General Wood was promoted to president. General Wood imagined Sears
retail stores would carry both hard and soft goods and be located not in the
center of the city but near its perimeter, with easy access by car. He believed
that people in the suburbs would always need shoes and hammers. By 1931
Sears had more than 350 retail establishments in addition to its thriving mail-
order business. Ward’s soon followed the Sears retailing approach and opened
its own stores, generally in small towns, but it was never able to catch up with
Sears and closed for good in 2001.
The years of the Great Depression and the Second World War saw a few major
changes in retailing technology, linked to the rise of supermarkets and the
completely new world of packaged consumer goods and retail hardware these
new self-service stores required (see Petrovic, Chapter 3 this volume). But in
1956 two seemingly disconnected events occurred that were to have profound
effects on modern retailing and global sourcing of retail products: the inter-
state highway system and the shipping container.
65
Frederick H. Abernathy and Anthony P. Volpe
66
Technology and Public Policy
Shipping containers
The second great disruptive innovation of 1956 was the birth of shipping with
ocean-going containers. There have been articles in our newspapers for dec-
ades about the importance of intermodal transportation hubs bringing sub-
way, rail, and surface bus service together at city centers. For the global flow of
manufactured goods and produce, the ocean link with rail and trucking has
been the most difficult to achieve, and it took most of the post-Second World
War era to succeed.
Ocean-going containers, like most technological innovations important to
retailing, did not begin with the goal of improving the way goods are shipped
across the oceans. Rather, it all began when Malcom McLean, the owner of
one of the largest trucking firms in the US in the early 1950s, attempted to find
a cheaper way to ship products to New York from the South. Because the
Interstate Commerce Commission (ICC) set trucking rates for all firms, a
persistent focus on reducing operating costs was a primary path to higher
profits and further expansion. In 1953 McLean had the revolutionary idea of
sending his trailer trucks from North Carolina to New York and Boston by
putting them on old Second World War cargo ships. The ICC had jurisdiction
over costal shipping and had allowed shipping rates to be significantly lower
than highway trailer shipping because water way shipping was slower.
McLean was the only person who saw the value of this rate discrepancy, and
he moved to take advantage of it. The Port of New York Authority was looking
to expand its activities and welcomed McLean to create a terminal at the
Newark docks. McLean first thought to send trailers onto the ships, then
trailers without their wheels, and finally special containers designed to allow
them to be stacked and lifted from and onto trailers at each end of the sea
trip. The first test of this final concept was held in April 1956 with the sailing
of a converted Second World War tanker, the Ideal-X.
The first voyage was from Port Newark to Houston with fifty-eight contain-
ers on board. Special extra-large dockside cranes had to be placed on shore to
load and unload the 33-foot containers, but the trip was a great success. And,
as Levinson (2006: 52) wrote:
For McLean, though, the real triumph came only when the costs were tallied.
Loading loose cargo on a medium-size cargo ship cost $5.83 per ton in 1956.
McLean’s experts pegged the cost of loading the Ideal-X at 15.8 cents per ton.
With numbers like that, the container seemed to have a future.
The entrepreneurial energy, drive, and skill required by McLean to make this
into a successful venture is described in detail in Marc Levinson’s marvelous,
insightful, and heavily documented book, The Box (2006).
67
Frederick H. Abernathy and Anthony P. Volpe
In 1956 few might have been willing to bet that McLean and others would
be able to overcome the objections of the International Longshoremen’s and
Warehousemen’s Union, the various port authorities, the ICC, the railroads,
and the local communities that had to allow the huge areas needed for current
intermodal port facilities. But succeed they did, and now the biggest ports in
the world are no longer London or New York. Singapore, Shanghai, and Hong
Kong are the top three in terms of containers handled per year. According to
the list of busiest container ports, in 2007 Singapore was reported to have
handled 27,000,000 TEUs (20-foot equivalent units).8
The two largest US ports, Los Angeles and Long Beach, were numbers 13 and
15 on the list of the busiest container ports in 2007; New York/New Jersey was
number 19 with less than 20 percent of the volume of Singapore. The port
facilities to handle millions of containers per year can only be called gigantic.
The cranes that lift the containers from the ship one at a time must be able to
lift the 30,480 kg of a fully loaded container and place it on a trailer that drives
on the roadway between the legs of the crane.
In 2008 the largest ship in the worldwide container fleet was the Emma
Maersk, a part of the Maersk Line fleet.9 The ship is 397 meters long and
56 meters wide. It can carry 10,500 TEUs, according to the company, but
others list the capacity as 15,200 TEUs. The weight of the ship is about 1.5
times the weight of a modern USA aircraft carrier. The ship has 1,000 plugs for
refrigerated containers, making it possible to ship vast quantities of meat and
produce around the world. This class of vessel expends just 1 kWh of energy to
transport one ton a distance of 66 kilometers; a jumbo jet, in comparison,
could transport only one ton of cargo 0.5 kilometers on 1 kWh of energy. In
other words, the largest and newest ocean-going container vessel is 132 times
as efficient in using energy to transport cargo as a modern airplane carrying
freight. The ship requires a crew of only thirteen, making the operating cost
very low. Worldwide shipment by container continued to expand, rising from
137.2 million TEUs in 1995 to 417 million TEUs in 2006, while the share
of shipping to and from the US ports fell from 16.3 percent in 1995 to only
11.1 percent in 2006 (US Department of Transportation 2008).
68
Technology and Public Policy
69
Frederick H. Abernathy and Anthony P. Volpe
trains. This shipping of goods of all kinds happens without the product being
touched by human hands from the factory in South Asia or the farm in Chile
to the nearby retail store. The present volume of global product sourcing has
been made possible in large part because of international standards of all sorts
of systems: hardware, software, electronics, commercial laws, and clear com-
munications back and forth along the entire sourcing channel. International
trade benefits from vast prior investments in multi-purpose infrastructures.
70
Technology and Public Policy
71
Frederick H. Abernathy and Anthony P. Volpe
different books or SKUs on their shelves, but for a store it is important to know
how many units they have of each SKU. A single volume of a given book is
generally enough for a library, but more than one T-shirt of a given size is
absolutely essential for the store. To meet expected demand with an adequate
number of units across an entire apparel collection is a staggering task. Over
10 percent of material in the classic book on retailing used at the Harvard
Business School in the late 1930s is devoted to Merchandise Control (McNair,
Gragg, and Teele 1937: 211–62), the term used then for inventory control. If a
food store has sold all its cans of a particular kind of soup, it can often get more
in the next-day delivery from a chain’s warehouse/distribution center, where
the necessary inventory of high turnover items is carried for next-day delivery.
Most food stores’ items outside of produce are, in fact, replenishable items.
That is not the case for department stores: only a fraction of their items are
replenishable. Before bar codes and lean retailing, a department store might
need to carry a substantial inventory of popular basic items such as jeans and
underwear on the shelves of the store, in the back room, and in the central
warehouse/distribution center. This is no longer the case.
Modern lean retailing requires detailed and complex relationships between
a retailer and each of his suppliers of basic items (Abernathy et al. 1999). The
retailer’s central computer places orders with a supplier’s computers on Sun-
day evening for a specified number of units of each SKU for each store in the
area served by that retailer’s distribution center. The manufacturer must pick
and pack the order for each store, placing the items in a carton for each store,
with the correct bar-coded shipping label. The code on the shipping container
is a scannable bar code but not in the UPC format. The code on the carton
designates the particular store for which it is intended. All the cartons for the
many stores are loaded onto a trailer for delivery to the retailer’s distribution
center. Each distribution center might service 100 or more individual stores.
A trailer backs into a specified loading dock of the distribution center at a
time prespecified, to the minute. A portion of the distribution center’s power-
driven conveyor system extends into the manufacturer’s trailer, and the driver
unloads the cartons onto the conveyor. As a given carton moves along the
power-driven conveyors, laser beams scan the five visible surfaces of the
carton looking for the bar code containing the precise code to allow automatic
sorting. Gates automatically switch the carton onto the trailer designated for
that store. More automated paperwork is actually done than has been just
described; for example, there must be an open-to-buy order from the retailer to
the manufacturer, etc., before any shipment will be accepted. The checking,
verifying, and recording that at one time was all hand paper work is now
accomplished with bar codes, laser scans, and computers. Cartons go from the
manufacturer’s distribution center to the designated store’s trailer without
human intervention except for loading on and off the conveyor on opposite
72
Technology and Public Policy
The retailers do have memories. They remember the armies of stock clerks stamp-
ing prices on every candy bar, and then restamping them when the next sale came
along—every one of them! They remember the checkout clerks trying to read the
handwritten pricing on those packages of T-bone steak, and reading $1.45 instead
of $4.45, and losing three dollars on every sale. And they remember taking endless
inventories; filling out paper reorder pads so that they’d know how much to
reorder; and the huge amount of counting that went on as merchandise was
received in the stores. All that tedious effort! . . . And the manufacturers remember.
They remember receiving all those paper orders through the mail. Processing the
returns and reductions when we didn’t ship exactly what the customer had asked
73
Frederick H. Abernathy and Anthony P. Volpe
for because we couldn’t keep track of all customers’ numbering schemes, and we
transcribed those orders incorrectly as they came in the door. And remember how
difficult it was to track all of the inventory in our warehouses as it was picked and
loaded onto our customer’s trucks?
74
Technology and Public Policy
75
This page intentionally left blank
Part Two
Making Consumer Markets
This page intentionally left blank
3
Introduction
In 1953, the Italian business consultant Ezio Diotallevi described to his Amer-
ican colleagues the main reason why the concept of self-service could not
succeed in Italy:
How would our public react to the mute coldness of a [self-service] store in which
there is a complete lack of the cordial incentive to buy and the exciting stimulus of
discussion and where the psycho-economic aspect of buying and selling is reduced
to a dialogue—and a silent one at that—between the buyer and the inanimate
goods. (Report on the A.T. 45/157 USA Mission, Sept.–Oct. 1953, 29, quoted in
R. T. Davis 1959: 44)
His opinion, apart from its rhetorical flourish, was not unusual amongst
West European businessmen and policy experts. The European housewife,
they reasoned, would neither put up with the impersonal shopping environ-
ment of the American-style supermarket, nor accept standardized, pre-pack-
aged, canned, and frozen items in place of the variety of fresh products
available in traditional European stores and open markets (Dunn 1962).
Moreover, even if she did want to convert to such an unfamiliar method of
buying, this would have had little practical consequence: the lack of the
supporting infrastructure, the limited size of retail stores and of living quar-
ters, the low rate of ownership of cars and refrigerators, and the absence of a
sizable middle class, all conspired against adopting an American style of
consumption.
Only a few years later, in the late 1950s, a “self-service revolution” swept
through most of Western Europe. Between 1953 and 1959, the number of self-
service stores increased from 229 to 1,663 in France, from 119 to 1,785 in the
Netherlands, and from 203 to 17,132 in West Germany (Henksmeier 1960).
Misha Petrovic
Even in Italy, where the adoption of self-service did not take off until the late
1960s, its slow spread could be traced to highly restrictive municipal regula-
tions and the lobbying efforts of small retailers rather than to the alleged lack
of acceptance by consumers (Sternquist and Kacker 1994).
The self-service revolution of the 1950s was not the first time that a marketing
concept that originated in the USA spread to Europe. By the beginning of the
twentieth century the USA lead in advertising, selling, and other mass-marketing
techniques was already obvious to many European observers, and since that time
the flow of marketing innovations across the Atlantic has been mostly unidirec-
tional. The elements of American consumer markets were at the same time envied
and celebrated, detested and reviled, but most of them eventually found their
place in the evolving European consumer society. Only in the years after the
Second World War, however, did the US model of consumer society become the
obvious and most visible standard of global modernity. The “American way of
life,” with its emphasis on the mass ownership of cars and appliances and mass
consumption of standardized and affordable goods, emerged as the immediate
target of modernization efforts for West European nations, and, a decade later, for
Japan as well. It also became a major weapon in the Cold-War propaganda, where
the deficiencies of the Soviet system were most plainly visible in its failure to
deliver attractive consumer goods to its own population, let alone export them
to the rest of the world. (M. I. Goldman 1960; De Grazia 2005)
80
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
the world population has access, though still limited, to the world of modern
goods and services.
While the processes of globalization of modern retailing and of the spread of
the “American model” have largely been one and the same, they have rarely
involved, at least until very recently, direct internationalization efforts by
American retailers. Compared to most other sectors, retailing shows a
surprising lack of concentration and of the global reach typical of most
major multinational firms. Out of the top forty largest retailers in the world,
each with annual sales of over $20 billion in 2008, over half operate only in
their headquarters’ country, or in a small number of neighboring countries
(Deloitte 2009). This limited reach is particularly characteristic for US retailers.
Fifteen out of the top forty global retailers are headquartered in the USA, but
only three of those have operations outside North America.2 The globalization
of retailing, insofar as it involves direct investment and the concomitant
replication of stores and concepts by large multinational retailers, is still in
its early stages. The story presented in this chapter, accordingly, follows two
parallel strands. One of them deals with the global spread of modern, “Amer-
icanized” formats of consumer goods markets; the other, with the somewhat
limited role that major multinational retailers have played in making and
replicating those markets across national and regional borders.
Today, there exists a considerable literature on the globalization of retailing,
but most of it is focused either on the internationalization strategies of retail
firms or on changes and reactions within national retail sectors. This chapter
has a different focus: on how the market-making efforts of retailers trans-
formed consumer goods markets around the world.3 In line with the rest of
the book, it examines those market makers that are commonly described as
retailers—that is, those that sell goods and services directly to consumers
through owned or franchised outlets. These retailers are the “full package”
market makers of consumer goods markets, compared to those engaging in
consumer marketing but not operating retail stores, such as many consumer
goods manufacturers and brand-name managers, or those selling consumer
services but not goods, such as retail banks, hotels, airlines, and amusement
parks. The two latter groups are obviously highly visible in the contemporary
global economy, contain many of the world’s largest firms, and have played a
major role in the development of global consumer markets. Despite following
only one thread of the overall complex process of making, maintaining,
emulating, and replicating consumer markets, limiting one’s attention to
retailers has a distinct advantage of focusing on the most complex type of
such markets, in which selling a wide variety of goods and services is com-
bined with the direct contact with the consumer.
The first part of the chapter describes the emergence and evolution of the
standardized “packages” of market mechanisms in the USA. Replication and
81
Misha Petrovic
82
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
83
Misha Petrovic
84
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
of the early 1900s came to be widely different by the end of the Second World
War. Department stores based their success on selling a wide range of goods
to a wide range of consumers and making the buying process streamlined
and easy. They utilized economies of scale in purchasing, and were ready
to experiment with new methods of marketing and management. These
features placed them at the center of the movement to create new mass
markets for consumption goods and would continue to define such a move-
ment throughout the twentieth century, long after department stores them-
selves had lost their central position to supermarkets, shopping malls, and
big-box stores.
As they evolved from drapery stores to fashion houses to true general
merchandisers, department stores managed to redefine the world of goods
for their customers. Even if they never truly democratized the world of con-
sumption, as most of their wares were priced out of the reach of most people
most of the time, they did democratize the access to the world of goods,
through creating new habits of browsing and shopping. In the market based
on specialized small shops, where the process of buying was highly interac-
tional, and thus embedded in social custom and status distinctions, the world
of goods remained highly segmented. The department store managed to
reorganize large parts of this world, putting an ever broader range of goods
on the single continuum of affordability. Consumers who would have never
dared to enter a piano store or inquire about a price of a cashmere shawl in an
upscale specialty shop, could now see pianos and cashmere shawls alongside
thousands of other products in the department store, each with a clear and
posted price, and contemplate saving for one, especially if they could find
them on one of the seasonal sales or clearance events.
85
Misha Petrovic
with each other less on price and more through offering an ever-expanding
range of free services. They took the “high road” that would gradually
transform them into high-margin high-service specialty stores, often with
many leased departments selling branded goods. This type of retail format
would survive throughout the twentieth century, with well-known names
such as Macy’s and Nordstrom’s, Harrods and Debenhams, Galeries Lafay-
ette and Le Printemps, Isetan and Takashimaya still active today, but it will
never again play such a central role in consumer goods markets as it did at
the beginning of the twentieth century.
The other, “low road,” which consisted of selecting a smaller range of
cheaper, standardized goods and selling them at low margins but with a
high turnover, might have looked much less promising to the established
department store operators at the time. Yet, it gradually became established
as the core of all developed retailing systems and remains so today, repre-
sented by retail giants such as Wal-Mart, Carrefour, and Tesco. In the USA, this
path was initially taken by variety stores, such as Woolworth’s, Grant’s, and
Kresge’s, and small grocery stores selling packaged goods such as A&P, Kroger,
and Safeway; it was then successfully emulated and expanded by “junior”
department stores such as J. C. Penney’s, and mail-order catalogs turned into
store operators such as Sears and Montgomery Ward’s.
The secret of these retailers’ success was not in their focus on a range of
merchandise that was somehow more central and more representative of
consumer taste than that of upscale department stores. In fact, such a
merchandise mix evolved only gradually and was defined by the main
operators’ success as much as being the precondition of such a success.
Rather, the main advantage of these retailers was in their ability to address
the second major limit of the department store expansion: standardizing the
market and bringing it closer to the consumer through a rapid replication of
outlets. The early twentieth-century US department store was too large, too
idiosyncratic, and too embedded in its downtown surroundings to be easily
replicated. A few large downtown stores tried to overcome these limits by
opening smaller suburban branches. Others financed or acquired depart-
ment stores in smaller towns. Yet the real success of department store
replication had to await the maturation of planned shopping centers in
the 1960s, and by that time department stores had already been relegated
to a peripheral role in the American landscape of consumer goods markets.
In contrast, the ability of the variety and grocery-store operators to replicate
rapidly their more modest stores, and thus bring their market format to a
much broader range of consumers, enabled them to assume a central place
in making consumer goods markets, first in the USA, and then around the
world.
86
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
87
Misha Petrovic
grocery chain stores had already somewhat declined from its 1930 peak, there
were still 417 A&P stores in Buffalo, NY, 300 in Cleveland, 289 in Newark, NJ,
and 104 in Providence, RI, in addition to 695 stores in Chicago and 370 in
Detroit. In the same year, Safeway operated 504 stores in Los Angeles, 262 in
San Francisco, and 107 in Denver, while American Stores had 721 stores in
Philadelphia alone (Zimmerman 1939).
The standardization of chain-store elements and policies was achieved
through the weeding-out of unprofitable and badly managed stores as well
as through strict operating instructions and manuals and frequent inspection.
The importance of standardization can be understood only in relation to the
high turnover rates of retail stores in general, and grocery stores in particular.
Lebow (1948: 13) estimated that:
In the first 39 years of this century, some 16 million businesses opened their doors
and in the same 39 years, over 14 million closed up. All but a small fraction of
these were small businesses and all but a tiny percentage were engaged in distribu-
tion. For the past 50 years only seven out of ten grocers have reached their second
year and only four out of ten reach their fourth year.
GENERAL-MERCHANDISE CHAINS
Variety chains evolved from the humble beginnings of small-town five-and-
dime stores of the late nineteeneth century. In these stores every item cost
either 5 or 10 cents, and the assortment depended on whatever bargains the
store owner could secure from wholesalers. Catering to the small-town resi-
dents and immigrant masses in large port cities, five-and-dime stores became
known in the 1880s as the poor person’s department stores (Raucher 1991). By
the turn of the century, a few of these stores had expanded rapidly by adopting
the chain-store format. Woolworth’s, the largest such chain, operated more
than 600 stores in 1910, and was the second biggest retailer in the nation after
Sears. By 1920, most five-and-dime stores (but not Woolworth’s) adopted the
moniker of “limited price variety stores” as they sold an increasing proportion
of higher priced articles. In 1929, 89 percent of the variety-store sales was
captured by chain-store operators, with more than half of this accounted for
by just two major operators, Woolworth’s and S. S. Kresge. Variety stores had a
large impact on the reorganization of the world of products. They pushed
further the logic of selling “affordables,” not just by selling cheap articles but
by helping mass consumers recognize an increasing variety of products as
affordable and comparable in price. The marketing strategy of the limited
88
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
89
Misha Petrovic
90
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
91
Misha Petrovic
By the early 1960s, the main elements of this transformation had been
established in American retailing, creating a set of retail formats that, in
most aspects, would be recognizable today. Small chain grocery stores were
replaced by large, self-service supermarkets. Large planned shopping centers
offered a proper home to both general merchandise and specialty chain-store
operators, and gave a new lease on life to the department store. And, some of
the most successful general merchandisers and specialty-store operators that
did not participate in the shopping-center boom developed the free-standing
big-box store format. Apart from their differences, all three formats were based
on combining strategies of scrambled merchandising, a dramatic increase in
size, and simplification and standardization of the selling process, most nota-
bly through “self-service.” All of them were also highly replicable and, as they
spread throughout the American landscape, they for the first time crossed that
critical threshold at which there were enough modern retailers in contact with
each other to assure rapid adoption of innovations.
92
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
93
Misha Petrovic
94
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
expansion into non-food lines, if much more cautiously. Health and beauty
aids, magazines, books and stationery, toys, soft goods, housewares, and
cleaning products, all found their way into supermarkets in the 1930s and
1940s, and in 1954 a study of non-food merchandising found the majority
of supermarkets carrying extensive lines of these products (Super Market
Merchandising 1954).
SELF-SERVICE AS SELF-SELLING
In addition to size, location, and store appeal, and the breadth of the mer-
chandise mix, the supermarket’s other major draw for the consumer was its
emphasis on self-service. The idea of a self-service grocery store had been tried
to some degree many times before, most famously in Clarence H. Saunders’s
franchised Piggly Wiggly stores.13 The synergies achieved by combining the
self-service format with store size and a broad merchandise assortment sur-
prised even the most enthusiastic early operators of supermarkets, let alone
the more conservative chain-store operators. The less sales service they were
offered, and the greater the variety of merchandise, the more consumers
bought on each trip to the supermarket. And this rule held for non-food as
much as for food items, for packaged articles as much as for produce, and even,
as A&P and Safeway were soon to find out, for store brands as for nationally
advertised ones. At the beginning of the supermarket development it was
often assumed that the success of self-service represented little more than
the trade-off consumers were willing to make between retail service and low
prices. Only gradually did it become clear that, for most customers, self-service
meant better service. Early surveys of consumer behavior show that the free-
dom from high-pressure selling and the “leisure of choice” figured quite
prominently in consumers’ preference for shopping at supermarkets (Regan
1963; Bucklin 1972). Shorter queues were another major advantage of the
supermarket. Although initially viewed with suspicion, by the late 1930s self-
service was already considered a convenience, rather than a matter of neces-
sity, and was featured prominently in supermarkets’ advertising (Zimmerman
1955).
The adoption of self-service signified the transition from the focus on
interactional aspects of selling, defined as a diffuse set of retail services
provided by store clerks, to a focus on creating and improving the features of
the marketplace. Now to a large extent it was the consumer who performed
traditional “selling services” for herself, searching for products, and compar-
ing their prices, quality, and characteristics; yet these activities were per-
formed in a new type of market structure defined and controlled more than
ever by the retailer. The commitment to the self-service format also led super-
markets to reorganize the physical aspect of the store—the architecture, signs,
entrances, fixtures, displays, shopping carts, checkout points, and so on—in a
95
Misha Petrovic
way that would be emulated by most “discount” retailers. In this context, the
rise of general-merchandise discounters in the USA, from the early leaders
such as Korvette and Vornado, to the 1960s creations such as Kmart, Target,
Woolco, and Wal-Mart, represented little more than an adaptation of super-
markets’ retailing strategies to an assortment of products—apparel, luggage,
home furnishings, toys—traditionally sold in department stores (McNair and
May 1976).
THE MALL
Shopping centers may be the most ubiquitous aspect of the contemporary
retail landscape in the USA. Loosely defined as clusters of retail stores,
planned, owned, and managed as a unit, they capture more than half of all
non-automotive retail sales and employ one in every fifteen Americans
(Cohen 2002). Depending on the definition, there were anywhere between
60,000 and 100,000 shopping centers in the USA in 2008, ranging from small-
scale neighborhood centers (strip malls) to super-regional malls often exceed-
ing a million square feet of retail space. Although the history of planned retail
centers in the USA goes back to the late 1920s, the shopping center boom that
would transform American retailing started only in the mid-1950s, and was
closely related to the government tax policy (the Accelerated Depreciation Act
of 1954), making development of large centers a particularly attractive busi-
ness proposition for real-estate developers, including the financial giants such
as Prudential and Equitable (Hanchett 1996, 2000). In 1955, there were still
only about twenty large regional shopping centers in the USA, all of them of
the open-air variety. In 1956, Victor Gruen built the first fully enclosed
shopping mall, Southdale near Minneapolis, which featured what was to
become the classic mall format with two department stores as anchors and a
two-level parking space (see Hardwick 2004). By the end of that year the
number of large centers in operation had more than doubled. Ten years
later, there were nearly 400 such shopping malls in the USA, and “the mall”
as the largest, most visible, and, arguably, most innovative shopping-center
format had become not only the favorite leisure destination for most Amer-
icans but also a new form of community center for suburbs and small towns.
The interaction between large institutional investors, enterprising develo-
pers, and major chain-store operators brought about the standardization of
the development process as well as of the shape of America’s new market-
places. For enterprising retailers in all major sectors, this offered vast oppor-
tunities for expansion with advantages of modern infrastructure, on favorable
lease terms, and in environments more hospitable than traditional downtown
shopping districts. At the same time, the growth opportunities created by new
shopping centers were clearly stacked in favor of large stores over the smaller
ones, and chain-store operators over the independents.
96
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
97
Misha Petrovic
recommended list price. During the early 1960s, many major chains, most of
them department or variety store operators, entered the ranks of discounters.
In 1962 alone, more than twenty retail chains started discount operations,
prompting Fortune magazine to publish a comprehensive study of the new
trend, spanning four issues of the magazine and titled “The Distribution
Upheaval” (Lebhar 1963). As the leaders in cost-cutting and labor-saving
innovations that passed a considerable share of those savings on to the
consumer, discounters were a highly undesirable competition to established
department stores, and the latter often used their clout to ban the “price
cutters” from shopping malls. This led to the development of the standard
free-standing big-box store, oftentimes loosely incorporated into a roadside
shopping center, along with a few smaller service and retail shops.
On the consumer side, the format itself was hardly new; in fact, it
represented little more than the application of the supermarket model to
non-grocery retailing. What was new, however, and what paralleled the
other two massive transformations of American consumer markets brought
about by supermarkets and shopping centers, was how rapidly the discount-
ing format was adopted in the broadly defined general-merchandise sector
and also how rapidly, once the adoption had reached critical mass in the
early 1970s, those new discounters emerged as the leaders in technological
and market-making innovation. By 1990, the Big Three of the general-mer-
chandise discounters, Wal-Mart, Kmart, and Target, had joined the exclusive
list of the top ten US retailers. The following year, Wal-Mart surpassed Sears as
the largest American retailer, only the third retailer in eighty years to occupy
that spot.
By the late 1960s, the American system of consumer goods markets was
beginning to approach the degree of concentration of major chain-store
operators that would make the rapid diffusion of market innovations possible.
At the same time, the absolute size of the market ensured that few chains had
nationwide presence and that there was little direct competition between
major operators. In 1991, when it became the biggest retailer in the world,
Wal-Mart still operated in only twenty-eight US states, and almost exclusively
in small towns (Vance and Scott 1994). Major supermarket operators also
remained mostly regional, the revenue share of the top twenty firms in
grocery retailing approaching 50 percent only by the end of the century.
This situation created little pressure on American retailers to pursue interna-
tional expansion; it also enabled the most efficient retailers to grow very fast,
as they wrestled the sales out of the hands of the least efficient competition
first. In 1967, chain stores captured just under 50 percent of the total retail
sales in general merchandise and food. By 2002, this figure had risen to nearly
80 percent. Yet the sales share of the ten largest US retailers rose only slightly
in the same period, most of this increase being due to the phenomenal growth
98
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
99
Misha Petrovic
100
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
population had access to modern consumer markets, and even today there
are few retailers that have a truly global reach. The reasons for this relate to
the complexity of consumer goods markets. In general, the more complex
markets, in terms of numbers and diversity of products (goods and services,
and the ways to combine them), trading partners, and transaction mechan-
isms, are more difficult to emulate and replicate. Consumer goods markets,
given that they involve complex packages of goods and services, many
diverse trading partners, and disparate transactions, are typically more diffi-
cult to replicate than business-to-business markets, those for services only,
and those where transactions are few and highly standardized.
Within the overall process of the global diffusion of modern retailing prac-
tices, there are several distinct types. The diffusion of separate market mechan-
isms or marketing techniques is the most common one, and the easiest to
achieve. The departmental organization of a large store, the concept of self-
service, centralized checkouts and cash registers, and online browsing for
consumer goods, are all examples of some elements of consumer goods mar-
kets that have traveled exceptionally well. The diffusion of full retail formats
has also been widespread, but until recently limited to simpler markets,
such as those for fast food, cars and gasoline, or luxury items. Within these
categories of goods, the firms that tightly control product management in
supply markets, through branding, design, and even through performing
manufacturing activities, are typically in a better position to replicate con-
sumer markets for their products than the firms that engage exclusively in
retailing. Yet their growth is also limited by the scope of their merchandise
assortment. On the other hand, the firms that sell many different types of
products not only cannot afford to organize the production and design of all
such products, but are also limited by the difficulties of replicating retail
outlets. The process of the international adoption of the supermarket format,
described in the following sections, provides a good example of the difficulties
and obstacles related to emulation, let alone replication, of more complex
market formats.
The process of internationalization, understood as the replication of outlets
in another country, is another type of diffusion of modern retailing, and it
presents additional problems to the retailer. Amongst those, the differences
between national “consumer cultures,” while often highly visible, might not
be the most significant factor. Regulatory contexts, organization of supplier
markets, and the increased complexity of organizational structure and man-
agement are typically more important.
The aggregate result of the diffusion and replication of market mechan-
isms and formats by many individual retailers is the emergence of local
systems of consumer goods markets. Such systems do not always, or even
commonly, emerge at the national level, although governments’ regulatory
101
Misha Petrovic
efforts and the way in which official statistics are generated, suggest that this
is the case. More commonly, the diffusion, replication, and competition
processes are local, or subnational, and sometimes they are transnational
or even global in character. The process of forming such systems of con-
sumer goods markets is initially limited to the emergence of a few modern
firms that deploy and promote modern retailing methods. Once these firms
reach a certain critical size and visibility, the recognition and subsequent
diffusion of best practices between firms is accelerated and the formats
standardized. Center–periphery structures emerge to channel the flow of
innovation to other areas and less innovative firms. Direct competition
between leading retailers usually develops quite late, but has major conse-
quences in terms of the integration of the market system. Competitive
threats, whether actual or potential, lead not only to the further standardi-
zation of most successful formats, but also to the proliferation of comple-
mentary formats—that is, to formats that support and co-evolve with each
other. Thus the rise of large suburban supermarkets may encourage the
development of a dense network of small convenience stores, one-stop
shopping co-evolves with fast-food chains, and so on.
102
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
103
Misha Petrovic
The second wave, 1945–1970: big-box retailing comes to Europe and Japan
In contrast to the first wave of diffusion of American retail formats, the second
wave was generated by a more concerted effort by various organizations, most
notably US productivity missions and assistance agencies, but also private
organizations such as Rockefeller’s International Basic Economy Corporation
(IBEC) (see Broehl 1968), firms such as National Cash Registry, trade associa-
tions, and enterprising retailers.
In the war-ravaged economies of Western Europe, most of the effort under
the US-organized Economic Recovery Program (ERP), better known as the
Marshall Plan, was initially focused on distributing American-made staple
goods and rebuilding the infrastructure in order to alleviate “hunger, poverty,
desperation and chaos.”15 With the intensification of the Cold War, especially
from 1950 on, the productivity aspect became paramount, and a part of
enhancing productivity concerned the dismal state of “distribution” (Schröter
2005).
SUPERMARKETS
The initial attempts to modernize European distribution by using the Ameri-
can model focused on the introduction of separate market mechanisms, most
notably self-service (Henksmeier 1960; Dawson 1981). The supermarket was
the first US retail format to be systematically introduced, and the slow spread
of supermarkets shows how complex and often difficult was the process of
adoption of full retail formats (see A. Goldman 1981; Goldman, Ramaswami,
and Krider 2002; Shaw, Curth, and Alexander 2004). The supermarket, just as
the planned shopping center and the big-box store, evolved in a context
characterized by widespread ownership of automobiles, cheap suburban
land made available for retail stores and amenities, as well as large storage
and refrigeration facilities at consumers’ homes. None of these conditions was
particularly well satisfied in the Western European urban centers of the 1950s,
and even less so in Japan. Supermarkets also required a large number of well-
established and marketed brands of pre-packaged, standardized consumer
products, and a broad range of new technologies of packaging, display, and
delivery. For an entrepreneur, starting a supermarket entailed a high capital
investment in the store and its fixtures, from refrigerated cabinets to check-
outs. It also necessitated a change in mindset, since it involved training and
supervising a different type of labor, and engaging in different marketing and
selling techniques. Licensing restrictions, government regulations, high taxes,
and the animosity of small retailers all presented further obstacles, making the
required investment for opening a supermarket three times higher in Europe
than in the USA (Schröter 2004).
104
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
105
Misha Petrovic
SHOPPING CENTERS
In comparison to the development of the supermarket, the spread of the
shopping center in Europe involved fewer problems and modifications. This
was the result of the much larger size of such undertakings, which were often
actively supported by local governments, developed by established archi-
tectural and construction firms, and underwritten by major institutional
investors, all of which had substantial access to the skills and knowledge
accumulated by their American counterparts. The first such planned shopping
centers in Europe were developed in the 1960s, including the first examples of
large-scale “regional” shopping malls of American style and size, such as
Elephant and Castle in London (1965), Europa Center in Berlin (1965), and
Parly II near Versailles (1969). Unlike in the USA, many of these shopping
centers were built within the existing urban area, rather than on its outskirts,
as a part of the effort to revitalize urban neighborhoods. In the UK and France,
the activity peaked in the 1970s, and by the end of that decade, the best
European shopping-center developers were matching the US ones in sophisti-
cation if not in size.
By 1970, then, the retail landscape in Europe started to resemble that of the
USA, although only in isolated pockets. Modern gas stations became ubiqui-
tous, as did smaller self-service stores. Large supermarkets and hypermarkets
were dotted around new suburban areas, while planned shopping centers and
revamped department stores provided shopping attractions within urban
cores. Perhaps more importantly, the most successful European operators
had developed skills and capacities to operate stores that nearly matched US
size, assortment, and operational efficiency, and those operators would
become one of the major forces in the globalization of retailing in the follow-
ing period.
106
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
store network, and in 1965 operated 1,100 stores in Britain, 277 in Canada,
112 in West Germany, and 10 in Mexico. The world’s largest retailer, Sears,
operated 41 retail stores in Brazil, Colombia, Mexico, Peru, and Venezuela.
Safeway, the largest of the US supermarket operators, entered the UK in 1962,
Australia in 1963, and Germany in 1964. Yet these isolated examples only
underscore the relative lack of internationalization efforts in the period. Then,
as much as today, large US retailers of food and general merchandise rarely
looked for expansion opportunities abroad because of the virtually unlimited
opportunities for growth in the domestic market. European retailers, on the
other hand, had much more limited growth opportunities at home; but they
had not yet developed the critical size and organizational competence for
international expansion.
107
Misha Petrovic
108
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
109
Misha Petrovic
MARKET MAKERS
After 1989, the understored, drab retail landscapes of Eastern Europe be-
came major expansion targets of Western European retailers. By 2000, they
were dominated by supermarkets and hypermarkets operated by Metro,
Casino, Carrefour, Auchan, Tesco, Aldi, Lidl, and other leading Western
chains, including a few local power players such as Slovenian Merkator.
Southern Italy, Spain, Portugal, and Greece were all fully incorporated into
the EU retail market during this period, and significant modernization
occurred in smaller markets such as Macedonia, Albania, and Montenegro.
The two large economies on the periphery of Europe, Turkey and Russia,
managed to develop major domestic retail operators even while opening up
their retail sector to foreign entry. The giant Russian retail market attracted
retailers such as Metro, Auchan, and Spar Coop, but the domestic discount
chains such as Pyaterochka and Kopeika, and supermarket/hypermarket
operators such as Seventh Continent and Perekrestok, have so far been
able to compete. In 2006, the merger of Perekrestok and Pyaterochka cre-
ated the first Russian food retail giant, the X5 Retail group, with over
$5 billion in revenues.
110
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
111
Misha Petrovic
112
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
that even the most successful Internet retailers have not yet been able to
achieve the consumer traffic of large general-merchandise retailers, let alone
their revenues. Amazon.com and eBay, the two leading e-retailers, had over
fifty million unique users in November 2008, during the peak of the shopping
season. But Wal-Mart and Target websites attracted thirty-nine million and
thirty-six million shoppers in the same period, and their physical stores
several times as many. In general, almost half of the sales of the 100 largest
e-retailers is captured by large retail chains’ websites, and the rest is split
between manufacturer and brand-name managers and the “pure” e-retailers.
Ten of the top fifteen US e-retailing sites in 2008 were online outposts of major
mass retailers.
The 250 largest world retailers captured over $3.6 trillion in retail sales in
2007, or more than one-third of the estimated world’s total, and the top ten
alone accounted for more than $1 trillion (Deloitte 2009). Nine of the top ten
and almost 40 percent of the top 250 largest retailers operated markets that
combined food and general-merchandise assortments, indicating an increas-
ing integration of market formats around the cluster of supermarket, hyper-
market, superstore, warehouse, and similar big-box, scrambled merchandising
formats. While these large retailers still rarely compete directly with each other
outside their home markets, they play a major role in making consumer and
supplier markets around the world, and thus represent a key organizing force
in today’s global economy.
The global market for consumer goods should not be seen as a set of
segmented, separate national markets, despite the regulatory attempts of
many governments to limit the expansion of large retailers and, in particular,
foreign ones, within their jurisdiction. Rather, the system of global consumer
markets is being increasingly organized as an integrated center–periphery
structure, where there is a steady flow of innovations from retailers in the
core countries toward less-developed economies. The core economies’ retailers
are not only the most modern and efficient; they also collectively control the
major share of consumer goods markets, thus enabling very rapid diffusion
and replication of innovations and best practices.
Large retailers are often uniquely positioned to test new market mechanisms
and store formats. While market innovations often start from small retail
firms, once they achieve some success, they can be quickly adopted by large
chains. The adoption of supermarkets by small-store grocery chains and the
role European department stores played in starting single-price variety stores
are some early examples of such a process. The adoption of online retailing by
113
Misha Petrovic
114
US Retailing and its Global Diffusion
115
Misha Petrovic
116
4
Introduction
118
Globalization of European Retailing
119
Michael Wortmann
The various retail innovations and new retail formats, most of them originat-
ing in the United States, met very different environments when US multi-
nationals tried to transfer them to their affiliates in Europe or when European
retail entrepreneurs tried to implement them in their home countries. Retail
structures were quite different to start with, and established retailers, espe-
cially small traditional retailers, had a very different position in the market
and were differently organized and differently embedded in their country-
specific social and political environments. Thus, the reactions of established
retailers, but also of consumers, city planners, and politicians, toward change
and modernization in the retail industry, and especially toward big-box retail-
ing, differed significantly. This led to different patterns of retail modernization
and to quite different structures of the retail industries in the single European
countries.
The UK in the 1950s was still Europe’s most advanced economy, and, thus,
the UK led the supermarket revolution in Europe, introducing self-service and
increasing the size of stores, which became increasingly organized as chains.
In addition, the UK economy traditionally had a liberal regulatory environ-
ment, and the development of new retail formats went relatively unre-
stricted.2 Increased competition was supported by the difficulties of
enforcement and finally the abolishment of resale price maintenance in
1964, increasing the pressure on retailers to modernize store formats and
ownership structures (Guy 2007). Supermarket chains quickly developed,
amongst them Sainsbury’s and Tesco. In addition, the UK was most open to
foreign investment, which—because of cultural and language proximity—
came especially from the USA (Godley and Fletcher 2001). The US supermar-
ket chain Safeway was one of the first entrants into the UK market in 1962
(Shaw and Alexander 2006).
In France, retail change started somewhat more slowly than in the UK, but
eventually became more of a true retail revolution. This began in 1963, when
120
Globalization of European Retailing
121
Michael Wortmann
122
Globalization of European Retailing
Table 4.1. Top-five national grocery retailers, four European countries, 2007
France Italyb
123
Michael Wortmann
UK <400 m2
400–1,000 m2
1,000–2,500 m2
>2,500 m2
France
Germany
Italy
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
%
Figure 4.1. Grocery market share according to store size, four European countries, 2006
Source: Nielsen Company (2007); own careful estimates for small stores (<400 m²) in France,
because original data omitted traditional stores.
124
Globalization of European Retailing
1960s, but its overwhelming expansion began only in the 1970s, when Rewe,
Tengelmann, the Schwarz Group (Lidl), and some other companies also devel-
oped their own hard-discount formats (Wortmann 2004). All these companies
profited from the retail regulation that limited store size, and left other
aspects, such as assortments, distribution centers, or ownership, unregulated.
They were also supported by the abolishment of retail price maintenance in
1974. Since the 1980s, the hard discounters have slightly broadened their
assortments, introducing dairy products, fresh produce, and meat. Even with
a very limited assortment (between 600 and 1,600 SKUs), hard discounters
have conquered over 40 percent of the German grocery market.
But, the two largest grocery retailers in Germany are still the buying groups
Edeka and Rewe. Both have some thousand members, each which runs its own
stores, usually supermarkets of various sizes. These groups increasingly operate
as integrated systems, with a growing centralized steering capacity for assort-
ments, prices, and store appearance. In addition, these groups run more and
more stores that are owned by the groups’ central headquarters. Rewe has
invested considerably in the development and expansion of new retail for-
mats, especially its hard-discount chain Penny. Edeka has grown recently
through the takeover of the German voluntary chain Spar (then number
seven in the German market) from the French ITM, which had been unable
to run it successfully.
Another format that has developed quite successfully in Germany is the
cash and carry (C&C) markets, where Metro is clearly the market leader.
Through the takeover of the German stores from Wal-Mart, which had tried
to enter the German market through two acquisitions in 1998–9, and the
merger of these with its own chain of Real stores, Metro has become the
biggest operator of large grocery stores in Germany. But stores with more
than 5,000 square meters have a market share of only 13.5 percent in German
grocery retailing, while stores with less than 800 square meters still capture
over 50 percent; within this group, discounters with a total market share of
over 40 percent have pushed all other kinds of small stores aside.
After having analyzed how the different patterns of retail development in
the four biggest West European countries have been shaped by different
general and retail-specific institutional legacies, we will now look more closely
at how the different types of retailers that have developed under the different
conditions in these countries have internationalized their operations.8
Carrefour
When Carrefour, then France’s number two retailer, and Promodès, also
amongst the top five, merged in 1999, they created the world’s second largest
125
Michael Wortmann
retailer with a combined turnover of €54 billion. With this merger, Carrefour
had become a truly multiple format retailer. While Carrefour had been the
pioneer of the hypermarket and had realized 78 percent of its sales in these
very large stores that combine food and non-food assortments, Promodès,
originally a wholesale company, was stronger in supermarkets (37 percent),
but also operated hypermarkets (42 percent) and other formats including
hard-discount stores (7 percent). Both companies operated more than 9,000
stores in 26 countries.
Carrefour had been founded in 1959 by two entrepreneurs, Marcel Fournier
and Louis Defforey, in Annecy in eastern France, where they opened a first
supermarket at a crossroads (literally carrefour) in 1960.9 At a time when there
were only a very few self-service stores in France, this store became an imme-
diate success; and its next supermarket already had a large parking lot. Follow-
ing a trip to the United States, visits to several stores, and participation in
seminars by the retail guru Trujillo in Dayton, Ohio, the two entrepreneurs
invented a new store concept. The first hypermarket (hypermarché) was opened
in Sainte-Geneviève-des-Bois, on the outskirts of Paris, in 1963. This store had
a sales area of 2,500 square meters, 12 checkouts, and 400 parking spaces. Its
assortment was concentrated in food, but it also carried a large range of non-
food items. Carrefour’s hypermarkets quickly became larger and larger. In the
early 1970s the average store size was 10,000 square meters. The hypermarket
that opened in 1972 south of Toulouse, with its 23,000 square meters, is still,
in 2010, the largest hypermarket in Europe.10 The additional floor space was
increasingly used for an extended non-food assortment. Cheap land in com-
mercial areas, accessible by highways, and a simple architecture reduced
construction costs per square meter to one third of traditional supermarkets
(Bell et al. 2004). Hypermarkets were to become the backbone of Carrefour’s
rapid growth. But Carrefour did not only establish its own outlets; the com-
pany also entered into partnerships and licensing agreements with several
other companies, which set up hypermarkets under the Carrefour brand,
amongst them Docks de France, Docks du Nord-Mielle (later Cora),11 as well
as Comptoirs Modernes and Promodès, which all operated their own hyper-
market brands a few years later. The latter were to be merged into the new
Carrefour more than two decades later (Lhermie 2003).
Internationalization began in 1969, one year before Carrefour was intro-
duced at the Paris stock exchange. The first hypermarket abroad was opened in
Belgium, in cooperation with Delhaize le Lion (which had a 70 percent share
in the store).12 Three stores were opened before Carrefour withdrew in 1978.
The next country it entered was Switzerland: Carrefour held 25 percent in two
hypermarkets; but sold its share in 1991. Great Britain followed in 1971,
where four Carrefour hypermarkets were set up in cooperation with Dee
(90 percent); here Carrefour withdrew in 1983.13 In 1972 Carrefour entered
126
Globalization of European Retailing
Italy; but, after opening two stores, it again withdrew. In Austria Carrefour
opened a hypermarket (100 percent owned) at Shopping City Süd near Vienna
in 1976, then Austria’s largest food store; two years later Carrefour sold 51
percent and withdrew completely in 1990. The first Carrefour hypermarket in
Germany was set up in cooperation with the German Stüssgen Group (60
percent) and the Belgian Delhaize le Lion (20 percent) in Mainz in 1977. Since
further expansion failed, because of restrictive zoning policies, Carrefour with-
drew less than two years later.
Only one of seven European market entries in the 1970s was to become
successful: Spain. In a joint venture with Grupo Radar, which held 50 percent,
the first hypermarket was opened in El Prat de Llobregat near Barcelona in
1973. In 1986, Carrefour took 100 percent in the company, which now
operated under the name of Pryca ( precio y calidad, price and quality). Shortly
after Carrefour had introduced the new format into Spain, other French
chains (amongst them Promodès (see below)) as well as Spanish companies
followed (Cuesta 2004).
Carrefour’s plans for internationalization were not limited to Europe. Car-
refour was the first international grocery retailer to enter the Latin American
market. In 1975 it set up its first hypermarket in Brazil. The first hypermarket
in Argentina followed in 1982. Expansion in Latin America was very slow at
first, as Carrefour experimented with the layout and the organization of its
first stores (Bell et al. 2004); in 1985 there were still only ten stores. The
operations in both countries were eventually to become very successful. Mar-
ket entry into further Latin-American countries came much later. In Mexico
Carrefour set up a joint venture with the local retail group Gigante, starting
hypermarket operations in 1994. Four years later, Carrefour hypermarkets
were also opened in Colombia, Chile, and, as a franchise, the Dominican
Republic.
Carrefour also tried to enter the United States, opening its first outlet in
1988 in Philadelphia: a huge hypermarket, very similar to those it operated in
France. At that time, Wal-Mart had already experimented with its own hyper-
market format called Hypermart, which was very much a copy of Carrefour’s
French hypermarket outlets; and in the same year, 1988, Wal-Mart opened its
first supercenter. A little later, Carrefour reacted by opening its second hyper-
market in the United States, in Voorhees (NJ), this time somewhat smaller
(and looking more like a warehouse club). Both stores were closed down in
1993, probably because of competition from nearby Wal-Mart stores.
At about the same time, Carrefour also turned to Asia and opened its first
hypermarket in 1989 in Taiwan, in a joint venture with President Group,
Taiwan’s largest food manufacturer, which held 40 percent.14 After Carrefour
had set up a first hypermarket in Malaysia in 1994, also in cooperation with a
local partner, other Asian countries quickly followed. In China, Carrefour
127
Michael Wortmann
began operations in 1995; and in 1996, it entered Thailand, South Korea, and
Hong Kong; Singapore followed in 1997, and Indonesia in 1998. Within just
five years, Carrefour had entered seven new Asian markets.
Parallel to this intercontinental expansion, Carrefour strengthened its posi-
tion in its domestic and other European markets. An important step had been
the creation in 1976 of a private “brand-free” or “no-name” label (produits
libre) for a limited range of low-priced basic foods, offered in simple white
packages. In 1978, after Aldi and others had firmly established the hard-
discount format in Germany, Carrefour launched its own chain of hard-
discount stores in France, called Ed. Attempts to enter the UK, Denmark,
and Italy failed. A further step consolidating Carrefour’s number one position
in the French hypermarket segment was the acquisition of its smaller compe-
titors, Euromarché and Montlaur, in 1991.
New attempts, after the failures in the 1970s, to enter European markets
beyond France and Spain were made in 1993. Carrefour opened its first own
hypermarket in Italy and also acquired Al Gran Sole, which owned four
hypermarkets in the country. The same year, Carrefour set up its first hyper-
market in Turkey in a joint venture with the second largest Turkish firm, the
conglomerate Sabanci, which was also involved in joint ventures with food-
processing firms such as Philip Morris Kraft and Danone (Tokatli and Eldener
2002). Finally, Carrefour’s expansion into Eastern Europe began relatively late,
when it opened its first hypermarket in Lodz, Poland, in 1997.
Paul-Auguste Halley, one of the founders of Promodès, the multinational
retailer that merged with Carrefour in 1999, had been amongst the pioneers of
the self-service concept in France when he opened some of the first super-
markets in the 1950s. Promodès itself was established through the merger
of two wholesale companies in 1961. This tradition of wholesaling is also
reflected in the operations of Promocash cash and carry markets, which
started in 1965, and still operate today. In 1969, Promodès also began
operating its supermarkets under the Champion banner; by the end of 1970
there were already 43 Champion supermarkets, and in 1990 there were over
350, most of them being franchised. Promodès had operated hypermarkets
under a franchise agreement with Carrefour under the Carrefour banner since
1970, but the first hypermarket branded Continent was set up two years later,
and Promodès’s hypermarket sales grew at about the same speed as supermar-
ket sales. Promodès also expanded its wholesale activities with neighborhood
stores and convenience stores, which were franchised under the Shopi (1973)
and 8 à Huit (1977) brands. Several acquisitions in the 1980s and 1990s also
added to Promodès’s domestic growth—amongst them 128 supermarkets
from Primistères in 1988, Codec and Félix Potin convenience stores in 1990
and 1996, as well as Cattau from Tesco consisting of 7 hypermarkets, 73 super-
markets, and a few neighborhood stores in 1997 (see below).
128
Globalization of European Retailing
129
Michael Wortmann
started several wholesale activities. But about ten years later Promodès left the
United States, and sold its Red Food holdings to the Dutch retailer Ahold
(1994).
Before the merger with Carrefour, the operations of Promodès were highly
concentrated in France (63 percent of sales in 1987) and Spain (28.5 percent).
Further European activities were concentrated in Italy, where Promodès had
bought the supermarket chain GS (6 percent) (see below) and Greece
(1.6 percent). In Taiwan, where a Continent hypermarket had opened in
1995, Promodès sold out to its local partner in 1998. Hypermarket operations
in Indonesia, in cooperation with local partner Sinar Mas, were just about to
start in 1998. Compared with Promodès, Carrefour, despite the fact that its
two main markets were also France (57 percent of sales in 1998) and Spain
(over 10 percent), was much more global, with operations in several Latin-
American (23 percent) and Asian (6 percent) countries. But its business was
concentrated in hypermarkets, while Promodès was much more diversified as
regards formats.
In 1999, three years after French hypermarket giant Auchan had merged
with Docks de France (Mammouth), and Metro had established itself as Eur-
ope’s biggest retailer, and two years after Wal-Mart had entered the European
stage, Carrefour and Promodès merged their activities. This new Carrefour was
now Europe’s largest and the world’s second largest retailer. In addition to the
merger, a large number of other companies in France and abroad were
acquired between 1998 and 2000.
The most important was the acquisition of Comptoirs Modernes, a very old
family business that had started a self-service store in France as early as 1949,
and now consisted of 16 Carrefour branded hypermarkets, a chain of over 400
supermarkets (Stoc), and about 300 convenience stores (Comod; Marché Plus).
Comptoirs Modernes had also been operating in Spain since 1988, where it
had developed a group of over 100 supermarkets under various, frequently
acquired brands, such as Maxor and Supeco. Promodès had also recently
(1987) expanded its Spanish operations when it acquired a chain of 61 Simago
supermarkets.
In addition to the strengthening of the new Carrefour’s position in its two
core markets, France and Spain, the group also expanded its activities into
other European countries. In 2000 Carrefour bought Italian Gruppo GS, with
which Promodès had cooperated since 1997, and which owned more than 20
hypermarkets, as well as networks of almost 300 supermarkets (two-thirds
franchised) and over 500 convenience stores (DìperDì; mostly franchised).
Carrefour was now operating 31 hypermarkets in Italy. Also in 2000 Carrefour
re-entered the Belgian market, acquiring GB (Grand Basar) the country’s
leading retailer, in which Promodès had taken a minority share in 1998. GB
operated 60 hypermarkets, as well as 73 integrated and 350 franchised
130
Globalization of European Retailing
131
Michael Wortmann
Parallel to its merger with Promodès and the various European acquisitions,
in Latin America Carrefour now added more supermarkets to its hypermarket
business—also by acquisitions. In Brazil in 1998–9, it bought 6 local super-
market chains with a total of 85 stores, amongst them 23 stores of Lojas
Americanas—the company that had been the joint-venture partner of Wal-
Mart when it entered Brazil in 1994. Since 2001 Día discount stores have also
operated in Brazil. In 2007, by acquiring 34 hypermarkets from Atacadao,
Carrefour became Brazil’s number one food retailer. In Argentina, Carrefour
started Día operations in 1999, and by adding over 130 supermarkets of the
leading local chain Norte to its 21 hypermarkets two years later became the
number one grocery retailer in Argentina, too.
In contrast to these two countries, in Colombia, where Carrefour had set up
its first hypermarket in 1998, the company grew only internally and, as of
2010, still operates only hypermarkets, which it has partly adapted to different
kinds of neighborhoods. Here Carrefour is only the number two, far behind
Casino. In two other Latin-American countries, Carrefour decided to leave: it
sold its seven hypermarkets in Chile in 2004, and in 2005 a further twenty-
nine hypermarkets in Mexico.
In Asia, Carrefour further expanded its hypermarket activities. In Taiwan
the number of outlets was doubled from twenty-four (2000) to forty-eight
(2007), which was only partly due to an agreement with Tesco, by which
Carrefour traded its Czech hypermarkets for six hypermarkets in Taiwan. In
Indonesia where Carrefour had opened its first hypermarket in 1998, in the
middle of the Asian financial crisis, it has recently speeded up expansion,
opening seventeen outlets in 2006–7 and buying a 75 percent stake in the
local retailer Alfa Retailindo, which operated twenty-nine supermarkets of
various sizes, in early 2008. These were the only acquisitions Carrefour made
in Asia, where most of the growth so far had been generated internally.
In China in the beginning of the 2000s, Carrefour had serious problems
with government authorities, resulting from the way it had operated its first
hypermarkets. Carrefour’s Chinese retail operations had been owned by joint-
venture companies with different local partners in which Carrefour held only
a minority, but these operating companies were linked by management con-
tracts with additional joint-venture companies in which Carrefour owned a
majority. This allowed Carrefour effectively to control its retail operations in
China, bypassing restrictive legislation that did not allow majority ownership.
Following some legal wrangling, public apologies by Carrefour, and—at the
same time—a loosening of tight regulation, 89 hypermarkets were set up after
2002. By May 2008 Carrefour operated 113 hypermarkets all over the country,
form Shenzhen to Harbin and from Shanghai to Urumqi. Attempts to add
supermarkets to its Chinese stores were halted after two years. But the Día
132
Globalization of European Retailing
discount chain that started operations in 2003 has already grown to nearly
300 stores, concentrated in Shanghai and Beijing.
While Carrefour has managed to become the leading foreign retailer in
Taiwan, Indonesia, and—at least for a time—China,16 as well as in Singapore,
where it operates two hypermarkets, it has been much less successful in
Malaysia (twelve outlets) and Thailand, where its twenty-seven hypermarkets
bring it only to fifth place amongst Thailand’s grocery retailers. In Hong Kong,
South Korea, and Japan, where again Carrefour was unable to become one of
the leading retailers, it withdrew from the markets, by selling its stores to local
companies or, in Japan, by franchising the stores out to Aeon, Japan’s largest
retailer.
By 2008 Carrefour was the second biggest retailer of the world; it was
number one not only in Europe and its home country France but also in
Spain, Belgium, and Greece, in Brazil and Argentina, in Taiwan and Indonesia;
and number two in Italy, Poland, and Turkey, as well as being the second
largest foreign-owned retailer in China. France accounted for 43.4 percent
of total net sales of €108.6 billion; other European countries accounted for
39.1 percent, Latin-America for 11.1 percent, and Asia for 6.4 percent.
In 2008, 1,302 ( in 2007: 1247) hypermarkets accounted for 59.0 percent of
the group’s total sales. The vast majority of these hypermarkets were located
outside France (228): in Western Europe, Carrefour operated hypermarkets in
Spain (168), Italy (69), Belgium (57), Greece and Cyprus (31), and Turkey (22).
In Eastern Europe Carrefour’s hypermarkets were located in Poland (78) and
Romania (21). Its presence in Latin America was concentrated in Brazil (162),
Argentina (67), and Colombia (59). And in East and South East Asia it was
focused on China (134), Taiwan (59), Indonesia (37), Thailand (27), Malaysia
(12), and Singapore (2). In addition, franchised outlets operated in Japan (7),
nine Arab countries (27), and the Dominican Republic (1), as well as in French
overseas departments and territories.
Supermarkets accounted for 23.6 percent of total sales, mostly under the
Champion banner. This business is relatively less internationalized and still
concentrated in Europe. In countries outside Europe, supermarkets have fol-
lowed the expansion of hypermarkets. Out of 2,919 supermarkets, 1,001 were
in France, 508 in Italy, 444 in Belgium, many operated by franchisees and
licensees; others were in Greece and Cyprus (229), and in Poland (225), Turkey
(125), and Spain (98). The few supermarkets outside Europe were concentrated
in Argentina (112) and Brazil (39). Convenience stores, which are mostly
franchised, are the least internationalized store type: of the 4,813 stores,
over two-thirds were in France and most others in Italy (1,016), Belgium
(191), and Greece and Cyprus (256).
Discount stores, accounting for 10.2 percent of the group’s sales, are a very
special case. While the discount business of Carrefour under the Ed banner,
133
Michael Wortmann
Aldi
The brothers Karl and Theodor Albrecht ran their first shop, originally owned
by their mother, in Essen in the Ruhr area from 1946.17 Like many others in
the early post-war period, this little store sold a very limited range of products.
By 1950 the Albrechts had expanded and owned thirteen shops. It was in this
period that they developed some central elements of their hard-discount
retailing strategy. When the German economy recovered and an increasingly
diversified range of products became available on the wholesale market, the
Albrechts discovered that they could make a good business by sticking to
the limited product range, since this allowed them to keep their costs low.
In the early 1950s their shops concentrated on the fastest-moving articles and
offered only one product of each kind. In total, only between 250 and 280
different products were offered. Besides helping to reduce purchase prices,
since products could be bought in larger quantities, this improved the effi-
ciency of sales work, since the lack of choice encouraged customers to decide
quickly what to buy. As Karl Albrecht explained in 1953, the company
“adhered to the principles of low prices as well as that of limited selection . . .
we went so far as to exclude whole product categories. The reason? Turnover.”
There were no decorations, counters and shelves were kept very simple, and all
products were visibly displayed for the customers. This helped to keep total
sales costs down to 11 percent and personnel costs to between 3.1 percent and
3.7 percent of turnover. Advertising expenditure was less than 0.1 percent,
since “all our promotions are put into discount prices.”18
This concept allowed the Albrechts to expand dramatically. By 1960, the
number of outlets had increased to 300. The following year, the two Albrecht
brothers divided their business into two clearly separated areas, Nord and Süd,
with Theo in the north and Karl in the south; this division was later extended
to an agreed segmentation of foreign markets as well. The first “real” Aldi
(Albrecht Discount) store opened in 1962 in the Ruhr-area city of Dortmund.
It combined the principles described above with the new concept of self-
service, which had slowly started to spread in Germany in the mid-1950s
134
Globalization of European Retailing
(Henksmeier 1988). The first Aldi outlets had an average sales area of some-
where above 200 square meters and sold only a small assortment of 400 fast-
moving packaged grocery products that could be easily (and cheaply) handled
and stored. By 1974 there were already 1,000 Aldi stores in Germany.
Up to the present, Aldi has remained true to its original principles of
concentrating on a limited number of high-sale, fast-moving goods, keeping
in-store presentation of goods as simple as possible (products are left in their
cardboard boxes or even on the palette), and reducing service to the mini-
mum. The high turnover/space ratio and low store and personnel costs, which
allow low sales margins, combined with the low cost of sourcing made possi-
ble by large-scale buying, enable Aldi to offer its products at very low prices.
Almost all products sold at Aldi stores are private labels with fancy names
made up like branded products. They are frequently sourced from mid-sized
manufacturers that, while typically able to maintain reliable long-term sup-
plier relationships, remain highly dependent on Aldi.
Aldi Nord and Süd are, in 2010, still family owned. They do not publish
annual reports or any similar information and do not have public-relations
departments. The internal ownership and management structures of the
group are complex and inscrutable. Distribution and sales activities are
organized in local companies consisting of forty or fifty stores grouped around
their distribution center. This unit size also defines the minimum size for
international activities (except for intra-EU border regions).
The international expansion of Aldi (Süd) started as early as 1967, when the
company took over the small Austrian retail chain Hofer. Aldi transformed the
stores to its own concept and used the Hofer stores as a platform for further
growth. Austria is the only country where Aldi discount stores do not operate
under the Aldi banner. Other neighboring countries were entered by Aldi
Nord: the Netherlands in 1973 and Belgium in 1976, again by acquiring
small local firms as starting platforms. The first stores in Denmark (1977)
concluded the first phase of market entries into neighboring European
countries. In all these countries Aldi was the first company to introduce the
hard-discount concept. In Austria, the Netherlands, and Belgium Aldi was able
to grow quickly, while in Denmark it was soon confronted with competition
from Dansk Supermarked’s own discount chain Netto, started in 1981.19
In 1976 Aldi Süd entered the United States. It acquired some fifty stores from
Benner Tea of Iowa and remolded the stores to its own hard-discount concept,
even though US stores are a bit larger and carry more products (about 1,400
regular SKUs) than the German original.20 Since then, operations have spread
continuously from Kansas to the East Coast, recently even down to Florida.
Today, Aldi owns over 1,000 stores in 29 states. In 1979 Theo Albrecht from
Aldi Nord made an investment that was very untypical for the company. He
acquired the California-based retailer Trader Joe’s. In stores of 1,500 square
135
Michael Wortmann
meters, it sold about 2,500–3,000 quality food items, many of them specialties
with a gourmet touch. As in Aldi stores, about 80 percent of the items are
private labels. Even though this company is managed quite independently
from Aldi’s hard-discount operations, there are certainly synergies, especially
in sourcing European-style food products. Trader Joe’s has developed
extremely well and by 2009 operated over 300 stores in 23 states.
During the 1980s, partly in reaction to the emergence of competitors in
Germany’s discount segment, Aldi introduced some changes to its business
model. It started to broaden its regular assortment, which until then had been
limited to canned and dry foods, with new products: in particular, dairy
products were introduced as well as fresh produce. The number of SKUs
increased to over 600 at Aldi Nord and 700 at Aldi Süd. But the still limited
range of products allowed Aldi to avoid costly investments in IT systems and
scanner checkouts for a long time. These were installed only in the early
2000s. With this wider assortment Aldi competed not only with newly
emerging discounters, such as Penny, Plus, and Lidl, which were all somewhat
“softer,” but also with traditional supermarkets.21 In addition, Aldi, like other
discounters, began to sell various non-food products, such as kitchenware,
textiles, toys, or stationery products, and even TV sets and computers. Since
Aldi stores, because of German regulations, cannot expand their store size, it is
not possible to keep all these products in stock at the same time. Instead, they
are sold as one-off special offers, which change once or twice a week. All these
products are manufactured exclusively for Aldi, and are usually sourced
through specialized importers. At Aldi, these products account for over
20 percent of total sales, making the company one of the top ten apparel
retailers in Germany. Its special-offer computers have also become quite pop-
ular since the mid-1990s.
In 1988–90, in a second phase of internationalization, Aldi Nord entered
France and Luxembourg, while Aldi Süd turned to the UK. In France, Aldi
faced competition not only from local companies like Ed (Carrefour) or Leader
Price (Casino) but also from Aldi’s German arch rival Lidl, which entered
France as its first foreign market in 1989 and has since become the number
one discounter in the country. Faced with this situation, Aldi bought 74 Día
stores from Promodès in 1996, an unusual step for Aldi, which usually prefers
to grow internally. The UK also proved to be a difficult environment for Aldi—
as for hard discounters in general, which have been unable to overcome their
poor image in an environment of high brand awareness. Generally, the 1990s
were characterized by the addition of further stores in those countries that
Aldi had already entered, and by the expansion of Aldi Nord into Eastern
Germany.
By the end of the 1990s, a third phase of internationalization began. In 1999
Aldi Süd expanded from the UK to Ireland, and in 2001 it turned to Australia,
136
Globalization of European Retailing
where its entry raised furious public debates. But Aldi was able to do well, even
without acquiring a starting base in this faraway market. In 2002 Aldi Nord set
up its first stores in Spain, where it had to struggle with Día as well as Lidl,
which had already entered the market. A few stores were opened in Portugal,
supplied from distribution centers in Spain. In 2005 Aldi Süd entered Switzer-
land, a non-EU market dominated by local supermarket chains and character-
ized by relatively high retail prices. In 2008 Aldi Süd entered Greece, where it
was able to operate thirty-five stores.
Amongst the larger German discounters, Aldi was the last to enter Eastern
Europe. In 2005 the first stores were opened in Slovenia, operating under the
Hofer banner and managed from Austria. Austria was also used as a spring-
board to enter Hungary, where it proceeded to operate over fifty stores. Aldi
Nord has also turned to Eastern Europe, opening a distribution center and
some forty stores since 2008 in Poland.
By 2008 Aldi was operating about 8,500 stores worldwide, of which over
7,000 were in Europe, including 4,200 in Germany. About 80 percent of all
Germans live within walking distance of an Aldi store, and at least 70 percent
of all households use one of these stores at least ‘occasionally’. In its home
country, Aldi is the fifth biggest grocery retailer. And the company has a
similarly strong position in Austria, Belgium, and the Netherlands. However,
in other countries, such as the UK or Spain, it is not even amongst the top ten
grocery retailers. In the USA Aldi, including Trader Joe’s, ranks only at about
the twentieth place. But this—seemingly—weak position in several host
countries is no problem for Aldi and other hard discounters, as they can
generate high cross-border synergies (see below).
Metro
The German retail conglomerate Metro AG was Europe’s largest retailer until
the 1999 merger between Carrefour and Promodès. Metro is active in a broad
range of retail and trading activities, including food retailing in large stores
under various brands, Galeria Kaufhof and Horten department stores, various
specialized retail chains such as Media-Markt and Saturn (trading consumer
electronics and home appliances), as well as a broad range of other activities,
many of which have been divested since 1998.
The most important division were cash and carry outlets operating under
the Metro and Makro brands in Germany as well as in seventeen other
countries, contributing 40 percent to total sales at that time. The company
Metro SB-Großmarkt was founded in 1963 by two established wholesale
businessmen. One year later, Otto Beisheim became managing director and
the company established its first self-service wholesale outlet in Mühlheim, in
137
Michael Wortmann
the heart of the Ruhr area. This self-service wholesale outlet operated on an
area of 14,000 square meters catering to small retailers and other businesses.
Even though the cash and carry concept, which had originated in the USA,
had been introduced to Germany before, Metro, because of its financial re-
sources, became by far the most successful company in this field. After 1967
the company was owned in equal parts by the families of Schmidt-Ruthen-
beck, the co-founder, and Haniel, the owner of the huge trading company
Franz Haniel & Cie., as well as its general manager Otto Beisheim. By 1970
there were already thirteen Metro cash and carry outlets in Germany. Their
status as a wholesaler leaves C&C big boxes unaffected by restrictive German
special planning regulation, which was to restrict other large retail formats.
Internationalization also started quite early. In 1968 Metro and the Dutch
family-owned conglomerate Steenkolen Handelsvereniging (SHV) struck a
partnership agreement to combine their forces on international markets. In
some countries SHV would hold 60 percent and Metro 40 percent in opera-
tions under the Makro brand, while in other countries Metro would hold
60 percent and SHV 40 percent, and operations were to be branded Metro.
The first outlet was opened the same year in Amsterdam. In 1970–1 further
Makro stores followed in Belgium and the UK, while Metro stores were opened
in Austria, Denmark, and France. With the opening of a Metro store in Italy
and a Makro store in Spain in 1972, the first phase of foreign-market entries
was completed. Only eight years after its first German cash and carry outlet,
Metro operated outlets in nine European countries.
During the 1980s a long period of acquisitions and diversifications as well as
corporate restructurings began, which ended only in 1998. By 1986 Metro
gained a controlling interest in Kaufhof, one of four big German department
store chains originating from the end of the nineteenth century, which also
owned a chain of around 100 Kaufhalle variety stores. In 1994, Kaufhof
acquired Horten department stores.22 In the late 1980s, Kaufhof had also
expanded into specialized non-food retailing; it acquired two chains of larger
stores specializing in consumer electronics and household appliances, Media-
Markt and Saturn, which were merged to form Media-Saturn-Holding in 1990.
Other diversifications of Metro and Kaufhof turned to shoe stores (Reno),
office equipment (Sigma), and a computer store franchise system (Vobis).
By 1993 Metro had step by step gained majority control in another big
German retail conglomerate, the Asko group. Asko had started as a regional
consumers’ cooperative in the late nineteenth century, which was trans-
formed into a stock-listed corporation in 1972 and had since grown through
specializing in larger food stores (under the Basaar banner) while abandoning
smaller ones. It had also acquired several grocery retail groups, which were
themselves frequently the results of merger processes amongst smaller retail
companies that had started to set up larger out-of-town stores in the 1960s, at
138
Globalization of European Retailing
a time when restrictive retail legislation had not yet been introduced. The
large grocery store format developed in Germany is called SB-Warenhaus—
literally: self-service warehouse. These stores are frequently referred to
as hypermarkets, as we will do in this chapter, even though they are
usually somewhat smaller than their French counterparts and carry only
about 25–40 percent non-food products.23
One of the groups acquired by Asko was Schaper, which owned some cash
and carry outlets, Extra supermarkets, as well as several hypermarket chains,
such as Real, Esbella, and Continent (in cooperation with Promodès (see
above)). Another group acquired in 1990 was Deutsche SB-Kauf. This com-
pany consisted of what was left over from another company, which until
recently had been known as Coop AG and which still owned a large number
of stores of various formats, sizes, and brands (Comet, Tip, and so on). Coop
had developed from the merger of around a hundred local consumer coopera-
tives during the 1970s and 1980s, and had a very complicated and opaque
ownership structure, including various trade unions as well as its own man-
agers, frequently former trade unionists. Coop was dissolved in 1988, follow-
ing one of Germany’s greatest business scandals. Asko also engaged in a
partnership with Massa Group, which like Asko was amongst the top ten
German grocery retailers at that time. But Asko also ventured into new busi-
nesses: it established the DIY chain Praktiker, bought the apparel retailer
Adler, which owned apparel factories in Germany, Sri Lanka, and South
Korea, and took 50 percent in a chain of furniture stores.
In 1996 Metro merged its German cash and carry business, together with
the various activities of Kaufhof and Asko, into the newly founded stock-listed
Metro AG, which immediately became Europe’s number one retailer. Former
Metro general manager Beisheim, who had retired from active management in
1994, and the Schmidt-Ruthenbeck and Haniel families still owned the major-
ity of this company through Metro Holding AG, which had been founded in
Baar, Switzerland, several years previously—probably for tax reasons. The
Metro and Makro cash and carry operations outside Germany were still held
directly by this Swiss holding, together with the Dutch company SHV. In
1998, Metro bought all the shares of SHV in the joint European operations,
and transferred their ownership to Metro AG. At that time, Metro had already
started to set up its own (100 percent owned) cash and carry stores in China
and Romania in 1996 (see below).
SHV kept its activities under the Makro cash and carry brand in Latin
America and Asia. By 2009 SHV ran 72 outlets in Brazil, 19 in Argentina, 29
in Venezuela, and 13 in Colombia. In Asia, SHV had been active in Thailand,
Indonesia, China, the Philippines, Malaysia, and South Korea. South Korean
stores were sold to Wal-Mart in 1999, stores in Malaysia were sold to Tesco in
2007, while stores in the Philippines, China, and Indonesia were sold to local
139
Michael Wortmann
partners. In Thailand, by 2009, SHV was running about forty Makro cash and
carry outlets; and a joint venture in Pakistan, started in 2006, operates another
four stores.
Parallel to the integration of these various activities of Kaufhof and Asko,
Metro also tried to get rid of several businesses defined as non-core: the apparel
manufacturing and retailing activities of Adler, the variety stores of Kaufhalle,
and some unprofitable department stores of Kaufhof, the participation in a
furniture store chain, the grocery discount chain Tip, the computer store
franchise Vobis, the shoe stores Reno, the office equipment stores Sigma,
and several other companies, combining sales of nearly $10 billion, were
transferred to a special holding company in which Metro held only 49 per-
cent, and were to be sold whenever possible. The Sigma office equipment
stores were, for example, sold to Staples. In 2005 Metro also divested its
chain of Praktiker DIY stores, originally started by Asko in the 1970s. Praktiker
had become the number four European DIY retailer, which had also entered
Greece, Poland, Hungary, Turkey, Romania, and finally Bulgaria.
From 1998 on, Metro concentrated on four core businesses, integrated in
four divisions: cash and carry (Metro, Makro), food retail (Real, Extra), non-
food specialty stores (especially Media-Saturn), and department stores (Galeria
Kaufhof). In these four business areas, brand integration and internationaliza-
tion were pushed forward from the early 1990s. The department stores of
Kaufhof and Horten were integrated under the Galeria Kaufhof concept and
brand, while smaller and unprofitable stores were sold. In 2001, fifteen depart-
ment stores of Inno in Belgium were added and subsequently also refurbished.
Even though this seems a small step of internationalization, it is remarkable in
the department-store business, where European companies rarely have left
their home market.
The former Kaufhof subsidiary Media-Saturn-Holding became a true cate-
gory killer in the fields of consumer electronics, information and telecommu-
nication products, office equipment, as well as small and large electric
appliances. It carried traditional European manufacturer brands, low-profile
brands of specialized German importers as well as most international com-
puter brands, and also Chinese Haier appliances; but there were no private
labels. Store managers usually owned a participation of around 10 percent in
the single stores and had some degree of autonomy concerning assortment,
pricing, and even advertising. By the mid-1990s there were already 150 Media-
Markt and Saturn stores in Germany, as well as a few stores in France (from
1989), Austria (1990), and Switzerland (1994). Hungary, Poland, and Spain
followed soon after, and in 1999 Media World, a group with twenty-three
stores, was acquired in Italy. Since 2000 the company has entered the Nether-
lands, Portugal, Greece, Sweden, Russia, Turkey, and Luxembourg. At the end
of 2008, there were 768 Media-Markt and Saturn stores, about half of them in
140
Globalization of European Retailing
Germany (367), 315 in Western Europe, and 86 in Eastern Europe. Stores also
became much larger over time: average size grew from 2,500 square meters in
1998 to 3,100 square meters in 2007.
The various food retail chains that Metro had acquired through Asko were
restructured from the early 1990s on. This ultimately led to the divestment of
over 250 supermarkets to the German group Rewe in 2008, while the larger
162 hypermarkets, with an average size of 7,068 square meters, were consoli-
dated under the Real banner chain, which was further expanded in 1998 with
the acquisition of 94 Allkauf and 20 Kriegbaum stores. The Real chain was also
internationalized. The first four stores abroad were opened in Poland in 1997,
and the first Turkish store followed just one year later. After 2005 stores were
also opened in Romania and Russia. In 2006 Metro also acquired nineteen
Géant hypermarkets from the French retailer Casino in Poland. In the same
year, Metro also acquired all eighty-five German Wal-Mart stores. Wal-Mart
had entered the German market in 1997–8 when it took over the stores of
Wertkauf and Eurospar. The reasons for its failure are probably manifold and
cannot be discussed here, but it should be noted that the combined sales of
Wal-Mart in Germany were only a fraction (little more than 10 percent in
2005) of Wal-Mart/Asda sales in the UK, stores—though large by German
standards—were small for Wal-Mart, and the buying organizations of the
two acquired chains were highly fragmented. In 2009, Real operated around
340 hypermarkets in Germany, 54 in Poland, 21 in Romania, 14 in Russia, 13
in Turkey, and 1 in Ukraine.
Amongst the four business divisions of Metro, cash and carry has always
been the core and also the most internationalized. In Germany, most of the
cash and carry markets that had been operated by various acquired companies
were converted to the Metro cash and carry brand. By 2008, Metro had
increased the number of cash and carry markets in Germany to 126, from
about 50 in 1986.
By 1972, Metro, together with its Dutch Partner SHV, had set up outlets in
eight European countries. The two partners then started a second round of
internationalization, beginning in the Mediterranean in the early 1990s.
Metro cash and carry markets were opened in Turkey, and Makro markets in
Portugal, Morocco, and Greece, by 1992. In 1994 expansion turned toward
Eastern Europe: the first stores were opened in Hungary (Metro) and Poland
(Makro); the Czech Republic (Makro) followed in 1997. In 1996 Metro had
also started fully owned operations in Romania.
Another country that Metro entered on its own was China. Here it partnered
with Shanghai-based conglomerate Jinjiang Group, which took 40 percent in
the operations. A first store was opened in Shanghai in 1996. This was a risky
investment, because the Shanghai government licensed such new retail opera-
tions, knowing all the while that at that time the Chinese central government
141
Michael Wortmann
had not allowed foreign companies to hold a majority stake in retail compan-
ies (Wang and Zhang 2005). It did so only in 1998, and Metro received the first
license for the operation of cash and carry outlets throughout China in 1999.
This was welcomed by Metro as a breakthrough for accelerated expansion over
the coming years. Metro has since expanded in the Shanghai area, but also all
over Eastern and Central China. In China, Metro took some innovative mea-
sures. For example, it established training kitchens at its Shanghai and Beijing
stores, whose mission—according to its website—is, on the one hand, to raise
the level of service to professionals by increasing the product knowledge of
Metro staff, “and on the other, through the training of cooking skills, [to]
influence professionals and raise the awareness of Metro’s profile” in China.24
In 2006, Metro raised its stake in the Chinese operation to 90 percent.
After 1998 Metro entered a large number of Eastern European countries:
Bulgaria, Slovakia, Croatia, Russia, Ukraine, Moldova, and Serbia. Besides
China, selected Asian countries were also entered: Japan and Vietnam in
2002, India in 2003, Pakistan in 2007, and Kazakhstan in 2009. In Japan,
Metro joined forces with the huge conglomerate Marubeni, which holds 20
percent in the new company.
Metro’s most important division is also its most internationalized. In 2008,
655 Metro cash and carry outlets accounted for sales of €33 billion, just about
half of total Metro group sales; only 17 percent thereof was realized by its 126
German outlets. Metro is the market leader in the cash and carry business, not
only in Germany, but also in the UK (33 stores), France (91), and Italy (48), as
well as in several other countries, such as Belgium (11), the Netherlands (17),
Poland (29), Romania (24), Russia (48), Slovakia (5), Turkey (13), the Czech
Republic (12), and in China (38).
Metro’s food retailing business, with total sales of €11.6 billion, is much less
internationalized. In Germany, in 2009, Metro’s 343 Real stores were number
two in the hypermarket business, behind Schwarz Group’s Kaufland chain,
while in Poland, Metro’s 50 stores make it also number two, behind Tesco. The
category specialist Media-Markt/Saturn, with its 768 stores and total sales of
€19 billion is highly internationalized. It is the European market leader, ahead
of British DSG International, former Dixons.
Today, Metro is the world’s fourth biggest retailer, with total sales of over
€68 billion. With 39 percent of these sales in Germany, nearly 35 percent in
other Western European countries,25 and nearly 25 percent in Eastern Europe,
Metro is—despite its high degree of internationalization—a very European
company; only 3 percent of its sales are outside Europe, in five Asian countries,
including China, and Morocco.
142
Globalization of European Retailing
Tesco
Jack Cohen started as a grocery market stall holder in London and opened his
first store in 1929. By the end of the 1930s, there were already 100 Tesco stores,
grouped around a modern food warehouse. During two trips to the United
States before and after the Second World War, Cohen learned about the self-
service concept.26 After some experiments with this innovation in the UK, he
opened a first self-service supermarket in 1956. Tesco was soon expanding by
setting up new stores, but also through a large number of acquisitions, adding
several hundred stores to its portfolio. By the late 1960s, the supermarket
chain consisted of about 800 stores. Its supermarkets had also become larger
and larger. In 1968, the first store was opened that was labeled a superstore; it
extended over 4,000 square meters.
In the 1970s Tesco abolished trading stamps and started its “Operation
Checkout” campaign, reducing prices to undercut those of its main competi-
tors. The company also decided to close some 500 small stores and prioritized
the development of large out-of-town superstores where parking was conve-
nient and a higher volume of business could be generated. The 1980s saw the
introduction of computerized checkouts as well as Tesco’s own private labels
for high-quality products, supplemented somewhat later—in reaction to for-
eign hard discounters entering the UK market—by the low-priced Tesco Value
brand. In 2009 more than 10,000 Tesco branded SKUs account for 48 percent
of total sales, the highest share of any full-assortment retailer in the European
Union.
In the early 1980s Tesco had tried to establish its own chain of discount
stores; but the forty-five outlets that had been established were sold after only
four years of trial and error. Tesco, in cooperation with Marks & Spencer, also
began to invest in greenfield shopping centers that held Tesco superstores as
anchor stores. The first of these out-of-town shopping centers had a 6,100-
square-meter Tesco superstore with 900 employees and 42 computerized
checkout counters. By the beginning of the 1990s, Tesco had reduced the
number of its stores to 371, 150 of which were superstores, which generated
most of the company’s sales and profits. And by 1994, after an acquisition of
fifty-seven stores in Scotland and northern England, Tesco had become the
number one grocery retailer in the UK. In the same year Tesco also started
operating a new store format, the Tesco Express convenience stores.
Tesco’s first steps toward internationalization came quite late in comparison
to its main competitors. It started with Ireland in 1979; but the majority share
taken in a local retail chain was divested seven years later. When Tesco took a
majority in a regional retail chain in northern France in 1992, it was unable to
use this as a springboard for further expansion; Tesco withdrew from France in
143
Michael Wortmann
1997, selling its activities to Promodès. While these first two foreign invest-
ments directed toward neighboring mature retail markets had failed, Tesco’s
further expansion into the emerging markets of Eastern Europe and Asia were
to become successful (Dawson, Larke, and Choi 2006).
In 1994 Tesco entered Hungary, acquiring the local Global supermarket
chain with forty-three small stores for £15 million, and, one year later,
it acquired Savia, a chain of thirty-six small supermarkets in Poland, for
£8 million. In both cases Tesco used these companies to acquire some know-
ledge of the local markets including a pool of experienced managers that Tesco
would later use for establishing its own large stores, while closing down the
acquired ones.
The next countries to be entered were the Czech Republic and Slovakia.
Here, Kmart from the USA had acquired thirteen department and variety
stores from the former Czechoslovak government in 1992. Kmart’s problems
in the United States prompted the company to sell the six Kmart stores in the
Czech Republic and the seven stores in Slovakia, most of which were quite
profitable, to Tesco in 1996. With these acquisitions, Tesco was dealing for the
first time with a broad range of non-food merchandise lines, and the company
used the experience that it made with these stores as a starting point to depart
radically from its established superstore format in the UK (Palmer 2005). Tesco
had decided to develop its own hypermarket stores. This new format devel-
oped conjointly in the UK home market and in the distant markets of Eastern
Europe. After a short period of experimentation, hypermarkets became the
main driver of Tesco’s growth in the new century.
In the UK, Tesco opened its first hypermarket in 1997 under the new banner
of Tesco Extra. This store covered over 9,300 square meters, with one-quarter
of the sales area occupied with non-food assortments. By the end of 1999
Tesco operated five hypermarkets in the UK. By the end of 2007 there were
166. The average size of Tesco’s hypermarkets is now about 6,500 square
meters, but at several of these stores non-food accounts for some 40 percent
of sales space. Tesco’s share in the UK non-food market has grown from about
1 percent to over 8 percent since 2000.27
In 1997 Tesco entered the Irish market for the second time, this time
acquiring the supermarket businesses of Associated British Food (ABF),
which had been the market leader both in the Republic of Ireland with
seventy-five supermarkets and in Northern Ireland with thirty-four supermar-
kets. Since then store assortments have been expanded so that they now
include clothing, household, entertainment, and other non-food ranges. A
first Tesco Extra was opened in 2005. In 2003 Tesco entered Turkey, acquiring
the local operator of five hypermarkets, Kipa, which had started operations ten
years previously. Additional openings have increased the number of hyper-
markets to twenty-six. Express convenience stores have also been added.
144
Globalization of European Retailing
From the late 1990s, Tesco speeded up expansion in Eastern Europe. After it
had acquired small companies in Hungary and Poland as local platforms, it
focused its expansion on the hypermarket format, which it was just develop-
ing. In 1998 it opened its first own hypermarkets in Poland, and then in 2002
acquired thirteen hypermarkets (of 5,600–14,200 square meters) from Dohle.
The German company had been the first to introduce hypermarkets into
Poland in 1994. Then, in 2006, Tesco bought 146 soft discount stores from
French Casino. In Hungary, Tesco mainly expanded by setting up new hyper-
markets. Similarly, in the Czech Republic and in Slovakia, the acquired Kmart
stores were transformed and additional hypermarkets were added. In the
Czech Republic Tesco acquired eleven hypermarkets from Carrefour in
2005—in exchange for its outlets in Taiwan. In 2006, Tesco added twenty-
seven supermarkets, bought from German Edeka, to its network.
Internationalization into Asia started in 1998 and right from the start con-
centrated mostly on hypermarkets. Thailand was the first country it entered;
there it acquired a controlling interest in Lotus, then a chain of thirteen
hypermarkets, part of the huge conglomerate Charoen Pokphand Group.28
From this base, Tesco Lotus has built a very strong position made up of 420
stores trading across four formats, including 81 hypermarkets, 307 Express
stores, and 32 supermarkets. In 1999, Tesco formed a joint venture with the
South Korean conglomerate Samsung, which started with two Homeplus
hypermarkets; several new stores have been opened every year since. In
2005, Tesco also acquired twelve hypermarkets from the Korean company
Aram-Mart, and in 2008 Tesco bought thirty-six Homever stores, many of
which were formerly Carrefour hypermarkets. The third Asian market entered
was Taiwan, but here Tesco was unable to grow against strong competitors
that had entered the market before, and thus it handed its six hypermarkets
over to Carrefour in 2006.
In 2002, a joint venture with Malaysia’s conglomerate Sime Darby—with
Tesco holding 70 percent—opened its first three hypermarkets and slowly
added more stores. In 2007, Tesco acquired eight Makro cash and carry stores
from Dutch SHV, which retreated from the market. In 2004, Tesco entered the
Chinese market by founding a 50:50 partnership with Ting Hsin International
Group, which at that time operated twenty-five Hymall hypermarkets in the
Shanghai area. Tesco soon increased its stake to 90 percent, and also opened
further stores in the Beijing and Guangzhou regions. The first Tesco-branded
store, called Tesco Legou, opened in Beijing in February 2007.
While market entry and initial growth in the four Asian emerging markets
of Thailand, South Korea, Malaysia, and China were concentrated on hyper-
markets, Tesco later added convenience Express stores to its networks. The
latest country was China, where the first Express store was opened in Shanghai
in 2008. In Japan, where Tesco acquired several smaller chains in 2003–5, the
145
Michael Wortmann
The sixteen leading European grocery retailers, as listed in Table 4.2, come
from five European countries: Tesco, Sainsbury’s, and Morrisons from the UK;
Carrefour, Casino, Auchan, Leclerc, and Intermarché from France; Metro,
Rewe, Schwarz Group, Aldi, Edeka, and Tengelmann from Germany; Ahold
from the Netherlands, and the Delhaize Group from Belgium. Amongst these
sixteen companies, only two do not have international store operations; these
are the British superstore chains Sainsbury’s and Morrisons. Three other
groups show a very limited level of internationalization; these are all buying
groups: the French voluntary group of independent hypermarkets Leclerc, the
voluntary group of supermarkets Intermarché, and the German cooperative of
supermarket owners Edeka. Intermarché had taken over the German volun-
tary group Spar, then Germany’s seventh biggest grocery retail group,29 with
about 4,000 supermarkets; but in 2005 Spar was sold to Edeka. Edeka, too, has
recently given up most of its international operations, which had been quite
small anyway. The German Rewe is the only buying group amongst the top
146
Table 4.2. Top sixteen European grocery retailers, store count, 2007, and sales, 2008
Store count Home West East Other Latin Asian Africa Gross sales 2008 (€bn)
country Europe Europe DCs America LDCs
Total
(continued)
Table 4.2. (Continued)
Store count Home West East Other Latin Asian Africa Gross sales 2008 (€bn)
country Europe Europe DCs America LDCs
Total
150
Globalization of European Retailing
151
Michael Wortmann
Table 4.3. The biggest grocery retailers, five Eastern European countries, 2006
Metro (DE) Tesco (UK) Schwarz (DE) Coop Jednota (SK) Metro (DE)
Jerónimo Martins (PO) CBA (HU) Ahold (NL) Tesco (UK) Rewe (DE)
Tesco (UK) Metroa (DE) Tesco (UK) Metro (DE) Carrefour (FR)
Carrefour (FR) Co-op (HU) Metro (DE) Schwarz (DE) CBA (HU)
Auchan (FR) Reál (HU) Rewe (DE) Rewe (DE) L. Delhaize (BE)
a
In a joint venture, Metspa, with Spar Austria.
Source: EHI Retail Institute (2008).
has been very successful, first to Spain and Latin America, and later to Asia,
Eastern Europe, and some other South European countries. Auchan has con-
centrated more on Southern Europe (Spain, Italy, and Portugal) as well as five
Eastern European countries; it was only later that it started expansion into
China (1999) and Taiwan. Casino, the leading supermarket chain in France,
has concentrated its internationalization on hypermarkets (Géant) and runs
over 250 hypermarkets in the emerging markets of Latin America (174) and
Asia (72). Another French hypermarket chain, Cora, owned by Belgian Louis
Delhaize,31 has expanded into Hungary and Romania.
Tesco, the only internationalized British grocery retailer, has also concen-
trated its internationalization on hypermarkets, a format that was unknown
to British retailing before Tesco’s internationalization began. The two leading
German hypermarket chains, Kaufland belonging to the Schwarz Group and
Real belonging to Metro, are much less internationalized and have transferred
their hypermarket formats to some East European countries. It is remarkable
that over 75 percent of all non-domestic hypermarkets owned by the top
sixteen companies (in 2007) are located in the emerging markets of Latin
America (18 percent), Asia (28 percent), and Eastern Europe (30 percent);
and, of those hypermarkets operating in other European countries, the major-
ity is located in the less developed retail markets of Southern Europe.
Operators of hypermarkets usually aim to be amongst the top three or so
retailers in each country they enter. In countries where they were unable
to reach this goal after a few years of operation, they often sold their activities
to local companies or, more frequently, to other European hypermarket com-
panies (on international retail divestment, see Burt, Dawson, and Sparks
2004). Operators of hypermarkets can realize relatively few cross-border sy-
nergies and thus need to consolidate their activities in each country they
enter. This is due to the fact that they have to adapt their operations and
their assortment to different national environments—ranging from specific
legal regulations to different consumer tastes.32 Since, for their food depart-
ments, hypermarkets source a large share locally—according to companies’
websites, over 80 percent or even 90 percent—these retailers have to gain
152
Globalization of European Retailing
market share in order to gain buying power vis-à-vis their suppliers and to be
competitive. At the same time they are increasingly rationalizing their local
supply chains.33 In the business literature, such an international strategy is
frequently called multinational or multi-domestic, while a strategy that stan-
dardizes and integrates across borders neglecting national particularities, as do
grocery hard discounters, is labeled global (see Porter 1986; for the retail
industry, see Salmon and Tordjman 1989).
However, for the non-food assortments of hypermarkets, which are to a
large extent private-label ranges, the situation is somewhat different. While
here ultimate buying decisions are made by central buyers working for the
different subsidiaries in the single countries who know the different national
consumer preferences, these buyers are supported by globally operating buy-
ing organizations. These usually have their head office in Hong Kong and
branch offices in a large number of mostly Asian countries. Metro’s Real
hypermarkets are linked to Metro Group Buying, whose antecedents have
operated in Hong Kong since the 1970s. Schwarz Group’s Kaufland had been
a member of the buying group Markant, whose subsidiary Markant Trading
Organization Ltd operates in Hong Kong and Asia; in 2005, the company also
set up its own Kaufland Hong Kong Ltd. Carrefour had set up its Hong Kong
office in 1995; and the other French operators of hypermarkets, Auchan,
Casino and Leclerc (Siplec), also have their own Hong Kong-based buying
organizations in Asia. Tesco moved the headquarter of Tesco International
Sourcing to Hong Kong in 2004; by 2009 “more than 60 percent of all clothing
and 40 percent of other non-food products sold in Tesco’s UK stores, as well as
most of the non-food items sold in the 12 other countries Tesco operates in,
are procured via the retailer’s global sourcing office.”34 Thus while hypermar-
kets source most of their foods locally, their equally important non-food
assortments are increasingly sourced on a global scale, allowing for some
cross-border synergies—for example, when choosing, monitoring, and bar-
gaining with suppliers.35
Hypermarkets seem to have been the ideal grocery retail format to enter the
emerging markets of Eastern Europe, Latin America, and Asia, as well as the
less-developed retail markets of Southern Europe.36 One reason for hypermar-
kets being so suitable is that they can operate as stand-alone sites. Because of
their size, hypermarkets do not need the support of distribution centers. These
were usually set up only after a company had established at least a handful of
hypermarket outlets in a certain country. In a third step, the established
distribution infrastructures were then sometimes used to serve smaller stores,
such as supermarkets, convenience stores, and also discount stores, which
cannot operate standing alone.37
Internationalization patterns of retail companies from the four biggest
Western European countries depend highly on the formats these companies
153
Michael Wortmann
operate. As we have seen, the development of retail formats has been shaped
by retail regulations embedded in national general and retail-specific institu-
tional traditions. In Italy, tight retail regulations did not allow the develop-
ment of modern retail companies, and no internationally competitive retailers
have developed there. Instead, Italy became a host country for foreign retai-
lers, especially for hypermarket chains from France. In Germany, retail regula-
tions limiting store size, originally intended to protect small independent
retailers, have helped (as an unintended consequence) limited-assortment
hard discounters to become the leading retail format in this country—a retail
format that could also grow in niches in other developed retail markets. In the
UK, where early and unrestricted retail modernization led to the gradual
transformation of supermarkets into superstores, a format not fit for interna-
tionalization, Tesco remained the only British multinational retail company;
it developed the hypermarket format only in the context of its internationali-
zation. Finally, in France, the invention of the hypermarket at a time when
supermarkets had not yet fully developed, as well as ineffective regulations,
have made France home for the strong operators of hypermarkets, the format
most appropriate for internationalization in the emerging markets of Eastern
Europe, Asia, and Latin America.
154
5
Introduction
Rapid technological change and the emergence of the World Wide Web
(WWW) have enabled many new firms to rewrite the rules of doing business
in different retail sectors of the US economy. Since the advent of the Netscape
Corporation’s browser software, Navigator, in December 1994, online retail
sales have grown steadily. In 2007 the US Commerce Department indicated
that online retail sales amounted to $108.7 billion in 2006, representing an
increase of 23.5 percent over 2005. In contrast, US total retail sales in 2006
increased 5.8 percent from 2005 to reach a total of $3.9 trillion. In 2006,
online retail sales accounted for 2.8 percent of total US retail sales, and were
expected to double over the next few years.
There is now a large body of knowledge that highlights and discusses the
Internet’s growing universality, and its impact on society in general, and
commerce in particular. It is oft-noted that the Internet signals a fundamental
shift in the nature of competition in certain, if not all, industries (Armstrong
and Hagel 1996; Grove 1996; Evans and Wurster 1997). To many observers,
the Internet presents both an opportunity and a threat for commerce. On the
one hand, it is perceived as a threat because it enables people and businesses to
connect directly, thereby sidestepping intermediaries such as distributors and
retailers (Gates 1995; Lohr 1997). Also, since the Internet has the potential
fundamentally to alter the “economics of information” (Evan and Wurster,
1997), and the way information is communicated, it threatens incumbents in
many retail sectors such as music retailing, travel, and book retailing, to name
a few. Prior to the Internet, many firms in such retail sectors exploited the
information asymmetries between buyers and sellers to make profits. The
Suresh Kotha and Sandip Basu
In other words, falling “transaction costs” (Williamson 1979) and the avail-
ability of information via the Internet are eroding the profit margins and the
competitive advantages of businesses in many retail sectors.
On the other hand, the Internet provides new entrants, in numerous in-
dustries, with opportunities to alter the dynamics of competition. Many new
ventures that did not exist prior to commercialization of the Internet have
now become household names. They include firms such as eBay, Amazon.
com, Yahoo, Google, RealNetworks, ETrade, and Expedia, to name a few.
Interestingly, the same technology that was once perceived as a disruptive
threat is now enabling existing brick-and-mortar retailers such as Barnes &
Noble, Borders Books and Music, Best Buy, Circuit City, and Wal-Mart,
amongst others, to become multi-channel players and compete in physical
as well as online markets. In other words, over time brick-and-mortar retailers
have found ways to leverage and complement their brick-and-mortar experi-
ence and skills to compete effectively online.
Early online retailers (for example, Amazon.com) had the task of “making
the market” to ensure their own sustainability and profitability in the
emerging online retail sectors. For a business, making a market involves the
execution of a series of interrelated activities designed to get important stake-
holders to buy into its “new” business model (Dedrick and Kraemer, Chapter
11 this volume). Therefore, market-making activities often have outcomes
that not only benefit the firm initiating these activities, but extend to all
incumbents and even future entrants in the particular industry. As discussed
in detail later, these outcomes involve the transfer of market power to incum-
bents from other players in the particular retail sector’s value chain.
The purpose of this chapter is (1) to illustrate how online goliaths such as
Amazon.com and eBay have become market makers over a short time period
(less than a decade) using new Internet technologies and the emerging online
medium for interaction (that is, the cyber marketplace); and (2) to describe
how online retailers continue to be market makers as Internet technologies
evolve and change.
156
Amazon and eBay
Table 5.1. Online retailers vs top ten specialty retailers and general merchandisers
Online retailers
Amazon.com 237 10,711 26 190 47 13,900
eBay 383 5,970 31 1,126 4 12,900
Top ten specialty retailing firms
1 Home Depot 17 90,837 11 5,761 1 305,760
2 Costco 32 60,151 14 1,103 4 99,000
3 Lowe’s 45 46,927 9 3,105 12 157,349
4 Best Buy 72 30,848 12 1,140 16 128,000
5 Staples 125 18,161 13 974 17 56,542
6 TJX 133 17,516 9 738 7 125,000
7 Gap 144 15,943 0 778 30 154,000
8 Office Depot 156 15,011 5 516 89 38,000
9 Toy “R” Us 202 12,206 8 28 — 59,000
10 Circuit City 215 11,598 11 140 127 46,007
157
Suresh Kotha and Sandip Basu
and has over time expanded beyond books. In less than a decade, it has
become an important market maker in its own right by connecting thousands
of smaller online and brick-and-mortar retailers to a vast group of online retail
customers that it has managed to attract and retain on its website. In contrast,
eBay.com brings together millions of buyers and sellers in an online market-
place daily, and has become a cultural phenomenon in its own right (The
Economist 2005). eBay is a “pure” online intermediary that connects millions
of buyer and sellers worldwide without taking control of or carrying inven-
tory. In doing so, it has created a marketplace that spans many retail sectors
and geographical locations around the world. Using the power of many, the
company delivers the efficiency of a global market to buyers and sellers,
irrespective of their size or location (The Economist 2005).
Using these two examples, we discuss how the presence of these online
retailers has impacted incumbents or brick-and-mortar retailers such as Barnes
& Noble, and others. Many established brick-and-mortar retailers have reacted
to moves from online retailers such as Amazon.com and eBay by entering the
online retailing sector themselves, and finding innovative ways to leverage
their physical assets online. We conclude this chapter by highlighting some
trends in online retailing and how online retailers are enabling further market-
making activity as they continue to evolve and change.
158
Amazon and eBay
promotion and marketing (Kotha 1998). Amazon served its millionth cus-
tomer in the autumn of 1997, after which its customer base quickly grew to
ten million by the spring of 1999—less than four years since the company’s
inception. By 2006, the company’s sales revenues reached over $10.7 billion
(a figure that was higher than Nordstrom, another well-known Seattle-based
retailer), and profits were $190 million.
159
Suresh Kotha and Sandip Basu
Chains
Independents
Superstores
160
Amazon and eBay
turn supply the hundreds of retail bookstores located throughout the country.
According to industry estimates in 1996, wholesalers accounted for almost
30 percent of publishers’ sales. In contrast to publishing and book retailing,
wholesalers are highly concentrated, with firms such as Ingram Book Co.
commanding the major share (50 percent in 1995) of the market. Competi-
tion in the wholesale sector revolves around the speed of delivery and the
number of titles stocked. Ingram, for instance, receives more than 70 percent
of its orders electronically and offers one-day delivery to about 82 percent of
its US customers. In 1994, the average net profit for wholesalers was less than
1.5 percent. This figure was down from the traditional margins of about
2 percent a few years earlier (Publishers Weekly 1996a).
At the time of Amazon.com’s entry into the industry in 1995, bookstore
chains sold more books than independents for the first time (Philadelphia
Business Journal 1996). Retail bookstores, independents, and general retailers
accounted for 35–40 percent of industry revenues. From 1975 to 1995, the
number of bookstores in the USA increased from 11,990 to 17,340, and these
bookstores accounted for about 21 percent of the total retail book sales. The
superstores, such as Barnes & Noble and Borders Books and Music, accounted
for about 15 percent of all retail sales. Estimates suggest that from 1992
through 1995, superstore bookstore sales grew at a compounded rate of
71 percent while non-superstore sales grew at a rate of 4 percent.
During the mid-1990s, industry experts were cautioning that a shakeout
was inevitable in smaller markets. Superstores, originally confined to big
metropolitan areas, were increasingly entering markets with populations of
150,000 or less. Industry estimates indicated that superstores had to make
around $200 a square foot to turn a profit. A typical Barnes & Noble superstore
needed, for example, $3 million to $4 million in sales revenues to break even.
Some industry observers questioned whether smaller cities could support one
or more of these mammoth stores and whether superstores in these locations
could sell enough books to turn a profit (Publishers Weekly 1996b). Mr Vlahos,
a spokesperson for the American Booksellers’ Association, noted (as quoted
in New York Times 1996): “In the three years from 1993 to 1995, 150 to 200
independent-owned bookstores went out of business—50 to 60 in 1996
alone . . . By contrast in the same period, approximately 450 retail superstore
outlets opened, led by Barnes & Noble and the Borders Group, with 348
openings.” It was under these conditions, when Barnes & Noble (the industry
leader in book retailing) was in the midst of one of its biggest rollouts, that
Bezos launched Amazon.com as an online bookstore.
As Figure 5.2 illustrates, all of the participants in the book-retailing value
chain could, in theory, directly reach end customers using Internet technolo-
gies. In 1997, the largest US distributor of books, Ingram, attempted to enter
the “retailing” segment. It tested a service to create new online retailers to
161
Suresh Kotha and Sandip Basu
Chains
Independents
Consumers
Authors Publishers Wholesalers
Superstores
Majors
Numerous Independents Two Players
Book Clubs
Online Stores
Figure 5.2. Book industry value chain after the entry of online book stores such as
Amazon.com
mitigate the growing power of Amazon.com. All the would-be retailers had to
do was lure the shoppers to their respective website. Ingram handled every-
thing else, from maintaining the would-be-retailers’ website to taking orders,
processing credit-card billings, and shipping the books directly from Ingram’s
warehouses. In effect, the virtual bookshops became little more than a retail
façade of Ingram. However, after six months of test marketing, it quietly
pulled the plug (Bianco 1997). Ingram’s experimental foray into online retail-
ing failed in part because many of the new online entrants were unable to
attract enough customers to their websites. Thus, the possibility that all the
industry players could reach end-customers directly in book retailing failed to
materialize.
With the emergence of online retailing, however, independent brick-and-
mortar bookstores continue to go out of business. Additionally, as customers
migrate to online bookstores, established book chains (for example, Dalton
books) are finding it difficult to compete, and book clubs are no longer in a
162
Amazon and eBay
163
Suresh Kotha and Sandip Basu
164
Amazon and eBay
165
Suresh Kotha and Sandip Basu
166
Amazon and eBay
brand. When it first opened, eBay offered 10 product categories, but by mid-
1998 it was offering 846 categories organized into 12 major categories, with
collectibles accounting for the majority of the listings. By 2002, automobiles
had become the single largest category traded on eBay (based on global
annualized gross merchandise sales), accounting for nearly four times the
revenues generated by collectibles. At the end of 2006, eBay had 222 million
registered users (more than the combined population of France, Spain, and
Britain), of which 82 million were considered as active users (users who had
bid for or listed items within the past year). At the time, the number of items
listed on the company’s website was 2.4 billion. eBay’s net revenues for the
year were $5.9 billion, and the net income was $1.12 billion.
167
Suresh Kotha and Sandip Basu
168
Amazon and eBay
169
Suresh Kotha and Sandip Basu
online store fronts established by eBay users in locations around the world
(eBay 2006). Using customized pages, operators of eBay stores are able to
showcase all their listings and describe their respective businesses.6 Also,
eBay provides a variety of tools to build such stores, manage operations,
promote products, and track performance.
eBay and Amazon.com have, through their market-making activities, trans-
formed retailing since 1995 and in doing so they have become household
names. Despite entering different retail sectors in the mid-1990s, their mar-
keting-making actions were more similar than different in many ways. First,
both companies transformed the retail sectors they entered: eBay transformed
the auctions market by moving such activity online, and Amazon.com trans-
formed book retailing by transforming this sector’s value chain before enter-
ing other retail sectors. Second, both companies through their market-making
actions have come to dominate their respective retail sectors. Both Amazon.
com and eBay pioneered many innovations (for example, 1-click ordering,
personalized websites, escrow and insurance) that were directed at creating an
“ecosystem” so that online retail could emerge, grow, and flourish. Third,
both firms rapidly expanded their product categories, thus affecting many
retail sectors of the economy. Further, they expanded their operations outside
the USA and thereby extended their market-making activities beyond the
US retail markets to help the emergence and growth of online markets
in other parts of the world. They have empowered customers around the
world through information, so that they can make better-informed retailing
decisions.
Finally, both have enabled smaller players to compete successfully alongside
large retailers by providing a technology platform out of which they could
operate. This has prompted some like Bob Kagle of Benchmark capital, a well-
known Silicon Valley venture-capital company, to note that “eBay is in a
position to give back to America what Wal-Mart took away—the notion of
the Main Street merchant. Mom and Pop running their little shop, doing
business with other people, making a living at it, and feeling good about it”
(quoted in Bradley and Porter 2000: 4). For these merchants, all or most of
their income comes from selling on eBay’s website (CNBC 2005). If eBay
employed the people who operated mom-and-pop stores on its website, it
would be the United States’ second largest employer after Wal-Mart. Amazon.
com too has made it possible for many small merchants to use its technology
platform to reach end customers. The company now derives over 25 percent of
its sales through the activity of such merchants. This emergence of such small
operators is an interesting counter-development to the trend highlighted in
Chapter 1, where it was argued that large retailers like Wal-Mart were captur-
ing a lion’s share of the retail sales globally, and thus consolidating the retail
industry.
170
Amazon and eBay
We now turn to describe trends in online retailing and how retailers continue
to be market makers, as Internet technologies and business models evolve in
retailing. We begin by examining how the online retailing landscape has
changed since 1995.
Hard
Houses
Cars
Ease of transaction
Loans
Flights
Books
CDs
Easy
Less More
Value added by online services
171
Suresh Kotha and Sandip Basu
1 Motors 16,508 11
2 Consumer Electronics 4,880 25
3 Clothing and Accessories 4,540 16
4 Computers 4,052 13
5 Home & Garden 3,584 24
6 Books/Movies/Music 3,124 4
7 Collectibles 2,684 6
8 Sports 2,584 11
9 Business and Industrial 2,232 19
10 Toys 2,136 10
11 Jewels & Watches 1,972 13
12 Cameras & Photo 1,524 6
13 Antiques & Art 1,352 12
14 Coins & Stamps 1,320 26
a
Worldwide annualized gross market value (GMV) for the three months ended Mar. 31, 2007.
Source: eBay (2007).
on eBay, a fact that surprised even its own management. Of the fourteen
categories that traded with over a $1 billion in gross market value, coin and
stamps ranked last, with annualized sales reaching $1.3 billion (see Table 5.2).
Collectibles and antiques had also fallen behind many other categories on
eBay’s website. However, in terms of change in growth from the previous year,
coins and stamps were still robust.
172
Amazon and eBay
available online that many retail sectors have found the online space to be a
viable marketplace for their products.
173
Suresh Kotha and Sandip Basu
174
Amazon and eBay
and together provide a vast selection of items not found in big retail stores,
including Wal-Mart. For smaller players who target specific niche markets, ties
with search engines or traffic aggregators, such as Google, provide visibility
based on relevant online users’ searches (Morgan Stanley Report 2006). Ties
with aggregators, while helping aggregators diversify, also divert traffic from the
aggregators’ to the niche players’ websites.
However, according to Forrester, the movement toward one-stop shopping
convenience is also resulting in the consolidation of the industry, as larger
online retail companies acquire smaller players that sell niche products with
low-cost structures (Forrester Research Inc. 2007). However, it does not seem
likely that such consolidation will result in fewer niche players in the future.
This is because the relatively low level of barriers-to-entry is one of the most
alluring features of the Internet and continues to draw thousands of entrepre-
neurs to set up businesses on the Internet.
175
Suresh Kotha and Sandip Basu
the demise of many established retail firms. However, since the mid-1990s,
many established brick-and-mortar retailers have adapted by pursuing multi-
channel strategies where online retail complements their physical presence
(Grosso, McPherson, and Shi 2005). For instance, brick-and-mortar retailers
are driving traffic to their physical stores by using techniques such as gift
cards, rich-media advertisements, and e-mail notifications via the Internet.
Their websites offer convenience, product information, and updates on pric-
ing and promotions, whereas their physical stores offer customers the ability
to touch and feel their goods before purchase. Some retailers, such as Best Buy,
are also allowing customers to order online, and then pick up their product at
their physical locations. Additionally, if a customer who ordered online is not
satisfied with the purchase, he or she can return the merchandise at the closest
brick-and-mortar location. In other words, companies are leveraging the com-
plementary advantages of both the physical and virtual channels better to
meet customer needs.7
The debate by the mid-2000s was no longer about whether “pure” online
retailers or brick-and-mortar retailers would dominate the Internet; rather,
since that time, the debate has centered more on how retailers in general are
finding innovative ways to employ available Internet technology to create
new, and to maintain existing, customer markets. In doing so, they continue
to dominate other members of their respective value chains.
Concluding Thoughts
Despite the extensive media coverage accorded to the emergence and growth
of online retailing, it still represents a small, although growing, sector of
overall retailing. The future penetration of online retailing is still expected to
be less than 10 percent of total US retail sales in the next few years. Although
this number might seem small, the major impact of online retailers lies not
in the displacement of physical incumbents but in transforming the ways that
these incumbents operate. Online retailers such Amazon.com and eBay,
through their market-making activities, have fundamentally altered the retail
landscape. Most importantly, Amazon.com and eBay have forced “tradi-
tional” brick-and-mortar retailers in many retail sectors around the world to
respond and adapt their business models to find innovative ways to compete
effectively. Today, the issue is not whether brick-and-mortar retailers will
survive vis-à-vis online players, but more about how retailers can continue
to amass market power using Internet technologies.
According to Forrester Research Inc. (2010), online retail in both the USA and
Western Europe remains “poised for a robust period of double-digit growth
176
Amazon and eBay
over the next five years. [ . . . ]. In the US, Web shopping will account for
8 percent of total retail sales by 2014,” up from 6 percent in 2009. However,
this trend in online shopping is not limited to the USA. As eBay and Amazon.
com continue to diffuse Internet technologies around the world, many shop-
pers around the world will eventually begin to experience the wonders of online
retailing. Moreover, as brick-and-mortar retailers co-opt Internet technology,
they will also help the growth of online retailing. As global Internet users begin
to exceed a billion, both brick-and-mortar retailer and online retailers as market
makers are poised to transform retailing, as we currently understand it.
177
This page intentionally left blank
Part Three
Making Supplier Markets
This page intentionally left blank
6
Introduction
Since the 1970s, the world’s most globally engaged economies have become
increasingly demand-responsive economies. By demand-responsive economies,
we mean that such economies are organized “backwards” from demand to
production, instead of “forward” from production to demand. In making this
claim, we are arguing that global retailers, generating intermediary demand in
anticipation of final demand, have superseded manufacturers as the driving
force that organizes, directly through supply chain contracts and indirectly
through their vast market power, whole sectors of the global economy.
On the surface, this change may not seem all that significant. Ever since
Adam Smith, economists have recognized that factors relating to demand are
prominent features of all advanced market economies. Without demand, so
the dictum goes, supply withers. The timelessness of this maxim, however,
masks the changes that have occurred in how supply and demand are config-
ured over time. Conceptualized in the abstract, supply and demand are merely
aggregations, respectively, of all sellers and all buyers relative to a good. Far
from being static, in reality, at different times and places, supply and demand
represent very differently organized groups of sellers and buyers. Since the
writing of Chamberlin (1962 [1933]) and Robinson (1969 [1933]) on “monop-
olistic competition,” economists have recognized that the organization of
sellers relative to buyers matters, but implications of monopolistic competi-
tion have seldom been applied to retailers, in large part because retailers have
been seen as merely conduits between manufacturers and final consumers.1
More importantly, the implications of monopolistic competition have not
been applied at the level of national economies. As we point out in this
Gary G. Hamilton and Cheng-shu Kao
chapter, global retailers, or “big buyers” as Gary Gereffi (1994b) calls them, are
not benign intermediaries. They are big enough to influence the internal
organization of entire economies. Big buyers not only create demand; they
also organize suppliers and develop supplier markets to fill that demand.
Through using advanced consumer research, point-of-sales (POS) informa-
tion, supply-line management, and sophisticated information technology,
retailers and merchandisers have restructured the relationship between buyers
and suppliers, making the latter a price-sensitive organizational extension of
the former. These forged links between the market-focused big buyers, on the
one hand, and globally dispersed and largely faceless manufacturers, on the
other hand, have had direct repercussions on economies around the world. In
general, the more globally involved the capitalist economy, the more demand
responsive that economy has become.
How do economies become demand responsive, and what empirically and
theoretically does that mean? This chapter gives a detailed answer to this ques-
tion by showing how the Taiwanese economy developed in response to orders
given by global retailers and brand-name merchandisers. In the first section, we
use disaggregated trade data to demonstrate that the globalization of supplier
markets for US-based retailers and brand-name merchandisers occurred first and
most pervasively in East Asia, especially in Taiwan and South Korea, and to show
the differential effects of these markets on structuring these Asian economies.
The establishment of these suppliers in East Asia created what is known as “the
Asian Miracle,” the extraordinarily rapid and ongoing industrialization that
occurred from 1965 through to the present day. A lot has been written about
Asian economic development, but what is less known is that, in response to the
retailers’ orders, Asian economies developed in very different ways.2
In the main section of the chapter, drawing on hundreds of interviews done
over a period of over twenty years, we show how these supplier markets
in Taiwan actually developed and how many of these suppliers, in turn,
responded to changing economic conditions by moving their businesses to
Mainland China. These interviews allow us to specify how the Taiwan econ-
omy became organized “backwards” from the development of consumer
markets in the USA to the development of suppliers markets for final and
intermediate goods in East Asia.
Modern retailers are the “makers” of two types of markets, consumer markets
and supplier markets.3 In the last half of the twentieth century, both types of
markets grew tremendously, and became increasingly global and increasingly
182
The Asian Miracle and Demand-Responsive Economies
183
Gary G. Hamilton and Cheng-shu Kao
35
30
25
20
%
15
10
0
1890 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
Trade/GNP Trade in goods/GNP
Figure 6.1. US total foreign trade and trade in goods as a percentage of GNP, 1890–2000
184
The Asian Miracle and Demand-Responsive Economies
80
70
60
50
%
40
30
20
10
0
1965 1975 1985 1995
Electronics Shoes Luggage/leather Toys Sporting goods
Apparel Photo Appliances
brands to get around fair-trade laws. As retailers expanded in the late 1950s
and 1960s, large department stores, such as Macy’s and Sears, began to use
private labels more extensively. Kenmore washers and Craftsman tools are two
examples of Sears’s in-house brands, but the use of in-house brands for cloth-
ing and shoes also became commonplace. This expansion of garment and
footwear production quickly exceeded the capacity (and willingness) of US
manufacturers to provide these goods and led to the increasing use of Asian
intermediaries (for example, Japanese trading companies) to fill the orders.
185
Gary G. Hamilton and Cheng-shu Kao
90
80
70
% of total US Imports
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1975 1985 1995 1975 1985 1995 1975 1985 1995 1975 1985 1995 1975 1985 1995 1975 1985 1995
Apparel Electronics Footwear Leather goods Sporting goods Toys and dolls
China/Taiwan/Hongkong Japan/Korea
Figure 6.3. Imports from East Asia as a percentage of total US imports of consumer
goods 1975–1995
6,000
5,000
4,000
3,000
2,000
1,000
0
1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988
Figure 6.4. Number of seven-digit TSUSA categories of US imports from South Korea
and Taiwan, total and footwear + garments (F&G) combined, 1972–1988
Note: F+G: footwear and garments combined.
186
The Asian Miracle and Demand-Responsive Economies
Most writers miss the significance of these US-bound exports. They typically
emphasize the large volume and rapid growth of exports, which they explain
through a “supply-side” narrative extolling the economic prowess of the
exporting country. Using aggregated trade data, typically supplied by the
exporting countries, they note the overall similarity in the exports, and as a
consequence the overall similarity amongst the NICs. The similarity is indeed
there—at the third digit TSUSA level. Feenstra and Hamilton (2006) show the
“export landscape” for both South Korea and Taiwan using TSUSA data ag-
gregated to three digits from 1972 to 1988. From these landscapes, it is
apparent that most of the export value from these economies is primarily in
just a handful of major categories and that, with a few exceptions, the export
landscapes of the two countries look very similar. Moreover, the principal
categories of exports from both South Korea and Taiwan are exactly those
categories of consumer goods that fueled the retail revolution in the United
States: garments, footwear, bicycles, toys, televisions, microwaves, computers,
thousands of plastic household and office items, and a large array of electronic
components that in turn became the building block of a vast and growing
number of other products.
If we survey the main items of exports throughout the period from 1972 to
1985, it becomes clear that products secured through contract manufacturing
form an extremely high percentage of the total exports. For instance, accord-
ing to a report on the Korean garment industry, “until 1988, approximately
95 percent of garment exports were produced under contract to foreign firms,
rather than under Korean-owned labels” (Lee and Song 1994: 148). According
to Levy’s analysis (1988: 46) of the footwear industry in South Korea and
Taiwan, “in the initial phases of export expansion, export business in both
nations was based overwhelmingly on the fulfillment of orders placed by
Japanese trading companies, and designed for the US market.” Japanese trad-
ing companies were soon supplanted as Western firms began to place their
orders directly. In both countries, Western brand-name merchandisers, such
as Nike and Reebok, controlled the export footwear industry (Levy 1988,
1991). Also, in his case study of the manufacture of personal computers in
the two countries, Levy (1988) cites figures from the trade associations for
electronic appliances showing that 84 percent of Korean-made personal com-
puters and 72 percent of Taiwan-made computers were sold under non-local
brand names. Taiwan was also the world’s largest exporter of bicycles during
the 1980s and early 1990s, and its export industry until the late 1980s was
largely OEM manufacturing (Cheng and Sato 1998). At one point in the late
1970s, Schwinn placed an order of 100 million bicycles with Giant, “which
was then only a small factory” (Cheng and Sato 1998: 7).
If we examine the lists of exported finished manufactured products in those
early years of economic growth, it is difficult to find any major product
187
Gary G. Hamilton and Cheng-shu Kao
188
The Asian Miracle and Demand-Responsive Economies
Neither Nike nor Reebok had the organizational capacity . . . to meet . . . surges in
demand by subdividing . . . enormous orders amongst dozens of small, efficient
producers. Instead both companies turned to the giant Korean footwear factories,
which had inhouse operations in excess of forty production lines. Firms met
[these] orders by expanding their capacity even further. [A consequence of these
orders was] continued dependence of Korean footwear industry on a single foot-
wear item—non-rubber athletic shoes—which accounted in 1985 for an over-
whelming 71.3 percent of Korean footwear exports . . . By contrast to Korea,
footwear exports from Taiwan have become increasingly diversified over time . . .
[The] small size [of Taiwanese firms] affords Taiwanese producers the flexibility
necessary to fill rapidly shifting niches for small volume fashion items.
189
Gary G. Hamilton and Cheng-shu Kao
2,500
2,000
1,000
500
0
72 76 80 84 88 75 79 83 87
Figure 6.5. Categories of US imports of footwear from South Korea and Taiwan,
1972–1988
Now we will turn to the Taiwanese case in order to show the process by
which these supplier markets emerged and by which the entire economy
changed as a consequence.
It is hard to date the first moment when industrialization began, and perhaps
it is useless to do so. But it is certain that the new economic trend in Taiwan
began when the first big buyers arrived. We do not know who these buyers
were, because no one sufficiently noticed them to record their arrival. It is also
190
The Asian Miracle and Demand-Responsive Economies
certain that the initial intermediaries were not the Taiwanese themselves. In
those early years, as far as the Taiwanese were concerned, Taiwan was a closed
island, and they and their resources were locked inside. Martial law was
enforced. The government strictly controlled both people and money. The
Taiwanese, therefore, simply did not know the foreign markets for which they
would soon be making products. And, of course, very few locals spoke any
English at all. The historical context makes it clear that the foreign buyers
came to Taiwan before the Taiwanese went to the buyers in the USA, Europe,
and Japan, as they would do with increasing frequency in the 1980s.
191
Gary G. Hamilton and Cheng-shu Kao
192
The Asian Miracle and Demand-Responsive Economies
the intermediate goods needed to make a product, and then coordinate the
delivery of the goods to retail markets in Japan or more frequently in the USA.
Third, during the late 1960s, Taiwan was the largest recipient of Japanese
foreign investment (Economist Intelligence Unit 1983). Records on foreign
direct investments in Taiwan show that the absolute total of US investments
exceeded investments from Japan, but Japanese investments involved over
three times as many individual investments than those from the USA (Duan
1992: 236). These figures point to a different investment strategy between the
US and Japanese businesses. On the US side, a few large US multinationals (for
example, RCA) set up stand-alone manufacturing plants in export-processing
zones producing consumer electronics, and on average these investments
were much larger than FDI (foreign direct investment) from Japan. In fact,
in 1975, nine of the ten largest companies in Taiwan by revenues were all
American companies; the other one, Philips Electronics Industries, was a
Dutch company (Chu and Amsden 2003: 28). By contrast, guided by the
general trading companies, Japanese companies usually established joint ven-
tures with Taiwanese firms. Some of these Japanese companies themselves
were modest-sized companies; others were subsidiaries of the large Japanese
business groups. In both cases, however, the firms established with Japanese
direct foreign investment were smaller and economically more diverse than
American firms. Typically, the Japanese firm controlled the technology and
supervised the manufacturing process, and a Japanese trading company
secured the order and then marketed the final product. In the 1960s, Hitachi,
Matsushita (Panasonic), Sanyo Electric, Ricoh, Mitsubishi Electric, Casio,
amongst many other Japanese firms, started operations in Taiwan.
Fourth, although the figures seem more like rough estimates than firm
assessments, a number of analysts (Olson 1970; Wade 1990; Fields 1995;
Feenstra and Hamilton 2006) state that Japanese general trading companies
served as the broker for over half of Taiwan’s exports from the late 1960s
through most of the 1970s. If this figure is accurate, then we must conclude
that the general trading companies were not just mere merchants, but were
rather active agents in financing, supervising, and supplying the Taiwanese
manufacturers. In effect, the Japanese trading companies initiated Taiwan’s
supplier markets.
This seminal role, however, did not last long, for very soon Western buyers
and Taiwanese trading companies began to play active roles in establishing
Taiwanese suppliers of goods ordered by Western retailers and brand-name
merchandisers. In the resulting mix, Japanese trading companies increasingly
began to specialize in a narrow, but still important segment of the overall
market economy—namely, in supplying Taiwanese manufacturers with capi-
tal goods and intermediate inputs required in the manufacturing process:
machine tools, the gear boxes for bicycles, and specialty metals and chemicals
193
Gary G. Hamilton and Cheng-shu Kao
194
The Asian Miracle and Demand-Responsive Economies
195
Gary G. Hamilton and Cheng-shu Kao
196
The Asian Miracle and Demand-Responsive Economies
Although we did not ask many questions about the process of obtaining
orders, we did ask again and again how factory owners were able to make
the products for which they had the orders. Many of products were extraordi-
narily complex or required very complex manufacturing procedures. It always
seemed remarkable to us that the Taiwanese manufacturers, often with very
limited education, had been able to figure out how to make the products that
they were, in fact, making. For instance, the Chairman of Thunder Tiger, a
firm making airplanes for the hobbyist market, had only an elementary school
education, and yet, amongst his many accomplishments, he had figured out
how to manufacture miniature drone jet airplanes. Chairman Tseng, the
manufacturer of plastic lawn chair furniture, who at the time of our interview
had huge contracts from both Wal-Mart and Kmart, had only the equivalent
of a junior high education, and yet he invented a one-step manufacturing
process to change raw plastic into finished products. Their stories are not
unusual. In fact, most factory owners in Taiwan’s first wave of industrializa-
tion not only did not have advanced degrees, but also had no training in
manufacturing in general or in making their specific product in particular.
The question that we asked repeatedly was how did they learn to make the
products. The answer that we received was always some form of imitation and
innovation based on an existing product. This process of imitation and
innovation is usually a very difficult and complex process. The term often
given to this process is “reverse engineering,” which makes the process sound
simple, but there is nothing easy or automatic about copying someone else’s
design. In the case of OEM production, the big buyers would often bring the
samples, sometimes amounting to nothing more than just an idea designed
on paper, with them to Taiwan, and ask the manufacturers, or more likely the
owners of trading companies, “Can you make it for such and such a price?”
Then, before they could obtain the order, they would have to deliver a
197
Gary G. Hamilton and Cheng-shu Kao
prototype, just to show that they could do it. The turnaround time on such a
query was often very short, because frequently the buyers would just sit in
their hotels waiting for the prototype to appear. With a very short lead time,
the Taiwanese manufacturers would have to produce their prototype.
This process of innovating based on an existing product design is a skill that
Taiwan manufacturers learned to perfect. In the first decade of rapid growth,
many of the OEM products were comparatively simple and were ordered in
fairly small batches. Taiwanese manufacturers learned how to produce these
products in a variety of ways, some from their experience in working in other
factories, some from instructions provided by Japanese trading companies and
suppliers of machine tools, and some from the big buyers themselves. How-
ever, once in business, they learned quickly from others in their production
network. In this context, learning was both singular and collaborative.
It was singular in the sense that one firm typically took the lead to produce
the prototype. The owner and key employees of this firm would design and
make a prototype. At this stage, very few people might be involved, but those
people would have to have a lot of knowledge about the product, and would
have to go to some lengths to acquire this knowledge. Factory owners fre-
quently told us that they would obtain this knowledge by going to trade
shows, by finding samples of similar products and taking them apart, by
closely reading trade journals where new developments were announced,
and by pursuing others who had knowledge about the product or materials
the products were made of. Wherever they obtained this knowledge, they
would then actively try to innovate on the design to come up with something
special that would give their goods a distinctive feel.
Learning was also collaborative in the sense that the process of production
was a function of the network and not simply of the firm. Therefore, learning
how to produce a given prototype required considerable cooperation amongst
a group of independent manufacturers. These manufacturers would have to
work together very closely on coordinating all aspects of production. In the
course of this collaboration, the division of labor amongst manufacturers had
to be cost effective, because any inefficiencies would cut into their collective
profits. The network of producers, therefore, would constantly learn how to
produce products with higher quality while achieving lower costs and how to
work together seamlessly. This process of manufacturing also led to improve-
ments in product design.
In another location, we show how this combination of individual imitative
by, and cooperation amongst, business people is anchored in distinctively
Chinese patterns of social organization (Kao and Hamilton 2009). We refer to
these patterns as an adaptation of “round-table etiquette” applied to eco-
nomic activity, with the result that Taiwanese business people could quickly
take advantage of money-making opportunities that began to appear in the
198
The Asian Miracle and Demand-Responsive Economies
1970s. The constant interaction between the product and the process of
production, as well as between the firm and the networks of which the firms
are a part, created in Taiwan’s first wave of industrialization a particularly
dynamic approach to manufacturing. Some examples from our interviews
will illustrate these various levels of interaction.
199
Gary G. Hamilton and Cheng-shu Kao
with the Japanese company, he was able to upgrade the quality of his luggage
and then to land some additional OEM contracts.
In 1980, while running a successful luggage export business, Ling Suen-yi
was approached by a friend of a friend. This person owned a jack factory,
which he wanted to sell. The factory was not doing well, and the person
wanted to sell the factory to the Ling family at an attractive price. A few
years earlier another jack factory had opened in Chiayi called Hsinfu. The
owner of Hsinfu and Ling Suen-yi were friends, and, sensing an opportunity,
Ling Suen-yi hoped to collaborate with Hsinfu to produce a wider range and
larger quantity of hydraulic jacks. The year before they bought the jack
factory, the person we interviewed, the son, Ling Wen-chuen, had just
graduated from National Taiwan University in Taipei, with a BS degree in
Forestry. In the year after his graduation, he had worked for his father in the
luggage company, learning sales and marketing and making use of the English
he had learned in college. When Ling Suen-yi bought the jack factory in 1981
for NT$20 million, his son, Ling Wen-chuen, immediately became the general
manager.
In the late 1970s, in addition to Kai Hsiang and Hsinfu, four other jack
assembly factories started operation in Chiayi. Although each one was inde-
pendent and in competition with the other firms and although each had a
network of dedicated subcontractors, they also shared some subcontractors
who made specialized parts. As a function of being part of an extensive
network of assembly factories and overlapping parts suppliers, the entire
agglomeration of firms, although internally competitive, shared substantial
knowledge about how to manufacture products with hydraulic components.
As general manager of Kai Hsiang, Ling Wen-chuen made good use of this
information to improve the production facilities in his factory.
The agglomeration of jack factories in Chiayi created a large demand for
steel of a certain size and quality. Not far from Chiayi, near Kaohsiung, is the
state-owned steel mill, China Steel, as well as several large privately owned
steel mills. At first, the jack factories ordered steel from some of these factories,
but they soon switched their orders to a newly established local steel mill. This
firm had been established in the late 1970s by a local man who had worked as
an apprentice in one of the Kaohsiung mills. As the jack factories began to
receive substantial orders, this person was encouraged to open a mini-mill
dedicated to serving the specific needs of the jack manufacturers in Chiayi.
In the first years of operation, Kai Hsiang was a subcontract manufacturer
for Hsinfu, which was then on its way to becoming the world’s largest pro-
ducer of hydraulic jacks. Ling Wen-chuen told us that, in the first year of
operation, they made NT$200 million in total revenues, with profit margins
running at about 6 percent. After two years, they were able to turn a profit. As a
subcontract assembly firm for Hsinfu, however, Kai Hsiang depended on
200
The Asian Miracle and Demand-Responsive Economies
Hsinfu’s ability to get OEM orders. Although the firm was quite successful,
Ling Wen-chuen wanted to expand his business. Using his English language
skills, he went to Taipei, and eventually to the USA, to meet American buyers.
When we asked him how he knew what firms to go to, he said that that was no
problem. What he had done was to go to the subcontracted firm in Chiayi that
was making the brand-name-labeled cardboard boxes used to package the
finished jacks and to see what American companies were ordering jacks. He
then went to those companies, and, as a result, he was able get substantial
OEM orders on his own behalf. These orders allowed him to expand his
network of subcontractors. By 1987, within six years of buying the jack
factory, Kai Hsiang became the second largest jack assembly firm in Chiayi.
Our first interview with Ling Wen-chuen was in 1990. Within five years of
that first interview, most of the jack assembly firms in Chiayi, including Kai
Hsiang, had moved operations to Mainland China. The Ling family luggage
business continues in full operation, with one large factory in Mainland China
and the small factory in Chiayi, where the high-end luggage continues to be
made. The factory making animal feed ended operations at about the time
that the farmers in southern Taiwan began to quit raising animals and seafood
so extensively because of pollution among other causes. No longer running
their agribusiness, Ling Suen-yi’s wife opened a stock brokerage firm. The Ling
family jokingly called their businesses “nomadic” (youmu), because they never
stopped searching for new opportunities to make money.
201
Gary G. Hamilton and Cheng-shu Kao
In the early 1970s, as Ta Chia was just becoming the center of Taiwan’s bicycle
production, there were many opportunities in this region to enter the industry
in one capacity or another. With only very little capital and acting on the
advice of a friend, Lin and his wife decided to start a company making plastic
saddle bags that attach to the rear fender of low-end bicycles. They called their
company Jun-ye (successful enterprise), and, depending on the workload,
employed between ten and twenty people, all from the local village. Their
orders for the saddle bags came from other firms in Ta Chia. These bags would
be attached to the bicycles in the final stages of assembly, just before the
bicycles were packaged and shipped to the OEM buyers.
Building on his personal connections within the local community of bicycle
assemblers and part suppliers, Chairman Lin, in 1978, got an opportunity to
establish a new firm to make one of the technologically most difficult parts to
manufacture, the frame. He called his firm Yeh-Bao (wild treasure) in Chinese
and A-PRO in English. At the beginning they used low-end metals, mainly
aluminum and stainless steel, to construct the frame. The first couple of years,
he recalled, were extremely difficult, because he had to work out the produc-
tion technique for making the frame solid and unbreakable. To accomplish
this task, precision welding is absolutely crucial, because so much pressure is
placed on critical points on a bicycle, particularly the metal fork holding the
front wheel. “Can you imagine,” he said, “a 200 pound American guy riding
on a ten pound bicycle at a speed of 30 miles an hour. Oh boy, the frame has to
hold together. You know an automobile has four wheels, but a bicycle only
has two.”
Because competition at the low end was so tough, Chairman Lin decided he
had to upgrade his position in the network of firms around Ta Chia. He
borrowed money from his friends and bought new equipment in order to
improve the quality of his frames. He also began to use new metals, such as
carbon graphite, titanium, as well as higher grades of aluminum and steel.
Then he hired the best welders he could find, paying then double and some-
times treble the going local wage for welders. When he first bought the
specialty metals from a Japanese company, the Japanese company sent repre-
sentatives to teach him and his welders the best techniques to cut and weld
the frames. But Chairman Lin complained to us that Japanese companies
never explain everything. They always keep some of the core technology to
themselves. Therefore, as they began to work with the new metals, Lin and his
employees had to work out many of the problems on their own, and they had
to test and retest the durability of their frames. Chairman Lin, however,
continued to buy the high-end materials from Japan (for example, titanium
and carbon graphite) and to rely on Japanese manufacturers for key com-
ponent parts, such as the Shimano gear boxes.
202
The Asian Miracle and Demand-Responsive Economies
Once they had perfected the manufacturing process, Chairman Lin began to
participate in international bicycle fairs, usually held in Cologne Germany
and New York, and he started to obtain OEM orders, especially from Europe.
His own business quickly improved. He had successfully upgraded his firm’s
position in the manufacturing network, just as the entire network had also
upgraded itself as an OEM producer for major European and American retailers
of bicycles. As Yeh-Bao grew in size, the firm was able to handle yet larger and
more differentiated orders. Chairman Lin’s strategy matched the strategy of
the entire network of firms—namely, to make differentiated products of mass-
produced low-end and middle-range bicycles and batch produced high-end
models, this along with a lot of bicycle accessories.
By 1992, when we interviewed Chairman Lin the first time, he had estab-
lished six independent factories in Taiwan, each making different component
parts. The very first firm, Jun-ye, was still in operation, then managed by Lin’s
wife and making sophisticated bicycle accessories. Yeh-Bao was the largest of
the six firms. Chairman Lin was the owner and boss (laoban) of each of these
factories. We asked him, since he was making so many different bicycle parts,
why not integrate vertically and make the entire bicycle himself, or at least
become a downstream assembler. He answered decisively that that would not
be a wise move. If you try to integrate vertically in Ta Chia, he said, “then
everyone will be your competitor. If you keep your firms separate, then you
will be everyone’s supplier.” He said there were other reasons not to integrate
as well. If you make a small number of products, you do not have to make a
huge capital investment in any one of them. Modest investments, he said, get
better returns with lower risks. Finally, he noted that Taiwan’s tax codes also
favor having multiple companies rather than one big firm. Continually start-
ing small firms means that you can deduct start-up costs, which would not be
available if one began a new operation within an existing firm. Also, multiple
firms create multiple lines of credit. One big company has only one credit line.
And, finally, different sizes of firms are subject to different tax rates. Although
all these reasons are important, he reflected, the main reason not to integrate
vertically is the risk of going it alone, of trying to make money without help
from others.
Chairman Lin thought it was much better for him to make himself indis-
pensable within the overall network of firms. The bicycle industry is continu-
ally changing, he said; it is a “fashion industry.” A network of firms is much
more flexible in changing with the trends than is one big vertically integrated
firm. “It used to be that the big firms in South Korean would make huge
quantities of bicycles,” but the Taiwanese producers were able to follow the
trends so much faster that the “Koreans got out of the bicycle business.”
203
Gary G. Hamilton and Cheng-shu Kao
204
The Asian Miracle and Demand-Responsive Economies
market, but the price per unit was very low. American buyers for the main
retail outlets, especially Kmart, Sears, and Wal-Mart, then only a regional
discounter, began to place orders in Taiwan. The raw plastic material used to
make the flip-flops was readily available in Taiwan from Nanya Plastics, a
subsidiary of Formosa Plastics. Working through a local trading company, the
Tsai brothers were able to land a contract for a quantity of these plastic shoes. At
the same time that this was occurring, the US demand for flip-flops surged,
which led in turn to much bigger orders. The US buyers for the retail chains
then began to come directly to the suppliers, Pou Chen included, and began to
work closely with them to increase both the quantity and the quality of the
products. Chairman Tsai recalled being especially impressed with the buyers
from Wal-Mart, with whom he gradually developed a close relationship.
In the early 1970s, Pou Chen began to receive some direct orders from the
main retail buyers. In response to these orders, Pou Chen increased the size of
its factory and began to develop its own subcontracting network. At this time
the market for non-leather shoes in the United States began to diversify. Pou
Chen’s breakthrough came when the company got some large orders for a new
type of shoe, a canvas-covered plastic shoe, variously called a “sneaker” or
“tennis shoe.” The construction was fairly easy and the unit price was very
low. Working with its production network, however, Pou Chen was able to
keep its production costs low, produce these shoes in large quantities, and still
make everyone a profit. At the same time that Pou Chen’s orders for sneakers
began to come in, two related developments pushed Taiwan shoe manufac-
turers in new directions. First, the technology used in making shoes changed
dramatically when Mitsubishi’s general trading company, CITC, transferred
Japanese technologies for making shoes to Taiwanese suppliers. CITC was one
of the primary intermediaries between a range of specialized retailers of sport-
ing goods and Taiwanese shoe manufacturers. In Japan at the time, a new type
of shoe was being developed, a highly functional and durable shoe that would
become known as the “athletic shoe.” These shoes required new machinery,
advanced plastic materials, and high-quality sewing and lamination techni-
ques. Making these shoes was also very labor intensive. Taking advantage of
Taiwan’s cheaper labor costs and batch production techniques, CITC taught
Taiwanese suppliers the new shoe-making technologies and also sold them
the machines and the materials to make the shoes.
The German shoe manufacturer Adidas had been trying to create a similar
type of shoe with technologies similar to those developed by the Japanese.
Keeping in step with its Japanese competitors, Adidas, in 1971, decided to try
contract manufacturing in Taiwan as well, and signed an agreement with
Hwagang, a shoe company located in northern Taiwan. In the following
year, 1972, Reebok came to Taiwan, as did the Japanese company Mizuno.
These companies signed contracts with a number of the shoe manufacturers,
205
Gary G. Hamilton and Cheng-shu Kao
amongst them Chinglu, a firm located in the same county as Pou Chen.
Although they had been in business for only about five years, all these con-
tracts for athletic shoes made Taiwanese shoe manufacturers one of the main
global suppliers for this new type of athletic shoe.
The extraordinarily rapid growth of the Taiwan’s shoe manufacturers cre-
ated huge demand for specialized inputs and for the machinery to make shoes,
much of which were initially supplied by the Japanese trading companies. By
the mid-1970s, local firms began to emerge that supplied both the inputs and
the machinery. This follows the general rule in demand-responsive econo-
mies: orders for final products come first, markets for intermediate inputs for
those products come later, which encourages niche suppliers for intermediate
inputs to emerge.
The second important development in Taiwan’s shoe industry was the
arrival of Nike and a surging global demand for athletic shoes that was in
part created by Nike. In the early 1970s, Kihachiro Onitsuka, the owner of
Asics Tiger, cooperated with the American company called Blue Ribbon
Sports, which later became Nike, to manufacture a shoe designed by Phillip
Knight. Knight’s story is well known. He saw that there was no shoe designed
for running and other athletic endeavors. He designed the shoe and con-
tracted with Asics Tiger to make it. In only a few years after their introduction,
Nike captured a huge share of the newly developed market in athletic shoes in
the USA. At first this market seemed to be a niche market that filled, as well as
created, demand from the new popularity for jogging and aerobics. But the
niche expanded, as more and more athletic-type shoes were worn for all
occasions. At the beginning, Asics Tiger made Nike shoes, but, with competi-
tion from Adidas and Reebok, Knight decided to move his contract
manufacturing out of Japan. He split his orders between footwear manufac-
turers in South Korea and Taiwan, with Korean companies making mass-
produced shoes for low-end markets and Taiwanese companies making the
batch-produced specialty shoes. In Taiwan, Nike’s lead firm was Fung-Tai, also
located in Taichung County, about 30 minutes north of Yuanlin.
From 1966 to 1985, the global export of sport shoes from Asia grew 1,200
times. Most of these shoes were produced in only two countries, Taiwan and
South Korea. By 1985, Taiwan and South Korea produced 50 percent of all
shoes imported into the USA. By this time, American shoe manufacturers had
gone into a decline from which they would never recover. Because of the
sudden demand in the USA, for these new types of shoes, the large retailers
and trade-name merchandisers did a lot of research on how to put the shoes
together to get maximum performance. In the early years, recalled Tsai Chi-
ray, when Pou Chen made flip-flops and sneakers for the big-box retailers,
price was the most important issue. Later, when Pou Chen began to cooperate
with the brand-name merchandisers, the ability to use advanced technology
206
The Asian Miracle and Demand-Responsive Economies
was more important than price. What all these brand-name companies most
needed were manufacturers who could transform these R&D models into a
manufactured commodity that yielded a good profit for all concerned. The
secret of the Taiwan manufacturers was the know-how to do this.
As Pou Chen continued to make sneakers for the big-box retailers, it started
to invest heavily in the new equipment needed to produce athletic shoes,
equipment sold to it by CITC. By 1977, it also set up its own internal research
division (Neibu Yanjiu Xiaozu) to further develop materials to make shoes. It
began to do some subcontracting work for other Taiwanese firms that had
primary orders for athletic shoes. Then, in 1979, it received its first order from
Adidas through a local trading company arm of Hwagang. At the time Hwa-
gang handled all Adidas’s local sales; the sales agent did a large portion of
Adidas’s contract manufacturing, and arranged for subcontracts to do the
remainder. The arrangement was very successful for Pou Chen. Then, in
1982, Pou Chen became the primary OEM manufacturer for New Balance,
and gained a good reputation for the quality of its shoes. The quality of its
production attracted Reebok, which signed an agreement with Pou Chen in
1988. Then, in 1989, Nike signed on as well.11
By the time Pou Chen received its first big contract from Nike, Pou Chen was
then transferring much of its manufacturing capacity to China. The golden
period for Taiwan’s shoe production was just ending, and the great rush to
China was just starting. In retrospect, we can see that, in 1989, the golden
period for Pou Chen was just about to begin.
Demand-Responsive Manufacturing
Between the late 1960s and 1985, Taiwanese manufacturers developed into
sophisticated suppliers of consumer goods for global markets. In the begin-
ning of the period, they had very little experience in any kind of
manufacturing and very limited knowledge of the consumer goods that they
would soon be making for overseas markets. At the end of the period, they had
advanced expertise in the process of manufacturing for OEM buyers and
equally advanced knowledge of the products that they were making. In
slightly over fifteen years, Taiwanese manufacturers, the Taiwanese economy,
and the global economy had become tightly interconnected and transformed.
After 1985, in the wake of the Plaza Accord that raised the value of Taiwan’s
currency about 40 percent relative to the US dollar, Taiwan manufacturers had
increasing difficulty meeting the price points set by US retailers and brand-
name merchandisers. In the next decade, from 1985 to 1995, waves of Taiwan-
ese SMEs (small and medium-sized enterprises) began to move to Mainland
China, and, once in China, the lead firms having the major contracts
207
Gary G. Hamilton and Cheng-shu Kao
208
The Asian Miracle and Demand-Responsive Economies
OEM production is to work for the return contract. Meet the buyer’s
expectations in quality, quantity, and price point the first time. If the
buyers come back, then they will have made money and will feel as
though they could make more. The third principle of OEM is to make
money for yourself. How you achieve these three principles is through
taking calculated risks. However, if you do not make money for yourself,
you will not be able to survive. Maybe you will not make money with the
first few contracts, but if you make yourself indispensable to your buyers,
you will make lots of money over the long haul.
How do you organize to make money for your buyers? As we said, you do
that by organizing from the perspective of the buyer. Organize backward
from the product itself and from the order for that product. You have the
specifications for the product, and you know how many they want. Do
not try to develop a totally new product. Simply try to reproduce an
existing product with high quality, at low cost, and in the desired
quantity. The production unit you organize is in direct response to the
product and the orders. Different ways to organize production evolve over
time, but in the early years it was always a production network.
How do you organize to make money for yourself? First, establish a
foothold in the production networks, learn by doing, make incremental
changes to improve what you are doing, cost down the production
process, and accept low margins in the short run in the hopes of receiving
larger margins going forward. Be a network player. And accept the
network agreements about the profit margin. When the opportunity
arises, fill the niches that appear in the production process or develop new
niches that others will find useful.
Second, try to get multiple orders for the same product from different
sources. Multiple orders will allow you to develop a strategy of product
differentiation, based on standardized parts for all models.
Third, modularize the production across the producing units. Standardize
each step in the production to make the manufacturing process
transparent to all those engaged in making the product. Adopt external
standards for the products, as specified by the buyer, and adopt internal
standards for the process of production, as developed and specified by the
network of independent manufacturers.
Conclusion
209
Gary G. Hamilton and Cheng-shu Kao
210
7
“Wal-Mart’s business model does not work without us”—so said Professor
John Liu, the Director of the CY Tung International Centre for Maritime
Studies at Hong Kong Polytechnic University. The “us” to whom he referred
are those people who specialize in logistics and maritime services. Liu was
giving a tour of the state-of-the-art training center at his university, training
that prepares technicians to deliver efficient, predictable, and low-cost service
to global customers like Wal-Mart. The “basic tools of global retailing,” he
continued, “are containerized shipping and the Internet.” He might have
added a few items to his list of tools, but his point was well made. Global
retailing and global logistics are so intimately and thoroughly interconnected
that it is difficult to tell where one starts and the other stops.
Not so long ago, logistics meant simply the tasks of organizing and coordi-
nating the transportation of goods.1 Now practitioners have extended the
term to cover the entire cycle of designing, ordering, placing into production,
and transporting goods to final markets. The activity of integrating all aspects
of this cycle is called “supply-chain management,” and supply-chain manage-
ment is at the heart of the market-making successes of Wal-Mart and all other
large global retailers.
The market-making competence of these retailers can be seen in their ability
to organize their suppliers and service providers, backwards from anticipated
demand, so that even the smallest factory making components for a contract
manufacturer will respond quickly to the decisions that retailers make. Rely-
ing on point-of-sale (POS) data collected electronically, retailers make deci-
sions about the future production of goods, specific product mixes for specific
locations, delivery schedules, inventory flows, and a large assortment of other
Edna Bonacich and Gary G. Hamilton
212
Global Logistics, Global Labor
footwear (Pou Chen).2 The same process happens in nearly every sector of
production in which large retailers and merchandisers predominate, includ-
ing the production of food, as Chapter 10 shows.
The next chapters in this part document this process. To achieve maximum
efficiency in time and costs, retailers need large-scale manufacturers and
service providers that flexibly and responsibly do most of the tasks required
to get a product into the store. Global logistics allows those manufacturers to
be located anywhere in the world, in any location that offers retailers and
merchandisers the most advantages in time and cost.
In this chapter, we take the process one step further. The same process that
concentrates manufacturing in specific locations also reshapes the markets for
skilled and unskilled workers. It is, perhaps, inaccurate to call these new
markets for labor global in scope, because labor is not as globally mobile as
the goods that labor produces. Still, supply-chain management makes the
conditions and cost of labor at each link of the chain an object of calculation
in assessing the efficiency of the overall chain. The globalization of
manufacturing and logistics, therefore, has the effect of separating the control
of labor from the actual conditions and locations of work. Supply-chain
managers view labor, like any other component of the supply chain, as a
factor that needs to be assessed and controlled, and manufacturers, wherever
they are located, need to view their workers from the point of view of supply-
chain managers, no matter how distant.
Moreover, these supply-chain managers measure logistical services in the
same way they do manufacturing costs. The transportation and warehousing
sectors must also keep their costs at a minimum, including their labor costs.
Not only production, but also distribution workers’ wages and working con-
ditions must be kept in line in order to keep global production profitable from
the retailers’ point of view.
213
Edna Bonacich and Gary G. Hamilton
supply-chain logistics for the branded products that end up in the retailers’
stores. A strong indicator of both types of buying is found in maritime statistics.
Focusing only on ocean transportation of containerized products (which
accounts for over 80 percent of the value of total imports in the USA, the
remainder entering by air or land transportation across the borders), and only
on imports to the United States, we can see the importance of imports and
maritime services in retailers’ management of their supply chains.4 In 2008,
according to Leach (2010: 22), 17,121,000 TEUs (or 20-foot equivalent units,
the standardized measure of container volume; one standardized container
holds two TEUs) were imported into the United States, which in a recession
year had declined slightly from the high point in 2006 (18,611,000 TEUs) to
about the same volume of imports as in 2005. The Journal produces an annual
list of the top 100 shippers (referring to importers, rather than shipowners,
which are known as carriers) that import goods to the United States using
ocean transportation. Of the total TEUs for 2008 ( Journal of Commerce 2009:
22A), 720,000 TEUs, one out of every twenty-four imported containers, was
brought in by Wal-Mart. The next biggest importer was Target, with 445,800
TEUs, and the third was Home Depot, with 300,400 TEUs. Thirty-six of the top
100 importers were retailers, as were six of the top seven, which in addition to
the above included Sears, Lowe’s, and Costco.
Amongst the top 100 importers were also foreign firms that manufacture
electronic goods (for example, LG, Samsung, Panasonic, Cannon, Sony, and
Hon Hai), brand-name merchandisers that contract firms to manufacture their
products (for example, Nike, Jarden, Whirlpool, and Mattel), as well as a
number of automotive companies, parts manufacturers, and food distributors
(for example, Dole and Chiquita). All of these firms import goods for which
they supervise the distribution. Giant retailers, however, stand out as the
major maritime importers to the USA, with Wal-Mart being head and
shoulders above the rest.
Wal-Mart’s dominance of the importers’ list is not new, and its lead has
been widening, even in a time of recession. The giant retailer’s growth as an
importer can readily be traced during the first decade of the twentieth century.
In 2001 the company brought in 260,000 TEUs. By 2003 the imports leaped to
471,600 TEUs, again in 2004 to 576,000 TEUs, to 695,000 TEUs in 2005.
Although overall imports fell in 2008 from its high in 2007, Wal-Mart’s total
was 720,000 TEUs for both years. This rise in retailers’ imports is not simply a
Wal-Mart phenomenon, but rather reflects the tremendous growth of manu-
factured imports to the United States in recent years. Target’s imports grew
from 121,000 in 2001 to 445,800 TEUs in 2008, and Home Depot’s rose from
80,000 to 300,400 TEUs over the same period.
To gain some perspective on these numbers, consider the last firm on the list
of the top 100 importers, Dal-tile, a manufacturer of tiles that is owned by
214
Global Logistics, Global Labor
215
Edna Bonacich and Gary G. Hamilton
began to pour into ships, ports, intermodal connections, railways, and truck-
ing, so that, by the mid-1970s, the world’s major ports were container ports
capable of accommodating larger and larger container ships. And, in general,
the size and importance of these ports followed the size and importance of
international trade in those locations that followed supplier markets for global
retailing.
In 1969, the list of the world’s largest container ports listed only one Asian
port, Yokohama, in seventh place, which had about four times less volume
than first place New York (Levinson 2006: 209). By 1980, New York continued
to top the list, but three of the top five were Asian ports: Hong Kong, Kaoh-
siung, and Singapore. Ten years later, in 1990, four out of the top five were
Asian ports (Kobe, in addition to the three above), and New York had dropped
to ninth place on the list. In 1998, the container port in Shanghai joined the
top ten for the first time; the port in Hong Kong, listed amongst the top ten
since the early 1970s, reverted to China with the retrocession in 1997. By
2000, New York had slipped to fourteenth place on the list, and five of the six
largest ports were in Asia, including Hong Kong and Shanghai. By 2008, all the
top five were Asian ports and New York had fallen to twentieth place on the
list. Of these, three of the top five and seven of the top twenty ports were
Chinese (in order: Shanghai, Hong Kong, Shenzhen, Ningbo, Guangzhou,
Qingdao, and Tianjin).
In 1980, the USA imported $1.1 billion worth of goods from China, far below
Taiwan’s US-bound exports valued at $6.7 billion. By 1990, despite a decade of
rapid growth in US imports from Asia, China still exported only a little over
$15 billion of goods to the USA, by which time Taiwan’s exports to the USA
had grown to about $22 billion. After 1990, however, China’s exports to the
USA (as well as to the rest of the world) leaped forward to over $45 billion in
1995, $100 billion in 2000, $243 billion in 2005, and $337.8 billion in 2008.
In 2008, China’s trading surplus with the entire world was $295.5 billion; in
the same year, China’s trading surplus with the USA was $266.3 billion—the
largest trade deficit ever seen between two countries.5
The rise of China reflects a rapid consolidation of global manufacturing. In
the decades preceding China’s rise, Japan, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and South
Korea became, increasingly, the primary locations where US retailers and
brand-name manufacturers located suppliers for the consumer goods that
they would, in turn, sell to their customers. As the previous chapter shows,
US retailers and their buyers had taken an active role in creating suppliers that
could competently provide the right goods at the right time at the right price.
216
Global Logistics, Global Labor
217
Edna Bonacich and Gary G. Hamilton
followed first by Taiwan, then Japan and South Korea. Japanese and South
Korean investments poured into northeastern China, which could easily be
reached by ship via the Yellow Sea. Hong Kong and Taiwan investment
initially went into the Pearl River Delta, but later also flowed into the area
around Shanghai. In the opening decade of the new millennium, China
became the site of the world’s leading manufacturers and exporters of con-
sumer products.
In the ongoing debate in the USA and Europe about whether China’s
economic policies are unfairly taking advantage of the rest of the world, very
few analysts discuss the role of global retailers and foreign manufacturers in
China. Nonetheless, more than any other single factor, global retailers drive
China’s exports. More than 50 percent of China’s exports come out of firms
not owned by Chinese nationals (Blonigen and Ma 2010). To this total, we can
add the exports of many other firms that local Chinese do own and operate. It
is obvious that very few Chinese firms make any markets in any products
outside China, and so it is equally obvious that global retailers, brand-name
merchandisers, and a range of trading companies acting as intermediaries
between retailers and manufacturers control most of the market making for
Chinese exports.
218
Global Logistics, Global Labor
We are involved in all production in Asia, not just private label. We engage in the
direct importing of both private label and branded goods. We work with the
producers, oversee the production of our goods, and set up specifications for our
products. It makes no difference whether the products are branded or private label.
In neither case do we own any factories, so we are always dealing with someone
else’s factories.
219
Edna Bonacich and Gary G. Hamilton
The big-box retailers vary a great deal in their sophistication, so you can’t general-
ize. They make general forecasts, and then fill in the details using POS data. In
terms of sophistication, Wal-Mart wrote the book, and rewrites it every day. Target
is trying to keep up, as is Best Buy and Home Depot. For example, Target will
budget shelf space for a certain product, and they lose money if it isn’t there on
time. They reckon they save $100 million for every day they can take out of the
transit time. So the supply chain is incredibly important to them. But what they
mainly seek seems to be visibility, not replenishment orders. They want to make
sure that goods are moving as planned. They want a glass pipeline. They want to
be able to see where their SKUs are.
220
Global Logistics, Global Labor
The marriage between retailing and logistics has had substantial effects on
labor markets around the world. Giant retailers use their considerable size and
economic power, directly and indirectly, to pressure manufacturers and ser-
vice providers to improve their efficiency and to lower their costs, including,
importantly, their labor costs. They also exercise their influence on labor
standards in both supplier and consumer markets to push for government
and corporate policies that make labor a flexible component of supply-chain
management. Retailers’ influence has the effect of moving the site of control
over labor from the place of work (for example, the shop floor, the factory) to
the supply-chain managers, who make the crucial decisions about which firms
supply goods and services and at what cost.
It is important to recognize that this shift in the locus of control over labor
does not necessarily lower labor standards. Nor is it, necessarily, the intention
of retailers to do so. In the effort to make supply chains more efficient and
flexible in terms of quality and cost of goods and speed of delivery, retailers
help to “modernize” the economies of developing countries. They force firms
in both developed and developing countries to rationalize their production
and distribution methods. Also, through codes of conducts, which they typi-
cally post on their websites, retailers and brand-name merchandisers may
even improve the conditions and increase the wages of workers in those
firms relative to what they are in other firms in the same location (see our
discussion on this point below). However, whether they improve the condi-
tions and wages for workers or not is an ancillary outcome of the retailers’
most important task, which is efficiently and effectively to manage their
supply chains. And, insofar as they do so, then the supply chains, as well as
the economies in which they are embedded, become demand responsive—
that is, they become effectively organized backward from demand to supply.
The extensive use of contract manufacturing, or outsourcing, is known as
“flexible production.” It is typically praised because it encourages production
on an as-needed basis (limiting the costs of inventory accumulation), and
avoids overproduction of unwanted goods that cannot be sold. Moreover, it
allows for the production of small batches of specialized goods that can be
targeted for specialized consumer groups and tastes. Flexible production is
associated with product differentiation, with the multiplication of styles of
products (and SKUs) of the same brand, such as the array of types and colors of
IPods a customer can buy from Apple.
Flexibility, or contingent relationships, works well for retailers, but makes
life difficult for the contract manufacturers and service providers. In turn,
flexibility also makes life more difficult for the employees of these firms,
employees who face increased contingency in the form of piece-rate,
221
Edna Bonacich and Gary G. Hamilton
The system of labor that has emerged in southeastern China is a good illustra-
tion of the indirect impact that retailers have on the conditions of workers
engaged in manufacturing. Southeastern China, especially the large area in
the hinterland of Hong Kong and Guangzhou in the Pearl River Delta, is the
most important of China’s three main export-producing areas. Many manu-
facturers from Hong Kong and Taiwan have located their factories in this
region, and many Chinese firms have grown up in this area to supply services
and component parts for these foreign-owned factories.
This area of Guangdong province has also been the site of a number of
studies investigating worker conditions in these factories. Because these for-
eign-owned factories are responding to greatly expanded orders for goods, the
factories have grown very large and the number of workers employed is huge
when compared to the size and employment figures of these factories before
they were relocated to China. For example, as described in Chapter 6, the
footwear manufacturer Pou Chen was only a medium-sized firm in Taiwan
before it began to move its manufacturing operations to China in the 1980s.
As reported in Chapter 9, Pou Chen, whose Mainland name is Yue Yuen, now
222
Global Logistics, Global Labor
The denial of local hukou (residency rights) to migrant workers, combined with
their plentiful supply and lack of access to legal information and support, has
created a large pool of super-exploitable, yet highly mobile or flexible industrial
workforce for China’s new economy, catering to global consumers . . . [The policy]
has served very well China’s economic growth strategy of being the world’s “most
efficient” (lowest cost) producer . . . China can continue to draw labor from rural to
urban areas and export-processing zones without having to raise the wages much
above the rural-subsistence level.
The “China price” is based on China’s low labor costs, which result directly
from China’s policies to maintain this very large pool of temporary workers
who are least able effectively to organize to secure their labor rights (A. Chan
2001).
Because most workers in China’s export-processing factories are migrants,
the factory owners typically provide large dormitories to house their employ-
ees with “anywhere from eight to twenty workers per room” and large cafeter-
ias to feed them (Pun 2009: 158). These dormitories are close, and often even
attached, to the factories themselves. The majority of those living in the
dormitories are young, single women. These workers have little to no privacy,
are closely supervised, and are required to follow the rules and regulations set
forth by the owners. According to Smith and Pun (2006), the “dormitory
labour regime” is unlike the dormitory system found in the paternalistic
textiles factories in nineteenth-century Japan, which was set up to house
single female workers fulfilling multi-year contracts. By contrast, in China,
the dormitory system provides short-term facilities for temporary workers.
These workers work seasonally and intensively, often preferring to work over-
time to earn as much money in as short a time as possible. They provide the
factory with a highly flexible labor force that offers, as a rule, little resistance to
the demands of management. With this system of labor control, argues Pun
(2009; see also Smith and Pun 2006), factory owners can lengthen the work
day, suppress wage demands, access labor on a just-in-time basis, exert direct
223
Edna Bonacich and Gary G. Hamilton
controls over the labor process, and rely on government policies and rural
families’ need for money to replenish the supply of temporary migrants.
This system of labor control is closely connected to the purchasing system that
retailers and brand-name merchandisers have developed over time. Retailers
and merchandisers are reluctant to hold inventories of goods, and thus they
push inventory management down into the factory, where just-in-time pro-
duction becomes a necessary condition for getting contracts. Factories, as well
as the Chinese government itself, have responded to this evolving system of
export production by developing a just-in-time workforce that is capable of
responding to big buyer demands.
Retailers do not want to be labeled as creators of “sweatshop-like” condi-
tions in factories making products that they have ordered. Fearing the con-
sequences of a bad reputation, most retailers and merchandisers have devised
codes of conduct and systems of oversight that are supposed to ensure com-
pliance from their contract manufacturers. These codes of conduct are typi-
cally posted on the website of these firms, so that all interested parties can see
them. In addition, many of these companies have banded together to form, in
the United States, the Fair Labor Association (FLA), which promotes the
independent monitoring of the global supply chain to prevent labor abuses.
Another group, which began in the United Kingdom but has a global orienta-
tion, is called the Ethical Trading Initiative (Birchall 2007).
Researchers, investigating the extent to which contract manufacturers in
China have implemented these codes of conduct, have come up with counter-
intuitive results. Sum and Pun (2005) find three paradoxes that are outcomes
of the adoption of codes of conduct. First, the competition in contract
manufacturing to engage in “just-in-time, low-cost and fashion-conscious
production,” on the one hand, and the big buyers’ requirement to implement
extensive codes of conduct for labor, on the other hand, have led manufac-
turers to use “compliance with labor codes” as a marketing strategy to obtain
more and larger contracts (Sum and Pun 2005: 197). The name of the contract
manufacturing game is to obtain the contracts in the first place, and, for this
task, adopting a code of conduct is useful, if not necessary.
Second, codes of conduct are doubly useful as a tool to “encourage workers
to cooperate with management to avoid the loss of contracts and hence future
employment opportunities” (Sum and Pun 2005: 197). Summaries of the
codes of conduct are posted on the walls of the factories, where they are visible
to inspectors. In relation to outsiders, such as big-buyer and third-party in-
spectors, managers encourage workers to enter into a “tactical alliance” that
224
Global Logistics, Global Labor
protects the factory from social auditing by outsiders. Workers are trained to
answer questions in ways that comply with the code of conducts, even though
the actual conditions of work are quite different.
Third, outwardly adopting a code of conduct requires contract manufac-
turers to develop “elaborate managerial and audit/documentation systems
to defend the [contract manufacturer] against charges of infringing the Code
. . . [Hence] more effort goes into paperwork than into actual advancement of
labour rights protection” (Sum and Pun 2005: 197).
The weakness of the codes-and-monitoring system goes beyond China, as is
shown in an October 2006 revelation that Tesco (the giant British retailer that
belongs to the Ethical Trading Initiative) was producing clothing in factories
in Bangladesh that employed children. According to a Financial Times reporter
(Birchall 2007), “the case illustrated the limits of systems established to moni-
tor conditions in sectors such as clothing, footwear and toys. Wayward fac-
tories have become adept at covering up abuses, and even when monitors flag
problems, little progress seems to be made in reducing them.” A study
(described in the same article) that investigated the effectiveness of the Ethical
Trading Initiative found that monitoring has helped to eliminate child labor
and improve factory safety, but has had little effect on the rights to form
unions and to achieve any job security.
Neil Kearney, of the International Textiles, Garment and Leathers Workers
Federation (ITGLWF)—a federation of trade unions in these industries from
around the world—puts these efforts in perspective:
As a leader of an anti-sweatshop group put it: “If retailers are not willing to
change the way they deal with their purchasing practices and be transparent
about that, then codes will never be effective” (Birchall 2007).
US retailers can play a critical role in the reproduction of sweatshops,
whether they intend to or not. The sheer size of their ordering power, coupled
with huge competitive pressures amongst contractors and intermediaries to
win the work, create a breeding pool for sweatshop proliferation. Most impor-
tant, however, is the determination of retailers to cut costs to the bare bone,
which leaves little room for contractors to maintain labor standards.
As an example, let us briefly consider Wal-Mart’s relations with its suppliers in
China, the country where most of its offshore production is located. The home
office of Wal-Mart Global Procurement is in Shenzhen, China. By locating
225
Edna Bonacich and Gary G. Hamilton
there, the company could exercise great oversight over its suppliers and over the
factories they use (Useem 2004). Wal-Mart, however, is not just a passive
recipient of Chinese-produced goods, but an active producer of those goods.
The company is a major actor in China, not only as an expanding retailer, but,
perhaps more importantly, as a shaper of production. Ex-store manager Leh-
man, interviewed for the television program Is Wal-Mart Good for America?,8
reported that the company’s pressure to cut production and shipping costs is
just as intense in China as in the United States. The “natural” cheapness of
Chinese production is not enough for Wal-Mart. The company puts pressure on
already poor conditions to lower them still further.
Wal-Mart’s procurement staff members are constantly making deals with
hundreds of Chinese manufacturers on a daily basis in order to produce goods
tailored to Wal-Mart’s own stringent specifications; these include pricing,
quality assurance, efficiency, and delivery. Wal-Mart is also known to demand
that its suppliers change their bookkeeping systems and improve their logis-
tics to meet rigid delivery schedules while maintaining the lowest price mar-
gins. In exchange for Wal-Mart contracts, Chinese companies are often
required to open up their books to Wal-Mart, and cut prices where necessary,
if Wal-Mart decides the supplier’s profit margins are too large. Wal-Mart
demands rock-bottom prices and forces its clients to cut costs in order to
remain in contention for export orders.9
In a Wall Street Journal article of November 13, 2003, author Peter Wonacott
tells the following story. Ching Hai is a contract manufacturer that produces
juicers, fans, and toasters for some of the largest retailers, with Wal-Mart as its
largest client. Over the previous decade, the average wholesale price for Ching
Hai’s products had almost halved, from $7 to $4, in order for it to continue
doing business with the stringent cost demands of Wal-Mart. Wal-Mart’s
Chinese producers have had to find ways to lower their costs, which often
leads to further demands on their labor force. Ching Hai was forced to cut its
labor force in half, while maintaining the same level of orders. The company
had a starting wage of $32 a month, which was lower than the local minimum
wage, and a high rate of workplace accidents, and many employees had to
work eighteen-hour days. In spite of all the cost-cutting efforts, the company
was barely profitable. Pun and Yu (2008) also found a similar relationship
between Wal-Mart’s procurement practices and the codes of conduct that
Wal-Mart wants its suppliers to follow.
In December 2006, a Hong Kong-based group, China Labor Watch, accused
Wal-Mart of using suppliers that failed to pay legal wages or to provide proper
working conditions.10 The group surveyed 169 employees at 15 Wal-Mart
suppliers in China and found that some of them paid workers as little as half
the minimum wage, threatened to fire workers if they did not comply with
mandatory overtime, and provided no required health insurance. One
226
Global Logistics, Global Labor
company had a single bathroom for 2,000 workers. Some of the firms fined
employees as much as an hour’s pay for arriving one minute late to work. And
some were behind in paying wages.
Labor in Distribution
The process of importing requires various types of labor, including: the work
of seafarers on the container vessels; the work of longshore and other dock
workers; the work of railroad employees, who move the cargo inland; the work
of truckers, who transport ocean containers to railheads and warehouses in
the vicinity of the ports, where they are transloaded for trucking to inland
destinations, and the work of warehouse and distribution center employees.
These workers are the backbone of the logistics system. They are the people
who enable the containerized freight to arrive safely, accurately, and in a
timely manner at your local retail outlets.
Statistics show that US logistics costs have declined significantly since
the early 1980s. They dropped from around 14.5 percent of GDP in 1982, to
8.5 percent in 2003 (Wilson 2004). The logistics industry prides itself that the
reason for this shift lies in all the efficiency gains of supply-chain manage-
ment. Inventory costs have been cut, and so have the costs connected with
most of the modes of freight transportation. Yet we can ask, how much have
these gains been made at the cost of workers? In their study of these questions,
Bonacich and Wilson (2008) found that, in general, conditions have worsened
for logistics workers.
US seafarers used to have strong unions, but their jobs have been almost
entirely outsourced. Steamship companies, which transport containers across
the ocean, often use what are called “flags of convenience.” This involves
registering ships in countries like Panama and Liberia, where there is little or
no regulation of conditions on board the vessels. In addition, the steamship
lines employ crewing companies to recruit seafarers, often from the poorest
countries of the world. While container ships can be cleaner than some other
types of ships, seafarers work for longer hours, as well as much longer tours of
duty, than did US unionized workers. Of course, their pay is a fraction of the
earlier system.
Longshore workers still have good jobs, at least on the Pacific Coast, where
the International Longshore and Warehouse Union (ILWU) continues to have
considerable clout. The steamship lines and terminal operators that employ
the dock workers, organized as the Pacific Maritime Association (PMA), have
made serious efforts to undermine the union. In 2002, during a contract
dispute, they locked ILWU workers out, and brought the Pacific Coast ports
to a halt for eleven days. The lockout failed to break the power of the union,
227
Edna Bonacich and Gary G. Hamilton
though it did gain some technological concessions for the employers (Olney
2003). However, the union is always under threat, as some very powerful
forces are arrayed against it.
As suggested above, trucking can be divided into a number of types. Here we
focus on one particular area of trucking—namely, port drayage. These truckers
haul containers from the ports to their first drop-off point. In Southern
California this drop-off point is typically either a railhead, where the contain-
ers are loaded onto a train to be shipped to the Midwest or East, or a local
warehouse or distribution center, where the container is unloaded and the
goods are prepared for further shipping to their ultimate destinations.
The truckers engaged in port drayage, or port truckers, used to be members
of the International Brotherhood of Teamsters (IBT), but their jobs have been
deunionized. This occurred when trucking was deregulated in the late 1970s
and 1980s by the federal government, and many drivers were converted from
employees to independent “owner operators.” In fact, port truckers still work
for trucking companies, but as so-called independent contractors, which
means that they have to own their own rigs and pay for upkeep and insurance.
The switch to non-union truckers was accompanied by a shift from largely
native-born to immigrant drivers. Having broken the union in this field, the
employers switched to a lower-cost labor force.
The railroads have a long history of unionization, and unions are still
prevalent in the industry. But railroad workers have been heavily impacted
by efforts to cut the cost of freight train operations. The principal form that
labor cost cutting has taken is the elimination of thousands of jobs. The
consequence has been that railroad workers have to adapt to difficult work
schedules and to increased danger of accidents.
In terms of warehousing, a major agglomeration of warehouses and distri-
bution centers has been developed just east of Los Angeles County, in the
Inland Empire counties of San Bernardino and Riverside. All the giant retailers,
as well as many smaller ones, maintain import warehouses there. Wal-Mart,
Target, Home Depot, Costco, Sears, Walgreen’s, Staples, Kohl’s, Toys “R” Us,
Big Lots, and Ross Stores are amongst the retailers that run distribution centers
in the area. One of the reasons for locating in this area was the availability of
relatively low-cost land and abundant space for new construction. But another
reason is the relatively low-wage, mainly non-union labor force that lives in
the area. In addition, a huge temporary labor industry has now grown up
around these distribution centers to provide them with contingent workers on
an as-needed basis.
In examining the various groups of workers involved in the logistics system,
Bonacich and Wilson (2008) came to the conclusion that there were four
key features of the changes that had occurred for workers in the previous
twenty-five or thirty years. First, labor has been made more contingent, even
228
Global Logistics, Global Labor
It is difficult to trace the exact line of retailer pressure to reduce logistics costs,
and the impact on workers. At one level, this pressure is compacted into a
single transaction: the rates paid to the steamship lines for ocean shipping.
Every year these rates are negotiated, and pressure is put on the steamship
lines to push the rates down.
The steamship line rates are so important because they often encompass
railroad and trucking costs. The steamships frequently offer door-to-door
rates, where a single fee covers the entire cost of transportation from a Chinese
port to the importer’s warehouse in the United States. The lower the rate
negotiated with the ocean carriers, the lower is likely to be the rates that are
paid to the railroad and trucking companies, which in turn translates into
pressure on wages and working conditions all along the line.
The big retailers are known for their ability to get special rates from the
transportation community. They can leverage their huge volume to their
advantage. Wal-Mart, for example, pays a significantly lower rate than the
average-sized importer. The giant retailer “makes the market” on setting
the price for the lowest ocean freight rate, and other importers bargain with
the steamship companies relative to Wal-Mart’s price.
The clearest evidence of retailer interference in logistics labor costs came
with the 2002 West Coast ports lockout. In order to “reform” labor conditions
at the ports, and reduce the power of the ILWU, a new group was formed
called the West Coast Waterfront Coalition (WCWC). (The group persists as
The Waterfront Coalition, or TWC.) This group, amongst which large retailers,
including Wal-Mart, were prominent members, played an important role in
helping to pressure the PMA (and the Bush administration) to take a firm
stand against the ILWU in labor negotiations. Giant retailers, who have so
much at stake in the cost of logistics, wanted to ensure that their interests were
strongly pursued.
229
Edna Bonacich and Gary G. Hamilton
Conclusion
230
8
Introduction
232
Making the Global Supply Base
chains tend to exercise more control in GVCs even as they focus less on in-
house production and more on design, marketing, and value-added services.
Because goods in producer-driven chains are technology intensive and, early
on, domestic suppliers lacked technical competence to make the required
inputs, production in East Asia was largely accomplished by MNC affiliates—
a fact examined in great detail in the literature on the MNC (Vernon 1971;
Zanfei 2000; Yamin and Sinkovics 2009).
Although firms have been operating internationally since the days of the
British East India Company, suppliers and supply bases tended to be domestic
and beyond the reach of retailers and buyers without international operations.
Foreign affiliates of MNCs, often motivated by local content rules, gradually
increased their use of local suppliers, but were forced by these same rules to
develop redundant supply relationships in each of the countries or regions
where they produced. By the end of the 1990s, this situation had changed
markedly. The most capable suppliers became more “global” by establishing
new plants, acquiring customer facilities, and purchasing smaller local and
regional producers. Suppliers and supply-chain intermediaries from East Asia
also set up facilities to serve customers from a larger set of locations. With this
new supply base in place, retailers, branded merchandisers, and manufac-
turers, whether they were selling globally or simply seeking to cut operating
costs to compete at home, could quite easily tap into supplier capabilities in
multiple locations without the cost, risk, or time required to set up their own
factories and nurture local supply chains from scratch. The next step was to
simplify these supply relationships by using the same set of global suppliers in
each of the regions where production was carried out.
Thus, the rise of the global supply base is not simply a story of more and
better producers coming on-stream in East Asia to supply MNC affiliates in
producer-driven sectors, nor of retailers in buyer-driven sectors placing
increasingly large orders with firms and intermediaries in East Asia. The two
trends are connected. This chapter lays out how the new global supply base
emerged. It is a complex story, one that has played out differently in various
places and in diverse industries. Indeed, much of our understanding of the
dynamics of GVCs comes from detailed research on how these production
chains have evolved in specific industries. We rely on a series of sector- and
firm-level examples, largely from three sectors that dominate manufactured
goods trade—electronics, apparel, and motor vehicles—to highlight several
different facets of the phenomenon.
In this chapter, we first present some evidence of how suppliers based in
advanced economies, especially US-based suppliers to technology-intensive
industries such as electronics and motor vehicle industries, began to establish
global operations in the late 1980s, and then accelerated their global expansion
the 1990s. Second, we describe how the sourcing strategies of transnational
233
Timothy Sturgeon, John Humphrey, and Gary Gereffi
Lead firms did not only increase their reliance on suppliers through their
global buyers and offshore affiliates in the 1990s. Outsourcing was a major
strategy at home too, and as a result domestic suppliers won huge volumes of
new business and grew spectacularly. As US-based companies embraced the
main elements of “corporate re-engineering and restructuring” (Harrison
1994) with its focus on core competence, asset variability, and maximization
of shareholder value, most outsourcing began domestically. In the 1990s,
however, the largest suppliers and service providers in these industries and
product categories developed global-scale operational footprints. In some
instances, the motivation of suppliers was to expand their own market
reach, but more often it was to provide integrated global supply capabilities
for their largest customers.
Within the United States, the movement toward outsourcing began with
non-manufacturing services, such as information technology, accounting,
and call centers. By the 1980s, large companies were also outsourcing routine
business functions such as accounting, legal services, advertising, billing, and
payroll (Rabach and Kim 1994). Firms divested themselves of non-core activ-
ities such as provision of food, security, and janitorial services for their build-
ings. Despite recent alarm in the United States about “services offshoring”
(see Sturgeon et al. 2006), most of these services remain difficult or impossible
to source offshore—for both practical and regulatory reasons—and continue,
in large part, to be provided by home-based suppliers (Batt, Doellgast, and
Kwon 2006; Neilsen 2008). Nevertheless, there are some significant and very
large-scale exceptions to this in industries where processes can be segmented,
linkages between activities codified, and inputs and outputs transmitted elec-
tronically. Examples include call-center-based services, back-office business
functions, IT services, enterprise computing, clinical trials, and contract
medical research. In recent years, the economic geography of these services
industries has begun to resemble the manufacturing industries—consumer
234
Making the Global Supply Base
235
Timothy Sturgeon, John Humphrey, and Gary Gereffi
236
Making the Global Supply Base
around the world, Flextronics, with its strategy of “vertical integration,” oper-
ates nine huge “industrial parks,” where it has invited many of its most
immediate suppliers of product-specific components (bare printed circuit
boards and plastic enclosures) to co-locate with its final assembly plants for
rapid response in regional markets.2
The sale and spin-off of in-house manufacturing and parts operations
underline the structural shift that was occurring in these industries from in-
house production to global outsourcing, and the accumulation of this off-
loaded capacity within a relatively small number of huge suppliers shows the
dramatic consolidation and increasing integration of the global supply base.
But outsourcing, as such, does not tell the entire story. In the electronics
industry, fast-growing lead firms with little if any in-house production cap-
acity, such as EMC, Sun Microsystems, Cisco, and Silicon Graphics, also
demanded that suppliers provide global support.
In some key locations, lead firms did not necessarily have plants to sell or
spin-off, especially in newer locations such as China and Eastern Europe.
Because of this, a great deal of the global expansion of suppliers in the 1990s
was either “organic” in character, involving the enlargement of existing facil-
ities and the establishment of new, “greenfield” plants,3 or achieved through
the acquisition of regional suppliers, in what some industry participants refer
to as the “rolling-up” of regional supply bases into an (albeit imperfectly)
integrated global supply base.
237
Timothy Sturgeon, John Humphrey, and Gary Gereffi
sales of $14.1 billion. Since then, Lear has suffered from the severe financial
difficulties plaguing the automotive supply base, along with most other large
suppliers. While 2008 revenues and employment are down from the peak in
2000, the company’s geographic footprint has continued to expand.4
The spin-off of the internal parts divisions of General Motors and Ford in
the late 1990s created the world’s two largest and most diversified automotive
parts suppliers almost overnight, Delphi and Visteon. Because they were spun
out of huge parent firms with strong international operations, these “new”
suppliers were born with a global footprint and the capability to supply
complete automotive subsystems. For example, Visteon was born with broad
capabilities in chassis, climate, electronics, glass and lighting, interior and
exterior trim, and power trains. In 2000 the company operated 38
manufacturing plants in the USA and Canada; 23 in West Europe; 21 in
Asia; 9 in Mexico; 6 in East Europe; and 4 in South America; system and
module engineering work was carried out in 1 facility in Japan, 3 in Germany,
3 in England, and 4 in the United States. Like Lear and other large global
suppliers with significant business with the American automakers, Visteon has
experienced deep financial trouble in recent years. Nevertheless, the com-
pany, in 2010, still has a global footprint, with 21 manufacturing facilities
and 2 technical centers in the United States and Canada, 8 manufacturing
facilities and 2 technical centers in Mexico, 43 manufacturing facilities and 5
technical centers in Asia Pacific, 23 manufacturing plants and 10 technical
centers in Western Europe, 8 manufacturing plants and 2 technical centers in
Eastern Europe, and 6 manufacturing facilities in South America. The shift, in
the main, has been from the United States and Western Europe to Asia.
The emergence of global suppliers was mostly, but not solely, a phenome-
non of American firms. European and a few Japanese motor vehicle parts
suppliers followed their customers into new markets and went on acquisition
sprees to gain both a global footprint and the ability to supply larger sub-
systems of the car. Examples include Continental, Bosch, and Siemens
(Germany), Valeo (France), and Yazaki and Denso ( Japan).
By the late 1990s it had become a requirement for automotive suppliers,
large electronics contract manufacturers, and suppliers in several other sectors
to have a global footprint. In separate interviews conducted in 2000, Sturgeon
and Lester (2004: 69–70) quote managers at two global automotive suppliers
as saying:
The industry began to change 5–10 years ago. If a supplier doesn’t have a global
strategy, it can’t bid. New projects are no longer seen as an opportunity to expand
globally—instead, a supplier must have a global base in place to even make a bid.
This forces suppliers to have a global supply system in place.
238
Making the Global Supply Base
Suppliers must support assemblers as a sole source for global product lines to
support commonalization. We must supply the same part, with the same quality
and price, in every location. If [the automaker] says to go to Argentina, we must go
or lose existing, not just potential, business. Logistics are becoming a key competi-
tive advantage; we must have the ability to move production to where customer’s
facilities are.
239
Timothy Sturgeon, John Humphrey, and Gary Gereffi
to tap the available quota for export to the United States under the Multi-Fiber
Agreement (MFA). This triggered investment in countries that would not
otherwise have large-scale apparel assembly, such as Sri Lanka and Bangladesh.
In contrast to the pattern set in the 1970s and 1980s, control did not migrate to
local suppliers in these new locations. Rather, customer service and network
coordination functions stayed in the suppliers’ headquarters in Taiwan, Hong
Kong, Korea, and Singapore, while production was partially and sometime
completely relocated to less-developed countries.
Gereffi (1994a) calls this pattern “triangle manufacturing,” with developed-
country buyers, Hong Kong and South Korean intermediaries, and developing-
country factories creating a tripartite spatial division of labor. On top of this,
regional production systems, in which American and European apparel man-
ufacturers had been steadily moving production to nearby countries with
lower costs, such as Turkey, Morocco, Mexico, and the Caribbean Basin,
began to be penetrated by a few of the largest East Asian manufacturers and
intermediaries. As more countries were added over time, more complex
regional and even global-scale production systems emerged, with coordination
functions handled by East Asian suppliers and intermediaries. In the following
sections, we show the variety of paths to international production using a few
case studies.
240
Making the Global Supply Base
move from thirteenth place to eighth place amongst global garment exporters
between 1988 and 1992. About one-third of foreign-owned plants were set up
by South Korean firms, and another third were established by firms from Hong
Kong, Taiwan, and Singapore (Shin and Lee 1995: 187).
As with the contract garment assembly plants used by US companies in
Mexico and Central America, the new Indonesian plants were inserted into a
much broader division of labor. In many cases, they used materials and
equipment supplied from South Korea. Two-thirds of their inputs were im-
ported and two-thirds of output was exported (Dicken and Hassler 2000: 270).
The plants were also linked with their parent company’s marketing operations
and through these to global buyers in the United States and Europe. A Taiwan-
ese apparel manufacturer in Indonesia described how orders arrived at the
plant:
90% of our orders for Indonesia are coming from our Taiwanese head office. The
remaining 10% are orders from agents and representative offices in Jakarta. The
Taipei office is working with the buying offices directly in America or their repre-
sentative offices in Hong Kong or Singapore. Our main market is the US where we
sell 80% of our products. (cited in Dicken and Hassler 2000: 275)
Similar processes were evident in China, where firms from Hong Kong and
Taiwan created complex value chains with chain management and chain
coordination functions at home and production operations in China. In
many cases, firms from Taiwan and Hong Kong have relocated manufacturing
plants to the Chinese mainland, but maintained ownership.
241
Timothy Sturgeon, John Humphrey, and Gary Gereffi
242
Making the Global Supply Base
innovations and cost controls. The danger, as always for the trader, is that the
manufacturer and the buyer will deal directly with each other. In fact, this has
happened again and again, as both manufacturers and buyers have gained
competencies. Li & Fung has tried to shore up its position by offering turn-key
solutions, including product design services, and by helping buyers assure
their customer that their products meet labor and environment standards
with its “responsible sourcing” program.6
243
Timothy Sturgeon, John Humphrey, and Gary Gereffi
were not successful, and the bulk of Uraco’s business remained in providing
contract manufacturing services and precision-engineered metal parts to for-
eign firms operating in the South East Asian region. As traditional distribution
networks in the region matured, the need for the company’s distribution
services waned as well.
Nevertheless, in 1995 the company underwent a successful initial public
offering on the Singaporean stock exchange. In 1996, as revenues were ap-
proaching $53 million, Uraco won an important contract to manufacture
flatbed scanners for Hewlett Packard. In this year the company was operating
82,000 square feet of production space in three Singaporean factories, and
165,000 square feet of nearby production space in five factories in Johor and
Selangor, Malaysia (Business Times Online 1996a). In 1997, the firm reorganized
its business into three divisions: precision machining, contract manufacturing,
and investment (Business Times Online 1996b, 1997). The company’s troubles
were not over, however, and flagging profitability led to a management reshuf-
fle in 2000 and a name change, to Beyonics, in 2001. The company returned to
profitability in 2001, when it generated nearly $300 million in revenues, with
62 percent coming from contract manufacturing services, 29 percent from
precision engineering, and 9 percent from distribution (Geocities 2004).
The company’s product and service offerings are electronics manufacturing
services (that is, contract manufacturing), medical and consumer plastic injec-
tion molding and assembly, precision engineering services, precision metal
stampings, and precision tooling design and fabrication services. This is a
highly focused and complementary product portfolio, covering many of the
processes and a few of the basic products required to produce a wide variety of
electronics and closely related goods. The company has followed the rest of
the electronics contract manufacturing industry toward the bundling of ser-
vices to enable the production of complete products through its acquisitions
of precision plastic moldings suppliers Techplas (in 2000) and Pacific Plastics
(in 2002). In 2003 the company merged with a similar Singaporean contract
manufacturer, Flairis Technology Corporation, to achieve additional econo-
mies of scale and scope. The company’s distribution activities and attempts at
selling its own branded products have been dropped entirely.
With this tighter focus the company has expanded dramatically. According
to the market research newsletter Manufacturing Market Insider, Beyonics reven-
ues of $1.57 billion (with a razor-thin net profit of 0.3 percent) ranked the
company thirteenth on a list of the world’s largest electronics contract manu-
facturers in 2008.8 Through a combination of internal expansion and acquisi-
tion, Beyonics has developed a solid regional manufacturing footprint,
most notably by establishing “vertically integrated” electronics contract
manufacturing campuses in Kulai, Malaysia, in 2005; Suzhou, China, in 2006;
244
Making the Global Supply Base
245
Timothy Sturgeon, John Humphrey, and Gary Gereffi
sourcing options. This process of co-evolution has meant that Taiwan’s elec-
tronics industry has been able to develop without a significant cadre of local
lead firms. From the late 1970s to the present day, sourcing from Taiwan has
expanded from computer monitors, to various components and subsystems,
to complete desktop and notebook PC systems.
Firms from the American PC industry have played an especially important
role in the development of Taiwan’s electronics contract manufacturing sec-
tor. In the early 1980s, IBM began sourcing PC monitors from television and
television tube producers in Taiwan, including Tatung and Chung Hua. As the
demand for PCs expanded rapidly and the open architecture of IBM-compati-
ble PCs became firmly established in 1984 with the IBM model AT, some
entrepreneurial firms in Taiwan, such as Acer and Mitac, recognized the
opportunities and moved aggressively to develop the capability to design
PCs and peripheral devices based on the emerging standard. IBM’s modular
system architecture relied on a central processing unit supplied by Intel and
on an operating system from Microsoft, and, because the contracts famously
did not block Intel and Microsoft from selling to IBM’s competitors, a bevy of
new entrants, intense price competition, and a series of boom and bust cycles
soon followed. These conditions caused contract manufacturing to become a
popular strategy for lead firms in the United States seeking to cut costs and
limit investments in fixed capital.
The surging demand for contract manufacturing services encouraged exist-
ing Taiwan-based contract manufacturers producing consumer electronics
and electronic components, such as Hon Hai, to develop capabilities to assem-
ble PCs. Then, in the late 1980s, a set of firms that had been focused on the
design and manufacture of hand-held calculators entered the field. These
firms, which included Quanta, Compal, and Inventec, eventually became
the dominant notebook computer producers, in part because the design and
assembly competencies that drove miniaturization in calculators were well
suited to notebook computers, where small size, low weight, and efficient
power consumption are key factors for success. Although much simpler,
calculators are similar to PCs in that they are built around a central processing
unit that determines system architecture and most of the product’s
functionality.
The modular system architecture of PCs, and the dominant role of the
central processing unit (CPU) and operating system software in setting system
architecture, along with intense competition and short product life cycles,
created the conditions for the emergence of a set of firms that specialized in
the iterative, post-architectural portions of product design. This includes, for
example, the board-level input/output system (BIOS) of the PC, which deter-
mines how the machine handles the input and output from its main board to
the other elements of the system, such as storage and displays; and industrial
246
Making the Global Supply Base
247
Timothy Sturgeon, John Humphrey, and Gary Gereffi
The making of the global supply base was enabled by the deployment of
information technologies, which, along with better standards for sharing
information, enabled companies to achieve more precise forms of coordina-
tion, even with highly complex and technologically sophisticated products
and processes, a mode of governance that we have referred to elsewhere to as
value-chain modularity (Sturgeon 2002; Gereffi, Humphrey, and Sturgeon
2005). By the end of the 1990s, the depth and breadth of the global supply
base, along with new Internet-based tools for buyer–supplier matchmaking,
quotation, and operational coordination, was opening a new chapter in the
development of the global supply base, in which the barriers to global sour-
cing could fall far enough to encourage smaller and less technologically adept
retailers and start-ups to engage in global sourcing.
On the supply side, new requirements to respond rapidly to buyers and
make timely deliveries of complex products from multiple locations around
the world put a premium on size and technological competence, and raised
barriers for new entrants. Smaller local suppliers in developing countries were
often relegated to the margins of the value chain, if they were included at all.
The result was a process of consolidation, where the largest suppliers gained at
the expense of smaller, regional producers. Today, in the midst of an unprece-
dented global economic slowdown, the survival of this system has come into
question on several fronts. Even prior to the current crisis, supplier profitabil-
ity in some sectors, such as automotive and electronics, had been low to
negative for many years (Sturgeon, Van Biesebroeck, and Gereffi 2008).
Repeated severe economic cycles, previously contained within specific regions
and industries, and now being experienced across the board, have exacerbated
this persistent low profitability in the global supply base, triggering a wave of
plant closures and driving some of the largest and most capable firms to
248
Making the Global Supply Base
Value-chain modularity
The making of the global supply base has been enabled by rapid advances in
computerized design, automated production planning and inventory control,
logistics and production planning software, and robotic manufacturing equip-
ment. Tighter integration between lead firms and suppliers has been facili-
tated by the development of global industry standards (both open and de
facto), not only in the electronics industry, where standards at the component
level have created modularity in system design, but in all global industries. For
example, even when components are unique to specific products and design
architecture is integral and proprietary, as they are in the motor vehicle
industry, information technology can help firms coordinate cross-border ac-
tivities; exchange complex design files; track incoming, in-process, and fin-
ished inventories; and direct the shipment of finished goods directly from
factories to lead firms. In services, information technology and low-cost, high-
bandwidth communications systems installed during the late 1990s facilitate
the expansion of remote call centers for after-sales service and the real-time
provision of a host of other business services. Because these are not capabilities
that can be acquired cheaply or maintained easily, and because they allow
suppliers to handle larger and more diverse orders, increasing value-chain
modularity has helped to drive consolidation in the global supply base.
249
Timothy Sturgeon, John Humphrey, and Gary Gereffi
250
Making the Global Supply Base
operations and offer a broader package of services. In fresh fruits and vegeta-
bles, the large supermarkets in the UK, such as Tesco and Asda (owned by
Wal-Mart), rationalized the supply systems that they had developed in
the1980s and 1990s. They have begun to outsource functions such as planning
year-round supply, customer research, and benchmarking (product variety,
space allocated to different products, and so on) to “category managers.”
According to one leading UK importer, the goal is to reduce the number of
direct suppliers for the complete fruit and vegetable product offering from
dozens to perhaps three or five. These first-tier suppliers will be responsible
for organizing the rest of the chain (Dolan and Humphrey 2004).
This overarching trend, from vertically integrated lead firms with “captive”
supply bases dedicated to them, to outsourcing into a series of national and
regional supply bases, to consolidation and the rise of global suppliers, is
depicted in Figure 8.1. The role of modularity in facilitating this transition is
depicted in the character of inter-firm linkages, shifting from idiosyncratic to
1
Lead firms with captive supply bases (pre-1986)
End users
First tier
2 3
Lead firms with shared, modular suppliers in regional Value chain modularity with supplier consolidation;
supply bases (1986-1997) an integrated global supply base (1998–2009)
251
Timothy Sturgeon, John Humphrey, and Gary Gereffi
codifiable, standardized, and modular in later periods. Note that we define the
“value chain” as the full range of value-added activities, from component and
material production to end use, and the “supply chain” as the specific set of
companies that serve a specific lead firm in the context of producing a specific
product or service.
Conclusions
This chapter has outlined how the new global supply base has come about,
how it has begun to remake the global economy, and what its prospects are
going forward. Retailers have been only one of several driving forces in the
development of this supply base. While the global supply base is concentrated
252
Making the Global Supply Base
Technology
bubble
1991–2 Asian
US recession financial
crisis
1985–6
PC bubble
Figure 8.2. World imports of intermediate, capital, and final goods, 1962–2006
in East Asia, it now extends far beyond that region, creating a more-or-less
integrated network of plants, service facilities, distribution and collection
points, and logistics hubs in key locations across the globe.
Suppliers from developed countries, especially the United States, expanded
their roles and set up global operations through the 1990s. Beginning in the
late 1990s, decisions by lead firms (retailers and technology-intensive produ-
cers alike) sought to simplify and consolidate their sourcing networks and in
the process created a new class of global suppliers. As global suppliers added
capabilities and scale, they began to offer their customers turn-key access to a
full package of manufacturing processes, finished products, complete product
lines, and even complementary bundles of services, including product design,
component purchasing, final packaging, global logistics, and after-sales repair.
To establish their global footprints and provide full-package capabilities,
global suppliers invested in new plants, acquired regional competitors and
facilities previously owned by MNC affiliates, and in some cases “vertically
integrated” by entering the business of upstream and downstream component
suppliers and service providers.
While global suppliers have lowered the bar for lead firms to participate in
global value chains, they have at the same time raised the bar for local
manufacturing firms that want to enter GVCs as suppliers. As global suppliers
expanded their operational footprint to new locations, such as Southern Asia,
Central America and the Caribbean, Eastern and Central Europe, parts Of sub-
Saharan Africa, and the Middle East, it became harder for new entrants to
compete. Firms and countries that try to enter global value chains today must
253
Timothy Sturgeon, John Humphrey, and Gary Gereffi
meet standards and performance requirements that are much higher than
firms entering one or two decades ago.
Within these broad patterns, there is plenty of room for variation in com-
pany strategy, even in what might appear to be the same market niches. Thus,
The Limited and Gap, Nike and Reebok, Ford and Toyota, Coca Cola and
Pepsi, Hewlett Packard and Fujitsu, and so on, might follow different specific
strategies related to outsourcing and offshoring based on managerial choices
(Berger 2005) or the institutional norms of the company’s home country
(Lane and Bachmann 1997; Sturgeon 2007). A major theme in this chapter
is that market making in global supply chains is not just about offshoring,
fragmentation, and specialization. By highlighting that there is consolidation,
concentration, and rebundling going on in particular locations and within
MNCs around the globe, we reinforce the core idea that market making takes
place through the exercise of “power” by big firms and large countries. These
issues are captured by the GVC perspective, and introduce critical elements of
agency and institutional variation into the story that would be lost in a
straightforward “market-forces” account of global integration.
This chapter has emphasized the self-reinforcing, co-evolutionary character
of the market-making process. In earlier chapters in this volume, we have seen
how experiments with global sourcing in the 1970s and 1980s by a handful of
pioneering retailers and multinational manufacturing firms created the initial
markets for export-oriented economies in East Asia. Retailers and branded
manufacturers in rich countries became more experienced with international
outsourcing; developing countries acquired the infrastructure and capabilities
needed to sustain more complex operations; and suppliers upgraded their
capabilities in response to larger orders for more complex goods. As these
resources improve over time, more lead firms gain the confidence to embrace
the twin (and often entwined) strategies of outsourcing and offshoring. The
global supply base has been made in a self-reinforcing cycle of outsourcing
and supply-base upgrading that connects firms across developed and develop-
ing countries; its frontiers and capabilities continue to evolve.
254
9
In the following discussion I will argue that the emergence of giant transna-
tional contractors may alter the dynamic of global supply chains, including
the current seemingly unstoppable dominance of giant US- and EU-based
retailers as market makers. At the very least, I will argue, the rise of China as
an economic power will probably impact on the current dynamic in several
ways. At a minimum, giant contractors—“Big Suppliers”—are themselves
market makers for their own suppliers, exerting increasing control over key
aspects of the production supply chain. More speculatively, if the current
trends continue, the giant contractors may come to challenge the power of
all but the biggest “Big Buyers” they serve. This could alter the governance
structure of some global supply chains, raising the possibility that Taiwanese-
and Chinese-based multinational “Big Suppliers” may themselves someday
morph into “Big Buyers,” challenging the firms they now serve. In other words,
the current shift in the governance structure of global market dynamics—from
manufacturer to retailer—may turn out to have been merely a stage, associated
in part with the ready availability of low-cost labor in the rising East Asian
economies during the past three decades. But, as these economies mature,
moving from export-oriented industrialization to producing for their own
internal markets, the dynamics that once favored the growing power of US-
and EU-based “Big Buyers” may also shift, eroding the market-making ability of
the latter relative to multinationals based in the East Asian economies.
The appearance of giant factories as global suppliers for Wal-Mart and other
large retailers is a largely unexpected development, since so many business
and management theorists, emphasizing “flexible specialization,” the “virtual
corporation,” and other forms of decentralized production and distribution,
have argued that the era of the gigantic production facility was over (see, e.g.,
Piore and Sabel 1986; Kapinsky 1993; Pine and Davis 1999). No longer would
entrepreneurs assemble tens of thousands of workers at capital-intensive fac-
tory complexes like River Rouge or Cannon Mills. But since the late 1990s,
giant transnational corporations have emerged, mainly from Hong Kong,
Taiwan, South Korea, and China, that operate massive factories under contract
with consumer goods buyers—retailers and branded merchandisers—a trend
that may well portend a dramatic twenty-first-century shift of organizational
power within global supply chains. The emergence of these giant transna-
tional contractors has yet to be examined.
In the textile and apparel industries, for example, the consolidation of
production, both at the factory and the country level, is highly pronounced,
and will greatly accelerate now that the thirty-year-old Multi-Fiber Agreement
256
Transnational Contractors in East Asia
257
Richard P. Appelbaum
Esquel’s vertically integrated operations ensure the highest quality in every step of
the apparel manufacturing process. Production begins in Xinjiang province in
northwestern China, where the Group grows its own Extra Long Staple (ELS)
Cotton and Organic Cotton, continues through spinning, weaving, dyeing,
manufacturing, packaging and retailing.5 Esquel’s textile and apparel production
is complemented by strong product development capabilities. The Group’s design
and merchandising team work closely with its research and development center to
create unique finishings such as wrinkle-free and nanotechnology performance
qualities that consistently give Esquel the cutting edge in the apparel industry.
258
Transnational Contractors in East Asia
Today, TAL boasts that it is one of the few Asian suppliers capable of handling a
variety of EDI documents, such as purchase order (PO), advance ship notice (ASN),
invoice, point-of-sales (POS) data, order status, etc. . . . From the late 1990s to
today, the hurdle has once again been raised: firms are now being asked to
synchronize their supply and demand activities far more effectively and this
means ensuring that far-flung product development, marketing/sales, and supply
chains are in close coordination. TAL responded by enabling vendor managed
inventory with customers such as J. C. Penney. In doing so, TAL was able to link its
designers and its factory floors half a world away to the points of sale in the US,
resulting in ever greater efficiencies for its customers and expanded business
opportunities for TAL . . . Now as an integrated synchronization services provider
with manufacturing capabilities, TAL not only has visibility into demand at the
retailer’s point of sale, i.e. to demand from the final consumer, but can link this
information back directly to production operations on the factory floor as well as
to product development and R&D activities. (Koudal and Long 2005)
The new process is one from which Penney is conspicuously absent. The entire
program is designed and operated by TAL Apparel Ltd. . . . TAL collects point-of-
sale data for Penney’s shirts directly from its stores in North America, then runs the
numbers through a computer model it designed. The Hong Kong company then
decides how many shirts to make, and in what styles, colors and sizes. The
manufacturer sends the shirts directly to each Penney store, bypassing the retail-
er’s warehouses—and corporate decision makers. (Kahn 2003)
259
Richard P. Appelbaum
TAL provides similar services to Brooks Brothers and Land’s End. Vendor-
managed inventory gives the manufacturer increased market-making power
over its suppliers, thereby signaling some shift in power from retailer to
contractor: it is now the contractor, rather than the retailer, who manages
the supply chain (Kahn 2003). TAL’s New York City-based design team devel-
ops the style, TAL analyzes sales data to determine the quantity to produce for
J. C. Penney stores, and TAL’s Asian factories turn out the product. According
to one management consultant who has studied the industry: “You are giving
away a pretty important function when you outsource your inventory man-
agement. That’s something that not a lot of retailers want to part with” (cited
in Kahn 2003).
The third kind of supply-chain management, according to Cao (2005), is the
third-party coordinated supply chain, in which garment trading companies pro-
vide the coordination, oversee quality control, and sometimes provide fashion
design. The prime example of this form of supplier market making is the Li &
Fung Group, the giant multinational trading company is based in Hong Kong,
with a staff of 25,000 distributed across more than 70 offices in 40 countries
and territories, with 2006 revenues of $10.4 billion (Li & Fung 2007). As
discussed in the Chapter 8, trading companies such as Li & Fung have become
more powerful, taking the lead in supply-chain management (Kahn 2004b;
Pun 2005). Li & Fung is organized into three core businesses: exporting
services, value-chain logistics, and retailing.
Li & Fung Ltd manages the export supply chain for a variety of consumer
goods,9 “work[ing] together to find the best source for different
components or processes, and drawing on a global network of some
10,000 factories.” Activities span the supply chain, including initial
product development and design, raw material sourcing, production
planning, factory sourcing, manufacturing control, quality assurance,
export documentation, and shipping consolidation. Its venture capital
fund invests in consumer products companies in Europe and the United
States. By way of example (this from an interview with Li & Fung CEO
Victor Fung in the Harvard Business Review), the company might fill a large
order by sourcing its yarn from Korea, doing the dyeing in Taiwan,
purchasing buttons and zippers in China, and assembling the final
product in Thailand (Magretta 2002).
Integrated Distribution Services (IDS) Group provides “value-chain
logistics” throughout Asia in “three core business areas”: marketing (sales,
billing, and collection), logistics (shipping, warehousing, and delivery),
and manufacturing (fabrication, testing, and packaging).
Li & Fung Retailing Ltd operates more than 950 retail outlets, with 11,500
employees, in Greater China, Singapore, Malaysia, Thailand, Indonesia,
260
Transnational Contractors in East Asia
the Philippines, and South Korea for Toys “R” Us, Circle K, and Branded
Lifestyle. Toys “R” Us is a joint venture with the US-based parent
company (in 1999, Li & Fung acquired 100 percent ownership of the
business in Hong Kong, Taiwan, Singapore and Malaysia). Branded
Lifestyle represents major European and US brands in Asia, seeking to
establish a consciousness of “brand values” for its clients (these include
Salvatore Ferragamo and Calvin Klein, amongst others).
261
Richard P. Appelbaum
the ending of the MFA, which, as noted elsewhere, has encouraged major
apparel companies to concentrate production in a smaller number of much
larger facilities in a relative handful of countries. In addition to the labor cost
savings that would result from concentrating production in China, Liz Clai-
borne and Luen Thai executives believe that “the real gains would come by
reorganizing their entire production process so as to be able to cut down on
turnaround times for new clothes and coordinate logistics” (Kahn 2004a).
Having everyone in a single location—designers, fabric and raw-material sup-
pliers, sewing—is viewed as significantly cutting costs and improving turn-
around time, “getting new styles into stores faster.”
Instead of having 100 people spread between New York and Asia doing the same
job, the new supply-chain city will enable the two companies to reduce staff to 60
people in China, concentrating all functions closer to the factory floor . . . By
moving all but the most critical designers and trend spotters to Asia, the company
can dispense with the tedious back and forth, slashing precious weeks off produc-
tion times and getting up-to-minute fashions into stores sooner . . . In the new
supply-chain city, everyone from the fabric mill to the store will use the same
scan-and-track inventory system. Goods can roll off the factory floor and go
straight to a store . . . (Khan 2004a)
262
Transnational Contractors in East Asia
leading manufacturer of athletic shoes, but also because of the growth of its
Greater China (China, Taiwan, and Hong Kong) wholesale and retail opera-
tions. In terms of its manufacturing capabilities, Yue Yuen manages what are
probably the world’s largest footwear manufacturing plants in Dongguan,
China (with over 15 million square feet of manufacturing floor space) and
Ho Chi Minh City, Vietnam (1.3 million square meters) (Yue Yuen 2007a). Its
sprawling factory complex in Dongguan alone reportedly employs some
110,000 workers, including 21,000 for Nike and 13,000 for Adidas. The Nike
production sector includes recently renovated dormitories for its workers
(eight women to a spartan room, in two rows of bunk beds), cafeteria, and a
recently constructed “activities center” that includes a library and reading
room, karaoke and dancing facility, a chess room, and meeting rooms and
classrooms. Nike reportedly invested some $4.5 million in these renovations;
it uses the new facilities to offer workers courses in personal finances, compu-
ters, and counselling.16
As of September 2006 Yue Yuen expansion into wholesale and retail sales
boasted a network of more than 2,100 wholesale distributors in the greater
China region, operating 640 retail outlets, distributing products from the
major brands made in its factories (Merk 2003; Yue Yuen 2007b).17 Revenues
from the company’s wholesale and retail operations in Greater China grew by
four-fifths over the previous year—although they still represented only a small
percentage (5.4 percent) of total revenues. As of FY 2006, Asian markets
accounted for 30 percent of Yue Yuen’s total turnover—second only to the
United States (38 percent) (Yue Yuen 2007b). The company remains bullish
about its wholesale and retail operations. The company, however, did not
meet its goal of opening 1,000 additional stores or counters by 2008, a goal
based in part on its belief, in 2007, that the Beijng Olympics would serve as a
catalyst for increased sporting goods sales in China (Yue Yuen 2007b).18
Yue Yuen is also engaged in the upstream production of raw materials, shoe
components, and even production tools—affording a high degree of vertical
integration over its supply chain. In 2002, for example, it acquired Pou Chen’s
interest in sixty-seven upstream footwear material providers, including raw
materials, equipment, and shoe components (Yue Yuen 2006). It is also seek-
ing downstream integration, in terms of exerting tighter control over its
logistics. As the company reported
263
Richard P. Appelbaum
The company is clearly emerging as a market maker with regard to its own
suppliers, as well as its Asian consumers. Yet, when dealing with major brands
such as Nike or Reebok, how much of a market maker is Yue Yuen in the retail
sector? When Yue Yuen’s costs rose sharply in 2004,19 it was able to pass on
less than a third of the cost increase to its customers, forcing the company to
post a 1.6 percent year-to-year decline in profits, the first such decline in
twelve years. While some analysts regard this decline as indicative of the
relatively weak bargaining power of even the largest contractors vis-à-vis the
brands that rely on them (Fong 2005), others disagree (Hermanson 2005).
Moreover, the company reported that, in 2006, “the average selling price
continued its upward trend, reflecting the product mix change and the
increase in underlying material costs” (Yue Yuen 2007b), suggesting that it
was in fact able to pass on some of its cost increases to its buyers.
Whereas Wal-Mart’s relationship with its suppliers is famously fleeting,
determined purely by price considerations, the athletic footwear industry
requires close cooperation between buyer and supplier, achieved through
stable, ongoing relationships. Yue Yuen, for example, began as a supplier for
Wal-Mart in the 1970s, but eventually developed the know-how, technologi-
cal capacity, and size to move up to high-end brands such as Nike. Because the
major brands require a highly diversified product mix and flexible production
systems, Yue Yuen’s high degree of vertical integration (including control over
inputs and logistics) enables it to work with customers that require rapid
market response. These same requirements afford the company a fair amount
of bargaining power with even its largest customers.
Yue Yuen is already engaged in a limited way in original brand
manufacturing; is it likely to “learn through doing,” and eventually replace
Nike and its other clients as a leading designer and retailer of athletic shoes?
Nike and Yue Yuen are highly dependent on one another, reducing the
probability that Nike will cut production if Yue Yuen begins to market its
own low-cost brands in China (Ho 2005). On the other hand, Yue Yuen is a
highly profitable business, thanks to its broad and loyal client base; it is
unlikely to threaten those relationships by creating potentially competing
brands (K. W. Chan 2005; Pun 2005).
At the present time, it is clear that, while Yue Yuen is a powerful market
maker with regard to its own suppliers, it remains subordinate to its buyers,
particularly the largest ones such as Nike. Beginning with design, and
throughout the complex process of manufacturing athletic footwear (which
involves as many as 200 different steps), Nike’s hand is felt—as is evidenced by
the thousand production specialists Nike employs to work closely with its
suppliers (Merk 2006: 6–8). Yue Yuen is more dependent on Nike than the
reverse;20 moreover, it has carved out a highly profitable niche as the world’s
leading supplier, a niche it would not want to jeopardize.21 Jeroen Merk,
264
Transnational Contractors in East Asia
who has conducted a detailed study of Nike’s relationship with Yue Yuen,
concludes:
Even though Yue Yuen has enough skills and cash to launch their own brand, they
deliberately decided not to do so because that would make them a direct competi-
tor of many of their customers. In fact, Yue Yuen is very concerned with protecting
brand secrets. The company makes sure that its R&D centre never puts competing
brands in the same place. This also implies that Yue Yuen cannot break into
end-markets directly. (Merk 2006: 17)
The company will make the most of the 2008 Beijing Olympics to gain market share
in the mainland . . . Pou Chen executives emphasized that their company would
never develop own-branded shoes to rival its customers including Nike. Yue Yuen
has long promoted Nike, Adidas and Reebok sport shoes at its stores. (Taiwan 2007)
China’s rapid economic growth has averaged around 9 percent annually since
1990. Even allowing for exaggerated claims and poor governmental statistics,
China’s growth is explosive by any standards. Bear in mind that this is an
average; the growth poles of China—South China in Guangdong Province
around the Pearl River Delta, Shanghai, and the Yangtze River Delta—are
growing at much greater rates. The lion’s share of this growth is concentrated
in South China, which accounts for nearly half of all the country’s exports.
The region boasts the highest concentrations of manufacturing, the largest
factories, the greatest influx of labor from rural areas, the world’s third and
fourth busiest ports (in Hong Kong and Shenzhen), and the world’s largest
freight facility (IAM Journal 2005: 17).
A wide range of consumer goods industries have contributed to this growth.
As noted previously, China is predicted to account for as much as half of the
world’s textile exports once the full effect of the end of the MFA is realized. In
2004, China accounted for 45.1 million computers, an increase of 39 percent
from just one year earlier; 70.5 million air-conditioning units (an increase of
43 percent), 30.3 million refrigerators (30 percent), and 23.5 million washing
machines (19 percent). Similar yearly increases were posted in metal-cutting
machinery (36 percent), cement equipment (63 percent), metal rolling equip-
ment (60 percent), and tractors (84 percent). “Morgan Stanley . . . says that
China now absorbs half of the world’s cement production, a fourth of its
265
Richard P. Appelbaum
copper, and a fifth of its aluminium” (IAM Journal 2005: 15). This accelerated
growth has created enormous energy needs; the International Energy Agency
reports that China accounted for a third of the increase in global demand for
oil between 2002 and 2004 (IAM Journal 2005: 13–14).
Government policy in China has fostered the creation of vibrant industrial
districts comprised of clusters of suppliers, manufacturers, and contractors
that specialize in a single product, fostering economies of scale, lowering
transaction costs, and cutting prices. It has opened land for the development
of industrial parks, given tax benefits to businesses, built transportation net-
works and other infrastructure, and subsidized utilities. Private companies,
with government support, build factory complexes that include dormitories
and hospitals. The resulting clusters create synergies that foster technological
development (Barboza 2004). According to Ruizhe Sun, president of the China
Textile Information Center: “In terms of vertical supply chain, China has no
competition. We have button makers, fabric makers, thread makers, zipper
makers, you name it” (cited in Barboza 2004).
At the high end of the technology spectrum, the Shenzhen campus of
Huawei Technologies—manufacturer of globally competitive telecommunica-
tion equipment—boasts a research center, football fields, swimming pools,
and housing for 3,000 families. Baosteel, based in Shanghai, is in 2010 the
third largest producer of steel in the world. The Lenovo Group, amidst much
fanfare, bought IBM’s ailing PC business in December 2004. The Haier Group,
China’s leading maker of home appliances, has offices in 100 countries.
And TCL Electronics, China’s most profitable maker of televisions, acquired
the TV business of France’s Thomson in 2004; its website claims TCL-
Thomson Electronics to be “the largest color television enterprise in the
world.” More than a dozen Chinese companies number amongst the Fortune
Global 500 (see Table 9.1). And China is investing heavily in the next
266
Transnational Contractors in East Asia
If you look at Europe, it’s difficult to green-field or grow a company of much size.
But you can build an enormous-sized company in China if you make some fairly
aggressive assumptions about what’s going to happen to it. It’s the one place in the
world where you could replicate Wal-Mart’s success in the US.
Yet even Wal-Mart may face an uphill battle in China. China’s state-run
Shanghai Brilliance group, China’s largest retailer, claims sales of $8.1 billion
in 3,300 stores. And Wal-Mart is also competing with France’s Carrefour,
which has 60 “hypermarkets” with sales of $2 billion (C. Chandler 2005).
Yet the biggest challenge to retail expansion in China may be cultural: with
small apartments and limited space for consumer items, the growing number
of middle-class Chinese shoppers are accustomed to shopping on foot, making
frequent trips for small volume purchases.
267
Richard P. Appelbaum
giant retailers and equally giant contractors, may be replicating the vertical
integration characteristic of the earlier “Fordist” organization of production.
These dynamics remain poorly understood. What is needed is long-term
research to chart the impact of changes in retailing and contracting. In partic-
ular, I would suggest a number of interrelated questions that could guide
systematic, long-term investigations, focusing principally on China, but also
on East Asia generally—bearing in mind that the present moment is but a
snapshot with the changing dynamics of the world economy:
How does the trend toward concentration of production in large
transnational contractors impact the relative power of contractors
vis-à-vis retailers in supply-chain networks—for example, the ability of
contractors to negotiate production costs, or “move up” into such higher
value-added activities as designing and marketing their own labels?
How do recent innovations in supply-chain management influence the
relationship between big buyers and their suppliers—for example, when
the largest suppliers take over many of the functions of supply-chain
management from retailers? What is the role of giant trading companies,
such as Li & Fung, which appear to be becoming increasingly central in
supply-chain management?
What will be the impact if a growing number of retailers move
geographically closer to their principal suppliers—for example, in the
form of Luen Thai’s “supply-chain city” (a move that also undoubtedly
signals a desire to be closer to China’s rapidly emerging markets)?
How does the rise of China as an industrial power change the dynamics of
the global supply chains in which Chinese firms are involved? Will
China’s largest suppliers move increasingly into retailing, first locally,
then regionally? How will this affect the dominance of the world’s current
retail giants? And how will China’s growth in capital-intensive industries
(such as shipbuilding, automotive, aircraft, construction, and so on) affect
the relative power of retail-controlled supply chains?
To what extent will the emergence of large contractors generate linkages
with other firms and sectors that contribute to industrial upgrading and
more broadly based economic development? Does their vertical
integration restrict the formation of local economic linkages that might
stimulate more broad-based economic growth?
Finally, what will be the impact of China’s move into advanced
technologies, on the dynamics of global supply chains?
268
Part Four
Industries and Market Making
This page intentionally left blank
10
Introduction
Today you could walk into supermarkets or a supercenter (selling food and
general merchandise) in Mexico City or Shanghai or hundreds of other cities
around the world and think you had just entered an upscale store in an
American or European suburb. Of course, once you looked at the customers
and employees or at some of the different food products, you would realize
you were not in the USA or Europe. However, the general appearance and
operation of the supermarket would appear very familiar. In the late 1980s,
modern food retailing was pretty much exclusive to the United States, Western
Europe, and a few other economically advanced countries such as Australia
and Canada. In a phenomenally short period (since the middle 1990s), mod-
ern food retailing has spread around the world to countries in Latin America,
Asia, Eastern Europe, and even parts of Africa. The global expansion of mod-
ern food retailing is an excellent example of the concept of market making.
Food retailers are remaking their consumer and supplier markets.
On the consumer side, supermarkets and other formats such as supercenters
have transformed the food shopping experience for hundreds of millions of
consumers around the world. People in Brazil, China, South Africa, and
dozens of other countries who used to shop only at open-air public markets,
street vendors, and small family-operated stores are going to modern super-
markets and supercenters as well as other modern retail formats (such as
chains of hard discounts, neighborhood stores, and convenience stores).
They are no longer waited on personally by the shopkeeper or vendor, but,
like Americans and Western Europeans, they are walking up and down the
aisle making their own selections before checking out. The selection of pro-
ducts is many times greater typically than in the traditional markets and stores
Benjamin Senauer and Thomas Reardon
and the overall quality, variety, and safety of the food much better. In addi-
tion, in many cases the prices are lower than in the traditional markets and
small shops, especially at first in processed foods, and with a lag, in fresh
foods.
At the same time, modern food retailing has so dramatically altered the
consumer market that it has also reshaped the supply chain. Most aspects of
the traditional agro-food systems, including production, transportation, and
marketing, in developing countries have been markedly inefficient. They have
been characterized by low productivity levels, high post-harvest losses because
of factors such as spoilage, and poor quality and food safety standards.
Although there are many additional variations, we will cover only the basic
store formats of modern food retailing. Supermarkets are departmentalized,
self-service stores that carry a wide selection of food and household goods that
are consumed regularly. Most supermarkets are now part of a chain of stores.
They are substantially larger and have a much broader selection than tradi-
tional grocery stores. Customers move along aisles stocked with products with
a cart or basket to fill. The items are paid for at cash registers in the front of the
store. Many of these features, which we take for granted, were remarkable
innovations when they first appeared. The first self-service grocery store was
opened in 1916. Before that clerks had to wait on each customer and get the
items wanted from behind counters. Many products were kept in bulk form
and were measured out and packaged for customers. The New York-based King
Cullen (1930) and Big Bear (1932) stores are typically considered the first real
supermarkets. By 1937, there were 3,000 supermarkets in operation in forty-
seven states (Zimmerman 1955).
Supermarkets spread rapidly in the 1950s and 1960s, along with the growth
of suburbs. Supermarkets and the food manufacturing industry grew together
in a symbiotic relationship. Supermarket chains developed their price advan-
tage over traditional retailers by buying in bulk and thus exploiting economies
of scale. The natural partner from whom to buy in bulk was a large-scale food
manufacturer. In the same way, to establish mass brand presence, be priced
competitively, and develop economies of scope with a diversity of products,
large food manufacturers found supermarket chains to be natural partners,
with clear advantages over mom-and-pop shops in all but the manufacturer’s
degree of bargaining power with the client. This symbiosis was as true of large
food manufacturers and supermarkets in the USA in the 1940s as it is in
developing countries today.1 Jointly, supermarkets and large food manufac-
turers transformed the consumer food market. While this is true in general,
272
The Global Spread of Modern Food Retailing
some of the largest early supermarket chains, such as A&P, the largest retailer
in the world in the mid-twentieth century, had quite a strained relation with
many big manufacturers, and relied to a large extent on private labels. In the
case of A&P, this strategy eventually contributed to its downfall, mostly at the
hand of the antitrust authorities.
Supercenters, such as those operated by Wal-Mart, began to appear in the
USA in the 1990s; they combined a supermarket and mass merchandise
retailing in a single, very large store. A similar combination format actually
appeared in France first, where it was referred to as a hypermarket. The so-
called combination stores were common in the USA before they appeared in
France. In fact, French managers went to the USA to study the principles of
modern retailing, and came up with the hypermarket format.
Wholesale clubs, such as Sam’s Club and Costco, also carry both food and
general merchandise. They require a membership to shop, and lean toward
large sizes and bulk sales. Limited-assortment stores, such as Aldi and Sav-A-
Lot, are small, “bare-bones”, “hard-discount” food stores. They typically carry
fewer than 2,000 items and few, if any, perishables. Convenience stores, such
as 7-Eleven, offer a very limited selection of food and non-food items (Food
Institute 2007).
The Universal Product Code (UPC) providing bar codes on individual
packages was adopted in the 1970s. Scanners came into use to expedite
checkout and eliminate the necessity of stamping a price on each item.
However, unlike in other retail sectors where scanners were adopted, few
advances in the overall supply chain occurred. There was an imbalance of
bargaining power between the food retailers and the major food manufac-
tures, which favored the latter in the USA, as large food manufacturers had
innovated with national brands in the late 1800s and early 1900s when super-
markets were in their infancy. Therefore, well-established food manufacturers
had considerable bargaining power until well into the late twentieth century,
when the pendulum of market power swung toward the retailers. In contrast,
the market power balance has clearly been on the side of the large retailers in
the UK from the mid-twentieth century (Wrigley and Lowe 2002).
Manufacturers had adopted the practice of periodically running large
batches of a product and then pushing it through the system with special
discounts. The distribution system had become bloated with inventories sit-
ting in warehouses. The inventory cost hurt retailers’ competitiveness. Hence,
food retailers instituted a version of “lean inventory management” in the early
1990s under the banner Efficient Consumer Response, widely referred to as
ECR. The development of ECR was in large part a response to Wal-Mart, with
its highly efficient distribution system and “every day low pricing” (EDLP)
strategy. Wal-Mart had already affected supermarket sales in household mer-
chandise and was beginning to open supercenters, which directly competed
273
Benjamin Senauer and Thomas Reardon
with supermarkets (King and Phumpiu 1996; Coggins and Senauer 1999). ECR
was designed to “drive costs” from the distribution system, a phrase fre-
quently used. ECR used the advances in information technology to link
retailers, distributors, and suppliers electronically, so that they could coordi-
nate more closely. Timely, accurate, paperless information on sales, inventory
replenishment needs, and payments were to flow one way, with a smooth,
continual product flow matched to consumption in the other direction. Ware-
houses became distribution centers with the goal of speeding the flow of
goods rather than storing inventory. Direct store delivery, in which a truck-
load was sent directly from the supplier to retail stores without ever going
through a distribution center, was adopted for some products. The most
innovative and best-managed food retailers were most successful at achieving
the goals of ECR and thus achieving a competitive advantage with lower costs
(King and Phumpiu 1996; Coggins and Senauer 1999).
By the end of the 1990s the major food retailers had largely remade the
supply chain in the USA and Western Europe. With their control of the flow of
information, they now had the upper hand in their relationship with food
manufacturers and other suppliers. The shift in power from food manufac-
turers to retailers in the USA (following a trend that had occurred a decade or
more before in the UK) was also affected by the waves of consolidation that
occurred in US food retailing and the growth of “private-label” or “store-
brand” products, which competed directly with the national brands. (Both
the consolidation and the private-label trends started later in the USA than in
the UK, as discussed in Wrigley and Lowe (2002).) For example, stores began to
sell cereals that were similar to General Mills’s Cheerios and Kellogg’s Corn-
flakes, but that sold at a much lower price. The new supply-chain practices
allowed food retailers efficiently to expand geographically. These practices
also helped in chains’ internationalization.
By 2005, many of the major food retailers in Europe and some of the
major chains in the United States were operating internationally, as shown
in Table 10.1 (Supermarket News 2007). The two largest global general-
merchandise retailers, Wal-Mart and Carrefour, are also the world’s two lead-
ing food retailers. This is because food accounts for at least a third of the sales
revenue of their most important store formats, Wal-Mart Supercenters and
Carrefour Hypermarkets. Wal-Mart is, in fact, the largest US food retailer, as is
Carrefour in France, its home country. As they have entered the markets of
developing countries like Mexico and transition countries like Poland, food
has been an even more important component of their strategy. This is because
people with lower incomes spend a higher proportion of their household
budgets on food.
Deloitte, the accounting and consulting firm, publishes an annual Global
Powers of Retailing study. The 2007 report makes clear that the fastest sales
274
The Global Spread of Modern Food Retailing
growth for the world’s 250 largest retailers is occurring outside the developed
countries. Their average sales growth was only 2.4 percent in France in FY
2005 and 2.1 percent in the UK, whereas it was 20.3 percent in Latin America.
The majority of the top 250 global retailers are involved in food retailing.
Some 54 percent operated supermarkets, superstores, or other formats in
which food products constituted a major proportion of retail sales (Deloitte
2007).
Wal-Mart de Mexico provides a good example of international business
operations of a major global retailer. Wal-Mart’s expansion outside the United
States began in 1991 in Mexico. In a joint venture with the Mexican retailer
Cifra, the country’s largest and strongest retailer at the time, a Sam’s Club was
opened in Mexico City. Wal-Mart acquired majority ownership of Cifra in
1997, and the name was changed to Wal-Mart de Mexico. After Wal-Mart had
bought Cifra, it kept the experienced local managers, but introduced its
efficient US purchasing and distribution system, while investing in expansion.
Just as in the United States, Wal-Mart’s core strategy was focused on low prices
(Malkin 2004). Today Wal-Mart is the largest general-merchandise and food
retailer in Mexico. However, the acquisition by Soriana of Gigante in Decem-
ber 2007 means that there is now a large domestic rival. Wal-Mart operated
several formats in Mexico, with a total of 783 stores in 103 cities throughout
the country and 140,000 employees. Wal-Mart de Mexico sales were equiva-
lent to $18.3 billion in 2006. Total sales grew by 15.3 percent in 2006 in real
terms (corrected for inflation)—more than three times the rate of GDP/capita
growth—with comparable store (for stores open more than a year) real sales
growth of 6.9 percent. With sales growth that is much more robust than it has
been in the United States for Wal-Mart in recent years, it should not be
surprising that Wal-Mart de Mexico expanded rapidly, investing $1.1 billion
and opening 120 new stores since 2004 (Wal-Mart 2007).
275
Benjamin Senauer and Thomas Reardon
276
The Global Spread of Modern Food Retailing
these front-runners, almost approaching the 70–80 percent share for the
United States or France. South America and parts of developing East Asia
and transition Europe had thus seen in a single decade the same development
of supermarkets that the United States experienced in five decades.
There is a second set of countries perched at the tail end of the first wave and
near the start of the second wave, which we class with the first wave, with their
supermarket “take-off” in the mid-1990s, such as Costa Rica and Chile, with
close to 50 percent market share by 2002 (Reardon and Berdegué 2002), and,
in 2003, South Korea with 50 percent (Lee and Reardon 2005), the Philippines
and Thailand with approximately 50 percent each (Thailand Development
Research Institute 2002; Manalili 2005), and South Africa with 55 percent
(Weatherspoon and Reardon 2003).
Second Wave. The second-wave countries include parts of South East Asia
and Central America and Mexico, and Southern-Central Europe, where the
share went from around 5–10 percent in 1990 to 30–50 percent by the early
2000s, with the take-off occurring in the mid- to late 1990s; examples of rapid
growth by 2003 include Mexico with a 40 percent share of supermarkets in
total food retail (see Reardon, Berdegué, and Timmer 2005), Colombia with a
47 percent share (see Hernandez 2004), Guatemala with 36 percent in 2002
(see Orellana and Vasquez 2004) Indonesia with 30 percent (Rangkuti, 2003),
and Bulgaria with 25 percent (Dries, Reardon, and Swinnen 2004).
Third Wave. The third wave includes countries where the supermarket
revolution take-off started only in the late 1990s or early 2000s, reaching
about 10–20 percent of national food retail by circa 2003; they include some
of Africa (see below), some countries in Central and South America (such as
Nicaragua (see Balsevich 2005), Peru, and Bolivia), and some countries in
South East Asia (such as Vietnam (see Tam 2004)), China, India, and Russia.
The latter three countries were the foremost destinations for retail foreign
direct investment (FDI) in the world in 2004 (T. Burt 2004) and remain so
in 2010.
China had no supermarkets in 1989, and food retail was nearly completely
controlled by the government; the sector began in 1990, and by 2003 had
climbed meteorically to a 13 percent share in national food retail, with $71 bil-
lion of sales, 30 percent of urban food retail, and growing the fastest in the
world, at 30–40 percent per year (Hu et al. 2004). Many of the driving forces
for supermarketization were in place (rising incomes, urbanization), and it
merely took a progressive privatization of the retail market and, even more
importantly, a progressive liberalization of retail FDI, which started in 1992
and culminated in 2004, to drive immense competition, even a full-out race,
in investment amongst foreign chains and between foreign chains and
domestic chains. This expansion and competition greatly accelerated in
2005 with the full liberalization of FDI that occurred as a condition to
277
Benjamin Senauer and Thomas Reardon
accession to WTO by China. Russia is a similar case, with a late start because of
policy factors holding back the take-off despite propitious socioeconomic
conditions, and then a very rapid take-off spurred on by an immense compe-
tition in investments underway in the early and mid-2000s (Dries and
Reardon 2005).
India is an interesting case, with its substantial middle class acting as a
“springboard” for the spread of supermarkets; the country is amongst the
top three retail FDI candidates in the world and is poised at the edge of a
supermarketization take-off, although the share in food retail is still only, at
most, 5 percent. In 2010, FDI is still far from fully liberalized, and regulations
concerning joint ventures in retail still block what observers think is an
imminent flood of foreign investment. Yet already a massive wave of domestic
capital investment, which should rise to $20 billion sometime before 2015, is
rushing into the Indian retail sector and already beginning to transform it,
fueled by rapid economic growth. Even though retail FDI by 2008 was not yet
liberalized, Metro and other global chains have already entered and operate
cash and carry stores (wholesale to small shops and food service and hotels),
and joint ventures have started, such as Bharti with Wal-Mart, with the latter
assuring the “back end” operations while Bharti assures the “front end” of
retailing, opening stores in March 2008 (Reardon and Gulati 2008).
Sub-Saharan Africa presents a very diverse picture, with only one country
(South Africa) firmly in the first wave of supermarket penetration (Weath-
erspoon and Reardon 2003), and the rest either in the early phase of the “third
wave” take-off of diffusion or in what may be a pending—but not yet started—
take-off of supermarket diffusion. Kenya (Neven and Reardon 2004) and
Zambia (Neven et al. 2006) are in the early phase of the “third wave,” and
have substantial numbers of supermarkets, initiated by both domestic invest-
ment and FDI from South Africa. This investment was attracted by a middle-
class base and high urbanization rates, but supermarket penetration is still
approximately where South America was in the early 1980s. The share of
supermarkets in urban food retail is about 10–20 percent in the large/medium
cities, and the share of produce hovers around 5 percent (see Neven and
Reardon 2004 for Kenya). Even with mainly domestic investment and some
South African retail capital and technology, there is still considerable uncer-
tainty about the rate at which the supermarket sector in these countries will
grow. The great majority of Africa, however, can be classified as not yet
entering a substantial “take-off” of supermarket diffusion. At the upper end
of this group are a score or so of supermarkets in countries like Mozambique
and Tanzania, Uganda, and Angola, places where South African retail FDI is
just starting (see Weatherspoon and Reardon 2003 for evidence on invest-
ments by the South African chain Shoprite) and may by 2020 be recognizable
as a “fourth wave.” Supermarkets in these countries show signs of early growth
278
The Global Spread of Modern Food Retailing
279
Benjamin Senauer and Thomas Reardon
90
80
70
60
Percent of sales
50
40
30
20
10
20 0
20 5
10
19 0
45
19 0
55
19 0
65
19 0
75
19 0
19 5
19 0
95
0
0
4
8
8
9
20
19
19
19
19
19
supermarkets penetrate first the upper-income, then the middle, and later the
poorer consumer segments; (2) supermarkets have already penetrated well
beyond the middle class into the food markets of the poor in the first-wave
countries and some of the second-wave countries (as can be seen in comparing
the supermarkets’ share in food retail versus the share of the middle and upper
classes in overall population in these countries); (3) while upper and middle
consumer segments are increasingly buying fresh produce from supermarkets,
the poor still mainly buy processed staples (rice, wheat and maize flour, edible
oil, bread, noodles, snacks, beverages, and condiments, as well as dairy) from
supermarkets.
An example is a household survey carried out in Nairobi, Kenya, in 2003
that interviewed a sample of 445 food shoppers, which covered all income
groups. The survey found that a surprising 80 percent of the households
shopped at a supermarket at least once a month and that the figure was
60 percent for even the poorest families in Nairobi. However, higher- and
upper-middle-income households, which essentially constitute what will be
referred to as the emerging global middle class in developing countries in a
later section of this chapter, were crucial in terms of sales. Although they made
up only 15 percent of Nairobi’s population, they accounted for 44 percent of
supermarkets’ sales. The study revealed a clear pattern in what was purchased
at supermarkets, which were mostly processed foods. Only 15 percent of those
sampled bought fresh fruits and vegetables there. Poorer households bought
mostly easy-to-store bulk items like sugar and soap and purchased less than
280
The Global Spread of Modern Food Retailing
The global expansion of modern food retailing is being driven by factors that
can be placed in three categories. As shown in Table 10.2, one can distinguish
between push or supply-side, pull or demand-side, and external enabling
factors. Food retailers in the advanced economies are increasingly faced with
domestic markets that are saturated, particularly in Western Europe, which
has pushed them to go abroad. Profits in many cases are under pressure from
intense competition. In these highly developed countries, expenditures on
food are still growing, but very slowly, especially for groceries as opposed to
restaurant and other food service meals.
In addition, food retailers are more capable of operating over far broader
geographic areas because of the innovations in information technology,
which allow them to monitor closely inventories and track the movement
of goods through the supply chain. They have been able to improve greatly
Table 10.2. Factors driving the spread of modern food retailing
281
Benjamin Senauer and Thomas Reardon
the efficiency of their supply chains. The companies with the highest effi-
ciency have a competitive advantage that they have tried to transfer to their
operations in other countries. Another push/supply-side factor is that large
retailers must be concerned if they let major international competitors get well
established in a particular foreign market first (Reardon, Timmer, and Berde-
gué 2004; Senauer and Venturini 2005).
At the same time there are demand-side forces that can be thought of as
pulling major food retailers to expand into other countries, especially those
with emerging market economies. Many of these countries, especially some of
the largest, such as Brazil, China, and India, have been experiencing robust
economics growth. China’s economy has grown at 10 percent or more annu-
ally for over a decade. Expenditures on food are growing rapidly in these
countries. According to Engel’s Law, the lower the initial per capita income
level of the population the greater will be the expansion in food demand for a
given rise in income. With additional income, many of the people in these
developing countries want to add more animal protein and greater variety and
improved quality to their diets, which have been dominated by one or two
staples, such as corn, rice, or wheat (Senauer and Venturini 2005).
The emerging middle class in seventeen developing and three transition
countries was estimated to contain over one billion people in 2000. These
consumers lived in households with at least $2,500 in income per person
(Myers and Kent 2003). Foreign currencies were compared to US dollars
using purchasing power parity (PPP) to correct for distortions in foreign
currency exchange rates. In another analysis that focused on food expendi-
tures, the emerging middle class was identified as persons living in households
with annual total consumer expenditures per capita of $2,695 per capita or
more in 2000, a very similar level to the other study. Based on data for Lima,
Peru, the emerging middle class corresponded to the top quintile in terms of
per capita expenditures. The households in the top quintile spent over three
times more on fresh vegetables, fresh fruit, and red meat than the average
purchases of people in the lower four quintiles. They spent over four times
more on yogurt, butter, and cheese; and over six times more on prepared foods
consumed at home (Senauer and Goetz 2004). This makes clear why this
middle class is so attractive to food retailers. The size of the emerging middle
class in China in 2003 was estimated to be 352 million, in India 105 million,
in Russia 89 million, in Brazil 57 million, all of which continue to grow rapidly
(Senauer 2005).
In addition, the increasing urbanization and growing participation of
women in jobs outside the home have created opportunities for modern
food retailers. Also, the ownership of a refrigerator allows a family to shift its
food shopping patterns. With a refrigerator, people do not need to shop as
frequently, even daily in many cases for fresh foods, or as close to home, as
282
The Global Spread of Modern Food Retailing
they would without a refrigerator. They can stock up on less frequent trips to a
more distant supermarket (Reardon, Timmer, and Berdegué 2004).
With rapid economic growth and large populations, the size of not just the
present, but especially the future potential, market for retail food in countries
such as China and India makes them extremely attractive opportunities.
Beyond that, the larger scale that can be achieved with expansion in a country
or a region, or even globally, allows for increased efficiency. There are scale
economies in a distribution system that serves more stores. The investments
in information technology and logistics can afford to be greater and the costs
of distribution centers and transport are spread over more retail outlets.
Traditional food production and marketing systems are burdened by ineffi-
ciencies and marked by low levels of capital, labor, and land productivity.
Post-harvest crop losses during storage, transportation, and marketing are
frequently in the order of 30 percent. Losses may be even higher for perishable
products, such as fresh fruits and vegetables, since they were not kept chilled
during distribution, which also affects quality.
Although trade liberalization has dominated the globalization debate, retail
(and processing) FDI liberalization is a far larger force in affecting the “remak-
ing of markets” in developing countries. In fact, the liberalization of retail FDI
in many developing countries in the early 1990s was the main “sufficient”
factor (beyond the necessary factors of the propitious demand-side situation
of rising incomes and urbanization) to initiate the supermarket revolution in
the 1990s in developing countries (Reardon and Timmer 2007).
Moreover, the global expansion of food retailers, as with other industries,
has been facilitated by the globalization of other services, including the
financial industry, as well as by improvements in communication with the
Internet and transportation, with convenient jet travel to most places in
the world. The movement of information and key personnel is crucial to a
global business. Food preferences still vary significantly between countries,
and even within regions of many nations. However, cultural globalization has
brought preferences closer together, which makes it easier for food retailers to
expand internationally.
283
Benjamin Senauer and Thomas Reardon
284
The Global Spread of Modern Food Retailing
and trucking capacity. Carrefour applies the same quality certification to some
200 items globally, and other international retailers are also applying similar
quality standards across countries (Reardon and Berdegué 2002).
Considerable attention has been given to the effects of the World Trade
Organization (WTO) accords and CODEX Alimentarius (an international food
code) protocols on agro-food quality and safety standards. In reality, the
private standards established by global food retailers have a greater impact in
many cases, except for the international trade of basic agricultural commod-
ities. Likewise, there has been a focus on the potential for exporting fruits and
vegetables and other agricultural products from developing countries to the
industrial ones. However, the domestic market opportunity may be greater.
For example, supermarkets in Latin America buy 2.5 times more produce to
sell to local consumers than these countries export to the rest of the world
(Reardon and Berdegué 2002).
Why are modern retailers in developing countries moving toward procure-
ment system modernization? In many countries, modern food retailers have
found the traditional wholesale markets and distribution systems challenging.
Javier Gallegos (2003), who was the head of marketing for Hortifruti, the
dedicated produce wholesaler for the CARHCO chain of supermarkets in
Central America (bought by Wal-Mart in 2006), clearly outlined the short-
coming of the traditional supply chain:
The market is fragmented, unformatted, and lacks standards. The growers produce
low quality products, use bad harvest techniques; there is a lack of equipment and
transportation, there is no post-harvest control and infrastructure; there is no
market information. There are high import barriers and corruption. The informal
market does not have: research, statistics, market information, standardized pro-
ducts, quality control, technical assistance, infrastructure. (Gallegos 2003)
285
Benjamin Senauer and Thomas Reardon
fresh produce. For example, Ahold, a Dutch supermarket chain, and Tesco, a
British chain, both operate central distribution centers (DCs) to serve their
stores in the Czech Republic, Hungary, and Poland. Carrefour, the French
hypermarket chain, distributes to fifty stores in southeastern Brazil from a
DC in Sao Paulo. Procurement of perishable products such as fresh fruits and
vegetables and dairy products, which used to be largely local, has become
regional and even, in some cases, global. Centralization increases scale econo-
mies and efficiency, although transportation costs typically increase (Reardon
and Timmer 2007; Reardon, Timmer, and Berdegué 2004).
The second pillar is moving from relying on spot markets, such as tradi-
tional wholesale markets and brokers, to wholesalers and logistics firms,
which are specialized for product categories and dedicated to meeting the
needs of modern food retailers. Hortifruti was established to procure the
fresh produce for the major supermarket chain in Central America. Freshmark
serves a similar function for Shoprite, the largest supermarket chain in Africa.
At the same time, the retailers require these dedicated wholesalers and their
suppliers to adopt best-practices distribution and logistics processes. These
practices include electronic interchanges replacing paper transactions. Physi-
cal improvements in how, especially fresh, products are harvested, shipped,
and stored are required, with a continuous cold (refrigerated) chain from the
grower/shipper to the retail store. These changes have improved both effi-
ciency and product quality (Reardon, Timmer, and Berdegué 2004; Reardon
and Timmer 2007).
The third pillar involves establishing longer-term contractual relations with
“preferred suppliers,” usually via the dedicated wholesalers. This practice is an
example of “vertical coordination,” which brings many of the benefits of
vertical integration via acquisition and merger without the costs and manage-
ment problems. A food processor or producer is “listed” as a preferred supplier.
The contract usually contains incentives for the supplier to stay with the
buyer and to make the investments in equipment and processes to meet the
particular requirements of the retailer. If a supplier does not meet the retailer’s
expectation, they can be “delisted,” losing a major customer. Xincheng Foods
acts as the primary produce wholesaler for the two largest food retail chains in
China. Xincheng leased some 1,000 hectares (about 2,500 acres) of prime farm
land, hired farm workers, invested in tractors, drip irrigation, and greenhouses
to supply high-quality produce to the supermarkets and to the export market,
Xincheng also contracted with some 4,500 small farmers for additional pro-
duction (Hu et al. 2004; Reardon and Timmer 2007).
The final element of modernizing the supply chain is the implementation
of private quality and food safety standards by the retailers that its suppliers
must meet. The regulation of food safety and quality has not been a primary
concern for the governments in developing countries. Even if rules and
286
The Global Spread of Modern Food Retailing
regulations are in place, the monitoring and enforcement are usually missing.
The private standards substitute for the absence of government regulation and
also serve several other important purposes. The safety of the food supply
should be a government responsibility, but in its absence large food retailers
need to consider both their liability and public reputation.
Private standards also harmonize the product and delivery attributes
amongst partners in the supply chain, which improves efficiency and reduces
transaction costs. The food retailers can also use their private quality and
safety standards as a means of differentiating themselves from the competi-
tion. Global food retailers can lower costs by applying the same standards
across countries. Carrefour started to apply the same quality certification
to numerous items globally, for example (Reardon and Berdegué 2002).
Finally, though, the food retailers need sufficient market power to impose
their standards and suppliers capable of actually meeting them (Reardon and
Timmer 2007).
The global spread of modern food retailing is bringing more change to the
agricultural sector in many developing countries than decades of government
programs, projects by non-governmental organizations (NGOs), and
international development assistance. The procurement requirements of
modern food retailers offer both opportunities and challenges for agricultural
producers. Becoming a supplier to a supermarket chain can open the door to a
market that is growing in terms of volume, value added, and diversity. Produ-
cers can move from supplying a local market to one that is regional, national,
and even international.
To supply a large domestic food retail chain increasingly requires producers
to meet the same standards of efficiency, quality, reliability, and food safety
necessary to export to international markets. To fulfill these requirements,
though, requires improvements in production techniques and substantial
investments in everything from information technology to modern packing
houses with cooling units. Food retailing is a low-margin business typified in
general by a high level of price competition. These pressures mean retailers are
pushing their suppliers to lower product and transaction costs. Not surpris-
ingly, supermarket procurement becomes increasingly dominated by the most
capable farmers and firms, which are normally the larger operations (Reardon
and Timmer 2007).
Small farmers with limited assets are largely being excluded from the super-
market supply chain because they lack the knowledge or capital to make the
necessary changes and investments. To understand the reasons more fully, we
287
Benjamin Senauer and Thomas Reardon
288
The Global Spread of Modern Food Retailing
289
Benjamin Senauer and Thomas Reardon
290
11
Introduction
Since the mid-1980s, personal computer makers have been steadily changing
from manufacturers to market makers. Leading PC makers once designed and
built their own PCs and sold them through a mix of direct and mostly indirect
distribution channels.1 PCs were built to forecast, and fluctuating demand led
to alternating periods of costly inventory build-up and product shortages.
Given the rapid depreciation and obsolescence of PCs and their components,
and the common practice of price protection given to retailers, this produc-
tion and distribution model was very costly to PC manufacturers.
This model was severely disrupted in the 1990s by the rise of direct sales
specialists Dell and Gateway. By selling directly to the customer and building
only products to order, these companies were able to reduce inventory and
introduce new products without needing months to clear out old inventory in
the channel. Dell’s rapid growth and superior financial performance, in par-
ticular, put enormous pressure on the rest of the industry, eventually driving
some competitors out of the market and forcing others to revamp their
distribution channels and supply chains. While different models were applied
over the years, PC makers moved to selling directly to the customer or to
working closely with retailers to match supply and demand through sophisti-
cated marketing, forecasting and supply-chain management. A key element
has been the use of the Internet as a distribution channel and information
technology more generally to streamline processes within the firm and across
the supply chain.
Jason Dedrick and Kenneth L. Kraemer
The impacts are greatest in the USA, where direct sales increased from less
than a quarter to over one half of the market between 1995 and 2005. The
direct channel is especially important in serving the commercial market,2
where PC makers offer a variety of services together with hardware to support
IT departments in organizations. In the indirect channel, aimed at the con-
sumer market, sales shifted from dealers and specialist stores to larger con-
sumer electronics and office retailers, such as Best Buy and Office Depot, who
work closely with PC makers to shape and efficiently fulfill market demand.
The US pattern contrasts with other markets. Worldwide the indirect
channel accounts for two-thirds of sales, and the dealer/reseller segment is
larger than retail. Retail exhibits many different local patterns as a result of
local consumer preferences, government regulations, and differences in his-
torical evolution. This local complexity makes it difficult for branded PC
makers to become global market makers. Instead, branded PC makers such
as Dell, HP, Acer, Sony, and Toshiba are forced to adjust their distribution
models to fit local markets. Internet sales, in particular, are constrained by
consumer preferences and by the quality of IT and delivery infrastructure
(Kraemer et al. 2006).
In some country markets, domestic competitors maintain extensive dealer
networks (for example, NEC, Toshiba and Fujitsu in Japan, Samsung in Korea,
and Lenovo in China). Elsewhere, local retailers developed their own store
brand PCs, or collaborated with local companies to act as market makers (for
example, Germany, Brazil). In many markets, “white-box”3 PCs make up a large
share of the market. In these markets, small local shops build PCs for individual
customers or small businesses. However, while there is a great deal of variation,
the global trend is also toward more direct sales and toward large electronics
retailers taking market share away from specialist dealers and resellers.
Although PC makers have become market makers, retailing PCs to commer-
cial customers and consumers, the PC industry offers a different and interest-
ing twist on the “market-makers” theme. In other industries, retailers used
their relationship with the final customer to gain leverage over brand-name
manufacturers. They also developed store brands, essentially coordinating the
manufacturing process, even though they did not own any factories them-
selves. In the PC industry, major branded manufacturers became market
makers in their own right, primarily by selling directly to the final customer,
and also in collaboration with major retailers. PC makers perform market-
making activities such as targeting markets, defining products, capturing
customers, organizing efficient supply chains, and integrating hardware, soft-
ware, services, and content to deliver new user experiences. Meanwhile, some
retailers have developed “store” brands, but most have either lacked the ability
to compete directly with brand-name vendors, or decided it is not profitable to
try to do so.
292
Market Making in the Personal Computer Industry
Component Retailer/
CM/ODM PC maker Distributor Customer
suppliers reseller
293
Jason Dedrick and Kenneth L. Kraemer
Component
CM/ODM PC maker Customer
suppliers
customers could easily compare, configure, and buy PCs online from the PC
vendor, or place the order by phone. In the consumer market, while many
customers began to buy direct, many still preferred shopping in a physical
store. However, the retail market for PCs changed. Whereas the indirect
channel dominated with 76 percent of PC shipments in 1995, direct sales
accounted for nearly 55 percent of all PC shipments by 2005 (see Table 11.1).
Many variations of market making are used in the direct and indirect models,
with different companies choosing different mixes of the two. Four such
variations in the US PC market are shown in Table 11.2 and are described here.
294
Market Making in the Personal Computer Industry
295
Jason Dedrick and Kenneth L. Kraemer
When these models are applied to the branded PC firms in the industry, it is
clear that no single firm fits the direct and indirect models perfectly, although
Dell and Gateway were closest to the direct model and HP and Compaq were
closest to the indirect model in 2000. Since then, the companies have chosen
296
Market Making in the Personal Computer Industry
Apple 36 39 53 13 11 43 7 4
Dell 0 0 0 6 100 67 15 27
Gateway 0 67 1 3 99 25 8 5
HP 20 51 80 21 0 24 2 5
Compaqb 34 - 58 — 8 — 2 —
IBM 30 0 57 51 14 36 6 13
a
Note that this column contains values for 2000 rather than 1995. The 1995 values for each vendor add to 100. Internet
sales were 0% in 1995, the year that the Internet was opened for commerce.
b
Compaq was acquired by HP in 2002. Its 2005 data are included in HP’s results.
Source: IDC (2007).
different mixes of the two models, with their distinct patterns apparent when
changes in channel use from 1995 to 2005 are compared (see Table 11.3).
The table shows the following:
All PC makers listed moved to greater use of direct sales, but indirect sales
still dominate for most companies.
Although all PC makers moved to greater Internet sales by 2005, they
comprise only 5 percent for Apple, Gateway, and HP with a greater share
for IBM (13 percent) and Dell (27 percent). Gateway actually went
down in its Internet share between 2000 and 2005.
Dell, which was 100 percent direct in 1995, has remained largely direct,
with 27 percent of sales from the Internet. Dell has begun to use value-
added resellers and system integrators (6 percent), mainly for the SME
market, where its own direct sales force is too expensive and which retail
is not equipped to serve.
Hewlett-Packard, which was 100 percent indirect in 1995, had become
nearly 30 percent direct in 2005, partly by acquiring Compaq, which had
established a direct sales business. The ratio of retail to VAR/SI shifted
from 2:8 to 5:2.
Apple moved the farthest toward engaging in its own market-making
activity. Whereas only 18 percent of shipments were direct in 1995,
47 percent were direct by 2005. This change was largely through its own
retail stores and telesales rather than the Internet.
297
Jason Dedrick and Kenneth L. Kraemer
These individual patterns illustrate that the industry remains dynamic, with
each firm seeking relative advantage through different combinations of direct
and indirect approaches to market making.
298
Market Making in the Personal Computer Industry
Customer markets
Market and product Hardware and software, e.g., Hardware, software, and a
definition HP/Compaq “relationship”, e.g., Dell
Capture customers Vendor provides the box; Vendor offers custom box and
retailers and resellers offer relationship through vendor
“value beyond the box”: touch direct sales force, inbound
& feel, additional software, and outbound call centers
services
Vendor develops brand; retailers Vendor develops brand, makes
do advertising sales calls to capture
customers
Develops customized website,
offers PC services to lock in
customers
Incentives and risk Incentives for channel partners, Vendor and suppliers bear risk;
but vendor takes inventory risk no retail
Collaborative variation involves
shared risk by retailer and
vendor
Demand management Only what is in inventory. Can match demand and supply;
Retailers can push products can shape demand
with advertising and sales
Supplier markets
Product management Vendor designs product, Vendor designs product,
procures key components, procures key components,
manages supply chain does final assembly, manages
logistics and distribution
centers
Outsourcing Development, manufacturing, Development, manufacturing,
assembly, logistics, support
distribution, support
IT-based supply-chain Vendor supply–push; IT critical Customer demand–pull; IT
management for supply-chain management critical for demand signals &
supply chain mgt.
299
Jason Dedrick and Kenneth L. Kraemer
In addition, the PC maker is able to provide umbrella marketing for its retail
partners and to mount joint advertising campaigns to promote sell-through of
all products with the retailers. For example, eMachine’s collaborative model,
which focused on market making with large electronics retailers, was also
adopted by Gateway when it acquired the firm. A similar approach has been
taken by HP for its HP and Compaq brand PCs, which are the biggest sellers by
far in the US retail market. As will be seen below, the collaborative model was
emulated outside the USA by the German PC maker Medion, which collabor-
ated with the very large supermarket chains and mass retailers in Europe.
In contrast to the supply–push approach, the direct model involves a
demand–pull approach to market making (see Table 11.4). For customer mar-
kets, vendors promote customization (build to order), standardization (down-
load of corporate standard software to all PCs), and low cost, especially to
commercial customers (business, government, education) to attract their busi-
ness. Vendors take orders through their own direct sales force, call centers, or
the Internet, giving vendors direct understanding of customer demand and
the ability to detect new market trends early. The direct relationship also
enables the vendor to up-sell customers by offering related products at low
cost (computer plus printer, monitor, training and service), sell components
that are in inventory by offering discounts, and shape demand by offering
newer technologies at the same price as current ones. Vendors develop adver-
tising to build brand image, promote specific products, and drive customers to
their websites and call centers. A substantial direct sales force and “executive
centers” are also used to promote large commercial contracts. For example,
Dell has executive centers located at manufacturing plants whose purpose is to
sell customers on the Dell model and Dell’s execution of it through briefings,
an in-plant tour, and an informal lunch or reception with Dell executives and
staff (Dell interview 2000).
Commercial contracts usually involve thousands and frequently tens of
thousands of PCs to be delivered over several years, which have major im-
plications for supplier markets. Vendors are able to forecast demand better,
plan production, and negotiate prices with suppliers based on known
demand. Because the PCs are built to the customer’s order and delivered direct
as a complete package, there is no inventory in distribution. Inventory in the
supply chain can be reduced through IT, supply-chain management, and
factory systems. And, because the vendor controls final assembly and logistics,
it can better ensure product quality and timely delivery, even when parts of a
complete system (for example, monitors or peripherals) are shipped direct to
the customer from suppliers’ factories.
The result is a brand image of low cost, customization, and advanced
technology, a package that helped propel Dell to be the industry leader for
commercial markets, and, for a while, Gateway to be a leader for direct sales to
300
Market Making in the Personal Computer Industry
301
Jason Dedrick and Kenneth L. Kraemer
The impacts of market making by PC makers and others have been largely
positive for customers while quite mixed for suppliers.
Customers
Consumers are offered a richer variety of purchasing options thanks to the
innovation in market making by the PC industry. They can shop and buy
online, or window shop online and buy in a vendor’s retail store, or choose
from a number of physical retail outlets. The ability of PC makers and retailers
to eliminate excess inventory also means lower prices and fresher products
with the most recent technologies. Consumers also benefit from more product
information and the ability to compare prices online, even if they shop in
person. However, consumers now have fewer choices of retail PC brands, as a
result of mergers (HP–Compaq, Gateway–eMachines, Lenovo–IBM), and the
exit of brands from the US market, such as AST, Packard Bell, and Acer (which
is just returning to the US market with their purchase of Gateway, as well as
their own branded products). HP (including its Compaq brand) controls over
half of the in-store retail PC market, with only Gateway, Sony, and Toshiba as
major competitors in the USA. Yet, given the rapid introduction of new
products and ever lower prices, it is hard to argue that consumers are suffering
from this consolidation.
Commercial customers reap all these consumer advantages and more. With
build-to-order procurement and systems that download corporate approved
software and system images and the ability to migrate to newer technologies
that come along for the platform, large firms can more easily manage PC
resources from procurement to disposition. Furthermore, they achieve greater
standardization of platforms. Small and midsize businesses (SMBs) can acquire
installation and maintenance services through channel partners (VARs and
SIs) or through white-box makers as well as from their vendors.
Suppliers
The PC makers’ market-making activities that led to industry consolidation
also increased their market power over their ODM/CM contractors and the
entire supply chain. It impacted on the industry structure, the way firms must
do business, the roles they perform, and their prices and profits.
302
Market Making in the Personal Computer Industry
INDUSTRY STRUCTURE
The branded PC makers reduced the number of suppliers they do business
with, resulting in a two-tier supplier structure of very large and midsize-to-
small firms. Although they use fewer contractors and engage in long-term
relationships with them, the PC makers still shift contracts for specific pro-
ducts amongst suppliers based on cost, quality, or unique capabilities (Dedrick
and Kraemer 2006).
DOING BUSINESS
PC makers have adopted just-in-time supply hubs and vendor-owned inven-
tory to reduce inventory costs. Contract manufacturers are pushed to provide
direct shipment services. In some cases, the PC maker never takes physical
possession of the product, which is built by outside suppliers and shipped
directly to the end customer or retailer. The exception is build-to-order assem-
bly, which Dell and others keep inside their own factories (Kraemer, Dedrick,
and Yamashiro 2000). However, IBM–Lenovo outsourced build-to-order pro-
duction in the USA and Europe, and Apple did the same in the USA, so there
appears to be no real barrier to complete outsourcing of manufacturing.
SUPPLIER ROLES
As PC makers have shifted their focus from manufacturing to retailing/market
making, their suppliers have taken on new roles. ODMs, mostly Taiwanese
companies who design and manufacture PCs for all of the major PC vendors,
now:
do new product development, especially for notebook PCs;
provide warranty and repair services in some cases.
303
Jason Dedrick and Kenneth L. Kraemer
Outside the USA, the market-making picture is quite different. The direct sales
model for PCs has been successful only in some markets. For example, Dell’s
market share is 35 percent in the USA, but only 18 percent worldwide (IDC
2006). Comparison of the US and worldwide trends shows that there is
growing use of the direct model generally, but that the indirect model still
dominates outside the USA (Table 11.5).6 Moreover, the rest of the world tends
304
Market Making in the Personal Computer Industry
Lenovo — 1 — 56 — 37 — 6
Acer 31 3 67 96 3 0 10 0
Fujitsu — 10 — 64 — 23 5 3
Sony — 49 — 33 — 5 10 13
Toshiba 56 — 44 - 0 — 2 —
305
Jason Dedrick and Kenneth L. Kraemer
the market. They buy assembled notebooks from the ODMs, assemble desk-
tops themselves, and install PCs for consumers and small businesses.
These differences suggest multiple models in different places rather than an
emerging global model for PC or consumer electronics retailing. Market
making for PCs is almost always local and must be done through local distri-
bution networks. The need for localization is also a reason why many vendors
or their contract manufacturers must keep some local final assembly capabil-
ities, and/or very sophisticated supply-chain and logistics systems. Because
other markets are much less PC-centric than the USA and more focused on
wireless technologies and games (for example, Japan, Korea, China), the
power of mobile service providers and interactive game services is greater.
In their case, the focus is on the service rather than the sale of the hardware
per se.
Under these circumstances, the branded PC and consumer electronics ma-
kers or retailers in the USA face significant hurdles if they are to become truly
global market makers. Moreover, it is in the interest of the core technology
standard setters such as Intel to limit the market power of any would-be global
market maker. Standards issues become even thornier on a global level. Gov-
ernments and local actors become involved, and often different standards
prevail in different countries. While the Wintel standard became a de facto
global standard, there are, and will be, multiple standards for 3G cell phones,
DVDs, wireless networking, and many other technologies. As we move into
the next phase of the PC and consumer electronics industries, we may see
more fragmentation of market making rather than more standardization, with
the fragmentation aided by governments and technology alliances amongst
competing groups of companies.
306
Market Making in the Personal Computer Industry
Convergence
Partly because of the systems integration hurdle and also because of competing
visions, the PC-centric orientation of the PC industry is being challenged by
network-centric and PC-independent visions. The network-centric idea is that
user applications and content will be stored on the Internet and accessible from
anywhere with a variety of devices such as an MP3 player, PDA, phone, or PC—
but the PC will no longer be central. The PC-independent vision is that the
functionality of a PC will be built into some consumer electronic devices such
as TVs, set-top boxes, and DVRs (for example, Tivo) and consumers will no
longer require a media center PC. It is unclear which of these visions (or some
other) will hold sway in the future, but it is likely that the PC will play a
significant role in convergence.
Apple’s music service illustrates such convergence. What is being sold is an
entertainment ecosystem rather than just an MP3 product. Apple integrated
an independent device (the iPod) with the PC (Mac or Wintel). The iTunes
software provides the capability to download songs stored on the network
(the Internet-based iTMS), to manage a music library, to play songs, and to
transfer them to the iPod. Apple needed to keep tight control over the hard-
ware, software, and electronic commerce components in order to make a
market for digital music. HP tried to do the same with digital photos, but it
had to be more open in allowing interconnection with competing camera, PC,
and printer brands. Apple is trying to extend the iPod success with the
iPhone, which adds communication capabilities and phone carriers to the
ecosystem.
307
Jason Dedrick and Kenneth L. Kraemer
Standards
At the technology end, the big issue is standards. Here the problem is that
companies need to establish standards for products to work together, but
some hope to capture monopoly profits by having their own standards
adopted. Also, no one wants to cede power and profits to a future Microsoft
or Intel. The result is often years of delay in introducing technologies, or a
profusion of standards that do not work together in the home. In the PC
industry, Microsoft and Intel set the standards, and everyone else (except
Apple) went along. In the digital home era, everyone from Microsoft and
Intel to Sony, Toshiba, Nokia, Cisco, and even Yahoo! and Google are all
trying to set standards. PC makers who do not create technologies are left in
the position of lining up on one standard or another, or supporting multiple
standards, and hoping to be right. Retailers are in the same position, as no
retailer has the market power to determine standards by its own choice of
what to carry.
308
Market Making in the Personal Computer Industry
APPENDIX
309
Jason Dedrick and Kenneth L. Kraemer
310
Notes
Introduction
1. The latest information about the global spread of shopping centers can be found at the
website of the International Council of Shopping Centers: www.icsc.org/index.php.
2. The monumental works by the late Alfred D. Chandler, Jr (1962, 1977, 1990) bear
vivid testimony to the accuracy of this statement that large manufacturers were
driving the US and European economies.
3. Recently Nelson Lichtenstein also titled his book on Wal-Mart The Retail Revolution:
How Wal-Mart Created a Brave New World of Business (2009). Though the book is
certainly one of the best studies on Wal-Mart, it is also narrowly focused on a single
firm, and so misses most of what we describe here as the main characteristics of the
retail revolution.
4. Since we have not dedicated a distinct chapter to the issues of consumption, we
address it here in rather more detail than the first four trends, which are each dealt
with extensively in various chapters of this volume. A major part of this section is
drawn from Hamilton and Fels (2010).
5. Sears and Kmart merged in 2004 into Sears Holding Corporation. Federated and
May Department Stores merged in 2005.
6. For a good review of these arguments, see Ailawadi (2001).
7. Morris Tabaksblat, the CEO of Unilever, describes this fundamental change in
marketing in the following way: “The maker can no longer make the consumer do
what he decides . . . The era of ‘push selling’ is definitely over. We are now well and
truly in the era of ‘pull marketing.’ . . . The question is no longer, ‘What can we sell
the consumer?’ but ‘What learning can we draw from the consumer in terms of his or
her needs and then how can we help satisfy those needs?’” (G. E. Morris 1997).
8. Cortada (2004) emphasizes that “No segment of the American economy has
changed so much because of information technology than [sic] retail, with the
possible exception of the Trucking Industry” (p. 258). Also: “Other factors also
played a part—such as globalization and national economic conditions, to men-
tion two obvious ones—but other than in banking, one would be hard pressed to
find an industry influenced so profoundly by one family of technologies” (p. 272).
9. The US figure is an estimate, because the official figures for the retail industry do not
include non-employer firms. The number of non-employer firms engaged in retail-
ing is reported separately, but the number of persons working in such firms is only
an estimate. At the same time, this number certainly does not represent more than
Notes
15% of all retailing employment in the USA, while it is as high as 45% in Spain and
over 60% in Italy.
10. This analysis suggests that occupational categories should no longer be thought of
in national terms, but rather as global divisions of labor. If we use commodity-
chain or value-chain analysis, we should see that product creation, manufacture,
distribution, and sale are truly global in character. For instance, Harvey Molotch’s
book Where Stuff Comes From (2003) allows us see how product design has become a
highly professionalized occupation that is quite distinct from other occupations
relating to manufacturing, marketing, and sales—all of which in one form or
another can be outsourced.
Chapter 1
1. The main reason that the productionist bias is less recognized is that it squares
better with the common-sense view of the economy. The equilibrium bias is often
criticized as being too “artificial,” an accusation that has little theoretical merit, but
is easy to accept intuitively. The productionist perspective, on the other hand,
seems a natural way to define the economy as being about satisfying human
“material” needs or increasing wealth. When criticized at all, this is typically
done from the “consumerist” perspective, which misses yet again the crucial
importance of market making for the organization of the economy.
2. Theories that suffer from equilibrium bias typically see the firm as a “production
function.” This creates theoretical problems (see, e.g., Mirowski 1989) for the
discussion of how the marginalist theorists of the first half of the twentieth century
struggled with the notion of production. But, in principle, production becomes a
problem only insofar as it is externally determined.
3. Indeed, a typical reaction of so many theories suffering from the productionist bias
is to see “distribution” as a realm that can be organized, just like production, on the
engineering principles of efficiency.
4. We will spend more time discussing the productionist than the equilibrium bias,
because we see this volume as primarily countering the productionist viewpoint.
Throughout the volume, we attempt to establish the importance of market making
by retailers—i.e., by the type of economic actor that, not being involved in pro-
duction in any major sense, was also the most ignored and misunderstood by
productionist theories. These theories have been developed mostly in fields of
“applied economics,” from industrial organization and development (industriali-
zation) policy, to organization studies and business history. If we are successful in
completing this task, we believe that we will have set a firm foundation from which
to counter the equilibrium bias of mainstream economics. This later task would
include putting market-making activities and their institutional outcomes squarely
in the center of economic theory, and is clearly beyond the scope of our current
discussion.
5. Throughout this chapter we use generic terms buying and selling to denote market
activities in general, instead of more specific terms such as retailing and marketing.
312
Notes
313
Notes
13. The misunderstanding of the retailer’s role, or even of the market-making activity
in general, is pervasive in the productionist literature. At best, retailers are seen as
efficient distributors of goods and services, but their expenses on advertising, their
pricing and promotional strategies, and other market-making activities are seen as
unnecessary and wasteful from the perspective of the society. The identification of
the true price with the manufacturer-suggested price has been the basis of the retail
(resale) price-maintenance policies, ubiquitous in the developed economies of the
mid-twentieth century. Interestingly, one of the main objections in the post-
Depression era was not that retailers inflate prices so much as that they sell below
the recommended price, thus undermining the manufacturer’s goodwill and repu-
tation of its products, and leading to harmful competition.
14. The exceptions to this, as shown in Petrovic (Chapter 3 this volume), were a few
very large retail department stores, mail-order operators, and early chain stores,
such as A&P and Woolworth’s. Most of them, however, grew large by integrating
wholesaling and retailing functions, and sometimes operating as wholesalers for
other retailers, too.
15. These two well-known strategies of consumer markets pricing are distinguished by
the intensity and frequency of price promotions. The “hi–low” strategy offers
frequent and deep price promotions (markdowns, rebates, coupons) over a sub-
stantial part of merchandise assortment, while maintaining high prices on non-
sale items; the everyday low price strategy is the opposite.
16. Store brands (private brands/labels, own brands) refer to goods that are either
directly manufactured or, more commonly, branded by the retailer. Such brands
have been on the rise, in terms of both the proportion of sales and brand recogni-
tion and status, across many categories of products, especially non-durables. A
single mass retailer, such as Wal-Mart, Tesco, or Carrefour, can easily manage
thousands of products under several dozen store brands. Other mass retailers,
such as Ikea, offer only store brand merchandise.
Chapter 2
1. It is bad enough that automobile lights come in a bewildering array of sizes and
bases that make it necessary to shop for new auto lamps with the car’s owners’
manual in hand.
2. Public safety in an elevator remains a cause of concern to many, but such fears have
been dramatically reduced by yearly safety inspections required by local building
codes. The inspection report is normally dated and posted in each elevator, near the
phone for calls to help if the elevator should stall.
3. National BankAmericard, Inc. (NBI) was spun out of the Bank of America in 1970 to
run the BankAmericard Program. This provided issuing banks with a share of
ownership of the network.
4. See Cardweb.com, Inc.
5. If a manufacturer refused to provide a different code format desired by a second
retailer, the manufacturer feared that it might be forced to comply by the Federal
314
Notes
Chapter 3
1. Hypermarkets, and hard discounters, which have often been hailed as specifically
European contributions to modern retail formats, are, in fact, not only adaptations
of the US formats, but were, in most cases, a result of direct emulation of the latter
by European entrepreneurs who traveled to the USA after the war (Colla 2003;
Schröter 2004).
2. While nominally many European retailers have a much higher international pres-
ence, this presence is almost always regional. For instance, out of the twenty-five
315
Notes
non-US-based firms on the top forty list, only six have operations in the USA, and
only eight, including the two leading Japanese firms, Seven and I, and Aeon, have
operations in Japan.
3. This means that several other retail globalization issues, such as the retailers’ role in
making “supplier markets,” the organizational structure and evolution of retail
firms, as well as the influence of the retail evolution on overall economic develop-
ment, will have to be ignored or addressed only in passing.
4. Department stores were the core form of organizing the new world of goods of
industrial capitalism, compared not only to smaller specialty stores, but also to
often grand, yet temporary formats such as world fairs and universal expositions
(Greenhalgh 1988; Rydell 1989). For their relation with the broader culture of
collecting, displaying, and organizing objects in the nineteenth century, see Harris
(1990) and Bennett (1995).
5. Parisian Bon Marché, the most famous department store of the nineteenth century,
distributed 1.5 million catalogs for the winter season of 1894, 260,000 of these
abroad (Crossick and Jaumain 1999). A few years later, US mail-order giants Sears
and Montgomery Ward, which served as “department stores” for rural America,
would distribute between three million and four million catalogs several times a
year, each containing more than a thousand pages (Hoge 1988).
6. At the same time, the smaller size of German department stores and the availability
of financing led to the early development of department store chains, an issue that
US department stores faced only in the 1930s (Coles 1999).
7. As Nystrom (1930) points out, there were a number of wholesale–retail
partnerships in the mid-nineteenth century that could be qualified as chain-store
organizations. A. T. Stewart had a controlling interest in several stores outside New
York, and in the early 1860s opened fully owned branches in Boston, Philadelphia,
and Chicago. A&P, however, was probably the first retailer to open several stores of
similar design and manage them in a centralized manner.
8. Other notable chains that started before 1910 included Kroger (1882) and National
Tea Company (1899) grocery stores, Kress (1896), Kresge (1897), and W. T. Grant’s
(1906) variety stores, United Cigar Stores (1900), and J. C. Penney stores (1902).
9. Those numbers, impressive as they are, do not fully capture the extent of the chain
revolution, since many firms that legally figured as independents in the 1929
Census, were in fact linked to chain-type organizations through franchising and
other agreements. The number should perhaps be increased by at least 20,000–
30,000 franchised car dealerships and by up to 40,000 franchised gasoline stations,
which do not count as chain stores according to the Census definition. At the same
time, the Census number obviously includes a large proportion of very small chains
that consisted of only two or three stores, and thus does not give us a very good
indicator of the extent of market integration through replication.
10. See, for instance, the survey reported by Beckman and Nolan (1938), in which
“sanitary and clean” and “good store appearance” were not only low on the list of
reasons for buying from chain stores, but were also cited with the same frequency
as the reasons to buy from independents.
316
Notes
11. In 1920, there were two car makers and two oil companies among the biggest ten
US companies, and in 1930 the number of oil companies on the list increased to
four (Collins and Preston 1961). Today, the same two car makers, Ford and General
Motors, are still on the list, and the number of oil companies decreased to three, but
only because another two major gas station operators, BP and Royal Dutch/Shell,
are not domestic companies. Out of the current top twenty largest global compa-
nies (by revenues), eleven are either car makers or oil refiners, and an additional
two, Wal-Mart and Carrefour, are chain-store operators.
12. Early DuPont company studies of supermarket shopping, conducted between 1945
and 1959, attracted a lot of attention by showing that up to two-thirds of actual
purchases are unplanned, and that this percentage increased over time (Clover
1950; Shaffer 1960). Of course, the more the supermarket’s merchandise assort-
ment got standardized, the more customers could shop without a specific purchase
plan in mind. Trying to account for this fact, Stern (1962) distinguished between
four different types of impulse buying, from “reminder buying” to “pure impulse
buying.”
13. There were more than 3,000 such stores in 1929, exhibiting a standardized and
patented layout of a single U-shaped path through the store, which exposed
customers to the entire merchandise assortment arranged on wall shelves and in
cases. However, Piggly Wiggly stores were small and stocked with a very basic line
of grocery merchandise; hence they could not benefit from the effect of self-service
either on consumers’ shopping behavior or on operating costs.
14. The only exception to this could be the development of e-retailing in the late
1990s. However important this new format might become in the future, the
focus on the globalization of established American retail formats in this chapter
means that online retailing will be mentioned only in passing. For a more detailed
discussion within this volume, see Chapter 5 by Kotha and Basu. The rest of this
section builds on Petrovic and Hamilton (2006).
15. This famous phrase appears in George Marshall’s speech at Harvard, on June 5,
1947, which signaled the beginning of the ERP (see, e.g., http://en.wikipedia.org/
wiki/Marshall_Plan).
16. Early operators of European hypermarkets, as well as of somewhat similar Japanese
“general superstores,” consciously emulated operations of American supermarkets.
17. The same period witnessed a rapid international expansion of US automotive
services, hotel/motel chains, car rentals, and other similar franchises that are not
being covered in this survey. Individual companies’ data in this section are derived
from companies’ annual reports and websites, unless indicated otherwise.
18. Several lists of the largest shopping centers are available, including the ones
provided by Emil Pocock (2009) at Eastern Connecticut University, by Tom Van
Riper (2007) for Forbes.com, and on Wikipedia. The claim here is based on Pocock’s
list; according to other lists, the number of Asian malls in the top ten would be seven
or nine. The tenant composition was assessed from the shopping centers’ websites.
317
Notes
Chapter 4
1. A report of the European Productivity Agency wrote in 1954: “When Europe is
taken as a whole the tendency for self-service seems to be more an experiment than
a development” (cited by Schröter 2005: 79).
2. Generally land-use policies in the UK are much more restrictive than in most other
European countries, but this was typically not directed toward the discrimination
of certain retail formats.
3. Thus hypermarkets are very similar to the supercenters of Wal-Mart in the United
States (see below).
4. Looming in the background at that time were the successes of the extreme right-
wing party the NPD at several state-level elections in 1966–7.
5. General exemptions existed for certain assortments, especially for furniture and
DIY (do-it-yourself) products such as household repair suppliers.
6. Fears among the political establishment of petit bourgeoisie radicalism among
dissatisfied small retailers might have been a reason for the introduction of social
protectionist regulation in France, as a contemporary UK report (Hall 1971: 53)
points out, referring explicitly to the Poujadist movement in France.
7. Retail price maintenance had already been abolished in 1945, subject to the possi-
bility of ministerial exceptions. These exceptions were also abolished in 1973.
8. These analyses are to a large extent based on materials published by the
companies in print or on the Internet. In addition, various press reports
have been used.
9. On the history of Carrefour, see Lhermie (2003); see also Burt (1986), Dupuis, Choi,
and Larke (2006), and Durand and Wrigley (2009).
10. The hypermarket has nearly the size of Wal-Mart’s biggest supercenter at Cross-
gates Commons in Albany, which opened in May 2008. Its 259,650 square feet
(24,100 square meters) are spread over two floors, while most European hypermar-
kets are completely at ground level.
11. Cora later became part of the Belgian Group Louis Delhaize.
12. Delhaize le Lion is not to be confused with its Belgian competitor Louis Delhaize.
13. Some of these stores were later converted to Gateway Superstores, which were later
taken over by Asda, and thus are part of Wal-Mart today.
14. President Group was already in a partnership with Southland Inc. to manage over
800 7-Eleven stores in Taiwan.
15. The handover of another four hypermarkets in Slovakia to Tesco was barred by
local authorities for monopoly reasons.
16. Because of a huge acquisition by Wal-Mart, it has now lost this position in China.
17. On the history of Aldi, see Brandes (2004); see also Wortmann (2004).
18. This description of the origins of the Aldi discount strategy is based on one of the
very few public statements of Karl Albrecht in 1953, cited in Brandes (2004: 20–2).
19. Netto also acquired Carrefour’s unsuccessful Danish Ed stores in 1995.
20. The concept is described on the US home page of Aldi (www.aldifoods.com), even
though some of the features described here as typical for the Aldi discount concept
can be found in all German—and many European—supermarkets: here customers
318
Notes
have to pay for shopping bags, there is no assistant to bag groceries, and there is
a coin system for shopping carts, which have to be returned to the store by
customers.
21. Aldi stores and supermarkets had frequently existed in a kind of symbiosis: con-
sumers would combine the extremely low prices for basic foods at an Aldi store
with the variety found in a nearby supermarket. Aldi and Edeka had several times
engaged in joint property development.
22. Because two other department-store chains also merged the same year, when
Karstadt acquired Hertie, the whole German department-store sector became con-
solidated into two groups.
23. A brief overview of the national varieties of different retail formats can be found in
Zentes, Morschett, and Schramm-Klein (2007: 13–18).
24. www.metro.com.cn/kitchen_1.htm (accessed May 5, 2008).
25. Including Greece and Turkey.
26. On the history of Tesco, see especially Dawson, Larke, and Choi (2006).
27. In 2005, Tesco started operations of a store format (Homeplus) that sells only non-
food products, mostly the same items available at Extra hypermarkets.
28. Metro’s partner SHV also held a small share in these operations.
29. The large stores of the Spar group were taken over by Wal-Mart.
30. The store count underestimates the size of supermarket operations in the United
States, since these stores are usually much larger—similar to British superstores—
than those in other countries.
31. See n. 12 above.
32. The dimensions of retailers’ embeddedness are further explored by Wrigley, Coe,
and Currah (2005) and Tacconelli and Wrigley (2009).
33. On the rationalization of local grocery supply chains and their impact on local
suppliers, see Senauer and Reardon, Chapter 10 this volume.
34. www.telegraph.co.uk (accessed Nov. 13, 2009).
35. Discount companies like Aldi do all their global sourcing of private-label non-food
items via specialized import companies. Since discounters offer most non-food
items only once or twice a year, they do not build up the know-how and organiza-
tional structures needed for direct sourcing.
36. At the same time, there is no cross-penetration between the three large European
countries of modern retailing, the UK, France, and Germany—despite several
attempts starting in the late 1960s and continuing to the mid-1990s. In these
countries it has been impossible for foreign hypermarket chains to gain the size
needed to achieve competitive buying power. Foreign hypermarket entries by the
United States failed, too. Thus the success of Wal-Mart in the UK, where it bought
Asda, one of the leading grocery retailers (with sufficient buying power of its own),
has remained an exception, while its failure in Germany rather proves the rule.
37. It is difficult to make a general statement about cash and carry, another format not
restricted by German retail regulations. The fact that Metro is concentrated in
Europe is at least partially due to the fact that it was SHV, its former ally, that
expanded into the emerging markets of Latin America and Asia.
319
Notes
Chapter 5
1. A survey commissioned by the American Booksellers’ Association found that some
106 million adults purchased about 456.9 million books in any given quarter. The
survey, which looked at book-buying habits of consumers during the calendar year
1994, revealed that six in ten American adults (60%) say they purchased at least one
book in the last three months. Annually that corresponds to 1.8 billion books sold,
an average of 17 books per book-buying consumer a year. The average amount paid
for the three most recent books purchased by consumers in the previous thirty days
was about $15.
2. With the growing popularity of Amazon.com, the issue is not whether companies
in the traditional value chain will be dis-intermediated, but more about how
incumbents such as Barnes & Noble and others could effectively leverage their
physical assets and compete against Amazon.com.
3. These included computer hardware and software, consumer electronics, antiques
and collectibles, books and comics, automotive, and miscellaneous (Cohen 2002).
4. According to eBay: “A merchant can open a PayPal account and begin accepting
credit card payment within a few minutes. Merchants are approved instantly for a
PayPal account, and do not need to provide a personal guaranty, acquire any
specialized hardware, prepare an application, contact a payment gateway or encrypt
customer data. Furthermore, PayPal charges lower transaction fees than most mer-
chant accounts, and charges no setup fees and no recurring monthly fees” (eBay
2006: 5).
5. Although “off-eBay” penetration of PayPal represented only about 2% of retail
ecommerce opportunity worldwide in 2005, the company was making concerted
efforts in getting online retailers to accept payment through PayPal. For example,
eBay signed up Apple’s iTunes store (the largest legal music retail website in the
world) to accept PayPal.
6. The benefit of using a store format is that it enables sellers to list their items for sale
at lower insertion and final value fees than regular auction and fixed-price listing.
7. It should be noted that direct retailers with physical stores (e.g., L. L. Bean, Eddie
Bauer) captured 52% of the Internet sales as early as 2003, and those without stores
(e.g., Amazon) garnered 31%. This should not be a surprise, because the Internet
represents an evolutionary technology (as opposed to a disruptive one) that helps
direct retailers further to improve their efficiencies in reaching and interacting with
customers, rather than just through mailing them catalogs.
Chapter 6
1. For an exception, see Spulber (1996, 1998).
2. For a related discussion of this literature, as well as an analysis of the rise of
capitalism in East Asia, see Hamilton (2006).
3. For a more complete discussion of the transformation of US retailing after the
Second World War, see Feenstra and Hamilton (2006) and Hamilton, Petrovic,
and Feenstra (2006).
320
Notes
4. During the decades after the American occupation of Japan had ended, Japanese
business groups grew at a pace much faster than Japan’s rapidly growing economy.
In addition to selling finished products, the general trading companies for the main
business groups imported intermediate goods needed by firms within the group.
However, in the 1960s, as the main keiretsu firms grew more proficient in securing
their own inputs and marketing their own products, many in Japan began to worry
that the trading companies would lose their central role. This decline in local
business “led to a belief that the trading companies would gradually become less
and less useful and would eventually die out, a belief popularized in the so-called
‘demise theory’” (Kojima and Ozawa 1984: 13). This belief prompted most trading
companies to internationalize their operations.
5. Constance Lever-Tracy (2000) argues that Japanese trading companies had only a
limited role in the development of East Asian economies outside Japan. However,
her argument misses the important contribution that the Japanese trading compa-
nies made to create competent suppliers in Taiwan and South Korea.
6. The Kuomintang government, however, did not help in this matter. The govern-
ment banned the speaking of Japanese in public, a law that was in force after 1947.
The mainland migrants to Taiwan, of course, viewed the Japanese with dislike and
distrust. After all, they had fought a war against the Japan. Taiwanese residents,
however, did not experience the Second World War in the same way. Although
they were not without hard feelings toward the former colonizers, local Taiwanese
could deal with the Japanese without animosity.
7. Among the top ten exports were two types of TVs, one type of radio, one type of
integrated circuit for an unspecified final product, one type of Christmas tree lights
and one type of mahogany plywood, as well as three types of clothing (acrylic
sweaters, knit shirts, and trousers made from synthetic material) and one category
of footwear (vinyl shoes), all for women and girls. The consumer electronic pro-
ducts were likely made in factories wholly or partially owned by Americans or
Japanese, but the other products likely came from factories owned by Taiwanese.
8. It was not until 1990, however, that most multinational manufacturers withdrew
from Taiwan (Chu and Amsden 2003: 37).
9. This number is, of course, sizable in its own right, especially as compared to Korea
in the same period (Feenstra and Hamilton 2006: 268–72).
10. It is almost certain that the Tsai brothers owned other shoe companies in the
region. At the time, the general pattern was to own multiple companies and
thereby to be a part of multiple networks, instead of creating one big firm to
integrate the operations vertically.
11. Nike’s agreement with Pou Chen came after Nike had made a near disastrous
attempt to contract production from Chinese firms in China. In the 1980s, Nike
located a manufacturer in China to make a large portion of their shoes, but the effort
failed because of poor-quality manufacturing and the lack of supporting suppliers.
Then Nike returned its operation to Taiwan, and started to work with Pou Chen.
12. This chapter is drawn from a book on which we are currently working, entitled
Making Money: How the Asian Economy Works from an Asian Point of View. We would
like to thank the Rockefeller Foundation for supporting a portion of the research
reported here. Also, an early version of this chapter appeared in Y. W. Chu (2010).
321
Notes
Chapter 7
1. For a full analysis of the changing nature of logistics, see Bonacich and Wilson
(2008). This chapter draws on that analysis.
2. As explained in Chapter 9, Li & Fung is a Hong Kong-based trading company that
arranges apparel manufacturing with a large number of retailers and brand-name
merchandisers, including Wal-Mart, and with hundreds of apparel manufacturers.
The Wall Street Journal reported on January 29, 2010 that Wal-Mart had signed a
sourcing deal with the giant merchandise provider Li & Fung with the expectation
that it would buy $2 billion worth of goods through Li & Fung in the first year of
the deal.
3. Even though retailers order and arrange for transportation of goods, the retailer
may not assume actual ownership of these goods until the final sell occurs. A
number of suppliers in Taiwan explained to Hamilton that Wal-Mart required
them to pay for storage of their goods until the actual sale took place, at which
time Wal-Mart owned the product—i.e., at the moment of sale.
4. Ocean shipping also includes bulk shipping—not just containers. This includes
things like lumber and big machinery, as well as automobiles, some of which are
now containerized.
5. For statistics relating to US and China trade, see www.uschina.org/statistics/
tradetable.html.
6. This was a phone conversation on July 1, 2004.
7. All Chinese citizens are classified, according to a household registration system,
called the hukou system, as “rural” or “urban” permanent residents and are assigned
rights and privileges accordingly. Rural migrants moving to a urban location are
necessarily temporary migrants and cannot receive the “minimum protection”
(dibao) in the form of social services that is available to people classified as urban
residents (Chan 2009).
8. www.pbs.org.
9. http://moneycentral.msn.com/content/P82353.asp.
10. “Wal-Mart Suppliers Face Abuse Accusations,” Los Angeles Times, Dec. 9, 2006,
p. C4.
Chapter 8
1. A Wall Street Journal article focusing on Oracle, GM, Pepsi, and other US big firms
suggests that the pendulum may now be swinging back to vertical integration
(Worthen, Tuna, and Scheck 2009).
2. Countries with Flextronics industrial parks are Poland, Hungary (2), Mexico (2),
Brazil, India, and China (2). See www.flextronics.com/about/pages/industrialparks.
aspx.
3. At Celestica, for example, 40% of global capacity expansion was “organic” in
nature.
322
Notes
4. According to the company’s website, in 2008 Lear’s net sales were $13.6 billion,
employment was 71,000, the number of facilities was 210, and the number of
countries was 36 (www.lear.com/jsp/common.jsp?page=al_co_companyoverview,
accessed Jan. 15, 2010).
5. See www.lifung.com/eng/global/home.php (accessed Dec. 2, 2009).
6. See www.lifung.com/eng/business/responsible.php for more information (accessed
Dec. 12, 2009).
7. The opportunity for electronic component distribution in Singapore and Malaysia
stemmed from the lack of an adequate conduit to connect local chip assembly and
test operations with the growing subassembly and product-level manufacturing
that foreign firms were doing in the region. Offshore affiliates of both semiconduc-
tor and product-level firms had increased their Asian operations, and Uraco’s new
distribution arm helped to connect the dots.
8. www.mfgmkt.com (accessed Aug. 12, 2009).
9. In addition to computer-aided design (CAD) tools, capital equipment in these
facilities included 86 electronic circuit board assembly lines using surface-mount
technology (SMT), 250 plastic molding machines, 85 metal die-casting machines,
1,000 computer numerically controlled (CNC) drill and tap machines, and 30
multi-spindle high-speed coil winding machines.
10. This section is adapted from Sturgeon and Lee (2005).
Chapter 9
1. See also Malone (2002); Speer (2002); Just-style.com (2003); Kearney (2003);
McGrath (2003); Nordås (2004).
2. www.nht.com.tw/en/about-2.htm.
3. The following information comes from Esquel’s website, www.esquel.com/en/
index.html.
4. Esquel’s client list includes Banana Republic, Brooks Brothers, Hugo Boss, J. Crew,
J. C. Penney, Marks and Spencer, Nike, Nordstom, Polo Ralph Lauren, and some
fifteen other leading brands (www.esquel.com/en/index6.html).
5. Esquel’s Gaoming factory complex (Guangdong Province) does the weaving, dye-
ing, and assembly. The firm’s recently opened weaving mill occupies 29 acres, and
is described as “China’s most advanced woven fabric manufacturing facility,” an
environmentally friendly facility featuring “the textile industry’s most advanced
machinery and advanced computer control systems to reduce operational errors,
ensure quality and shorten production time” (www.esquel.com/en/index7.html).
6. See www.vendormanagedinventory.com.
7. The following information comes from TAL’s website, www.talgroup.com/eng/
home.html.
8. The company was originally called South China, then—through a collaboration
with Jardine Matheson—became the textile Alliance Group (TAL).
9. In addition to garments and footwear, Li & Fung export management includes
furnishings, toys, stationery, home products, sporting goods, and travel goods.
323
Notes
10. Yue Yuen, the world’s leading manufacturer of footwear, became a “strategic
shareholder” in Luen Thai when it acquired a 9.9% stake in 2004; this firm is
discussed below.
11. A second supply-chain city is being developed in Qing Yuan, also in Guangdong
Province; in addition, Luen Thai maintains supply-chain centers in the USA and
the Philippines (Luen Thai 2006).
12. Luen Thai’s principal customers also include Polo Ralph Lauren, Limited Brands,
Adidas, Dillard’s, Nike, and Fast Retailing (Luen Thai 2006).
13. Yue Yuen Industrial Holdings is the principal source of Pou Chen’s shoe
production; as of June 2004, Pou Chen held 50.1% of the stock in Yue Yuen
(www.yueyuen.com).
14. Yue Yuen’s fiscal year ends on September 30.
15. China, Indonesia, and Vietnam together account for 90% of all athletic footwear
production (Merk 2006).
16. I visited the Nike/Yue Yuen factory in Dongguan in September 2005, as a guest of
Nike. The immaculate and ultra-modern activities center, newly opened, showed
no signs of having yet been used; even the polished glass tables had no smudges or
fingerprints.
17. Other clients include Polo Ralph Lauren, Kenneth Cole, Calvin Klein, and NBA
Properties. Yue Yuen is the exclusive China licensee for Converse, Wolverine, and
Hush Puppies (Xinhua 2007). About 60% of Yue Yuen’s footwear production is for
Nike, Reebok, and Adidas-Salomon (Merk 2003).
18. Based on its Interim Report for the first six months of FY 2007 (ending March 31),
the company’s growth trajectory appears to be continuing, despite rising wage
pressures and the continuing cost of the petroleum-based imports that constitute
a major part of the company’s costs. Yue Yuen added 14 additional production
lines, bringing its total to 387; its year-to-year production of shoes increased 15%
(111 million pairs for the six-month period); and wholesale/retail sales grew by
37%, accounting for 8.0% of total revenues (in comparison with 5.4% for FY 2006)
(Yue Yuen 2007c). On the other hand, on July 26, 2007, Credit Suisse initiated
coverage on Yue Yuen with an “underperform” call because of what it regarded as
the company’s “decreasing exposure to the retail business sector,” claiming that
“Yue Yuen is actively considering spinning off its retail business arm in China”
(Xinhua 2007).
19. The cost of the petrochemicals that comprise a significant portion of the raw
materials used in making shoes increased 50–60% (Fong 2005).
20. In 2002, 28% of Yue Yuen’s athletic shoe production was for Nike, yet it supplied
only 15% of Nike’s total demand (Merk 2006: 16).
21. Yue Yuen’s net profit rate in 2002 (11.9%) was higher than Nike’s (6.2%), Reebok’s
(2.9%), or Adidas’s (3.4%) (Merk 2006: 17). The company has continued to post
near double-digit profits (10.02% in 2006) (http://finance.google.com/finance?
q=HKG:0551).
22. According to one frequently cited statistic, “if Wal-Mart were a country, it would be
China’s sixth-largest export market.” Wal-Mart executives talk of doubling their
purchases from Chinese suppliers (C. Chandler 2005).
324
Notes
Chapter 10
1. See, e.g., Farina et al. (2005), for the case of dairy processing and retail in Argentina
and Brazil.
2. The existence of these early supermarket chains serving a tiny niche market in
some developing areas, e.g., in Puerto Rico, was noted as early as 1953 by Holden
(1953) in the Holden–Galbraith study.
Chapter 11
1. Direct channels include telephone and Internet sales made directly by the manu-
facturer. Indirect sales involve sales to distributors and/or retailers.
2. The commercial market refers to enterprise, SMEs, governments, education, and
other organizational segments, whereas the consumer market refers to households
and individuals.
3. “White box” refers to generic PCs that carry the brand of the retailer or distributor
rather than the manufacturer.
4. Although admittedly, many customers in those countries already pay close to zero
for Windows, and for application software, given high piracy rates.
5. Numbers based on field interviews with ODMs and suppliers by the authors.
6. Indirect sales worldwide are over 66% of total sales; excluding the USA would make
the figure much higher.
7. This research is supported by a grant from the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation to the
Personal Computing Industry Center at The Paul Merage School of Business,
University of California, Irvine. We gratefully acknowledge the International
Data Corporation (IDC) for providing data for the study and Paul Gray for com-
ments on the chapter.
325
References
Abaza, M. (2001). “Shopping Malls, Consumer Culture and the Reshaping of Public
Space in Egypt,” Theory, Culture, and Society, 18/5: 97–122.
Abernathy, F. H., Dunlop, J. T., Hammond, J. H., and Weil, D. (1999). A Stitch in Time:
Lean Retailing and the Transformation of Manufacturing: Lessons from the Apparel and
Textile Industries. New York: Oxford University Press.
Abolafia, M. Y. (1996). Making Markets: Opportunism and Restraint on Wall Street.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Adams, H. (1973 [1918]). The Education of Henry Adams. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Adelman, M. A. (1966). A & P: A Study in Price-Cost Behavior and Public Policy. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press.
Ailawadi, K. (2001). “The Retail Power-Performance Conundrum: What Have We
Learned?” Journal of Retailing, 77/3: 299–318.
Akinwande, A., Fuller, D., and Sodini, C. (2005). “Leading, Following or Cooked Goose:
Explaining Innovation Successes and Failures in Taiwan’s Electronics Industry,” in
S. Berger and R. Lester (eds), Global Taiwan: Building Competitive Strengths in a New
International Economy. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe.
Alexander, A., Shaw, G., and Curth, L. (2005). “Promoting Retail Innovation: Knowledge
Flows during the Emergence of Self-Service and Supermarket Retailing in Britain,”
Environment and Planning, 37/5: 805–21.
Amazon.com (1998). Annual Report. http://phx.corporate-ir.net/phoenix.zhtml?
c=97664&p=irol-reportsannual.
Armstrong, A., and Hagel, J. (1996). “The Real Value of On-line Communities,” Harvard
Business Review (May–June), 134–41.
Asian Food Marketing Association (2004). “Workshop Proposal: The Rise of Supermar-
kets—Improving Performance and Competitiveness in Agro-Food Systems,” mimeo.
Bair, J. (2009) (ed.). Frontiers of Commodity Chain Research. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford
University Press.
Baldwin, C. Y., and Clark, K. B. (2000). Design Rules: The Power of Modularity. Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
Balsevich, F. (2005). “Essays on Producers’ Participation, Access and Response to the
Changing Nature of Dynamic Markets in Nicaragua and Costa Rica,” unpublished
doctoral dissertation, Michigan State University, East Lansing.
Balsevich, F., Berdegué, J. A., Flores, L., Mainville, D., and Reardon T. (2003). “Super-
markets and Produce Quality and Safety Standards in Latin America,” America Journal
of Agricultural Economics, 85/5: 1147–54.
References
Barboza, D. (2004). “In Roaring China, Sweaters Are West of Socks City,” New York
Times, Dec. 24.
Barger, H. (1955). Distribution’s Place in the American Economy since 1869. Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
Barth, G. (1980). City People: The Rise of Modern City Culture in Nineteenth-Century
America. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Batt, R., Doellgast, V., and Kwon, H. (2006). “Service Management and Employment
Systems in US and Indian Call Centers,” in S. Collins and L. Brainard (eds), Brookings
Trade Forum 2005: Offshoring White-collar Work—The Issues and Implications. Washing-
ton: Brookings Institution.
Beckman, T., and Nolan, H. (1938). The Chain Store Problem. Columbus, OH: McGraw-
Hill.
Bell, D. E., Lai, R., and Salmon, W. J. (2004). “Globalization of Retailing,” in J. Quelch
and R. Deshpande (eds), The Global Market: Developing a Strategy to Manage across
Borders. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 288–312.
Bennett, T. (1995). The Birth of the Museum. London: Routledge.
Berekoven, L. (1986). Geschichte des deutschen Einzelhandels. Frankfurt am Main:
Deutscher Fachverlag.
Berger, S. (2005). How We Compete. New York: Doubleday.
Bianco, A. (1997). “Virtual Bookstores Start to Get Real,” Business Week, Oct. 27,
pp. 146–7.
Bianco, A. (2006). The Bully of Bentonville: How the High Cost of Wal-Mart’s Everyday Low
Prices is Hurting America. New York: Currency/Doubleday.
Birchall, J. (2007). “An Onus on Retailers to Keep Hands Clean,” Financial Times, Jan 15.
Bliss, P. (1960). “Schumpeter, the ‘Big’ Disturbance and Retailing,” Social Forces, 39/1:
72–6.
Blonigen, B. A., and Ma, A. C. (2010). “Please Pass the Catch-up: The Relative
Performance of Chinese and Foreign Firms in Chinese Exports,” in R. C. Feenstra
and S. J. Wei (eds), China’s Growing Role in World Trade. Chicago: Chicago University
Press.
Bluestone, B., Hanna, P., Kuhn, S., and Moore, L. (1981). The Retail Revolution: Market
Transformation, Investment, and Labor in the Modern Department Store. Boston: Auburn
House Publishing Company.
Bonacich, E. (2005). “Labor and the Global Logistics Revolution,” in R. P. Appelbaum
and W. I. Robinson (eds), Critical Globalization Studies. New York: Routledge, 359–68.
Bonacich, E., with Hardie, K. (2006). “Wal-Mart and the Logistics Revolution,” in
Nelson Lichtenstein (ed.), Wal-Mart: The Face of Twenty-First Century Capitalism.
New York: New Press, 163–87.
Bonacich, E., and Luce, S. (2006). “China and the US Labor Movement,” paper presented
at the Annual Meeting of the American Sociological Association in Montreal.
Bonacich, E., and Wilson, J. B. (2005). “Hoisted by its own Petard: Organizing Wal-
Mart’s Logistics Workers,” New Labor Forum, 14/2: 67–75.
Bonacich, E., and Wilson, J. B. (2006). “Global Production and Distribution: Wal-Mart’s
Global Logistics Empire with Special Reference to the China/Southern California
Connection,” in S. Brunn (ed.), Wal-Mart World. New York: Routledge, 227–41.
327
References
Bonacich, E., and Wilson, J. B. (2008). Getting the Goods: Ports, Labor and the Logistics
Revolution. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Bonaglia, F., Goldstein, A., and Mathews, J. (2007). “Accelerated Internationalization
by Emerging Multinationals: The Case of the White Goods Sector,” Journal of World
Business, 42: 369–83.
Bowles, Samuel (1986). “The Production Process in a Competitive Economy: Walrasian,
neo-Hobbesian, and Marxian Models,” in L. Putterman (ed.), The Economic Nature of
the Firm: A Reader. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 329–55.
Bradley, S. P., and Porter, K. A. (2000). “eBay, Inc. Case Study,” Journal of Interactive
Marketing (Autumn), 73–97.
Brandes, D. (2004). Bare Essentials: The Aldi Way to Retail Success. Frankfurt am Main:
Campus.
Brinkley, J. (1992). “On Tape: A President Intrigued by a Scanner,” New York Times,
Feb. 13, sect. A.
Broehl, W. G., Jr (1968). The International Basic Economy Corporation. Washington:
National Planning Association.
Brown, S. A. (1997). Revolution at the Checkout Counter: The Explosion of the Bar Code.
Wertheim Publications in Industrial Relations. Cambridge, MA.: Harvard University
Wertheim Publications Committee, distributed by Harvard University Press.
Bucklin, L. P. (1967). Shopping Patterns in an Urban Area. Berkeley and Los Angeles:
University of California, Institute of Business and Economic Research.
Bucklin, L. P. (1972). Competition and Evolution in the Distributive Trades. Englewood
Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Burt, S. (1984). “Hypermarkets in France: Has the Loi Royer had any Effect?” Interna-
tional Journal of Retail & Distribution Management, 12/1: 16–19.
Burt, S. (1986). “The Carrefour Group: The First 25 Years,” International Journal of
Retailing, 1/3: 54–78.
Burt, S. (1994). “Carrefour: Internationalising Innovation,” in P. J. McGoldrick (ed.),
Cases in Retail Management. London: Pitman, 154–64.
Burt, S., Dawson, J., and Larke, R. (2006). “Royal Ahold,” in J. Dawson, R. Larke, and
M. Mukoyama (eds), Strategic Issues in International Retailing: Concepts and Cases.
London: Routledge, 140–69.
Burt, S., Dawson, J., and Sparks L. (2004). “The International Divestment Activities of
European Grocery Retailers,” European Management Journal, 22/5: 483–92.
Burt, T. (2004). “Global Retailers Expand Markets,” Financial Times, June 22, p. 15.
Business History Review (2008). “Special Issue on Alfred D. Chandler, Jr,” 82/2: 203–319.
Business Times Online (1995). “Precision Engineering Group Uraco Plans Expansion in
Jahor,” July 14, p. 3, www.businesstimes.com.sg.
Business Times Online (1996a). “Uraco Aims to Boost Revenue to US$400m,” Apr. 22,
www.businesstimes.com.sg.
Business Times Online (1996b). “Uraco Tops Actives with 16.7m Shares Traded,” Dec. 12,
www.businesstimes.com.sg.
Business Times Online (1997). “Uraco Managing Director Quits: 3 Executives Replace
Him,” Jan. 23, www.businesstimes.com.sg.
328
References
Calder, L. G. (1999). Financing the American Dream: A Cultural History of Consumer Credit.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Cao, N. (2005). “Different Structures in the Textile Industry’s Supply Chain,” Peking
University Luen Thai Center for Supply Chain System R&D Bulletin, Apr. 30, trans.,
www.pkultc.com/englishindex.asp.
Chamberlin, E. H. (1962 [1933]). The Theory of Monopolistic Competition: A Reorientation
of the Theory of Value. 8th edn. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Chan, A. (2001). China’s Workers under Assault: The Exploitation of Labor in a Globalizing
Economy. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe.
Chan, K. W. (2005). Associate Director, Hong Kong Christian Industrial Committee,
interview, Sept. 15.
Chan, K. W. (2009). “From Made-in-USA to Made-in-China: Global Financial Crisis and
Migrant Workers in China,” unpublished manuscript.
Chan, R. (2005). “Intel in New Push for the Clone Notebook Market,” DigiTimes.com.
Dec. 9.
Chandler, A. D., Jr (1962). Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of the American
Industrial Enterprise. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Chandler, A. D., Jr (1977). The Visible Hand. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Chandler, A. D., Jr (1990). Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Chandler, A. D., Jr, and Daems, H. (1980). Managerial Hierarchies: Comparative Perspec-
tives on the Rise of the Modern Industrial Enterprise. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
Chandler, C. (2005). “The Great Wal-Mart of China,” Fortune Magazine, 151/15, July 25,
www.fortune.com/fortune/print/0,15935,1081806,00.html.
Chang, C. C. (2005). “The Role of Retail Sector in Agro-food System,” Chinese Taipei.
Presentation at the Pacific Economic Cooperation Council’s Pacific Food System
Outlook 2005–6 Annual Meeting in Kun Ming, China, May 11–13.
Chapman, S. (1992). Merchant Enterprise in Britain from the Industrial Revolution to World
War I. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Cheng, L. L., and Sato Y. (1998). “The Bicycle Industries in Taiwan and Japan:
A Preliminary Study toward Comparison between Taiwanese and Japanese Industrial
Development,” Joint Research Program Series, No. 124. Tokyo: Institute of Developing
Economies.
Chessel, M.-E. (1999). “Training Sales Personnel in France between the Wars,” in
S. Jaumain and G. Crossick (eds), Cathedrals of Consumption: The European Department
Store 1850–1939. Aldershot: Ashgate, 279–98.
Chu, W. W., and Amsden, A. (2003). Chao yue hou jin fa zhan: Taiwan de chan ye sheng ji
ce lue. Taipei: Lian Jing.
Chu, Y. W. (2010) (ed.). Chinese Capitalism: Historical Emergence and Political Implica-
tions. London: Palgrave, Macmillan.
Chua, B. H. (2003). Life Is Not Complete without Shopping: Consumption Culture in Singa-
pore. Singapore: Singapore University Press.
Clover, V. T. (1950). “Relative Importance of Impulse-Buying in Retail Stores,” Journal of
Marketing, 15/1: 66–70.
329
References
Clower, R., and Howitt, P. (1996). “Taking Markets Seriously: Groundwork for a Post
Walrasian Macroeconomics,” in David Colander (ed.), Beyond Microfoundations: Post
Walrasian Macroeconomics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
CNBC (2005). The eBay Effect: Inside a World-Wide Obsession, documentary, June 29.
Coase, R. (1937). “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, 4 (Nov.), 386–405.
Coggins, J., and Senauer, B. (1999). “Grocery Industry,” in D. C. Mowery (ed.), US
Industry in 2000: Studies in Competitive Performance. Washington: National Academy
Press, 155–78.
Cohen, A. (2002). “Is this any Place to Run a Business?” Fortune Small Business (Nov.),
55–65.
Coles, T. (1999). “Department Stores as Retail Innovation in Germany: A Historical–
Geographical Perspective on the Period 1870–1914,” in S. Jaumain and G. Crossick
(eds), Cathedrals of Consumption: The European Department Store 1850–1939. Alder-
shot: Ashgate, 72–96.
Colla, E. (2003). “France,” in S. Howe (ed.), Retailing in the European Union: Structures,
Competition and Performance. New York: Routledge, 23–55.
Collins, N., and Preston, L. E. (1961). “The Size Structure of the Largest Industrial Firms,
1909–1958,” American Economic Review, 51/5: 986–1011.
Cortada, J. (2004). The Digital Hand: How Computers Changed the Work of American
Manufacturing, Transportation, and Retail Industries. New York: Oxford University
Press.
Coulter, J., Goodland, A., Tallontire, A., and Stringfellow, R. (1999). “Marrying Farmer
Cooperation and Contract Farming Service Provision in Liberalizing Sub-Saharan
Africa,” Natural Resources Perspectives, No. 48, Overseas Development Institute
(ODI), United Kingdom.
Crossick, G., and Jaumain, S. (1999). “The World of the Department Store: Distribution,
Culture and Social Change,” in S. Jaumain and G. Crossick (eds), Cathedrals of
Consumption: The European Department Store 1850–1939. Aldershot: Ashgate, 1–45.
Cuesta, V. (2004). “Treinta años de hipermercados en España ¿Saturación o renova-
ción?” Distribución y Consumo (Mar.–Apr.), 46–56.
Cunningham, E., Lynch, T., and Thun, E. (2005). “A Tale of Two Sectors: Diverging
Paths in Taiwan’s Automotive Industry,” in S. Berger and R. Lester (eds), Global
Taiwan: Building Competitive Strengths in a New International Economy. Armonk, NY:
M. E. Sharpe.
Davis, H. B. O. (1985). Electrical and Electronic Technologies: A Chronology of Events and
Inventors from 1940 to 1980. Metuchen, NJ: Scarecrow Press.
Davis, R. T. (1959). The Changing Pattern of Europe’s Grocery Trade: A Comparison of Seven
Markets with the United States. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.
Dawson, J. A. (1981). “Innovation Adoption in Food Retailing: The Example of Self-
Service Methods,” Service Industries Review, 1/2: 22–35.
Dawson, J., Larke, R., and Choi S. C. (2006). “Tesco: Transferring Marketing Success
Factors Internationally,” in: J. Dawson, R. Larke, and M. Mukoyama (eds), Strategic
Issues in International Retailing: Concepts and Cases. London: Routledge, 170–95.
de Grazia, V. (2005). Irresistible Empire: America’s Advance through Twentieth-Century
Europe. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
330
References
Dedrick, J., and Kraemer, K. L. (1998). Asia’s Computer Challenge: Threat or Opportunity
for the United States and the World? New York: Oxford University Press.
Dedrick, J., and. Kraemer K. L. (2006). “Is Production Pulling Knowledge Work to
China: A Study of the Notebook PC Industry,” IEEE Computer, 39/7: 36–42.
Dedrick, J., Kraemer K. L., and MacQuarrie, B. (2001). “Gateway Computer: Using
E-Commerce to Move beyond the Box and to Move More Boxes,” working paper,
Personal Computing Industry Center, The Paul Merage School of Business,
Irvine, CA.
Delgado, C. L., Hopkins, J., and Kelly, V. A. (1998). “Agricultural Growth Linkages in
Sub-Saharan Africa,” research report no. 107, Washington: International Food Policy
Research Institute.
Deloitte (2007). 2007 Global Powers of Retailing: The Search for Sustainable Growth. New
York: Deloitte, Touche, and Tohmatsu.
Deloitte (2009). Feeling the Squeeze: Global Powers of Retailing 2009. New York: Deloitte
Development LLC.
Denis, C., McMorrow, K., and Röger, W. (2004). “An Analysis of EU and US Productivity
Developments,” European Economy, Economic Papers, 208 (July).
Dicke, T. S. (1992). Franchising in America: The Development of a Business Method,
1840–1980. Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press.
Dicken, P., and Hassler, M. (2000). “Organizing the Indonesian Clothing Industry in
the Global Economy: The Role of Business Networks,” Environment and Planning A,
32/2: 263–80.
Dirven, M., and Faiguenbaum, S. (2003). “Dynamics of Santiago’s Wholesale Market of
Lo Valledor and its Forward and Backward Linkages,” paper presented at the FAO
technical workshop on “Globalization of the Food System: Impacts on Food Security
and Nutrition,” Oct. 8–10, Rome.
Dolan, C. and Humphrey, J. (2004). “Changing Governance Patterns in the Trade in
Fresh Vegetables between Africa and the United Kingdom,” Environment and Planning
A, 36/3: 491–509.
Dorward, A., Kydd, J., Morrison, J., and Urey, I. (2004). “A Policy Agenda for Pro-Poor
Agriculture Growth,” World Development, 32/1: 73–89.
Dries, L., and Reardon, T. (2005). “Central and Eastern Europe: Impact of Food Retail
Investments on the Food Chain,” London: FAO Investment Center – EBRD Coopera-
tion Program, Report Series No. 6, Feb.
Dries, L., Reardon T., and Swinnen J. (2004). “The Rapid Rise of Supermarkets in Central
and Eastern Europe: Implications for the Agrifood Sector and Rural Development,”
Development Policy Review, 22/9: 525–56.
Dries, L. and Swinnen, J. F. M. (2003). “The Impact of Globalization and Vertical
Integration in Agri-Food Processing On Local Suppliers: Evidence from the Polish
Dairy Sector,” paper presented at the FAO technical workshop on “Globalization of
the Food System: Impacts on Food Security and Nutrition,” Oct. 8–10, Rome.
DSN Retailing Today (2002). “40th Anniversary: Forty People and Events that have
Shaped Mass Market Retailing,” 41/15.
Du Ling (2003). “Taiwanese Investment in South Africa, Swaziland, and Lesotho:
A Case Study by Ambassador Du Ling,” statement by Representative Du Ling, Taipei
331
References
Liaison Office in the Republic of South Africa at the African–Asian Society, Balalaika
Hotel, Sandton, June 12, www.roc-taiwan.org.za/press/20030909/2003090901.html.
Duan, C. P. (1992). Taiwan zhan hou jing ji. Taipei: Ren jian chu ban she.
Dunlop, J. T., and Rivkin, J. W. (1997). “Introduction,” in S. A. Brown, Revolution at the
Checkout Counter. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1–38.
Dunn, W. S. (1962). “French Retailing and the Common Market,” Journal of Marketing,
26/1: 19–22.
Dunning, J. H. (1979). “Explaining Changing Patterns of International Production: In
Defense of the Eclectic Theory,” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 41/4:
269–95.
Dunning, J. H. (2000). “The Eclectic Paradigm as an Envelope for Economic and
Business Theories of MNE Activity,” International Business Review, 9 (Spring), 163–90.
Dupuis, M., Choi, S. C., and Larke, R. (2006). “Carrefour Being Aware of the Domestic
Market,” in J. Dawson, R. Larke, and M. Mukoyama (eds), Strategic Issues in Interna-
tional Retailing, London: Routledge, 91–113.
Durand, C. and Wrigley, N. (2009). “Institutional and Economic Determinants of
Transnational Retailer Expansion and Performance: A Comparative Analysis of
Wal-Mart and Carrefour,” Environment and Planning A, 41: 1534–55.
eBay (2006). Annual Report, http://investor.ebay.com/secfiling.cfm?filingid=950134-
07-4291.
eBay (2007). Quarterly Report, April 25, 2007, http://files.shareholder.com/downloads/
ebay/118201758x0x91268/649ccffe-1298-4bd0-ab53-1b33e9f9abd2/eBayInc-
Q12007EarningsRelease.pdf.
The Economist (1997). “A Survey of Electronic Commerce,” May 10, pp. 1–18.
The Economist (2005). “Meg and the Power of Many,” June 9.
Economist Intelligence Unit (1983). Japanese Overseas Investment. London: Economist
Intelligence Unit.
EHI Retail Institute (2007). Handel aktuell. Ausgabe 2007/08. Struktur, Kennzahlen und
Profile aus dem deutschen und internationalen Handel. Cologne: EHI Retail Institute.
EHI Retail Institute (2008). Retail Fact Book: Structures, Key Figures, and Profiles of the
International Retail Trade Sector. Cologne: EHI Retail Institute.
Emmet, B., and Jeuck, J. (1950). Catalogues and Counters: A History of Sears, Roebuck and
Company. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Euromonitor (2002). Retail Trade International. London: Euromonitor plc.
European Comission (2009). Europe’s Digital Competitiveness Report: Main Achievements of the
2010 strategy, 2005–2009. Brussels, Aug. 4, http://ec.europa.eu/information_society/
eeurope/i2010/docs/annual_report/2009/com_2009_390_en.pdf (accessed Aug. 8,
2009).
Evans, D. S., and Schmalensee, R. (2005). Paying with Plastic: The Digital Revolution in
Buying and Borrowing. 2nd edn. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Evans, P. B., and Wurster, T. S. (1997). “Strategy and the New Economics of Informa-
tion,” Harvard Business Review (Sept.–Oct.), 70–83.
Farina, E. (2002). “Consolidation, Multinationalization and Competition in Brazil:
Impacts on Horticulture and Dairy Products Systems,” Development Policy Review,
20/4: 441–57.
332
References
Farina, E. M. M. Q., Gutman G. E., Lavarello, P. J., Nunes, R., and Reardon T. (2005).
“Private and Public Milk Standards in Argentina and Brazil,” Food Policy, 30/3:
302–15.
Feenstra, R. C. (1998). “Integration of Trade and Disintegration of Production in the
Global Economy,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12/4: 31–50.
Feenstra, R. C., and Hamilton G. G. (2006). Emergent Economies, Divergent Paths:
Economic Organization and International Trade in South Korea and Taiwan. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Feenstra, R. C., and Wei, S. J. (2010) (eds). China’s Growing Role in World Trade. Chicago:
Chicago University Press.
Fields, K. J. (1995). Enterprise and the State in Korea and Taiwan. Ithaca, NY: Cornell
University Press.
Fishman, C. (2006). The Wal-Mart Effect: How the World’s Most Powerful Company Really
Works—and how it’s Transforming the American Economy. New York: Penguin Press.
Flextronics (2003). Corporate Fact Sheet Asia. CD-ROM files. Singapore.
Fong, M. (2005). “Why Yuan Revaluation May Not Be a Cure-All,” Wall Streeet Journal.
Feb. 1, p. A11.
Food Institute (2007). Food Industry Review, 2005 Edition, Elmwood Park, NJ: Food
Institute.
Forrester Research Inc. (2007). “US Retail eCommerce Forecast, 2006 to 2011,” May 4.
Forrester Research Inc. (2010). “Forrester Forecast: Double-Digit Growth for Online Retail
in the US and Western Europe,” Business Wire Mar. 8; ProQuest Newsstand, ProQuest
Web, Sept. 3.
Fukami, G. (1953). “Japanese Department Stores,” Journal of Marketing, 18/1: 41–9.
Gallegos, J. (2003). “CSU: Corporacion Supermercados Unidos: Excelencia sin Bar-
reras,” PowerPoint presentation, Hortifruti, San Jose, Costa Rica.
Gates, B. (1995). The Road Ahead. New York: Penguin.
Geocities (2004). “Beyonics Technology,” company profile, www.geocities.com/fa_book/
Benyonics_181201.html (accessed Jan. 23, 2004).
Gereffi, G. (1994a). “The International Economy and Economic Development,” in
N. Smelser and R. Swedberg (eds), The Handbook of Economic Sociology. Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 206–33.
Gereffi, G. (1994b). “The Organization of Buyer-Driven Global Commodity Chains:
How US Retailers Shape Overseas Production Networks,” in G. Gereffi and M. Korze-
niewicz (eds), Commodity Chains and Global Capitalism. Westport, CT: Praeger,
95–122.
Gereffi, G. (1999). “International Trade and Industrial Upgrading in the Apparel
Commodity Chain,” Journal of International Economics, 48/1: 37–70.
Gereffi, G. (2006). The New Offshoring of Jobs and Global Development. Geneva: Interna-
tional Labour Organization, International Institute for Labour Studies.
Gereffi, G., Humphrey J., and Sturgeon T. (2005). “The Governance of Global Value
Chains,” Review of International Political Economy, 12/1: 78–104.
Gereffi, G., and Memedovic O. (2003). The Global Apparel Value Chain: What Prospects
for Upgrading by Developing Countries. Vienna: United Nations Industrial Development
333
References
334
References
and Production Technology Division (EPTD), Discussion Paper No. 92, International
Food Policy Research Institute, Washington.
Hall, M. (1971). “The Small Unit in the Distributive Trades: Committee of Inquiry on
Small Firms,” Research Report No. 8. London: Her Majesty’s Stationery Office.
Hamilton, Gary G. (2006) (ed.). Commerce and Capitalism in Chinese Societies. London:
Routledge.
Hamilton, G. G., and Fels, D. (2010). “Consumerism and Self-Representation in an Era
of Global Capitalism,” in J. Hall, L. Grindstaff, and M.-C. Lo (eds), Handbook of
Cultural Sociology. London: Routledge.
Hamilton, G. G., and Kao, C. S. (2006). “Reflexive Manufacturing: Taiwan’s Integration
in the Global Economy,” in G. G. Hamilton, Commerce and Capitalism in Chinese
Societies. London: Routledge, 184–200.
Hamilton, G. G., and Kao, C.-S. (2009). “The Round Table: A Reconsideration of
Chinese Business Networks,” in Wong Siu-lun (ed.), Paradigms and Perspectives on
Hong Kong Studies. Hong Kong: University of Hong Kong Press, 175–200.
Hamilton, G. G., and Kao, C.-S. (forthcoming). Making Money: How the Global Economy
Works from an Asian Point of View.
Hamilton, G. G., Petrovic, M., and Feenstra R. C. (2006). “Remaking the Global Econ-
omy: US Retailers and Asian Manufacturers,” in G. G. Hamilton (ed.), Commerce and
Capitalism in Chinese Societies. London: Routledge, 146–84.
Hanchett, T. W. (1996). “US Tax Policy and the Shopping-Center Boom of the 1950s
and 1960s,” American Historical Review, 101/4: 1082–110.
Hanchett, T. W. (2000). “Financing Suburbia, Prudential Insurance and the Post-World
War II: Transformation of the American City,” Journal of Urban History, 26/3: 312–28.
Hansell, S. (1998). “Private Sector: Creator of the On-Line Swap Meet,” New York Times,
Nov. 15.
Hantuba, H., and de Graaf, J. (2003). “Linkages between Smallholder Farm Producers
and Supermarkets in Zambia,” paper presented at the FAO technical workshop
on “Globalization of the Food System: Impacts on Food Security and Nutrition,”
Oct. 8–10, Rome.
Hao, Y.-P. (1986). The Commercial Revolution in Nineteenth Century China: The Rise of
Sino-Western Mercantile Capitalism. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California
Press.
Hardwick, M. J. (2004). Mall Maker: Victor Gruen, Architect of an American Dream.
Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.
Harris, N. (1990). Cultural Excursions: Marketing Appetites and Cultural Tastes in Modern
America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Harrison, B. (1994). Lean and Mean: The Changing Landscape of Corporate Power in the Age
of Flexibility. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Hatch, W., and Yamamura, K. (1996). Asia in Japan’s Embrace: Building a Regional
Production Alliance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Henksmeier, K. (1960). The Economic Performance of Self-Service in Europe: A Report. Paris:
OEEC.
Henksmeier, K. (1988). “50 Jahre Selbstbedienung: ein Rückblick,” Dynamik im Handel.
Sonderausgabe‚ 50 Jahre Selbstbedienung (Oct.), 10–37.
335
References
336
References
337
References
338
References
Lewis, W. W. (2004). The Power of Productivity: Wealth, Poverty, and the Threat to Global
Stability. Chicago: Chicago University Press.
Lhermie C. (2003). Carrefour ou l’invention de l’hypermarché. 2nd edn. Paris: Vuibert.
Li & Fung (2007). Li & Fung Group website, www.lifunggroup.com/front.html (ac-
cessed Aug. 30 2007).
Lichtenstein, N. (2006) (ed.). Wal-Mart: The Face of Twenty-First-Century Capitalism.
New York: New Press.
Lichtenstein, N. (2009). The Retail Revolution: How Wal-Mart Created a Brave New World
of Business. New York: Metropolitan Books.
Lohr, S. (1997). “Digital Commerce,” New York Times. May 19, p. C5.
Longstreth, R. (1999). The Drive-In, the Supermarket, and the Transformation of Commer-
cial Space in Los Angeles, 1914–1941. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Lowe, M., and Wrigley, N. (2009). “Innovation in Retail: Internationalisation: Tesco
in the USA,” International Review of Retail, Distribution and Consumer Research, 19/4:
331–47.
Luen Thai (2006). “Investor Relations: About Us,” http://luenthai.quamnet.com/
luenthai/IR-index.htm.
Luen Thai (2007). Luenthai Holdings Limited, Annual Report 2006, Apr. 20, www2.
luenthai.com/files/LTN20070419219.pdf.
Lüthje, B. (2005). “Global Production, Industrial Development, and New Labor Re-
gimes in China: The Case of Electronics Contract Manufacturing,” in M. Gallagher,
C. K. Lee, and A. Park (eds), China: The Labor of Reform. London: Routledge.
MacDonald, S. B., and Gastmann, A. L. (2001). A History of Credit and Power in the
Western World. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.
McGrath, P. (2003). Chairman of the Board of United States Association of Importers of
Textile and Apparel (USA ITA), testimony before the United States International
Trade Commission, Investigation 332-448, “Competitiveness of the Textile and
Apparel Industries Investigation,” Jan. 22, http://usaita.com.
McNair, M. P., and May, E. G. (1976). The Evolution of Retail Institutions in the United
States. Cambridge, MA: Marketing Science Institute.
McNair, M. P., Gragg, C. I., Jr, and Teele, S. F. (1937). Problems in Retailing. 1st edn.
New York and London: McGraw-Hill.
McNichol, D. (2006). The Roads that Built America: The Incredible Story of the US Interstate
System. New York: Sterling Publishing Company.
MacPherson K. L. (1998) (ed.). Asian Department Stores. Honolulu, HI: University of
Hawaii Press.
Magretta, J. (2002). “Fast, Global, and Entrepreneurial: Supply Chain Management,
Hong Kong Style,” Harvard Business Review, enhanced edn, Oct., original article
published in Harvard Business Review (Sept.–Oct. 1998: 103–14).
Mahoney, T., and Sloane, L. (1966). The Great Merchants, America’s Foremost Retail
Institutions and the People Who Made Them Great. NY: Harper and Row.
Malkin, E. (2004). “Mexican Retailers Unite Against Wal-Mart,” New York Times, July 9.
Malone, S. (2002). “Who Loses to China?” Women’s Wear Daily, Nov. 26.
Manalili, N. M. (2005). “The Changing Map of the Philippine Retail Food Sector: The
Impact on Trade and the Structure of Agriculture and the Policy Response,”
339
References
340
References
Myers, N., and Kent, J. (2003). “New Consumers: The Influence of Affluence on the
Environment,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Science, 100/8: 4963–8.
Natawidjaja, R., Reardon, T., and Shetty, S., with Noor, T. I., Perdana, T., Rasmikayati,
E., Bachri, S., and Hernandez, R. (2007). Horticultural Producers and Supermarket Devel-
opment in Indonesia. UNPAD/MSU/World Bank. World Bank Report No. 38543, pub-
lished by the World Bank/Indonesia, July.
National Postal Museum (2008). “Precious Packages—America’s Parcel Post Service,”
www.postalmuseum.si.edu/exhibits/2b2f_parcel.html (accessed June 19, 2008).
Nelson, R. R., and Winter S. G. (1982). An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Neven, D., and Reardon, T. (2003). “The Rapid Rise of Kenyan Supermarkets: Impacts
on the Fruits and Vegetables System,” paper presented at the FAO technical work-
shop on “Globalization of the Food System: Impacts on Food Security and Nutri-
tion,” Rome, Oct. 8–10.
Neven, D., and Reardon, T. (2004). “The Rise of Kenyan Supermarkets and Evolution of
their Horticulture Product Procurement Systems,” Development Policy Review, 22/6
(Nov.), 669–99.
Neven, D., Reardon, T., Chege, J., and Wang, H.-L. (2005). “Supermarkets and Con-
sumers in Africa: The Case of Nairobi, Kenya,” Staff Paper 2005-04, Dept. of Agricul-
tural Economics, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI.
Neven, D., Katjiuongua, H., Adjosoediro, I., Reardon, T., Chuzu, P., Tembo, G., and
Ndiyoi, M. (2006). “Food Sector Transformation and Standards in Zambia: Small-
holder Farmer Participation and Growth in the Dairy Sector,” Staff Paper 2006–18,
May, Michigan State University, East Lansing.
New York Times (1996). “A Nonchain Bookstore Bucks the Tide,” Sept. 8, p. 4.
New York Times (2006). “Demystifying the eBay Selling Experience,” Jan. 21, p. 5.
New York Times (2007). “Wal-Mart’s Welcome to India Includes Demonstrations,” Feb.
23, p. C3.
Nielsen, P. B. (2008) (ed.). ‘International Sourcing: Moving Business Functions Abroad’,
Statistics Denmark, www.dst.dk/publ/InterSourcing.
Nielsen Company (2007). “Trends in Online Shopping: A Global Nielsen Consumer
Report,” http://th.nielsen.com/site/documents/GlobalOnlineShoppingReportFeb08.
pdf.
Nordås, H. K. (2004). The Global Textile and Clothing Industry Post the Agreement on
Textiles and Clothing. Geneva: World Trade Organization.
Nystrom, P. H. (1917). Retail Store Management. Chicago: LaSalle Extension University.
Nystrom, P. H. (1930). Economics of Retailing. New York: Ronald Press Company.
O’Hara, M. (1995). Market Microstructure Theory. Oxford: Blackwell Publishing.
Offutt, S., and Gunderson, C. (2005). “Farm Poverty,” Amber Waves of Grain, Sept.,
www.ers.usda.gov/AmberWaves/September05/Features/Farm Poverty.htm (accessed
Apr. 7, 2007).
Olney, P. (2003). “On the Waterfront: Analysis of ILWU Lockout,” New Labor Forum,
12/1: 28–37.
Olson, L. (1970). Japan in Postwar Asia. New York: Praeger Publisher.
341
References
Ordanini, A., Kraemer, K., and Dedrick, J. (2006). “Medion: The ‘Orchestrator’ Business
Model,” IT in Business, Center for Research on Information Technology and Orga-
nizations, UC Irvine, Nov.
Orellana, D., and Vasquez, E. (2004). “Guatemala Retail Food Sector Annual, 2004,”
GAIN Report Number GT4018, Washington: USDA Foreign Agricultural Service.
Orlove, B. (1997) (ed.). The Allure of the Foreign: Imported Goods in Postcolonial Latin
America. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Palmer, M. (2005). “Retail Multinational Learning: A Case Study of Tesco,” International
Journal of Retail and Distribution Management, 3/1: 23–48.
Pasdermadjian, H. (1954). The Department Store: Its Origins, Evolution, and Economics.
London: Newman Books.
Pellegrini, L. (1996). La distribuzione commerciale in Italia. Bologna: Il Mulino.
Petrovic, M., and Hamilton G. G. (2006). “Making Global Markets: Wal-Mart and its
Suppliers,” in N. Lichtenstein (ed.), Wal-Mart: The Face of Twenty-First-Century Capi-
talism. New York: New Press, 107–42.
Philadelphia Business Journal (1996). Sept. 27.
Pine, J. B., and Davis, S. (1999). Mass Customization: The New Frontier in Business
Competition. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Piore, M. and Sabel C. (1986). The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity. New
York: Basic Books.
Pocock, E. (2009). “Largest Shopping Malls,” www.easternct.edu/~pocock/MallsWorld.
htm (accessed Oct. 2, 2009).
Porter, M. (1986). Competition in Global Industries. Boston: Harvard Business School
Press.
Potz, P. (2002). “Die Regulierung des Einzelhandels in Italien: Grundlagen und Einfluss
auf die Handelsstruktur,” WZB Discussion Paper FS I 02-104, Berlin.
Prahalad, C. K., and Hamel, G. (1990). “The Core Competence of the Corporation,”
Harvard Business Review, 68/3: 79–91.
Prime, N. (1999). “IKEA: International Development.” in M. Dupuis and J. Dawson
(eds), European Cases in Retailing. Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishers, 33–48.
Publishers Weekly (1996a). Jan. 1.
Publishers Weekly (1996b). Mar 11.
Pun, N. (2005). Director, China Working Women’s Network, interview, Sept. 15.
Pun, N. (2009). “The Making of a Global Dormitory Labour Regime: Labour Protection
and Labour Organizing of Migrant Women in South China,” in Rachel Murphy (ed.),
Labour Migration and Social Development in Contemporary China (London: Routledge).
Pun. N., and Yu, X. M. (2008). “When Wal-Mart and the Chinese Dormitory Labour
Regime Meet: A Study of Three Toy Factories in China. China Journal of Social Work,
1/2: 110–29.
Rabach, E., and Kim, E. M. (1994). “Where is the Chain in Commodity Chains? The
Service Sector Nexus,” in G. Gereffi and M. Korzeniewicz (eds), Commodity Chains and
Global Capitalism. Westport, CT: Praeger, 123–41.
Ralston, B., Kraemer, K. L., and Dedrick J. (2004). “The Retail Model in the Computer
Industry: eMachines,” working paper, Personal Computing Industry Center, The
Paul Merage School of Business, Irvine, CA, June.
342
References
Rangkuti, F. (2003). “Indonesia Food Retail Sector Report 2003,” USDA GAIN Report.
ID3028, Nov. 12.
Rappaport, E. D. (1995). “A New Era of Shopping: The Promotion of Women’s Pleasure
in London’s West End, 1909–1914,” in L. Charney and V. R. Schwartz (eds), Cinema
and the Invention of Modern Life. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California
Press, 130–55.
Rappaport, E. D. (2000). Shopping for Pleasure: Women in the Making of London’s West
End. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Raucher, A. R. (1991). “Dime Store Chains: The Making of Organization Men,
1880–1940,” Business History Review, 65/1: 130–63.
Reardon, T. (2003). “The Rapid Rise of Supermarkets in Latin America and Asia: Funda-
mental Effects on Domestic Agri-food Systems and Trade,” paper presented at the
Global Market for High-Value Food Workshop, Economic Research Service, US
Department of Agriculture, Washington, Feb.14, www.farmfoundation.org (accessed
Aug. 27, 2003).
Reardon, T. (2005). “Emerging Market Opportunities and Challenges from the Rise of
Supermarkets,” Power Point presentation, USDA’s 2005 Agricultural Outlook Forum,
US Department of Agriculture, Washington.
Reardon, T., and Berdegué, J. A. (2002). “The Rapid Rise of Supermarkets in Latin
America: Challenges and Opportunities for Development,” Development Policy
Review, 20/4: 371–88.
Reardon, T., and Berdegué, J. A. (2007). “The Retail-Led Transformation of Agrifood
Systems and its Implications for Development Policies: A Background Paper Prepared
for the World Bank’s World Development Report 2008: Agriculture for Develop-
ment,” Rimisp and MSU, Jan.
Reardon, T., Berdegué, J. A., and Timmer, C. P. (2005). “Supermarketization of the
Emerging Markets of the Pacific Rim: Development and Trade Implications.” Journal
of Food Distribution Research, 36 (Mar.): 3–12.
Reardon, T., and Gulati, A. (2008). “The Rise of Supermarkets and their Development
Implications: International Experience Relevant for India,” IFPRI Discussion Papers
752, International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI).
Reardon, T., and Timmer, C. P. (2007). “Transformation of Markets for Agricultural
Output in Developing Countries since 1950: How Has Thinking Changed,” in
R. Evenson and P. Pingali (eds), Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Volume III, New
York: Elsevier, 2807–55.
Reardon, T., Timmer, P., and Berdegué, J. A. (2004). “The Rapid Rise of Supermarkets in
Developing Countries: Induced Organizational, Institutional, and Technological
Change in Agrifood Systems,” eJADE, Electronic Journal of Agricultural and Development
Economics, 1/2: 168–83.
Reardon, T., Timmer, C. P., Barrett, C. B., and Berdegué, J. A. (2003). “The Rise of
Supermarkets in Africa, Asia and Latin America,” American Journal of Agricultural
Economics, 85/5: 1140–6.
Reardon, T., Codron, J.-M., Busch, L., Bingen, J., and Harris, C. (1999). “Strategic Roles of
Food and Agricultural Standards for Agrifood Industries,” contributed paper selected
for presentation at the IAMA World Food and Agribusiness Forum, Florence, Italy.
343
References
Reardon, T., Berdegué, J. A., Echánove F., Cook, R., Tucker, N., Martínez, A., Medina,
R., Aguirre, M., Hernández, R., and Balsevich, F. (2007). “Supermarkets and Horticul-
tural Development in Mexico: Synthesis of Findings and Recommendations to USAID
and GOM,” report submitted by MSU to USAID/Mexico and USDA/Washington, Aug.
Regan, W. J. (1963). “The Service Revolution,” Journal of Marketing, 27/3: 57–62.
Resseguie, H. E. (1965). “Alexander Turney Stewart and the Development of the
Department Store, 1823–1876,” Business History Review, 39/3: 301–22.
Reuters (2006). “Circuit City chases service with new Firedog brand,” CNET News.com
11/1/06. Also, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Firedog.
Rezabakhsh, B., Bornemann, D., Hansen, U., and Schrader, U. (2006). “Consumer
Power: A Comparison of the Old Economy and the Internet Economy,” Journal of
Consumer Policy, 29: 3–36.
Rindova, V. P., Petkova, A. P., and Kotha, S. B. (2007). “Standing Out: How New Firms
in Emerging Markets Build Reputation,” Strategic Organization (Jan.–Mar.), 31–70.
Robinson, J. (1969 [1933]). The Economics of Imperfect Competition. 2nd edn. London:
Macmillan.
Ross, A. (2004). Low Pay, High Profile: The Global Push for Fair Labor. New York: New
Press.
Ross, R. J. S. (2004). Slaves to Fashion: Poverty and Abuse in the New Sweatshops. Ann
Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Rouibah, K., Khalil, O., and Hassanien, A. E. (2009) (eds). Emerging Markets and
E-Commerce in Developing Economies. Hershey, PA: Information Science Reference.
Runsten, D. (2003). “Globalization, NAFTA, and the Restructuring of Mexican Food
Processing: Consequences for Small Producers,” paper presented at the FAO technical
workshop on “Globalization of the Food System: Impacts on Food Security and
Nutrition,” Oct. 8–10, Rome.
Rydell, R. (1989). “The Culture of Imperial Abundance: World’s Fairs in the Making of
American Culture,” in S. Bronner (ed.), Consuming Visions, Accumulation and Display
of Goods in America, 1880–1920. New York: W. W. Norton, 191–216.
Salmon, W. J., and Tordjman, A. (1989). “The Internationalisation of Retailing,” Inter-
national Journal of Retailing, 4/2: 3–16.
Scheybani, A. (1996). Handwerk und Kleinhandel in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland:
Sozialökonomishcer Wandel und Mittelstandspolitik 1949–1961. Munich: Oldenbourg.
Schröter, H. G. (2004). “‘Revolution in Trade’: The Americanization of Distribution
in Germany during the Boom Years, 1949–75,” in A. Kudo, M. Kipping, and
H. G. Schröter (eds), German and Japanese Business in the Boom Years: Transforming
American Management and Technology Models. New York: Routledge, 246–67.
Schröter, H. G. (2005). Americanization of the European Economy: A Compact Survey of
American Economic Influence in Europe since the 1880s. Dordrecht: Springer.
Schumpeter, J. A. (1950). Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. New York: Harper.
Scranton, P. (1994). “Manufacturing Diversity: Production Systems, Markets, and an
American Consumer Society, 1870–1930,” Technology and Culture, 35/3 (July),
476–505.
Scranton, P. (1999). “Multiple Industrializations: Urban Manufacturing Development
in the American Midwest, 1880–1925,” Journal of Design History, 12/1: 45–63.
344
References
Senauer, B. (2005). “The Growing Market for High-Value Food Products in Developing
and Transition Countries,” Journal of Food Distribution Research, 32/1: 22–7.
Senauer, B., and Goetz, L. (2004). “The Growing Middle Class in Developing Countries
and the Market for High Value Food Products,” ICFAI Journal of Agricultural Economics,
1/2: 7–12.
Senauer, B., and Venturini, L. (2005). “The Globalization of Food Systems: A Concep-
tual Framework and Empirical Patterns,” in E. DeFrancesco, L. Galletto, and
M. Thiene (eds), Food, Agriculture, and the Environment. Milan: Franco Angeli Press.
Shaffer, J. D. (1960). “The Influence of ‘Impulse Buying’ or In-the-Store Decisions on
Consumers’ Food Purchases,” Journal of Farm Economics, 42/2: 317–24.
Shaw, G., and Alexander, A. (2006). “Interlocking Directorates and the Knowledge
Transfer of Supermarket Retail Techniques from North America to Britain,” Interna-
tional Review of Retail, Distribution and Consumer Research, 16/3: 375–94.
Shaw, G., Curth L., and Alexander, A. (2004). “Selling Self-Service and the Supermarket:
The Americanisation of Food Retailing in Britain, 1945–1970,” Business History, 46/4:
568–82.
Shin, H. Y., and Lee, Y.-I. (1995). “Korean Direct Investment in Southeast Asia,” Journal
of Contemporary Asia, 25/2: 179–96.
Smith, A. (1977 [1776]). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Smith, C., and Pun, N. (2006). “The Dormitory Labour Regime in China as a Site for
Control and Resistance,” International Journal of Human Resource Management, 17/8:
1456–70.
Smith, D. (1996). “Going South: Global Restructuring and Garment Production in
Three East Asian Cases,” Asian Perspective, 20/2: 211–41.
Solomon, B. (2001). The Heritage of North American Steam Railroads: From the First Days of
Steam Power to the Present. Pleasantville, NY: Reader’s Digest.
Sparks, L. (1996). “Reciprocal Retail Internationalisation: The Southland Corporation,
Ito-Yokado and 7-Eleven Convenience Stores,” in G. Akehurst and N. Alexander
(eds), The Internationalisation of Retailing. London: F. Cass, 57–96.
Speer, J. K. (2002). “Sourcing in China: Firms Discuss Advantages, Issues,” Bobbin, Jan. 1,
www.apparelmag.com/bobbin/search/search_display.jsp?vnu_content_ id=1431921.
Spulber, D. F. (1996). “Market Microstructure and Intermediation.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives 10/3 (Summer), 135–52.
Spulber, D. F. (1998). Market Microstructure: Intermediaries and the Theory of the Firm.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Stern, H. (1962). “The Significance of Impulse Buying Today,” Journal of Marketing,
26/2: 59–62.
Sternquist, B., and Kacker, M. (1994). European Retailing’s Vanishing Borders. Westport,
CT: Quorum Books.
Strasser, S. (1995). Satisfaction Guaranteed: The Making of the American Mass Market.
Washington: Smithsonian Institution Press.
Sturgeon, T. (2002). “Modular Production Networks: A New American Model of Indus-
trial Organization,” Industrial and Corporate Change, 11/3: 451–96.
345
References
346
References
347
References
348
References
Winkler, H. A. (1991). Zwischen Marx und Monopolen: Der deutsche Mittelstand vom
Kaiserreich zur Bundesrepublik Deutschland. Frankfurt am Main: Fischer.
Winter, S. G., and Szulanski. G. (2001). “Replication as Strategy,” Organization Science,
12/6: 730–43.
Woodward, R. B. (2007). “Making a Pilgrimage to Cathedrals of Commerce,” New York
Times, Mar. 11, sect. Travel.
Worthen, B., Tuna, C., and Scheck, J. (2009). “Companies More Prone to Go Vertical,”
Wall Street Journal, Dec. 1, http://online.wsj.com/article/SB125954262100968855.
html (accessed Jan. 15, 2010).
Wortmann, M. (2004). “Aldi and the German Model: Structural Change in German
Grocery Retailing and the Success of Grocery Discounters,” Competition and Change,
8/4: 425–41.
Wrigley, N., Coe, N., and Currah, A. (2005). “Globalizing Retail: Conceptualizing the
Distribution Based Transnational Corporation, TNC,” Progress in Human Geography,
29: 437–57.
Wrigley, N., and Lowe, M. (2002). Reading Retail: A Geographical Perspective on Retailing
and Consumption Spaces. London: Arnold.
Xinhua (2007). “China’s Yue Yuen ‘Underperform’ on Low Retail Exposure: Credit
Suisse,” July 26, www.quamnet.com/fcgi-bin/news.fpl?par2=2&par3=02&par4=
20070726121705361886einens.
Yamin, M., and Sinkovics, R. R. (2009). “Infrastructure or Foreign Direct Investment?
An Examination of the Implications of MNE Strategy for Economic Development,”
Journal of World Business, 44/2: 144–57.
Yen, C.-H. (1998). “Wing On and the Kwok Brothers: A Case Study of Pre-War Chinese
Entrepreneurs,” in K. L. MacPherson (ed.), Asian Department Stores. Honolulu, HI:
University of Hawaii Press, 47–65.
Yeo, V. (2006). “Intel Pushes for Conformity in Notebooks,” CNET News.com, Dec. 4,
http://news.com.com/Intel+pushes+for+conformity+in+notebooks/2100-1005_3-
6060277.html?tag=nefd.top.
Yeung, H. W.-C. (2009). “Regional Development and the Competitive Dynamics of
Global Production Networks: An East Asian Perspective,” Regional Studies, 43/3:
325–51.
Young, J. D. (1998). “Sun Yatsen and the Department Store: An Aspect of National
Reconstruction,” in K. L. MacPherson (ed.), Asian Department Stores. Honolulu, HI:
University of Hawaii Press, 33–46.
Yue Yuen (2006). Yue Yuen Industrial Holdings, Limited Factsheet, http://202.66.146.
82/listco/hk/yueyuen/factsheet/fs060206.pdf.
Yue Yuen (2007a). Yue Yuen Industrial Holdings, “Production Facilties,” www.
yueyuen.com/bOverview_productionFacilities.htm.
Yue Yuen (2007b). Yue Yuen Industrial Holdings, Limited Press Release, “Yue Yuen
Announces FY 2006 Results,” Jan. 18, www.yueyuen.com/press_file/4Q2006-press.
pdf.
Yue Yuen (2007c). Yue Yuen Industrial Holdings, Limited Press Release, “Yue Yuen
Announces 2007 Interim Results,” June 21, www.yueyuen.com/press_file/2QFY2007-
English.pdf.
349
References
350
Index
A&P 87–8, 90, 92, 95, 150, 272–3 Au bonheur des dames (Zola) 83
Abaza, M. 8 Auchan 124
Abernathy, F. H. 15, 72, 74, 255 Australia 103, 136–7, 151
Abolafia, M. Y. 36 Austria 1118, 127, 135, 137, 138, 150
Adams, Henry 35 automobile industries 51–2, 61, 89, 235, 238–9
Adelman, M. A. 93 consolidation 239
Adidas 112, 206, 207, 263 dealerships 89–90
advertising 51, 82, 94, 95, 97, 134 disruptive technologies 64, 66
Africa 232, 257 globalization 239
PC shipment share 310t11.A5
African Growth and Opportunity Act Bachmann, R. 254
(AGOA) 242 Bair, J. 15
agriculture 27, 290 Balsevich, F. 11, 276, 277, 279
developed countries 289 Bank of America (BOA) 55
Aguirre, M. 11, 276, 279 BankAmericard 55
Ahold 27, 130, 150, 286 bar codes 5, 15, 23, 46, 57–8, 59, 61, 70, 71, 72,
Akinwande, A. 247 117, 273
Aldi 4, 9, 21, 24, 106, 117, 119, 124–5, 134–7, Barboza, D. 266
137, 273 Barger, H. 87
Alexander, A. 104, 118, 120 Barnes & Noble 161, 163
Allawadi, K. 14 Barth, G. 82
Amazon.com 24, 112, 113, 156, 157–9, 160, Batt, R. 234
161, 162, 163–6, 167, 169, 170, 177–8 Belgium 103, 126, 127, 130, 131, 135, 137,
America, see USA 138, 140, 150
Amsden, A. 193, 195 Bell, D. E. 126, 127
anticompetitive behaviour/practices 12, 18 Bell Labs 55
antitrust authorities 273 Bennett, T. 83
apparel industry 15, 91, 239–40, 256–7 Berdegué, J. A. 11, 276, 277, 279, 282, 283,
bar codes 71 284, 285, 286
China 257, 258, 261 Berekoven, L. 121
Indonesia 240 Berger, S. 254
Apple Computers 10, 296, 297, 307 Beyonics 243, 244
Armstrong, A. 155 Bianco, A. 9, 162
ARPAnet 70 big buyers, see global retailers
Asda 118, 122, 123, 129 big-box retailers 5, 11, 18, 23, 52, 60, 85, 97,
Asia 23, 102, 111, 120, 130, 132, 142, 152, 98, 99, 106, 108, 112, 117, 119, 138
219, 261 1945–1970 104
design manufactures 28 big suppliers, see giant retailers
economies 6, 182 Bingen, J. 284
ports 216 Birchall, J. 224, 225
Asia Pacific PC shipment share 309t11.A1 Bliss, P. 42
AsiaOceania 11 Blonigen, B. A. 21, 218
Asian financial crisis (1997) 217 Bluestone, B. 3, 183
Asian Miracle 16, 17, 25, 182 Bon Marché (Paris) 84
Index
Bonacich, E. 211, 219, 220, 227, 228, 255 chain stores 5, 14, 23, 91, 95, 96, 97, 98–9
Bonaglia, F. 239 buyerdriven 15
book industry 161 history of 87
value chain prior to online retailing 160, Chamberlin, E. H. 181
160t5.1, 162t5.2 Chan, A. 223
Borders 161 Chan, K. W. 223, 264
Bornemann, D. 19 Chandler, Alfred D. 3, 32, 36, 58
Bowles, Samuel 31 Chandler, C. 267
Box, The (Levinson) 67 Chang, C. C. 276
Bradley, S. P. 166, 170 Chang, R. 301
Brandes, D. 134 Chapman, S. 35
brand values 261 Chege, J. 281
brands 18, 86, 90, 97–8, 164 Cheng, L. L. 187, 201
manufacturing 264 Chessel, M. E. 84
name merchandisers 4, 38, 40, 43, 45, 46, Chile 70
182, 187, 214, 215, 221, 233, 292 China 11, 19, 22, 103, 112, 150, 167, 182,
prices 219 208, 235, 237, 247, 256, 268, 283, 286
USA 6 apparel industry 257, 258
brick-and-mortar retailers 156, 157, 158, 159, bicycle industry 220
162, 163, 164, 167, 175, 176–8 cash and carry 142
Brinkley, J. 60 competition 200
broadband communications 74, 173–4 contract manufacturers 21, 26, 224, 226
Broehl, W. G. 104 convenience stores 110
Brown, C. 234 economic development 20, 21, 265, 268,
Brown, S. A. 58, 71 282, 290
Bucklin, L. P. 92, 95 employment 17, 223
Burt, S. 108, 123, 126, 150, 152 exports 20–1, 25, 218
Burt, T. 277 to USA 216
Busch, L. 284 foreign direct investment (FDI) 217–18
Bush, President George H. 60, 61 global champions 266t9.1
business groups (keiretsu) 189, 192 government policy 266
Japan 193 manufacturing 207, 217, 244
Taiwan 208 retail formats, modern 115
business models 4, 90, 171, 177, 261, 291 social organization 198
buyers and sellers 15, 155–6, 158, 181 supermarkets 109, 277, 279
eBay.com 167, 168 textile industry 258
China External Trade Development Council 196
Canada 107 China Labor Watch 226
Cao, N. 258, 260 Choi, S. C. 108, 126, 143, 144
capital goods, world imports 253f8.2 Chu, W. W. 193, 195
capitalism 2, 31, 34, 35, 36, 82, 182, 210 Chu, Y. W. 210
Caribbean 257 Chua, B. H. 8
Carrefour 4, 9, 10, 16, 21, 24, 27, 41, 49, 86, clothing, see apparel industry
108, 111, 117, 118, 119, 121, 124, Clover, V. T. 93
125–7, 150, 274, 284, 285, 286 Clower, R. 37
China 127–8, 132–3, 152, 267 Coase, R. 31
internationalization 126, 145, 151–2 codes of conduct 224
Latin America 127 CODEX Alimentarius 285
and Promodès 125, 137 Codron, J.M. 284
Carrefour 127–8, 132–3, 152 Coe, N. 152
cars, see automomobiles Coggins, J. 274
cartel 45 Cohen, A. 96, 166
cash and carry 119, 122, 125, 137, 137, 138, Coles, T. 83, 84, 103
139, 141, 142, 278 Colla, E. 80, 123
Celestica 236 Collins, N. 91
Central America 257, 285 Communist Manifesto, The (Marx and
Central Europe, PC shipment share 310t11.A4 Engels) 34
352
Index
competition 12, 39, 42, 43–4, 45, 63, 121, 212, Davis, S. 256
276, 281 Dawson, J. A. 104, 143, 144, 150, 152
China 200, 277 De Grazia, V. 80, 103
direct 102, 114–5 Debenhams 86
global 232 Dedrick, J. 245, 292, 295, 296, 303, 305
horizontal 43, 44 Dell 4–5, 28, 49, 291, 293, 296, 297, 300–1,
price 43 303, 304
competitive advantage 19, 164, 230, 282 Deloitte 2, 81, 113, 274, 275
consumer electronics 194–5, 257, 306 demand-pull 298
consumer goods 45–6, 86, 94 demand-responsive economies 16, 25, 181–2,
consolidation 267–8 190, 221
developed countries 108 demand-responsive manufacturers 207, 208
East Asia 6, 25 demand-side 281, 282, 283
Europe 111 Denis, C. 16
globalization 255 Denmark 135, 138
markets 2, 10, 19, 101, 111–12, 115–16 department stores 23, 40, 64–5, 71, 80, 82–3,
global 113; internalization of 81 93, 94, 98, 102–3, 110, 138, 185
modern 103 Austalia 103
USA 6, 41, 100 China 103
imports of 185; 1970–2010 99–100 down-town 121
consumer markets 23, 40, 42, 43, 44, 84, Europe 35, 103
182–3, 212 France 84
consumer power 19, 100–1 Great Britain 84
Consumer Credit Protection Act 1968 (USA) 57 inventory control 71, 72
consumption 6, 7, 82 Japan 84, 103
patterns 18, 19 limits of 85
containers, see shipping, containers replication of 103
contract manufacturing 5, 10, 21, 26, 208, 212, USA 35, 91, 183
218, 221–2, 236, 243–4, 250, 303 decline of 97
Beyonics 244 developed countries 240, 253, 254, 299
China 224, 226 developing countries 231, 232, 242, 248, 254,
East Asia 26, 188 255, 257
and supply chain 27 food retailers 274, 283, 284, 285, 286
Taiwan 245–6 white-box makers 305–6
convenience stores 42–3, 90, 99, 102, 107, 131, Dicke, T. S. 89
133, 273 Dicken, P. 241
Cook, R. 11, 276, 279 digital home 306, 307
Cortada, J. 15 Diotallevi, Ezio 79
Costco 2, 4, 9, 10, 11, 21, 42, 100, 214, 273 discount stores 23, 96, 98, 99, 132–3, 143, 151,
Coulter, J. 288, 289 188, 273
credit: disk-drive manufacturers 243
cards 51, 56–7, 97, 169 disruptive technologies 52, 53, 61
industry 55 air conditioning 53
technology, use of 56 automobiles 64
Crossick, G. 82, 83, 103 early 51, 61
Cunningham, E. 235 Internet 61
Currah, N. 152 railroads 61, 66
Curth, L. 104, 118 distribution 5, 33, 102, 104
customer services 163–4, 165 centers 72–3, 89, 276, 286
PCs 307 channels 38, 39, 45, 291, 293
Cusumano, M. 247 direct 294f11.2; indirect 293f11.1
Czech Republic 11, 109, 122–3, 131, 132, 141, Europe 104
144, 145, 150, 152, 276, 286 “The Distribution Upheaval” (Lebhar) 98
division of labor 33
Daems, H. 36 Doellgast, V. 234
Davis, H. B. O. 60 Dolan, C. 251
Davis, R. T. 79 domestic markets 107, 111, 119
353
Index
354
Index
355
Index
356
Index
357
Index
358
Index
359
Index
360
Index
Rozelle, S. 277, 284, 286 containers (TEUs) 52, 61, 65, 67, 74, 211,
rural free delivery (RFD) 64 214–15, 227
Russia 141, 278, 284 bar codes 72; size 69–70; standards 69
Rydell, R. 83 flags of convenience 227
ports 68, 216
Sabel, C. 256 shoe manufacturers, Taiwan 204–7
Safeway 92, 95, 120, 123 shopping centers/malls 1–2, 4, 18, 23, 85, 86,
Sainsbury’s 123, 150 109, 117, 183, 215
Salmon, W. J. 126, 127, 153 developing countries 109–10
Sam’s Club 100, 273, 275, 276 Europe 106
Sato, Y. 187, 201 greenfield 143
scanning devices 15, 23, 46, 58, 59–60, 61, spatial planning 121–2
70–1, 117, 136, 273 USA 2, 50–1, 92, 96, 97, 99, 183–4
Scheck, J. 236 store fronts 52; suburban 51–2
Scheybani, A. 121 Singapore 8, 128, 133, 150, 216, 241, 243
Schmalensee, R. 55 Sinkovics, R. R. 233
Schrader, U. 19 small businesses 12–13
Schröter, H. G. 80, 104, 105, 106, 118 smart-chip technology 57
Schumpeter, J. A. 42 smart modems 55–6
Scott, R. V. 98 Smith, Adam 32, 33, 181
Scranton, Philip 2 Smith, C. 223
Sculle, K. A. 90 Smith, D. 240
Sears, Roebuck and Co 9, 41, 52, 63–4, 65, social welfare mechanisms 13
66, 86, 88, 89, 90, 97, 98, 107, 183, Sodini, C. 247
185, 214 Solectron 236
Second World War 65, 115 Solomon, B. 61, 62
department stores after 84–5 Song, H. K. 187
USA 90, 184 sourcing strategies 233–4, 245–6, 257
manufacturers 183 South Africa 278
selfservice 48–9, 65, 93, 95, 104, 143, 279 South Asia 69, 70, 74, 110, 257
adoption of 105 South East Asia 97, 133 244
France 79, 126, 128 South Korea 26, 111, 115, 145, 182, 185, 186,
Germany 134 189, 203, 216, 303
Great Britain 120 Indonesian apparel industry 240–1
grocery chains 95, 272 economy 187–8
Italy 79 foreign direct investment (FDI) 217–18
Netherlands 79 intermediaries 241
retailers 119 Japanese trading companies 191
supermarkets 92, 94, 95 mass produced goods 189
West Europe 79 shoe manufacturers 206
West Germany 79 Soviet Union 103, 110
Selfridge, Gordon 102 Spain 108, 127, 129, 130, 137, 138, 150, 152
sellers, see buyers and sellers Sparks, L. 90, 107, 152
selling 28, 39, 43, 95, 104 speciality stores 11, 23, 40, 51, 86, 92, 97, 112,
full package 40 119, 157t5.1
new methods of 42 Japan 105
see also mass selling Speer, J. K. 257
Senauer, B. 109, 274, 282 Spulber, D. F. 36–7, 181, 241
7-Eleven 43, 90, 107, 109, 273 stakeholders 159
Seven-I Holdings Company 107, 111 standards 56, 284
Shaw, G. 104, 118, 120 adoption of 73, 209
Shell 90 container shipping 69
Shetty, S. 284 global industry 249
Shi, C. 177 technology 308
Shin, H. Y. 241 standards of living 105, 117
shipping: start-ups 203
coastal 67 Sternquist, B. 80, 108
361
Index
362
Index
363
Index
364