Macroeconomics
Macroeconomics
Macroeconomics
Macroeconomics
Textbook in Economics for Class XII
2019-20
ISBN 81-7450-715-9
First Edition
March 2007 Phalguna 1928 ALL RIGHTS RESERVED
q No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system
Reprinted or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical,
February 2008 Magha 1929 photocopying, recording or otherwise without the prior permission of the
publisher.
February 2009 Magha 1930
January 2010 Magha 1931 q This book is sold subject to the condition that it shall not, by way of trade,
be lent, re-sold, hired out or otherwise disposed of without the publisher’s
January 2011 Magha 1932 consent, in any form of binding or cover other than that in which it is
January 2012 Magha 1933 published.
January 2013 Pausa 1934 q The correct price of this publication is the price printed on this page, Any
January 2014 Pausa 1935 revised price indicated by a rubber stamp or by a sticker or by any other
means is incorrect and should be unacceptable.
December 2014 Pausa 1936
December 2015 Pausa 1937
February 2017 Magha 1938
January 2018 Magha 1939
January 2019 Pausa 1940
OFFICES OF THE PUBLICATION
PD 300T BS DIVISION, NCERT
NCERT Campus
Sri Aurobindo Marg
New Delhi 110 016 Phone : 011-26562708
© National Council of Educational
Research and Training, 2007 108, 100 Feet Road
Hosdakere Halli Extension
Banashankari III Stage
Bengaluru 560 085 Phone : 080-26725740
CWC Campus
Opp. Dhankal Bus Stop
Panihati
Kolkata 700 114 Phone : 033-25530454
CWC Complex
Maligaon
Guwahati 781 021 Phone : 0361-2674869
Publication Team
` 75.00
Head, Publication : M. Siraj Anwar
Division
2019-20
Foreword
The National Curriculum Framework (NFC) 2005, recommends that
children’s life at school must be linked to their life outside the school.
This principle marks a departure from the legacy of bookish learning
which continues to shape our system and causes a gap between
the school, home and community. The syllabi and textbooks
developed on the basis of NCF signify an attempt to implement this
basic idea. They also attempt to discourage rote learning and the
maintenance of sharp boundaries between different subject areas.
We hope these measures will take us significantly further in the
direction of a child-centred system of education outlined in the
National Policy on Education (1986).
The success of this effort depends on the steps that school
principals and teachers will take to encourage children to reflect on
their own learning and to pursue imaginative activities and
questions. We must recognise that, given space, time and freedom,
children generate new knowledge by engaging with the information
passed on to them by adults. Treating the prescribed textbook as
the sole basis of examination is one of the key reasons why other
resources and sites of learning are ignored. Inculcating creativity
and initiative is possible if we perceive and treat children as
participants in learning, not as receivers of a fixed body of knowledge.
These aims imply considerable change in school routines and
mode of functioning. Flexibility in the daily time-tables is as
necessary as rigour in implementing the annual calendar so that
the required number of teaching days are actually devoted to
teaching. The methods used for teaching and evaluation will also
determine how effective this textbook proves for making children’s
life at school a happy experience, rather than a source of stress or
problem. Syllabus designers have tried to address the problem of
curricular burden by restructuring and reorienting knowledge at
different stages with greater consideration for child psychology and
the time available for teaching. The textbook attempts to enhance
this endeavour by giving higher priority and space to opportunities
for contemplation and wondering, discussion in small groups, and
activities requiring hands-on experience.
The National Council of Educational Research and Training
(NCERT) appreciates the hardwork done by the textbook development
committee responsible for this textbook. We wish to thank the
Chairperson of the advisory group in Social Sciences, Professor Hari
Vasudevan, and the Chief Advisor for this textbook, Professor Tapas
Majumdar, for guiding the work of this committee. Several teachers
2019-20
contributed to the development of this textbook; we are grateful to their principals
for making this possible. We are indebted to the institutions and organisations
which have generously permitted us to draw upon their resources, material and
personnel. We are especially grateful to the members of the National Monitoring
Committee, appointed by the Department of Secondary and Higher Education,
Ministry of Human Resource Development under the Chairpersonship of Professor
Mrinal Miri and Professor G.P. Deshpande, for their valuable time and contribution.
As an organisation committed to systemic reform and continuous improvement in
the quality of its products, NCERT welcomes comments and suggestions which will
enable us to undertake further revision and refinement.
Director
New Delhi National Council of Educational
16 February 2007 Research and Training
iv
2019-20
Textbook Development Committee
CHAIRPERSON, ADVISORY COMMITTEE FOR SOCIAL SCIENCE TEXTBOOKS AT THE HIGHER
SECONDARY LEVEL
Hari Vasudevan, Professor, Department of History, University of Calcutta,
Kolkata
CHIEF ADVISOR
Tapas Majumdar, Professor Emeritus of Economics,
Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi.
ADVISOR
Satish Jain, Professor, Centre for Economics Studies and Planning,
School of Social Sciences, Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi
MEMBERS
Debarshi Das, Lecturer, Department of Economics, Punjab University,
Chandigarh
Saumyajit Bhattacharya, Senior Lecturer, Department of Economics,
Kirorimal College, University of Delhi, New Delhi
Sanmitra Ghosh, Lecturer, Department of Economics, Jadavpur
University, Kolkata
Malbika Pal, Senior Lecturer, Department of Economics, Miranda House,
University of Delhi, New Delhi
MEMBER-COORDINATOR
Jaya Singh, Lecturer, Economics, Department of Education in Social
Sciences, NCERT, New Delhi
2019-20
Acknowledgement
The National Council of Educational Research and Training
acknowledges the invaluable contribution of academicians and
practising school teachers for bringing out this textbook. We are
grateful to Subrato Guha, Assistant Professor, Jawaharlal Nehru
University, for going through our manuscript and suggesting relevant
changes. We thank Sunil Ashra, Associate Professor, Management
Development Institute, Gurgaon, for his contribution. We also thank
our colleagues Neeraja Rashmi, Reader, Curriculum Group; M.V.
Srinivasan, Ashita Raveendran, Pratima Kumari, Lecturers,
Department of Education in Social Sciences and Humanities, (DESSH),
for their feedback and suggestions.
We would like to place on record the precious advise of (Late)
Dipak Banerjee, Professor (Retd.), Presidency College, Kolkata.
We could have benefited much more of his expertise had his health
permitted.
The practising school teachers have helped in many ways. The
council expresses its gratitude to S.K. Mishra, PGT (Economics),
Kendriya Vidyalaya, Uttarkashi, Uttarakhand; Ambika Gulati, Head,
Department of Economics, Sanskriti School; B.C. Thakur, PGT
(Economics), Government Pratibha Vikas Vidyalaya, Surajmal Vihar;
Ritu Gupta, Principal, Sneh International School, Rashmi Sharma,
PGT (Economics), Kendriya Vidyalaya, JNU Campus, New Delhi.
We also thank Savita Sinha, Professor and Head, DESSH for her support.
Special thanks are due to Vandana R.Singh, Consultant Editor, for going
through the manuscript.
The council gratefully acknowledges the contributions of Dinesh Kumar,
In-charge, Computer Station; Amar Kumar Prusty, Copy Editor, in shaping
this book. The contribution of the Publication Department in bringing
out his book is duly acknowledged.
This textbook has been reviewed with the support of Archana
Aggarwal, Assistant Professor, Hindu College; Malabika Pal,
Associate Professor, Miranda House; Lokendra Kumawat, Assistant
Professor, Ramjas College; T. M. Thomas, Associate Professor,
Deshbandhu College, Delhi School of Arts and Commerce and Rashmi
Sharma, Assistant Professor, (DCAC). Their contributions are duly
acknowledged.
The council is also thankful to Tampakmayum Alan Mustofa, JPF;
Farheen Fatima, and Amjad Husain, DTP Operators, in shaping this
textbook.
2019-20
Contents
F OREWORD
? iii
1. INTRODUCTION 1
1.1 Emergence of Macroeconomics 5
1.2 Context of the Present Book of Macroeconomics 6
2019-20
4.3.3 The Multiplier Mechanism 61
4.4 Some More Concepts 64
viii
2019-20
Chapter 1
Introduction
You must have already been introduced to a study of basic
microeconomics. This chapter begins by giving you a
simplified account of how macroeconomics differs from the
microeconomics that you have known.
Those of you who will choose later to specialise in
economics, for your higher studies, will know about the
more complex analyses that are used by economists to
study macroeconomics today. But the basic questions of
the study of macroeconomics would remain the same and
you will find that these are actually the broad economic
questions that concern all citizens – Will the prices as a
whole rise or come down? Is the employment condition of
the country as a whole, or of some sectors of the economy,
getting better or is it worsening? What would be reasonable
indicators to show that the economy is better or worse?
What steps, if any, can the State take, or the people ask
for, in order to improve the state of the economy? These
are the kind of questions that make us think about the
health of the country’s economy as a whole. These
questions are dealt within macroeconomics at different
levels of complexity.
In this book you will be introduced to some of the basic
principles of macroeconomic analysis. The principles will
be stated, as far as possible, in simple language.
Sometimes elementary algebra will be used in the
treatment for introducing the reader to some rigour.
If we observe the economy of a country as a whole it will
appear that the output levels of all the goods and services
in the economy have a tendency to move together. For
example, if output of food grain is experiencing a growth, it
is generally accompanied by a rise in the output level of
industrial goods. Within the category of industrial goods
also output of different kinds of goods tend to rise or fall
simultaneously. Similarly, prices of different goods and
services generally have a tendency to rise or fall
simultaneously. We can also observe that the employment
level in different production units also goes up or down
together.
If aggregate output level, price level, or employment
level, in the different production units of an economy,
2019-20
labour which is sold and purchased against wages is referred to as
wage labour).
If we apply the above mentioned four criteria to the countries of
the world we would find that capitalist countries have come into
being only during the last three to four hundred years. Moreover,
strictly speaking, even at present, a handful of countries in North
America, Europe and Asia will qualify as capitalist countries. In many
underdeveloped countries production (in agriculture especially) is
carried out by peasant families. Wage labour is seldom used and
most of the labour is performed by the family members themselves.
Production is not solely for the market; a great part of it is consumed
by the family. Neither do many peasant farms experience significant
rise in capital stock over time. In many tribal societies the ownership
of land does not exist; the land may belong to the whole tribe. In
such societies the analysis that we shall present in this book will
not be applicable. It is, however, true that many developing countries
have a significant presence of production units which are organised
according to capitalist principles. The production units will be called
firms in this book. In a firm the entrepreneur (or entrepreneurs) is
at the helm of affairs. She hires wage labour from the market, she
employs the services of capital and land as well. After hiring these
inputs she undertakes the task of production. Her motive for
producing goods and services (referred to as output) is to sell them
in the market and earn profits. In the process she undertakes risks
and uncertainties. For example, she may not get a high enough price
for the goods she is producing; this may lead to fall in the profits
that she earns. It is to be noted that in a capitalist country the
factors of production earn their incomes through the process of
production and sale of the resultant output in the market.
In both the developed and developing countries, apart from the
7
private capitalist sector, there is the institution of State. The role of
the state includes framing laws, enforcing them and delivering justice.
Introduction
The state, in many instances, undertakes production – apart from
imposing taxes and spending money on building public infrastructure,
running schools, colleges, providing health services etc. These
economic functions of the state have to be taken into account when
we want to describe the economy of the country. For convenience we
shall use the term “Government” to denote state.
Apart from the firms and the government, there is another major
sector in an economy which is called the household sector. By a
household we mean a single individual who takes decisions relating
to her own consumption, or a group of individuals for whom decisions
relating to consumption are jointly determined. Households also save
and pay taxes. How do they get the money for these activities? We
must remember that the households consist of people. These people
work in firms as workers and earn wages. They are the ones who
work in the government departments and earn salaries, or they are
the owners of firms and earn profits. Indeed the market in which the
firms sell their products could not have been functioning without the
demand coming from the households. Moreover, they can also earn
rent by leasing land or earn interest by lending capital.
2019-20
way macroeconomics differs from microeconomics. To recapitulate briefly,
in microeconomics, you came across individual ‘economic agents’ (see
box) and the nature of the motivations that drive them. They were
‘micro’ (meaning ‘small’) agents – consumers choosing their respective
optimum combinations of goods to buy, given their tastes and incomes;
and producers trying to make maximum profit out of producing their
goods keeping their costs as low as possible and selling at a price as
high as they could get in the markets. In other words, microeconomics
was a study of individual markets of demand and supply and the ‘players’,
or the decision-makers, were also individuals (buyers or sellers, even
companies) who were seen as trying to maximise their profits (as
producers or sellers) and their personal satisfaction or welfare levels
(as consumers). Even a large company was ‘micro’ in the sense that it
had to act in the interest of its own shareholders which was not
necessarily the interest of the country as a whole. For microeconomics
the ‘macro’ (meaning ‘large’) phenomena affecting the economy as a
whole, like inflation or unemployment, were either not mentioned or
were taken as given. These were not variables that individual buyers or
sellers could change. The nearest that microeconomics got to
macroeconomics was when it looked at General Equilibrium, meaning
the equilibrium of supply and demand in each market in the economy.
Economic Agents
By economic units or economic agents, we mean those individuals
or institutions which take economic decisions. They can be
consumers who decide what and how much to consume. They may
be producers of goods and services who decide what and how much
to produce. They may be entities like the government, corporation,
banks which also take different economic decisions like how much
to spend, what interest rate to charge on the credits, how much to 3
tax, etc.
Introduction
Macroeconomics tries to address situations facing the economy as a
whole. Adam Smith, the founding father of modern economics, had
suggested that if the buyers and sellers in each market take their
decisions following only their own self-interest, economists will not need
to think of the wealth and welfare of the country as a whole separately.
But economists gradually discovered that they had to look further.
Economists found that first, in some cases, the markets did not or
could not exist. Secondly, in some other cases, the markets existed
but failed to produce equilibrium of demand and supply. Thirdly, and
most importantly, in a large number of situations society (or the State,
or the people as a whole) had decided to pursue certain important
social goals unselfishly (in areas like employment, administration,
defence, education and health) for which some of the aggregate effects
of the microeconomic decisions made by the individual economic agents
needed to be modified. For these purposes macroeconomists had to
study the effects in the markets of taxation and other budgetary
policies, and policies for bringing about changes in money supply, the
rate of interest, wages, employment, and output. Macroeconomics has,
2019-20
Adam Smith
2019-20
1.1 EMERGENCE OF MACROECONOMICS
Macroeconomics, as a separate branch of economics, emerged after the
British economist John Maynard Keynes published his celebrated book
The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money in 1936. The
dominant thinking in economics before Keynes was that all the labourers
who are ready to work will find employment and all the factories will be
working at their full capacity. This school of thought is known as the
classical tradition.
Introduction
also a shrewd foreign currency speculator.
2019-20
1.2 CONTEXT OF THE PRESENT BOOK OF MACROECONOMICS
We must remember that the subject under study has a particular
historical context. We shall examine the working of the economy of a
capitalist country in this book. In a capitalist country production
activities are mainly carried out by capitalist enterprises. A typical
capitalist enterprise has one or several entrepreneurs (people who
6 exercise control over major decisions and bear a large part of the risk
associated with the firm/enterprise). They may themselves supply the
Introductory Macroeconomics
capital needed to run the enterprise, or they may borrow the capital. To
carry out production they also need natural resources – a part consumed
in the process of production (e.g. raw materials) and a part fixed (e.g.
plots of land). And they need the most important element of human
labour to carry out production. This we shall refer to as labour. After
producing output with the help of these three factors of production,
namely capital, land and labour, the entrepreneur sells the product in
the market. The money that is earned is called revenue. Part of the
revenue is paid out as rent for the service rendered by land, part of it is
paid to capital as interest and part of it goes to labour as wages. The
rest of the revenue is the earning of the entrepreneurs and it is called
profit. Profits are often used by the producers in the next period to buy
new machinery or to build new factories, so that production can be
expanded. These expenses which raise productive capacity are examples
of investment expenditure.
In short, a capitalist economy can be defined as an economy in
which most of the economic activities have the following characteristics
(a) there is private ownership of means of production (b) production
takes place for selling the output in the market (c) there is sale and
purchase of labour services at a price which is called the wage rate (the
2019-20
labour which is sold and purchased against wages is referred to as
wage labour).
If we apply the above mentioned four criteria to the countries of
the world we would find that capitalist countries have come into
being only during the last three to four hundred years. Moreover,
strictly speaking, even at present, a handful of countries in North
America, Europe and Asia will qualify as capitalist countries. In many
underdeveloped countries production (in agriculture especially) is
carried out by peasant families. Wage labour is seldom used and
most of the labour is performed by the family members themselves.
Production is not solely for the market; a great part of it is consumed
by the family. Neither do many peasant farms experience significant
rise in capital stock over time. In many tribal societies the ownership
of land does not exist; the land may belong to the whole tribe. In
such societies the analysis that we shall present in this book will
not be applicable. It is, however, true that many developing countries
have a significant presence of production units which are organised
according to capitalist principles. The production units will be called
firms in this book. In a firm the entrepreneur (or entrepreneurs) is
at the helm of affairs. She hires wage labour from the market, she
employs the services of capital and land as well. After hiring these
inputs she undertakes the task of production. Her motive for
producing goods and services (referred to as output) is to sell them
in the market and earn profits. In the process she undertakes risks
and uncertainties. For example, she may not get a high enough price
for the goods she is producing; this may lead to fall in the profits
that she earns. It is to be noted that in a capitalist country the
factors of production earn their incomes through the process of
production and sale of the resultant output in the market.
In both the developed and developing countries, apart from the
7
private capitalist sector, there is the institution of State. The role of
the state includes framing laws, enforcing them and delivering justice.
Introduction
The state, in many instances, undertakes production – apart from
imposing taxes and spending money on building public infrastructure,
running schools, colleges, providing health services etc. These
economic functions of the state have to be taken into account when
we want to describe the economy of the country. For convenience we
shall use the term “Government” to denote state.
Apart from the firms and the government, there is another major
sector in an economy which is called the household sector. By a
household we mean a single individual who takes decisions relating
to her own consumption, or a group of individuals for whom decisions
relating to consumption are jointly determined. Households also save
and pay taxes. How do they get the money for these activities? We
must remember that the households consist of people. These people
work in firms as workers and earn wages. They are the ones who
work in the government departments and earn salaries, or they are
the owners of firms and earn profits. Indeed the market in which the
firms sell their products could not have been functioning without the
demand coming from the households. Moreover, they can also earn
rent by leasing land or earn interest by lending capital.
2019-20
N
= ∑ i =1 Ci + Cm. Let Cm denote expenditure on the imports of consumption goods.
Therefore C – Cm denotes that part of aggregate final consumption expenditure
that is spent on the domestic firms. Similarly, let I – I m stand for that part of
aggregate final investment expenditure that is spent on domestic firms, where
I is the value of the aggregate final investment expenditure of the economy and
out of this I m is spent on foreign investment goods. Similarly
G – Gm stands for that part of aggregate final government expenditure that is
spent on the domestic firms, where G is the aggregate expenditure of the
government of the economy and Gm is the part of G which is spent on imports.
N
Therefore, ∑ i =1
Ci ≡ Sum total of final consumption expenditures
N
received by all the firms in the economy ≡ C – Cm; ∑ i =1 I i ≡ Sum total of final
investment expenditures received by all the firms in the economy ≡ I – Im;
N
∑ Gi ≡ Sum total of final government expenditures received by all the firms
i =1
in the economy ≡ G – Gm. Substituting these in equation (2.3) we get
N N
∑ i =1
RVi ≡ C – Cm + I – Im + G – Gm + ∑ i =1
Xi
N
≡C+I+G + ∑ i =1
X i – (Cm + Im + Gm)
≡C+I+G+X– M
N
Here X ≡ ∑ i = 1 X i denotes aggregate expenditure by the foreigners on the
exports of the economy. M ≡ Cm + Im + Gm is the aggregate imports expenditure
incurred by the economy.
We know, GDP ≡ Sum total of all the final expenditure received by the firms
in the economy.
In other words
N
GDP ≡ ∑ i =1
RVi ≡ C + Ι + G + X – M (2.4)
22 Equation (2.4) expresses GDP according to the expenditure method. It may
be noted that out of the five variables on the right hand side, investment
Introductory Macroeconomics
M M M M
GDP ≡ ∑ i =1
Wi + ∑ i =1
Pi + ∑ i =1
In i + ∑ i =1
Ri ≡ W + P + In + R (2.5)
M M M M
Here, ∑ i =1
Wi ≡ W, ∑ i =1
Pi ≡ P, ∑ i =1
In i ≡ In, ∑ i =1
Ri ≡ R.
2019-20
Taking equations (2.2), (2.4) and (2.5) together we get
N
GDP ≡ ∑ i =1
GV Ai ≡ C + I + G + X – M ≡ W + P + In + R (2.6)
It is to be noted that in identity (2.6), I stands for sum total of both planned
and unplanned investments undertaken by the firms.
Since, the identities (2.2), (2.4) and (2.6) are different expressions of the same
variable, namely GDP, we may represent the equivalence by Fig. 2.2.
Now, let us look at
X–M P N
a numerical example åi =1GVA i
to see how all the three G In
methods of estimating I R
GDP give us the same C W
answer. GDP
Example: There are
two firms, A and B.
Suppose A uses no
raw material and Expenditure Income Product
produces cotton worth Method Method Method
Rs. 50. A sells its cotton Fig. 2.2: Diagramtic Representation of GDP by the Three Methods
to firm B, who uses it
to produce cloth. B sells the cloth produced to consumers for Rs. 200.
1. GDP in the phase of production or the value added method:
Recall that value added (VA) = Sales – Intermediate Goods
Thus,
VAA = 50 - 0 = 50
VAB = 200 - 50 = 150
Thus,
GDP = VAA + VAB = 200.
Sales 50 200
Intermediate
0 50
consumption
2019-20
corporations employing a large number of people to single entrepreneur
enterprises. But what happens to these commodities after being produced? Each
producer of commodities intends to sell her output. So from the smallest items
like pins or buttons to the largest ones like aeroplanes, automobiles, giant
machinery or any saleable service like that of the doctor, the lawyer or the financial
consultant–the goods and services produced are to be sold to the consumers.
The consumer may, in turn, be an individual or an enterprise and the good or
service purchased by that entity might be for final use or for use in further
production. When it is used in further production it often loses its characteristic
as that specific good and is transformed through a productive process into
another good. Thus a farmer producing cotton sells it to a spinning mill where
the raw cotton undergoes transformation to yarn; the yarn is, in turn, sold to a
textile mill where, through the productive process, it is transformed into cloth;
the cloth is, in turn, transformed through another productive process into an
article of clothing which is then ready to be sold finally to the consumers for
final use. Such an item that is meant for final use and will not pass through any
more stages of production or transformations is called a final good.
Why do we call this a final good? Because once it has been sold it passes out
of the active economic flow. It will not undergo any further transformation at the
hands of any producer. It may, however, undergo transformation by the action
of the ultimate purchaser. In fact many such final goods are transformed during
their consumption. Thus the tea leaves purchased by the consumer are not
consumed in that form – they are used to make drinkable tea, which is consumed.
Similarly most of the items that enter our kitchen are transformed through the
process of cooking. But cooking at home is not an economic activity, even though
the product involved undergoes transformation. Home cooked food is not sold
to the market. However, if the same cooking or tea brewing was done in a
restaurant where the cooked product would be sold to customers, then the
same items, such as tea leaves, would cease to be final goods and would be
10 counted as inputs to which economic value addition can take place. Thus it is
not in the nature of the good but in the economic nature of its use that a good
Introductory Macroeconomics
2019-20
We may note here that some commodities like television sets, automobiles
or home computers, although they are for ultimate consumption, have one
characteristic in common with capital goods – they are also durable. That is,
they are not extinguished by immediate or even short period consumption;
they have a relatively long life as compared to articles such as food or even
clothing. They also undergo wear and tear with gradual use and often need
repairs and replacements of parts, i.e., like machines they also need to be
preserved, maintained and renewed. That is why we call these goods
consumer durables.
Thus if we consider all the final goods and services produced in an economy
in a given period of time they are either in the form of consumption goods (both
durable and non-durable) or capital goods. As final goods they do not undergo
any further transformation in the economic process.
Of the total production taking place in the economy a large number of
products don’t end up in final consumption and are not capital goods either.
Such goods may be used by other producers as material inputs. Examples are
steel sheets used for making automobiles and copper used for making utensils.
These are intermediate goods, mostly used as raw material or inputs for
production of other commodities. These are not final goods.
Now, to have a comprehensive idea of the total flow of production in the
economy, we need to have a quantitative measure of the aggregate level of final
goods produced in the economy. However, in order to get a quantitative
assessment – a measure of the total final goods and services produced in the
economy – it is obvious that we need a common measuring rod. We cannot
add metres of cloth produced to tonnes of rice or number of automobiles or
machines. Our common measuring rod is money. Since each of these
commodities is produced for sale, the sum total of the monetary value of
these diverse commodities gives us a measure of final output. But why are
we to measure final goods only? Surely intermediate goods are crucial inputs
to any production process and a significant part of our manpower and capital
11
stock are engaged in production of these goods. However, since we are dealing
with value of output, we should realise that the value of the final goods already
2019-20
In contrast, capital goods or consumer durables once produced do not wear
out or get consumed in a delineated time period. In fact capital goods continue
to serve us through different cycles of production. The buildings or machines in
a factory are there irrespective of the specific time period. There can be addition
to, or deduction from, these if a new machine is added or a machine falls in
disuse and is not replaced. These are called stocks. Stocks are defined at a
particular point of time. However we can measure a change in stock over a
specific period of time like how many machines were added this year. Such
changes in stocks are thus flows, which can be measured over specific time
periods. A particular machine can be part of the capital stock for many years
(unless it wears out); but that machine can be part of the flow of new machines
added to the capital stock only for a single year when it was initially installed.
To further understand the difference between stock variables and flow
variables, let us take the following example. Suppose a tank is being filled with
water coming from a tap. The amount of water which is flowing into the tank
from the tap per minute is a flow. But how much water there is in the tank at a
particular point of time is a stock concept.
To come back to our discussion on the measure of final output, that part
of our final output that comprises of capital goods constitutes gross
investment of an economy1. These may be machines, tools and implements;
buildings, office spaces, storehouses or infrastructure like roads, bridges,
airports or jetties. But all the capital goods produced in a year do not
constitute an addition to the capital stock already existing. A significant part
of current output of capital goods goes in maintaining or replacing part of
the existing stock of capital goods. This is because the already existing capital
stock suffers wear and tear and needs maintenance and replacement. A part
of the capital goods produced this year goes for replacement of existing capital
goods and is not an addition to the stock of capital goods already existing
and its value needs to be subtracted from gross investment for arriving at the
measure for net investment. This deletion, which is made from the value of
12 gross investment in order to accommodate regular wear and tear of capital,
is called depreciation.
Introductory Macroeconomics
1
This is how economists define investment. This must not be confused with the commonplace
notion of investment which implies using money to buy physical or financial assets. Thus use of the
term investment to denote purchase of shares or property or even having an insurance policy has
nothing to do with how economists define investment. Investment for us is always capital formation,
a gross or net addition to capital stock.
2019-20
capital good.2 In other words it is the cost of the good divided by number of years
of its useful life.3
Notice here that depreciation is an accounting concept. No real expenditure
may have actually been incurred each year yet depreciation is annually
accounted for. In an economy with thousands of enterprises with widely varying
periods of life of their equipment, in any particular year, some enterprises are
actually making the bulk replacement spending. Thus, we can realistically
assume that there will be a steady flow of actual replacement spending which
will more or less match the amount of annual depreciation being accounted
for in that economy.
Now if we go back to our discussion of total final output produced in an
economy, we see that there is output of consumer goods and services and
output of capital goods. The consumer goods sustain the consumption of
the entire population of the economy. Purchase of consumer goods depends
on the capacity of the people to spend on these goods which, in turn, depends
on their income. The other part of the final goods, the capital goods, are
purchased by business enterprises. They are used either for maintenance of
the capital stock because there are wear and tear of it, or they are used for
addition to their capital stock. In a specific time period, say in a year, thetotal
production of final goods can thus be either in the form of consumption or
investment. This implies that there is a trade-off. If an economy, produces
more of consumer goods, it is producing less of capital goods and vice-
versa.
It is generally observed that more sophisticated and heavy capital goods
raise the ability of a labourer to produce goods. The traditional weaver would
take months to weave a sari but with modern machinery thousands of pieces of
clothing are produced in a day. Decades were taken to construct the great
historical monuments like the Pyramids or the Taj Mahal but with modern
construction machinery one can build a skyscraper in a few years. More
production of newer varities of capital goods therefore would help in the greater
13
production of consumer goods.
But aren’t we contradicting ourselves? Earlier we have seen how, of the total
2
Depreciation does not take into account unexpected or sudden destruction or disuse of
capital as can happen with accidents, natural calamities or other such extraneous circumstances.
3
We are making a rather simple assumption here that there is a constant rate of depreciation
based on the original value of the asset. There can be other methods to calculate depreciation in
actual practice.
2019-20
Thus the economic cycle not only rolls on, higher production of capital goods
enables the economy to expand. It is possible to find another view of the circular
flow in the discussion we have made so far.
Since we are dealing with all goods and services that are produced for the
market, the crucial factor enabling such sale is demand for such products backed
by purchasing power. One must have the necessary ability to purchase
commodities. Otherwise one’s need for commodities does not get recognised by
the market.
We have already discussed above that one’s ability to buy commodities comes
from the income one earns as labourer (earning wages), or as entrepreneur
(earning profits), or as landlord (earning rents), or as owner of capital (earning
interests). In short, the incomes that people earn as owners of factors of production
are used by them to meet their demand for goods and services.
So we can see a circular flow here which is facilitated through the market.
Simply put, the firms’ demand for factors of production to run the production
process creates payments to the public. In turn, the public’s demand for goods
and services creates payments to the firms and enables the sale of the products
they produce.
So the social act of consumption and production are intricately linked and,
in fact, there is a circular causation here. The process of production in an economy
generates factor payments for those involved in production and generates goods
and services as the outcome of the production process. The incomes so generated
create the capacity to purchase the final consumption goods and thus enable
their sale by the business enterprises, the basic object of their production. The
capital goods which are also generated in the production process also enable
their producers to earn income – wages, profits etc. in a similar manner. The
capital goods add to, or maintain, the capital stock of an economy and thus
make production of other commodities possible.
2019-20
entire income of the economy,
therefore, comes back to the
producers in the form of sales
revenue. There is no leakage
from the system – there is no
difference between the amount
that the firms had distributed in
the form of factor payments
(which is the sum total of
remunerations earned by the
four factors of production) and
the aggregate consumption
expenditure that they receive as
sales revenue.
In the next period the firms
will once again produce goods Fig. 2.1: Circular Flow of Income in a Simple Economy
and services and pay
remunerations to the factors of production. These remunerations will once
again be used to buy the goods and services. Hence year after year we can
imagine the aggregate income of the economy going through the two sectors,
firms and households, in a circular way. This is represented in Fig. 2.1. When
the income is being spent on the goods and services produced by the firms, it
takes the form of aggregate expenditure received by the firms. Since the value
of expenditure must be equal to the value of goods and services, we can
equivalently measure the aggregate income by “calculating the aggregate value
of goods and services produced by the firms”. When the aggregate revenue
received by the firms is paid out to the factors of production it takes the form
of aggregate income.
In Fig. 2.1, the uppermost arrow, going from the households to the firms,
represents the spending the households undertake to buy goods and services 15
produced by the firms. The second arrow going from the firms to the households
2019-20
the firms, it will be called product method. At C, measuring the sum total of all
factor payments will be called income method.
Observe that the aggregate spending of the economy must be equal to the
aggregate income earned by the factors of production (the flows are equal at A
and C). Now let us suppose that at a particular period of time the households
decide to spend more on the goods and services produced by the firms. For the
time being let us ignore the question where they would find the money to finance
that extra spending since they are already spending all of their income (they
may have borrowed the money to finance the additional spending). Now if they
spend more on the goods and services, the firms will produce more goods and
services to meet this extra demand. Since they will produce more, the firms
must also pay the factors of production extra remunerations. How much extra
amount of money will the firms pay? The additional factor payments must be
equal to the value of the additional goods and services that are being produced.
Thus the households will eventually get the extra earnings required to support
the initial additional spending that they had undertaken. In other words, the
households can decide to spend more – spend beyond their means. And in the
end their income will rise exactly by the amount which is necessary to carry out
the extra spending. Putting it differently, an economy may decide to spend more
than the present level of income. But by doing so, its income will eventually rise
to a level consistent with the higher spending level. This may seem a little
paradoxical at first. But since income is moving in a circular fashion, it is not
difficult to figure out that a rise in the flow at one point must eventually lead to
a rise in the flow at all levels. This is one more example of how the functioning of
a single economic agent (say, a household) may differ from the functioning of
the economy as a whole. In the former the spending gets restricted by the
individual income of a household. It can never happen that a single worker
decides to spend more and this leads to an equivalent rise in her income. We
shall spend more time on how higher aggregate spending leads to change in
aggregate income in a later chapter.
16 The above mentioned sketchy illustration of an economy is admittedly a
simplified one. Such a story which describes the functioning of an imaginary
Introductory Macroeconomics
2019-20
2.2.1 The Product or Value Added Method
In product method we calculate the aggregate annual value of goods and services
produced (if a year is the unit of time). How to go about doing this? Do we add
up the value of all goods and services produced by all the firms in an economy?
The following example will help us to understand.
Let us suppose that there are only two kinds of producers in the economy.
They are the wheat producers (or the farmers) and the bread makers (the bakers).
The wheat producers grow wheat and they do not need any input other than
human labour. They sell a part of the wheat to the bakers. The bakers do not
need any other raw materials besides wheat to produce bread. Let us suppose
that in a year the total value of wheat that the farmers have produced is Rs 100.
Out of this they have sold Rs 50 worth of wheat to the bakers. The bakers have
used this amount of wheat completely during the year and have produced
Rs 200 worth of bread. What is the value of total production in the economy? If
we follow the simple way of aggregating the values of production of the sectors,
we would add Rs 200 (value of production of the bakers) to Rs 100 (value of
production of farmers). The result will be Rs 300.
A little reflection will tell us that the value of aggregate production is not Rs
300. The farmers had produced Rs 100 worth of wheat for which it did not need
assistance of any inputs. Therefore the entire Rs 100 is rightfully the contribution
of the farmers. But the same is not true for the bakers. The bakers had to buy Rs
50 worth of wheat to produce their bread. The Rs 200 worth of bread that they
have produced is not entirely their own contribution. To calculate the net
contribution of the bakers, we need to subtract the value of the wheat that they
have bought from the farmers. If we do not do this we shall commit the mistake
of ‘double counting’. This is because Rs 50 worth of wheat will be counted twice.
First it will be counted as part of the output produced by the farmers. Second
time, it will be counted as the imputed value of wheat in the bread produced by
the bakers.
Therefore, the net contribution made by the bakers is, Rs 200 – Rs 50 = Rs 150. 17
Hence, aggregate value of goods produced by this simple economy is Rs 100 (net
2019-20
Here all the variables are expressed in terms of money. We can think of the
market prices of the goods being used to evaluate the different variables listed
here. And we can introduce more players in the chain of production in the
example and make it more realistic and complicated. For example, the farmer
may be using fertilisers or pesticides to produce wheat. The value of these inputs
will have to be deducted from the value of output of wheat. Or the bakers may
be selling the bread to a restaurant whose value added will have to be calculated
by subtracting the value of intermediate goods (bread in this case).
We have already introduced the concept of depreciation, which is also known
as consumption of fixed capital. Since the capital which is used to carry out
production undergoes wear and tear, the producer has to undertake replacement
investments to keep the value of capital constant. The replacement investment
is same as depreciation of capital. If we include depreciation in value added
then the measure of value added that we obtain is called Gross Value Added. If
we deduct the value of depreciation from gross value added we obtain Net Value
Added. Unlike gross value added, net value added does not include wear and
tear that capital has undergone. For example, let us say a firm produces Rs 100
worth of goods per year, Rs 20 is the value of intermediate goods used by it
during the year and Rs 10 is the value of capital consumption. The gross value
added of the firm will be, Rs 100 – Rs 20 = Rs 80 per year. The net value added
will be, Rs 100 – Rs 20 – Rs 10 = Rs 70 per year.
It is to be noted that while calculating the value added we are taking the
value of production of firm. But a firm may be unable to sell all of its produce. In
such a case it will have some unsold stock at the end of the year. Conversely, it
may so happen that a firm had some initial unsold stock to begin with. During
the year that follows it has produced very little. But it has met the demand in the
market by selling from the stock it had at the beginning of the year. How shall we
treat these stocks which a firm may intentionally or unintentionally carry with
itself? Also, let us remember that a firm buys raw materials from other firms. The
part of raw material which gets used up is categorised as an intermediate good.
18 What happens to the part which does not get used up?
In economics, the stock of unsold finished goods, or semi-finished goods,
Introductory Macroeconomics
or raw materials which a firm carries from one year to the next is called
inventory. Inventory is a stock variable. It may have a value at the beginning
of the year; it may have a higher value at the end of the year. In such a case
inventories have increased (or accumulated). If the value of inventories is less
at the end of the year compared to the beginning of the year, inventories have
decreased (decumulated). We can therefore infer that the change of inventories
of a firm during a year ≡ production of the firm during the year – sale of the
firm during the year.
The sign ‘≡’ stands for identity. Unlike equality (‘=’), an identity always holds
irrespective of what variables we have on the left hand and right hand sides of it.
For example, we can write 2 + 2 ≡ 4, because this is always true. But we must
write 2 × x = 4. This is because two times x equals to 4 for a particular value of
x, (namely when x = 2) and not always. We cannot write 2 × x ≡ 4.
Observe that since production of the firm ≡ value added + intermediate
goods used by the firm, we get, change of inventories of a firm during a year
≡ value added + intermediate goods used by the firm – sale of the firm during
a year.
For example, let us suppose that a firm had an unsold stock worth of Rs
100 at the beginning of a year. During the year it had produced Rs 1,000
2019-20
worth of goods and managed to sell Rs 800 worth of goods. Therefore, the
Rs 200 is the difference between production and sales. This Rs 200 worth of
goods is the change in inventories. This will add to the Rs 100 worth of
inventories the firm started with. Hence the inventories at the end of the year
is, Rs 100 + Rs 200 = Rs 300. Notice that change in inventories takes place
over a period of time. Therefore it is a flow variable.
Inventories are treated as capital. Addition to the stock of capital of a firm
is known as investment. Therefore, change in the inventory of a firm is treated
as investment. There can be three major categories of investment. First is the
rise in the value of inventories of a firm over a year which is treated as
investment expenditure undertaken by the firm. The second category of
investment is the fixed business investment, which is defined as the addition
to the machinery, factory buildings and equipment employed by the firms.
The last category of investment is the residential investment, which refers to
the addition of housing facilities.
Change in inventories may be planned or unplanned. In case of an unexpected
fall in sales, the firm will have unsold stock of goods which it had not anticipated.
Hence there will be unplanned accumulation of inventories. In the opposite
case where there is unexpected rise in the sales there will be unplanned
decumulation of inventories.
This can be illustrated with the help of the following example. Suppose a
firm produces shirts. It starts the year with an inventory of 100 shirts. During
the coming year it expects to sell 1,000 shirts. Hence, it produces 1,000
shirts, expecting to keep an inventory of 100 at the end of the year. However,
during the year, the sales of shirts turn out to be unexpectedly low. The firm
is able to sell only 600 shirts. This means that the firm is left with 400 unsold
shirts. The firm ends the year with 400 + 100 = 500 shirts. The unexpected
rise of inventories by 400 will be an example of unplanned accumulation of
inventories. If, on the other hand, the sales had been more than 1,000 we 19
would have unplanned decumulation of inventories. For example, if the sales
2019-20
later. As a result, the injection/absorption of the money is of permanent nature.
However, there is another type of operation in which when the central bank buys
the security, this agreement of purchase also has specification about date and
price of resale of this security. This type of agreement is called a repurchase
agreement or repo. The interest rate at which the money is lent in this way is
called the repo rate. Similarly, instead of outright sale of securities the central
bank may sell the securities through an agreement which has a specification
about the date and price at which it will be repurchased. This type of agreement
is called a reverse repurchase agreement or reverse repo. The rate at which
the money is withdrawn in this manner is called the reverse repo rate. The Reserve
Bank of India conducts repo and reverse repo operations at various maturities:
overnight, 7-day, 14- day, etc. This type of operations have now become the
main tool of monetary policy of the Reserve Bank of India.
The RBI can influence money supply by changing the rate at which it gives
loans to the commercial banks. This rate is called the Bank Rate in India. By
increasing the bank rate, loans taken by commercial banks become more
expensive; this reduces the reserves held by the commercial bank and hence
decreases money supply. A fall in the bank rate can increase the money supply.
2019-20
consumption for the individual i is ci, aggregate consumption will be
2019-20
where Y is the real GDP and P is the general price level or the GDP
deflator. The above equation tells us that transaction demand for money is
positively related to the real income of an economy and also to its average
price level.
The Speculative Motive
An individual may hold her wealth in the form of landed property, bullion,
bonds, money etc. For simplicity, let us club all forms of assets other than
money together into a single category called ‘bonds’. Typically, bonds are
papers bearing the promise of a future stream of monetary returns over a
certain period of time. These papers are issued by governments or firms for
borrowing money from the public and they are tradable in the market. Consider
the following two-period bond. A firm wishes to raise a loan of Rs 100 from the
public. It issues a bond that assures Rs 10 at the end of the first year and Rs
10 plus the principal of Rs 100 at the end of the second year. Such a bond is
said to have a face value of Rs 100, a maturity period of two years and a
coupon rate of 10 per cent. Assume that the rate of interest prevailing in
your savings bank account is equal to 5 per cent. Naturally you would like to
compare the earning from this bond with the interest earning of your savings
bank account. The exact question that you would ask is as follows: How
much money, if kept in my savings bank account, will generate Rs 10 at the
end of one year? Let this amount be X. Therefore
5
X (1 + ) = 10
100
In other words,
X= 10
(1 + 5 )
100
This amount, Rs X, is called the present value of Rs 10 discounted at
the market rate of interest. Similarly, let Y be the amount of money which
if kept in the savings bank account will generate Rs 110 at the end of two 45
years. Thus, the present value of the stream of returns from the bond should
2019-20
Taking equations (2.2), (2.4) and (2.5) together we get
N
GDP ≡ ∑ i =1
GV Ai ≡ C + I + G + X – M ≡ W + P + In + R (2.6)
It is to be noted that in identity (2.6), I stands for sum total of both planned
and unplanned investments undertaken by the firms.
Since, the identities (2.2), (2.4) and (2.6) are different expressions of the same
variable, namely GDP, we may represent the equivalence by Fig. 2.2.
Now, let us look at
X–M P N
a numerical example åi =1GVA i
to see how all the three G In
methods of estimating I R
GDP give us the same C W
answer. GDP
Example: There are
two firms, A and B.
Suppose A uses no
raw material and Expenditure Income Product
produces cotton worth Method Method Method
Rs. 50. A sells its cotton Fig. 2.2: Diagramtic Representation of GDP by the Three Methods
to firm B, who uses it
to produce cloth. B sells the cloth produced to consumers for Rs. 200.
1. GDP in the phase of production or the value added method:
Recall that value added (VA) = Sales – Intermediate Goods
Thus,
VAA = 50 - 0 = 50
VAB = 200 - 50 = 150
Thus,
GDP = VAA + VAB = 200.
Sales 50 200
Intermediate
0 50
consumption
2019-20
Table 2.3: Distributions of factor incomes of firms A and B
Firm A Firm B
Wages 20 60
Profits 30 90
Recall that GDP by income method = sum total of factor incomes, which is
equal to total wages received (workers of A and B) and total profits earned (by A
and B), which is equal4 to 80 + 120 = 200.
basic prices lie in between: they include the production taxes (less production
subsidies) but not product taxes (less product subsidies). Therefore in order to
arrive at market prices we have to add product taxes (less product subsidies) to
the basic prices.
As stated above, now the CSO releases GVA at basic prices. Thus, it includes
the net production taxes but not net product taxes. In order to arrive at the GDP
(at market prices) we need to add net product taxes to GVA at basic prices.
Thus,
2019-20
2.3 SOME MACROECONOMIC IDENTITIES
Gross Domestic Product measures the aggregate production of final goods and
services taking place within the domestic economy during a year. But the whole
of it may not accrue to the citizens of the country. For example, a citizen of India
working in Saudi Arabia may be earning her wage and it will be included in the
Saudi Arabian GDP. But legally speaking, she is an Indian. Is there a way to take
into account the earnings made by Indians abroad or by the factors of production
owned by Indians? When we try to do this, in order to maintain symmetry, we
must deduct the earnings of the foreigners who are working within our domestic
economy, or the payments to the factors of production owned by the foreigners.
For example, the profits earned by the Korean-owned Hyundai car factory will
have to be subtracted
from the GDP of India.
The macroeconomic
variable which takes
into account such
additions and
subtractions is
known as Gross
National Product
The foreigners have a share in your domestic economy.
(GNP). It is, therefore,
Discuss this in the classroom.
defined as follows
GNP ≡ GDP + Factor income earned by the domestic factors of production
employed in the rest of the world – Factor income earned by the factors of
production of the rest of the world employed in the domestic economy
Hence, GNP ≡ GDP + Net factor income from abroad
(Net factor income from abroad = Factor income earned by the domestic factors
of production employed in the rest of the world – Factor income earned by the
factors of production of the rest of the world employed in the domestic economy).
We have already noted that a part of the capital gets consumed during the 25
year due to wear and tear. This wear and tear is called depreciation. Naturally,
2019-20
We can further subdivide the National Income into smaller categories. Let us try
to find the expression for the part of NI which is received by households. We shall
call this Personal Income (PI). First, let us note that out of NI, which is earned by
the firms and government enterprises, a part of profit is not distributed among the
factors of production. This is called Undistributed Profits (UP). We have to deduct
UP from NI to arrive at PI, since UP does not accrue to the households. Similarly,
Corporate Tax, which is imposed on the earnings made by the firms, will also have
to be deducted from the NI, since it does not accrue to the households. On the other
hand, the households do receive interest payments from private firms or the
government on past loans advanced by them. And households may have to pay
interests to the firms and the government as well, in case they had borrowed money
from either. So, we have to deduct the net interests paid by the households to the
firms and government. The households receive transfer payments from government
and firms (pensions, scholarship, prizes, for example) which have to be added to
calculate the Personal Income of the households.
Thus, Personal Income (PI) ≡ NI – Undistributed profits – Net interest
payments made by households – Corporate tax + Transfer payments to
the households from the government and firms.
However, even PI is not the income over which the households have complete
say. They have to pay taxes from PI. If we deduct the Personal Tax Payments
(income tax, for example) and Non-tax Payments (such as fines) from PI, we
obtain what is known as the Personal Disposable Income. Thus
Personal Disposable Income (PDI ) ≡ PI – Personal tax payments – Non-tax
payments.
Personal Disposable Income is the part of the aggregate income which
belongs to the households. They may decide to consume a part of it, and
save the rest. In Fig. 2.3 we present a diagrammatic representation of the
relations between these major macroeconomic variables.
NFIA D
26
GDP GNP NNP ID - Sub
Introductory Macroeconomics
(at
Market NI UP + NIH
Price) (NNP at + CT –
FC) TrH
PI PTP +
NP
PDI
Fig. 2.3: Diagrammatic representation of the subcategories of aggregate income. NFIA: Net
Factor Income from Abroad, D: Depreciation, ID: Indirect Taxes, Sub: Subsidies, UP: Undistributed
Profits, NIH: Net Interest Payments by Households, CT: Corporate Taxes, TrH: Transfers recived
by Households, PTP: Personal Tax Payments, NP: Non-Tax Payments.
2019-20
what is the maximum amount of goods and services the domestic economy
has at its disposal. Current transfers from the rest of the world include
items such as gifts, aids, etc.
• Private Income = Factor income from net domestic product accruing to
the private sector + National debt interest + Net factor income from abroad
+ Current transfers from government + Other net transfers from the rest of
the world.
5
Following the System of National Accounts 2008 (SNA2008) given by the United Nations in
partnership with some other agencies, countries are now switching to new aggregates. India shifted
to these aggregates a few years back.
2019-20
5. Gross National • GNPMP is the value of all the final goods
and services that are produced by the
Product at Market
normal residents of India and is
Prices (GNPMP) measured at the market prices, in a year.
• GNP refers to all the economic output
produced by a nation’s normal residents,
whether they are located within the
national boundary or abroad.
• Everything is valued at the market prices.
GNPMP = GDPMP + NFIA
11. GVA at factor cost • GVA at basic prices - Net Production Taxes
2019-20
2.4 NOMINAL AND REAL GDP
One implicit assumption in all this discussion is that the prices of goods and
services do not change during the period of our study. If prices change, then
there may be difficulties in comparing GDPs. If we measure the GDP of a country
in two consecutive years and see that the figure for GDP of the latter year is
twice that of the previous year, we may conclude that the volume of production
of the country has doubled. But it is possible that only prices of all goods and
services have doubled between the two years whereas the production has
remained constant.
Therefore, in order to compare the GDP figures (and other macroeconomic
variables) of different countries or to compare the GDP figures of the same country
at different points of time, we cannot rely on GDPs evaluated at current market
prices. For comparison we take the help of real GDP. Real GDP is calculated in
a way such that the goods and services are evaluated at some constant set of
prices (or constant prices). Since these prices remain fixed, if the Real GDP
changes we can be sure that it is the volume of production which is undergoing
changes. Nominal GDP, on the other hand, is simply the value of GDP at the
current prevailing prices. For example, suppose a country only produces bread.
In the year 2000 it had produced 100 units of bread, price was Rs 10 per bread.
GDP at current price was Rs 1,000. In 2001 the same country produced 110
units of bread at price Rs 15 per bread. Therefore nominal GDP in 2001 was Rs
1,650 (=110 × Rs 15). Real GDP in 2001 calculated at the price of the year 2000
(2000 will be called the base year) will be 110 × Rs 10 = Rs 1,100.
Notice that the ratio of nominal GDP to real GDP gives us an idea of how the
prices have moved from the base year (the year whose prices are being used to
calculate the real GDP) to the current year. In the calculation of real and nominal
GDP of the current year, the volume of production is fixed. Therefore, if these
measures differ it is only due to change in the price level between the base year
and the current year. The ratio of nominal to real GDP is a well known index of
prices. This is called GDP Deflator. Thus if GDP stands for nominal GDP and 29
GDP
2019-20
Where C is Autonomous expenditure and c is the marginal propensity to
consume.
How can this relation be
Y
shown as a graph? To answer
this question we will need to recall
the “intercept form of the linear Y=a+bX
equation”,
Y = a + bX
θ
Here, the variables are X and
Y and there is a linear relation
between them. a and b are
constants. This equation is
a
{ X
Fig. 4.1
depicted in figure 4.1. The
constant ‘a’ is shown as the
“intercept” on the Y axis, i.e, the Intercept form of the linear equation.
value of Y when X is zero. The
constant ‘b’ is the slope of the line
i.e. tangent θ = b.
C
Consumption Function –
Graphical Representation
C=C+cY
Using the same logic, the
consumption function can be
shown as follows:
Consumption function,
α
2019-20
compared to 2000, the GDP of the country in 2001 was higher by Rs10. But
this has happened when 90 per cent of people of the country have seen a drop in
their real income by 10 per cent (from Rs 10 to Rs 9), whereas only 10 per cent
have benefited by a rise in their income by 100 per cent (from Rs 10 to Rs 20). 90
per cent of the people are worse off though the GDP of the country has gone up.
If we relate welfare improvement in the country to the percentage of people who
are better off, then surely GDP is not a good index.
2. Non-monetary exchanges: Many activities in an economy are not evaluated
in monetary terms. For example, the domestic services women perform at
home are not paid for. The
exchanges which take place in the
informal sector without the help
of money are called barter
exchanges. In barter exchanges,
goods (or services) are directly
exchanged against each other.
But since money is not being used
here, these exchanges are not
registered as part of economic
activity. In developing countries,
where many remote regions are
underdeveloped, these kinds of
exchanges do take place, but they
are generally not counted in the
GDPs of these countries. This is
a case of underestimation of GDP.
Hence, GDP calculated in the
standard manner may not give us How uniform is the distribution of GDP? It still
a clear indication of the seems that a majority of the people are poor and
productive activity and well-being a few benefited.
31
of a country.
3. Externalities: Externalities refer to the benefits (or harms) a firm or an
2019-20
At a very fundamental level, the macroeconomy (it refers to the economy that we
Summary
study in macroeconomics) can be seen as working in a circular way. The firms
employ inputs supplied by households and produce goods and services to be sold to
households. Households get the remuneration from the firms for the services
rendered by them and buy goods and services produced by the firms. So we can
calculate the aggregate value of goods and services produced in the economy by
any of the three methods (a) measuring the aggregate value of factor payments
(income method) (b) measuring the aggregate value of goods and services produced
by the firms (product method) (c) measuring the aggregate value of spending received
by the firms (expenditure method). In the product method, to avoid double counting,
we need to deduct the value of intermediate goods and take into account only the
aggregate value of final goods and services. We derive the formulae for calculating
the aggregate income of an economy by each of these methods. We also take note
that goods can also be bought for making investments and these add to the productive
capacity of the investing firms. There may be different categories of aggregate income
depending on whom these are accruing to. We have pointed out the difference between
GDP, GNP, NNP at market price, NNP at factor cost, PI and PDI. Since prices of goods
and services may vary, we have discussed how to calculate the three important
price indices (GDP deflator, CPI, WPI). Finally we have noted that it may be incorrect
to treat GDP as an index of the welfare of the country.
Key Concepts
National Income
Expenditure method of calculating Income method of calculating
National Income National Income
Macroeconomic model Input
Value added Inventories
Planned change in inventories Unplanned change in inventories
Gross Domestic Product (GDP) Net Domestic Product (NDP)
Gross National Product (GNP) Net National Product (NNP)
(at market price)
NNP (at factor cost) or Undistributed profits
National Income (NI)
Net interest payments made Corporate tax
by households
Transfer payments to the Personal Income (PI)
households from the government
and firms
Personal tax payments Non-tax payments
Personal Disposable Income (PDI) National Disposable Income
2019-20
Private Income Nominal GDP
Real GDP Base year
GDP Deflator Consumer Price Index (CPI)
Wholesale Price Index (WPI) Externalities
1. What are the four factors of production and what are the remunerations to
? each of these called?
2. Why should the aggregate final expenditure of an economy be equal to the
Exercises
?
pays sales tax worth Rs 30, takes home Rs 200 and retains Rs 220 for
improvement and buying of new equipment. He further pays Rs 20 as income
tax from his income. Based on this information, complete Raju’s contribution
to the following measures of income (a) Gross Domestic Product (b) NNP
2019-20
?
at market price (c) NNP at factor cost (d) Personal income (e) Personal
disposable income.
11. The value of the nominal GNP of an economy was Rs 2,500 crores in a particular
year. The value of GNP of that country during the same year, evaluated at the
prices of same base year, was Rs 3,000 crores. Calculate the value of the GNP
deflator of the year in percentage terms. Has the price level risen between the
base year and the year under consideration?
12. Write down some of the limitations of using GDP as an index of welfare of a
country.
Suggested Readings
1. Bhaduri, A., 1990. Macroeconomics: The Dynamics of Commodity Production, pages
1 – 27, Macmillan India Limited, New Delhi.
2. Branson, W. H., 1992. Macroeconomic Theory and Policy, (third edition), pages
15 – 34, Harper Collins Publishers India Pvt Ltd., New Delhi.
3. Dornbusch, R and S. Fischer. 1988. Macroeconomics, (fourth edition) pages 29–
62, McGraw Hill, Paris.
4. Mankiw, N. G., 2000. Macroeconomics, (fourth edition) pages 15–76, Macmillan
Worth Publishers, New York.
Appendix 2.1
Table 2.5: GVA and GDP for India at constant (2011-12) prices6
34 PE (Provisional Estimates)
S.No. Item 2017–18
Introductory Macroeconomics
6
These are provisional estimates released by the CSO in 2018.
2019-20
Appendix 2.2
(First Advance
S.No. Item Estimates)
2017–18
(Rs. Lakh
Crore)
5. Valuables 2.54
8. Discrepancies 2
2019-20
Money and Banking
2019-20
money itself with respect to other commodities. In the above example, a rupee is
worth 1 ÷ 2 = 0.5 pencil or 1 ÷ 10 = 0.1 pen. Thus if prices of all commodities
increase in terms of money i.e., there is a general increase in the price level, the
value of money in terms of any commodity must have decreased – in the sense
that a unit of money can now purchase less of any commodity. We call it a
deterioration in the purchasing power of money.
A barter system has other deficiencies. It is difficult to carry forward one’s
wealth under the barter system. Suppose you have an endowment of rice which
you do not wish to consume today entirely. You may regard this stock of surplus
rice as an asset which you may wish to consume, or even sell off, for acquiring
other commodities at some future date. But rice is a perishable item and cannot
be stored beyond a certain period. Also, holding the stock of rice requires a lot of
space. You may have to spend considerable time and resources looking for people
with a demand for rice when you wish to exchange your stock for buying other
commodities. This problem can be solved if you sell your rice for money. Money
is not perishable and its storage costs are also considerably lower. It is also
acceptable to anyone at any point of time. Thus money can act as a store of
value for individuals. Wealth can be stored in the form of money for future use.
However, to perform this function well, the value of money must be sufficiently
stable. A rising price level may erode the purchasing power of money. It may be
noted that any asset other than money can also act as a store of value, e.g. gold,
landed property, houses or even bonds (to be introduced shortly). However,
they may not be easily convertible to other commodities and do not have universal
acceptability.
Some countries have made an attempt to move towards an economy which
use less of cash and more of digital transactions. A cashless society describes an
economic state whereby financial transactions are not connected with money in
the form of physical bank notes or coins but rather through the transfer of digital
information (usually an electronic representation of money) between the
transacting parties. In India government has been consistently investing in various
reforms for greater financial inclusion. During the last few years’ initiatives such 37
as Jan Dhan accounts, Aadhar enabled payment systems, e –Wallets, National
2019-20
3.2.2. Supply of Money
In a modern economy, money comprises cash and bank deposits.
Depending on what types of bank deposits are being included, there are
many measures of money1. These are created by a system comprising two types
of institutions: central bank of the economy and the commercial banking system.
Central bank
Central Bank is a very important institution in a modern economy.
Almost every country has one central bank. India got its central bank in
1935. Its name is the ‘Reserve Bank of India’. Central bank has several
important functions. It issues the currency of the country. It controls
money supply of the country through various methods, like bank rate, open
market operations and variations in reserve ratios. It acts as a banker to the
government. It is the custodian of the foreign exchange reserves of the economy.
It also acts as a bank to the banking system, which is discussed in detail later.
From the point of view of money supply, we need to focus on its function of
issuing currency. This currency issued by the central bank can be held by the
public or by the commercial banks, and is called the ‘high-powered money’ or
‘reserve money’ or ‘monetary base’ as it acts as a basis for credit creation.
Commercial Banks
Commercial banks are the other type of institutions which are a part of
the money-creating system of the economy. In the following section we look at
the commercial banking system in detail. They accept deposits from the public
and lend out part of these funds to those who want to borrow. The interest rate
paid by the banks to depositors is lower than the rate charged from the borrowers.
This difference between these two types of interest rates, called the ‘spread’ is the
profit appropriated by the bank.
The process of deposit and loan (credit) creation by banks is explained below.
In order to understand this process, let us discuss a story.
38 Once there was a goldsmith named Lala in a village. In this village,
people used gold and other precious metals in order to buy goods and
Introductory Macroeconomics
1
See the box on the measures of money supply at the end of the chapter.
2019-20
have risen to 125 kgs now. It seems that Lala has created money out of thin air!
The modern banking system works precisely the way Lala behaves in this example.
Commercial banks mediate between individuals or firms with excess funds
and lend to those who need funds. People with excess funds can keep their funds
in the form of deposits in banks and those who need funds, borrow funds in
form of home loans, crop loans, etc. People prefer to keep money in banks because
banks offer to pay some interest on any deposits made. Also, it may be safer to
keep excess funds in a bank, rather than at home, just as people in the example
above preferred to keep their gold with Lala instead of keeping at home. In the
modern context, given cheques and debit cards, having a demand deposit makes
transactions more convenient and safer, even when they do not earn any interest.
(Imagine having to pay a large amount in cash – for purchasing a house.)
What does the bank do with the funds that have been deposited with it?
Assuming that not everyone who has deposited funds with it will ask for their
funds back at the same time, the bank can loan these funds to someone who
needs the funds at interest (of course, the bank has to be sure it will get the
funds back at the required time). So the bank will typically retain a portion of the
funds to repay depositors whenever they demand their funds back, and loan the
rest. Since banks earn interest from loans they make, any bank would like to
lend the maximum possible. However, being able to repay depositors on demand
is crucial to the bank’s survival. Depositors would keep their funds in a bank
only if they are fully confident of getting them back on demand. A bank must,
therefore, balance its lending activities so as to ensure that sufficient funds are
available to repay any depositor on demand.
2019-20
The accounting rule states that both sides of the account must balance. Hence
if assets are greater than liabilities, they are recorded on the right hand side as
Net Worth.
Net Worth = Assets – Liabilities
Assets Liabilities
Net Worth Rs 0
But is there a limit to money or credit creation by banks? Yes, and this is
determined by the Central bank (RBI). The RBI decides a certain percentage of
deposits which every bank must keep as reserves. This is done to ensure that no
bank is ‘over lending’. This is a legal requirement and is binding on the banks.
This is called the ‘Required Reserve Ratio’ or the ‘Reserve Ratio’ or ‘Cash Reserve
Ratio’ (CRR).
Cash Reserve Ratio (CRR) = Percentage of deposits which a bank must
keep as cash reserves with itself.
Apart from the CRR, banks are also required to keep some reserves
in liquid form in the short term. This ratio is called Statutory Liquidity
Ratio or SLR.
In our fictional example, suppose CRR = 20 per cent, then with deposits of Rs
100, our bank will need to keep Rs 20 (20 per cent of 100) as cash reserves. Only
the remaining amount of deposits, i.e., Rs 80 (100 – 20 = 80) can be used to give
loans. The statutory requirement of the reserve ratio acts as a limit to the amount
of credit that banks can create.
We can understand this by going back to our fictional example of an economy
with one bank. Let us assume that our bank starts with a deposit of Rs 100
made by Leela. The reserve ratio is 20 per cent. Thus our bank has Rs 80 (100 – 20)
2019-20
to lend and the bank lends out Rs 80 to Jaspal Kaur, which shows up in the
bank’s deposits in the next round as liabilities, making a total of Rs 180 as
deposits. Now our bank is required to keep 20 per cent of 180 i.e. Rs 36 as cash
reserves. Recall that our bank had started with Rs 100 as cash. Since it is
required to keep only Rs 36 as reserves, it can lend Rs 64 again (100 – 36 = 64).
The bank lends out Rs 64 to Junaid. This in turn shows up in the bank as
deposits. The process keeps repeating itself till all the required reserves become
Rs 100. The required reserves will be Rs 100 only when the total deposits become
Rs 500. This is because for deposits of Rs 500, cash reserves would have to be
Rs 100 (20 per cent of 500 = 100). The process is illustrated in Table 3.2.
. . . .
. . . .
. . . .
. . . .
... . . .
41
The first column lists each round. The second column depicts the total
deposits with the bank at the beginning of each round. Twenty per cent of these
deposits need to be deposited with the RBI as required reserves (column 3). What
the bank lends in each round gets added to the deposits with the bank in the
next round. Column 4 indicates the Loans made by the banks.
Table 3.3: Balance Sheet of the Bank
Assets Liabilities
Loans Rs 400
2019-20
Since the bank is only expected to keep 20 per cent of its deposits as reserves,
thus, reserves of Rs 100 (20per cent of 500 = 100) can support the deposits of Rs
500. In other words, our bank can give a loan of Rs 400. Table 3.3 demonstrates
its balance sheet.
M1 = Currency + Deposits = 0 + 500 = 500
Thus, money supply increases from Rs 100 to Rs 500.
Given a CRR of 20 per cent, the bank cannot give a loan beyond Rs 400.
Hence, requirement of reserves acts as a limit to money creation.
impact the deposits and hence, the money supply. In the previously discussed
example, what would the money multiplier be if the RBI increases the reserve
ratio to 25 per cent? Notice that in the previous case, Rs 100 in reserves could
support deposits of Rs 400. But the banking system would now be able to loan
Rs 300 only. It would have to call back some loans to meet the increased reserve
requirements. Hence, money supply would fall.
Another important tool by which the RBI also influences money supply is
Open Market Operations. Open Market Operations refers to buying and selling
of bonds issued by the Government in the open market. This purchase and sale
is entrusted to the Central bank on behalf of the Government. When RBI buys a
Government bond in the open market, it pays for it by giving a cheque. This
cheque increases the total amount of reserves in the economy and thus increases
the money supply. Selling of a bond by RBI (to private individuals or institutions)
leads to reduction in quantity of reserves and hence the money supply.
There are two types of open market operations: outright and repo. Outright
open market operations are permanent in nature: when the central bank buys
these securities (thus injecting money into the system), it is without any promise
to sell them later. Similarly, when the central bank sells these securities (thus
withdrawing money from the system), it is without any promise to buy them
2019-20
later. As a result, the injection/absorption of the money is of permanent nature.
However, there is another type of operation in which when the central bank buys
the security, this agreement of purchase also has specification about date and
price of resale of this security. This type of agreement is called a repurchase
agreement or repo. The interest rate at which the money is lent in this way is
called the repo rate. Similarly, instead of outright sale of securities the central
bank may sell the securities through an agreement which has a specification
about the date and price at which it will be repurchased. This type of agreement
is called a reverse repurchase agreement or reverse repo. The rate at which
the money is withdrawn in this manner is called the reverse repo rate. The Reserve
Bank of India conducts repo and reverse repo operations at various maturities:
overnight, 7-day, 14- day, etc. This type of operations have now become the
main tool of monetary policy of the Reserve Bank of India.
The RBI can influence money supply by changing the rate at which it gives
loans to the commercial banks. This rate is called the Bank Rate in India. By
increasing the bank rate, loans taken by commercial banks become more
expensive; this reduces the reserves held by the commercial bank and hence
decreases money supply. A fall in the bank rate can increase the money supply.
2019-20
spends this income over the month on the output produced by the firm –
the only good available in this economy! Thus, at the beginning of each
month the worker has a money balance of Rs 100 and the firm a balance of
Rs 0. On the last day of the month the picture is reversed – the firm has
gathered a balance of Rs 100 through its sales to the worker. The average
money holding of the firm as well as the worker is equal to Rs 50 each. Thus
the total transaction demand for money in this economy is equal to Rs 100.
The total volume of monthly transactions in this economy is Rs 200 – the
firm has sold its output worth Rs 100 to the worker and the latter has sold
her services worth Rs 100 to the firm. The transaction demand for money of
the economy is again a fraction of the total volume of transactions in the
economy over the unit period of time.
In general, therefore, the transaction demand for money in an economy,
d
M T , can be written in the following form
hand side of the above equation, T, is a flow variable whereas money demand,
MdT , is a stock concept – it refers to the stock of money people are willing to
hold at a particular point of time. The velocity of money, v, however, has a
time dimension. It refers to the number of times every unit of stock changes
hand during a unit period of time, say, a month or a year. Thus, the left
hand side, v.MdT, measures the total value of monetary transactions that
has been made with this stock in the unit period of time. This is a flow
variable and is, therefore, equal to the right hand side.
We are ultimately interested in learning the relationship between the
aggregate transaction demand for money of an economy and the (nominal)
GDP in a given year. The total value of annual transactions in an economy
includes transactions in all intermediate goods and services and is clearly
much greater than the nominal GDP. However, normally, there exists a
stable, positive relationship between value of transactions and the nominal
GDP. An increase in nominal GDP implies an increase in the total value of
transactions and hence a greater transaction demand for money from
equation (3.1). Thus, in general, equation (3.1) can be modified in the
following way
MdT = kPY (3.3)
2019-20
where Y is the real GDP and P is the general price level or the GDP
deflator. The above equation tells us that transaction demand for money is
positively related to the real income of an economy and also to its average
price level.
The Speculative Motive
An individual may hold her wealth in the form of landed property, bullion,
bonds, money etc. For simplicity, let us club all forms of assets other than
money together into a single category called ‘bonds’. Typically, bonds are
papers bearing the promise of a future stream of monetary returns over a
certain period of time. These papers are issued by governments or firms for
borrowing money from the public and they are tradable in the market. Consider
the following two-period bond. A firm wishes to raise a loan of Rs 100 from the
public. It issues a bond that assures Rs 10 at the end of the first year and Rs
10 plus the principal of Rs 100 at the end of the second year. Such a bond is
said to have a face value of Rs 100, a maturity period of two years and a
coupon rate of 10 per cent. Assume that the rate of interest prevailing in
your savings bank account is equal to 5 per cent. Naturally you would like to
compare the earning from this bond with the interest earning of your savings
bank account. The exact question that you would ask is as follows: How
much money, if kept in my savings bank account, will generate Rs 10 at the
end of one year? Let this amount be X. Therefore
5
X (1 + ) = 10
100
In other words,
X= 10
(1 + 5 )
100
This amount, Rs X, is called the present value of Rs 10 discounted at
the market rate of interest. Similarly, let Y be the amount of money which
if kept in the savings bank account will generate Rs 110 at the end of two 45
years. Thus, the present value of the stream of returns from the bond should
2019-20
10 (10 + 100)
+ = 107.33 (approx.)
(1 + 6 ) (1 + 6 )2
100 100
It follows that the price of a bond is inversely related to the market
rate of interest.
Different people have different expectations regarding the future
movements in the market rate of interest based on their private information
regarding the economy. If you think that the market rate of interest should
eventually settle down to 8 per cent per annum, then you may consider the
current rate of 5 per cent too low to be sustainable over time. You expect
interest rate to rise and consequently bond prices to fall. If you are a bond
holder a decrease in bond price means a loss to you – similar to a loss you
would suffer if the value of a property held by you suddenly depreciates in
the market. Such a loss occurring from a falling bond price is called a
capital loss to the bond holder. Under such circumstances, you will try to
sell your bond and hold money instead. Thus speculations regarding future
movements in interest rate and bond prices give rise to the speculative
demand for money.
When the interest rate is very high everyone expects it to fall in future
and hence anticipates capital gains from bond-holding. Hence people convert
their money into bonds. Thus, speculative demand for money is low. When
interest rate comes down, more and more people expect it to rise in the
future and anticipate capital loss. Thus they convert their bonds into money
giving rise to a high speculative demand for money. Hence speculative
demand for money is inversely related to the rate of interest. Assuming a
simple form, the speculative demand for money can be written as
rmax – r
MdS = r – r (3.4)
min
46
where r is the market rate of interest and rmax and rmin are the upper and
Introductory Macroeconomics
2019-20
come down. However, if the market rate of interest is already low enough
so that everybody expects it to rise in future, causing capital losses, nobody
will wish to hold bonds. Everyone in the economy will hold their wealth in
money balance and if additional money is injected within the economy it
will be used up to satiate people’s craving for money balances without
increasing the demand for bonds and without further lowering the rate of
interest below the floor rmin. Such a situation is called a liquidity trap. The
speculative money demand function is infinitely elastic here.
In Fig. 3.1 the speculative demand for money is plotted on the
horizontal axis and the rate of interest on the vertical axis. When r = rmax,
speculative demand for money is zero. The rate of interest is so high that
everyone expects it to fall in future and hence is sure about a future
capital gain. Thus everyone has converted the speculative money balance
into bonds. When r = rmin, the economy is in the liquidity trap. Everyone is
sure of a future rise in interest rate and a fall in bond prices. Everyone
puts whatever wealth they acquire in the form of money and the
speculative demand for money is infinite.
Total demand for money in an economy is, therefore, composed of
transaction demand and speculative demand. The former is directly
proportional to real GDP and price level, whereas the latter is inversely
related to the market rate of interest. The aggregate money demand in
an economy can be summarised by the following equation
d d
Md = M T + M S
rmax r
or, Md = kPY + (3.5)
r rmin
2019-20
giving the person purchasing power equal to the value printed on the note.
The same is also true of coins. Currency notes and coins are therefore
called fiat money. They do not have intrinsic value like a gold or silver
coin. They are also called legal tenders as they cannot be refused by any
citizen of the country for settlement of any kind of transaction. Cheques
drawn on savings or current accounts, however, can be refused by anyone
as a mode of payment. Hence, demand deposits are not legal tenders.
2
See Appendix 3.2 for an estimate of the variations in M1 and M3 over time.
2019-20
Box No. 3.2: Demonetisation
Demonetisation was a new initiative taken by the Government of India in
November 2016 to tackle the problem of corruption, black money, terrorism
and circulation of fake currency in the economy. Old currency notes of
Rs 500, and Rs 1000 were no longer legal tender. New currency notes in the
denomination of Rs 500 and Rs 2000 were launched. The public were advised
to deposit old currency notes in their bank account till 31 December 2016
without any declaration and upto 31March 2017 with the RBI with
declaration
Further to avoid a complete breakdown and cash crunch, notes
government had allowed exchange of Rs 4000 old currency the by new
currency per person and per day. Further till 12 December 2016, old currency
notes were acceptable as legal tender at petrol pumps, government hospitals
and for payment of government dues, like taxes, power bills, etc.
This move received both appreciation and criticism. There were long
queues outside banks and ATM booths. The shortage of currency in
circulation had an adverse impact on the economic activities. However, things
improved with time and normalcy returned.
This move has had positive impact also. It improved tax compliance as a
large number of people were bought in the tax ambit. The savings of an
individual were channelised into the formal financial system. As a result,
banks have more resources at their disposal which can be used to provide
more loans at lower interest rates. It is a demonstration of State’s decision
to put a curb on black money, showing that tax evasion will no longer be
tolerated. Tax evasion will result in financial penalty and social
condemnation. Tax compliance will improve and corruption will decrease.
Demonetisation could also help tax administration in another way, by shifting
transactions out of the cash economy into the formal payment system.
Households and firms have begun to shift from cash to electronic payment
technologies.
49
2019-20
Barter exchange Double coincidence of wants
Key Concepts
Money Medium of exchange
Unit of account Store of value
Bonds Rate of interest
Liquidity trap Fiat money
Legal tender Narrow money
Broad money Currency deposit ratio
Reserve deposit ratio High powered money
Money multiplier Lender of last resort
Open market operation Bank Rate
Cash Reserve Ratio (CRR) Repo Rate
Reverse Repo Rate
2. What are the main functions of money? How does money overcome the
shortcomings of a barter system?
3. What is transaction demand for money? How is it related to the value of
transactions over a specified period of time?
4. What are the alternative definitions of money supply in India?
5. What is a ‘legal tender’? What is ‘fiat money’?
6. What is High Powered Money?
7. Explain the functions of a commercial bank.
8. What is money multiplier? What determines the value of this multiplier?
50 9. What are the instruments of monetary policy of RBI?
Introductory Macroeconomics
Suggested Readings
1. Dornbusch, R. and S. Fischer. 1990. Macroeconomics, (fifth edition) pages 345 –
427, McGraw Hill, Paris.
2. Sikdar, S., 2006. Principles of Macroeconomics, pages 77 – 89, Oxford
University Press, New Delhi.
2019-20
Appendix 3.1
Year M1 M3
(Narrow Money) (Broad Money)
1999-00 3417.96 11241.74
2000-01 3794.33 13132.04
2001-02 4228.24 14983.36
2002-03 4735.58 17179.36
2003-04 5786.94 20056.54 51
2004-05 6497.66 22456.53
The difference in values between the two columns is attributable to the time deposits
held by commercial banks.
2019-20
Changes in the Composition of the Sources of Monetary Base Over Time
Appendix 3.3
Components of Money Stock
2019-20
Chapter 4
Chapter 4
Determination of Income and
Employment
We have so far talked about the national income, price level,
rate of interest etc. in an ad hoc manner – without
investigating the forces that govern their values. The basic
objective of macroeconomics is to develop theoretical tools,
called models, capable of describing the processes which
determine the values of these variables. Specifically, the
models attempt to provide theoretical explanation to
questions such as what causes periods of slow growth or
recessions in the economy, or increment in the price level,
or a rise in unemployment. It is difficult to account for all
the variables at the same time. Thus, when we concentrate
on the determination of a particular variable, we must hold
the values of all other variables constant. This is a stylisation
typical of almost any theoretical exercise and is called the
assumption of ceteris paribus, which literally means ‘other
things remaining equal’. You can think of the procedure as
follows – in order to solve for the values of two variables x
and y from two equations, we solve for one variable, say x,
in terms of y from one equation first, and then substitute
this value into the other equation to obtain the complete
solution. We apply the same method in the analysis of the
macroeconomic system.
In this chapter we deal with the determination of National
Income under the assumption of fixed price of final goods
and constant rate of interest in the economy. The
theoretical model used in this chapter is based on the theory
given by John Maynard Keynes.
2019-20
had planned to consume during the same period. Similarly, investment
can mean the amount a producer plans to add to her inventory. It may
be different from what she ends up doing. Suppose the producer plans
to add Rs 100 worth goods to her stock by the end of the year. Her
planned investment is, therefore, Rs 100 in that year. However, due to
an unforeseen upsurge of demand for her goods in the market the
volume of her sales exceeds what she had planned to sell and, to meet
this extra demand, she has to sell goods worth Rs 30 from her stock.
Therefore, at the end of the year, her inventory goes up by Rs (100 –
30) = Rs 70 only. Her planned investment is Rs 100 whereas her
actual, or ex post, investment is Rs 70 only. We call the planned
values of the variables – consumption, investment or output of final
goods – their ex ante measures.
In simple words, ex-ante depicts what has been planned, and ex-post
depicts what has actually happened. In order to understand the
determination of income, we need to know the planned values of different
components of aggregate demand. Let us look at these components now.
4.1.1. Consumption
The most important determinant of consumption demand is household
income. A consumption function describes the relation between
consumption and income. The simplest consumption function assumes
that consumption changes at a constant rate as income changes. Of
course, even if income is zero, some consumption still takes place. Since
this level of consumption is independent of income, it is called
autonomous consumption. We can describe this function as:
C = C + cY (4.1)
The above equation is called the consumption function. Here C is
54
the consumption expenditure by households. This consists of two
Introductory Macroeconomics
2019-20
the consumers does not increase consumption at all (MPC = 0) or use
entire change in income on consumption (MPC = 1) or use part of the
change in income for changing consumption (0< MPC<1).
Imagine a country Imagenia which has a consumption function
described by C=100+0.8Y .
This indicates that even when Imagenia does not have any income,
its citizens still consume Rs. 100 worth of goods. Imagenia’s autonomous
consumption is 100. Its marginal propensity to consume is 0.8. This
means that if income goes up by Rs. 100 in Imagenia, consumption will
go up by Rs. 80.
Let us also look at another dimension of this, savings. Savings is
that part of income that is not consumed. In other words,
S =Y − C
Since, S =Y − C ,
∆ (Y − C )
s=
∆Y
∆Y ∆C
= −
∆Y ∆Y
= 1− c 55
Income Determination
Some Definitions
2019-20
4.1.2. Investment
Investment is defined as addition to the stock of physical capital (such
as machines, buildings, roads etc., i.e. anything that adds to the future
productive capacity of the economy) and changes in the inventory (or
the stock of finished goods) of a producer. Note that ‘investment goods’
(such as machines) are also part of the final goods – they are not
intermediate goods like raw materials. Machines produced in an economy
in a given year are not ‘used up’ to produce other goods but yield their
services over a number of years.
Investment decisions by producers, such as whether to buy a new machine,
depend, to a large extent, on the market rate of interest. However, for simplicity,
we assume here that firms plan to invest the same amount every year. We can
write the ex ante investment demand as
I= I (4.2)
where I is a positive constant which represents the autonomous (given or
exogenous) investment in the economy in a given year.
56 where Y is the ex ante, or planned, ouput of final goods. This equation can be
further simplified by adding up the two autonomous terms, C and I , making it
Introductory Macroeconomics
Y = A + c.Y (4.3)
where A = C + I is the total autonomous expenditure in the economy. In
reality, these two components of autonomous expenditure behave in different ways.
C , representing subsistence consumption level of an economy, remains more or
less stable over time. However, I has been observed to undergo periodic fluctuations.
A word of caution is in order. The term Y on the left hand side of equation (4.3)
represents the ex ante output or the planned supply of final goods. On the other
hand, the expression on the right hand side denotes ex ante or planned aggregate
demand for final goods in the economy. Ex ante supply is equal to ex ante
demand only when the final goods market, and hence the economy, is in
equilibrium. Equation (4.3) should not, therefore, be confused with the
accounting identity of Chapter 2, which states that the ex post value of total
output must always be equal to the sum total of ex post consumption and ex
post investment in the economy. If ex ante demand for final goods falls short of
the output of final goods that the producers have planned to produce in a
given year, equation (4.3) will not hold. Stocks will be piling up in the warehouses
which we may consider as unintended accumulation of inventories. It should
be noted that inventories or stocks refers to that part of output produced which
is not sold and therefore remains with the firm. Change in inventory is called
2019-20
inventory investment. It can be negative as well as positive: if there is a rise in
inventory, it is positive inventory investment, while a depletion of inventory is
negative inventory investment. The inventory investment can take place due to
two reasons: (i) the firm decides to keep some stocks for various reasons (this is
called planned inventory investment) (ii) the sales differ from the planned level of
sales, in which case the firm has to add to/run down existing inventories (this is
called unplanned inventory investment). Thus even though planned Y is
greater than planned C + I, actual Y will be equal to actual C + I, with
the extra output showing up as unintended accumulation of inventories
in the ex post I on the right hand side of the accounting identity.
At this point, we can introduce a government in this economy. The major
economic activities of the government that affect the aggregate demand for final
goods and services can be summarized by the fiscal variables Tax (T) and
Government Expenditure (G), both autonomous to our analysis. Government,
through its expenditure G on final goods and services, adds to the aggregate
demand like other firms and households. On the other hand, taxes imposed by
the government take a part of the income away from the household, whose
disposable income, therefore, becomes Yd = Y – T. Households spend only a fraction
of this disposable income for consumption purpose. Hence, equation (4.3) has to
be modified in the following way to incorporate the government
Y = C + I + G + c (Y – T )
Note that G – c.T , like C or I , just adds to the autonomous term A . It does
not significantly change the analysis in any qualitative way. We shall, for the
sake of simplicity, ignore the government sector for the rest of this chapter.
Observe also, that without the government imposing indirect taxes and subsidies,
the total value of final goods and services produced in the economy, GDP, becomes
identically equal to the National Income. Henceforth, throughout the rest of the
chapter, we shall refer to Y as GDP or National Income interchangeably.
57
4.3 DETERMINATION OF EQUILIBRIUM INCOME IN THE SHORT RUN
Income Determination
You would recall that in microeconomic theory when we analyse the equilibrium
of demand and supply in a single market, the demand and supply curves
simultaneously determine the equilibrium price and the equilibrium quantity.
In macroeconomic theory we proceed in two steps: at the first stage, we work out
a macroeconomic equilibrium taking the price level as fixed. At the second stage,
we allow the price level to vary and again, analyse macroeconomic equilibrium.
What is the justification for taking the price level as fixed? Two reasons can
be put forward: (i) at the first stage, we are assuming an economy with unused
resources: machineries, buildings and labours. In such a situation, the law of
diminishing returns will not apply; hence additional output can be produced
without increasing marginal cost. Accordingly, price level does not vary even if
the quantity produced changes (ii) this is just a simplifying assumption which
will be changed later.
2019-20
Where C is Autonomous expenditure and c is the marginal propensity to
consume.
How can this relation be
Y
shown as a graph? To answer
this question we will need to recall
the “intercept form of the linear Y=a+bX
equation”,
Y = a + bX
θ
Here, the variables are X and
Y and there is a linear relation
between them. a and b are
constants. This equation is
a
{ X
Fig. 4.1
depicted in figure 4.1. The
constant ‘a’ is shown as the
“intercept” on the Y axis, i.e, the Intercept form of the linear equation.
value of Y when X is zero. The
constant ‘b’ is the slope of the line
i.e. tangent θ = b.
C
Consumption Function –
Graphical Representation
C=C+cY
Using the same logic, the
consumption function can be
shown as follows:
Consumption function,
α
2019-20
Aggregate Demand: Graphical Representation
The Aggregate Demand function shows the total demand (made up of
consumption + investment) at
each level of income. Graphically
Aggregate Demand=C+I+cY
it means the aggregate demand
function can be obtained by
vertically adding the
consumption and investment C=C+cY
function.
L
Here, OM = C I=I
J
OJ = I
M
OL = C + I
O
The aggregate demand Fig. 4.4
function is parallel to the
consumption function i.e., they Aggregate demand is obtained by vertically
have the same slope c. adding the consumption and investment
It may be noted that this functions.
function shows ex ante demand.
Supply Side of Macroeconomic Equilibrium
In microeconomic theory, we show the supply curve on a diagram with price on
the vertical axis and quantity supplied on horizontal axis.
In the first stage of
macroeconomic theory, we are
taking the price level as fixed.
Here, aggregate supply or the
GDP is assumed to smoothly
move up or down since they are
Aggregate Supply
Aggregate Supply
59
unused resources of all types
Income Determination
available. Whatever is the level
of GDP, that much will be
supplied and price level has no
role to play. This kind of supply 45 o
1000 GDP, Y
Now, the 450 line has the feature Fig. 4.5
that every point on it has the
same horizontal and vertical Aggregate supply curve with 45o line.
coordinates.
Suppose, GDP is Rs.1,000 at point A. How much will be supplied? The answer
is Rs.1000 worth of goods. How can that point be shown? The answer is that
supply corresponding to point A is at point B which is obtained at the intersection
of the 450 line and the vertical line at A.
Equilibrium
Equilibrium is shown graphically by putting ex ante aggregate demand and
supply together in a diagram (Fig. 4.6). The point where ex ante aggregate
demand is equal to ex ante aggregate supply will be equilibrium. Thus,
2019-20
equilibrium point is E and
equilibrium level of income is
C + I + cY = Y
Y (1 − c) = C + I
C+I (4.4)
Y=
(1 − c )
in c .
2. Change in investment: we have assumed that investment is
autonomous. However, it just means that it does not depend on
income. There are a number of variables other than income which
can affect investment. One important factor is availability of credit:
easy availability of credit encourages investment. Another factor is
interest rate: interest rate is the cost of investible funds, and at
higher interest rates, firms tend to lower investment. Let us now
concentrate on change in investment with the help of the following example.
Let C = 40 + 0.8Y , I = 10 . In this case, the equilibrium income (obtained by
equation Y to AD ) comes out to be 2501.
Now, let investment rise to 20. It can be seen that the new equilibrium will be
300. This can be seen by looking at the graph. This increase in income is due to
rise in investment, which is a component of autonomous expenditure here.
When autonomous investment increases, the AD1 line shifts in parallel
upwards and assumes the position AD2. The value of aggregate demand at
1
1 Y = C + I = 40 + 0.8Y + 10 , so that Y = 50 + 0.8Y , or Y= 50 = 2 50
1 − 0 .8
2019-20
output Y1* is Y1* F, which is greater than the value of output 0Y 1* = Y1* E1 by an
amount E1F. E1F measures the amount of excess demand that emerges in the
economy as a result of the increase in autonomous expenditure. Thus, E1 no
longer represents the equilibrium. To find the new equilibrium in the final
goods market we must look for the point where the new aggregate demand
o
line, AD2, intersects the 45 line. That occurs at point E2, which is, therefore,
the new equilibrium point. The
new equilibrium values of output
and aggregate demand are Y2* and
AD*2, respectively.
Note that in the new
equilibrium, output and aggregate
demand have increased by an
amount E 1G = E 2G, which is
greater than the initial increment
in autonomous expenditure, ∆ I
= E 1F = E 2 J. Thus an initial
increment in the autonomous
expenditure seems to have a
multiplier on the equilibrium Fig. 4.7
values of aggregate demand and Equilibrium Output and Aggregate Demand in
output. What causes aggregate the Fixed Price Model
demand and output to increase by
an amount larger than the size of the initial increment in autonomous
expenditure? We discuss it in section 4.3.3.
Income Determination
The production of final goods employs factors such as labour, capital,
land and entrepreneurship. In the absence of indirect taxes or subsidies, the
total value of the final goods output is distributed among different factors of
production – wages to labour, interest to capital, rent to land etc. Whatever is
left over is appropriated by the entrepreneur and is called profit. Thus the
sum total of aggregate factor payments in the economy, National Income, is
equal to the aggregate value of the output of final goods, GDP. In the above
example the value of the extra output, 10, is distributed among various factors
as factor payments and hence the income of the economy goes up by 10.
When income increases by 10, consumption expenditure goes up by (0.8)10,
since people spend 0.8 (= mpc) fraction of their additional income on
consumption. Hence, in the next round, aggregate demand in the economy
goes up by (0.8)10 and there again emerges an excess demand equal to
(0.8)10. Therefore, in the next production cycle, producers increase their
planned output further by (0.8)10 to restore equilibrium. When this extra
output is distributed among factors, the income of the economy goes up by
(0.8)10 and consumption demand increases further by (0.8)210, once again
creating excess demand of the same amount. This process goes on, round
after round, with producers increasing their output to clear the excess
demand in each round and consumers spending a part of their additional
2019-20
income from this extra production on consumption items – thereby creating
further excess demand in the next round.
Let us register the changes in the values of aggregate demand and output at
each round in Table 4.1.
The last column measures the increments in the value of the output of
final goods (and hence the income of the economy) in each round. The second
and third columns measure the increments in total consumption expenditure
in the economy and increments in the value of aggregate demand in a similar
way. In order to find out the total increase in output of the final goods, we
must add up the infinite geometric series in the last column, i.e.,
10 + (0.8)10 + (0.8)2 10 + .........·∞
10
= 10 {1 + (0.8) + (0.8)2 + .......·∞} = = 50
1 – 0.8
The increment in equilibrium value of total output thus exceeds the initial
increment in autonomous expenditure. The ratio of the total increment in
62 equilibrium value of final goods output to the initial increment in autonomous
expenditure is called the investment multiplier of the economy. Recalling that
Introductory Macroeconomics
10 and 0.8 represent the values of ∆ I = ∆ A and mpc, respectively, the expression
for the multiplier can be explained as
∆Y 1 1
The investment multiplier = = = (4.5)
∆ A 1− c S
where ∆Y is the total increment in final goods output and c = mpc . Observe
that the size of the multiplier depends on the value of c . As c becomes larger the
multiplier increases.
2019-20
Paradox of Thrift
If all the people of the economy increase the proportion of income they
save (i.e. if the mps of the economy increases) the total value of savings in
the economy will not increase – it will either decline or remain unchanged.
This result is known as the Paradox of Thrift – which states that as
people become more thrifty they end up saving less or same as before.
This result, though sounds apparently impossible, is actually a simple
application of the model we have learnt.
Let us continue with the example. Suppose at the initial equilibrium
of Y = 250, there is an exogenous or autonomous shift in peoples’
expenditure pattern – they suddenly become more thrifty. This may
happen due to a new information regarding an imminent war or some
other impending disaster, which makes people more circumspect and
conservative about their expenditures. Hence the mps of the economy
increases, or, alternatively, the mpc decreases from 0.8 to 0.5. At the
initial income level of AD *1 = Y 1* = 250, this sudden decline in mpc will
imply a decrease in aggregate consumption spending and hence in
aggregate demand, AD = A + cY , by an amount equal to (0.8 – 0.5) 250
= 75. This can be regarded as an autonomous reduction in consumption
expenditure, to the extent that the change in mpc is occurring from some
exogenous cause and is not a consequence of changes in the variables
of the model. But as aggregate demand decreases by 75, it falls short of
the output Y *1 = 250 and there emerges an excess supply equal to 75 in
the economy. Stocks are piling up in warehouses and producers decide
to cut the value of production by 75 in the next round to restore
equilibrium in the market. But that would mean a reduction in factor
payments in the next round and hence a reduction in income by 75. As
income decreases people reduce consumption proportionately but, this
time, according to the new value of mpc which is 0.5. Consumption
expenditure, and hence aggregate demand, decreases by (0.5)75, which 63
creates again an excess supply in the market. In the next round,
Income Determination
therefore, producers reduce output further by (0.5)75. Income of the
people decreases accordingly and consumption expenditure and
aggregate demand goes down again by (0.5) 2 75. The process goes on.
However, as can be inferred from the dwindling values of the successive
round effects, the process is convergent. What is the total decrease in
the value of output and aggregate demand? Add up the infinite series 75
+ (0.5) 75 + (0.5)2 75 + ........ ∞ and the total reduction in output turns out
to be
75
= 150
1 – 0.5
But that means the new equilibrium output of the economy is only Y *2 =
100. People are now saving S *2 = Y 2* – C *2 = Y 2* – ( C + c2.Y2* ) = 100 – (40 + 0.5 ×
100) = 10 in aggregate, whereas under the previous equilibrium they
were saving S *1 = Y 1* – C *1 = Y 1* – ( C + c1.Y 1* ) = 250 – (40 + 0.8 × 250) = 10 at
the previous mpc, c1 = 0.8. Total value of savings in the economy has,
therefore, remained unchanged.
When A changes the line shifts upwards or downwards in parallel.
When c changes, however, the line swings up or down. An increase in mps,
2019-20
or a decline in mpc, reduces the slope of the AD line and it swings
downwards. We depict the situation in Fig. 4.8.
At the initial values of
the parameters, A = 50 AD
and c = 0.8, the
equilibrium value of the AD1 = A + c1Y
output and aggregate AD1* E1
demand from equation AD2 = A + c2Y
*
(4.4) was AD2
E2
–
50 A
Y1* = = 250
1 – 0.8
Under the changed 45°
value of the parameter c =
0.5, the new equilibrium 0 Y2* Y1* Y
value of output and
aggregate demand is Fig. 4.8
50
Y 2* = = 100 Paradox of Thrift – Downward Swing of AD Line
1 – 0.5
The equilibrium output and aggregate demand have declined by 150.
As explained above, this, in turn, implies that there is no change in the
total value of savings.
Full employment level of income is that level of income where all the factors
of production are fully employed in the production process. Recall that
equilibrium attained at the point of equality of Y and AD by itself does not signify
full employment of resources. Equilibrium only means that if left to itself the
level of income in the economy will not change even when there is unemployment
in the economy. The equilibrium level of output may be more or less than the
full employment level of output. If it is less than the full employment of output,
it is due to the fact that demand is not enough to employ all factors of
production. This situation is called the situation of deficient demand. It
leads to decline in prices in the long run. On the other hand, if the equilibrium
level of output is more than the full employment level, it is due to the fact
that the demand is more than the level of output produced at full employment
level. This situation is called the situation of excess demand. It leads to rise
in prices in the long run.
2019-20
Summary
When, at a particular price level, aggregate demand for final goods equals
aggregate supply of final goods, the final goods or product market reaches its
equilibrium. Aggregate demand for final goods consists of ex ante consumption,
ex ante investment, government spending etc. The rate of increase in ex ante
consumption due to a unit increment in income is called marginal propensity
to consume. For simplicity we assume a constant final goods price and constant
rate of interest over short run to determine the level of aggregate demand for
final goods in the economy. We also assume that the aggregate supply is
perfectly elastic at this price. Under such circumstances, aggregate output is
determined solely by the level of aggregate demand. This is known as effective
demand principle. An increase (decrease) in autonomous spending causes
aggregate output of final goods to increase (decrease) by a larger amount
through the multiplier process.
Key Concepts
propensity to save?
2. What is the difference between ex ante investment and ex post investment?
3. What do you understand by ‘parametric shift of a line’? How does a line
shift when its (i) slope decreases, and (ii) its intercept increases?
4. What is ‘effective demand’? How will you derive the autonomous expenditure
65
multiplier when price of final goods and the rate of interest are given?
Income Determination
5. Measure the level of ex-ante aggregate demand when autonomous
investment and consumption expenditure (A) is Rs 50 crores, and MPS is
0.2 and level of income (Y) is Rs 4000 crores. State whether the economy
is in equilibrium or not (cite reasons).
Suggested Readings
1 . Dornbusch, R. and S. Fischer. 1990. Macroeconomics, (fifth edition) pages
63 – 105. McGraw Hill, Paris.
2019-20
Chapter 5
Chapter 5
Governmentt Budget
Governmen
and the Economy
We introduced the government in chapter one as denoting
the state. We stated that apart from the private sector,
there is the government which plays a very important role.
An economy in which there is both the private sector and
the Government is known as a mixed economy. There are
many ways in which the government influences economic
life. In this chapter, we will limit ourselves to the functions
which are carried on through the government budget.
This chapter proceeds as follows. In section 5.1 we
present the components of the government budget to bring
out the sources of government revenue and avenues of
government spending. In section 5.2 we discuss the topic of
balanced, surplus or deficit budget to account for the
difference between expenditures and revenue collection. It
specifically deals with the meaning of different kinds of
budget deficits, their implications and the measures to
contain them. Box. 5.1 deals with fiscal policy and a simple
description of the multiplier. The role the government plays
has implications for its deficits which further affect its debt-
what the government owes. The chapter concludes with an
analysis of the debt issue.
2019-20
5.1.1 Objectives of Government Budget
The government plays a very important role in increasing the welfare of
the people. In order to do that the government intervenes in the economy
in the following ways.
Allocation Function of Government Budget
Government provides certain goods and services which cannot be provided
by the market mechanism i.e. by exchange between individual consumers
and producers. Examples of such goods are national defence, roads,
government administration etc. which are referred to as public goods.
To understand why public goods need to be provided by the
government, we must understand the difference between private goods
such as clothes, cars, food items etc. and public goods. There are two
major differences. One, the benefits of public goods are available to all
and are not only restricted to one particular consumer. For example, if
a person eats a chocolate or wears a shirt, these will not be available to
others. It is said that this person’s consumption stands in rival
relationship to the consumption of others. However, if we consider a
public park or measures to reduce air pollution, the benefits will be
available to all. One person’s consumption of a good does not reduce the
amount available for consumption for others and so several people can
enjoy the benefits, that is, the consumption of many people is not
‘rivalrous’.
Two, in case of private goods anyone who does not pay for the goods
can be excluded from enjoying its benefits. If you do not buy a ticket,
you will not be allowed to watch a movie at a local cinema hall. However,
in case of public goods, there is no feasible way of excluding anyone
from enjoying the benefits of the good. That is why public goods are
called non-excludable. Even if some users do not pay, it is difficult and
sometimes impossible to collect fees for the public good. These non-
paying users are known as ‘free-riders’. Consumers will not voluntarily 67
2019-20
Stabilisation Function of Government Budget
The government may need to correct fluctuations in income and employment.
The overall level of employment and prices in the economy depends upon the
level of aggregate demand which depends on the spending decisions of millions
of private economic agents apart from the government. These decisions, in turn,
depend on many factors such as income and credit availability. In any period,
the level of demand may not be sufficient for full utilisation of labour and other
resources of the economy. Since wages and prices do not fall below a level,
employment cannot be brought back to the earlier level automatically. The
government needs to intervene to raise the aggregate demand.
On the other hand, there may be times when demand exceeds available output
under conditions of high employment and thus may give rise to inflation. In
such situations, restrictive conditions may be needed to reduce demand.
The intervention of the government whether to expand demand or reduce it
constitutes the stabilisation function.
1
The India Tax system witnessed a dramatic change with the introduction of the GST
(Goods and Services Tax) which encompasses both goods and services and was be implemented by
the Centre, 28 states and 7 Union territories from 1 July, 2017.
2
A Finance Bill, presented along with the Annual Financial Statement, provides details on the
imposition, abolition, remission, alteration or regulation of taxes proposed in the Budget.
2019-20
Government Budget
Revenue Capital
Budget Budget
Tax Non-tax Plan Revenue Non-plan Revenue Plan Capital Non-plan Capital
Revenue Revenue Expenditure Expenditure Expenditure Expenditure
Revenue Expenditure 69
3
A case against this kind of classification has been put forth on the ground that it has
led to an increasing tendency to start new schemes/projects neglecting maintenance of
existing capacity and service levels. It has also led to the misperception that non-plan
expenditure is inherently wasteful, adversely affecting resource allocation to social sectors
like education and health where salary comprises an important element.
2019-20
government. The main items of non-plan expenditure are interest payments,
defence services, subsidies, salaries and pensions.
Interest payments on market loans, external loans and from various reserve
funds constitute the single largest component of non-plan revenue expenditure.
Defence expenditure, is committed expenditure in the sense that given the national
security concerns, there exists little scope for drastic reduction. Subsidies are
an important policy instrument which aim at increasing welfare. Apart from
providing implicit subsidies through under-pricing of public goods and services
like education and health, the government also extends subsidies explicitly on
items such as exports, interest on loans, food and fertilisers. The amount of
subsidies as a per cent of GDP was 2.02 per cent in 2014-15 and is 1.7 percent
of GDP in 2015-16 (B.E).
Capital Expenditure
There are expenditures of the government which result in creation of
physical or financial assets or reduction in financial liabilities. This
includes expenditure on the acquisition of land, building, machinery,
equipment, investment in shares, and loans and advances by the central
government to state and union territory governments, PSUs and other
parties. Capital expenditure is also categorised as plan and non-plan in
the budget documents. Plan capital expenditure, like its revenue
counterpart, relates to central plan and central assistance for state
and union territory plans. Non-plan capital expenditure covers various
general, social and economic services provided by the government.
The budget is not merely a statement of receipts and expenditures.
Since Independence, with the launching of the Five-Year Plans, it has
also become a significant national policy statement. The budget, it has
been argued, reflects and shapes, and is, in turn, shaped by the country’s
economic life. Along with the budget, three policy statements are
mandated by the Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management Act,
70 2003 (FRBMA)4. The Medium-term Fiscal Policy Statement sets a three-
year rolling target for specific fiscal indicators and examines whether
Introductory Macroeconomics
4
Box 5.2 provides a brief account of this legistation and its implication for Government
finances.
5
The 2005-06 Indian Budget introduced a statement highlighting the gender sensitivities
of the budgetary allocations. Gender budgeting is an exercise to translate the stated gender
commitments of the government into budgetary commitments, involving special initiatives
for empowering women and examination of the utilisation of resources allocated for women
and the impact of public expenditure and policies of the government on women. The 2006-
07 budget enlarged the earlier statement.
2019-20
to raise the amount through taxes in order to keep the budget balanced. When
tax collection exceeds the required expenditure, the budget is said to be in surplus.
However, the most common feature is the situation when expenditure exceeds
revenue. This is when the government runs a budget deficit.
Table 5.1: Receipts and Expenditures of the Central Government, 2017-18 (B.E.)
Item 3 in Table 5.1 shows that revenue deficit in 2017-18 was 1.9 per cent
of GDP. The revenue deficit includes only such transactions that affect the current
income and expenditure of the government. When the government incurs a
revenue deficit, it implies that the government is dissaving and is using up the
savings of the other sectors of the economy to finance a part of its consumption
expenditure. This situation means that the government will have to borrow not
only to finance its investment but also its consumption requirements. This will
lead to a build up of stock of debt and interest liabilities and force the government,
6
More formally, it refers to the excess of total expenditure (both revenue and capital)
over total receipts (both revenue and capital). From the 1997-98 budget, the practice of
showing budget deficit has been discontinued in India.
2019-20
eventually, to cut expenditure. Since a major part of revenue expenditure is
committed expenditure, it cannot be reduced. Often the government reduces
productive capital expenditure or welfare expenditure. This would mean lower
growth and adverse welfare implications.
Fiscal Deficit: Fiscal deficit is the difference between the government’s total
expenditure and its total receipts excluding borrowing
Gross fiscal deficit = Total expenditure – (Revenue receipts +
Non-debt creating capital receipts)
Non-debt creating capital receipts are those receipts which are not borrowings
and, therefore, do not give rise to debt. Examples are recovery of loans and the
proceeds from the sale of PSUs. From Table 5.1 we can see that non-debt creating
capital receipts equals 0.6 per cent of GDP, obtained by subtracting, borrowing
and other liabilities from total capital receipts (4.5 – 3.9). The fiscal deficit,
therefore turn out to be 3.9 per cent of GDP. The fiscal deficit will have to be
financed through borrowing. Thus, it indicates the total borrowing requirements
of the government from all sources. From the financing side
Gross fiscal deficit = Net borrowing at home + Borrowing from
RBI + Borrowing from abroad
Net borrowing at home includes that directly borrowed from the public
through debt instruments (for example, the various small savings
schemes) and indirectly from commercial banks through Statutory
Liquidity Ratio (SLR). The gross fiscal deficit is a key variable in judging
the financial health of the public sector and the stability of the economy.
From the way gross fiscal deficit is measured as given above, it can be
seen that revenue deficit is a part of fiscal deficit (Fiscal Deficit =
Revenue Deficit + Capital Expenditure - non-debt creating capital
receipts). A large share of revenue deficit in fiscal deficit indicated that
72
a large part of borrowing is being used to meet its consumption
Introductory Macroeconomics
2019-20
exceed receipts) rather than a balanced
budget (when expenditure equals
receipts). In what follows, we study the
effects of introducing the government
sector in our earlier analysis of the
determination of income.
The government directly affects
the level of equilibrium income in two
specific ways – government
purchases of goods and services (G)
increase aggregate demand and
taxes, and transfers affect the
relation between income (Y) and How does the Fiscal Policy try to achieve
disposable income (YD) – the income its basic objectives?
available for consumption and
saving with the households.
We take taxes first. We assume that the government imposes taxes that
do not depend on income, called lump-sum taxes equal to T. We assume
throughout the analysis that government makes a constant amount of
—
transfers, TR . The consumption function is now
—
C = C + cYD = C + c(Y – T + TR ) (5.1)
2019-20
1
*
So (Y + ∆Y ) =
1− c
(
C − cT + cTR + I + G + ∆G) (5.4a)
Changes in Taxes
We find that a cut in taxes increases
disposable income (Y – T ) at each
AD
level of income. This shifts the E'
Y = AD
aggregate expenditure schedule C + I + G' – cT
upwards by a fraction c of the
decrease in taxes. This is shown in E C + I + G – cT
Fig 5.2.
From equation 5.3, we can calculate
the tax multiplier using the same
method as for the government
expenditure multiplier. Y
Y* Y'
1 Fig. 5.1
∆Y * = ( − c) ( ∆T ) (5.7)
1− c Effect of Higher Government
Expenditure
The tax multiplier
74 ∆Y –c
= = (5.8)
∆T 1– c
Introductory Macroeconomics
2019-20
EXAMPLE 5.1
Assume that the marginal propensity to consume is 0.8. The government
expenditure multiplier will then be
1 1 1
= = = 5. For an
1– c 1 – 0.8 0.2
increase in government spending by
100, the equilibrium income will
1
increase by 500 ( ∆G = 5 × 100) .
1−c
The tax multiplier is given by
–c –0.8 –0.8
= = = –4.
1– c 1 – 0.8 0.2
2019-20
∆Y = ∆ G + c (∆Y – ∆T) since investment does not change (∆I = 0)
(5.12)
—
C = C + c (Y – tY + TR ) = C + c
—
AD
(1 – t ) Y + c TR Y = AD
(5.14) AD = C + cY + I + G
We note that proportional taxes not
only lower consumption at each
AD' = C + c(1 – t)Y + I + G
level of income but also lower the
slope of the consumption function.
The mpc out of income falls to c (1
– t). The new aggregate demand
schedule, AD′, has a larger
intercept but is flatter as shown in
Y
Fig. 5.3.
Fig. 5.3
Now we have Government and Aggregate Demand
—
AD = C + c(1 – t)Y + c TR + I + G (proportional taxes make the AD schedule
flatter)
= A + c(1 – t)Y (5.15)
—
76 Where A = autonomous expenditure and equals C + c TR + I + G. Income
determination condition in the product market is, Y = AD, which can be written
Introductory Macroeconomics
as
Y = A + c (1 – t )Y (5.16)
Solving for the equilibrium
level of income
1
Y * = 1 – c(1 – t ) A (5.17)
so that the multiplier is given
by
∆Y 1
= 1 – c (1 – t ) (5.18)
∆A
Comparing this with the
value of the multiplier with
lump-sum taxes case, we find
that the value has become
smaller. When income rose as
a result of an increase in
government spending in the
case of lump-sum taxes, Increase in Government Expenditure (with
proportional taxes)
2019-20
consumption increased by c
times the increase in income. AD = Y
With proportional taxes, AD
consumption will rise by less, (c AD' = C + c(1 – t')Y
– ct = c (1 – t)) times the increase +I+G
E'
in income.
For changes in G, the multiplier AD = C + c(1 – t)Y + I + G
will now be given by
E
∆Y = ∆ G + c (1 – t)∆Y (5.19)
1
∆Y = 1 – c (1 – t ) ∆G (5.20) Y Y' Y
EXAMPLE 5.2
In Example 5.1, if we take a tax rate of 0.25, we find consumption will now
rise by 0.60 (c (1 – t) = 0.8 × 0.75) for every unit increase in income instead of
the earlier 0.80. Thus, consumption will increase by less than before. The
1 1 1
government expenditure multiplier will be 1 – c (1 – t ) = = = 2.5
1 – 0.6 0.4
which is smaller than that obtained with lump-sum taxes. If government
expenditure rises by 100, output will rise by the multiplier times the rise in
government expenditure, that is, by 2.5 × 100 = 250. This is smaller than the
increase in output with lump-sum taxes. 77
2019-20
During boom years, when employment is high, tax receipts collected to
finance such expenditure increase exerting a stabilising pressure on high
consumption spending; conversely, during a slump, these welfare
payments help sustain consumption. Further, even the private sector has
built-in stabilisers. Corporations maintain their dividends in the face of a
change in income in the short run and households try to maintain their
previous living standards. All these work as shock absorbers without the
need for any decision-maker to take action. That is, they work
automatically. The built-in stabilisers, however, reduce only part of the
fluctuation in the economy, the rest must be taken care of by deliberate
policy initiative.
Transfers: We suppose that instead of raising government spending in goods
—
and services, government increases transfer payments, TR . Autonomous
—
spending, A , will increase by c∆ TR , so output will rise by less than the amount
by which it increases when government expenditure increases because a part
of any increase in transfer payments is saved. Using the method used earlier
for deriving the government expenditure multipier and the taxation multiplier
the change in equilibrium income for a change in transfers is given by
c
∆Y = ∆TR (5.21)
1–c
or
∆Y c
= (5.22)
∆TR 1– c
EXAMPLE 5.3
We suppose that the marginal propensity to consume is 0.75 and we have
lump-sum taxes. The change in equilibrium income when government
1
purchases increase by 20 is given by ∆Y = ∆ G = 4 × 20 = 80. An
1 − 0.75
78
0.75
increase in transfers of 20 will raise equilibrium income by ∆Y = ∆TR
Introductory Macroeconomics
1 – 0.75
= 3 × 20 = 60. Thus, we find that income increases by less than it increased
with a rise in government purchases.
Debt
2019-20
By borrowing, the government transfers the burden of reduced
consumption on future generations. This is because it borrows by issuing
bonds to the people living at present but may decide to pay off the bonds
some twenty years later by raising taxes. These may be levied on the young
population that have just entered the work force, whose disposable income
will go down and hence consumption. Thus, national savings, it was argued,
would fall. Also, government borrowing from the people reduces the savings
available to the private sector. To the extent that this reduces capital
formation and growth, debt acts as a ‘burden’ on future generations.
Traditionally, it has been argued that when a government cuts taxes and
runs a budget deficit, consumers respond to their after -tax income by
spending more. It is possible that these people are short-sighted and do not
understand the implications of budget deficits. They may not realise that at
some point in the future, the government will have to raise taxes to pay off
the debt and accumulated interest. Even if they comprehend this, they may
expect the future taxes to fall not on them but on future generations.
A counter argument is that consumers are forward-looking and will base
their spending not only on their current income but also on their expected
future income. They will understand that borrowing today means higher
taxes in the future. Further, the consumer will be concerned about future
generations because they are the children and grandchildren of the present
generation and the family which is the relevant decision making unit,
continues living. They would increase savings now, which will fully offset
the increased government dissaving so that national savings do not change.
This view is called Ricardian equivalence after one of the greatest
nineteenth century economists, David Ricardo, who first argued that in
the face of high deficits, people save more. It is called ‘equivalence’ because
it argues that taxation and borrowing are equivalent means of financing
expenditure. When the government increases spending by borrowing today,
which will be repaid by taxes in the future, it will have the same impact on
the economy as an increase in government expenditure that is financed by
a tax increase today.
It has often been argued that ‘debt does not matter because we owe it 79
to ourselves’. This is because although there is a transfer of resources
2019-20
fixed unless we assume that income cannot be augmented. If government deficits
succeed in their goal of raising production, there will be more income and,
therefore, more saving. In this case, both government and industry can borrow
more.
Also, if the government invests in infrastructure, future generations may
be better off, provided the return on such investments is greater than the
rate of interest. The actual debt could be paid off by the growth in output.
The debt should not then be considered burdensome. The growth in debt
will have to be judged by the growth of the economy as a whole.
Deficit Reduction: Government deficit can be reduced by an increase in
taxes or reduction in expenditure. In India, the government has been
trying to increase tax revenue with greater reliance on direct taxes (indirect
taxes are regressive in nature – they impact all income groups equally).
There has also been an attempt to raise receipts through the sale of
shares in PSUs. However, the major thrust has been towards reduction
in government expenditure. This could be achieved through making
government activities more efficient through better planning of
programmes and better administration. A recent study7 by the Planning
Commission has estimated that to transfer Re1 to the poor, government
spends Rs 3.65 in the form of food subsidy, showing that cash transfers
would lead to increase in welfare. The other way is to change the scope
of the government by withdrawing from some of the areas where it
operated before. Cutting back government programmes in vital areas
like agriculture, education, health, poverty alleviation, etc. would
adversely affect the economy. Governments in many countries run huge
deficits forcing them to eventually put in place self-imposed constraints
of not increasing expenditure over pre-determined levels (Box 5.2 gives the
main features of the FRBMA in India). These will have to be examined keeping
in view the above factors. We must note that larger deficits do not always
signify a more expansionary fiscal policy. The same fiscal measures can
give rise to a large or small deficit, depending on the state of the economy.
For example, if an economy experiences a recession and GDP falls, tax
80 revenues fall because firms and households pay lower taxes when they earn
less. This means that the deficit increases in a recession and falls in a
Introductory Macroeconomics
7
“Performance Evaluation of the Targeted Public Distribution System” by the Programme
Evaluation Organisation, Planning Commission.
2019-20
Summary
Public goods
Automatic stabiliser
Discretionary fiscal policy
Ricardian equivalence
Box 5.2: Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management Act, 2003 (FRBMA)
In a multi-party parliamentary system, electoral concerns play an 81
important role in determining expenditure policies. A legislative provision,
8
This has been rescheduled by one year to 2009-10, primarily on account of a shift in
plan priorities in favour of revenue expenditure - intensive programmes and schemes.
2019-20
through tax revenues, the necessary adjustment has to come from a
reduction in expenditure.
3. The actual deficits may exceed the targets specified only on grounds of
national security or natural calamity or such other exceptional grounds
as the central government may specify.
4. The central government shall not borrow from the Reserve Bank of India
except by way of advances to meet temporary excess of cash disbursements
over cash receipts.
5. The Reserve Bank of India must not subscribe to the primary issues of
central government securities from the year 2006-07.
6. Measures to be taken to ensure greater transparency in fiscal operations.
7. The central government to lay before both Houses of Parliament three
statements – Medium-term Fiscal Policy Statement, The Fiscal Policy
Strategy Statement, The Macroeconomic Framework Statement along
with the Annual Financial Statement.
8. Quarterly review of the trends in receipts and expenditure in relation to
the budget be placed before both Houses of Parliament.
The act applies to the central government. However, 26 states have
already enacted fiscal responsibility legislations which have made the
rule based fiscal reform programme of the government more broad
based. Although the government has emphasised that the FRBMA is an
important instituional mechanism to ensure fiscal prudence and support
macro economic balance there have been fears that welfare expenditure
may get reduced to meet the targets mandated by the Act.
FRBM Review Committee
In the last thirteen years since the FRBM act was enacted, the Indian
economy has graduated to a middle income country. At the time of
enactment of the FRBM, there was a general thinking that fiscal rules
were better than discretion. However, since then the advanced countries
have moved away from this but in India, the government has affirmed its
faith in the fiscal policy principles set out in the FRBM. Therefore, there
82
is support for retaining the basic operational framework designed in
Introductory Macroeconomics
Goods and Service Tax (GST) is the single comprehensive indirect tax,
operational from 1 July 2017, on supply of goods and services, right from the
manufacturer/ service provider to the consumer. It is a destination based
consumption tax with facility of Input Tax Credit in the supply chain. It is
applicable throughout the country with one rate for one type of goods/service.
It has amalgamated a large number of Central and State taxes and cesses. It
has replaced large number of taxes on goods and services levied on production/
sale of goods or provision of service.
As there have been a number of intermediate goods/services, which
were manufactured/provided in the economy, the pre GST tax regime
imposed taxes not on the value added at each stage but on the total value
of the commodity/service with minimal facility of utilisation of Input Tax
2019-20
Credit (ITC). The total value included taxes paid on intermediate goods/services.
This amounted to cascading of tax. Under GST, the tax is discharged at every
stage of supply and the credit of tax paid at the previous stage is available for
set off at the next stage of supply of goods and/or services. It is thus effectively
a tax on value addition at each stage of supply. In view of our large and fast
growing economy, it addresses to establish parity in taxation across the
country, and extend principles of ‘value- added taxation’ to all goods and
services.
It has replaced various types of taxes/cesses, levied by the Central
and State/UT Governments. Some of the major taxes that were levied by
Centre were Central Excise Duty, Service Tax, Central Sales Tax, Cesses
like KKC and SBC. The major State taxes were VAT/Sales Tax, Entry Tax,
Luxury Tax, Octroi, Entertainment Tax, Taxes on Advertisements, Taxes
on Lottery /Betting/ Gambling, State Cesses on goods etc. These have
been subsumed in GST.
Five petroleum products have been kept out of GST for the time being
but with passage of time, they will get subsumed in GST. State Governments
will continue to levy VAT on alcoholic liquor for human consumption.
Tobacco and tobacco products will attract both GST and Central Excise
Duty. Under GST, there are 6 (six) standard rates applied i.e. 0%, 3%,5%,
12%,18% and 28% on supply of all goods and/or services across the
country.
GST is the biggest tax reform in the country since independence and
was rolled out on the mid-night of 30 June/1 July, 2017 during a special
midnight session of the Parliament. The 101th Constitution Amendment Act
received assent of the President of India on 8 September, 2016. The amendment
introduced Article 246A in the Constitution cross empowering Parliament and
Legislatures of States to make laws with reference to Goods and Service Tax
imposed by the Union and the States. Thereafter CGST Act, UTGST Act and
SGST Acts were enacted for GST. GST has simplified the multiplicity of taxes
on goods and services. The laws, procedures and rates of taxes across the
country are standardised. It has facilitated the freedom of movement of goods
and services and created a common market in the country. It is aimed at 83
reducing the cost of business operations and cascading effect of various taxes
2019-20
is the level of equilibrium income? (b) Calculate the value of the government
expenditure multiplier and the tax multiplier. (c) If government expenditure
increases by 200, find the change in equilibrium income.
6. Consider an economy described by the following functions: C = 20 +
0.80Y, I = 30, G = 50, TR = 100 (a) Find the equilibrium level of income
and the autonomous expenditure multiplier in the model. (b) If government
expenditure increases by 30, what is the impact on equilibrium income?
(c) If a lump-sum tax of 30 is added to pay for the increase in government
purchases, how will equilibrium income change?
7. In the above question, calculate the effect on output of a 10 per cent
increase in transfers, and a 10 per cent increase in lump-sum taxes. Compare
the effects of the two.
8. We suppose that C = 70 + 0.70Y D, I = 90, G = 100, T = 0.10Y (a) Find
the equilibrium income. (b) What are tax revenues at equilibrium income?
Does the government have a balanced budget?
9. Suppose marginal propensity to consume is 0.75 and there is a 20 per
cent proportional income tax. Find the change in equilibrium income for
the following (a) Government purchases increase by 20 (b) Transfers
decrease by 20.
10. Explain why the tax multiplier is smaller in absolute value than the
government expenditure multiplier.
11. Explain the relation between government deficit and government debt.
12. Does public debt impose a burden? Explain.
13. Are fiscal deficits inflationary?
?
14. Discuss the issue of deficit reduction.
15. What do you understand by G.S.T? How good is the system of G.S.T as
compared to the old tax system? State its categories.
84
Suggested Readings
Introductory Macroeconomics
2019-20
Open Economy
Macroeconomics
2019-20
economic agents will accept a national currency only if they are convinced that
the amount of goods they can buy with a certain amount of that currency will
not change frequently. In other words, the currency will maintain a stable
purchasing power. Without this confidence, a currency will not be used as an
international medium of exchange and unit of account since there is no
international authority with the power to force the use of a particular currency
in international transactions.
In the past, governments have tried to gain confidence of potential
users by announcing that the national currency will be freely convertible
at a fixed price into another asset. Also, the issuing authority will have
no control over the value of that asset into which the currency can be
converted. This other asset most often has been gold, or other national
currencies. There are two aspects of this commitment that has affected
its credibility — the ability to convert freely in unlimited amounts and the price
at which this conversion takes place. The international monetary system has
been set up to handle these issues and ensure stability in international
transactions.
With the increase in the volume of transactions, gold ceased to be the
asset into which national currencies could be converted (See Box 6.2).
Although some national currencies have international acceptability, what is
important in transactions between two countries is the currency in which
the trade occurs. For instance, if an Indian wants to buy a good made in
America, she would need dollars to complete the transaction. If the price of
the good is ten dollars, she would need to know how much it would cost her
in Indian rupees. That is, she will need to know the price of dollar in terms of
rupees. The price of one currency in terms of another currency is known as
the foreign exchange rate or simply the exchange rate. We will discuss
this in detail in section 6.2.
between residents of a country with the rest of the world for a specified time period
typically a year. There are two main accounts in the BoP — the current account
and the capital account1.
1
There is a new classification in which the balance of payments have been divided into three
accounts — the current account, the financial account and the capital account. This is as per the
new accounting standards specified by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) in the sixth edition of
the Balance of Payments and International Investment Position Manual (BPM6). India has also
made the change but the Reserve Bank of India continues to publish data accounting to the old
classification.
2019-20
Buying foreign goods is expenditure from our country and it becomes the
income of that foreign country. Hence, the purchase of foreign goods or imports
decreases the domestic demand for goods and services in our country. Similarly,
selling of foreign goods or exports brings income to our country and adds to the
aggregate domestic demand for goods and services in our country.
Macroeconomics
Open Economy
Current Account Balanced Current Current Account
Surplus Account Surplus
2019-20
of imports of invisibles of a country in a given period of time. Invisibles
include services, transfers and flows of income that take place between
different countries. Services trade includes both factor and non-factor
income. Factor income includes net international earnings on factors
of production (like labour, land and capital). Non-factor income is net
sale of service products like shipping, banking, tourism, software
services, etc.
88
Introductory Macroeconomics
2019-20
(spending more than it receives from sales to the rest of the world)
must finance it by selling assets or by borrowing abroad. Thus, any
current account deficit must be financed by a capital account surplus,
that is, a net capital inflow.
Current account + Capital account ≡ 0
In this case, in which a country is said to be in balance of payments
equilibrium, the current account deficit is financed entirely by
international lending without any reserve movements.
Alternatively, the country could use its reserves of foreign exchange
in order to balance any deficit in its balance of payments. The reserve
bank sells foreign exchange when there is a deficit. This is called official
reserve sale. The decrease (increase) in official reserves is called the
overall balance of payments deficit (surplus). The basic premise is that
the monetary authorities are the ultimate financiers of any deficit in
the balance of payments (or the recipients of any surplus).
We note that official reserve transactions are more relevant under a
regime of fixed exchange rates than when exchange rates are floating.
(See sub heading ‘Fixed Exchange Rates’ under section 6.2.2)
Autonomous and Accommodating Transactions
International economic transactions are called autonomous when
transactions are made due to some reason other than to bridge the gap
in the balance of payments, that is, when they are independent of the
state of BoP. One reason could be to earn profit. These items are called
‘above the line’ items in the BoP. The balance of payments is said to be
in surplus (deficit) if autonomous receipts are greater (less) than
autonomous payments.
Accommodating transactions (termed ‘below the line’ items), on the
other hand, are determined by the gap in the balance of payments, that
is, whether there is a deficit or surplus in the balance of payments. In 89
other words, they are determined by the net consequences of the
Macroeconomics
Open Economy
autonomous transactions. Since the official reserve transactions are
made to bridge the gap in the BoP, they are seen as the accommodating
item in the BoP (all others being autonomous).
Errors and Omissions
It is difficult to record all international transactions accurately. Thus,
we have a third element of BoP (apart from the current and capital
accounts) called errors and omissions which reflects this.
Table 6.1 provides a sample of Balance of Payments for India.
Note in this table, there is a trade deficit and current account deficit
but a capital account surplus. As a result, BOP is in balance.
2019-20
Box 6.1: The balance of payments accounts presented above divide the
transactions into two accounts, current account and capital account.
However, following the new accounting standards introduced by the
International Monetary Fund in the sixth edition of the Balance of Payments
and International Investment Position Manual (BPM6) the Reserve Bank of
India also made changes in the structure of balance of payments accounts.
According to the new classification, the transactions are divided into three
accounts: current account, financial account and capital account. The most
important change is that almost all the transactions arising on account of
trade in financial assets such as bonds and equity shares are now placed
in the financial account. However, RBI continues to publish the balance of
payments accounts as per the old system also, therefore the details of the
new system are not being given here. The details are given in the Balance of
Payments Manual for India published by the Reserve Bank of India in
September 2010.
c. Transfers 32
5. Current Account Balance [ 3+ 4] –38
6. Capital Account Balance 41.15
[6a + 6b + 6c + 6d + 6e + 6f]
a. External Assistance (net) 0.15
b. External Commercial Borrowings (net) 2
c. Short-term Debt 10
d. Banking Capital (net) of which 15
Non-resident Deposits (net) 9
e. Foreign Investments (net) of which 19
[6eA + 6eB]
A. FDI (net) 13
2019-20
B. Portfolio (net) 6
f. Other Flows (net) –5
7. Errors and Omissions 3.15
8. Overall Balance [5 + 6 + 7] 0
9. Reserves Change 0
Macroeconomics
Open Economy
To make it simple, let us consider that India and USA are the only countries
in the world and so there is only one exchange rate that needs to be determined.
Demand for Foreign Exchange
People demand foreign exchange because: they want to purchase goods and
services from other countries; they want to send gifts abroad; and, they want to
purchase financial assets of a certain country.
A rise in price of foreign exchange will increase the cost (in terms of
rupees) of purchasing a foreign good. This reduces demand for imports
and hence demand for foreign exchange also decreases, other things
remaining constant.
Supply of Foreign Exchange
Foreign currency flows into the home country due to the following
reasons: exports by a country lead to the purchase of its domestic
goods and services by the foreigners; foreigners send gifts or make
transfers; and, the assets of a home country are bought by the foreigners.
A rise in price of foreign exchange will reduce the foreigner’s cost (in terms of
USD) while purchasing products from India, other things remaining constant.
This increases India’s exports and hence supply for foreign exchange may
2019-20
increase (whether it actually increases depends on a number of factors,
particularly elasticity of demand for exports and imports.
to pay more rupees for a dollar now (i.e., Rs 70). It indicates that the value of
rupees in terms of dollars has fallen and value of dollar in terms of rupees
has risen. Increase in exchange
rate implies that the price of
foreign currency (dollar) in Rs/$ D
terms of domestic currency D
(rupees) has increased. This is S
called Depreciation of domestic
currency (rupees) in terms of e1
foreign currency (dollars). e*
Similarly, in a flexible D'
exchange rate regime, when the
price of domestic currency D
(rupees) in terms of foreign S
currency (dollars) increases, it is
called Appreciation of the $
Fig. 6.2
domestic currency (rupees) in
t e r m s o f f o r e i g n c u r r e n c y Effect of an Increase in Demand for Imports in
(dollars). This means that the the Foreign Exchange Market
2019-20
value of rupees relative to dollar has risen and we need to pay fewer rupees
in exchange for one dollar.
Speculation
Money in any country is an asset. If Indians believe that British pound is going
to increase in value relative to the rupee, they will want to hold pounds. Thus
exchange rates also get affected when people hold foreign exchange on the
expectation that they can make gains from the appreciation of the currency.
This expectation in turn can actually affect the exchange rate in the following
way. If the current exchange rate is Rs. 80 to a pound and investors believe that
the pound is going to appreciate by the end of the month and will be worth
Rs.85, investors think if they gave the dealer Rs. 80,000 and bought 1000
pounds, at the end of the month, they would be able to exchange the pounds for
Rs. 85,000, thus making a profit of Rs. 5,000. This expectation would increase
the demand for pounds and cause the rupee-pound exchange rate to increase
in the present, making the beliefs self-fulfilling.
Interest Rates and the Exchange Rate
In the short run, another factor that is important in determining exchange rate
movements is the interest rate differential i.e. the difference between interest
rates between countries. There are huge funds owned by banks, multinational
corporations and wealthy individuals which move around the world in search of
the highest interest rates. If we assume that government bonds in country A pay
8 per cent rate of interest whereas equally safe bonds in county B yield 10 per
cent, the interest rate differential is 2 per cent. Investors from country A will be
attracted by the high interest rates in country B and will buy the currency of
country B selling their own currency. At the same time investors in country B
will also find investing in their own country more attractive and will therefore
demand less of country A’s currency. This means that the demand curve for
country A’s currency will shift to the left and the supply curve will shift to the
right causing a depreciation of country A’s currency and an appreciation of 93
country B’s currency. Thus, a rise in the interest rates at home often leads to an
Macroeconomics
Open Economy
appreciation of the domestic currency. Here, the implicit assumption is that no
restrictions exist in buying bonds issued by foreign governments.
Income and the Exchange Rate
When income increases, consumer spending increases. Spending on imported
goods is also likely to increase. When imports increase, the demand curve for
foreign exchange shifts to the right. There is a depreciation of the domestic
currency. If there is an increase in income abroad as well, domestic exports will
rise and the supply curve of foreign exchange shifts outward. On balance, the
domestic currency may or may not depreciate. What happens will depend on
whether exports are growing faster than imports. In general, other things
remaining equal, a country whose aggregate demand grows faster than the rest
of the world’s normally finds its currency depreciating because its imports grow
faster than its exports. Its demand curve for foreign currency shifts faster than
its supply curve.
Exchange Rates in the Long Run
The purchasing Power (PPP) theory is used to make long-run predictions about
exchange rates in a flexible exchange rate system. According to the theory, as
long as there are no barriers to trade like tariffs (taxes on trade) and quotas
2019-20
(quantitative limits on imports), exchange rates should eventually adjust so that
the same product costs the same whether measured in rupees in India, or dollars
in the US, yen in Japan and so on, except for differences in transportation. Over
the long run, therefore, exchange rates between any two national currencies
adjust to reflect differences in the price levels in the two countries.
EXAMPLE 6.1
If a shirt costs $8 in the US and Rs 400 in India, the rupee-dollar exchange rate
should be Rs 50. To see why, at any rate higher than Rs 50, say Rs 60, it costs
Rs 480 per shirt in the US but only Rs 400 in India. In that case, all foreign
customers would buy shirts from India. Similarly, any exchange rate below Rs
50 per dollar will send all the shirt business to the US. Next, we suppose that
prices in India rise by 20 per cent while prices in the US rise by 50 per cent.
Indian shirts would now cost Rs 480 per shirt while American shirts cost $12
per shirt. For these two prices to be equivalent, $12 must be worth Rs 480, or
one dollar must be worth Rs 40. The dollar, therefore, has depreciated.
2
market in order to absorb this
excess supply which has been
marked as AB in the figure. Thus,
through intervention, the
Government can maintain any
exchange rate in the economy. But
it will be accumulating more and
more foreign exchange so long as Foreign Exchange Market with Fixed Exchange
this intervention goes on. On the Rates
other hand if the goverment was to
set an exchange rate at a level such as e2, there would be an excess demand for
dollars in the foreign exchange market. To meet this excess demand for dollars,
the government would have to withdraw dollars from its past holdings of dollars.
If it fails to do so, a black market for dollars may come up.
In a fixed exchange rate system, when some government action increases the
exchange rate (thereby, making domestic currency cheaper) is called Devaluation.
On the other hand, a Revaluation is said to occur, when the Government decreases
the exchange rate (thereby, making domestic currency costlier) in a fixed exchange
rate system.
2019-20
6.2.3 Merits and Demerits of Flexible and Fixed Exchange Rate Systems
The main feature of the fixed exchange rate system is that there must be
credibility that the government will be able to maintain the exchange rate at the
level specified. Often, if there is a deficit in the BoP, in a fixed exchange rate
system, governments will have to intervene to take care of the gap by use of its
official reserves. If people know that the amount of reserves is inadequate, they
would begin to doubt the ability of the government to maintain the fixed rate.
This may give rise to speculation of devaluation. When this belief translates into
aggressive buying of one currency thereby forcing the government to devalue, it
is said to constitute a speculative attack on a currency. Fixed exchange rates
are prone to these kinds of attacks, as has been witnessed in the period before
the collapse of the Bretton Woods System.
The flexible exchange rate system gives the government more flexibility and
they do not need to maintain large stocks of foreign exchange reserves. The
major advantage of flexible exchange rates is that movements in the exchange
rate automatically take care of the surpluses and deficits in the BoP. Also,
countries gain independence in conducting their monetary policies, since they
do not have to intervene to maintain exchange rate which are automatically
taken care of by the market.
Macroeconomics
Open Economy
Box 6.2 Exchange Rate Management: The International Experience
The Gold Standard: From around 1870 to the outbreak of the First World
War in 1914, the prevailing system was the gold standard which was the
epitome of the fixed exchange rate system. All currencies were defined in
terms of gold; indeed some were actually made of gold. Each participant
country committed to guarantee the free convertibility of its currency into
gold at a fixed price. This meant that residents had, at their disposal, a
domestic currency which was freely convertible at a fixed price into another
asset (gold) acceptable in international payments. This also made it possible
for each currency to be convertible into all others at a fixed price. Exchange
rates were determined by its worth in terms of gold (where the currency
was made of gold, its actual gold content). For example, if one unit of say
currency A was worth one gram of gold, one unit of currency B was worth
two grams of gold, currency B would be worth twice as much as currency A.
Economic agents could directly convert one unit of currency B into two
units of currency A, without having to first buy gold and then sell it. The
rates would fluctuate between an upper and a lower limit, these limits being
set by the costs of melting, shipping and recoining between the two
2019-20
Currencies3. To maintain the official parity each country needed an adequate
stock of gold reserves. All countries on the gold standard had stable exchange
rates.
The question arose – would not a country lose all its stock of gold if it
imported too much (and had a BoP deficit)? The mercantilist4 explanation
was that unless the state intervened, through tariffs or quotas or subsidies,
on exports, a country would lose its gold and that was considered one of the
worst tragedies. David Hume, a noted philosopher writing in 1752, refuted
this view and pointed out that if the stock of gold went down, all prices and
costs would fall commensurately and no one in the country would be worse
off. Also, with cheaper goods at home, imports would fall and exports rise (it
is the real exchange rate which will determine competitiveness). The country
from which we were importing and making payments in gold would face an
increase in prices and costs, so their now expensive exports would fall and
their imports of the first country’s now cheap goods would go up. The result
of this price-specie-flow (precious metals were referred to as ‘specie’ in the
eighteenth century) mechanism is normally to improve the BoP of the
country losing gold, and worsen that of the country with the favourable
trade balance, until equilibrium in international trade is re-established at
relative prices that keep imports and exports in balance with no further
net gold flow. The equilibrium is stable and self-correcting, requiring no
tariffs and state action. Thus, fixed exchange rates were maintained by an
automatic equilibrating mechanism.
Several crises caused the gold standard to break down periodically.
Moreover, world price levels were at the mercy of gold discoveries. This
can be explained by looking at the crude Quantity Theory of Money, M
= kPY, according to which, if output (GNP) increased at the rate of 4 per
cent per year, the gold supply would have to increase by 4 per cent per
year to keep prices stable. With mines not producing this much gold, price
levels were falling all over the world in the late nineteenth century, giving
rise to social unrest. For a period, silver supplemented gold introducing
96 ‘bimetallism’. Also, fractional reserve banking helped to economise on gold.
Paper currency was not entirely backed by gold; typically countries held
Introductory Macroeconomics
3
If the difference in the rates were more than those transaction costs, profits could be
made through arbitrage, the process of buying a currency cheap and selling it dear.
4
Mercantilist thought was associated with the rise of the nation-state in Europe during
the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries.
2019-20
authorities guaranteed the convertibility of the dollar into gold at the fixed
price of $35 per ounce of gold. The second-tier of the system was the
commitment of monetary authority of each IMF member participating in
the system to convert their currency into dollars at a fixed price. The latter
was called the official exchange rate. For instance, if French francs could
be exchanged for dollars at roughly 5 francs per dollar, the dollars could
then be exchanged for gold at $35 per ounce, which fixed the value of the
franc at 175 francs per ounce of gold (5 francs per dollar times 35 dollars
per ounce). A change in exchange rates was to be permitted only in case of
a ‘fundamental disequilibrium’ in a nation’s BoP – which came to mean a
chronic deficit in the BoP of sizeable proportions.
Such an elaborate system of convertibility was necessary because the
distribution of gold reserves across countries was uneven with the US
having almost 70 per cent of the official world gold reserves. Thus, a credible
gold convertibility of the other currencies would have required a massive
redistribution of the gold stock. Further, it was believed that the existing
gold stock would be insufficient to sustain the growing demand for
international liquidity. One way to save on gold, then, was a two-tier
convertible system, where the key currency would be convertible into gold
and the other currencies into the key currency.
In the post–World War II scenario, countries devastated by the war
needed enormous resources for reconstruction. Imports went up and
their deficits were financed by drawing down their reserves. At that
time, the US dollar was the main component in the currency reserves
of the rest of the world, and those reserves had been expanding as a
consequence of the US running a continued balance of payments deficit
(other countries were willing to hold those dollars as a reserve asset
because they were committed to maintain convertibility between their
currency and the dollar).
The problem was that if the short-run dollar liabilities of the US
continued to increase in relation to its holdings of gold, then the belief
in the credibility of the US commitment to convert dollars into gold at 97
the fixed price would be eroded. The central banks would thus have an
overwhelming incentive to convert the existing dollar holdings into gold,
Macroeconomics
Open Economy
and that would, in turn, force the US to give up its commitment. This
was the Triffin Dilemma after Robert Triffin, the main critic of the Bretton
Woods system. Triffin suggested that the IMF should be turned into a
‘deposit bank’ for central banks and a new ‘reserve asset’ be created
under the control of the IMF. In 1967, gold was displaced by creating
the Special Drawing Rights (SDRs), also known as ‘paper gold’, in the
IMF with the intention of increasing the stock of international reserves.
Originally defined in terms of gold, with 35 SDRs being equal to one
ounce of gold (the dollar-gold rate of the Bretton Woods system), it has
been redefined several times since 1974. At present, it is calculated
daily as the weighted sum of the values in dollars of four currencies
(euro, dollar, Japanese yen, pound sterling) of the five countries (France,
Germany, Japan, the UK and the US). It derives its strength from IMF
members being willing to use it as a reserve currency and use it as a
means of payment between central banks to exchange for national
currencies. The original installments of SDRs were distributed to member
countries according to their quota in the Fund (the quota was broadly related
to the country’s economic importance as indicated by the value of its
international trade).
2019-20
The breakdown of the Bretton Woods system was preceded by many
events, such as the devaluation of the pound in 1967, flight from dollars to
gold in 1968 leading to the creation of a two-tiered gold market (with the
official rate at $35 per ounce and the private rate market determined), and
finally in August 1971, the British demand that US guarantee the gold
value of its dollar holdings. This led to the US decision to give up the link
between the dollar and gold: USA announced it would no longer be willing
to convert dollars into gold at 35$ per ounce.
The ‘Smithsonian Agreement’ in 1971, which widened the permissible band
of movements of the exchange rates to 2.5 per cent above or below the new
‘central rates’ with the hope of reducing pressure on deficit countries, lasted
only 14 months. The developed market economies, led by the United Kingdom
and soon followed by Switzerland and then Japan, began to adopt floating
exchange rates in the early 1970s. In 1976, revision of IMF Articles allowed
countries to choose whether to float their currencies or to peg them (to a single
currency, a basket of currencies, or to the SDR). There are no rules governing
pegged rates and no de facto supervision of floating exchange rates.
The Current Scenario: Many countries currently have fixed exchange rates.
The creation of the European Monetary Union in January, 1999, involved
permanently fixing the exchange rates between the currencies of the
members of the Union and the introduction of a new common currency, the
Euro, under the management of the European Central Bank. From January,
2002, actual notes and coins were introduced. So far, 12 of the 25 members
of the European Union have adopted the euro.
Some countries pegged their currency to the French franc; most of these
are former French colonies in Africa. Others peg to a basket of currencies,
with the weights reflecting the composition of their trade. Often smaller
countries also decide to fix their exchange rates relative to an important
trading partner. Argentina, for example, adopted the currency board system
in 1991. Under this, the exchange rate between the local currency (the
peso) and the dollar was fixed by law. The central bank held enough foreign
98 currency to back all the domestic currency and reserves it had issued. In
such an arrangement, the country cannot expand the money supply at
Introductory Macroeconomics
will. Also, if there is a domestic banking crisis (when banks need to borrow
domestic currency) the central bank can no longer act as a lender of last
resort. However, following a crisis, Argentina abandoned the currency board
and let its currency float in January 2002.
Another arrangement adopted by Equador in 2000 was dollarisation
when it abandoned the domestic currency and adopted the US dollar.
All prices are quoted in dollar terms and the local currency is no longer
used in transactions. Although uncertainty and risk can be avoided,
Equador has given the control over its money supply to the Central
Bank of the US – the Federal Reserve – which will now be based on
economic conditions in the US.
On the whole, the international system is now characterised by a
multiple of regimes. Most exchange rates change slightly on a day-to-day
basis, and market forces generally determine the basic trends. Even those
advocating greater fixity in exchange rates generally propose certain ranges
within which governments should keep rates, rather than literally fix them.
Also, there has been a virtual elimination of the role for gold. Instead, there
is a free market in gold in which the price of gold is determined by its
demand and supply coming mainly from jewellers, industrial users, dentists,
speculators and ordinary citizens who view gold as a good store of value.
2019-20
Summary
Macroeconomics
Open Economy
funds yielding a rate of growth higher than the interest rate.
2019-20
Box 6.3: Exchange Rate Management: The Indian Experience
India’s exchange rate policy has evolved in line with international and
domestic developments. Post-independence, in view of the prevailing
Bretton Woods system, the Indian rupee was pegged to the pound sterling
due to its historic links with Britain. A major development was the
devaluation of the rupee by 36.5 per cent in June, 1966. With the
breakdown of the Bretton Woods system, and also the declining share of
UK in India’s trade, the rupee was delinked from the pound sterling in
September 1975. During the period between 1975 to 1992, the exchange
rate of the rupee was officially determined by the Reserve Bank within a
nominal band of plus or minus 5 per cent of the weighted basket of
currencies of India’s major trading partners. The Reserve Bank intervened
on a day-to-day basis which resulted in wide changes in the size of
reserves. The exchange rate regime of this period can be described as an
adjustable nominal peg with a band.
The beginning of 1990s saw significant rise in oil prices and
suspension of remittances from the Gulf region in the wake of the Gulf
crisis. This, and other domestic and international developments, led to
severe balance of payments problems in India. The drying up of access
to commercial banks and short-term credit made financing the current
account deficit difficult. India’s foreign currency reserves fell rapidly from
US $ 3.1 billion in August to US $ 975 million on July 12, 1991 (we may
contrast this with the present; as of January 27, 2006, India’s foreign
exchange reserves stand at US $ 139.2 billion). Apart from measures
like sending gold abroad, curtailing non-essential imports, approaching
the IMF and multilateral and bilateral sources, introducing stabilisation
and structural reforms, there was a two-step devaluation of 18 –19 per
cent of the rupee on July 1 and 3, 1991. In march 1992, the Liberalised
Exchange Rate Management System (LERMS) involving dual exchange
100
rates was introduced. Under this system, 40 per cent of exchange
Introductory Macroeconomics
2019-20
? 1. Differentiate between balance of trade and current account balance.
Exercises
2. What are official reserve transactions? Explain their importance in the balance
of payments.
3. Distinguish between the nominal exchange rate and the real exchange rate. If
you were to decide whether to buy domestic goods or foreign goods, which rate
would be more relevant? Explain.
4. Suppose it takes 1.25 yen to buy a rupee, and the price level in Japan is 3 and
the price level in India is 1.2. Calculate the real exchange rate between India
and Japan (the price of Japanese goods in terms of Indian goods). (Hint: First
find out the nominal exchange rate as a price of yen in rupees).
5. Explain the automatic mechanism by which BoP equilibrium was achieved
under the gold standard.
6. How is the exchange rate determined under a flexible exchange rate regime?
7. Differentiate between devaluation and depreciation.
8. Would the central bank need to intervene in a managed floating system?
Explain why.
9. Are the concepts of demand for domestic goods and domestic demand for
goods the same?
10. What is the marginal propensity to import when M = 60 + 0.06Y? What is
the relationship between the marginal propensity to import and the
aggregate demand function?
11. Why is the open economy autonomous expenditure multiplier smaller
than the closed economy one?
12. Calculate the open economy multiplier with proportional taxes, T = tY ,
instead of lump-sum taxes as assumed in the text.
13. Suppose C = 40 + 0.8Y D, T = 50, I = 60, G = 40, X = 90, M = 50 + 0.05Y
(a) Find equilibrium income. (b) Find the net export balance at equilibrium
income (c) What happens to equilibrium income and the net export balance
when the government purchases increase from 40 and 50 ? 101
14. In the above example, if exports change to X = 100, find the change in
Macroeconomics
Open Economy
equilibrium income and the net export balance.
15. Suppose the exchange rate between the Rupee and the dollar was Rs.
30=1$ in the year 2010. Suppose the prices have doubled in India over
20 years while they have remained fixed in USA. What, according to the
purchasing power parity theory will be the exchange rate between dollar
and rupee in the year 2030.
16. If inflation is higher in country A than in Country B, and the exchange
rate between the two countries is fixed, what is likely to happen to the
trade balance between the two countries?
17. Should a current account deficit be a cause for alarm? Explain.
18. Suppose C = 100 + 0.75Y D, I = 500, G = 750, taxes are 20 per cent of income,
X = 150, M = 100 + 0.2Y . Calculate equilibrium income, the budget deficit or
?
surplus and the trade deficit or surplus.
19. Discuss some of the exchange rate arrangements that countries have entered
into to bring about stability in their external accounts.
2019-20
Suggested Readings
1. Dornbusch, R. and S. Fischer, 1994. Macroeconomics, sixth edition,
McGraw-Hill, Paris.
2. Economic Survey, Government of India, 2006-07.
3. Krugman, P.R. and M. Obstfeld, 2000. International Economics, Theory
and Policy, fifth edition, Pearson Education.
OF IN
With consumers and firms having an option to buy goods produced at home and
abroad, we now need to distinguish between domestic demand for goods and the
demand for domestic goods.
2019-20
levels and the nominal exchange rate to be constant, hence R will be fixed. From
the point of view of our country, foreign income, and therefore exports, are considered
exogenous (X = X ).
The demand for imports is thus assumed to depend on income and have
an autonomous component
M = M + mY, where M > 0 is the autonomous component, 0 < m < 1. (6.5)
Here m is the marginal propensity to import, the fraction of an extra rupee
of income spent on imports, a concept analogous to the marginal propensity to
consume.
The equilibrium income would be
Y = C + c(Y – T ) + I + G + X – M – mY (6.6)
Taking all the autonomous components together as A , we get
Y = A + cY – mY (6.7)
or, (1 – c + m )Y = A (6.8)
1 A
or, Y* = (6.9)
1 – c +m
In order to examine the effects of allowing for foreign trade in the income-
expenditure framework, we need to compare equation (6.10) with the equivalent
expression for the equilibrium income in a closed economy model. In both
equations, equilibrium income is expressed as a product of two terms, the
autonomous expenditure multiplier and the level of autonomous expenditures.
We consider how each of these change in the open economy context.
Since m, the marginal propensity to import, is greater than zero, we get a
smaller multiplier in an open economy. It is given by
∆Y 1
The open economy multiplier = = 1 – c +m (6.10)
∆A
EXAMPLE 6.2 103
If c = 0.8 and m = 0.3, we would have the open and closed economy multiplier
Macroeconomics
Open Economy
respectively as
1 1 1
= = = 5 (6.11)
1– c 1 – 0.8 0.2
and
1 1 1
1 – c + m = 1 – 0.8 + 0.3 = 0.5 = 2 (6.12)
2019-20
The second term in equation (6.10) shows that, in addition to the elements for
a closed economy, autonomous expenditure for an open economy includes the
level of exports and the autonomous component of imports. Thus, the changes in
their levels are additional shocks that will change equilibrium income. From
equation (6.10) we can compute the multiplier effects of changes in X and M .
∆Y * 1
= (6.13)
∆X 1 – c +m
∆Y * –1
= 1– c +m (6.14)
∆M
An increase in demand for our exports is an increase in aggregate demand for
domestically produced output and will increase demand just as would an increase
in government spending or an autonomous increase in investment. In contrast,
an autonomous rise in import demand is seen to cause a fall in demand for domestic
output and causes equilibrium income to decline.
104
Introductory Macroeconomics
2019-20
Adam Smith (1723 – 1790) Regarded as the father of modern
Economics. Author of Wealth of Nations.
Aggregate monetary resources Broad money without time deposits
of post office savings organisation (M3).
Automatic stabilisers Under certain spending and tax rules,
expenditures that automatically increase or taxes that automatically
decrease when economic conditions worsen, therefore, stabilising
the economy automatically.
Autonomous change A change in the values of variables in a
macroeconomic model caused by a factor exogenous to the model.
Autonomous expenditure multiplier The ratio of increase (or
decrease) in aggregate output or income to an increase (or decrease)
in autonomous spending.
Balance of payments A set of accounts that summarise a country’s
transactions with the rest of the world.
Balanced budget A budget in which taxes are equal to government
spending.
Balanced budget multiplier The change in equilibrium output that
results from a unit increase or decrease in both taxes and government
spending.
Bank rate The rate of interest payable by commercial banks to RBI
if they borrow money from the latter in case of a shortage of reserves.
Barter exchange Exchange of commodities without the mediation
of money.
Base year The year whose prices are used to calculate the real GDP.
Bonds A paper bearing the promise of a stream of future monetary
returns over a specified period of time. Issued by firms or
governments for borrowing money from the public.
Broad money Narrow money + time deposits held by commercial
banks and post office savings organisation.
Capital Factor of production which has itself been produced and
which is not generally entirely consumed in the production process.
Capital gain/loss Increase or decrease in the value of wealth of a
bondholder due to an appreciation or reduction in the price of her
bonds in the bond market.
Capital goods Goods which are bought not for meeting immediate
need of the consumer but for producing other goods.
2019-20
Capitalist country or economy A country in which most of the production is
carried out by capitalist firms.
Capitalist firms These are firms with the following features (a) private ownership
of means of production (b) production for the market (c) sale and purchase of labour
at a price which is called the wage rate (d) continuous accumulation of capital.
Cash Reserve Ratio (CRR) The fraction of their deposits which the commercial
banks are required to keep with RBI.
Circular flow of income The concept that the aggregate value of goods and services
produced in an economy is going around in a circular way. Either as factor
payments, or as expenditures on goods and services, or as the value of aggregate
production.
Consumer durables Consumption goods which do not get exhausted immediately
but last over a period of time are consumer durables.
Consumer Price Index (CPI) Percentage change in the weighted average price
level. We take the prices of a given basket of consumption goods.
Consumption goods Goods which are consumed by the ultimate consumers or
meet the immediate need of the consumer are called consumption goods. It may
include services as well.
Corporate tax Taxes imposed on the income made by the corporations (or private
sector firms).
Currency deposit ratio The ratio of money held by the public in currency to that
held as deposits in commercial banks.
Deficit financing through central bank borrowing Financing of budget deficit
by the government through borrowing money from the central bank. Leads to
increase in money supply in an economy and may result in inflation.
Depreciation A decrease in the price of the domestic currency in terms of the
foreign currency under floating exchange rates. It corresponds to an increase in
the exchange rate.
Depreciation Wear and tear or depletion which capital stock undergoes over a
106 period of time.
Devaluation The decrease in the price of domestic currency under pegged exchange
Introductory Macroeconomics
2019-20
External sector It refers to the economic transaction of the domestic country with
the rest of the world.
Externalities Those benefits or harms accruing to another person, firm or any
other entity which occur because some person, firm or any other entity may be
involved in an economic activity. If someone is causing benefits or good externality
to another, the latter does not pay the former. If someone is inflicting harm or bad
externality to another, the former does not compensate the latter.
Fiat money Money with no intrinsic value.
Final goods Those goods which do not undergo any further transformation in the
production process.
Firms Economic units which carry out production of goods and services and employ
factors of production.
Fiscal policy The policy of the government regarding the level of government
spending and transfers and the tax structure.
Fixed exchange rate An exchange rate between the currencies of two or more
countries that is fixed at some level and adjusted only infrequently.
Flexible/floating exchange rate An exchange rate determined by the forces of
demand and supply in the foreign exchange market without central bank
intervention.
Flows Variables which are defined over a period of time.
Foreign exchange Foreign currency, all currencies other than the domestic
currency of a given country.
Foreign exchange reserves Foreign assets held by the central bank of the country.
Four factors of production Land, Labour, Capital and Entrepreneurship. Together
these help in the production of goods and services.
GDP Deflator Ratio of nominal to real GDP.
Government expenditure multiplier The numerical coefficient showing the size
of the increase in output resulting from each unit increase in government spending.
Government The state, which maintains law and order in the country, imposes
taxes and fines, makes laws and promotes the economic wellbeing of the citizens.
107
Glossary
Great Depression The time period of 1930s (started with the stock market crash
in New York in 1929) which saw the output in the developed countries fall and
unemployment rise by huge amounts.
Gross Domestic Product (GDP) Aggregate value of goods and services produced
within the domestic territory of a country. It includes the replacement investment
of the depreciation of capital stock.
Gross fiscal deficit The excess of total government expenditure over revenue
receipts and capital receipts that do not create debt.
Gross investment Addition to capital stock which also includes replacement for
the wear and tear which the capital stock undergoes.
Gross National Product (GNP) GDP + Net Factor Income from Abroad. In other
words GNP includes the aggregate income made by all citizens of the country,
whereas GDP includes incomes by foreigners within the domestic economy and
excludes incomes earned by the citizens in a foreign economy.
Gross primary deficit The fiscal deficit minus interest payments.
High powered money Money injected by the monetary authority in the economy.
Consists mainly of currency.
Households The families or individuals who supply factors of production to the
firms and which buy the goods and services from the firms.
2019-20
Imports Purchase of goods and services by the domestic country to the rest of the
world.
Income method of calculating national income Method of calculating national
income by measuring the aggregate value of final factor payments made (= income)
in an economy over a period of time.
Interest Payment for services which are provided by capital.
Intermediate goods Goods which are used up during the process of production of
other goods.
Inventories The unsold goods, unused raw materials or semi-finished goods which
a firm carries from a year to the next.
John Maynard Keynes (1883 – 1946) Arguably the founder of Macroeconomics as
a separate discipline.
Labour Human physical effort used in production.
Land Natural resources used in production – either fixed or consumed.
Legal tender Money issued by the monetary authority or the government which
cannot be refused by anyone.
Lender of last resort The function of the monetary authority of a country in which
it provides guarantee of solvency to commercial banks in a situation of liquidity
crisis or bank runs.
Liquidity trap A situation of very low rate of interest in the economy where every
economic agent expects the interest rate to rise in future and consequently bond
prices to fall, causing capital loss. Everybody holds her wealth in money and
speculative demand for money is infinite.
Macroeconomic model Presenting the simplified version of the functioning of a
macroeconomy through either analytical reasoning or mathematical, graphical
representation.
Managed floating A system in which the central bank allows the exchange rate to
be determined by market forces but intervene at times to influence the rate.
Marginal propensity to consume The ratio of additional consumption to additional
108 income.
Introductory Macroeconomics
2019-20
up to get an unit of foreign currency; the price of foreign currency in terms of
domestic currency.
Nominal (GDP) GDP evaluated at current market prices.
Non-tax payments Payments made by households to the firms or the government
as non-tax obligations such as fines.
Open market operation Purchase or sales of government securities by the central
bank from the general public in the bond market in a bid to increase or decrease
the money supply in the economy.
Paradox of thrift As people become more thrifty they end up saving less or same
as before in aggregate.
Parametric shift Shift of a graph due to a change in the value of a parameter.
Personal Disposable Income (PDI) PI – Personal tax payments – Non-tax payments.
Personal Income (PI) NI – Undistributed profits – Net interest payments made by
households – Corporate tax + Transfer payments to the households from the
government and firms.
Personal tax payments Taxes which are imposed on individuals, such as income
tax.
Planned change in inventories Change in the stock of inventories which has
occurred in a planned way.
Present value (of a bond) That amount of money which, if kept today in an interest
earning project, would generate the same income as the sum promised by a bond
over its lifetime.
Private income Factor income from net domestic product accruing to the private
sector + National debt interest + Net factor income from abroad + Current transfers
from government + Other net transfers from the rest of the world.
Product method of calculating national income Method of calculating the
national income by measuring the aggregate value of production taking place in
an economy over a period of time.
Profit Payment for the services which are provided by entrepreneurship.
Public good Goods or services that are collectively consumed; it is not possible to 109
exclude anyone from enjoying their benefits and one person’s consumption does
Glossary
not reduce that available to others.
Purchasing power parity A theory of international exchange which holds that the
price of similar goods in different countries is the same.
Real exchange rate The relative price of foreign goods in terms of domestic goods.
Real GDP GDP evaluated at a set of constant prices.
Rent Payment for services which are provided by land (natural resources).
Reserve deposit ratio The fraction of their total deposits which commercial banks
keep as reserves.
Revaluation A decrease in the exchange rate in a pegged exchange rate system
which makes the foreign currency cheaper in terms of the domestic currency.
Revenue deficit The excess of revenue expenditure over revenue receipts.
Ricardian equivalence The theory that consumers are forward looking and
anticipate that government borrowing today will mean a tax increase in the future
to repay the debt, and will adjust consumption accordingly so that it will have the
same effect on the economy as a tax increase today.
Speculative demand Demand for money as a store of wealth.
Statutory Liquidity Ratio (SLR) The fraction of their total demand and time deposits
which the commercial banks are required by RBI to invest in specified liquid assets.
Sterilisation Intervention by the monetary authority of a country in the money
2019-20
market to keep the money supply stable against exogenous or sometimes external
shocks such as an increase in foreign exchange inflow.
Stocks Those variables which are defined at a point of time.
Store of value Wealth can be stored in the form of money for future use. This
function of money is referred to as store of value.
Transaction demand Demand for money for carrying out transactions.
Transfer payments to households from the government and firms Transfer
payments are payments which are made without any counterpart of services
received by the payer. For examples, gifts, scholarships, pensions.
Undistributed profits That part of profits earned by the private and government
owned firms which are not distributed among the factors of production.
Unemployment rate This may be defined as the number of people who were unable
to find a job (though they were looking for jobs), as a ratio of total number of people
who were looking for jobs.
Unit of account The role of money as a yardstick for measuring and comparing
values of different commodities.
Unplanned change in inventories Change in the stock of inventories which has
occurred in an unexpected way.
Value added Net contribution made by a firm in the process of production. It is
defined as, Value of production – Value of intermediate goods used.
Wage Payment for the services which are rendered by labour.
Wholesale Price Index (WPI) Percentage change in the weighted average price
level. We take the prices of a given basket of goods which is traded in bulk.
110
Introductory Macroeconomics
2019-20
NOTE
2019-20
NOTE
2019-20