Alternatives To Inflation Targeting: Central Bank Policy For Employment Creation, Poverty Reduction and Sustainable Growth
Alternatives To Inflation Targeting: Central Bank Policy For Employment Creation, Poverty Reduction and Sustainable Growth
Alternatives To Inflation Targeting: Central Bank Policy For Employment Creation, Poverty Reduction and Sustainable Growth
POLITICAL ECONOMY
Real Exchange Rate, Monetary Policy
and Employment: Economic Development
in a Garden of Forking Paths
Roberto Frenkel and Lance Taylor
September 2006
Inflation Targeting:
418 North Pleasant Street
Amherst, MA 01002
Employment Creation,
[email protected]
www.umass.edu/peri/
Number 2
January 2006
by
Roberto Frenkel
and
Lance Taylor
Arnhold Professor and Schwartz Center for Economic Policy Analysis (CEPA), New School
University, New York
Abstract An appropriate level of the real exchange rate (RER) can be a key support for growth,
employment creation, and overall development of the “real economy,” but programming the RER
is macroeconomically complicated. The coordination issues it raises must be addressed with due
attention given to controlling inflation, reducing financial fragility and risk, and aiming toward full
employment of available resources. Thus, managing the exchange rate necessarily encompasses
The exchange rate affects any economy through many channels. It scales the national price
system to the world’s, influences key macro price ratios such as those between tradable and non-
tradable goods, capital goods and labor, and even exports and imports (via the costs of
intermediate inputs and capital goods, for example). The exchange rate is an asset price, partially
determines inflation rates through the cost side and as a monetary transmission vector, and can
have significant effects (both short and long run) on effective demand.
Correspondingly the exchange rate can be targeted toward many policy objectives. In
developing and transition economies, five have been of primary importance in recent decades:
Resource allocation: Through its effects on the price ratios just mentioned, the exchange
rate can significantly influence resource allocation, especially if it stays stable in real terms for an
extended period of time. Through effects on both resource allocation and aggregate demand, a
relatively weak rate can help boost employment, a point of concern in light of stagnant job
Economic development: often in conjunction with commercial and industrial policies, the
exchange rate can be deployed to enhance overall competitiveness and thereby boost
Finance: The rate shapes and can be used to control expectations and behavior in
financial markets. Exchange rate policy “mistakes” can easily lead to highly destabilizing
consequences.
External balance: The trade and other components of the current account usually
respond to the exchange rate, directly via “substitution” responses and (at times more
Inflation: The exchange rate can serve as a nominal anchor, holding down price
increases via real appreciation and/or maintenance by the authorities of a consistently strong
2
rate. As will be seen below, it can also serve as an important transmission mechanism for the
All these objectives have figured in recent policy experience. Use of the exchange rate to
try to improve external balance has been central to countless stabilization packages over the
decades, especially in small poor economies. The inflation objective became crucial in middle-
income countries in the last quarter of the 20th century (and is notably less urgent as of 2005).
Along with capital market liberalization, fixed rates were significant contributors to the wave of
But in many ways the resource allocation and developmental objectives can be the most
important in the long run – the central point of this paper. We trace the reasons why in the
following section on channels of influence. We then take up the policy implications, contrasting
the use of the exchange rate as a development tool in conjunction with its other uses (often in
coordination with monetary policy) to maintain external balance, contain inflation, and stabilize
asset markets,
Following Frenkel (2004), in this section we trace out three ways in which the exchange
rate can have medium- to long-term impacts on development. We begin with overall resource
Resource Allocation
The traditional 2 x 2 trade theory model is a useful starting point. It does focus on the key
role of relative prices. It does not take into consideration important non-price components of
industrial and commercial polices. Both themes are woven into the following discussion.
The Lerner Symmetry Theorem (1936) is a key early result. Its basic insight is that if only
the import/export price ratio is relevant to resource allocation, then it can be manipulated by either
that “under appropriate conditions” (at hand in the textbooks) only one need be employed.
importable, and non-tradeable in a “Ricardo-Viner” model. Two price ratios – say importable/non-
3
tradeable and exportable/non-tradeable – in principle guide allocation. The real exchange rate
(RER or ρ ) naturally comes into play as the relative price between the non-tradeable and a
Hicksian aggregate of the two tradeable goods. 1 These observations lead to two important policy
puzzles.
The first has to do with “level playing fields.” As applied in East Asia and elsewhere,
industrial policy often involved both protection of domestic industry against imports by the use of
tariffs and quotas, and promotion of exports through subsidies or cheap credits. In the case of a
with e as the nominal exchange rate (defined as units of local currency per unit of foreign), t the
tariff, and Pm* the world price. Similarly if the internal price Pe for exports is set from abroad we
have
The level playing field rests on the trade theorists’ notion that internal and external
relative prices of tradeable goods should be equal, Pm / Pe = Pm* / Pe* . This situation can be
all that industrial policy does is give more or less equal protection to both imports and exports,
then its costs, administrative complications, and risks of rent-seeking and corruption are
In a Ricardo-Viner set-up, with Pn as a price index for non-tradeables the price ratios
Pe / Pn and Pm / Pn become of interest. Positive values of t and s move domestic relative prices
in favor of tradeable goods. From a more or less mainstream perspective (Woo, 2005) this
1
Just to be clear, we will treat the RER as the ratio of tradeable to non-tradeable price indexes.
Real devaluation or weakening the RER means that ρ increases.
4
The world, however, is a bit more complicated. If the home country is exporting a
Pe* = Pe (1 − s ) / e (2b)
so that the foreign price of home exports is set by the subsidy and exchange rate. Presumably, a
lower value of Pe* stimulates sales abroad. Moreover, if the economic bureaucracy has the
requisite motivation and organization, it can tie export subsidies to the attainment of export,
productivity, and other targets and so pursue a proactive industrial policy. In such a context,
import protection and export promotion serve different purposes: the former allows domestic
production to get started along traditional infant industry lines, while the latter enables national
Now focus on the exchange rate. An increase in the nominal rate e would also switch
incentives toward production of tradeables, without the need for extravagant values of s and t.
This simple observation is in fact a strong argument in support of the use of a depreciated RER
with μ as the weight in a tradeable goods price index, then a high value of e means that the real
Of course, a weak RER may not be a sufficient condition for long-term term development.
For example it may usefully be supplemented by an export subsidy or tariff protection to infant
industries with their additional potential benefits as mentioned above. Even without an effective
bureaucracy, generalizing Lerner symmetry to a Ricardo-Viner world suggests that more than one
policy instrument may be helpful because there are two relative price ratios that can be
manipulated. The rub is that a strong exchange rate implies that commercial/industry policy
interventions also have to be strong, with correspondingly high intervention costs. A weak RER
may be only a necessary condition for beneficial resource reallocation to occur, but a highly
appreciated real exchange rate is likely to be a sufficient condition for “excessive intervention” in
2
Again, these arguments are old. Ocampo and Taylor (1998) provide a recent summary.
5
a situation in which development cannot happen. It is hard to find examples of economies with
strong exchange rates that kept up growth for extended periods of time.
Labor Intensity
Continuing with the allocational theme, it is clear that the exchange rate will affect relative
prices of imported intermediates and capital goods on the one hand, and labor on the other.
Moreover, the RER largely determines the economy’s unit labor costs in terms of foreign
currency.
To explore the implications, we can consider the effects of sustained real appreciation on
different sectors. Producers of importables will face tougher foreign competition. To stay in
business they will have to cut costs, often by shedding labor. If they fail and close down, more
jobs will be destroyed. If home’s export prices Pe* are determined by a relationship like (2b),
similar logic applies to that sector. In non-tradables, which will have to absorb labor displaced
from the tradeable sectors, jobs are less likely to open up insofar as cheaper foreign imports in
the form of intermediates and capital goods substitute for domestic labor. On the whole, real
appreciation is not likely to induce sustained job creation and could well provoke a big decrease
in tradeable sector employment. Reasoning in the other direction, RER depreciation may prove
employment-friendly.
In both cases, it is important to recognize that a new set of relative prices must be
expected to stay in place for a relatively long period if these effects are going to work through.
Changes in employment/output ratios will not happen swiftly because they involve restructuring
firms and sectoral labor market behavior. This must take place via changes in the pattern of
output among firms and sectors, by shifts in the production basket of each firm and sector, and
adjustments in the technology and organization of production. These effects arise from a
restructuring process in which individual firms and the organization of economic activity adapt to a
new set of relative prices. Gradual adjustment processes are necessarily involved.
Finally, in the long run if per capita income is to increase there will have to be sustained
labor productivity growth with employment creation supported by even more rapid growth in
6
Macroeconomics
The question is how a weak exchange rate (possibly in combination with other policies
aimed at influencing resource allocation among traded goods) fits into the macroeconomic
system. Much depends on labor market behavior in the non-traded sector. Following Rada (2005)
Assume that output in the tradable sector is driven by effective demand, responding to
investment, exports, and import substitution as well as fiscal and monetary policy. The level of
imports depends on economic activity and the exchange rate (along with commercial/industrial
policies). A worker not utilized in tradable sectors must find employment in non-tradables,
For concreteness, we assume that almost all labor not employed in tradeables finds
tradeable sector employment and L is the economically active population, then employment in
Y n − w n L n = Y n − w n (L − L t ) = 0 . (4)
Demand for Y n is generated from the value of tradable sector output Pt X t . At the same time,
real output X t determines Lt and thereby L n . Suppose that Pt is set by mark-up pricing on
variable costs including labor and imports. Then from both the demand and supply sides an
increase in X t leads to a tighter non-traded labor market which should result in an increase in
Non-tradable labor services become more valuable when economic activity rises. In national
7
accounting terms this signals a productivity increase in the sector because each worker
producers a higher value of output in terms of tradable goods, or a general price index. In other
FIGURE 1
If workers in both sectors don’t save, then their behavior does not influence overall
macroeconomic balance. Leaving aside a formal treatment of fiscal and monetary instruments for
Demand injections come from investment I t , exports E t and changes in the magnitude of the
import coefficient a via import substitution. Saving leakages come from profits with π as the
tradeable sector profit share and s the saving rate as well as from “foreign saving” in the form of
imports. Equation (5) is the vertical “Macroeconomic equilibrium” line in Figure 1. Together, the
two schedules determine X t and w n . In the lower quadrant, the trade deficit is assumed to be
Now consider the outcomes of a devaluation. It will have impacts all over the economy,
including a loss in national purchasing power if imports initially exceed exports, redistribution of
purchasing power away from low-saving workers whose real wages decrease, a decline in the
real value of the money stock, and capital losses on the part of net debtors in international
currency terms. Presumably exports will respond positively to an RER depreciation but that may
take time if “J-curve” and similar effects matter. Another positive impact on the demand for
tradables will come form import substitution, reducing the magnitude of the coefficient a.
One implication is that for a given level of output, the trade deficit should fall with
devaluation, or the corresponding schedule should shift toward the horizontal axis in the lower
quadrant. If devaluation is contractionary, the Macro equilibrium schedule will shift leftward in the
upper quadrant, reducing X t , w n , and the trade deficit further still. In this case, real devaluation
8
should presumably be implemented together with expansionary fiscal and monetary policies. As
discussed in detail below, exchange rate strategies must be coordinated with other policy moves.
If export demand and production of import substitutes are stimulated immediately or over
time by a sustained weak RER, the macroeconomic equilibrium curve should drift to the right,
So far, the analysis has taken labor productivity as a constant. Medium and long run
considerations have to take into account the evolution of productivity. For the tradeable sector,
this question can be analyzed in terms of Figure 2, sketched verbally but not actually drawn by
Kaldor in his 1966 Inaugural Lecture (published in Kaldor, 1978). To the traditional diagram we
follow Rada and Taylor (2004) by adding dashed “Employment growth contours” with slopes of 45
degrees. Each one shows combinations of the output growth rate ( Xˆ t = (dX t / dt ) / X t = X& t / X t )
and labor productivity growth rate ( ξ Lt ) that hold the employment growth rate ( Lˆt = Xˆ t − ξ Lt )
constant. Employment growth is more rapid along contours further to the SE.
FIGURE 2
Movements across contours show the effects on employment growth of shifts in the
diagram’s two solid curves. The “Kaldor-Verdoorn” schedule represents a “technical progress”
ξ Lt = ξ Lt + γX̂ t (5)
in which the productivity trend term ξ Lt could be affected by human capital growth, industrial
The “Output growth” curve reflects the assumption that more rapid productivity growth
can make output expand faster, for example by reducing the unit cost of exports. The diagram
presupposes that this effect is rather strong because the slope of the Output growth line is less
9
If a depreciated RER stimulates net export growth, the Output growth curve will shift to
&& , and L̂ all to increase. One might also imagine that the trend rate
the right, causing ξ Lt , X t t
ξ Lt of productivity growth could rise in the new regime. The Kaldor-Verdoorn schedule would shift
upward, and with a relatively flat output growth curve, all three growth rates would rise.
However, if the slope of the Output growth curve were to exceed 45 degrees, effective
demand would not increase as rapidly as productivity so that L̂t would have to fall.
the share of tradable sector employment in the total. Then λLˆ t + (1 − λ )Lˆ n = Lˆ where L̂ is overall
1 ˆ
Lˆ n = [L − λ ( Xˆ t − ξ Lt )] .
1− λ
Let the elasticity of demand for non-tradables with respect to X t be υ .Differentiating (4) then
gives
1
wˆ n = υXˆ t + [λ ( Xˆ t − ξ Lt ) − Lˆ ]
1− λ
Even taking into account the favorable effects on employment of a weak exchange rate that were
mentioned above, a low demand elasticity υ and fast labor force growth Lˆ could mean that a
strong export performance translates into weak or even negative wage and productivity growth in
the non-traded sector. A case like this calls for fiscal and social policies intended to foster
demand for non-tradables and compensate for the negative effects on income distribution and
employment.
For the reasons just indicated, a competitive and stable RER can make a substantial
contribution to economic growth and employment creation. Programming the RER, however, is
no easy task. It is most directly impacted by the nominal exchange rate, itself influenced by many
factors, but also depends on the overall inflation rate and shifting relative prices. Nor can the RER
be the only macro policy objective. In any economy, there are bound to be multiple and partially
10
conflicting objectives. And all policies – exchange rate, fiscal, monetary, and
The following discussion focuses on these exchange rate coordination issues in the
context of middle income economies with at least sporadic access to private international capital
markets. Although they are not addressed in detail here, somewhat similar questions can easily
arise in low income countries receiving official capital inflows, especially if they jump to levels of
10-20% of GDP as suggested in the discussion of the Millenium Development Goals (MDG).
So how can policy-makers target the RER while at the same time controlling inflation,
reducing financial fragility and risk, and aiming toward full employment of available resources?
Our focus necessarily has to shift from the “real economy” to encompass monetary and
the monetary authorities, if only because they have been at center stage in recent policy debates.
To set the stage, a few observations about how the nominal exchange rate fits into the
Theories that can reliably predict the level of the rate and its changes over time when it is
not strictly pegged do not exist. (The fact that pegs not infrequently break down means they do
not have 100% predictive power either.) In present circumstances in developing and transition
economies (especially those at middle income levels) it is not unreasonable to assume that a
more-or-less floating rate is determined in spot and future asset markets; in effect the spot rate
floats against its “expected” future values. The quotation marks mean that we view expectations
along Keynesian lines as emerging from diverse opinions on the part of market participants about
how the rate may move. “Beauty contests” which magnify small shifts in average market opinion
and other sources of seemingly capricious market behavior can easily come into play (Eatwell
With regard to the level of the rate, it is useful to think about a simple bond market
11
i = f (e, e& exp , M ) (6)
with i as the local interest rate, e the spot exchange rate, e& exp the expected (as an aggregate of
by market perceptions) change in the rate over time, and M an index of monetary relaxation. A
high or depreciated value of e means that national liabilities are cheap as seen from abroad. It
should be associated with high local bond prices or low interest rates. If expected depreciation
e& exp rises, on the other hand, foreign wealth-holders will want to shift away from local liabilities
and i will increase. Open market bond purchases will increase M and be associated with a
reduction in i .
Over the past couple of decades under conditions of external liberalization, most
developing economies have been afflicted by high local interest rates and appreciated currencies.
The dynamics of the exchange rate will be influenced by interest rates, because it is an
asset price. One crucial question is whether lower domestic rates will tend to make the nominal
rate depreciate or appreciate. If it tends to rise (or depreciate) over time, then exchange rate
dynamics can be a powerful mechanism for transmitting the effects of expansionary monetary
Standard arbitrage arguments as built into interest rate parity theorems imply that the
expected change in the spot rate e& exp should be an increasing function of the difference between
domestic and foreign rates. If myopic perfect foresight applies, the expected change will be equal
to the observed change (up to a “small” error term). Hence a lower local interest rate should
cause appreciation over time. On Wall Street, such an analysis of exchange rate movements is
A “speculative” view is that the exchange rate will depreciate when the local interest rate
decreases. 3 This view makes intuitive sense insofar as low interest rates should make national
liabilities less attractive. It was perhaps first advanced macroeconomically by Minsky (1983) and
can be made consistent with the parity theorems if it is assumed that there is a relatively strong
3
To be more precise, the change over time in the spot rate e& = de / dt will turn negative when i
decreases if the operational view applies and positive when the speculative view is true.
12
positive feedback of expected exchange rate increases into the domestic interest rate via the
Recent macroeconomic history (Frenkel, 2004) suggests that the speculative view is the
Avoiding Catastrophes
The most fundamental justification for avoiding a persistently strong exchange rate is that
be expansionary (at least in the short run), is anti-inflationary and reduces import costs (including
foreign junkets for those who can afford them). However, for the reasons discussed above it can
have devastating effects on resource allocation and prospects for development. Moreover, fixed
or quasi-fixed strong real rates can easily provoke destabilizing capital flow cycles as perhaps
first described analytically by Frenkel (1983) and re-enacted many times since
.The existence and severity of these cycles is in practice a powerful argument for a stable
exchange rate regime built around some sort of managed float (details below). A floating rate
does appear to moderate destabilizing capital movements in the short run, and is therefore a
useful tool to deploy. At the same time, the central bank has to prevent the formation of
expectations that there will be RER appreciation, which can easily become self-fulfilling along
necessary, is one way the bank can orient expectations around a competitive RER.
Trilemmas
Possibilities for central bank intervention are often said to be constrained by a “trilemma”
among (1) full capital mobility, (2) a controlled exchange rate, and (3) independent monetary
policy. Supposedly, only two of these policy lines can be consistently maintained. If the authorities
try to pursue all three, they will sooner or later be punished by destabilizing capital flows, as in the
run-up to the Great Depression around 1930 and Britain and Italy's difficulties during the ERM
13
The trilemma as just stated is a textbook theorem which is, in fact, invalid. Even with free
capital mobility, a central bank can undertake transactions in both foreign and domestic bonds
(not to mention other monetary control maneuvers) to regulate the money supply, regardless of
Nevertheless, something like a trilemma can exist in the eye of a beholder. There are
practical limits to the volume of interventions that a central bank can practice, along with
complicated feedbacks. Possibilities for sterilizing capital inflows or outflows are bounded by
available asset holdings. Volumes of flows depend on exchange rate expectations which in turn
So how does the market decide when a perceived trilemma is ripe to be pricked? The
fact that no single form of transaction or arbitrage operation determines the exchange rate means
that monetary authorities have some leeway in setting both the scaling factor between their
country's price system and the rest of the world's and the rules by which it changes. However,
their sailing room is not unlimited. A fixed rate is always in danger of violating what average
market opinion regards as a fundamental. Even a floating rate amply supported by forward
markets can be an invitation to extreme volatility. Volatility can lead to disaster if asset
preferences shift markedly away from the home country's liabilities in response to shifting
perceptions about fundamentals or adverse "news." Unregulated international capital markets are
at the root of any perceived trilemma. It is a practical problem that must be evaluated in each
case, taking into account the context and circumstances of policy implementation.
The implication is that if it wishes to target the RER, the central bank has to maintain
tolerable control over the macroeconomic impacts of cross-border financial flows in a world with
relatively open foreign capital markets. For the sake of clarity, it makes sense to analyze
situations of excess supply and excess demand for foreign capital separately.
Large capital inflows can easily imperil macro stability. Indeed, central bank attempts to
sterilize them by selling domestic liabilities from its portfolio may even bid up local interest rates
14
and draw more hot money. Preservation of monetary independence in this case may well require
capital market regulation. Measures are available for this task. 4 They do not work perfectly, but
can certainly moderate inflows during a boom. Booms never last forever; the point is that the
authorities can use capital market interventions to slow one down to avoid an otherwise inevitable
crash.
If there are capital outflows too large to manage with normal exchange rate and monetary
contraction. If the exchange rate has been maintained at a relatively weak level, the external
deficit is not setting off financial alarm bells, and inflation is under control, then there are no
circumstances, the way for the authorities to maintain a policy regime consistent with a targeted
Contrary to IMF-style opinion that all runs against a currency must be triggered by poor
fundamentals (even if they momentarily escape the notice of the authorities and IMF officials), it is
perfectly clear that they can arise for reasons extraneous to economic policy – think of a political
crisis, the fallout from mismanagement of an important bank, or the impacts of financial contagion
from a regional neighbor. In all such cases, outflow controls can be used to maintain an existing
policy package in place. They may not have to be utilized for very long. 5
Monetary Policy
In a developmental policy regime, monetary policy must be designed in view of its likely
effects on the RER, inflation control, and the level of economic activity. There is nothing very
surprising here – in practice central banks always have multiple objectives. In the United States,
despite lip service to controlling price inflation, the Federal Reserve certainly responds to the level
of economic activity and financial turmoil (witness the 1990s stock market bubble and the LTCM
4
For an ample menu, see papers by Deepak Nayyer, Eric Helleiner, and Gabriel Palma in
Eatwell and Taylor (2002) and Epstein, Grabel and Jomo (2003). Salih Neftci and Randall Dodd
assess the possibilities of using financial engineering to circumvent controls.
5
Argentina, for example, successfully managed exchange controls and capital outflow restrictions
in mid-2002. The measures were transitory. They were gradually softened as buying pressure in
the exchange market diminished.
15
near-crisis). In many developing countries, central banks intervene more or less systematically in
the exchange markets. The proposal here is that these interventions should help support a
developmentally oriented RER for the reasons presented above. That is, the nominal rate should
move to hold the RER in the vicinity of a stable competitive level for an extended period of time.
Inflation targeting, on the other hand, is the current orthodox buzzword. The nominal
exchange rate and other policies should be programmed to ensure a low, stable rate of inflation.
opposed to the nominal exchange rate and the central bank cannot manage the money supply,
there is no nominal anchor on inflationary expectations. The inflation rate cannot be controlled.
As we have seen, in practical terms the trilemma can be circumvented, allowing the
monetary authorities to bring developmental objectives into their remit. But they have to take at
First, many developing countries now have low to moderate inflation rates, demoting
Second, will low interest rates tend to set off inflationary nominal depreciation (under
“speculative” exchange rate dynamics as discussed above)? RER targeting can help the central
Third, shifts in aggregate demand likely to result from changes in the exchange rate and
monetary policy must be taken into account, and appropriate offsetting policies deployed.
Fourth, also as mentioned above, some mix of temporary capital inflow or outflow
controls may be needed to allow the central bank to regulate monetary aggregates and interest
Finally, unstable money demand and other unpredictable factors mean that the monetary
authorities have to be alert and flexible. Indeed, “inflation targeting” is a codeword for orthodox
recognition that quantitative monetary and even interest rate targets are impractical. It is a means
The point being made here is that discretion can and should serve other ends. A stable
competitive RER in coordination with sensible industrial and commercial policies can substantially
16
improve prospects for economic development. Surely that should be the over-riding goal of the
monetary and all other economic authorities in any developing or transition economy.
References
Eatwell, John, and Lance Taylor (2000) Global Finance at Risk: The Case for International
Eatwell, John, and Lance Taylor (eds., 2002) International Capital Markets: Systems in
Epstein, G., I. Grabel, and K.S. Jomo (2003): “Capital Management Techniques in Developing
Countries: An Assessment of Experiences from the 1990s and Lessons for the Future,”
Frenkel, Roberto (2004) “Real Exchange Rate and Employment in Argentina, Brazil, Chile, and
Mexico,” Paper prepared for the Group of 24, Washington, D.C. September
Kaldor, Nicholas (1978) “Causes of the Slow Rate of Growth of the United Kingdom” in Further
Lerner, Abba P. (1936) "The Symmetry between Import and Export Taxes," Economica 3: 306-
313
Minsky, Hyman P. (1983) “Monetary Policies and the International Financial Environment,” St.
Ocampo, Jose Antonio, and Lance Taylor (1998) “Trade Liberalization in Developing Economies:
Modest Benefits but Problems with Productivity Growth, Macro Prices, and Income
Okun, Arthur M. (1962) "`Potential GNP:' Its Measurement and Significance," reprinted in Joseph
Pechman (ed.) Economics for Policy-Making, Cambridge MA: MIT Press, 1983
Rada, Codrina (2005) “A Growth Model for a Two-Sector Open Economy with
17
Endogenous Employment in the Subsistence Sector,” New York: Schwartz Center for
Rada, Codrina, and Lance Taylor (2004) “Empty Sources of Growth Accounting, and Empirical
Replacements à la Kaldor with Some Beef,” New York: Schwartz Center for Economic
Taylor, Lance (2004) “Exchange Rate Indeterminacy in Portfolio Balance, Mundell-Fleming, and
Uncovered Interest Rate Parity Models,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 28: 205-227
Verdoorn, P. J. (1949) "Fattori che Regolano lo Sviluppo della Produttivita del Lavoro,"
L'Industria, 1: 3-10
Woo, Wing Thye (2005) “Some Fundamental Inadequacies in the Washington Consensus:
Misunderstanding the Poor by the Brightest,” in Jan Joost Teunissen (ed.) Stability,
Growth, and the Search for a New Development Agenda: Reconsidering the Washington
18
Non-tradeable Macroeconomic Equilibrium
sector wage
wn
Non-tradeable
equilbrium
Tradeable sector
output X t
Trade deficit
19
Labor Employment
productivity growth
ξ Lt rate
growth contours
Output growth
Kaldor-Verdoorn
Output growth
rate X̂
t
Figure 2: Output, labor productivity, and employment growth in the tradeable sector
20