8
ISER Working Paper Series
The Sources of Interindustry
Wage Differentials
Priscila Ferreira
Institute for Social and Economic Research, University of Essex
Department of Economics, University of Minho
No. 2009-13
March 2009
www.iser.essex.ac.uk
Non-technical summary
Empirical analysis using cross-sectional data commonly …nd signi…cant wage di¤erences
across industries. That is, some industries appear to pay higher wages than others to what
appear to be equal workers employed in what appear to be equal …rms. However, in a perfectly
competitive labour market with similar workers and …rms, these di¤erences should not exist as
wage di¤erences across industries will encourage workers to move between …rms, which would
equalises wages. To the extent that inter-industry wage di¤erences may re‡ect the existence
of non-competitive mechanisms, they are an empirical …nding di¢cult to explain in labour
economics.
In this paper we investigate the existence and sources of inter-industry wage di¤erences.
First, we analyse the size and persistence of wage di¤erences between industries. Second, we
look at the e¤ect of the characteristics of the worker, the …rm and the match between the
two. This allows us to answer questions related to (i) the nature of wage di¤erences: is it
because wages are truly di¤erent, or are they due to di¤erent types of workers employed by the
industries, and (ii) which of these e¤ects are the most important in explaining di¤erences in
wages across industries?
Analysis of the period 1986-2000 suggest the existence of important inter-industry wage
di¤erentials. Workers with the same characteristics working in …rms with observably equal
characteristics have di¤erent wages depending on the industry in which they are employed.
The wage di¤erences identi…ed are considerable, with some industries paying wages that are
more than 41% above the economy average while others pay wages that are more than 26%
below the average. Amongst the industries paying the lowest wages, we …nd the Manufacture
of furniture, Textiles, Clothing and Restaurants and cafés. The industries paying the highest
wages tend to be related to …nancial intermediation like Banking or Insurance, the Electricity,
gas and water supply services.
However, the estimated inter-industry wage structure is greatly weakened when controlling
for unobserved characteristics of workers (e.g., unobserved ability), suggesting that the raw
di¤erences are due to the concentration of high wage workers in certain industries and not
to genuine di¤erences in wages paid by …rms across industries. Further analysis, controlling
for unobserved characteristics of …rms, shows that compensation policies of …rms vary across
industries and that by changing industries workers may enjoy substantial wage growth. We
thus conclude that inter-industry wage di¤erences re‡ect di¤erent treats given by …rms across
industries.
Why might …rms treat their workers by paying them wages above the economy average?
Our results indicate that workers who are paid more than the economy average are less likely
to quit. Therefore, we conclude that there is a possibility that …rms gain from long term
employment relationships. In these circumstances above-average wages are a pro…t maximising
strategy because the costs of higher wages may be o¤set by the bene…ts of reduced turnover.
This is consistent with a labour market in which industry speci…c skills are important and
where e¢ciencies are gained from creating incentives to worker-…rm attachments.
The sources of interindustry wage di¤erentials.
Priscila Ferreiray
University of Essex, U.K. and University of Minho, Portugal
31st March 2009
Abstract
We analyse the nature of interindustry wage di¤erentials using Portuguese data. Estimates from models controlling for observed worker and …rm characteristics reveal signi…cant and persistent raw interindustry di¤erentials, which questions the competitive
model of the labour market. However, estimates controlling for unobserved worker heterogeneity suggest that the raw di¤erentials are due to the concentration of high wage
workers in certain industries and not to genuine di¤erences in compensation across industries. However, a complete decomposition shows that (i) …rm e¤ects on average explain
70% of the industry wage premia, and (ii) genuine and sizeable interindustry wage di¤erentials exist. These di¤erentials are shown to increase the time to separation from …rms,
and are therefore compatible with the competitive model.
Keywords: interindustry wage di¤erentials; unobserved worker …rm and match e¤ects; job
mobility
JEL Classi…cation: C33, J21, J31, J62, J63.
I thank Stephen Jenkins for discussions. I also thank Mark Taylor, and participants in the Warsaw International Economic Meeting 2008, the Leibniz Seminar on Labor Research (Berlin Network of Labor Market
Research, November 2008), the Brown Bag Seminar at the Toulouse School of Economics (March 2009), and
the 8th GEP PG Conference for helpful comments and suggestions. I am grateful to the Statistics Department,
Ministry of Employment, Portugal, for access to Quadros de Pessoal. Funding by Fundação para a Ciência e a
Tecnologia (contract SFRH/BD/14713/2004) is also acknowledged.
y
Correspondence to: ISER, University of Essex, Colchester CO4 3SQ, UK. E-mail:
[email protected]
1
Introduction
Empirical analyses using cross-sectional data commonly …nd signi…cant wage di¤erentials across
industries. That is, some industries appear to pay higher wages than others to observably equal
workers employed in observably equal …rms. However, in a perfectly competitive labour market
with homogeneous workers and …rms, these di¤erences should not exist as wage di¤erences
across industries will prompt mobility of workers that equalises wages. To the extent that
interindustry wage di¤erentials may re‡ect the existence of noncompetitive mechanisms, they
are an empirical …nding di¢cult to explain in labour economics. Noncompetitive mechanisms,
however, are not the only possible explanation for these di¤erentials. Such a wage structure can
arise because our observed measures of the qualities of workers are imperfect. Therefore, high
wage industries may either be hiring high wage workers or be composed of high wage …rms, or
have a combination of both. This means that substantial wage di¤erences across industries can
be either a consequence of the type of workers employed, or of di¤erent compensation policies
of …rms. A …rst purpose of this paper is to investigate the existence and sources of interindustry
wage di¤erentials. Are cross-sectional industry wage di¤erentials true wage di¤erences, or are
they a consequence of unobserved individual heterogeneity? What is the relative importance of
unobserved worker, …rm and match e¤ects in explaining di¤erences in wages across industries?
Due to lack of appropriate longitudinal linked employer and employee data, decompositions
of wage di¤erentials are not common in the literature. The Portuguese data set used here,
Quadros de Pessoal, enables us to estimate worker, …rm and match unobserved e¤ects using the
techniques developed in Abowd et al. [AKM] (1999) and Woodcock (2008a), and to decompose
the interindustry wage di¤erentials into proportions attributable to each of these unmeasured
components. Therefore, our analysis contributes to the ongoing debate on the sources of the
industry wage structure, and adds to existing evidence for France and the U.S.A.
If interindustry wage di¤erentials exist and persist over time, even after controlling for
worker and …rm characteristics, then wages play roles other than providing signals for labour
reallocation. That is, wages do not re‡ect temporary di¤erences in productivity caused by
Comments on earlier versions of this paper were received at presentations in the Warsaw International
Economic Meeting 2008, the Leibniz Seminar on Labor Research (Berlin Network of Labor Market Research,
November 2008), and the Brown Bag Seminar at the Toulouse School of Economics (March 2009).
1
shifts in the relative demand for labour between industries. There are two possible explanations for the existence of wage di¤erences across industries. Either …rms are not maximising
pro…ts, or …rms …nd it pro…table to pay higher wages. The latter is the main hypothesis of
e¢ciency wage models, which argue that higher wages can increase output and so wages above
opportunity costs are pro…t maximising. Although e¢ciency wage models can be grouped in
categories such as shirking, turnover, adverse selection and fair wages, these categories are not
mutually exclusive. Firms may be paying higher wages to accomplish a combination of objectives. However, we can use them individually to test the competitive model. One possibility
is to analyse the relationship between the industry wage premia and turnover. Krueger and
Summers (1988) suggest that if workers in high wage industries truly receive economic rents
then we could expect to …nd a negative relationship between turnover and interindustry wage
di¤erentials. In this case the cost of higher wages would be at least partially o¤set by the
bene…ts derived from reduced turnover rates. In this context, the second aim of this paper is to
investigate the relationship between the industry wage premia and separations from …rms. This
analysis is done using duration models in which the dependent variable is the time to separation
from …rms, and where the industry wage premia is included amongst the explanatory variables.
Our main …ndings can be summarised as follows. Firstly, we …nd that wages di¤er across
industries in Portugal and that the dispersion of wage di¤erentials is fairly stable over time.
Hence, temporary variations in productivity are not the main force driving the industry wage
structure. Secondly, our decomposition of the raw interindustry wage di¤erentials into components due to worker, …rm and match e¤ects reveals that unobserved …rm e¤ects are the
major source of the observed di¤erences in wages. Therefore, interindustry job mobility can
have a large impact on the wages received as the nature of the di¤erences is not due to a portable component of compensation (worker e¤ects), but to di¤erent compensation policies across
…rms. Thirdly, we …nd that the industry wage premium is positively associated with the time
to separation from …rms. This suggests that the mechanisms generating wage dispersion across
industries may be compatible with predictions of the competitive model, insofar as it can be
pro…t maximising for …rms to pay higher wages in order to reduce turnover costs.
The paper is structured as follows. The next section discusses the issues associated to the
identi…cation of interindustry wage di¤erentials in empirical analyses. In Section 4, we docu2
ment cross-sectional di¤erences in wages across industries in Portugal and identify their sources.
Section 5 describes the statistical approach used to identify the importance of unobserved heterogeneity in generating these di¤erentials. In Section 6 we decompose the raw interindustry
wage di¤erentials into proportions due to unobserved person, …rm and match e¤ects. In Section 7, the competitive model is tested by analysing the relationship between the time workers
take to separate from …rms and the industry wage premia identi…ed in the previous section.
Summary and conclusions are presented in Section 8.
2
Theoretical background
In a competitive model where all workers and jobs are homogeneous, information and search
costs are low, and issues of worker motivation and risk shifting are not important, the long run
labour market equilibrium is characterized by identical wages for all workers and little unemployment. Transitory wage di¤erentials that re‡ect di¤erentials in labour productivity (caused
by demand ‡uctuations at the …rm level, or at any labour market segment level) induce labour
mobility. As there is no reason for workers to form attachments to speci…c …rms or industries,
they will respond to wage di¤erentials and move between segments, equalizing productivity and
restoring wage equality across segments. Therefore, in equilibrium, the competitive model with
perfect information entails all workers with the same worker/job match characteristics obtaining
the same wage. The model implies the nonexistence of unemployment, because wages adjust until the demand for workers equals their supply and the labour market clears. This suggests that
wage dispersion and unemployment are closely related. Di¤erences in wages generate worker
‡ows across …rms, and transitions between jobs can involve a period of unemployment. The
model also predicts the nonexistence of wage di¤erentials associated with the industry where
the worker is employed, except if these are compensating di¤erentials for nonpecuniary aspects
of the job. However, reality appears not to comply with these predictions, as introducing the
industry of employment commonly adds explanatory power to a wage equation which explains
wages solely in terms of worker, …rm and worker/…rm match characteristics. The existence and
persistence of wage di¤erentials leads us to the question of how wages are determined. This is
an important issue, because understanding the wage determination process is fundamental to
3
understanding labour mobility and unemployment.
Responses in the literature to observed interindustry wage di¤erentials range from denial of
their existence to accepting that these di¤erences are true. The …rst approach complies with the
competitive model and argues that observed cross-sectional wage di¤erences between industries
are illusory rather than re‡ecting true industry di¤erences in compensation. According to this
view the observed wage structure is generated by unobserved heterogeneity of workers and job
characteristics. Higher wage industries may be compensating workers for their unmeasured
labour quality, or for some less desirable working conditions or job characteristics that a¤ect
the utility of workers. If measures of the worker’s productive abilities are imperfect and if
workers in high wage industries have more productive ability than others, then the industry
wage premia could simply be re‡ecting the earnings capacity of its workforce. In this case,
changing industries will not be associated with wage gains or losses for workers because the
observed di¤erences are due to a portable component of compensation that will follow the
worker to whatever industry he moves to.
The second approach accepts that there are interindustry wage di¤erentials even when
controlling for the nature of work and the quality of workers. One possible cause of such wage
di¤erentials is the existence of worker-…rm attachments. These appear if e¢ciencies are gained
when workers remain with speci…c …rms or industries for extended periods. If e¢ciencies
outweigh the gains in productivity that might come from reallocating labour in response to
every transitory demand shock, then the labour market structure, employment rules, and wage
structures adjust to encourage long-term attachments and to limit day-to-day competition in
the labour market. The result is a segmented labour market where market competition is
limited, and workers become attached to speci…c …rms or industries with competition taking
place only at speci…c ports of entry to internal labour markets. If workers do not compete in
a single aggregate labour market, the labour market is expected to adjust less rapidly than
suggested by the neoclassical model because wages play roles other than providing signals for
labour reallocation.
E¢ciency wage models provide some alternative explanations for the existence of industry
speci…c wages. Krueger and Summers (1988) and Thaler (1989) group these models into four
categories: (i) in shirking models, high wage industries should be those with high monitoring
4
costs and that have relatively higher costs of employee shirking; (ii) in turnover models, high
wage industries are those in which turnover costs are highest; (iii) in adverse selection models,
high wage industries are those more sensitive to labour quality di¤erences or have higher costs
of measuring quality; (iv) in fair wage models, industries with high pro…ts will pay higher
wages, because workers believe that fairness requires …rms to share rents. Therefore, despite
predictions from the competitive model that a pro…t maximising …rm o¤ers wages equal to the
value of marginal productivity of labour, there can be reasons why …rms pay supra competitive
wages and create incentives for long term attachments of its workforce. These can be part of
a pro…t maximising strategy of …rms, and hence not fully incompatible with the neoclassical
model.
When longitudinal data on workers became available, within-worker transformations and
…rst di¤erenced regressions were commonly applied in empirical studies of interindustry wage
di¤erentials, in the 1980s and early 1990s, to eliminate the e¤ect of worker unobserved heterogeneity, and to identify the sources of the industry e¤ects estimated using cross-sectional data.
The results are as varied as the predictions of the models discussed. Murphy and Topel (1987)
…nd evidence that two thirds of the observed di¤erential can be explained by unmeasured worker
characteristics. On the other hand, despite not identifying the sources of interindustry wage
di¤erentials, Krueger and Summers (1987) …nd empirical regularities that lead them to conclude
that unmeasured worker characteristics cannot explain such di¤erentials. These regularities include evidence suggesting that: (i) by changing industries workers receive wage changes similar
to the industry e¤ects found in cross-sectional data; (ii) the industry premia/penalty is similar
for di¤erent types of quality of workers; and (iii) wage di¤erentials can be explained by product
market characteristics. Blackburn and Neumark (1992), by including measures of worker abilities (test scores) in their regressions, conclude that ability can only account for a small portion
(10%) of interindustry wage di¤erences observed in cross-sectional analysis. Gibbons and Katz
(1992) conclude that a major proportion of interindustry wage di¤erences cannot be explained
by the sorting of workers across industries by unobserved productive ability.
More recently, questions of the sources of the industry wage structure have resurfaced due to
the emergence of longitudinal linked employer-employee data. Yet, the results using this type of
data remain varied. Using French data, Goux and Maurin (1999) …nd that the wage structure
5
is mainly due to unmeasured labour quality and that the potential wage gain from switching
industries would be less than 3%. Furthermore, the authors conclude that these remaining
true di¤erentials do not persist over time. Also using French data, AKM (1999) conclude
that person e¤ects are relatively more important in explaining the di¤erentials found in crosssectional analysis. The same result is obtained by Abowd, Finer and Kramarz (1999) with data
for the State of Washington and applying the same decomposition as AKM (1999). Woodcock
(2008) using American data …nds that, controlling for match e¤ects, …rm e¤ects are responsible
for 72% of the variance in raw interindustry wage di¤erentials.1 The di¤erence between the
…ndings of Goux and Maurin (1999) and other papers using matched worker-…rm data might
be due to the di¤erent techniques applied. The other studies use similar statistical methods to
decompose the raw interindustry wage di¤erentials found in cross-sectional data, and all provide
evidence of the existence of pure interindustry wage di¤erentials. This paper will add to the
small empirical literature that controls for measured and unmeasured characteristics of both
sides of the labour market. The methodology developed in AKM (1999) is used to distinguish
between the two leading explanations of the industry wage structure found in cross-sectional
analysis.
3
Data used and the Portuguese labour market
3.1
The Quadros de Pessoal data
The data used in this analysis is the Quadros de Pessoal (Lists of Personnel) from Portugal.
The Quadros de Pessoal is a longitudinal data set with matched information on workers and
…rms. Since 1985, the survey has been annually collected (in March until 1993, and in October
from 1994 onwards) by the Portuguese Ministry of Employment and the participation of …rms
with registered employees is compulsory. The data include all …rms (about 200 thousand per
year) and employees (about two million per year) within the Portuguese private sector. The
analyses in this paper are derived from data collections for each year from 1986 to 2000, with
1990 excluded because the database was not built in that year. Although the survey continues,
1
In contrast with the other studies using linked employer-employee that disaggregate industry coding to a
detailed level (more than 90 industries), Woodcock (2008) uses only 8 SIC Major Divisions.
6
the data currently available for analysis ends in 2000.
Each …rm and each worker has a unique registration number which allows them to be traced
over time. All information
on both …rms and workers
is reported by the …rm. In general,
the information refers to the situation observed in the month when the survey is collected. In
some cases, namely information on dates, reported data may refer to dates in the past (i.e.,
before the data collection month or to previous years) but is limited to the past within the
speci…c …rm where the worker is employed. Information on workers includes, for example,
gender, age, education level, level of skill, occupation, date of admission in the …rm, date of
last promotion, monthly wages (split into some of its components) and monthly hours of work.
Firm level data include, for example, the industry, location, number of workers, number of
establishments, and legal structure.
Some data management was carried out before implementing any analysis. First, we converted the data from a set of time series-cross sections into longitudinal panel data format.
Second, to overcome computer memory size limitations, a 10% random sample of workers was
selected from the cleaned panel data set. Third, because we will compute estimates of unobserved person and …rm e¤ects, we select only the observations that belong to the largest group
of connected workers and …rms. This sample contains 1,823,572 observations related to 377,866
workers, 98,438 …rms and 589,826 matches over time.2
3.2
The Portuguese labour market
The labour market in Portugal is very regulated. Employment protection regulation covers a
wide range of issues such as the conditions under which individual dismissal are fair or unfair,
the procedures for individual (and collective) notice and dismissal, severance payments, rules
to the use of …xed-term contracts and of temporary work agency employment.
In general, labour market law favours employment security and gives preference to contracts
of employment of inde…nite duration, and most collective agreements (agreements reached after
collective bargaining) make provision for career paths within the …rm. This is achieved by,
2
More details on the sample selection and construction of groups of connected workers and …rms can be
found in Ferreira, (2009b).
7
e.g. de…ning a set of general rules on the criteria for automatic and merit-based promotions.3
However, while a promotion (career progress) can be decided unilaterally and requires only
an agreement between the worker and the …rm, downgrading a worker to a lower category is
more di¢cult. Downgrading can not be decided unilaterally, and even when the worker and the
…rm agree with it a special justi…cation and authorization from the Ministry of Employment is
required.
Wages are negotiated yearly and are updated in January (if collective bargaining takes
longer to reach an agreement, wages are updated retroactively). Collective negotiations usually
occur at the occupation and industry level, and coverage of workers is generally irrespective
of union membership. This is a result of existing mechanisms of extension of contracts: (i)
an employer accepting an agreement usually applies it to all of its workforce; and (ii) under
certain circumstances the Government can extend the negotiated contracts by law. Collective
bargaining de…nes wage ‡oors for di¤erent categories of workers, but employers can deviate
from this agreed wage level and pay higher wages.
Restrictive employment legislation is a barrier to labour mobility, one of the focal points
of this paper. Low levels of job mobility, in turn, create incentives for …rms to use …xed-term
contracts and reduces the incentives for …rms to provide training.4 Nevertheless, in spite of
the rigid legal setting and the nature of collective bargaining, Portugal was reported by OECD
in 2003 to have one of the lowest unemployment rates in the EU and a high degree of wage
‡exibility in the private sector and when the country is faced with economic shocks (OECD,
2003).
4
Industry a¢liation and wages
In the competitive model the wages of workers do not depend on …rm or industry a¢liation.
This prediction is usually tested by de…ning a wage function as follows:
yijt = x ;t + k(j(i;t)) +
3
4
ij
Although merit promotions are totally dependent on the employer’s will.
For more details see OECD (2006).
8
(1)
where yijt is the logarithm of real monthly wages of worker i = 1; :::; N in …rm j = 1; :::; J
in period t = 1; :::; T ; x ;t is the vector of observed time varying covariates of workers (i; t)
and …rms (j; t); k = 1; :::; K is a vector of mutually exclusive dummy variables indicating the
industry a¢liation of …rm j; and
ij
is the idiosyncratic error.
and
are the parameters
to estimate. If wages do not depend on industry a¢liation, then the parameters
should be
jointly equal to zero. In what follows, we test this prediction.
4.1
Cross-sectional interindustry wage di¤erentials
To assess the existence and stability of relative wages across industries we estimate model (1)
using annual data for the period from 1986 to 2000. In all our speci…cations, we control for
worker and …rm observed characteristics. Worker related variables include the type of job
mobility experienced by the worker within the last year (automatic or merit promotion, entry
to the …rm after a short or long period of non-employment), gender, years of seniority at the
…rm and its square, years of potential labour market experience and its square, monthly hours
of work and its square, education level (up to ISCED 0/1, ISCED 2, ISCED 3, ISCED 5/6),
skill level split into 3 categories (low, medium, high), occupation (ISCO 9 major categories),
and a dummy for part time or full time work. Firm-related covariates include percentage
of foreign capital, size of …rm (micro, small, medium or large), legal structure of the …rm
(public …rm - ruled by private sector laws, sole proprietor, anonymous partnership, limited
liability company and other), instrument of collective regulation (4 categories), and region (20
categories). Macroeconomic conditions are controlled for by inclusion of year indicators.
The central variable of our analysis is the industry a¢liation of the …rm. The classi…cation
of industries in Portugal follows the European Standard Industrial Classi…cation (SIC codes).
However, until 1994 (inclusive) the coding followed a revision approved in 1978, and from 1995
onwards the coding follows a revision approved in 1993. This change in the coding system makes
harmonization over the period di¢cult and the highest level of disaggregation possible with the
data results in 43 di¤erent industries. Descriptive statistics of the variables are presented in
Table 1.
[Table 1 about here]
9
The cross-sectional estimates of equation (1) for the period 1986-2000 are shown in Tables
2 and 3. These suggest the existence of important interindustry wage di¤erentials. Industry
parameters are, in general, individually statistically signi…cant and, contrary to the competitive
prediction, the hypothesis that the
coe¢cients are simultaneously null is rejected (see F-
statistics in the tables). Therefore, workers with the same observed characteristics working in
…rms with observably equal characteristics have di¤erent wages depending on the industry in
which they are employed.
The wage di¤erences identi…ed are considerable, with some industries paying wages that are
more than 41% above the economy average while others pay wages that are more than 26%
below the average. Amongst the industries paying the lowest wages, we …nd the Manufacture of
furniture, Textiles, Clothing and Restaurants and cafés, where the wage penalty ranges from 8%
to 26% below the economy average. The industries paying the highest wages tend to be related
to …nancial intermediation like Banking or Insurance, the Electricity, gas and water supply
services, and productive services such as transport. The wage premia paid by these industries
ranges between 8% to 41% above the economy average. There is considerable dispersion in this
wage structure, the estimated standard deviations of the industry coe¢cients range from 8%
to 11% in the period. This suggests that interindustry mobility can have a large impact on
wages.5
[Tables 2 and 3 about here]
The estimated industry wage structure, however, can be partially transitory and therefore
not stable over time. That is, due to demand ‡uctuations some industries may lower wages
relative to the wages paid elsewhere without leading workers to switch to expanding industries.
We assess the role of transitory shocks by analysing the degree of linear association between
the industry wage structure observed in one point in time, with that observed in other points in
time. For this purpose we compute correlations between the 43 industry coe¢cients observed
in each year with those observed in 1986. As is shown in Table 4, the industry wage structure
was fairly stable in the period 1986-2000. Weighted correlations between relative wages in 1986
5
The magnitudes of the weighted standard deviations are comparable to those obtained by Krueger and
Summers (1988) and Goux and Maurin (1999).
10
and all of the subsequent years range from 0.76 to 0.98 which suggests that the structure barely
changed in the 15 year period analysed.6 Therefore, we conclude that temporary variations in
productivity do not seem to drive the structure of wages between industries.7
[Table 4 about here]
4.2
Contribution of industry a¢liation to wage dispersion
Taken with the previous results, we see that industry a¢liation is a signi…cant and stable
determinant of wages. We now determine its relative importance in explaining observed wage
dispersion using analysis of covariance. In model (1), the total proportion of wage variation
explained by the covariates (X) and industry a¢liation (K) is given by the R2 of the regression.
If X and K were not correlated, regressions of log wages on each of the covariates alone would
give a unique decomposition of the contribution of each set of variables to the total explained
variation. However, the possible collinearity between the two sets implies there is no unique
variance decomposition. Nevertheless, we can identify the bounds of the share of variance
explained by each set of variables.
The share of wage variation unambiguously associated to K is given by the increase in the
explanatory power arising from adding industry dummies to a wage regression already including
X. This marginal contribution of K corresponds to the minimum estimate of the relative size
of the variance contributed by K. The upper bound for the importance of the industry e¤ects
is given by the R2 of a wage equation including only industry dummies.
For this analysis (and that which follows) the observations for the period from 1986 to 2000
are pooled.8 The basic decomposition of the sources of wage dispersion is presented in Table
5. The proportion of the variance in wages explained by the covariates and industry a¢liation
together is 72%. The covariates (industry) …rst speci…cation allows identi…cation of the portion
of wage variation associated unambiguously to the industry (covariates) e¤ects. Therefore, the
6
There is a discrete fall (of about 0.05) in the strength of the correlation between 1994 and 1995, this fall
is most likely to have been caused by the change in the industry coding system than by an e¤ective decrease in
the correlations between the wage structure observed in the years post 1994 with that observed in 1986.
7
According to Krueger and Summers (1987), the structure persists and changes only moderately over longer
intervals.
8
For all the speci…cations in which the data is pooled, the right hand side and left hand side variables are
N P
J
P
Tij y ij
coded in deviations from the grand means, where the grand mean of yijt , e.g., is given by: y =
:
T
i=1j=1
11
minimum estimates of the relative size of the variance contributed by industry and covariates
is 2% and 43%, respectively. The upper bound is 29% for industry e¤ects and 70% for the
covariates. The large range in the explanatory power (e.g. industry e¤ects account for between
2% and 29% of wage variation) arises from a large degree of collinearity between industry and
the covariates. These results are in line with those obtained by Dickens and Katz (1987) for
the U.S.A., who …nd that industry e¤ects account for between 7% to 30% of wage variation
using 1983 CPS data. They suggest that industry a¢liation is an important factor explaining
wage dispersion and that noncompetitive mechanisms may be at work in the labour market.
[Table 5 about here]
4.3
Raw interindustry wage di¤erentials
As mentioned previously, a non-competitive labour market is not the only possible explanation
for the observed interindustry wage di¤erentials resulting from model (1). Our data set allows us
to test whether the industry wage structure remains after we control for unobserved worker, …rm
and match e¤ects. Therefore, we can investigate if true interindustry wage di¤erentials exist
or if the di¤erentials observed in cross-sectional data simply re‡ect an unequal distribution of
unmeasured heterogeneity across industries. Before considering the simultaneous impact of the
three types of unobserved e¤ects, we …rst analyse, with the pooled data, how interindustry wage
di¤erentials change as we gradually control for worker and …rm heterogeneity. These results are
shown in Table 6, and each of its columns includes additional controls. Column (1) displays the
results of a model that controls only for industry a¢liation and time e¤ects. This column gives
us the unadjusted wage di¤erentials between industries, i.e., the di¤erence between average
wages in the industry and the economy wide average of wages. Column (2) adds to the model
observed worker characteristics, this column gives us interindustry wage di¤erentials adjusted
for worker characteristics. In column (3) observed …rm characteristics are added as controls.
The di¤erentials observed in this column are what we will, henceforth, call raw interindustry
wage di¤erentials. That is, they summarize the industry wage structure adjusted for all the
worker and …rm characteristics that we can observe in the data. Column (4) additionally
controls for unobserved worker heterogeneity using the within-worker transformation.
12
From column (1) we conclude that, similar to our previous cross-sectional results, the industries paying the highest wages are Banking, and Insurance, Electricity, gas and water supply
services for which the unadjusted wage premia are more than 66%. Those paying the lowest
wages are Clothing, Furniture and Shoes manufactures, for which the unadjusted wage penalty
is more than 40%. With no controls for any type of heterogeneity, the standard deviation of
the estimated industry wage premia is 29%, which suggests that substantial wage growth can
be realized by changing industries. However, the estimates are very sensitive to whether worker
observed heterogeneity is controlled for.
As we can see from column (2), the explanatory power of the model increases signi…cantly
(from 33% to 68%) when we control for measured worker characteristics, while the dispersion
of wages across industries is almost halved (the standard deviation is now 0.15). Adding …rm
observed characteristics (column 3) further increases the explanatory power of the model (to
72%). While in some industries adding observed characteristics of …rms hardly a¤ects the
estimated industry e¤ect (compared to the model in column 2), in some others it substantially
reduces it. This is re‡ected in inter-industry wage dispersion, as the standard deviation of the
interindustry wage e¤ects falls from 0.15 to 0.10. Thus, it seems that observed characteristics
of workers and …rms explain much of the observed di¤erences in wages across industries.9
If unmeasured ability is time invariant and equally rewarded in all industries, then unobserved productive ability is an individual …xed e¤ect that disappears using the within-worker
transformation.10 The estimates from the model that applies this transformation are presented
in column (4). In this model the explanatory power of observed worker and …rm characteristics
is greatly reduced: the R2 is now 47%. This suggests that unmeasured labour quality is correlated with measured characteristics and shows the importance of controlling for unobserved
e¤ects. Furthermore, much less variation in wages across industries remains. The standard deviation of wages across industries is now 0.06, which means that workers who change industries
experience small wage changes. These results are in line with those obtained, for example, by
9
Using the 2002 European Structure of Earnings Survey, Magda et al. (2008) …nd similar results for the
dispersion of interindustry wage di¤erentials presented in columns 1, 2 and 3 of Table 6. In a group of 11
Eastern and Western European countries, Portugal was found to be one of the countries with highest dispersion
in the interindustry wage structure when controls for observed worker and …rm characteristics are included.
10
The condition that ability is rewarded equally in every industry is what makes it a worker-speci…c …xed
e¤ect, otherwise there is matching (Gibbons and Katz, 1992). If matching exists, the ability of the worker is of
the same level in every industry, but the quality of the match (hence compensation) may di¤er across industries.
13
Goux and Maurin (1999) and Carruth et al. (2004) after controlling for person unobserved
heterogeneity.
[Table 6 about here]
Our …ndings suggest that wages may be being set competitively but more able workers are
concentrated in certain industries, making wages appear to be larger in some industries than in
others. That is, industries paying higher wages are di¤erent from other industries in that they
hire a higher proportion of high wage workers. This could drive us to conclude, as Murphy
and Topel (1987), that most of the raw interindustry wage di¤erentials (in column 3) are due
to unobserved worker heterogeneity and not to true di¤erences in …rm compensation policies
across industries. However, so far, we have not accounted for unobserved characteristics of
…rms, despite …rms being the wage determining units and industry being a characteristic of the
…rm. If industry is a wage contour, then ignoring compensation policies of …rms in a study of
interindustry wage di¤erentials is a major weakness.11 Moreover, as Goux and Maurin (1999,
p. 506) suggest, "if the interindustry di¤erentials are not measured as an average of …rm
e¤ects, an uncertainty over the correct interpretation of estimated industry e¤ects will persist."
This means that the analysis cannot be complete until we disentangle the roles of workers and
…rms in de…ning the industry wage structure. If …rms are an important factor in explaining
interindustry wage di¤erences then, as Krueger and Summers (1987) suggest, the dispersion in
wages between industries must be decomposed into three parts, the part due to person e¤ects,
the part due to …rm e¤ects and the part due to the covariance between the two. To do this, we
use AKM’s (1999) exact decomposition.
5
Statistical approach
5.1
Unobserved heterogeneity and interindustry wage di¤erentials
In the previous section we speci…ed a competitive model of wage determination that only
considers observed characteristics of workers and …rms, and unobserved worker characteristics
11
A wage contour is de…ned by Dunlop (1964, p. 17) as a stable group of …rms "[...] which are so linked
together by (a) similarity of product markets, (b) by resort to similar sources of labour force, or (c) by common
labour market organization that they have common wage making characteristics".
14
as determinants of wages. We now specify a match e¤ects model that considers not only
observed characteristics, but also unmeasured worker, …rm and match e¤ects.12 This will allow
the estimation and decomposition of interindustry wage di¤erences into parts attributable to
unobserved individual, …rm, and worker-…rm match heterogeneity. The match e¤ects model
estimates a wage equation of the type:
y =X +D +F
where X(N
means); D(N
Z)
+G +
(2)
is the matrix of observable time varying covariates (in deviations from the grand
N)
is the matrix of indicators for worker i = 1; :::; N ; F(N
J)
indicators for the …rm at which worker i is employed at period t; and G(N
of indicators of worker-…rm matches. y is a (N
is the matrix of
M)
is the matrix
1) vector of log monthly real wages (also in
deviations from the grand means).13 The set of parameters to estimate are ; the Z
of coe¢cients on the covariates; , the N
…rm e¤ects; and
the M
1 vector of worker e¤ects;
, the J
1 vector
1 vector of
1 vector of unobserved match e¤ects.
Because industry is a characteristic of the …rm, the pure interindustry wage di¤erential,
conditional on the same information as in equation (2), is de…ned as
k
for some industry
classi…cation k = 1; :::; K.14 Therefore, the de…nition of the pure industry e¤ect ( k ) is the
aggregation of the pure …rm e¤ects ( ) within the industry, that is
k
T
N X
X
1(K(J(i; t)) = k)
Nk
i=1 t=1
J(i;t)
(3)
where
Nk
J
X
1(K(j) = k)Nj
j=1
and K(j) is a function denoting the industry a¢liation of …rm j.15 This aggregation of J …rm
12
This section follows very closely the framework developed in section 2.1 in AKM (1999), and Woodcock’s
(2008a) extension to incorporate match e¤ects.
13
In the presence of an unbalanced panel dataset (as we have here) where both workers and …rms can enter
T
P
or exit the panel during the period of analysis, the total number of observations per worker is N =
Ti:
i=1
14
Model (1) does not consider …rm e¤ects. Therefore, it involves the aggregation of …rm e¤ects into industry
dummy indicators.
15
These equations, e.g. correspond to those found in AKM (1999) p. 258.
15
e¤ects into
(2),
K(J(i;t)) ,
J(i;t)
k
industry e¤ects corresponds to including industry indicator variables in equation
and de…ning what is left of the pure …rm e¤ect as a deviation from industry e¤ects,
16
K(J(i;t)) .
In matrix notation:
y = X + D + F A + (F
where the matrix A, J
(4)
K, with element ajk = 1 if K(j) = k; classi…es each of the J …rms
into one of the K industries. The parameter vector
the pure …rm e¤ects. (F
FA ) + G +
, K
1, is the weighted average of
F A ) is the …rm e¤ect net of industry e¤ects. This e¤ect can
also be expressed as MF A F , where MF A is the matrix that obtains deviations from industry
means. The least squares estimates of equation (4) have no biases due to omitted variables
or to aggregation as (4) only decomposes F
into two orthogonal components: the industry
e¤ects F A , and the …rm e¤ects net of the industry e¤ect (F
F A ). It is worth noticing
that, because industry a¢liation is de…ned as a characteristic of the …rm, we do not have to
actually run model (4). Pure industry e¤ects, F A , are standard averages of …rm e¤ects within
the industry, as shown in (3). An alternative method of computing these averages (and to make
the orthogonal decomposition of the pure …rm e¤ects) is to specify a model that regresses the
pure …rm e¤ects (F ), estimated from equation (2), on the set of mutually exclusive dummy
variables for the K industries.17
If wages are in fact determined according to speci…cation (2), that is if the expected values or
probability limit of unobserved worker, …rm and match e¤ects are non-zero, then the estimated
returns to the observed characteristics, industry a¢liation included, are biased if we use model
(1).18 AKM (1999) discuss the biases that arise due to omitted residual …rm e¤ects (column
4 of Table 6), and to omitted person and residual …rm e¤ects (column 3 of Table 6) when
16
Authors attempt to use industry classi…cations as detailed as to have more than 90 industry codes. The
reason for decomposing industrial aggregates into the most detailed level possible is related to the possibility that
average compensation policies of …rms may vary across …ner levels of classi…cation and not within aggregates,
and so estimates can be subject to aggregation biases. The pure industry e¤ects, however, are not subject to
this bias because they are computed from …rm-level estimates. (Woodcock, 2008)
17
To clarify, we know that in a model without a constant: Yi = Xi + ui , Yi = E[Y jXi ] + ui . Therefore,
the coe¢cients obtained are the pure industry e¤ects (F A ), or average …rm e¤ects within the industry, and the
residual from this regression is the remaining, or residual, …rm e¤ect (F
F A ): (This result is true because
industry dummies are mutually exclusive and their covariance is zero.)
18
In the case where person, …rm and match e¤ects have non-zero expectation, the bias would not exist only
if these components were orthogonal to the observed covariates, which is unlikely.
16
we specify the wage equation as a function of unobserved person and …rm heterogeneity only
(that is, the match e¤ect (G ) is included in the error term). Woodcock (2008a) extends this
discussion by deriving the biases caused by the omission of match e¤ects when wages are also
determined by match unobserved heterogeneity.
Understanding the nature and composition of these biases is the tool for decomposing the
raw interindustry wage di¤erentials (column (3) of Table 6) into the contributions due to worker,
…rm, and match e¤ects. Consequently, in the next section we revise the biases generated by the
omission of the three components of unobserved heterogeneity, focussing solely on the industry
coe¢cients, and explain the procedure to identify the relative importance of each unobserved
e¤ect in explaining the raw interindustry wage di¤erentials.19
5.2
Omission of person, …rm and match e¤ects
If the true data generation process is given by equation (2) but estimates of industry e¤ects are
based upon a model that omits person, …rm and match e¤ects (and so we estimate some
instead of the pure industry e¤ect, ), this implies that D ; (F
,
F A ) and G of model (4)
are moved into the error term and our model takes the form
y=X
where " = (F
+ FA
+"
(5)
F A ) + D + G + . Because the set of regressors can be broken up in
two groups, in this case X (observed characteristics of workers and …rms) and F A (industry
e¤ects), we can transform (5) as follows
y = PW y + M W y = X
where W = [X
+ FA
+ MW y
(6)
F A]; PW = X(X 0 X) 1 X 0 ; is the matrix that averages the observations across
time for each individual and has typical element ui: ; and MW = I
PW ; is the matrix that
obtains the deviations from individual means and has typical element uit
19
The focus on industry coe¢cients only is for clarity of reasoning. Similarly, the
the same biases and so this discussion also applies to them.
17
ui: .
and
are
parameters su¤er from
the least squares estimates obtained from (5). Premultiplying (6) by (F A)0 MX we obtain
A 0 F 0 M X y = A0 F 0 M X F A
and solving with respect to
we obtain the estimator of industry e¤ects20
= (A0 F 0 MX F A) 1 A0 F 0 MX y:
Under the assumption that
(7)
is uncorrelated with (but correlated with the other components
of the error term of (5)), and because MX annihilates X (that is, MX X = 0); the expectation
of (7) is
E[
that is the estimator
]=
+ (A0 F 0 MX F A)
1
A0 F 0 MX (MF A F
+D +G )
is equal to the pure industry e¤ects, , plus the sum of the employment-
duration weighted average of the residual …rm e¤ect, the person and match e¤ects inside the
industry, given X. This means that the bias is equal to the sum of the weighted portion of …rm,
person and match e¤ects that is explained by the included covariates. Given that the pure …rm
e¤ect, F , is equal to the sum of the pure industry e¤ect, F A ; with the residual …rm e¤ect,
F
F A ; we can rearrange the previous equation and obtain
E[
] = (A0 F 0 MX F A)
1
+ (A0 F 0 MX F A)
A0 F 0 M X F
1
+ (A0 F 0 MX F A)
1
A0 F 0 M X D +
(8)
A0 F 0 M X G :
This expression shows that the raw interindustry wage di¤erential, i.e. the di¤erential obtained
in a model that does not include unobserved worker, …rm and match e¤ects, can be decomposed
into the sum of the industry average …rm e¤ect, the industry average person e¤ect and the
industry average match e¤ect, each of these averages conditional on X. These averages are
the expectation of the least squares estimator in auxiliary regressions of each of the omitted
20
These estimates are obtained from a Frisch-Waugh-Lovell (FWL) regression. In a model in which the
regressors can be split into two groups, and these are transformed to be mutually orthogonal, then OLS estimates
of the parameter of interest obtained either from the original speci…cation or from the modi…ed model are
numerically identical. See Davidson and MacKinnon (2004) for a thorough presentation of the FWL theorem.
18
regressors on the included regressors.21 Equation (8) is exact if the values of
and
and
are
known in which case we can have a consistent estimate of the decomposition based in (8). The
decomposition is done in the following section.
6
The sources of interindustry wage di¤erentials
In this section we decompose the raw interindustry wage di¤erentials into proportions due to
person, …rm and match e¤ects, as shown in equation (8). The raw wage di¤erentials,
are estimated using model (1). The person, ; …rm,
;
; and match, ; e¤ects are estimated
from the match e¤ects speci…cation (2). The estimation of this model involves a three-step
procedure. Firstly,
is estimated after transforming (2) into deviations from match-speci…c
means. Results from partitioned regression imply that b is a consistent estimate of . Secondly,
b and b are computed using the person and …rm e¤ects model (a model without unobserved
match e¤ects as in AKM, 1999).22 Finally, the match e¤ects estimator is de…ned as the error
from the regression of worker-…rm matches on a constant and on the person and …rm e¤ects
estimated previously.23 This match e¤ect can be correlated with the observed covariates, but
is orthogonal to the person and …rm e¤ects.
6.1
Pure interindustry wage di¤erentials
Before moving to the exact decomposition of the raw interindustry wage di¤erentials we present
the resulting industry wage structure when we control only for person and …rm e¤ects, and
when we also include match e¤ects in equation (2). We are thus able to establish whether true
interindustry wage di¤erentials exist after we control for all types of measured and unmeasured
heterogeneity. These results are shown in Table 7. To the extent that it adds further controls
for unobserved heterogeneity, this table can be considered a continuation of Table 6. Compared
21
This is easier to recognise if we compare the expression of each component of equation (8), with the logic
that connects equations (5) and (7).
22
These were estimated using the exact least squares solution (instead of the approximate method of AKM,
1999) as developed by Abowd, Creecy and Kramarz (2002), Ferreira (2009b).
T
ij
P
yijt xijt b
23
= (b
u + bi + b j + bij ); where b is the withinThat is, we estimate the following model: b
y ij =
Tij
t=1
match estimator of , and b and b are the worker and …rm unobserved e¤ects previously identi…ed using the
person and …rm e¤ects model.
19
to a speci…cation that includes only unobserved worker characteristics (Table 6, column 4), the
interindustry wage dispersion doubles when we also consider both person and …rm e¤ects (Table
7, column 1) or when we control for person, …rm and match e¤ects (Table 7, column 2). The
results for the match e¤ects model are unbiased estimates of interindustry wage di¤erentials.
The adjusted standard deviation is now 0.15, which suggests that unobserved abilities of workers
are not the sole factor in‡uencing productivity, hence wages, and that compensation policies of
…rms vary across industries.
[Table 7 about here]
The wage structure reported in Table 7 corresponds to our estimate of the pure interindustry
wage di¤erentials. These results, however, are an average for the 1986-2000 period and do not
allow us to verify the persistence of the pure interindustry wage structure over the 14 year
period. To assess how stable these di¤erentials are, we computed the annual average of …rm
e¤ects within industries and correlated the yearly industry coe¢cients with that observed in
1986. Our results reveal that the magnitude of the weighted correlations of the pure industry
e¤ects in 1986 with those of the following years ranges from 0.92 in 2000 to 0.999 in 1987
(see Table 8). Therefore, the pure interindustry wage di¤erentials are unlikely to be caused by
transitory shocks. Given the persistence and large dispersion of the pure interindustry wage
structure we understand that if a worker changes industries he can experience considerable
wage growth.
[Table 8 about here]
6.2
Decomposition of raw interindustry wage di¤erentials
We now proceed with the decomposition of the raw interindustry wage di¤erentials into a part
due to person e¤ects, a part due to …rm e¤ects and another part due to match e¤ects as shown
in equation (8). The raw industry e¤ects,
, estimated from equation (1), are presented in
column 3 of Table 6 for reference. The other components of equation (8), that is the industry
average …rm e¤ect (the …rst component of the equation) the industry average person e¤ect
(the second component), and the industry average match e¤ect (the third component) were
20
estimated using model (2). Results for the estimated version of equation (8), both when we are
in the context of a person and …rm e¤ects model or in the context of a match e¤ects model, are
presented in Table 9. These regressions yield an R2 of 1 and the coe¢cients on the industry
average person and …rm e¤ects are very close to 1, see column (1). The same is not true for the
coe¢cient of the average match e¤ects, suggesting less precision in its estimate.24 This means
that these components fully account for the raw industry e¤ects and that the estimates of the
interindustry wage di¤erentials are su¢ciently precise to allow an accurate decomposition. Since
the industry average person, …rm, and match e¤ects are centered to have a zero sample mean,
the terms high wage-worker, -…rm, or -match mean, respectively, workers, …rms or matches
whose e¤ect is greater than the economy-wide average of zero. The same interpretation applies
to the raw interindustry wage di¤erentials. The R2 in columns (2) through (4) show results for
the upper bound of the share of person, …rm and match e¤ects, respectively, in explaining the
raw interindustry wage di¤erentials. With the estimated version of equation (8) we …nd that
industry average person e¤ects are able to explain at most 31% while the industry average …rm
e¤ects explain a maximum of 90% of the observed dispersion in wages across industries.25
In Table 10 we present the exact decomposition of raw interindustry wage di¤erentials for
both the person and …rm e¤ects model and the match e¤ects model. This decomposition is
done in proportional terms as follows
share of
share of
due to individual e¤ects =
due to …rm e¤ects =
(A0 F 0 MX F A)
(A0 F 0 MX F A)
1
1
A0 F 0 M X D
A0 F 0 M X F
(a)
(b)
and
share of
due to match e¤ects =
(A0 F 0 MX F A)
1
A0 F 0 MX G
:
(c)
In the case of the person and …rm e¤ects model, (a) and (b) (shown in columns 2 and 3,
respectively) must add to 1, whilst in the case of the match e¤ects model, (a), (b) and (c)
24
The estimated unobserved e¤ects should have an impact equal to its size in the regression, therefore, its
coe¢cient should be one.
25
Note that, similar to AKM (1999), the person and …rm e¤ects are weakly correlated (correlation below
0.10) and so we expect little of the person e¤ect to be explained by the …rm e¤ect.
21
(shown in columns 4, 5 and 6, respectively) add up to 1. Regardless of the model used,
the average proportion of raw interindustry wage di¤erentials due to industry average person
e¤ects is about 30%, while the average proportion of raw di¤erentials due to the industry
average …rm e¤ects is close to 70%. Match e¤ects have a smaller role in explaining the raw
industry wage premia (3%). One could think that the low proportion explained by the match
e¤ects is due to the assumption that they are orthogonal to person and …rm e¤ects. However,
Woodcock (2008) also estimates negligible interindustry variation in the match e¤ects despite
not assuming orthogonality. We have also checked whether the average proportion explained by
each component would di¤er for the group industries paying wages above the economy average
and those paying wages below the economy average. The results remained unchanged. Both in
the case of high wage industries and low wage industries, industry average …rm e¤ects explain
close to 70% of the estimated raw di¤erential.
Our last exercise is to compute the correlation between the industry average person e¤ects
and the industry average …rm e¤ects. Using the person and …rm e¤ects model we obtain a
positive correlation (0.45) between these two components, which means that across industries
we have either high wage workers working in high wage …rms, or low wage workers in low
wage …rms. Therefore, from the person and …rm e¤ects model we conclude that the nature of
the raw interindustry wage di¤erentials is related to positive assortative matching, and that
the forces that sort person e¤ects are correlated with the forces that sort …rm e¤ects within
industries. This result contrasts with that obtained by Abowd et al. (2005), who …nd weak
positive correlations between industry average person and …rm e¤ects, and Woodcock (2008)
who, when using the person and …rm e¤ects model, …nds this correlation to be weak and
negative (-0.10). However, Woodcock (2008) …nds a positive correlation (0.60) between these
two components when using estimates from the hybrid match e¤ects model.
Our main …ndings can now be summarized as follows. We conclude that the raw interindustry wage di¤erentials are not a temporary disequilibrium in the labour market and are
not due to systematic di¤erences in unobserved labour quality across industries. Di¤erences in
compensation policies of …rms are the main source of the di¤erentials found in cross-sectional
analysis. The pure interindustry wage structure (computed as the average …rm e¤ects within
industry), on the other hand, shows considerable dispersion (weighted standard deviation of
22
0.15) and is also very persistent.
To some extent, the results found seem to re‡ect the nature of the Portuguese labour market.
Collective bargaining, the predominant means of wage negotiation in Portugal, on the one hand,
helps generating wage contours at the industry level as most of the collective agreements are
industry-wide and so cover …rms with di¤erent economic characteristics within the industry.
This helps explaining the existence and persistence of a genuine wage structure across industries.
On the other hand, we concluded that, in contrast to results found in other studies where
both unobserved worker and …rm e¤ects were important in explaining the interindustry wage
structure, the estimated wage di¤erentials in Portugal are mostly due to …rm e¤ects. This result
is compatible with a labour market with low levels of labour mobility, but high levels of wage
‡exibility. As …rms can choose to pay higher wages to adjust for speci…c economic conditions,
adjustments in the Portuguese labour market seem to be made via price rather than quantity,
while in other economies adjustments may occur through mobility (worker e¤ect) and price
(…rm e¤ect).
7
Testing the competitive model
We have found that true interindustry wage di¤erentials exist in the Portuguese economy.
Di¤erent …rms pay di¤erent wages to workers with the same characteristics (measured or unmeasured), and mobility across industries can generate substantial wage growth. However,
it is not yet clear whether non-competitive forces are at work in the economy, or whether
these di¤erentials are caused by mechanisms compatible with the competitive model such as
rent-sharing or e¢ciency wage explanations.
The hypothesis of rent sharing between …rms and workers is consistent with the fact that the
wage premia received by workers in a particular industry extends over many occupations within
the industry. It is also consistent with a positive relationship between pro…tability and wages
(Blanch‡ower, Oswald and Sanfey 1996); and with a negative correlation between turnover and
wage premia (Krueger and Summers, 1988). E¢ciency wage hypotheses are also consistent
with a negative association between industry wage di¤erences and turnover. One mechanism
that would generate this association is the existence of …rm (or industry) speci…c skills and
23
training. If some …rms have more speci…c skills than others and if they are providing training
to their workers, then they are contributing to increase the productivity of its workforce, and
making workers more costly to replace. This raises the threshold of the …rm in terms of
labour turnover, and provides incentives to increase wages in order to reduce the likelihood
of separation (Krause, 2000). If industry speci…c skills are more important than …rm speci…c
skills, then all …rms within a certain industry will be acting in similar way. Hence, levelling
up wages within the industry.26 If, on the other hand, the industry wage structure is generated
by compensating di¤erentials for unobserved working conditions, no association is expected to
be found between industry wage premia and quits. Therefore, the relationship between the
industry wage premia and separations from …rms provides a test of the competitive model of
industry wage determination.
In this section we examine the association between the industry wage structure identi…ed
in the previous section and the time workers take to separate from …rms. In the literature,
this analysis is typically done using worker-initiated separations, that is quits. We cannot
make such a distinction with our data. However, we have noticed in previous work (Ferreira,
2009b) that separations followed by short gaps (less than 1 year) of non-employment seem to
be ruled by a process di¤erent from that ruling separations followed by long gaps (longer than
1 year) of non-employment. In particular, we concluded that short gaps is more likely to be
formed by quits and long gaps by layo¤s. Hence, we use such a distinction in the present
analysis of the association between interindustry wage di¤erentials and separations.27 We
estimate parametric duration models where the dependent variable is the time to separate from
…rms, the independent variable of interest is the pure industry e¤ect (the e¤ect obtained after
controlling for all types of observed and unobserved heterogeneity), and the unit of observation
is employment spells.
26
Parent (2000), e.g., …nds that industry speci…c skills are more important then …rm-speci…c skills in determining wage growth.
27
Although, for robustness checks we also estimate models considering all separations together and separations followed by long periods of non-employment.
24
7.1
Interindustry wage di¤erentials and labour mobility
In this subsection we present the results obtained from estimating a duration model of the time
to quit a …rm assuming that time follows a loglogistic distribution.28 As well as the industry
wage premia estimated in the previous section, we also include the estimated residual …rm
e¤ects, person and match e¤ects to control for worker unobserved ability, …rm compensation
policies and match quality. The vector of observed covariates includes the age of the worker
(and its square), gender, educational level, skill level, occupation, part-time or full-time work,
dummy for having previously changed …rms, type of instrument of collective regulation, size
of …rm, legal structure of the …rm, percentage of foreign capital, region and year. Estimates
of the e¤ects of industry wage premia on the time to quit the …rm are presented in Table 11.
Given the functional form of the model, these coe¢cients measure relative changes in survival
time for a given absolute change in the regressors. A positive coe¢cient indicates that time
to separation is lengthened, while a negative coe¢cient indicates that time to separation is
shortened. Because industry e¤ects are measured in deviation from the grand means, these
e¤ects are measured against an economy wide average of zero.
The average e¤ect of interindustry wage di¤erentials on the time to separation is positive and
signi…cant, which means that the larger the industry wage premium, the longer workers take to
change …rms. In the case of quits, increasing the industry wage premium by one unit lengthens
the time to quit the industry by 37%.29 The coe¢cient on the industry wage premium is also
positive and signi…cant when we consider layo¤s (0.51) and all separations together (0.41).30
Our result is consistent with a context in which …rm or industry speci…c skills are important
and where the gains of retaining workers for long periods outweigh the gains in productivity
resulting from adjusting the labour force to every transitory demand shock. That is, …rms …nd
it optimal to pay wages above the competitive level in order to provide incentives for workers
28
Where a quit is separation that is followed by a period of non-employment that lasted less than one year.
The choice of loglogistic distribution follows from speci…cation tests. See Ferreira (2009a) for more details.
29
To clarify the interpretation, consider model (4) and that the estimated coe¢cient ( ) for industry k was
zero. If the coe¢cient is now 1, i.e. if the industry pays wages 100% above the economy average, then the time
to separate from a …rm in this industry, on average, increases by 37%.
30
We can think of two potential reasons for the larger e¤ect found for layo¤s than for quits. On the one
hand, if a worker is …red, a signal about his quality might be being sent to other …rms within the industry,
hence it takes longer to …nd a job. On the other hand, having worked for a high wage industry, workers have a
high reservation wage. Hence, it takes longer to …nd a matching o¤er and/or to adjust expectations.
25
to remain at the …rm. If the bene…ts …rms extract from this longer term attachment o¤set the
costs of higher wages, then this can be a pro…t maximising strategy. Therefore, the industry
wage di¤erentials found in our data might not be totally incompatible with the competitive
model.
8
Summary and conclusions
This paper examines the sources of interindustry wage di¤erentials. In a competitive labour
market, in the long run, homogeneous workers working in similar …rms are paid similar wages.
Wage di¤erences across segments of the labour market, be it …rms or industries, are due to
temporary di¤erences in productivity and are a signal for labour mobility. The ‡ow of workers across segments equalizes wages. However, cross-sectional analysis of wages typically …nd
that there are signi…cant and persistent di¤erences in wages across industries. Unsurprisingly,
our cross-sectional analysis using Portuguese data con…rms these results. The industry wage
structure in Portugal shows high dispersion at points in time and the di¤erentials persist over
time. These …ndings prompt the question of what explains the existence of a structure of wages
across industries.
The two most common explanations for the identi…ed cross-sectional interindustry wage
di¤erentials are that the wage structure found is due to imperfect measures of labour quality;
alternatively, genuine interindustry wage di¤erentials do exist and compensation policies of …rms
vary across industries. If the industry wage premia are real, then noncompetitive mechanisms
may be at work in the labour market, because by paying supracompetitive wages …rms might
not be maximising their pro…ts. On the other hand, and compatible with a competitive model,
…rms may …nd it pro…table to pay wages above the competitive level.
We examined the sources of interindustry wage di¤erentials using panel data over a 15
year period. Our models control for observed worker and …rm characteristics, but also for
unobserved worker, …rm and match heterogeneity. Results show that after controlling for all
types of heterogeneity the true interindustry wage di¤erentials are sizeable and persistent. This
means that compensation policies of …rms vary across industries and that by changing industries
workers enjoy substantial wage growth. Furthermore, we conclude that …rm compensation
26
policies are the main source of the di¤erentials found in cross-sectional analysis and explain,
on average, about 70% of the raw industry wage structure. Unmeasured worker abilities are
not as important and account for less than a third of such structure. We thus conclude that
interindustry wage di¤erentials are not a trick caused by unmeasured labour productive quality
and are not a temporary disequilibrium in the labour market, they re‡ect di¤erent treats given
by …rms across industries.
Why might …rms treat their workers by paying them supra-competitive wages? We focus
on the turnover strand of e¢ciency wage models to investigate if the industry wage structure is
caused by mechanisms compatible with the competitive model, by testing the e¤ect of the pure
wage premia on the time workers take to separate from …rms. Our results indicate that the
e¤ect of the industry wage premium on the time to quit …rms is positive and signi…cant. This
is consistent with a labour market in which industry speci…c skills are important and where
e¢ciencies are gained from creating incentives to worker-…rm attachments.
Some questions remain unanswered and demand further research into the black box of the
…rm. The major driving force of these di¤erentials or why they exist, has yet to be established.
Although e¢ciency wage models may provide reasons for …rms to pay higher wages, we still do
not know what di¤erences in the production functions of …rms make labour more valuable in
some industries than in others. If the reason is related to di¤erences in productivity, then we
should be able to identify what generates productivity dispersion across industries. Also any
association/causality between these wage contours and characteristics of the product market has
yet to be determined. Answers to these questions enhance our understanding of the mechanisms
determining why …rms pay nomcompetitive wages and why that happens with greater intensity
in some industries than others.
27
References
Abowd, John M., Robert H. Creecy and Francis Kramarz (2002) "Computing person and …rm
e¤ects using linked longitudinal employer-employee data." U.S. Census Bureau Technical
Paper No. TP-2002-06.
Abowd, John M., Hampton Finer and Francis Kramarz (1999) "Individual and …rm heterogeneity in compensation: an analysis of matched longitudinal employer-employee data
for the State of Washington." in Haltiwanger, J. C., J. I. Lane, J. R. Spletzer, J. J. M.
Theeuwes and K. R. Troske (editors): The Creation and Analysis of Employer-Employee
Matched Data. North-Holland, Amsterdam: 3-24.
Abowd, John M., Francis Kramarz, Paul Lengermann and Sébastien Roux (2005) "Persistent
interindustry wage di¤erences: Rent sharing and opportunity costs.", unpublished paper.
Abowd, John M., Francis Kramarz and David N. Margolis (1999) "High wage workers and
high wage …rms." Econometrica, 67(2):251-333.
Blackburn, McKinley and David Neumark (1992) "Unobserved ability, e¢ciency wages , and
interindustry wage di¤erentials." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(4): 1421-1436.
Blanch‡ower, David G., Andrew J. Oswald and Peter Sanfey (1996) "Wages, pro…ts and
rent-sharing." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(1): 227-251.
Carruth, Alan, William Collier and Andy Dickerson (2004) "Interindustry wage di¤erences and
individual heterogeneity." Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 66(5): 811-846.
Davidson, Russell and James G. MacKinnon (2004) Econometric Theory and Methods. Oxford
University Press, New York.
Dickens, William T. and Lawrence F. Katz (1987) "Interindustry wage di¤erences and industry
characteristics." in Kevin Lang and Jonathan S. Leonard (editors): Unemployment and
the Structure of Labour Markets. Basil Blackwell Inc., Oxford. 48-89.
Dunlop, John T. (1964) "The task of contemporary wage theory." in John T. Dunlop (editor):
The Theory of Wage Determination. Macmillan, London: 3-27.
Ferreira, Priscila (2009a) "The determinants of promotions and …rm separations.", ISER
Working paper No. 2009-11, University of Essex.
Ferreira, Priscila (2009b) "Returns to job mobility: the role of observed an unobserved factors."
ISER Working paper No. 2009-12, University of Essex.
Gibbons, Robert and Lawrence Katz (1992) "Does unmeasured ability explain interindustry
wage di¤erentials?" Review of Economic Studies, 59(3): 515-535.
Goux, Dominique and Eric Maurin (1999) "Persistence of interindustry wage di¤erentials:
A reexamination using matched worker-…rm panel data." Journal of Labor Economics,
17(3): 492-533.
Krause, Michael U. (2002) "interindustry wage di¤erentials and job ‡ows." CentER working
paper no. 2002-03.
28
Krueger, Alan B. and Lawrence H. Summers (1988) "E¢ciency wages and the interindustry
wage structure." Econometrica, 56(2): 259-293.
Krueger, Alan B. and Lawrence H. Summers (1987) "Re‡ections on the interindustry wage
structure." in Kevin Lang and Jonathan S. Leonard (editors): Unemployment and the
Structure of Labour Markets. Basil Blackwell Inc., Oxford: 17-47.
Jovanovic, Boyan and Robert Mo¢t (1990) "An estimate of a sectoral model of labor mobility."
Journal of Political Economy, 98(4): 827-852.
Magda, Iga, François Rycx, Ilan Tojerow and Daphné Valsamis (2008) "Wage di¤erentials
across sectors in Europe: an East-West comparison.", IZA DP No. 3830.
Murphy, Kevin M. and Robert H. Topel (1987) "Unemployment, risk, and earnings." in Kevin
Lang and Jonathan S. Leonard (editors): Unemployment and the Structure of Labour
Markets. Basil Blackwell Inc., Oxford: 103-140.
OECD [Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development] (2006). OECD Economic
Survey of Portugal, 2006. Paris: OECD.
OECD [Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development] (2003). OECD Economic
Survey of Portugal, 2003. Paris: OECD.
Parent, Daniel (2000) "Industry-speci…c capital and the wage pro…le: Evidence from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth and the Panel Study of Income Dynamics." Journal
of Labor Economics, 18(2): 306-323.
Thaler, Richard H. (1989) "Anomalies: Interindustry wage di¤erentials." Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 3(2): 181-193.
Woodcock, Simon (2008) "Wage di¤erentials in the presence of unobserved worker, …rm and
match heterogeneity." Labour Economics, 15(4): 772-794.
Woodcock, Simon (2008a) "Match e¤ects", unpublished paper, Department of Economics,
Simon Fraser University.
29
Tables
Table 1: Descriptive statistics of variables
Variable
Log monthly real wage
Seniority (years)
Experience (years)
Hours of work (monthly)
Yearly gap
Gender
Men
Women
Education
ISCED 1
ISCED 2
ISCED 3
ISCED 5/6
Occupations
Directors
Intellectual and scienti…c specialists
Professional, technical (intermediate)
Administrative and managerial workers
Clerical and sales workers
Agriculture, silviculture and …shing
Production and related workers
Equipment operators and labourers
Unquali…ed workers
Skill Level
High
Medium
Low
Type of work
Full time
Part time
Type of job mobility
Automatic promotion
Merit promotion
Separation, small gap
Separation, big gap
Size of …rm
Micro
Small
Medium
Large
Instrument of collective regulation
Collective agreement
Collective contract
Regulating law
Firm agreement
Legal structure of …rm
Public (Private market law)
Sole proprietor
Anonymous partnership
Limited liability company
Mean
6.3
8.7
22
170
0.14
61.7
38.4
71.6
11.3
12.6
4.6
1.7
2.0
8.3
14.1
8.5
1.26
25.6
13.9
18.0
18.4
43.5
38.1
91.5
8.4
7.7
2.9
1.6
3.1
9.2
25.0
29.2
36.6
4.0
82.7
3.8
8.7
4.8
5.3
29.0
55.2
Variable
Percentage of foreign capital
Region
Year
Industry
Agriculture
Silviculture
Fishing
Mining
Food products
Beverages
Tobacco
Textiles
Clothing
Leather
Shoes
Wood and cork
Furniture
Pulp, paper, paper prod.
Publishing and printing
Industrial chemicals
Other chemicals
Petrol, rubber, plastics
Ceramics
Glass
Other non-met min prod.
Base metals
Metallic products
Non-electric materials
Electric materials
Motor vehicles
Professional instruments
Other manufacturing
Elect., gas and water
Building
Wholesale trade
Retail trade
Restaurants and cafes
Hotels
Transport
Communications
Banking
Insurance
Real estate
Productive services - transport
Other productive services
Social services
Personal services
Mean
9.1
20 Districts
1986-2000
1.20
0.09
0.21
0.73
3.92
0.67
0.09
7.45
6.53
0.33
3.05
2.01
1.45
0.88
1.33
0.64
1.01
1.42
1.30
0.52
1.60
0.92
3.38
1.80
2.19
2.09
0.25
0.39
1.31
9.38
7.28
7.84
2.83
1.87
5.05
1.97
3.06
0.92
3.73
0.84
0.79
3.66
2.00
Note: These statistics are computed over the sample of 1,823,572 worker-year observations. Source: Own calculations
based on Quadros de Pessoal (1986-2000).
30
Table 2: Cross-sectional interindustry regression-adjusted wage di¤erences, 19861993
Industry
Agriculture
Silviculture
Fishing
Mining
Food products
Beverages
Tobacco
Textiles
Clothing
Leather
Shoes
Wood and cork
Furniture
Pulp, paper, paper prod.
Publishing and printing
Industrial chemicals
Other chemicals
Petrol, rubber, plastics
Ceramics
Glass
Other non-met min prod.
Base metals
Metallic products
Non-electric materials
Electric materials
Motor vehicles
Professional instruments
1986
-0.186
(0.010)
-0.071
(0.038)
-0.135
(0.021)
0.031
(0.009)
-0.064
(0.004)
-0.095
(0.009)
-0.102
(0.019)
-0.081
(0.003)
-0.124
(0.004)
-0.005
(0.012)
-0.087
(0.006)
-0.120
(0.005)
-0.239
(0.007)
0.047
(0.007)
-0.041
(0.007)
0.073
(0.007)
0.043
(0.007)
0.009
(0.006)
0.021
(0.008)
0.205
(0.010)
0.003
(0.006)
-0.013
(0.006)
-0.066
(0.004)
-0.073
(0.006)
0.056
(0.006)
0.008
(0.005)
-0.031
(0.014)
1987
-0.20
(0.010)
-0.046
(0.032)
-0.114
(0.022)
0.007
(0.009)
-0.073
(0.004)
-0.104
(0.009)
-0.077
(0.019)
-0.075
(0.003)
-0.095
(0.004)
0.021
(0.012)
-0.071
(0.005)
-0.109
(0.005)
-0.246
(0.007)
0.053
(0.007)
-0.046
(0.007)
0.067
(0.007)
0.034
(0.007)
-0.012
(0.006)
0.037
(0.007)
0.205
(0.010)
0.013
(0.006)
-0.026
(0.006)
-0.047
(0.004)
-0.070
(0.006)
0.065
(0.006)
0.043
(0.005)
-0.026
(0.014)
1988
-0.167
(0.009)
-0.041
(0.023)
-0.181
(0.032)
0.025
(0.009)
-0.078
(0.004)
-0.107
(0.009)
-0.028
(0.020)
-0.108
(0.003)
-0.108
(0.004)
0.018
(0.011)
-0.084
(0.005)
-0.114
(0.005)
-0.247
(0.007)
0.036
(0.007)
-0.049
(0.007)
0.105
(0.007)
0.081
(0.007)
0.091
(0.006)
0.041
(0.007)
0.168
(0.010)
-0.000
(0.006)
-0.010
(0.006)
-0.055
(0.004)
-0.051
(0.006)
0.084
(0.006)
0.005
(0.005)
-0.061
(0.016)
1989
-0.153
(0.009)
-0.054
(0.020)
-0.271
(0.025)
0.033
(0.008)
-0.089
(0.004)
-0.120
(0.009)
0.046
(0.021)
-0.115
(0.003)
-0.112
(0.004)
-0.008
(0.012)
-0.108
(0.005)
-0.095
(0.005)
-0.229
(0.007)
0.038
(0.007)
-0.031
(0.007)
0.094
(0.008)
0.058
(0.007)
0.115
(0.006)
0.029
(0.007)
0.152
(0.010)
0.035
(0.006)
-0.012
(0.007)
-0.047
(0.004)
-0.048
(0.006)
0.067
(0.006)
0.005
(0.005)
-0.048
(0.016)
1991
-0.106
(0.010)
-0.012
(0.029)
-0.185
(0.028)
0.076
(0.009)
-0.076
(0.004)
-0.123
(0.010)
0.117
(0.024)
-0.119
(0.004)
-0.113
(0.004)
-0.028
(0.013)
-0.135
(0.005)
-0.083
(0.006)
-0.234
(0.007)
0.075
(0.008)
0.019
(0.007)
0.052
(0.010)
0.058
(0.007)
0.101
(0.007)
0.033
(0.007)
0.118
(0.011)
0.054
(0.006)
-0.023
(0.008)
-0.039
(0.005)
-0.033
(0.006)
0.073
(0.006)
0.087
(0.006)
-0.044
(0.016)
1992
-0.126
(0.011)
-0.075
(0.031)
-0.217
(0.033)
0.099
(0.009)
-0.078
(0.004)
-0.112
(0.010)
0.003
(0.027)
-0.123
(0.004)
-0.128
(0.004)
-0.006
(0.013)
-0.114
(0.005)
-0.096
(0.006)
-0.219
(0.007)
0.034
(0.008)
0.014
(0.007)
0.066
(0.010)
0.067
(0.008)
0.073
(0.007)
0.029
(0.008)
0.098
(0.011)
0.041
(0.006)
-0.016
(0.008)
-0.028
(0.005)
-0.030
(0.006)
0.074
(0.006)
0.078
(0.006)
0.015
(0.017)
1993
-0.122
(0.011)
-0.023
(0.033)
-0.243
(0.033)
0.112
(0.009)
-0.069
(0.004)
-0.106
(0.010)
0.034
(0.027)
-0.138
(0.004)
-0.149
(0.004)
0.002
(0.013)
-0.114
(0.005)
-0.091
(0.006)
-0.261
(0.007)
0.030
(0.009)
0.033
(0.007)
0.086
(0.011)
0.058
(0.008)
0.074
(0.007)
0.011
(0.008)
0.099
(0.011)
0.025
(0.006)
-0.004
(0.008)
-0.019
(0.005)
-0.010
(0.006)
0.071
(0.006)
0.086
(0.006)
-0.049
(0.017)
(Continued on next page)
31
Table 2: (continued from previous page)
Industry
Other manufacturing
Elect., gas and water
Building
Wholesale trade
Retail trade
Restaurants and cafes
Hotels
Transport
Communications
Banking
Insurance
Real estate
Productive services - transp
Other productive services
Social services
Personal services
F-stat
Weighted SD
No. of obs
1986
-0.095
(0.011)
0.258
(0.007)
-0.052
(0.003)
0.014
(0.003)
-0.049
(0.004)
-0.091
(0.006)
0.031
(0.006)
0.109
(0.004)
0.091
(0.006)
0.289
(0.011)
0.413
(0.009)
0.102
(0.007)
0.287
(0.010)
-0.096
(0.009)
-0.088
(0.007)
-0.088
(0.006)
227.81
0.104
103,925
1987
-0.098
(0.011)
0.246
(0.007)
-0.068
(0.003)
0.009
(0.003)
-0.045
(0.004)
-0.110
(0.006)
0.020
(0.006)
0.126
(0.004)
-0.021
(0.021)
0.266
(0.010)
0.398
(0.008)
0.092
(0.007)
0.348
(0.009)
-0.108
(0.009)
-0.094
(0.006)
-0.068
(0.006)
250.50
0.103
104,893
1988
-0.112
(0.011)
0.232
(0.007)
-0.074
(0.003)
0.012
(0.003)
-0.048
(0.004)
-0.127
(0.006)
-0.001
(0.006)
0.110
(0.004)
0.131
(0.007)
0.305
(0.010)
0.360
(0.009)
0.064
(0.007)
0.267
(0.010)
-0.130
(0.009)
-0.086
(0.007)
-0.068
(0.006)
231.79
0.104
109,632
1989
-0.100
(0.010)
0.247
(0.007)
-0.060
(0.003)
0.012
(0.003)
-0.037
(0.004)
-0.121
(0.006)
0.020
(0.006)
0.108
(0.004)
0.022
(0.007)
0.369
(0.010)
0.348
(0.008)
0.041
(0.006)
0.335
(0.009)
-0.149
(0.008)
-0.111
(0.006)
-0.055
(0.005)
275.61
0.108
119,886
1991
-0.084
(0.011)
0.245
(0.008)
-0.068
(0.003)
0.020
(0.003)
-0.034
(0.004)
-0.121
(0.006)
-0.006
(0.006)
0.050
(0.005)
-0.016
(0.008)
0.243
(0.009)
0.263
(0.008)
0.017
(0.006)
0.277
(0.010)
-0.146
(0.008)
-0.100
(0.006)
-0.049
(0.005)
216.49
0.102
128,766
1992
-0.054
(0.012)
0.259
(0.008)
-0.076
(0.003)
0.030
(0.003)
-0.028
(0.004)
-0.120
(0.006)
-0.028
(0.006)
0.045
(0.005)
0.019
(0.007)
0.295
(0.010)
0.313
(0.008)
0.041
(0.006)
0.254
(0.010)
-0.143
(0.008)
-0.093
(0.006)
-0.038
(0.006)
224.71
0.109
132,284
1993
-0.057
(0.013)
0.236
(0.008)
-0.086
(0.003)
0.029
(0.003)
-0.009
(0.004)
-0.130
(0.006)
0.009
(0.007)
0.047
(0.005)
0.046
(0.008)
0.265
(0.010)
0.255
(0.008)
0.030
(0.006)
0.259
(0.010)
-0.127
(0.007)
-0.065
(0.006)
-0.029
(0.006)
220.92
0.107
130,095
Note: Because the model does not include a constant the resulting coe¢cients are proportionate di¤erences in wages between
a worker in a given industry and the average worker in the economy. Standard errors in parentheses. Weights are industry
employment shares for each year. Source: Own calculations based on Quadros de Pessoal (1986-2000).
32
Table 3: Cross-sectional interindustry regression-adjusted wage di¤erences, 19942000
Industry
Agriculture
Silviculture
Fishing
Mining
Food products
Beverages
Tobacco
Textiles
Clothing
Leather
Shoes
Wood and cork
Furniture
Pulp, paper, paper prod.
Publishing and printing
Industrial chemicals
Other chemicals
Petrol, rubber, plastics
Ceramics
Glass
Other non-met min prod.
Base metals
Metallic products
Non-electric materials
Electric materials
Motor vehicles
Professional instruments
1994
-0.140
(0.011)
-0.011
(0.031)
0.121
(0.031)
0.046
(0.010)
-0.086
(0.004)
-0.104
(0.010)
0.056
(0.029)
-0.158
(0.004)
-0.181
(0.004)
0.036
(0.013)
-0.133
(0.005)
-0.109
(0.006)
-0.248
(0.007)
0.049
(0.009)
0.007
(0.007)
0.091
(0.013)
0.074
(0.009)
0.059
(0.007)
-0.030
(0.008)
0.097
(0.011)
0.038
(0.006)
0.015
(0.009)
-0.033
(0.005)
-0.021
(0.007)
0.099
(0.006)
0.067
(0.007)
-0.122
(0.017)
1995
-0.110
(0.011)
-0.083
(0.026)
-0.051
(0.022)
0.060
(0.009)
-0.086
(0.004)
-0.072
(0.009)
0.059
(0.031)
-0.162
(0.004)
-0.174
(0.004)
0.046
(0.014)
-0.131
(0.005)
-0.077
(0.006)
-0.221
(0.006)
0.062
(0.009)
-0.008
(0.007)
0.120
(0.012)
0.083
(0.008)
0.052
(0.007)
-0.006
(0.007)
0.069
(0.011)
0.028
(0.006)
-0.018
(0.010)
-0.054
(0.005)
-0.004
(0.006)
0.048
(0.006)
0.078
(0.006)
-0.074
(0.015)
1996
-0.129
(0.011)
-0.024
(0.025)
-0.089
(0.023)
0.077
(0.010)
-0.085
(0.004)
-0.104
(0.010)
0.047
(0.032)
-0.165
(0.004)
-0.173
(0.004)
0.084
(0.013)
-0.138
(0.005)
-0.074
(0.006)
-0.198
(0.007)
0.063
(0.009)
-0.009
(0.007)
0.105
(0.011)
0.088
(0.008)
0.040
(0.007)
-0.040
(0.007)
0.111
(0.011)
0.039
(0.007)
-0.008
(0.010)
-0.047
(0.005)
0.008
(0.006)
0.010
(0.005)
0.047
(0.006)
-0.060
(0.014)
1997
-0.118
(0.010)
-0.013
(0.023)
-0.095
(0.022)
0.066
(0.009)
-0.090
(0.004)
-0.079
(0.010)
0.034
(0.031)
-0.163
(0.004)
-0.169
(0.004)
0.057
(0.014)
-0.116
(0.005)
-0.066
(0.006)
-0.193
(0.006)
0.098
(0.009)
0.012
(0.007)
0.095
(0.011)
0.076
(0.008)
0.012
(0.007)
-0.017
(0.007)
0.084
(0.011)
0.033
(0.006)
0.004
(0.010)
-0.034
(0.005)
0.017
(0.006)
0.018
(0.005)
0.048
(0.006)
-0.079
(0.015)
1998
-0.109
(0.10)
-0.019
(0.023)
-0.150
(0.022)
0.082
(0.009)
-0.090
(0.004)
-0.051
(0.010)
0.104
(0.029)
-0.158
(0.004)
-0.160
(0.004)
0.100
(0.015)
-0.109
(0.005)
-0.058
(0.006)
-0.169
(0.006)
0.084
(0.008)
0.001
(0.006)
0.060
(0.011)
0.065
(0.008)
0.037
(0.007)
-0.025
(0.006)
0.138
(0.010)
0.025
(0.006)
-0.006
(0.009)
-0.024
(0.004)
0.021
(0.005)
0.050
(0.005)
0.044
(0.005)
-0.106
(0.014)
1999
-0.090
(0.010)
0.055
(0.022)
-0.071
(0.023)
0.084
(0.009)
-0.097
(0.004)
-0.055
(0.010)
0.181
(0.027)
-0.178
(0.004)
-0.174
(0.004)
0.020
(0.015)
-0.129
(0.005)
-0.047
(0.006)
-0.180
(0.006)
0.078
(0.009)
0.010
(0.006)
0.062
(0.011)
0.059
(0.008)
0.026
(0.007)
-0.021
(0.006)
0.158
(0.010)
0.037
(0.006)
-0.017
(0.009)
-0.020
(0.004)
0.027
(0.006)
0.031
(0.005)
0.005
(0.005)
-0.040
(0.014)
2000
-0.078
(0.010)
0.076
(0.024)
-0.172
(0.023)
0.102
(0.009)
-0.103
(0.004)
-0.042
(0.010)
0.048
(0.027)
-0.151
(0.004)
-0.156
(0.004)
0.068
(0.016)
-0.123
(0.005)
-0.026
(0.006)
-0.165
(0.006)
0.043
(0.009)
0.026
(0.006)
0.073
(0.012)
0.064
(0.008)
0.047
(0.007)
-0.090
(0.006)
0.140
(0.011)
0.045
(0.006)
0.022
(0.010)
0.004
(0.004)
0.064
(0.006)
0.008
(0.006)
0.023
(0.005)
-0.073
(0.014)
(Continued on next page)
33
Table 3: (continued from previous page)
Industry
Other manufacturing
Elect., gas and water
Building
Wholesale trade
Retail trade
Restaurants and cafes
Hotels
Transport
Communications
Banking
Insurance
Real estate
Productive services - transp
Other productive services
Social services
Personal services
F-Stat
Weighted SD
No. of obs
1994
-0.071
(0.013)
0.301
(0.009)
-0.086
(0.003)
0.031
(0.004)
-0.029
(0.004)
-0.151
(0.006)
0.001
(0.006)
0.021
(0.005)
0.071
(0.008)
0.235
(0.010)
0.223
(0.009)
0.016
(0.005)
0.217
(0.011)
-0.160
(0.007)
-0.069
(0.006)
-0.032
(0.005)
227.19
0.110
130,439
1995
-0.107
(0.012)
0.277
(0.008)
-0.088
(0.003)
0.009
(0.003)
-0.025
(0.003)
-0.168
(0.005)
-0.013
(0.006)
-0.018
(0.005)
0.131
(0.007)
0.238
(0.009)
0.279
(0.009)
-0.072
(0.004)
0.214
(0.008)
0.047
(0.014)
-0.060
(0.006)
-0.018
(0.007)
238.22
0.108
134,981
1996
-0.103
(0.013)
0.230
(0.008)
-0.089
(0.003)
0.009
(0.003)
-0.024
(0.003)
-0.181
(0.005)
-0.012
(0.006)
-0.016
(0.005)
0.128
(0.007)
0.251
(0.009)
0.285
(0.008)
-0.075
(0.004)
0.238
(0.008)
0.062
(0.013)
-0.058
(0.006)
-0.022
(0.007)
241.78
0.108
134,284
1997
-0.111
(0.013)
0.239
(0.008)
-0.084
(0.003)
0.003
(0.003)
-0.017
(0.003)
-0.166
(0.005)
-0.027
(0.006)
0.020
(0.004)
0.130
(0.006)
0.191
(0.009)
0.300
(0.009)
-0.074
(0.004)
0.205
(0.008)
0.047
(0.012)
-0.068
(0.005)
-0.010
(0.006)
233.22
0.099
142,809
1998
-0.113
(0.013)
0.200
(0.008)
-0.088
(0.003)
0.002
(0.003)
-0.026
(0.003)
-0.154
(0.005)
-0.038
(0.005)
0.023
(0.004)
0.087
(0.006)
0.157
(0.009)
0.282
(0.008)
-0.069
(0.004)
0.167
(0.007)
0.037
(0.011)
-0.058
(0.005)
0.013
(0.005)
223.73
0.090
146,159
1999
-0.130
(0.013)
0.199
(0.008)
-0.081
(0.003)
-0.002
(0.003)
-0.024
(0.003)
-0.157
(0.005)
-0.034
(0.006)
0.050
(0.004)
0.052
(0.006)
0.165
(0.008)
0.257
(0.008)
-0.079
(0.004)
0.104
(0.007)
0.026
(0.011)
-0.067
(0.005)
0.006
(0.006)
224.50
0.091
150,921
2000
-0.081
(0.013)
0.103
(0.009)
-0.061
(0.003)
0.026
(0.003)
-0.007
(0.003)
-0.135
(0.005)
-0.015
(0.005)
0.070
(0.004)
0.037
(0.006)
0.117
(0.008)
0.281
(0.008)
-0.057
(0.003)
0.083
(0.007)
0.016
(0.010)
-0.036
(0.004)
-0.015
(0.005)
200.48
0.08
154,498
Note: Given that the model does not include a constant the resulting coe¢cients are proportionate di¤erences in wages
between a worker in a given industry and the average worker in the economy. Standard errors in parentheses. Weights are industry
employment shares for each year. Source: Own calculations based on Quadros de Pessoal (1986-2000).
34
Table 4: Persistence of the raw interindustry wage structure (k ) between 1986 and 2000
Year
1986
1987
1988
1989
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
Note:
Weighted correlation with 1986
1.00
0.979
0.979
0.962
0.921
0.938
0.914
0.891
0.839
0.839
0.838
0.822
0.807
0.761
Weights are average employment
shares of each industry in the period from
1986 to 2000.
Source:
Own calculations
based on Quadros de Pessoal (1986-2000).
Table 5: Analysis of sources of wage variation
Source of wage variation
Model with covariates and industry (A)
Error (1-A)
Model with covariates …rst:
Covariates (B)
Industry (A-B)
Model with industry …rst:
Industry (C)
Covariates (A-C)
Variance of log wages
Mean of log wages
Total no. of observations
No. of industries
No. of covariates
Share of TSS
0.718
0.282
0.699
0.019
0.292
0.426
0.276
0
1,823,572
43
74
Note: TSS stands for total sum of squares. Source: Own calculations based on Quadros de Pessoal (1986-2000).
35
Table 6: Estimated interindustry wage di¤erentials with di¤ering controls, pooled
data
Industry
Agriculture
Silviculture
Fishing
Mining
Food products
Beverages
Tobacco
Textiles
Clothing
Leather
Shoes
Wood and cork
Furniture
Pulp, paper, paper prod.
Publishing and printing
Industrial chemicals
Other chemicals
Petrol, rubber, plastics
Ceramics
Glass
Other non-met min prod.
Base metals
Metallic products
Non-electric materials
Electric materials
Motor vehicles
Industry
Add worker
& time
obs. e¤ects
(1)
-0.456
(0.003)
-0.348
(0.011)
-0.220
(0.007)
0.007
(0.004)
-0.180
(0.002)
0.042
(0.004)
0.360
(0.010)
-0.283
(0.001)
-0.444
(0.001)
-0.193
(0.005)
-0.403
(0.002)
-0.265
(0.002)
-0.430
(0.003)
0.177
(0.003)
0.046
(0.003)
0.400
(0.004)
0.276
(0.003)
0.128
(0.003)
-0.170
(0.003)
0.179
(0.004)
-0.020
(0.003)
0.100
(0.003)
-0.138
(0.002)
-0.007
(0.002)
0.105
(0.002)
0.169
(0.002)
(2)
-0.234
(0.003)
-0.117
(0.007)
-0.075
(0.007)
0.030
(0.003)
-0.105
(0.001)
-0.060
(0.003)
0.175
(0.007)
-0.181
(0.001)
-0.193
(0.001)
-0.049
(0.004)
-0.148
(0.001)
-0.153
(0.002)
-0.306
(0.002)
0.089
(0.002)
-0.038
(0.002)
0.162
(0.003)
0.092
(0.002)
0.053
(0.002)
-0.023
(0.002)
0.155
(0.003)
-0.003
(0.002)
0.008
(0.002)
-0.088
(0.001)
-0.038
(0.002)
0.123
(0.002)
0.081
(0.002)
Add …rm
obs. e¤ects,
(3)
-0.144
(0.003)
-0.030
(0.007)
-0.112
(0.007)
0.070
(0.002)
-0.082
(0.001)
-0.093
(0.003)
0.021
(0.007)
-0.126
(0.001)
-0.140
(0.001)
0.028
(0.004)
-0.112
(0.001)
-0.081
(0.002)
-0.213
(0.002)
0.056
(0.002)
-0.000
(0.002)
0.082
(0.003)
0.064
(0.002)
0.051
(0.002)
-0.004
(0.002)
0.135
(0.003)
0.032
(0.002)
-0.010
(0.002)
-0.034
(0.001)
-0.010
(0.002)
0.057
(0.002)
0.046
(0.002)
Add worker
unobs. e¤ects
(4)
-0.091
(0.004)
-0.035
(0.008)
-0.003
(0.008)
0.053
(0.004)
-0.040
(0.002)
-0.025
(0.004)
0.063
(0.019)
-0.045
(0.002)
-0.073
(0.002)
-0.017
(0.006)
-0.103
(0.003)
-0.063
(0.003)
-0.111
(0.003)
0.000
(0.004)
-0.025
(0.003)
0.061
(0.004)
0.004
(0.003)
0.035
(0.003)
0.023
(0.004)
0.107
(0.006)
0.034
(0.003)
-0.026
(0.003)
-0.042
(0.002)
-0.016
(0.002)
0.033
(0.002)
0.002
(0.002)
(Continued on next page)
36
Table 6: (continued from previous page)
Industry
Professional instruments
Other manufacturing
Elect., gas and water
Building
Wholesale trade
Retail trade
Restaurants and cafes
Hotels
Transport
Communications
Banking
Insurance
Real estate
Productive services - transp
Other productive services
Social services
Personal services
R2
Weighted SD
Industry
Add worker
& time
obs. e¤ects
(1)
-0.009
(0.006)
-0.249
(0.005)
0.656
(0.003)
-0.184
(0.001)
0.056
(0.001)
-0.163
(0.001)
-0.418
(0.002)
-0.063
(0.002)
0.278
(0.002)
0.509
(0.002)
0.719
(0.002)
0.663
(0.003)
-0.095
(0.002)
0.356
(0.003)
-0.339
(0.004)
-0.127
(0.002)
-0.024
(0.002)
0.33
0.287
(2)
-0.017
(0.004)
-0.147
(0.003)
0.405
(0.002)
-0.120
(0.001)
-0.020
(0.001)
-0.087
(0.001)
-0.213
(0.001)
0.006
(0.002)
0.147
(0.001)
0.263
(0.002)
0.384
(0.001)
0.340
(0.002)
-0.026
(0.001)
0.204
(0.002)
-0.085
(0.002)
-0.134
(0.001)
-0.055
(0.002)
0.68
0.153
Add …rm
obs. e¤ects,
(3)
-0.050
(0.004)
-0.093
(0.003)
0.251
(0.002)
-0.074
(0.001)
0.016
(0.001)
-0.024
(0.001)
-0.141
(0.001)
-0.008
(0.002)
0.056
(0.001)
0.083
(0.002)
0.250
(0.002)
0.309
(0.002)
-0.042
(0.001)
0.205
(0.002)
-0.087
(0.002)
-0.077
(0.001)
-0.025
(0.002)
0.72
0.100
Add worker
unobs. e¤ects
(4)
-0.011
(0.007)
-0.046
(0.004)
0.117
(0.007)
-0.050
(0.001)
-0.007
(0.001)
-0.035
(0.001)
-0.102
(0.002)
-0.003
(0.003)
0.041
(0.002)
0.086
(0.005)
0.184
(0.004)
0.236
(0.007)
-0.032
(0.002)
0.051
(0.003)
-0.021
(0.003)
-0.051
(0.003)
-0.056
(0.002)
0.47
0.064
Note: Because the model does not include a constant the resulting coe¢cients are proportionate di¤erences in wages between
a worker in a given industry and the average worker in the economy. Standard errors in parentheses. Weights are industry average
shares of employment in the period 1986-2000. The no. of observations is 1,823,572. Source: Own calculations based on Quadros
de Pessoal (1986-2000).
37
Table 7: Estimated interindustry wage di¤erentials with di¤ering controls
Industry e¤ect given X and:
person and …rm
e¤ects,
Industry
Agriculture
match e¤ects,
(1)
-0.244
(0.001)
-0.167
(0.005)
-0.010
(0.004)
0.025
(0.002)
-0.090
(0.001)
-0.027
(0.002)
0.202
(0.005)
-0.123
(0.001)
-0.186
(0.001)
-0.024
(0.003)
-0.216
(0.001)
-0.135
(0.001)
-0.291
(0.001)
0.100
(0.002)
-0.044
(0.001)
0.203
(0.002)
0.116
(0.002)
0.101
(0.001)
-0.056
(0.001)
0.186
(0.002)
0.004
(0.001)
0.037
(0.002)
-0.114
(0.001)
-0.081
(0.001)
0.090
(0.001)
0.053
(0.001)
Silviculture
Fishing
Mining
Food products
Beverages
Tobacco
Textiles
Clothing
Leather
Shoes
Wood and cork
Furniture
Pulp, paper, paper prod.
Publishing and printing
Industrial chemicals
Other chemicals
Petrol, rubber, plastics
Ceramics
Glass
Other non-met min prod.
Base metals
Metallic products
Non-electric materials
Electric materials
Motor vehicles
person, …rm and
(2)
-0.253
(0.002)
-0.173
(0.006)
-0.010
(0.004)
0.025
(0.002)
-0.093
(0.001)
-0.028
(0.002)
0.209
(0.006)
-0.127
(0.001)
-0.193
(0.001)
-0.025
(0.003)
-0.223
(0.001)
-0.140
(0.001)
-0.301
(0.001)
0.104
(0.002)
-0.046
(0.001)
0.210
(0.002)
0.120
(0.002)
0.104
(0.001)
-0.058
(0.001)
0.193
(0.002)
0.004
(0.001)
0.039
(0.002)
-0.118
(0.001)
-0.084
(0.001)
0.093
(0.001)
0.055
(0.001)
(Continued on next page)
38
Table 7: (continued from previous page)
Industry e¤ect given X and:
person and …rm
e¤ects,
Industry
Professional instruments
(1)
-0.044
(0.003)
-0.107
(0.003)
0.316
(0.001)
-0.145
(0.001)
-0.017
(0.001)
-0.106
(0.001)
-0.223
(0.001)
-0.028
(0.001)
0.101
(0.001)
0.212
(0.001)
0.383
(0.001)
0.357
(0.002)
-0.035
(0.001)
0.201
(0.002)
-0.055
(0.002)
-0.072
(0.001)
-0.050
(0.001)
-0.039
(0.000)
0.92
0.145
Other manufacturing
Elect., gas and water
Building
Wholesale trade
Retail trade
Restaurants and cafes
Hotels
Transport
Communications
Banking
Insurance
Real estate
Productive services - transp
Other productive services
Social services
Personal services
Constant
R2
Weighted SD
person, …rm and
match e¤ects,
(2)
-0.045
(0.003)
-0.111
(0.003)
0.328
(0.001)
-0.150
(0.001)
-0.018
(0.001)
-0.110
(0.001)
-0.231
(0.001)
-0.029
(0.001)
0.105
(0.001)
0.220
(0.001)
0.397
(0.001)
0.370
(0.002)
-0.036
(0.001)
0.208
(0.002)
-0.057
(0.002)
-0.075
(0.001)
-0.052
(0.001)
-0.041
(0.000)
0.94
0.150
Note: Because the model does not include a constant the resulting coe¢cients are proportionate di¤erences in wages between
a worker in a given industry and the average worker in the economy. Standard errors in parentheses. Weights are industry average
shares of employment in the period 1986-2000. The no. of observations is 1,823,572. Source: Own calculations based on Quadros
de Pessoal (1986-2000).
39
Table 8: Persistence of the pure interindustry wage structure (k) between 1986 and 2000
Year
1986
1987
1988
1989
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
Note:
Weighted correlation with 1986
1.00
0.999
0.998
0.995
0.989
0.988
0.984
0.978
0.945
0.943
0.935
0.935
0.923
0.922
Weights are average employment
shares of each industry in the period from
1986 to 2000.
Source:
Own calculations
based on Quadros de Pessoal (1986-2000).
Table 9: Estimates of the relation between the raw interindustry wage structure and industry average
person, …rm and match e¤ects
Independent variables
Person and …rm e¤ects model:
Industry average person e¤ect
Industry average …rm e¤ect
R2
Match e¤ects model:
Industry average person e¤ect
Industry average …rm e¤ect
Industry average match e¤ect
R2
(1)
0.996
(0.007)
0.998
(0.002)
1.000
1.057
(0.012)
1.047
(0.009)
2.343
(0.257)
1.000
Coe¢cients:
(2)
(3)
1.692
(0.391)
1.100
(0.058)
0.313
0.899
(4)
1.618
(0.374)
1.061
(0.055)
0.313
0.899
-25.014
(0.591)
0.978
Note: These are coe¢cients of a regression of raw interindustry wage di¤erential on
person and …rm e¤ects (for the person and …rm e¤ects model), and person, …rm and
match e¤ects (for the match e¤ects model). Standard errors in parentheses. Source:
Own calculations based on Quadros de Pessoal (1986-2000).
40
Table 10: Sources of raw inter industry wage di¤erentials, exact decomposition
Pooled OLS
Raw di¤erential
(
Industry
Agriculture
Silviculture
Fishing
Mining
Food products
Beverages
Tobacco
Textiles
Clothing
Leather
Shoes
Wood and cork
Furniture
Pulp, paper, paper prod.
Publishing and printing
Industrial chemicals
Other chemicals
Petrol, Rubber, Plastics
Ceramics
Glass
Other non-met min prod.
Base metals
Metallic products
Non-electric materials
Electric materials
Motor vehicles
Professional instruments
Other manufacturing
Elect., gas and water
Building
Wholesale trade
Retail trade
Restaurants and cafes
Hotels
Transport
Communications
Banking
Insurance
Real estate
Productive serv - transp.
Other productive serv.
Social services
Personal services
Average Proportion
)
(1)
-0.144
-0.030
-0.112
0.070
-0.082
-0.093
0.021
-0.126
-0.140
0.028
-0.112
-0.081
-0.213
0.056
-0.000
0.082
0.064
0.051
-0.004
0.135
0.032
-0.010
-0.034
-0.010
0.057
0.046
-0.050
-0.093
0.251
-0.074
0.016
-0.024
-0.141
-0.008
0.056
0.083
0.250
0.309
-0.042
0.205
-0.087
-0.077
-0.025
Person and …rm e¤ects model,
proportion of
Person e¤.
(2)
0.007
0.348
0.709
0.039
0.361
0.209
0.362
0.465
0.309
0.344
0.164
0.292
0.135
0.135
0.500
0.222
0.120
0.322
0.329
0.223
0.227
0.561
0.231
0.413
0.244
0.398
0.186
0.526
0.423
0.075
0.789
0.283
0.105
0.367
0.616
0.584
0.263
0.188
0.143
0.220
0.184
0.132
0.328
30.4%
due to:
Firm e¤.
(3)
0.993
0.652
0.291
0.961
0.639
0.791
0.638
0.535
0.691
0.656
0.836
0.708
0.865
0.865
0.500
0.778
0.880
0.678
0.671
0.777
0.773
0.439
0.769
0.587
0.756
0.602
0.814
0.474
0.577
0.925
0.211
0.717
0.895
0.633
0.384
0.416
0.737
0.812
0.857
0.780
0.816
0.868
0.672
69.6%
Match e¤ects model
proportion of
due to:
Person e¤.
Firm e¤.
Match e¤.
(4)
0.007
0.347
0.680
0.0379
0.349
0.203
0.362
0.450
0.300
0.342
0.162
0.284
0.131
0.133
0.499
0.220
0.117
0.321
0.329
0.221
0.225
0.562
0.230
0.414
0.237
0.387
0.184
0.510
0.409
0.073
0.756
0.281
0.102
0.366
0.600
0.563
0.255
0.182
0.142
0.212
0.173
0.130
0.329
29.8%
(5)
0.960
0.644
0.276
0.929
0.613
0.762
0.633
0.513
0.664
0.648
0.817
0.682
0.834
0.843
0.494
0.763
0.852
0.670
0.666
0.761
0.759
0.435
0.759
0.582
0.727
0.580
0.797
0.455
0.554
0.900
0.200
0.706
0.863
0.626
0.368
0.398
0.709
0.782
0.843
0.748
0.762
0.845
0.666
67.7%
(6)
0.033
0.009
0.044
0.033
0.037
0.035
0.005
0.037
0.036
0.010
0.021
0.034
0.035
0.024
0.007
0.016
0.030
0.009
0.005
0.018
0.016
0.003
0.011
0.004
0.036
0.033
0.019
0.035
0.038
0.027
0.044
0.014
0.035
0.008
0.036
0.039
0.036
0.036
0.014
0.040
0.065
0.025
0.005
2.5%
Note: column (1) is a transcription of column (3) of Table 6, it reports the estimated raw interindustry wage di¤erentials for
reference. Columns (2)-(6) report the proportional decomposition as described in subsection 6.2. Source: Own calculations based
on Quadros de Pessoal (1986-2000).
41
Table 11: Interindustry wage di¤erentials and time to separation
Industry premia
No. of obs
% separating
Quits
(small gap)
0.366
(0.063)
Layo¤s
(big gap)
0.512
(0.050)
All
separations
0.410
(0.040)
639,829
6.20
639,533
11.84
639,829
18.03
Note: Other covariates were included in the speci…cation, but their
coe¢cients are not reported here. The average industry e¤ect is
estimated from a regression in which the pure interindustry wage
di¤erential is included as a continuous variable. Source: Own
calculations based on Quadros de Pessoal (1986-2000).
42