Corporate Governance And Firm Performance
Sanjai Bhagat
Brian Bolton
April 2007
We thank Lucian Bebchuk, Paul Gompers and seminar participants at Cornell University,
Dartmouth College (Tuck), University of Chicago, University of Rochester, and Yale
University (Corporate Law Seminar) for helpful comments on a previous draft of this
paper.
Please address correspondence to Sanjai Bhagat, Leeds School of Business, University of
Colorado, Boulder, CO 80309-0419.
[email protected]
1
Corporate Governance And Firm Performance
ABSTRACT
How is corporate governance measured? What is the relationship between corporate
governance and performance? This paper sheds light on these questions while taking into account
the endogeneity of the relationships among corporate governance, corporate performance,
corporate capital structure, and corporate ownership structure. We make three additional
contributions to the literature:
First, we find that better governance as measured by the Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick
(GIM, 2003) and Bebchuk, Cohen and Ferrell (BCF, 2004) indices, stock ownership of board
members, and CEO-Chair separation is significantly positively correlated with better
contemporaneous and subsequent operating performance.
Second, contrary to claims in GIM and BCF, none of the governance measures are
correlated with future stock market performance. In several instances inferences regarding the
(stock market) performance and governance relationship do depend on whether or not one takes
into account the endogenous nature of the relationship between governance and (stock market)
performance.
Third, given poor firm performance, the probability of disciplinary management turnover
is positively correlated with stock ownership of board members, and board independence.
However, better governed firms as measured by the GIM and BCF indices are less likely to
experience disciplinary management turnover in spite of their poor performance.
The above results highlight the strategic importance of board incentives. Our
recommendations on board incentives are consistent with the implications of Hermalin and
Weisbach (2007).
2
I. Introduction
In an important and oft-cited paper, Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (GIM, 2003) study the
impact of corporate governance on firm performance during the 1990s. They find that stock
returns of firms with strong shareholder rights outperform, on a risk-adjusted basis, returns of
firms with weak shareholder rights by 8.5 percent per year during this decade. Given this result,
serious concerns can be raised about the efficient market hypothesis, since these portfolios could
be constructed with publicly available data. On the policy domain, corporate governance
proponents have prominently cited this result as evidence that good governance (as measured by
GIM) has a positive impact on corporate performance.
There are three alternative ways of interpreting the superior return performance of
companies with strong shareholder rights. First, these results could be sample-period specific;
hence companies with strong shareholder rights during the current decade of 2000s may not have
exhibited superior return performance. In fact, in a very recent paper, Core, Guay and Rusticus
(2005) carefully document that in the current decade share returns of companies with strong
shareholder rights do not outperform those with weak shareholder rights. Second, the riskadjustment might not have been done properly; in other words, the governance factor might be
correlated with some unobservable risk factor(s). Third, the relation between corporate
governance and performance might be endogenous raising doubts about the causality explanation.
There is a significant body of theoretical and empirical literature in accounting and finance that
considers the relations among corporate governance, management turnover, corporate
performance, corporate capital structure, and corporate ownership structure. Hence, from an
econometric viewpoint, to study the relationship between any two of these variables one would
need to formulate a system of simultaneous equations that specifies the relationships among these
variables.
What if after accounting for sample period specificity, risk-adjustment, and endogeneity,
the data indicates that share returns of companies with strong shareholder rights are similar to
3
those with weak shareholder rights? What might we infer about the impact of corporate
governance on performance from this result? It is still possible that governance might have a
positive impact on performance, but that good governance, as measured by GIM, might not be the
appropriate corporate governance metric.
An impressive set of recent papers have considered alternative measures of corporate
governance, and studied the impact of these governance measures on firm performance. GIM’s
governance measure is an equally-weighted index of 24 corporate governance provisions
compiled by the Investor Responsibility Research Center (IRRC), such as, poison pills, golden
parachutes, classified boards, cumulative voting, and supermajority rules to approve mergers.
Bebchuk, Cohen and Ferrell (BCF, 2004) recognize that some of these 24 provisions might
matter more than others and that some of these provisions may be correlated. Accordingly, they
create an “entrenchment index” comprising of six provisions – four provisions that limit
shareholder rights and two that make potential hostile takeovers more difficult. While the above
noted studies use IRRC data, Brown and Caylor (2004) use Institutional Shareholder Services
(ISS) data to create their governance index. This index considers 52 corporate governance
features such as board structure and processes, corporate charter issues such as poison pills,
management and director compensation and stock ownership.
There is a related strand of the literature that considers corporate board characteristics as
important determinants of corporate governance: board independence (see Hermalin and
Weisbach (1998, 2003)), stock ownership of board members (see Bhagat, Carey, and Elson
(1999)), and whether the Chairman and CEO positions are occupied by the same or two different
individuals (see Brickley, Coles, and Jarrell (1997)). Can a single board characteristic be as
effective a measure of corporate governance as indices that consider 52 (as in Brown and Caylor),
24 (as in GIM) or other multiple measures of corporate charter provisions, and board
characteristics? While, ultimately, this is an empirical question, on both economic and
econometric grounds it is possible for a single board characteristic to be as effective a measure of
4
corporate governance. Corporate boards have the power to make, or at least, ratify all important
decisions including decisions about investment policy, management compensation policy, and
board governance itself. It is plausible that board members with appropriate stock ownership will
have the incentive to provide effective monitoring and oversight of important corporate decisions
noted above; hence board independence or ownership can be a good proxy for overall good
governance. Furthermore, the measurement error in measuring board ownership can be less than
the total measurement error in measuring a multitude of board processes, compensation structure,
and charter provisions. Finally, while board characteristics, corporate charter provisions, and
management compensation features do characterize a company’s governance, construction of a
governance index requires that the above variables be weighted. The weights a particular index
assigns to individual board characteristics, charter provisions, etc. is important. If the weights are
not consistent with the weights used by informed market participants in assessing the relation
between governance and firm performance, then incorrect inferences would be made regarding
the relation between governance and firm performance.
Our primary contribution to the literature is a comprehensive and econometrically
defensible analysis of the relation between corporate governance and performance. We take into
account the endogenous nature of the relation between governance and performance. Also, with
the help of a simultaneous equations framework we take into account the relations among
corporate governance, performance, capital structure, and ownership structure. We make four
additional contributions to the literature:
First, instead of considering just a single measure of governance (as prior studies in the
literature have done), we consider seven different governance measures. We find that better
governance as measured by the GIM and BCF indices, stock ownership of board members, and
CEO-Chair separation is significantly positively correlated with better contemporaneous and
subsequent operating performance. Additionally, better governance as measured by Brown and
Caylor, and The Corporate Library is not significantly correlated with better contemporaneous or
5
subsequent operating performance.1 Also, interestingly, board independence is negatively
correlated with contemporaneous and subsequent operating performance. This is especially
relevant in light of the prominence that board independence has received in the recent NYSE and
NASDAQ corporate governance listing requirements.2 We conduct a battery of robustness checks
including (a) consideration of alternate instruments for estimating the system of equations, (b)
consideration of diagnostic tests to ensure that our instruments are valid and our system of
equations is well-identified, and (c) alternative estimates of the standard errors of our model’s
estimated coefficients. These robustness checks provide consistent results and increase our
confidence in the performance-governance relation as noted above.
Second, contrary to claims in GIM and BCF, none of the governance measures are
correlated with future stock market performance. In several instances inferences regarding the
(stock market) performance and governance relationship do depend on whether or not one takes
into account the endogenous nature of the relationship between governance and (stock market)
performance.3 For example, the OLS estimate indicates a significantly negative relation between
the GIM index and next year’s Tobin’s Q. However, after taking into account the endogenous
nature of the relation between governance and performance, we find a positive but statistically
insignificant relation between the GIM index and next year’s Tobin’s Q.
Third, given poor firm performance, the probability of disciplinary management turnover
is positively correlated with stock ownership of board members, and with board independence.
However, given poor firm performance, the probability of disciplinary management turnover is
negatively correlated with better governance measures as proposed by GIM and BCF. In other
1
The Corporate Library (TCL) is a commercial vendor that uses a proprietary weighting scheme to include
over a hundred variables concerning board characteristics, management compensation policy, and
antitakeover measures in constructing a corporate governance index.
2
See SEC ruling “NASD and NYSE Rulemaking Relating to Corporate Governance,” in
http://www.sec.gov/rules/sro/34-48745.htm, and http://www.sec.gov/rules/sro/nyse/34-50625.pdf.
3
The BCF index has become popular with industry experts giving advice to institutional investors on
investments and proxy voting; for example, see Hermes Pensions Management (2005), and
www.glasslewis.com.
6
words, so called “better governed firms” as measured by the GIM and BCF indices are less likely
to experience disciplinary management turnover in spite of their poor performance.
Fourth, we contribute to the growing literature on the relation between corporate
governance, and accounting and finance variables. Ashbaugh-Skaife, Collins, and Lafond (2006)
investigate the relation between corporate governance and credit ratings. They consider the GIM
index and various board characteristics including board independence and compensation as
separate governance measures. Cremers and Nair (2005) focus on the interaction between several
governance measures and firm performance. They consider the GIM index as a measure of
external governance and pension fund block ownership as a measure of inside governance; they
also investigate other similar governance measures. Defond, Hann and Hu (2005) consider the
cross-sectional relation between the market’s response to the appointment of an accounting expert
on the board and its corporate governance; they construct a governance index that gives equal
weight to six variables including board independence, the GIM index, and audit committee
structure. Bowen, Rajgopal, and Venkatachalam (2005) analyze the relation between corporate
governance, accounting discretion and firm performance; they consider several board
characteristics and the GIM index as separate measures of governance.4 Even this brief review of
the literature on the relation between governance, and accounting and finance variables suggests
lack of an agreed upon measure of governance. This study proposes a governance measure,
namely, dollar ownership of the board members – this measure is simple, intuitive, less prone to
measurement error, and not subject to the problem of weighting a multitude of governance
provisions in constructing a governance index. Consideration of this governance measure by
future researchers would enhance the comparability of research findings.
4
Given space constraints we are unable to review the vast and growing literature on the relation between
governance and finance, accounting, and corporate law variables; our apologies to the authors we have not
cited here. In addition to the papers noted above, we refer the reader to Erickson, Hanlon, and Maydew
(2006), Anderson, Mansi and Reeb (2004), Marquardt and Wiedman (2005), Rajan and Wulf (2006),
Bergstresser and Philippon (2006), Gillan (2006), Yermack (2006), Bushman, Chen, Engel and Smith
(2004), and Bebchuk and Cohen (2005).
7
The above findings have important implications for researchers, senior policy makers,
and corporate boards: Efforts to improve corporate governance should focus on stock ownership
of board members – since it is positively related to both future operating performance, and to the
probability of disciplinary management turnover in poorly performing firms. Proponents of board
independence should note with caution the negative relation between board independence and
future operating performance. Hence, if the purpose of board independence is to improve
performance, then such efforts might be misguided. However, if the purpose of board
independence is to discipline management of poorly performing firms, then board independence
has merit. Finally, even though the GIM and BCF good governance indices are positively related
to future operating performance, policy makers and corporate boards should be cautious in their
emphasis on the components of these indices since this might exacerbate the problem of
entrenched management, especially in those situations where management should be disciplined,
that is, in poorly performing firms.5 Finally, our recommendations on incentive effects of board
stock ownership are consistent with the implications of Hermalin and Weisbach (2007) who
analyze the role of disclosure on the contractual and monitoring relationship between the board
and the CEO. Hermalin and Weisbach highlight the costs and benefits of greater disclosure.
Greater stock ownership by the board would help internalize these costs and benefits at the
decision-making (board) level.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The next section briefly reviews the
literature on the relationship among corporate ownership structure, governance, performance and
capital structure. Section III notes the sample and data, and discusses the estimation procedure.
Section IV presents the results on the relation between governance and performance. Section V
5
There is considerable interest among senior policy makers and corporate boards in understanding the
determinants of good corporate governance, for example, see New York Times, April 10, 2005, page 3.6,
“Fundamentally;” Wall Street Journal, October 12, 2004, page B.8, “Career Journal;” Financial Times
FT.com, September 21, 2003, page 1 “Virtue Rewarded.”
8
focuses on the impact of governance in disciplining management in poorly performing
companies. The final section concludes with a summary.
II. Corporate Ownership Structure, Corporate Governance, Firm Performance, and
Capital Structure
Some governance features may be motivated by incentive-based economic models of
managerial behavior. Broadly speaking, these models fall into two categories. In agency models,
a divergence in the interests of managers and shareholders causes managers to take actions that
are costly to shareholders. Contracts cannot preclude this activity if shareholders are unable to
observe managerial behavior directly, but ownership by the manager may be used to induce
managers to act in a manner that is consistent with the interest of shareholders. Grossman and
Hart (1983) describe this problem.
Adverse selection models are motivated by the hypothesis of differential ability that
cannot be observed by shareholders. In this setting, ownership may be used to induce revelation
of the manager's private information about cash flow or her ability to generate cash flow, which
cannot be observed directly by shareholders. A general treatment is provided by Myerson (1987).
In the above scenarios, some features of corporate governance may be interpreted as a
characteristic of the contract that governs relations between shareholders and managers.
Governance is affected by the same unobservable features of managerial behavior or ability that
are linked to ownership and performance.
At least since Berle and Means (1932), economists have emphasized the costs of diffused
share-ownership; that is, the impact of ownership structure on performance. However, Demsetz
(1983) argues that since we observe many successful public companies with diffused shareownership, clearly there must be offsetting benefits, for example, better risk-bearing.6 Also, for
6
Investors preference for liquidity would lead to smaller blockholdings given that larger blocks are less
liquid in the secondary market. Also, as highlighted by Black (1990) and Roe (1994), the public policy bias
in the U.S. towards protecting minority shareholder rights increases the costs of holding large blocks.
9
reasons related to performance-based compensation and insider information, firm performance
could be a determinant of ownership. For example, superior firm performance leads to an increase
in the value of stock options owned by management which, if exercised, would increase their
share ownership. Also, if there are serious divergences between insider and market expectations
of future firm performance then insiders have an incentive to adjust their ownership in relation to
the expected future performance. Himmelberg, Hubbard and Palia (1999) argue that the
ownership structure of the firm may be endogenously determined by the firm’s contracting
environment which differs across firms in observable and unobservable ways. For example, if the
scope for perquisite consumption is low in a firm then a low level of management ownership may
be the optimal incentive contract.
In a seminal paper, Grossman and Hart (1983) considered the ex ante efficiency
perspective to derive predictions about a firm’s financing decisions in an agency setting. Novaes
and Zingales (1999) show that the optimal choice of debt from the viewpoint of shareholders
differs from the optimal choice of debt from the viewpoint of managers.7 While the above focuses
on capital structure and managerial entrenchment, a different strand of the literature has focused
on the relation between capital structure and ownership structure; for example, see Grossman and
Hart (1986) and Hart and Moore (1990).
This brief review of the inter-relationships among corporate governance, management
turnover, corporate performance, corporate capital structure, and corporate ownership structure
suggests that, from an econometric viewpoint, to study the relationship between corporate
governance and performance, one would need to formulate a system of simultaneous equations
7
The conflict of interest between managers and shareholders over financing policy arises because of three
reasons. First, shareholders are much better diversified than managers who besides having stock and stock
options on the firm have their human capital tied to the firm (Fama (1980)). Second, as suggested by Jensen
(1986), a larger level of debt pre-commits the manager to working harder to generate and pay off the firm’s
cash flows to outside investors. Third, Harris and Raviv (1988) and Stulz (1988) argue that managers may
increase leverage beyond what might be implied by some “optimal capital structure” in order to increase
the voting power of their equity stakes, and reduce the likelihood of a takeover and the resulting possible
loss of job-tenure.
10
that specifies the relationships among the abovementioned variables. We specify the following
system of four simultaneous equations:
Performance = f1(Ownership, Governance, Capital Structure, Z1, ε1),
(1a)
Governance = f2(Performance, Ownership, Capital Structure, Z2, ε2),
(1b)
Ownership = f3(Governance, Performance, Capital Structure, Z3, ε3),
(1c)
Capital Structure = f4(Governance, Performance, Ownership, Z4, ε4),
(1d)
where the Zi are vectors of control variables and instruments influencing the dependent variables
and the εi are the error terms associated with exogenous noise and the unobservable features of
managerial behavior or ability that explain cross-sectional variation in performance, ownership,
capital structure and governance. The estimation issues for the above equations are discussed in
the next section.
III. Data and Estimation Issues
A. Data
In this section we discuss the data sources for board variables, performance, leverage and
instrumental variables. All variables including governance measures are described in Table 1.
Board Variables: We obtain data on board independence, board ownership, and CEO-Chair
duality from IRRC and TCL. We also obtain board size, median director ownership, median
director age and median director tenure from these sources. The stock ownership variable does
not include options. We consider the dollar value of stock ownership of the median director as the
measure of stock ownership of board members. Our focus on the median director’s ownership,
instead of the average ownership, is motivated by the political economy literature on the median
voter; see Shleifer and Murphy (2004), and Milavonic (2004). Also, directors, as economic
agents, are more likely to focus on the impact on the dollar value of their holdings in the company
rather than on the percentage ownership.
11
Performance Variables: We use Compustat and Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP)
data for our performance variables. We use the annual accounting data from Compustat for
calculating return-on-assets (“ROA”) and Tobin’s Q. Following Barber and Lyon (1996), we
calculate ROA as operating income before depreciation divided by total assets. For robustness,
we also consider operating income after depreciation divided by total assets. Similar to GIM, we
calculate Tobin’s Q as (total assets + market value of equity – book value of equity – deferred
taxes) divided by total assets. We use the CRSP monthly stock file to calculate monthly and
annual stock returns. We calculate industry performance measures by taking the four-digit SIC
code average (excluding the sample firm) performance for the specific time period.
Leverage: Consistent with Bebchuk, Cohen and Ferrell (2004), Graham, Lang, and Shackleford
(2004), and Khanna and Tice (2005) we compute leverage as (long term debt + current portion of
long term debt) divided by total assets. For robustness, we also consider alternative definitions of
leverage as suggested by Baker and Wurgler (2002).
Instrumental Variables: The choice of instrumental variables is critical to the consistent
estimation of (1a), (1b), (1c), and (1d).8 Our choice of instrumental variables is motivated by the
extant literature; additionally, all of our analyses involving instrumental variables include tests
for weak instruments as suggested by Stock and Yogo (2004), and the Hausman (1978) test for
endogeneity. Also, we perform the Hahn and Hausman (2002) weak instrument test, the HansenSargan overidentification test, the Cragg-Donald test for model identification, and the AndersonRubin test for the joint significance of the set of endogenous variables in our system of equations.
Additionally, we consider alternate instruments than the ones noted below. This is discussed later
in this section and in section IV.B.1 below. We identify the following variables as
instruments for ownership, performance, governance, and capital structure.
8
The choice of appropriate instruments while never easy, is especially challenging in the context of this
study. Almost any instrument variable identified for a particular endogenous variable in equation (1) will
plausibly (based on extant theory and/or empirical evidence) be related to at least another, and possibly
more, endogenous variable(s) in (1). Ashbaugh-Skaife, Collins, and Lafond (2006) make a similar point.
12
CEO Tenure-to-Age: A CEO that has had five years of tenure at age 65 is likely to be of
different quality and have a different equity ownership than a CEO that has had five years of
tenure at age 50. These CEOs likely have different incentive, reputation, and career concerns.
Gibbons and Murphy (1992) provide evidence on this. Therefore, we use the ratio of CEO tenure
to CEO age as a measure of CEO quality, which will serve as an instrument for CEO ownership.
Treasury Stock: Palia (2001) suggests that a firm is most likely to buy back its stock
when it believes the stock to underpriced relative to where the managers think the price should
be. Thus, the level of treasury stock should be correlated with firm performance and firm value.
We use the ratio of the treasury stock to total assets as the instrument for performance.9
Currently Active CEOs on Board: Hallock (1997) and Westphal and Khanna (2003)
emphasize the role of networks among CEOs that serve on boards, and the adverse impact on the
governance of such firms. Ex ante, there is no reason to believe that this variable will be
correlated with firm performance. We consider the percentage of directors who are currently
active CEOs as an instrument for governance.
Capital Structure instrument: We use the modified Altman’s Z-score (1968) suggested in
MacKie-Mason (1990) as the instrument for leverage. This measure is a proxy for financial
distress; the lower the Z-score, the greater the probability of financial distress. We expect this
variable to be positively correlated with leverage.10
Table 2 presents the descriptive statistics and sample sizes for the variables for all
available years and for just 2002. Table 3 presents the parametric and non-parametric correlation
coefficients among the performance and governance variables.
B. Estimation Issues
9
We consider the sum of share repurchases during the past three years (as a fraction of total assets) as an
alternative instrumental variable. The results are robust to this alternative specification.
10
We also considered Graham’s (1996) marginal tax rate as an instrument for leverage. The Stock and
Yago (2004) test indicates that this is a weak instrument.
13
The instruments for performance, governance, ownership and capital structure in
equations (1a), (1b), (1c) and (1d) have been discussed above. Regarding the control variables:
Prior literature, for example, Core, Holthausen and Larcker (1999), Gillan, Hartzell and Starks
(2003), and Core, Guay and Rusticus (2005), suggests that industry performance, return volatility,
growth opportunities and firm size are important determinants of firm performance. Yermack
(1996) documents a relation between board size and performance. Demsetz (1983) suggests that
small firms are more-likely to be closely-held suggesting a different governance structure than
large firms. Firms with greater growth opportunities are likely to have different ownership and
governance structures than firms with fewer growth opportunities; see, for example, Smith and
Watts (1992), and Gillan, Hartzell and Starks (2003). Demsetz and Lehn (1985), among others,
suggest a relation between information uncertainty about the firm as proxied by return volatility
and its ownership and governance structures.
Given the abovementioned findings in the literature, in equation (1a), the control
variables include industry performance, log of assets, R&D and advertising expenses to assets,
board size, standard deviation of stock return over the prior five years, and the instrument is
treasury stock to assets. In equation (1b), the control variables include R&D and advertising
expenses to assets, board size, standard deviation of stock return over the prior five years, and the
instruments is percentage of directors who are active CEOs. In equation (1c), the control
variables include log of assets, R&D and advertising expenses to assets, board size, standard
deviation of stock return over the prior five years, and the instrument is CEO tenure to CEO age.
In equation (1d), the control variables include industry leverage, log of assets, R&D and
advertising expenses to assets, standard deviation of stock return over the prior five years, and the
instrument is Altman’s modified Z-score.
We estimate this system using ordinary least squares (OLS), two-stage least squares
(2SLS) to allow for potential endogeneity, and three-stage least squares (3SLS) to allow for
potential endogeneity and cross-correlation between the equations. If any of the right-hand side
14
regressors are endogenously determined, OLS estimates of (1) are inconsistent.11 Properly
specified instrumental variables (IV) estimates such as the two stage least squares (2SLS) are
consistent. The problem is which instruments to use, and how many instruments to use.
Regarding the number of instruments, we know we must include at least as many instruments as
we have endogenous variables. The asymptotic efficiency of the estimation improves as the
number of instruments increases, but so does the finite-sample bias (Johnston and DiNardo 1997).
Choosing “weak instruments” can lead to problems of inference in the estimation.
An instrument is “weak” if the correlation between the instruments and the endogenous
variable is small. Nelson and Startz (1990) and Bound, Jaeger and Baker (1995) were among the
first to discuss how instrumental variables estimation can perform poorly if the instruments are
weak. Nelson and Startz show that the true distribution of the instrumental variables estimator
may look nothing like the asymptotic distribution. Bound, Jaeger and Baker focus on two related
problems. First, if the instruments and the endogenous variables are weakly correlated, then even
a weak correlation between the instruments and the error in the original structural equation
(which should be zero) can lead to large inconsistencies in the IV estimates; this is known as the
“bias” issue related to weak instruments. Second, finite sample results can differ substantially
from asymptotic theory. Specifically, IV estimates are generally biased in the same direction as
OLS estimates, with the magnitude of this bias increasing as the R2 of the first-stage regression
between the instruments and the endogenous variable approaches zero; this is known as the “size”
issue related to weak instruments.
11
This point is made in most econometric textbooks; for example, Johnston and DiNardo (1997, page 153)
state, “Under the classical assumptions OLS estimators are best linear unbiased. One of the major
underpinning assumptions is the independence of regressors from the disturbance term. If this condition
does not hold, OLS estimators are biased and inconsistent.” Kennedy (2003, page 180) notes, “ In a system
of simultaneous equations, all the endogenous variables are random variables – a change in any disturbance
term changes all the endogenous variables since they are determined simultaneously…As a consequence,
the OLS estimator is biased, even asymptotically.” Maddala (1992, page 383) observes, “…the simultaneity
problem results in inconsistent estimators of the parameters, when the structural equations are estimated by
ordinary least squares (OLS).”
15
More recently, Stock and Yogo (2004) formalize the definitions and provide tests to
determine if instruments are weak. They introduce two alternative definitions of weak
instruments. First, a set of instruments is weak if the bias of the instrumental variables estimator,
relative to the bias of the OLS estimator, exceeds a certain limit b. Second, the set of instruments
is weak if the conventional α -level Wald test based on instrumental variables statistics has a size
that could exceed a certain threshold r. These two definitions correspond to the “bias” and “size”
problems mentioned earlier, and yield a set or parameters that define a “weak instruments set.”
For a set of valid instruments, we need to compare the OLS estimates with the IV estimates
to determine if IV estimation is necessary. To do this, we use the Hausman (1978) specification
test alternatively known as the Wu-Hausman or Durbin-Wu-Hausman test. The test statistic is
constructed as follows:
h ≡ ( βˆOLS − βˆ IV )′(var(βˆOLS ) − var(βˆ IV )) −1 ( βˆOLS − βˆ IV ) .
This statistic has a chi-square distribution with degrees of freedom equal to the number of
potentially endogenous regressors. If the difference between the OLS and IV estimates is “large,”
we conclude that OLS is not adequate. We use this same test to compare OLS to 2SLS, OLS to
3SLS, and 2SLS to 3SLS. If the instruments are valid, we can use this test to determine which
estimation method should be used.12
IV. Corporate Governance and Performance
Table 4 summarizes our main results of the relationship between governance and
performance. While previous studies have used both stock market based and accounting measures
of performance, we primarily rely on accounting performance measures. Stock market based
performance measures are susceptible to investor anticipation. If investors anticipate the
corporate governance effect on performance, long-term stock returns will not be significantly
12
By construction, if the IV variance is larger than the OLS variance, the test statistic will be negative. In
this case, we rely on the OLS estimates because of the smaller variance.
16
correlated with governance even if a significant correlation between performance and governance
indeed exists.13
In Table 4, Panels A through G, we report the results for the relationship between
operating performance (ROA) and the following governance measures respectively: GIM index,
BCF index, TCL index, Brown and Caylor index, stock ownership of the median board member,
CEO-Chair duality, and board independence. In each panel we report the OLS, 2SLS, and 3SLS
estimates of the equation in (1a); we perform Hausman (1978) tests to guide our choice of which
set of estimates to consider for inference purposes. In each panel, we report three measures of
operating performance: contemporaneous return-on-assets (ROA), next year’s ROA, and next two
years’ ROA. Given that information needed to construct the various governance measures for a
particular year are released to market participants some time during the first two quarters of the
year, the impact of governance on performance will be observed on both the contemporaneous
and subsequent operating performance. Core, Guay, and Rusticus (2005) consider just the next
year’s operating performance. However, it is possible that to the extent governance impacts
performance, operating performance may be impacted for the next several years. For this reason,
we also consider the next two years’ operating performance.
Table 4, Panel A, highlights the relationship between the GIM governance index and
operating performance (ROA). Consider the results under the “Next 1 Year Performance.” The
Hausman test suggests we consider the 2SLS estimates for inference. The Stock and Yogo (2004)
test indicates that our instruments are appropriate. There is a significant negative correlation
between the GIM index and next year’s ROA. Given that lower GIM index numbers reflect
stronger shareholder rights (better governance), the above results are consistent with a positive
relation between good governance, as measured by GIM, and operating performance. Results
using the contemporaneous operating performance are similar. This relation is negative but
13
However, to aid the comparison of our results with the extant literature, in Table 4, Panel H, we report
results considering stock return and Tobin’s Q as performance measures.
17
insignificant when we consider the operating performance of the next two years. These results are
consistent with GIM’s finding of a positive relation between good governance and performance
for the period 1990-1999, and extends their findings to the most recent period, 2000-2004.
However, it is important to note that GIM’s finding of a positive relation between good
governance and performance is based on long-term stock returns as the measure of performance,
and does not take into account the endogeneity of the relationships among corporate governance,
performance, capital structure, and corporate ownership structure.14 As noted above, if investors
anticipate the effect of corporate governance on performance, long-term stock returns will not be
significantly correlated with governance even if a significant correlation between performance
and governance exists. Indeed, as the results in Table 4, Panel H, indicate there is no significant
relation between GIM’s measure of governance and next year’s stock returns, or Tobin’s Q.15
In Table 4, Panel B, we note the relationship between the BCF governance index and
operating performance. Again, the Hausman test suggests we consider the 2SLS estimates for
inference, and the Stock and Yogo (2004) test indicates that our instruments are appropriate.
There is a significant negative correlation between the BCF index and next year’s ROA. Similar
to the GIM index, lower BCF index numbers reflect better governance; hence, these results are
consistent with a positive relation between good governance, as measured by BCF, and operating
performance. Results using the contemporaneous and next two years’ operating performance are
similar. However, similar to GIM, BCF’s finding of a positive relation between good governance
and performance is based on long-term stock returns. The results in Table 4, Panel H, indicate
14
Consistent with the findings reported here, Core, Guay and Rusticus (2005) also find a positive relation
between the GIM index and next year’s ROA. However, these authors do not take into account the
endogeneity of the relationships among corporate governance, performance, capital structure, and corporate
ownership structure.
15
These findings are consistent with those of Core, Holthausen and Larcker (1999) who conclude that their
governance measures “more consistently predict future accounting operating performance than future stock
market performance.”
18
there is no significant relation between BCF’s measure of governance and next year’s stock
returns, or Tobin’s Q.16
The relation between TCL’s measure of good governance and operating performance is
detailed in Table 4, Panel C. While this relation is negative and statistically significant for the
contemporaneous year, it is not significant for next year’s and the next two years’ operating
performance.
Table 4, Panel D notes a negative but insignificant relation between Brown and Caylor’s
measure of good governance and operating performance. Since this index is available only for
2002, and we have operating data only through 2003, we do not report the relation between this
index and next two years’ operating performance.
In Table 4, Panel E, we note the relation between the dollar value of the median director’s
stock ownership and operating performance. We find a significant and positive relation between
the dollar value of the median director’s stock ownership and contemporaneous and next year’s
operating performance. This relation is positive but insignificant when we consider the operating
performance of the next two years.
The relation between CEO-Chair duality and operating performance is documented in
Table 4, Panel F. CEO-Chair duality is negatively and significantly related to contemporaneous,
next year’s and next two years’ operating performance.17 This result, along with the results for
GIM and BCF, suggests that greater managerial control leads to worse future operating
performance.
16
For robustness, we also estimate the performance-governance relation for each of the seven governance
measures using the fixed effects estimator. The results are consistent with the results reported here. One
positive feature of panel data and the fixed effects estimator is that if there are firm-specific time-invariant
omitted variables in the estimated equation, the coefficients are estimated consistently. However, if the
omitted variables are not stationary over time, the fixed effects estimated coefficients are inconsistent; see
Wooldridge (2002). When the omitted variables are non-stationary, the instrumental variable technique can
yield consistent estimates if the instruments are valid. As noted above, we use the Stock and Yogo (2004)
weak instruments test to ascertain the validity of the instruments used in Table 4.
17
Note that the governance variable CEO-Chair duality is 1 if the CEO is Chair and 0 otherwise. Hence, a
negative relation between CEO-Chair duality and performance is equivalent to a positive relation between
CEO-Chair separation and performance.
19
Table 4, Panel G, details the relation between board independence and performance.
Board independence is negatively and significantly related to contemporaneous, next year’s and
next two years’ operating performance. This result is surprising, especially considering the recent
emphasis that has been placed on board independence by the NYSE and NASDAQ regulations;
however, it is consistent with prior literature (for example, Hermalin and Weisbach (2003)).
In summary, these results demonstrate that certain complex measures of corporate
governance – GIM and BCF – and certain simple measures – director ownership and CEO-chair
separation – are positively associated with current and future operating performance. Other
measures seem to be less reliable indicators of performance.18 It is also important to note that the
estimation method used does matter in certain cases. For example, consider the performancegovernance relationships estimated in Table 4, Panel H. The OLS estimate indicates a
significantly negative relation between the GIM index and next year’s Tobin’s Q. However, the
2SLS estimate is positive but statistically insignificant for next year’s Tobin’s Q. The Hausman
(1978) specification test suggests that the 2SLS estimates are more appropriate for statistical
inferences. Similarly, the OLS and 2SLS estimates for the relation between the BCF index and
future Tobin’s Q are statistically and economically different. Again, the Hausman (1978)
specification test suggests that the 2SLS estimates are more appropriate for statistical inferences.
For this reason, we believe it is important to rely on inferences after controlling for the
endogeneity between governance and performance.
A. Economic Significance of Impact of Governance on Performance
Table 5 notes the elasticities for G-Index, E-Index, and median director ownership with
respect to operating performance. We find that a 1% improvement in governance as measured by
18
We find that the relation between the GIM governance index and abnormal stock returns (after adjusting
for market, size, book-to-market, and momentum factors) is not robust to either the construction of the
abnormal stock return, or the sample period. Detailed results will be provided on request.
20
the G-Index is associated with a 0.854% change in operating performance in the current period, a
0.763% change in next year’s operating performance, and a 0.287% change in the next two years’
operating performance. The economic impacts for the E-Index and for director ownership are
slightly lower for contemporaneous and next year’s performance, and are about the same for the
next two years’ operating performance.
Table 2 indicates that the G-index and median director ownership are uncorrelated. This
suggests that a composite measure of governance that combines the information contained in the
G-index and median director ownership has the potential of being a more powerful predictor of
operating performance, than either measure by itself. To ensure robustness, we consider the nonparametric (rank) information of these two governance measures. For each year, all firms are
ranked from best to worst governed with respect to each of the two governance variables. We
sum these two ranks to get a composite index (Composite G-Ownership index) for each year for
each sample firm.19 We find that a 1% improvement in governance as measured by the composite
index is associated with a 1.874% change in operating performance in the current period, a
1.567% change in next year’s operating performance, and a 1.520% change in the next two years’
operating performance.
B. Robustness Checks
B.1. Validity and Strength of Instruments
First, following the suggestion of Larcker and Rusticus (2005), we consider an alternate
set of instruments in addition to the instruments noted above. For example, we consider (one
year) lagged performance for performance, lagged ownership for ownership, and lagged leverage
for leverage. Results using these instruments are consistent with the results reported above.
19
Year 2002 has 1,301 sample firms, which means the highest possible Composite G-Ownership index is
2,602. The lowest possible Composite G-Ownership index is 2. The actual composite governance index
varies from a low of 40 to a high of 2,594. We consider the natural logarithm of the Composite GOwnership index because of its better distributional properties.
21
We have conducted the Stock and Yogo (2004) test to ensure that our instruments are
strong. There are two other weak instrument tests. First, Hahn and Hausman (2002) present a test
similar in spirit to the Hausman (1978) specification test. Second, the Hansen-Sargan test
regresses the second stage residuals on the full set of instruments, and uses the sample size times
the uncentered R2 from the regression as the test statistic; see Davidson and MacKinnon (2004). If
the system (1a) – (1d) is correctly specified, the asymptotic distribution of the test statistic is chisquare with degrees of freedom being the difference between the number of instruments and
regressors. If the chi-square statistic in the Hansen-Sargan test does not reject the null hypothesis,
this implies that the instruments are valid and the system (1a) – (1d) is correctly specified. We
presented the Stock and Yogo test results above because, in our opinion, its test statistic is easier
to interpret; also, the Stock and Yogo test is consistent with the motivation of the prior research
on weak instruments; for example, see Bound, Jaeger and Baker (1995) or Staiger and Stock
(1997). However, we also perform the Hahn and Hausman weak instrument test, and the HansenSargan overidentification test; inferences from these tests are consistent with the reported Stock
and Yogo test results.
Third, following the suggestions of Stock, Wright and Yogo (2002) and Hall, Rudebusch
and Wilcox (1996) we perform the Cragg-Donald test for model identification. The CraggDonald test indicates that our system of equations is well-specified.
Fourth, we perform the Anderson-Rubin test suggested by Dufour (1997) to test the joint
significance of the set of endogenous variables in our system of equations. The Anderson-Rubin
test supports the joint significance of our set of endogenous variables.
B.2. k-class estimators
In the case of simultaneously determined variables, 2SLS can address this problem by
using instrumental variables to obtain a predicted value of the endogenous regressor ( Y ), then
22
using this predicted value in the structural equation ( Ŷ ). There are estimators other than the
2SLS estimator, such as the k-class estimator that can address the endogeneity problem. The kclass of estimators are instrumental variables estimators where the predicted values used in the
second stage structural equation take a special form; see Kennedy (2003) and Guggenberger
(2005):
Yi * = (1 − k )Y + kYˆ .
For consistent estimates the probability limit of k must equal 1.20
The results in Table 6 with k=0 and with k=1 are identical to the results in Table 4, for
OLS and 2SLS, respectively. Recall that in Table 4, we showed that, based on the Hausman
specification test, 2SLS was preferred to OLS for all governance measures. This means that there
is some bias or inconsistency in the OLS estimation that is causing the OLS and 2SLS
estimations to be different. By scanning down each column in Table 6, it is apparent that the kclass estimators produce a very slow, non-linear progression from the OLS results to the 2SLS
results. Using the Hausman (1978) specification test, we compare each sequential estimation.
For every measure of governance, the Hausman specification test indicates that the k=1.0 results
are different from the k=0.9 result. This suggests that only using k=1.0 (2SLS) produces
estimates that are completely free of simultaneity bias. As long as there is any part of the actual
endogenous regressor used in the second stage structural regression, which is the case for k less
than 1.0, the simultaneity bias causes the regression results to be inconsistent.
The results for k-class estimators and next year’s operating performance, next two years’
operating performance, stock return and Tobin’s Q (for contemporaneous and for the two
additional time periods) as the performance measures are consistent with the results reported in
Table 4.
20
Certain maximum likelihood estimators, such as the limited information maximum likelihood (LIML)
and the full information maximum likelihood can also be included in the k-class. The results using these
estimators are qualitatively similar to the 2SLS results.
23
B.3. Estimation of Standard Errors
Standard econometric textbooks note that OLS standard errors are biased when the
residuals are correlated. In panel data, such as the one we consider here, residuals for a particular
firm may be correlated across years, or for a particular year the residuals may be correlated across
the sample firms. Two recent papers, Petersen (2005) and Wooldridge (2004) provide a careful
analysis of the impact of correlated residuals on the bias in standard errors in panel data. We
consider the suggestions of these authors in considering the robustness of our estimated
performance-governance relationship to alternative standard error estimation methods. Petersen
(2005) notes, “In the presence of a fixed firm effect both OLS and Fama-MacBeth standard error
estimates are biased down significantly. Clustered standard errors which account for clustering by
firm produce estimates which are unbiased.” Table 7, Panel A, summarizes the performancegovernance relationship using OLS and clustered (Rogers) standard errors; these results are
qualitatively similar to those in Table 4.
While Petersen’s work is quite helpful in understanding the standard error estimates for a
single equation model, it is unclear how his conclusions might apply to a system of simultaneous
equations. Note that both the economics and econometrics of the performance-governance
relationship as analyzed above strongly suggests that this relationship needs to be estimated as a
system of simultaneous equations as in (1a), (1b), (1c), and (1d). We estimate the performancegovernance relationship using 2SLS and heteroscedasticity adjusted White and clustered (Rogers)
standard errors, respectively. Also, we estimate the performance-governance relationship using
OLS with fixed effects estimator including firm and year fixed effects, and OLS with fixed
effects estimator with clustered (Rogers) standard errors, respectively. These results are
consistent with those reported earlier and are summarized in Table 7, Panel B.
B.4. Alternative Measures of Leverage
24
It is possible that the results reported above regarding the performance-governance relation are
sensitive to the construction of the leverage variable. In the capital structure literature, there does not
appear to be any agreed upon measure of leverage. For our primary analyses, we use the measure that
appears frequently in corporate finance studies: All long term debt divided by assets. To test the
sensitivity of our results to this definition of leverage, we run the analyses in Table 4 using five alternative
definitions of leverage:
(1)
LongTermDebt
TotalAssets
(This is used in Table 4 – includes current portion of long term
debt.)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
LongTermDebt
(Excluding current portion of long term debt.)
TotalAssets
TotalAssets − BookEquity
TotalAssets
TotalBookLiabilities
TotalAssets
TotalAssets − BookEquity
(Per, Baker & Wurgler (2002).21)
TotalAssets
BookDebt
(Per, Baker & Wurgler (2002).)
TotalAssets − BookEquity + MarketEquity
We find that our results regarding the relation between performance and
governance are robust to alternative definitions of leverage.
V. Corporate Governance and Management Turnover
The preceding analysis focused on the relation between governance and performance
generally. However, governance scholars and commentators suggest that governance is especially
critical in imposing discipline and providing fresh leadership when the corporation is performing
particularly poorly. It is possible that governance matters most in only certain firm events, such
21
Definitions (3) and (5) differ in the Compustat variables used, specifically for Book Equity. Definition
(3) uses Compustat data item #216, “Stockholders’ Equity.” Definition (5) defines Book Equity as total
assets less total liabilities (item 181) and preferred stock (item 10) plus deferred taxes (item 35) and
convertible debt (item 79). The correlation between the leverage variables based on the two definitions is
0.90.
25
as the decision to change senior management. For this reason, we study the relationship between
governance, performance, and CEO turnover.
Using Compustat’s Execucomp database, we identify 1,923 CEO changes from 1993 to
2003. Table 8 documents the number of disciplinary and non-disciplinary CEO turnovers during
this period. Our criteria for classifying a CEO turnover as disciplinary or non-disciplinary is
similar to that of Weisbach (1988), Gilson (1989), Huson, Parrino, and Starks (2001), and Farrell
and Whidbee (2003). CEO turnover is classified as “non-disciplinary” if the CEO died, if the
CEO was older than 63, if the change was the result of an announced transition plan, or if the
CEO stayed on as chairman of the board for more than a year. CEO turnover is classified as
“disciplinary” if the CEO resigned to pursue other interests, if the CEO was terminated, or if no
specific reason is given.
We consider a multinomial logit regression.22 The dependent variable is equal to 0 if no
turnover occurred in a firm-year, 1 if the turnover was disciplinary, and 2 if the turnover was nondisciplinary. We consider the past two years’ stock return as the performance measure. We
estimate the following baseline equation:
Type of CEO Turnover = g1 (Past 2 years’ stock return, Z1, ε1).
(2a)
The Z1 vector of controls includes CEO ownership, CEO age, CEO tenure, firm size, industry
return and year dummy variables. These control variables are motivated by a substantial extant
literature on performance and CEO turnover; for example, see Huson, Parrino, and Starks (2001),
Farrell and Whidbee (2003), and Engel, Hayes and Wang (2003). To determine the role that
governance plays in CEO turnover, we create an interactive variable that is equal to (Past 2 years’
stock return x Governance). The reason behind this is that if the firm is performing adequately,
good governance should not lead to CEO turnover; only when performance is poor do we expect
22
We also considered a fixed effects logit estimator model. However, there are concerns regarding the bias
of such an estimator. Greene (2004) documents that when the time periods in panel data are five or less (as
is the case in this study), nonlinear estimation may produce coefficients that can be biased in the range of
32% to 68%.
26
better governed firms to be more likely to replace the CEO. To measure this effect, we estimate
the following modified version of equation (2a):
Type of CEO Turnover = g2 (Past 2 years’ stock return, Governance,
(Past 2 years’ stock return x Governance), Z1, ε2).
(2b)
Table 9 highlights the relation between different measures of governance and disciplinary
CEO turnover. Table 9, Panel A, details the multinomial logit regression results for the
determinants of disciplinary CEO turnover. Consider first the baseline results without governance
variables in the regression. The baseline results indicate that a firm’s stock market returns during
the previous two years, CEO stock ownership, and CEO tenure are significantly negatively
related to disciplinary CEO turnover; these findings are consistent with the prior literature noted
above. Interestingly, we find that the prior two years’ returns of similar firms in the industry is
significantly positively related to disciplinary CEO turnover.
Does good governance have an impact on disciplinary CEO turnover directly, or is
governance related to disciplinary turnover only in poorly performing companies? The results in
Table 9, Panel A, shed light on this question. Note that when the governance variables are
included, the prior return variable is not significant in five of the seven cases, suggesting that bad
performance alone is not enough to lead to a change in senior management. Also note that the
governance variable by itself is statistically not significant in most cases.23 This suggests that
good governance per se is not related to disciplinary turnover. The coefficient of the interactive
term (Past 2 years’ stock return x Governance) sheds light on the question whether governance is
related to disciplinary turnover only for poorly performing firms. The interactive term suggests
that good governance as measured by the dollar value of the median director’s stock ownership
and the percentage of directors who are independent, increases the probability of disciplinary
23
When the CEO is also the Chairman, he is less likely to experience disciplinary turnover.
27
turnover for poorly performing firms.24 25 Both the GIM and BCF measures of good governance
are negatively related to the probability of disciplinary turnover for poorly performing firms. This
suggests that better governed firms as measured by the GIM and BCF indices are less likely to
experience disciplinary management turnover in spite of their poor performance. Finally, when
the CEO is also the Chairman, he is more likely to experience disciplinary turnover given poor
firm performance.
Table 9, Panel B, details the multinomial logit regression results for the determinants of
non-disciplinary CEO turnover. We do not expect any relation between good governance and
non-disciplinary CEO turnover both unconditionally, and conditional on poor prior performance;
the results in Panel B are consistent with this.
A. Robustness Checks
First, we have highlighted above the endogenous relationships among corporate
governance, performance, capital structure, and corporate ownership structure. It is possible that
management turnover and performance (and ownership) are also endogenous. To address
turnover endogeneity we estimate a system of five equations: 1a, 1b, 1c, 1d, and 2b.26 Motivated
by the findings of Fich and Shivdasani (2005) we use percentage of board members who are on
more than four boards as instrument for CEO Turnover; the Stock-Yogo (2002) test, the Hahn
and Hausman (2002) test and the Hansen-Sargan test suggest that this is an appropriate
24
The finding of the probability of disciplinary CEO turnover (given poor prior firm performance)
increasing with greater board independence is consistent with the extant literature, for example, see Fich
and Shivdasani (2005), and Weisbach (1988).
25
The economic importance of the dollar ownership of the median director is greater than board
independence. We calculate the predicted probability of disciplinary and non-disciplinary turnover, using
the coefficient estimates from Table 9. When all parameters are measured at their mean values, the
probability of disciplinary turnover is 2.28% with the dollar ownership of the median director as the
governance variable; this increases to 12.55% when the (Past Return x Director $ Ownership) interaction
term decreases by one standard deviation. The corresponding probabilities are 2.90% and 7.96% for board
independence.
26
Woolridge (2002) cautions about the two-stage estimation procedure when the dependent variable in one
of the equations is dichotomous. However, on the basis of the evidence in Angrist (2001) and Alvarez and
Glasgow (1999) we interpret the signs of the two-stage estimates in the usual way.
28
instrument. Results from taking turnover endogeneity into account are entirely consistent with the
disciplinary turnover results noted in Table 9, Panel A.
Second, due to data limitations the sample periods and sample sizes for the various
governance measures are different in Table 9, Panels A and B. It is possible that the significant
relationship between a governance measure and disciplinary turnover in a poorly performing firm
may be sample-period specific, or is being influenced by the different sample sizes. To address
this concern, we consider disciplinary turnovers only for the period 2000 through 2002 for all
governance measures. The results are consistent with the results reported above.27
Third, for reasons noted in section IV.B.3. (page 23) above, we computed the clustered
(Rogers) standard errors for the coefficients in the CEO turnover model; the results are consistent
with those reported in Table 9.
Fourth, it is possible that the board considers industry adjusted performance instead of
firm performance in deciding whether to discipline the CEO. Results considering industry
adjusted performance are similar to that reported above.
VI. Summary and Conclusions
Our primary contribution to the literature is the consistent estimation of the relationship
between corporate governance and performance, by taking into account the inter-relationships
among corporate governance, corporate performance, corporate capital structure, and
corporate ownership structure. We make four additional contributions to the literature:
First, instead of considering just a single measure of governance (as prior studies in the
literature have done), we consider seven different governance measures. We find that better
governance as measured by the GIM and BCF indices, stock ownership of board members, and
CEO-Chair separation is significantly positively correlated with better contemporaneous and
27
Motivated by the findings of Huson, Parrino and Malatesta (2004) we also controlled for turnovers as a
consequence of takeover pressure and other types of forced turnover. The results are qualitatively similar to
that noted above.
29
subsequent operating performance. Also, interestingly, board independence is negatively
correlated with contemporaneous and subsequent operating performance. This is especially
relevant in light of the prominence that board independence has received in the recent NYSE and
NASDAQ corporate governance listing requirements. We conduct a battery of robustness checks
including (a) consideration of alternate instruments for estimating the system of equations, (b)
consideration of diagnostic tests to ensure that our instruments are valid and our system of
equations is well-identified, and (c) alternative estimates of the standard errors of our model’s
estimated coefficients. These robustness checks provide consistent results and increase our
confidence in the performance-governance relation as noted above.
Second, contrary to claims in the literature, none of the governance measures are
correlated with future stock market performance. In several instances inferences regarding the
(stock market) performance and governance relationship do depend on whether or not one takes
into account the endogenous nature of the relationship between governance and (stock market)
performance. For example, the OLS estimate indicates a significantly negative relation between
the GIM index and next year’s Tobin’s Q, and the GIM index. However, the 2SLS estimate is
positive but statistically insignificant for next year’s Tobin’s Q. The Hausman (1978)
specification test suggests that the 2SLS estimates are more appropriate for statistical inferences.
The 2SLS results suggest no relationship between the GIM index and future Tobin’s Q. For this
reason, we believe it is important to rely on inferences after controlling for the endogeneity
between governance and performance.
Third, given poor firm performance, the probability of disciplinary management turnover
is positively correlated with stock ownership of board members, and with board independence.
However, better governed firms as measured by the GIM and BCF indices are less likely to
experience disciplinary management turnover in spite of their poor performance.
Fourth, this study proposes a governance measure, namely, dollar ownership of the board
members, that is simple, intuitive, less prone to measurement error, and not subject to the
30
problem of weighting a multitude of governance provisions in constructing a governance index.
Consideration of this governance measure by future accounting, finance, and corporate law
researchers would enhance the comparability of research findings.
Can a single board characteristic be as effective a measure of corporate governance as
indices that consider multiple measures of corporate charter provisions, management
compensation structure, and board characteristics? Corporate boards have the power to make, or
at least, ratify all important decisions including decisions about investment policy, management
compensation policy, and board governance itself. It is plausible that board members with
appropriate stock ownership will have the incentive to provide effective monitoring and oversight
of important corporate decisions noted above; hence board ownership can be a good proxy for
overall good governance. Furthermore, the measurement error in measuring board ownership can
be less than the total measurement error in measuring a multitude of board processes,
compensation structure, and charter provisions. Finally, while board characteristics, corporate
charter provisions, and management compensation features do characterize a company’s
governance, construction of a governance index requires that the above variables be weighted.
The weights a particular index assigns to individual board characteristics, etc. is important. If the
weights are not consistent with the weights used by informed market participants in assessing the
relation between governance and firm performance, then incorrect inferences would be made
regarding the relation between governance and firm performance.
The above findings have important implications for researchers, senior policy makers,
and corporate boards: Efforts to improve corporate governance should focus on stock ownership
of board members – since it is positively related to both future operating performance, and to the
probability of disciplinary management turnover in poorly performing firms. Finally, our
recommendations on incentive effects of board stock ownership are consistent with the
implications of Hermalin and Weisbach (2007).
31
Proponents of board independence should note with caution the negative relation between
board independence and future operating performance. Hence, if the purpose of board
independence is to improve performance, then such efforts might be misguided. However, if the
purpose of board independence is to discipline management of poorly performing firms, then
board independence has merit. Finally, even though the GIM and BCF good governance indices
are positively related to future operating performance, policy makers and corporate boards should
be cautious in their emphasis on the components of these indices since this might exacerbate the
problem of entrenched management, especially in those situations where management should be
disciplined, that is, in poorly performing firms.
References
Altman, Edward I., 1968, Financial Ratios, discriminates analysis, and the prediction of corporate
bankruptcy, Journal of Finance 23, 589-609.
Alvarez, R. and G. Glasgow, 1999, Two-stage estimation of non-recursive choice models, California
Institute of Technology working paper.
Anderson, Ronald C., Sattar A. Mansi and David M. Reeb, 2004, Board characteristics, accounting report
integrity, and the cost of debt, Journal of Accounting and Economics 37, 315-342.
Angrist, J., 2001. Estimation of limited dependent variable models with dummy endogenous regressors:
Simple strategies for empirical practice, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 19, 2-16.
Ashbaugh-Skaife, Hollis, Daniel W. Collins and Ryan LaFond, 2006, The effects of corporate governance
on firms’ credit ratings, Journal of Accounting and Economics, forthcoming.
Bergstresser, Daniel and Thomas Philippon, CEO incentives and earnings management, Journal of
Financial Economics 80, 511-530.
Baker, M. and J. Wurgler, 2002, Market timing and capital structure, Journal of Finance 57, 1-32.
Barber, Brad and John Lyon, 1996, Detecting abnormal operating performance: The empirical power and
specification of test statistics, Journal of Financial Economics 41, 359-400.
Bebchuk, Lucian, Alma Cohen, and Allen Ferrell, 2004, What matters in corporate governance?, Working
paper, Harvard Law School
Bebchuk, Lucian and Alma Cohen, 2005, The costs of entrenched boards, Journal of Financial Economics
78, 409-433.
Berle, A.A. and G. Means, 1932, The Modern Corporation and Private Property, Macmillan, New York.
32
Bhagat, Sanjai and Bernard Black, 2002, The non-correlation between board independence and long term
firm performance, Journal of Corporation Law 27, 231-274.
Bhagat, Sanjai, Dennis Carey and Charles Elson, 1999, Director ownership, corporate performance, and
management turnover, The Business Lawyer 54.
Black, Bernard, 1990, Shareholder passivity reexamined, Michigan Law Review 89, 2550.
Bound, John, David A. Jaeger, and Regina M. Baker, 1995, Problems with instrumental variables
estimation when the correlation between the instruments and the endogenous explanatory variable
is weak, Journal of the American Statistical Association 90, 443-450.
Bowen, Robert M., Shivaram Rajgopal and Mohan Venkatachalam, 2005, Accounting discretion, corporate
governance, and firm performance, University of Washington working paper.
Brickley, James A., Jeffrey L. Coles, and Gregg Jarrell, 1997, Leadership structure:
Separating the CEO and chairman of the board, Journal of Corporate Finance, 3, 189-220.
Brown, Lawrence D. and Marcus L. Caylor, 2004, Corporate governance and firm performance, Georgia
State University working paper.
Bushman, Robert, Qi Chen, Ellen Engel and Abbie Smith, 2004, Financial accounting information,
organizational complexity and corporate governance systems, Journal of Accounting and
Economics 37, 1670201.
Carhart, Mark M., 1997, On persistence in mutual fund performance, Journal of Finance 52(1), 57-82.
Core, John E., Wayne R. Guay, Tjomme O. Rusticus, Does weak governance cause weak stock returns?
An examination of firm operating performance and investors’ expectations, Journal of Finance,
Forthcoming, 2005.
Core, John E., Robert W. Holthausen, and David F. Larcker, 1999, Corporate governance, chief executive
officer compensation, and firm performance, Journal of Financial Economics 51, 371-406.
Cragg, John G. and Stephen G. Donald, 1993, "Testing Identifiability and Specification in Instrumental
Variable Models," Econometric Theory 9, 222-240.
Cremers, Martijn K.J., and Vinay B. Nair, 2005, Governance mechanisms and equity prices, Journal of
Finance 60, 2859-2894.
Davidson, Russell, and James G. MacKinnon, 2004, Estimation and Inference in Econometrics, Oxford
University Press, New York.
Defond, Mark L., Rebecca N. Hann and Xuesong Hu, 2005, Does the market value financial expertise on
audit committees of boards of directors? Journal of Accounting Research 43, 153-193.
Demsetz, Harold, 1983, The structure of ownership and the theory of the firm, Journal of Law and
Economics 26, 375-390.
Demsetz, Harold and Kenneth Lehn, 1985, The structure of corporate ownership: Causes and
consequences, Journal of Political Economy 33, 3-53.
Dufour, J., 1997, Some impossibility theorems in econometrics, with applications to structural and dynamic
models, Econometrica 65, 1365-1389.
33
Engel, Ellen, Rachel M. Hayes, and Xue Wang, 2003, CEO turnover and properties of accounting
information, Journal of Accounting and Economics 36, 197-226.
Erickson, Merle, Michelle Hanlon and Edward L. Maydew, 2006, Is there a link between executive equity
incentives and accounting fraud? Journal of Accounting Research 44, 113-143.
Fama, Eugene F., 1980, Agency problems and the theory of the firm, Journal of Political Economy 88, 288307.
Farell, K.A. and Whidbee, D.A., 2003, The impact of firm performance expectations on CEO turnover and
replacement decisions, Journal of Accounting and Economics 36, 165-196.
Fich, Eliezer M. and Anil Shivdasani, Are busy boards effective monitors?, Journal of Finance,
Forthcoming, 2005.
Gibbons, Robert and Murphy, Kevin J, 1992. Optimal incentive contracts in the presence of career
concerns: Theory and evidence," Journal of Political Economy 100(3), 468-505.
Gillan, Stuart L., Jay C. Hartzell, Laura T. Starks, 2003, Industries, investment opportunities and corporate
governance structures, Working paper.
Gillan, Stuart L., Recent developments in corporate governance: An overview, Journal of Corporate
Finance 12, 381-402.
Gompers, Paul A., Joy L. Ishii, and Andrew Metrick, 2003, Corporate governance and equity prices,
Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(1), 107-155.
Gilson, Stuart C., 1989, Management turnover and financial distress, Journal of Financial Economics 25,
241-262.
Graham, J.R., 1996, Proxies for the corporate marginal tax rate, Journal of Financial Economics 42, 187221.
Graham, J.R., M.H. Lang and D. A. Shackelford, 2004, Employee stock options, corporate taxes, and debt
policy, Journal of Finance 59, 1585-1618.
Greene, William H., 2004, The Behavior of the Fixed Effects Estimator in Nonlinear Models, The
Econometrics Journal 7.
Grossman, Sanford and Oliver D. Hart, 1983, An analysis of the principal-agent problem, Econometrica ,
51, no 1, 7-45.
Grossman, Sanford and Oliver D. Hart, 1986, The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and
lateral integration, Journal of Political Economy 44, 691-719.
Graham, John R, 1996, Debt and the marginal tax rate, Journal of Financial Economics 41, 41-73.
Guggenberger, Patrick, 2005, Finite-sample evidence suggesting a heavy tail problem of the generalized
empirical likelihood estimator, UCLA Department of Economics working paper.`
Hahn, Jinyong and Jerry A. Hausman, 2002, A new specification test for the validity of instrumental
variables, Econometrica 70, 163-189.
Hall, A., G. Rudebusch and D. Wilcox, 1996, Judging instrument relevance in instrumental variables
estimation, International Economic Review 37, 283-298.
34
Hallock, Kevin F., 1997, Reciprocally interlocking boards of directors and executive compensation, Journal
of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 32, 331-344.
Harris, Milton, and Artur Raviv, 1988, Corporate control contests and capital structure, Journal of Financial
Economics 20, 55-86.
Hart, Oliver D. and John Moore, 1990, Property rights and the theory of the firm, Journal of Political
Economy 48, 1119-1158.
Hausman, Jerry A., 1978, Specification tests in econometrics, Econometrica 46, 1251-1271.
Hermalin, Benjamin E. and Michael S. Weisbach,, 1998, Endogenously chosen boards of directors and
their monitoring of the CEO, American Economic Review 88, 96-118.
Hermalin, Benjamin and Michael Weisbach, 2003, Boards of directors as an endogenously determined
institution: A survey of the economic evidence. Economic Policy Review, 9: 7-26.
Hermalin, Benjamin and Michael Weisbach, 2007, Transparency and corporate governance, University of
California and University of Illinois working paper.
Hermes Pensions Management, 2005, Corporate governance and performance, Lloyds Chambers, London,
U.K.
Himmelberg, Charles P., R. Glenn Hubbard, and Darius Palia, 1999, Understanding the determinants of
managerial ownership and the link between ownership and performance, Journal of Financial
Economics 53, 353-384.
Huson, Mark R. Robert Parrino and Laura T. Starks, 2001, Internal monitoring mechanisms and CEO
turnover: A long-term perspective, Journal of Finance 54(6), 2265-2297.
Huson, Mark R., Paul H. Malatesta and Robert Parrino, 2004, Managerial succession and firm
performance, Journal of Financial Economics 74, 237-275.
Jensen, Michael, 1986, Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers, American
Economic Review 76, 323-329.
Jensen, Michael, and William Meckling, 1976, Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs, and
ownership structure, Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305-360.
Jensen, Michael, and Jerold B. Warner, 1988, The distribution of power among corporate managers,
shareholders and directors, Journal of Financial Economics 20, 3-24.
Johnston, Jack and John DiNardo, 1997, Econometric Methods, Fourth edition, The McGraw-Hill
Companies.
Kennedy, Peter, 2003, A Guide to Econometrics, Fifth Edition, MIT Press.
Khanna, N. and S. Tice, 2005, Pricing, exit, and location decisions of firms: Evidence on the role of debt
and operating efficiency, Journal of Financial Economics 75, 397-428.
Larcker, David F. and Rusticus, Tjomme O., 2005, On the use of instrumental variables in accounting
research, Stanford University working paper.
Linck, James S., Jeffry M. Netter and Tina Yang, 2005, The determinants of board structure, University of
Georgia working paper.
35
MacKie-Mason, Jeffrey K., 1990, Do taxes affect corporate financing decisions? Journal of Finance 45,
1471-1493.
Maddala, G.S., 1992, Introduction to Econometrics, Second Edition, MacMillan.
Milanovic, Branko, Do more unequal countries redistribute more? Does the median Voter hypothesis
hold?, World Bank policy research working paper series, Carnegie Endowment for International
Peace, 2004
Morck, Randall, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny, 1988, Management ownership and market
valuation, Journal of Financial Economics 20, 293-315.
Myerson, Roger, 1987, Incentive compatibility and the bargaining problem, Econometrica 47, 61-73.
Nelson, Charles R. and Richard Startz, 1990, Some further results on the exact small sample properties of
the instrumental variables estimator, Econometrica 58, 967-976.
Novaes, Walter, and Luigi Zingales, 1999, Capital structure choice under a takeover threat, University of
Chicago working paper.
Palia, Darius, 2001, The endogeneity of managerial compensation in firm valuation: A solution, Review of
Financial Studies 14, 735-764.
Petersen, Mitchell A., 2005, Estimating standard errors in finance panel data sets: Comparing approaches,
Nortwestern University working paper.
Roe, Mark J., 1994, Strong managers, weak owners: The political roots of American corporate finance,
Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Shleifer, Andrei and Kevin M. Murphy, Persuasion in politics, American economic association papers and
proceedings, Vol. 94, No. 2, May 2004
Smith, Clifford W. and Ross L. Watts, 1992, The investment opportunity set and corporate financing,
dividend and compensation policies, Journal of Financial Economics 32, 263-292.
Staiger, Douglas and James H. Stock, 1997, “Instrumental Variables Regression with Weak Instruments,”
Econometrica 65(3), 557-586.
Stock, James H., and Motohiro Yogo, 2004, “Testing for weak instruments in linear IV regression, in
D.W.K. Andrews and J.H. Stock, eds., Identification and Inference for Econometric Models:
Essays in Honor of Thomas J. Rothenberg. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Stock, J., J. Wright and M. Yogo, 2002, A survey of weak instruments and weak identification in
generalized method of moments, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 20, 518-529.
Stulz, Rene M, 1988, Managerial control of voting rights: Financing policies and the market for corporate
control, Journal of Financial Economics 20, 25-54.
Westphal, James D. and Poonam Khanna, 2003, Keeping Directors in Line: Social Distancing as a Control
Mechanism in the Corporate Elite, Administrative Science Quarterly 48, 361-398.
Weisbach, Michael S., 1988, Outside directors and CEO turnover, Journal of Financial Economics 20, 432460.
Wooldridge, J.M., 2002, Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, MIT Press, Cambridge,
Massachusetts.
36
Wooldridge, J.M., 2004, Cluster sample methods in applied econometrics, Michigan State University
working paper.
Yermack, David, 1996, Higher market valuation for firms with a small board of direcxtors, Journal of
Financial Economics 40, 185-211.
Yermack, David, 2006, Flights of fancy: Corporate jets, CEO perquisites, and inferior shareholder returns,
Journal of Financial Economics 80, 211-242.
37
TABLE 1
Description of Variables
This table presents descriptions of variables used in this study. It also shows the years for which we have data available and the total number of
observations we have of each variable. The full sample period is from 1990 to 2004.
Panel A: Governance Variables
(A)
GIM G-Index
The G-Index is constructed from data compiled by the Investor Responsibility Research Center ("IRRC"), as described in
Gompers, Ishii, Metrick (2003). A firm's score is based on the number of shareholder rights-decreasing provisions a firm
has. The index ranges from a feasible low of 0 to a high of 24. A high G-Score is associated with weak shareholder
rights, and a low G-Score is associated with high shareholder rights.
(B)
19902002
11,736
19902002
11,736
20012003
4,168
2002
1,003
TCL Benchmark Score
The Corporate Library is an independent investment research firm providing corporate governance data, analysis & risk
assessment tools. The benchmark score is based on the following criteria: whether the board is classified, whether the
outside directors constitute a majority on the board, whether the board has an independent chairman or lead director,
whether the audit committee consists of only independent directors, whether the board has adopted a formal governance
policy, number of directors with more than fifteen years tenure, number of directors who serve on more than four boards,
number of directors older than seventy years old, and CEO compensation structure. The index ranges from a feasible low
of 0 to a high of 100. This data was provided to us by TCL. For more information, see www.thecorporatelibrary.com.
(D)
Sample
Size
BCF E-Index
The E-Index is constructed from IRRC data as described in Bebchuk, Cohen, Ferrell (2004). It uses a 6-provision subset
of the G-Index. The index ranges from a feasible low of 0 to a high of 6; a high score is associated with weak shareholder
rights and a low score is associated with high shareholder rights.
(C)
Years
Available
BC GovScore
The GovScore is constructed from data compiled by Institutional Shareholder Services ("ISS"), as described in Brown,
Caylor (2004). Fifty-two firm characteristics and provisions are used to assign a score to each firm. The feasible range of
scores is from 0 to 52. A high score is associated with better corporate governance.
38
TABLE 1 (Continued)
Description of Variables
Panel A: Governance Variables (continued)
(E)
Board Independence
The number of unaffiliated independent directors divided by the total number of board members. In some cases, we use
the INDEP measure from Bhagat, Black (2001). This measure is constructed from data provided by IRRC and TCL.
(F)
Panel B: Performance Variables
(A)
Return on Assets
We measure ROA as operating income divided by end of year total assets (Compustat data item 6). In general, following
Barber and Lyon (1996), we use operating income before depreciation (Compustat data item 13). Unless otherwise
noted, this is our measure for ROA. In some cases, we use operating income after depreciation (Compustat data item
178). These cases are pointed out explicitly.
(B)
Stock Return
(C)
Tobin's Q
We use the CRSP monthly stock file to calculate one-year compound returns, including dividends.
We use the Tobin's Q measure as in Gompers, Ishii and Metrick(2003): (Book Value of Assets + Market Value of
Common Stock - Book Value of Common Stock - Deferred Taxes) / Book Value of Assets.
6,126
1998-2002
6,130
1998-2002
8,847
1998-2002
8,334 to
9.311
Years Available
Sample Size
1990-2004
21,681
1990-2004
16,936
1990-2004
17,587
1990-2004
16,228 19,922
1990-2004
18,503 21,902
Last 2 Years Performance
For ROA and Tobin's Q, we use the average measure for years t-2 and t-1. For Stock Return, we use the one-year
compound return for years t-2 and t-1.
(E)
1998-2002
Alternative Governance Measures
In some anslyses, we consider six alternative measures of corporate governance: (1) the percentage of directors who are
currently active CEOs, (2) the percentage of directors currently serving on more than four boards, (3) the percentage of
directors who have served on the sample firm's board for more than fifteen years, (4) the percentage of directors who are
older than seventy years old, (5) the percentage of directors who are women, and (6) the percentage of directors who do
not own any stock in the sample firm.
(D)
9,317
CEO Chair-Duality
A dummy variable equal to 1 if the CEO is also the chairman of the board. This measure is constructed from data
provided by IRRC and TCL.
(I)
1996-2003
Median Director Percent Value Ownership
The percentage ownership of the firm's total voting power is calculated for all directors. We take the median director's
ownership as the governance measure as this individual can be viewed as having the 'swing' vote in governance related
matters. This variable is calculated from data provided by IRRC and TCL.
(H)
Sample Size
Median Director Dollar Value Ownership
The dollar value of the stock ownership / voting power is calculated for all directors. We take the median director's
holdings as the governance measure as this individual can be viewed as having the 'swing' vote in governance related
matters. This variable is calculated from data provided by IRRC and TCL.
(G)
Years Available
Industry Performance
For all industry performance measures, we calculate the mean performance for each SIC four-digit classification. We do
this for ROA, return, and Tobin's Q as discussed above. One-year and two-year performance is calculated as above.
39
TABLE 1 (Continued)
Description of Variables
Years
Available
Sample
Size
19922003
13,044
19902004
17,438
Years
Available
Sample
Size
19902004
24,255
19902004
21,230
19962003
17,993
19922003
10,990
19922003
10,651
19982003
15,360
The number of years the median director has been on the board, obtained from IRRC and TCL.
19982003
15,360
The standard deviation of the monthly stock return for the five preceding years.
19902004
15,272
Panel C: Other Endogenous Variables
(A) CEO Ownership
The percent of the firm's stock owned by the CEO. This variable is constructed from the Execucomp database and
provided by TCL.
(B)
Leverage
Long term debt (data item 9) / Total Assets (data item 6).
Panel D: Other Variables
(A) Assets
Compustat data item 6
(B)
Expenses
R&D and Advertising Expenses / Total Assets. R&D is Compustat data item 46 and advertising is data item 45.
Similar to Palia (2001), we use a dummy variable to identify firms for which this variable is not missing.
(C)
Board Size
The total number of directors, obtained from IRRC and TCL.
(D)
CEO Age
The age of the CEO, obtained from Execucomp and TCL.
(E)
CEO Tenure
The number of years the CEO has been CEO, obtained from Execucomp and TCL.
(F)
Director Age
The median director's age, obtained from IRRC and TCL.
(G)
(H)
Director Tenure
Risk
40
TABLE 2
Descriptive Statistics
This table presents the mean, median and number of observations for the primary performance, governance and control variables used in this study.
Statistics for all available years and for 2002 only are presented.
Mean
All Available Firm Years
Median
# of Obs.
Mean
2002 Only
Median
# of Obs.
A. Governance Variables
Log $ Value, Median Director
Dollar value, median director
% holdings, median director
GIM G-Index
BCF E-Index
BC GovScore
TCL benchmark score
% independent directors
CEO-Chair duality
% directors, CEOs
% directors, on 4+ boards
% directors, 15+ years tenure
% directors, over 70
% directors, women
% directors, 0 shares
13.334
617,814
0.19%
9.218
2.107
23.479
60.132
63.69%
77.56%
24.65%
3.36%
14.16%
9.00%
8.79%
7.90%
13.289
590,582
0.04%
9.000
2.000
22.000
61.000
64.71%
100.00%
20.00%
0.00%
0.00%
0.00%
9.09%
0.00%
6,126
6,126
6,130
11,736
11,736
1,003
4,168
9,317
8,847
9,311
8,334
8,705
8,515
8,782
8,656
14.090
1,315,517
0.10%
9.030
2.224
22.469
56.750
63.84%
66.90%
25.44%
6.34%
14.61%
8.02%
8.95%
23.83%
12.564
286,109
0.02%
9.000
2.000
22.000
55.000
66.67%
100.00%
23.08%
0.00%
9.09%
0.00%
9.09%
11.11%
1,482
1,482
1,481
1,894
1,894
2,538
1,534
1,997
1,994
1,997
1,997
1,997
1,997
1,997
1,997
B. Performance Variables
Return, annual
ROA, annual
Tobin's Q, annual
17.13%
13.80%
2.072
12.76%
13.54%
1.508
16,936
21,681
17,587
-12.99%
11.00%
1.631
-10.75%
10.88%
1.298
1,485
1,680
1,456
C. Other Variables
CEO holdings, %
Leverage (Debt / Assets)
Assets (x $1,000,000)
CEO Age
CEO Tenure
Director tenure, average
2.92%
42.69%
1,341
54.628
8.859
7.534
0.34%
43.21%
1,226
55.000
7.909
5.060
13,044
17,438
24,255
10,990
10,651
19,718
2.64%
43.00%
2,704
54.942
6.491
8.761
0.31%
44.29%
2,293
55.000
4.000
8.300
1,598
1,684
1,727
1,744
2,143
1,920
41
TABLE 3
Correlation Coefficients
This table presents the correlation coefficients for the performance and governance variables. The
performance variables are in Panel A and the governance variables are in Panel B. The Pearson
correlation coefficients are above the diagonal and the Spearman rank correlation coefficients are below
the diagonal. Significant coefficients at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels are noted by ***, ** and *,
respectively.
Panel A:
Return
Return
ROA
0.321***
Tobin's Q
0.58***
ROA
Tobin's Q
0.345***
0.475***
0.196***
0.251***
Panel B:
GIM GIndex
GIM G-Index
BCF EIndex
TCL
Benchmark
Score
BC
GovScore
% Independent
Director
Holdings
CEO-Chair
Duality
0.719***
-0.327***
-0.105***
0.275***
0.005
0.088***
-0.358***
-0.161***
0.263***
-0.083***
0.062**
0.314***
0.088***
-0.116***
-0.201***
0.354***
-0.013
0.089***
-0.147***
0.183***
BCF E-Index
0.726***
TCL Benchmark
Score
-0.343***
-0.377***
BC GovScore
-0.11***
-0.169***
0.311***
% Independent
0.286***
0.263***
0.069**
0.345***
Director Holdings
0.013
-0.073***
-0.125***
-0.032
-0.141***
CEO-Chair Duality
0.09***
0.068**
-0.179***
0.078**
0.194***
42
0.043*
0.048*
TABLE 4
Panels A-G: Simultaneous Equations System Estimation, Performance Measured by Return on Assets
Panel H: Simultaneous Equations System Estimation, Performance Measured by Return on Assets, Stock Return, and Tobin’s Q
This table presents the coefficient estimates for performance, governance, CEO ownership, and leverage as estimated in the following
system:
(1a) Performance = f1(Ownership, Governance, Leverage, Log(Assets), Industry Performance, (R&D and
Advertising Expenses) / Assets, Board Size, Stock Volatility, Treasury Stock / Assets, ε1),
(1b) Governance = f2 (Performance, Ownership, Leverage, (R&D and Advertising Expenses) / Assets, Board
Size, Stock Volatility, Active CEOs on Board, ε2)
(1c) Ownership = f3 (Performance, Governance, Log(Assets), Leverage, (R&D and Advertising Expenses) /
Assets, Board Size, Stock Volatility, CEO Tenure / CEO Age, ε3)
(1d) Leverage = f4 (Performance, Governance, Ownership, Industry Leverage, Log(Assets), (R&D and Advertising Expenses)
/ Assets, Board Size, Stock Volatility, Altman’s Z-Score, ε4)
Only the coefficients for governance, CEO ownership and leverage from the first equation (1a) are presented in Panels A-G since this is
the primary relationship that this study is concerned with. Performance is measured by Return on Assets (“ROA”). Ownership is
measured by the percent of stock owned by the CEO at time t in all panels (“CEO Own”). Leverage is measured as long term debt to
assets. Governance is measured by a different variable in each panel. All governance variables are as of time t. In Panel A, the
Gompers, Ishii and Metrick (2003) G-Index is used as the governance variable. In Panel B, the Bebchuk, Cohen and Ferrell (2004) EIndex is used as the governance variable. In Panel C, TCL Benchmark score is used as the governance variable. In Panel D, the Brown
and Caylor (2004) GovScore is used as the governance variable (data is available only for 2002). In Panel E, the dollar value of the
median director’s stock holdings is used as the governance variable. In Panel F, a dummy variable equal to 1 if the CEO is also the
Chair of the board, 0 otherwise, is used as the governance variable. In Panel G, the percent of directors who are independent is used as
the governance variable. Results are presented using performance in time t, t+1, and t+1 to t+2. Each system is estimated using OLS,
2SLS, and 3SLS. The Hausman (1978) specification test is performed on each system to determine which estimation method is most
appropriate. The null hypothesis is that the methods are equivalent, so the null is rejected for high h-statistics. The Stock and Yogo
(2004) test for weak instruments is also performed. The F-statistics from the first-stage regression for each of the three potentially
endogenous regressors in equation (1a) – Ownership, Governance and Leverage - are presented. If the F-statistic exceeds the critical
value (using 5% bias) from Stock and Yogo (2004), the instruments are deemed to be valid. The number of observations used in each
panel-performance period varies so to maximize the sample size for the panel-performance period. Coefficient estimates are presented,
with p-values in parentheses.
In Panel H, the results from the previous seven panels are summarized. The results are presented using next year’s Return on Assets as
the performance measure, for all seven governance variables and for all three estimation methods. The results using next year’s stock
return and next year’s Tobin’s Q are also presented. Only the coefficient estimate on the governance variable is presented; p-values
are in parentheses. The estimation method deemed most appropriate by the Hausman (1978) specification test is in bold.
43
Table 4
Panel A:
Gompers, Ishii and Metrick (2003) G-Index is the governance measure ("Gov")
Return on Assets is the performance measure ("ROA")
Contemporaneous Performance
OLS
ROA =
2SLS
ROA =
3SLS
ROA =
Sample Size
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Estimate
-0.001
0.053
-0.061
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.013
0.185
-0.045
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.013
0.191
-0.045
Next 1 Year Performance
pvalue
(0.10)
OLS
ROA =
(0.01)
(0.00)
(0.01)
2SLS
ROA =
(0.02)
(0.00)
(0.01)
3SLS
ROA =
(0.02)
(0.00)
4,600
Sample Size
Hausman (1978) Specification Test:
p-value
h-statistic
(0.00)
OLS v. 2SLS
66.84
(0.01)
OLS v. 3SLS
48.79
(0.87)
2SLS v. 3SLS
19.96
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Estimate
-0.001
0.073
-0.035
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.011
0.326
-0.014
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.011
0.334
-0.014
4,561
Next 2 Years Performance
pvalue
(0.03)
OLS
ROA =
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.03)
2SLS
ROA =
(0.00)
(0.13)
(0.02)
3SLS
ROA =
(0.00)
(0.13)
Sample Size
h-statistic
78.62
69.29
18.09
p-value
OLS v. 2SLS
OLS v. 3SLS
2SLS v. 3SLS
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
34.02
232.02
106.98
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.92)
Estimate
-0.001
0.021
-0.040
p-value
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.004
0.093
-0.032
(0.16)
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.004
0.098
-0.032
3,416
h-statistic
37.69
103.40
31.63
p-value
OLS v. 2SLS
OLS v. 3SLS
2SLS v. 3SLS
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
24.76
172.11
87.70
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
(0.10)
(0.00)
(0.29)
Stock and Yogo (2004) Weak Instruments Test:
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
35.52
215.21
98.74
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
44
(0.02)
(0.10)
(0.00)
(0.07)
(0.00)
(0.15)
(0.06)
(0.00)
Table 4
Panel B:
Bebchuk, Cohen and Ferrel (2004) E-Index is is the governance measure ("Gov")
Return on Assets is the performance measure ("ROA")
Contemporaneous Performance
OLS
ROA =
2SLS
ROA =
3SLS
ROA =
Sample Size
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Estimate
-0.004
0.042
-0.059
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.034
0.066
-0.038
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.037
0.076
-0.038
Next 1 Year Performance
pvalue
(0.00)
OLS
ROA =
(0.03)
(0.00)
(0.01)
2SLS
ROA =
(0.55)
(0.00)
(0.00)
3SLS
ROA =
(0.49)
(0.00)
4,600
Sample Size
Hausman (1978) Specification Test:
p-value
h-statistic
(0.00)
OLS v. 2SLS
74.15
(0.00)
OLS v. 3SLS
174.70
(0.00)
2SLS v. 3SLS
132.80
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Estimate
-0.005
0.061
-0.033
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.031
0.211
-0.008
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.032
0.223
-0.008
4,561
Next 2 Years Performance
pvalue
(0.00)
OLS
ROA =
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.02)
2SLS
ROA =
(0.07)
(0.43)
(0.01)
3SLS
ROA =
(0.05)
(0.43)
Sample Size
h-statistic
96.53
244.20
138.60
p-value
OLS v. 2SLS
OLS v. 3SLS
2SLS v. 3SLS
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
32.63
232.05
106.98
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
Estimate
-0.002
0.015
-0.039
p-value
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.015
0.025
-0.028
(0.07)
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.017
0.033
-0.028
3,416
h-statistic
40.19
92.33
152.60
p-value
OLS v. 2SLS
OLS v. 3SLS
2SLS v. 3SLS
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
23.90
172.11
87.70
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
(0.06)
(0.00)
(0.00)
Stock and Yogo (2004) Weak Instruments Test:
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
35.03
215.21
98.74
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
45
(0.00)
(0.22)
(0.00)
(0.75)
(0.00)
(0.04)
(0.67)
(0.00)
Table 4
Panel C:
TCL Benchmark Score is the governance measure ("Gov")
Return on Assets is the performance measure ("ROA")
Contemporaneous Performance
OLS
ROA =
2SLS
ROA =
3SLS
ROA =
Sample Size
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Estimate
0.000
0.067
-0.043
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.005
-0.089
-0.038
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.005
-0.090
-0.038
Next 1 Year Performance
pvalue
(0.05)
OLS
ROA =
(0.03)
(0.00)
(0.05)
2SLS
ROA =
(0.63)
(0.01)
(0.04)
3SLS
ROA =
(0.62)
(0.01)
2,199
Sample Size
Hausman (1978) Specification Test:
p-value
h-statistic
(0.09)
OLS v. 2SLS
38.24
OLS v. 3SLS
-5.26
(1.00)
2SLS v. 3SLS
0.65
Next 2 Years Performance
Estimate
0.000
0.073
-0.015
p-value
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.003
0.133
-0.004
(0.27)
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.003
0.135
-0.004
2,138
(0.26)
OLS
ROA =
(0.02)
(0.23)
2SLS
ROA =
(0.45)
(0.77)
(0.26)
3SLS
ROA =
(0.45)
(0.76)
Sample Size
h-statistic
31.96
11.88
1.01
p-value
OLS v. 2SLS
OLS v. 3SLS
2SLS v. 3SLS
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
20.40
100.48
48.38
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
(0.28)
(1.00)
(1.00)
Estimate
0.000
0.013
-0.036
p-value
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.002
-0.037
-0.032
(0.21)
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.002
-0.049
-0.032
977
h-statistic
14.64
79.79
8.00
p-value
OLS v. 2SLS
OLS v. 3SLS
2SLS v. 3SLS
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
13.85
50.33
27.16
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
(0.98)
(0.00)
(1.00)
Stock and Yogo (2004) Weak Instruments Test:
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
25.58
102.33
37.91
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
46
(0.56)
(0.60)
(0.00)
(0.78)
(0.00)
(0.22)
(0.71)
(0.00)
Table 4
Panel D:
Brown and Caylor (2004) GovScore is the governance measure ("Gov")
Return on Assets is the performance measure ("ROA")
Contemporaneous Performance
OLS
ROA =
2SLS
ROA =
3SLS
ROA =
Sample Size
Next 1 Year Performance
pvalue
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Estimate
0.000
-0.141
-0.041
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.004
0.211
-0.032
(0.60)
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.003
0.202
-0.032
(0.70)
(0.53)
OLS
ROA =
(0.00)
(0.01)
2SLS
ROA =
(0.30)
(0.09)
3SLS
ROA =
(0.33)
(0.08)
811
Sample Size
Hausman (1978) Specification Test:
p-value
h-statistic
(0.98)
OLS v. 2SLS
14.60
(1.00)
OLS v. 3SLS
6.63
(0.68)
2SLS v. 3SLS
24.11
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
pvalue
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Estimate
0.000
0.087
-0.032
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.005
0.057
-0.024
(0.61)
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.005
0.007
-0.024
(0.65)
773
h-statistic
10.92
71.82
-1.39
p-value
OLS v. 2SLS
OLS v. 3SLS
2SLS v. 3SLS
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
6.05
30.23
19.04
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
(1.00)
(0.00)
-
Stock and Yogo (2004) Weak Instruments Test:
First-Stage
F-Statistic
8.40
28.50
17.06
Next 2 Years Performance
47
(0.85)
(0.05)
(0.08)
(0.82)
(0.29)
(0.98)
(0.27)
NA
Table 4
Panel E:
Log of Dollar Value of the median director's stock ownership is the governance measure ("Gov")
Return on Assets is the performance measure ("ROA")
Contemporaneous Performance
OLS
ROA =
2SLS
ROA =
3SLS
ROA =
Sample Size
Next 1 Year Performance
pvalue
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Estimate
0.011
0.047
-0.038
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
0.006
0.211
-0.040
(0.01)
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
0.005
0.179
-0.038
(0.02)
(0.00)
OLS
ROA =
(0.01)
(0.00)
2SLS
ROA =
(0.00)
(0.00)
3SLS
ROA =
(0.00)
(0.00)
5,101
Sample Size
Hausman (1978) Specification Test:
p-value
h-statistic
(0.00)
OLS v. 2SLS
127.70
OLS v. 3SLS
-2123.00
(0.00)
2SLS v. 3SLS
1407.00
Next 2 Years Performance
pvalue
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Estimate
0.010
0.050
-0.018
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
0.005
0.287
-0.017
(0.04)
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
0.004
0.206
-0.015
(0.08)
5,053
(0.00)
OLS
ROA =
(0.01)
(0.03)
2SLS
ROA =
(0.00)
(0.06)
3SLS
ROA =
(0.00)
(0.09)
Sample Size
h-statistic
148.60
1.75
6.64
p-value
OLS v. 2SLS
OLS v. 3SLS
2SLS v. 3SLS
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
185.11
257.66
107.23
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
(0.00)
(1.00)
(1.00)
Estimate
0.004
0.013
-0.034
p-value
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
0.002
0.112
-0.032
(0.16)
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
0.002
0.112
-0.032
(0.18)
3,814
h-statistic
42.93
17.29
-16.70
p-value
OLS v. 2SLS
OLS v. 3SLS
2SLS v. 3SLS
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
139.53
197.45
92.74
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
(0.04)
(0.94)
-
Stock and Yogo (2004) Weak Instruments Test:
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
180.22
250.54
96.51
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
48
(0.00)
(0.32)
(0.00)
(0.01)
(0.00)
(0.01)
(0.00)
Table 4
Panel F:
CEO-Chair Duality (1 if CEO is Chair, 0 otherwise) is the governance measure ("Gov")
Return on Assets is the performance measure ("ROA")
Contemporaneous Performance
OLS
ROA =
2SLS
ROA =
3SLS
ROA =
Sample Size
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Estimate
0.002
0.076
-0.054
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.029
0.348
-0.043
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.028
0.328
-0.041
Next 1 Year Performance
pvalue
(0.47)
OLS
ROA =
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
2SLS
ROA =
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
3SLS
ROA =
(0.00)
(0.00)
5,101
Sample Size
Hausman (1978) Specification Test:
p-value
h-statistic
(0.00)
OLS v. 2SLS
126.10
OLS v. 3SLS
-539.00
2SLS v. 3SLS
-26.10
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Estimate
0.000
0.079
-0.033
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.029
0.418
-0.017
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.028
0.394
-0.016
5,053
Next 2 Years Performance
pvalue
(0.88)
OLS
ROA =
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
2SLS
ROA =
(0.00)
(0.06)
(0.00)
3SLS
ROA =
(0.00)
(0.07)
Sample Size
h-statistic
158.10
0.16
-39.30
p-value
OLS v. 2SLS
OLS v. 3SLS
2SLS v. 3SLS
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
177.21
257.71
107.47
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
(0.00)
(1.00)
-
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Estimate
-0.004
0.026
-0.039
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.017
0.142
-0.034
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.017
0.137
-0.033
3,814
h-statistic
78.00
-64.00
6.59
p-value
OLS v. 2SLS
OLS v. 3SLS
2SLS v. 3SLS
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
164.80
197.54
93.35
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
(0.00)
(1.00)
Stock and Yogo (2004) Weak Instruments Test:
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
164.59
250.54
96.51
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
49
p-value
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
Table 4
Panel G:
Percentage of directors who are independent is the governance measure ("Gov")
Return on Assets is the performance measure ("ROA")
Contemporaneous Performance
OLS
ROA =
2SLS
ROA =
3SLS
ROA =
Sample Size
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Estimate
-0.045
0.049
-0.055
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.131
0.083
-0.054
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.130
0.079
-0.054
Next 1 Year Performance
pvalue
(0.00)
OLS
ROA =
(0.01)
(0.00)
(0.00)
2SLS
ROA =
(0.32)
(0.00)
(0.00)
3SLS
ROA =
(0.34)
(0.00)
5,101
Sample Size
Hausman (1978) Specification Test:
p-value
h-statistic
(0.00)
OLS v. 2SLS
78.69
(1.00)
OLS v. 3SLS
8.34
(1.00)
2SLS v. 3SLS
9.73
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Estimate
-0.052
0.045
-0.033
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.121
0.164
-0.027
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.120
0.162
-0.027
5,053
Next 2 Years Performance
pvalue
(0.00)
OLS
ROA =
(0.02)
(0.00)
(0.00)
2SLS
ROA =
(0.54)
(0.00)
(0.00)
3SLS
ROA =
(0.06)
(0.00)
Sample Size
h-statistic
68.54
-3.18
4.54
p-value
OLS v. 2SLS
OLS v. 3SLS
2SLS v. 3SLS
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
161.12
257.71
107.47
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
(0.00)
(1.00)
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
Estimate
-0.020
0.009
-0.040
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.068
0.029
-0.037
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
-0.068
0.027
-0.037
3,814
h-statistic
36.39
-4.41
2.11
p-value
OLS v. 2SLS
OLS v. 3SLS
2SLS v. 3SLS
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
118.53
197.54
93.35
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
(0.13)
(1.00)
Stock and Yogo (2004) Weak Instruments Test:
Gov
CEO Own
Leverage
First-Stage
F-Statistic
160.33
250.54
96.51
Critical
Value
9.53
9.53
9.53
50
p-value
(0.00)
(0.49)
(0.00)
(0.01)
(0.62)
(0.00)
(0.01)
(0.64)
(0.00)
Table 4
Panel H: Only the coefficient estimate on the governance variable in (1a) is presented; p-values are in parentheses. The estimation
method deemed most appropriate by the Hausman (1978) specification test is in bold.
Predicted
Sign
GIM G-Index
BCF E-Index
TCL
Benchmark
BC GovScore
-
-
+
+
Director
Ownership
+
CEO-Chair
Duality
-
Board
Independence
+
Next 1 Year's ROA
OLS
2SLS
3SLS
Next 1 Year's Return
OLS
2SLS
3SLS
Next 1 Year's Tobin's Q
OLS
2SLS
3SLS
-0.001
-0.011
-0.011
-0.003
-0.013
-0.014
-0.045
0.156
0.164
(0.03)
(0.03)
(0.02)
(0.44)
(0.71)
(0.69)
(0.00)
(0.11)
(0.10)
-0.005
-0.031
-0.032
0.001
-0.021
-0.022
-0.143
0.242
0.227
(0.00)
(0.02)
(0.01)
(0.89)
(0.81)
(0.81)
(0.00)
(0.33)
(0.36)
0.000
-0.003
-0.003
0.002
0.000
0.000
0.003
0.037
0.048
(0.26)
(0.27)
(0.26)
(0.14)
(0.97)
(0.97)
(0.38)
(0.20)
(0.09)
0.000
-0.005
-0.005
0.007
-0.049
-0.099
-0.003
0.034
0.125
(0.85)
(0.61)
(0.65)
(0.09)
(0.41)
(0.04)
(0.76)
(0.81)
(0.35)
0.010
0.005
0.004
0.020
0.008
0.005
0.235
0.000
-0.003
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.01)
(0.00)
(0.64)
(0.77)
(0.00)
(1.00)
(0.96)
0.000
-0.029
-0.028
-0.007
-0.064
-0.058
-0.005
0.209
0.189
(0.88)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.75)
(0.29)
(0.34)
(0.94)
(0.23)
(0.28)
-0.052
-0.121
-0.120
-0.038
-0.250
-0.249
-0.666
0.634
0.662
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.42)
(0.33)
(0.33)
(0.00)
(0.40)
(0.38)
51
TABLE 5
Economic Significance of Governance Measures
In this table we report the elasticity of each significant governance measure, relative to operating
performance (“ROA”). We include the following four governance measures for year t:
Gompers, Ishii and Metrick’s (2003), median director stock ownership, and the Composite GOwnership Index which is constructed as follows: For each year, all firms are ranked from best
to worst governed with respect to G-Index and median stock ownership, separately; we sum
these two ranks to get the composite index for each year for each sample firm. Operating
performance is measured by Return on Assets (“ROA”) in three time periods: t, t+1, and t+1 to
t+2. We calculate the elasticity using the coefficients reported in Table 4, and using the means
and medians for each specific estimation sample. In Panel A, we report the elasticity using the
mean values for governance and performance; in Panel B, we report the elasticity using the
median values.
Panel A – Elasticity measured at means:
GIM G-Index
BCF E-Index
Director Ownership
Composite Index
ROAt
ROAt+1
ROAt+1 to t+2
0.854
0.583
0.588
1.874
0.763
0.529
0.500
1.567
0.287
0.266
0.236
1.520
ROAt
ROAt+1
ROAt+1 to t+2
0.864
0.557
0.607
1.967
0.779
0.510
0.516
1.645
0.296
0.264
0.244
1.611
Panel B – Elasticity measured at medians:
GIM G-Index
BCF E-Index
Director Ownership
Composite Index
52
TABLE 6
k-Class Estimators
In this table we report the results of estimating equation (1a) using different k-class estimators. We estimate equation (1) using
contemporaneous operating performance (“ROA”) and using the four governance variables. We estimate equation (1) using a different
value of k in each iteration, ranging from k=0.0 (OLS) to k=1.0 (2SLS), in increments of 0.1. We also report the 3SLS results for
comparison. Each column presents the results for a single governance measure and each value of k. Only the coefficients on the
governance variable from equation (1a) are presented; p-values are in parentheses.
k = 0.0 (OLS)
GIM GIndex
-0.001
BCF EIndex
-0.004
TCL
Benchmark
Score
0.000
Brown &
Caylor
GovScore
0.000
$ Value of
Median
Director's
Holdings
0.011
CEO-Chair
Duality
(=1 if Dual)
0.002
% of
Directors
Independent
-0.045
(0.10)
(0.00)
(0.05)
(0.53)
(0.00)
(0.47)
(0.00)
k = 0.1
-0.001
-0.005
0.000
0.000
0.011
0.002
-0.045
(0.11)
(0.00)
(0.06)
(0.54)
(0.00)
(0.55)
(0.00)
k = 0.2
-0.001
-0.005
0.000
0.000
0.011
0.002
-0.046
(0.11)
(0.00)
(0.07)
(0.56)
(0.00)
(0.64)
(0.00)
k = 0.3
-0.001
-0.005
-0.001
0.000
0.011
0.001
-0.047
(0.12)
(0.00)
(0.08)
(0.57)
(0.00)
(0.75)
(0.00)
k = 0.4
-0.001
-0.005
-0.001
-0.001
0.011
0.001
-0.048
(0.12)
(0.00)
(0.09)
(0.58)
(0.00)
(0.89)
(0.00)
-0.001
-0.005
-0.001
-0.001
0.011
0.000
-0.050
(0.12)
(0.00)
(0.10)
(0.60)
(0.00)
(0.95)
(0.00)
-0.001
-0.005
-0.001
-0.001
0.011
-0.001
-0.053
(0.12)
(0.00)
(0.11)
(0.61)
(0.00)
(0.76)
(0.00)
k = 0.7
-0.001
-0.006
-0.001
-0.001
0.010
-0.003
-0.056
(0.12)
(0.00)
(0.13)
(0.62)
(0.00)
(0.54)
(0.00)
k = 0.8
-0.002
-0.006
-0.001
-0.001
0.010
-0.006
-0.062
(0.11)
(0.00)
(0.14)
(0.64)
(0.00)
(0.30)
(0.00)
k = 0.9
-0.002
-0.008
-0.001
-0.001
0.009
-0.012
-0.074
(0.09)
(0.01)
(0.15)
(0.64)
(0.00)
(0.09)
(0.00)
k = 1.0 (2SLS)
-0.013
-0.034
-0.005
-0.004
0.006
-0.029
-0.131
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.05)
(0.60)
(0.01)
(0.00)
(0.00)
3SLS
-0.013
-0.037
-0.005
-0.003
0.005
-0.028
-0.130
(0.01)
(0.00)
(0.04)
(0.70)
(0.02)
(0.00)
(0.00)
k = 0.5
k = 0.6
53
TABLE 7
Robustness to Serial Correlation of Errors
In this table we report the results from estimating equation (1a) using different approaches to address the possibility of serially correlated errors.
We consider the full system of equations in (1), but used different estimation methods than in Table 4 as necessary for each approach. We
consider five different approaches. In Panel A, we report results using OLS and clustered (Rogers) standard errors. In Panel B, we report results
using 2SLS clustered standard errors, 2SLS using White standard errors, two fixed effects models, plus results from Table 4 for comparison. The
performance measure is next year’s Return on Assets (ROAt+1). Only the coefficients on the governance variable from equation (1a) are
presented; p-values are in parentheses.
Panel A: OLS and clustered (Rogers) standard errors. Only the coefficients on the governance variable from equation (1a) are presented; p-values
are in parentheses.
Governance Variable
ROAt
# of Observations
ROAt+1
# of Observations
ROAt+1 to t+2
# of Observations
$ Value of
Median
Director's
Holdings
CEOChair
Duality
(=1 if
Dual)
% of Directors
Independent
GIM GIndex
BCF EIndex
TCL
Benchmark
Score
Brown &
Caylor
GovScore
(OLS)
-0.001
-0.004
0.000
0.000
0.011
0.002
-0.045
(0.31)
(0.00)
(0.09)
(0.57)
(0.00)
(0.61)
(0.00)
4,600
4,600
2,199
811
5,101
5,101
5,101
-0.001
-0.005
0.000
0.000
0.010
0.000
-0.052
(0.19)
(0.00)
(0.31)
(0.84)
(0.00)
(0.92)
(0.00)
4,561
4,561
2,138
773
5,053
5,053
5,053
-0.001
-0.002
0.000
-
0.004
-0.004
-0.020
(0.12)
(0.00)
(0.60)
-
(0.00)
(0.12)
(0.00)
3,416
3,416
977
-
3,814
3,814
3,814
54
Panel B: Only the coefficients on the governance variable from equation (1a) are presented; p-values are in parentheses.
Governance Variable
OLS, Table 4
OLS, Clustered SE
2SLS, Table 4
2SLS, Clustered SE
2SLS, White SE
Fixed Effects
Brown &
Caylor
GovScore
$ Value of
Median
Director's
Holdings
CEOChair
Duality
(=1 if
Dual)
% of Directors
Independent
GIM GIndex
BCF EIndex
TCL
Benchmark
Score
-0.001
-0.005
0.000
0.000
0.010
0.000
-0.052
(0.03)
(0.00)
(0.26)
(0.85)
(0.00)
(0.88)
(0.00)
-0.001
-0.005
0.000
0.000
0.010
0.000
-0.052
(0.19)
(0.00)
(0.31)
(0.84)
(0.00)
(0.92)
(0.00)
-0.011
-0.031
-0.003
-0.005
0.005
-0.029
-0.121
(0.03)
(0.02)
(0.27)
(0.61)
(0.04)
(0.00)
(0.00)
-0.011
-0.031
-0.003
-0.005
0.005
-0.029
-0.121
(0.07)
(0.09)
(0.23)
(0.84)
(0.07)
(0.01)
(0.01)
-0.011
-0.031
-0.003
-0.005
0.005
-0.029
-0.121
(0.05)
(0.10)
(0.09)
(0.84)
(0.06)
(0.02)
(0.04)
-0.005
-0.004
0.000
-
0.003
0.002
-0.017
Firm and Year FE
(0.00)
(0.02)
(0.25)
-
(0.00)
(0.42)
(0.02)
FE, Clustered SE
-0.005
-0.004
0.000
-
0.003
0.002
-0.017
Firm and Year FE
(0.01)
(0.08)
(0.30)
-
(0.03)
(0.50)
(0.06)
55
TABLE 8
Reasons for CEO Turnover
This table presents the classifications for reasons why CEO turnover occurred in a specific year. Lexis-Nexis archives were reviewed
to determine the stated reason for why a CEO left the firm. CEO turnover data was obtained from Compustat’s Execucomp database.
CEO Turnover is classified as “Non-disciplinary” if the CEO died, if the CEO was older than 63, if the change was the result of an
announced transition plan, or if the CEO stayed on as chairman of the board for a nontrivial length of time. CEO Turnover is classified
as “Disciplinary” if the CEO resigned to pursue other interests, if the CEO was fired, or if no specific reason is given.
Non-Disciplinary Turnover
(1)
Disciplinary Turnover
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
1993
Deceased
1
Older Than 63
2
Retired /
Succession
Plan
13
(6)
(7)
CEO Stayed
as Chair
4
Corporate
Control
0
Resigned
12
Terminated
3
No Reason
Given
0
No
Information
0
Total
35
1994
1
13
45
1995
5
15
52
28
2
23
2
1
0
115
44
4
51
4
1
0
176
1996
3
12
54
44
4
38
5
1
4
165
1997
1
13
61
38
6
47
5
2
0
173
1998
4
17
57
40
17
57
5
3
1
201
1999
1
19
66
41
4
63
1
2
1
198
2000
3
14
81
45
8
84
5
3
1
244
2001
6
23
79
54
7
76
6
4
0
255
2002
3
17
36
44
1
72
9
0
0
182
2003
2
22
34
36
1
69
10
3
2
179
Total
30
167
578
418
54
592
55
20
9
1,923
% of Total
1.6%
8.7%
30.1%
21.7%
2.8%
30.8%
2.9%
1.0%
0.5%
56
TABLE 9
Multinomial Logit Models for CEO Turnover
This table presents the results from multinomial logistic regressions estimating the probability of CEO Turnover. The dependent
variables are type of CEO turnover: 1 = Disciplinary turnover, 2 = Non-disciplinary turnover, 0 = no turnover. No turnover is the
baseline category. Baseline results are presented in the first column; all other columns present results including Governance and
(Performance x Governance) variables. The other control variables are described in Table 1. Year dummy variables are included but
are not shown. Panel A presents the results for disciplinary turnover for all available years; Panel B presents the results for nondisciplinary turnover for all available years.
Panel A: Disciplinary Turnover
Governance Variable
Intercept
Baseline
Performance
-11.200
GIM GIndex
-9.424
BCF EIndex
-9.646
TCL
Benchmark
Score
-4.917
BC
GovScore
-2.232
$ Value of
Median
Director's
Holdings
-2.753
CEO-Chair
Duality
(=1 if Dual)
-4.124
% of Directors
Independent
-3.673
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.25)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
-2.029
-0.404
-0.860
-4.390
-2.474
0.529
-1.526
0.234
(0.00)
(0.74)
(0.18)
(0.02)
(0.57)
(0.66)
(0.00)
(0.72)
Industry Return, Last 2
years
Governance
1.079
1.506
1.514
0.961
1.353
1.051
1.058
1.101
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.03)
(0.21)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
-
-0.009
0.023
0.019
-0.064
-0.031
-0.760
-0.414
-
(0.81)
(0.77)
(0.10)
(0.21)
(0.50)
(0.00)
(0.26)
(Return, Last 2 years x
Governance)
CEO Own %
-
-0.220
-0.700
0.041
0.038
-0.208
-0.887
-3.559
Return, Last 2 years
-
(0.11)
(0.01)
(0.16)
(0.84)
(0.03)
(0.07)
(0.00)
-10.234
-6.135
-6.064
-7.636
-16.344
-9.316
-8.715
-10.924
(0.00)
(0.06)
(0.07)
(0.04)
(0.20)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
-0.079
-0.069
-0.069
-0.086
-0.226
-0.084
-0.037
-0.088
(0.04)
(0.25)
(0.25)
(0.10)
(0.06)
(0.09)
(0.41)
(0.03)
CEO Age
0.011
0.018
0.019
0.032
0.051
0.015
0.012
0.011
(0.28)
(0.25)
(0.23)
(0.02)
(0.08)
(0.24)
(0.27)
(0.27)
CEO Tenure
-0.029
-0.049
-0.048
-0.046
-0.042
-0.027
-0.031
-0.030
(0.02)
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.27)
(0.07)
(0.02)
(0.02)
1993-2003
8,965
1993-2002
3,329
1993-2002
3,329
2001-2003
3,488
2002
788
1998-2002
4,766
1996-2003
6,871
1996-2003
7,278
Size (Assets)
Years Included
Sample Size
57
Panel B: Non-disciplinary Turnover
Governance Variable
Intercept
Return, Last 2 years
Industry Return, Last 2
years
Governance
(Return, Last 2 years x
Governance)
CEO Own %
Size (Assets)
CEO Age
CEO Tenure
Years Included
Sample Size
BC
GovScore
-7.577
$ Value of
Median
Director's
Holdings
-9.809
CEO-Chair
Duality
(=1 if Dual)
-12.053
% of Directors
Independent
-11.665
Baseline
Performance
-13.696
GIM GIndex
-11.506
BCF EIndex
-11.589
TCL
Benchmark
Score
-10.011
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
-0.333
0.327
0.113
-0.048
-1.744
-1.507
-0.268
0.229
(0.05)
(0.70)
(0.80)
(0.97)
(0.66)
(0.12)
(0.33)
(0.63)
0.187
0.562
0.564
-0.134
0.353
0.375
0.150
0.245
(0.43)
(0.12)
(0.12)
(0.71)
(0.70)
(0.18)
(0.57)
(0.32)
-
0.014
0.070
0.005
-0.067
-0.016
-1.071
-0.071
-
(0.65)
(0.25)
(0.60)
(0.13)
(0.67)
(0.00)
(0.81)
-
-0.064
-0.164
-0.004
0.045
0.081
0.040
-0.824
-
(0.50)
(0.38)
(0.82)
(0.79)
(0.22)
(0.90)
(0.27)
-19.271
-17.296
-17.090
-15.420
-8.386
-15.350
-18.282
-19.644
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.07)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
-0.015
-0.065
-0.062
-0.012
-0.073
0.001
0.059
-0.020
(0.60)
(0.15)
(0.17)
(0.77)
(0.43)
(0.97)
(0.06)
(0.51)
0.133
0.133
0.133
0.130
0.123
0.129
0.136
0.136
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
0.018
0.016
0.017
0.028
0.022
0.010
0.011
0.013
(0.00)
(0.10)
(0.09)
(0.00)
(0.26)
(0.19)
(0.14)
(0.06)
1993-2003
8,965
1993-2002
3,329
1993-2002
3,329
2001-2003
3,488
2002
788
1998-2002
4,766
1996-2003
6,871
1996-2003
7,278
58