AMERICAN ANTHROPOLOGIST
Planting and Performing: Anxiety, Aspiration, and “Scripts”
in Telangana Cotton Farming
Andrew Flachs
ABSTRACT On cotton farms in Telangana, India, performance draws attention to farmers’ work not merely as
an economic activity but as directed toward different kinds of audiences and in conversation with different roles,
stages, and scripts. Importantly, this performance is contextualized by a neoliberal seed market where a seasonal
deluge of accelerated and consumerist seed marketing diminishes the value of experiential knowledge in favor of
the expansion of private genetically modified (GM) seed sales. This article draws on mixed methods and qualitative
fieldwork conducted between 2012 and 2016 on cotton farms in Telangana to explore the use of “scripts” in rural
life: the learned and socially mediated mental maps that reflect sets of rules, values, patterns, or expectations in
smallholder commercial agriculture. The script of manci digubadi (good yield) helps order and justify GM cottonseed
decision making in rural Telangana, where seed knowledge is uncertain, environmental feedback is ambiguous, and
social emulation dominates farmer choices. While being cautious not to present performance in such a way that
questions authenticity or presupposes either fatalism or economic rationalism, I argue that scripts help farmers
navigate cotton agriculture amid uncertain GM cottonseed markets and the anxieties and aspirations of neoliberal
rural India. [performance, agriculture, development, biotechnology, South Asia]
RESUMEN En fincas algodoneras en Telangana, India, representación llama la atención al trabajo de agricultores
no sólo como una actividad económica sino como dirigida hacia diferentes tipos de audiencias y en conversación
con roles, escenarios y guiones diferentes. De manera importante, esta representación está contextualizada por un
mercado de semillas neoliberal donde un diluvio estacional de un mercadeo de semillas acelerado y consumista
disminuye el valor del conocimiento experiencial en favor de la expansión de ventas de semillas privadas modificadas
genéticamente (GM). Este artı́culo se basa en métodos mixtos y trabajo de campo cualitativo conducidos entre 2012
y el 2016 en fincas algodoneras en Telangana para explorar el uso de “guiones” en la vida rural: los mapas mentales
aprendidos y socialmente mediados que reflejan los conjuntos de reglas, valores, patrones, o expectativas en
agricultura comercial de pequeños agricultores. El guión de manci digubadi (productividad buena) ayuda a ordenar
y justificar la toma de decisiones sobre semillas GM de algodón en Telanaga rural, donde el conocimiento sobre
semillas es incierto, la retroalimentación ambiental es ambigua, y la emulación social domina las opciones del
agricultor. Mientras siendo precavido de no mostrar una representación de tal manera que cuestiona la autenticidad
o presupone ya sea fatalismo o racionalismo económico, argumento que los guiones ayudan a los agricultores a
navegar la agricultura del algodón en medio de mercados de semillas de algodón GM inciertos y las ansiedades y
aspiraciones de la India rural neoliberal. [representación, agricultura, desarrollo, biotecnologı́a, Asia del Sur]
C 2019 by the American Anthropological Association.
AMERICAN ANTHROPOLOGIST, Vol. 121, No. 1, pp. 48–61, ISSN 0002-7294, online ISSN 1548-1433.
All rights reserved. DOI: 10.1111/aman.13175
Flachs • Telangana Cotton Farming
T
heories of performance in quotidian life describe how
individuals navigate audiences of experts, peers, markets, and ecologies, but these theories also illuminate how
different actors construct identities that articulate with historical and material contexts. Focusing on performance on
cotton farms in Telangana, India, draws attention to farmers’
work not merely as an economic activity but as an activity
directed toward different kinds of audiences and in conversation with different roles, stages, and scripts. Importantly,
this performance is contextualized by a neoliberal seed market where a seasonal deluge of accelerated and consumerist
seed marketing diminishes the value of experiential knowledge in favor of the expansion of private genetically modified
(GM) seed sales. Telangana has become infamous as a site of
agrarian crisis characterized by farmer suicide, pest attacks,
and low yields (Deshpande and Arora 2010; Galab, Revathi,
and Reddy 2009). The introduction of GM seeds aimed
to assuage that crisis, although farmers’ ecological knowledge underlying seed choices and cotton-plant management
has suffered since more than 1,200 GM seed brands have
been released to the Telangana market (Stone, Flachs, and
Diepenbrock 2014).
From 2012 to 2016, I conducted ethnographic research
in Telangana, surveying farming households about their experiences with GM hybrid cottonseeds. Initially, my research
asked how Telangana cotton farmers made agricultural decisions and rationalized that decision-making process as the
private GM seed market exploded, leading to widespread
seed uncertainty that Stone (2007) has termed “agricultural deskilling.” While conducting surveys of agricultural decisions among randomly sampled, wealth-stratified
households from five cotton-growing villages in Telangana
(Appendix A),1 I asked farmers to reflect on their yields,
seed choices, and pesticide applications. In practice, this was
a complicated task because rural Telangana is not a region
where farmers keep accurate records. Like all anthropologists, I contrasted the answers that I received with events
that I had personally observed through long-term fieldwork,
an ethnographic check against the reductive nature of a survey. In the course of collecting quantifiable data, I accumulated statistical noise, which was scrawled on the margins
of household surveys when farmers forgot which seeds they
had planted, over- or underreported their yields, or incorrectly named a seed brand that they had showed to me. I
then asked the same cotton farmers to develop justifications
for their seed choices, an ironic research goal because I was
investigating how difficult it is to decide which seed to plant
in the first place.
When asked to dredge up reasons for their seed decisions, most farmers sighed manci digubadi annakunthunnanu
(literally, “I’m hoping for a good yield”). This seemingly
simple answer suggests a variety of meanings in everyday
life. On Telangana cotton farms, as on all farms, farmers use
yield as a way to measure a return on investment. Yet few
cotton farmers carefully document, analyze, and improve
49
every aspect of their farm management as if these small
farms were factories preparing quarterly reports. Farmers
experience ambiguous costs (inputs and labor) and benefits
(profits), and so lean heavily on emulating the decisions of
their neighbors or seeking the advice of experts external to
the farming household, including pesticide shop managers
and university extension agents. Wanting good yields can be
very far from knowing how to get them, let alone taking a
series of clearly defined to steps to achieve them.
Even if farmers could gather clear cost-benefit information for their seed selection, cotton farming and the search
for a good yield is simultaneously a social question. A robust
cotton field is a public stage visible to friends, rivals, family,
and other passersby. The hope for a good yield encompasses the hope for good weather, pest resistance, fertilizer
response, profits, and an impressive and healthy field that
stands as public proof of one’s good agricultural decisions.
Household economics and aspirations influence how farmers
rationalize those choices, which are in turn entangled with
political, economic, and social desires on local, national, and
international scales (Agrawal and Sivaramakrishnan 2000;
Taylor 2014). In this essay, I argue that hoping for a good
yield is a kind of script about seed choice that emerges from
a growing neoliberal instability in rural India’s agrarian political economy. Following Harvey (1991, 2007), I describe
the GM cottonseed market and agrarian sector as neoliberal to call attention to a rollback of state extension services
aimed at more marginal farmers, an increasing emphasis on
expertise and resources produced off the farm, and the ways
in which the privatization of the GM cotton sector has led to
quickening cycles of seed adoption and disadoption, a deluge
of new brands, and aggressive marketing.
Making sense of this complexity is important for at
least two reasons. First, rural Telangana cotton farmers remain at a stubbornly public risk for suicide and indebtedness
(Menon and Uzramma 2018; Taylor 2014). The agrarian
distress at the root of these suicides is complex and multifaceted, but it is driven by a combination of unreliable
credit (Mohanty 2005; Taylor 2013), agricultural management uncertainty (Flachs 2016), and rising pest attacks and
pesticide use (Kranthi 2014). Further, the crisis hits hardest
the poorest farmers lacking reliable irrigation (Gupta 2017;
Gutierrez et al. 2015). As the first decision that cotton farmers make, and one that they cannot take back, seed choices
and their rationalization are central to this distressed agrarian
political economy.
Second, the ways in which Indian cotton farmers are said
to choose seeds is part of a larger international conversation
about the spread of GM crops. Policymakers (Mohan 2013)
and prominent agricultural economists (Herring and Rao
2012; Qaim 2009) see seed decisions as a form of economic
rationalism, citing GM cotton’s near-universal adoption as
a sign that “the farmer knows better than any scientist or
activist . . . if he finds that a new variety yields more,
he will expand his acreage regardless” (Aiyar 2013). This
50
American Anthropologist • Vol. 121, No. 1 • February 2019
argument assumes that the experience of GM agriculture in
India is best explained as an amalgamation of well-informed
choices. By working with commercial, state, and scientific
experts who emphasize greater yields and profits, and then
judging themselves and each other by these standards, farmers help to generate a discourse about yields and rational
seed choices indistinguishable from Indian agribusiness’ neoliberal discourse of choice, individual responsibility, and
ever-increasing yields. Economic rationalist logic persists
across publications citing high adoption and objective costbenefit calculation to argue that farmer wisdom and corporate interests are aligned in the Indian cotton sector (Herring
2015; Monsanto 2012). Academic and popular writers then
use Indian farmers’ seed choices as evidence of GM crops’
potential to save (Fedoroff 2011; Herring and Rao 2012;
Qaim 2009) or ruin (Hakim 2016; Jha 2013; Shiva et al.
2002) farmers around the world. Farmers may or may not
be wiser than activists and agricultural scientists, but I argue that this focus on economic rationalism is the wrong
lens through which to explore rural life and land management. Instead, I show that agricultural decision making and
the lived experience of GM crops can be better understood
from an anthropological perspective that considers the relationships between external expertise, farmer knowledge,
and daily farm work as they are contextualized within the
broader expectations of the neoliberal political economy of
rural India.
I begin by presenting survey data on farmer seed choices,
seed knowledge, and yields that show how farmers do not
and cannot rely on experiential learning when choosing the
seeds they sow in their fields. I then contextualize these
data within the broader political context of neoliberal rural
India and the expansion of private GM seeds. I argue that
performance, particularly the iterative and contingent ways
that farmer-actors search for acceptable responses from a
host of audiences, can better inform this study of agricultural knowledge. Building on the scholarship on agricultural
performance (Batterbury 1996; Bell 2010; Gupta 1998;
Peter et al. 2009; Richards 1989, 1993; Vasavi 1999, 2012),
I argue that anthropology is ideally suited to explain how
farmers make decisions within the uncertainty and anxiety of neoliberal rural India. Specifically, I argue that manci
digubadi, Telangana farmers’ preferred rationalization, is a
kind of script (Vanclay and Enticott 2011) that makes sense
of agricultural development and justifies cottonseed choices
in the absence of reliable experiential knowledge.
FLAWS WITH RATIONAL CHOICE
Over four consecutive years of cotton-season research, almost all of the nearly four hundred farmers I spoke with
claimed to be switching seeds in the hopes that their new
seed would bring a good yield. This is the obvious answer
for a high-investment commodity crop. Of course, farmers hope for a good yield with a new seed. Farmers define
this goodness in terms of plant health, boll size, boll number, pickability, and insect resistance, but all of these are
subservient to a seed’s potential to yield a large amount of
undamaged, heavy cotton that will fetch a good price in
the market. As a researcher studying how Telangana cotton
farmers navigated this private seed market, I found manci
digubadi to be a frustratingly vague and self-evident claim.
Yet it underscores how some farmers are so willing to chase
the hope of success that they forgo elements of the agricultural skilling process (Stone 2007), learning little about the
seeds that they plant in their field before switching to new
brands that they hope will bring manci digubadi.
Telangana cotton farmers in the Warangal district have
increasingly planted particular seed brands en masse only
to abandon them the following year (Stone, Flachs, and
Diepenbrock 2014), justifying their choices to myself, to
research assistants, to each other, and to themselves with
manci digubadi. In one extreme case, a Dalit2 farmer who
planted the Mahyco company’s Neeraja seed for nine years
abandoned that seed in favor of Kaveri’s Jaadoo seed, which
he had never planted but heard was successful in a neighboring village. Moreover, he worked for a Reddy3 farmer
who owned ten acres, a large plot in rural Telangana, and
saw that this pedda raytu4 was sowing Jaadoo. “Last year
those who planted this seed reaped a good yield. Everyone
is planting this seed this year,” he explained, despite having
no firsthand knowledge of the yields or relative inputs and
labor that any of these other farmers invested in their cotton
crop. Still, it would be foolish of him to miss this potential
windfall. The hope for high yields takes precedence over
firsthand knowledge and is matched by the fear of missing a
trend.
As one clear and locally important measure of “good”
is the yield response, these unusual swings in seed popularity might follow a kind of economic rationalism. Yield and
profit are the benchmarks by which economists and policymakers (Herring 2013; Kathage and Qaim 2012; Qaim
and Zilberman 2003) measure GM cotton’s success, so I
collected agronomic data on farmers’ inputs and outputs.
Surprisingly, even though farmers justify their seed choices
with the hope for manci digubadi, the most popular seeds
that “everyone is planting” all bring forth similar yields. The
yields for the six most popular seeds during my study period
are all within the range of variation for cotton as a whole
(Figure 1), even as farmers aggressively adopted one after another. Despite farmers’ explicit rationalizations, these data
suggest that farmers have no reliable measure for what constitutes good yields. At the very least, these data show that
farmers cannot realize their desired yield potentials because
of the vagaries of weather, inputs, water, and pests. The
statistical equality of yields across different popular brands
contradicts a simplistic economic rationalism that would explain group popularity in particular seed brands as a product
of farmers’ careful observation of possible seed choices.
In one case, a farmer triumphantly compared his seed
choices to those of his neighbor, whose cotton failed to
produce high yields. “See how much stronger and taller
my plants are,” he bragged. The following year, he planted
Flachs • Telangana Cotton Farming
Boxplots and data for 2013 popular seed yields. Source:
Author Farmer Survey (2012–2014). (Adapted from Flachs, Stone, and
Shaffer 2017) [This figure appears in color in the online issue]
FIGURE 1.
51
gain detailed knowledge about seasonal variation in seed
quality. Even if cotton farmers track their neighbors’ seed
choices, several factors—including pesticide sprays, labor
inputs, and fertilizer applications—still vary widely between
fields.
Farmer knowledge suffers in this context, as indicated
by a consensus analysis of agricultural knowledge across
the sample villages. While consensus around an observation
would not necessarily mean that the farmers were “correct”
in describing a particular seed’s attributes, it would indicate
that farmers generally agreed on a brand’s qualities. I asked
farmers to predict boll size and growth habit, crucial factors
that reflect yield, fertilizer response, and susceptibility to
pest damage, for each cottonseed they sowed in 2014. The
spread of answers I received shows a consistent divergence
of farmer opinions (Table 1). Farmers planting a given seed
rarely agreed on boll size or growth habit (with the exception
that Ankur 3028 and Jackpot would produce large bolls), while
“I do not know” (DNK) was as likely an answer about a seed
choice as anything else. Linguistically, farmers often couched
their descriptions by placing the suffix “-ta” at the end of
their verbs, indicating that their descriptions were based on
secondhand knowledge—hoped for but not confirmed.
NEOLIBERAL SPEEDUPS AND INDIAN COTTON
Average number of years farmers plant cottonseeds (2012–
2014). Source: Author Farmer Survey (2012–2014). (Adapted from
Flachs, Stone, and Shaffer 2017) [This figure appears in color in the
online issue]
FIGURE 2.
something new, explaining, “I heard it might have a better yield.” The allure of a new and potentially better seed
is too much to resist. Farmers on average planted their
cottonseeds for only a season and a half before switching to something new (Figure 2)—hardly enough time to
The introduction of private GM seeds has transformed
farmer practices and discourses in seed selection by continually speeding up new seed options, intensifying branding and marketing, and centralizing expertise off the farm
in biotechnology labs and vendor shops. Since the 1970s,
farmers have had the option to buy publicly and privately
distributed hybrid seeds. Hybrids, seeds bred to overproduce given an optimal combination of fertilizers and water
but that cannot be saved and replanted, ask farmers to be
consumers rather than producers of seed knowledge. As
Stone (2007) argues, this process has accelerated with the
introduction of GM technology in India, in which a privately
controlled genetic trait is bred into a hybrid seed. In the first
three decades that Indian farmers could buy hybrid cottonseeds, about one-third planted them (36 percent), and only
half (55 percent) of those seeds came from private-sector
distributors (Basu and Paroda 1995). GM seeds took only
ten years to capture more than 90 percent of the Indian market and have been distributed entirely through the private
sector. By 2015, GM cotton was so ubiquitous in India that
the Cotton Corporation of India stopped bothering to report
the percentage of GM cotton sown.
Because patented GM technology is bred exclusively
into hybrid seeds controlled by private companies in India,
agricultural extension scientists whom I met in Warangal
were relegated to conducting tests on publically available
non-GM cotton, which few farmers planted, or renting
their land to private companies who paid scientists to assist with corporate field trials. Meanwhile, one high-level
Monsanto India employee explained to me that private companies are allowed to “market the same hybrid code, the
52
American Anthropologist • Vol. 121, No. 1 • February 2019
TABLE 1.
Farmer Consensus on Cottonseed Attributes for the Thirteen Most Popular Seeds in 2014 (adapted from Flachs and Stone 2018)
Boll size
Growth habit
Seed name
Small
Medium
Large
DNK
Tall
Both
Bushy
DNK
N
Yuva
ATM
Jaadoo
Jackpot
Dr. Brent
Sarpanch
Bhakti
Mallika
Neeraja
Ankur 3028
Padmaja
Rasi
Denim
4 (%)
5
6
4
16
4
0
6
21
0
0
12
0
18
34
36
29
24
17
32
47
50
17
50
50
50
51
43
51
64
48
33
45
47
21
75
25
25
33
27
18
6
4
12
46
23
0
7
8
25
12
17
31
36
26
25
40
29
36
24
36
50
12
25
33
31
23
28
18
28
33
23
12
29
17
62
38
17
14
12
19
14
12
8
18
35
21
17
0
12
17
24
30
28
43
20
29
23
29
14
17
25
25
33
104
61
47
28
25
24
22
17
14
12
8
8
6
Source: Author Farmer Survey (2014).
same basic thing under different brand names,” which Stone
(2007) and Herring (2007) observed led farmers to accidentally sow multiple varieties of the same misleadingly labeled
seeds. “You may want [to label the same seed under different brands] partly because the Indian farmer is looking for
diversification,” the Monsanto India employee continued,
“even if your product is very, very good.” While beneficial
to agribusiness, this diversification of seed branding does not
provide farmers with clearer information about the seeds
they sow. It is hard enough to learn the differences between
different seed brands but impossible if farmers unwittingly
plant the same seed twice—an intensification of branding
and new seed distribution characteristic of Stone’s (2007)
agricultural deskilling.
Interestingly, where the seed market functions differently, farmers retain far more knowledge and control, and
seed rationalizations are more complicated. Farmers choose
public-sector varieties of rice and heirloom vegetables very
differently from how they choose cottonseeds (Flachs and
Stone 2018; Flachs, Stone, and Shaffer 2017). Here, farmers describe “good yields” as a function of taste, adopt and
abandon seeds more slowly, and rely more on experiential knowledge to make decisions. Public-sector breeding
accounts for the vast majority (87 percent) of rice seeds
planted by Telangana farmers in this study, an inherently
slower and more participatory process than that seen in cotton extension services. By contrast, GM cottonseeds are
solely bred by private breeders. Industry priorities, which
now include herbicide tolerance and dense planting (Stone
and Flachs 2017), drive the development of new cotton
phenotypes.
The explosion of private brands and the now nearuniversal control of the cottonseed market by private companies has led to a deluge of marketing, advertisement,
brand diversification, and poor retail experiences, as I will
describe through ethnographic examples below. Farmers’
desire for the most popular seeds represents one element
in a larger consumerist context: rural Indians seek Japanese
motorcycles or Korean smartphones and place themselves
in a transnational imagined community defined by urban,
modern, high-tech globalization (Cayla and Eckhardt 2008).
Aggressive GM cottonseed branding and marketing led to
shortages of some of the most popular seed brands in Telangana in 2012 (The New Indian Express 2012; Wadke 2012),
facilitating a black market for seeds smuggled from neighboring states. Similar stories of seed smuggling made headlines
again in 2018 when farmers sought unapproved herbicidetolerant GM seeds (Jadhav 2018). In neither case did farmers
have firsthand knowledge that the seeds would be efficacious
in their own fields.
After the Indian government liberalized the economy in
the 1990s, Indians experienced a host of familiar neoliberal
conditions: public-sector services diminished as agricultural
markets became more exposed to global commodity prices
(Rao and Suri 2006; Walker 2008), state development programs and national attention shifted from rural to urban
centers even as agrarian distress manifested through farmer
suicides (Aiyer 2007), new development programs exacerbated rural inequality and exploited labor relationships related to caste and credit access (Gupta 2017; Mohanty 2005;
Taylor 2013), and brand-conscious consumption expanded
precipitously across the country (Guha 2008; Linssen,
Flachs • Telangana Cotton Farming
Kempen, and Kraaykamp 2010). While cotton agriculture is
inherently speculative (Gupta 2017), mixed-methods agronomic (Gutierrez et al. 2015) and qualitative social (Münster
2015; Vasavi 2012) research shows that poorer farmers, especially those who lack irrigation facilities and who belong
to historically marginalized communities, are at the greatest risk for suicide and spiraling debt. The combination of
faster seed cycles, diminishing rural resources, increased
consumerism, and decreasing firsthand seed knowledge exacerbate the contemporary moment of speculation, suicide,
and rural distress.
The explosion of private seed brands in this formerly
public market is accompanied by expansions in pesticides,
fertilizers, consultations, and herbicides that farmers encounter. These accelerate input treadmills, in which farmers
use ever-increasing amounts of pesticides and fertilizers to
manage monocultures (Stone and Flachs 2017), as well as
the time-space compression and uncertainty that accompany
late consumer capitalism (Harvey 1991). Just as fashion,
cuisine, and consumer products discussed by Harvey have
become more volatile and ephemeral for consumers around
the world, so too are cotton farmers immersed in the aggressive marketing and inherent instability of hundreds of
new seed brands each year. Farmers’ hope for great yields
is bound to a fear of missing out on popular seeds, manifesting collectively as herding behavior to and from popular
products (Stone, Flachs, and Diepenbrock 2014).
So what do we make of manci digubadi? Accepting the
answer at face value does not make sense; the aggregated
survey data presented above show that there is no yield
rationale to choosing particular seeds, that farmers gamble by switching seeds frequently, that farmers themselves
don’t know very much about the seeds they are planting,
and that the market is increasingly confusing. Seed choice
and its performance on these farms occurs amidst a deluge
of marketing, competition, consumption, and the persistent erosion of experiential knowledge. In a sector where
Telangana farmers may only make a clear profit one out
of four years (Reddy 2017), farming is a highly speculative activity balanced against variations in weather, pricing,
pests, labor, or soil conditions that influence yields or profits
(Gupta 2017). Manci digubadi helps farmers continue to rationalize their gambles despite the uncertainty of seeds and
payoffs, especially as agricultural policymakers champion
India’s rising national yields and technological innovations
(Aiyar 2013; The Economic Times 2013). This is where
performance becomes analytically helpful.
Despite not knowing which seeds they should plant,
farmers must still perform as they justify choices to one
another, save face, and brag. Thus, in spite of all this uncertainty, cottonseed choice is a fundamentally hopeful decision. As I discuss in the following section, farmers hope that
they have chosen the right seed that will bring the harvest
they need and the social recognition they crave in a place
where high-yielding farmers are celebrated in local newspapers alongside reports of farmer suicides (Deccan Chronicle
53
2018; The Hindu 2013). Seed choice is paradoxically crucial yet uncertain. This suggests that manci digubadi is an
important benchmark for agricultural decision making, not
because it reveals an agronomic truth but because it is a
kind of script (Bardone 2013; Vanclay and Enticott 2011)
that helps farmers makes sense of this neoliberal agrarian
stage. My household surveys show that annual debts and incomes are roughly equal (Flachs, Stone, and Shaffer 2017),
a thin margin of error in a region infamous for agrarian crisis
(Galab, Revathi, and Reddy 2009; Vaidyanathan 2006). The
seed is the first decision farmers make, a path-dependent
decision (David 2007) that sets farmers onto routes from
which they cannot deviate. Manci digubadi offers a way to
rationalize this important choice when one must perform a
justification.
SCRIPTS AND PERFORMANCE IN AGRICULTURE
One morning in June 2014, I met Shiva on the bus to
Warangal, a large regional city. A member of the historically marginalized Banjara tribe, Shiva had walked to the
bus stop from his hamlet (Telugu: thanda) on the outskirts of
the town proper. Shiva watched as the bus passed billboards
and posters for cottonseeds. Even our bus was painted with a
seed advertisement. “Maybe I’ll buy Dr. Brent, maybe ATM,”
he said noncommittally, listing names he has seen advertised
in his village. “I heard that the harvests of ATM came well
last year for Vikram Rao,” he continued, naming a wealthy
landowner in the village to which his thanda is adjacent. “My
cousins worked as laborers for his farm. They said the plants
looked strong.” Stepping off the bus, we were bombarded
by signs, posters, vendors, and jingles hawking cottonseeds
in Warangal’s main seed shop district. Shiva entered a shop
and stood at the back, waiting for others to finish their
business.
“What’s good this year?” asked Shiva. “All my seeds are
good,” answered the clerk, who wore a gold ring and whose
eyes traveled across me to the next customer, a Telugu caste
patron. “Many people have been buying ATM this year. Buy
that.” Shiva nodded his head, and two packets of ATM, enough
to plant an acre, went into a black plastic bag. “What about
Jackpot, did others have a good yield (manci digbuadi) last
year?” he asked, naming another brand. The clerk shrugged,
saying that it is a good seed but that it isn’t as popular
this year. Instead, he offered pesticides and fertilizers that
Shiva refused because he didn’t need them yet. “Okay, are
you finished then?” the clerk asked, still eyeing potential
customers walking by. Shiva left, deciding to purchase two
packets of ATM after all. I stayed for a moment to watch the
next interaction, and the clerk shook his head. “It’s always
the same with these Banjara people. They don’t know what
they’re buying and they only buy cheap seeds, they never
buy the quality fertilizers or pesticides that go with them.”
On the bus back, we met another cotton farmer from a
thanda near Shiva who was carrying a television on his lap.
Shiva looked enviously at the television and muttered to me,
“He had a good yield last year, and he was able to sell it at a
54
American Anthropologist • Vol. 121, No. 1 • February 2019
great price.” Shiva paused for a moment. Still looking at the
television, he added, “I had a normal yield last year, but at
least I was still able to buy [his wife] Laxmi a new sari after
the harvest, for the Diwali festival.”
There is a much to unpack in this single day of seed buying. Like Dalit farmers, Shiva is among the first generation
of Banjara farmers to move from full-time wage labor to
farming in pursuit of the cultivation of the kind of modernity promised by India’s neoliberal reforms (Pandian 2009;
Ramamurthy 2011; Vasavi 2012). The recommendations
and tacit endorsement of Vikram Rao push Shiva toward
ATM, while the clerk tries to rush him out of his shop.
Shiva’s concerns and anxieties are brushed aside in a brief,
careless suggestion: buy ATM, many people are. Shiva could
refuse an offered brand out of righteous indignation or an
independent streak, but what would be the point? Like many
other farmers, he has little firsthand information on which
to judge the seeds.
In these interactions, “good yield” serves several purposes. Manci digubadi on the bus stands in for Shiva’s hope
to match the success of Vikram Rao’s yields, a chance to
reach Rao’s status as a member of the historically powerful Velama caste.5 On the ride home, Shiva’s invocation
of manci digubadi shows the competitive side of farming, in
which a fellow farmer can achieve good yields that translate into televisions and other coveted consumer symbols
(Linssen, Kempen, and Kraaykamp 2010). Even Laxmi’s
dress is a way to signal manci digubadi through his conspicuous consumption. In the shop, manci digubadi cuts through
advertising and uncertainty regarding Jackpot, justifying a
gamble on an unknown seed. Ramamurthy (2011) has called
this kind of rationalization the vernacular calculus of the
economic, in which marginalized communities historically
denied land tenure aspire to upward mobility through commodity agriculture. Although Telangana cotton agriculture
is rarely profitable for the most marginal farmers (Gutierrez
et al. 2015; Reddy 2017), the economic calculation to grow
cotton is structured less by cost-benefit analyses than by an
aspiration to overcome historical marginalization and generational poverty. Ramamurthy cites Dalit farmers who grow
cotton even though they would likely make more money
as laborers and who stress the existential value of working
one’s own land. Similarly, by invoking a Velama farmer
historically associated with the ruling zamindar family that
presided over his region, Shiva links the good yields from
Rao’s ATM with his own desire for a piece of this public
display of farming prowess.
Sometimes, farmers who work part time on Reddy or
Velama neighbors’ lands simply ask those neighbors to bring
them an extra packet of whatever they are buying. Rajaiah,
a Dalit farmer who weeds the field of his Reddy neighbor,
gambles that this high-status person chooses lucrative seeds.
“I ask him to bring back some of whatever he thinks is good for
my own fields,” Rajaiah explains. To farm is to claim a piece
of this upward mobility, although, as Ramamurthy (2011)
and Vasavi (2012) show, these historically marginalized new
farmers lack the social or economic resources available to
the landlords who made profits growing cash crops during
India’s green revolution. “We’re the same caste,” explained
one Reddy farmer when I asked if he could trust the advice
of a local shop owner. “He wouldn’t lie to me.” Although
they, too, rely on expert advice, such farmers are not rushed
along in the shops or condescended to like Shiva was. Beyond
buying seeds for their neighbors, one recent agricultural economic study (Maertens 2017) found that better-educated and
larger farmers belonging to Open Caste communities tend to
influence the seed choices of others in their village networks.
Shiva’s aspirations to manci digubadi are also aspirations
to land stewardship, social mobility, respect in shops, and
clarity in the cotton market at the moment when he will
purchase one among hundreds of possible brands. Shiva had
spent the previous year learning how another seed, Neeraja,
responded to different fertilizers and fought off pests. He
listened to his neighbors to learn how deep the root stretched
to collect water on their unirrigated fields. But that was only
one season, and he can never know for certain if one of the
hundred seeds behind the Warangal clerk holds a greater
potential this year.
Agrarian studies scholarship has used performance as a
metaphor for the inventiveness and adaptability of agricultural knowledge (Richards 1989, 1993) based in quotidian
practice (Leslie and McCabe 2013; Netting 1993). Such performances are largely improvised, but they can be structured
(Batterbury 1996) or actively impeded (Scott 1998) by a political economy where environmental signals are difficult to
understand (Flachs 2016; Herring 2007; Stone 2007). Yet
even in this highly commodified landscape where branding
erodes experiential knowledge, farmers still make and justify choices. Manci digubadi is a rationalization that continues
to make sense as farmer-consumers seek out the newest
technology and gamble that by investing more they can obtain greater yields. This is an aspirational decision, and my
analysis of farmer decision making contextualizes quotidian
practice within the ways that farmers hope to farm well.
Other scholarship on agrarian performance asks how
farmers conceptualize rural identity within their larger political economy. Agriculture helps signal social values that
resonate in a rural community, ranging from masculinity
(Peter et al. 2009) to Christian land stewardship (Stoll 2002),
the pursuit of postcolonial modernity (Pandian 2009), or
environmentalism (Silvasti 2003). As India’s neoliberal reforms shifted development priorities from rural to urban
areas, cotton farmers internalized their precarity as individual, shameful failures set against the dominant success
story of India’s urban, high-tech development (Münster
2012; Vasavi 2012). The degree to which Telangana cotton farmers see themselves as part of that neoliberal success
story informs their performed rural identity. Analyzing daily
practices as performative acts, Butler (1990) and Bourdieu
(1977) ask how social categories like the sexed body or class,
respectively, are produced through daily performances that
normalize those categories. For farmers sifting through a
Flachs • Telangana Cotton Farming
rapidly changing seed market and aspiring to participate in
the neoliberal rural gains championed by Indian agribusiness, manci digubadi helps to normalize a cotton agriculture
with deeply ambivalent returns. Manci digubadi is the performance that remains possible for farmers seeking profits and
recognition from their agriculture. Other farmers abandon
the agricultural stage altogether and sell their land, move
to urban centers, or even commit suicide in protest (Sarma
2017).
All such performances require an audience, and the
multiple ways in which farmers deploy manci digubadi suggest
that this script is flexible. Rural sociologists (Bardone 2013;
Vanclay and Enticott 2011) describe scripts as moments
that structure public agrarian performances, emerging from
iterative course corrections in the field. As a shared set
of phrases or ideas, they help farmers justify agricultural
decisions to themselves, officials, families, neighbors, and
other audiences. Scripts reveal how farmers are conditioned
to follow rules and norms (Silvasti 2003), help to define the
parameters of good farming (Vanclay, Silvasti, and Howden
2007), and illuminate how farmers justify choices as a way
of aspiring to live the lives they want to live (Leith and
Vanclay 2017). As the seed market continuously erodes
farmers’ adaptive and learned responses to agroecological
stimuli (Stone 2007), farmers make and rationalize seed
decisions in ways that align with neoliberal discussions about
yield, choice, and the purpose of cotton agriculture. The
manci digubadi script thus both constructs a worldview and
is reduced from it, limiting the range of options that people
perceive are available to them (Vanclay and Enticott 2011).
This is an insight not just into agricultural decision making
but into the neoliberal stakes behind its justification. What
kind of farming is made possible by the explosion of choices in
the seed market, and how do farmers adopt the discourse of
modernist agricultural development when coming to terms
with those new possibilities?
MANCI DIGUBADI AS A SCRIPT
While unhelpful in fine-grained analyses of agricultural decision making or ground-truthing seed technology, manci
digubadi illuminates how farmers engage with agricultural
development. Scripts imply performers and stages, drawing
our analytic attention to the ways in which farmers stake
social claims witnessed by audiences, including neighbor
farmers, media, shops, and visiting researchers. Scripts both
reflect and create the expectations and norms of the performance. First, they introduce a shared vocabulary from the
economic and social conditions of one’s life. In neoliberal
rural India, technocratic interventions and crisis narratives
have driven the quest for ever greater yields since the green
revolution (Cullather 2013). For agricultural scientists and
policymakers, as well as for the farmers themselves, good
yields are by definition a necessary and desirable part of farming. Second, repeated justifications to auditors of various
kinds reinforce the notion that one’s response is correct or
incorrect. In a climate of frequent audits, including national
55
production updates, fluctuating commodity stock prices,
farm-level research, and neighbors walking by, farmers frequently justify their seed choices to others. As a repeated
justification, manci digubadi reinforces the notion that seed
choices should be made on the basis of good yields and that
good yields are a reasonable criterion for having made past
decisions. That farmers do not agree on seed qualities, do
not plant them long enough to observe such qualities, and
reap similar yields from all seeds is not important. Indeed,
manci (good) is not a precise term. What matters is that manci
digubadi is an acceptable response to this diverse audience.
In the context of systemic market uncertainty, the script
becomes the justification.
Manci digubadi provides a way to respond to a question that has no good answer. Nationally, this refrain has
developed a circular logic. Farmers are collectively praised
by agribusiness for their choice of GM hybrid cottonseeds
(Mohan 2013; Monsanto 2012), bolstered by data on national yield increases (Kathage and Qaim 2012), which legitimizes the justifications of farmers seeking some reason
to choose one seed over the other. Understanding the hope
for good yields as a performed script illuminates the ways in
which, for farmers and analysts, the biotechnology capitalist
world of cotton agriculture has limited the range of options
that performers find available to them. Cotton agricultural
decision making has become scripted and performed as the
search for a good yield. This normalizes the private seed
market even as it masks the uncertainties and anxieties at the
edges of cotton farming: suicide, debt, frustration with stagnant yields, evolved resistance to target pests, uncertainty as
to which seeds are best, a growing reliance on off-farm experts, and the rural–urban migration that leads older farmers
to sell or lease much of their land.
While shop owners and agricultural extension officers
that I met discriminated between seed brands by their growth
habit (bushy, branching cottons are ill-suited to dense planting) or leaf hairs (a physiological defense against pests that
suck juices from leaves and spread plant diseases), farmers remained fixated on brands. English names like ATM or
Jackpot and Telugu names like Jaadoo (magic) or Sarpanch
(a village-level political leader) make promises that farmers
do not know if they can trust. Most packets bear suggestive
images, like ATM, with a picture of an anthropomorphic cash
dispenser shooting cotton bolls out of its cash slot; Dr. Brent,
bearing a smiling, studious man in glasses and a red turban;
and Jaadoo, bearing a chicken laying golden eggs. Other,
less-showy brands simply bear enormous cotton bolls. One
Banjara farmer, when predicting the size of her seed’s cotton boll, referenced the image on the front of the packet.
“It will be huge,” she said, “look at the picture.” “Are these
pictures accurate,” I asked, surprised at her rationale. She
laughed. “Of course not, but who knows. This one might
be.” Her hope for a large boll also includes her hope for
an easier picking season when the cotton ripens, as it is almost always women, rather than men, who do the picking.
While both she and the men in her family who buy the
56
American Anthropologist • Vol. 121, No. 1 • February 2019
seeds hope for big, full cotton plants and high yields, the
specific ways in which they hope for a good yield can differ.
Ultimately, neither the women who pick and weed cotton
nor the men who buy, spray, and plow it know much about
the differences between these brands. Reading the barrage
of advertisements and hoping for a good yield based on the
image is, as farmers recognize, not the best rationale, but it
feeds into the hopefulness with which farmers choose seeds.
These are existential as well as agricultural threats.
Manci digubadi gives some order, a stage direction, to farmer
performances. Simplifying the innumerable variables of
farm life, this script helps to place farming within a shared
narrative of neoliberal India, defined by high-tech development and rising power in the global political economy
(Aiyer 2007; Münster 2012). “One must switch seeds at a
minimum every three years,” explained one Reddy cotton
farmer. “The new seeds have the best science.” His use of
the English word “science” in his justification highlights how
Telangana farmers connect themselves to India’s high-tech
success story, including GM seeds, with the newest and best
technology. Just as Ramamurthy (2017) shows with the use
of “technic,” “science” helps farmers join dominant state
narratives of success defined through technical knowledge,
industrial capitalism, and the professional expertise of the
government bureaucracy. As a material product, seeds
make social worlds possible by bringing together families
and by fulfilling religious duties (see Gold 2003). Cotton,
in particular, holds a special place in the Indian imaginary,
creating possibilities for beauty and complex displays of
status (Herring and Gold 2005; Ramamurthy 2003), including India’s national aspirations in the global commodity
economy (Beckert 2014; Guha 2007). Manci digubadi
would not resonate if it did not allow farmers to couch
their personal experiences within these broader narratives.
Drawing from empirical fieldwork in the UK and eastern
Australia, and commenting on Silvasti’s (2003) work in
Finland, Vanclay and Enticott (2011) describe four forms
of such cultural scripts: expected responses, catchphrases,
parables, and common lines of argument. Manci digubadi
serves all four purposes.
Farmer seed choices have expanded, even as seed
selection itself has become an increasingly uncertain
agricultural decision. From the three GM cottonseeds first
available to farmers in 2002, farmers now choose between
more than 1,200 private seed brands (USDA Foreign
Agricultural Service 2015). This neoliberal paradox gives
farmers more consumer choice but less-steady ground on
which to weigh options and make decisions. When the farm
is a stage that reflects one’s abilities, success, and potential
to provide for a household, manci digubadi is an expected
response to the GM cottonseed as a commodity. Using the
text-mining program Automap (Carley and Diesner 2005)
to create a semantic list (Lambert 2017) from six farmer
focus groups, I found that the word pairing “good yield” was
three times more common than any other grouping of words
and phrases used to justify seed choices, including weather,
expert suggestions, personal observations, pest responses,
and responses to other agronomic conditions. Farmers
buy seeds because they have the potential for economic
return, and that justification informs buying decisions, the
observations of neighbors, and the sales pitches of vendors,
none of whom have much empirical data to prefer one seed
over another. This reinforces the normative message: seeds
are tools for good yields, and thus seeds chosen should be
chosen because of this yield factor. Moreover, “good yields”
are a familiar justification for cotton because it is a cash
crop. Others have documented the search for good yields
as a justification for other cash crops like tobacco, hybrid
rice, and hybrid maize (Gupta 1998; Vasavi 2012).
As a catchphrase, manci digubadi is the only consistent
rationale given to describe cottonseed choices. Farmers do
not agree on the agronomic qualities of seeds or plant seeds
based on their observed yields. In one analysis, I found that
farmers who planted given seeds were significantly less likely
to plant them in the future and were far more likely to plant
seeds that they saw in neighbors’ fields (Flachs, Stone, and
Shaffer 2017). The performance of the script and the act of
justification serve a much greater purpose than the ostensible
meaning behind those words. The agronomic question of
good yields is very difficult to answer, but as a catchphrase,
manci digubadi alleviates some of this choice anxiety.
Scripts as parables are opportunities for farmers to couch
an argument within assumed sequences of events, conveying moral or normative instructions. Vanclay, Silvasti, and
Howden (2007) describe stories of farmers whose hard work
allowed them to persist even as other family farms failed,
mirrored by extension workers who celebrate hard workers
for adapting to new ways of life (Vanclay and Enticott 2011).
Manci digubadi is now inseparable from national media and
commercial branding in cotton agriculture. Farmers gossip
about spectacular yields on farms that they have never seen,
referencing seeds profiled in newspapers or on television.
The highest agricultural offices celebrate yield as the product
of wise seed choice in nationalistic terms (Aiyar 2013; The
Economic Times 2013), and farmers and seed vendors match
their enthusiasm. Yield is the benchmark by which agribusiness and state development groups measure cotton farming
(Herring 2013; Qaim 2009), so farmers also embrace the
language of producing bumper crops and maximizing returns on investments. As with all moralizing parables, the
danger of chasing high-yielding seeds also creeps into justifications of manci digubadi. Seed shortages of wildly popular
cottonseeds in 2012, 2013, and 2014 led to widespread
accusations of spurious “duplicate” or fake seeds sold by
brokers and smugglers taking advantage of farmer demand.
Seed smugglers continue to be apprehended by the police
(The Hindu 2017), while in 2014 companies placed full-page
newspaper notices that showed farmers how to spot fakes.
The parable of the good, aspirational yield is kept in motion
both by the celebrated stories of high-yielding farmers in
rural news media and by the threat of gambling and losing
with black market seeds.
Flachs • Telangana Cotton Farming
The script reveals farmers’ explicit and implicit audiences. Manci digubadi is a response to fellow farmers and the
assurance of shop owners, but it also reflects the expectations
of crop scientists and the larger discourse of agricultural economics mediated through policy, news, and shops. Farmers
can be deeply troubled by their own uncertainties and reliance on shops, but they have few alternative sources of
information. The script is a way to understand and justify
one’s decisions, especially when asked to justify them in
conversation with audiences ranging from curious neighbors
to foreign anthropologists.
TAKING SCRIPTS OFF THE FARM
Introduced as a solution to a crisis of pest attacks and low
yields, GM cotton has been judged largely on its promise to
raise yields (Herring 2015; Scoones 2006). Through public discourse in newspapers, on television, and in scientific
reports, Telangana farmers have adopted this measure of
success, justifying all seed choices in the context of the manci
digubadi script. Since 2010, by which time most farmers had
adopted GM cotton, national yields have largely stagnated
(Kranthi 2016; Stone 2011). Yet this script persists. More
than just an economic hope, manci digubadi encompasses the
neoliberal vision of success in GM cotton agriculture: invest
more, choose more, earn more, and produce more. Farmers
internalize this through the performance of the right kind of
farmer, who takes advice but chooses freely, makes the right
decision, cares for his farm by investing agrochemicals, and
reaps the rewards of this hard work.
Unquestioned in this story is why yields would plateau
when almost all farmers plant GM cotton, why hybrids are
water intensive when so many farmers lack irrigation, why
the hybrid seeds are exclusively Gossypium hirsutum species
so vulnerable to nontarget pests that total insecticide use
has now surpassed pre-GM levels (Kranthi 2014), or what
farmers will do now that some bollworms show resistance
to the insecticidal genes (Aryai 2016). Also unquestioned is
why the world needs so much cotton; the planet produces far
more cotton than could be spun into clothing, a glut that has
lasted several years (Patwardhan 2015; USDA Foreign Agricultural Service 2016). India and other states bear the cost
of this global surplus by providing minimum support prices,
effective subsidies against global market rates. Further down
the supply chain, this ever-increasing stock is spun into cheap
clothing at the expense of worker rights and safety, exported
to wealthy markets in the United States and Europe, and
eventually sold back to poorer nations through large-scale
donations that suppress domestic industry (Beckert 2014;
Brooks 2015).
This analysis has practical and theoretical contributions.
Scripts themselves are undertheorized in the social study of
agriculture, which is too often seen not as a set of socioecological performances but as a set of economic decisions. The
reduction of agricultural complexity to manci digubadi illustrates how farmer decision making has increasingly narrowed
its scope in ways that benefit agribusiness but place farmers
57
at risk. The explosion of possible seed brands that farmers
can choose from is the most obvious way that agribusiness
takes advantage of this uncertainty, but as farmers adopt the
script they also adopt the logic of agricultural economists
who see no reason to plant cotton other than to pursue good
yields.
Farmer decisions cannot be understood without considering agriculture’s performative nature or the neoliberal stages on which this performance occurs. Taking manci
digubadi seriously as a script provides a vocabulary through
which we can understand larger contexts, roles, cultural
norms, and the unseen work of various agricultural values
at play in rural India. These include subjective discourses
about farming well in the effort to be a successful person,
village- and farmer-level conceptions of development and
progress, the temporal acceleration of the seed market, and
the singular focus of the academic agricultural community
on quantifiable increases in production. All of these agrarian norms are reflected in the manci digubadi script but because this script breaks down under ethnographic scrutiny,
it masks a deep ambivalence about what it means to have
“good” yields.
As consumers of seeds, farmers often have little basis
for choosing the seeds they sow. As producers of cotton,
farmers invest and effectively gamble in the hope of reaping
a large harvest for a global market already facing a cotton
glut. This problem stems from the rapid diversification of
a private seed market as well as the uncertain local agricultural conditions in which farmers evaluate those seeds
across their own and neighbor fields. India’s cotton sector
has been increasingly capitalized over the past twenty years,
first through pesticides and hybrid seeds and now through
GM seeds and herbicides. As the performance of knowledge
and self are further squeezed into the limiting script of manci
digubadi with the growth of herbicides and high-density cotton planting systems (Stone and Flachs 2017), farmers will
continue to perform the role of consumers seeking economic
returns. This has helped drive increases in urban industrial
production, export, and gross domestic product on the positive side, and rural inequality, the dissolution of rural safety
nets through neoliberal policies, and farmer suicide on the
negative side.
Finally, the lens of performance combats a persistent
question in Indian cotton agriculture: If GM seeds are not
inherently better, why have farmers adopted them with
such enthusiasm? This question, posed in endless variation
by economists (Herring and Rao 2012; Kathage and Qaim
2012), critical observers (Kranthi 2016; Stone 2013), and
government officials (Mohan 2013), presumes an economic
rationalism: farmers simply do what’s best. But to really
do what is best, farmers must have a way of knowing
what choices will be best. Because knowing what’s best is
often quite difficult for farmers, my focus on performance
illuminates the larger socioeconomic context in which
farmers choose GM seeds, year after year. Manci digubadi
is about more than just yields. This script reveals a search
58
American Anthropologist • Vol. 121, No. 1 • February 2019
for social recognition, personal satisfaction, relief, and
affirmation from an audience of shop owners, agricultural
scientists, neighbors, and relatives that these yields might
bring. By recognizing that the ultimate goal of agriculture
is as much about the performance of good farming as it is
about yield production, we understand the complexity of
agriculture as a social act.
Andrew Flachs
Assistant Professor of Anthropology, Depart-
ment of Anthropology, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN 47907,
USA;
[email protected]
NOTES
Acknowledgments.
The author is grateful to the Department
of Education Jacob K. Javits Fellowship Program, the Volkswagen
Foundation, and the National Geographic Society Young Explorer’s
Grant for funding this research. Ranjith Nakka Kumar and Arun
Vaynala Kumar provided valuable research assistance, Ram Mohan
Rao and Vandita Rao provided indispensable logistical help in India.
Glenn Davis Stone and Zoe Nyssa, along with three anonymous
reviewers, provided valuable comments on this manuscript.
1. Selected villages represented a range of variation in urban connectivity, soil quality, access to irrigation, and ethnicity, which
in this context differentiates members of the Banjara Scheduled
Tribe (ST) from ethnic Telugu caste communities.
2. Member of India’s historically marginalized Scheduled Caste
community.
3. Member of India’s historically landowning and Open Caste
community.
4. Literally a large farmer, this term also connotes high socioeconomic status.
5. Another high-status, historically landlord Open Caste.
6. Rural town here refers to rural villages at least forty minutes
to the nearest minor city but with reliable electricity and transportation routes. Town refers to villages within twenty minutes
of the nearest minor city. Rural refers to villages lacking reliable
transportation or electricity, where population density is lower.
The differences and meaning of those differences between village
types and ethnicities will be explained in greater detail below.
REFERENCES CITED
Agrawal, Arun, and K. Sivaramakrishnan, eds. 2000. Agrarian Environments: Resources, Representations, and Rule in India. Durham,
NC: Duke University Press.
Aiyer, Ananthakrishnan. 2007. “The Allure of the Transnational:
Notes on the Some Aspects of the Political Economy of Water
in India.” Cultural Anthropology 22 (4): 640–58.
Aiyar, Swaminathan S. Anklesaria. 2013. “Higher Yields & Farmer
Preferences Show, Bt Cotton Detractors Spreading Patent Falsehoods.” The Economic Times, January 30. https://economictimes.
indiatimes.com/swaminathan-s-a-aiyar/higher-yields-farmerpreferences-show-bt-cotton-detractors-spreading-patentfalsehoods/articleshow/18246681.cms.
Aryai, Shishir. 2016. “Is Bt Cotton No Longer Safe against Pink
Bollworm?” Times of India, February 13. http://timesofindia.
indiatimes.com/city/nagpur/Is-Bt-Cotton-no-longer-safeagainst-pink-bollworm/articleshow/50967835.cms.
Bardone, Ester. 2013. “My Farm Is My Stage: A Performance
Perspective on Rural Tourism and Hospitality Services in
Estonia.” Thesis, University of Tartu. http://dspace.utlib.
ee/dspace/handle/10062/34504.
Basu, A. K., and R. S. Paroda. 1995. Hybrid Cotton in India: A Success
Story. Bangkok: Asia-Pacific Association of Agricultural Research
Institutions.
Batterbury, Simon P. J. 1996. “Planners or Performers? Reflections on Indigenous Dryland Farming in Northern Burkina Faso.” Agriculture and Human Values 13 (3): 12–22.
https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01538223.
Beckert, Sven. 2014. Empire of Cotton: A Global History. New York:
Knopf.
Bell, Michael Mayerfeld. 2010. Farming for Us All: Practical Agriculture
and the Cultivation of Sustainability. State College: Penn State
Press.
Bourdieu, Pierre. 1977. Outline of a Theory of Practice. Translated by Richard Nice. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Brooks, Andrew. 2015. Clothing Poverty: The Hidden World of Fast
Fashion and Second-Hand Clothes. London: Zed Books.
Butler, Judith. 1990. Gender Trouble: Feminism and the Subversion of
Identity. New York: Routledge.
Carley, Kathleen M., and Jana Diesner. 2005. Automap: Software for
Network Text Analysis. Pittsburgh, PA: Center for Computational
Analysis of Social and Organizational Systems.
Cayla, Julien, and Giana M. Eckhardt. 2008. “Asian Brands and
the Shaping of a Transnational Imagined Community.” Journal of Consumer Research 35 (2): 216–30. https://doi.org/
10.1086/587629.
Cullather, Nick. 2013. The Hungry World: America’s Cold War Battle against Poverty in Asia. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
David, Paul. 2007. “Path Dependence: A Foundational Concept for
Historical Social Science.” Cliometrica 1 (2): 91–114. https://
doi.org/10.1007/s11698-006-0005-x.
Deccan Chronicle. 2018. “Burdened by Debt, 2 Farmers Commit
Suicide in Telangana.” Deccan Chronicle, March 6. https://www.
deccanchronicle.com/nation/crime/060318/burdened-bydebt-2-farmers-commit-suicide-in-telangana.html.
Deshpande, R. S., and Saroj Arora. 2010. “Editor’s Introduction.”
In Agrarian Crisis and Farmer Suicides, edited by R. S. Deshpande and Saroj Arora, 1–42. New Delhi: SAGE Publications
India.
The Economic Times. 2013. “Farmers Prefer Growing Genetically
Modified Crops: Sharad Pawar.” The Economic Times, August
27. https://economictimes.indiatimes.com/news/economy/
agriculture/farmers-prefer-growing-genetically-modifiedcropssharad-pawar/articleshow/22095086.cms.
Fedoroff, Nina V. 2011. “Genetically Engineered Food for All.”
New York Times, August 18. http://www.nytimes.com/2011/
08/19/opinion/genetically-engineered-food-for-all.html.
Flachs • Telangana Cotton Farming
Flachs, Andrew. 2016. “Redefining Success: The Political Ecology
of Genetically Modified and Organic Cotton as Solutions to
Agrarian Crisis.” Journal of Political Ecology 23 (1): 49–70.
Flachs, Andrew, and Glenn Davis Stone. 2018. “Farmer Knowledge across the Commodification Spectrum: Rice, Cotton, and
Vegetables in Telangana, India.” Journal of Agrarian Change.
https://doi.org/10.1111/joac.12295.
Flachs, Andrew, Glenn Davis Stone, and Christopher Shaffer. 2017.
“Mapping Knowledge: GIS as a Tool for Spatial Modeling
of Patterns of Warangal Cotton Seed Popularity and Farmer
Decision-Making.” Human Ecology 45 (2): 143–59. https://
doi.org/10.1007/s10745-016-9885-y.
Galab, S., E. Revathi, and P. Prudhvikar Reddy. 2009. “Farmers’
Suicides and Unfolding Agrarian Crisis in Andhra Pradesh.” In
Agrarian Crisis in India, edited by D. Narasimha Reddy and Srijit
Mishra. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.
Gold, Ann Grodzins. 2003. “Vanishing: Seeds’ Cyclicality.” Journal
of Material Culture 8 (3): 255–72. https://doi.org/10.1177/
13591835030083002.
Guha, Ramachandra. 2008. India after Gandhi: The History of
the World’s Largest Democracy. New York: Harper Collins
Publishers.
Guha, Smit. 2007. “Genetic Change and Colonial Cotton Improvement in Nineteenth and Twentieth Century India.” In Situating
Environmental History, edited by Ranjan Chakrabarti, 307–22.
New Delhi: Manohar.
Gupta, Akhil. 1998. Postcolonial Developments: Agriculture in the
Making of Modern India. Durham, NC: Duke University
Press.
Gupta, Akhil. 2017. “Farming as Speculative Activity: The Ecological
Basis of Farmers’ Suicides in India.” In The Routledge Companion to the Environmental Humanities, edited by Ursula K. Heise,
Jon Christensen, and Michelle Niemann, 185–93. London:
Routledge.
Gutierrez, Andrew Paul, Luigi Ponti, Hans R. Herren,
Johann Baumgärtner, and Peter E. Kenmore. 2015. “Deconstructing Indian Cotton: Weather, Yields, and Suicides.”
Environmental Sciences Europe 27 (1): 12. https://doi.org/
10.1186/s12302-015-0043-8.
Hakim, Danny. 2016. “Doubts About the Promised Bounty
of Genetically Modified Crops.” New York Times, October
29. http://www.nytimes.com/2016/10/30/business/gmopromise-falls-short.html.
Harvey, David. 1991. The Condition of Postmodernity: An Enquiry into
the Origins of Cultural Change. Oxford: Wiley-Blackwell.
Harvey, David. 2007. A Brief History of Neoliberalism. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Herring, Ronald J. 2007. “Stealth Seeds: Bioproperty, Biosafety,
Biopolitics.” Journal of Development Studies 43 (1): 130–57.
https://doi.org/10.1080/00220380601055601.
Herring, Ronald J. 2013. “Reconstructing Facts with Bt Cotton: Why
Scepticism Fails.” Economic and Political Weekly 48 (33): 63–66.
Herring, Ronald J. 2015. “State Science, Risk and Agricultural
Biotechnology: Bt Cotton to Bt Brinjal in India.” Journal
of Peasant Studies 42 (1): 159–86. https://doi.org/10.1080/
03066150.2014.951835.
59
Herring, Ronald J., and Ann Grodzins Gold. 2005. “Biology and
Utility: Meanings and Histories.” Economic and Political Weekly 40
(38): 4117–20.
Herring, Ronald J., and N. Chandrasekhara Rao. 2012.
“On the ‘Failure of Bt Cotton’: Analysing a Decade
of Experience.” Economic and Political Weekly 47 (18):
45–53.
The Hindu. 2013. “Use of Bt. Cotton Increased Yield, Farmers’
Income: Pawar.” The Hindu, August 29. http://www.thehindu.
com/news/national/use-of-bt-cotton-increasedyield-farmersincome-pawar/article5069072.ece.
The Hindu. 2017. “Spurious Cotton Seeds Seized.” The Hindu, June
9. http://www.thehindu.com/news/national/telangana/spur
ious-cotton-seeds-seized/article18869248.ece.
Jadhav, Rajendra. 2018. “India Farmers Sow Unapproved Monsanto
Cotton Seeds, Risking Arrest.” Reuters, June 12. https://www.
reuters.com/article/us-india-cotton/india-farmers-sowunapproved-monsanto-cotton-seeds-risking-arrest-idUSKBN1J
80YT.
Jha, Dilip Kumar. 2013. “Bt Cotton Losing Steam, Productivity at
5-Yr Low.” Business Standard India, February 7. http://www.
business-standard.com/article/markets/bt-cotton-losingsteam-productivity-at-5-yr-low-113020601016_1.html.
Kathage, Jonas, and Matin Qaim. 2012. “Economic Impacts and
Impact Dynamics of Bt (Bacillus Thuringiensis) Cotton in India.”
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 109 (29): 11652–56.
https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1203647109.
Kranthi, K. R. 2014. “Cotton Production Systems—Need for a
Change in India.” Cotton Statistics & News 38, December 16,
pp. 4–7.
Kranthi, K. R. 2016. “Technology and Agriculture: Messed in India!”
The Indian Express blog. March 10. http://indianexpress.
com/article/india/india-news-india/technology-andagriculture-messed-in-india/.
Lambert, Natalie J. 2017. “Text Mining Tutorial.” In Group Processes:
Data-Driven Computational Approaches, edited by Andrew Pliny
and Marshall Scott Poole, 93–117. New York: Springer International Publishing.
Leith, Peat, and Frank Vanclay. 2017. “Placing Science for Natural
Resource Management and Climate Variability: Lessons from
Narratives of Risk, Place and Identity.” Sociologia Ruralis 57 (2):
155–70. https://doi.org/10.1111/soru.12124.
Leslie, Paul, and J. Terrence McCabe. 2013. “Response Diversity and
Resilience in Social-Ecological Systems.” Current Anthropology 54
(2): 114–43. https://doi.org/10.1086/669563.
Linssen, Rik, Luuk van Kempen, and Gerbert Kraaykamp. 2010.
“Subjective Well-Being in Rural India: The Curse of Conspicuous Consumption.” Social Indicators Research 101 (1): 57–72.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-010-9635-2.
Maertens, Annemie. 2017. “Who Cares What Others Think (or
Do)? Social Learning and Social Pressures in Cotton Farming
in India.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 99 (4): 988–
1007. https://doi.org/10.1093/ajae/aaw098.
Menon, Meena, and Uzramma. 2018. A Frayed History: The
Journey of Cotton in India. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
60
American Anthropologist • Vol. 121, No. 1 • February 2019
Mohan, Vishwa. 2013. “Sharad Pawar Bats for GM Crops in House,
Holds up Bt Cotton as Success Story.” Times of India, August 28.
http://timesofindia.indiatimes.com/india/Sharad-Pawar-batsfor-GM-crops-in-House-holds-up-Bt-cotton-as-success-story/
articleshow/22109722.cms.
Mohanty, B. B. 2005. “‘We Are Like the Living Dead’: Farmer
Suicides in Maharashtra, Western India.” Journal of Peasant Studies 32 (2): 243–76. https://doi.org/10.1080/030661505000
94485.
Monsanto. 2012. “India Cotton Success.” http://www.monsanto.
com/improvingagriculture/pages/celebrating-bollgard-cottonindia.aspx.
Münster, Daniel. 2012. “Farmers’ Suicides and the State in India: Conceptual and Ethnographic Notes from Wayanad,
Kerala.” Contributions to Indian Sociology 46 (1–2): 181–208.
https://doi.org/10.1177/006996671104600208.
Münster, Daniel. 2015. “Farmers’ Suicides as Public Death: Politics, Agency and Statistics in a Suicide-Prone District (South
India).” Modern Asian Studies 49 (5): 1580–605. https://doi.
org/10.1017/S0026749×14000225.
Netting, Robert McC. 1993. Smallholders, Householders: Farm Families
and the Ecology of Intensive, Sustainable Agriculture. Stanford, CA:
Stanford University Press.
The New Indian Express. 2012. “A Mayhem Called Mahyco
Seed Shortage.” The New Indian Express, June 25.
http://newindianexpress.com/states/andhra_pradesh/article
550368.ece.
Pandian, Anand. 2009. Crooked Stalks: Cultivating Virtue in South India.
Durham, NC: Duke University Press Books.
Patwardhan, Mayank. 2015. “Global Glut in Cotton to Persist.”
Business Standard India, June 10. http://www.businessstandard.com/article/markets/global-glut-in-cotton-topersist-115061000904_1.html.
Peter, Gregory, Michael Mayerfeld Bell, Susan Jarnagin, and
Donna Bauer. 2009. “Coming Back Across the Fence:
Masculinity and the Transition to Sustainable Agriculture*.” Rural Sociology 65 (2): 215–33. https://doi.org/
10.1111/j.1549-0831.2000.tb00026.x.
Qaim, Matin. 2009. “The Economics of Genetically Modified
Crops.” Annual Review of Resource Economics 1:665–94. https://
doi.org/10.1146/annurev.resource.050708.144203.
Qaim, Matin, and David Zilberman. 2003. “Yield Effects of Genetically Modified Crops in Developing Countries.” Science 299
(5608): 900–902. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1080609.
Ramamurthy, Priti. 2003. “Material Consumers, Fabricating Subjects: Perplexity, Global Connectivity Discourses, and Transnational Feminist Research.” Cultural Anthropology 18 (4): 524–50.
https://doi.org/10.1525/can.2003.18.4.524.
Ramamurthy, Priti. 2011. “Rearticulating Caste: The Global Cottonseed Commodity Chain and the Paradox of Smallholder Capitalism in South India.” Environment and Planning A: Economy and
Space 43 (5): 1035–56. https://doi.org/10.1068/a43215.
Ramamurthy, Priti. 2017. “Technic.” South Asia: Journal of South Asian
Studies 40 (2): 400–403.
Rao, P. Narasimha, and K. C. Suri. 2006. “Dimensions of
Agrarian Distress in Andhra Pradesh. Economic and Po-
litical Weekly.” Economic and Political Weekly 41 (16):
1546–52.
Reddy, A. Amarender. 2017. “Agrarian Economy of Telangana.”
Report delivered at the Telangana Economic Association Conference, March 10, Hyderabad, India.
Richards, Paul. 1989. “Agriculture as a Performance.” In Farmer First:
Farmer Innovation and Agricultural Research, edited by Robert
Chambers, Arnold Pacey, and Lori Ann Thrupp, 39–42.
London: Intermediate Technology.
Richards, Paul. 1993. “Cultivation: Knowledge or Performance?” In
An Anthropological Critique of Development: The Growth of Ignorance,
edited by Mark Hobart, 61–78. New York: Routledge.
Sarma, Ch. R. S. 2017. “Spurious Seeds Playing Havoc with Farmers’
Lives in AP, Telangana.” Hindu Business Line, December 15.
https://www.thehindubusinessline.com/economy/agribusiness/spurious-seeds-playing-havoc-with-farmers-lives-inap-telangana/article9992518.ece.
Scoones, Ian. 2006. Science, Agriculture and the Politics of Policy: The
Case of Biotechnology in India. New Delhi: Orient Blackswan.
Scott, James C. 1998. Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to
Improve the Human Condition Have Failed. New Haven, CT: Yale
University Press.
Shiva, Vandana, Afsar H. Jafri, Ashok Emani, and Manish Pande.
2002. Seeds of Suicide. New Delhi: Research Foundation for
Science, Technology, and Ecology.
Silvasti, Tiina. 2003. “The Cultural Model of ‘the Good
Farmer’ and the Environmental Question in Finland.” Agriculture and Human Values 20 (2): 143–50. https://doi.org/
10.1023/A:1024021811419.
Stoll, Steven. 2002. Larding the Lean Earth: Soil and Society in Nineteenth
Century America. New York: Hill and Wang.
Stone, Glenn Davis. 2007. “Agricultural Deskilling and the Spread of
Genetically Modified Cotton in Warangal.” Current Anthropology
48 (1): 67–103.
Stone, Glenn Davis. 2011. “Field versus Farm in Warangal: Bt Cotton,
Higher Yields, and Larger Questions.” World Development 39 (3):
387–98.
Stone, Glenn Davis 2013. “A Response to Herring and Rao.” Economic
and Political Weekly 48 (33): 70–72.
Stone, Glenn Davis, and Andrew Flachs. 2017. “The Ox Fall
Down: Path-Breaking and Technology Treadmills in Indian
Cotton Agriculture.” Journal of Peasant Studies. https://doi.
org/10.1080/03066150.2017.1291505.
Stone, Glenn Davis, Andrew Flachs, and Christine Diepenbrock.
2014. “Rhythms of the Herd: Long Term Dynamics in Seed
Choice by Indian Farmers.” Technology in Society 36 (1):
26–38.
Taylor, Marcus. 2013. “Liquid Debts: Credit, Groundwater and
the Social Ecology of Agrarian Distress in Andhra Pradesh,
India.” Third World Quarterly 34 (4): 691–709. https://doi.
org/10.1080/01436597.2013.786291.
Taylor, Marcus. 2014. The Political Ecology of Climate Change Adaptation: Livelihoods, Agrarian Change and the Conflicts of Development.
New York: Routledge Earthscan.
USDA Foreign Agricultural Service. 2015. Cotton: World Markets and
Trade. Washington, DC: USDA.
Flachs • Telangana Cotton Farming
USDA Foreign Agricultural Service. 2016. China and Hong Kong:
Challenges and Opportunities. Washington, DC: USDA.
Vaidyanathan, A. 2006. “Farmers’ Suicides and the Agrarian Crisis.”
Economic and Political Weekly 41 (38): 4009–13.
Vanclay, Frank, and Gareth Enticott. 2011. “The Role and Functioning of Cultural Scripts in Farming and Agriculture.” Sociologia Ruralis 51 (3): 256–71. https://doi.org/10.1111/
j.1467-9523.2011.00537.x.
Vanclay, Frank, Tiina Silvasti, and Peter Howden. 2007. “Styles,
Parables and Scripts: Diversity and Conformity in Australian
and Finnish Agriculture.” Rural Society 17 (1): 3–8. https://
doi.org/10.5172/rsj.351.17.1.3.
61
Vasavi, A. R. 1999. Harbingers of Rain: Land and Life in South Asia.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Vasavi, A. R. 2012. Shadow Space: Suicides and the Predicament of Rural
India. Gurgaon: Three Essays Collective.
Wadke, Rahul. 2012. “Mahyco Denies It Sold Its Seeds in Black Market.” The Hindu, July 15. http://www.thehindubusinessline.
com/industry-and-economy/agri-biz/article3658632.ece?
homepage=true&ref=wl_home.
Walker, Kathy Le Mons. 2008. “Neoliberalism on the Ground in
Rural India: Predatory Growth, Agrarian Crisis, Internal Colonization, and the Intensification of Class Struggle.” Journal of
Peasant Studies 35 (4): 557–620.
Appendix A
Village Distribution of Farmer Respondents
Village names
(changed)
Households
surveyed
Average
cotton
landholding
(acres)
Kavrupad
Ralledapalle
Srigonda
Gongapalle
Orukonda
All Banjara
All Telugu
Caste
66
62
69
60
60
134
183
6.76
3.86
5.92
4.34
6.52
5.18
6.18
Average
cotton yield,
2013 (quintals)
Ethnic
composition
Soil quality
Village type6
6.95
6.97
6.44
7.71
7.84
7.01
7.70
Caste/Banjara
Banjara
Caste/Banjara
Caste
Caste
Banjara
Caste
Mixed
Poor
Mixed
Good
Good
Poor
Mixed
Rural town
Rural
Rural town
Town
Town
Rural
Rural
town/town