7KH&KDQJLQJ1DWXUHRIWKH2(&'6KDGRZ(FRQRP\
0DXUL]LR%RYL
5REHUWR'HOO·$QQR
,6$( ,VWLWXWRGL6WXGLH$QDOLVL(FRQRPLFD
8QLYHUVLWjGL)RJJLD
Piazza dell’Indipendenza, 4
00185 - Roma - Italy
e-mail:
[email protected]
Largo Papa Giovanni Paolo II, 1
71100 – Foggia - Italy
e-mail:
[email protected]
$EVWUDFW
As recently suggested, the shadow economy and its determinants (taxation, regulations, corruption, etc.) are
linked such that just two stable equilibria are possible. In the good one there is a small hidden sector, large
fiscal revenues and honest/ appreciated institutions. The other (bad) equilibrium is quite the opposite. Our
paper examines the links between these variables in relatively uncorrupt systems. Unlike mainstream
literature, we suggest that a continuum of SE equilibrium rates can emerge and that taxation and
underground activities can be positively correlated. Empirical evidence for OECD countries broadly
supports the model.
-(/&ODVVLILFDWLRQ
.H\ZRUGV
H26, K42, O17.
shadow economy; multiple equilibria; taxation; rule of law.
1
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=985867
1RQ7HFKQLFDO6XPPDU\
The Shadow Economy (SE) is of great importance for the economy because it has relevant repercussions
on the many aspects of economic and social life of a country. Despite of that, only recently the economic
literature addressed its pervasive nature.
In the spirit of Allingham-Sandmo (AS, 1972), the economic literature has been associating the presence of
SE mainly with taxation - the bigger the tax burden, the greater the hidden income. Basically, tax evasion is
a gamble taken by private agents and limited “public-sector” feedbacks are considered. Recently, another
strand of the research (Johnson HWDO., 1997; Friedman HWDO, 2000) underlines the importance of institutional
failures, such as excessive regulations, inefficiency of the bureaucracy and corruption. Its basic message is
that there are links between SE and its causes such that just two extreme, stable, equilibria are possible. In
the “good” one, a wide tax base and large public revenues are ruled by an efficient and uncorrupt
government, which rises the costs to be underground (LH. the expected penalty and the exclusion from
appreciated public services). In this optimal situation, public institutions are honest and well functioning
because sufficiently supported by large flows of public receipts. In the “bad” equilibrium, the spiral works
in the opposite direction, unavoidably leading to inefficient and corrupt institutions operating side-by-side
to a large irregular sector. In contrast to the AS framework, it implies that
KLJKHU
tax burdens can be
associated with OHVVSE.
Against this backdrop, we offer some additional theoretical considerations supported by an empirical
analysis. The main novelty of our paper lies in arguing that moving away from the bad equilibrium may lead
to different good equilibria. In fact, the recent literature focuses in particular on the bad equilibrium
because it deals with underdeveloped/ transitional countries, leaving unexplored important questions on
uncorrupt governments’ choices. It motivates the present work. Since outside the bad equilibrium, in fact,
these governments may prefer to be revenue-maximizing or tax rates minimizing. From the optimal SE
ratio standpoint, government’s choices are clearly not neutral and may restore the AS positive relationship
between tax rates and tax evasion. In addition, as for the revenue-maximizing case, we claim that important
feedbacks between the variables emerge – good/ large institutions need high tax rates/ revenues and may
incur in over-regulation; public expenditures may suffer from decreasing productivity in hampering the SE,
calling for ever growing tax receipts. Thus, a relatively uncorrupt revenue-maximizing government may
suffer from non-zero tax evasion both for taxation and for institutional reasons.
Our model raises important testable implications, when the experiments deal with relatively uncorrupt
economic systems – i) honest bureaucracies may suffer from a significant share of SE, ii) KLJKHU tax rates can
be associated with
PRUH
SE, iii) the efficiency of the public sector could be positively related to SE, iv)
capitalistic (LH with a small public sector) countries should show the minimum, although strictly positive,
SE ratio. The first two items are in contrast to the institutional literature. In particular, the second implies
that some situations may cause the AS tradition switching over the recent approach. The third suggests the
2
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=985867
presence of non linear relationships between some of the variables involved. The latter logically follows
from the others.
The empirical analysis of the underground economy must be led and valued, by definition, very carefully.
Therefore, while broadly confirming the theoretical model, the exercises here proposed can realistically
offer only some indicative correlations. On the positive side, dealing with OECD countries we afford to
perform panel estimations over several years. This is hardly found in literature, which is usually limited to
cross-section analyses. Finally, what pointed out in this paper contributes to the ongoing debate,
corroborating previous empirical results and offering new insights.
6,17(6,
L’economia sommersa è fenomeno pervasivo e permanente e l’analisi economica che la riguarda sembra
potersi suddividere in due tronconi. Il primo si sofferma sulla relazione tra sommerso e tassazione. Il
secondo, più recente, ha sottolineato l’importanza delle istituzioni economiche nel determinare il livello di
economia in nero. La dicotomia discende, tra l’altro, dal fatto che l’approccio istituzionale è rivolto
soprattutto ai paesi meno sviluppati, dove il potere di tassare è inversamente collegato al livello di
corruzione presente nei poteri pubblici. Infatti, un suo interessante risultato empirico è che, analizzando
anche i paesi più poveri, economia sommersa e aliquote fiscali mostrano una correlazione negativa. Il
contrario di quanto teorizzato dal filone di ricerca nato quasi quarant’anni fa dai lavori microeconomici di
Allingham e Sandmo. Inoltre, non avendo la possibilità di tassare, un paese non può finanziare istituzioni
buone ed efficienti, il che, secondo i teorici “istituzionali”, lo inchioda in un equilibrio cattivo.
Il nostro lavoro propone di allargare anche ai paesi appartenenti all’OCSE l’analisi istituzionale. Il motivo è
capire quali sono, in paesi dotati di istituzioni relativamente poco corrotte e sufficientemente efficienti, le
relazioni che possono instaurarsi tra alcune istituzioni economiche (le regolamentazioni dei mercati, la
bontà dell’apparato burocratico, la tassazione, ecc) e l’economia sommersa. Un modello teorico e i risultati
empirici sembrano convergere verso le seguenti indicazioni:
•
anche i paesi maggiormente industrializzati devono convivere con una quota non indifferente e non
temporanea di economia sommersa;
•
nei paesi maggiormente industrializzati l’economia nascosta aumenta con la tassazione;
•
nei paesi maggiormente industrializzati l’economia nascosta aumenta con la pervasività delle
istituzioni, ancorché esse siano delle buone istituzioni;
•
tra i paesi maggiormente industrializzati, sono quelli maggiormente orientati verso il mercato (cioè
quelli maggiormente capitalistici) a mostrare il minore livello (comunque non zero) di economia
sotterranea.
3
INTRODUCTION
The shadow economy1 (SE) has several impacts on the economic system, some positive, some negative.
Despite improvements and efforts (OECD, 2002), national accounts are still biased by the underground
activities and this can mislead the policymakers. The SE affects the design of the national tax systems and
triggers links between legal and illegal activities, it may impose constraints to the public revenues generation
and, therefore, limit the provision of the public goods/ services. On the positive side, the SE allows
bypassing excessive regulations, provides an alternative social safety net, and may be the necessary first-step
for training the new taxpayers. The SE is persistent and widespread in time and in space. According to
Schneider and Enste’s survey (2000), during the last decades the underground sector was nearly threequarters of the officially recorded GDP in Nigeria and Thailand, but it amounted to a noteworthy 15
percent in the OECD countries as well.
Mainstream literature on SE may be roughly divided into two clusters. The first associates the presence of
SE mainly with taxation (Allingham and Sandmo, AS, 1972 and followers). An alternative, more recent,
view underlines the importance of institutional failures such as excessive regulations, inefficiency of the
bureaucracy and corruption (Johnson
HW DO
., 1997; Friedman
HW DO
., 2000, Rosser
HW DO
2003). The former
points out that, FHWHULVSDULEXV, the bigger the tax burden, the greater the hidden income in order to increase
the disposable income. The latter points out that, just like another kind of tax, regulations are costly to be
satisfied and can stimulate the ‘quit option’ (LH the decision to go underground). The efficiency of the
public sector is then connected with the SE because a more efficient bureaucracy increases the expected
value of the penalty and this lowers, other things being equal, the optimal level of SE. Furthermore, a
reduced quality and quantity of public services, because of the bad government, may discourage individuals
from using these services and make them less willing to pay for them. It is important to observe that the
above mentioned variables are strictly interrelated and that only some combinations of their values are
possible. In fact, the recent literature shows that economic systems can be locked in two very different
stable equilibria, one good and one bad. In the former, a wide tax base and large public revenues are ruled
by efficient and uncorrupt governments, which rises the costs to be underground (LH. the expected penalty
and the exclusion from public services). On the other hand, public institutions are honest and well
functioning because sufficiently supported by large flows of public receipts. In the latter, the spiral works in
the opposite direction, unavoidably leading to inefficient and corrupt institutions operating side-by-side to a
large irregular sector. This “system-wide” standpoint suggests that
KLJKHU
tax burdens could be associated
1
The unobserved sector of the economy has nor a commonly accepted definition, neither a commonly used name. A
plethora of terms suggestive of different situations (underground, subterranean, moonlight, hidden, irregular, shadow,
black, informal, etc.) have been used to call it. We will indifferently use here some of them. Regarding to the
definition, a good benchmark is worked out in 1993 by the System of National Accounts (SNA): the underground
economy is the value-added activities that the official statistics do not register although they should (see also OECD,
2002). This definition seems to be sufficiently close to the kind of underground activity here studied, although there is
no need for them to be equal given the different targets between the present work and the SNA.
4
with OHVVSE which, actually, is an interesting empirical result of the institutional approach.
In line with this recent strand of the literature and motivated i) by the multifaceted nature and ii) by the
widespread and enduring presence of a non trivial share of SE even in developed countries, we propose a
simple model supporting some testable implications. The main novelty of our theoretical setting lies in
arguing that, once escaped from the bad equilibrium, different good equilibria are possible. Unlike AS (and
followers) and the institutional literature, this paper points out the effects of government’s choices on the
private sector, with this latter reacting only to some extent. In fact, the AS tradition focuses especially on
the private sector analysis. On the other hand, the institutional literature deals with private agents’ choices
and their effects on the public sector, with the government modeled as a passive player. Possibly, this is so
because this strand of the research is particularly interested in studying underdeveloped/ transitional
countries, likely lying in the bad equilibrium. However, it leaves unexplored important questions on
uncorrupt governments’ choices, which may well actively prefer to be,
HJ
, revenue-maximizing or tax-
burden-minimizing. We want to fill this gap because, as for the SE equilibrium, government’s preferences
are clearly not neutral. In addition, as for the revenue-maximizing case, we claim that important feedbacks
between the variables emerge – good/ large institutions need large revenues and may incur in overregulation; on the other hand, public expenditures may suffer from decreasing productivity in hampering
the SE, calling for ever growing tax receipts.
Our model raises important testable implications, when the experiments deal with relatively uncorrupt
governments – i) even honest bureaucracies may chronically show a significant share of SE, ii)
KLJKHU
tax
rates can be associated with PRUHSE, iii) due to its necessary tax-funding, the efficiency of the public sector
could be positively related to SE, iv) capitalistic (LH with a small public sector) countries should show the
minimum, although strictly positive, SE optimal ratio. The first two items are in contrast to what claimed by
the institutional literature. In particular, the second implies that some situations may cause the AS tradition
switching over the new approach. The third suggests the presence of non linear relationships between the
variables involved. The latter logically follows from the others. Available data for OECD countries over
fifteen years are somewhat coherent with our intuitions.
The paper is organized as follows. Sections II and III describe, respectively, the theoretical model and the
data. Sections IV to VI explain and perform empirical tools and analyses. Concluding remarks and an
appendix close the paper.
,
A SIMPLE THEORETICAL MODEL
The present model sketches out authority’s and taxpayers’ behavior, focusing on the relationship between
SE, rule of law, labor market regulations and taxation. This model is different in several aspects and
encompasses the existing ones in allowing multiple2, actually infinite, equilibria that include the dichotomic
2
Other differences between this model and its predecessors will be mentioned throughout the paper.
5
situation described by Johnson
HW DO
. (1997) and by Friedman
HW DO
. (2000). Before proceeding, some word
about corruption is necessary. If corruption is above a certain threshold, it becomes a special cause of
underground economy, in the sense of eclipsing the weight of any other parameter of the taxpayers’
maximand. In other words, once pushed underground because of the widespread corruption, agents do not
worry about taxation or regulations paying, and feeling, bribes as a ‘catch-all tax’. Empirical results by
Johnson
HWDO
. (1997) support this view. Only a relatively high expected penalty could dampen the decision
to go underground, but corruption undermines the legal system both directly and indirectly via lower
government resources3. Also, as argued by Wei, corruption tax more than taxes because (Wei, 1997, p. 4):
“corruption, unlike tax, is not transparent, not preannounced, and carries a much poorer enforcement of an
agreement between a briber and a bribed. In other words, corruption embeds arbitrariness and creates
uncertainty”. Finally, corruption and intrusive regulations go hand in hand (De Soto, 1989; Djankov HW DO,
2002) because, on the one side, pervasive regulations create room for bribing while, on the other side, a
highly corrupt bureaucracy can generate intrusive and discretionary regulations as a means of realizing
economic rents. Against this backdrop, the following analysis especially deals with relatively uncorrupt
systems, where the effect of other determinants of subterranean activities could play some role. As for the
main causes of the SE we maintain what suggested by the literature. In other words, we model the
relationships between SE, taxation (t= tax rate, T= revenues), rule of law (r) and regulations (e) in relatively
uncorrupt countries. We address it with a threefold analysis – i) how individuals affect and are affected by
the variables; ii) how the variables affect each other; iii) how governments affect and are affected by the
variables.
In our model, like in the Allingham-Sandmo framework, once decided to operate taxpayers must decide the
amount of income to under-report4. This option depends on the relative expected costs (&) and revenues
(5). The former is a positive function of the penalty times the probability to be caught (U), and of the share
of hidden income \). The assumption that all taxpayers operate regularly with some share of hidden income
has the consequence that all taxpayers have access to publicly provided goods/ services5. This situation is
common in developed countries and explains why publicly provided goods are not in the cost function. On
the other hand, some public good is not excludible; while some other is means-tested and should rather be
in the revenues function. Finally, the presence of a share of completely underground taxpayers does not
affect model’s predictions. In the present model there is only one type of government outlay that can
modify the optimal portion of hidden activity chosen by taxpayers (\ ) - by financing the rule of law,
governments may increase the expected penalty and,
FHWHULV SDULEXV
, may shrink
\
. Actually, some types of
3
Empirical studies report a positive correlation between the number of public officials involved in corruption and the
level of the public wages (Tanzi, 1998). It can be read as a switch between tax receipts and bribes.
4 The hypothesis that tax rates are associated more with the tax evasion than with the labor supply is developed in the
so called New Tax Responsiveness approach (Goolsbee, 1999).
5 This is different from existing models. In Johnson HW DO. (1997), the option faced by taxpayers is to be either totally
regular, or totally irregular. In Friedman HWDO (2000), firms can conceal a portion of their production diverting some of
it in a lower productivity (underground) market. Some government resources, spent to enhance firms’ productivity in
regular markets, are in the entrepreneurs’ maximand.
6
regulations6 could reduce \, but, unlike U, we assume that they can be implemented for free. The costs of
producing underground are supposed to be quadratic in \, increasing at increasing rates. This is so because,
given U, diverting a growing amount of income could be easier and easier to be detected. Moreover, as
argued by Cross and Shaw (1982), expenditures to learn about evasion activities are more and more costly
for the taxpayer. So,
\
is not only easier and easier to be detected, but it is harder and harder to be
concealed. The revenues depend on the tax rate (W), on excessive regulations (H), and on the share of SE.
The tax rate measures the gain of hiding one unit of income so the total revenue from tax evasion is W*\. As
for H, the logic is that respecting regulations is costly and only declared income must conform to regulations.
Otherwise stated, in the present setting H is just another sort of (linear) tax rate in disguise. The payoffs of
being underground are assumed linearly increasing in the share of undeclared income, and the cost curve
should cut the revenues line from below. More formally (using a widespread notation),
C= C(U, \) with C(0)=0; CU>0; C\> 0; C\\>0
R= R(WH \) with R(0)= 0; RW>0; R\>0; RH>0
F.O.C.\
C= R.
)LJXUH
: Taxpayers’ equilibrium
C, R
C = C(r, yi)
R = R(t, e, yi)
y*
yi
Note: Share of undeclared income (y*) according to the exogenous arguments of
the Costs (r=rule of law), and of the Revenues (e=regulations, t= tax rate) functions.
We assume that taxpayers take (HUW) as given. That is, they choose the optimal share of SE just to equate
their relative marginal costs and revenues, but not in order to modify (HUW). Alike, taxpayers are supposed
to be indifferent in paying the same amount of different combinations of taxes, expected penalties and
license fees. Following an (exogenous) increase in the level of the tax rate, the revenue function becomes
steeper and meets the cost function for a higher \ .
6
Some kind of regulation (HJ, on the healthy and on the safety of the workers), can improve labour productivity. As
in Friedman HW DO (2000), in this model over-regulation does not generate public resources. However, unlike them, in
this model over-regulation does not coincide with corruption. This is so because in our case over-regulation may be
due to too big, but uncorrupt, bureaucracies.
7
Private sector’s decisions are not the end of the story because of the complex links between all the involved
variables. The following Figure 2 aims at helping the discussion, showing model-consistent (possible)
combinations of the variables. It is important to note that it is a simultaneous qualitative (LH no metric)
static representation of our conjectures.
: Potential Equilibria in the Shadow Economy
)LJXUH
e
(1)
yi*
(4)
T*
r/e
r
A
B
t*, r/e
C
r
T*
(2)
t*
(3)
Legend: r=rule of law, e= regulations, t*= Laffer-optimal tax rate, T*= Lafferoptimal government receipts, y*= equilibrium share of undeclared income.
In Figure 2 we highlight three kinds of equilibria7 (A, B, C) according to different but equally self-consistent
values of the variables. While the position “A” may be thought of as being close to the bad equilibrium8
mentioned in the two-equilibria literature, situations such as B and C can not be addressed within that
framework. In fact, working with a linear “y;T” relationship, it argues that y=0 (T= max) and T=0 (y= 1) are
the only two conceivable stable equilibria – a marginal move from an intermediate equilibrium will
definitively attract the system in the bad or in the good equilibrium. We think that this view is too extreme
and that other stable positions can be rationalized, when focusing on developed countries. To this end, we
point out the presence of some peculiarities in the proposed relationships. As for the ‘H7 · function (see
Figure 2 – upper-left panel), we suppose the presence of a threshold level inverting the negative slope. The
intuition behind is that above a certain value, government activity becomes so intrusive (from the ‘cradle to
7
We use a star (*) to indicate optimal values of the variables. T and t are ‘Laffer optimal’ (see the explanation in the
main text).
8 A-equilibria must be seen as the situations with the highest share of SE. That is, in panel 4 of figure 2, there are not
triplets (HUW) such that a C-equilibrium is above an A-equilibrium.
8
the grave’) that, despite its efficiency (see Figure 2 - lower-left panel), the
%XUHDX
just can not avoid over-
regulating. For instance, public goods and services might be offered at prices lower than the market ones,
leading to an excess of demand that needs to be regulated. In addition, the government’s size (in terms of
T) may trigger over-regulations simply to justify its own presence. We then point out the presence of a
threshold value for U (U) and a positive connection between the institutional setting (UH), the government
revenues (7) and the tax rate (W). As for the former, in line with the bad-equilibrium story, we argue that at
or below (U) the government is just too much inefficient for collecting revenues by taxation9. As for the
latter, an explanation can be offered via an analysis DOj Laffer. Let10 7 W(\), and W = tax rate maximizing 7
(7PD[ ≡ 7 ). Basically, for any given level of UH, W
W
(and, accordingly, 7
7
of \ is one in absolute value. For W< W , a one percent increase in W improves
) when the tax rate elasticity
7
because \ increases by less
than one percent. The opposite applies when W> W . We can see the ‘UH; W*’ function as the higher envelope
of the optimal points of the different Laffer curves created by growing values of the ratio
UH
. The idea
behind is that poor institutions reach the (W ; 7 ) optimal point at very low levels of these variables, and
their Laffer curve is very low. For UH
0, W
0 and 7
panel). If a country could afford to have a higher
UH
like in the U ≤ U case (see Figure 2 – lower-left
it can, for any given W , collect higher
of the lower \. But the new equilibrium will probably have higher
threshold value for
7
, greater
7
are associated with
UH
UH
7
just because
, 7 and W . This is because above the
ratios which increase lesser and lesser until stop
growing11. In turn, it means that somewhere the growth of 7 must be related to greater tax rates12.
The closing model question is to understand how governments establish the rules-of-the-game, that is the
values of (HUW). In other words, why governments should choose to stay in (or close to) an ‘A-equilibrium’
and not, for instance, in (or close to) a ‘B-equilibrium’? We do not explicitly set up authorities’ behavior,
assuming that the values of taxpayers’ parameters are determined by the government depending on
historical, cultural, ethnical, geographical, political factors (Diamond, 1997; La Porta HW DO., 1999; Torsten
HW
DO
., 2001; Guiso HWDO., 2003) here not modeled. Otherwise stated, while bureaucracies actively try to modify
the triplet (H U W), they do that amid slow-motion exogenous constraints. Even if these factors are outside
the model, and quite because of this ‘degree-of-freedom’, we are strongly tempted to speculate about them.
A country which, because of its history, culture, etc., has very fragile and unfair institutions may opt (or
simply can not avoid) to impose more bribes than taxes using a widespread network of regulations (Aequilibrium). A consolidated social democracy is likely to put more weight to the public revenuesmaximization target, setting some combinations of taxpayers’ parameters such that it stays near the C9 Panels (1) and (2) are drawn such a way that above-threshold values of 7 are associated with values of H and U such
that UH keeps increasing, although at a lower rate (see Figure 2 - panel 3). One may think to a decreasing marginal
‘productivity’ of U in terms of T* and, as mentioned, to an ever growing over-regulation activity stemming from a
bigger and bigger bureaucracy. For very high values of 7 , UH becomes constant and then, possibly, decreasing.
10 (1-y) is the share of regular product (y ) under the hypothesis that, once decided to operate, taxpayers just choose
r
how much income to hide: y+ yr =1. Note that W does not impact on the level of total GDP, but only on y and yr.
11 Actually, panel 4 of Figure 2 should have a third axis in order to show the area in which the behaviour of UH and W
diverges.
12 See Friedman HWDO (2000) for a different way to reach a similar conclusion.
9
equilibrium. A similar reasoning will lead a ‘pure capitalistic’ country to implement
ODLVVH]IDLUH
policies to
reduce as much as possible the presence of the state in the economic system. Even this PLQLPXP state needs
a strictly positive amount of public revenues, which leads to a non-zero SE optimum ratio (see fig. 1). On
the other hand, despite their very different fiscal environments, tax revolts are much more likely in a
capitalistic country (HJ in 1978 in the US) than in a Scandinavian social democracy. In sum, it is easy to
imagine this country in a B-type equilibrium13. Each point of the kinked curve drawn in Figure 2 – upperright panel - is a potential equilibrium because it is made by feasible/ optimal combinations of the taxpayers’
parameters (see also Fig. 1). Given the different ‘speed of behavior’ featuring bureaucracies and agents (with
the latter much more flexible) a country may be, for instance, in a ‘transition point’ between A and B or
between B and C, etc. What is important here is that government’s options and taxpayers’ reactions reduce
the number of possible combinations of the variables leaving, anyway, the room for several equilibria.
Our model raises important testable implications, when the experiments deal with relatively uncorrupt
economic systems – i) even honest bureaucracies may chronically suffer from a significant share of SE, ii)
KLJKHU
tax rates can be associated with
PRUH
SE, iii) the efficiency of the public sector could be positively
related to SE, iv) capitalistic (LH with a small public sector) countries should show
PLQLPD
, albeit strictly
positive, SE ratios. The first two items are in contrast to the institutional literature. In particular, the second
implies that some situations may cause the AS tradition switching over the new approach. The third
suggests the presence of non linear relationships between the variables involved. The latter logically follows
from the others.
,,
THE DATA SET
The collected data set consists of almost three-yearly (1990, 1993, 1995, 1998, 2000, 2003) panel of twentyone OECD countries. We limit the data set to twenty-one OECD countries owing to data limitations for
Turkey, for recent OECD members (transition countries, Korea, Mexico) and for smaller countries
(Luxembourg, Iceland). While the choice to focus on OECD countries reduces the degrees of freedom, it
also should reduce the heterogeneity of the countries under observation (see section 6), on the one hand,
and it should increase the reliability of the data set, on the other hand. Finally and most importantly, it is
more likely that other causes of the SE can emerge if countries are relatively uncorrupt, as the most
developed ones should be (Mauro, 1995).
The panel data includes nine variables: the Shadow Economy as percentage of declared GDP (SE); GDP
per capita at constant 1990 prices in US Dollars (GDP cap); an index of the Rule of Law (RoL); an index of
Labor market Regulation (Reg); an index of corruption (CPI); the total tax revenues as percentage of
declared GDP (T1); the taxes on personal income as percentage of declared GDP (T2); the Income tax, in
Djankov HW DO. (2002) show empirically that countries with more democratic and more limited governments have
lighter regulations.
13
10
percentage of gross wage, for single persons without children (T3); the employee contributions, in
percentage of gross wage, for single persons without children (T4).
While we relegate further details on data sources and transformations in appendix 1, it is worth noticing
that, unlike mainstream literature, we compute the SE ratio as percentage of declared GDP. The logic to
refer to ‘corrected’ tax rates runs as follows. National account data are, in OECD countries, ‘exhaustive’
(OECD, 2002). This is so because incomes are relatively easy to hide, consumption is not. Otherwise stated,
GDP figures are comprehensive of the non-observed sectors via demand-side adjustments. Accordingly,
the ‘real’ fiscal pressure on regular agents must be computed only on their income. Clearly, to the extent a
part of the hidden activity remains outside the official GDP and/ or agents are not completely (dis)honest,
this procedure generates an overestimation of fiscal pressure. But, it is worth repeating, this error is likely to
be lower than that resulting from not-corrected data. In the following table 1 we have organized the
collected dataset according to some of the suggestions emerged in section 2.
7DEOH
B
B
B
B
B
B
B
C
C
C
C
&RXQWULHV
6(
Switzerland
USA
Japan
Austria
New Zealand
Netherlands
UK
France
Australia
Ireland
Canada
7.8
8.9
10.1
10.5
10.9
12.4
12.9
12.9
13.2
13.7
14.6
A
A
A
*'3
FDS
35115.2
25488.7
26475.1
23931.4
14335.5
22245.6
19687.5
22650.4
21282.0
19662.4
22863.6
$YHUDJH%
Denmark
Germany
Norway
Sweden
Finland
14.8
15.9
15.9
16.9
17.0
29033.9
23061.8
33214.5
30354.8
28948.5
$YHUDJH&
A
: Averages over years 1990-2003. OECD Countries.
Portugal
Belgium
Spain
Greece
Italy
$YHUDJH$
8QZHLJKWHG2(&'
&3,
8.80
7.67
6.42
7.51
9.33
8.56
8.56
7.42
8.57
7.40
8.98
9.47
7.82
8.85
9.14
8.93
5RO
5HJ
7
7
7
7
8.9
8.7
8.0
8.9
8.9
9.1
8.8
7.8
8.9
8.6
8.9
6.4
7.2
5.9
5.6
7.7
6.3
7.1
5.8
6.6
6.5
6.8
31.9
29.1
29.1
40.5
36.3
38.7
34.3
43.9
30.4
31.8
37.1
10.7
10.9
6.2
9.4
14.5
9.1
10.4
6.7
12.5
9.8
13.7
10.2
17.9
7.2
9.6
21.4
8.4
16.9
12.0
24.4
19.2
20.6
28.2
7.8
0.2
17.8
9.4
6.2
0.0
6.5
0.0
15.5
5.5
9.1
8.9
8.9
8.8
9.1
5.5
14.0
6.9
4.5
10.6
12.7
15.3
8.8
2.8
8.1
8193.1
21926.8
15270.3
9086.1
21093.5
35.7
45.0
33.1
35.6
41.5
36.8
20.3
21.9
27.7
27.3
5.3
5.8
5.7
4.7
4.8
25.5
9.2
11.1
18.8
14.7
7.7
8.0
7.3
6.3
7.0
47.0
37.5
41.3
48.0
46.5
18.1
19.2
20.5
24.7
24.9
6.67
6.70
5.57
5.27
4.57
6.4
5.4
6.0
5.9
6.2
6.5
27.0
12.2
2.1
18.2
6.1
13.5
13.2
19.9
12.3
Note: the first column (tentatively) indicates the type of equilibrium (see section 2). SE= Shadow Economy as
percentage of declared GDP; GDP cap= real GDP per capita; CPI=index of corruption; RoL= index of the Rule of
Law; Reg= index of Labor market Regulation; for CPI, RoL and Reg indexes vary from 1 to 10 (10= “better”);
T1= total tax revenues as percentage of declared GDP; T2= taxes on personal income as percentage of declared
GDP; T3= Income tax as percentage of gross wage, for single persons without children; T4= employee
contributions, as percentage of gross wage, for single persons without children.
11
,,,
A PRELIMINARY CLUSTER ANALYSIS
Notwithstanding the obvious
FDYHDWV
surrounding the statistics referring to the SE and to variables such as
Rule of Law, Regulation, etc., even from the simple observation of the data a number of stylized facts come
out. They seems to be noteworthy and in line with the model’s predictions.
)LJXUH
: A, B, C - equilibria in OECD countries
9,3
Finland
Denmark
Netherlands
&HTXLOLEULD
Germany
NewCanada
Zeland^
Austria
Norway
Sweden
Switzerland
Australia
UK
USA
Ireland
0LGGOH6(
%HTXLOLEULD
/RZ6(
5XOHRIODZ
8,2
Belgium
Japan
France
Portugal
7,1
Spain
$HTXLOLEULD
+LJK6(
Italy
Greece
6,0
28%
36%
7D[EXUGHQ
44%
Note: The values of Rule of Law (Rol) and Tax Burden (T1) are drawn from table 1.
12
: The relative position of high shadow economy (SE) in OECD countries
)LJXUH
8,1
9,3
DenmarkFinland
Netherlands
SwitzerlandAustria
Germany
New Zeland^
Canada
Norway
Australia
Sweden
UK
USA
Ireland
✺ 8,2
USA
✚ 6,9
✦ ✥✧
✤✓
✣✖
✢✙
Belgium
Japan
✵✹
✸✷
New Zeland^
France
+LJK
Portugal
✵✶
6(
✳✴
Spain
7,1
Canada
Australia
Ireland
Denmark
Netherlands
Finland
Switzerland
Japan
5,7
Italy
UK
Austria
France
Norway
Sweden
Belgium
Spain
GermanyPortugal
6(
Greece
4,5
6,0
14% ★✂✩✍✪✝✫☎✬ ✭✡✮☞✯ ✬✂✰✍✬✂✱✜✲
7%
21%
14% ✂✁✍✄✝✆☎✞ ✟✡✠✛☛ ✞✂✌✍✞✂✎✜✏
7%
28%
Sweden
Denmark
Finland
44%
44%
Italy
❇✶
Norway
Austria
Netherlands
Germany
Canada
New Zeland^
UK
+LJK
36%
Greece
Portugal
6(
Spain
✘✙
✗
✕✖
7,3
✻✛✼✾✽ ✿ ✬✂❀☎❁❂✪ ✭
8,5
28%
✒✓
Italy
Norway
Austria
+LJK
Netherlands
Germany
6(
Canada
New Zeland^
Portugal
UK
Spain
Switzerland
Ireland
Australia
USAJapan
✔
36%
28%
6,0
21%
Belgium
France
✚
Ireland Switzerland
Australia
USA
Japan
28%
Italy
Greece
Sweden
DenmarkFinland
Belgium
France
❈
❆
❅✴
❄
❃✹
+LJK
14% ✂✁☎✄✝✆☎✞ ✟✡✠☞☛ ✞✂✌✍✞✂✎✑✏
7%
21%
Greece
28%
Data tell that SE ratios are large in Italy, Greece, Spain, Belgium, and Portugal. It holds both for different
estimates of the SE and over the period 1990-2003. It is hard to think about an exclusively tax-induced SE
in these countries because, as Figure 4 clearly shows (lower-right panel), they share a significantly lower tax
burden than that imposed in Scandinavian economic systems. Much more suspicious-looking seems to be
the weakness of the legal system and the intrusive labor market regulations (upper-side panels). The view
that institutional failures can be more important than taxes in promoting the shadow economy is already
present in the literature (Johnson
HW DO
. 1998, 1999; Friedman
HW DO
. 2000; and, for an intra-country analysis,
Bovi and Castellucci, 2001). Following what suggested by Friedman
HW DO
(2000) it can be said that only
governments with a relatively good level of rule of law and economic freedom can sustain high tax rates14.
Recalling model’s prescriptions and noticing that the tax rate correction exacerbates fiscal ratios, it is
important to observe that countries with the largest SE have not the highest tax burdens, but the worst
bureaucracies. The English speaking countries (United States, United Kingdom, Ireland, Australia, New
Zealand and Canada) are featured by the lowest values of both SE, taxation and regulation burden in the
sample. Thus, one can be tempted to say that these countries share B-equilibria (see also figure 3).
Data for the remaining OECD countries show other possible combinations of the indicators suggesting
that, summing up: i) the theoretical framework set up in section 2 seems to be congruent with the data set;
14
In passing, it is noteworthy that in the Southern part of Italy the tax wedge is smaller and the shadow economy is
larger than in the rest of the country (Bovi and Castellucci, 2001).
13
ii) the nature of the SE changes across the most developed countries; iii) even among the most developed
countries, none of them can avoid to live together with some strictly positive share of underground
economy.
,9
The
THE PANEL DATA MODEL
SULPD IDFLH
evidence of an association between the SE and its hypothesized causes suggests going on
with a more rigorous econometric analysis. Panel analysis provides a powerful method to test empirically
the theoretical hypotheses. It allows considering both the space and time dimension of the data. Alternative
types of panel model specification can be suitable for our analysis. In contexts like this one, the usual
question is the individual specific effects should be assumed to be fixed (Fixed effects model) or random
(Random effects model). According to Baltagi (1995), the fixed effects model is the appropriate
specification if the analysis is focusing on a specific set of N units and the inference is restricted to the
behavior of this set of units. The Random effects model, on the other hand, is an appropriate specification
if we are drawing N individuals randomly from a large population and want to draw inferences about the
entire population. In light of these arguments, a fixed effects model is the proper specification in our case.
In the subset of Fixed effects models can have constant slopes but intercepts that differ according to the
cross-sectional unit (country). In other words, there are significant differences among countries but no
significant temporal effects. A more general fixed effects panel model allows the intercept to vary across
country and over time. In equation 1, we formally describe a regression model with n-1 country dummies
and t-1 time dummies:
❉
\❋ ●
❊
−1
= ∑ α ❋ '& ❍ ❋ + ∑ δ ● '7❍ ● + [ ′❋ ● β + ε ❋ ●
❍
=1
❍
(1)
=1
with: L = 1, 2,..., 21 ; W = ’90,’93,’95,’98,’00,’03 ;
'& ❏ ■
1
=
0
if L =
M
RWKHUZLVH
and
'7❑▼▲
1
=
0
if M = W
RWKHUZLVH
An important assumption in these models is the independence of the explanatory variables and the random
error components. In this case the regressors are said to be ‘exogenous’ and are assumed to be determined
outside the model. Failure of this assumption may lead to biased or inconsistent estimates. A usual
technique for dealing with variables that are correlated with the error term (endogeneity) is to instrument
them. Valid instruments must i) be uncorrelated with the error term and ii) explain part of the variability in
the endogenous regressors. In our setting these requirements are quite demanding. A potentially useful, and
sometimes used, data set is that developed by La Porta
HW DO
(1999). However, they suggest instruments
such as type of religion, latitude, type of colonization, etc., whose variation in time does not allow
constructing proper endogeneity tests. While this prevents addressing causality issues, the proposed
14
experiments can offer some support to model’s predictions. Moreover, it is worth noticing that the
institutional indexes (CPI, Reg and RoL), are to some extent predetermined by construction (see Appendix
1), shrinking the simultaneity problem. As for the other variable, the tax burden, we try to get robust results
taking advantage of three different measures. Then, unlike other works, we perform F-tests to select the
best model as for the presence of time and/ or space differences in our panel. All in all, it means that the
empirical efforts we propose can realistically offer only some indicative correlations, which, however, is
enough for consolidating our theoretical suggestions.
In our empirical models, all variables are taken in logarithmic transformation.
percentage of declared GDP] and
[
P
◗
\
◆
❖
= [Shadow Economy as
= [GDP per capita; Index of corruption; Index of the Rule of Law;
Index of labor market Regulation; Total tax revenues as percentage of declared GDP; taxes on personal
income as percentage of declared GDP; Income tax, in percentage of gross wage, for single persons
without children; Employee contributions, in percentage of gross wage, for single persons without
children].
9
THE ECONOMETRIC EVIDENCE
In this section, we empirically test some of the predictions of the theoretical framework set up in section II.
First of all we have to verify if the selected OECD countries are relatively uncorrupt, that is if their SE
shares are orthogonal to the corruption index. Table 2 lists the main results of the “corruption” experiment.
15
7DEOH
: Correlations between Shadow Economy and its causes in OECD countries.
'HSHQGHQW9DULDEOHVKDUHRI6KDGRZHFRQRP\RQGHFODUHG*'3
02'(/6
5HJUHVVRUV
GDP per capita
Corruption
Rule of Law
Regulation
T1
T2
T3
T4
,
,,
,,,
-0.08
-0.03
1.19**
-0.28
0.51**
0.15
0.09
1.48***
-0.38
0.19
0.18
1.54**
-0.35
0.43***
$GMXVWHG5
❘
2EVHUY
0.726
126
0.734
125
0.11*
-0.10
0.700
106
)WHVWVIRU3RROLQJ
,
,,
,,,
Fully pooled model Vs
Fixed country effect
Fully pooled model Vs
Fixed time effect
Fixed country effect Vs
Fix. country & time eff.
Fixed time effect Vs
Fix. country & time eff.
Fully pooled Vs
Fix. country & time eff.
F-stat= 5.00***
d.f. (20,100)
F-stat= 7.93***
d.f. (5,115)
F-stat= 3.71***
d.f. (20,95)
F-stat= 3.73***
d.f.(5,95)
F-stat= 5.30***
d.f.(25,95)
F-stat=6.87***
d.f. (20,99)
F-stat=14.46***
d.f. (5,114)
F-stat=3.62***
d.f. (20,94)
F-stat=3.97***
d.f.(5,94)
F-stat=7.11***
d.f.(25,94)
F-stat=5.54***
d.f. (18,81)
F-stat=10.31***
d.f. (5,94)
F-stat=3.19***
d.f. (18,76)
F-stat=3.30***
d.f.(5,76)
F-stat=5.67***
d.f.(23,76)
***Denotes significant at 1% level; ** Denotes significant at 5% level; * Denotes
significant at 10% level. All variables are log-levels. There are three country and time
effects models (I, II, III) according to the three different tax burdens (T1; T2; T3 and
T4). Dummies not reported. Other details under table 1.
All reported regressions are modeled including, thus controlling for, fixed countries and time effects (see
equation 1). This is so because this kind of model is the “final winner” of a battery of pooling tests,
comparing all the possible pairs of alternative models. We omit to report the dummies for the sake of
brevity and replicate the econometric procedure for three models (called I, II, III, in the following tables)
according to the three alternative kinds of tax burdens. The goodness-of-fit statistic is quite comforting and
a general evaluation of the estimated equations shows that all the estimated correlations are robust to
variations in the covariates. Moreover, trials without GDP per capita as control variable give similar
outcomes15. So, we are somewhat reassured that we are studying uncorrupt “above threshold” economies.
However, and this is our point, relatively uncorrupt does not means to be totally regular and, according to
our model, these systems may well show associations with other SE-triggering variables. This is confirmed
by table 2. In particular, unlike what emphasized by the institutional literature, all the experiments point out
that tax burdens are
SRVLWLYHO\
correlated with the SE. Also, the elasticity with respect to the rule of law is
positive, suggesting that the uncorrupt OECD countries are, on average, on the increasing “developed-
15
They are available upon request.
16
economy” part of Figure 2 (LH the less-elaborated part of the two-equilibria theory). Although with the
expected sign, the index of labor market regulation is statistically not different from zero over the three
model specifications.
The second group of econometric exercises we present (table 3) aims at comparing estimates obtained by
considering, separately, countries characterized by the highest (A and C countries) and the lowest (B
countries) level of SE in the sample16. The logic behind is that, due to the high tax burden of C-countries
and to the bad institutional setting of A-countries, one should expect a greater sensitivity of SE to its causes
in the former cluster.
7DEOH
Shadow Economy and its causes in OECD countries. Sub-sample space analysis
'HSHQGHQW9DULDEOHVKDUHRI6KDGRZHFRQRP\RQGHFODUHG*'3
02'(/6
5HJUHVVRUV
+6(
,
GDP per capita
Rule of Law
Regulation
T1
T2
T3
T4
$GMXVWHG5
❘
2EVHUY
-0.72
1.49**
0.21
1.13**
+6(
,,
-0.22
2.07***
-0.35
+6(
,,,
-0.39
1.74*
0.17
/6(
,
-0.06
-0.40
-0.40
0.39*
1.77***
0.574
60
0.639
59
/6(
,,
0.10
0.43
-0.40
/6(
,,,
0.35
1.43
-0.40
0.24
0.22
-0.14
0.403
53
0.611
66
0.609
66
0.29
-0.09
0.590
53
Results are obtained by considering two separate panels: H-SE are OECD countries with the highest
level of SE as % of declared GDP (Italy, Greece, Spain, Belgium, Portugal, Finland, Sweden, Norway,
Germany, Denmark); L-SE are OECD countries with the lowest level of SE as % of declared GDP
(Switzerland, USA, Japan, Austria, New Zealand, Netherlands, United Kingdom, France, Australia,
Ireland, Canada). F-tests suggest country and time effects for all the three models (dummies and Ftests not reported). Other details under tables 1 and 2.
The estimates collected in table 3 indicate that the fit of the regressions for sub-panels are broadly similar
for five out of six models (but H-SE, III). In terms of figure 2, L-SE countries are close to the Bequilibrium. That is, they cluster around the “corners” of the panels, which may explain why they show
(almost) no significant correlations. While not significant, it is worth noticing that the GDP per capita
coefficients are greater in the H-SE experiments than in the L-SE ones. This is somewhat expected due to
the lower homogeneity of the A+ C group as compared to the B team. Furthermore, confirming our DSULRUL,
both the tax burden and the rule of law coefficients are large, positive and significant for high-SE countries.
Otherwise stated, even among uncorrupt (good-equilibrium?) countries, data reveal different elasticities17 of
16
Referring only to A- or C-countries would dramatrically reduce the degrees of freedom and, in turn, the reliability of
the estimates.
17 An empirical confirmation of this statement is provided by Scandinavian countries where, tax rate, size of public
sector, are higher than Mediterranean countries (e.g. Italy, Greece, Spain) but their levels of (estimated) SE are lower
(Dell’Anno and Schneider, 2003). Alike, due to its worse local institutional setting, in the Southern part of Italy the tax
17
tax and institutional variables with respect to the SE. Finally, results show the increase (decrease) in the
magnitude of the taxation and RoL coefficients for High (Low) SE countries with respect to the pooled
case (see table 2). All in all, these robust18 findings are coherent with the model’s prescriptions.
9,
CONCLUDING REMARKS
In this paper some considerations about the underground wealth of “uncorrupt” nations have been
organized in a graphical analysis, with some attempt to test them. The proposed theoretical model suggests
that the SE generates critical thresholds that produce many different equilibrium states. Each of these states
has a different optimal level of the SE ratio, which may be of any size, but zero. Thus, the model enriches
the suggestions of previous works (Johnson
HW DO
., 1997; Friedman
HW DO
, 2000; Schneider, 2003), which
argued for the existence of just two extreme stable equilibria, one bad and one good, according to the level
of the SE. We argued that if corruption is not paramount, countries move away from the bad (high SE)
equilibrium but, unlike what suggested by the existing works, they may end up with different “good”
equilibria. The kind of good equilibrium achieved depends on government choices which, in turn, depend
on historical, cultural, etc. exogenous factors. Also, the fiscal and institutional environment where private
agents operate is not explicitly designed to have a zero-SE ratio. Otherwise stated, the disparate attitude of
policymakers towards taxation, efficiency/ pervasiveness of the bureaucracy, etc., leads the private sector to
hide a peculiar share of income. This optimal choice, in turn, impacts on the public side of the economic
system. As a consequence, both the level and the nature of the equilibrium SE ratios may be different in
relatively uncorrupt countries.
The empirical analysis of the underground economy must be led and valued, by definition, very carefully.
The lack of valid instruments hampers intriguing normative discussions. For instance, as emphasized by the
proposed theoretical model, the underground economy can reduce government resources and this can lead
to a more inefficient bureaucracy. Thus, it is far from clear that the correlation is causal. While this means
that the empirical results are not suitable for normative implications, the proposed exercises can realistically
offer some indicative correlations. On the positive side, what pointed out in this paper contributes to the
ongoing debate, corroborating previous empirical results and offering new insights. Then, we have
controlled for the presence of significant differences across countries and over time. This is hardly found in
literature. Last, but not least, the empirical analysis of relatively uncorrupt economic systems (which should
share the most reliable/ comparable data) is congruent with the theoretical setting – i) even honest
bureaucracies may chronically show a significant share of SE, ii) KLJKHU tax rates can be associated with PRUH
SE, iii) due to its necessary tax-funding, the efficiency of the public sector could be positively related to SE,
wedge is smaller and the shadow economy is larger than in the rest of the country (Bovi and Castellucci, 2001).
18 Similar results, available on request, are obtained without controlling for per capita GDP or adding the index of
corruption (statistically not significant in each and every experiment).
18
iv) capitalistic (LH with a small public sector) countries should show the minimum, although strictly positive,
SE optimal ratio.
19
$SSHQGL['DWD6RXUFHV
The sources of the data are: Schneider (2005a, 2005b) for SE; United Nation Statistical on-line
database for ‘GDP per capita at constant 1990 prices in US Dollars’; the Transparency International on-line
database19 for Corruption; Gwartney and Lawson (2005) for ‘Rule of Law’ and ‘Labor market regulation’;
the OECD Revenue Statistics (2005) for T1 and T2; OECD Taxing Wages (2006) for T3 and T4. Further,
the data spans from 1990 to 2003,
LH
there are 48 observations for each country. However, due to the
logarithmic transformations of the data and to 13 missing values (T2Finland,1993; T3Australia,1990; T3Australia,1993;
T3France,1990; T4Australia,1990; T4Australia,1993; T4Australia,1995; T4Denmark,1990; T4Germany,1990; T4Italy,1990; T4Italy,1993;
T4Portugal,1990; T4Portugal,1993) the sample is reduced to 22 observations. Accordingly, the final unbalanced panel
used for estimating equations (1) consisted of a cross-section of 21 countries over 6 time periods.
Data on the Shadow Economy for OECD countries are available from different sources and different
methods20. Considering that it is difficult to evaluate the SE estimates, because full scope information for
these types of estimates is never available, any evaluation of reliability of SE estimates methodologies to
estimate SE is incomplete. Needless to say, no method has imposed itself as being clearly superior to the
others. Aware of these limitations, this work uses the estimates published by Schneider (2005a) for the years
1990, 1995, 2000 and Schneider (2005b) for the years 2002 and 2003. This article collects different sources
and different methods (Currency demand approach in combination with Dynamic Multiple Indicators
Multiple Causes approach). For a fuller treatment of these subjects we refer the reader to the cited paper
and Schneider and Enste (2000). According to the treatment of T1 and T2, even the SE is calculated as
percentage of declared GDP:
6(❲❨❳
,
❙❚❯❱
JGS❲❩❳
,
=
α ❲❨, ❳
, where: α ❬❩, ❭ are the Schneider’s estimates of SE as percentage of official GDP.
1 − α ❲❨, ❳
Data on ‘GDP per capita’ at constant 1990 prices in US Dollars are available form United Nation
Statistical on-line database.
The Corruption Perceptions Index (CPI) published by the Transparency International ranks several
countries according to the extent of corruption from 1995. CPI relates to perceptions of the degree of
corruption as seen by businesspeople, risk analysts and the general public and ranges between 10 (perfectly
clean) and 0 (highly corrupt). Corruption Perceptions Index is annually published from 1995. The missing
data in the years 1990 and 1993 are substituted respectively by the averages over the period ‘88-’92 and ’92’94.
Data on the ‘Rule of Law’ are available from the Fraser Institute, which elaborates an index running
from 0 to 10 (lower numbers mean worse legal environment). In particular, we use as proxy of RoL the
Area 2 of the Index of Economic Freedom, so called ‘/HJDO6WUXFWXUHDQG 6HFXULW\RI3URSHUW\5LJKWV· published
by Gwartney and Lawson (2005) (data retrieved from www.freetheworld.com). The missing data in the
19
KWWSZZZLFJJRUJFRUUXSWLRQLQGH[KWPO
20
This way to proceed is usual in literature. Widely cited works analyses the black economy aggregating several sources
of data (HJ. Friedman HWDO., 2000; Schneider and Enste, 2000).
20
years 1993 and 1998 are substituted respectively by the averages over the period ‘90-’95 and ’95-‘00. The
key ingredients accounted by this index are: rule of law, security of property rights, an independent
judiciary, and an impartial court system Gwartney and Lawson (2005, p. 7).
Data on ‘Labor market Regulation’ are also available from the Fraser Institute. This index running
from 0 to 10 (lower numbers mean worse regulation). This index considers several kinds of restrictions that
entry into labor market and interferes with the freedom to engage in voluntary exchange. The second (5B)
considers labor-market regulations infringe upon the economic freedom of employees and employers (HJ
minimum wages, dismissal regulations, centralized wage setting, extensions of union contracts to no
participating parties, unemployment benefits that undermine the incentive to accept employment, and
conscription (Gwartney and Lawson 2005, p. 8). The missing data in the years 1993 and 1998 are
substituted respectively by the averages over the period ‘90-’95 and ’95-‘00.
Data on total tax revenues and taxes on personal income are published by OECD (2005). T1 and T2
are derived by the original data according the following formula:
7
1❲❨, ❳
❙❚❯❱
JGS❲❩❳
=
,
β ❲❨, ❳
, where: β ❬❨, ❭ are the published data on OECD (2005) and α ❬❩, ❭ are the Schneider’s
1 − α ❲❨, ❳
estimates of SE.
The second set of tax burdens is extracted by Taxing Wages (OECD, 2006). The personal income
taxes, in percentage of gross wage, for single persons without children are extracted by table D.2. This
sample has missing data in the year 1990. We use for 1990 the averages over the period 1989-1991.
Finally, the employee contributions, in percentage of gross wage, for single persons without children
are calculated as difference between table D.3 and table D.2. There are missing data in the years 1990 and
1998. They are substituted respectively by the averages over the period ‘89-’91 and ’97-‘99.
. The measurement of the tax burden is subject to controversy: ‘DOO FXUUHQW PHDVXUHV UHYLHZHG KDYH DW OHDVW
VRPH LPSRUWDQW VKRUWFRPLQJV
’ (OECD, 2000, p. 3). Just to mention, which is the tax rate pushing people
underground? Is it the top or the average tax marginal rate? And what about tax reliefs, allowances, etc.? We
use OECD data because OECD periodically computes statistics on tax burdens that, at least, allow reliable
cross-country comparisons for several years. Some of these tax burdens are here used as alternative
measures to improve the robustness of the findings.
21
5HIHUHQFHV
Allingham, Michael, G. and Agnar Sandmo (1972). Income Tax Evasion: A Theoretical Analysis, -RXUQDORI
3XEOLF(FRQRPLFV
. 1: 323-338.
Baltagi, Badi H. (1995). (FRQRPHWULF$QDO\VLVRI3DQHO'DWD. Chichester: John Wiley and Sons.
Bovi, Maurizio (2005). The Dark, and Independent, Side of the Italian Labour Market. /DERXU19: 721-748.
Bovi, Maurizio and Laura Castellucci (2001). Cosa sappiamo dell’economia sommersa in Italia al di là dei
luoghi comuni? Alcune proposizioni empiricamente fondate. (FRQRPLD3XEEOLFD 6: 77-119.
Cross, Rodney and G.K. Shaw (1982). On the Economics of Tax Aversion. 3XEOLF)LQDQFH. 37: 36-47
Dell'Anno, Roberto and Frederich Schneider (2003). The Shadow Economy of Italy and other OECD
Countries: What do we know? -RXUQDORI3XEOLF)LQDQFHDQG3XEOLF&KRLFH31: 97-120.
De Soto, Hernando (1990). 7KH2WKHU3DWK New York, NY: Harper and Row.
Djankov, Simeon, Rafael, La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Schleifer (2002). The
Regulation of Entry, 4XDUWHUO\-RXUQDORI(FRQRPLFV. 117: 1-37.
Friedman, Eric, Simon, Johnson, Daniel Kaufmann, and Pablo Zoido-Lobaton (2000). Dodging the
Grabbing Hand: The Determinants of Unofficial Activity in 69 Countries, -RXUQDORI3XEOLF(FRQRPLFV.
76: 459-494.
Goolsbee, Austan (1999). Evidence on the High-Income Laffer Curve from Six Decades of Tax Reform,
%URRNLQJ3DSHUVRQ(FRQRPLF$FWLYLW\
2: 1-47.
Guiso, Luigi, Paola Sapienza and Luigi Zingales (2003). People’s Opium? Religion and Economic Attitudes,
-RXUQDORI0RQHWDU\(FRQRPLFV
50: 225-282.
Gwartney, James, D. and Robert, A., Lawson (2005).
(FRQRPLF )UHHGRP RI WKH :RUOG $QQXDO 5HSRUW
Vancouver B.C., The Fraser Institute.
Hsiao, Cheng (1986). $QDO\VLVRI3DQHO'DWD. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Johnson, Simon, Daniel Kaufmann, and Andrei Schleifer (1997). The Unofficial Economy in Transition,
%URRNLQJ3DSHUVRQ(FRQRPLF$FWLYLW\
2: 159-239.
Johnson, Simon, Daniel Kaufmann, and Pablo Zoido-Lobaton (1999). Corruption, Public Finances and the
Unofficial Economy, WRUOG%DQN:RUNLQJ3DSHU N. 2169.
Johnson, Simon, Daniel Kaufmann, and Pablo Zoido-Lobaton (1998). Regulatory Discretion and the
Unofficial Economy$PHULFDQ(FRQRPLF5HYLHZ. 88: 387-392.
La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny (1999). The Quality of
Government, -RXUQDORI/DZ(FRQRPLFVDQG2UJDQL]DWLRQ 15: 222-279.
Mauro, Paolo (1995). Corruption and Growth, 4XDUWHUO\-RXUQDORI(FRQRPLFV. 110: 681-712.
OECD (2006). 7D[LQJ:DJHV. Paris, OECD.
OECD (2005). 5HYHQXH6WDWLVWLFV Paris, OECD.
OECD (2002). 0HDVXULQJWKH1RQ2EVHUYHG(FRQRP\$+DQGERRN Paris, OECD.
OECD (2000). 7D[EXUGHQV$OWHUQDWLYHPHDVXUHV. Paris, OECD Tax Policy Studies.
22
Rosser, Barkley J. Jr., Ahmed, E. and M.V. Rosser (2003). Multiple unofficial economy equilibria and
income distribution dynamics in systemic transition. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 25 (3):
425-447.
Schneider, Friedrich (2005a). Shadow economies around the world: what do we really know?
(XURSHDQ
-RXUQDORI3ROLWLFDO(FRQRP\
. 21: 598-642.
Schneider, Friedrich (2005b). Shadow Economies of 145 Countries all over the World: What Do We Really
Know? &HQWHUIRU5HVHDUFKLQ(FRQRPLFV0DQDJHPHQWDQGWKH$UWV &5(0$ :RUNLQJ3DSHU 2005-13.
Schneider, Friedrich (2003). The development of the Shadow Economies and Shadow Labor Force of 22
Transition and 21 OECD Countries. ,=$GLVFXVVLRQSDSHU, n. 514.
Schneider, Friedrich, and Dominik H. Enste (2000). Shadow Economies: Size, Causes, and Consequences,
-RXUQDORI(FRQRPLF/LWHUDWXUH
38: 77-114.
Tanzi, Vito (1998). Corruption Around the World: Causes, Consequences, Scope, and Cure,
,QWHUQDWLRQDO
0RQHWDU\)XQG:RUNLQJ3DSHU
. 63: 1-39.
Torsten, Persson, Guido Tabellini, and Francesco Trebbi (2001). Electoral Rules and Corruption
:RUNLQJ3DSHU
&(6LIR
. 416: 1-41.
Transparency International (2000). &RUUXSWLRQ3HUFHSWLRQ,QGH[, Transparency International (data available for
download from http:/ / www.icgg.org/ corruption.index.html).
United Nation Statistical on-line database (2006). GDP per capita/ breakdown at constant 1990 prices in US
Dollars
(all
countries).
Data
available
for
download
from
http:/ / unstats.un.org/ unsd/ snaama/ dnllist.asp
Wei, Shang-Jin (1997). Why is Corruption So Much More Taxing Than Tax? Arbitrariness Kills, in 1DWLRQDO
%XUHDXRI(FRQRPLF5HVHDUFK:RUNLQJ3DSHU
, N. W6255.
23
View publication stats