State-building in Europe
The Revitalization of Western European Integration
Why and how was the process of Western European integration
relaunched in the 1980s and 1990s? This volume suggests a new
framework of analysis of the European state-building tradition. Based
on qualitative research (including more than thirty interviews with
protagonists) and detailed case studies and policy analyses (the genesis
of the Single Market programme and the Single European Act, Esprit
technology corporatism, biotechnology, EU regional and social
policy), the authors show that new forms of cooperation between
political and economic actors have developed, at both transnational
and supranational level. The book shows how the European Commission, bureaucratic cabinets, national diplomats, transnational
companies, pressure groups and representatives of the regions have set
in motion a process that is changing statehood in Europe dramatically.
This discussion of the origins of this process is a valuable contribution
to the debate on the future of Europe in the world system.
is Professor of Sociology at the University of
Zurich. He is the author of ®fteen books and numerous articles, most
recently Western Society in Transition (1996).
VO L K E R B O R N S C H I E R
State-building in Europe
The Revitalization of Western European Integration
Edited by Volker Bornschier
published by the press syndicate of the university of cambridge
The Pitt Building, Trumpington Street, Cambridge, United Kingdom
cambridge university press
The Edinburgh Building, Cambridge, cb2 2ru, UK www.cup.cam.ac.uk
40 West 20th Street, New York, ny 10011±4211, USA www.cup.org
10 Stamford Road, Oakleigh, Melbourne 3166, Australia
Ruiz de AlarcoÂn 13, 28014 Madrid, Spain
# Cambridge University Press 2000
This book is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception
and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements,
no reproduction of any part may take place without
the written permission of Cambridge University Press.
First published 2000
Printed in the United Kingdom at the University Press, Cambridge
Typeset in Plantin 10 /12pt [ c e ]
A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library
Library of Congress Cataloguing in Publication data
State-building in Europe: the revitalization of Western European integration /
edited by Volker Bornschier.
p.
cm.
Includes bibliographical references.
isbn 0 521 78103 5 (hb)
1. European federation. I. Bornschier, Volker.
JN15.S74 2000 341.242'2±dc21 99-085966
isbn 0 521 78103 5 hardback
isbn 0 521 78619 3 paperback
Contents
List of ®gures and tables
List of contributors
Preface
Acknowledgements
Part I: State-building and Political Entrepreneurship
1 Western Europe's move toward political union
Volker Bornschier
2 Tying up the Luxembourg package of 1985
Patrick Ziltener
Part II: The Core Elements in Recasting the European
Bargain
page vii
viii
xi
xv
1
3
38
73
3 The origins of the Single Market
Nicola Fielder
75
4 Esprit and technology corporatism
Simon Parker
93
5 EC regional policy: monetary lubricant for economic
integration?
Patrick Ziltener
6 EC social policy: the defeat of the Delorist project
Patrick Ziltener
122
152
Part III: Conclusions beyond the Single European Act of 1986 185
7 Lobbying for a Europe of big business: the European
Roundtable of Industrialists
Michael Nollert in collaboration with Nicola Fielder
187
v
vi
Contents
8 Biotechnology in the European Union: a case study of
political entrepreneurship
Michael Nollert
9 European integration after the Single Act: changing and
persisting patterns
Patrick Ziltener
210
244
10 The state of the European Union
Volker Bornschier
264
Appendix: List of interview partners
Bibliography
Index
285
287
308
Figures and tables
Figures
1.1 The genesis of the Single European Act
8.1 Dialogue committees of the Commission and interest
organizations
page 36
239
Tables
1.1 Shares in world outward stock of foreign direct investment,
selected countries, 1914, 1960, 1978 and 1992
1.2 World stock of foreign direct investment by headquarter
region, 1980 ±1995
1.3 The distribution of the world's 100 largest transnational
corporations according to home base and average global
assets, 1992
2.1 The formation and development of political initiatives at
European level and their expression in the Single European
Act, 1981±1985
3.1 Steps towards the Single Market as the core element of the
Single European Act
3.2 The role of industry: steps of the European Roundtable of
Industrialists towards the Single European Act and beyond
6.1 Intergovernmental conference 1985: initiatives in the social
policy area and their results in the Single European Act
6.2 Article 118 of the treaties establishing the European
Communities as modi®ed by the Single European Act
7.1 The centrality of Roundtable companies in 1994
7.2 Connectors between Roundtable companies, 1994
8.1 Expenditure on the biosciences in the EU, 1984±98
22
23
25
66
80
89
158
159
205
206
220
vii
Contributors
Volker Bornschier was born in Witten, Germany, in 1944. After
studying sociology, economics and psychology, he received his PhD in
sociology in 1972. He has been a professor in the Faculty of Philosophy
at the University of Zurich since 1981. He has published ®fteen books
and well over a hundred articles in leading social science journals and in
edited volumes. His latest monograph is Western Society in Transition
(New Brunswick and London, Transaction Publishers, 1996; with
German and Chinese editions in 1998). He co-edited and contributed
to the volume on The Future of Global Con¯ict (London, Sage, 1999). He
is actively engaged in many professional associations (the International
Sociological Association [ISA], the European Sociological Association
[ESA], the Swiss Sociological Association, and the International Studies
Association) and has organized parts of international or world conferences, for example, the panels on `The Future of Globalization' at
the 1998 ISA world conference in Montreal, and a series of sessions on
the theme of `Will Europe Work?' at the 1999 ESA conference in
Amsterdam. Since 1997 he has been director of the Sociological
Institute of the University of Zurich, and he is on the board of the World
Society Foundation, which sponsors social science research world-wide
(he served as president from 1983 to 1997). His areas of interest are
social change and its various dimensions and manifestations, international competitiveness, economic sociology and questions of political
economy and of world society.
Nicola Fielder was born in London in 1966 and moved to Switzerland
at the age of 10, where she completed her education. She gained a
Master's degree and a PhD in sociology from Zurich University. From
1992 to 1996 she collaborated on Bornschier's research team.
Throughout her university studies she also worked part time in the area
of employment and training and is at present directing a regional
employment centre for the City of Zurich.
viii
List of contributors
ix
Michael Nollert, born in Zurich in 1960, received his PhD from the
University of Zurich in 1991. He is senior member of Bornschier's team
at the Sociological Institute in Zurich. From 1993 to 1995 he was a
research fellow at the University of Trier (Germany). His research areas
are political sociology, social con¯icts (collective protest, crime), corporatism, European associations, and intercorporate relations. At the
moment he is working at the University of Zurich, directing research on
interlocking directorates in Switzerland and the Netherlands. He has
published numerous articles and a book.
Simon Parker earned his BA Honours in political science from
Concordia University in Montreal. He was awarded a Master's degree
in international relations at Sussex University, where he submitted a
thesis on the potential of a Gramscian theory of global hegemony
entitled `Theories of Hegemony: The Confusing and the Confusion of
American Hegemony'. He has worked for the Open University, the City
University and the University of Zurich in both teaching and research
positions. Currently, he teaches history and geography at the Riverside
School in Switzerland.
Patrick Ziltener was born in St. Gallen, Switzerland, in 1967. He
studied sociology, history and economics at the University of Basel and
at the Freie UniversitaÈt in Berlin and received his MA in sociology at the
University of Zurich in 1994. From 1995 to 1997 he was coordinator of
the research project `The Genesis of the Single European Act' at the
Sociological Institute of the University of Zurich, where he currently
works in both teaching and research positions. His PhD thesis on
`Strukturwandel der europaÈischen Integration' (`The Structural Transformation of European Integration') was accepted by the University of
Zurich in autumn 1997. He is involved in exchange and cooperation in
research on European integration within the European Sociological
Association.
Preface
Western Europe's move toward political union entered widespread
public debate only at the beginning of the 1990s. In fact, it had begun
almost a decade earlier, culminating in 1985 in a bargain that recast the
European Community: the Single European Act. At the time, these
events hardly received the attention they deserved. However, they
marked a historic step from a Community paralysed by lethargy and
budgetary squabbling in the `Eurosclerosis' era to one in which the
Community proved its worth by creating political structures `that will
give it a prime role in helping de®ne the post-Cold War world order', as
the Community presented itself to the world at Seville's 1992 Universal
Exposition. One key protagonist of the decisive events, in fact one of the
architects of the Single Market project, commented as follows: `There
are turning points in history. Frequently only dimly perceived at the
time but later clearly identi®ed. The renaissance of the Community
which was launched by the Internal Market Programme and, in its
wake, the Single European Act is likely to prove such a turning point'
(Cock®eld 1994: 157).
The signi®cant change within the Community during the mid-1980s
became evident in two events that ®nd their expression in two documents published by the Community: the Commission's White Paper
(CEC 1985) for the European Council (heads of state and governments) regarding the completion of the internal market, and the Single
European Act, adopted in December 1985 by the European Council
and formally approved by the Council of Ministers (ministers of foreign
affairs) on 28 February 1986. The White Paper was a political initiative
of the Commission. As such it was not exceptional. Within the
European Community the Commission is a supranational body, whose
independence from the member states was set out in the treaties of
1958. The Commission is simultaneously a partner of and in opposition
to the Council (Fusion Treaty, Article 15). Because of the multitude of
its functions, the Commission plays a key role within the Community ±
it is its motor, has a right to make proposals in the legal process (which
xi
xii
Preface
then are agreed upon by the Council) and has the exclusive right to
propose initiatives. The plans, programmes and memoranda of the
Commission are believed to advance the development of the Community. All this was agreed upon in the treaties of 1958, albeit the
Commission's position vis-aÁ-vis the Council was in fact weakened
during the years of the so-called Luxembourg Compromise.
The White Paper had already been roughly prepared when Jacques
Delors assumed the presidency in January 1985. As our research shows,
the ®rst initiatives of the Commission to complete the internal market
can be traced as far back as 1981. The internal market project was a
collaboration between the Commission and the European Roundtable
of Industrialists (ERT). The ERT is an informal panel founded on the
initiative of Commissioners Etienne Davignon and FrancËois-Xavier
Ortoli in April 1983; it was composed of seventeen top European
industrialists, and was later expanded to forty members. This informal
panel linked the leading European transnational industrialists with the
protagonists of the Commission. Wisse Dekker ± head of Philips and a
central ®gure in the Roundtable ± created with his paper `Agenda for
Action: Europe 1990' (see Dekker 1984, 1985b) an important conceptual basis for the White Paper `Europe 1992' by the Commission's vicepresident Lord Cock®eld (CEC 1985). European transnational business
urged the Commission to act as a political entrepreneur.
Of course, formally and as foreseen by the constitution, the member
states of the Community had to become active and renegotiate the
original treaty for the Single European Act. According to our hypothesis,
which has also been substantiated empirically, the initiative did not
originate in the Council (representing the member states). The Council
agreed on and transformed the new project compiled earlier by the
Commission into applicable law. The renewed treaty brought about a
marked broadening and overstepping of the original EC treaties. In our
understanding, the Single European Act marks the transition to statehood (see also chapter 1). It regulates policy cooperation at European
level by treaty and changes existing treaties of the Community at the
same time, and it is for precisely this reason that it is called the Single
European Act.
This volume ± going to press a dozen years after the Single European
Act became de®nitely effective ± reports on our research of this signi®cant and remarkable shift in European state-building. Obviously, the
fully mature Western national state is not the ®nal West European
innovation. In the European Union following this qualitative change in
integration, the European state is once again remodelled and forced out
of its national boundaries. We focus on the forces and protagonists of
Preface
xiii
the 1980s. This is in no way a classical historical analysis but a
theoretically guided attempt to look for the social forces that produced
this (in historical perspective) astonishing new beginning of European
state-building.
The volume is divided into three parts, at the beginning of which the
individual chapters are brie¯y introduced. In Part I we re¯ect on the
world systemic forces, on the institutional and conjunctional preconditions that paved the way for the Commission's political entrepreneurship
in the 1980s. Our theory suggests an elite pact that shapes our understanding of the decisive events beyond the current neofunctionalist and
neorealist explanations of European integration. It focuses on a bargain
between European transnational corporations and the Commission.
Two groups of actors ± transnationals and states ± are considered to
shape the world political economy via the theoretical mechanism of the
world market for social order and protection. In this theoretical framework of competition among political entrepreneurs for mobile capital
and of competition among economic entrepreneurs for state services
and protection, we may assume similar competitive strategies for both
classes of actors. Not only transnationals but also states may form
strategic alliances or even merge. Such mergers of state services are,
however, much easier if supranational institutional preconditions are
present and available for political entrepreneurship. The mechanism of
bargaining between political and economic undertakings and the
implied economic competition between governments are part of a
cyclical theory of social change, which refers to the rise and decline of
societal models and of hegemons (Bornschier 1988, 1996). The pressure to rearrange the political economy is most urgent when cornerstones of a societal model (Keynesianism) and interstate coordination
run into crisis and when the relative decline of the hegemon (United
States) and emerging new competitors ( Japan) jeopardize the stability of
the world political economy. Since these events became apparent during
the 1970s, the theory can suggest an explanation of why the initiative
was taken in the early 1980s and not sooner or later. To date, the
originally quite constrasting views on the role of the supranational and
transnational intervention to push the Single European Act in the 1980s
seem to converge in the recent debate (see Moravcsik 1998, 1999).
In Part II we put the hypotheses derived from our theory to the
empirical test by analysing four relevant policy areas that formed the
core in recasting the European bargain as manifested in the Single
European Act: the Single Market; the imitation of Japanese technology
corporatism; building up a supranational cohesion regime through the
revised regional policy; and the attempt to tie the envisaged societal
xiv
Preface
model to European postwar traditions by establishing ± albeit less
forceful ± cohesion and social and economic convergence as goals at the
Community level.
Part III contains chapters that offer conclusions beyond the Single
European Act. The ®rst focus is the evolution of the European Roundtable of Industrialists ± the powerful ally of the Commission in pushing
the internal market. The second topic is the European biotechnology
policy up to the mid-1990s ± the working of technology corporatism
outside the integrated circuit sector where it originated at the beginning
of the 1980s. These developments from a later period are used to
reassess the relaunch of the mid-1980s, to evaluate the processes it
triggered and to look at the evolution of the actors involved. The volume
ends with a chapter re¯ecting the outcome: the state of the European
Union. Rather than looking at it as an un®nished federal state, we
interpret this European state of nations as a renewed compromise
between old European processes ± nationalism and liberalism.
The Bibliography includes the numerous documents we used in our
research. The complete list of all our interview partners ± from the
Commission, the roundtables, participants in the policy-making
process, and major political actors as well as experts ± is in the
Appendix.
Acknowledgements
The research reported in this volume was initiated by a guideline paper
by the editor presented at the First European Conference of Sociology
in August 1992 on `The Rise of the European Community. Grasping
toward Hegemony? Or Therapy against National Decline?' (see
Bornschier 1994). However, the research would not have been possible
without external funding, which considerably augmented the editor's
own institutional resources and thus allowed the engagement of several
junior researchers in the project and to pay for ®eldwork expenses.
A ®rst research phase from 1992 to 1993 on `The Acceleration of
Western European Integration as a Part of the Social Transition at the
Core of World Society' was partially funded by the World Society
Foundation (Zurich, Switzerland), whose contribution is gratefully
acknowledged. At this stage, Nicola Fielder started her intensive ®eldwork to investigate the origins of the Single European Act, but several
others (Felix Keller, Michael Nollert, Irene Bloch and Doris Aebi) also
contributed to certain research questions. Considerably larger funding
for continued research on `The Origins of the Single European Act' has
been provided by a grant to the editor from the Swiss National Science
Foundation (grant no. 12±41988.94), for which we are indeed very
grateful. Nicola Fielder, Michael Nollert, Simon Parker, Felix Keller
and Patrick Ziltener participated in this second research phase from
1995 to 1997; Patrick Ziltener was also in charge of coordinating the
research team. In order not to exceed the normal book length and to
guarantee coherence, not all our accumulated research results could be
included in this volume. Furthermore, the present volume bene®ted a
lot from the copyediting done by Richard Schauf¯er, who also translated
a couple of chapters. We would like to thank him as well as Ann Stafford
who translated one chapter, Heinz Gabathuler for his ®ne work on the
index and Marianne Schindler for her careful proofreading and
secretarial help. Finally, we would like to acknowledge the stimulating
and helpful comments and suggestions we received from numerous
colleagues, as well as at conferences where we presented results from
xv
xvi
Acknowledgements
our research, among them the First, Second and Third European
Conference of Sociology (1992 in Vienna, 1995 in Budapest, and 1997
at the University of Essex in Colchester, England) and the Eighth
International Conference on Socio-Economics ( July 1996 in Geneva).
Grateful mention should be made of Volker Rittberger's very early
suggestion to include members of the Committee of Permanent
Representatives of the member states in Brussels (COREPER) on our
list of interviewees. Special thanks go to our numerous interviewees ±
protagonists, witnesses and experts (see the list in the Appendix) ± who
shared their memories, views and time with us, thus contributing
enormously to the empirical base of this volume. Last but not least,
mention should be made of the various helpful comments by
anonymous reviewers for Cambridge University Press who stimulated
the ®nal revisions of the typescript.
I
State-building and Political Entrepreneurship
Western Europe's move toward political union in the middle of the
1980s took place after years of Eurosclerosis and its impact was only
dimly perceived by most observers at the time. Chapter 1 by Volker
Bornschier develops a novel explanation for this remarkable shift in
Europe's political economy. In the context of the then fading lustre of
the United States, the hegemon of the postwar era, and the seemingly
limitless economic ascent of Japan, the path toward economic and
political union represented Europe's attempt to remain a player in the
post-hegemonic round of competition. The resurgence of economic
globalization that started in the 1970s and a tighter closing of ranks by
the European states are contradictory only at ®rst glance. The ®rst
implies a shift in power between the state and the economy in favour of
the transnational economy, to which regional integration is an answer, a
new deployment of an old weapon by states. In the political world
economy, ®rst economic enterprises and then states compete with one
another. On the other hand, economic enterprises and states are
dependent on each other. The supply of state-based order and support
as a locational condition and the demand for this by economic enterprises must be united in practice. Here, negotiations are the typical form
of exchange. Chapter 1 suggests that the qualitative change of West
European integration in the ®rst half of the 1980s was the result of an
alliance between European transnational corporations ± represented by
the European Roundtable of Industrialists ± and the Commission. It is
made very clear that this was the decisive impulse, the necessary
condition to overcome Eurosclerosis.
However, neither the Commission nor such an informal group as the
European Roundtable of Industrialists can change or amend the treaties
between the member states. This can result only from a successful
intergovernmental conference, which presupposes a number of prerequisites, especially the constitution of a `balanced' package deal.
Chapter 2 focuses not on the causal factors behind the single initiatives
but on the `tying up' process and the corresponding interest mediation
1
2
State-building and political entrepreneurship
among the actors involved, a process that was concluded after several
months of negotiations at the Luxembourg summit of December 1985.
Based on the theoretical considerations of chapter 1 and completing it,
the reconstruction of this process furnishes the proof that even the ®nal
phase of the genesis of the Single Act cannot be explained in a purely
intergovernmentalist matter. With respect to both the impulse that
triggered the relaunch of European integration ± the alliance between
transnational corporations and the Commission ± and the complicated
constitution of the Luxembourg package that made the elite bargain
palatable to the member states, the Commission as a supranational
actor was of paramount importance. These two chapters together serve
as a background for the sectional analyses in Part II, which survey the
formation of the main political initiatives ± the Single Market project,
technology corporatism, social and regional policy ± that were anchored
in the Single Act and, in some areas, the further development of these
policy areas.
1
Western Europe's move toward political
union
Volker Bornschier
The revitalization of Western Europe
The 1980s witnessed dramatic changes in world society. Political orders
that seemed to be rigidly ®xed changed within only a few years. The
sudden acceleration of West European integration is a case in point and
the topic of this volume. To be sure, another historic event needs
mentioning. In the short time between November 1989 ± the fall of the
Berlin Wall ± and the end of 1991 ± the of®cial dissolution of the Soviet
Union ± the East±West con¯ict, which had marked the postwar era,
became history.
In a booklet distributed at Seville's 1992 Universal Exposition, the
European Community (EC) presents itself to the world as follows:1
Now an economic giant, the Community is striving to consolidate the Single
Market into an economic and monetary union and to put in place political
structures that will give it a prime role in helping de®ne the post-Cold War
world order. (CEC 1992: 2)
Since the post-Cold War world order is mentioned in the above quote,
the coincidence in time of the Treaty on European Union ± agreed by
the heads of state and government of the European Community at their
summit in Maastricht in December 1991 ± along with the dissolution of
the Soviet Union and German reuni®cation could suggest that statebuilding in Europe and the end of the East±West divide are related.
However, this is a mistaken perspective. Western Europe embarked on
its path to a new and additional form of statehood as early as the ®rst half
of the 1980s, as manifested in the Single European Act signed in
February 1986 by the then twelve member states.
After so many years during which the Community was paralysed by
lethargy and squabbling over budgets, this relaunch of the Community
1
The exhibition presented in the Community Pavilion was entitled: `From Renaissance
Europe to the Renaissance of Europe'. One main topic in the pavilion was `The
European Community: A Great 20th Century Discovery' ± the theme of the 1992 Expo
being `The Age of Discoveries'.
3
4
State-building and political entrepreneurship
in the mid-1980s was remarkable. The 1991 Maastricht Treaty on
European Union continued this earlier move to a new European state
level beyond the nation-states; it was not as exceptional when compared
with the new beginning in the 1980s, although in terms of public
attitudes it was more controversial.
What in¯uenced the remarkable relaunch of integration in Europe,
which culminated for the ®rst time in the mid-1980s? The aforementioned publication of the European Community provides a clue that
illuminates the framework within which the revitalization of the politico-economic development of Western Europe must be positioned ±
the so-called triad: `The Community is one of the three pillars, along
with the United States of America and Japan, on which the system of
pluralist democracy and market economy is built' (ibid.). During the
1970s and early 1980s Western society found itself caught between the
advent of a new technological style and the dissolution of its Keynesian
era politico-economic regime. The dissolution of the societal model,
which brought many years of economic crisis in its wake, went hand-inhand with a relative economic decline of the United States ± the
Western hegemonic power of the postwar era ± and the seemingly steady
ascent of Japan. The new Far Eastern industrial giant set about pushing
the European powers from second place behind the United States, into
third place.
These challenges ± the loss of hegemonic stability and the emergence
of a strong new competitor ± were clearly perceived by Europe's
economic and political elites of that time, and their leading protagonists
responded with a European answer advocating competition in a world of
hegemonic transition. Yet, the European Community's claim to a
`prime' role could be misunderstood as a bid for mastery in global
affairs. This was simply not the case, as the protagonists knew quite
well.
The political Euro-entrepreneur Jacques Delors, who assumed the
presidency of the EC Commission in Brussels on 7 January 1985, and
brought fresh impetus to the Community by building on initiatives that
dated back to the early 1980s, clearly stated in an interview the order of
the day (Delors 1991: 20f.): `Out of the dynamic economic and
commercial power which we already are, a great political power must
develop.' He explained this with reference to a `historical responsibility'
and felt it would be sad if `the Europeans of the year 2010 . . . were to
become mere spectators of history'. Anxiety about projecting European
brilliance into the future appears in Jacques Delors' warning: `We must
move quickly; otherwise Europe will become an archaeological excavation site, where Americans and Japanese search for lost ideas and ways
Western Europe's move toward political union
5
of life' (Delors 1991: 21). State-building needs political entrepreneurship; and in this context, one of the leading ®gures who met the
challenge, Jacques Delors, has already been mentioned. But since the
new project was taking form beyond the level of the nation-states, the
institutional independence of the EC Commission, which was already
stipulated in the original treaty of the Community of 1958, was surely a
prerequisite for initiative and supranational entrepreneurship.
But for whom do state-builders venture such a project against the
historical forces of the vested interests of nation-states? One motive was
mentioned: projecting Europe's role into the future. To be sure, states
that want to be successful in the long run need to seek legitimacy in the
eyes of their citizens. Consequently, the concept of the `European social
area' presented by Delors to the European Parliament only two months
after he assumed presidency of the Commission was designed to balance
the Common Market project, whose leading architect was Lord Cock®eld, then the Commission's vice-president.
In order to explain why, one has to consider that states and business
in the capitalist world political economy are inextricably interrelated.
States provide territorially bounded public goods which ± if of good
quality ± help economic enterprises to prosper. This applies not only to
the average ®rm that normally does business only within the framework
of a single state, but more importantly ± and this is a point neglected in
the recent debate on globalization ± to transnational corporations. In
order to compete successfully, these corporations, although economically active around the world, need a strong home base allowing for
economies of scale in large markets with common economic regulation.
They prosper if backed by strong governments that protect their interests both at home and abroad. It was Etienne Davignon, vice-president
of the Commission at the end of the 1970s and in the early 1980s, who
recognized that global competition required a strategic view of science
and technology and who became the architect of what later was termed
the new technology policy of the Community. However, in the context
of bargains between the demand for and supply of public goods and
protection in the world, it is not only the interests of enlightened
European statesmen that are involved, but also those of the transnational European economic elite. Among many others, Wisse Dekker,
president of Philips Electronics, was an in¯uential spokesman for this
group in the early 1980s.
Europe met the challenge of the changing world political economy
brie¯y outlined above by initiating a new European societal model, for
which the Single European Act marks the beginning. This not only
brought several new key elements to the political economy of Western
6
State-building and political entrepreneurship
Europe, but also added a new and additional level to European statehood.
This chapter is aimed at generating explanations and providing a fresh
perspective on what was happening in Europe during the 1980s and
what is still under debate in the 1990s. The remaining chapters of this
volume will investigate in detail whether such hypotheses hold when
confronted with the facts. We begin this chapter by placing the revitalization of European integration in the 1980s in the context of European
state-building. In the remainder of this chapter we elaborate our explanation of the integration thrust and the key actors involved in it.
State-building in Europe
Why do we stress the role of the Single European Act in the course of
West European integration, given that the process had been proceeding
for about twenty-®ve years prior to that treaty? The Act is the decisive
point of departure for European economic integration toward a new,
additional level of statehood in Europe. Under the banner bearing the
magic inscription `Europe 92', Western Europe was preparing to transform itself economically and politically. How can this be viewed within
the framework of the European state-building process?
Looking back
Elsewhere, we have analysed the tortuous paths of capitalist and state
evolution (see Bornschier 1988: ch. 11; 1996: ch. 10). The process of
state-building is normally divided into phases. A frequently cited model
was suggested by Stein Rokkan (1975, 1981), according to whom the
fully mature nation-state can be recognized by four features: central
power, standardized culture, political mass participation and extensive redistributive policies. In a developmental perspective, Rokkan identi®es the
following phases: penetration (the extension of central control over a
territory and a population); standardization (the homogenization of
administration through the creation of a bureaucracy and of the population through the creation of the nation); participation (increasing
political participation of expanding groups leading to mass participation); and redistribution (the elaboration and coordination of redistributive policies by the welfare state).
In contrast to this developmental theoretical approach, we have
advanced a different formulation. We see the modern state as the
outcome of a multitude of con¯icts, which it still re¯ects today. These
are expressed, for example, by the tension between the state as a
Western Europe's move toward political union
7
community striving for equality and as a power centre. Furthermore, in
the course of its con¯ictive evolution the state was forced to assume a
number of functions by a system that was always more extensive than
any particular state, however powerful the latter may have been.
Economic and economically motivated competition in the European
and later the expanding world system was the starting point and
attendant circumstance of this con¯ictive process. Max Weber already
saw states and capitalism as interrelated, and the condition of their
con¯ictive dynamic, which promoted state-building as well as the
unfolding of capitalism, is the decentralized state system, i.e. the
absence of a world state. This con¯ict selects ever more ef®cient forms
of the state and the capitalist economy. To this day, two opposing
principles ± nationalism and liberalism ± have been the basis for and the
permanent accompanying features of modern state-building, their interplay shaping the modern state. Nonetheless, the unfolding of the state
project did not take place in only one location; rather, the opposition of
these principles and the originally very differently shaped states adopted
a zigzag course through Europe.
From a long historical perspective, we suggest that social arrangements that enjoyed high-quality protection had an edge over their
competitors in the world system. This should be understood in comparative-historical terms, i.e. social formations as compared with their
contemporary competitors. For this reason they were successful and, for
a while, leaders in capitalist development. Freer arrangements of wage
labour, greater opportunities for larger parts of the population, and
more liberal institutions were typical of all the industrial leaders of the
modern world system. This also holds when one goes back beyond
Venice and North Holland, which pioneered the world economy project
in European modernity. Since the nineteenth century, this option,
typical of ascending social formations, became even more urgent owing
to increasing levels of industrial complexity. Those who tried to `buck
this trend' never reached the peak of the world industrial pyramid.
The tortuous paths of state evolution and of the development of
capitalism suggest that the modern state originated from diverse roots,
but that competition between models enforced convergence. In the
encompassing framework of the world political economy there is little
use in trying to assign primacy to the political logic of economic action or
the economic logic of political action. It seems obvious that the market
and economic competition are politically motivated and based on
political will. As collective goods of this kind cannot be produced by the
market, the political logic of economic action naturally applies. At the
same time, the economic logic of state policy also applies, because
8
State-building and political entrepreneurship
collective goods as prior conditions for markets ± provided and regulated
by the state ± compete with each other. It is no surprise that such
interrelationships resulted in the European welfare state, since claims to
basic goods and equal opportunity cannot be adequately met by
economic dynamics alone. Unless it meets such claims, capitalism may
not last. However, solutions to the problem of creating legitimacy are
not without their contradictions. Social welfare ± according to Stein
Rokkan the ®nal stage of the fully mature West state ± will be rearranged
in the future. The welfare state cannot be considered the ®nal West
European innovation in this regard, and the emergence of a new supranational European level of statehood should be understood in this
context.
Situating the recent move
West European integration represents in some respects a continuation
of, while in other respects an overcoming of, previous features of the
European state-building process. The continuation of the 500-year-old
European state-building process refers to the concentration of politicoterritorial rule (Elias [1969] 1977) ± an implosion of originally 500
state-like structures to only two dozen (Tilly 1975: 15). On the other
hand, the European Union exhibits features that point to an earlier
successful yet atypical state project to be discussed at the end of this
section.
West European integration is a social innovation in several respects:
(1) The process will mean the end of a multistate balance of power in
Europe. The problem of the distribution of power at the core of the
world system was posed anew after Western Europe lost its previous
undisputed leadership earlier in the twentieth century. Thus, West
European integration by no means creates a concentration of power
for the whole of the capitalist core, which will remain at least
trilateral.
(2) The uni®cation project does not conform to two crucial characteristics of state-building according to the West European model
(Rokkan 1975, 1981). As far as can be anticipated, the future
Union will not have a prominent central authority or a standardized
culture. Thus, the integration process will not continue the
European nation-state-building tradition.
(3) During previous changes of the societal model, one constant was
obvious: the articulation of the linkage between the political and
economic realms, although it differed between societal models,
always took place within the framework of nation-states. Through
Western Europe's move toward political union
9
the Single European Act and later the Treaty on European Union,
for the ®rst time a supra-state linkage of the two realms has been
created that goes beyond loose international regimes. This is new, as
is the extension of welfare state issues to the interstate determination of life chances.
(4) Finally, West European integration is developing in the direction of
a new state level that exhibits certain similarities with an earlier
European state project (see below). However, for the ®rst time in
European history, the state is relying not on military structures for
the integration of such a huge and economically potent body, but
rather on a legal and economic community, which does not aim to
deprive its members of their cultural speci®cities.
Legal and economic issues are the point of departure for some
remarks we would like to make on statehood. A community as a type of
political body is characterized by the rule of shared laws based on
treaties. According to the dominant doctrine, communities are not
(federal) states in the true sense (Nicolaysen 1991). From a social
science perspective, such an exclusive distinction does not make much
sense, however. In any case, communities are characterized by supranationality according to legal principles (Nicolaysen 1991). In sectors
speci®ed by treaties, sovereignty is assigned to the community and thus
supranationality is created.
To distinguish communities from states, constitutional law points to
the fact that communities cover only limited goals, that is, communities
are only a means of functional integration (Nicolaysen 1991). Here we
must ask whether Europe's goals have really been as limited as this since
the emergence of the Single European Act.
How communities can claim statehood could be determined on
normative-theoretical grounds. Yet, for empirical sociology it is also
useful to de®ne statehood as a variable with threshold values in a
descriptive, factual way. Whether statehood in this sense is reached
depends not only on threshold values, however, but also on the societal
type that circumscribes the role of the state. The characteristics of the
societal type under discussion are the market economy and political
democracy.
As economic actors, the people in the states of the European Community became fully integrated citizens of the Community with the
adoption of the Single European Act. With respect to citizenship, the
new Community is only indirectly endowed with legitimacy by these
economic actors by way of democratic elections of the heads of state and
government who negotiate and renew the treaties. This is true despite
the fact that the European Parliament is directly elected and has been
10
State-building and political entrepreneurship
gradually upgraded by the Single European Act and the subsequent
revisions. Its increased weight notwithstanding, the Parliament's jurisdiction does not match the jurisdiction of national parliaments. If we
measure these developments with reference to the criteria of the societal
type, we must therefore conclude that statehood is being developed in a
different way.
Yet, in the important sphere of the market economy, statehood has
already gone quite far. With reference to the market economy we can
thus claim that a community assumes state character: (a) if important
public goods are created by the community; (b) if the community has its
own ®nancial jurisdiction and its own ®scal resources; and (c) if
remaining central areas of state functions (e.g. foreign policy, security,
currency) are at least coordinated between the member states and if the
community is at least party to such coordination. According to such a
list of criteria, the European Community can be said to have added a
level of proper statehood to the European political system since the
adoption of the 1986 Single European Act (rati®ed 1987) ± and thus
prior to the 1991 Maastricht Treaty on European Union (rati®ed in
1993).
Some points of clari®cation must be added to these observations. The
signi®cant change within the Community during the mid-1980s
becomes evident in two events that ®nd expression in two documents
published by the Community: the Commission's White Paper (CEC
1985) for the European Council (heads of state and government)
regarding the completion of the internal market, and the Single
European Act, adopted in December 1985 by the European Council
and formally approved by the Council of Ministers (ministers of foreign
affairs) on 28 February 1986. The White Paper was a political initiative
of the Commission; as such it was not exceptional, because within the
European Community the Commission is a supranational body, whose
independence from the member states was already set out in the treaties
of 1958. The Commission is at the same time a partner of and in
opposition to the Council (Fusion Treaty, Article 15). Owing to the
multitude of its functions, the Commission plays a key role within the
Community ± it is its motor, has a right to make proposals in the legal
process (which then are formally agreed upon by the Council) and is
mandated to take initiatives. The plans, programmes and memoranda of
the Commission are believed to advance the development of the Community. All this was already agreed upon in the treaties in effect since
1958.
The White Paper had already been prepared when Jacques Delors
assumed the presidency in early 1985. The ®rst initiatives of the
Western Europe's move toward political union
11
Commission to establish the internal market can be traced back at least
to 1981. The completion of the internal market project was worked out
between the Commission and the European Roundtable of Industrialists
(ERT). The ERT is an informal panel founded on the initiative of
Commissioners Etienne Davignon and FrancËois-Xavier Ortoli in April
1983; it was composed of seventeen top European industrialists, and
was later expanded to forty members. Wisse Dekker ± head of Philips,
already an in¯uential ®gure in the ERT and later its president, who
formulated the `Agenda for Action: Europe 1990' (see Dekker 1984,
1985b) ± and Lord Cock®eld ± then vice-president of the Commission,
under whose auspices the White Paper `Europe 1992' (CEC 1985) was
drafted ± were bound together by more than common intentions. At
least since April 1983, the informal panel of the ERT (informal because
it is not a body within the institutional framework of the Community)
linked these two protagonists of the transnational European economy
and the Commission.
Naturally, formally and as foreseen by the constitution, the member
states of the Community had to become active and renegotiate the
original treaty for the Single European Act. According to our hypothesis,
the initiative did not originate in the Council (representing the member
states). The Council only transformed the new project into applicable
law. The renewed treaty brought about a marked extension and superseding of the original EC treaties. The Single European Act, with the
single market as its core element (see chapter 3), marks the transition to
a new supranational level of statehood.
The Single European Act is called single precisely because it regulates
European policy cooperation by treaty and changes existing treaties of
the Community at the same time. Since its adoption, the new superior
body of the Community, the European Council (heads of state and
government of the member states), coordinates political and economic
policies with the president of the Commission, who is a member of the
European Council with equal rights.
The intentions of the new formulation of the treaty are evident. The
Single European Act is explicitly understood as a step towards
European union (see its preamble). Part II of the Single European Act
includes changes to the original European Economic Community treaty
affected by the new one, and Part III regulates political cooperation in
Europe. In the ®rst instance, the provisions regarding the establishment
of the internal market by the end of 1992 are worth mentioning. These
conceptions of `Europe 92' were the most prominent in the headlines at
the time.
The Community had already operated as a common market.
12
State-building and political entrepreneurship
However, despite the elimination of tariffs on intra-EC trade, the
domestic markets of Community members had remained fairly fragmented owing to non-tariff barriers that proliferated and even intensi®ed during the economic downturn of the 1970s. Only the completion
of the internal market programme, which erased the variety of non-tariff
barriers that sheltered domestic ®rms from competition, created, via
deregulation or harmonization, a single market for merchandise, services, labour, and capital. This provides both greater opportunities for
economies of scale as well as economies of common governance. In
terms of protection and regulation, this means a restructuring: the locus
at which the public good is provided is the Community and no longer
the single member state.
The renewed treaty also involved substantial changes in the institutional frameworks. The procedure for enacting law changed as follows.
The majority vote in the Council was extended. Now, for all decisions
concerning the internal market, quali®ed majority votes are stipulated.
In connection with the alignment of legal regulations, either a quali®ed
majority vote or the mutual recognition of the equivalence of regulations
in the member states is called for. Further, the participation of the
European Parliament in formulating legislation and its budgetary
authority are expanded. Finally, the treaty broadens the role of the
European Court of Justice by way of coordination with the Court of
First Instance.
In addition, the agreement concerning extensions of the earlier
authority of the European Community as well as new authority is worth
mentioning. The section regarding the progress of economic and social
cohesion (Part V) represents a new jurisdiction. This area is supposed to
shape the policies of cohesion and represents a collective good: solidarity.
What is more, the Community obtains the authority to support
research and technological development to advance international competitiveness (Part VI). This section is designed to shape technological
capital for international competition, which again is a collective good.
Last but not least, environmental policy now partly falls under the
jurisdiction of the Community (Part VII).
Earlier authority has also been signi®cantly extended, for example in
connection with social policy (improvement of working conditions,
minimum standards, dialogue between social partners) and economic
policy (the anchoring of the European Monetary System and its
corresponding institutional changes).
These brie¯y described elements of the renewed treaty allow us to
speak of the Community's statehood with respect to the sphere of the
Western Europe's move toward political union
13
market economy insofar as it provides public goods on its own rather
than simply coordinating member state activities. For the ®rst time, a
supranational provision of such goods common to the Community is
detached from the nation-states of the members. It should be made very
clear that this did not abolish the nation-states; quite the contrary. The
member states, although they lost competencies to the Community,
remain powerful because they have the sole legislative power in terms of
the revision and extension of Community law.
Therefore, the European Union remains a somewhat strange hermaphrodite, between a state confederation and a federal state. Is it not too
early to speak of state-building in Europe? In many respects, the new
form is a novelty, but it has at least one European antecedent which
made history for a century. Earlier in this section we already pointed to
the very different roots of state-building in Europe. The theory of the
social contract also distinguishes between these two poles: the `contract
of association' and the `contract of domination' (Dahrendorf 1992: 47).
In a philosophical perspective, Immanuel Kant can be linked to the
former variant, whereas the latter can be traced back to Thomas
Hobbes. During the aforementioned process of amalgamation, the
modern core state was in¯uenced more strongly by the `trade and
economic state' as a `contract of association' than by the colossal
rapacious states founded on domination and military power. The
European Union supports this process towards a state characterized by
a plurality of power centres at different levels bound to the principle of
subsidiarity and numerous checks and balances. Similarities with the
Republic of the United Netherlands cannot be overlooked despite the
centuries that lie between the two.
In The Perspective of the World, Fernand Braudel ([1979] 1984)
reports the boundless astonishment of contemporaries in the face of the
vertiginous rise and unexpected power of such a small and in some
respects entirely new country as North Holland. `Can the United
Netherlands be called a ``state''?,' Braudel (1984, 3: 193) asks, and then
goes on to explain:
the seven provinces considered themselves sovereign, and that they were
moreover divided into tiny urban republics. It is also true that none of the
central institutions ± the Council of State or Raad van Staat . . . and the StatesGeneral which also sat in the Hague and was a permanent delegation of
ambassadors from the provinces ± had in theory any real power at all. Every
important decision had to be referred to the provincial States and approved by
them unanimously. Since the interests of the provinces diverged considerably ±
in particular those of the coastal from those of the inland provinces ± this system
was a perpetual source of con¯ict.
14
State-building and political entrepreneurship
Apart from the `vertiginous rise', it is possible today to detect many
parallels with the European Union in this description by simply changing certain institutional designations.
Theoretical considerations
The decline of the Keynesian societal model
Elsewhere we have analysed Western society as a sequence of rising and
decaying societal models (Bornschier 1988, 1996). Since the beginning
of the nineteenth century three societal models can be discerned:
(1) The liberal societal model of the founding era, formed after the
liberal uprisings of 1830±48 and dissolving in the late 1860s.
(2) The class-polarized model of the post-foundation era, originating
following the widening of political participation and the extension
of compulsory education in the 1880s and dissolving after the turn
of the century.
(3) The societal model of the re-allocative market economy and welfare
state era that integrated neocorporatist and Keynesian elements in
varying degrees, originating among pioneers (Sweden, United
States, Switzerland) in the early 1930s and spreading after the
Second World War. Since the late 1960s, this model has begun to
dissolve and, since the early 1980s, has actually entered a phase of
decay in certain countries (most obviously the United Kingdom and
the United States).
In order to further clarify the term societal model, it seems appropriate to discuss somewhat more precisely the three spheres ± i.e.
normative theories, politico-economic regime, and technological style ±
that were linked to each other in the last societal model.
Normative theories
The swing in doctrines related to economic policy was very important
for the last societal model. The then emerging normative theory for
solving economic and social problems may be summarized using the
following formula. The state was regarded as the solution for pressing
problems that were the result of both the world economic crisis and a
new technological style. Yet, the state was not only the solution;
normatively ®xed state intervention also allowed the integration of
reformist socialism into the new societal model. Solidarity and redistribution, two socialist demands, were no longer in fundamental contradiction with a liberal position. The new guiding principles of economic
policy in the welfare state era legitimized solidarity and redistribution as
Western Europe's move toward political union
15
virtues that would stimulate economic growth. Yet the neoliberal and
monetarist uprisings of the 1970s undermined the basic consensus
regarding normative theories that had lasted for decades and introduced
a new motto: Less State Intervention ± More Freedom.
Politico-economic regime
The dominant normative theory of the neocorporatist±Keynesian
societal model, with its interventionist guiding principles, created the
possibility for a class pact for economic stability, social paci®cation and
growth, thus promising a `democratization' of wealth. The past societal
model was therefore characterized by two new linkages within the
politico-economic regime: ®rst, a new linkage between the economy and
the state; second, a new linkage between capital and labour. However,
from a comparative perspective, the extent of cooperation and linkage of
interests has differed among core countries. Despite the similarities, one
®nds different degrees of neocorporatist policy-making, i.e. of intermediation of organized interests coordinated by the state.
Technological style
Procedural changes in the chemical industry were originally the key
element of the technological style of that era. Using the new ¯ow
production, it became possible to produce the key factor ± energy
(oil) ± at diminishing relative prices for a long time. In addition, there
were signi®cant innovations in the shaping of formal organization.
Mention should be made of `scienti®c management', the division of
labour, and the reorganization of large corporations. The growth of
the ®rm was conditional upon a far-reaching separation of ownership
and control, which in turn led to changes in the composition of the
economic elite. By redistributing income and positions in favour of
the distinctly enlarged middle classes, the renewed organization
created mass demand, which reinforced mass production and the
diffusion of the technological style. Finally, the new style offered a new
mix of goods.
The 1970s announced the advent of a new technological style integrating and linking new productive, distributive and administrative
elements. This style was formed during the 1980s by successively
substituting information intensity for the material and energy intensity
of the former style. The advance in productivity was a result of increasingly inexpensive micro-electronics and digital telecommunications.
Computers are the new key product and chips the new raw materials. By
changing the shape of organizations, the structure of jobs and the
patterns of consumption, the new style will alter the appearance of
16
State-building and political entrepreneurship
social life ± the changes being possibly even more dramatic than those
resulting from the former style.
The state meets technology
The notion of technological style was originally proposed by Carlota
Perez (1983, 1985), and later developed by Bornschier (1988, 1996).
The advantage of Perez's approach in comparison with earlier conceptualizations of technological change (e.g. Schumpeter) is that she
models the socio-institutional sphere ± governed by states ± as an
indispensable element of technological style. Today we are witnessing a
shift toward a new technological style. `Telematics' or `digitalization' is
the new key project that has replaced `automobilization'.
In order to understand discontinuous technological change in a
model of the sequence of technological styles that shape markets, the
structure of ®rms and lifestyles, it is necessary to examine the links
between two subsystems that embody important aspects of the concept
of technological style. Carlota Perez points to two interrelated subsystems of the process of the succession of technological styles: (1) the
techno-economic subsystem, which is characterized by faster adaptation
due to the logic of more individualized choices, and (2) the socioinstitutional subsystem based on the collective logic of political choices,
in which change is more conjunctural.
Both the techno-economic and the socio-institutional subsystems
adjust to each other during a long-term economic upswing. The adjustment of the socio-institutional system is a necessary part of the evolution
and diffusion of the new technological style. The institutional infrastructure that is able to support a new technological style is subject to a
political logic. This needs to be de®ned, and new institutions need to be
created in political struggles, not only within nation-states but also in
the world market and the world polity.
A new technological style starts to emerge only when the old style
reaches the limits of further diffusion and pro®ts based on it decline.
Even if the advantages of the new style become obvious, it cannot
take over immediately. A struggle between the two styles thus begins,
which can be compared to Schumpeter's (1939) notion of `creative
destruction'.
The other important brake on the emergence of a new style is the
mismatch between the two subsystems: `The transition to a new
techno-economic regime cannot proceed smoothly, not only because
it implies massive transformation and much destruction of existing
plant, but mainly because the prevailing patterns of social behavior in
Western Europe's move toward political union
17
the existing institutional structure were shaped around the requirements and possibilities created by the previous paradigm' (Perez
1985: 445).
The contradictions between the new technology and the old institutions explain the kind of limited economic recovery that occurred in the
1980s, while institutions such as Keynesianism, welfare states and
labour unions came under pressure or even deteriorated. The coherence
of the technological style begins to dissolve as soon as the long-wave
economic peak is reached, i.e. when the permeation of the style, with its
speci®c range of products, reaches saturation point and induces a surge
of investments aimed at rationalization. To reach an equilibrium of
production and consumption, two kinds of invention are necessary.
Innovations aimed at saving labour in the productive apparatus alone
(i.e. innovations that increase output with the same work-time input)
lead to disequilibria if they are not linked to inventions that fascinate
people so that they want to spend their leisure consuming these goods
and services, and are even prepared to work overtime to acquire them.
In the Keynesian societal model, ¯ow technology and Taylorism were
examples of process innovations, whereas television sets and cars represented the second type of invention, leading to the supply of hitherto
unknown goods and services.
During the alteration of the technological style these two types of
inventions do not occur simultaneously. This is a built-in disequilibrating mechanism that increases disparities and delays the emergence
of a new style. This disparity produces its effects slowly because initially
induced industries continue to expand. To take the example of the
automobile, the induced growth effects consisted of the army of
mechanics and gas station employees, the new tourist industry and
public investments in roads, bridges and tunnels. Still, the downswing
triggered by the mismatch of production with consumption gains
momentum and is reinforced by entrepreneurs who act defensively in
the face of crisis. They rationalize their production through new
methods that already incorporate elements of the coming technological
style. The widening gap between process and product innovations
during the transition from the 1960s to the 1970s has been demonstrated empirically by Alfred Kleinknecht (1987). Only the match
between the technological possibilities and the institutional infrastructure brings about a fresh range of products and services, and thus a new
match between productive opportunities and consumption that leads to
the unfolding of a new technological style.
18
State-building and political entrepreneurship
European proposals for technology corporatism and protection
The supranational political entrepreneurs in Europe were well aware of
these transitions by the end of the 1970s and the beginning of the 1980s.
Etienne Davignon, at that time vice-president of the Commission, is a
case in point. In an essay `Europe at the End or Before a New Upswing?'
which he published in a volume edited by Ralf Dahrendorf (1981) ±
himself a former Commissioner ± Davignon outlined the policy recommendations that later became part of the new Community legislation.
Davignon looks at the competition as one between industrial nations,
spurred by the emergence of new competitors, involving structural
adjustments of old industrial branches and innovation with regard to
new ones, among which he especially mentioned micro-electronics,
space and biotechnology. He suggested that in the competitive restructuring the resulting future world division of labour should be left neither
to accident nor to fate but should instead be the result of concerted
policies to foster innovations embedded in `reasonable' decisions about
investment and research. He especially pointed to the route Japan had
already chosen earlier in this ®eld (Davignon 1981: 169). What he
proposed was nothing less than an `independent European answer'.
Davignon's postulates were the following:
First of all, a market for the introduction of new products must be established,
where the demand regarding the creation of European norms and standards as
well as the expansion of public demand can be stimulated. Secondly, there must
be real support to enable suf®cient positioning in the world markets . . . Finally,
Europe should make it possible to improve coordination of the respective
national research and development activities.' (Davignon 1981: 183; our
translation)
The point of reference is very obvious. Under the heading `The Telematics Revolution: the Barriers Must Fall in Europe', Davignon points
to the new technological revolution already going on, with the core area
in telematics:
The question is whether the Europeans ± and this really concerns the whole
continent and not simply a country or several countries ± want to gain one of the
®rst places in the current competition or whether they will content themselves
with passively observing the strategies that their American and Japanese
competitors are following. The answer is simple. Europe can no longer allow
itself to stand aside when modern technology is on the agenda, otherwise it must
accustom itself now to the fact that it will soon be ranked among the also-rans.
Our autonomy is at stake. (Davignon 1981: 184; our translation)
This project of technology corporatism and of protection was clearly
linked to the other core areas of the renewal:
Western Europe's move toward political union
19
We want to create a truly European market, a common market, which offers
businesses the same chances that their American and Japanese competitors
have. (Davignon 1981: 185; our translation)
In order to legitimize his approach he continues:
Quite a few people ask themselves why the EC Commission does concern itself
with telematics. Furthermore, they say that on the telematics market everything
appears to be going well and that business `copes very well without the
technocrats from Brussels'. But that only serves to con®rm our diagnosis; that
is, that in Europe one just muddles through . . . Europe manufactures only
10 per cent of world production of highly developed electronic components,
whereas the EC represents 25 per cent of the world market in this sector. That
means that the distance from our competitors will become increasingly larger.
European industry must set itself the goal of producing one-third of the world
market in the area of telematics by the end of the 1980s. This is a dif®cult goal
but it is attainable ± and it is the unanimous opinion of all, that is, of
governments, business and the EC Commission. (Davignon 1981: 186; our
translation)
From this early statement (published in 1981!) it becomes obvious that
protagonists in the Commission coded the transition towards a new
European societal model in terms of competition with `Japan' and the
`USA' and that early on they proposed a European answer in the form of
a proposal by the EC Commission (Davignon 1981: 187).
This approach not only shaped the later Single European Act (see
above) but became part of the of®cial normative theory of the Commission. Karl-Heinz Narjes (1988: 396), then vice-president of the Commission stated:
It was not until 1980 that the Community was able to take a strategic view of
science and technology. It was then that the Commission ®rst stated its belief
that it was not possible to devise a new model for society, to secure Europe's
political and economic autonomy, or to guarantee commercial competitiveness
without a complete mastery of the most sophisticated technologies.
By the early 1990s the approach of technology corporatism and protection had become a standard core element of EC policy. The Commission justi®ed its common procedure by pointing to competitive pressure
and insuf®cient R&D funds in information technologies (CEC, 1991a:
8). `The Community therefore developed a global strategy in the ®rst
half of the 1980s in close collaboration with industry and with research
institutions' (CEC, 1991a: 10; our translation). This is followed by a list
of different elements, the support of business as well as measures against
side-effects and a vision: `preparation of the transition to a society, in
which information is seen as a raw material, which is used in agreement
with the social partners and on the basis of the corresponding offers for
education and training' (CEC 1991a: 10).
20
State-building and political entrepreneurship
It was not only protection inside the EC that was envisioned in these
tasks. In the words of the Commission: `Considering the growing
challenges in the area of Information and Communication Technologies
the Community must prove its joint action towards third party states.
This applies to the bilateral relationship of the EC to the US and to
Japan, as well as in international institutions like the General Agreement
on Tariffs and Trade, International Standards Organization or International Telecommunications Union' (CEC 1991a: 71).
Key structures and shifts of globalization
During the late 1980s a new term entered popular discourse: globalization. At least ®ve different dimensions of globalization need to be
distinguished: common ecological constraints, values and institutions,
globalization of communication, political globalization, and economic
globalization. Here we brie¯y consider only the last.
Economic globalization means globe-spanning economic relationships. The interrelationships of markets ± ®nance, goods and services ±
and the networks created by transnational corporations (TNCs) are the
most important manifestations of this. Transnational corporations are
companies owning business assets in more than one country. TNCs
thus own stock of foreign direct investment (FDI). Foreign trade and
foreign direct investment can be considered mutual substitutes only to a
limited degree. Normally there is considerable overlap between foreign
trade and foreign direct investment patterns; about half of world trade is
channelled by TNCs. Before we come to structures of foreign trade and
stocks of foreign direct investment let us brie¯y look at shifts in the
relative importance of foreign trade and stocks of foreign direct investment in the world economy.
The relative importance of both foreign trade and stock of foreign
direct investment increased in the postwar era, although not continuously. Exports as a percentage of GDP of Western developed countries
(Bairoch 1996: 175) ¯uctuated around 9 per cent between 1950 and
1968 and, after a `dramatic' surge, ¯uctuated between 14 and 15 per
cent from the middle of the 1980s to 1993.
World stock of foreign direct investment in relation to world product
(Bornschier and Chase-Dunn 1999: 295, table 14.2) was around 4.5
per cent between 1960 and 1980 (rising slightly from 4.4 to 4.8) but had
doubled by 1991 to 8.5 percent. This obviously large increase of the
relative weight of foreign trade and foreign production is also referred to
as evidence of a `recent' economic globalization. But this assumption of
a recent increase is a myth not backed by historical ®gures. As early as
Western Europe's move toward political union
21
1890 and 1913 we can observe ®gures of the relative importance of
foreign trade and foreign direct investment that were reached again only
in the 1980s (Bairoch 1996; Bornschier and Chase-Dunn 1999), and
the growth rate of world trade between 1870 and 1913 was even a bit
higher than that between 1980 and 1990 (UNCTAD 1994: 127).
Obviously there are tides of globalization in the world economy. The
Keynesian societal model of the hegemonic West, which started with
democratic pioneers in the early 1930s following the world economic
crisis, was a long period of limited globalization when compared with
earlier and later periods. When the Keynesian societal model started to
dissolve around the end of the 1960s, foreign trade and foreign direct
investment began to surge. This has led to increased competition in the
world political economy since the late 1960s ± one of the decisive
elements, we suggest, for an explanation of the integrational thrust in
Europe.
Structures in the global economy
As can be seen from table 1.1, during the British hegemony about half
of the total stock of foreign direct investment (FDI) was owned by
transnational corporations headquartered in the United Kingdom. In
1914, US companies already owned 18.5 per cent, almost the same as
companies headquartered in France and Germany together. During the
heyday of American hegemony, about half of the world stock was owned
by companies headquartered in the USA. This position has been rapidly
deteriorating since the end of the 1960s, one indication of a relative
industrial decline of US hegemony since that time.
Other indications of considerable shifts in the postwar era relate to
shares in world production: the US and West European shares have
been declining since 1967 whereas Japan's share has been increasing
until the advent of the 1990s (UNCTAD 1994: 157). The same applies
to shares in world trade (see Bornschier 1988: 410). Western Europe's
share rose from 1950 until 1972 but declined in the 1970s and 1980s,
whereas the share of the United States has been declining since the late
1950s. Japan's share in world trade has continuously increased since
1950, and continued to do so even during the 1970s and the 1980s.
What we can learn from these facts, and especially from the longer
view that the 1914 ®gures in table 1.1 make possible, is that hegemonies
rise and decline, and these are rather long-term processes. Moreover, we
observe the often forgotten fact that hegemonic states in the world
political economy, i.e. those that can set the rules of the game, not only
have comparatively large internal markets (in Britain's case) or even a
22
State-building and political entrepreneurship
Table 1.1. Shares in world outward stock of foreign direct investment, selected
countries, 1914, 1960, 1978 and 1992
Percentage of world total
United States
United Kingdom
France
Germany
Japan
1914
1960
1978
1992
18.5
45.5
12.2
10.5
0.1
49.2
16.2
6.1
1.2
0.7
41.4
12.9
3.8
7.3
6.8
25.3
11.4
8.3
9.2
13.0
Source: UNCTAD 1994: 131 (based on John H. Dunning).
huge one (in the case of the USA), but also have the strongest position
in the world with respect to transnational corporations. Therefore, for
economic transnationals to be allied with a strong state, or even better
with a hegemon, seems to have provided a competitive edge. Thus,
transnational business and strong states (in terms of internal market and
external stature) are competitive advantages ± something that advocates
of the thesis that economic globalization will result in a `withering away
of the state' completely ignore.
Let us brie¯y look at Japan, a strong nation-state with a considerable
internal mass market after the war. Compared with Britain early in the
twentieth century and with the USA in mid-century, Japan's position is
still moderate in terms of the share that Japanese transnational corporations control. But, compared with the big European players (Britain,
France and Germany), Japan has not only threatened to push them
from second place behind the United States into third place, but has
actually succeeded in doing so (see table 1.1). Europe reacted, as we
already know from earlier statements in this chapter. Let us therefore
look now at the aggregated ®gures for the European Community given
in table 1.2.
Table 1.2 shows a remarkable share of the stock of foreign direct
investment owned by European economic transnationals headquartered
in the European Union. This share increased after the relaunch, but this
was mainly due to new members. Compared with the Japanese and even
the US share, this aggregated European Union share looks quite
impressive and does not invite fears about the EU's future world
position.
But the ®gures in table 1.2 tell only half the story. Two arguments are
relevant here. First, part of the `foreign' direct investment of European
transnational corporations is actually located within the European
Western Europe's move toward political union
23
Table 1.2. World stock of foreign direct investment by headquarter region,
1980±1995
Percentage of world total
1980
1985
1990
1995
North America:
USA and Canada
Western Europe
EU share
Developed Asia:
Japan and `Four Tigers'
Other
TOTAL
47.3
46.1
39.8
42.6
45.6
39.1
30.5
50.7
42.3
29.8
48.8
44.3
3.9
2.7
100
7.1
4.7
100
14.2
4.6
100
16.1
5.3
100
US$ billion
514
686
1,684
2,730
Source: computed from UNCTAD 1996: 245±8.
Notes: The shares for the European Community and later European Union (EU) cover
only the member states at the time. The new members Spain and Portugal added 0.9 per
cent to the 1990 ®gures, and the new members Sweden, Finland and Austria added 3.25
per cent. The `Four Tigers' are Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea and Taiwan.
Union. The share ®gures for the European Union are thus not exactly
comparable to the ones for Japan and the United States, since owning
stocks in France in the case of a Dutch transnational corporation does
not mean overcoming the same obstacles as owning similar stock there
for a Japanese or US company. Figures for intra-EU `foreign' direct
investment by European transnational corporations are very dif®cult to
obtain (see United Nations 1993), but rough estimates for the years
between 1975 and 1985 suggest that 21 per cent of the total foreign
direct investment ¯ows to the European Community originated from
transnational corporations headquartered in the European Community
itself (United Nations 1993: 48f ). If these ®gures are correct, they reveal
the astonishing fact that intra-EC foreign direct investment has been
much lower than intra-EC trade, which according to easily available
standard sources was slightly higher than 50 per cent around 1980. This
would suggest that until the completion of the internal market in 1992,
which was legislated by the Single European Act, the barriers to investment were more substantial than the barriers to trade. And, looking at it
from the perspective of the early 1980s, only after eliminating the many
non-tariff barriers and the creation of common governance for doing
business in the European Community would European transnational
corporations achieve stronger economies of scale, which would trigger
many cross-border acquisitions and foreign direct investment. This is
24
State-building and political entrepreneurship
what the Single Market, which came into effect in 1993, made possible.
One important implication of this is that, in terms of building up a
stronger home base beyond the nation-state, i.e. by taking advantage of
economies of scale and common economically relevant governance in a
truly integrated market, deregulation within the European Community
must have been among the prime interests of the European transnational
business.
Big shots and small fry among the transnational corporations
The second argument for why the aggregated EU ®gures of its share in
the world stock of foreign direct investment do not tell the whole story
relates to the size of transnational corporations. In the mid-1990s,
almost 40,000 transnational corporations were doing business around
the world through their almost 270,000 foreign subsidiaries. Compared
with the ®gures for 1968 this is a big increase (Bornschier and ChaseDunn 1999: 295, table 14.1). Yet, most of these TNCs are comparatively small fry. Let us therefore consider the big shots ± the group of the
world's 100 largest transnational corporations.
In 1992, these 100 largest transnationals held about US$3.4 trillion in
global assets. We need to stress here that even these big shots of the
world economy have a strong home base, since on the average `only'
about 40 per cent of their global assets are outside their home countries
(®gures from UNCTAD 1994: xxi). From the ®gures in this source we
can estimate that the largest 100 transnationals had average global assets
of US$34 billion and an average foreign asset ± i.e. outside their home
country ± of US$13.6 billion. Compared with average foreign assets of
only US$57 million in the whole universe of the transnational corporations, this is one indication of the enormous concentration and huge
differences in size.
Let us now, in table 1.3, turn to the distribution of the largest 100
transnationals according to home base and average assets. Among the
largest 100, the numerical shares of economic transnationals headquartered in the United States, Japan and the European Union correspond
well with the respective shares in the total world stock of foreign direct
investment. What is striking in table 1.3 are the differences in average
size according to global assets ± both in the home country and abroad.
Among the 100 largest transnationals, those headquartered in the
United States and Japan are huge on the average, and the average assets
of Japanese transnationals equal those of the US transnationals. The
TNCs from the European Union, however, are on the average only half
Western Europe's move toward political union
25
Table 1.3. The distribution of the world's 100 largest transnational
corporations (TNCs) according to home base and average global assets, 1992
Home base
European Union
United States
Japan
Switzerland
Canada
Other
Number
of TNCs
Average assets at
home and abroad
(US$ billion)
43
29
16
25.4
46.6
46.4
6
3
3
19.7
9.9
14.1
Source: Computed from UNCTAD 1994: 6±8.
Notes: The top 100 are selected from the universe of 39,000 TNCs according to the
absolute size of their foreign assets. Membership in the EU as of 1 January 1995. `Other':
one each headquartered in Norway, Australia, and New Zealand.
the size of their counterparts in the triad. We can conclude that, among
the big shots of the world economy at the beginning of the 1990s, the
Europeans were comparatively weak, at least on average and in terms of
assets. This evidences a big motive at the beginning of intensi®ed world
economic competition: to look for a change by aspiring to economies of
scale and protection in a greater European area.
Processes in the world political economy
The political and economic spheres are necessarily linked in the world.
This is why political and economic entrepreneurs have to bargain to
come to terms. States in the market economy cannot prosper without
enterprises, which for their part need state services and protection.
Elsewhere, we have explained and analysed the underlying theoretical
ideas in more detail (see Bornschier 1988: ch. 14; 1996: ch. 3).
The world market for protection argument is inspired by the work of
Max Weber, Otto Hintze and Frederic C. Lane, and emphasizes that
social order, also termed protection, is a territorially bounded public
utility. Production, trade and ®nancial transactions are conditional upon
social prerequisites; they require protection. Property rights must be
respected and people have to be motivated or forced to engage in
exchange relationships. Protection is by no means a secondary factor
of production, but is at least as important as labour, knowledge,
organizational resources, ®nancial means and credit. In our perspective,
26
State-building and political entrepreneurship
protection is a neglected element of national economic production
functions; it represents social capital provided and maintained by states.
Governments, which can be understood as political undertakings,
produce `order' and sell this public utility to capitalist enterprises as well
as to the citizens under their rule. By means of supplying this utility,
governments affect the locational quality of their territory in the framework of the world economy.
One important implication of this is that states engage not only in
politico-military competition, but also in genuinely economic competition within this world market for social order. This is the case not only
because capital and labour are to a certain extent mobile among states,
but also because different social orders imply varying degrees of longterm economic success. Governments normally react quite sensitively to
this world market for social order. In an attempt to keep their political
and military equilibrium they are forced to produce the political preconditions for economic success. If they fail or perform only unsatisfactorily, they can neither attain nor preserve core status in the world
economy.
In order to understand the basic argument better let us emphasize
that protection, although politically created, shares certain characteristics with land, insofar as it is also territorially bounded. The implications
of this theory can be stated from the point of view of states or capitalist
®rms: ®rst, those states will be the strongest that provide effective
protection conducive to innovation and investment at a cost that is
worth the services; secondly, those capitalist ®rms will prosper the most
that can choose or are fortunately placed in a network of economic
transactions effectively protected, again at a price worth the services.
Advantages thus accrue to both sides: higher returns due to effective
protection provide competitive edge for capitalists and enhance their
accumulation, while higher returns due to more taxable income when
enterprises prosper also provide a larger resource base for the state. We
stress that in our theory it is not the capitalist state per se that is most
favourable to economic success, but any state that reconciles capitalist
pro®t logic with claims to legitimacy among citizens, based on demands
for security, equality and ef®ciency. Although legitimacy is attached to a
social order, we suggest that its enduring effect rests not on ideology but
on features of the social structure that re¯ect the meeting of such
demands.
Having at least brie¯y presented all the elements we wish to use for
the generation of hypotheses, we move now to an explication of the
latter.
Western Europe's move toward political union
27
Explanations for the integrational thrust
The accelerated integration of Europe has spurred an intense scholarly
debate (Sandholtz and Zysman 1989; Moravcsik 1991; Cameron 1992;
George 1993; Bornschier 1994; Green Cowles 1995; Robinson 1995;
Fielder 1997; Ziltener 1999); and Moravcsik's (1998, 1999) most
recent, respectable contributions are aimed not at closing but at
renewing the debate over the fundamental causes of European integration. Here, we propose to mention only very brie¯y the controversy
between neofunctionalists and neorealists in the political science
debates to clarify the particularities of our own approach.
Neofunctionalism and neorealism
The analysis of West European integration has revived the old controversy between neofunctionalists and neorealists (George 1991: 20±4),
while some contributions represent a combination of perspectives
(George 1992, 1993; Cameron 1992).
The central idea behind neofunctionalism is that of a `spillover', and
here a distinction is made between `political spillover' and `functional
spillover'. Functional spillover pertains to the dynamics that occur when
states decide to integrate certain economic sectors, forcing them to
integrate further sectors in order for the integration of the ®rst to
succeed. These dynamics are seen as resulting from the interdependence
of economic sectors. Political spillover is the result of a new political
reality in connection with the shift of political decisions from the
national to the supranational level. As decisions are now made at the
supranational level, relevant interest groups and other political actors
shift their lobbying to the supranational level to in¯uence the decisionmaking process. Those interest groups that bene®t from integration
then start pressuring their national governments into shifting ever more
political functions to the supranational level. According to neofunctionalist theory, both spillover processes should be spontaneous and incremental because they result from the internal logic of integration. They
not only occur in the lower realms of politics, but move from these
technical areas to higher political ®elds of state sovereignty such as
defence, security and currency.
Neorealists, on the other hand, believe that because governments
have been elected by the people, and therefore have legitimized power,
they remain the truly signi®cant actors in the integration process and
defend national interests. Neorealists do not believe that a spillover from
low to high politics will occur. Defence, security and currency, which
28
State-building and political entrepreneurship
represent the essence of state sovereignty, will remain excluded from the
integration process. Yet, the neorealists see the power structure in the
overarching and global context as an important element reactively
in¯uencing states' decisions.
Neorealist explanations of this kind have various weaknesses, which
stem from the fact that these perspectives regard nation-states as the
only relevant actors and take too narrow a view of government motives.
Neofunctionalism, on the other side, has too limited an understanding
of transnational actors, and neglects the possibly far-reaching initiatives
stemming from them.
Transnational corporations in search of a political entrepreneur
The theoretical perspective advanced earlier may overcome some of the
theoretical limitations resulting from an approach centred on policy. As
already mentioned, two kinds of `enterprises' are relevant for the
processes in the world economy: states and ®rms. Thus, a framework is
suggested that integrates supply of, and demand for, order. Together
with the rise and decay of societal models, this approach seems
promising, especially when we focus on questions of timing and of the
protagonists behind the relaunch of European integration in the 1980s.
According to our argument, states compete with each other not only
in a politico-military sense ± the classical form of their competition ± but
also in the framework of the world economy, essentially mediated by the
production factor of social order guaranteed by the state. Thus, states
also compete in a genuinely economic way and, in addition, they are
forced to re-create, improve, or qualitatively reorganize interstate
regulatory mechanisms in case they should break down or prove
insuf®cient.
The idea of competition for protection on the world market enriches
the theoretical apparatus in one important respect. The economic
motives of political undertakings ± even more, the view thus implied
that states are producers of economically valuable goods ± become
important. Such motives are added to the classic ones of security and
power politics. In this our perspective differs from the neorealist
approach. It also differs from neofunctionalism because the economic
motives of state actors become predominant when the world economy
is central to status distribution and when transnational corporations
increasingly force states to compete with each other as sites of economic
activity.
If we start from the competition of political entities supplying order
and economic enterprises demanding order, it is easy to assume similar
Western Europe's move toward political union
29
strategies for states and economic enterprises. While competing they
may cooperate, build strategic alliances or even merge. Contrary to the
neofunctionalist argument, such processes are not automatic results of
internal spillovers; rather, they are primarily generated by the competitive conditions of the world political economy. Such strategic alliances
or even mergers are much more likely to happen ± or may only be
possible ± if supranational institutional preconditions are met and
available for political entrepreneurship. This was the case with the
European Commission, whose independent role was stipulated at its
inception in 1958.
Our theoretical perspective thus differs in important respects from the
functionalist and realist theories of international relations. The argument from the theory of protection rent is as follows. European transnational corporations asked the political entrepreneurs in Europe to
provide them with the locational advantages their rivals were enjoying in
the United States and Japan. This demand stimulated the negotiation of
a new state project along the lines of a wide homogeneous market
combined with strategic planning, particularly with regard to the ever
more important production factor of technology.
This project was forged in the informal European Roundtable of
Industrialists (ERT). With his paper `Agenda for Action: Europe 1990',
Wisse Dekker, a central ®gure in the ERT, created an important
conceptual basis for the White Paper authored by the Commission's
Lord Cock®eld. The EC Commission acted as a political entrepreneur,
launched and popularized the project, overcame the resistance of governments, and submitted it to the Council for decision. The Commission's own motives and interests are discussed brie¯y below.
It should be made clear that it was not European businesses as such
that pushed the project, since most of them took advantage of national
protection within the early phase of the European Community, when
non-tariff barriers to trade and many restrictions on investment and
national monopolies still prevailed. Thus it was also not the European
business associations, which already existed at the Community level and
represented numerous enterprises, but rather the transnational
European business elite, with their considerable business stakes outside
their headquarter countries, who were pushing to have the same opportunities as their global competitors by broadening their home base
(allowing for greater economies of scale) and by getting support from
strategic technology policy. This is not to suggest a conspiracy theory of
European integration, since the position of European big business as
represented in the European Roundtable was overtly clear and publicly
stated. This becomes evident from the ®rst Policy Memorandum of the
30
State-building and political entrepreneurship
European Roundtable of Industrialists, which was of®cially transmitted
to the Commission in 1983:
Despite the efforts of the European Community to liberalize trade, Europe
remains divided into national markets with different industrial structures. This
prevents many enterprises from reaching the size necessary to withstand the
pressure of competition from non-European concerns. But the European
market must serve as a single `home base' so that European ®rms can develop
into powerful competitors on world markets. (Niggli 1989: 167)
This is not to say that all other business was against the project, but the
others were fragmented in terms of interest and on average rather
neutral; some would gain, some would lose. This divided position
contrasts with that of the European transnational corporations, all of
which were on the winning side and had the resources to take advantage
of the new possibilities.
Furthermore, our explanation does not completely neglect the political entrepreneurs of the existing nation-states in the Community. On
the average, however, they needed to be pushed hard ± a process that
actually took many years (see also chapter 3), since their national
constituencies were diverse in terms of winners and losers created by
deregulation. Thus with respect to political entrepreneurs in Europe,
our hypothesis is very clear: in the end it was the transnational level that
was decisive.
Discussion
Our hypotheses were truly ex ante ones that needed to be tested
empirically, and the remaining chapters in this volume explain what we
have gathered in terms of detailed evidence, from which readers may
draw their own conclusions. Yet, we must admit that we were aware of
the ®ne and inspiring work of Sandholtz and Zysman (1989) when we
started studying the qualitative change of European integration in 1991.
They had already pointed to changes in the world economy as necessary
factors for the revitalization of the European integration project.
Drawing on our own previous research in other ®elds, we extended and
re®ned this approach to European integration.
What happened in the world political economy during the decisive
years we mentioned? For decades Europe had ceased to be the centre of
the world political economy. After the `civil war' of 1914±18, the
European powers had to relinquish this role to the United States, which
actually assumed it only after the Second World War. The European
powers took their place behind the United States after the Second
World War and were startled when, owing to the hegemonic decline of
Western Europe's move toward political union
31
the United States since the end of the 1960s, the previous stability of the
world economic structure was no longer guaranteed and the impressive
rise of Japan thrust Europe into third place in the world.
This perspective has been linked to the interests of the European
transnational corporations. The competitive disadvantages of Europe as
an industrial site were ®rst directly felt and articulated by the European
transnational corporations. After the economic crisis of the 1970s, the
United States and particularly Japan recovered much more easily than a
Europe immobilized by `Eurosclerosis' ± a term coined by American
observers. The United States, despite its loss of competitiveness, was
able to take advantage of its own huge and rather homogeneous internal
market; and Japan enjoyed the advantage of its elaborate strategic
planning, which had been essential for Japan's extraordinary rise for
decades. It was the (certainly mild and ¯exible) `planned economy', tied
indeed to capitalistically inspired business and oriented to long-term
strategic goals that made Japan big, without being laissez-faire.
The other pressure for Europe's revival concerns the cyclical
dynamics of societal models. The Western societal model disintegrated
towards the end of the 1970s. Former hegemonic normative theories
such as Keynesianism were replaced by monetarist and supply-side
oriented ones after the world summit in Bonn in 1978. In 1982 the new
doctrine was anchored in the Organization for Economic Cooperation
and Development (OECD) paradigm for a new economic policy of the
Western world. The technological style, characterized by Fordist mass
production, reached its limits, and the political shifts at the turn of the
1980s destroyed the unquestioned position of former politico-economic
regimes in the postwar era. In terms of this approach, recasting the
European Community can be explained as a move towards a renewed
European societal model, a remarkable innovation in terms of European
history. Many statements by Commissioners support such a view, for
example: `Truly `1992' will mean a transformation of society. Mentalities and habits will change. Everywhere the key players in the economy
realize that the future lies in the fullest sense in Europe' (Karel van
Miert, Member of the European Commission, quoted in CEC 1992: 8).
Recently, key EC publications can even be found using one of our
central terms (Bornschier 1988, 1996). The White Paper of December
1993 declares: `The new model of European society calls for less passive
and more active solidarity' (CEU 1993: 15, emphasis added).
The relative decline of the hegemon
We have mentioned the relative losses of the economic position of the
United States in the 1970s and 1980s. But hegemony also has an
32
State-building and political entrepreneurship
important institutional dimension. In this view, the relaunch of the
European Community must also be seen as an answer to contradictions
inherent in the interventionist role of the state ± a cornerstone of the
neocorporatist-Keynesian societal model. Economic interventions are
free of major interstate con¯icts only if they are embedded in, and
curbed by, international regimes.
One important pillar of this coordination was the US dollar±gold
exchange regime of Bretton Woods. In 1971, the United States, which
had established this system, was no longer in a position to defend the
dollar. From an institutional viewpoint, the hegemonic power of the
USA was abdicated at the moment when it gave up the exchange
system that it had created by `suspending' its obligation to maintain
the US dollar±gold parity. By 1973, as the European countries were
forced to switch to ¯oating rates, the system of ®xed exchange rates
completely broke apart, and the discipline of coordinating economic
policies no longer existed. The important, even irreplaceable linkage
had broken, because ± as hegemonic stability theory would argue ± no
country was in a position or willing to guarantee the international
exchange system. The hegemonic crisis of the United States and the
disintegration of the societal model, which depended on interstate
coordination of economic policy, are mutually linked. Both factors
work together to explain the integrational momentum of the European
Community in the 1980s.
We consider as a suf®cient explanation, however, the alliance of
European transnational economic and political entrepreneurs at the
supranational level to ensure Europe's economic position in the world
by strengthening the home base and thus to guarantee Europe's future
prosperity. Both interests were easy to put together since in this respect
they were indeed congruent. Our explanation proposes to answer the
question: who were the actors, who gave the impulse for the relaunch?
By pointing to an elite bargain between the two classes of European elite
± transnational and supranational ± we do not imply that these two were
decisive for other aspects of European integration. The formal role of
the Commission, as spelled out in the treaties, may vary in its effectiveness. Before the 1980s the Commission was not always a strong actor in
European politics, and in the 1990s this situation is again similar. Once
the project was successful, the European transnational elite turned
instead to normal interest-group politics, albeit within a new institutional setting. The Roundtable is still active and has even expanded its
membership over time, but it does not seem to be in¯uencing further
European state-building ± although it has a big stake in moulding
concrete policies within the framework achieved.
Western Europe's move toward political union
33
The interests of the Commission itself and the signi®cance of
citizens
So much for the origins of the elite pact. Apart from `more market and
strategic planning of technology', shaping solidarity and cohesion was a
cornerstone of the Single European Act from the beginning. Indeed, it
was Delors' project to supplement `more market in the community' ±
the European approach to a socially embedded deregulation ± with, in
his words, an `espace europeÂen organiseÂ'. The welfare state, which
offered a base of equal life chances for its citizens, has been a speci®cally
West European strength during the postwar era. Delors explicitly used
this as a building block of the renewed European societal model. It is
clearly embedded in the normative theories (see chapters 5 and 6). To
be sure, the emphasis on this in the Single European Act and even in the
later Treaty on European Union remained limited. This may be
explained as a tactical choice. But the substantial increase in ®nancial
endowments of the regional funds in 1988 and the cohesion fund
created by the Maastricht Treaty are evidence of a novel, supranational
approach towards equalizing life chances within Western Europe.
Although we have argued that the Commission took up the demand
by transnationals for a larger market and greater strategic planning, we
do not wish to promote the false impression that the Commission was
acting only as an overall agent for the European transnationals ± as the
agent for the transnational European capitalist class ± and had no
interest itself in the launching of a project that included more than mere
national deregulation and quasi-corporatist steps to advance technology.
Enlightened state-builders most probably know from European history
that successful state projects always take better care of the interests of
citizens, compared with their less successful competitors. Delors knew
that too, and it coincided with the interests of the supranational political
entrepreneur.
Political entities and their representatives must legitimize themselves.
In this respect, the situation of the EC Commission is very precarious.
Even if the European Parliament was somewhat strengthened by the
Single European Act, normal democratic legitimization is still achieved
only indirectly through the democratically appointed and controlled
representatives of the member states in the Council. This situation, even
before the Single European Act, weakened the Commission as it
simultaneously strengthened the Council. As a result, the political
ambitions of the Commission were blocked. However, at an earlier
point the Commission began, through opinion polls, to make direct
contact with the citizens of the European Community to ®nd out their
views on political questions. Under the auspices of the Commission, a
34
State-building and political entrepreneurship
biannual survey of the opinions of EU citizens has been conducted since
the early 1970s ± the so-called Eurobarometer studies.
As an improvised substitute for the weak representation of the
European population, this polling of opinions by way of the Eurobarometer has a considerable political function for the Commission insofar as
it endeavours to legitimize its policies by reference to popular acceptance
of the Community project. However, at the end of the 1970s and
beginning of the 1980s, support for the European Community sank to a
long-term low and remained there until 1984 (see Bornschier 1996:
366). At the end of this period in which `Eurosclerosis' was re¯ected in
the mood of the public, the new Delors Commission began to make the
project to rebuild Europe more palatable to citizens. Since then, Delors
has made `Europe '92: The Social Community' his political platform:
`More social equality in Europe ± a lively and humane society, is what
the EC is seeking for its 340 million members' (CEC 1992: 2).
After launching the political package, which included not only the
interests of the European transnationals but also the Commission's
quest for legitimacy ± i.e. a larger market, strategic planning and social
cohesion and convergence ± and which was then formalized in the
Single European Act, public support among the citizens of the Community increased sharply after 1985 until the early 1990s, as the poll
results show (see Bornschier 1996: 366; Sandholtz 1993: 22). Without a
doubt, the social dimension is the weakest part in the new political
package of the 1980s ± partially owing to the resistance of some member
countries, particularly the United Kingdom.
Final remarks on competing explanations
The emphasis in our explanation is on the timing of events and the
protagonists relevant for Europe's move toward political union in the
mid-1980s. As the 1980s dawned, certain constellations became apparent. The Western societal model had decayed during the 1970s, and
the hegemon was no longer able to guarantee stability. Europe was
confronted with Japan's success in mastering the world economic crisis
on the one hand, and challenged by America's experiment under
President Reagan to defend its world economic position on the other. At
this juncture, the `demand' of transnational European business and the
`supply' of the supranational EC Commission met and provided the
impetus for a relaunch of integration, by renewing the European societal
model to create the conditions for post-hegemonic competition in the
world economy.
Our explanation for the rebuilding of Western Europe is somewhat
Western Europe's move toward political union
35
similar to the explanation advanced by Sandholtz and Zysman (1989)
and can also be brought into line with Stephen George's (1993) idea of
the linkage of supranational and national levels. Of course, the
European transnationals not only exerted in¯uence on the Commission
but were also mediated by national governments, which were thus
forced to take up the case of the Commission. But we maintain that the
supranational link was clearly more in¯uential.
Our perspective is, however, in clear contradiction to Andrew Moravcsik's (1991) purely neorealist explanation. He claims that the Single
European Act can be explained as the playing out of the national
interests of the three big member states: Germany, France and Britain.
In what amounts to a sort of game theory explanation, the three big
states are seen to have converged on the lowest common denominator of
their national preferences. This view stresses that the heads of government and their direct representatives took the lead in the negotiations
and produced the breakthrough that is represented by the Single
European Act (SEA). The substantial difference between his and our
theoretical positions has become evident from this chapter. On an issuespeci®c level, one of the core empirical questions is thus whether the
governments of the big countries took the lead via the EC Council of
Ministers (intergovernmental institutionalism) as Moravcsik originally
maintained, or whether this role was played by the transnationals
together with the EC Commission (transnational and supranational
institutionalism), as we maintain. Figure 1.1 not only schematically
summarizes our arguments but also lists the competing hypothesis.
Recently, however, Moravcsik (1998, 1999) has changed his position, at
least with regard to the supranational and transnational intervention
that pushed the Single European Act of 1985. He concedes the supranational and transnational in¯uence and acknowledges that the `highly
technical ``package deal'' [of the SEA was] backed by a new, transnational constituency of multinational ®rms' and `supranational entrepreneurs had a signi®cant, if still decidedly secondary, in¯uence on the
SEA' (Moravcsik 1999: 285, 292).
Not at all in dispute, however, is the extraordinary signi®cance of the
thrust toward a new beginning in the mid-1980s, which continued with
the Maastricht Treaty on European Union, by which time European
integration had become more controversial among the European public.
Some thoughts about why this is so will follow at the end of this volume
(see also Anderson 1995a: 451). In any case, Europe is on the move;
although struggling with the problem of unemployment, it looks toward
the future and articulates nothing less than `the new model of European
society'.
Figure 1.1 The genesis of the Single European Act
Legend:
a,b,c,d Causal factors and mechanisms
I, II, III Social actors
A,B
Central institutions of the European Community along with the European Parliament and the European Court
of Justice, as de®ned by the Treaties of 1957 and 1965.
DV
Dependent variable: the Single European Act (1986), a restructuring, deepening and widening of the
European Community.
Comments:
1. According to EC law the ®nal resolution on the Single European Act can only be passed by the Council. This is not a
point of debate. It is the path to the ®nal agreement on which the various authors differ.
.
Elite Bargain
.
Alternative Elite Bargain
(a,b,c,d) -> I -> A -> B -> DV (Single European Act)
`transnational networks & supranational institutionalism'
II (mainly the `big three': F, GB, FRG) -> B -> DV (Single European Act)
`intergovernmental institutionalism'
2. The population of the European Community (III) in¯uences the process indirectly via the elections of the respective
governments and through the Eurobarometer surveys.
2
Tying up the Luxembourg package of 1985:
prerequisites and problems of its constitution
Patrick Ziltener
`L'initiative vient toujours d'en haut!'
FreÂdeÂric Moreau in Flaubert's Education sentimentale
A considerable part of the debate on the reasons for the integration
thrust in the 1980s is based on the not always precise differentiation
between statements on the origins of political initiatives, the corresponding agenda setting, the mediation of interests and thus the transformation of the initiative and its adoption. This is shown with the often
undifferentiated use of the terms `1992 Initiative', `EC reform', `Single
European Act' (SEA), etc. Furthermore, the origins of political initiatives and the prerequisites for their success (or failure) are often
imprecisely distinguished from each other. This chapter chronologically
and logically follows chapter 1 in that it reconstructs the process of the
construction of a successful package deal, the Luxembourg package, by
making reference to the analysis of the causal factors of the integration
relaunch. The Luxembourg package 1 is hereby de®ned as the entirety of
the agreements on the insertion or amendment of articles in the EC
treaties, as they were formulated during the intergovernmental conference in 1985, which together form the Single Act and which were
adopted by the Council of Ministers in 1986.
The ®rst section presents some theoretical considerations on the
conditions for success of a package deal. The following section describes
important integration projects and processes for forming alliances. The
®rst six months in 1984 are seen as the `take-off' phase for the SEA.
1
The Luxembourg package must not be confused with the so-called Luxembourg
Compromise, the informal regulation enforced by De Gaulle during the integration
crisis in 1965/6. According to this regulation, each government has a right to veto in the
case of `vital national interests'. This agreement enforced the principle of unanimous
decision in the Council of Ministers and was therefore of major importance for the
institutional blockades of the EEC in the following years. An actual veto culture emerged
(Teasdale 1993). The Commission and the European Court of Justice never accepted
this regulation. On the connection between the Luxembourg Compromise and the SEA,
see chapter 9.
38
Tying up the Luxembourg package
39
The Commission's changing role, its actual `rebirth' as a result of an
altered situation and as a precondition for the creation of a negotiation
package, is then discussed. The SEA being such a heterogeneous treaty,
the question of `authorship' can hardly be answered in globo in a sensible
way. To answer the question, the Luxembourg package has to be
deconstructed into its different elements. I therefore present an overview
of the origins of the different elements of the SEA and the logic of the
entire Luxembourg package.
On integration projects and the prerequisites for their
success
The strongest arguments for an intergovernmentalist explanation can
inevitably be found in the analysis of the negotiations at an intergovernmental conference, which is the prerequisite for a change in the
EU treaties. In such a process it becomes very clear that the national
governments are still the strongest actors in the political system at the
European level. It is hardly contestable that they view the EU through
the lens of their own policy preferences and that they try to ensure that
negotiation outcomes are as close as possible to what they perceive to be
their respective national interests.2 However, it can also be argued that
an intergovernmental approach cannot adequately explain the result of
an intergovernmental conference. Below, in marked contrast to neorealism and other theoretical approaches, we conceptualize some theoretical constructs that can be used as the theoretical framework proposed
here for the analysis of the process that we refer to as `tying up the
Luxembourg package'.
National, transnational and supranational actors have different normative ideas on the desired aims of the European integration process and the
necessary, appropriate and possible means for their realization. In the
following, the entirety of these normative ideas of a collective actor on
aims and means is de®ned as the actor's integration project. An integration
project need not be coherent and without contradictions, and in most
cases it is not. It can be changed not only, as in the case of the member
states, as a result of change of government, but also as a result of a change
of policy preferences, shifts in the underlying interest structure, experiences from strategic policy, altered external pressure and/or altered
reception of this pressure, etc. Therefore, integration projects are always
concrete and historically determined. They result from compromises
2
To Moravcsik (1991: 25), `EC politics is the continuation of domestic policies by other
means'. For the following, see also Sandholtz (1993: 3), Pierson and Leibfried (1995),
H. Wallace (1996a,b), W. Wallace (1996).
40
State-building and political entrepreneurship
between different interests. Several parties can agree on a joint integration
project. In this chapter, several integration projects will be described: the
federalist projects, the change in French European policy, and the project
of the Delors Commission and its in¯uence on the Luxembourg package.
In studying the development of the European integration process in
its different stages, analytical essays and statements by the parties
concerned very soon reveal the decisive importance of so-called package
deals. Typical conditions for the development of package solutions are
negotiation systems with a pluralist structure of interests, with several
parties that are more or less equal with respect to organizational
resources. On the EU level, such negotiation packages gain a speci®c
relevance, mainly owing to institutional particularities, especially the
dominant position of the member states' governments. The unanimity
principle in the Council of Ministers ± which was the normal case up to
the SEA and still dominates in many policy areas ± makes political
barter (logrolling ) inevitable. This especially applies to changing the
treaties at intergovernmental conferences.
The following conditions must be ful®lled so that a negotiation
package ready for adoption can be constituted:
(1) As a prerequisite, the integration projects of the actors involved
must contain common elements that could form the core of such a
package. This requires relatively convergent political orientations.
(2) A party is necessary that not only suggests initiatives, but also
carries out the strategic focusing and mediation of interests and
elaborates compromise wordings that the majority can accept
( political entrepreneurship). A successful package needs to be supported by an alliance of several parties (non-hegemonic cooperation).
(3) Dynamizing factors: ®rst, there need to be institutional and/or
informal procedures at several levels that prevent blockade strategies
or at least impede them, secondly, a package solution is a temporary
compromise, a balance of powers in ¯ux, which is agreed to only in
consideration of expected developments.
These points are elaborated below.
Relative convergence
Relative convergence in the perception of the actual challenges and
problems and of basic policy orientations, especially of national
economic policies, is a necessary, but not a suf®cient, condition for an
integration thrust.3 Relative convergence does not at all mean an
3
The importance of relative convergence as a prerequisite for an integration process is
commonly accepted. For Moravcsik (1991: 21; 1998: ch. 5), an `essential precondition
Tying up the Luxembourg package
41
`identity of interests'; rather it means an increasing overlapping of the
concepts of content, means and range of state regulation. This is the
precondition for the de®nition of one or more core projects of common
interest. These have to be so important within the framework of the
entire political and economic concept of the parties involved that they
are prepared to accept the elements of the compromise that are undesirable from their point of view ± the costs of reaching the aim.
In his evaluation of the possibilities for a relance europeÂenne (European
relaunch) at the beginning of the 1980s, Hrbek (1982: 16) noted that
the deepening of the Community requires `a certain amount of homogeneity or at least visible convergence of basic positions, of conceptions
of aims and means including the priorities which need to be considered'.
This was de®nitely not the case in 1982 and it did not seem to be likely
in the near future. Several developments changed this in the two
following years. Of central importance was the series of changes of
government in the EC states toward conservative governments or
government coalitions dominated by conservatives (see Cameron 1992:
56ff; Jones 1993). The end of the socialist/communist government in
France in 1983, in which Jacques Delors4 was minister for economic
affairs, was also the end of the last attempt in Europe to revive the
Keynesian societal model.5 From 1983 onwards, economic policy
orientations were relatively convergent in Western Europe, heading
4
5
for reform was the convergence of economic policy prescriptions of ruling party
coalitions'. For Cameron (1992: 58f ), the general `rightward shift in the ideological
center of gravity' greatly facilitated the development of `an initiative that, above all,
sought to create a market free of the intrusions and obstacles erected by interventionist
governments'. See also Sandholtz and Zysman (1989: 108ff ).
Delors' role in this change is illuminated by the fact that the adopted austerity and
stabilization plan carried his name. There are good arguments for Moravcsik's
(1998: 373) claim that `it may well be that Delors' action as ®nance minister of France
contributed as much to the SEA as did his actions as president of the Commission'.
All political actors estimate that the political changes in France had a large in¯uence on
the integration process. Etienne Davignon (EC Commissioner until 1984) replies to the
question of why the integration thrust started in 1985/6: `a number of things had
appeared. One was the total failure of national measures to deal with the economic
crisis. The clearest example of that was the failure of the re¯ation policy of the Mauroy
government after the change of majority in France, after Monsieur Mitterrand won the
election; basically it was all to the advantage of the neighbours of France, who exported
more into France, and in no way to the advantage of French producers. Measures of a
national nature taken to try to improve employment, did not work, sectoral measures
did not work, it appeared that what was needed was something at a European level'
(interview on 6 April 1993). According to Karl-Heinz Narjes (EC Commissioner
1981±88), too, the big thrust for the Single Market became possible only after the
French government under Mitterrand `left its course of national, socialist economic
policy' in 1982/3 (in an interview with Der Spiegel, No. 1, January 1989). To VeÂdrine
(1996: 286), Mitterrand's European policy from 1984 to 1992 was inconceivable
without the austerity measures (rigueur), without which the French±German tandem
would not have functioned.
42
State-building and political entrepreneurship
toward austerity (see Uterwedde 1988: 189). This does not mean that
there were no more policy differences between national strategies in
Western Europe. The political spectrum from Thatcherist policy to
socialist modernization policy in France remained broad and this
caused the majority of the disputes during the integration relaunch of
the 1980s.
As a further prerequisite, a positive reference to the `European
level', to the institutions of the Community, is needed within the
framework of convergent strategies. For a long time, this was missing
in the case of the French socialists and the British Labour Party, since
the EC was perceived more as part of the problem than as part of the
solution. Even after the re-orientation of the French socialists in their
European policy, a certain caution towards the Community institutions remained for some time. The EUREKA project, an initiative by
the French government that was more multilateral than supranational,
proves this.
Political entrepreneurship
Given the de®nition of one or several core projects, the `®ne tuning'
starts: the package has to be tied. Institutional questions and procedural
modalities have to be solved. On the basis of its power in steering the
political process at European level, the Commission was successfully
able to use its role as political entrepreneur to promote its integration
project again and again.
The initiative function of the Commission as a `constitutional
assignment' has already been pointed out in chapter 1. Another
important point when de®ning political entrepreneurship is the
`ambition' of the half-yearly changing Council presidencies. These have
important functions for pushing or delaying certain dossiers, as is
especially evident in social policy (chapter 6). This de®nitely applies to
intergovernmental conferences, where the country with the presidency
ful®ls a strategically important function concerning the formulation of
mediatory compromises.
The main question is the implementation of majority decisions in the
Council of Ministers, since this implies that the `reinsurance' of the
national governments is either given up or preserved, i.e. the possibility
of blockading further integration dynamics. Resistance to integration
has to be cleared, with side payments and/or exemption regulations
(safeguard clauses, opting out, etc). Package solutions are based on
political logrolling. Hubert VeÂdrine, Mitterrand's adviser, describes
how each political initiative is linked to consideration of which
Tying up the Luxembourg package
43
exchanges could be tied to it. These can even reach beyond the EU
framework.6
In contrast to the neorealist approach, we hold that package solutions
are complicated negotiation results that do not have to be based on the
lowest common denominator. Acceptance depends much more on the
perception of a `well-balanced outcome' by all parties. At the least, the
costs must not exceed the expected advantages in consideration of the
further development of integration. In comparison with international
regimes, owing to the level of integration already achieved, withdrawing
participation in the integration process is tied to much higher costs.
Therefore, parties whose interests have not been considered
`adequately' tend to demand far-reaching exemption regulations that
allow an opting out with regard to further integration steps rather than
leave the EU.
Non-hegemonic cooperation
The European integration process is based on non-hegemonic cooperation, because no state can enforce further progress as a result of its
power resources and/or institutional position (see Moravcsik 1991: 25).
Therefore, each integration step requires an alliance of several states.
History has shown several times, however, that it has never been
possible to carry out such an integration project without or against the
countries that are politically at the centre of European integration,
especially Germany and France.7 This is an unwritten European
`constitutional reality' which is strongly embedded in the consciousness
and strategic calculations of the actors, as many interviews have
shown.
Nevertheless, the smaller states are by no means a quantite neÂgligeable,
i.e. politically negligible factors. The EU's decision-making system
partially compensates for real inequality with formal equality. Several
smaller states can `pool' their political weight and, combined with their
aggregated authority in the decision-making process, they can maximize
their in¯uence. The Benelux countries have often done this and continue to do so. However, the relative smallness of member states seldom
leads to a common interest or even an integration project; this is only
6
7
VeÂdrine (1996: 283): `Ces eÂchanges ne se limitent pas, en effet, au seul champ
communautaire: la France est presque toujours engageÂe ailleurs au meÃme moment ± au
Conseil de SeÂcuriteÂ, dans la preÂparation du prochain sommet des Sept, par exemple ±,
dans d'autres neÂgociations ouÁ elle peut avoir besoin de tel ou tel de ses partenaires
europeÂens.'
The same applied to questions concerning the budget: nothing could be adopted against
the will of the two net payers (until 1985), Germany and the United Kingdom.
44
State-building and political entrepreneurship
likely to happen when discussing rules of procedure. Alliances between
states with similar structural conditions, as well as similar political and
economic interests, independent of their relative size, are much more
frequent. In the case of monetary policy at the intergovernmental
conference in 1985, Belgium joined France in demanding an expansion
of EC competences, whereas the Netherlands, being a country with a
strong currency, tended to favour Germany's position.
Dynamizing factors
The most neglected factor in explaining the integration thrust of the
1980s is the one that Delors called `dynamics'. This means not the
spillover effects that the neofunctionalist integration theory refers to
(Haas 1958; Lindberg and Scheingold 1970), but the fact that the
planning horizon of actors usually surpasses the current political
agenda. Some parts of the integration project can strategically be
postponed and addressed later, after the adoption of the package, when
the constellation of actors has changed or after the revision of the
project. Again, the changing Council presidency is very important
among the member states, as it is linked to a considerable amount of
power to set the agenda.
Dynamics result from integration projects, not from functional spillover effects. It is a question of political and economic interests whether
or not, for example, tax harmonization, social policy regulations, a
monetary union or, as a general alternative, regulatory competition of
systems are seen as `logical' consequences of an integrated market.
Projects and alliances
The period of the formation of relative convergence between member
states was characterized by a number of mostly unsuccessful integration
projects. In studying two federalist8 or institutionalist initiatives, some
prerequisites for failure can be determined. In addition, beneath this
history, some factors can also be identi®ed that in mid-term assumed
large importance.
8
In this section and in the following, the term federalism/federalist is used in the sense of
a project to establish common institutions at European level (`centralization'). In the
German language, the term means the exact opposite, namely the maintenance or
creation of a decentralized institutional structure. The term `federalist integration
projects' refers to the generalized wish to establish or extend European institutions.
Tying up the Luxembourg package
45
The Genscher±Colombo initiative, 19819
Named after the German and the Italian foreign ministers, this initiative
for a `European Act' as a `step towards union', towards `Europe's
political unity', aimed at the completion of the Common Market, a
common foreign policy and an increase in majority decisions in the
Council of Ministers. The integration project included the development
of a number of areas such as research and technology policy and social
and regional policy.
The German±Italian integration project had a strong federalist
orientation. In both countries, there was consensus among the different
political parties on the desirability and feasibility of a West European
federal state, with control and legal authority increasing with the expansion of economic competences. Accordingly, the European Parliament,
in particular, would have to be developed into an actual analogue to
national parliaments. This was clearly rejected by the British, Danish
and French governments.10 Even increased cooperation in foreign
affairs, which was the area most likely to achieve consent, there was
resistance from Ireland as well as reservations by the United Kingdom
and France in view of an expansion into security policy.
During the German Council presidency,11 this initiative led to the
adoption of the Stuttgart Solemn Declaration (1983), which avoided
the term `Act'. Concerning institutional development, the most important points it contained were the con®rmation of an active and expandable role for the Commission as well as the statement that the
implementation of decision-making procedures as provided in the Rome
treaty (i.e. majority voting in the Council) is of decisive importance for
improving the EC's capacity to act. However, the Stuttgart Declaration
did not represent fundamental agreement to a common integration
project. An effective limitation of the Luxembourg Compromise was not
made (Teasdale 1993: 572). Moreover, ®ve of the ten member states
(France, the United Kingdom, Denmark, Ireland and Greece) con®rmed their adherence to the national power of veto on principle after
the conference. Along with the results of the following Greek Council
presidency, especially the failure of the summit in Athens, this refutes
the thesis that Stuttgart represented the launch of the rocket's ®rst
9
10
11
In Europa-Archiv 2±1982; cf. Genscher (1981), Hrbek (1982: 12ff ). On German EC
policy in this period in general, see Bulmer and Paterson (1987), Wessels and
Regelsberger (1988).
For the French position see SecreÂtariat d'Etat aupreÁs du Premier Ministre and
Commissariat GeÂneÂral du Plan (1983: 85). This report emphasizes that an `Act', if it
were to be adopted, would have to be far removed from its original ambitions.
See Ungerer (1983a, b), Mertes (1983).
46
State-building and political entrepreneurship
stage, as the German foreign minister Genscher stated in retrospect
(1995: 368).12
In addition to the non-binding Solemn Declaration, `special negotiations' were also adopted in Stuttgart. Monthly special conferences of the
Council were to prepare a package solution for the Community's most
important problems (budget, ®nancing, agricultural policy, enlargement). All governments agreed that the problems should be solved as a
package. According to the Greek prime minister, Papandreou, the
Stuttgart `compromise between diverging concepts' did not prove to be
sustainable, as it was based on `contradictory and ambiguous formulations' (Europa-Archiv 3-1984, D65). The existing possibilities for
dealing with a question or postponing regulations on other questions
had been practically non-existent. `A solution in one area required a
compensating solution in another. That was the sense of the ``package'',
or, if you prefer this term, of the overall solution.' (ibid., D64). The
Athens summit in December 1983, at which a package solution was
supposed to be adopted, failed entirely, so that even the usual common
conclusions were renounced.
Even if the ®rst attempt towards a solution for the EC's structural
problems failed, ®elds had been outlined in these special negotiations,
con®dence had been built up and the directions of possible compromises explored. However, the Commission criticized the procedure
chosen in Stuttgart as a `distortion of the community's procedures',
which forti®ed the `tendency to progressive hypertrophy of the role
assigned to the European Council' (ibid., D69). The Commission had
reached a very low point in its in¯uence.
The European Parliament draft treaty on European Union
A second source of initiatives for a federal Europe, in addition to the
German±Italian cooperation but not separate from it, is the European
Parliament. In 1979 it was directly elected for the ®rst time and it has
been looking for a new, more adequate role ever since. Following an
initiative by MPs around Altiero Spinelli (the so-called Crocodile
Group), the European Parliament established a committee on institutional problems in 1981, `convinced that the fact that it has been elected
by direct universal suffrage gives it both increased authority and
12
The second step had been the SEA, the third had been the Maastricht treaty. Doutriaux
(1992: 94) also advocates the thesis of `relaunch of the European construction in
Stuttgart in 1983'. Grosser (1989: 384f ), however, states that the failure of the
European summits in Athens in December 1983 and in Brussels in 1984 showed how
unproductive the pompous Solemn Declaration had been.
Tying up the Luxembourg package
47
additional duties in the performance of its democratic tasks'.13 A draft
treaty establishing the European Union14 was presented early in 1984.
This draft proposed a transition from the method of intergovernmental
cooperation to `common action' in an institutional equilibrium between
Parliament, Commission and Council in many policy areas. In the
Council, general majority voting was planned, except in areas where it
was explicitly stated otherwise in the treaties. The recourse to `vital
national interests' (Luxembourg Compromise) was given a transitional
period of ten years to its complete abolition.
The Italian and German Members of Parliament had already dominated the committee; the plenary vote also showed that the draft was
mainly supported by MPs of the original core Europe ± except France.
Hopes that the draft could become a crystallization point for a more
thorough debate soon disappeared. The draft was never discussed by
the national governments, but became a topic of academic debates. It
was given a symbolic reference in Council decisions, and a Commission
spokesman called it the `decisive impulse' towards EC reform
(Ehlermann 1988: 57). Nevertheless, it remains unclear what led to the
SEA being mentioned in close connection with the European Parliament
draft treaty.15 The sole fact that the draft was never discussed in the
Council, but also a comparison of the contents, reveals the fundamental
difference between the approaches of these initiatives.
The most important reason for the failure of the federalist integration
projects between 1981 and 1984 was their institutionalist orientation.
This approach of creating a supranational state could and can rely only
on the consent of mainly the political elite of some member countries,
and partly also their populations. Without the other two big member
states, or with their only partial inclusion, especially France, the
German±Italian project did not stand a chance of initiating real change.
As a supranational actor, the European Parliament is too weak to
develop suf®cient pressure towards this aim. Until mid-1984, the
Commission was greatly slowed down by the EC's overhang of internal
problems in its function as a political entrepreneur. Apart from the
13
14
15
Resolution of 9 July 1981; in Gazzo (1985: 18).
In Europa-Archiv 8±1984, D209ff. See the most comprehensive Bieber, Jacque and
Weiler (1985) and Wessels (1984).
As, for example, Schnorpfeil (1993: 25f ); similarily, Sidjanski (1992: 155). Lodge
(1985: 204) characterizes the debate on EC institutions at the Milan summit as being
`the direct result and culmination of the European Parliament's pressure to reform EC
decisionmaking in line with its draft Treaty establishing the European Union'. Biehl
(1988: 64), however, speaks of a failure of the European Parliament's constitutional
initiative; he states that the SEA has a different, namely intergovernmental, character.
48
State-building and political entrepreneurship
preparations for the southern enlargement, it was primarily the
demands for special clauses by Greece and the United Kingdom that
burdened the EC political system. PASOK, winner of the 1981 elections
in Greece, had promised a referendum on EC membership during its
election campaign and demanded a special status for Greece in the EC,
justi®ed with reference to its comparatively lower level of economic
development. During the preparation of the EC budget for 1980, the
prospect of the United Kingdom having to pay about 20 per cent of the
member states' ®nancial contributions and only receiving about 10 per
cent of the community's expenditure appeared. This was mainly due to
the fact that the agricultural sector in the United Kingdom is much
smaller and thus receives comparatively much less `pro®t' from the
common agricultural policy, which at that time was still about threequarters of the EC budget. The conservative Thatcher government
made this a central issue, which dominated all European Council meetings up until Fontainebleau ( June 1984). The government's pertinacity
and political inconsiderateness on this question led to one of the worst
paralysations of the EC apparatus for ®ve years. Whether justi®ed or
not, the battle-cry `I want my money back!' was traumatically imprinted
on the memories of many people who were active in the EC political
system at that time, as we gathered from practically all the interviews.
Two developments in 1983 were of great importance for the preparation of the integration thrust. First, in April 1983 the European Roundtable of Industrialists (ERT) was founded, and thus for the ®rst time a
transnational coalition of large-scale entrepreneurs that could directly
in¯uence further EC development was under way (see chapter 7).
Secondly, the French government de®nitively abandoned `Keynesianism in one country' and reoriented its European policy.
The French project of a European relaunch
By the second year of the French left government, the necessity for
medium- to long-term alternative strategic concepts had emerged. In
June 1982 ± the month of the ®rst austerity measures ± a working group
of of®cials from the Commissariat du Plan and the foreign ministry, of
scientists and of industrial and trade union representatives was established. This working group had to evaluate `the areas where and the
states with which it would be desirable to start negotiations to establish
agreements or programmes of cooperation by taking into account the
action of the EC' (our translation), with reference to the preparation of
the ninth plan (1984±8).
The ®nal report, Quelle strateÂgie europeÂenne pour la France dans les
Tying up the Luxembourg package
49
anneÂes 80?,16 was presented in April 1983. The reason for its suggestions
is its analysis that no West European country is capable of mastering the
large challenges on its own, namely Europe's decreasing competitiveness
in the triad competition, the micro-electronic revolution, the employment problem and the crisis of social systems. Only European initiatives
could prevent the decline into an `economic balkanization' (p. 29). The
suggested measures included the creation of a large market (by
eliminating non-tariff trade barriers), which, however, must be defended
against the outside. They also focused on the promotion of technological
research and development as well as industrial cooperation. This was
closely linked to the proposed creation of a `social Europe', since this
would be the only way to overcome workers' resistance to technological
innovation (p. 35).
The report acknowledged the widespread scepticism concerning a
new launch of the project for a `social Europe', due in no small part to
the history of the French memorandum for a European social area in
1981. That memorandum advocated EC-wide cooperation in employment policy; it was practically ignored ± with the exception of support
from the socialist European parliamentary group and Danish interest in
some of the social policy suggestions ± and was never discussed in the
Council. The report made the point that an `ambiguõÈte fondamentale'
existed toward the precise role of the European level (p. 177). At the
institutional level, a return to majority decisions in the Council of
Ministers was suggested in certain cases, `tout en respectant l'esprit du
compromis de Luxembourg' (`respecting the spirit of the Luxembourg
Compromise'; p. 86). A revision of the treaty, the report said, would not
necessarily be required for this. The report also suggested a Europe with
different integration speeds (Europe diffeÂrencieÂe) if there was resistance to
further integration steps. Additionally, the Commission presidency
should be strengthened.
Jacques Moreau, president of the working group,17 emphasized that
the present construction of Europe had been developed along the
German±French axis and that it was to be expected that Germany
16
17
SecreÂtariat d'Etat aupreÁs du Premier Ministre and Commissariat GeÂneÂral du Plan
(1983). On the background of French European policy, see especially Uterwedde
(1988), Wurm (1993), Lequesne (1993) and Gerbet (1995).
It can be said of Jacques Moreau that he embodied the French integration project. A
socialist and trade unionist (CFDT) like Delors, he was elected Delors' successor in
1981 as chairman of the European Parliament's Economic and Monetary Affairs
Committee (1981±84); at the same time he was a member of the European
Parliament's institutional committee that elaborated the draft of the treaty, then adviser
to the Delors Commission and later president of the Economic and Social Committee
(1988±92). He complains that the institutional dimension of European integration was
neglected in this report (interview on 18 September 1996).
50
State-building and political entrepreneurship
would continue to be available for a `projet commun'. This question
should be the main focus of France's European strategy, according to
Moreau (p. 17f ). The report played an important role in preparing the
French presidency of the Council in the ®rst six months of 1984.
Mitterrand had already made a `basic decision for Europe' (Grosser
1989: 386) ± the franc was to remain within the European Monetary
System ± without consulting the minister for European affairs
(Lequesne 1993: 62). In the course of 1983, French European policy
increasingly became an `inner-circle topic' which was discussed among a
very small number of top politicians. The huge power of the French
president, due to his constitutional position, enables such processes.
According to Haywood (1993: 281), `all Mitterrand's major Euroinitiatives have been kept secret until the last minute'. Shortly before the
beginning of the French Council presidency, Mitterrand nominated a
close con®dant, Roland Dumas, as the new minister for European
affairs. This was linked to a distinct up-grading of the European affairs
ministry (Lequesne 1993: 64).
Especially in Bonn, these changes were carefully observed ± and
understood. According to Genscher, the German embassy in Paris
considered Dumas' nomination to be a decision of great importance for
European policy. They knew of the close friendship between Dumas and
Mitterrand (Genscher 1995: 367). Another directive decision by Mitterrand was also of great importance for the re-establishment of German±
French con®dence. A high-level German diplomat told us in an interview that `the unspoken, atmospheric reservations' against Mitterrand ±
that he might be a `windiger Geselle' (`dubious fellow') ± began to melt
away as the break with the communists became predictable.
The take-off, 1984
With the economic policy convergence, a Single Market started to
emerge as the main project of a new integration thrust. However, it was
still a long way to a comprehensive package solution to revitalize
European integration. The projects differed tremendously as regards the
necessity and the scope of an institutional reform of the Community.
Additionally, there were varying concepts of the Community's role in
industrial policy and the harmonization of regulations as a necessary
follow-up to the realization of the Single Market.
First of all, the problems that were paralysing any further progress
had to be solved: (a) the British desires for budgetary correctives; (b) the
necessary increase in ®nancial resources; and (c) control of agricultural
expenses. Mitterrand took an important, active role in this process, a
Tying up the Luxembourg package
51
role that can only partially be explained by the French Council presidency. He actually assumed the political entrepreneurship owing to the
lack of con®dence that the Commission enjoyed at that time. It is
generally noted that in 1984 Mitterrand preferred to discuss his projects
in bilateral talks with other heads of government.18 In Brussels, it was
often commented that the Commission had become the secretariat of
the Council of Ministers. The series of special negotiations that had
already been started in 1983 was thus continued. According to De Ruyt
(1989), who claims that the genesis of the SEA began with the French
Council presidency, the numerous bilateral contacts (instead of Council
meetings) emerged as a new way of dealing with problems.
The British perceived increasing chances of an answer to their
demands. Thatcher (1993: 537) writes that she hoped for a shift in
Mitterrand's position, the French president being `someone who
relished a diplomatic success and would probably be prepared to
sacri®ce French national interests ± at least marginally ± in order to
secure one'. As a reason for the French efforts to solve the budget
question, Foreign Secretary Howe (1994: 399) reveals the fact that
France was facing the transition to becoming a net contributor to the
Community budget.
It took another failed summit to aggravate the situation (Brussels,
March 1984). Then the United Kingdom, facing increasing pressure
from other member countries, realized that a compromise had to be
found to stay in the game. According to Taylor (1989: 8; see Moravcsik
1998: 351), the British took the French threats of a Europe differencieÂe
seriously.
Mitterrand used a series of occasions to advertise the French initiative. His speech to the European Parliament in May 1984 was especially
important, where he said: `A new situation calls for a new treaty . . .
which must not, of course, be a substitute for existing treaties, but an
extension of them to ®elds they do not currently cover. . . . France,
ladies and gentlemen, is available for such an entreprise.'19 For
Mitterrand, this included a restriction of the national power of veto to
`speci®c' cases, not its general abolition. Once again he emphasized the
necessity of a `Europe of different speeds or variable geometry'.
18
19
E.g. Stadlmann (1984: 451); see Kohl in Europa-Archiv 10±1984, D287.
In Gazzo (1985: 85). According to De Ruyt (1989: 49), this speech was understood as
a `coup d'envoi de la nouvelle initiative institutionelle'. Again, a few interpretations see
this speech as replying to the European Parliament's draft treaty. In my opinion,
because of the coincidence in time, Mitterrand appears to be referring to it purely
rhetorically. This is revealed by the fact that the French initiative had a strong
intergovernmental orientation; in particular, it did not consider an extension of the
European Parliament's role.
52
State-building and political entrepreneurship
At the European Council in Fontainebleau in June 1984, the budget
problem was solved.20 The British agreed to a compromise suggestion
elaborated through close German±French cooperation (see Genscher
1995: 370). This compromise solution did not indicate a fundamental
agreement on the future development of the EC, but it did mean that
the way to further reform was no longer obstructed. The heads of state
and government followed Mitterrand's suggestion (Lequesne 1993:
148) and established an Ad Hoc Committee for Institutional Affairs
(the so-called Dooge Committee) to discuss institutional issues of the
future reform. Members of this committee were personal representatives
of the heads of state and government as well as representatives of the
Commission. Therefore, as Mitterrand explained after Fontainebleau,
the committee stood `outside traditional structures', even though still
linked to the Commission.21 The `special path' was thus continued. The
work in the Dooge Committee soon showed that the European Parliament's draft treaty, despite Parliament's demands, would not be used as
a basis for negotiations between member states.
Therefore, the beginning of the constitution of the Luxembourg
package can be dated to mid-1984 (see Moravcsik 1991: 39; 1998: 352,
360f ). But that goal was still a long way ahead. Another development
during the French Council presidency was also of great importance: the
course for a new Commission was set.
The rebirth of the Commission
The Commission under Gaston Thorn, like all Commissions since the
Luxembourg Compromise, was suffering strongly restricted capacities
to act. Emil NoeÈl, secretary-general of the Commission, describes this
as follows:
From being the moving spirit or arbitrator when the Council could decide by
quali®ed majority only upon a Commission proposal, it found itself relegated to
the role of a mere technical adviser when unanimity became the rule. The result
was, irrespective of the calibre of the Commissioners and the Commission's
President, the Commission's in¯uence dwindled and the supreme power of the
Council was con®rmed, although the Council was unable to make full use of
this power. (1987: 5)22
20
21
22
The agreement to the complex package cannot be reported here, though it can be
reconstructed quite easily; see especially Europa-Archiv 15-1984, Ungerer (1984),
Butler (1986).
In his press conference on 26 June, 1984 (Europa-Archiv 15-1984, D445).
However, George (1991: 15) states that a re-strengthening of the EC Commission that
already started with the assignment of Commission president Roy Jenkins, who carried
out a fundamental reform of the internal structure of the Commission. Thorn
completed it and established a basis for Delors' policy.
Tying up the Luxembourg package
53
Several times, Thorn tried to start institutional reform initiatives, in
vain. With the Cassis de Dijon decision which the European Court of
Justice ruled in 1979, the Commission had actually been given a strong
weapon for achieving a Single Market. Its importance was realized only
after a second judgment in 1980. During the recession, the Commission
was very cautious about applying it, and it was not until 1984 that it
increasingly made references to the judgment.23 The most important
achievements of the Commission were in research and development
policy, with the Esprit project, an initiative of Commissioner Etienne
Davignon (chapter 4).
The previous history of the Delors Commission begins with
Mitterrand's diplomatic offensive in spring 1984. The political diary of
Mitterrand's adviser, Jacques Attali, allows a precise reconstruction of
how the president achieved Germany's approval of a French president
of the Commission, even though it should have been a German
according to implicit rules (see Howe 1994: 404). In bilateral talks,
Mitterrand ruled out the most promising candidate, Etienne Davignon,
who had been the most prominent member of the previous Commission. According to Attali (1993: 617), Mitterrand spoke to Belgian
Prime Minister Martens mentioning his scepticism about Davignon; he
said Davignon was accused of being too America-friendly and was also
from the European aristocracy. Be that as it may, towards the end of
the French Council presidency, the list of candidates for the Commission presidency consisted of two important French politicians, both
of whom had been ministers in the Mauroy government until the
middle of 1984: ex-Foreign Minister Claude Cheysson and Jacques
Delors.
Delors appeared more likely to embody an imaginary centre of the
different political landscapes in the EC than Cheysson. Furthermore,
Delors' central role in the implementation of the French austerity policy
had received high marks from other national governments as well as
from political adversaries. Delors had been `credited with reining back
the initial left-wing socialist policies of President Mitterrand's Government and with putting French ®nances on a sounder footing' (Thatcher
1993: 547, see also Howe 1994: 404). Thus Delors' candidacy also
found support in London.24
It became clear to Delors on his `inaugural journey' through the
23
24
This was indicated to me by Jacques Pelkmans, who also made me realize that the
application of this judgment presupposed enormous mutual con®dence among the
member states.
See also Attali (1993: 651). Thatcher initially supported the candidacy of Davignon
(Attali 1993: 659).
54
State-building and political entrepreneurship
capitals of the EC member states25 that the completion of the EC
internal market by means of deregulation, as proposed by European
business representatives, must become the sole undisputed core of the
new thrust toward integration.
The politics of Jacques Delors
Referring to Delors' role, it is often pointed out that `the initiative' had
already been prepared before the new Commission's assumption of
of®ce. Here again, a distinction must be made: the Single Market
project was indeed practically elaborated (see chapter 3); but the question of how far and which institutional reforms it should be linked to
was by no means solved. Additionally, and Delors knew this, the Single
Market project could only be enforced in a package together with
integration steps in other policy areas, especially `¯anking measures'.
Personally he had already consistently endorsed the Common Market as
the only basis for a project opposed to the decline of Europe. In contrast
to the views of some national governments and interest groups,
however, for Delors as well as for the French government, the creation
of an internal market was not an end in itself. As the Commission
president often repeated: `on ne tombe pas amoureux d'un grand
marcheÂ!' (`One does not fall in love with a big market!') An increased
comprehension of Delors' policy and its motives is necessary, since he
strongly determined the Commission's integration project from 1985
until the Maastricht Summit and beyond.
As a minister in the Mauroy government, Delors explained his basic
orientation in economic policy in an article in 1981 as a careful dose of
different instruments: cautious stimulation of the national budget; a
socially fairer tax system, which encourages saving and entrepreneurial
initiative; an active employment policy (training, mobility, job placement); an anti-in¯ationary monetary policy; a more differentiated credit
policy, connected with structural reforms with the goal of effective
decentralization and market competition; and ¯exible planning aimed at
structural recovery, which would make it possible to take advantage of
the achievements of the new industrial revolution. The goal is a largely
decentralized economy, in which a functioning market and planning
based on incentives are mutually reinforcing, which in turn concentrates
power on the most important national goals (Delors 1981: 107f ).
A central aspect of his concept was concertation, the involvement of
`social partners' in the formulation and implementation of political
25
He met with heads of state and government and with national parliamentarians, as well
as with trade union leaders and employers; see Delors (1992); Ross (1995a).
Tying up the Luxembourg package
55
programmes. As minister of ®nance he invited entrepreneurs and union
representatives to talks, and in the interest of the trade unions advanced
a law based on the Swedish model concerning the arrangement of wageearner funds ( fonds salariaux).
In contrast to many other French politicians, including those in his
own party, the EC and in particular the Common Market had always
played an important, positive role in Delors' politics. In his 1981 article
on the situation in France he wrote that, in order to withstand the
external challenge, France not only must get on with the tasks of the
1980s, it must also be able to count on the fact that European cooperation will develop positively, whereby the domains of industry, energy
and research receive priority and do so on the basis of a genuine
common market. Likewise, according to Delors (1981: 107), the EC
must absolutely pursue a common external policy if it is to strengthen its
autonomy and to secure its future.
Because of the unusual position of the political current in the socalled DeuxieÁme Gauche to which Delors belongs, it is useful to examine
its roots, looking at Delors' political biography.26 Delors' view of the
world was stamped by personalisme, a progressive form of Catholic social
doctrine, which demarcates itself from liberal, utilitarian individualism
and from the communist collectivism. Its emphasis on agreement,
balancing competing interests, and cooperation between different societal groups was surely a root of Delors' project. Delors became involved
in a union, the ConfeÂdeÂration FrancËaise et DeÂmocratique du Travail
(CFDT) and became a director in its research department. In 1961 he
published an article entitled `A Trade Union Approach to the Commissariat au Plan', the central French planning apparatus. In this article he
proposed an annual meeting of the government, the employers and the
unions, which would ®x a minimum wage and an average level of wage
increases. In return for being fully associated with the planning process
± what he called `democratic planning' ± the unions would accept
binding agreements. This was Delors' stepping stone to the French
Commissariat du Plan.
In France at this time there was still no such politique contractuelle, the
analogue to the Swedish and German neocorporatist model. In February
1968, on the basis of a report by Delors and FrancËois-Xavier Ortoli
(later to become EC Commission president), tripartite talks were held
under Pompidou, where for the ®rst time employers and the communist
trade union, CGT, sat together at the same table. Chaban-Delmas, the
reform-minded prime minister under Pompidou, summoned Delors as a
26
Biographical details from Grant (1994) and Ross (1995a).
56
State-building and political entrepreneurship
consultant on social affairs. From this position Delors strongly advocated
the development of a politique contractuelle. The talks resulted in approximately sixty so-called Contrats de ProgreÁs, company agreements between
employers and unions over wage increases, working hours and other
issues.
`Social-delorisme' (a term coined by the French magazine L'Express),
understood as a political current within the DeuxieÁme Gauche, was
characterized from the beginning by its basic reformist attitude and its
af®rmation of the market mechanism in combination with social responsibility. Another basic tenet was a belief in the superiority of concertation
as opposed to administrative management. A certain proximity to
German or Swedish social democratic models cannot be overlooked.
After joining the Socialist Party under Mitterrand, Delors entered its
circle of experts, where he took over the area concerned with international economics. Beginning in 1976 Delors served for three years as
a representative in the French National Assembly. In 1979 he was
elected to the European Parliament, where he was chairman of the
economic and monetary affairs committee. He belonged to the so-called
Amigo Group of social democratic parliament members, which included
among others Ripa Di Meana of Italy (later a member of the Dooge
Committee and the Delors Commission); Piet Dankert of the Netherlands (later president of the European Parliament); and Jacques
Moreau.
Although the new integration launch had to start with the economic
sphere, it was always Delors' aim to bring the project back into `balance'
(`reÂeÂquilibrer') to achieve the primacy of politics (Delors 1992: 17). For
Delors, European cooperation is the ®ght not only against economic
decline but also against social regression (Delors 1992: 70). The
`European societal model' (le modeÁle europeÂen de socieÂte ) has a central
orientation function for Delors; it is characterized by values such as
solidarity, a high level of social protection, and concertation of all partners
in production. It is no surprise that one of Delors' ®rst measures as
Commission president was to revive the social dialogue at the European
level (see chapter 6).
As the only supranational political entrepreneur, a `corporate actor'
(Coleman 1990) with established political independence, fully developed rights of initiative and thereby great possibilities in agenda-setting,
the Commission was well suited for implementing Delors' project.
`Intelligent maximalism' is the institutional duty of the Commission.27
Delors conceived the Commission in its central role as `ingeÂnieur de la
27
A term used by Ross (1995a: 95). For further evidence regarding the role of the
Commission, see Louis and Waelbroeck (1989), Ludlow (1991), Hrbek (1996) and
Tying up the Luxembourg package
57
construction europeÂenne' (engineer of European construction) and made it
clear from the time he took of®ce that the Commission's right of
initiative would be fully utilized (Delors 1992: 46). It must develop the
capacity to exhaust its restricted possibilities as far as they are given by
the treaties and allowed by the intergovernmental context.
Ross (1995a: 158ff ) speaks of a `Delorist leadership system'. There
was a gradual, but wholesale, change of administrative leadership at
Directorate General level. Nearly all newly appointed people enjoyed
the con®dence of Delors and his cabinet. Delors' cabinet was the backbone of the system. Larger than that of other Commissioners, it
included about ten people, three-quarters of whom were French, many
coming from the French Socialist Party and/or the CFDT. The head of
cabinet, Pascal Lamy, whose view of the world was also derived from a
left-Catholic standpoint, had worked with Delors in the French ministry
of ®nance and had participated there in the preparation of the economic
change of course in 1982±3. The non-French members were recruited
predominantly from EC Directorates General. When necessary, his
cabinet bypassed those of other Commissioners and established parallel
networks to achieve the desired results. Delors' hierarchical, centralized
managerial system also attracted, hardly surprisingly, internal and
external criticism (`Bonapartism').
The question of which integration steps in which policy areas and of
which institutional reforms could be linked to the Single Market project
was decisive for the Delors Commission right from the beginning.
According to Cameron (1992: 51), `by broadening the range of issues to
be discussed', Delors created `the possibility for bargains, trade-offs,
and alliances to be struck across the issues of market reform and
institutional reform'.28 On the basis of the considerations in this
chapter, this means no less than creating the possibility of a package
solution and thus the adoption of the entire Luxembourg package,
including the Single Market project.
The Commission not only had the con®dence of the national
governments, but also planned its work with an exact knowledge of what
was possible by exhausting all available means. It had a new strong
28
Cini (1996); for the institutional prerequisites of the Commission's capacity to act, see
Schmidt (1998: 49ff ).
Cameron (1992: 51) goes even further: `Moreover, in proposing an intergovernmental
conference on the two subjects of reform, Delors and his Commission succeeded in
giving the internal market initiative the aura of progressive, democratizing reform. The
con¯ation of market enlargement and institutional reform may have further promoted
the internal market initiative by attracting it to some segments of the political elite and
the public who would otherwise have been opposed to it or, at best, indifferent.' I do
not think that it was the institutional progress achieved by the SEA that was attractive
to the `federalists'; rather it was the inherent possibilities of an extended dynamics.
58
State-building and political entrepreneurship
leadership, which indeed actually enabled the Commission's important
role in the constitution of the Luxembourg package in the ®rst place.
Tying up the Luxembourg package
The previous sections have shown how the prerequisites for the adoption of the Luxembourg package were each ful®lled step by step in the
years preceding 1985: relative political convergence, the overcoming of
the paralysing obstructions and blockades, and the rebirth of the
Commission as political entrepreneur. In this section, the dynamics of
the SEA negotiations will be reviewed. Since only a survey of a much
broader research project can be given in the following, I have chosen to
present this synopsis in a table. First of all, however, I shall make a few
preliminary methodological remarks.
As mentioned at the outset, a heterogeneous treaty such as the Single
Act must be broken down into its individual parts. But even if the
individual elements are analysed, it is not easy to determine the `authorship'. How can this question be `operationalized'? Surely, the most
important indicator for doing this is the extent to which one or several
actors are interested in a dossier, in the advances and initiatives as well as
the `ambition' of the project. The content of a political initiative has to
be compared with the outcome, in this case Council decisions and the
SEA's ®nal version. Then it can be decided which has been enforced in
principle, partially, and/or modi®ed within the entire compromise.
With such an evaluation, for example, the extraordinary importance
of the cooperation between the Commission and the European Roundtable of Industrialists regarding the Single Market project can be
proved. Or it can be shown that the two French initiatives of 1981
(espace social europeÂen, or European social area) and 1983 (espace
industriel europeÂen, or European industrial area) were relevant for the
content of the SEA to extremely different extents'.
Of course, not all elements of the SEA can be traced back to a
particular, concrete initiative, especially on questions of the further
institutional development of the EC (e.g. majority voting in the Council,
European Parliament rights). These have often been on the agenda
permanently or repeatedly since the foundation of the EC, and are part
of a general reform debate. However, the integration projects of the
different governments and of the transnational and supranational actors
can be reconstructed relatively well on the basis of their bargaining
position and suggestions before and during negotiations.
Furthermore, the EC's institutional characteristics, especially rules of
procedure, have to be considered when determining the `authorship'.
Tying up the Luxembourg package
59
For example, as mentioned above, the country holding the Council
presidency has a decisive organizational initiative function (®rst halfyear of 1985 Italy, second half-year Luxembourg). Then there is the
extraordinary role of the EC Commission: Even though an intergovernmental conference strengthens the role of the national governments and their Permanent Representatives compared with the normal
EC decision-making process, the Commission, if it has the political and
organizational capability, can play a strategically important role. In the
case of the Luxembourg conference, the Commission anticipated proposals from member states in some areas. The member states forwent
submitting proposals or made only amendments. Naturally, this renders
the evaluation of `authorship' more complicated.
`Deconstructing' the Single Act, it must never be forgotten that the
package could be adopted only as a whole.
The decision for an intergovernmental conference: Pandora's box is opened
In March 1985, the Dooge Committee presented its ®nal report.29 The
committee had evaluated the possible content of a project for the
`establishment of a political unity' (preface). The following aims were
given priority:
. creating a genuine internal market by the end of the decade on the
basis of a precise timetable, the immediate mutual recognition of
national standards, the free movement of capital and the creation of a
European ®nancial market, hand in hand with the strengthening of
the European monetary system, the promotion of economic
convergence and the creation of a technological Community;
. promoting the common values of civilization: measures to protect the
environment, the gradual achievement of a European social area
(dialogue between employers and employees, regulatory harmonization, promotion of common cultural values);
. searching for an external identity by strengthening political and
security cooperation.
On the basis of the submitted reservations and added remarks by
individual representatives of heads of state and government, the controversial points can easily be identi®ed. Apart from very frequent
reservations by the Danish and Greek representatives, there are also
German reservations about a further development of the monetary
policy and about economic policy convergence, and Irish reservations
about cooperation in foreign policy (security policy). However, the most
29
Ad Hoc Committee for Institutional Affairs, Report to the European Council, Brussels,
29±30 March 1985, Luxembourg 1985.
60
State-building and political entrepreneurship
important disagreements occurred concerning institutional reform. On
the question of the voting procedure in the Council, the Danish, Greek
and British representatives were against the establishment of a new
general principle that decisions should be made by quali®ed or simple
majority. British and Greek reservations were also submitted against the
extension of the European Parliament's functions. The report ends with
the suggestion of an intergovernmental conference to negotiate the draft
treaty on European Union.
The following months were characterized by a Franco-GermanItalian accord on taking a qualitative step forward (possibly via a new
treaty) at Milan (Lodge 1985) on the one hand and by a strong
diplomatic offensive by the United Kingdom to prevent an intergovernmental conference on the other hand.
The British integration project30 focused on two elements: the
internal market and increased cooperation in external policy. In the
memorandum The British Government's Approach, the following was
outlined:
The United Kingdom wants to see greater European unity. Within the
European Community this means Europe united as a single market. We also
want unity in dealing with the outside world: a Europe united in its approach to
external policy, which not only consults together but acts together and is seen by
others as a cohesive political entity.31
To reach these aims, an intergovernmental conference was not considered necessary. It was even considered dangerous, since it would, as
Foreign Secretary Howe put it, open a `Pandora's box' full of federalistoriented suggestions for changing the treaty. To establish a Single
Market, the British suggested a legally non-binding gentlemen's agreement on the inclusion of national vetoes on these questions, which
hardly found an audience.32
The Italian government wanted to enforce a decision for an intergovernmental conference within its Council presidency.33 Article 236 of
30
31
32
33
On the background and history of British European policy, see especially Volle (1989a,
b), George (1990) and Wurm (1993).
Memorandum for the House of Lords Select Committee on the European Communities: European Union, prepared by the Foreign and Commonwealth Of®ce; in
Select Committee on European Legislation, 21st Report, Session 1984±85, Appendix;
citation on p. 21.
`Many times I explained this informal `British' approach to groups of bewildered
continental parliamentarians, for whom charters, declarations, solemn acts, single acts,
constitutions even, were their real raison d'eÃtre' (Howe 1994: 408).
The strategy of the Italian government was known and the Milan decision was
predictable. In May, Foreign Minister Andreotti, after informal consultations in the
various capitals, presented a `draft mandate for the Intergovernmental Conference' to
his colleagues. He also explained his intentions in an article in Corriere della Sera on
25 June 1985 (both documents in Gazzo 1985). See, in contrast, Howe (1994: 409).
Tying up the Luxembourg package
61
the Treaty of Rome enables the convening of an intergovernmental
conference by majority decision in the Council.34 The `federalist bloc'
strongly supported this procedure. They knew that the decision of the
French government, which was ambivalent concerning the question of
institutional reform, would be decisive. From the point of view of the
Danish diplomat Mùller, who had been a representative on the Dooge
Committee: `They rightly targeted France as the key to the whole issue.
If they could swing France to support a conference to amend the Treaty,
they reckoned they would rally the original six member states (plus
Ireland) against the sceptical and reticent British, Danes and Greeks'
(Mùller 1988: 195).
In close German±French cooperation, the positions in the different
policy areas were coordinated, and extended by talks with the Italian
government. A series of ambitious suggestions by the federalists were
victims of this procedure. The governments of the three Benelux
countries also met to formulate a common position. They focused on
institutional reform, especially the generalization of majority voting in
the Council, and the extension of the competences of the Commission
and of the European Parliament. They demanded decisions concerning
a single market and a common technology policy in order to mobilize
the whole European technological potential and to strengthen the
European Monetary System and its further development.
Meanwhile, the Commission was very busily elaborating its proposals.
At the Milan Summit (28 / 29 June 1985), it presented the White Paper
on Completing the Internal Market and a memorandum for a technological community, and both met acceptance. As foreseen, the Italian
president, Craxi, demanded a vote on convening an intergovernmental
conference, which was actually adopted against votes from the United
Kingdom, Denmark and Greece. This led to a dramatic situation (see
Genscher 1995: 373; Thatcher 1993: 548ff ). France and Ireland had
changed sides, which was decisive. From Mùller's point of view:
There is no reason to underestimate the signi®cance of this event. It meant a
fundamental swing in France's European policy and tilted the balance between
member states. France had hitherto pursued a sceptical or negative line towards
an institutional reform. Now France was ready to negotiate such a reform, albeit
without specifying how far it was prepared to go. (Mùller 1988: 196)
Milan was the stage for the decision to link the realization of the
Single Market project to institutional reform. Pandora's box was
opened. This extension of the reform process was a prerequisite for the
34
De®nitely an important institutional prerequisite for the integration thrust of the
1980s. It is a speculation, but an interesting one, to imagine the development if
unanimity had been prescribed ± the Europe differencieÂe?
62
State-building and political entrepreneurship
acceptance of the Single Market and put it into a broader context (see
Cameron 1992: 56). This may have brought the de®nitive support of all
those who had favoured the Genscher±Colombo initiative, the Stuttgart
Declaration and the draft treaty of the European Parliament.
The intergovernmental conference: the `chainsaw massacre' 35
As early as July 1985, the Luxembourg Council presidency presented a
®rst draft treaty. In September, the two working groups in charge of
preparing the conference were constituted: the Dondelinger Group for
the revision of the treaties, and the Political Committee for `political
cooperation' (common foreign policy). Without much effect, the
European Parliament recollected its own draft treaty in its statement at
the inauguration of the intergovernmental conference (IGC) and
demanded to be included in the elaboration of the treaty.
At the ®rst meeting of the intergovernmental conference, on 9 October
1985 in Luxembourg, Commission president Delors recalled the
meaning of this act with dramatic words and presented the integration
project of the Commission. He announced proposals in the following
areas: the internal market, technological research and development, the
environment, economic and social cohesion, the powers of the Commission and the European Parliament, monetary aspects and culture.
Concerning the areas of energy, industry and health policy, the Commission forwent presenting proposals as it assumed that progress could also
be made in these areas without amendments to the treaty (EC Bulletin
9±1985, 1.1.1).
In principle, the bulk of these proposals was already in the Commission's programme for 1985. Yet, the Commission's active role and the
extent of its proposals was still a surprise for many. In this way, the
Commission helped to de®ne the agenda and dissuaded many governments from putting forward ideas of their own.
According to Delors, the conference table would have remained
empty during the ®rst six to eight weeks if the Commission had not
presented any proposals. He de®ned four areas in which the Commission wanted to concentrate on the extension of the EC's competences:
the Single Market, research and technological development, economic
and social cohesion, and a `certain monetary capacity' (`capaciteÂ
35
The reconstruction of the intergovernmental conference is based mainly on interviews
with political actors, periodical EC bulletins, the documents in Gazzo (1985, 1986),
newspaper articles, Kramer (1985), Gulman (1987), De Zwaan (1986), De Ruyt
(1989), Grant (1994), Attali (1993), Ross (1995a), and Middlemas (1995).
Tying up the Luxembourg package
63
moneÂtaire'). The last area was Delors' careful term for the dossier with
the least chance of being adopted.
The most remarkable element of the Commission proposals is
`economic and social cohesion'. This area had not appeared in the
negotiations before the intergovernmental conference. In the Commission programme for 1985, the project for a `European social area' and
regional aid were separate. The Commission also did not present any
proposals on social policy as such. On the one hand, this is surely
connected to the role that the Commission allotted to the social
dialogue. On the other hand, I also interpret this as an expression of
Delors' strategy of bundling up these politically sensitive areas into an
additional package of `¯anking measures' with a new title. The aim was
to tie these areas as closely as possible to the core project, the Single
Market, not least as a result of the experience of the 1981 French
initiative for a social area. Delors also argued in this way in presenting
the Commission's project. The Commission assumed that realizing the
Single Market would have negative effects if there were no supporting
measures. From his point of view, supporting measures were: the
development of less privileged regions, the improvement of employment
possibilities and of living and working conditions, the promotion of
social innovation and the transformation of declining sectors. As well as
transferring ®nances, he wanted a coordination of national economic
policies. The embodiment of the Commission project would have
entrusted the Community institutions with a relatively comprehensive
welfare state mandate.
The strategy of creating a `supporting package' did not work. Ireland,
Italy and Greece rejected the `overloaded' cohesion package, and
demanded concentration on the interstate transfer of resources. It was
not just the wealthier member states ± for fear of massive expansions of
the redistribution of resources ± that rejected the transfer of competences in economic policy; Greece rejected this as well. Additionally, the
strategy was foiled, especially as regards the harmonization of social
policy, when the British enforced the explicit non-application of
majority voting concerning workers' rights and interests (Art. 100a).36
Owing to the initiative of the Danish government, social policy was
actually discussed after all during the conference, with the effect that
36
This suggested interpretation takes into account the position of the peripheral states,
thus explaining what Moravcsik (1991: 46, 1998: 372) describes as follows: `in late
September and early October 1985, Delors dropped strong advocacy of monetary and
social reform and chose to stress instead the links between internal market reform,
majority voting, and the increases in structural funds needed to gain support from
Ireland and the Southern countries.'
64
State-building and political entrepreneurship
occupational health and safety were linked to the core project (see
chapter 6).
In addition to the Commission's political entrepreneurship, German±
French cooperation also played an important role during the intergovernmental conference. Thatcher (1993: 552) writes that `the
Franco-German axis was again as strong as it had been under President
Giscard and Chancellor Schmidt'. This was the case on all levels, not
just at the higher level of the European Council, where ± at joint
working breakfasts ± Mitterrand and Kohl `prestructured' the following
meetings.
During the intergovernmental conference the fact was recon®rmed
that nothing could be enforced against the will of Germany and/or
France. The political power of Italy and the Benelux states was insuf®cient to balance, together with the Commission, German or French
doubts and reservations. Furthermore, as soon as the German±French
cooperation weakened, the intergovernmental conference lacked a
driving force to turn the Commission's far-reaching proposals into
generally acceptable treaty texts. A political observer explained that the
reason success can be achieved only in the event of German±French
agreement is because all measures either cost Bonn money or restrict
Parisian sovereignty.
In October, a European Parliament delegation took the ¯oor at the
intergovernmental conference. The European Parliament had actually
been regularly informed about the state of affairs. However, the delegation criticized the non-observance of the Parliament's draft treaty and
called for stronger participation in the ®nal work of the conference. In
particular, the planned improvements in the European Parliament's
competences were considered to be absolutely insuf®cient.
The Council presidency stated in its interim results that most delegations considered it vital to preserve the present institutional balance and
thus not to alter the distribution of powers between the different
Community institutions. Other delegations pointed out that it would be
dif®cult to avoid making some adjustment to the present institutional
balance if the envisaged reform was to have any real substance.
In some areas an agreement was achieved quickly, especially concerning the extension of foreign policy cooperation, which had been
planned as a separate treaty for some time. The environmental regulations, where majority decisions were not proposed, also caused no
dif®culties.
Within the internal market dossier, a lot of harmonization proposals
were left out. The British, who advocated the principle of ®scal competition, fought successfully against the planned tax harmonization. The
Tying up the Luxembourg package
65
safeguard clauses referring to the Single Market threatened to multiply
during the conference. The fact that these were again reduced is
attributable to Delors' efforts and his German±French support. The
Danish and the German governments in particular, anxious to avoid any
lowering of their high national standards for health, safety and environmental protection, enforced the possibility of maintaining higher
national protection standards in these areas.
On the question of ®nancing the Community research and technology
policy, Delors complained about an `unusual coalition of those who do
not want to do much and those who fear that money will go into this
area instead of into structural funds' (press conference on 27 November
1985, in Gazzo 1986: 83ff ). The most disputed issues were the question
of European Parliament rights and the monetary policy dossier.
Delors described the way the concept of an `espace organise ', an
`organized area' (as it was understood by the Commission), was dealt
with ± its increasing reduction to deregulation ± as a `chainsaw massacre'
(ibid.).
During the ®nal phase of the intergovernmental conference, uni®ed
pressure from the German±French duo was again desperately needed,
as well as several rings of the alarm bell from the Commission, for the
completion of the package. This was not achieved until the 28-hour
meeting of the European Council in Luxembourg itself (2/ 3
December 1985). Even after intensive negotiations by the foreign
ministers at the weekends preceding the summit, some points had
remained unclear.
Not until a follow-up meeting in the middle of December did Delors
manage to unite the two areas (a common foreign policy and the other
dossiers), which had been planned as two separate treaties for a long
time, into an Acte Unique, or single document. The name of the
package, which emphasizes the unity of the elements, was proposed by
the Commission president. Table 2.1 presents an overview of the
formation and development of political initiatives at the European level
and, if relevant, how they are re¯ected in the Single European Act
(SEA).
The SEA: `Constitutional reform serving the Common Market'?
The Commission spokesman de®ned the SEA as a `constitutional
reform serving the Common Market' (Ehlermann 1988). This touches
the core of the Luxembourg package, especially if quali®ed majority
voting is used as an indicator of the transition to supranationality. The
principle of quali®ed majority voting ± the abolition of the `veto culture'
Table 2.1. The formation and development of political initiatives at European level and their expression in the Single
European Act (SEA), 1981±1985
Initiative(s)
Policy area:
Single Market
Research and
technology policy
Cohesion policy
Monetary policy
(anchoring the European
monetary system,
monetary union as goal)
Social policyc
Environment policy
Cultural policy
Foreign policy
cooperation
Institutional development:
Change of treaty through
IGC (according to Art.
236 of the Treaties)
Expansion of the
executive competences
of the Commission
Supportersa
Opponentsa
Roundtable of Industrialists/
Commission, White Paper
adopted at Milan; submission
to the IGC by the Commission
Commission/Information
Technology Roundtable
(Esprit); F with German support (EUREKA); Commission
submission adopted at Milan
(`new technological dimension')b; submissions to IGC
by Commission, G and DK
Greek demands for more
transfer payments; submissions
F to IGC by Commission,
IRL, F and GR
F, Commission; submissions to
IGC by Commission, B, NL
French initiative for a European
social area (1981); submissions
to IGC by DK, B, F and
Commission
Submissions to IGC by
G, Commission and DK
Benelux
Submission at Milan by
Commission; submissions
to IGC by Commission, NL
Consent; in dispute: range
and scope of necessary harmonization; some reservations
and temporary exemption
clauses
Consent in principle; controversy over decision-making
process (G, F, UK gave up
rejection of majority voting;
unanimity maintained for
framework programmes; protection of net contributors)
Art. 13±19 SEA, Declaration nos. 3, 4, 6 (Annex
SEA); Art. 8 a-c, 99, 100a,
mod. Art. 57, 59, 70, 84 of
the Treaties
Art. 24 SEA; Art. 130 f±q
of the Treaties
G, UK act
as brake
Agreement by postponing
question of amount of
®nances
Art. 23 SEA;
Art. 130 a±e of the Treaties
I, LUX
G, UK, NL
Germany yielded; G and
UK elaborated compromise
suggestion as a last offer
Art. 20 SEA;
Art. 102a of the Treaties
UK, G
Partial agreement with
restrictions
Art. 21, 22 SEA;
Art. 118a, b of the Treaties
Consent (unanimity rule
maintained)
Art. 25 SEA,
Declaration no. 9 (Annex
SEA); Art. 130r±t of the
Treaties
Could not be discussed any
further owing to lack of time
Consent; dispute over
institutional organization
±
Benelux,
UK, GR,
IRL, F,
DK
Commission
Benelux
Majority decision at Milan;
opponents outnumbered
Consent in principle, but
necessity for change of treaty
disputed; agreement by postponing ®xing of implementation regulations
Commissiond Refused
Foreign policy cooperation: creation of a
(separate) political
secretariat
Extension of European
Parliament's competences
French proposal, part of
German-French submission at
Milan
Genscher±Colombo initiative;
German submission at Milan;
submissions to IGC by G and B
Commission, UK, F
Benelux
Creation of the possibility of `institutional
differentiation'
French initiative; French
submission to IGC
Commission UK
a
Outcome
I
(P, SP)
Submissions to IGC by
Commission, NL and I
Genscher±Colombo initiative;
British and German±French
submission at Milan; submissions to IGC by I and NL
European Parliament demand,
Dooge Report; I, G
Mode of agreement
Agreement to compromise
suggestion: small extension of
competences (so-called
cooperation procedure)
Refused
Art. 30 SEA
IGC 1985
Art. 10 SEA,
Declaration no. 1
(Annex SEA); Extension
Art. 145 of the Treaties
±
Arts. 6±12 SEA
±
The table can be read only `positively'; i.e. a blank under `Supporters' or `Opponents' does not mean that the initiative was not supported or opposed but
that the data do not allow a secure and/or unequivocal identi®cation.
The Commission and the French government worked together in close cooperation after Milan to elaborate the initiative.
c
See the detailed table 6.1 (p. 158).
d
The Commission rejected the establishment of a separate secretariat, and demanded the `uniformity of the institutions'.
Source: based on the analysis of primary sources, interviews with actors and secondary literature (see note 35).
b
68
State-building and political entrepreneurship
± was not generally prescribed and was closely restricted to a few areas.
The institutional reform thus remained closely circumscribed. The role
of the supranational actors ± the Commission and the European
Parliament (see Bieber, Pantalis and Schoo 1986) ± had been strengthened only to a very small extent.
The SEA is a package solution based on logrolling. The Single
Market project had to include the interests of the countries with
comparatively higher standards of protection (health, environment, etc.)
as well as those of the economically less developed countries. As regards
cohesion policy regulations, it was a question of setting up ± under the
Commission's clear leadership ± the supporting measures of regional
policy for the Single Market, i.e. compensatory payments for opening
up markets in the Southern countries.
There was consent on embodying of research and technology policy
in the treaties. The controversial question was the extent to which the
interests of the three big contributors (Germany, France and the United
Kingdom) were to be protected by maintaining the principle of unanimity voting. The smaller member countries and the Commission
managed to enforce the introduction of majority voting on individual
research projects (Art. 130q), while unanimity remains necessary for the
adoption of framework programmes.37
The package character is also visible in respect to the inclusion of
monetary policy regulations. Opposing this inclusion, Germany and the
United Kingdom were confronted with a strong pressure group (France,
Belgium and the Commission being the core). In the course of the
conference, the German government realized that the entire package
was in danger if such regulations were not included. Annoying the
British, the German government gave up its principled resistance;
through close cooperation between Germany and the United Kingdom,
a compromise formula was elaborated beyond which both countries
were not prepared to go. Even if this primarily stipulated the status quo,
it did mean the explicit `embodiment' of a dossier, an important prerequisite for further dynamics in this ®eld.
Also, from the perspective of the individual countries it is evident that
the SEA was a package solution based on logrolling. In exchange for the
realization of the Single Market, the United Kingdom had to accept
institutional reforms, the inclusion of new competences in the treaties as
well as a predictable extension of regional compensation (cohesion
policy). The British government did not consider the price too high and
37
This outcome contradicts Moravcsiks' (1991) thesis that the SEA can be explained
solely by an agreement among the three big member states, which had a policy focusing
on the principle of the maintenance of sovereignty.
Tying up the Luxembourg package
69
was therefore quite satis®ed with what was achieved.38 The bartering
character is especially noticeable in a summarizing statement by the
British foreign secretary, Howe (1994: 457), on the ®rst stage of the
integration thrust in the 1980s:
The Cock®eld single-market programme was all put through pretty well on time
and we were enabled to carry the free-market case into other ®elds ± further
than many of our partners had expected. On the other hand we found ourselves
facing on some social and environmental matters a more extensive use of
Community powers than we had regarded as foreseeable or legitimate. Both
trends can probably be attributed to the impact of the Single European Act
upon what might be called the `culture' of the Community and its institutions.
The habit of working together, of sharing sovereignty, of give and take, which we
had so strongly urged for the Single Market was not something that could be
ruthlessly con®ned.
However, it would be wrong to reduce the SEA to a barter between
the United Kingdom and the other EC member states. The German
government put aside political doubts concerning the regulatory orientation of the planned common technology policy and agreed to a future
large ®nancial burden, reluctantly accepted monetary policy provisions
and had to accept distinct restrictions regarding the (desired) institutional reform. The original French integration project had a much
stronger emphasis on intergovernmental cooperation. Although the
initiative in technology policy can be considered partially a French
success, their integration project was only weakly embodied in other
areas. This includes social policy, and an extremely weak formulation
emphasizing the goal of monetary union was adopted only after a huge
effort.
The federalists, who were given some federalist rhetoric in the
Preamble, criticized the outcome. The SEA was far from being the
federalists' hoped-for `quantum leap'. In particular the improvement of
the position of the European Parliament was considered completely
inadequate. The European Parliament stated that the SEA, `in spite of
the few improvements it contains, is far from establishing the European
Union to which the Heads of State and of Government of the Member
38
Thatcher wrote that she had been pleased with what had been achieved in terms of the
content of the SEA and indicated that she had no regrets about having signed it.
Majority voting for the enforcement of its core element, the creation of the Single
Market, was accepted by all. In this manner the `interests of Great Britain' were
preserved: `I had surrendered no important British interest . . . The ®rst fruits of what
would be called the Single European Act were good for Britain. At last, I felt, we were
going to get the Community back on course, concentrating on its role as a huge market,
with all the opportunities that would bring to our industries.' (Thatcher 1993: 555f ).
For Taylor (1989: 14) `the SEA can be judged a considerable British achievement. In
its details it re¯ected UK interests in a nuanced and comprehensive way.' See Wurm
(1993: 347) and Middlemas (1995: 148).
70
State-building and political entrepreneurship
States have repeatedly made formal commitments'39. For the Commission, the SEA was `a compromise showing progress', even if on the
whole it did not ful®l the Commission's hopes.40 Delors announced the
continuation of the Commission's strategy.
Those who advocated more ambitious integration projects felt that
the negotiation process was disappointing on the whole; some even
thought it had been a `chainsaw massacre'. For these actors, however, it
was more important that after several years of total stagnation there had
been negotiations at all that offered the prospect of further integration
steps. The price had been high, since the nation-state lost its regulating
capacities as a result of the complete opening of the market, and their
substitution at supranational level was (and is) rather insecure. It is
precisely this dynamic perspective of certain actors that is decisive for
understanding the beginning of the integration thrust in the 1980s;
without it, the integration thrust of the 1980s, and especially the debate
about the `social dimension' and the project of economic and monetary
union, cannot be understood.
On 16 January 1986, despite its harsh criticism, the European
Parliament approved the SEA by 209 to 62 votes with 14 abstentions.
The Italian government had made the European Parliament's approval a
condition of its consent. The foreign ministers signed the SEA on
17 February 1986 in Luxembourg, with the exception of the Italian,
Greek and Danish foreign ministers. These had to await the outcome of
the Danish referendum on 27 February. The SEA was approved by 56.2
per cent of the Danish population, so that the last three foreign ministers
signed the SEA.
Conclusion
In the ®rst section, I suggested a list of conditions for the successfull
constitution of a negotiation package:
(1) prerequisite: common elements in the integration projects due to
relative convergence;
(2) political entrepreneurship and the formation of alliances;
(3) dynamizing factors: institutional procedures, projects to extend
integration, strategic postponement.
The process that led to the conquest of previous obstacles to integration
and to the constitution of a political package that could be adopted can
be reconstructed as follows:
The implementation of a Single Market and technological coopera39
40
European Parliament statement on 17 April 1986, in Gazzo (1986: 147f ).
EC Bulletin 12±1985, 1.1.1; see Gazzo (1986: 108f ).
Tying up the Luxembourg package
71
tion were the decisive common elements of the integration projects of
the political and economic actors starting in 1983, after the collapse of
the ®nal attempt to revitalize the Keynesian societal model (point (1)
above). Whether and to what extent these were to be linked to
institutional reform was controversial. The decision in favour of an
intergovernmental conference was enabled:
. because its opponents could not present a plausible alternative
process for reaching the objective of a Single Market;
. because of the pressure from the `federalist bloc' and the Commission, to whom the Single Market and institutional reform were part of
a project for further integration and who received support from the
French government for the extension of supranationality (point (2)),
. because of institutional mechanisms (majority decision for convening
an intergovernmental conference) (point (3)).
With the opening of `Pandora's box', a series of interested actors was
able to elaborate initiatives in various policy areas, which were embodied
in the Single European Act with varying success. In this process, the role
of the Commission was important because its skillful policy management contributed a lot to opening dossiers and leaving them open, as well
as ®nding compromise solutions (point (2)).
Studying the integration thrust in the 1980s shows that the Commission's treaty-based monopoly on initiatives does not apply in reality,
especially in speci®c historical phases such as the years from 1983.
Before the Commission's `rebirth', political entrepreneurship was
repeatedly taken up by individual national governments or certain
`blocks', sometimes even bypassing the Commission. This de®nitely
changed during the preparatory phase of the 1985 intergovernmental
conference. At an intergovernmental conference itself, the Commission's power is inevitably diminished, even if it exploits its role to the
full, as it did in 1985.
Part of the Commission's newly won strength can surely be explained
by the support from the German±French tandem; the entire reform
dynamics is unthinkable without its pace-making function (point (2)).
Additionally, the European economic elite supported the Commission in
the two core areas, which gave the Commission special possibilities of
in¯uence. The Commission successfully established a campaign around
the adopted Single Market programme to rehabilitate the EC as a whole.
The initiative was started from above, based on bargains between
political and economic elites. This continued the tradition of European
integration. Jacques Delors (1993: 3) de®ned it as the `Jean Monnet
method'. Accordingly, the method of the Community's founders
amounted to a `kind of enlightened despotic government':
72
State-building and political entrepreneurship
Competence and freedom of the mind were seen as a suf®cient legitimization for
action; the subsequent consent of the population was considered adequate. The
secret of success consisted of creating an inward dynamics, of clearing resistance
to integration by bundling different economic interests together and enabling
decisions on comprehensive negotiation packages. (Our translation)
This statement contains some of the aforementioned conditions for an
integration thrust: the creation of dynamics, the bundling of interests
and the creation of package solutions.
The interests behind the relaunch of European integration varied.
Some wanted to create a more adequate basis for economic competitiveness in the world market through the liberation from barriers to
economic rationality; others wanted to regain national sovereignty in the
sense of capacities for regulatory action and intervention with the
objective of elevating the social achievements of the postwar model to a
higher level. The fact that the outcome, the Single Act, corresponded
much more to the former interests only super®cially con®rms an interpretation of the process as lowest-common-denominator bargaining.
Rather, the many minor treaty amendments in the Act ± though
neglected in most analyses ± eventually turned out to be important for
subsequent integration dynamics.
II
The core elements in recasting the
European bargain
Without doubt, the internal market programme was the core element in
recasting the European bargain with the Single European Act of 1986.
Chapter 3 by Nicola Fielder reports the ®ndings from analysing the
relevant documents and from interviewing protagonists, witnesses and
experts (see list of interview partners in the appendix to this volume).
How energetically the Commission pushed the internal market and
how vigorously the European Roundtable of Industrialists demanded it
is clearly revealed by the empirical evidence. Chapter 3 points not only
to the mutually reinforcing constellation at this transnational and
supranational level, but also to the linkages between national
and supranational levels in explaining the decisive events of the mid1980s. The evidence for the latter ± which has already been suggested
in the literature ± thus slightly modi®es our original hypothesis.
The European proposals for technology corporatism are researched in
more detail in chapter 4 by Simon Parker. From this it becomes evident
that these initiatives go back to the late 1970s and also that the resulting
new procedures clearly pre-date the Single European Act, which,
however, included the by then established new praxis into Community
law. The ®nding of a certain post-SEA disintegration of the alliance
between the Commission and the Information Technology Roundtable
is worth mentioning. We will come back to this when we deal with
developments in a later period (see Part III).
The internal market as well as European technology corporatism were
obvious manifestations of elite bargains between the Commission and
the various Roundtables. How do we explain the other elements of the
integrational thrust of the 1980s? Chapter 5 by Patrick Ziltener analyses
why the cohesion target was anchored in the Luxembourg package and
suggests that the extension of EC regional policy was in principle a side
payment in order to gather enough support among the member states
for the core element of the revised treaty: the internal market. This
chapter shows that the alliance between the European Roundtable of
Industrialists and the Commission to push that core element would have
73
74
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
been ineffective if the Commission had not been successful in offering a
balanced package deal. In the end this initiated an important step in the
direction of a supranational structural policy and the beginning of a new
cohesion regime.
Was the politicization of social policy following the Single Act an
after-effect of intensi®ed economic integration or was weak social policy
regulation together with the abundance of social rhetoric merely an
expression of selling the elite pact to the European public? Neither was
the case, concludes Patrick Ziltener in chapter 6. He suggests that the
Europeanization of the social dimension was a cornerstone in the
Commission's integration project ± it was not of special interest to the
Roundtable and it was backed only by few governments. This suggests
clear evidence for the Commission's own interests in this area, independent from both the Roundtable and most governments. Why, then, was
the social dimension ranked relatively low in the Luxembourg package?
The design of this policy area in the Act agreed upon in early 1986
remained narrow for merely tactical reasons so as not to endanger the
strategic goal of the renewal of the societal model in a European framework. The tactical procedure of anchoring this policy area moderately in
the Single Act was risky. In the long run, the entire strategy, as measured
by the original intentions of the supranational political entrepreneur,
failed ± as evidenced by the defeat of the Delorist project.
3
The origins of the Single Market
Nicola Fielder
Introduction
The Single European Act was formally approved by the European
Council in February 1986. When Maastricht hit the headlines in the
early 1990s, the Single European Act instantly became history.
However, it was the Single Market programme ± the main content of
the Single European Act ± and the years of preparation leading up to it
that really gave new momentum to European integration after the
`Eurosclerosis' of the 1970s.
The process that led to the Single European Act was never publicly
discussed. The architects and initiators of the Single Market have not
become household names; however, it is these protagonists and their
efforts that are the subject of this chapter.
The thesis guiding our empirical research on the new momentum
in European integration suggests a collaboration between the Commission of the European Communities and European transnational
business represented by the European Roundtable of Industrialists, as
stated in more detail in chapter 1. This explanation contrasts with
other theories, which have placed the governments of the three main
European Community member states ± Germany, France and the
United Kingdom ± in the foreground. The empirical evidence to
support our explanation was gathered by analysing various articles and
papers and the of®cial documents of the European Communities and
from interviews with witnesses and protagonists of the integration
process.
Three main points from the contents of the Single European Act must
be emphasized. First, Article 13, which provides an amendment to
Article 8a of the EEC Treaty, requests the institutions of the Community `to adopt measures with the aim of progressively establishing the
internal market over a period expiring on 31 December 1992. The
internal market shall comprise an area without internal frontiers in
which the free movement of goods, persons, services and capital is
75
76
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
ensured in accordance with the provisions of this Treaty.' Secondly, the
Single European Act states that unanimity of decisions is no longer
required for regulations and directives pertaining to the establishment of
the internal market, but that `the Council shall issue directives, acting by
a quali®ed majority'. Thirdly, the Single European Act moves away
from the objective of a harmonization of national laws and regulations,
which had proven time consuming and fruitless, and calls for the mutual
recognition of laws and regulations between member states, setting only
minimal standards.
The Single European Act was the decisive step towards the completion of the internal market, installing the relevant proposals of the
White Paper of 1985 as Community law. The White Paper from the
Commission to the European Council contains 300 proposals necessary
for the completion of the common market and includes a timetable for
the realization of the proposals made.
But what were the reasons for this sudden acceleration of European
integration? Why did it happen in the early to mid-1980s? Who were the
main actors behind this relaunching of the Single European Market?
Theoretical explanations have been suggested in chapter 1. Here we
look at the empirical evidence. At the level of the formal legislative
process, it is impossible to decide between the competing hypotheses
(see chapter 1). Of course, the Council formally approved the Single
European Act with its core new element of the Single Market. For
constitutional reasons, this could not be otherwise. However, in order to
glimpse behind the scenes ± to detect and clarify the social forces at
work and to see who were the important protagonists ± we analysed
documents published before the decision. This is described in the next
section of this chapter. In order to substantiate our explanation, we had
to verify the documents and supplement them with interviews with
protagonists and witnesses. This was necessary because our thesis
stresses the informal relationships and negotiations between the representatives of different social forces which, precisely because of their
informal character, are not clearly re¯ected in documents. In the
following section we therefore present in detail the evidence from our
interviews. In order to demonstrate the parallel development of initiatives from the Commission and from the Roundtable of European
Industrialists, we then present the sequence of initiatives taken by the
European Roundtable to push the Single Market. Finally, we evaluate
this evidence against the claim that the Council, and especially the three
big member states, pushed the initiative. Here, we draw on valuable
evidence from interviews with members of the Committee of Permanent
Representatives (COREPER).
The origins of the Single Market
77
What the of®cial documents reveal
The ®rst document to be looked at is the White Paper of June 1985
from the Commission to the European Council (CEC 1985). The
White Paper consists of 300 proposals and was compiled by the
Commission; the full title is Completing the Internal Market. White Paper
from the Commission to the European Council. Various authors attribute a
lot of the writing of the White Paper to Lord Cock®eld, the Internal
Market Commissioner in the ®rst Delors Commission, but not all of it.
The most relevant part of the White Paper, as far as the question of
the actors in the acceleration of the integration process is concerned, is
the introduction, which includes quotes from declarations by the
European Council and states:
The Heads of State and Governments at the European Council meeting in
Copenhagen in 1982 pledged themselves to the completion of the internal
market as a high priority. The pledge was repeated at Fontainebleau in June
1984; at Dublin in December of that year; and, most recently, in March 1985.
The time for talk has now passed. The time for action has come. That is what
this White Paper is about. (CEC 1985: 5)
As Lord Cock®eld said in an interview (9 March 1993), these declarations were quoted deliberately not to pay tribute to the heads of
government but to nail them, to demonstrate to them that what was
proposed in the White Paper, was what they had asked for and, in doing
so, to force them to take positive action ± a point also emphasized by
Maria Green Cowles (1995). A further important fact is that the
necessity for mutual recognition of laws and regulations and a return to
majority voting are already included in the White Paper and do not ®rst
appear in the Single European Act (see also chapter 2).
In the White Paper various references are made to previous documents
pertaining to the internal market, for instance the `Programme of the
Commission for 1985', which was presented to the European Parliament
on 6 March, in which the Commission states that: `The Commission will
be asking the European Council to pledge itself to completion of a fully
uni®ed internal market by 1992' (CEC 1985: 4). The document on
Consolidating the Internal Market (CEC 1984b) includes the following
central statements, which we quote here in full:
4. If the bene®cial effects of the internal market have been only partly realised,
this is because, in spite of the spectacular progress made in the 1960s, the
integration process slowed noticeably in the second half of the 1970s as the
periods of economic recession were accompanied by a foot-dragging decline in
the decision-making capacity of the Community lawgivers and by a decline in
the observance of rules laid down by law. But in the early 1980s the European
78
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
Council imparted a fresh political impetus and signi®cantly revived the process
of establishing the internal market. (pp. 1f )
8. This decisive breakthrough [realization of the internal market] will require
neither new policies nor new budgetary resources. But what is needed is the
adoption of a limited number of proposals that are already before the Council,
the bene®cial effects of which will far outweigh the adjustment efforts
intrinsically associated with this dynamic venture. (p. 3)
44. The Council's inaction cannot relieve the Commission of its obligation to
take whatever measures are necessary to ensure the free movement of goods
within the Community under conditions which are consistent with the aims of
the Treaty. (p. 14)
The `fresh political impetus' mentioned under point 4 of the document
came at least in part from the Commission itself, as the documents
Communication from the Commission to the Council on the State of the
Internal Market (COM (81) 313) of 17 June 1981 and Commission
Communication to the Council on Re-activating the European Internal
Market (COM (82) 735) of 15 November 1982 show. Here again are
some of the central comments in full detail:
III. However, the continental dimension of the European internal market is an
indispensable condition for the success of the historic process of structural
change which European industry must carry out in the eighties, to ensure the
consolidation of the international competitiveness of European industry and to
reaf®rm the European Community as the most important partner in world
trade. (CEC 1981a: 2)
V. The decline in con®dence which threatens the internal market must
immediately be halted by convincing political action. (ibid: 2)
VII. The European Council is therefore requested
± to con®rm the basic importance of the internal market for the Community
and emphasize the need for its rapid achievement;
± to instruct the Council of Ministers to achieve tangible progress in the second
half of 1981. (ibid: 3)
Another interesting paragraph on the very ®rst page of COM (82) 735
demonstrates the strong belief of the Commission that European
businesses must be assured that their activities will be able to develop in
an economic unit comparable in size to those of Japan and America. The
Commission states that such assurance has not been achieved because
the necessary decisions have not been taken by the Council, despite the
fact that the problem issues have been clearly identi®ed and fully
discussed (CEC 1982a: 1).
These statements show that the Commission realized the importance,
in fact the necessity, of a Single Market for European business, even if
they do not speci®cally state that European business was at that time
pushing for such a programme.
The origins of the Single Market
79
The documents show clearly the energetic support of the Single
Market programme from the Commission. The answers given by the
European Council, on the other hand, appear as automatic responses
without any real content. As early as 1982 the European Council
declared: `The European Council . . . instructs the Council: ± to decide,
before the end of March 1983, on the priority measures proposed by the
Commission to reinforce the internal market.'1 Very little was forthcoming, however. One year later the same applied to the `Solemn
Declaration on European Union' (pp. 1f ):
The Heads of State or Government of the member states of the European
Communities, meeting within the European Council, are convinced that, in
order to resolve the serious economic problems facing the member states, the
Community must strengthen its cohesion, regain its dynamism and intensify its
action in areas hitherto insuf®ciently explored.
And, in the same document:
The Heads of State or Government underline the particular importance of the
Commission as guardian of the Treaties of Paris and Rome and as a driving
force in the process of European integration. They con®rm the value of making
more frequent use of the possibility of delegating powers to the Commission
within the framework of the Treaties. (ibid.: 11)
However, the heads of state or government allowed themselves plenty of
time, stating that they would `subject this Declaration to a general
review as soon as the progress achieved towards European uni®cation
justi®es such action, but not later than ®ve years from signature of the
Declaration' (ibid.: 20).
The main results of the analysis of Community documents are
presented chronologically in table 3.1.
The analysis of documents provided a ®rst indication of the importance of the Commission in pushing the Single Market programme into
being; similar evidence cannot be found in the documents adopted by
the European Council.
European business is also mentioned in the European Communities'
documents as a chief supporter of the internal market programme.
Further evidence for the importance of these actors was then gathered
from interviews with witnesses and further documentation, including an
article by the president of FIAT, Giovanni Agnelli (1989), which states
that `1992 was born for sound economic reasons and those forces
continue to be its engine. Ironically, it was politicians who in 1957 ®rst
1
`Declarations by the European Council Relating to the Internal Market', in Completing
the Internal Market. White Paper from the Commission to the European Council. June 1985,
p. 3. These declarations were included in the White Paper in order to nail the heads of
governments to comments they had made, according to Lord Cock®eld in the interview
I did with him.
80
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
Table 3.1. Steps towards the Single Market as the core element of the Single
European Act
. Communication from the Commission to the Council on the State of the Internal Market
(17 June 1981, COM (81) 313 ®nal):
The decline in con®dence which threatens the internal market must immediately be halted
by convincing political action. (p. 2)
This initiative was on the agenda of the Meeting of the Council, 29 ±30 July 1981.
Although the European Council (heads of governments and states), meeting on 29 and 30
June, `echoed the alarm sounded by the Commission', there was no effective action
(quoted from the Communication from the Commission to the Council: Consolidating the
Internal Market, June 1984, p. 8).
. Commission Communication to the Council on Re-Activating the European Internal Market
(15 November 1982, COM (82) 735 ®nal):
As the Commission has never ceased to af®rm . . . European undertakings must be assured
that their activities will be able to develop in an economic unit similar in size to the American
market and distinctly bigger than the Japanese market (. . .) To date, this has not been
achieved. Although the problem issues have been clearly identi®ed and fully discussed, the
decisions have not yet been taken. (p. 1)
Following this the European Council convened in Copenhagen, 3±4 December 1982:
`The Heads of State and Governments at the European Council meeting in Copenhagen
in 1982 pledged themselves to the completion of the internal market as a high priority'
(quoted from the White Paper, CEC 1985: 5). The outcome of the meeting was highly
in¯uential on the Solemn Declaration on European Union in Stuttgart, 19 June 1983.
. (Communication from the Commission to the Council: Consolidating the Internal Market
(13 June 1984, COM (84) 305 ®nal):
The Council's inaction cannot relieve the Commission of its obligation to take whatever
measures are necessary to ensure the free movement of goods within the Community under
conditions which are consistent with the aims of the treaty. (p. 14)
The renewed drive will produce results only if the business community is again convinced
that the European market is attractive. (p. 3)
This initiative was highly in¯uential on the following events:
The Meeting of the European Council in Fontainebleau, 25±26 June 1984:
It [the European Council] asks the Council and the Member States to put in hand without
delay a study of the measures which could be taken to bring about in the near future the
abolition of all police and customs formalities for people crossing intra-Community
frontiers. (Quoted from the White Paper, `Declarations by the European Council Relating to
the Internal Market', CEC 1985: 3)
The Meeting of the Council in Dublin, 3±4 December 1984:
The European Council . . . agreed that the Council, in its appropriate formations, should
take steps to complete the Internal Market, including implementation of European
standards. (Quoted from the White Paper, `Declarations by the European Council Relating
to the Internal Market', CEC 1985: 3)
The `Programme of the Commission for 1985', presented to the European Parliament on 6 March
1985:
The Commission will be asking the European Council to pledge itself to completion of a
fully uni®ed internal market by 1992.
The origins of the Single Market
81
The Meeting of the Council in Brussels, 29±30 March 1985:
[T]he European Council laid particular emphasis on the following . . . ®elds of action:
(a) action to achieve a single large market by 1992 thereby creating a more favourable
environment for stimulating enterprise, competition and trade; it called upon the Commission to draw up a detailed programme with a speci®c timetable before its next meeting.
(Quoted from the White Paper, `Declarations by the European Council Relating to the
Internal Market' CEC 1985: 3)
. Completing the Internal Market: White Paper from the Commission to the European Council
( June 1985):
The Heads of State and Governments at the European Council meeting in Copenhagen in
1982 pledged themselves to the completion of the internal market as a high priority. The
pledge was repeated at Fontainebleau in June 1984; at Dublin in December of that year;
and, most recently, in March 1985. The time for talk has now passed. The time for action
has come. That is what this White Paper is about. (p. 5)
Europe stands at the crossroads. We either go ahead ± with resolution and determination ±
or we drop back into mediocrity. We can now either resolve to complete the integration
of the economies of Europe; or, through a lack of political will to face the immense problems
involved, we can simply allow Europe to develop into no more than a free trade area.
(p. 55)
The White Paper was approved at the Meeting of the European Council, Milan, June
1985.
. Single European Act (1987)
The Single European Act . . . is an expression of the political resolve voiced by the Heads of
State or Government, notably at Fontainebleau in June 1984, then at Brussels in March
1985 and at Milan in June 1985, to transform the whole complex of relations between their
States into a European Union, in line with the Stuttgart Solemn Declaration of June 1983.
(p. 27)
conceived the idea of a common market ± often over objections from the
business community. Now the situation has been reversed; it is the
entrepreneurs and corporations who are keeping the pressure on politicians to transcend considerations of local and national interest.'
What our interviews revealed
The interview partners consisted of two former Commissioners, both
repeatedly named by various authors as important protagonists in
launching the completion of the Single Market, one member of the
internal market Directorate General in one of the aforementioned
Commissioners' team, four representatives of national governments and
as such members of the Committee of Permanent Representatives, two
founder members of the European Roundtable of Industrialists, the
head of the European representative of®ce of a major European corporation, and a top of®cial of the Union of Industries of the European
82
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
Community (UNICE), all of whom had been in Brussels since the early
1980s or longer; and other informants (see list of interviewees in the
appendix to this volume).
Only a few interviewees expressed the need to remain anonymous;
most seemed used to being interviewed for articles and their names
being mentioned. However, in respect for the wishes of some of the
interviewees, only three witnesses will be named here as they are
extremely important protagonists and did not express the wish to
remain anonymous.2
Lord Cock®eld served as Minister of State for the UK Treasury from
May 1979 to April 1982, as Secretary of State for Trade from April
1982 until June 1983, and as Chancellor of the Duchy of Lancaster
from 1983 until his nomination by Margaret Thatcher as British
Commissioner in September 1984. During his term as Secretary of
State for Trade he served as the British representative on the Internal
Market Council, which was founded by the European Council in
Copenhagen in December 1982. He was a vice-president of the Commission and was Commissioner responsible for the Directorates
General Internal Market (DG III), Customs Union and Taxation
(DG XXI) and Financial Institutions (DG XV).
Vicomte Davignon was Commissioner for Belgium in two EC Commission terms of of®ce. From 1977 until 1981 he was head of the
internal market Directorate General (DG III) and from 1981 until the
end of 1984 he was the Commissioner responsible for industry, energy
and research. Since 1987 he has headed the SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale de
Belgique and become a member of the European Roundtable of
Industrialists, the body he himself established in 1983.
Professor Dr. W. Dekker was President of Philips Electronics N.V. for
many years. He has recently become chairman of the Supervisory Board
of Philips. From 1988 until 1992 he was chairman of the European
Roundtable of Industrialists and has been a member of the Roundtable
since the very beginning.
The Philips company actively supported the European market integration process. In 1985, for instance, the company submitted a report
to the Commission entitled `Europe 1990. An Action Plan for Europe'.
The report was prepared under Wisse Dekker's instruction and was seen
by most observers as the basis for the White Paper (see Dekker 1984,
1985b).
2
I will, however, refrain from putting names to any of the quotations taken from the
interviews, as some of the interviewees asked not to be quoted. This was mainly due to
the fact that not all the interviews were held in the interviewee's mother tongue, which
inhibited two of the candidates.
The origins of the Single Market
83
One of the ®rst points to be evaluated was the names mentioned by
the interviewees. Generally, Jacques Delors and Lord Cock®eld were
spoken of as the most important people at the time in pushing the
integration process forward. Etienne Davignon is seen as the initiator
and promoter of discussions between the European Community and the
European industrialists regarding what was necessary to keep European
industry in competition with the United States and Japan. These
dicussions led to Esprit and various other invaluable programmes.
Another name that was mentioned frequently was that of Karl-Heinz
Narjes, the Commissioner responsible for the Internal Market General
Directorate before Lord Cock®eld:3
Davignon of course after a while left the Commission, because he had been
there for two terms and then he went to the SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale de Belgique and
he also became a member of the European Roundtable of Industrialists and he
has been absolutely one of the driving forces, he has been very active and very
useful.
Well, in fact less spectacular progress had already been made by the previous
Commission under the leadership of Mr. Narjes, who was then responsible for
industry, but that was more a process of petits pas . . . and then the company
Philips of Eindhoven, they presented here a sort of agenda for European
enterprises towards integration and it was all about the internal market, so that
when President Delors came and when Lord Cock®eld was nominated to be
responsible for these matters, they put the threads together and made a formal
proposal, a comprehensive proposal of all that had to be done to achieve a true
Single Market and they attached to it a timetable, and those two elements ±
comprehensiveness and a timetable, a ®xed calendar ± were the main causes of
success and these two aspects facilitated the progress towards the internal
market.
Various interviewees said that the success of Delors and Cock®eld was
based on work done by Narjes, but that they were the ones who
succeeded in putting the work into a simple political programme that
could be easily implemented and that included an end date.
It is interesting to see that the names mentioned ®rst were names of
members of the Commission. The importance of the Commission as a
whole was also emphasized by all the interviewees, for example in the
following quotations:
Underlying this is what has always been my view and also Jacques Delors' view
3
Karl-Heinz Narjes was chef de cabinet of Walter Hallstein during Hallstein's presidency of
the Commission (1958±1967). He then headed the Directorate General for press and
information until 1972, when he returned to German politics. From 1981 he again
headed a Directorate General, this time taking responsibility for the internal market and
customs union in the Thorn Commission. He continued to play an important role in the
®rst Delors Commission, taking over new responsibilities such as information
technology.
84
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
and that is that the Commission is the driving force of the Community, it always
has been. If you look at the times when the Community makes great progress,
it's because you had a strong Commission. The Community made great
progress when you had a strong Commission under Hallstein at the beginning,
the Community made great progress when you had a strong president in
Jacques Delors in the ®rst of the Delors Commissions, when you get a weaker
Commission, in the second Commission, progress is slower and when you get a
much weaker Commission, as you have under the third Delors Commission,
you wonder really where you're looking to for the progress at all. The
Commission is the driving force of the Community and this is why it's so
important that it's right of initiative should neither be taken away nor watered
down and it is of necessity that the Commission is the driving force, because if
you have twelve member states where else can the driving force come from,
because the tendency of member states is to start by looking after their own
interests. I've always said that the Community is a little bit like a stage-coach
drawn by twelve horses some of which have got harnessed in the wrong way
round; it's only the chap with the whip who makes them run at all and the chap
with the whip is the Commission.
The Commission itself, President Delors, his Commissioner for the Internal
Market and Industry, and the ministers of industry at that time [were the main
actors in the Single Market project]. Also important is the fact that the social
partners in the Community ®rst have been invited to discuss together at
Community level with President Delors about all consequences of the internal
market, this has been the beginning of the social dialogue, and, secondly, they
have rapidly agreed on supporting the Commission in [its] efforts to pushing the
governments ahead and I think the Commission has played a very effective and
well-organized role.
Because of the fact that the local governments are so reluctant very often to act
and to give away a little bit of their authority, they have created a vacuum, in
that vacuum Brussels, the Commission has worked, they have taken initiatives,
Cock®eld, the White Paper, and other things, they take initiatives.
Two interviewees mentioned that, as the Council does not have any
right of initiative, the initiatives must come from the Commission. All
interviewees con®rmed the active and creative role of the Commission
among the European Community institutions. However, all the interviewees voiced the opinion that the support the Commission received
from European industrialists for the Single Market programme was
absolutely vital.
I think [the in¯uence of the European Roundtable of Industrialists on the
Commission and the White Paper was] very strong, but not to such an extent
that the industry could more or less dictate what they have to do; that of course
was impossible, but there has been a very, very fruitful cooperation between the
Roundtable and the Commission.
Once a majority of industrialists, not only industrialists, I mean, services and so
on and so forth, started playing an important role, once the reaction that the
The origins of the Single Market
85
governments began getting from what I call in a vague term economic operators
became: `No, this is not nonsense, you must look at this carefully, because we
are interested in this also,' there was a change in the atmosphere, so what came
about was a certain consistency, in between what the people were saying
everywhere, people who didn't like it were saying it in Brussels and were saying
it at home, people who liked it were saying it in Brussels and were also saying it
at home, and so this created a sense that something might happen and created
this sense of delegation and enterprise, which I think was very important. I
think, if the Commission comes up with the best proposals in the world, which
nobody supports, they will die; it needs somebody who says, it's not only
intellectually interesting or stimulating, it's also something ± and I can
permanently come back to my point ± that we need (. . .).
In addition to showing the connections between the Commission and
industry, these quotes also suggest support for Stephen George's (1993)
network theory, which stresses the importance of looking at the links
between the national and the supranational levels.
Other EC institutions are not reported in the interviews to have had
close contact with the industrialists and are not mentioned as important
actors in the process of completing the internal market. Contact with
the Council was and is mostly indirect through the Commission or via
the national governments.
The European Parliament was said to have supported the work of the
Commission, but its role was not actually emphasized by any of the
interviewees. The most important national politicians appear to have
been Kohl, Thatcher and Mitterrand, but in their roles as ®nal decisionmakers not as initiators.
The interviews with former Permanent Representatives showed that
the work of the Committee of Permanent Representatives has increased
over the years, but again they are not initiators; they build more
permanent links between the Commission and the national governments
and prepare decisions, trying to come to a general agreement before a
proposal is put before the Council. The UNICE of®cial was the only
interviewee who mentioned working with the Permanent Representatives. Members of the European Roundtable go directly to their government leaders with what they have to say. One member did not even
know what the Committee of Permanent Representatives is.
All the interview partners emphasized the fact that the Single
European Act was the result of a new impetus and not the reason for it.
The Single European Act did at the time produce other innovations, but
the Euro-pessimism of the seventies was broken by new initiatives as
early as 1981 and 1982.
The belief that global structural changes and the failure of national
strategies were an important prerequisite for the acceleration of the
86
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
integration process, which all the authors on European integration
voiced, is echoed in the remarks of the interviewees:
It became clear that there was an important concern about the increased
competition out of Japan and out of the United States and so it became clear
that the instrument which was lacking to improve the competitivity of the
European industry was to enjoy the advantages of one single market, and it
slowly ®ltered through that this was a real need.
[I]f we want to survive in the world of competition, especially vis-aÁ-vis the
Japanese, that we have to have an economy of scale, as an industry we must have
an economy of scale, and the economy of scale was not available at that time,
because we were operating in all kinds of different countries. (. . .) So then the
idea . . . gradually became very clear that we must have a united Europe, and of
course there was the EC, there was the Treaty of Rome, but there was not much
substance in it yet, it was all political talk and there was not much done really for
industry, so then we thought we should give it a little push.
[A]bove all there was the industrial syndrome, and this is terribly important,
that during the last ten years, the lost ten years, the United States and Japan had
continued to surge ahead and Europe had fallen behind and there is one statistic
I always used to quote, because you only need one, and that was that in the ®eld
of information technology the European Community accounted for 30 per cent
of the demand and 10 per cent of the production. You only need that one
statistic to show what had happened.
In summary, the interviews show a general consensus for the hypothesis of Commission leadership with invaluable support from European
industry. This support was made very clear at both national and supranational level, and was perhaps voiced most comprehensively by the
members of the European Roundtable of Industrialists, although they
were certainly not alone. In various statements made during the interviews it became apparent that the Commission was the European Community institution to which industry and other organizations made their
needs known. Very little direct contact was kept up with the Council and
even less with members of the Committee of Permanent Representatives, although such contacts did exist. However, contacts were made via
governments.
There also seems to be general agreement on the main protagonists:
Delors, Cock®eld, Davignon and, in the preliminary stages, Narjes.
There is a slight question mark over who gave the European Single
Market programme its end date of 1992. Some claim it was Delors;
others say it was Lord Cock®eld. What is clear is that the actual
achievement of putting the proposals for the creation of a Single Market
into a simple yet complete political programme with a clear time-frame
was one of the most important steps towards the completion of the
internal market.
The origins of the Single Market
87
One comment frequently made about Delors was that after his
election as president of the Commission he travelled to all the national
governments and discovered that there was agreement in one policy area
and that was the Single Market, which was why he made this his goal. I
propose that this agreement had been reached as a result of preparatory
work by the previous Commission, but also of the in¯uence of industrialists on their national governments.
Lord Cock®eld undeniably played a leading role in the integration
process over a long period of time, as he himself is quick to recall.
However, he could not have succeeded on his own. He received great
support from Delors, as he remarks in a speech he made in December
1992 (Cock®eld 1992: 3):
In these more troubled days when reputations can so often be clouded by
unjusti®ed criticism may I say that the complete trust invested in me by Jacques
Delors, his clarity of vision and unfailing support were a major factor in the
success of my own endeavours.
For quite some time he also enjoyed the support of Margaret Thatcher.
Furthermore, one must not forget that he was also supported by all the
other Directors General and their staff, not to mention his own staff, as
he states in the same speech mentioned above and as mentioned by one
of the interviewees. There were very few people in the Commission who
did not support the Single Market programme wholeheartedly.
If Cock®eld was the main executor of the completion of the internal
market, Davignon ± whose support for the integration process continued long after he left the Commission ± was certainly the far-sighted
political entrepreneur who paved the way. His visions (see chapter 1)
and efforts to set up contacts with industry and his initiative to establish
the European Roundtable of Industrialists ± thus creating important
channels through which the demands and proposals of industry could
be communicated ± were vital elements on the road to a Single Market.
The initiatives of the European Roundtable of
Industrialists
Founded in 1983, the European Roundtable of Industrialists was the
strongest and most visible supporter of the Commission's Single Market
programme, though not the only one. Its efforts to in¯uence national
governments were invaluable, (see also chapter 9). The members are
charismatic personalities who have something to say and are used to
making themselves heard.
It is not a coincidence that a Commissioner ± Etienne Davignon ± was
one of the main instigators of the Roundtable. The cooperation between
88
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
Commission and Roundtable has continued, although it is perhaps less
intense now than it was at the time of the build-up to and the
implementation of the Single Market programme as the core element of
the Single European Act.
The similarity of the views of the protagonists from both the Commission and the European Roundtable of Industrialists was obviously
already evident at the beginning of the 1980s. The Commission argued
in one of its 1982 communications to the Council that European ®rms
must be assured that their activities would be able to develop in an
economic unit similar in size to the American market and distinctly
bigger than the Japanese market (see table 3.1). The Roundtable
expressed the very same view in its ®rst Policy Memorandum, of®cially
handed over to the Commission in June 1983. This stated that, despite
the efforts of the European Community to liberalize trade, Europe
remained fragmented into national markets, which prevented enterprises from reaching the size necessary to compete with non-European
corporations. It demanded that the European market must develop into
a single `home' base in order for European companies to become better
competitors (see table 3.2).
In analogy to table 3.1, the development of the initiatives taken by the
Roundtable is presented in table 3.2. The table shows the chronological
initiatives taken by the European Roundtable of Industrialists to
promote and accelerate the Single Market programme. What is striking
is the parallel development of the initiatives from the Commission and
from the Roundtable. This substantiates the evidence from our interviews, which stress the close cooperation between both groups of
protagonists to push the project of an effective Single Market.
We can thus conclude that our research has produced a variety of
evidence that clearly contradicts the contention by Moravcsik (1991)
that the initiative was taken by the big three prevailing in the Council.
Rather, our theoretical explanation of an elite pact between the
European transnationals and the EC Commission is empirically substantiated by the documents as well as by our interviews with witnesses,
who con®rm the tight cooperation between the Roundtable and the
Commission in preparing the Single Market.
Discussion
One could object that, in relying on of®cial documents and on interviews with members of the Commission and of the European business
elite, one naturally dismisses the role the Council and the big three
member states played (as suggested by the competing hypothesis).
The origins of the Single Market
89
Table 3.2. The role of industry: steps of the European Roundtable of
Industrialists towards the Single European Act and beyond
1982/1983: P. Gyllenhammar promotes a `Marshall Plan for Europe' to increase growth
and to build industry and infrastructure in Europe.
Autumn 1982: Meeting between Gyllenhammar and Davignon. List of possible
candidates for a European Roundtable of Industrialists.
6±7 April 1983: ®rst meeting of the European Roundtable. First point of discussion: the
lack of a homogeneous Euro-market.
1 June 1983: second meeting: `European Roundtable Charter'.
10 June 1983: Memorandum to Commissioner Davignon: `Foundations for the Future of
European Industry':
The European market must serve as the uni®ed `home' base necessary to allow European
®rms to develop as powerful competitors in world markets.'
January 1984: third meeting of the European Roundtable: European Venture Capital
Association (EVCA) formally announced, designed to encourage transnational investments in Europe and forge close relations between new technologically innovative ®rms
and large industrial companies.
December 1984: `Missing Links: Upgrading Europe's Transborder Infrastructure': ®rst
of®cial report published by the European Roundtable:
It has been evident since six nations signed the Treaty of Rome in 1957 that Europe's
political and economic destiny lay in closer co-operation and fewer trade barriers. Yet
progress towards the creation of a European Common Market continues to be frustratingly
slow. (p. 7)
11 January 1985: `Europe 1990: An Agenda for Action' (Philips/Wisse Dekker).
June 1985: `Changing Scales'.
14 June 1985: European Roundtable±EC Commission meeting. (Since June 1985
European Roundtable±Commission meetings have taken place every six months.)
28 November 1985: telexes from CEOs of major European multinational companies to
their national governments:
As leading industrialists based in the European Communities . . . we urge you to exercise
your full in¯uence so that the forthcoming topmeeting will produce concrete results. Stop.
Not only is the credibility of European political leaders at stake, but European industry
badly needs a clear signal that the major objectives of the Treaty of Rome will be realised
within the next ®ve years. Stop. Even a clear statement that this would not be the case,
would ± although not hoped for ± be helpful as this would end the prolonged period of
uncertainty with which industry has to cope under the present situation and which forms a
signi®cant obstacle on the way to expanding our activities and intensifying our efforts to
build a strong and competitive European position.' (Telex from Wisse Dekker to J. C.
Ramaer, 28 November 1985)
June 1986: `Europe is Urgent' symposium. Watchdog group: Internal Market Support
Committee (IMSC).
September 1986: `Making Europe Work'.
June 1987: statement by IMSC on indirect taxes and message to government leaders at
the Luxembourg summit: `show political will, or European industry will invest elsewhere'.
December 1987: letter from Sir Patrick Sheehy (IMSC) to Lord Cock®eld:
The IMSC. . .remains in full support of your proposals as the only means of removing the
barriers at the frontiers and we have taken every opportunity to say so to national
governments. It will be no surprise to you to learn that we have had a very negative response.
We have therefore decided to redouble our efforts to ®nd ways of presenting our arguments
in a persuasive way.' (Quoted in Maria Green Cowles 1995: 519f )
90
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
First of all, it has never been a question of debate that the Council is
de jure the decision-maker in the European Community and it is not a
matter of debate here. It is a given fact. The question remains, however,
of how these decisions are made and how much initiative comes from
the Council.
Looking at the evidence presented above and by Green Cowles
(1995) in full detail, it is revealed that in the case of the Single Market
the Council was not left with much room to decide. The governments of
the member states knew exactly what was at stake. They had been
lobbied by industrialists in their own countries and urged by the
Commission which path of action should be taken.
What was the role of the members of the Committee of Permanent
Representatives, the mediators between the Council and the Commission? They prepare all the decisions of the various Councils and thereby
render the workload of the ministers and heads of state and government
more manageable. If the permanent representatives in their preparatory
meetings have found that an issue is uncontested among the member
states, then the Council simply gives the ®nal stamp of approval. In
other cases there may be some details left for debate. On the other hand,
the permanent representatives also inform the Commission about the
views of the Council. In some cases the Commission may modify its
proposals if they meet with strong resistance in the preparatory discussions of the Committee of Permanent Representatives.
Our interviews with members of the Committee of Permanent Representatives, however, did not reveal any indication of the Committee of
Permanent Representatives being involved in any sort of initiative
regarding the Single Market. This adds to the evidence that the Council
or heads of governments were not the initiators. In fact the Single
Market project was so well prepared that it went through Council fairly
smoothly in the end.
How energetically the internal market project was pushed by the
Commission is clearly revealed by our empirical work. This political
initiative of the Commission was not exceptional, because within the
European Community the Commission is a supranational body, whose
independence from the member states was already set out in the treaties
of 1958. The Commission is at the same time a partner of and in
opposition to the Council (Fusion Treaty, Article 15). Because of the
multitude of its functions the Commission plays a key role within
the Community ± it is its motor, has a right to make proposals in the
legal process (which then are agreed upon or rejected by the Council)
and holds the mandate to take initiatives. The plans, programmes
and memoranda of the Commission advance the development of the
The origins of the Single Market
91
Community. All this was agreed upon in the treaties in effect since 1958.
The Commission did not always use its power to launch initiatives, as
was mentioned in chapter 2. One must be careful, however, to avoid
simply seeing the Commission as a homogeneous entity. As one interviewee pointed out, even in a weak Commission, such as the Thorn
Commission, there were what he termed `barons', strong Commissioners, in this case Davignon and Ortoli.
A further important fact is the openness of the Commission towards
industry and organizations such as UNICE. As one interviewee put it,
`in some ways the Commission welcomes the in¯uence of pressure
groups'. When we review the role of the European Roundtable of
Industrialists, we must not forget that industry is represented by other
organizations as well. In the case of the Single Market, however, the
European Roundtable was the predominant representative. But it would
be false to conclude that European big business could dictate; rather
`there has been very, very fruitful cooperation between the Roundtable
and the Commission', as one of the protagonists stated in his interview.
This is what our hypotheses spelled out in chapter 1 suggest, and it is
modelled in ®gure 1.1 on page 36 as a bold line ± without arrows ±
between the two actors. It was a close cooperation of the two actors.
They both needed each other and neither could have succeeded without
the support of the other.
This, however, was not only a mutually reinforcing constellation at
the supranational level, but also a multi-level phenomenon. Linkages
between national and supranational levels in explaining European integration processes are also emphasized by Stephen George (1993).
Indeed, we found that the in¯uence of the European transnational
corporations was exerted not only directly on the Commission, but also
through their national governments, which were thus compelled to fall
into line with the Commission. In addition, the Commission not only
could count on European big business lobbying their governments but
strengthened its impact by assigning to the European Roundtable a
quasi-of®cial status in Brussels. In turn, the weight of the Roundtable
gave decisive support to the Commission's project. It was this kind of
collaboration that paved the way for the Single Market project.
This ®nding of a multi-level process suggests a slight modi®cation of
the hypothetical scheme in ®gure 1.1 on page 36. In contrast to the
graphical presentation there, the in¯uence of the European transnational business elite on their national governments should better be
symbolized by a bold arrow, as between the Commission and the
Council, because our investigations suggest that this in¯uence was just
as vital for the completion of the Single Market.
92
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
While pointing to the importance of the alliance between the Roundtable and the Commission, it is important to remember that this chapter
deals only with the Single Market policy area and the conclusions
derived from the empirical evidence related to this cannot simply be
transferred to other policy areas. This is probably particularly true in the
case of the European Roundtable of Industrialists. For obvious reasons
the Single Market was a project that was extremely close to their hearts.
On the other hand, over the years the European Roundtable has
expressed interest in other areas with various publications. However,
there are invariably certain areas that would not be of interest to the
members of the Roundtable. As one interviewee mentioned, other
associations such as UNICE are forced to take a stance on every issue.
The European Roundtable in contrast picks out subjects that it sees as
being of economic, strategic and political core interest and importance.
The initiative role of the Commission is easier to generalize and also
supported by our ®ndings on other policy areas in this volume. In the
1980s it effectively provided political entrepreneurship and assumed
responsibility at the European level. This is evidenced in one of the most
important documents that the Commission of the European Communities has ever completed ± the White Paper of 1985 launching the
Single Market.
In 1985, elites in Europe decided to go ahead. How the European
integration will evolve only the future will show. In any event, it will have
been built on foundations that were laid by the initiative and collaboration of the Commission of the European Communities and the
European Roundtable of Industrialists.
4
Esprit and technology corporatism
Simon Parker
Framing the question
The Single European Act of 1986 incorporated a new Article enshrining
the Commission's power to enact technology policy. This chapter
examines the roots of this change in the European political economy. We
have focused on the creation of the European Strategic Programme of
Research and Development (Esprit) in the early 1980s because we
believe that it was through the creation of this programme that the
Commission won the right to be active in the ®eld of technology policy.
The later inclusion of a speci®c article in the revised treaties can be seen
as a case of formalizing an existing practice.
Furthermore, we will analyse this policy initiative in order to determine whether or not, in both its design and execution, Esprit may be
said to constitute an incidence of technology corporatism, a concept
that has already been brie¯y introduced in chapter 1. The issue that
concerns us here is from where or from whom the new initiative in the
realm of technology policy came and which interests were behind it. In
this way it addresses the notion that political entrepreneurs heard the
call of European transnational ®rms to improve the offer `Europe' as a
condition for their remaining in Europe ± which was phrased more
along the lines of `this is what needs to happen in our economic, social
and political system if we are to be able to succeed in the international
economy'. The thesis is that political actors heard this plea from capital
and went about trying to achieve changes in the economic and social
system that suited capital, all the while keeping in mind that these
changes had to be sold to the public, and in this sense ful®lling one of
the basic roles of the state, which is to legitimize the social, economic
and political order. For this reason, chapter 1 refers to the Single
European Act as an elite pact constructed between transnational capital
and political entrepreneurs in the European Commission. Chapter 3 has
suggested evidence that this view is adequate for explaining the genesis
of the Single Market programme. Here we analyse whether analogous
93
94
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
forms of cooperation between European transnational corporations and
the Commission were the basis of the institutionalization of technology
policy at the European level, the second remarkable element of the
Luxembourg package to change the political economy of Europe. This
is why we review the history of Esprit in more detail, identify the main
protagonists and assess their roles. We then investigate whether the
decision-making process in the 1980s in the ®eld of technology policy
can be characterized as `technology corporatism'.
The notion of technology corporatism
Technology corporatism is employed in the above-mentioned theoretical
context to denote a state of affairs in which industry, the state and
`science' (alternatively, politics, economics and science) cooperate in
order to achieve a more competitive `societal model' (Bornschier 1996:
377). This concept is based on Bornschier's understanding of the
Japanese experience and it clearly differs from traditional notions of
corporatism, which denote a particular relationship between the state,
capital and labour.
Several problems exist with this de®nition, particularly in relation to
one pillar of the so-called corporatist structure, namely that of science.
At times, science, in this theory, is constructed as an actor or participant
in a political process termed corporatist owing to the institutionalized
roles of three actors, thus making a link with the traditional state±
capital±labour corporatist model (Bornschier 1996: 387). At the same
time however, science, or technology as it is frequently called, is also
referred to as the ®eld in which this corporatist structure is said to exist,
as in the term `technology corporatism'. Clearly, it would present
dif®culties for the theory if science is taken to be both a participant and
also a context. It also leaves unanswered the question of who, if we are
referring here to actors, is science? In the case of Esprit, it is not strictly
true that there were no representatives other than those of the Commission and the leading European information technology (IT)
companies present. However, the participants who came from
universities or research institutes were few in number and apparently of
limited in¯uence. In EC Commissioner Davignon's testimony before
the House of Lords Select Committee on the European Communities,
these participants are mentioned in the general description of the
Esprit decision-making process, but then never again referred to once
Davignon has turned to explaining to the Lords how things really
work.
However, the idea of technology corporatism may still be usefully
Esprit and technology corporatism
95
employed if we do not insist on making corporatism a triangular affair.
Thus, relationships between actors within the policy-making process
and in the consequent execution of that policy may be termed corporatist if a central actor (in this case capital), which normally exists outside
the state structure, is given an institutionalized role in the state policymaking process. We do not employ the concept of corporatism simply to
describe a situation in which the in¯uence of a particular actor or actors
in public policy-making is signi®cant. Such situations are far from
uncommon and may have much to do with the individuals concerned
and therefore do not represent any kind of a change in the principles
that may be said to lie behind state action. To be clear, what we ®nd
interesting and novel in the case of Esprit is not the fact that capital
exerted signi®cant in¯uence on a public policy-making process but that
this in¯uence was institutionalized at the European level.
To summarize the argument: we will use the term `technology corporatism' to refer to a particular form of relationship between actors in the
policy-making process in the ®eld of technology, in particular information technology and the Esprit programme which dominated the Commission's activities in this ®eld. We will not attempt to create a `third
force' (science) as a participant simply to make the label corporatist
appear more immediately relevant. Rather, we will consider this
relationship to be corporatist to the extent that it is institutionalized.
However, our research has suggested that the in¯uence of the
European Information Technology Industry Roundtable appears to
have declined since Esprit was established, although its formal,
institutionalized role in the decision-making apparatus of Esprit remains
unchanged.1 Therefore, we caution that, although formal corporatist
relations may continue to exist, it may be wrong to conclude from this
that the relationship between the Commission and industry has
remained unchanged.
Coinciding interests
We argue in this chapter that industry, in the form of the European
Information Technology Industry Roundtable, played a vital role in the
design of Esprit and that this role became institutionalized when the
Council accepted the Commission's proposals to establish the Esprit
programme. Furthermore, because this role was institutionalized, we
may speak of technology corporatism as being present.
1
This raises the question of whether it is suf®cient to examine relationships on the basis
of institutionalized links alone or if there must be some way of assessing in¯uence and
integrating this into our analysis.
96
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
It is interesting to note that the role of the information technology
(IT) industry was one of the strongest cards the Commission had in its
hand when it sought approval for its IT plans. The Commission was at
great pains to show member states how closely it was working with
industry in designing Esprit, that the programme was industry designed
rather than coming from bureaucrats in Brussels.
The interests between the European leaders of IT industry and the
Commission coincided around a particular project, not on all issues,
and not permanently. In the case of the Commission's technology policy
there was such a coincidence of interests over a speci®c problem in the
®rst half of the 1980s (Europe's performance in the new high technology
industries). This alliance resulted in concrete policies, but the interests
of both parties later diverged, and thus their relationship today looks
quite different from the way it did a decade ago.
According to Bornschier's theory, European integration was largely a
result of political entrepreneurs responding to the demands of European
capital. The ®ndings of Fielder in regards to the internal market project
and the importance of corporate interests represented by the European
Roundtable of Industrialists suggest support for this theory (see
chapters 1 and 3). In the case of technology policy, in particular IT
policy, the picture is slightly different.
The Esprit initiative
The initiative that became Esprit, which we suggest was the foundation
for the enlargement of the Commission's responsibilities in the realm of
technology policy later con®rmed in the Single European Act, originated in late 1979 with the Commission and not industry, and thus with
political entrepreneurs rather than capital.
However, there is no question that an informal alliance was constructed between representatives of the largest IT ®rms and the Commission similar to the alliance around the issue of the internal market
policy. Out of this alliance emerged concrete policy initiatives that the
Commission then advanced to the Council. Furthermore, this alliance
was in turn crucial to the success of these proposals. Speci®cally, this
alliance resulted in the creation of a proposal that would see the
Commission overseeing a research programme designed to `provide the
basic technologies which European industry needs to be competitive
with that of Japan and the USA' (CEC 1982b).
The European Strategic Programme for Research and Development
in Information Technologies (Esprit) was the ®nal name given to the
project. The intention of the programme was not simply to channel
Esprit and technology corporatism
97
public resources into industry to provide the means to achieve a `catchup'. Instead, the goal was to create incentives in order to encourage
inter-®rm and academic-industry collaboration based on the realization
that such collaboration was necessary in order to (a) pool resources and
(b) end duplication of research (CEC 1982b). As much as generating
new products, the programme would be seen to be successful insofar as
the links established between ®rms became ongoing and independent of
Esprit itself. Thus Esprit was intended to foster a change in the way
European ®rms related to one another. The leitmotiv for the programme
was the apparent Japanese success in involving private ®rms in setting
public policy objectives in speci®c industrial areas, and the evident close
collaboration between American industry and academic research
institutes and universities (see Mytelka and Delapiere 1987; CEC
1982c: 10, 24±5; House of Lords Select Committee on the European
Communities 1984: 169±70).
In order to achieve this goal of encouraging inter-®rm collaboration,
speci®c projects within the programme had to include ®rms from at
least two different Community countries. To discourage the idea that
the programme was a new way of offering public subsidies to private
activities, all funding commitments were on a 50/50 basis between the
Community and participating ®rms. As this programme was envisioned
as a way of responding to the threat of American and Japanese IT
dominance, foreign ®rms were banned from participating. For reasons
that we will discuss in more detail below, the projects were limited to
collaboration in pre-competitive research and development (R&D). Five
main areas were selected upon which Esprit would ®rst concentrate:
advanced micro-electronics, advanced information processing, software
technology, systems for of®ce automation, and computer integrated
¯exible manufacturing (CEC 1982c: 8±10).
The Council agreed to the Commission's request to begin a pilot
phase of Esprit at the Versailles European Summit in June 1982. This
phase was launched when the initial call for proposals was made in
February 1983 with the Commission in possession of a budget of 11.5
million ECU. In November 1983 the Commission took a request to the
Council for funding of Esprit proper, following the generally acknowledged success of this pilot phase. This request was for a ten-year
programme, broken into two ®ve-year phases. The Council eventually
agreed to the Commission's request in February 1984. By 1984 then,
Esprit I was up and running. Understanding the climate from which it
arose, and accounting for its relatively speedy victory over Euroscepticism, however, requires going back to developments of the
previous decade.
98
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
The technology-gap scare of the 1970s
According to many observers at the time, Europe was not responding
successfully to the technological revolution under way since the 1970s.
Furthermore, it was increasingly argued that failure to respond successfully now would mean that Europe would not be in possession of the key
to the economies of tomorrow. Even worse, Europe would in all likelihood then become an economically dependent region and its very
existence as a unique culture would be threatened.
At the end of the 1970s there was a general feeling that the IT
revolution posed a double threat to Europe. On the one hand lay the
importance of IT to the economies of tomorrow ± master these
technologies now or the race for economic survival will be lost. In this
view, if the race were lost and Europe became dependent on foreign
sources for this key raw material, the consequences would be nothing
short of catastrophic. Ultimately, according to a report drawn up within
the Science, Research and Development Directorate General of the
Commission (DG XII), nothing less than the distinct quality of
European society stood to be lost in the struggle.
The basis for Europe to participate in the international division of labour is
highly exposed if not already in imminent danger. If Europe does not master the
new information technology, the survival of European industry in a free trade
world economy is at risk. This is equivalent to putting the existence of our open
economies, and of our open societies, into question. Unfortunately the
questions of industrial survival and societal design are often treated as if they
were separate or even con¯icting objectives. (FAST 1984: 70)
The autonomy of Europe's economy (and the diversity of sociocultural identities
in Europe) will, to a great extent, depend upon the capacity for scienti®c and
technological innovation in the space/electronic technology sector (FAST
1984: 165).
This view was held not just in Brussels. The head of planning staff in
the German foreign ministry, Konrad Seitz, author of Die japanischamerikanische Herausforderung: Deutschlands Hochtechnologie-Industrien
È berleben (Seitz 1991), expressed the same sentiment when
kaÈmpfen ums U
referring to the debate unleashed by the American announcement of the
Strategic Defense Initiative (SDI) a few years later: `the research effort
undertaken here [SDI] could make a decisive contribution to bringing
about the technological advance which would drive the American
economy forward into the twenty-®rst century and at the same time
make Europe de®nitively dependent' (Seitz 1985: 154).
Although it is important to note that the discussions that culminated
in Esprit pre-dated the announcement of SDI, the Commission began
Esprit and technology corporatism
99
to argue that intervention was necessary in order to reverse a trend
already seen to be menacing. In making this argument, the Commission
adopted two approaches. The ®rst concerned itself with the issue of why
the IT sector required government intervention if it was to grow as it
should (and the normative undertones here are indeed very strong). The
other addressed the question of why this intervention would be better
made at the European level, i.e. if overseen by the Commission.
The Commission had begun to argue, in the late 1970s, that hightech industries, in particular the IT industry, have special characteristics
that warrant, if not require, government action in the form of various
kinds of support. According to this analysis, there is a chronic tendency
for under-investment by industry. The existence of limited incentives for
companies to undertake investment is due to the fact that much of the
R&D carried out is long term and high risk. Also, owing to the considerable costs involved in R&D in this industry, there are very high barriers
to entry (for a review of the market failure arguments justifying government intervention in the IT sector, see MuÈller 1990).
This is frequently considered to be a problem that justi®es state
intervention when the social bene®ts of investment, in terms of the
developments that result (for example the protection or creation of a
country's competitive advantages), may be shown to outweigh the
private, corporate gains. The Commission in this case took the view that
the social gains did indeed outweigh the private:
Concurrently, with the present economic crisis, Europe is suffering from
declining competitiveness in its industry. This has resulted in an increasing loss
of markets and in a consequent rise in unemployment. Increasing competition
from Europe's major industrial competitors is being experienced even more in
the high technology industries which are the key to Europe's future growth . . .
[because] . . . [i]nformation technologies affect the entire fabric of the economy.
Their rapid application offers the key to increased competitiveness in virtually
all main sectors in manufacturing industry and in the service sector . . . [and]
. . . it is also a major growth sector. (CEC 1982c: 1).
This technical-barriers-to-investment argument is often countered with
the claim that, if business is not willing to invest in something, then
there is usually good reason for this. The Commission's response to this
criticism, which forms the basis of the second prong of its two-pronged
argument, is the construction of the `European logic' view (called the
`Costs of Non-Europe' by the Commission). This same argument
underpins the internal market project.
In this view, the commercial weaknesses of European companies, not
just in the IT industry, are due to the absence of a market large enough
to make the attainment of economies of scale possible. Only the
100
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
presence of such economies of scale would permit R&D costs, which are
particularly high in the IT industry, to be recouped, and thus provide
the necessary incentives to investment. This was the prime advantage
enjoyed by Europe's American and Japanese competitors, according to
the Commission. `We want to create a truly European market, a
common market, which offers business the same chances that their
American and Japanese competitors have' (House of Lords Select
Committee 1984: 185).
Compounding the problem of fragmented markets in the European
IT industry is the presence of nationalistic habits, national procurement
policies and lack of harmonization of regulatory policies and of technical
standards (see Sharp and Pavitt 1993; MuÈller 1990). The lack of
common standards is particularly damaging because it means that not
even in basic components can economies of scale be reached. It had
been estimated in the early 1980s that critical mass in sales could be
reached with the capture of about 5 per cent of world market share. At
the time the European market represented 25 per cent of the world IT
market, thus giving European ®rms a potentially suf®cient home market
in which to achieve economies of scale. It was reasoned that a large part
of Europe's failure to achieve this level could be accounted for by the
fragmentation of their `home' market. Japanese and American success
was taken as proof of this proposition. It was argued that the Americans
and Japanese were able to operate pro®tably in the various European
national markets only because they can subsidize the production of nonstandardized products for smaller markets from their high-volume sales
of standardized products in their home markets, where they have long
achieved economies of scale.
Although it is beyond the scope of this chapter to go into detail on this
point, it is worth noting that the Commission's arguments about the
potential bene®ts of economies of scale, and therefore of the internal
market, have come in for criticism for a number of reasons. Criticism
has included a critique of the methodologies used to calculate the
®gures presented as supporting the `costs of non-Europe' scenario
(Tsoukalis 1993: 90±2; see also Cutler 1989). There are also those who
point out that economists are prone to speak increasingly of diseconomies of scale in today's post-Fordist economy.2
2
When the multi-plant, multi-product ®rm is now commonplace, in `those practical
discourses on management which are not burdened with an obsolete model of the ®rm,
the concept of economies of scale has been increasingly marginalised' Cutler (1989: 63);
Sharp and Pavitt (1993) have pointed out that, `the ®xation with scale has meant that
governments failed to recognise that size could not compensate for poor management;
indeed often, as Britain learned to its cost, it often compounded the problem.' An
interesting research paper could be to analyse the discourse relating to the Single Market
Esprit and technology corporatism
101
Nevertheless, the Commission was largely successful in making the
case that the creation of a European market and home base for
European companies was necessary, as the eventual success of the
Single Market initiative indicates. What it still had to prove was that a
European effort to rescue the IT industry was called for, rather than the
`national champions' strategies of the past. It did so by convincing
enough people that,
as regards technology development projects of international size, the Community alone is able to provide the strategy, market and potential framework
which can give to these projects their full weight, and impact on the European
innovation potential . . . [sic] . . . The Community can play a more direct part
where the European dimension allows more ef®cient new ways to stimulate,
such as the promotion of more European cooperation groupings and joint
ventures at enterprise level in key sector technologies, or the promotion of
new technology-based ®rms with a European market perspective. (CEC
1981b: 8).
These `new ways to stimulate' ®rms active in the IT industry centred
around encouraging inter-®rm cooperation, particularly at the R&D
stage, in an attempt to emulate what was seen to be the basis for the
success of Japan and the USA ( Japan through the Ministry of International Trade and Industry (MITI) and the USA through the constant
movement of employees from one company to another) (see CEC
1981b: 14±15).
In 1977 Etienne Davignon became Commissioner for Industry
(DGIII) with the intention of changing the Community's image of being
concerned only with propping up sunset industries such as steel to a
more positive one of encouraging growth in the industries of tomorrow.
In testimony before the House of Lords Select Committee on the
European Communities, Davignon reported that when he came to look
closely at the IT industry he had been dismayed by the lack of incentives
for ®rms to collaborate with other European ®rms. `There was no
incentive for cross-border co-operation. Every state had programmes,
and very often they were good, but because they were of a national
nature there was no incentive for cross-border co-operation.' (Davignon,
House of Lords Select Committee 1984: 169).
Davignon looked to the USA and Japan in particular as offering
models that Europe needed to adopt. Speci®cally, he credited the close
collaboration between ®rms and acknowledged the part played by the
state in directing or focusing research effort in Japan as playing a
project because most of it is shaped around the metaphor of `purifying' the member
state economies by removing barriers to (natural) trade that exist as a result of policies
(i.e. man-made).
102
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
signi®cant role in the economic and technological success of Japan.
Davignon was not alone in seeking new models that would provide
answers to Europe's problems, and across Europe changes were under
way in policies that affected IT.
Poor national responses
Sandholtz (1992) has argued that national politicians were also seeking
new ways to promote their high-tech industries in the early 1980s, and
were thus in what he terms a `policy adaptive mood' at the time when
Esprit was ®rst proposed. Although it is true that the national champion
strategies of the past were increasingly being openly criticized, Sandholtz
may be overestimating the extent to which they were in fact discredited.
Although Davignon's call to seek European solutions to industrial
problems was publicly accepted by almost everyone at the time, it would
be too much to deduce from this that national champion strategies were
no longer accepted. If it were the case that national champion strategies
were no longer a popular policy instrument, it would be surprising to
®nd that as late as 1994 the Commission was still publishing studies in
which it claimed that national champion strategies cannot be sustained
any longer (Delapierre and Zimmermann 1994: 159). Rather, it seems
reasonable to conclude that there was an awareness that European
initiatives could help, but they were never really intended to replace
national champion strategies.
Nevertheless, there was a change under way in most member states in
science and technology policies. This shift was on the whole towards a
policy direction that saw the state playing an important role in encouraging industry-industry and industry-academia collaboration, i.e. the
cornerstone of technology corporatism. In a survey of science and
technology (S&T) policy from 1980 to 1984 in France, Germany, the
Netherlands, Sweden and the United Kingdom, Lederman noted that
in each of these countries important changes in emphasis and approach
had recently occurred (Lederman 1985: 131±2). Although Lederman
pointed out that there are differences between the countries in the exact
priorities set and means selected, all undertook public policy changes
that were aimed at: increasing funding levels for academic research;
strengthening efforts to focus S&T resources on economic and social
objectives; building activities to encourage academic±industry±government research and training cooperation; enacting special programmes
and creating incentives to increase industrial R&D and international
technological competitiveness. Furthermore, these countries had all
selected the same core areas on which to concentrate these efforts,
Esprit and technology corporatism
103
namely information technology,3 biotechnology, production technology
and materials science.
United Kingdom
For example, the Alvey Programme in Great Britain has almost exactly
the same objectives and employs essentially the same means as Esprit in
achieving those objectives. Indeed, the very same people running the
Alvey Directorate were responsible for overseeing Britain's work within
Esprit, and the similarities between the programmes were so great as to
become an issue within Britain.
France
In 1981 the French government under Mitterrand began its famed policy
of national economic revival, and here as well the IT sector occupied an
important plank in the government's plans to remake France into a
strong and independent economic power (see Moynot 1987). The IT
industry ®gured importantly in this plan to rejuvenate French industry,
and measures included the nationalization of leading ®rms such as
Thomson and Bull. As well, there was a concentration of public
resources into particular IT areas in the FilieÁre Electronique, although
management of the new state ®rms was encouraged to collaborate with
European ®rms. These goals, as well as those intended to raise the
purchasing power of French consumers, required massive increases in
state funding.
By 1983, however, it had become clear that the spending levels
involved in these plans were not sustainable over a longer period of time
by one country alone. The result was a marked shift away from a go-italone policy towards a strong pro-European policy, and France became a
champion of European efforts. As one indication of this shift, the minister
for research and industry, who had headed the drive to make France an
independent power in the IT industry, Jean-Pierre CheveÁnement, was
replaced by the pro-European Laurent Fabius in 1983. Interestingly,
Fabius was chairman of the Council of Research Ministers of the EC
when the Commission's Esprit programme eventually came up for
approval (the reaction from the Research Council was highly supportive).
It had taken the French government less than three years to evolve from a
vigorous promoter of national champions and independence into an
enthusiastic advocate of European collaboration.
The reasoning behind the new attitude towards Europe within the
French government is spelt out in an analysis prepared by a top-level
3
In Britain, 1982 was declared the `Year of Information Technology'.
104
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
think tank of the French government in 1982/3 (Secretariat d'Etat
aupreÁs du Premier Ministre et Commissariat GeÂneÂral du Plan 1983;
Mytelka 1995; Sandholtz 1992: 146±51). In a wide-ranging consideration of what France's strategy towards Europe should be for the 1980s,
the IT industry is singled out for its importance and a detailed case built
for expanding incentives for inter-®rm collaboration at the European
level.
Germany
The situation in the Federal Republic of Germany has never been so
clearly pro-European in the ®eld of IT as it was to become in France
(Sandholtz 1992: 152±4). Nevertheless, when Hans-Dietrich Genscher
appointed Konrad Seitz as head of his planning staff, a shift towards a
more pro-European stance became evident. During the years Esprit was
being developed, the German government was essentially split between
those who favoured the principle of state intervention to support key
industries (and there was little disagreement that IT was one of these),
and those who thought the market should be left to provide the solutions
to the industry's acknowledged problems. The former could be found in
the ministry of research and technology, and were therefore open to the
underlying philosophy of Esprit, although they had reservations about
the extent of it, and the latter were dominant in the ministry of ®nance
and economics.
For these reasons, Germany was one of only two states (the other
being Britain, although for reasons that had little to do with Esprit
itself ) to raise signi®cant opposition to the approval of the ®rst phase of
Esprit. Germany's concern however was with the expansion of the
Commission's budget that Esprit entailed, rather than with any fundamental opposition to the programme (Ward and Edwards 1990: 114).
In general, Davignon's intentions and later the goals embodied in
Esprit, and indeed the approach taken with regard to improving the
competitiveness of high-tech industry in Europe later con®rmed in the
Single European Act, did not run against the grain insofar as the
emerging consensus on public policy for advanced technology was
concerned. Rather, when the Commission took its approach to the
matter to the member states it was more or less pushing against an open
door. To this extent, it is accurate to conclude, with Sandholtz, that
member states were in a `policy adaptive mood'.
Indeed, the arguments in favour of focusing attention on and adopting
measures to improve the Community's competitive position in the new
technologies were so successful that they paved the way for Article 130
Esprit and technology corporatism
105
of the Single European Act. The various paragraphs of this Article
reiterate the conclusions already reached in the debate surrounding the
launch of Esprit, such as the primary need to strengthen the scienti®c
and technological base of European industry and to encourage international competition. The consensus that the Community should
involve itself only in programmes or activities that support pre-competitive research is found in Article 130f. The paragraph immediately
following describes the necessity of encouraging collaboration among
European ®rms (see De Ruyt 1989: 202±7). Esprit had broken new
ground, was at the time considered a success and therefore was used as a
model for setting out the Community's rights in the ®eld of research and
technology.
The failure of earlier European IT initiatives
Although member states were in a relatively receptive mood at the time,
the Commission faced a hurdle in convincing industry itself that it had
the competence and the vision to offer industry the kind of support it
felt it required. In particular, the Commission had to overcome a certain
amount of mistrust of intra-European collaboration on the part of
industry owing to the failure of the UNIDATA initiative. This initiative
had been one of the most important such collaborative attempts to date.
UNIDATA was a collaborative project, begun in 1971 in the form of a
consortium between Philips, Siemens and CII in order to start producing mainframe computers. Their goal was to compete with IBM, which
dominated the market at the time in Europe and around the world. The
project, which had been moving at a snail's pace, was undermined in
1975 when the French government, which owned CII, decided to merge
it with Honeywell-Bull. This would have the effect of bringing an
American ®rm into the consortium, which had been created as a
response to the American dominance of the market. Both Siemens and
Philips made it clear during the pre-merger discussions that HoneywellBull would no longer be welcome in the consortium. Both also made it
clear that without the participation of CII there was not much point in
continuing the joint effort. The French government decided to press
ahead with the merger and consequently the consortium and the
attempt it represented (to ®nd a European response to foreign domination) came to an unhappy end (Sandholtz 1992: 96±7).
The Commission had secured agreement from the Council in 1974 for
a medium-term project on the application, development and production
of data-processing systems by linking it to the UNIDATA project. The
collapse of UNIDATA left this project in the ®eld of data-processing
106
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
without a leg (or mainframe?) to stand on, with the result that there was
no longer a coordinated response in Europe to the American and growing
Japanese dominance of this market (Sharp 1989: 204±5).
This unsuccessful attempt at intra-European collaboration also
poisoned the waters of European collaboration for the rest of the
decade, and hung over the discussions with industry that had begun on
an informal basis in the Directorate General of the Commission for
Industry (DG III) towards the end of the 1970s. This was one of the
reasons there was no great enthusiasm for intra-European collaboration
in the IT sector, even though there was, as was pointed out earlier, a
growing feeling that such collaboration was necessary.
To compound this scepticism towards collaboration between
European ®rms, industry's view was that the Commission was not
technically competent to carry out signi®cant policies in the IT sector.
Furthermore, they reasoned, even if they were able to overcome this
problem of competency, industry saw the Commission as handicapped
by the fact that the Council usually took so long to come to a decision
that even those policies that might have an effect came so late that they
were doomed to be ineffective (Sandholtz 1992: 98±9).
Designing the programme
In 1978, determined to take action in the ®eld of IT, the Commission
created a secretariat within the Science, Research and Development
Directorate General (DG XII) in order `to contribute to the de®nition
of long-term Community research and development objectives and
priorities and thus to the development of a coherent science and
technology policy in the long term' (FAST 1984: 187).
The group was of®cially named Forecasting and Assessment in the
Field of Science and Technology (FAST) and was charged with studying
the effect of structural change within the Community.4 Davignon, who
was Commissioner for Industry (DG III) at the time, began working
with members of the FAST team looking into long lead-time R&D
which is characteristic of many IT products (source: interview 1, see
appendix to chapter). Eventually, Davignon was to take over this
specialist group by moving it into his Directorate General and having it
report directly to him, thus by-passing the regular bureaucratic channels
within the Commission. Davignon gave the group the new title of
Information Technology Task Force (ITTF) (Ringrose 1994: 74).
4
The report of the FAST group was submitted to the Commission in December 1982,
and later published under the title Eurofutures: The Challenge of Innovation Commission
of the European Communities in association with the journal Futures (FAST, 1984).
Esprit and technology corporatism
107
As part of its work, the ITTF proposed a draft `European Strategic
Programme for R&D in Information Technology' for discussion with
industry in late 1979 (interview 1). According to the FAST report, the
®nal Esprit proposal was the result of a `preparatory research project of
about 18 months duration which was conceived within FAST' (FAST
1984: 165). In the literature on the subject, the shape of the programme
that was to become Esprit is generally agreed to have emerged out of the
roundtable discussions held between Davignon and the largest IT ®rms.
There is evidence that suggests that the draft proposal came from the
Information Technology Task Force ®rst, but then was signi®cantly
revised with industry (interviews 1 and 2). Nevertheless, there is little
disagreement over the conclusion that the initiative came ®rst from
Davignon and his team and was developed further with industry. For
the purposes of this chapter, it is suf®cient then to note that the initiative
did not come from industry in the ®rst place.
The draft proposal, which already stressed the promotion of intra-European collaborative research, was presented to an informal
meeting of the largest twelve ®rms in the IT industry, namely Siemens,
Nixdorf, Olivetti, Thomson CSF, GEC, ICL, AEG, Plessey, Philips,
CGE, CII-Honeywell Bull, STET. The Information Technology Task
Force had wanted to ascertain industry's reaction to its proposals before
taking them to Davignon. According to the GEC representative, such
roundtable discussions were originally `part of a rather wider industrial
discussion organised by the Commission in terms of how European
industry should respond, particularly to the Japanese threat in the total
scheme of information technology, computers, telecommunications and
all of the industrial implications of information technology' (House of
Lords Select Committee 1984: 35). This industry group became known
as the Big 12, and not long after, in 1980, they established themselves as
the European Information Technology Industry Roundtable (EITIRT)
in order to advise the Commission on the development of European
R&D programmes in the Information and Communication Technologies (ICT) domain (EITIRT 1995) and to coordinate their work with
the Commission.
Initially, industry was sceptical about the bene®ts and workability of
collaborative research, being still bruised after the UNIDATA failure
and continuing to doubt the Commission's competence (Sharp 1989:
209). Also, the idea of collaborative research with European ®rms,
which was what the ITTF proposal contained, was not immediately
welcomed by the group. An English participant in the ®rst roundtable
discussions recalled:
108
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
In this country and throughout the EEC, we were very slow to recognise [that
collaborative research could bene®t all parties]. We started with the assumption
that companies were going to compete with one another and therefore they
could not possibly share research results. (House of Lords Select Committee
1984: 35±6)
Nevertheless, the discussions continued and the participants in the
roundtable studied the proposal, and considered the arguments, as well
as going over the ®gures, until they were more convinced that what was
being proposed was reasonable. At this point the Information
Technology Task Force, under Roland HuÈber, felt con®dent enough to
take the draft proposal to Davignon, who was the one with the power to
make it actually happen (interview 1).
However, Davignon was not prepared to accept the proposal until he
had heard for himself industry's opinion of it, so in 1980 he called
together the heads of the Big 12 (comprising 70 per cent of the industry
at the time) and of®cially tabled the proposal for discussion (Sharp
1989).5 This meeting is usually considered to be the moment when the
European Information Technology Industry Roundtable was formally
founded, although it must be remembered that this group had in fact
been meeting regularly before this date.
At Davignon's roundtable meeting he heard that the Big 12 were in
general agreement with the outlines of the proposal. The addition of
Davignon's charisma and political skills then made the difference in
terms of winning industry's full commitment (interviews 1, 2 and 3).
Despite their initial scepticism, the participants eventually agreed that
collaboration was possible in the form put forward and should focus on
pre-competitive research in order to avoid two potential problems.
First, the participants were competitors and this way they would not
have to share secrets with each other about products that were close to
the market (interview 4).6 Secondly, such collaborative agreements
would not run foul of Community competition legislation (WalsumStachowicz 1994: 110±11).
Moreover, one can see in Esprit's focus on pre-competitive research
an incomplete resolution of the struggle between what Cox (1993) calls
state-capitalist and hyper-liberal societal models. Mytelka argues that:
Underlying the design of ESPRIT was also the strong antipathy to state
5
6
The members of the original discussions were representatives from the Big 12, and from
DG III, DG XII and Narjes' cabinet.
This problem proved to be real when in the Fourth Framework Programme, as a result of
public pressure to move the projects closer to the market in order to show tangible results
of the time and money being spent on Community R&D programmes, the IT companies
found themselves unable to put together the same number of agreements precisely
because they were competing with each other in the ®elds covered (interview 4).
Esprit and technology corporatism
109
intervention in the economy that constituted the reigning ideology of the day.
Administrative guidance of the sort that MITI has made famous, industrial
policy and even the type of indicative planning practised in France were spurned
and market forces enshrined. This was also the period in which governments in
Europe and North America equated partnerships with collusion and anticompetitive behaviour. Combined, these two ideological predilections led to an
initial emphasis on pre-competitive R&D projects within ESPRIT. (Mytelka
1993: 57)7
However, the fact is that Esprit did entail granting a signi®cant role for
the Commission in the IT industry, particularly in bringing ®rms
together (the broker-state). As will be discussed below in more detail,
the framework created to manage the programme called for close
cooperation between industry and the Commission, suggesting that a
clear separation of state and capital was not achieved. For this reason we
believe that the outcome had more in common with the state-capitalist
model than with the hyper-liberal one.
As mentioned, it is signi®cant that it was the Information Technology
Task Force that made the initial proposal, in contrast to the Single
Market project, where the initiative came from the European Roundtable of Industrialists (ERT, not to be mixed up with the IT Roundtable). In terms of Bornschier's thesis (that Esprit was the result of an
elite pact between industry and political entrepreneurs in Brussels),
however, the fact that the initiative came from the latter and not from
industry is not so signi®cant. There is no disagreement among observers
that both industry and the Commission worked out the details of the
programme and went on to form an alliance of sorts (of which more
below) to get the programme accepted in the Council. Therefore, we
may still speak of an elite pact.
Once Davignon had heard that industry stood behind the programme
he then felt he needed to know that they would take the programme
seriously and actually do something with the money. For this reason he
made funding for projects available on a 50/50 basis; that is, the
Commission would put up 50 per cent of the costs of a project and the
project members themselves would bring the other 50 per cent. According to Davignon, this funding arrangement was not popular among
the ®rms present because they were `accustomed that in the old systems,
who paid was the national government, so you had a shared programme,
the Community paid x per cent and the budget of the state paid x per
cent', and the company put up little, if anything. Davignon's strategy
was to ensure that the Commission's money would be well spent:
7
See also Kennedy (1989), who suggests that the concern with `competitiveness' has
replaced a concern with industrial policy.
110
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
I said: `How will I know that this scheme is really something, which is for you of
the essence, not something that you are ready to do to get a subsidy, but
something, which is so important in your strategy that you are ready to put your
money on the table, because you feel it's that important'.(Interview 5)
This tactic also meant that the programme would be twice as large as
whatever ®gure the Council agreed to. Since this ®gure was unlikely to
be large at ®rst, this mechanism allowed the programme to be large
enough still to make an impact. Indeed, the fact that Davignon
approached the Council with a modest spending request, made even
more attractive by being presented in the form of a pilot project
requiring no long-term commitment of funds, is regarded as important
to the success of his proposal (Sharp 1989: 209).
We agree fully with Peterson when he concludes:
In political terms, Davignon and the Commission, and later the French
proponents of Eureka required support from Europe's Big 12 ®rms to place
collaborative R&D on the agenda of European governments, and ultimately to
channel the political momentum for new schemes to support of wider political
agendas. The Commission's agenda included overcoming the EC's history of
failure in collaborative programmes, new collaborative programmes, and
ultimately linking support for collaborative R&D to the [Single European
Market] initiative. (Peterson 1991: 280±1)
When the backing of industry had been won, the next step was to go
about convincing the member states that the Commission should have a
role to play in trying to improve the state of Europe's IT industry, and
then that this programme, which by now of®cially carried the name
Esprit, was the right way to do it.
Selling the programme
In May of 1982 the Commission presented the Council with a communication entitled Towards a European Strategic Programme for Research
and Development in Information Technologies in which it clearly spelt out
its analysis and intentions in the IT sector (CEC 1982c). In proposing
a European Strategic Programme of Research and Development in
Information Technology, the Commission was basing its competence to
act in this ®eld on Article 235 of the EEC Treaty, which permits the
Commission to take the appropriate measures in areas where the treaty
has not provided the necessary powers.
In June of the same year the Council of Research Ministers concluded
that the Community indeed required such a programme in order to
increase the competitiveness of the IT industry. It recommended that
the Council of Ministers make available funds for the pilot phase, details
Esprit and technology corporatism
111
of which were soon to be presented by the Commission. In August the
Commission presented its proposals for this pilot phase, with a budget
of 11.5 million ECU. In the meantime, IT Roundtable companies
discussed with their respective home governments their enthusiasm for
the programme, and in December 1992 the Council gave its approval
(interviews 4 and 6).
The thirty-eight projects undertaken in the pilot phase of Esprit were
generally deemed to be a success, and when in June 1983 the Commission presented the ten-year Esprit Phase 1 to the Council for approval
there was little opposition to the plan itself. There was, however,
dif®culty in getting approval for the budget of the programme because
of the opposition of Germany and Britain. Both countries had made
their approval of Esprit contingent on an acceptable solution to the
question of budgetary reform. It must be stressed that these reservations
were not due to any real disagreement with Esprit, or because the two
wished to see an alternative plan enacted (Ward and Edwards 1990:
113±14). Rather, at the time Britain was pushing for a change in the
way its ®nancial contributions were calculated, and Germany was trying
to limit the Commission's expenditures, and to achieve this, insisted
that funds for Esprit be found within the Community's Framework
Programme (i.e. funds already allocated).
In the end, the Commission responded with a compromise proposal
and an agreement was reached in February 1984 on a budget of 750
million ECU over ®ve years and 1,500 million ECU over ten years, and
staggered so that no new money would be required for the ®rst two years.
After the agreement had been reached, Thatcher publicly stated on
several occasions her and her government's support for Esprit, singling it
out as precisely the kind of programme the Community should be
mounting. Nevertheless, her strategy of holding Esprit hostage had been
very unpopular both at home and with her partners on the Council.
To review, the agreement ®nally reached was for the ®rst ®ve-year phase
of a ten-year programme of funding for collaborative research in the
®eld of IT, with the aim of strengthening Europe's competitiveness in
this industry. Consortia involving two or more companies, universities
or private research institutes from at least two countries within the
Community (and exceptionally from outside it) could bid for money to
support pre-competitive R&D projects in one of the ®ve ®elds selected.
These ®elds were: advanced micro-electronics, with a special emphasis
on the design and production of very large-scale integrated chips; the
design of software technology; advanced information processing; of®ce
systems; and computer-aided manufacturing, or robotics.
112
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
In all the interviews we conducted, the importance of industry
lobbying of national governments in getting Esprit accepted by the
Council was repeatedly stressed.8 Therefore, we may conclude that
industry, through the European Information Technology Industry
Roundtable, had become the ally of the Commission in putting forward
a proposal that increased the scope of the latter's competences, and in
transferring authority over technology policy to a signi®cant degree to
the Commission. Industry, again through the Roundtable, had played
an integral role in drawing up the Esprit programme. As mentioned
above, the fact that the Commission had been captured by industry in
this ®eld was the Commission's trump card in securing agreement to
Esprit in the Council (see Davignon's comments, House of Lords Select
Committee 1984: 170).
Corporatist technology policy in practice
Thus, there is evidence of technology corporatism in the way in which
Esprit was drafted, i.e. in the policy-making process. As the following
discussion will illustrate, there is also evidence of technology corporatism in the execution of this policy, where the institutionalized in¯uence of the European Information Technology Industry Roundtable in
particular, but also of industry in general, is noteworthy.
Esprit is a ten-year programme although its budget is allocated in
®ve-year instalments. A workplan is devised on a yearly basis which
speci®es the exact areas for which funding will be made available and
for which project proposals may be submitted. The Information
Technology Task Force (ITTF) ± which was later converted into the
Directorate General of the Commission for Telecommunications,
Information Industries and Innovation DG XIII ± adopts the annual
workplans once they have been agreed with two other bodies, the Esprit
Management Committee and the Esprit Advisory Board (Sandholtz
1992; Ringrose 1994; Walsum-Stachowicz 1994; and various Commission documents). The ITTF also organizes the evaluation of projects
submitted by independent experts, and passes these recommendations
on to the EMC.
Membership of the Esprit Management Committee (EMC) consists
of two representatives from each member state, usually from government but occasionally from industry or academia. Voting is by quali®ed
majority. The EMC, as well as being consulted on the draft of the yearly
workplans, also has an important say in the selection of projects,
8
For a study that reaches a similar conclusion, see Peterson (1991: 276).
Esprit and technology corporatism
113
ensuring through its input that the policy of juste retour (fair return) is
adhered to (Ringrose 1994: 130±1).
The Esprit Advisory Board (EAB) plays a similar role to that of the
EMC in that it gives advice on the workplans and in the selection of
projects. It is made up of experts selected by the Commission from
industry and academia, of®cially working in a private capacity. During
the ®rst years of Esprit, up to half of the membership of the EAB was
from Roundtable ®rms; the rest were from universities, small and
medium-sized enterprises and research institutes. Only later were information technology users included in the EAB. This remains one of the
important places in the policy execution process where the interests of
industry are represented.
Still, the in¯uence of the Roundtable companies is felt strongest in the
aptly named Esprit Steering Committee (ESC) even though it has no
of®cial standing. Membership is essentially the Roundtable ®rms, plus
academics and small and medium-sized enterprises to give it added
legitimacy. The ESC's role is to give advice to the ITTF/Commission
and it was set up originally to advise Davignon on the creation of Esprit.
It was through the ESC in particular, but also through the Roundtable's
informal contacts with ITTF/Commission members, that industry controlled the shape of Esprit during the early years. On the basis of her
interviews, Ringrose concludes that, `in the closed forum of the ESC,
Esprit's largest projects were designed and because those projects
received the majority of Esprit funds, Esprit's budget was effectively
dispersed according to gentlemen's agreements in the ESC' (Ringrose
1994: 128).
It would seem possible then to conclude that not only was the
relationship between the Commission and the European Information
Technology Industry Roundtable very close, but, because it was institutionalized, we may speak of an instance of technological corporatism.
The Commission depended heavily on the technical input of the Roundtable in designing and executing Esprit. It also depended on the
lobbying in¯uence of the Roundtable ®rms with the governments of
their member states in the quest to secure agreement to the expansion of
the Commission's competences.
Clearly, such a relationship of dependence of political actors upon
organized industrial actors is not without its parallels in many political
systems, nor is it something novel for industrial interests to have
in¯uence on policy-making within a democracy. But, to summarize the
argument so far, what is novel and noteworthy here is the extent to
which organized interests, the European Information Technology
Industry Roundtable in particular, played an institutionalized role in the
114
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
policy-making process and in the execution of this policy at the
European level.
Technology corporatism ten years on
Although we have concluded that the relationship between the Commission and the European Information Technology Industry Roundtable is
an incidence of technological corporatism, the in¯uence of the EITIRT,
in the view of both the Roundtable and Directorate General of®cials
(DG XIII), has declined considerably since the 1990s (interviews 1, 3,
4, 6). We are thus faced with the question of what this means for their
corporatist relationship.
On the one hand, the formal integration of the Roundtable of
European information technology ®rms into the policy-making process
involved in Esprit (setting the objectives and focus of the programme
and project selection, as well as taking part as project participants) has
not changed signi®cantly, although there has been a marked decrease in
the percentage of projects in which members of the Roundtable are
involved. Thus, the institutionalized role has not changed much as such.
On the other hand however, the openness of the Commission to the
input and in¯uence of the European Information Technology Industry
Roundtable has declined to a signi®cant extent, to the point where both
recognize that the relationship has undergone a major change.
If the key point, as we have argued in this chapter, is the institutionalized aspect of the Roundtable's in¯uence in the ®eld of information
technology, then this in¯uence has been only slightly reduced by the
developments just described. The decline in in¯uence occurred as a
result of other interests being represented in the policy-making process,
thereby breaking the Roundtable's monopoly on industrial policy input.
These interests are for the most part also industrial ones, including
enhanced visibility of small and medium-sized enterprises and increasingly software producers, as well as organized representations from
foreign ®rms (for example, American producers' associations, the American Chamber of Commerce, etc.) (interview 4). These developments
re¯ect a recent change in focus of the Commission towards support for
user interests in the Community.
In terms of the more informal side of the Roundtable's in¯uence
however, there is general agreement that it is no longer as popular
among policy-makers in the Commission as it once was (interviews 1, 4,
6; Walsum-Stachowicz 1994). Nevertheless the decline of the in¯uence
of the Roundtable in policy-making in Brussels is not easily measured. It
may be illustrated by the views of those involved that the Commission is
Esprit and technology corporatism
115
no longer so eager to listen to the Roundtable's views. Alternatively, we
may see it in the decline of the share of Esprit projects going to its
members.
We may also ®nd evidence in the failure of proposals made by the
European Information Technology Industry Roundtable in 1989 to
further institutionalize their role in technology policy-making in the
Community. One proposal, contained in a White Paper issued by the
Roundtable, recommended that regular meetings between its working
groups and of®cials from the Directorates General who were concerned
with these technical areas be held on a regular basis (interview 3;
Roundtable, internal paper). Such meetings had been taking place but
were not bound to do so on the basis of any formal agreement.
More ambitiously, the European Information Technology Industry
Roundtable called in this paper for meetings between the chief executives of the Big 12 and the president of the Commission and his/her
Commissioners, also to be held on a ®xed, regular basis. The Commission declined to accept these proposals. We are thus left with the
question of whether the fact that the proposals were not accepted should
be taken as a symbol of the Roundtable's declining in¯uence. Or,
equally, we could ask whether the fact that the Roundtable felt it
necessary to formalize a relationship that had existed for many years
might be evidence that it too perceived a weakening of its in¯uence
which it hoped to arrest. At the minimum, it would seem safe to
conclude that there has been a decline in the Roundtable's in¯uence
with the Commission relative to its in¯uence when Esprit was launched.
Concrete answers to the question of why the Roundtable's in¯uence is
decreasing are dif®cult to ®nd. The Commission's inability to live up to
its promises regarding funding for the Joint European Submicron
Silicon Initiative ( JESSI) is cited as one reason for the Commission
`losing the industry lobby'. Another may be found in the public criticism
by Brussels of an apparent lack of European `engagement' by industry.
Members of DG XIII and the European Information Technology Industry Roundtable also had a serious falling out over the issue of billing
for hours worked on Esprit, with DG of®cials accusing the industry of
over-billing (interview 1).
In her study of corporate in¯uence on the policy-making process in
the information technology sector in Brussels, Walsum-Stachowicz concludes that, from a position of almost total monopoly of corporate policy
input into Esprit, the Roundtable's in¯uence has signi®cantly weakened
(Walsum-Stachowicz 1994: 279±80). Several reasons are offered for
this development. One view is that it is a result of the increasing
ineffectiveness of the Roundtable itself in putting forward a coherent
116
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
strategy or view as it sought to expand its mandate. From focusing on
purely technical matters associated with information technology, the
Roundtable has begun to put forward positions relating to wider issues
of the shape of the Community's economic and political system (see
recent EITIRT position papers, including EITIRT (1995) Europe and
the Global Information Society in which the Roundtable describes its
mission as contributing `to a dialogue with the European Commission
on all aspects of EU policies and programmes in the information and
communication domain').
This move has accentuated the divergence of interests held by
members of the European Information Technology Industry Roundtable. When, for example, the Roundtable turns to address the question
of state intervention in or regulation of industry, the fact that Thomson
is still owned by the French state means agreement will necessarily be
dif®cult to reach. Such differences remained hidden when the group was
addressing only technical matters (interviews 2 and 3). The result has
been positions or statements that are often so watered-down and noncommittal in terms of a speci®c policy direction (in other words, they
comprise lowest common denominator preferences) that they have been
of little substance and carried little weight (interviews 4 and 6; see also
Walsum-Stachowicz 1994: 291±2).
Although there is some recognition of this as a factor explaining their
declining in¯uence in Brussels, Roundtable members themselves point
to another factor. They claim that their voice, rather than having grown
less sure, has simply been drowned out by the proliferation of voices in
Brussels, both as Community membership has expanded and as other
groups have organized and taken their case to Brussels (interviews 3, 4,
6). Interest group representation in Brussels is certainly exploding and
the Commission is becoming the lobbying target of more and more
interest groups, so this explanation may hold some truth.
The Roundtable of IT industrialists also argues that it has become
less and less interested in attracting the Commission's attention. It has
become a general complaint among the largest in the IT industry that
the Commission's technology policy has become too `politicized' by the
addition of objectives that are no longer strictly technology or industry
driven. As a result, the Commission's policies have become less effective
as they have increasingly been linked to Community goals in the ®elds of
social cohesion or regional policy (interviews 2, 4, 6). In their review of
Community technology policy, Starbatty and Vetterlein have suggested
that it is indeed no coincidence that Article 130f ± q of the SEA, which
lays down the Community's brief in Research and Technology, is
preceded directly by articles referring to its responsibilities in the realm
Esprit and technology corporatism
117
of economic and social cohesion (Starbatty and Vetterlein 1989: 147).
One of industry's complaints is indeed that the Commission has begun
using the former to meet its needs in the latter.
With this politicization of technology policy, the resulting policy is of
less and less relevance to the larger IT companies that make up the
European Information Technology Industry Roundtable. As one
industry of®cial put it, what is the point of Siemens bringing a less
technologically advanced company from, say, Greece into a consortium
simply to supply a component when the same is available down the
street from a well-experienced provider (interview 2)? Clearly, the only
difference for Siemens may be that it no longer quali®es for EU money
in supporting this venture. According to industry, the potential of
strengthening the international competitiveness of Europe's IT industry
has been sacri®ced to `politics'.
Walsum-Stachowicz also suggests that member state governments are
more inclined to be open to Roundtable lobbying when they have a
national champion on it. We have suggested that having the backing of
these national champions was one reason Esprit received such a warm
reception by member state governments when it was originally tabled.
However, as the Community has expanded southward, more countries
without an IT national champion are represented in the Council. As
such, it is hardly surprising that the focus on supporting Europe's larger
IT ®rms, most of which come from larger states, has shifted towards a
focus on small and medium-sized enterprises, sometimes the only ®rms
a country may have in the IT industry. The relative weight of the pro-IT
intervention has been reduced as a consequence (Walsum-Stachowicz
1994: 318). Furthermore, many of these newer members are precisely
those countries to which the bulk of social and regional policies are
directed. This may also account for the apparent `politicization' of
technology policy.
Yet another factor warrants consideration in analysing the decline of
the Roundtable's in¯uence in Brussels, namely, the role that structural
change in the economies of Europe and in the IT industry itself has
played in changing the terms of the game. In the ®rst place, the question
needs to be posed: how relevant are programmes that portray the world
in terms of competing blocs when the major players within the international economy are becoming globalized? Equally, is it possible that
the Roundtable's in¯uence has declined because `Europe' is no longer
so important to its members, which are increasingly global in their
operations and strategy and thus paying less attention to their relationship with policy-makers in Brussels?
Although there is no doubt something in this argument, it must not
118
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
be forgotten that, for all their presence in global markets, European IT
®rms are still European based insofar as the largest proportion of their
sales and their strongest market position continue to be found in
Europe. Siemens, for example, conducts nearly 60 per cent of its
business with customers outside of Germany, but still around two-thirds
of all value-added work takes place in that country, suggesting that even
the label `European' may be exaggerated. As a result it cannot be the
case that Europe is no longer important to these companies, although it
may be possible to argue that a European strategy alone can no longer
be suf®cient.
It is beyond the scope of this chapter to offer more than a few passing
thoughts on this question. Those remaining large IT ®rms of European
origin are increasingly global companies (as many argue they must be to
survive) and thus the criticism that they exhibit a lack of engagement in
things European would seem misplaced ± it is their strategy to be global
and not simply European. Indeed, the goal of Esprit was to make them
global players, even though a good deal of the rhetoric was about
enhancing Europe's place in the international economy.
Furthermore, some criticism has been levelled at the Commission's
policies in the technology sector, in particular that of Esprit, as representing a strategy of catch-up (Mytelka 1993), where too little emphasis
is placed on the conditions that generate innovation and technological
development. On the one hand, as suggested above, the link made
between Esprit and the internal market strategy, and thus the importance of economies of scale, is arguably relevant only when an established market is being challenged. In the case of integrated circuits, to
take one example, economies of scale had been attained by Japanese and
American ®rms long before the Europeans mounted their defence. This
meant that American and Japanese ®rms enjoyed ®rst-mover advantage,
and any company seeking to challenge their market position would have
to capture similar economies of scale to do so.
But this might only be the case in technological catching-up, which
involves challenging established market positions in the context of an
open, liberal economy where simply barring access to markets is no
longer a widely acceptable policy option. In the case of technological
innovation, it may be far more important to pay attention to the factors
that contribute to the innovative dynamic, and here small and mediumsized enterprises may play a central role.
Furthermore, there has been a shift away from supporting the
growth of an indigenous IT industry as an end in itself towards placing
questions of national or `bloc' origin in the background and concentrating on matters of how technology is used and integrated into the
Esprit and technology corporatism
119
economy and society. This focus apparently gives more weight to
market-push rather than technology-push objectives. For example, in a
recent of®cial description of Esprit placed on the Internet, we are told
that the Fourth Framework programme is focused on the emerging
information society and the construction of its infrastructure. In the
1980s and early 1990s, the Esprit programme followed a technologypush policy in which emphasis was `placed on encouraging cooperation
between IT enterprises and strengthening the Union's information
technology industry. Now the focus is on helping to develop the
services and technologies that underpin the emerging information
technology. To do this effectively means paying greater attention to
the needs of users and the market' (Esprit electronic home page at
http://www.cordis.lu/esprit/home/html).
How much of this change is a result of the realization that large IT
®rms are not European but global, and therefore that there is little to be
gained in transferring public money to them? It is certainly possible to
claim that small and medium-sized enterprises are more bound to a
particular geographical location than are the large IT ®rms of the
European Information Technology Industry Roundtable. And clearly,
the information society in Europe, if it is created, will not then get up
and move off-shore. As a result, it may be easier to create a consensus
on spending money on something anchored and `European' rather than
`global' and footloose.
As we can see, explanations of the declining in¯uence of the EITIRT
tend to fall into one of two categories. First, there are arguments that
maintain that the Roundtable became increasingly unhappy with the
Commission and its policies both because those policies were less
effective and because they were increasingly less relevant to members of
the Roundtable as their business strategies evolved. A second line of
explanation focuses on the Commission and its perceived move away
from dependency on and happiness with the Roundtable and its
members. Also within this category are arguments that suggest that the
goals of the Commission changed following expansion of the Community, in particular the increasing use of technology policy to satisfy
other goals such as regional cohesion. Clearly, there is signi®cant
overlap in both sets of explanations and many are mutually reinforcing
rather than being mutually exclusive.
What does this mean for our theory of technology corporatism? We
began with the thesis that, when the participation of a private (nonstate) actor is institutionalized in a public policy-making process, then
we may speak of corporatism. We have shown that such a relationship
existed in the ®eld of IT policy between the Commission and the
120
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
European Information Technology Industry Roundtable and we have
therefore referred to this as a case of technology corporatism. However,
we have also suggested that this relationship had changed in signi®cant
respects a decade later.
In the case of the EITIRT and the Commission, various changes
occurred, internal and external to the process, that altered the place of
the relationship we have described as corporatist in the general policymaking process (as well as in the business strategies of the ®rms
involved). In addition, the goals of both industry and the Commission
changed. As we suggested at the beginning of this chapter, the interests
of industry and those of the Commission coincided around a particular
project and formal structures were created that were appropriate to
implementing that project. However, although a corporatist structure in
the realm of European technology policy was created which remains, the
interests of both the Commission and industry have changed, putting
into question the relevance of such formal structures for analysis.
In a very formal sense, as long as decision-making within the Esprit
programme remains unchanged, i.e. the Roundtable's in¯uence remains
institutionalized, then we may continue to speak of technology corporatism as being present. Clearly, though, this would not be helpful
because it overlooks the fact that the relationship has changed in a
fundamental way. Therefore, our theory must be made to take account
of the fact that merely being party to an institutionalized relationship
is not enough to guarantee signi®cant in¯uence over that process.
Similarly, that process itself may become less important to the actors
concerned, as we suggest has occurred in the case of European technology policy.
We may therefore conclude from this that analysis must focus on the
interests of actors involved in policy-making processes and not simply
the institutional structures within which these relationships exist. As the
interests of actors change over time, formal structures may no longer be
the de®ning in¯uence over their actions or of policy outcomes, as the
case of European technology policy illustrates.
Conclusion
This chapter has presented support for the view that the common
European technology policy ± ®rst embodied in the Esprit project ± was
a core element of the integration relaunch and was initiated by the
Commission, albeit in close collaboration with the largest European
information technology companies. Our research, consisting of a review
of primary and secondary sources and interviews, leads us to the
Esprit and technology corporatism
121
conclusion that member states played only a minor role in this process,
contrary to the view prevalent in many studies of this subject.
It is clear that during the late 1970s and early 1980s there was a
general shift within European states towards a policy of supporting hightechnology industries, which foreshadowed the guiding principles of
Esprit. However, the Commission at this time was able to seize the
initiative at the European level and secure member state agreement to a
programme that had the private and public support of the largest
information technology companies acting through the European Information Technology Industry Roundtable, and thereby succeeded in
signi®cantly expanding its own powers.
Insofar as the shape of technology policy is concerned, this chapter
draws attention to the fact that the Commission acted as an agent in
encouraging increased collaboration between large ®rms, universities and
private research institutes in the information technology industry, rather
than leaving this solely to the market. The Commission accomplished this
primarily through its command of funding resources with which it was
able to instigate the formation of an in¯uential information technology
industry lobby. For this reason, we may speak of this new constellation of
interests and role of the state as of a form of technology corporatism,
boldly exempli®ed in both the design and the execution of Esprit.
Looking at the practice of this collaboration ten years on, we ®nd,
however, that the in¯uence of the European Information Technology
Industry Roundtable in the policy process has declined. Therefore, we
end by cautioning that the degree of in¯uence exerted by actors may not
be directly deduced from the fact that they can be said to be party to a
corporatist relationship.
Appendix: interview partners used as sources in this
chapter
1 Mr R. HuÈber, Director of the Information Technology Task Force of
DG III under Commissioner Davignon.
2 Mr J. Moritz, Deputy Director of Corporate Research and Development, Siemens.
3 Mr W. Wagner, Director, Industrial Of®ce European Information
Technology Industry Roundtable.
4 Mr J. Vanhumbeeck, Siemens, Liaison Of®ce to the European Union.
5 Vicomte E. Davignon, Commissioner, DG III (transcript from Nicola
Fielder's interview).
6 Dr N. Hazewindus, Corporate Product Development Coordination,
Philips International.
5
EC regional policy: monetary lubricant for
economic integration?
Patrick Ziltener
The cohesion target ± introductory remarks to
chapters 5 and 6
Along with the internal market project and technology policy, regional
and social policy elements are additional important political dimensions
of the integration thrust of the 1980s. The consistency with which the
cohesion target is reinforced in its various formulations in the conclusions
of European summit meetings and annual Commission programmes is
impressive. This no doubt re¯ects the societal consensus in all member
states of the EC regarding the necessity and desirability, in accordance
with Marshall's famous de®nition of social policy, `to use political power
to supersede, supplement or modify operations of the economic system
in order to achieve results which the economic system would not achieve
on its own' (Marshall 1975: 15). The principle of state-organized
balancing between classes and regions was and is a central element of
the Western postwar model (Bornschier 1996), even when there were
and are different forms and levels of development among the member
states (see Esping-Andersen 1990; Schmid 1995). This societal consensus continues to exist in Western Europe, as surveys show (Ferrera
1993), even during the present tumultuous times of ®scal crisis and
system rebuilding.
In this context, the de®nition of the functions that the European
Community, as one level of statehood in Europe, is supposed to take on
remains controversial. In fact, in the 1980s the cohesion target was
anchored in the treaties, which represented a marked expansion of the
`welfare state mission' of the Community. For the proponents of a
European federal state, the existing EC functions in this domain are
stages on the way to a supranational system of social policy regulation
with ®nancial equalization. Others characterize the regional and social
policy elements as `bargaining chips required to soothe members that
feared the rigour of the open market that was promised' (Colchester and
Buchan 1990: 22), as the price for the deepening of economic integra122
Regional policy
123
tion, whose realization promised to create `bene®ts for all' (see Cock®eld
1994: 44f ).
Chapters 5 and 6 aim to explain the status of the social policy and
regional policy elements in the integration thrust of the 1980s. In both
cases, the question arises as to which protagonists seized the initiative(s)
that became part of package deals. The concept of the integration
project is taken up again (see chapter 2). The determination of the role
of the various protagonists involved in this process is explained in these
chapters by examining the degrees of `success' in the two policy areas
and their present state of development.
The main focus of this chapter is the reconstruction of the development of EC regional policy between 1984, the `take-off' phase of the
integration thrust, and 1988, when the `promise was redeemed' through
the adoption of the Delors Package, that is, when the regional policy
regulations of the Single European Act were realized. This is preceded
by a section on the origins of regional policy in the Community in the
1970s. The last section contains a comparative look at the regional
policy component of the Maastricht intergovernmental conference
along with some theoretical conclusions, and shows that the process that
took place between 1985 and 1988 had a paradigmatic character.
Framing the question
From the obvious close connection between the extension of EC
regional policy and important advances of European integration, the
thesis that this policy is in principle a side payment can be derived. On
the one hand, it is said that regional policy is not a core aspect of the
process (despite the fact that a package deal might not have come into
existence without these elements). On the other hand, in the context of
the `logrolling' that is part of the process, such side payments buy
approval and eliminate the possibility of blocking the integration
project.
The side-payment thesis is widely debated among scholars, especially
in the neorealist literature, with its emphasis on the dominance of the
intergovernmental principle in EC regional policy. The counter-position
disputes the reduction of the dynamic in this policy arena to interstate
negotiations, emphasizes the role of supranational protagonists, and
uses the neofunctionalist spillover mechanism as part of its argument.
According to this argument, integration in one policy area should result
in pressure for integration in other policy areas; in this case, market
integration should create increasing pressure for the construction of a
supranational regional balance.
124
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
The side-payment thesis abbreviates the development of EC regional
policy to certain moments, as a rule to the European summit meetings.
That equalization and compensation payments serve as a lubricant in
the context of package deals is undisputed. What is not taken into
account, however, is that in the case of regional policy we are dealing
not only with an ongoing system of ®nancial transfers without foreseeable
end, but with a system that was increasingly organized according to
supranationally formulated criteria.1 Thus: if a policy package can be
approved only with side payments, then the allocation of functions with
respect to the distribution of resources, i.e. the division of authority
between the different levels, is not necessarily ®xed yet. For Schmitter
(1971: 237), this was the second fact that had to be explained, in
addition to the scope of issues to be resolved through integration;
namely, the question of the level of authority that was delegated to
regional institutions.
The range of possible designs for compensation is de®ned by two
ideal-typical variations: (a) an interstate ®nancial transfer, whereby
resources are determined according to criteria worked out through the
national political systems, and in which the Commission's only function
would be that of a `clearing house', or (b) a supranational polity, which
uses the grant and support funds according to criteria and objectives
de®ned through the political system at European level.
The actual policy represents a mixture of elements of both types; the
ratio has clearly changed in the course of development. The question of
the reasons for anchoring regional policy in the treaties must therefore
be expanded into a question about the reasons for the respective design
of its praxis. This leads to surprising results with respect to assessing the
role of certain protagonists.
A brief look at the beginning: regional policy for the
juste retour
In the EEC treaty of 1957, the regional policy dimension appears in
various contexts. In the preamble, the formulation of a regional policy
goal was accepted: the member states are `anxious to strengthen the
unity of their economies and to ensure their harmonious development
by reducing the differences existing between the various regions and the
backwardness of the less favoured regions'. (EC treaties, Article 235).
1
The formulation of Allen (1996: 209) follows a similar line, according to which the
debate revolved around whether or not the growth of the structural funds `has promoted
a new pattern of ``multi-level governance'' or re¯ects side payments to facilitate package
deals'.
Regional policy
125
However, nothing was said about EC functions as a means for achieving
this goal; the utmost con®dence was placed in the equalizing effects of
the Common Market.
The funds established through the Treaty of Rome had a regional
policy dimension to their activities from the beginning. The European
Agricultural Guidance and Guarantee Fund (EAGGF) provided means
for the modernization of agriculture. The Treaty of Paris (1951), which
established the European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC), intended
to use ®nancial methods for regions with problems that emerged as a
result of structural economic changes (conversion assistance).2 The
European Investment Bank (EIB) granted loans and secured funding for
various activities including investments that contributed to the attainment of the Community's aforementioned goal of harmonious development, and above all infrastructural projects. As a bank, the EIB followed
the normal economic principles for granting credit.
It should be noted that the legitimacy of regional policy at the level of
the nation-state is expressly acknowledged in the EC treaty in that such
state intervention does not fall under the general prohibition against
measures distorting competition (see Article 92, Treaty of Rome).
On the one hand, this absence of a comprehensive common regional
policy is attributable to the relative homogeneity of the then Community
of six; only Italy encompassed a large problem area (Mezzogiorno). On
the other hand, welfare state balancing functions were indisputably the
domain of individual nation-states in the early phase of European
integration, and regional policy was primarily perceived in terms of its
social components, and to a lesser extent as an instrument of economic
guidance (ToÈmmel 1994: 38).
In this early phase, regional policy initiatives and demands emanated
from the supranational bodies. The European Assembly (which later
became the European Parliament) demanded consideration of regional
policy concerns with the implementation of EC policies as well as the
coordination of regional development efforts at the level of the nationstate. The Commission formulated its ®rst regional policy goals in the
early 1960s. In 1965 it published a Report on Regional Policy (EC Bulletin
8±1965) in which it emphasized the necessity for Community-wide
measures. This was justi®ed with the argument that the Common
Market had intensi®ed regional disparities. As instruments for addres2
The European Social Fund (ESF) awarded funds for labour market policy measures for
vocational training and resettlement of unemployed people. More than any other
country, West Germany pro®ted from this arrangement, which very quickly led to the
demand for a stronger regionalization of the disbursements. In the reform of 1983 it was
decided that 40 per cent of the ESF funds should go toward the prioritized crisis
regions.
126
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
sing this problem, the report recommended the coordinated expenditure
of existing funds and interstate policy coordination. The efforts to
stimulate the creation of a special regional policy fund came from the
Economic and Social Committee. The integration crisis of 1965±6
terminated this ®rst debate. The Commission undertook a new venture
in 1969, but this did not resonate in the Council.
The establishment of the original regional fund was part of a package
deal that included the ®rst round of enlargement of the EC in 1973
(Denmark, the United Kingdom and Ireland) as well as the economic
and monetary union (EMU) project. Comparatively speaking, the two
island nations were less prosperous countries with clear regional problems. What might have been decisive was that the United Kingdom
with its small agricultural sector, was to become a net contributor to the
Community budget, whose primary expenditures were agricultural subsidies. What the British wanted was an institutionalized subsidy from
the EC for British expenditure in those regions, not a Community
regional policy with a supranational steering centre.
In 1969, the agreed upon monetary union project was approved only
through the use of compensatory payments. Italy, in particular, which
had frequently used changes in the exchange rate of the lira as an
instrument to strengthen the competitiveness of its export-oriented
industry, raised demands in this regard. Along with new members the
United Kingdom and Ireland, Italy formed a pressure group allied with
supranational actors, each of which had clearly different motives for the
demand for a ®nancial redistribution within the Community.
At the Paris summit in 1972, the European Regional Development
Fund (ERDF) was established. Its goal was the elimination of structural
and regional imbalances within the Community. The determination of
the ®nancial scope of the fund was postponed, principally because West
Germany and the Netherlands made their approval contingent on the
®nal realization of the EMU. Shortly afterwards, the EC was severely
shaken by the oil crisis and the recession that followed. The EMU
project vanished without a sound in the eddy of the anti-crisis strategies
of the individual states (see Busch 1978).
The planned regional fund did not fall victim to the crisis. In 1974 the
Labour Party came to power in the United Kingdom, `a party not
enthusiastic about Community membership' (George 1991: 194) and
one determined to renegotiate the conditions for British membership.
This demand was confronted by a strong French±German alliance. The
problem of the British contribution became intensi®ed through the
increasingly pressing Italian±Irish demand for a common regional
policy. The governments of these two countries threatened to boycott
Regional policy
127
the European Council at the end of 1974 if the realization of the agreedupon fund did not occur. As a result, a positive decision was taken at the
meeting: the fund would be instituted on 1 January 1975, and the
granting of funds3 would be carried out according to a ®xed ratio.
Although another supranational institution was erected in the process,
we cannot speak of a true supranationalization of regional policy in light
of how the fund worked. With the ®xed distribution ratio, the principle
of the juste retour (fair return) was adhered to, that is, the claim of the
member states to a balanced relationship between payments and
receipts, and not a regional policy based on superordinate criteria. A
coordination of national regional policies was not intended, nor was
there any anchoring of Community regional policy in the treaties. The
European Regional Development Fund was based on Article 235,4
whereby each decision falls explicitly under the unanimity rule of the
Council. According to the terms of the so-called Luxembourg Compromise, this was the generally accepted rule; however, being based on this
part of the treaty constrained future possibilities in this domain. Thus,
the national governments were in the driver's seat and the functions of
the Commission in this regard were accordingly minimal.
In the context of the ®rst reform of the Regional Fund in 1979, the
Commission managed to set up a `quota-free sector', whose funds could
be allocated according to the Commission's own criteria and also
outside of the domain de®ned by the national governments. The argument for a common policy in this area was that compensation for the
negative effects of European integration was also supposed to be made
through Community policy. However, the Council restricted this sector
to 5 per cent of the fund's resources. Nevertheless, this should not be
underestimated in terms of its importance for the further development
of regional policy at the European level. With it, the principle of regional
policy as a juste retour measure was undermined, and the supranational
institutions were on their way to supranational policy-making.
In the context of the establishment of the European Monetary System
(EMS), Ireland and Italy again raised the demand for an increase in
3
4
This amounted to 1.3 billion ECU for three years; in 1975 the expenditures for regional
policy comprised 4.8 per cent of the Community budget. The total amount was far
lower than that regarded by the poorer countries as a minimum; this amount was only
about half of the sum contained in the Commission's proposal. The European
Parliament criticized the inadequate allocation. Thus, the fund was `too small to have
any signi®cant impact on regional disparities and thus cannot be seen either as the basis
for a serious common regional policy or as a signi®cant contribution towards the sort of
convergence that would have aided the EMU process' (Allen 1996: 213).
According to Article 235, the so-called general clause, the Community can become
active anywhere it believes necessary `in the course of the operation of the common
market'.
128
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
compensation payments. However, this time they did so without the
support of the British, who were sceptical about the EMS. But the
United Kingdom too would have pro®ted from the extension of the
Regional Fund. A new form of compensation was agreed upon, namely
subsidies on the interest rates of multi-annual credits for the two
countries (George 1991: 197f ).
Some important elements for the further development of Community
regional policy can be derived from this short presentation on its origins.
Among these is surely a con®rmation of the interpretation of EC
development as a sequence of package deals, within which ®nancial
transfers represent an important component. The postponement of the
decision regarding the level of funding is something that we will return
to in our discussion of the summits in Luxembourg (1985) and
Maastricht (1991).
The connection between the admission of new member states and the
questions of ®nancial compensation is evident. The result of this phase
of EC enlargement would certainly have turned out to be more signi®cant if it really had been about cushioning the blow of EMU, and not
predominantly about a juste retour measure. Equally important to note is
the advancing role of the supranational institutions,5 in particular the
Commission, even if they only succeeded to a limited degree in this
phase. Here one must always keep in mind the way the Community
functioned in the era of the Luxembourg Compromise.
Southern enlargement and reforms
During the stagnation phase of European integration, which lasted until
1984, the possibilities for the Commission were largely constrained (see
chapter 2); thus the initial dynamic in the area of regional policy
remained as yet undeveloped. With the EC's second big round of
enlargement, encompassing the Mediterranean countries of Greece
(1981) and Spain and Portugal (1986), another extension of regional
policy was foreseeable. The Commission's interest was in linking the
necessary expansion of the fund through the southern enlargement to a
supranationalization of authority over regional policy.
At ®rst this did not succeed. The admission of Greece in 1981 made
the Council increase the means of the Regional Fund. But these covered
only the additional costs of support for Greece, while for the remaining
5
With respect to demands for a European regional policy beyond an interstate logic, the
Economic and Social Committee went the furthest. It also introduced ± to my
knowledge for the ®rst time in the history of EC regional policy ± the proposal for
including subnational state bodies in the policy-making process.
Regional policy
129
states (whose percentage in the allocation ratio declined) the funds de
facto remained the same.
With its proposal for a new fund regulation in 1981,6 the Commission
strove to rebuild the previous system. Instead of approving only single
projects, broad programmes were to be developed that were designed to
lend greater coherence to regional policy. With these programmes the
possibility of indirect in¯uence over the policies of the member states
would have been created. Moreover, the Commission demanded an
increase in the quota-free sector to 20 per cent of the fund. In addition,
the content of support was supposed to be modernized in the direction
of a more strongly innovative structural policy. The European Council
accepted the programme approach in 1983 but did not follow the
remainder of the Commission's proposal. Instead, it revised the previous
system of ®xed allocation ratios into a system of indicative ranges (upper
and lower boundaries for a particular country rather than a ®xed quota).
Simultaneously, to the sorrow of the Commission, it decided to abolish
the quota-free sector.
The new fund regulation7 adopted during the French Council presidency in 1984 nevertheless represented a crucial step in the direction
of a supranational structural policy. According to Article 5, `Community
programmes' were to be promoted and `national programmes of Community interest' were to be supported as a matter of priority. This meant
de facto a total realignment of the fund with respect to Community
goals. According to the regulation, the determination of these goals
takes place through the political system at the European level. Through
the introduction of indicative ranges, pressure is exerted on member
states' policies, because only with an alignment of these policies with
Community goals can contributions from Brussels be maximized.
Var®s, the Commissioner then responsible for regional policy, wrote
that, although the proposals of the Commission with respect to the new
Regional Fund ordinance were not fully incorporated, its concerns were
largely addressed in the improved content of the new ordinance.8
ToÈmmel (1994: 54) comes to the conclusion that the ground that the
Commission lost through the abolition of the quota-free sector could be
recovered many times over in the long run through this reform.
Greece's earlier date of admission, relative to Spain and Portugal,
6
7
8
In EC Bulletin 4±1981. The Commission counted on the reform proposals of the
Economic and Social Committee. The demand for reform was also emphasized by the
European Parliament and external expert committees.
Of®cial Journal L 169/1984; for an overview see Franzmeyer, Seidel and Weise 1993:
17ff. The decision on the Commission's demand for a doubling of funds for the ERDF
was postponed; the reform came into effect on 1 January 1985.
In his foreword to COM (85) 516 ®nal.
130
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
created political friction that demanded `lubricants'. Although not
following the British demand for a renegotiation of contributions,
Greece's socialist government pleaded in a 1982 memorandum for
special status within the EC for its country, including exemption from
certain regulations and ®nancial assistance. Prime Minister Papandreou
justi®ed his demand for additional ®nancial resources with reference to
the need to solve the structural problems created by underdevelopment
in the Mediterranean region, and simultaneously to address the negative
effects of the (desirable) enlargement of the Community to the Iberian
countries.9 He thus sent a message that Greece's approval of southern
enlargement was going to be obtained only through the granting of side
payments.10 With the Integrated Mediterranean Programmes, adopted
at the end of March 1985, the `Greek problem' was solved. This
involved a special measure with a seven-year term, from which areas in
France and Italy also pro®ted. It did not fall directly under the Regional
Fund, although it was partially ®nanced through it. The only con¯icts
that arose were over the level of ®nancial assistance.11 According to
McDonald (1985: 134f ), fund payments in the years following Greece's
admission to the EC played an important role in PASOK's renewed
electoral victory in June 1985, because they made public works projects
and income increases for farmers possible. Surely this development
contributed to the increasingly more pragmatic European policy of the
Greek socialists. Their actual `pro-European turn' took place later,
however (see Kasakos 1991).
The side-payment character of the Integrated Mediterranean
Programmes was made particularly clear by the fact that these were onetime measures and not ongoing programmes. Nevertheless, these
measures had consequences for the further construction of the system,
because the Commission advanced its regional policy project through
this framework. This was done by the Commission building elements of
its project into these measures, for example the extension of its control
functions and cooperation with implementing authorities at regional
and local levels. ToÈmmel (1994: 84) argues that, through the creation of
new, informal structures for negotiating policy concepts and their
implementation and ad hoc programming, a fundamentally new mode
9
10
11
In his speech of 13 December 1983 before the European Parliament (Europa-Archiv
3/1984, D67).
The Integrated Mediterranean Programmes were quite correctly described as side
payments or even more bluntly as the buying of Greece's vote. Out of many similar
statements, we make reference here only to the customarily direct remarks of the
British prime minister in her memoirs: `the Greek Danegeld had to be paid . . . Greece
could expect a bonanza' (Thatcher 1993: 546).
4.1 billion ECU, of which Greece was assured 2 billion, were authorized.
Regional policy
131
of operation was created, a new `style', which constituted direct cooperation between the Commission and member states and simultaneously
guaranteed the Commission `gentle' dominance over the whole event.
In this way the Commission based its role on the disbursement of funds;
it took the initiative for a programme and exercised in¯uence over its
content through the criteria for granting funds.
Thus, each extension of EC regional policy is connected with a
con¯ict over authority between the intergovernmental and the supranational level. On the basis of the growth of authority in the relevant
area ± better put, the progressive conquest of authority by the Commission ± and with the support of the European Parliament and the
Economic and Social Committee, by this time the regional policy of the
EC had clearly become more than an interstate juste retour system. The
admission of Spain and Portugal would not by itself necessarily have
resulted in a change in the system, but could have signi®ed a simple
enlargement of the system, as in the case of Greece. However, since 1984
the enlargement had been overlaid with a powerful new integration
dynamic, whose roots were described in chapters 1 and 2.
Anchoring the cohesion target: regional policy in the
Luxembourg package
From the beginning it was clear that the creation of an internal market
would have regional policy implications. In this context and under the
heading `completion of the Treaty', the Dooge Committee report
emphasized the goal of the `promotion of economic convergence',
within which it included `the promotion of solidarity amongst the
Member States aimed at reducing structural imbalances . . . through
the strengthening of speci®c Community instruments and a judicious
de®nition of Community policies'.12 The argument of Greece in the
comments added to the ®nal report by the Greek representative to the
committee, Iannis Papantoniou, are noteworthy in this regard:
The overall gains from economic integration are not only unevenly distributed,
but may also disguise losses for the less prosperous regions. The creation,
therefore, of an integrated market and a technological community needs to be
supplemented by a very substantial effort to strengthen the Community's
cohesion by promoting regional development and the convergence of living
standards.13
On the one hand, the basic concept behind the Greek integration
12
13
Ad Hoc Committee for Institutional Affairs, Report to the European Council, Brussels,
29±30 March 1985, Luxembourg, 1985.
Ibid., comments by Mr Papantoniou, Annex B.
132
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
project was that the convergence of economies is a prerequisite for
further integration. However, the Greek government was against the
strengthening or expansion of supranational procedures. On the other
hand, the demand for greater compensation payments, which were
supposed to make convergence possible, was linked to every subsequent
step toward further integration.
The starting point for the negotiations taking place at the intergovernmental conference, which led to the adoption of the Single
European Act in December 1985, was unfavourable for the Greek
position of scepticism toward the deepening of integration. Spain and
Portugal, allies in the ®ght for compensation payments in exchange for
the total liberalization of trade, did not yet participate in the conference
as full members. Moreover, they were generally much more favourable
toward further integration. This was also true of Ireland, which was an
ally in regional policy too; the Irish, given their traditional neutrality,
were primarily concerned with the issue of foreign policy cooperation.
Blocking the intergovernmental conference was only a theoretical possibility, considering the strong alliance among France, Germany, Italy
and the Benelux countries, especially since the foreseeable core issue of
those negotiations, the internal market project, was also a central
concern of the United Kingdom. Therefore the only possibility for
Greece was to seek to maximize both exemptions and compensatory
payments.
On the question of regional equalization payments, the economically
weaker countries had found a strong advocate in the Delors Commission. As shown in the previous section, the Commission had succeeded
in clearly developing its own role in Community regional policy in
conjunction with fund reforms. As a result of its `rebirth' in the context
of the revitalization of the integration process after 1984, the political
weight of the Commission in the decision-making process generally
increased (see chapter 2, p. 52). The Commission moved decisively to
use the new dynamic to extend and strengthen the supranationalization
of regional policy.14 The strategy of the Commission at the inter14
See Delors' report to the European Parliament on the Commission's working
programme for 1985 in Europa-Archiv 7/1985, D195. Delors had already sharply
criticized the mode of operation of EC regional policy in 1983 when he was still a
minister in the French government: `The regional fund is no more than the clandestine
operation of ``juste retour '' or ``fair return''. The administration which gains is the one
which has the best contacts and which best known [sic] how to use the formulae. As to
the social fund, no-one really knows where they are anymore . . . This structural fund
must be reformed just as the agricultural structure funds.' Nevertheless, he defended
the fundamental necessity of European `®nancial and social solidarity'. For this
purpose, Delors continued, real Community instruments and truly encompassing
programmes needed to be developed, `instead of this itsy-bitsy practice of a fair return'.
Regional policy
133
governmental conference was to bundle the relevant measures together
into a `¯anking package' designed to co-opt the opposition and to link
this as closely as possible to the internal market project. Delors said in
his speech at the opening of the conference that the creation of a large
market can have positive effects for all only if it is supported by such
measures (EC Bulletin 9±1985, 1.1.1).
Using the term `economic and social cohesion', the Commission
advanced various social and structural policy proposals.15 According to
these proposals, the goals of Community cohesion policy would have
been very broad (Article 1 ± Objectives): `Community action will aim at
strengthening its economic and social cohesion in particular by improving the living standards, working and employment conditions of the
peoples of the Member States, and by reducing the disparities between
its different regions and the disadvantages of the poorer regions.'
According to the proposed Article 2, these objectives would have been
taken into account in all measures associated with the creation of the
internal market and Community policies. In light of the relatively scarce
resources of the Community, the Commission also envisioned a central
role for itself in coordinating the policies of the member states.
Delors' strategy did not meet with approval, even by those countries
interested in the extension of regional policy. These countries criticized
the overloading of the regional policy portfolio. As a result, the proposed
`¯anking package' was disassembled, but the concept of cohesion
remained a label on the dossier.
The Commission's project included proposals for anchoring and
de®ning the objectives of the structural funds in the treaty. The role of
the Commission in the organization of credit was to be strengthened,
i.e. it was to be allowed to enter into contracts for borrowing, to grant
loans, and to act as a guarantor for loans. In the treaty as proposed, a
regulation was to be approved that envisioned a reform of the structural
funds with the goal of improving coordination and increasing their
economic and social ef®ciency. Although this reform required the
unanimous approval of the Council, quali®ed majority voting would
generally apply to future decisions. Delors justi®ed the necessity of a
reform of the structural funds by noting that over the course of time
these had lost their corrective function and served only to redistribute
appropriations. The goal, as he saw it, must be a real coordination of all
15
Speech by Delors at a colloquium in Paris, October 1983, published in Vandamme
(1985: ix ± xx); quotation from p. xvf.
`Commission's Proposals of 30.9.1985 on Cohesion, the Powers of the Commission,
and Culture' (in Gazzo 1986: 38f ). The Venturini Report (1988: 41) describes the
Commission's view of the logic of the SEA as `building a balanced area without
frontiers'.
134
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
®nancial instruments, a diversi®cation of their resources and a concentration of their interventions on more clearly de®ned tasks (EC Bulletin
9±1985, 1.1.1).
During the conference, Greece and Ireland submitted a paper with
proposals regarding regional policy, but these had no great impact in
light of the extensive and highly polished (through multiple revisions)
proposal by the Commission (see Grant 1994: 75). The French
government's `Amendment on Differentiation and Cohesion' (in Gazzo
1986: 53.), largely supported the Commission's proposal, including the
extension of its role in the capital market. Regarding the question of
quali®ed majority voting in the Council, however, the French adopted a
more reserved posture.
No one disputed the principle of anchoring the regulations on
`economic and social cohesion' in the treaty, especially with respect to
references therein to the regional fund. The economically weaker countries emphasized that appropriate practical provisions in this sector were
a condition for acceptance of the proposals on the internal market and
also wanted concretely to de®ne the ®nancial level of these measures.16
Other member states emphasized the opportunities and the generally
positive effects of an internal market and believed that in principle
`cohesion' was independent of the internal market, and was above all a
political problem that could be managed in the ®rst instance by the will
of individual states to adopt an economic policy approach to the
problem (EC Bulletin 9±1985, 1.1.2). Again and again, Delors clari®ed
to this tendency that the policy package had to be taken as a whole,
including the compensatory policies. At the same time, he played a
moderating role with respect to the regional policy demands and here
made reference to the intended reform of the European Regional
Development Fund. In a provisional appraisal, he noted: `Although
there is an unusual coalition of those who would like more and those
who do not want much in the area, it seems to me we could reach a
solution.' He simultaneously warned of a `clumsy compromise on
budgetary transfers. We have greater ambitions for the Community.'17
The package-deal character of the emerging compromise solution is
revealed by Delors' complaint that, in the area of technological development policy, there was a negative constellation of forces composed of
those who remained basically sceptical of these measures and those who
were afraid that too much Community money would ¯ow into this area
instead of into the structural funds.
16
17
Report by the Council Presidency of the Preparatory Group, 21 October 1985 (in
Gazzo 1986: 58).
In his press conference of 27 November 1985 (Gazzo 1986: 86).
Regional policy
135
At the December 1985 session of the European Council there were no
longer any basic differences regarding the regulations on economic and
social cohesion. Italy still demanded the inclusion of a regulation
regarding the ®nancial provision of the structural funds, which required
the funds be disbursed `in an adequate manner'. In response, other
governments wanted to safeguard themselves against continuing
demands by introducing a requirement that this be done `in the context
of the available budget'. Both were initially taken up at the meeting only
to be dropped in response to the immediate reservations of several
member states.18
The result of the intergovernmental conference with respect to
regional policy was Article 23 of the Single European Act, which
became Article 130a ±e of the EC Treaty. For the ®rst time, this
explicitly anchored the Community's regional policy in the treaty and
thus made it an accepted and integrated part of EC politics.
Article 130a contains a general formulation of the EC's goal of
strengthening its economic and social cohesion in order to promote the
harmonious development of the Community as a whole. This is concretized by the provision that the gap between the various regions and
the underdevelopment of the least-favoured areas should be reduced. As
mentioned above, this did not correspond to the original project of the
Commission to bring together social and regional policy concerns. The
approved formulation does, however, provide a clear basis for a
Community regional policy. The question of when the `harmonious
development of the Community as a whole' can be said to have been
achieved and what constitutes the economic and social dimensions of
`cohesion' remains open (see Vogel-Polsky 1991: 56). More concrete
and more readily operationalized is the goal of reducing the gap between
the regions. It is also important that in this Article the regions are
mentioned without any reference to their national af®liation, that is, the
nation-state's mediation of their interests.
The second paragraph, however, emphasizes the level of the member
states in a manner that was not foreseen in the Commission's project.
Both the Commission and the countries interested in promoting
regional policy regarded as a success the formulation that the goals
named in the ®rst paragraph would be taken into consideration in all
Community policies and in the realization of the internal market. The
position of the economically liberal countries is re¯ected in the formulation that the realization of the internal market as such contributes to
the realization of the regional policy goals.
18
Instead, reference was made in one of the SEA declarations (No. 8) to previous
decisions in this context (EC Bulletin 12±1985, 1.1.3). See Toth (1986).
136
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
In comparison with the original proposal by the Commission, the
de®nition of the instruments to be applied turned out to be relatively
restrictive. The expansion of the Commission's possibilities through
granting it a role in the capital market was not accepted, and the
enumeration of the existing structural funds was designed to preclude a
mandate for the creation of new ones. The de®nition of the tasks of the
Regional Fund (Article 130c) corresponds with the formulation of the
1984 rules governing the fund: the intention is to contribute to the
`development and structural adjustment of regions whose development
is lagging behind' as well as to `the conversion of declining industrial
areas'. The last two paragraphs de®ne the procedure for reforming the
structural funds. Any proposal by the Commission must be approved
unanimously by the Council; the implementing decisions must be taken
with a quali®ed majority vote. As we have already mentioned, regulations regarding the provision of funding were avoided; it was clear to all
participants that this had to take place in the context of a package deal
that would include the other important ®nancial questions (the increase
of the Community's own resources, the reduction of agricultural
subsidies).
Commission President Delors characterized the regional policy aspect
of the SEA as a `balance', which offered the Community an opportunity
to overcome its present existence as a free trade zone (EC Bulletin
11±1985, 1.1.2). He stated: `We followed a path that is somewhat
removed from the idea of ``juste retour ''. One of our fundamental ideas is
to ensure that the structural funds are not conceived of in a narrow
budget perspective of ``juste retour '', but instead constitute a contributory factor towards the Community's economic and social cohesion.'19
The then prime minister of Luxembourg and president of the
European Council, Jacques Santer, described the formulation of the
paragraph on structural policy as the result of a `dif®cult equilibrium',
one that in the eyes of many failed to live up to their bold vision of what
could have been done. The Single Act, however, pointed out which way
to go (EC Bulletin 12±1985, 1.1.1).
Despite its formally restricted power, the Commission was able to
play an important role in the area of regional policy at the intergovernmental conference. Not only did it put the ®rst proposal on the
table, around which further negotiations were held; in a manner of
speaking the Commission became the `spokesperson' for the economically weaker countries. As a supranational political entrepreneur, the
Commission supported the expansion of the system in accordance with
19
In his press conference of 8 January 1986 (Gazzo 1986: 109).
Regional policy
137
the basic goals of the European integration process, in conjunction with
its own interest in strengthening its role in policy formulation and
enlarging the pool of available resources. With the established unanimity
principle regarding the regulation of the funds, the governments of the
net-payer countries were in the driver's seat. Although it was hardly
practical to hold back or reverse the development toward supranational
policy-making, they still possessed crucial leverage through postponing
the determination of the ®nancial resources of the fund. With the
demand for rationalization and increased ef®ciency (Article 130d),
requests for the further development of regional policy increased, even
though the previous reform, adopted in January 1985, had just come
into effect and had hardly made an impact. In this way, the internal
reform dynamic of EC regional policy, which resulted primarily from
the dif®culties of policy implementation, was overlaid and reinforced by
an innovation thrust `from outside', which itself was the result of the
dif®culties of economic integration (ToÈmmel 1994: 57). Simultaneously, it was emphasized on a regular basis that the EC must not go
down the path toward becoming a `redistribution machine'.20 The
secretary-general of the Commission, Emil NoeÈl (1987: 9), de®ned the
heart of the matter in that debate over funding resources: `The main
bene®ciaries are loudly demanding that they be increased, while other
Member States are unconvinced that the money is put to good use, and
suspect that it is more a matter of straight budget transfers than of real
aid for economic development.'
The dif®cult redemption of the promise: the ®rst
Delors Package
Establishing the funding for regional policy promised by the Single Act
was only possible in the context of rearranging the revenues and expenses
of the Community and a more equitable distribution of contributions.21
Very quickly it became clear that the individual dimensions could not be
compartmentalized as they had been by the Council of Ministers.
In the ®rst half of 1986, the Commission did not want to rush the
sought-after development by prematurely raising budget problems. The
majority of Commission members agreed that this would provoke a
crisis, since at this time each discussion would escalate into sterile
20
21
See, for example, the remarks by Peter M. Schmidbauer, then Bavarian state minister,
in EG Magazin 9±10/1985: 3.
Along with the well-known British demands, the main problem raised in this regard
was the regressive effect of the VAT-dependent contributions to the EC budget; this
was criticized because of its discriminatory effect on economically weaker countries.
138
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
confrontations. Delors in particular pleaded for deferring discussion of
®nancial problems for the time being. The counter-position was articulated by Commissioner Ripa di Meana, who believed that `eluding the
®nancial crisis, prevaricating and postponing, is to bury one's head in
the sand, which is not new in the Community history, and which led to
the current impasse' (Agence Europe, 26 June 1986: 7). The June 1986
summit did not result in any conclusions regarding regional policy.
Delors made it clear to the press that the southern member states had
emphasized that the establishment of the internal market must be
accompanied by parallel advances in structural policy.
A Commission study group led by T. Padoa-Schioppa was assigned to
clarify the regional effects of the planned internal market and to
elaborate policy recommendations. The 1987 report of this group,
which took its name from its Italian chairperson, came to the conclusion
that, in order to improve the ef®ciency of the allocation of resources, the
internal market must be accompanied by the expansion of both the
structural funds and the European Monetary System, which would
ensure economic and monetary stability and equity. This legitimated
initiatives by the Commission in the area of regional policy; however,
the report itself, making reference to the subsidiarity principle, advocated a wide-ranging relinquishment of regulatory measures at the
European level and the `competition of rules', which was later invoked
against other Commission projects, including those in the social policy
area (Padoa-Schioppa 1987; see Venturini 1988: 73; Vogel 1991: 36).
Preparing the Delors Package
In autumn 1986, proposals were prepared in internal Commission
seminars that in their subsequent modi®ed form became known as the
Delors Package.22 No formal agenda was established; the ®rst deadline
dealt with the elaboration of the Commission's overall strategy for the
remainder of its mandate as well as for the budgetary and ®nancial
problems of the Community. A second deadline was set for agricultural
and structural policy and the reform of the funds.23
22
23
This descriptive label was given at a press conference of the Belgian government at the
beginning of its Council presidency (the ®rst half-year in 1987). The name was taken
up by the press and its use quickly spread, according to Falkner (1994: 146), whose
research is primarily based on an analysis of the press releases of the press agency
Agence Europe, and on whom I relied in this section.
The ®rst product of work in the area of structural policy was the document COM (86)
401 ®nal of September 1986 on the contents and procedures for the application of an
integrated concept, in which the goal of coordination of the different structural policy
activities was elaborated.
Regional policy
139
There are indications that the British government sought to prevent
debates on economic and social policy as well as the future funding of
the EC during its Council presidency (second half of 1986). Although
the Commission had already sought an initial discussion of these
problems at the London summit in 1986, they were not put on the
agenda. Nor were the structural funds mentioned in any of the Council
documents presented by the Council presidency. Delors was granted
only ten minutes to speak on the future funding of the EC. The
European Parliament referred to this situation as a `growing lack of a
connection between Council decisions under the British presidency and
both the economic and social reality of the Community and economic
and social proposals backed by the Commission and the Parliament'
(Agence Europe, 12 December 1986).
At the conclusion of the summit, Delors announced that he would
make a tour of the capitals at the beginning of 1987 `to explain the
Commission's proposals for future ®nance for the Community, and
again to revise them if necessary' (Agence Europe, 4 December 1986: 5).
This decision appears to have come about under pressure from the
national governments, which wanted to register their views before the
Commission's proposals were made public. The national governments
might have been motivated by their experiences with the dynamic new
Commission at the intergovernmental conference. At that time, the
Commission had advanced its projects on the basis of three papers
submitted by three Commissioners responsible for these areas: New
Own Resources for the Community (Commissioner Christopherson), The
CAP and the Development of the Community (Commissioner Andriessen),
and The Reform of the Structural Funds with a View to the Economic
Cohesion of the Community (Commissioner Var®s). In Var®s's paper he
proposed that the mechanisms of the structural funds (with the exception of the regional fund) should henceforth not follow any strict
regionalization but should be guided by `goals' established on the basis
of previously agreed upon priorities; this was done to ensure that the
proposals would at least have a chance of being accepted by the
governments. Within the Commission, there were controversies over the
most promising strategy for carrying out its project. Delors thought
`that taking too ®rm a position should be avoided, as this would risk
causing reactions in the opposite sense and accentuate the differences
between the various national governments' (Agence Europe, 9 January
1987: 5). Other Commission members wanted to formulate some points
more sharply. Commissioner Ripa di Meana proposed an offensive
strategy in cooperation with the European Parliament against the action
demanded by the governments. The tour of the capitals demanded by the
140
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
governments and their predictable ex ante voting was criticized (especially
by members of the European Parliament) as an inadmissible restriction
of the Commission's right to take the initiative. The European Parliament itself felt excluded from this informal negotiation process in any
case. Delors declared that his trip `will make no change in the Commission's institutional role and . . . in no way modify the Parliament's
powers' (Agence Europe, 8 January 1987: 1). One gets the impression that
Delors hoped to improve the odds for the Commission's ambitious
project by coordinating the Commission's plans with and obtaining
informal pre-approval of them from the individual governments rather
than following the regular Community decision-making process.
Searching for a compromise on a tour of the capitals
In addition to the sixteen-page document on the reforms prepared by
Delors, the heads of state and government were also presented with the
aforementioned three papers on speci®c topics. The positions of the
governments probably did not surprise Delors. Greece, Spain, Portugal
and Ireland emphasized the urgency of the structural funds reform and
wanted the agricultural subsidies lowered in favour of cohesion payments. An increase in the Community's own resources was supposed to
make the latter possible, independent of the complicated and lengthy
reform of the agricultural policy that was anticipated. France and
Germany did not want fundamentally to change the mechanism of
Community agricultural policy, a central component of the `basic business structure' of the EC since its inception. In addition, Delors had to
wrestle again with the new right-wing French government over support
for regional policy. Prime Minister Jacques Chirac criticized the structural funds as `une pompe aÁ ®nances pour les pays en voie de deÂveloppement de l'Europe' (`a ®nancial pump for the underdeveloped countries
in Europe') and announced an alliance with Germany and the United
Kingdom to block the whole package. The Netherlands and the United
Kingdom pressed for a lowering of the agricultural subsidies and an
improvement in budget discipline; the British government renewed its
demand for an equitable distribution of contributions.
The ®nal version of the Commission's project was presented in
February 1987 along with its slogan, Making a Success of the Single Act.24
24
Communication of the EC Commission of 15 February 1987 regarding a new
perspective for Europe (COM (87) 100 ®nal; see EC Bulletin, Supplement, 1±1987).
Later expanded in COM (87) 101 ®nal on ®nancing the budget and COM (87) 64
®nal on the agro-monetary system. See Jacques Delors' speech `ReÂussir l'Acte Unique'
before the European Parliament on 18 February 1987 (Delors 1992: 50ff; EC Bulletin
2±1987).
Regional policy
141
It contained a proposal to increase the Community's own resources to
1.4 per cent of the GNP of the EC, doubling the assets of the structural
funds as part of a macroeconomic growth strategy; this was linked to the
completion of the internal market. By means of an alignment and
concentration of regional policy support into ®ve goals, the Commission
planned to reach the necessary ef®ciency threshold for Community
policy. The reform of the Regional Fund continued that of 1984 and
re¯ected the experience gained with the Integrated Mediterranean
Programmes. In particular, the close involvement of regional and local
bodies in all stages of the programme implementation process from
planning through monitoring to assessment was to be strengthened and
formalized.
The Commission's project found support in the European Parliament
and the Economic and Social Committee (EC Bulletin 11±1987); both
bodies demanded an even greater increase in the assets of the structural
funds. The Economic and Social Committee called the doubling of
assets completely insuf®cient and also wanted economic and social
forces incorporated into the policy-making process in addition to government agencies. The Union of Industrial and Employers' Confederations of Europe (UNICE) described the Commission's proposal as the
`correct approach [and one that] constitutes the minimum required for
achieving the economic objectives of the SEA'.25 The European Trade
Union Confederation (ETUC) also supported the Commission's proposal in principle, but criticized the lack of coherence of its strategy. The
ETUC believed that structural policy was one of three elements necessary in a package of supplementary measures aimed at the completion of
the internal market, the other two being the social dimension and a
macroeconomic policy for growth and employment.26
In the Council of Ministers, the alignment with respect to priority
goals and the concentration of funds was not controversial. However,
con¯icts arose as expected with respect to the division of funds between
the so-called horizontal goals (which all countries could claim) and
those that were reserved for interventions in speci®c regions. Blocs were
formed along the usual lines when it came to the most controversial
topic of the provision in funds. For the Mediterranean countries and
Ireland, a doubling of funds was the minimum demand. The core
countries pleaded for a system improvement instead of a system expansion, i.e. for an increase in the ef®ciency of intervention activities instead
of a signi®cant increase of funding. The countries interested in the
25
26
UNICE position paper of 26 June 1987 on the `Delors Package' and the reform of the
structural funds.
Position paper of April 1987 (ETUC 1988, Appendix to the Activity Report 85/87: 9f ).
142
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
extension of the system linked their demands not only to support for
other elements of the budget reform, but also to the realization of the
internal market, and thus the realization of the SEA.27 The United
Kingdom stood alone in declining to support the whole concept.
The summit meetings throughout 1987 showed that the negotiations
were still far from reaching agreement. In view of this situation and on
the basis of the fact that they all supported the Commission project,
UNICE, the ETUC and European Centre of Public Enterprises
(CEEP) formulated a joint opinion in December, in which they
demanded ± in vain ± a quick decision. Coordinated German±French
efforts also failed to break the impasse. Delors revised the Commission's
proposal numerous times, including one variant with a sharply reduced
increase in the Community's own resources, according to which only
the funds for interventions in less developed areas would be doubled.
Even this could not produce a consensus.
Agreement on the Delors Package
In response to the failure of the special summit of February 1988 in
Brussels, the Commission took up its original proposal again. The
possibility of restricting the doubling of assets to funds for the economically weaker countries remained actively discussed. This would have
meant a doubling of 56.6 per cent of the assets of the structural funds,
since this was the proportion that went to the peripheral countries in
1987. In light of the looming failure of a third summit, the pressure on
all the actors involved grew. Delors prepared his colleagues for
additional emergency sessions and began to threaten the resignation of
the entire Commission if the package was not approved. In a speech to
the Economic and Social Committee, he denounced four or ®ve
member states for wanting to transform the internal market into `a plain
trade market' without supporting common structural and social policy
measures (Agence Europe, 29 January 1988: 6).
At the critical summit itself, from the beginning everything revolved
around the question of the realization of Article 23 of the Act ± the
issue of whether the principal support should be directed to less
developed regions or to entire countries deserving support. The
country-based solution, for which France was the principal advocate,
was excluded by Italy. From the Italian point of view, a preferable
solution was (as was proposed by the German Council presidency) that
all regions with less than 75 per cent of the average economic output of
27
Falkner (1994: 151) con®rms the seriousness of these threats on the basis of her
research.
Regional policy
143
the EC would be supported, since this would have included the
Mezzogiorno region. Such a regulation would have excluded parts of
Spain from structural fund intervention, however, which is why Spain's
preference was the country-based model. An agreement was nowhere in
sight, so the discussion moved on to other issues (e.g. the de®nition of
the Community's own resources and agricultural policy reform). Since
this resulted in more impasses, following the traditional joint breakfast
Kohl and Mitterrand proposed that the negotiations be continued in
the unorthodox form of bilateral meetings. These took place between
the German presidency and the individual delegations, on the one
hand, and the Commission and governmental representatives, on the
other. In the end, the German Chancellor presented a compromise
proposal that approximated the complete package adopted the following night.
The Delors Package cannot be described and evaluated in detail here
(see EC Bulletin 2±1988; Lowe 1988; Franzmeyer, Seidel and Weise
1993). As indicated by its name, it represents a package deal, which
essentially incorporates the following points:
(1) an increase in the Community's ®nancial resources (an upper limit
of 1.2 per cent of total annual GNP);
(2) a contribution rebate for the United Kingdom;
(3) reform of the agricultural policy (in particular, a lowering of the
subsidies); and
(4) a generally intensi®ed control of budget expenditures and regulation
of the ®nancing of the structural funds.
A doubling of all funds until 1993 was approved; in the meantime, the
doubling of funds for the less developed regions (the primary objective)
was approved until 1992. The region-based approach became generally
accepted instead of the model based on focused support for entire
countries.
The rough outline of the reform of the structural funds was provided
by the Delors Package. On the basis of a proposal by the Commission
the details were to be unanimously approved by the Council, with the
implementation regulations approved through quali®ed majority
voting.28 Problems arose primarily over how to establish the exact list of
regions to be supported. The British prime minister again attacked the
principle of additionality, according to which EC monies must be used
not in place of national funding, but only as a supplement to it. She was
opposed to linking national spending to EC decisions, which would be
an insult to the principle of national sovereignty (Agence Europe, 5
28
See Of®cial Journal, of 15 July 1988, No. L 185/9.
144
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
November 1988: 13). The Council reached ®nal agreement on all issues
at the end of the year (EC Bulletin 12±1988).
The structural policy of the Community was guided by the approved
reform, which came into effect on 1 January 1989, and was oriented
toward ®ve priority goals:
. Objective 1: For regions where development is lagging behind (an
action goal of the European Regional Development Fund, the
European Social Fund, and the European Agricultural Guidance and
Guarantee Fund). Such a designation is given to a region if the GDP
per capita of the region falls below 75 per cent of the Community
average. The goal of intervention is to open up the potential for
regional development through investment, the creation and particularly the modernization of infrastructure, etc. Four-®fths of the
resources of the ERDF are designated for these regions. In pursuit of
this goal, the ERDF had secured funding for many such regions until
1993; according to the agreed upon formula for distributing these
monies, approximately 16 per cent goes to regions in Greece, 33 per
cent to Spanish regions, 25 per cent to Italian ones, 18 per cent to
Portuguese ones, and 6 per cent to Irish ones.
. Objective 2: For the adjustment of regions most negatively affected by
industrial decline (action goal of the ERDF and ESF). This designation is given if industrial employment is clearly in decline and
unemployment exceeds the EC average. In 1988 two programmes
were developed in this regard: RESIDER (conversion of iron and steel
districts) and RENAVAL (conversion of shipbuilding areas). In
pursuit of this goal, by 1993 the ERDF had secured funding for many
such regions; approximately 39 per cent goes to regions located in the
United Kingdom, 21 per cent to Spanish regions, 18 per cent to
French ones, 9 per cent to German ones, 6 per cent to Italian ones,
and 4 per cent to Belgian ones.
. Objective 3: Focus on long-term unemployment and the unemployment of youth (action goal of the ESF).
. Objective 4: Assistance for the adaptation of workers to industrial
change (action goal of the ESF).
. Objective 5: Promotion of adjustment in the agricultural and ®sheries
sectors and in rural areas (action goal of the EAGGF). Prerequisites
for quali®cation under this provision include a high proportion of
employment in agriculture as a share of total employment in the
region, a low level of income in agriculture, and below-average total
regional economic output.
Two bodies with advisory functions were established. One of these
had already existed in similar form as a committee of representatives of
Regional policy
145
member states and the EIB; the other was a completely new advisory
body, the Consultative Council of Regional and Local Authorities
(CCLRA, an advisory board within Directorate General XVI). The
CCLRA is composed of representatives of regional and local state
authorities, who are nominated either on the basis of their expert
knowledge or on the basis of their particular knowledge of the situation
in their region of origin; the board's agenda is determined by proposals
from the Commission.
The conditions for success
The eventual breakthrough with respect to the determination of ®nancial resources and the reform of the structural funds can be attributed to
several factors. The ®rst of these is surely the well-reasoned, active and
ef®cient strategy of the Delors Commission, for whom the Brussels
decisions represented the `third stage of the rocket' following the White
Paper on the internal market and the Single European Act (see
Ehlermann 1988; Biehl 1988: 67; Hort 1988: 424). A comparison of
the ®nal result with the original Commission project shows a surprisingly extensive congruence (see Sutcliffe 1995: 294; Allen 1996: 225f ).
At no time during the lengthy negotiations did their concept run up
against a comprehensive counter-proposal. For Helen Wallace
(1996b: 60), the Commission was able `to make its own preferred
proposals ``yesable'' to a surprising extent'.
Another factor that is dif®cult to weigh is the fact that the other
supranational actors,29 along with the large interest groups, stood
behind the Commission's proposal from the beginning. However, that
proposal was implementable only because it represented the redemption
of the promise of extending balance through regional policy embedded
in the Act and as such was supported by all national governments. The
obstructionism of the United Kingdom, and partially also of France,
can be explained in one sense as defence against what they viewed as
excessive demands. In another sense, the delays in the approval of the
Delors Package were central to the strategy of the net-payer countries to
reach decisions on compensatory payments only once the implementation of the internal market had become irreversible. This was increasingly the case in the course of 1987, and probably ®nally determined
29
Falkner (1994: 172) speaks justi®ably of the `secondary role' of the European
Parliament and the Economic and Social Committee. The Commission informed them
about its proposals only shortly before each of the crucial summit meetings, and the
European Parliament president could expound the position of the European Parliament
only in the context of a short audience prior to the beginning of the summit meetings.
146
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
with the decision of the Council of Ministers to liberalize the movement
of capital completely. Internal Market Commissioner Lord Cock®eld
praises that as the crucial element for the breakthrough: `because the
Heads of Government knew that they were going to declare the Single
Market irreversible when they came to the great meeting, the February
meeting was concluding the Delors package no.1, it was because they
knew that the Single Market was in the bag . . . that's the way the nexus
goes round!'30
In addition it must also be noted that the approval of the ambitious
package would probably not have been possible without the German
willingness to pay for a remarkable share of the funding. This is no
doubt based on the wealth of opportunities for the German economy in
a single market and, further, on the speci®c integration project of the
German government (see below).
An important step in the direction of a supranational structural policy
As indicated, the Delors Package and the reform of the structural funds
meant much more than simply the determination of ®nancial resources.
The apparently `technical' changes actually signi®ed a clearly strengthened role for planning and implementation of European regional policy
at the supranational level. This was not expressed in a formal expansion
of the authority of the Commission, but resulted from the type and
manner of the improvement and the increased ef®ciency of policy
formulation and implementation. Through its de®nition of the criteria
for receiving assistance and the regions to be assisted, and being charged
with the control of the implementation of the programmes, the Commission expanded its authority.31
The balance of power between the Commission and the member
states was shifted as a result of the enforcement of the additionality
principle and the creation of an additional advisory body at the
European level that was favourable to the Commission. Through the
CCLRA, the Commission can coordinate its intentions with regional
and local government authorities in advance of a decision. For Anderson
(1995b: 131), 1988 marks not only `the end of the second major
accession wave in the Community' but also `the beginning of the new
cohesion regime'.
30
31
Interview of 9 March 1993; see also Cock®eld (1994: 46).
Allen (1996: 227) comes to the conclusion that, `whilst the overall level of funding is
determined intergovernmentally, the Commission has gained a high degree of control
over the designation of both structural-fund objectives and the 'designated areas' (note
not regions) that they will apply to'.
Regional policy
147
Conclusion
In the total context of the integration thrust in the 1980s, regional policy
is a relevant policy area. This can be demonstrated in quantitative
terms: expenditure in the structural funds climbed from 4.8 per cent of
the EC budget to 9.1 per cent in 1987 and to 28 per cent in 1992. In
accordance with the decisions of Maastricht, 35 per cent of Community
expenditure (33 billion ECU) was projected for regional policy in 1999.
For the period 1994±9, around 170 billion ECU is available from the
Community's budget for structural policies. Over the decade 1989±99,
spending amounted cumulatively to 6.5 per cent of annual Community
GDP.32 This is far more than mere `bargaining chips'.33
In addition, in the course of the 1980s and 1990s a series of
qualitatively important shifts within the institutional order of the EC
took place. This resulted in the anchoring of regional policy in the treaty
via the SEA, and a number of important reforms of the regulations and
concrete practices of regional policy. As we have shown, all this led to
the development and transformation of the 1970s system of transfers
among nation-states ( juste retour ) in the direction of a European
structural policy instrument that follows extensive and supranationally
de®ned criteria and objectives. Still, Community regional policy continues to display a `hybrid' character.
`Maastricht' followed for the most part the same logic as the process
between 1984 and 1988, with the monetary union project taking the
place of the internal market. The peripheral countries tied the demand
for an increase in compensation to the realization of both projects. An
important difference between the intergovernmental conference of 1985
and Maastricht was the fact that Spain and Portugal were full members
at the time of the latter, and that Spain made use of this status (and its
comparatively greater weight). The Commission again took on a function that could be called that of an `advocate', although in the interest of
the approval of the total package it was forced to moderate the demands
of these countries again and again. Spain wanted a form of side
payments as more or less pure ®nancial transfers and with it more
32
33
Data from European Commission (1996a: 9). In order to emphasize the weightiness of
this commitment, the Commission compares it to the Marshall Plan aid to Europe,
which was equivalent to 1 per cent of US GDP per year and amounted cumulatively
(1948±51) to 4 per cent of US GDP (ibid.).
Here there is no mention made of attaining the goals (in particular with reference to the
question of the social and environmental compatibility of both initiated and proposed
projects). Tsoukalis (1993) evaluates the level of redistributed ®nancial resources as
signi®cant for the budgets of the peripheral countries, but still far from what was
necessary effectively to ®ght regional disparities or even decisively to promote
convergence. See also the assessment by ToÈmmel (1994).
148
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
independence regarding the use of funds; this was defeated by the
condition of ef®ciency controls imposed by the net-payer countries. In
turn, this led to an expansion of the system at the European level as an
obvious way out. A new fund was approved, the Cohesion Fund. This
fund will contribute up to 90 per cent of the funding of investments.
In the union treaty, regional policy was ever more strongly oriented
toward a modernization policy aimed at improving competitiveness.
With the establishment of the Committee of the Regions, the participation of the subnational governmental authorities was enhanced and
formalized further.34 To the indignation of the peripheral countries, the
budget decisions necessary for the Maastricht agreements were postponed and later approved in December 1992 as the Delors II Package.
At present the dynamic in this area seems to have reached a certain
immanent boundary. The willingness of the net-payer states to pay has
diminished owing to declining revenues and, in the case of the largest
contributor, to the costs of German reuni®cation. In addition, the
capacity of the recipient countries to absorb funds (in the sense of using
monies for projects meeting the criteria) is not unlimited. Moreover,
there was a backlash against the previous mode of integration as such. In
Maastricht, governments reacted against what they perceived as an alltoo-dynamic Commission. The post-Maastricht crisis (Deppe and
Felder 1993) revealed a general crisis of legitimation of the previous
type of integration.
Our reconstruction of the development of EC regional policy in the
context of the integration thrust of the 1980s revealed that a reduction
of the logic of this policy area to any variant of intergovernmentalism is
inadequate; this is true not only in the sense of the result of the changes
since the Single European Act but also in the genesis of those changes.
Not even an exclusive focus on intergovernmental conferences can
ignore the important role of the Commission as political entrepreneur.
Allen (1996: 225f ), who ± like Moravcsik (1998: 367) ± clearly credits
the Commission with the design of the reform of 1988, reduces its role
in elaborating the essential framework for structural fund activity to the
`assistance' provided in a `process of high-level interstate bargaining'.
We think that the function of the Commission in several respects goes
far beyond `assisting'.35 First, with the enhancement of its own role
34
35
On this point see Engel (1991), ToÈmmel (1994: 59ff ) and Timmermann (1995).
Sutcliffe's (1995: 294) assessment of the reform of 1988 proceeds in a similar direction.
Anderson (1995b: 133) emphasizes `the Commission's capacity to turn the member
governments' general recommendations for action into speci®c administrative arrangements that conferred on it an important role', and its ability `to position itself as the
actor best able to meet the demands of the member states for enhanced ef®cacy of the
fund'.
Regional policy
149
(self-interest in the expansion of the system), the Commission was able
to link the organization and implementation of agreements principally
reached between governments. Secondly, in the aforementioned manner
and with the incorporation of subnational governmental authorities, it
was able to modify the basic structure of the policy arena, insofar as the
monopoly of the national governments over the interplay between
domestic and foreign policy was broken. This was a decisive step in the
direction of multi-level governance.36 Thirdly, it took on the role of
supporter and advocate for the peripheral countries, especially for
the new members. This was consistent with its quasi-federalist views,
but also with the relative weakness of the state apparatuses of these
countries.
The strategy of the Delors Commission was successful, even in terms
of its temporal course. The embedding of the goal of `economic and
social cohesion' was the basis for a continuing dynamic in the area of
regional policy (although the same cannot be said for social policy; see
chapter 6). The method of postponing the establishment of the ®nancial
resources was in fact (from the point of view of the peripheral countries
and the Commission) a risk. Their strategy succeeded because the netpayer countries were ready to ful®l the promise contained in the Single
Act ± as soon as the creation of the internal market was irreversible. The
logic of this chain of events is often disregarded, which leads to de®cient
explanations of what took place.
The structural coupling of the extension of regional policy with
processes of further integration is also emphasized in neofunctionalist
theory. The concept of spillover is increasingly used in a `less functionalist' way in the recent literature.37 Here we return to the same old
problem: we are not talking about processes that are set in motion at
once, which lead to measures in other areas. Rather, we are speaking
36
37
See Marks (1992: 214), Bullmann (1994) and Hooghe (1996); for evidence of the
subsequently successful development of the in¯uence of the regions in Brussels, see the
analysis by McAleavey and Mitchell (1994).
Marks (1992: 198) discusses the `shift in Community resources to the structural funds'
as `forced spillover, in which the prospect of a breakthrough in one arena created intense
pressure for innovation in others'. For Swann (1996: ch 5), spillover also signi®es the
`expansive logic' that led to the dynamic after the SEA. George (1991) revises and
expands the concept, but in the case of regional policy comes to the conclusion that
`there seemed to be a clear functional spillover from the commitment to free the
internal market to the expansion of the regional fund . . . although the Thatcher
governments argued that it was not so' (George 1991: 227).
There are some formulations in older integration theory that are in line with what is
presented here. Nye (1971: 202) speaks of `deliberate linkages': `In contrast to pure
spillover . . . problems are deliberately linked together into package deals not on the
basis of technological necessity but on a basis of political and ideological projections
and political possibilities.'
150
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
about developments in several areas that are often simultaneous and
interconnected. In the context of package deals, policies are introduced
or expanded often as anticipated reactions against consequences perceived as undesirable.38 Thus we are not dealing with mechanisms that
become effective over the course of time, but rather with the political
discourses of the involved actors, that is with their integration projects.
Whether or not corrective measures accompany the creation of the
Single Market and the level of government on which these will be
established depends on their regulatory orientation.
The anchoring of regional policy in the treaty and the structural funds
reform of 1988 can be explained only with reference to the fact that the
peripheral countries, which understood that they potentially had less to
gain from the internal market had at their disposal the possibility of
blocking its implementation. As we have explained, buying them off
through side payments could have been accomplished through a purely
interstate ®nancial transfer. However, the development of regional
policy in the 1980s and 1990s was much more than this; it re¯ected two
additional elements that are fundamental to the integration thrust of the
1980s: (a) a consensus that tends toward the notion that the costs and
bene®ts of EC measures should be immediately distributed,39 and that
the creation of a Single Market alone (`negative integration') does not
guarantee this; and (b) the general desirability of further supranationalization (among the representatives of federalist integration projects; see chapter 2, pp. 44ff ).
One can say that this was the consensus among the large bloc of social
democratic and Christian democratic governments on the European
continent. For these countries, a European regional equalization system
was an inevitable and desirable cornerstone of the integration thrust of
the 1980s.40 Exceptions to this rule include the United Kingdom, and
38
39
40
For Anderson (1995b: 142), `the anticipated spatial effects of the single-market
initiative' were `the main impetus for the sweeping reform of the structural funds in
1988'. For more on the anticipation of the consequences of the internal market see,
especially the detailed discussion of the argument in Marks (1992). He proposes an
argument that is based on the assumption of `differential costs of economic risks',
thereby incorporating `unpredictability'.
Similarly, Begg and Mayes (1993: 149) write: `The reality of the EC is that the division
of costs and bene®ts is central to the political agreements needed to proceed with
integration.'
The reference to the normative content of integration projects does not mean that a
thesis of `altruistic bargaining' in the context of European integration is being put
forward here. The temporal sequence of the extension of regional policy makes its
`dependent', subordinate status quite clear. And the meaning of economic liberalization
for peripheral countries is re¯ected in developments in the balance of trade between
Spain, Portugal and Greece and the rest of the Community after they became
members. One cannot present the regional policy of the EC as `social policy'. There are
Regional policy
151
in a certain sense France, especially from 1986 to 1988. For the
conservative British government, regional policy actually represented an
undesirable, but inevitable, side payment. The reasons for the ultimate
approval by both countries lie in the fact that both countries clearly
pro®t from the resources distributed to achieve the second goal of
structural funds intervention, namely the transformation of old industrial structures; in addition, the United Kingdom was able to push
through a reduction in its contribution.
The decisive thing for the Commission as political entrepreneur was
that its project of setting up and expanding a supranational structural
policy was largely in unison with that of the large bloc of social
democratic and Christian democratic governments. That was the basis
on which it was possible to acquire authority in a step-by-step fashion.
In addition, the Commission was closely allied with the governments of
the peripheral countries. Moreover, it bene®ted from the experiences of
several previous experimental and reform phases in this policy area,
which gave it additional credibility. A comparison with the development
of social policy shows how important these factors are for success in
policy-making at European level.
no `claims' to payments (entitlements) on the part of individuals or regions. Rather,
regional policy is about the promotion of infrastructural investments, about an opening
of regions, from which the entire European economic area potentially pro®ts. The
start-up or restructuring assistance for businesses in peripheral regions incorporates
these into a new European division of labour.
6
EC social policy: the defeat of the
Delorist project
Patrick Ziltener
Introduction
The relatively low rank of the `social dimension' in the renewed push for
European integration in the 1980s provides the starting point for three
competing theses on the integration process.1 First, the cornerstone thesis
holds that, from the beginning, the Europeanization of social policy was
a cornerstone of the integration project as conceived by the supranational political entrepreneur, the EC Commission, and certain
governments. The conception of the social policy domain in the Single
Act (most importantly, Articles 21 and 22 of the Single European Act,
i.e. Articles 118a and 118b in the EC treaties) remained narrow for
purely tactical reasons so as not to endanger the strategic goal of
relaunching European integration. Second, the supplement thesis states
that the core of the project, which was legally established by the Single
Act, was the internal market. When it became apparent that this effort
might not be successful (particularly owing to the public debate about
its social consequences in the years 1987±8), it became necessary to
provide, albeit belatedly, a social policy cushion for the impact of the
internal market. According to neofunctionalist reasoning, the politicization of social policy following the Single Act was an aftereffect of
intensi®ed economic integration. The packaging thesis argues that the
weak social policy regulations together with the abundance of social
rhetoric were merely an expression of the selling of an elite pact to the
European public; it was simply a matter of `packaging the package'.
1
The theses of this chapter were developed jointly with Volker Bornschier. A preliminary
analysis of our research in this area, entitled `The Politics of the ``Social Dimension'' in
the Commission's Project to Revitalize Western European Integration', was presented to
the Second Conference of the European Sociological Association (ESA), Budapest,
Hungary, 1995 (part of which was published in Bornschier and Ziltener 1999). The ®rst
full version was presented to the 8th Conference on Socio-Economics/Communitarian
Summit, Session on `The Social Economy of European Integration' (Organizer:
Professor Stefan Immerfall), Geneva, Switzerland, 1996.
152
Social policy
153
According to this thesis, social policy regulations at the European level
were not really sought after by the main actors.
The packaging thesis and the cornerstone thesis contradict each
other. The explanatory power of the packaging thesis is undermined by
the fact that the social policy content in the integration projects of
important actors was far greater prior to the Single Act than it was
during the intergovernmental conference and in the ®nal agreement. On
the other hand, the cornerstone thesis can thoroughly explain this fact as
an expression of the tactical hindsight of the Commission and the
national governments that were progressive on matters of social policy;
the low social policy content of the Single Act was a result of
`postponing' rather than `packaging'.
The fact that social policy ®rst moved to centre stage some time after
the passage of the Single Act can be explained by both the cornerstone
thesis and the supplement thesis. The supplement thesis argues that it
was the successful adoption of the White Paper Completing the Internal
Market and rati®cation of the Single Act that awoke from their slumber
those actors (in particular, the European trade unions) interested in
social policy as part of the movement toward integration. By contrast,
the cornerstone thesis assumes that social policy was an essential
element of a renewed integration process from the beginning, and not a
post facto supplement. The supplement thesis and the packaging thesis
do not really contradict each other, but rather could be incorporated in
an expanded explanation. After the adoption of the Single Act, those
actors that stood behind a mere `packaging' of the elite pact could not
prevent other actors from pushing for the rhetoric to be turned into
concrete policy measures, that is, the Europeanization of social policy.
Thus, the real difference among these explanations of the social
policy debate lies between the cornerstone thesis, on the one hand, and
the two other theses (the supplement thesis and the packaging thesis)
on the other.
The focal point of the next section is the detailed social policy
information from the intergovernmental conference in 1985 and the
question of the roots of the different initiatives in this area. I then
discuss the reasons for the incorporation of some minimal social policy
elements into the Single Act and draw ®rst conclusions regarding the
assessments of the cornerstone and packaging theses. In the following
section, the social policy elements of the Act are understood as `vestiges'
of a more expansive integration project, one that can be associated for
good reason with the name Jacques Delors. I then examine the starting
point for the subsequent creation of a social dimension, and the allies
and opponents of this ambitious project. The supplement thesis is
154
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
evaluated in conjunction with a discussion about the context for the new
political dynamic with respect to social policy questions that developed
after 1987. The subsequent history of the EC Social Charter and the
Maastricht Treaty must be regarded as signs of the failure of the Delorist
project, and I present the basis for this controversial assessment.
The chapter closes with a ®nal evaluation of the three theses regarding
the status of the social policy dimension of the integration thrust of the
1980s. From the analysis of the development of this policy area, some
conclusions are also drawn with respect to the theoretical discussion of
integration. From a comparison with the more successfully developed
regional policies of the EC, some conclusions can be drawn regarding
the domain of social policy.
Social policy in the integration relaunch
From the beginning, it was foreseeable that the domain of social policy
would become the most controversial element of the integration thrust
of the 1980s. In fact, the Ad Hoc Committee for Institutional Affairs
(Dooge Committee) demanded in its ®nal report, submitted to the
European Council in Brussels in March 1985, a gradual realization of a
European social area as the `logical follow-on from an economically
integrated, dynamic, and competitive Community'.2
The concept of a European social area goes back to a 1981 memorandum by the French government in which Jacques Delors was a
cabinet member. In October 1981, Prime Minister Mauroy arranged for
Deputy Minister for European Affairs A. Chandernagor to prepare a
memorandum on the future of the EC in which, among other things, the
creation of an `espace social europeÂen' (European social area) was proposed.3 This programme included three objectives:
(1) placing employment at the centre of Community social policy by
developing cooperation and reorganizing Community policy;
(2) stepping up the social dialogue at the Community and national
level, both within the company and elsewhere;
(3) improving cooperation and consultation on matters of social
protection.
With the exception of Danish interest in some social policy recommendations, this initiative provoked no response from the other
2
3
Ad Hoc Committee for Institutional Affairs, Report to the European Council, Brussels,
29±30 March 1985, Luxembourg. Point 2, `Gradual achievement of a European Social
Area' as part of Chapter B, `Promotion of the common values of civilization'. See
Thatcher (1993: 550).
In EC Bulletin 11±1981; see Venturini (1988: 26), Lequesne (1989: 153f ) and Falkner
(1994: 188).
Social policy
155
European partners and was never discussed in the Council. Nevertheless, this memorandum is the birth certi®cate of the concept of a
European social area, which was taken up again some three years later
by the French government during its Council presidency. In his speech
on 7 February 1984 in The Hague, Mitterrand outlined the content of
the concept, whose thrust was the ®ght against unemployment in
Europe (Europa-Archiv 7/1984). As means toward this end he named,
among others, a pan-European ®xed reduction of working hours, the
acceleration and universalization of occupational training and the
expansion of social protection.4
At the same time, there were attempts at stimulating discussions
between employer organizations and trade unions at the European level.
At the inspiration of the French presidency (during the ®rst half of
1984), and subsequently also the Irish presidency, meetings were held
between the Council, the Commission, the Union of Industrial and
Employers' Confederations (UNICE) and the European Trade Union
Confederation (ETUC).5
Initially, these attempts at placing a social policy dimension on the
agenda of the Community, which were made within the overall push
toward integration, seemed successful. The Council of the Ministers of
Social Affairs concluded with promising statements in June 1984 (Social
Europe 2/1984): the creation of a European social area was characterized
as inseparably connected with increasing Europe's competitiveness.
Institutional differences between the social systems of the member states
would not exclude the development of European social policy. The
notion of a European social area was also contained in the Commission's
programme for 1985, presented by Delors in his introductory speech
before the European Parliament in March 1985. The realization of a
large market must, according to Delors, go hand in hand with the
creation and formation of a European social area. The positive effects of
this large market would be lost if some member states should try to
create for themselves a competitive advantage vis-aÁ-vis other states at
the expense of social policy. A European social area should prevent
4
5
According to Haywood, the concept of an `espace social europeÂen' ful®lled a dual function
for Mitterrand domestically: (a) as a bridge between the pro- and anti-integration
factions; and (b) as a means `to distinguish PS [Socialist Party] Euro-policy from
Giscardian policy, at the same time as socialist rhetoric was being stripped from PS
texts. Insistence on a social dimension to the internal market softened the blow of
accepting a neo-liberal structure, allowing the PS to retain a degree of socialist
credibility' (Haywood 1993: 274f ).
See Savoini (1984) and Kohler-Koch and Platzer (1986). In the course of 1984 there
was a series of informal contacts between the UNICE and the ETUC which were
subsequently resumed.
156
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
social dumping practices, which have an adverse effect on overall
employment (EC Bulletin, Supplement 4-1985).
These are but a few examples of how the `European social area'
project was repeatedly highlighted in of®cial EC documents. However,
until the intergovernmental conference, the social policy agenda was
repeatedly set aside. At the important summit of the European Council
in Milan, which adopted the White Paper on the completion of the
internal market, maintaining radio silence on social policy was the order
of the day.6 A French memorandum, addressed to the Council, could
do nothing to alter the situation. A section on `The European Social
Area' stated that the standardization of the internal market presupposed
`maximum homogeneity' in the social policy area.7
At the intergovernmental conference8 in the second half of 1985, the
attempt by the Commission closely to link a supplemental package of
social and regional policy measures designed to mitigate the anticipated
negative effects of the realization of the internal market failed (see
chapter 2, p. 63). Delors argued that the realization of the internal
market `raises some extremely tricky problems, particularly with regard
to safety and health. Harmonization of the rules is necessary because
there can be no market allowing reasonable competition unless there is
some measure of harmonization of the rules, and hence to some extent
of enterprises' costs'.9
The strategy of the Commission failed and, through the subsequent
separation of regional policy from social policy, no further concrete
suggestions were made in this regard once negotiations began. Once the
British pushed through the explicit invalidation of majority rule for the
rights and interests of workers (Article 100a), it became clear that there
was hardly any possibility for progress in this area. In the course of the
6
7
8
9
In the integration literature this abstinence from social policy at the Milan summit was a
`negative decisive moment', a phrase that captures the fact that social policy would not
become part of the project (Berie 1992: 57). Schlecht's (1990) thesis that the
Commission did not see the development of the European social system as a logical
prerequisite for the creation of a Single Market contrasts with our explanation of
`postponing' (see below).
In Europa-Archiv 16/1985, D446. Recommendations included measures for the
convergence of social security systems, for improvement of the systematic consultation
of the `social partners', and for the preparation of the concertation of elements
in¯uencing wage agreements in branches, particularly those in sectors regulated by EC
rules (steel industry, textile industry, etc.).
The reconstruction of the social policy debate at the intergovernmental conference in
1985 is based on interviews with protagonists who were directly or indirectly involved,
an evaluation of the EC Bulletin, and the documents in Gazzo (1985 and 1986), as well
as on De Ruyt (1989), Venturini (1988), Lequesne (1989), Attali (1993) and Howe
(1994).
Speech by Delors at the ®rst session of the intergovernmental conference in
Luxembourg (in Gazzo 1986: p. 25).
Social policy
157
conference, Delors submitted a proposal according to which Article 117
would have been supplemented through the incorporation of the
concept of a `European social area'. Although the concept was ®rmly
anchored in many Community documents and was not elaborated
beyond that, it was nonetheless rejected.
The Commission had become repeatedly frustrated to such an extent
that some national delegations then had to take up the effort to reopen
the issue. A Belgian proposal for securing fundamental rights was
incorporated into the Preamble of the Act. A French proposal wanted to
create the possibility that, if the `social partners' concluded a collective
agreement covering at least three countries, this (upon recommendation
by the Commission and with a quali®ed majority vote in the Council of
Ministers) could be declared binding on the whole Community. This
proposal had no chance, especially since the countries that did not want
to touch the principle of Tarifautonomie (autonomy of the `social partners' in collective bargaining) united in opposition with the opponents
of every EC function in this area. This coalition almost overturned
Article 22 of the Act (non-binding social dialogue at the European level;
Article 118b of the treaties). The ®nal formulation was taken from the
Dooge Report.
An initiative of the Danish government for an article regarding the
improvement of the work environment with respect to the health and
safety of workers was successful and became incorporated as a modi®cation to Article 21 of the Single Act (Article 118a of the treaties). The
remarkable thing here is that the minimum requirements in this area are
to be determined by a quali®ed majority of the Council. This is the only
social policy area in the Act in which quali®ed majority votes of the
Council are possible. In consideration of the southern member states, a
regulation that provided a step-by-step application according to levels of
development was incorporated. An accord regarding Article 21 ®rst
became possible after the end of the conference and after the British had
pushed through additional restrictive formulations (paragraph 2 on
protection of small and medium-sized businesses; paragraph 3 on the
possibility of maintaining more stringent regulations). According to an
interview with a high-ranking British diplomat, if these `reassurances'
had not been adopted, the article would have been overturned.
The various initiatives and their results are summarized in table 6.1,
and the modi®ed Article 118 of the treaties is presented in table 6.2.
Even prior to the conclusion of the intergovernmental conference,
the Commission president announced with strategic optimism: `That is
the basis for a fresh start.' He thanked the `happy initiative' of the
Danish government, which promoted the social dimension `in political
158
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
Table 6.1. Intergovernmental conference (IGC) 1985: initiatives in the
social policy area and their results in the Single European Act (SEA)
Initiative
By
Mode of agreement
`European social area'
France 1981; Dooge Rejected
Report; Commission
proposal at IGC:
Incorporation in
Art. 17 of the treaties
Anchoring fundamental Belgium
Agreed as general
rights
reference in Preamble
Improvement of the
Denmark
Agreed after incorporaworking environment
tion of various restrictions, e.g. small and
medium-sized undertakings clause (United
Kingdom)
Fighting unemployDenmark
Rejected
ment by means of
coordination of the
economic policies of
the member states
Creation of the
France
Agreed as non-binding
possibility of collective
`social dialogue'; combargaining at European
promise proposal of the
level
Commission
Results
None
Preamble SEA
(Section 3)
Art. 21 SEA,
Declaration No. 7
(Annex SEA); Art.
118a of the treaties
None
Art. 22 SEA;
Art. 118b of the
treaties
conditions which were not easy for it' while at the same time meeting
the expectations of several delegations.10 This statement only partially
re¯ects the fact that a dramatic `chainsaw massacre' (the term is
Delors') of the social policy proposals had just taken place, one
surpassed perhaps only by the one in the monetary policy area.
At a press conference on the last day of the Luxembourg Council, at
about midnight, Delors was of the opinion that the social policy content
of the Act must open a breach, if it was to be taken seriously (EC Bulletin
11±1985, 1.1.2). The choice of the word `breach' might well have
expressed the hope of a breakthrough by means of the established `social
dialogue'. The Italian Prime Minister Craxi criticized the open refusal
of every attempt to shape European cooperation in the social area more
concretely and more ef®ciently (ibid.). The national publics were only
dimly aware of the social policy content of the Single Act, and for that
reason it hardly played a role in the rati®cation debates.
In the integration literature, the social policy content of the Single Act
10
In his press conference of 27 November 1985 (Gazzo 1986: 85).
Social policy
159
Table 6.2. Article 118 of the treaties establishing the European Communities as modi®ed by the
Single European Act
Article 118
Without prejudice to other provisions of this Treaty and in conformity with its general
objectives, the Commission shall have the task of promoting close cooperation between
Member States in the social ®eld, particularly in matters relating to:
± employment;
± labour law and working conditions;
± basic and advanced vocational training;
± social security;
± prevention of occupational accidents and diseases;
± occupational hygiene;
± the right of association, and collective bargaining between employers and workers.
To this end, the Commission shall act in close contact with Member States by making
studies, delivering opinions and arranging consultations both on problems arising at
national level and on those of concern to international organizations.
Before delivering the opinions provided for in this Article, the Commission shall consult
the Economic and Social Committee.
Article 118a (SEA Article 21)
1. Member States shall pay particular attention to encouraging improvements, especially
in the working environment, as regards to health and safety of workers, and shall set as
their objectives the harmonization of conditions in this area, while maintaining the
improvements made.
2. In order to help achieve the objective laid down in the ®rst paragraph, the Council,
acting by a quali®ed majority on a proposal from the Commission, in cooperation with
the European Parliament and after consulting the Economic and Social Committee,
shall adopt, by means of directives, minimum requirements for gradual
implementation, having regard to the conditions and technical rules obtaining in each
of the Member States.
Such directives shall avoid imposing administrative, ®nancial and legal constraints in
a way which would hold back the creation and development of small and medium-sized
undertakings.
3. The provisions adopted pursuant to this Article shall not prevent any Member State
from maintaining or introducing more stringent measures for the protection of working
conditions compatible with this Treaty.
Article 118b (SEA Article 22)
The Commission shall endeavour to develop the dialogue between management and
labour at European level which could, if the two sides consider it desirable, lead to
relations based on agreement.
is predominantly seen as minimal, as representing little more than a
codi®cation of current practice (Moravcsik 1991: 43; 1998: 365),
signifying a mere quantitative improvement in the available social policy
instruments but hardly a qualitative leap (Schulte 1993a: 273), to be
understood `more as a ``by-product'' than a realization of the ``social
dimension'' that had been planned from the start' (Berie 1992: 58,
160
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
fn. 115).11 The two following sections discuss the explanation of the
social policy results of the intergovernmental conference of 1985 with
reference to the three theses mentioned earlier and assess their meaning
for the further development of EC social policy.
Explaining the content and the lack of content of the
Single Act
The fact that the anchoring of the concept of a `European social area'
was rejected by the majority can certainly be interpreted through the
packaging thesis; this is the direction of the analysis by Vogel-Polsky
(1991). As long as it was only inconsequential rhetoric, there was no
decisive resistance to the concept, but, as soon as it became an issue of
including it in the treaty, it was no longer acceptable. The concept itself
has never been de®ned concretely in any Community document; it was
therefore associated in the ®rst instance with the French proposals. That
these were not capable of being approved had been foreseeable for a
long time, based on the low level of resonance to the concept. However,
the explanation of the lack of receptivity to the concept must be
expanded. Another reason for it, as many interviewees from other
national delegations as well as those in the Brussels apparat explained,
was the `speci®cally French' character of the concept and the strategy
pursued. Whereas interviewees who were stamped by a Francophone
political culture resonated to visionary concepts for the elaboration of
policy, in other political cultures a tremendous scepticism prevailed
toward such proposals, whose content is only vaguely outlined and
whose legal consequences are therefore dif®cult to assess.
The adoption of Article 118a on occupational health and safety
proved of far-reaching signi®cance for the development of EC social
policy. Two aspects were of particular importance: (1) the explicit
establishment of majority voting in the Council (see Schnorpfeil
1994: 40): and (2) the lack of de®nition of the concept of the working
environment. The competence of the Community was not actually
broadened through Article 118a (see Pescatore 1986; Vogel-Polsky
1991); health and safety in the workplace were already explicitly
mentioned in Article 118. The previously unde®ned concept of the
working environment, however, can be traced back to the speci®cs of
Danish labour and social policy legislation regarding the term arbejdsmiljù, which subsumes areas such as working hours and the protection of
11
In this light, it is dif®cult to comprehend Sidjanski's (1992: 160f ) assessment that
social policy at the 1985 intergovernmental conference was an example of an `engrenage
dynamique'.
Social policy
161
youth. These two elements together enabled the Commission ± which is
responsible, on the basis of Article 100a, to strive for a high level of
protection12 ± in conjunction with the European Court of Justice, to
turn occupational health and safety legislation into the most important
and successful area of social policy legislation in the Community (see
Berie 1988; Eichener and Voelzkow 1994).
How can the adoption of Article 118a be explained? The Danish
interest in the generalization of its legislation is not only sociopolitically
but also economically motivated. A state that can generalize its `regulatory style' and level of regulation to the European level dismantles its
own `locational disadvantages'. The costs of adopting such measures fall
exclusively on other states. No doubt, one reason for the consent of the
other governments to the Danish proposal was that most understood it
relatively narrowly as a supplement to the technical occupational protections (safety of machinery, facilities, vehicles, tools, etc.) that belong
to the core areas of the harmonization policy, in the sense of the
reduction of import restrictions in the Single Market. In this respect
there is a trade policy background to all this.13 No one, not even the
British government, wanted intra-European competition with respect to
occupational health and safety.14 Great Britain had legal regulations in
this area that were comparable in scope and depth to those in other West
European countries. Moreover, the European employers' association
(UNICE) had also expressed its support for establishing baseline EC
rules in the area of occupational safety.15
However, the question is not yet clari®ed as to how the British
government accepted majority voting in the Council of Ministers in this
area and thereby gave up its veto right. Thatcher was prepared to accept
a larger number of majority decisions in the Council as the price for the
internal market (Thatcher 1993: 553). Can one therefore say that
Article 118a was a social policy element of a package deal? From our
interviews with members of the British delegation at the Luxembourg
intergovernmental conference, we know that majority decisions in the
occupational and social policy areas were not acceptable, even as part of
a package deal. Moreover, Article 118a was decided after the Luxembourg summit, at a session of the Council of Ministers, that is, at a time
12
13
14
15
Article 100a, para. 3: `The Commission, in its proposals envisaged in paragraph 1
concerning health, safety, environmental protection and consumer protection, will take
as a base a high level of protection.'
See Eichener and Voelzkow (1994: 388), Ross (1995b: 363) and Leibfried/Pierson
(1996: 190).
Everyone we interviewed made reference to this point.
UNICE position paper, The Social Dimension of the Internal Market, 30 November 1988;
see Tyszkiewicz (1989b: 49).
162
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
when the central issues of the internal market, research and development and cohesion were already signed, sealed and delivered. Obviously
the British government believed, on the basis of an (implicitly) narrow
understanding of the `working environment' and through the adoption
of restrictive clauses, that it was adequately safeguarded.
The further history of Article 118a is a de®nitive ®ght to the ®nish
over how far the concept of the working environment would reach. By
November 1986 the European Parliament had already demanded from
the Commission a broad interpretation of Article 118a; the Economic
and Social Committee followed suit (Beretta Report, in Venturini
1988). Every social policy action programme was accompanied by
confrontations about the scope of the article. Everywhere that the
Commission succeeded in making reference to Article 118a, prominent
steps toward harmonization at high level occurred.16 In 1991, for
example, a directive on improving occupational health and safety for
temporary workers was decided by majority vote, whereas both of the
other regulatory proposals regarding the protection of temporary
workers remained blocked. Thus, occupational health and safety have
developed far beyond a set of minimum regulations enacted for the sake
of the internal market into the most important area of EC social policy
legislation with far-reaching regulations ± most recently the 1996
European Court of Justice directive on working hours. In addition to
the British government, UNICE President Tyszkiewicz (1989b) also
severely criticized the Commission for its attempts to extend the validity
of Article 118a and with it the use of quali®ed majority voting to areas
that are expressly excluded by Article 100a. In his view, the politics of
the Commission were not compatible with the spirit and letter of the
Single Act (ibid.: 48).
The history of Article 118a reveals that, for some, it was clearly the
nucleus of EC social policy legislation, whose development, in the sense
of a `balanced approach', had to be forced, particularly since no social
policy demands could be pushed through at the intergovernmental
conference in 1985. For others, the internal market was suf®ciently
enhanced in its social dimension by the narrowly con®ned European
legislation on occupational health and safety as it applied to products
and production.
16
See Leibfried and Pierson (1996: 191). For the most part, one can attribute maximum
use of the potentialities of Article 118a to the Commission, but not ± Ross (1995b:
373) gives this impression ± to the article as such. Another factor is the special function
of the European standardization associations: Eichener and Voelzkow (1994) cover the
important function of the technical committees of the European standardization
organizations (CEN/CENELEC) and the clear overrepresentation of the high-regulation countries in them. See Konstanty and Zwingmann (1989).
Social policy
163
As we have mentioned, Article 118b only partially satis®ed the
projects of some actors regarding future collective bargaining at
European level. Delors called it `purely symbolic text', which was nonetheless important for the Commission because it was conducive to and
legitimated the continuation of dialogue at the European level.17 The
article contained nothing more than the current practice, which had not
been called into question by anyone (see Berie 1988). The decisive thing
for UNICE was the aspect of voluntariness; again and again, it emphasized the difference between dialogue and collective bargaining.18 Interviews with British diplomats yielded the same basis for the adoption of
the article; in addition, reference was made (with ironic undertones) to
the symbolic meaning of such texts for (continental) Europeans.
Our analysis of this phase of the revitalization of the European
integration process showed that important actors were also pursuing
inseparable social policy goals. These were relatively abstract, however
(something that actors in favour of them also admitted); and at the
Luxembourg intergovernmental conference they were unequivocally
subordinated. Here the cornerstone thesis is con®rmed, based on the
actions of the majority of the actors involved; the packaging thesis is
thereby rejected. To evaluate the cornerstone thesis, the social policy
integration project must be reconstructed more precisely, since,
although present from the outset, it can be only indirectly deduced.
Only in this way can the further development of this policy area up until
the Maastricht Treaty be understood and the supplement thesis be
discussed.
The Delorist project
The `European social area' project of Mitterrand and the then French
government has already been described. Its adoption as part of the
Luxembourg package was not achieved, and in 1986 France elected a
new rightist government led by Jacques Chirac. Throughout the
con¯ict-ridden cohabitation of a socialist president and a right-wing
government, President Mitterrand was clearly restrained in his role as
the most important promoter of social policy integration up to that time.
The role of the Commission therefore became even more important.
What was its project in this regard?
The goal pursued by the Delors Commission was a `mixed' method
17
18
Delors at a press conference, 27 November 1985 (Gazzo 1986: 87).
See UNICE position paper, The Social Dimension of the Internal Market, 30 November
1988: `The Single European Act rightly places emphasis on ``dialogue''. Dialogue . . . ,
not collective bargaining.'
164
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
`involving social regulation and harmonization of employment and
working conditions, characterized by a combination of Directives
and Regulations on the one hand and arrangements deriving from the
social dialogue on the other'.19 The social dialogue had a greater weight
in the project of the Commission than it did in that of a `European social
area'.
The project can therefore be called Delorist, because not only was the
Commission president its most important promoter and his cabinet20
the most important producer of ideas and corresponding concepts, but
he gave it its speci®c content. As shown in chapter 2, for Delors the
concept of concertation, the involvement of `social partners' in the
formulation and implementation of political programmes, had always
been a central part of his politics. It is therefore not surprising that
Delors, shortly after taking of®ce, invited representatives of the Union
of Industrial and Employers' Confederations (UNICE), the European
Centre of Public Enterprises (Centre EuropeÂen des Entreprises
Publiques, CEEP) and the European Trade Union Confederation
(ETUC) to talks at the `Val Duchesse', a small palace on the outskirts of
Brussels. The goals that Delors had pursued from the outset with the
`social dialogue' were re¯ected in the Venturini Report (see note 19).
The dialogue of `social partners' at the European level was supposed to
lead later to the recognition by the `social partners' of a `joint responsibility to manage the changes deriving from the single market and adopt
a more `European' attitude by planning their strategy within the framework of a Europe without frontiers and by managing their own internal
contradictions' (Venturini 1988: 63f ). In the area of the legal regulation
of labour relations, this meant subjecting European collective agreements to compulsory standardization and coordination with the various
national levels (intersectoral collective agreements, sectoral agreements,
company bargaining).
The thesis of an existing and speci®c European `societal model',
whose elements exist in all societies and their respective states (see
chapter 2, p. 56), provides the background and argumentation for the
Delorist project. As Delors often said, the social dimension is not an
invention of the Brussels bureaucracy, nor does it depend upon the
19
20
A formulation from the important Venturini Report (1988: 65). The Venturini Report
(whose original title is Un espace social europeÂen aÁ l'horizon 1992) did not have the status
of an of®cial position paper of the Commission, but drew from earlier work and
deliberations of the Commission.
Delors' cabinet was the site of conceptual innovation in the area of social policy; central
concepts and papers were drafted there, sometimes up to the point of detailed drafts.
When necessary, his cabinet circumvented those of other Commissioners and
established parallel networks to achieve the desired results.
Social policy
165
personal convictions of the president of the Commission; rather, it is
inherent in the form and manner in which the European nations have
progressed for decades (Delors 1988b: 6).
More broadly stated: for the political left, the revitalization of
European integration held the promise of recapturing political control of
the economy through a new system of supranational governance as well
as in industrial relations, internalizing the external effects that increasingly pre-empt the authority of individual national regimes and extricating European industrial relations from the dictates of competition
among regimes and market forces. Their goal was the defence and
continuation of the tradition of inclusion of unions and workers' interests in the shaping of industrial relations and political regulations in
general. In this sense, current efforts to add a social dimension to the
internal market are best understood as `attempts to preserve, if only by
default, the historical labour-inclusiveness of European industrial relations against strong economic and political pressures for deregulation by
anchoring it in tripartite supranational institutions able to promote a
new convergence among national regimes along labour-inclusive lines'
(Streeck 1993: 89).
If we have correctly described the Delorist project, the question arises
of why its advocates did not raise its realization to a conditio sine qua non
from the beginning. If one reconstructs the prehistory of the Single Act,
then the answer lies at hand: only through a strategic withholding of
controversial areas could the blockade of integration be overcome. In
this sense, we can understand the statement by EC Commissioner Lord
Cock®eld21 that a linkage with social policy demands would have clearly
slowed down the integration thrust, if not completely hindered it: `Had
``linkage'' been accepted it would have resulted in intolerable delay being
imposed on the Internal Market Programme and in the light of subsequent changes in the economic and political climate this delay could
well have frustrated the programme altogether' (Cock®eld 1994: 46).
Ross describes Delors' strategy as an attempt to seize the available
opportunities for action from the area of all political possibilities, to
accumulate through success the necessary resources and to invest these
again in the expansion of this area. Here Ross compares Delors' strategy
to a Russian doll, which consists of several dolls, each concealed inside
the other: `It was necessary to begin with proposals which would tap
most of the open dimensions of the opportunity structure and create
21
Compare the reference to Lord Cock®eld in Fels (1989: 162, fn. 1), which cites the
following: `If we had linked the social questions with the economic regulations neither
of the two would have moved ahead.'
166
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
forward momentum . . . Its success was immediately cashed in on new
initiatives: the Russian dolls' (Ross 1995a: 46).
With this strategy, the transition from market-creating to statebuilding was supposed to be achieved. In the course of the integration
process, elements of state-building would appear, that is, the transfer of
sovereignty in the direction of the EC, whose weight would thereby
become greater. Venturini (1988: 26) emphasizes the coherence of
Delors' strategy: the decision to begin with the `economic path', instead
of with the other three alternatives under consideration (institutions,
currency or defence), was outlined by Jean Monnet. After the adoption
and the ®xing of a timetable for the Single Market project, the subsequent strategy rested on the impetus provided by economic and social
interest groups (ibid: 28). We will see that Venturini describes exactly
the procedure Delors would follow in 1988.
The anchoring (albeit weakly) of social policy elements in the Act was
extremely important for Delors' strategy. From this foundation one
could push the development of this policy area (create a `breach').
Delors constantly tried to attach the same signi®cance to the Single Act
as he did to the Treaty of Rome with respect to its quasi-constitutional
legal status in terms of social policy and the `concertation' process.22 In
any case, this step-by-step process became a politically risky path,
considering the different goals of the national governments with respect
to integration and the structural weakness of actors who favoured the
development of social policy at the European level.
The situation after the Single Act ± allies and opponents
of the Commission
The administrative planning and management authorities within the EC
are largely self-suf®cient and only weakly in¯uenced by the representative political bodies of the EC (Bach 1993b: 265). However, Delors
cleverly recruited the support of the European Parliament and the
Economic and Social Committee as part of his strategy. They were allies
of the Commission insofar as they could be counted on as generally
sympathetic to integration and to the area of social policy (see Springer
1992). However, DaÈubler (1989: 43) points out the inverse proportion
operative here: the greater the advocacy of social policy in the drafts and
pronouncements of the various EC organs, the less their own decisionmaking authority in that domain.
22
Delors (1988c: 10f ) in his preface to the Cecchini Report on the `Cost of NonEurope'.
Social policy
167
The European Parliament
Since the 1960s the European Parliament has striven to turn the EC
into a `Grundrechtsgemeinschaft ' (community of fundamental rights) with
respect to social policy issues as well (ibid.: 52f ). In February 1984, the
draft treaty of the European Parliament for a European Union emphasized a `competing responsibility' within the proposed political union in
the areas of social and health policy. Article 56 of the draft treaty
regarding social and health policy included, among other things, the
creation of comparable conditions for the preservation and creation of
jobs, the need for the Community to take action in the area of rights of
association and collective bargaining (particularly with regard to the
conclusion of EC-wide wage agreements) and worker participation.
Generally, the EC would have committed itself under Articles 2 and 4 of
the draft to the maintenance and development of social rights, which
follow from the national constitutions and the European Social Charter.
However, the draft treaty was not seized upon as part of the integration
relaunch in 1984±5 (see chapter 2, pp.46f, 64).
In November 1986 the European Parliament adopted by a large
majority six reports on various aspects of the European social area,
calling in general for a strengthening of the role of the Economic and
Social Committee and the `social dialogue'.23 However, it was and is the
case that the in¯uence of the European Parliament is slight. This was
illustrated in 1989, when the European Parliament adopted a resolution
on the social dimension in which it considered the question of basic
rights for employees, a resolution that was not taken up by the other EC
bodies. It was further demonstrated by its lack of any role or in¯uence in
the negotiation process that produced the Social Charter, during which,
despite its protests, the European Parliament was simply bypassed (see
Falkner 1994: 184; Springer 1992: 90f ).
The Economic and Social Committee
The Economic and Social Committee has a consulting function for the
Commission and the Council of Ministers. It consists of representatives
of national and European associations (employers, workers and different
23
The Raggio Report proposed that the agreements of the `social partners' achieved up to
now at the Val Duchesse meetings could serve as a basis for a general directive laying
out the fundamental rights of all workers. The demand for a `Community framework
agreement on the basic rights of workers' (as it was formulated in the Bachy Report)
also emerged repeatedly in the reports. For the most important proposals of the
European Parliament and a list of its most important reports between 1986 and 1988,
see Venturini (1988: Annex 5).
168
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
interests such as craft workers, consumers and farmers), who are
appointed by the Council on the basis of nominations from the national
governments. One of its nine working parties covers the social policy
area and compiles position papers as part of the general EC decisionmaking process or in response to speci®c enquiries on the part of the
Council or Commission. It is noteworthy that the `social dialogue'
initiated by Delors, with its goal of the exchange of views and `informal'
agreement, has a somewhat unresolved relationship to the more formal
Economic and Social Committee, with its speci®c position in the EC
decision-making process. Streeck (1994: 16) speaks of a `de facto
replacement' and with it a displacement to `softer', less binding forms of
consultation.
The Economic and Social Committee, despite basically agreeing with
the Internal Market programme, sharply criticized the fact that it did
not contain concrete and approved proposals about a working programme for the realization of a European dimension in the social
sphere. In September 1987 it decided to prepare a position paper on the
social aspects of the internal market. The report by Beretta (The
European Social Area), published in November of the same year, stated
in paragraph 1.6, under the heading `Making a Success of the Internal
Market and European Social Area': `Adoption of Community legislation
guaranteeing basic social rights immune to competitive pressures is . . .
a key stage in the creation of the single market.'24 Both the European
Parliament and the Economic and Social Committee advocated a broad
interpretation of the social policy articles of the Single Act.
The European Court of Justice
To complete the picture we must mention the European Court of
Justice. Its consistent broadening of EC jurisdiction (Falke 1993)
contributed to a `Europeanization' of various policy areas. In the
domain of social policy, the Court emphasized the `indication of a social
responsibility of the Community' in the founding treaties of the EC and
also the Single Act and raised this to the level of a quasi-constitutional
welfare state principle.25
24
25
In Venturini (1988: Annex 6, see pp. 74, 102ff ); see Falkner (1994: 189).
See Streil (1986); Schulte (1993b) and Everling (1990). The strategic position of the
Court, particularly in terms of its social policy importance, is revealed by the fact that
Thatcher was rarely able actively to include the Court in her blocking strategy. Her
lawyers pointed out again and again to her that on questions of the Community and the
competence of the Commission the ECJ would favour a `dynamic and expansive' rather
than a restrictive interpretation of the treaty articles: `The dice were loaded against us'
(Thatcher 1993: 743).
Social policy
169
The `social partners'
The realization of the Delorist project naturally counted on the actors
who stood at the centre of the concept: the social partners. Through the
`social dialogue', they were supposed to be systematically tied in to the
integration relaunch from the beginning. The European trade unions
knew Delors' background and his earlier policies in France and accordingly had high hopes of the new Commission. In 1985, another unionist
had become a member of the new Commission: Alois Pfeiffer, who
represented the German trade union confederation (DGB) in the
European Trade Union Confederation. Responsible for economic and
regional policy, he fought long and hard for the social dialogue.
The European Trade Union Confederation, which in principle
favoured further integration, followed the tying up of the Luxembourg
package with some concern.26 In fact, the ETUC had early on expressed
itself in favour of the internal market project, but criticized the absence
of a social dimension in the Commission's White Paper. The simultaneous development of a `European social area' would be imperative in
order to prevent social regression through social dumping and the
lowering of standards for health and safety protection. During the
Luxembourg intergovernmental conference, the ETUC warned that the
Community, acting on the basis of the Commission's White Paper,
could be tempted to pursue a one-sided and fundamentally faulty
approach in its pursuit of the necessary greater European unity. The
ETUC embraced the Single Act, although it was not satisfactory from
its point of view, insofar as it did not always ensure a balance between
the economic and social dimension.
The Union of Industrial and Employers' Confederations of Europe
had actually declared itself in favour of `social dialogue' on a Community level in principle.27 It declined, however, to enter into binding
decisions, in the sense of EC-wide agreements, arguing that the
differences between the industrial relations and collective bargaining
traditions in the individual member states made that impossible.
Furthermore, social and labour market policies were deemed to be
genuine domains of the nation-state, and the bargaining power of the
national employers' associations would not have been suf®ciently
26
27
For ETUC's position concerning the integration relaunch, see its Activity Reports from
1985 onwards, especially its position paper on the internal market project of October
1985.
For UNICE's position concerning EC social policy see the position paper The Social
Dimension of the Internal Market (30 November 1988) and its monthly reports from
1985 onwards; see Kohler-Koch and Platzer (1986: 168ff ), Tyszkiewicz (1989a) and
Tiedemann (1989).
170
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
re¯ected. Some national member associations of the UNICE, such as
those in Italy, Luxembourg and France (with some exceptions), were
ready, primarily for domestic reasons, to lead the European `social
dialogue' with a higher degree of obligation and a broader spectrum of
themes. However, the majority of the UNICE member associations
declined the expansion of the dialogue. The UNICE favoured the
process of `natural convergence' as the main mechanism for the
development of European social policy. From that point of view,
the Commission was supposed to function as the centre for information
on `decentralized' initiatives that had been successful in promoting
competitiveness and innovation.
Only in the area of occupational health and safety did the UNICE
favour harmonization at the EC level. Tyszkiewicz, president of the
UNICE, justi®ed this as follows: `Health and safety and equal opportunities are of direct bene®t to all members of the work force. By
supporting action in these ®elds, employers demonstrate their refusal to
compete, within the EC, on humanitarian factors such as the health or
safety risks to which workers may be exposed, or on the equal rights of
women, or of minorities' (Tyszkiewicz 1989a: 73). These areas dealt
with `very speci®c cases where one could indeed argue the risk of unfair
competition' (Tiedemann 1989: 93, vice-president of the UNICE
Committee of Social Affairs). In other words, in the opinion of the
employers' representatives, in the areas with `humanitarian factors' no
`unfair' competition should exist, although in all other areas it should be
given free rein (see Silvia 1991: 634).
In fact, the `social partners' soon adopted common positions on
questions of training, motivation, information on and consultation
about the introduction of new technologies and on macroeconomic
questions (Venturini 1988: Annex 4). The value of these early results
was defended by DG V and other interested parties, often with reference
to the importance of these positions for building mutual trust between
employers and the trade unions. Relatively quickly, however, it became
clear that the dynamic Delors had hoped for would not develop. This is
no doubt connected to the very general formulation of Article 118b
(Vogel-Polsky 1991: 32f ); however, it is also simply an expression of the
dramatically diverging projects and expectations that lay behind it.28
After his initial optimism, Delors had to confess that after three-and-ahalf years the results were rather sobering. In a speech at the ETUC
Congress in 1988, he cited as reasons for this the fact that the involved
28
On the phase of the revitalization of the social dialogue, see among others Jahrbuch der
EuropaÈischen Integration 1985: 291ff, Kohler-Koch and Platzer (1986), Siebert (1989)
and Ross (1995a: 45).
Social policy
171
parties did not have a real mandate for negotiation at their disposal; that
from the standpoint of the `social partners' the joint opinions did not
amount to much for the countries that already were more developed in
these areas; and moreover that this approach of collective bargaining
was on the decline even at the national level in favour of bargaining at
the level of the branch or company. In Delors' estimation there was also
the danger that long-term fruitless activities undertaken as part of the
`social dialogue' could disguise the actual stagnation of social policy
(Delors 1992: 77f, cf. 121). In view of this situation, some national
governments indicated their impatience concerning the social policy
stagnation, and the trade unions emphasized that, for them, the `social
dialogue' was not the only way to develop Community-wide social
policy.29
The attempt at the subsequent creation of a social
dimension
Most advocates of the supplement thesis make reference to the events of
1988, when fears about the consequences of the realization of the
internal market spread among the trade unions, increasingly also among
politicians, and above all among members of the European Parliament
(see Berie 1992: 58; Mosley 1990: 154). Teague (1989: 75) emphasizes
that an almost inexplicable shift took place in favour of the Commission
and the other actors sympathetic to social policy integration. The
following explanatory factors can be brought to bear to explain the new
momentum in the social policy area from 1987 on.
First, from the viewpoint of the Commission, the regional policy
components of the `cohesion target' had been passed with the adoption
of the `Delors Package' in February 1988, and now it was time to deal
with its more controversial social policy components. In order to
generate a continuing dynamic, the level of pressure generated by
workers' organizations, which had been too low, had to be increased, in
particular with respect to governments that were still hesitant in this
area. In 1988 the Commission president toured from labour union
conference to labour union conference. In addition to his speech at the
Stockholm conference of the ETUC, Nourrir le dialogue sociale (`Fostering the Social Dialogue', in Delors 1992: 71ff ), in which he proposed
the establishment of a `Charte communitaire des droits des travailleurs'
(`Community Charter of Workers' Rights'), his visit to the Congress of
29
Hinterscheid, secretary-general of the ETUC, as cited in `CoheÂsion sociale et dialogue
social europeÂen dans la construction du marche inteÂrieur' published by Fondation
Europe et SocieÂte in Cahiers de la Fondation, no. 12±13, Paris, 1989, pp. 57ff.
172
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
the British TUC in Brighton was very important. Within the British
trade unions, a strategic re-evaluation of the EC had already been under
way for several months.30 The renewed electoral victory of the Conservatives in Great Britain in the summer of 1987 and the rati®cation of
the Single Act might have been decisive impulses for this. However, the
convergence of the unions' EC policies led to an increase in their
political weight at the European level. Thus the expansion of the groups
of actors (a development promoted by the Commission) can also be
regarded as a second factor.
A third factor was the constellation of member states. In 1987, with
the accession of Spain and Portugal, the coordinates of the debate at the
EC level about social policy shifted in a certain respect. On the one
hand, the danger of `social dumping' in a common market, considering
the signi®cantly enlarged disparities, assumed a new, intensi®ed dimension. On the other hand, the current governments of these countries
were comparatively pro-interventionist.
Another important factor was the ambitions of the Council presidencies of member states with a progressive position on social policy,
particularly Belgium and Denmark (®rst and second halves, respectively,
of 1987). In May 1987 the Belgian minister for social affairs, Hansenne,
advanced the concept of a `pedestal of social rights'.31 The Belgians'
(improvised) proposal was designed to reactivate the Commission to get
the `social dialogue' back on track, that is, to put social policy on the
agenda again.32 The Delors cabinet had also been discussing proposals
regarding fundamental social rights as a possible way to concretize the
`European social area'.33 From this point on, the core concept of the
post facto social policy for cushioning the impact of the internal market
30
31
32
33
See the TUC Report entitled Europe 1992: Maximising the Bene®ts ± Minimising the
Costs at the 1988 Congress; see The Times, 19 August 1988, p. 4, Silvia (1991: 632) and
Springer (1992: 124f ). Thatcher's still famous speech at the College of Europe in
Bruges (20 September 1988) must be understood as a reaction to Delors' speech in
Brighton. Against the growing pressure for social policy initiatives at the EC level she
counter-posed the concept of the EC as `a European Single Market with the minimum
of regulations ± a Europe of enterprise': `We have not successfully rolled back the
frontiers of the state in Britain only to see them reimposed at a European level, with a
European super-state exercising a new dominance from Brussels' (Thatcher 1993:
745). This speech provoked serious protest on the part of many national governments
and other political actors.
The Belgian memorandum carried the title La CEE va-t-elle craindre de garantir des
droits sociaux fondamentaux aÁ l'heure de la ¯exibiliteÂ? (see Vogel-Polsky (1991: 154) ).
Interview with an of®cial working for the Belgian Permanent Mission to the EC,
29 November 1995.
Interview with Patrick Venturini (DG V), 19 September 1996. According to him, a
`socle des droits fondamentaux' (`a pedestal of social rights') was an idea that had been
¯oating around; see also Ross (1995a: 43).
Social policy
173
develops: the Community Charter of the Fundamental Social Rights, or
Social Charter.34
The growing public pressure for a post facto social cushioning of the
impact of the internal market implied the threat of withdrawing support
for the European integration process and/or decreasing voter favour for
socialist and Christian democratic governments. This had a clear effect
on two important national governments: the French, again socialist
since Spring 1988, and the German. The latter, particularly during the
intergovernmental conference of 1985, had taken a very restrained
position on European social policy. This now began to change, no doubt
owing to the obvious irreversibility of the realization of the internal
market, but also because its Christian democratic majority was receptive
to public pressure for a social Europe.
All these factors have to be considered in context: 1988 was the year
in which a wider European public ®rst became aware of the Single Act,
i.e. of the internal market project. A widespread publicity campaign
undertaken by the Commission regarding `Project 1992' no doubt
contributed to this development. Moreover, as companies began to
prepare themselves for the common internal market, a wave of restructuring measures, takeovers, and mergers con®rmed the seriousness of
the project. The nearer the realization of the Single Market came, the
more the public debates intensi®ed with respect to anticipated undesirable outcomes, in particular rising unemployment and the threat of
`regime shopping' and `social dumping'.35 According to the Eurobarometer surveys, the percentage of respondents who thought the internal
market was a `good thing' dropped 6 ±10 per cent from Autumn 1987 to
Autumn 1988 in Belgium, Germany, France and the Netherlands.
At the European Council meeting in Hanover ( June 1988)36 it was
emphasized that the internal market measures must not reduce the level
of social protection in the member states. Moreover, the Single Market
was also supposed to serve as the means for improving the living and
34
35
36
In support of the `precedents' set by the European Social Charter of 1965 and the
entirety of the International Labour Organization (ILO) conventions, and re¯ecting its
receptiveness to the proposal by the Belgian Council chair of May 1987 and the
Economic and Social Committee position (the Beretta Report), the Venturini report
stated: `The idea of a body of guaranteed minimum social provisions±a charter of
fundamental rights±is one of the possible short-term solutions to the problem presented
by the existence of major disparities between the social legislation in force in the various
Member States. It has the advantage of not recommending Community laws,
unrealistic at the present time, but providing a framework, a joint minimum reference,
for the national system' (Venturini 1988: 70).
For the lines of argument, see, among others, Venturini (1988: 63) and DaÈubler
(1989: 2), and additional literature cited in note 42.
Final conclusions in Europa-Archiv 16/1988, D443ff; conclusions in the social policy
area also in Venturini (1988: 69); see also Delors (1992: 69f ).
174
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
working conditions and the work and health protection of all citizens.
For the ®rst time since 1974, the European Council thereby dealt
extensively and centrally with social policy at European level and underlined the necessity of creating, simultaneously and in a balanced
manner, the `social dimension' of the Single Market 1992 (BerieÂ
1992: 58; see DaÈubler 1989: 41).
Delors, whose mandate was extended for four years in Hanover, now
put the Brussels apparatus into high gear in order to make the most of
this new social policy momentum. He gave the Economic and Social
Committee a mandate to draft a Social Charter. In September 1988, the
Commission's social policy working programme was presented under
the title The Social Dimension of the Internal Market (Venturini 1988:
Annex 7). The trade unions thought this did not go far enough, while
the UNICE reacted positively with respect to a number of its proposals
(see Tyszkiewicz 1989a).
Evaluating the supplement thesis
In the ®rst part of this chapter, the packaging thesis was essentially
refuted, in that it could be shown that the `social dimension' held great
importance for key actors in the integration thrust, even though their
concern bore relatively little fruit. The explanatory power of the supplement thesis is more dif®cult to judge. A part of the dynamic corresponds
to the explanatory logic of neofunctionalist integration theory. The
unions, initially overrun by the integration dynamic and additionally
weakened through diverging EC policies, mobilized in response to the
progress of integration and subsequently tried to implement a `social
dimension'. National governments came under pressure to extend
integration `sectorally'.
On the other hand, the supplement thesis is at least partially refuted
through the con®rmation of the cornerstone thesis: what happened was
not simply an attempt at a subsequent creation of a social dimension,
but the realization of what was regarded as the cornerstone of the
integration project by several governments and the Commission. With
the possible exception of the project of the German government, no
prominent alteration of integration projects can be established in this
sense. The dynamic in this area, the (temporal) development of the
agenda, is mainly to be explained, as we have shown in this section, by
shifting resources and the interplay of the tactics of actors who desired
a European social policy from the beginning. Our argument is that
1988 signi®ed that the postponed Delorist project was back on the
agenda.
Social policy
175
The Social Charter and the Maastricht Treaty
The creation of a subsequent `social dimension' to the internal market
concentrated increasingly on efforts to implement a charter of
fundamental social rights. At the end of 1988, the European Trade
Union Confederation presented a draft of a legally binding Social
Charter,37 a body of important social rights, modes of implementation
and rights to sue for workers and/or unions. All thirty-six member
unions of the ETUC supported this draft. The demand of the ETUC
was formulated clearly: `1989 must become the year of social policy, just
as 1985 was the year of the White Paper.' In a speech to the European
Parliament in January 1989, Delors spoke of a Social Charter as the
means to make concrete `the European societal model' and to bring it to
life (Delors 1992: 121). He connected this with the hope for a breakthrough in the `social dialogue'. The UNICE spoke in favour of a Social
Charter, but not in legally binding form; the UNICE preferred to think
of it as a set of recommended standards, to which member states should
aspire.
In March of the same year, the meeting of labour and social ministers
in Seville made clear that, now as before, well-known fundamental
differences remained. The British Employment Secretary Norman
Fowler saw a Social Charter as `unnecessary regulation'.38 In February
the Economic and Social Committee presented its opinion on an EC
Social Charter.39 In May the Commission put its proposal on the table,
which recommended that the charter be given the character of a
non-binding `solemn declaration' (EC Bulletin 5-1989). Along with this,
the Commission proposed an action programme for implementation of
the points listed in the charter; these would have to be individually
reviewed and adopted by the Council of Ministers. These proposals for
non-binding status and the `splintering' of the project resulted in
furious criticism from the trade unions. The British government
remained in fundamental disagreement with a Social Charter in any
shape or form.
In the Spring 1989 Eurobarometer poll (March/April), a new question was taken up: `There is talk of adopting a charter of fundamental
social rights for the entire EC, that is, a set of common rules throughout
all the member countries for matters concerning the rights and respon37
38
39
ETUC, `Community Charter of Social Rights: A Report by the Executive Committee',
1988; see also Silvia (1991: 632ff ).
As cited in Jahrbuch der EuropaÈischen Integration (1989/90: 450).
Economic and Social Committee, Basic Community Social Rights: Opinion (CES 270/89),
February 1989.
176
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
sibilities of workers and employers. Do you think such a charter would
be a good/bad thing?' The results indicated popular support for the EC
Social Charter project. Approval of the idea was at or above 60 per cent
in all countries except Denmark, with only 47 percent, and the Federal
Republic of Germany, with only 57 percent. In France, Holland, Spain
and Italy approval was over 70 percent; the average for the entire EC
was 69 percent. In June, the socialist parties emerged as victors in the
elections to the European Parliament, but this did not perceptibly
in¯uence the future fate of the Social Charter.
At the EC summit in Madrid during the same month, Thatcher put
forward the argument that the voluntary Social Charter of the European
Council was quite suf®cient and that an EC document was not necessary. As she later explained, such a Community document `I knew
[would] be the basis of directives aimed at introducing the Delors brand
of socialism by the back door' (Thatcher 1993: 751). Although the
consent of the United Kingdom was not necessary for the adoption of a
non-binding charter, the decision was postponed; this was due perhaps
to the desire not to place the planned action programme into jeopardy
through the exclusion of the United Kingdom.
During the second half of 1989, under the French Council
presidency, the Social Charter became the main priority. In September
the Commission presented a new proposal, which responded to its
critics through simultaneously specifying and making ¯exible speci®c
points in the Charter. Neither attempts to create political pressure on
the part of the unions, which organized a demonstration in Brussels in
October under the slogan `For a Social Europe', nor further wateringdown of the Charter by the labour and social ministers could move
Fowler and the British government to agreement. Still, the Council of
Ministers stood by the watered-down version, a fact that is sometimes
taken as an indication that other national governments hid their own
opposition to the Charter behind the British rejection.
Solemnly, but without obligation: the Community Charter of the
Fundamental Social Rights of Workers
At the December 1989 meeting of the European Council in Strasbourg
the Community Charter of the Fundamental Social Rights of Workers (Social
Europe 1/1990) was adopted by eleven states as a political declaration of
intent of an advisory nature. The following `fundamental social rights of
workers' were listed therein: freedom of movement; employment and
remuneration; improvement of living and working conditions; social
protection; freedom of association and collective bargaining; vocational
Social policy
177
training; equal treatment for men and women; information, consultation
and participation for workers; health protection and safety at the workplace; protection of children and adolescents; and the integration of
elderly and disabled persons. The content of the Social Charter
essentially con®rmed the original social policy conception of the EC,
according to which social policy regulations at EC level were connected
®rst of all to the realization of the fundamental freedoms of the internal
market (see Schulte 1993b: xxxixf ).
On no account should the legally non-binding Social Charter be
mistaken for the ful®lment of the project for a `European social area' or
the `social dimension of the internal market'.40 The demand for a
Charter of binding rights, as conceived and demanded by the unions
and the European Parliament, whose enforcement would serve as the
basis upon which all could appeal, had not been ful®lled. Many
signi®cant individual agreements that the Commission had proposed
were discarded in the course of the negotiations; for example, agreements about questions of workers' rights with respect to transborder
services, working hours and the introduction of a guaranteed minimum
income. Additionally, the Council, in opposition to the Commission,
had determined that the Charter applied only to workers (instead
of to all citizens, as was originally proposed). Neither Community areas
of responsibility nor the obligations of member states to guarantee
these fundamental rights were approved; the Charter emphasized only
their `responsibility', and that only `in accordance with national
practices'.
Because of its non-binding character, the Charter was an act with
predominantly symbolic meaning; it was known to all that any real
disputes would arise in connection with the yet to be determined social
policy action programme. According to Berie (1992: 60), the Social
Charter, despite the fact that it had an indirect in¯uence on social policy
legislation, hardly ful®lled the expectations it had aroused. In particular,
it represented no progress in terms of the status quo, that is, the position
advocating minimal Community responsibilities in the area of social
policy legislation.
It became increasingly clear during the Social Charter negotiations
that, without a prior change in the treaty, no legal basis existed for
signi®cant social policy advances as part of European integration. The
opportunity for such a change had been missed with the Single Act
(see Berie 1992: 61), a consequence of the initial postponing of the
40
See the statements on this in the Commission's programme for 1991 in EC Bulletin,
Supplement 1±1991.
178
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
`social dimension'. The intergovernmental conference leading to the
Maastricht Treaty offered a chance for catching up.41
Social policy in the Maastricht Treaty
At the EC summit in Maastricht in December 1991, eleven states
decided, in light of British resistance, `to continue along the path laid
down in the 1989 Social Charter' and, leaving the United Kingdom
aside, to ®nalize for this purpose a Protocol on Social Policy. The Dutch
Council presidency had presented a more moderate draft than the ®rst
Commission draft in order to obtain the participation of the United
Kingdom. When it became clear in the course of the negotiations that
the UK would still not go along, the original draft was again taken up.
The Agreement on Social Policy provided for majority voting in the
Council in the areas of working environment and conditions, information and consultation of workers, equality between men and women,
and integration of persons excluded from the labour market (Article 2,
paragraph 1). Explicitly reserved for unanimous voting in the decisionmaking procedure are the areas of social security and social protection
of workers, protection of workers when their employment contract is
terminated, representation and collective defence of the interests of
workers and employers (including co-determination), conditions of
employment for third-country nationals, and ®nancial contributions for
promotion of employment and job creation (Article 2, paragraph 3).
Important areas of labour law are excluded from Community regulations, including `pay, the right of association, the right to strike or the
right to impose lock-outs' (Article 2, paragraph 6). Within the meaning
of `horizontal subsidiarity', the Agreement provides for an expanded
role for the `social partners' at both the national and EU levels (see
Baumann 1995: 18ff ). According to Article 2, paragraph 4, a member
state may entrust management and labour, at their joint request, with
the implementation of directives. Articles 3 and 4 regulate details of the
`social dialogue' and tripartite cooperation with the Commission. At the
EU level, two consultations are provided for; the `social partners' can
thereby inform the Commission whether they are in agreement on the
facts in a negotiation and want to conclude an agreement by means of
social dialogue. The `social partners' then have nine months to conclude
this process. If this time limit is not suf®cient to resolve the issues, the
41
The negotiations of the intergovernmental conference regarding social policy cannot be
presented here. On this point see, among others, Doutriaux (1992), Lange (1993),
Ross (1995a) and Moravcsik (1998: 452ff ).
Social policy
179
Commission may use its own means according to the usual legislative
process.
After Maastricht the social policy momentum dissipated. Just as it
had during the negotiations, the issue of economic and monetary union
continued to dominate. At the same time, results of the referenda in
Denmark and France re¯ected a strong upswing for opponents of the
integration process, at least in its existing form. The economic recession
of the 1990s and rising unemployment in Western Europe also changed
the social policy agenda of the EU: the social policy order of the day
shifted from constructing social regulatory policies at the European level
to recon®guring labour market and other arrangements to allow the
European economy to increase its competitiveness.
A ruling of the German Bundesverfassungsgericht (Federal Constitutional Court) in October 1993 is important for interpreting the Union
treaty and assessing future possibilities. According to Kaufmann-BuÈhler
(1994: 4) of the German Foreign Of®ce, from this decision it was
inferred that social policy remains in essence an issue for each of the
member states; thus, the Community is limited to supportive activities,
essentially with respect to minimum standards for occupational safety.
Further, the decision maintained that there is no legal basis in the
treaties for a common economic policy, much less a common social
policy.
The judgment of the Bundesverfassungsgericht is signi®cant not just
as a restriction on a central actor, the German government. In addition,
just like the anchoring of the subsidiarity principle in the Union treaty, it
has the function of excluding the `Monnet-ist' type of integration (see
pp. 71f ), and thus of restraining the Commission. If the `Monnet'
method can no longer be sustained, then this will become very evident
with the further development of European social policy. Only an
unambiguous expansion of the Community's areas of authority via the
treaty can alter this picture.
The defeat of the Delorist project
The balance sheet of social policy development in the framework of the
integration thrust of the 1980s is not simple to compile. The expert
literature is divided; part of the discussion revolves around the `Is the
glass half empty or half full?' conundrum. Answers that point to
successful harmonization in the area of occupational health and safety as
the main evidence of a successful EC social policy are not convincing
(for example, Eichener and Voelzkow 1994; see also Pierson and
Leibfried 1995: 436). This area is uniquely entitled to a special status;
180
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
one goal of this chapter has been to explain why this is so. In the
judgement of Wolfgang Streeck (1994, 1995), the second wave of social
policy proposals in the 1980s (which followed a progressive phase in the
1970s) was turned back even more decisively than the ®rst. Springer
(1992: 121f ) compares the body of social policies with the economic
measures contained in the White Paper and comes to the conclusion
that the two are in no way of equal weight.
With respect to the social dialogue at the European level, it is often
emphasized that this was initiated during a time when strong efforts
were (and indeed are still today) under way in most states towards
dismantling or decentralizing collective bargaining. Against this unfavourable background, the argument goes, the mere existence of such
negotiations and their anchoring in the treaties is important, and acts as
a signal for actors at the national level. Nevertheless, success must be
judged by the result, and this result does not correspond in large
measure to the projects of most political actors. The objection is often
made, and particularly by representatives of the Delorist project, that it
is too early to draw up a balance sheet, and that it took a long time to
satisfy the demand for successful institutionalization of corporatist
negotiation models at the national level as well.
From our point of view, the Delorist project itself must be taken as a
critical measuring stick for judging the development thus far of social
policy. The renewed integration process should not only serve the goal
of the preservation and improvement of the economic competitiveness
of Europe but also prevent social regression. This could occur only in an
espace organiseÂ, an organized area with common social standards set at a
high level. This has actually been true in only a few areas up to now;
most areas are characterized by a competitive articulation of national
standards (Ziltener 1999). The intensi®ed intra-European competition
in product markets, and also between locations with respect to investments and jobs, places heavy pressure on (expense) factors such as
social standards, wage levels and taxation. This `systems competition',
sought after by some political actors, does not correspond to the
Delorist concept of a balanced approach with the goal of achieving the
primacy of politics (see Delors 1992). Trade union circles refer to the
dynamic of deregulation and competition unleashed by the internal
market project, which has encompassed the labour markets as well as
national wage scales and social policy systems (see Kleinhenz 1990:
23f ). Cases of social dumping,42 the conscious exploitation of differ42
See on this point Teague (1989: 77ff ), Mosley (1990: 158ff ), Hagen (1992), Mueller
and Purcell (1992), Leibfried and Pierson (1996: 200f ), and, for the example of the
construction sector, Baumann (1995).
Social policy
181
ences among national or regional regulations and the playing off of one
workforce against the other within the Single Market by businesses have
in¯icted heavy damage on the `social image' of the EU.
So far, no dynamic has developed from the `social dialogue' that
would mitigate the increasing pressure felt at the national level by
achieving results at the European level.43 From this a sceptical assessment also follows with respect to the main goal of the Delorist project:
the preservation of the modeÁle europeÂen de socieÂte (the `European societal
model') and the protection of its labour-inclusiveness. For Delors
himself, what has been achieved up to now does not de®nitively
preclude the possibility of the (backward) development of the EU into
one big free-trade zone.44
Conclusion
Using the method of reconstructing the integration projects and the
implementation strategies of the central actors in the social policy area,
in this chapter we tested three theses regarding the role and weight of
this policy area in the integration thrust of the 1980s. The cornerstone
thesis received the greatest support from the evidence: from the beginning, the creation of a `European social area' was a central demand of
important actors in the revitalization of European integration. Articles
21 and 22 of the Single Act were not mere `packaging' for the internal
market project, although they are often interpreted as such; rather, they
were the `vestiges' of an ambitious social policy integration project,
which for strategic reasons was postponed so as not to hinder the
renewal of the integration process. By following this path, a departure
was made from the simultaneous realization of the European social area
explicitly demanded by Delors and the trade unions and from the policy
insisted on by the French government of maximum homogenization of
the social policy area as a precondition for an internal market.
In 1987±8, the representatives of the `social area' project renewed
their efforts at implementing it. These efforts had already been
connected with Delors' relaunching of the `social dialogue' in 1985 and
his offer of an alliance with the trade unions for the purpose of pushing
ahead with the `social dimension'. A series of favourable factors (Council
presidencies held by national governments that were progressive on
43
44
See CEU (1995a); for the discussion about structural obstacles see Windolf (1993),
Armingeon (1994) and Platzer (1994: 49).
Delors, in an interview in Die Zeit of 2 February 1996 on the question: `Do you exclude
the development of Europe into a big free trade zone?': `No, but I am against it. If the
political leaders of Europe lack farsightedness, it could come to that' (our translation).
182
The core elements in recasting the European bargain
social policy issues, the reorientation of the British trade unions and the
consequent strengthening of the European Trade Union Confederation
as a European actor, and public debates about the social consequences
of the Single Market project) reinforced the energy of the initiative(s).
But, in contrast to the allies of the Commission in the other central areas
of the integration package, this alliance was comparatively weak and it
met with the greatest resistance.
The `second try' started with the project of a charter of fundamental
social rights; the `one-sidedness' of the Single Act was supposed to be
corrected by it. This second attempt led, via many con¯ict-ridden
detours, to the Social Protocol of Maastricht, this time with the exclusion of the United Kingdom. However, in our view the social policy
dimension of the Treaty on European Union cannot be regarded as the
realization of the Delorist project.
If one reconnects this reconstruction of the development of the EC
social policy with the earlier theoretical discussion, the following conclusions can be drawn. First, if one focuses on the intergovernmental
conference of 1985 and the Single Act alone, an intergovernmentalist
explanation seems plausible. The end result in the area of social policy
was very close to the `lowest common denominator' among the member
states. The role of the Commission was restricted from the beginning;
its suggestions failed owing to the resistance of some member states. In
contrast to the regional policies, the Commission had to take on a
lawyer-like function for the actors that could not participate at the
intergovernmental conference and that had no possibility of blocking it.
If one takes a wider view of the entire process up to the Maastricht
Treaty, however, it is clear that analysing this policy area through the
reductionist logic of intergovernmentalism and its variants is inadequate. From the beginning, the Commission pursued a policy of
systematic inclusion and appreciation of interested actors. It successfully
promoted a dynamic conceptualized by the neofunctionalist theory as
spillover effect. The anchoring of an expanded role for the `social
partners' in the Union treaty brought a qualitatively new dimension to
the Community decision-making processes. This expansion makes it
possible to speak of a political multi-level system.
In this regard a comparison with the more successfull development of
regional policy (as reconstructed in chapter 5) points up some commonalities between the two policy areas. However, there are also major
differences that must be emphasized. The lack of any possibility for
non-governmental actors to block further integration has already been
mentioned. In addition, the `social partners' constitute a completely
different category from that of the `cohesion countries'. Whereas the
Social policy
183
latter were in principle more united in the demand for an extension of
Community regional policy, with few exceptions this was not the case
for the `social partners'. In particular, the European Trade Union
Confederation can hardly be characterized as a homogeneous actor. A
further difference is the comparatively higher level of development of
regional policy prior to the integration thrust of the 1980s; here the
necessary work of rebuilding the system should not be underestimated.
A critical difference is also re¯ected in the different degree to which EC
policy had repercussions in the nation-states. Cohesion payments may
indeed be ®nancially painful for net payers, but they do little to impair
the formation of a nation-state's regulatory options and accordingly
have few implications for sovereignty.
To summarize: in contrast to regional policy, in the social policy area
there were no actors capable of blocking integration to be `bought off'
and in addition no new, uncontested, instruments for doing it. The
establishment of common social standards (harmonization) as the sole
measure against social regression touches in a profound way the core of
the structure of `historic compromise' of the involved states and societies.
III
Conclusions beyond the Single European
Act of 1986
The signing of the Single European Act did not, however, make the
internal market a fait accompli. Chapter 7 by Michael Nollert, in
collaboration with Nicola Fielder, shows that this was also the view of
the European Roundtable of Industrialists and that they continued to
lobby for the goals set by the Act to be met. In studying the evolution of
the Roundtable from the 1980s to the 1990s its extraordinary position
becomes evident, especially when compared with the halfhearted EC
policy of the main European umbrella business organizations. The
Roundtables have been active ever since the early 1980s and even gained
in membership as well as interlinked economic power. But, having
successfully helped to push for the new European economic order, they
had no comparable in¯uence on other issues of the ongoing European
integration.
Looking again beyond the Single Act, chapter 8 by Michael Nollert
analyses the further development of European technology corporatism.
He investigates in detail the European biotechnology policy ± shaping an
industrial branch predicted to be among the most dynamic of the
twenty-®rst century. This chapter points to an enormous surge in funds
provided by the Commission and to the established dialogue between
the interest organizations and the Commission, which evidence the
working of technology corporatism outside the information and communication sector where it was ®rst established at the beginning of the
1980s. Yet, the limits of European technology corporatism already
mentioned in chapter 4 by Simon Parker are also evident in Michael
Nollert's chapter on biotechnology policy. The current challenges lie in
transregional alliances of the leading enterprises and in the massive
public reservations about EU biotechnology policy.
Chapter 9 by Patrick Ziltener looks at the Single European Act as a
milestone that started to change the political economy of Europe, from
the internal market project of the 1980s to the monetary union project
of the 1990s. Furthermore the actors and alliances that have been
addressed in the various chapters of this volume are brie¯y reviewed and
185
186
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
reassessed. The conclusion of chapter 9 is important for a correct
interpretation of our novel theoretical explanation of the events of the
integration thrust. We do not suggest that the obvious central role of the
Commission and the Roundtables in providing the decisive impulse for
the Single Act is a model that can be generalized to other events of the
now long history of European integration.
The ®nal chapter, by Volker Bornschier, addresses the outcome of the
processes that have been the topic of this volume: the puzzling nature of
the governance structures embodied in the institutions of the European
Union. Rather than looking at the EU as an un®nished federal state, it is
suggested that the EU should be seen as representing a renewed
compromise between old European processes ± nationalism and liberalism ± in an innovative multi-level composition of state power. What is
the position of this European State of Nations vis-aÁ-vis its competitors
in the triad ± the United States of America and Japan? With political
union, the European state, which was the model for the world, is
departing from the national framework it originally helped to create.
Might it become a model for the world for reconciling the different
manifestations of nationalism and liberalism in a multi-level system of
governance?
7
Lobbying for a Europe of big business: the
European Roundtable of Industrialists
Michael Nollert in collaboration with Nicola Fielder
`We value the fact that the ERT not only engages in lobbying, narrowly
de®ned, but also makes general proposals and elaborates general
projects. We have access on a higher level than all the associations,
unions, etc.; we are not lost among the many partners in dialogue, we
speak directly with Commission presidents, with the heads of government or at a minimum directly with the economic ministers.'
Helmut Maucher, President of the Board of Directors of Nestle and
chairman of the European Roundtable of Industrialists since 1996,
interview, 11 July 1995
Introduction
The signing of the Single European Act did not make the internal
market a fait accompli, a view shared by European Roundtable members,
whose actions became more pronounced. A watchdog group, the Internal Market Support Committee, was formed in December 1986; its
members met regularly with unions, heads of state and government, top
government of®cials and key commissions of the European Community
and emphasized the urgency of ful®lling the goals set by the Single
European Act.1 Nowadays, the European Roundtable of Industrialists
(ERT) is still considered one of the most in¯uential interest organizations in Brussels. The evidence for this consists not only of the selfdescription by the president of the Nestle administrative council and
interviews with representatives of European umbrella organizations but
also in the very origins of the Single European Act (see chapter 3).
In this chapter, we want to sketch the organization and development
as well as the ®nancial and management interconnections of the Roundtable. First, the history and the activities of the Roundtable up to the
passage of the Single European Act are outlined. Then we show that the
success of the Roundtable is based not only on the goodwill of the
1
All these ®ndings lend further support to the theory presented in chapter 3 of this
volume regarding the acceleration of the European integration process and the origins of
the Common Market.
187
188
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
Commissioner responsible for the internal market and industrial affairs,
but also on the inability of the public to in¯uence these matters and on
the low organizational capacity of European employers' associations. An
overview of the development of the Roundtable in the ®rst decade after
the Single European Act follows, showing that today the Roundtable's
goal of designing the internal market is a high priority. The ®nal section
offers network analyses of the ®nancial and management interconnections of the Roundtable.2 Here it appears that in the course of
the 1980s the Roundtable began to transform itself into a transnational
business network, one whose core is only slightly fragmented and is
dominated by the German, Belgian and French member-businesses.
The origin of the ERT and its in¯uence on the
Commission
The European Roundtable of Industrialists was the result of a collaboration between Etienne Davignon, at the time Commissioner of the
European Communities for the Internal Market and Industrial Affairs,
and Pehr Gyllenhammar, the chief executive of®cer (CEO) of Volvo.
Various CEOs were invited to join, and in April 1983 the ®rst meeting
took place in Paris. Since that ®rst meeting, the European Roundtable
has convened regularly. Regular meetings also take place between the
European Roundtable and the Commission of the European Communities. The Roundtable's secretariat is now based in Brussels and has
issued several publications on a variety of pan-European subjects.3
The history of the European Roundtable of Industrialists has been
thoroughly researched by Maria Green Cowles (1995), who begins her
study of the European Roundtable in 1982, when the Economist issued
its obituary for the European Community in response to the Eurosclerosis of the 1970s and the European Council's failure to take decisive
action.4 In the same year, Gyllenhammar started calling for European
business to take positive action in formulating industrial strategies for
the future and to cooperate on a European level to promote these
strategies. Gyllenhammar was in¯uenced and supported by Commissioner Etienne Davignon. Their discussions led to the decision to create
a cross-sectoral group of leading CEOs that would express its views on
the European economic situation and the European Communities'
industrial policy.
2
3
4
For assistance with the data collection and analysis, we thank Carmen Baumeler.
ERT publications: `Missing Links: Upgrading Europe's Transborder Ground Transport
Infrastructure' (1984); `Changing Scales' (1985); `Making Europe Work' (1986); etc.
`Alas, Poor Europe', The Economist 20 March 1982, pp. 11±12.
Lobbying for a Europe of big business
189
According to Green Cowles, the ®rst list of potential members of such
a group was drawn up in 1982 by Commission and Volvo staff. The
planning group included Fernand Braun, Director-General for Internal
Market and Industrial Affairs, Bo Ekman and Michael Hinks-Edwards,
corporate planners with Volvo, and Pierre Defraigne, chef de cabinet to
Commissioner Davignon. Seventeen of Europe's top businessmen5 were
recruited to the group and a preliminary meeting of top associates came
up with six key areas for the agenda of the European Roundtable: the
internal market, infrastructure, technology, jobs, environment and
®nance.
It should be noted here that many members of the Roundtable
already knew each other prior to its formation. For example, Giovanni
Agnelli (Fiat) ± the brother of a co-founder of the Roundtable, Umberto
Agnelli ± was friends with the owner of Volvo, Peter Wallenberg. Pehr
Gyllenhammar (Volvo) and Bernard Hanon (Renault) both belonged to
the association of automobile manufacturers. The board of the Geneva
International Management Institute is an important committee, and
includes both Gyllenhammar and Stephan Schmidheiny (former
Roundtable member). Gyllenhammar met Giovanni Agnelli and
Kenneth Durham (Unilever) as advisers to the Chase Manhattan Bank.
Finally, Gyllenhammar and Davignon were allied with the consulting
®rm of former US Secretary of State Henry Kissinger. One of the
important clients of Kissinger Associates was Umberto Agnelli. Some
members also met each other in the European Enterprise Group (Green
Cowles 1997), which in the early 1980s played the role of a think-tank
for the Union of Industrial and Employers' Confederations of Europe
(UNICE).
Another venue of Roundtable members is the so-called `Bilderberg
Club', which retains its importance even today. The group was initiated
by the British businessman Joseph H. Retinger, who was one of the
founding members of the European Movement. In 1952 he proposed to
his friend Prince Bernhard of the Netherlands, who at that time sat on
the boards of Royal Dutch±Shell and the Belgian holding company
SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale, that he summon a secret conference for the elites of
5
Umberto Agnelli, Fiat, Italy; Sir Peter Baxendell, Shell, United Kingdom; Carlo de
Benedetti, Olivetti, Italy; Wisse Dekker, Philips, the Netherlands; Kenneth Durham,
Unilever, United Kingdom; Roger Faroux, Saint-Gobain, France; Pehr Gyllenhammar,
Volvo, Sweden; Bernard Hanon, Renault, France; John Harvey-Jones, Imperial
Chemical Industries, United Kingdom; Olivier Lecerf, Lafarge CoppeÂe, France;
Helmut Maucher, NestleÂ, Switzerland; Hans Merkle, Bosch, Germany; Curt Nicolin,
Asea, Sweden; Louis von Planta, Ciba-Geigy, Switzerland; Antoine Riboud, BSN,
France; Wolfgang Seelig, Siemens, Germany; Dieter Spethmann, Thyssen AG,
Germany.
190
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
the NATO member states. In the USA, this proposal was principally
supported by the Rockefeller family, which controlled Chase Manhattan
Bank and Standard Oil. The ®rst meeting took place in 1954 at the
Bilderberg Hotel in Oosterbeek. Usually approximately 115 people
would take part in the annual discussions, of whom about 80 were from
Europe. At the moment, representatives on the Steering Committee
include Roundtable members and former Commissioners Etienne
Davignon and Peter D. Sutherland, former Roundtable members Percy
Barnevik and David De Pury (both Asea Brown Boveri), and Hilmar
Kopper (Deutsche Bank), who links several Roundtable ®rms (see table
7.2 below). Giovanni Agnelli sits on the advisory committee. At the
conference in 1996 in Toronto, participants included the Italian Commissioner Mario Monti, Giovanni Agnelli, Barnevik, Bertrand Collomb
(Roundtable member, Lafarge CoppeÂe) and Morris Tabaksblat (Roundtable member, Unilever).
Informal contacts were also made through the Trilateral Commission,
in which Giovanni Agnelli, Etienne Davignon and Poul Svanholm
participated in the early 1980s. The Trilateral Commission was convened for the ®rst time in 1973 by members of the Bilderberg Club; it
was designed to provide an opportunity for a selection of prominent
politicians, business leaders and academics from Europe, North
America and Japan to think about and discuss coordinated action on
issues of world historical importance (Gill 1991). In contrast to the
discussions of the Bilderberg Club, the results of the Trilateral Commission's proceedings were published.
In April 1983 the ®rst Roundtable meeting was held. This was the
`®rst time that European CEOs organised themselves to address
European policy matters publicly' (Green Cowles 1995: 505). At a press
conference following the meeting, Gyllenhammar spoke of the meeting
as a unique moment in European history, and indicated that there was a
common feeling among the industrialists that something had to be done
in Europe.
Shortly afterwards, at the second meeting of the European Roundtable, a memorandum to Commissioner Davignon was completed. It
was entitled `Foundations for the Future of European Industry' and
spoke ®rst and foremost of the need to promote a uni®ed European
market.6
The ideas and strategies of the European Roundtable were not only
presented to the Commission, however. They were expressed in articles
and press conferences by the newly formed European Roundtable
6
ERT, `Foundations for the Future of European Industry. Memorandum to Commissioner Davignon', 10 June 1983.
Lobbying for a Europe of big business
191
secretariat in Paris. Major European newspapers began to write about
the European Roundtable and its plans and progress.
In January 1984 the ®rst major European Roundtable project was
launched: the European Venture Capital Association, which was intended to encourage transnational investments in Europe. The second
European Roundtable project was announced by Gyllenhammar in
December 1984: `Missing Links: Upgrading Europe's Transborder
Ground Transport Infrastructure.' These projects were well received
and the `Missing Links' project provided the foundation for future
infrastructure work of not only the European Roundtable but also the
European Community.
At the end of 1984, Karl-Heinz Narjes, the new Commissioner for the
Internal Market and Industrial Affairs, presented his package of proposals for completing a European common market. The package has since
been described by insiders, business leaders and European Community
experts as unwieldy, uncoordinated and lacking a precise time-frame
(see chapter 3). Business leaders decided that they needed to develop
their own programme.
On 11 January, 1985, Wisse Dekker, the CEO of Philips and one of
the ®rst supporters of the European Roundtable, put forward his plan,
`Europe 1990',7 to an audience of 500 people in Brussels, including
Lord Cock®eld, who later became the author of the 1985 White Paper8
(see also Dekker 1996: 251±5). The paper contained a simple plan for a
uni®ed market with an exact timetable and was also sent to all the heads
of state and government of the European Community.
European Roundtable contacts with the new Delors Commission and
with government ®gures continued and strengthened in 1985. Jacques
Delors called for a Europe without borders in his inauguration speech
before the European Parliament only three days after the Dekker
programme was presented. The creation of the Common Market was
endorsed by the Council at its meeting in March 1985. At the same
time, veiled threats by Wisse Dekker and other CEOs that European
multinationals would take their companies overseas if the European
leaders did not follow through with their plans for a united Europe
appeared on the front page of the Financial Times.
In the following three months Cock®eld and his associates produced
the White Paper, a coherent programme with a de®nite time-frame. The
Council decisions on the Single European Act were taken in Milan
in June 1985 and in Luxembourg in December of the same year.
7
8
`Europe 1990. An Agenda for Action', Philips, 1984.
According to a statement made by Lord Cock®eld in an interview with Nicola Fielder in
March 1993.
192
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
According to Green Cowles, the European Roundtable members did
not seek to in¯uence the intergovernmental conference negotiations, as
these pertained mainly to powers and procedures of the European
Parliament, which were of little interest to the industrialists. However,
Dekker contacted over thirty CEOs to send a strong joint message to the
European Council, which was to meet in Luxembourg for a ®nal vote on
the Single European Act. The message telexed to the Council members
in the various languages of the European Community was straightforward: it told them to decide one way or another, but to decide. Industry
would then make its own determinations as to the future of its investment and growth strategies in Europe or elsewhere. Although Green
Cowles concedes that there is no evidence to suggest that these telexes
actually in¯uenced the ®nal vote on the Single European Act, they
without doubt represent the ®rst time that leaders of European transnational businesses united to speak out determinedly on a treaty
decision.
Organizational characteristics and bases of success
Undoubtedly, the founding of the European Roundtable is to a great
extent a re¯ection of global economic changes and the personal commitment of Etienne Davignon and some prominent big businessmen who
complained about the halfhearted Europe policy of the established
European umbrella organizations. This was also the opinion of the
former secretary-general of the Roundtable, Keith Richardson:9
`UNICE (the Union of Industrial and Employers' Confederations of
Europe) was weak and above all else incapable of formulating a Europe
policy' (Niggli 1989: 165). Nevertheless, the Roundtable's high degree
of in¯uence on policy formation in Brussels cannot be explained by
these factors. The extraordinary position of the Roundtable becomes
explicable only if one takes into consideration the clublike organization
of the Roundtable, the democracy de®cit in the European Union and
the organizational problems of the employers.
The Roundtable: a Club lobbying for the interests of big business
Political and economic interests can be articulated to the legislative and
executive powers directly or through the framework of associations. In
the nineteenth century, businesses attempted to in¯uence legislation
9
As of March 1998, Wim Philippa is the new secretary-general. He has worked for
Heineken and managed the European Union Relations of®ce for Ciba-Geigy in Brussels
for four years.
Lobbying for a Europe of big business
193
principally by means of informal contacts with those who were politically
responsible. Thus, for example, representatives of interests sought
contact with the then US President (1869±77) Ulysses S. Grant, who
made himself available in the lobby of the Willard Hotel on Pennsylvania
Avenue; this is how the concept of lobbying derived its name. Lobbying
was also a popular method of big enterprises in Europe. Thus, Swiss
economic policy in the nineteenth century was decisively shaped by
Alfred Escher. As a banker and railroad industrialist, he had at his
disposal extraordinary contacts within the Federal Council and, for a
long time, had no parliamentary opposition representing the workers or
competitors to fear. His opponents at the time therefore characterized
this ingenious style of government as the `Escher System' (Grossmann
and Decurtins 1993: 108).
With the strengthening of the trade union movement, employers were
forced to organize themselves collectively. The social clubs of the elite
were fertile ground for the organization of such interests. Within these
walls, leading business personalities were shielded from the public view
and could discuss business and common political concerns.
However, the selective access criteria of the clubs resulted in political
lobbying that covered only a limited spectrum of business interests. The
political ef®cacy of the clubs was weakened above all by the expansion of
the right to vote; indeed, decisions by the government that were friendly
to business interests could be unilaterally overturned at the ballot box.
In view of the vehement criticism of the opaque and informal exertion of
in¯uence by the clubs, businessmen were now under pressure to join
together in associations and to make the effort to legitimize the concerns
of employers in the eyes of the populace.
Nevertheless, such clubs have not disappeared. As a rule, they serve
their members nowadays as a means for making and maintaining
personal or business contacts. Such clubs still play a major role in Great
Britain (Wendling 1991) and Japan. Comparative studies point out that
British managers, in contrast to their German colleagues, still prefer to
meet in prominent clubs (e.g. Marylebone Cricket Club, Brook's,
White's, Pratt's, Boodle's, City of London, Carlton) rather than at
board meetings (Useem 1984). The Japanese shacho-kai are similar to
clubs. Here, informal monthly meetings of all the presidents of business
groups (keiretsu) take place. According to Gerlach (1992: 107), informal
meetings create a group identity and serve the formulation of political
positions. Important service clubs that are connected transnationally,
such as the Kiwanis, Lions Club and Rotary Club, as well as the
Bilderberg Club and the Trilateral Commission (see above), offer big
businessmen the opportunity for the informal exchange of information.
194
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
The European Roundtable combines elements of a club (Buchanan
1965; Useem 1984) and a conventional association. In fact, in comparison with business associations such as UNICE, it is comparatively
exclusive and therefore cannot claim to be representative to any great
extent. Moreover, the size of the membership is small, which results in
members knowing each other personally and being able to formulate
and sustain common political positions. It should be noted that the
Roundtable, in comparison with the traditional British clubs, does not
restrict itself to lobbying at the highest levels of government, but also has
at its disposal an association-like infrastructure and disseminates its
views to the public through its reports.
The structural bases of success
The strong political in¯uence of the Roundtable on the Commission
can be attributed, on the one hand, to the democracy de®cit in the EU,
which allows club-like and resource-rich organizations more in¯uence
than the European umbrella organizations (see Nollert 1996, 1997).
Indeed, the Roundtable, like the nineteenth-century clubs, can assume
that relying exclusively on lobbying will pay off as long as there is no
danger that the measures thus obtained will be overturned later by a
parliamentary veto. In the 1980s, the European Parliament still did not
have veto power or the right to initiate legislation and was in a position
only to reject unpopular proposals for the Commission. Club-like
organizations are still in a privileged position when it comes to
originating political measures, especially since the established Euroassociations are still characterized by ponderous, consensus-oriented
decision-making mechanisms.
On the other hand, the success of the European Roundtable is based
on the de®cient organizational capacity of business at the European
level. Olson (1968), Offe (1969) and Offe and Wiesenthal (1980) agree
that employers, in comparison with employees, enjoy a structural
advantage. Olson presumes that a greater heterogeneity of interests in
the business community does not have an adverse effect on its organizational capacity, in that along with a broader heterogeneity the possibility
increases that a single business will carry the bulk of the organizational
costs. Streeck (1991) also suspects that there is a greater heterogeneity
of interests among businesses, especially as he believes it is more dif®cult
to unify product market interests than it is to unify labour market
interests.
Traxler and Schmitter (1994) distinguish three dimensions of the
organizational capacity of Euro-associations: (a) the generalizability of
Lobbying for a Europe of big business
195
their claim to representation; (b) their capacity for control; and (c) their
associational capacity. The two authors assume that, at the national and
European levels, employers have less of a claim to representation and
less capacity for control than employees, while at the same time
employers enjoy a greater associational capacity. The organizational
problem of the employers is further accentuated at the European level
by the gap between export-oriented businesses, which are interested in a
deregulation of the European product market, and internal marketoriented businesses supported by individual nation-states. That the
employers are more capable as associations is demonstrated at the
national level by the greater extent to which employers are organized.
Conversely, employee associations, thanks to being fewer in number,
can generalize their claim to representation and require less effort to
commit their members to an agreement. The comparatively weak position of the European umbrella organization of businesses (the Union of
Industrial and Employers' Confederations of Europe) supports the
positions of both Olson and Streeck as well as Traxler and Schmitter.
The large number of European business associations (see Nollert 1996,
1997) speaks of a greater heterogeneity of interests as well as a lower
generalizability of their claims to representation. Further, the existence
of the Roundtable supports Olson's assumption that a greater chance
exists within a heterogeneous mass of businesses that individual
businesses will take on the expenses of the collective representation of
interests. Finally, the existence of the European Roundtable shows that
large ®rms, by virtue of their resources, are not only capable but also
ready to take control away from the national and European umbrella
organizations.
Limited representativeness and internal disputes
However, it must be noted that the Roundtable did not offer a representative image of big business in the European Community. Thus, within
the Roundtable, transnational businesses from small countries that are
highly dependent on foreign trade were and still are overrepresented.
Furthermore, four businesses from countries that were not even
members of the European Community ± Asea Brown Boveri and Volvo
(both based in Sweden) and Nestle and Ciba-Geigy (both based in
Switzerland) ± have belonged to the Roundtable since its inception. In
comparison, the large industries of the core countries (France, the
United Kingdom and Germany) are weakly represented. This might not
have been necessary because pluralistic models of the mediation of
political-economic interests had dominated in the three countries
196
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
(Nollert 1992). In other words, their businesses gained privileged access
to government in contrast to those that were joined together with labour
unions in a corporatist circle.
The limited representativeness of the Roundtable is also substantiated
through the network analyses in the anthology by Stokman et al. (1985).
Their ®ndings indicate that only Thyssen occupies a central position in
the German network. However, Siemens, in contrast to Bosch, is
extremely closely linked with Thyssen. It is also noteworthy that the
German Deutsche Bank is involved with every Roundtable business. Of
the three Dutch members (Royal Dutch±Shell,10 Philips and Unilever),
only Philips occupies a central position in their national network.
However, both Nestle and Ciba-Geigy belong to the core of the Swiss
network. French industry too is only partially represented. In fact,
Saint-Gobain and Danone (formerly BSN) are in the core, whereas
Renault and Lafarge CoppeÂe are not. Upon closer examination, it
appears that the French businesses represented in the Roundtable are
linked with holding company Compagnie de Suez (Lyonnaise des Eaux,
Saint Gobain, and Total). The second-largest holding company,
Paribas, is linked only ®nancially with Danone. Belgian industry is also
only partially represented. The businesses that sat at the Roundtable are
primarily those linked with the SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale (So®na, Petro®na and
Solvay). The partner businesses of the Groupe Bruxelloise Lambert, the
second-biggest holding company, are missing, however. Since the
British network is only weakly centralized, founding members Imperial
Chemical Industries and Royal Dutch±Shell cannot be regarded as its
representatives. A parent holding company in the United Kingdom,
namely the Prudential Corporation, is also overrepresented. The
business network in Italy is fragmented regionally. Fiat and Olivetti, the
two Roundtable members, belong to the `Turin Group'. The statecontrolled businesses in the region of Rome are not represented, nor are
the Milanese businesses controlled by the Pesenti and Falck families, the
state-controlled businesses in the Genoa region, or the businesses of the
Ferruzi and Gardini families. We can summarize at this point that, in
France, Belgium and Italy, the businesses of the Suez Group (e.g.
SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale) and the de Benedetti holding companies are overrepresented. Here it should be noted that Carlo de Benedetti (representative of Olivetti) even holds shares in Suez, which in turn controls the
SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale. The European Roundtable primarily encompasses
businesses that are globally active but at the same time are dependent on
10
Royal Dutch±Shell has grown out of an alliance of the Royal Dutch Petroleum
Company and the British Shell Transport and Trading Company, by which the two
companies merged their interests on a 60:40 basis.
Lobbying for a Europe of big business
197
European consumers and which therefore are in favour of an expansion
of the European internal market (see chapter 1).
The unity of the Roundtable businesses with respect to the internal
market project should not blind us to the fact that there are substantial
economic disputes among Roundtable members. Thus, for example, in
the 1980s, Gyllenhammars' Volvo tried unsuccessfully to penetrate the
sphere of the businesses controlled by Peter Wallenberg (including
among others Asea, Ericsson and Electrolux) through the involvement
of Atlas Copco and Stora Kopperberg. Conversely, Wallenberg for his
part is presently trying to incorporate Volvo into his empire (Weltwoche
1997).
The aggressive business policy of the Olivetti representative was a
major source of disputes. After a one-year guest appearance in the
management of Fiat, which was rewarded with a large number of shares
in Fiat, Carlo de Benedetti bought and redeveloped Olivetti's Turin
typewriter factory in 1986 and later Triumph-Adler's German of®ce
equipment factory. Parallel to this manoeuvre he also tried to put
together a European conglomerate of banks, insurance companies and
food businesses, which did not sit well with other Roundtable members.
De Benedetti succeeded in bringing in Europe's second-largest (after
Bosch) auto parts supplier only after he indicated that he was prepared
to separate out the domain of weapons and leave it under French
control.
Even more vehement was the resistance to majority participation by
de Benedetti in SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale. The Belgians asked the Parisian bank
Indosuez for help. According to Sand (1992), the Wallonian Davignon,
who became the head of the SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale after leaving the Commission, used his informal connections to Suez to ensure that Suez took
over a majority share in SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale and defeated de Benedetti's
1988 takeover attempt. De Benedetti was supported by the Flemish
Andre Leysen, the head of Gevaert, who sat on the boards of the
Roundtable members Bayer, VEBA and Philips.
On 19 March 1997, it was made public that the German steel ®rm
and Roundtable member Krupp (Gerhard Cromme) intended to take
over a majority of shares in Roundtable member Thyssen. Dieter Vogel,
the head of Thyssen, considered this a `hostile takeover attempt' and
accused Krupp of `Wild West manners' (Tages-Anzeiger, 19 March
1997: 33).
Discord was also expressed on the occasion of the planned merger of
Suez and Lyonnaise des Eaux, the business of then Roundtable president JeÂroÃme Monod. Roundtable member Louis Beffa, president of
Saint Gobain, complained in April 1997 that the merger took too little
198
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
account of his participation in Suez and demanded a bonus. The merger
was also awkward for Beffa because at the same time Saint Gobain was
also involved with the two big French rivals Lyonnaise des Eaux and
GeÂneÂrale des Eaux (CGE).
The ERT after the SEA: Constant In¯uence, New Goals
The activities of the European Roundtable of Industrialists during the
time leading up to the signing of the Single European Act were very
intense and the interest of its members in the matter at hand was
certainly extremely high. With the passage of the Single European Act,
the Roundtable had undoubtedly achieved its main goal. At that point it
therefore would have been possible for the members to retreat into their
businesses again and to engage future issues from within the framework
of the European umbrella organizations. Indeed, many of its most
prominent members have already departed. Among those who must be
mentioned in this regard are Pehr Gyllenhammar (Volvo), Umberto
Agnelli (Fiat), Wisse Dekker (Philips), Karl-Heinz Kaske (Siemens) and
Hans Merkle (Bosch). Of the founders, only Antoine Riboud (Danone,
formerly BSN), Helmut Maucher (NestleÂ) and Carlo de Benedetti
(Olivetti) remained.
But the European Roundtable is still an active lobbyist, with interests
in various areas such as infrastructure and unemployment. In 1988 the
secretariat was moved from Paris to Brussels. In the same year, Wisse
Dekker took over the leadership from Gyllenhammar. Between 1992
and 1996, JeÂroÃme Monod, the head of Lyonnaise des Eaux, held the
of®ce of chairman of the European Roundtable. In January 1996
Helmut Maucher of Nestle became the new chairman. In 1997 he
formalized relations between the Roundtable and the Union of Industrial and Employers' Confederations of Europe. The Roundtable meets
regularly and holds regular discussions with the European Commission.
Unlike associations such as UNICE, which must react to all regulations
issued by the Commission affecting its members, the European Roundtable selects areas that it views as important, organizes task forces to
research these areas, and then expresses its views based on the results of
this research.
The Roundtable's Competitiveness Advisory Group, initiated by the
`Competitiveness' working group in its 1994 report `European Competitiveness: The Way to Growth' (see below), has become a new and
especially important body through which the Roundtable exercises
in¯uence. Thus, the advisory committee newly created by the Commission works closely with the policy advisory group and is responsible for
Lobbying for a Europe of big business
199
reporting every six months to the Commission president (presently Sir
Iain Vallance, chairman of Roundtable member British Telecom) on the
competitiveness of European industry.
The members of the European Roundtable are also heard by their
national governments and their views are highly respected. The Roundtable's continuously high level of political in¯uence is illustrated by the
fact that the former supporter of the European Roundtable, Etienne
Davignon, as chairperson of the SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale, belongs to the
Roundtable himself. Also indirectly linked to the Roundtable is the
former General Director Fernand Braun, who presently advises the
VEBA Group (Germany). As one member of the European Roundtable
(Helmut Maucher) told us in an interview in November 1995, the
members of the European Roundtable have access to and are heard by
the president of the European Commission and by the heads of state or
government. Unlike those of unions and associations, their contacts are
made directly with the highest levels of government. It is no surprise
therefore, that Roundtable member Heinrich von Pierer (Siemens)
belonged to Helmut Kohl's closest circle of advisers (WirtschaftsWoche
1996). The view that the Roundtable in no way lost in¯uence after the
passage of the Single European Act is substantiated through our interviews with Wisse Dekker, Etienne Davignon, Herwig Kressler (chief
expert of the Advisory Group for Social Relations and Industrial
Policy), Fernand Braun (adviser to the VEBA Group) and Hannes
Glatz (the head of the Daimler-Benz of®ce in Brussels).
The membership structure of the Roundtable has certainly changed.
Additions include businesses from the South European member countries including Turkey (Pro®lo). In 1995, the European Roundtable
already included forty-six businesses from sixteen European countries
(see table 7.1 below) that together account for an annual turnover of
550 billion ECU and employ more than 3 million people worldwide.
The unequal representation of countries and industry branches has also
remained. Electronics, energy, food and machinery (industry) are well
represented; metals, banks, insurance companies, telecommunications
and transportation are not.
In 1991, the European Roundtable published the report `Reshaping
Europe', (ERT 1991b), which de®ned its goals for the 1990s. It
demanded a harmonization of the legal framework, a Community
industrial policy, the creation of a monetary union, expansion to the
east, and the promotion of world trade. Along with this, educational and
infrastructural measures were demanded, which were supported by two
brochures. In the brochure `Rebuilding Con®dence: An Action Plan for
Europe' (ERT 1992) demands were made for modernization and
200
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
increased competitiveness in the European Community and investments in the education, infrastructure, environment and technology
sectors. The `Missing Networks' catalogue (ERT 1991a) was a follow
up to the `Missing Links' brochure published in 1984. In `Missing
Links', the demand had been made to close three gaps in the
European transportation system (a tunnel under the English Channel,
a bridge connection between Denmark and Sweden, and an extension
of Route Nationale 134 with a tunnel under Col du Somport); thus,
`Missing Networks' demanded an extension of the European highway
network. In the years that followed, the Commission has also taken
this demand into account. The responsible Commissioner, Karel van
Miert, published four documents in 1993 in which he proposed to
build 15,000 kilometres of new highways within the framework of the
Trans European Network (TEN).
In November 1994, the White Paper of the Commission Growth,
Competitiveness, Employment (CEU 1993) was subject to commentary in
an ERT paper entitled `European Competitiveness: The Way to Growth
and Jobs'. The following demands are raised in it:
(1) with an eye toward lowering costs, energy, transportation and
telecommunications markets should be liberalized;
(2) the cost of capital and business taxes should be drastically reduced;
(3) the Commission should form a Competitiveness Advisory Group
and thereby institutionalize the dialogue between governments and
industry;
(4) Community educational and technology policies should be developed. Moreover, the transfer of knowledge should be promoted
between universities and businesses.
Prominent recent reports are `Education for Europeans' (ERT 1995),
calling for a reform of Europe's education system, `Investing in Knowledge' (ERT 1997) and `Job Creation and Competitiveness through
Innovation' (ERT 1998).
At present, reports are generated by twelve working groups on policy
issues (accounting standards, competitiveness, corporate governance,
education and development, employment and social policy, environment, European company statute, export controls, EU enlargement,
intergovernmental conference, informational society, and North±South
relations), each of which is chaired by a Roundtable member.
Since March 1994, the work of the European Roundtable has been
additionally supported through the European Centre for Infrastructure
Studies (ECIS) in Rotterdam. A Centre for Businesses, Regional Bodies
and Foundations will be ®nanced. It is supposed to promote the
exchange of scienti®c reports on infrastructure issues, the carrying out
Lobbying for a Europe of big business
201
of smaller studies and the development of conferences and research
networks.
The exchange of opinion among Roundtable members is no longer
restricted to its sessions in Brussels and meetings in the context of the
Trilateral Commission and the Bilderberg Club, which are largely
concealed from public view. Many of the Roundtable members meet
annually at the beginning of the year in Davos (Switzerland) to discuss
world economic trends and problems together at the World Economic
Forum with top politicians and representatives of international organizations. Members of the Roundtable are also present on the Executive
Committee of the World Business Council for Sustainable Development, which was formed in January 1995 and includes 120 enterprises
from 34 countries. These are Stephan Schmidheiny (former Roundtable
member and founder of the council), Percy Barnevik (Asea Brown
Boveri), Bertrand Collomb (Lafarge CoppeÂe) and Helmut Maucher
(NestleÂ). Numerous Roundtable members also represent enterprises
belonging to the World Business Council: Kymmene (Finland); Lafarge
CoppeÂe (France); Fiat and Pirelli (Italy); Philips and Unilever (Netherlands); Norsk Hydro (Norway); Volvo (Sweden); Asea Brown Boveri,
Hoffmann-La Roche and Nestle (Switzerland); Imperial Chemical
Industries and Royal Dutch±Shell (Netherlands, United Kingdom).
Fertile ground for a transnational business network
Finally, we turn to the following question: to what extent are the
informal contacts between the members of the European Roundtable
re¯ected in the construction of a transnational European business
network? The intermittently published `Reports on the Competition
Policy of the Commission' create the impression that, with the passage
of the Single European Act, transnational mergers and acquisitions in
the European Community increased tremendously (see Windolf 1993).
In view of the growing competitiveness within the European internal
market, the `national champions' saw their power to acquire other
businesses or to join with other ®rms increase. In fact, a pan-European
cooperation between large ®rms does not presuppose an inevitable
merger. It is suf®cient to build strategic alliances or joint ventures, or to
link together through mutual ®nancial or management connections. A
network analysis at two points in time ± 1984 and 1994 ± of the
interconnections between the Roundtable businesses through ®nancial
participation and through managers who hold management or board
responsibilities in at least two member businesses will help us answer the
question.
202
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
According to an analysis of transnational interconnections in Europe
in 1976 by Fenemma and Schijf (1985), we should expect that, above
all, Belgian and French as well as Dutch and German businesses
maintain close transnational contacts. A review of the economic and
®nancial newspapers of the European Union (WirtschaftsWoche 1991)
noted that Roundtable businesses are overrepresented in the network of
boards of directors, which at the beginning of the 1990s was still quite
weakly interconnected. Thus, among the seventeen people identi®ed as
having at least two seats, four Roundtable members and four nonmembers can be found who have two seats in Roundtable businesses.
Included among those holding three or more seats are Andre Leysen
(representative of Gevaert in the Roundtable) and Etienne Davignon
(representative of the SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale in the Roundtable). Among
those with two seats are Carlo de Benedetti (Olivetti) and Helmut
Maucher (NestleÂ). In addition, Roundtable businesses are connected
through Hilmar Kopper (Solvay, Pilkington), Henry C. Bodmer (Fiat,
Pirelli), FrancËois Laage de Meux (Olivetti, SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale) and
Niklaus Senn (VEBA, Siemens).
In order to answer the question regarding the structure of and
changes in the interconnections among Roundtable businesses, network
analyses were performed for 1984 and 1994 and compared.11 The types
of connections taken into account were ®nancial participation and
connections via top managers who hold seats in at least two member
businesses. The sources of data are the directories published by Moody's
International Manual (1985 edition) and Major Companies of Europe
(1996 edition). The only missing data are the business pro®les of
Olivetti in 1984 and of the Turkish holding company Pro®lo in 1994.
In contrast to the ®nancial participation data, the census of management interconnections was impeded in two ways. First, corporate law
varies considerably in Europe. In some countries, we ®nd a one-board
system, that is, no institutional separation between operational and
supervisory functions (for example, in the United Kingdom). However,
in Germany and the Netherlands, these two functions are performed by
two different committees (two-board system). In order to guarantee
comparability, and to simplify the coding process, in the case of the twoboard system the two committees are seen as two parts of a single super
committee. The second complication to be taken into account is that
Roundtable businesses become connected through more than just other
Roundtable members. It is possible that a manager of a non-member
business might sit on the boards of several Roundtable businesses.
11
Reviews of social network analysis methods are presented in Scott (1991) and
Wasserman and Faust (1994).
Lobbying for a Europe of big business
203
Similarly, a Roundtable representative might sit on the board of a nonmember business. In our analysis here, those links caused by a nonRoundtable member are also taken into account. We do not analyse
links among non-Roundtable businesses.
A principal ®nding of the network analyses is that the interconnections among members increased over the decade. In contrast to
1994, the founding members of the Roundtable in 1984 were sparsely
interlocked. We found not a single ®nancial interconnection and only
®fteen managerial interconnections; the latter involved at least indirect
connections involving only ®ve business (Unilever, Siemens, Thyssen,
Asea Brown Boveri, Volvo). The central business in 1984 was Unilever
(Roundtable representative: Kenneth Durham), which was directly
interconnected with Volvo (Pehr Gyllenhammar), Siemens (Wolfgang
Seelig) and Thyssen (Dieter Spethmann). This centrality was primarily
attributable to Spethmann from Thyssen, who held seats with Siemens
and Unilever. Of the remaining managers with two seats, we mention
here only Tore Browaldh, who is not a Roundtable member but who is
linked with Unilever and Volvo and thereby serves as a bridge between
German and Swedish industry.
In 1994 we can observe a comparatively greater number of ®nancial
and management interconnections. Bayer was ®nancially linked with
the Belgian ®rm Gevaert (100 per cent), while Gevaert has a 1 per cent
share in Bayer. VEBA was ®nancially linked with the British Cable &
Wireless (10.5 per cent). Davignon's SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale and So®na held
shares in Petro®na (12.7 per cent and 1.3 per cent respectively);
SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale and the Lyonnaise des Eaux were linked with Total
(3.6 per cent and 1 per cent respectively). Finally, the Fiat holding
company I®al had a 5.8 per cent ®nancial involvement with Danone
(formerly BSN).
As expected, the greatest number of ®nancial links are found in
Belgium, where the French holding company Compagnie de Suez, one
of the parent companies of the SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale, had indirect interconnections to French Roundtable ®rms. Suez was thus linked through
its 5 per cent share in Saint Gobain and its 17 per cent share in
Lyonnaise des Eaux. For its part, Saint-Gobain controlled over 6.3 per
cent of the stock and 10 per cent of the voting rights in Suez. On 11
April 1997, the boards of Suez and Lyonnaise des Eaux ®nally approved
a merger, thus deepening the interconnectivity. The apparently weak
interconnection among German businesses may be deceptive; the three
large banks Deutsche Bank, Commerzbank and Dresdner Bank were
represented in advisory bodies of Roundtable ®rms and were shareholders of Roundtable ®rms, thus forging indirect personal and ®nancial
204
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
connections between the German member ®rms. Not to be forgotten is
Peter Wallenberg's Investor AB, which controlled two Roundtable ®rms:
Asea Brown Boveri and Ericsson. The new chairperson of the board of
Investor AB is Percy Barnevik, the former head of the Asea Brown
Boveri conglomerate. According to Weltwoche (1997), the nomination of
the former head of Wallenberg's Electrolux as the head of Volvo went
too far even for Wallenberg, a founding member of the Roundtable, who
complained: `Sweden appears to occupy a rather unique position if one
considers how unilateral and monolithic we have become, and how
highly power is concentrated with us' (ibid.: 24).
Since 1994, the joint venture between former members Volvo and
Renault has been dissolved. In 1990, both ®rms had decided to work
together in divisions devoted to automobile, truck and bus production, a
deal cemented by an exchange of shares and the creation of three joint
committees. During the 1980s, a cartel also existed between Solvay and
Imperial Chemicals but in 1990 this soda ash cartel was outlawed and
®ned by the Commission. In addition, several contract joint ventures ±
such as that between Daimler-Benz and Siemens on traf®c control and
information systems ± and a number of capital joint ventures between
Roundtable businesses still exist: between Nestle and Danone (chocolate production: Cokoladovny); between Daimler-Benz and Asea Brown
Boveri (transport system: Adtranz), between Thyssen and Lyonnaise
des Eaux (water: Eurawasser), between Thyssen and VEBA (mobile
telephones: E-Plus Mobilfunk) and between Bosch and Siemens (household appliances: Bosch-Siemens HausgeraÈte).
The top board interconnections among Roundtable ®rms also increased between 1984 and 1994 from 15 to 122. However, the density
and centralization (see table 7.1), when compared with the values in
national networks, were still low. Thirty-three member businesses were
at least indirectly connected to one other member through their
management in 1994 (that is, have a `degree' score of 1). The only
businesses not connected with this group of thirty-three were the
members from Spain (CEPSA, TelefoÂnica and Iberdrola are themselves
interconnected), Portugal (Amorin), Finland (Kymmene), Denmark
(Carlsberg), Norway (Norsk Hydro, Statoil), Ireland ( Jefferson
Smur®t), Greece (Titan) as well as the British ®rms Cable & Wireless
and GKN.
In the centre of the network were the German ®rms VEBA (nine
interconnections) and Bayer (eight) and the Belgian ®rm Solvay (eight).
The German, Belgian and French ®rms were the most central. Volvo
was no longer on the list, owing to the departure of Gyllenhammar.
Unilever exhibited only an average level of centrality. What is more,
Lobbying for a Europe of big business
205
Table 7.1. The centrality of Roundtable companies in 1994
Company (branch)
VEBA (energy)
Bayer (chemistry)
Solvay (chemistry)
Danone (food)
SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale (holding)
Saint-Gobain (glass)
Daimler-Benz (holding)
Petro®na (energy)
So®na (holding)
Lyonnaise des Eaux (holding)
Philips (electronics)
Pilkington (building materials)
British Petroleum (energy)
Thyssen (machines)
Fiat (Automobile)
Gevaert (photo)
Krupp (machines)
Siemens (electronics)
Total (energy)
Unilever (food)
Nestle (food)
Asea Brown Boveri (engineering)
Bertelsmann (publishing)
Bosch (electronics)
Lafarge CoppeÂe (building mat.)
Pirelli (tyres)
Royal Dutch±Shell (energy)
B.A.T. Industries (tobacco)
British Steel (metals)
Ericsson (electronics)
Imperial Chemicals (chemistry)
Iberdrola (energy)
Olivetti (computers)
Hoffmann-La Roche (chemistry)
TelefoÂnica de EspanÄa (telecom)
Centralization
Degree
9
8
8
7
7
7
6
6
6
5
5
5
4
4
3
3
3
3
3
3
3
2
2
2
2
2
2
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
14.6%
Norm
Links
Betweenness
norm
20.45
18.18
18.18
15.91
15.91
15.91
13.64
13.64
13.64
11.36
11.36
11.36
9.09
9.09
6.82
6.82
6.82
6.82
6.82
6.82
6.82
4.55
4.55
4.55
4.55
4.55
4.55
2.27
2.27
2.27
2.27
2.27
2.27
2.27
2.27
19
20
15
10
14
10
12
13
16
9
6
8
5
12
3
3
3
13
4
5
7
8
4
2
5
4
3
2
1
4
3
2
3
2
2
8.34
4.35
18.13
5.38
5.38
7.70
7.12
0.94
12.29
0.64
5.04
3.28
7.59
7.17
6.34
0.00
0.00
0.74
1.88
4.85
9.41
3.28
0.49
1.42
4.37
3.28
1.48
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
15.6%
Solvay and So®na had unexpectedly high `betweenness' scores.12 That
is, both businesses, in comparison with Bayer and Petro®na, had
12
Unlike the measurement of `degree', `betweenness' indexes the extent to which an actor
is located between unlinked actors. Actors who are linked only with actors who are
connected to each other get a `betweenness' score of 0 (see Wasserman and Faust 1994:
188ff ).
206
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
Table 7.2. Connectors between Roundtable companies, 1994
Name
Management
Advisory body
Total
Hilmar Kopper
Yves BoeÈl (ERT)
Et. Davignon (ERT)
Andre Leysen (ERT)
Hermann Strenger
Jean Gandois
GeÂrard Mestrallet
GeÂrard Worms
Deutsche Bank
So®na, Petro®na
S. GeÂneÂrale
Gevaert
Bayer, VEBA
Bayer, D.-Benz, Pilkington, Solvay, VEBA
Danone, Petro®na, So®na, Solvay
Petro®na, S. GeÂneÂrale, So®na, Solvay
Bayer, Gevaert, Philips, VEBA
Bayer, Siemens, VEBA
Danone, Lyonn. des Eaux, S. GeÂneÂrale
Lyonn. des Eaux, Petro®na, S. GeÂneÂrale
Lyonn. des Eaux, S.GeÂneÂrale, St. Gobain
5
4
4
4
3
3
3
3
Suez
Note: Chairpersons of advisory bodies are also counted as members of management. ERT
= members of the Roundtable.
comparatively few redundant connections. The high number of links
re¯ects the fact that the ®rms in general and Siemens and Thyssen in
particular had multiple connections to the same ®rms. In contrast to
1984, in 1994 the non-members of the Roundtable were the most active
as connectors. This trend is also documented by table 7.2, which shows
that the central person was no longer a Roundtable member but the
chairperson of the management of Deutsche Bank, Hilmar Kopper. The
most central Roundtable members were the Belgians: BoeÈl, Davignon
and Leysen. From the list of the ®rms we can see that the boards of
Solvay, So®na, Petro®na, SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale, VEBA and Lyonnaise des
Eaux were the most popular venues of Roundtable members.
A familiar concept that designates the subgroups of a network is the
1±clique (see Wasserman and Faust 1994: 253ff ). This refers to groups
of actors that are all directly interconnected. In 1994, seven 1±cliques
could be identi®ed with at least three companies. Four of these involved
®ve companies: (1) Bayer, Daimler-Benz, Pilkington, Solvay, VEBA; (2)
Danone, Lyonnaise des Eaux, Petro®na, SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale, SaintGobain; (3) Danone, Petro®na, SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale, Saint-Gobain,
So®na; and (4) Danone, Petro®na, SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale, So®na, Solvay. In
addition, comparatively large 2±cliques can be identi®ed, i.e. groups of
actors linked at least indirectly by a maximum of two paths. The biggest
2±clique had ten companies; along with Bosch, Daimler-Benz, Gevaert,
Krupp, Philips, Pilkington, and Siemens, this group included the three
most central ®rms: Bayer, Solvay and VEBA.
The stability of the cliques is substantiated by the block procedure
and N-core analysis. Blocks designate components that do not disintegrate into two subcomponents after the rejection of one actor. In other
words: all block members connect to each other by at least two paths.
The block contains no communicatively privileged `bridges' (Burt
Lobbying for a Europe of big business
207
1992). The only block with more than three Roundtable members
involved the following twenty-four companies: Bayer, Bertelsmann,
Bosch, British Petroleum, Daimler-Benz, Danone, Fiat, Gevaert,
Krupp, Lafarge CoppeÂe, Lyonnaise des Eaux, Petro®na, Philips, Pilkington, Royal Dutch±Shell, SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale, Saint-Gobain, Siemens,
So®na, Solvay, Thyssen, Total, Unilever and VEBA. The central ®rms
were therefore not only directly linked but also interconnected through
numerous other paths. Thus, the network itself would not fall apart with
the exit of the representatives of So®na and Solvay, the two ®rms with
the outstanding `betweenness' scores. NestleÂ, which also distinguished
itself through a comparatively high `betweenness' score, was not contained in the block however. Indeed, the Swiss food conglomerate
formed a bridge between the network's centre (Solvay) and the peripheral businesses Asea Brown Boveri and Hoffmann-La Roche. Here it
should be noted that the link between Solvay and Nestle is to be
attributed not to Roundtable member Maucher, but rather to the
president of the board of the Credit Suisse bank, Rainer Gut.
Another measurement of the cohesion of a subnetwork is the N-core.
This is a group of actors who are directly connected with at least N
members of the group. In the present data set we identi®ed a 4±core,
which involved the following nine ®rms: Bayer, Danone, Daimler-Benz,
Lyonnaise des Eaux, Petro®na, Pilkington, SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale, Solvay
and VEBA. In other words, each of the listed nine businesses was
directly connected with at least four other businesses.
These different analyses of cohesion show that the central ®rms of the
network did not constitute separate, weakly connected subnetworks. In
other words: The centre of the network of Roundtable ®rms is only
slightly fragmented and is dominated by German, Belgian and French
businesses. The division of the presidency of the Roundtable re¯ects the
two axes that had already become visible in the research of Fennema
(1982) and Fennema and Schijf (1985). Thus, president Monod represents ®rms linked to the Suez Group (French and Wallonian-Belgian
businesses) and vice-president Leysen represents those ®rms linked to
the Deutsche Bank (German, Dutch and Flemish-Belgian businesses).
As second vice-president, Maucher plays the role of a neutral `old boy'.
Conclusion and outlook
In summary, we can say that the founding of the European Roundtable
re¯ected the halfhearted Europe policy of the main European umbrella
organization of the employers, the Union of Industrial and Employers'
Confederations of Europe. Dissatis®ed heads of export-dependent ®rms
208
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
considered it more effective to form an exclusive club and advance the
internal market project through it. However, the founding of the
European Roundtable is attributable not only to the business personalities involved (Gyllenhammar, Dekker, Maucher) and the active support
of the then Commissioner Davignon, but also to the general organizational weakness of the employers at a pan-European level. Thus, the
establishment of the European Roundtable con®rms the assumption
that large ®rms, thanks to their resources, can directly control the
representation of their own interests, without being dependent on a
European umbrella organization. This weakening of the system of
associations also becomes increasingly visible at the national level.
Indeed, thanks to weakened unions, ®rms no longer require the support
of an association. In other words, informal contacts with the government
have regained their meaning (see also WirtschaftsWoche 1996).
Even after the passage of the Single European Act, the European
Roundtable is still among the most in¯uential protagonists in Brussels.
However, in the 1990s its interest was focused more on particular issues
than on the project of European integration. The Roundtable considers
the principal challenges of the present to be lagging competitiveness, the
low job creation potential of European industry, the completion of the
Single Market project and, last but not least, the eastward expansion of
the European Union. In a message on 12 January 1997, to the ®fteen
heads of state of the member states signed by its new chairman Helmut
Maucher (NestleÂ) and Percy Barnevik (Asea Brown Boveri),13 the
Roundtable also indicated its willingness to cooperate with expansion
efforts and underscored at the same time its demand for a reform of the
decision-making structures of the Union in light of its future expansion
to twenty-®ve member states. In 1998 the Roundtable also began to
send a number of messages to European governments about the
Millennium Bug.
The Roundtable will serve as fertile ground for the development of
transnational business interconnections that will in¯uence the European
integration process well into the twenty-®rst century. Thus, by 1994
more than 70 per cent of the forty-six businesses were linked via
interlocking boards. Here we must also note that the German, Belgian,
British and French ®rms were ®nancially linked with ®nancial ®rms that
had good relationships at the national level with political representatives.
It is foreseeable that the network will condense even further. Thus, in
April 1997 a merger was initiated between Lyonnaise des Eaux and the
Compagnie de Suez, which is linked with the SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale and
13
The message, `EU Enlargement', can be read in its entirety at the following world wide
web address: http:/www.ert.be/2_activ/eu_enlargement.html.
Lobbying for a Europe of big business
209
Saint-Gobain. Moreover, Monod proposed to the head of the new
conglomerate and president of the Roundtable that Cromme (Krupp)
and Davignon (SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale) as well as a representative of NestleÂ
(Reto Domeniconi) be appointed to the board of Lyonnaise des Eaux±
Suez. Operationally, the new conglomerate is led by the former chairperson of Suez, Mestrallet, who already holds seats in Roundtable ®rms
(see table 7.2). Finally, the relations between Roundtable ®rms could
pave the way for capital joint ventures or even mergers such as that
between Krupp and Thyssen in 1998 after which Heinz Kriwet
(Thyssen) had to leave the Roundtable.
Although the Roundtable is still principally concerned with European
affairs, a number of its member enterprises (for example, in biotechnology, discussed in chapter 8) are tied into transnational alliances and
within the framework of the Transatlantic Business Dialogue support
free trade and free movement of investments between Europe and
North America. This dialogue was initiated by the two Commissioners
Martin Bangemann and Sir Leon Brittan and the American president
Bill Clinton in November 1995. In addition to representatives of the US
government and the Commission of the European Union, leading
managers from Europe and North America also take part in the annual
meetings, among them Peter Sutherland, former Commissioner and
present Roundtable representative of British Petroleum. The dialogue is
also supported by the European±American Business Council, an association to which approximately eighty European and American major
corporations and banks belong. It is surely no coincidence that Roundtable members Philips and Ericsson were among the founders of this
body, and that presently sixteen Roundtable member businesses also
belong to it.14 Likewise it is hardly surprising that the Council currently
favours a bilateral trade agreement between the European Union and
the United States of America. In light of the successful military integration of the two triad members through NATO, it would also be no big
surprise if in the end the Council ± analogous to the role of the Roundtable in the 1980s in Europe ± becomes the driving force for transnational economic integration at the beginning of the twenty-®rst
century.
14
Airbus Industrie, B.A.T. Industries, British Petroleum, British Telecom, Daimler-Benz,
Ericsson, Hoffmann-La Roche, Imperial Chemical Industries, NestleÂ, Nokia Group,
Norsk Hydro, Philips, Pirelli, Siemens, Unilever, VEBA.
8
Biotechnology in the European Union: a case
study of political entrepreneurship
Michael Nollert
`Just as ``telematics'' and its various areas of application were the focal
point of technological, scienti®c, and human activities in the 1980s,
experts believe that the biological revolution unleashed by discoveries
of biotechnology will become the greatest challenge of the 1990s.'
Etienne Davignon (1981: 189f, my translation)
Introduction
In this chapter we examine the question of whether technology corporatism ± established at the beginning of the 1980s ± also ¯ourishes
beyond the domain of information technology, where it was initiated
(see chapter 4). Moreover, we consider whether it shaped Europe's
competitive position in biotechnology, an industry widely considered to
be among the most dynamic in the twenty-®rst century.
The starting point of a European biotechnology policy was the
Commission's insight at the beginning of the 1980s that the Community
displayed a technological backwardness with respect to the USA and
Japan and that bio-industry could make a decisive contribution to
resolving the employment problem. Therefore, by the middle of the
1990s, the advancement of biotechnology was to become ± as Davignon
predicted above ± an established goal of the technology policy of the
European Union. Consequently, the Commission pushed for research
programmes and a corporatist policy formulation process that included
the participation of the interest organizations of bio-industry.
In contrast to information technology, however, the `national champions' in the chemical and pharmaceutical industries were not very
interested in European research programmes similar to Esprit (see
chapter 4). Indeed, they had already established transregional alliances
even before the ®rst programme was launched and preferred competitive
to pre-competitive research. Yet, during the 1990s their industry associations closely cooperated with the Commission because they regarded
existing regulations as too restrictive.
210
Biotechnology in the European Union
211
The ®rst sections that follow sketch out the continuous ascent of
biotechnology and genetic engineering in the agenda of the European
Union using (a) of®cial positions taken by the Commission; (b) research
programmes and regulative acts; and (c) the dialogue between the
Commission and European biotech organizations.1 This chronology of
the events broadly supports the view that the Commission acted as a
political entrepreneur (see chapter 1), while the European bio-industry
organizations have always been reactive rather than proactive. In the
®nal section, however, we suggest that two facts limit the establishment
of a biotechnology corporatism. First, the interest of the Commission in
increasing the competitiveness of European bio-industry is only partially
compatible with the global thinking of European chemical and pharmaceutical ®rms. Secondly, whereas information technologies have been
broadly adopted by the population, large segments of the population
and members of the European Parliament do not share the Commission's euphoria about genetic engineering.
Diagnoses and proposals of the Commission
Biotechnology in the broader sense includes all instruments for the
alteration of living organisms and plants by means of biological organisms, systems and processes. According to the de®nition of the
European Federation of Biotechnology (the European umbrella organization of scientists), biotechnology is `the integrated use of biochemistry,
microbiology and engineering sciences in order to achieve the technological application of the capacities of microorganisms, cultured tissue
cells and parts thereof '.2 Economically, the newest branch of biotechnology, genetic engineering, is the most promising. In 1973, Stanley
Cohen and Herbert Boyer, both Americans, succeeded for the ®rst time
in extracting genes from DNA molecules and transferring them to
bacteria. This recombinant DNA technology was the cornerstone for
the industrial use of genetically modi®ed organisms and plants.
Proceeding from the assessment that European industry exhibited
considerable backwardness in the development of key technologies
1
2
My thanks to Albert Klepsch (DG XII Science, Research and Development,
Department of Biotechnology and Society: Public Perception and Socioeconomic
Impacts, Brussels), Jens Krazek (CEAT, Bund fuÈr Umwelt und Naturschutz, Bonn),
Stefan Ryser (Hoffmann-La Roche, Senior Advisory Group Biotechnology, Basel),
Kristin Schreiber (DG III Internal Market and Industrial Affairs, Department of
Agroindustry and Biotechnology, Brussels), Christof Tannert (member of the European
Parliament, Socialist group, Berlin), Kathleen Vandendael (European Federation of
Pharmaceutical Industry Associations, Public Relations and Vaccines, Brussels) for
information.
EFB Newsletter, No. 4 (December 1981): 2.
212
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
when compared with the USA and Japan (Servan-Schreiber 1968), the
memorandum `The Industrial Policy of the Community' (CEC 1970)
and later the resolution of the Council of the European Community of
17 December 1973, regarding a common industrial policy urged the
member countries to promote their high-tech enterprises. Only two
years after Boyer's and Cohen's discovery the Commission concretized
its plans with respect to the collective advancement of biotechnology in
that it proposed a research programme, the Biomolecular Engineering
Programme, to the Council of Ministers. In that same year, the German
Commissioner responsible for science and technology, Ralf Dahrendorf,
created a `Europe Plus Thirty' study group, whose recommendations
led to the ®rst programme, `Forecasting and Assessment in Science and
Technology' (FAST, 1978±83). The ®rst provisional report of FAST's
ten-member group of experts (1982), which was summarized in the
book Eurofutures: The Challenge of Innovation (1984), contained among
other things a section on the prospects of a `bio-society' and a strategic
recommendation for the development of European bio-industry.
Proposals by the Commission to reduce the technological gap
As a result of the ®rst FAST report, the Commission emphatically and
repeatedly recommended biotechnology as a key technology and a
growth engine for the 1990s (see Davignon 1981). Thus, on 8 February
1983, Gaston Thorn, the president of the Commission, mentioned in a
speech that biotechnology should be stimulated just as information
technology had been previously. As a result, Directorate General III
(Internal Market and Industrial Affairs) and Directorate General XII
(science, technology and research) began negotiating a scienti®c sponsorship programme. The Commission also communicated to the
European Council on 3 June 1983 its report `Biotechnology: The Task
of the Community' (CEC 1983a), which included a list of the most
important defects of the European bio-industry:
(1) fragmentation of research efforts in basic biotechnology and in
some speci®c areas, namely agricultural foodstuffs, the chemical
industry and public health;
(2) a shortage of engineers and scientists with experience in modern
biotechnology;
(3) a lack of suf®cient European support for the infrastructure and
legislation for biotechnology.
After the Council of Ministers called on the member states to register
all biotechnology and genetic engineering research projects in its 1982
Recommendation 82/472, the European Council responded to the
Biotechnology in the European Union
213
Commission at the summit in Stuttgart with an appeal to create a
European network of scienti®c activity in the individual member states
and to develop a collective research programme. The appeal was further
supported by the Commission's report to the Council on 29 September
1983, `Biotechnology in the Community' (CEC 1983b), which concretized the recommended measures that had already been announced in
the Commission's earlier communication (CEC 1983a). In this document, the scienti®c importance of biotechnology is laid out, and the
competitive weakness and technological de®ciencies of European
bio-producers with respect to their American and Japanese counterparts,
as well as the danger of migration by scienti®c specialists, are noted. In
this connection, the diagnosis of the American Task Force of the White
House Of®ce of Scienti®c and Technology Policy is mentioned,
according to which Japan and not Europe will become the strongest
competitor to the US bio-industry. Thus, the European bio-industry was
seen to be suffering from a shortage of quali®ed scientists and engineers
(particularly in process technology), a lack of satisfactory cooperation
between enterprises and universities and insuf®cient research and development resources. Accordingly, the Commission called for an increase in
European competitiveness in the global biotech markets by means of the
following six Community actions in the period 1984±9:
(1) research and training programmes;
(2) harmonization of biotechnology policies;
(3) new regulations about agricultural production for industrial purposes;
(4) a European concept for regulations in the area of biotechnology;
(5) European law for securing intellectual property rights in the ®eld of
biotechnology;
(6) demonstration projects.
For the ®nancing of these actions, 200 million ECU were demanded,
most of which was aimed at the research and training programmes,
which were to receive 106 million, and the demonstration projects in the
®nal phase of the programme, which were to receive 80 million. By
contrast, only 6.6 million ECU were demanded for the harmonization
efforts and the activities of the committee for supervising the risks and
developing the regulations. Further intersectoral and transnational
unions of enterprises and associations were explicitly endorsed. Thus
the report mentioned Biogen, a medium-sized enterprise headquartered
in Geneva that belongs to a group of transnational companies, and the
European Federation of Biotechnology, as well as the national ad hoc
coordinating committees.
Under Karl-Heinz Narjes, who replaced Etienne Davignon in 1985 as
214
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
vice-president of the Commission and Commissioner for Science, Technology and Research, the technology-friendly posture of the Commission continued. However, although he prophesied in a 1989 article that
biotechnology would advance, along with information technology, telematics, new materials, aeronautics and new energy sources as the most
important European growth industries in the twenty-®rst century, in the
second half of the 1980s the Commission focused its efforts on information technology (see chapter 4).
Assessments and proposals after the Single European Act
In a speech on 17 January 1990, Commission President Jacques Delors
reinforced the request of the Community to support bio-industry by
calling for more basic research in the areas of the automotive industry,
air and space travel, electronics and biotechnology. Consequently, a
further communication by the Commission to the European Council
and the European Parliament followed in 1991 entitled `Promoting the
Competitive Environment for the Industrial Activities based on Biotechnology within the Community' (CEC 1991b). International distribution
strategies, the legal protection of inventions and the construction of
centralized and incomplete bio-databanks were identi®ed as the bases
for the current lack of competitiveness of European bio-industry. Particularly problematic was the fact that the Community could not protect
the research results of its producers through patents. The emphases on
bio-sciences in the recently concluded Third Framework Programme
was also reinforced. Finally, an adjustment of the existing guidelines,
biotechnology statistics, a standardized test process, mandatory research
efforts and public relations work as well as the institutionalization of the
ethical advisory group established in 1991 were also demanded.
Biotechnology was emphasized even more in the White Paper `Growth,
Competitiveness, Employment' (CEU 1993). Section B on the economic
prospects of biotechnology (pp. 100ff ) recapitulates the efforts up to the
present: `The Community has taken a number of initiatives, on the one
hand, to promote the competitiveness of bio-industries and, on the
other hand, to ensure the safe application of biotechnology. It implies
mainly funding of research and development and the putting into place
of a regulatory framework' (CEU 1993: 100). The lack of competitiveness was once again deplored and along with it the loss of potential jobs
as well as the sceptical and critical posture of the population toward
biotechnology:
Measuring innovative activity by patents ®led for relevant products in the USA,
the Community and Japan show[s] that patents ®led have increased from 1,100
Biotechnology in the European Union
215
per annum in the early 1980s to 3,350 per annum in 1990. In 1980 the
Community was in leading position, by 1990 the USA was ®ling 50 per cent
more patents than the Community. European Patent Of®ce (EPO) statistics
reveal a similar evolution: between 1980 and 1991 biotechnology patents ®led
with the EPO increased by a factor of 10, the most being ®led by US-based
companies . . .
. . . Current global indicators of the growth prospects of the biotechnology
industry are the following: in the USA the industry based on modern
biotechnology had a turnover of over US$ 8 billion in 1992, a growth rate of 28
per cent with employment growing at 13 per cent. It is estimated on the basis of
the observed rates of diffusion of biotechnology that the US biotechnology
industry's revenues will grow at an average rate of 40 per cent to reach US$ 52
billion by the year 2000. The current industry size in Japan is of®cially put at
US$ 3.8 billion and is estimated by the Ministry of International Trade and
Industry to reach US$ 35 billion by the end of the century. In the Community,
despite the emergence of a signi®cant number of ®rms and a substantial growth
in markets, primarily of bio-pharmaceuticals, to over US$ 3 billion, at the
current rate of growth, the value of output and employment is about the same as
that in Japan. It is therefore clear that by the year 2000 with an estimated world
market of ECU 100 billion for the biotechnology industry, the Community
growth rate will have to be substantially higher than at the present to ensure that
the Community will become a major producer of such products, thereby
reaping the output and employment advantages while at the same time
remaining a key player in the related research area. (CEU 1993: 101)
The Commission fears that the Community will become merely a
leading future market for bio-pharmaceuticals but not a leading future
producer, because technology hostility and social inertia with respect to
biotechnology have been more pronounced in the Community in
general than in the United States or Japan (CEU 1993: 102). In other
words, the Commission recommends: (a) deregulation of the biotech
sector: b) the creation of a scienti®c committee; c) the establishment of
science parks; d) investment incentives; e) public relations work for
biotechnology; and f ) a more vigorous discussion of the ethical aspects
(p. 102).
On 1 August 1994, the communication of the Commission to the
European Council, the European Parliament, and the Economic and
Social Committee ®nally appeared: `Biotechnology and the White Paper
on Growth, Competitiveness and Employment' (CEU 1994). In this
report, a recapitulation and assessment of the recommendations of the
White Paper are followed by suggestions for modifying Directive
90/219/EEC regarding the application of genetically modi®ed microorganisms in closed systems and Directive 90/220/EEC regarding the
deliberate release of genetically modi®ed organisms in the environment.
Thus, the goals of the communication of the Commission (CEC 1991b)
216
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
and the White Paper are underlined once again. Both small and
medium-sized enterprises on the one hand and the ethical aspects of
gene research on the other are accentuated.
At the conference of the European Council in Corfu in June 1994,
Delors highlighted once again the role of biotechnology as a growth
engine whose own growth should be accelerated through a relaxation of
the existing directives. Thus, the Commission conceded for the ®rst
time since the early 1980s the outstanding role of biotechnology as a
growth engine and at the same time kept in view the fact that European
bio-industry exhibits a drastic technological backwardness compared
with the United States and Japan. According to its documents, the root
of the competitive weakness of European biotech producers lies in the
lack of support from member states; a fragmented research landscape,
defective legal protection of biotechnological innovations, as well as
the lack of acceptance of genetic engineering among the population.
Accordingly, demands are made for strengthened research efforts; a
bio-patent Directive; and, since the White Paper (CEU 1993), a general
deregulation in the area of genetic engineering and a higher level of
acceptance among the population. Only a few member states doubted
the rationality of a collective technology policy. The United Kingdom,
the Netherlands and Germany expressed regulatory concerns
regarding the project of supporting private enterprises through public
means.
The assessments and proposals of the Commission were then
supported by several surveys conducted by Ernst & Young of enterprises
in Western Europe. The ®rst Ernst & Young biotech report (1994), for
example, indicated that Europe's total turnover in bio-industry had
already reached approximately 38 billion ECU. The branches of health,
then 15 billion ECU, foods, with 10 billion ECU, and diagnosis, with 8
billion ECU, had the largest commercial potential. Although bioindustry employed only a total of 184,000 people, 6 per cent of the
enterprises surveyed ± above all small and medium-sized enterprises ±
expected a 10±25 per cent increase in employment; 20 per cent
expected an increase of 25±50 percent; and 51 per cent expected an
increase of over 50 percent. According to the second Ernst & Young
report, Biotech 95 (1995), by the year 2000 total turnover might reach
90 billion ECU, despite stable and strong competition from the United
States and Japan. However, in Europe more is invested in absolute
terms than in the United States or Japan, although of course the rate of
increase in investment is rather small.
Biotechnology in the European Union
217
The pillars of European biotechnology policy
In retrospect, one could argue that the aforementioned documents of
the Commission probably exaggerated the backwardness of European
biotechnology ( Junne 1992). Thus, the often mentioned indicator for
the technological state of development ± the number of patents ± is of
only limited value, because, on the one hand, numerous inventions will
not be patented for reasons having to do with establishing power in the
market and, on the other hand, others of course will be patented but
may ultimately not be marketed or may serve exclusively to defend
against competitive products (Archibugi 1992). However, the pessimistic assessments by the experts of the Commission successfully
pushed ®rst for research programmes and then for a revision of
European biotech regulation.
European research programmes
As we have already noted, in a 1973 resolution on a common industrial
policy the Council of the European Community recommended that
enterprises with progressive technology be advanced. This intent was
institutionalized in Article 130f±q of the Single European Act (see also
chapter 4), wherein Article 130q forms the basis for the support for
research facilities, universities and enterprises for the implementation of
common projects. The multi-year Framework Programmes and research
institutes, which are directed jointly by the Community, the member
countries and the involved institutes and enterprises, are the main
political support for research. The frameworks are guided by a jointly
compiled catalogue of goals, by the principle of competitiveness and by
the principle that research projects are exclusively composed of teams
from member countries or associated states.
The value of furthering biotechnology research was still controversial
in the 1970s. From the beginning, it was mainly France that advocated
Community support for this effort (Moreau and Richonnier 1983;
BoissieÁre and Warusfel 1991), while the United Kingdom, Germany
and the Netherlands placed their faith in the research efforts of their
`national champions'.3
3
According to Sharp (1986: 183) in the 1980s France was initially the main state
supporting bio-industry and by far the most active EC member. In 1982±3,
expenditures for state biotechnology programmes in France totalled approximately US$
117 million; in the United Kingdom US$ 43.9 million; in Germany US$38 million; in
the Netherlands US$9.4 million; and in Italy US$4.6 million.
218
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
Thus, it was not until 1975 that the Commission was able to control
the dissent among member countries and to arrive at an agreement on
the ®rst biotech research programme, the Biomolecular Engineering
Programme (BEP), for the period 1982±5. Because of successful
protests against the project of supporting medical research, the programme limited itself with respect to gene technology research projects
to the areas of agriculture and foodstuffs, which was supposed to permit
the networking of the greatest number of research teams and laboratories from the various member states.
Having carried out the Engineering Programme, with a budget of 15
million ECU, in 1985 the second programme, the Biotechnology Action
Programme (BAP), with a budget of 55 million ECU, was launched.
With the linking of Spanish and Portuguese labs to this project in 1987,
this budget was increased by an additional 20 million ECU. The Action
Programme was designed principally to support projects that serve the
improvement of scienti®c infrastructure and education. Thus, the infrastructure was to be expanded by means of bio-databanks and `concerted
actions' as well as by dialogue between science, industry and the
population. European Laboratories Without Walls (transnational networks of university and private laboratories) were supposed to delve
deeply into speci®c questions and thus promote the understanding of
biotechnological processes in Europe. Altogether thirty-®ve laboratories
were formed with an average of six research teams from universities
and enterprises. As a rule, the teams met every six months in one of
the involved laboratories to exchange experiences. In addition, the
academics visited one of the associated partner laboratories for a few
weeks.
The Engineering and the Action Programmes were not elements of
the First Framework Programme, which was adopted in 1983 by the
Council and supported for the period 1984±7 with 3.75 billion ECU.
Against the recommendations of the Commission, which reserved 80
million ECU in the programme budget for biotechnology, the Council
of Ministers favoured a slight increase in the budget for information
technology and ultimately appropriated only 37.1 million ECU for
biotechnology (Ridinger 1991: 202). The biotech programme module
in the Second and Third Framework Programmes was the Biotechnological Research for Innovation, Development and Growth in Europe
(BRIDGE), which ran from 1989 to 1993 and absorbed 100 million
ECU. In contrast to the Action Programme, larger projects were now
given preference. Additionally, research teams from European non-EC
member countries were considered. However, large enterprises were still
to be prevented from participating in any projects other than those that
Biotechnology in the European Union
219
were part of the European Research Coordination Agency (EUREKA)
research programme, which was started in 1985.
Two agriculturally oriented programmes with concentrations in biotechnology and genetic engineering were running parallel to BRIDGE.
The programme European Collaborative Linkage of Agriculture and
Industry through Research (ECLAIR), endowed with 80 million ECU,
was approved by the member states on 23 February 1989; it furthers the
agro-industrial use of biotechnological knowledge. The programme Food
Linked Agro-Industrial Research (FLAIR), endowed with 25 million
ECU, was approved on 20 June 1989, and generally promotes biotechnological research in the food sector. In addition, on 29 June 1990, a
human genome analysis programme was approved, which ran over three
years and was supported by the Community with 15 million ECU.
In March 1992 the programme module BIOTECH I was approved by
the Council, to run from 1992 to 1994 and with a budget of 164 million
ECU. The goal of the programme was the production of biotechnological knowledge that can be utilized in the agricultural, industrial, health
and environmental sectors. For this purpose, molecular research was to
be particularly promoted, including such topics as protein structures
and antibody±antigen interactions, cell and organism research and
studies of the ecological as well as demographic aspects, that is, problems of the release and conservation of genetic resources.
In the Fourth Framework Programme biotechnology gained ground.
The Commission considered henceforth the areas of information
science, telecommunications, material sciences and biotechnology as
key technologies deserving promotion. A further change of course was
expressed in the effort to intensify cooperation with non-European,
principally American and Japanese research teams. The programme
module BIOTECH II, endowed with 552 million ECU, supports the
coordination of resources, in particular of national research programmes, horizontal activities in the sense of demonstration projects,
and investigations of the ethical, social and legal aspects and the socioeconomic consequences of biotechnology as well as the promotion of
dialogue among scholars, users and the public. The ®rst announcement
of the BIOTECH II programme on 17 July 1995, was completed after
the ®ling of 294 proposals. Fifty-six proposals were temporarily selected;
of these the `cell factories' module, with twenty projects, is the largest
area. Projects with biotechnological or gene technology content are also
being carried out as part of the biomedicine and health research
programmes (BIOMED I and II), with an emphasis on human genome
analysis and the agriculture and ®shery programme (Fisheries and
Agro-Industrial Research).
220
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
Table 8.1. Expenditure on the biosciences in the EU, 1984±98 (ECU
million)
Framework Programme
I
1984±87
Biotechnology
Agro-industrial technologies
Agricultural competitiveness
Biomedicine and health
Biosciences and technologies
for developing countries
Total for biotech
Grant total for all research
II
1987±91
III
1990±94
IV
1994±98
37
±
±
±
120
105
55
133
164
333
±
336
552
684
±
±
±
37
2,797
±
280
5,396
111
741
5,700
±
1,572
12,300
Source: various publications of the Commission
Table 8.1 shows that expenditures for EC research on biosciences in
the period 1984±98 doubled in the Second and Fourth Framework
Programmes when compared with the programmes that preceded them.
In contrast, the increase in the Third Programme, prepared during the
second half of the 1980s, was not very impressive. In sum, the expenditures for biotechnology in the narrow sense of the term (row 1 in table
8.1) rose from 37.1 million ECU in the First Framework Programme to
552 million ECU in the Fourth Framework Programme. Biotechnology
gained ground at the expense of information technology in both relative
and absolute terms. Thus, the share of expenditures for biotechnology
in the broad sense of the term (all rows in table 8.1) rises from under 1.4
per cent in the First Framework Programme to 12.8 per cent in the
Fourth. The opposite is true for the proportional expenditures for
information and communications technology, which declined considerably from the Second to the Fourth Framework Programme, from 42
per cent (2,275 million ECU), to 28 per cent (3,405 million ECU),
respectively. The Commission's proposal (9 April 1997) for the Fifth
Framework Programme (1998±2002), which demands a budget of
16,300 million ECU, underlines the importance of biotechnology and
will probably preserve its role in the European research agenda.
A prime example of an intensive use of the research programme is the
Belgian agricultural biotechnological enterprise, Plant Genetic Systems
(PGS). The enterprise was founded in 1982 by the University of Gent
and employs 135 staff members; it participates in numerous joint
ventures with North American and Indian enterprises and is a member
of the Senior Advisory Group Biotechnology. From the beginning, PGS
Biotechnology in the European Union
221
specialized in the manufacture of new kinds of grains, seed oils and
vegetables for the European and Asiatic markets. It currently holds 43
patents and has an additional 142 worldwide patent proposals under
examination. Its pioneer project was the development of a plant that is
resistant to attack by insects. The plant was developed by inserting a
gene that tells the plant cells to produce proteins that are poisonous to
insects. Since the mid-1980s PGS has participated in every biotechnology programme of the Community and cooperated additionally in
two EUREKA projects. PGS has also taken part in training programmes
of the European Union (Human Capital and Mobility, 1990±4) and
supports students by means of research scholarships.
Projects with biotechnological and gene technology content are also
supported by two European research programmes, COST (European
Cooperation in the ®eld of Scienti®c and Technical Research) and
EUREKA. Both programmes leave the content and ®nancing of the
projects to the participants; the programme of®ce examines only the
worthiness of each project and its term. Despite the minimal attractiveness of COST to private enterprises, the number of projects rose
continuously from 7 (1971) to 115 ( January 1995), thanks not least to
an increase in the number of member countries. The 13 projects with
biotechnological content (as of January 1995) concentrate on the
agricultural sphere. EUREKA, which covers nine technological areas
altogether, is more competitive and thus more attractive to the chemical
and pharmaceutical industries. According to the 1989 annual report by
the EUREKA secretariat (EUREKA 1989), since 1985 the number of
new projects with a biotechnological content increased four times more
than the number of new projects in the information technology sector.
In 1989, of the total of 241 projects, only 24 per cent were in the area of
information technology, and at that point already 19 per cent were in
biotechnology and 18 per cent were in the ®eld of robotics and automation. By the end of 1994, the sphere of medicine and biotechnology
included more than 120 active and 30 completed projects. In October
1994, the completed biotech projects represented about 14 per cent (28
projects) of the total of 202 completed projects. Of the 657 active
projects, 18.5 per cent were in the ®eld of genetic engineering
(EUREKA 1994). The high proportion of projects with biotechnological content should not obscure the fact, however, that the cost of
these projects (730 million ECU) measured as a share of the total costs
of all active projects (11,660 million ECU) was at the time a modest
6.3 percent. It is approximately the same in the Fourth Framework
Programme.
222
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
Arrangements, directives and regulations
Since the early 1980s the Commission has willingly soothed critics of
genetic engineering research and products with reference to the fact that
European enterprises are subject to comparatively more instruction than
their American and East Asian competitors. In fact, in its 1983 communication (CEC 1983b) the Commission had already insisted upon
mandatory legal boundaries for genetic engineering research. By 1988
three directives had been presented to the Council of Ministers and the
European Parliament for examination and subsequent approval in 1990:
European Union Directive 90/219 regarding the application of genetically modi®ed organisms in closed systems (lab Directive); Directive 90/
220 regarding the intentional release of genetically altered organisms
into the environment (deliberate release Directive); and Directive 90/
679 regarding protection from the dangers of working with biological
agents (protection Directive). Directive 93/39, which demands a
uniform authorization process for bio-high-tech products, followed in
1993.
On 1 September 1994, Regulation 2100/94 on Community protection of the genetic resources of plants and animals came into effect.
Since 1 October 1994, member states must also deal with the changes of
Directive 93/114, which replaces Directive 70/524/EEC regarding additives in animal feed. Additives that consist of genetically modi®ed
organisms are also now being newly reconsidered. In the second half of
the 1990s other measures were also being debated, including a directive
proposed by the Commission (91/414) regarding the evaluation of the
dangers of genetically modi®ed pesticides, amendments to Directives
70/457/EEC (seed traf®c) and 70/458/EEC (catalogue of sorts) and a
regulation of the Council regarding Community protection of plants'
and animals' genetic resources. Also under discussion is a bio-ethics
convention of the Council of Europe.
As controversial now as then is the evaluation of products containing
the growth hormone bovine somatotropin. The determining factor in
the decision by the Commission to forbid the use of this gene-technology-based animal medication in member states is Directive 87/22,
whereby all high-grade gene technology medicines are to be examined
before their use is authorized by the Community. After years of clari®cation of the after-effects (a moratorium) through the Committee for
Veterinary Medicine Products and the Ethical Advisory Group, in 1993
the Commission certi®ed two products from Monsanto and Eli Lilly,
with the implication that their use would be unobjectionable. Taking
into account the planned agricultural reform, which argues against
Biotechnology in the European Union
223
further expansion of meat and milk production, the Commission,
however, has up to now forbidden the use of bovine somatotropin
products and in December 1995 extended the moratorium for ®ve more
years. Moreover, on 1 January 1995, Directive 93/41/EEC superseded
the standard Directive 87/22/EEC regarding the authorization of technologically high-grade medicines.
In 1986, the Council of Ministers had already recommended Community regulation and acceleration of the test process for biotechnological medicines. With the opening of the European Medication
Evaluation Agency (EMEA) on 26 January 1995, this recommendation
was realized. As a result, all medicines developed in the European
Union are now subjected to a standardized authorization process. This
process is supposed to last 300 days, considerably less than the 500 days
required in the USA. Until now, European pharmaceutical enterprises
had to announce a newly developed product in all countries, and in the
most unfavourable case the authorization process could take up to six
years.
Since summer 1997, a regulation on `novel food' (258/97/EC) has
been in effect. It requires obligatory labelling for all European Union
states of any genetically modi®ed foods and food ingredients including
the genetic engineering procedure if the genetic modi®cation can be
proved. This regulation was put forward as early as 1992, but because of
furious opposition on the part of consumer associations and ecologically
oriented powers in the Council of Ministers and in the mediation
committee of the European Parliament no consensus could be reached
on it. After lengthy negotiations between the Commission, the Parliament (which had to consider no fewer than sixty-three amendments),
and the member countries, the ®rst compromise proposed by the
mediation committee of the Council of Ministers failed on 6 June 1995.
Sweden, Denmark, Germany and Austria and the majority of the
Parliament pleaded for a restrictive labelling requirement, whereas the
Commission, the Group of Advisers on the Ethical Aspects of Biotechnology and the biotech enterprises as well as the United Kingdom,
France, Belgium, Finland, Italy and Ireland considered such a conspicuous declaration to be hostile to consumers and wanted to label only
materials that could cause allergic reactions.
The views of enterprises and environmental groups with reference to
the content of the so-called bio-patent Directive are still incompatible.
The European Patent Convention of 5 October 1973, which seventeen
West European countries including Switzerland have signed, anticipated
that animals and plants are themselves patentable. Patent protection is
granted, however, only for species and plant varieties that are not
224
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
marked with breed- and/or variety-speci®c characteristics. According to
Article 53 of the Convention, patenting of inventions is also forbidden if
`their publication or utilization would offend the public order or
morals'. The Council of Europe's European agreement for the protection of vertebrates used in testing and for other scienti®c purposes,
which was also rati®ed in 1993 by Switzerland, allows gene technology
experiments with animals only if the terms of the agreement regarding
animal testing are observed. Since 6 February 1994, the European
agreement for the protection of animals employed in agriculture has
contained a protective clause for working animals that are the result of
either traditional animal breeding or genetic operations. Natural and
arti®cial breeding methods as well as food additives that cause the
animals pain and suffering are forbidden.
In 1983 the Commission moved to create mandatory legal protection
within the Community for intellectual property in biotechnology processes, following the American model (see CEC 1983b). This demand
was later emphatically strengthened by the Commission and has been
renewed since then in all of®cial documents. The directive was intended
to contain mandatory patent regulation, to guarantee the rights of
research institutions, to harmonize the permission procedures for bioproducts on the European domestic market and thereby to promote
gene technology research. From the point of view of the Commission,
the employers' associations and the Group of Advisers on the Ethical
Aspects of Biotechnology (see below), a regulation based on the
American model was indispensable and ethically justi®able. Enterprises
would be ready to invest in research only if biotechnological inventions
were protected for a certain period from access by the competition. In
1988, Directorate General III for Internal Market and Industrial Affairs
published a directive entitled `Proposal for a Council Directive on the
legal protection of biotechnology inventions' (COM (99) 496 ®nal ±
SYN 159).
Under the terms of the European patent agreement, the corresponding
patent applications are currently examined by the European Patent
Of®ce in Munich. By the end of 1995, the Of®ce had approved the ®rst
two patents for animal cells: one for the `Harvard cancer mouse', which
had been patented in 1988 in the United States, and one for a type of cell
that produces tumour-forming proteins. Altogether, 300 registrations for
genetically modi®ed organisms are currently being processed. In
November 1995 a three-day hearing took place at the Patent Of®ce in
Munich regarding the 1992 approval of the so-called cancer mouse
patent (patent No. 0 169 672). This was the ®rst patent for a genetically
altered animal ± a mouse that easily becomes ill with cancer.
Biotechnology in the European Union
225
Despite massive propaganda on the part of the Commission, on 1
March 1995, the European Parliament rejected the ®rst bio-patent
proposal put forward jointly by the Council and a parliamentary delegation, by a vote of 240 to 188, with 23 abstentions. Representatives of the
parliamentary majority ± Socialists, Greens, and Communists ± supported by Greenpeace and expert opinion from the Freiburg Ecology
Institute argued that genetically modi®ed life forms must be seen not as
inventions but as discoveries, and as such are not subject to protection.
For the ®rst time, the European Parliament exercised its veto power in
the decision-making process over recommendations of the Commission.
Opponents of bio-patents spoke accordingly of a `historic' decision,
while representatives of the Commission and the Council suspected that
with this decision the technological gap between Europe and the USA
and Japan would only increase. However, on 6 July 1998, the European
Parliament ended its opposition and adopted the revised Directive for
Patents in Biotechnology (98/44/EC), which harmonizes national laws
on biotechnological inventions but also provides that plant and animal
varieties and the processes of cloning human beings are not patentable.
A further victory for environmentalist organizations was the de facto
moratorium on the approval of genetically manipulated organisms, on
24 June 1999, in Luxembourg. In their declarations the ministers of
environment of Denmark, France, Greece, Italy, Luxembourg, Austria,
Belgium, Finland, Germany, the Netherlands and Sweden demanded a
more rigorous and transparent legal framework concerning potential
risks to health and the environment.
The dialogue between the Commission and the interest
organizations
From the beginning the Commission has attempted to incorporate
representatives of economic interests into its policy formulation process.
Thus, the formation of European umbrella organizations was actively
promoted and their experts were invited to participate in the advisory
bodies of the Commission. In contrast to diverse economic and cultural
interests, which primarily make use of informal channels of communication (lobbying), at the moment the biotech interests are well articulated in these advisory bodies. Nevertheless, European biotechnology
corporatism has remained fragmentary until now. This is due to a
weakly centralized system of associations and to narrow and selective
accessibility of the corporatist committees (corporatism without ecological interests), but also to an unreadiness on the part of the Commission to institutionalize dialogue with interest groups.
226
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
Interest organizations in the biotechnology sector
The biotechnology policy of the European Community is in¯uenced by
a variety of interest organizations. Whereas European industrial branch
associations, large enterprises and agricultural associations are working
for deregulation, environmentalists, consumer organizations and the
chemical workers' unions are ®ghting for restrictive directives and
regulations.
Biotech producers' associations
The interests of the biotech manufacturers at the level of the European
Union are manifested principally through the large umbrella organizations of the agrochemical and pharmaceutical industries. In addition,
the large European pharmaceutical manufacturers have their own lobbyists in Brussels and, since 1989, an organization that pursues biotech
interests exclusively.
Prior to the conclusion of the Single European Act the interests of the
biotech departments of large enterprises were principally represented by
the European umbrella organizations of the chemical and pharmaceutical industries. In 1972 the European Chemical Industry Council
(CEFIC) was founded, which today includes umbrella organizations
from the EU member states and from Switzerland and Norway. In light
of the growing in¯uence of the ecology movement on national legislation, the chemistry industry expected that its association would advocate
industry-friendly regulation at the European level: `The hope is that at
the European level the legislation can either be halted by opposition
from other states or, at least, can be signi®cantly modi®ed in an intergovernmental arena at a distance from the intrusion of domestically
powerful environmental groups' (Grant et al. 1989: 182).
The European Federation of Pharmaceutical Industry Associations
(EFPIA), founded in 1979, became the second important biotech
lobbyist alongside the CEFIC during the 1980s. Umbrella organizations
from fourteen Community member countries (with the exception of
Luxembourg) and from Switzerland and Norway belong to it. Thus,
some umbrella organizations, such as the Swiss Gesellschaft der Chemischen Industrie, are members of the organizations of both the
chemical industry and the pharmaceutical industry. In contrast to
CEFIC, however, the spectrum of activities of EFPIA is limited to
research, production and the marketing of medicines. Close contacts
exist therefore between it and Directorates General III, XII and XI,
which are responsible for the proposals for Directives 90/219, 90/220
Biotechnology in the European Union
227
and 90/679. Other important points of contact include: Directorate
General XV, which is concerned with the patenting of medicines;
Directorate General I (External Relations), which is concerned with
expansion to the east; and Directorate General V, which deals with
health issues. Above all, EFPIA advocates the deregulation of the
biotech industry and a simpli®cation of the medicine testing process.
The European Federation of Animal Health (FEDESA), founded in
1987, is also in favour of deregulation. This organization was founded in
response to the 1985 EC Regulation 89/649, which forbids the use of
hormone preparations in cattle-raising. Ten umbrella organizations
from EU member states and Switzerland belong to this association of
hormone producers. Similar to the composition of the CEFIC, there are
also twenty-three associated enterprises with of®ces in Europe and the
United States. The association is mainly focused on attaining an
all-European authorization for the use of the growth hormone bovine
somatotropin and/or a suspension of the moratorium on its use passed
by the Commission. For this purpose the association seeks to maintain a
high pro®le in the committees of Directorate General VI (Agriculture).
Additionally it is a member of the committee for the formation of the
European medicine testing institute of Directorate General III (Internal
Market and Industrial Affairs).
The European agricultural association, COPA, and the association of
agricultural cooperatives, COGECA, also work closely with the association of hormone producers (Burkhardt-Reich and Schumann 1983).
The main goal of both agricultural associations is the promotion of
biotechnological and gene technology processes, which result in animals
with more meat as well as rot- and pest-resistant plants.
The representation of biotech interests by CEFIC, EFPIA and
FEDESA became channelled and coordinated by the Forum for European Bioindustry Coordination (FEBC), founded in 1993. According
to its own statements, the Forum represents enterprises with altogether
5 million employees, of whom approximately 184,000 are working
directly in modern biotechnology. The main goals of the Forum are the
revision of Directives 90/219 and 90/220 (see above) and the patenting
of biotechnological and gene technology processes. The Forum represents only matters that are supported by all member associations.
Therefore, the industrial branch associations pursue additional lobbying
on their own.4
The Forum was the successor organization to the European
4
Thus the Association of Microbial Food Enzyme Producers in Western Europe
(AMFEP) demands, for example, in connection with the 1989 guideline proposal on
food additives, that the role of enzymes in food production has also to be considered.
228
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
Biotechnology Coordination Group (EBCG), which was founded at the
wish of Directorate General XII in 1985 and originally included the
following branch organizations: chemicals (CEFIC), pharmaceuticals
(EFPIA), food and feed enzymes (AMFEP), food (CIAA), pesticides
(GIFAP), patents (EBPG), agrochemicals (ECRAB), plant breeders
(COMASSO), animal health products (FEDESA) and plants and seeds
(GIBIP). New additions during the 1990s include the Euro-associations
of feedstuff additives producers (FEFANA), compound feed producers
(FEFAC), plant protection products (ECPA), diagnostic products
(EDMA), EuropaBio (Senior Advisory Group Biotechnology) and the
Farm Animal Industrial Platform (FAIP). In the meantime, the patents
association, the producers of agrochemicals and the producers of pesticides had all left the Forum.
During this period (1989±91) eight national organizations (Belgium,
Spain, Denmark, France, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal, the United
Kingdom) also belonged to the Coordination Group. However, in 1992
they left the Forum and formed the European Secretariat of National
Biotechnology Associations (ESNBA), headquartered in Brussels. According to the Secretariat, the Forum was neglecting the interests of the
small and medium-sized enterprises. Although dialogue between the
Forum and the Secretariat is only rudimentary, close contacts exist
between the plant breeders, the plants and seeds producers and Directorate General XI (Environment, Consumer Protection and Nuclear
Safety).
Discontented with Directives 90/219 and 90/220 and with lobbying
through the European Biotechnology Coordination Group, seven large
biotech enterprises (Ferruzi Group, Hoechst, ICI, Monsanto Europe,
RhoÃne-Poulenc, Sandoz and Unilever) founded a committee within the
umbrella organization of the chemical industry in 1989, known as the
Senior Advisory Group Biotechnology (SAGB). In their opinion, the
Coordination Group proved strikingly ineffective during the 1980s, and
suffered above all from the fact that the small and medium-sized
enterprises, thanks to the memberships of the national biotech associations, carried more weight. In addition, for most of the industrial
branch associations, biotechnology was just one focal point among
many. The rapid increase in membership and the expansion of the scope
of activity led in June 1991 to the organizational separation of the
Advisory Group from CEFIC. The ®rst president of the Group was
Peter Doyle, general director of British Zeneca. On 23 November 1993,
JuÈrgen Drews, a member of the medical faculty of the University of
Heidelberg and a staff member of Swiss Hoffmann-La Roche, assumed
the chairmanship.
Biotechnology in the European Union
229
By 1995 the Advisory Group already had thirty-two member enterprises, which together accounted for approximately 2 million employees
and over US$305 billion in turnover, and invested approximately
US$17 billion in research and development. The Group works closely
with the Forum for European Bioindustry Coordination, which is
expressed, among other ways, by the fact that both organizations have
their general secretariats in the same building.
The model for the Group is the in¯uential US Biotechnology Industry
Organization (BIO), to which approximately 800 enterprises and university research institutes belong. Along with the Japan Bioindustry
Association ( JBA) and the Industrial Biotechnology Association of
Canada (IBAC), both organizations belong to the International Bioindustry Forum (IBF), founded in 1990. The Group is a member of a
Steering Committee, an executive body to which the managements of
the member enterprises belong, and a Strategic Committee, which
bolsters its arguments through position papers developed by work
teams.
The main goal of the Senior Advisory Group is the creation of a
positive regulatory climate in Europe. According to the Group, Europe
suffers from a lack of acceptance of biotechnology and genetic engineering by the public and by the various governments. If this did not
change in the course of the 1990s, the Senior Advisory Group feared a
massive shift in production, which would be accompanied by a loss of
jobs and taxes. Therefore, the Group demands from the European
Union that it revise the existing directives and make them more friendly
to enterprises. Research policy is of secondary importance for Group
members, since they have suf®cient capacity for conducting their own
research and want to use their research results privately. Moreover, the
EU programmes basically promote only competitive research and thus,
in comparison with the EUREKA programme, are comparatively unattractive.
In addition, the Senior Advisory Group compiles position papers on
European biotechnology policy. In 1990 three position papers were
published, which provide information on the direction of their representation. In the ®rst paper, published in January 1990, Community Policy
for Biotechnology: Priorities and Actions (SAGB 1990a), the economic
signi®cance of biotechnology for the pharmaceutical, agricultural, food
and environment sectors was highlighted. Because of the neglect of
European bio-industry it was to be expected that the United States and
Japan would expand their current advantage even further. The demand
made to the European Community, therefore, was that it create a single
legal framework and industry-friendly boundaries for research. The
230
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
discussion of corresponding directives and regulations was to be transparent and accompanied by formally institutionalized consultation with
affected interest groups. It was noted that the member enterprises of the
Senior Advisory Group were already part of such consultation processes
in their home countries. More general suggestions followed for improving the competitiveness of European bio-industry. For example, it
was suggested that biotechnology research in the European Union adopt
a more distinctly European pro®le and that it support more ambitious
projects and research topics.
In July 1990 the paper Economic Bene®ts and European Competitiveness
(SAGB 1990b) was published. Once again, it called attention to the
economic signi®cance of biotechnology and the competitive weakness
brought on by over-regulation. This weakness is also expressed by the
asymmetrical ¯ow of investment from Europe to the United States and
the comparatively few European patent registrations. This state of
affairs was blamed not only on over-regulation and a lack of public
acceptance of biotechnology, but also on comparatively meagre public
research resources and, compared with the United States, decentralized
research activities at the level of the member states. Thus the demand
was made for biotechnology research in Europe to be coordinated
analogously to the United States at the federal level.
In October 1990 the interest expressed in January for an institutionalized dialogue was concretized. In the paper Creation of a Community
Task Force and an Independent Advisory Body (SAGB 1990c), two new
(quasi-)corporatist institutions were demanded. Analogously to the
areas of information technology and small and medium enterprises,
whose Task Forces were later transformed into independent Directorates General, the Community was to create a committee with representatives of the Commission, bio-industry and bioscience, in order to
elaborate mandatory political measures on the basis of a coherent
programme and to bring about the implementation of these measures.
Along with this, an independent commission of experts was to be
formed to deal with the ethical aspects of biotechnology.
In 1993 the Commission published a White Paper in which biotechnology was granted a central role as future engine of growth (see the ®rst
section of this chapter). According to statements by Stefan Ryser, a
member of the Strategic Committee, the Senior Advisory Group had not
collaborated on the text, although it was made aware of pre-publication
drafts of passages relevant to biotechnology and was permitted to
comment on them. Thus the Group commented very favourably on the
suggestions of the White Paper. In April 1994, the paper Biotechnology
Policy in the European Union. Prescriptions for Growth, Competitiveness and
Biotechnology in the European Union
231
Employment: A Response to the Union's 1993 White Paper on Growth,
Competitiveness and Employment (SAGB 1994a) was published. As
supporting measures, the Group demanded a dismantling of regulations
and investment barriers, tax privileges for enterprises that invest in
biotechnology, education and training programmes for small and
medium-sized enterprises, as well as better management of biotechnology policy by means of a Biotechnology Task Force.
Similarly, in April 1994 the paper Biotechnology Policy in the European
Union: Competitiveness, Investment and the Cycle of Innovation (SAGB
1994b) predicted that European enterprises would be inclined to shift
their research and development elsewhere. This process could only be
stopped if the research potential in the EU could be preserved and
readiness of enterprises to engage in research and development was not
hindered through regulation. Additional demands were made that gene
technology processes and inventions be granted patent rights and that
research and education at a European level be strengthened.
On 17 May 1994, the Senior Advisory Group commented on the
Commission's 1993 White Paper and proposed a plan of action
containing the following points (Agence Europe, cited in Reuters EU
Brie®ngs):
(a) The creation of an ad hoc, high-level task force for biotechnology,
which would deal with questions related to the economy and
competitiveness. This unit would include representatives of the
national authorities (ministries of economics and industry), the
European Commission (Biotechnology Coordination Committee),
industry, the world of ®nance, employers, the agricultural sector
and academia. As an advisory body, its main task would be to
develop goals and concrete measures that the Community should
take in this ®eld. The decision to set up this high-level group was
expected to be taken prior to the Industry Council in November;
the Senior Advisory Group hoped that this matter would be
addressed at the European summit in Corfu at the end of June.
(b) The implementation of a ®ve-point plan of action to improve the
competitiveness of Europe's biotechnology industry: (1) ensure
more effectiveness, greater transparency and more predictability
regarding Community regulations; (2) encourage and facilitate
investment in the biotechnology sector, notably by creating
dynamic small and medium-sized enterprises ± to this end, there
must be better protection for intellectual property, measures must
be taken to stimulate the European capital markets, public aid must
be granted to innovative basic research, etc.; (3) encourage risk
investment in biotechnology innovation (tax incentives, alleviation
232
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
of costs and other constraints that weigh on enterprises, especially
small and medium-sized enterprises, etc.); (4) improve the quali®cations and ¯exibility of workers (more political and ®nancial
support for the training of workers, mutual recognition of quali®cations, etc.); (5) provide broad-based leadership for biotechnology
competitiveness in key sectors: industry, agriculture, political
leaders, academia.
In 1995 the Senior Advisory Group, representing large ®rms, and the
European Secretariat of National Bioindustry Associations, representing
small and medium-sized enterprises, decided to share their of®ces in
Brussels. In late 1996, both organizations even decided to create a new
association, EuropaBio, which represents forty-seven big companies
(including seven member enterprises of the European Roundtable of
Industrialists: Akzo Nobel, Bayer, Danone, NestleÂ, Solvay, RhoÃnePoulenc and Unilever)5 and twelve national associations representing
some 700 biotech companies (as of June 1999). In 1998, Pol Bamelis
(Bayer) succeeded its ®rst chairman JuÈrgen Drews (Hoffman-La
Roche). According to its report Benchmarking the Competitiveness of
Biotechnology in Europe (EuropaBio 1997), Europe's position in biotechnology improved during the 1990s. However, the USA had still been
more successful than Europe in terms of turnover, research and development expenditures, number of companies and number of employees.
The report therefore recommends governments, media, universities and
research institutes to take actions to create a more positive business
environment.
Scientists, conservationists, consumers and unions
The most important interest group of scientists is the European Federation of Biotechnology (EFB), founded in 1978 in Interlaken. The
Federation has its main of®ce in Frankfurt and includes about sixty
groups. The Federation is committed to the use of biotechnology in
environmental protection and is in close contact with Directorate
General XI. As part of the Task Group on Public Perceptions of
5
The membership list, as of 1999, is as follows: Advanta, AgrEvo, Akzo Nobel, AresSerono, BASF, Bayer, Biogen, Bioresearch Ireland, Boehringer Ingelheim, Boehringer
Mannheim, British Biotechnology, Cargill, Celltech, Centocor, Danone, Dekalb
Genetics, Dompe Biotec, Dow AgroSciences, DSM-Gist, DuPont, Eli Lilly, Evotec
BioSystems, Hoffmann-La Roche, Genencor, Genset, Genzyme, Hoechst, Innogenetics, KWS, Limagrain, Monsanto, NestleÂ, Novartis, Novo Nordisk, PepsiCo,
Pharmacia, Pharming, Pioneer Genetique, Procter & Gamble, RhoÃne-Poulenc, Rothschild Asset Management, Schering, Smithkline Beecham, Solvay, Transgene, Unilever,
Zeneca.
Biotechnology in the European Union
233
Biotechnology, founded in 1991, its chairman, John Durant, is in charge
of the Eurobarometer items on biotechnology and documents them on
behalf of the Commission (Durant 1992; Durant, Bauer and Gaskell
1998).
Environmental protection interests perceive the four principal organizations re¯ecting their interests to be: the European Environmental
Bureau (EEB), the Coordination EuropeÂenne des Amis de la Terre
(CEAT), the Worldwide Fund for Nature (WWF) and Greenpeace. The
most active are Greenpeace and the CEAT, a network of thirty independent, national environmental organizations in twenty-nine countries. At
the beginning of 1995, the EU unit of Greenpeace declared itself in
opposition to the bio-patent proposal compromise of the mediation
committee of the European Parliament and the Council of Ministers. In
a communication directed to the parliamentarians, Greenpeace labelled
the patenting of genetically modi®ed creatures `immoral'. In addition,
Greenpeace pointed out that bio-patents would not solve the global
hunger problem, since the patent owners would logically like to sell their
products at the highest possible price. According to Greenpeace, biopatents should not serve to further the industry and their desire for
pro®ts ± at the expense of more moral, socially bene®cial and environmental values.
Owing to a shortage of ®nancial and personnel resources, in 1991 the
four environmental organizations formed the Biotechnology Clearinghouse, which obtains information about technology policy projects of
the Commission. Although the Clearinghouse was ®nancially supported
by the Concertation Unit of Biotechnology in Europe (CUBE; see
below), it was dissolved in 1995. It was replaced by the of®ce of Friends
of the Earth Biotechnology Europe (FEBE), which both obtains information and develops common positions in the policy formation process.
In contrast to the Clearinghouse, Friends of the Earth initially employed
three people and was supported ®nancially by the national Friends of
the Earth organizations. In this division of ®nancial support, the
German Bund fuÈr Natur und Umwelt (BUND) is responsible for the
area of biotechnology.
Consumer interests are currently represented by the Bureau of
European Consumers' Organizations (Bureau EuropeÂen des Unions des
Consommateurs: BEUC). The most important national consumer
associations belong to the Bureau; however, the of®ce in Brussels is
®nancially supported by the Community and thus engages in only
moderate criticism of the proposals of the Commission. The Bureau
advocated the most restrictive kind of obligatory labelling as part of the
novel food Regulation, although it does not fundamentally oppose novel
234
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
food. In a press release of 14 February 1994, the Bureau stated that it is
not opposed to research into, or the production of, novel foods and
novel food ingredients. Indeed, it recognized the potential bene®ts that
these could have for consumers and the environment. The Bureau did
demand, however, a highly visible and recognizable label for genetically
modi®ed organisms and a declaration of all ingredients manufactured
with gene technology. The Bureau is also critical of the position of the
Ethics Group of the European Biotechnology Coordination Committee
(see below), according to which consumers need only be informed that a
product contains genetically manipulated ingredients.
In comparison with the environmental protection and consumer
organizations, up to now the trade unions have played a subordinate role
in biotech affairs. The European Federation of the Chemical Unions
(FESCID), founded in 1988, is a union committee of the European
Trade Union Confederation (ETUC). It primarily advocates workplace
protection in bio-industry; thus, it welcomed Directive 90/679 on protection from dangers associated with working with biological agents (the
protection Directive). Because of limited ®nancial, personnel (fewer
than ®ve staff positions) and specialized resources, up to now the
Federation has limited itself to the demand for safety measures. Moreover, in contrast to the environmental protection organizations, the
trade unions are comparatively biotechnology friendly; in fact, they fear
that strict regulation will lead to a shift of research and production sites
and thus in the long run threatens those jobs.
Levels of corporatist dialogue
The most important level of the dialogue between members of the
European Union and biotech organizations are the committees,
which can be convened on an ad hoc basis by of®cials of the
Commission with regard to planned directives and regulations. The
paramount importance of these committees for the European biotech
producers is an expression of the extraordinary role of the Commission in the legislative process. According to the Community statutes
(Article 155 of the original agreement founding the EEC), EU norms
are initiated not by the Council of Ministers, but rather by the
Commission. Article 152 anticipates, of course, that the Commission
must take into consideration the suggestions of the Council.
However, the fact remains that the Council of Ministers has no right of
initiative. Thus, in the event of passivity on the part of the Commission,
the Council's only recourse under Article 175(1) is to ®le a complaint
for inactivity.
Biotechnology in the European Union
235
Interest groups are therefore forced to make their presence known
at the initiation of a directive or regulation. The starting point for a
proposal from the Commission to the Council of Ministers is a draft
text, which as a rule is initiated by one of the higher of®cials in the
affected Directorate General and is drawn up by a competent specialist. After that, the draft will be discussed with all interested Directorates General and Commission agencies and in the committees, in
which both representatives of member states as well as private interests sit. Often Commission of®cials also travel to the capitals of the
member countries to sound out the level of acceptance of the proposal. After an initial revision, the text is delivered to the cabinet of
the Commissioner responsible for the matter. After a second revision
by the cabinet, the text ultimately reaches the Commissioner. If the
text is approved by this Commissioner, the General Secretariat will be
asked to present the draft to the Commissioners. Next, the cabinet
members discuss the draft at their weekly meeting. If no further
differences of opinion exist, the text is recommended to the Commissioners for acceptance, that is, for publication. If disagreements still
exist, the Commissioners will debate further and, if need be, the text
is sent back to the responsible Directorate General for another
revision.
Since in the second phase the text of draft directives and regulations
will be examined by the European Parliament and possibly by the
Economic and Social Committee, the views of interest groups, professional lobbyists, politicians, of®cials of the Committee of Permanent
Representatives (COREPER) and the responsible committees of the
Parliament and the Economic and Social Committee will be sought out
in informal conversations and in the committees.
After publication the text is transferred to the Council of Ministers,
which presents it to the European Parliament and the Economic and
Social Committee for examination. In both main consulting bodies of
the European Union the text will now be discussed in the responsible
committees, criticized, and, if necessary, revised. In this way, positions
are taken on the issue after a period of six to twelve months.
The committee structure involves more than 300 standing committees and more than 1,000 issue-speci®c ad hoc advisory bodies. According to Grote (1990: 243) between 1980 and 1989 the number of
standing committees increased from 197 to 248. Here it must be understood that in the period 1980±4 the number increased from 197 to 241,
then declined to 225 in 1985, only to rise again to its current number.
The most extensive Directorate General is the one responsible for
agriculture (DG VI), with ®fty-eight standing committees in 1989. It is
236
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
followed by Directorate General III (Internal Market and Industrial
Affairs) with thirty-three; and Directorate General V (Employment,
Social Affairs, Education) and Directorate General XI (Environment,
Consumer Protection and Nuclear Safety) with twenty-six standing
committees each. In addition to these Commission committees, on an
annual basis there are more than 1,000 unspeci®ed meetings of Commission authorities with representatives of public and private institutions
and organizations (Budget of the EC, Article 250).
In addition, there are numerous committees in which an exchange of
experience and opinion occurs between the Commission and interest
groups. One example is Committee 233 on biotechnology of the
European Committee of Standardization. The committee is concerned
with creating uniform technical norms and instructions in the interest of
consumers. Participation in the committee is particularly important for
national associations, since manufacturers always seek to protect the
norms of their production location, especially from foreign competition.
The starting point for this committee was the view expressed in the
White Paper (CEC 1985: 19) that the danger of damage and accidents
could be decreased by means of uniform technical instructions. The
infrastructure for Committee 233 is provided by Directorates General
III and XII; it is currently charged with formulating the technical safety
requirements of the three biotechnology Directives. Since the adoption
of the novel food Regulation in 1997, the committee has also been
discussing the manner in which genetically modi®ed foods and food
ingredients should be labelled.
To coordinate the work of all the sections in the Commission that deal
with biotechnological questions, the Inter-service Biotechnology
Steering Committee was formed in 1984. This committee of departmental representatives was charged with implementing the stated goals
of the 1983 EC summit in Stuttgart. In light of strong differences of
opinion and problems of coordination among the various Directorates
General, in 1985 the committee proposed the formation of the
European Biotechnology Coordination Group.
Faced with widespread public scepticism regarding genetic engineering, the BRIDGE programme (see above) was supposed to contribute to `an increase of public awareness and understanding of
biotechnology'. The task of creating public acceptance was entrusted to
the Concertation Unit of Biotechnology in Europe (CUBE). CUBE was
formed in 1984 as a section of DG XII and served as the secretariat for
the Biotechnology Steering Committee. CUBE maintained close contact
with the bio-industry associations and supported the dissolution of the
Coordination Group, which it reproached for its inability to create
Biotechnology in the European Union
237
consensus.6 As the result of furious criticism on the part of the environmental organizations that CUBE was conducting free public relations
work in favour of biotech production, it was dissolved in 1992 (Dreyer
1993).
The central forum for the exchange of experience and opinion
between interest groups and the Commission is currently the issuespeci®c biotechnology roundtables, to which a selection of representatives are invited by Euro-associations and industry. On 11 July 1992, the
general secretary of the European Biotechnology Coordination Group
succeeded for the ®rst time in conducting a general discussion with
representatives of industry, labour unions and environmental organizations. On 29 September 1993, a discussion was conducted on the
regulatory aspects of biotechnology. In a communication of the Commission to the Council, the European Parliament and the Economic and
Social Committee explicit reference is made to the dialogue with the
biotech interests: `They will make further efforts, as they have in the
past, to conduct roundtable discussions' (COM (1992) 219 ®nal: 2).
According to statements by EU of®cials, however, the Commission does
not intend to institutionalize roundtable discussions. Thus, in 1996 the
Coordination Group renounced the `table talks' with interest organizations. Instead, a so-called `Trialogue' was held in March 1996, in which
the Council, the European Parliament and the Commission jointly
discussed how to proceed in light of the failed bio-patent Directive.
Interest groups are also contacted by the independent Group of
Advisers on the Ethical Implications of Biotechnology working for the
Commission since November 1991. In the mandated periods 1991±3
and 1994±6 the Ethics Group consisted of eight scientists, who provide
non-binding expert opinion regarding ethically controversial projects at
the request of EU sections. Chair of the group is Mrs NoeÈlle Lenoir,
chair of the UNESCO International Bioethics Committee. In the course
of their work, they also consult with representatives of industry. Beginning in 1998 the Ethics Group was integrated into the European Group
on Ethics in Sciences and New Technologies, which henceforth concerned itself with the ethical aspects of biotechnology as well as information technology.
Since 1995, Directorate General XII has included a Task Force on
Vaccines and Viral Diseases. This committee is authorized to coordinate
among agencies of the Commission that deal with vaccines and viruses
with respect to the development of industry projects in the Community.
The basis for this committee is Articles 130k, l, n of the Single
6
European Biotechnology Information Service, No. 4 ( July 1991).
238
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
European Act, which allows the European Union to work together with
individual member states in the ®eld of research. The task force has two
assignments: (1) to provide an overview of the research situation in
Europe; and (2) to elaborate a `research action plan' to improve the
position of European industry.
Figure 8.1 shows the different levels of dialogue between the Commission and the interest organizations. Above the thick dotted line are
located the committees and Directorates General of the European
Union that are directly involved with biotechnological questions. Below
the dotted line are the main organizations with biotech interests. On the
left and upper right side are the producers' associations and on the lower
right side the environmental organizations. It should be noted that in the
mid-1990s the of®ce of Friends of the Earth Europe worked for the
member organizations of CEAT, Greenpeace and the WWF at the same
time. On the upper right side is the umbrella organizations of environmentalists and scientists as well as EuropaBio, the new common federation of the Senior Advisory Group Biotechnology and the European
Secretariat of National Bioindustry Associations.
In addition to these formal connections, all organizations below the
thick dotted line have informal contacts with the listed Commission
committees. Thick lines denote especially close relationships between
committee members and/or members of interest organizations. Thus,
producer associations have close contact with the DG III (Internal
Market and Industrial Affairs) as well as with the European Biotechnology Coordination Committee.
Bio-industry interests ¯ow together even further in the formation of
the research programmes. Thus DG XII consults not only with independent scientists, but also with experts from industrial enterprises regarding the content of the research programme. There are of course
numerous issue-speci®c committees in the European Union in which
independent scientists examine the proposals for the research programme. However, these committees become involved only after the
directive of the research has already been initiated and exclusively
developed by scientists and associations (Tulder and Junne 1986;
Ridinger 1991). The body responsible for the biotechnology module in
the Framework Programmes is department E `Bioscience and Biotechnology' in DG XII. It is incumbent on the department to disseminate the programme documents, to appraise the project proposals and to
supervise the projects.
The central research policy committee, to which the representatives of
bio-industry have access, is the Industry Research and Development
Advisory Committee (IRDAC). This committee is convened by the
Biotechnology in the European Union
239
Figure 8.1 Dialogue committees of the Commission and interest
organizations
240
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
Commission. Its diverse teams debate the individual parts of the current
research programme and ultimately make a proposal regarding the
content of the programme to the cabinet of the Commissioner responsible for research, technology and development. Before the cabinet's
detailed proposal reaches the Council, the European Parliament and the
Economic and Social Committee, it will be evaluated by the Committee
of Experts of Science and Technology (CODEST), to which scientists
from public and private enterprises belong. The practice of the consultation process shows, however, that a cabinet proposal does not as a rule
encounter any serious opposition, although the budget proposed by the
Commission is often modi®ed by the Council.
A further possibility for contacts with responsible of®cials in DG XII
is afforded by the `industry platforms', that is, branch-speci®c events, at
which possible commercial applications of the results of the research are
demonstrated. Thus, since 1997 a Structural Biology Industrial Platform (not shown in ®g. 8.1) meets in members' companies or in
association with other events.
Current challenges: transregional enterprise alliances
and the lack of legitimacy
Although the recent report by EuropaBio (1997) and the reader by
Senker (1998) suggest that Europe's bio-industry has improved its
technological performance, European biotech producers still argue that
the efforts of the Commission are not suf®cient to increase their
competitiveness. Thus large ®rms, unlike the university institutes, have
been only moderately interested in offers of pre-competitive research.
This is not surprising, given that companies such as the large European
pharmaceuticals producers, for example, have suf®cient research capacities and would not want to relinquish their results to any potential
competitor. Also, European enterprises do not appear any more favourably disposed to inevitable cooperation with European rather than with
American or Japanese enterprises (see Tulder and Junne 1986; Junne
1992; Ohmae 1985; Esser 1993). Although the Commission is participating meanwhile in an EU±US task force for biotechnological research,
which conducted a workshop on `Methods of Communicating Biotechnology with the Public' in March 1992 and a conference on the
application of biotechnology to environmental protection in October
1994, now, as before, the idea of global competition between Europe,
the USA and Japan prevails in the Commission.
Nevertheless, one cannot overlook the fact that many `European
champions' have already formed numerous alliances with American and
Biotechnology in the European Union
241
Japanese enterprises while at the same time competing with other
European champions. According to Hagedoorn and Schakenraad
(1990: 177), of a total of 980 agreements signed in the ®eld of
biotechnology prior to 1988, 24 per cent (229) were between European
enterprises, 1 per cent (188) were between European and American
enterprises, and 3 per cent (30) were between European and Japanese
enterprises. This ®nding is corroborated by my network analysis of joint
ventures between the forty-®ve biotech enterprises, which are listed by
Hagedoorn and Schakenraad in the appendix of their article (p. 190).
Thus we can identify twenty-®ve groups of actors, all of whom directly
interact with each other (1-cliques; see Wasserman and Faust 1994:
253ff ), sharing at least three enterprises. However, only two of these
cliques include enterprises exclusively from EU member countries: (a)
Akzo Nobel (the Netherlands), Gist-Brocades (the Netherlands) and
Royal Dutch±Shell (the Netherlands/Great Britain), and (b) Bayer
(Germany), Hoechst (Germany) and Kabivitrum (Sweden). An additional clique includes RhoÃne-Poulenc (France), Royal Dutch±Shell and
Ciba-Geigy from non-EU Switzerland, while three cliques are purely
American and one is purely Japanese. In other words, eighteen of the
twenty-®ve cliques (72 percent) include enterprises from different continents.
A second challenge lies in massive public reservations about biotechnology policy. Despite costly public relations campaigns by the Commission, now as before a widespread scepticism regarding gene technology
processes and products prevails among the population of the member
countries. Meanwhile, according to Eurobarometer 1993, a majority are
in favour of the promotion of biotechnology and genetic engineering. A
more re®ned survey, however, shows that application of this technology
to livestock and the manufacture of foods is opposed by the majority,
just as it had been previously (Seifert and Torgersen 1996). The
scepticism among the population is the result not of a lack of knowledge,
as the Commission and bio-industry like to assume, but rather of better
knowledge about biotechnological processes. Thus, the Eurobarometer
investigations show that the well-informed Danes, Dutch and Germans
demand strict state controls over biotechnology and genetic engineering,
when compared with the poorly informed Spaniards, Portuguese and
Austrians.
Doubts are also expressed about the rationale of the research
programmes. The subsidizing of the programmes by private enterprises
through their research contributions undermines the competition policy
of the EU (Starbatty and Vetterlein 1990; Sturm 1992). Indeed, the
programmes support ± although not as blatantly as in the 1980s ± the
242
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
so-called `European champions'. At the end of 1995, the audit division
of the European Union issued a complaint that evaluators of the projects
are at the same time laying claim to project monies (Neue ZuÈrcher
Zeitung, 6 December 1995). Enterprises from large countries also pro®t
disproportionately. Thus the research programme serves to cement the
North±South technological cleavage ( Junne 1992).
The massive public reservations about the European Union's biotechnology policy cannot be eliminated simply by costly `information campaigns'. Rather, the Commission needs to orient itself to the proposals
of its groupe de re¯eÂxion (CEU 1995b) and make the committee work of
the Commission more transparent, formalizing it and giving critical
voices more of an audience. In fact, European interest groups are still
primarily dependent on informal contacts with EU of®cials, particularly
with respect to sponsoring their efforts, and for procuring (a) information about planned projects and committees; and (b) access to the
relevant committees. This demand for a democratization of policy
formation is not new. In the early 1980s, the Economic and Social
Committee and the European Parliament complained about the lack of
transparency of the Commission's work (e.g. the selection of experts,
the process of discussions). In 1985, the `Boserup Report' of the
European Parliament reminded the Commission that, according to the
Treaty of Rome, it was not the expert committees but rather the
Economic and Social Committee that was envisioned as the organ for
the representation of economic interests. The report further criticized
(a) the absence of clearness and transparency with regard to the
consultation activities of the Commission; (b) the fact that the Commission embodied no effective mechanisms and centralized control systems
for its committee activities; and (c) that the consultation process in large
measure has assumed an autonomous character and can no longer
simply be described as having occurred somehow under the care of the
Commission.
Owing to the process of co-decision-making, the European Parliament still has the possibility in the meantime to block the Commission's
proposals. If, for example, it was impossible in the 1980s for the
environmental organizations to inform themselves about impending
biotechnological projects of the Commission through the individual
Directorates General and thereafter to seek seats on the relevant
advisory bodies, today they can attempt to block the proposals of the
Commission through lobbying the Parliament and the national ministries of environment. Thus critics of genetic engineering were able to
celebrate their ®rst successes, namely the rejection of the bio-patent
Directive on its third reading and the de facto moratorium on the
Biotechnology in the European Union
243
approval of genetically manipulated organisms. So that such debacles do
not recur, the Commission must incorporate environmental organizations more fully in the process of policy formation, whether it likes it or
not.
The chronology of events presented above shows that from the early
1980s the Commission proceeded on the assumption that biotechnology
and genetic engineering would advance to become the growth industry
of the twenty-®rst century. In addition, the Commission assumed that
European bio-industry displayed a technological backwardness compared with the USA and Japan, and acted (in line with Bornschier's
argument) as a political entrepreneur for the creation of an industryfriendly legal environment and research programmes. Moreover, the
Commission actively promoted a positive image of genetic engineering
and bio-industry and expanded the dialogue with its leading organizations. From this perspective it can be understood why the criticism of
the leading employers' organizations has been moderate up to now. The
positive outlook of the responsible Commissioners is unanimously
appreciated.
Looking to the future, it is apparent that the dialogue between the
biotechnology producers and the Commission will have different focal
points from that between the producers of information technology and
the Commission. In particular, the large chemical and pharmaceutical
®rms, in light of their transregional alliances with primarily smaller,
specialized research ®rms, will not be enthusiastic about `research
corporatism' aÁ la Esprit. Of far greater interest to the biotechnology
®rms is the dialogue concerning directives and regulations regarding
genetic technology research and production; this concern is already
re¯ected by the public relations work of the European Union in favour
of genetic technology. Brie¯y stated, the interests of the biotechnology
®rms are substantially different from those of the information technology ®rms. Correspondingly, in their dialogue with the Commission,
it is not questions of research policy or programmes that are of primary
interest to biotechnology ®rms, but rather the development of an
industry-friendly regulatory framework based on the American model.
9
European integration after the Single Act:
changing and persisting patterns
Patrick Ziltener
Introduction
With and through the integration thrust of the 1980s, a qualitative
change in the interaction between economic and political actors has
developed in Western Europe. The Single European Act, now more
than a dozen years in force, marks the beginning of this process. The
massive underestimation of the meaning of the Single Act on the part of
most observers as well as actors involved in the integration process
remains nothing less than astounding. In retrospect, the assessment of
the actors who understood the Single Act as the ®rst result of a farreaching dynamic has been con®rmed. This is true on the economic
level, where a fundamental structural change was set in motion in
anticipation of the internal market, as well as on the political level. First,
elements of integration projects that had been set aside were put back on
the agenda in the 1980s, in particular the project of a European
monetary union, which became the core of the next policy package, the
Maastricht Treaty. The political dynamic after 1986 can also be traced
back to changes in the decision-making process at European level that
were effected through the Single European Act, especially the further
erosion of the `veto culture'. In addition, the Commission was able to
develop and maintain a strong, proactive role in many areas. Along with
this came successive expansions of the circle of involved political actors.
The new transnational forms of cooperation, without which the new
integration dynamic cannot be explained, developed further. This did
not lead to an end of the central position of the individual roundtables of
industrialists in Brussels, but they increasingly became one voice among
others. In sum, our analyses con®rm that a more and more complex
multi-level political system1 has developed in Western Europe.
1
A concept that an increasing number of integration researchers tend to use; see the
in¯uential essay by Scharpf (1994), Jachtenfuchs and Kohler-Koch (1996) and the
volumes edited by Marks et al. (1996), Hooghe (1996) and KoÈnig, Rieger and Schmitt
(1996).
244
European integration after the Single Act
245
Not all actors were equally successful, and not all policy areas became
`Europeanized' to the same extent. For many observers, the European
integration process still has a certain bias. It poses the question of the
future design of `statehood in Europe', especially its welfare state
elements, which have barely been incorporated by the political integration dynamic up to now. The elite pact between transnational and
supranational actors, which for us is the prominent element in our
explanation of the integration thrust of the 1980s, was the result of
speci®c historical conditions. It would therefore be incorrect to elaborate
a general theory of integration based on this phenomenon.
The effects of the Single European Act and the
continuing integration dynamic
The internal market as project and reality
Between 1985 and 1990, a process of economic adaptation occurred in
anticipation of the internal market in Western Europe. Investment in the
EC grew at a rate of 5.2 percent, clearly surpassing the 3 per cent
growth rate of GDP.2 Mergers and acquisitions within the EC increased
enormously (see Windolf 1993). Moreover, the project produced economic stimuli and served as a strong magnet for foreign investments,
especially from countries of the European Free Trade Association
(EFTA). The EC's proposal to create a European Economic Area
(EEA) represented an attempt to extend the internal market to the
territory of the EFTA nations. Negotiations got under way in 1990 and
led to the signing, on 22 October 1991, of a corresponding treaty, which
like the internal market was to take effect on 1 January 1993.
In light of these effects of the internal market project and the public
attention given to it, which the Commission cleverly promoted, farreaching changes also occurred in the political landscape of Western
Europe. In the EFTA nations in particular, joining the EC increasingly
became understood as something unavoidable. For these predominantly
social democratic governments, the new levels of integration and membership in the EC were ®nally accepted as prerequisites for political
action when the social dimension was placed on the agenda during 1988
(see chapter 6). The European Economic Area initiative was also used
by the EC for shielding the political dynamic within the Community
from a new round of expansion. Deepening integration had ®rst priority.
Alas, the ominous deadline that was linked with the internal market
2
According to Union Bank of Switzerland, Wirtschaftsnotizen, Nov./Dec. 1991.
246
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
project could not be kept. The delays in translating the White Paper into
action were less the work of the Commission than of the Council, as well
as the slow process of the adaptation and translation of its measures into
national law by the member states. A de®cit in actually executing the
project exists in all member states, although to considerably varying
degrees. The ®rst day of the year 1993 was nevertheless celebrated as
the `birthday' of the internal market, although it was overshadowed by
the post-Maastricht crisis. At the Amsterdam summit of July 1997, the
concluding session of the intergovernmental conference approved what
was probably the last Action Plan for Completing the Internal Market.
In 1993, in its White Paper on Growth, Competitiveness, Employment
(CEU 1993: 3), the Commission drew up the following balance sheet
under the title `The 1992 Objectives: A Tangible Reality':
(1) 9 million jobs created between 1986 and 1990;
(2) 0.5 per cent extra growth each year;
(3) a 3 per cent saving on the costs of international transport;
(4) investment up by one third between 1985 and 1990;
(5) three times more company mergers and acquisitions in the Community over the period in question;
(6) twice the number of European companies involved in mergers and
acquisitions in the rest of the world;
(7) a doubling of trade in the Community in sectors previously regarded
as sheltered from competition;
(8) 70 million customs documents done away with.
The continuing integration dynamic: the monetary union project
An important part of the continuing integration dynamic of the 1980s
can be traced back to the efforts of different actors belatedly to develop
a `social dimension', which had initially largely failed in the Single Act
(chapter 6). However, this did not become the centrepiece of the next
policy package; that role was played by the economic and monetary
union (EMU) project. Some actors saw monetary union as a logical
extension of the realization of the internal market; it was the cornerstone
of their integration project from the outset. In this category we would
include, in addition to the Commission, countries such as France3 and
Belgium; in fact both were dominated by German monetary policy,
without being able to really in¯uence it. Indeed, monetary policy
3
See SecreÂtariat d'Etat aupreÁs du Premier Ministre and Commissariat GeÂneÂral du Plan
(1983): ch. 3. This report sees the strengthening of the `monetary identity of Europe' as
an absolutely essential part of concerted macroeconomic regulation at the European
level. The establishment of an EMU was described at the time as a `pipe dream'. The
European integration after the Single Act
247
proposals were among the most controversial at the intergovernmental
conference of 1985; proportionally speaking, monetary policy content
in the Single Act was minimal, although strategically important (see
chapter 2, p. 68).
The monetary union project as such is older, having been a Community goal since 1969. The establishment of the European Monetary
System envisaged a monetary union. The central motive for a European
currency at the time, namely to provide a regional answer to world
monetary instability, was no longer as prominent in the second half of
the 1980s. The long phase of stability of the European Monetary
System had begun in 1987, after ®nal realignments; until 1991, it
functioned as a true ®xed-rate system. This was an expression of
sustained economic convergence in Western Europe. These factors
formed the background to the negotiations that led to the Maastricht
Treaty (see KraÈgenau and Wetter 1994: 68f ).
Following a once successful method, in 1987 EC corporate of®cials
founded the Association for Monetary Union to lobby for a European
monetary union. Its leaders came from such companies as Philips,
SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale de Belgique, Fiat, Total-CFP, RhoÃne-Poulenc and
Agfa-Gevaert. The smaller Committee for the Monetary Union of
Europe, chaired jointly by ValeÂry Giscard d'Estaing and Helmut
Schmidt, was founded in late 1986 and brought together government
of®cials, industrialists and bankers (including a Deutsche Bank
chairman) to push EC governments toward monetary union (Sandholtz
1993: 24). It is dif®cult to assess the in¯uence of these groups. In any
case, the development of the monetary union project cannot simply be
seen as being parallel to the internal market project; the weight of
`political' motives (in the narrower sense of the term) was clearly greater
than that of the `economic' ones. However, at the Hanover summit in
June 1988, the heads of state and government reaf®rmed the goal of a
monetary union. A committee under the leadership of Delors was
created to examine and develop concrete steps toward the realization of
a monetary union.4
It is historically incorrect to describe the change in the German
government's position as the `price' of German reuni®cation.5 The
4
5
centrepiece of the report's proposals was the establishment of a European monetary
fund.
It consisted of the central bank presidents of the member states, the general director of
the Bank for International Settlements, Alexandre Lamfalussy, as well as other experts.
The committee's task was not to discuss the goal of a monetary union as such but only
to submit a plan for attaining one.
For a (self-)description of the role of the German foreign secretary, see Genscher (1995:
387). He justi®es the initiative on the basis of the necessary and desirable (further)
248
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
so-called Genscher Memorandum of February 1988 had already advocated the creation of a European monetary area and a European central
bank. According to the memorandum, a monetary union was no longer
the ®nal stage or `coronation' of economic convergence (the previous
of®cial position) but a necessary catalyst for it. The change in the
German federal government's position might have taken place in the fall
or winter of 1987, after the approval of the Single Act, when the
implementation of the internal market was secured. In April 1988, the
German Christian democratic party (CDU) and the German Social
Democratic Party (SPD) voiced their approval of a European monetary
union. Economic policy circles in Germany, especially the Bundesbank,
were openly sceptical about a monetary union. They would be won over
to it only if the European central bank were to represent a superelevation of the Bundesbank, that is, make absolute the principles
underlying its policy.
Although two separate, parallel intergovernmental conferences (one
on the monetary union and one on the political union) prepared for
`Maastricht', it was one policy package.6 The core of the package was the
German `yes' to the monetary union (and with it the surrender of the
Deutsche Mark) and a solid timetable for it. The German conditions ±
the anchoring of an absolute policy orientation towards monetary
stability, the independence of the European central bank and the socalled convergence criteria as well as a (albeit minimal) strengthening of
the political dimension (the rights of the European Parliament) ± were
ful®lled. The (heterogeneous) policy package was supplemented in
Maastricht with another reinforcement of the cohesion policy and the
deepening of intergovernmental political cooperation (common foreign
and security policy, cooperation in the ®elds of justice and domestic
affairs).
The Luxembourg Compromise ± requiescat in pace?
In the recent literature, the Single Act's main effect is nearly unanimously said to be the overcoming of the Luxembourg Compromise.
The Commission's secretary-general NoeÈl (1987), pointed out that the
6
development of European integration, which increasingly inserted itself into a predictable East±West rapprochement. The prospect of German reuni®cation allowed the
pressure by France and Italy to increase, which clearly greatly accelerated the process.
See Stavenhagen (1991), Lipp and Reichert (1991), Doutriaux (1992), Artis (1992),
Corbett (1992), KraÈgenau and Wetter (1993) and Ross (1995a) on the Maastricht
negotiations. See in particular the collection of documents and analyses of the
intergovernmental conference on the political union in Laursen and Vanhoonacker
(1992).
European integration after the Single Act
249
Luxembourg Compromise was not included in the negotiations regarding the Single European Act; the latter makes no reference to it at
all. However, he did express his hope at the time that majority decisions
could eventually be enforced `whenever necessary and desirable'. In his
in¯uential critique of the Act, Pescatore (1986), a former judge at the
European Court of Justice, emphasized that the most important unanimity clauses not only would remain untouched but would even be
strengthened, especially with respect to the free movement of persons,
rights of employees, ®scal harmonization and economic and monetary
policy. For the ®rst time, this represented the embodiment of the partial
veto power of individual governments.
In the opinion of the British government, the Luxembourg Compromise was still valid after the adoption of the Single Act, as it stated in its
reports to the House of Commons.7 The British Foreign Affairs Committee, however, was very sceptical about whether the Luxembourg
Compromise was still intact.
The fear that the member states would continue to assert `vital
national interests' under the Luxembourg Compromise or that regulations similarly based on the mutual acceptance of such interests would
emerge was not con®rmed in the following years. Instead, a number of
cases have shown that the member states prefer to go to the European
Court of Justice and ®le a suit against the legal basis of a decision rather
than to assert `vital interests' during negotiations in the Council. Nevertheless, many decisions were still decided unanimously, whereas the
pressure exerted by the threat of a majority vote did lead to an increased
willingness to consent (Engel and Borrmann 1991: 262). Teasdale
(1993) also concludes that the Luxembourg Compromise actually
disappeared in the course of the 1980s, even though some governments
still refer to it, and that it no longer has any signi®cant bearing on the
way the Community functions. The `veto culture' has even been eroded
in areas that are not formally covered by the quali®ed majority principle.
In actual fact, since that time there has been only one attempt by a
member state to refer to the Luxembourg Compromise. In 1988 the
Greek government asserted its `vital national interest' when ®ghting
against a decision concerning the agricultural price system. However,
the other member states did not accept this, and the Greek government,
completely isolated, gave way.
7
See especially `The Single European Act: Observations by the Government' (Third
Report from the Foreign Affairs Committee, Session 1985±86, Cmnd. 9858); see also
Howe (1994: 458).
250
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
Beyond intergovernmentalism
The most important argument against neorealism is that `national interests' are increasingly being de®ned within the EU context. Membership
in the EU has become part of the interest calculation for governments
(and other actors). Even in non-integrated areas, the power of the
nation-state is more and more restricted and embedded in a tight
network of legal and institutional regulations owing to its EU membership. Economic integration, as well as political and legal integration, at
least of the EU's core, have reached a vast extent that meanwhile can
hardly be revised anymore (see Cameron 1992: 36ff ). Therefore, the
question of maintaining national sovereignty, which is emphasized by
neorealism, has different implications for EU members. The fact that
giving up (formal) national sovereignty is seen as a chance to regain real
sovereignty, at least partially, is only seemingly a paradox. It is the only
explanation for the French pressure towards a monetary union, for
example. German foreign policy is governed by historically caused
restrictions that at least partially oppose neorealist assumptions. The
analysis of such historically determined `structural conditions' is decisive
for understanding integration projects.
Moravcsik (1991: 42; see also 1998: 365) interprets the Single Act
negotiations in accordance with the three basic principles of his approach (intergovernmentalism, lowest-common-denominator bargaining, protection of sovereignty) as a `process of limiting the scope
and intensity of reform ± a process necessary to gain the acceptance not
only of Britain but also of other member states who, when it came to
drafting a document, suddenly proved quite jealous of their sovereignty.
The maximalist programme of broad reform was progressively sacri®ced
in favour of the minimalist programme limited to those procedural and
substantive changes needed to liberalize the internal market.' From our
point of view, it is more sensible to interpret the Single Act as a
compromise between different integration projects of (admittedly unequally strong) national, transnational and supranational actors than to
compare it to a hypothetical `maximalist programme'. It is also not clear
which project corresponds with or is equivalent to this `maximalist
programme': the project of the Commission or the project of the
federalists? Moreover, the lowest common denominator as a result
would have been the implementation of the Single Market project
through an agreement without institutional reform, practically a
European GATT, as proposed by the British government. The Single
Act already encompassed two core areas with elements of supranationality: the internal market and technology corporatism; the ex-
European integration after the Single Act
251
panded integration process after 1986 addressed the many areas in
which `strategic postponing' had taken place. A remarkable feature of
the Act is that it is also the consequence of the integration projects of
many national governments, which were prepared to transcend the
actual result and thus give up (formal) sovereignty. The erosion of the
`veto culture' after the Single Act con®rms that the vast majority of
national governments were ready for a new political praxis at European
level.
Repercussions on the political systems of the member states
The decline of the Luxembourg Compromise had repercussions on the
domestic politics of the member states. As a consequence, the focal
point of the lobbying by interest groups has changed. It no longer
suf®ces to put one's `own' government under pressure in order to
prevent an undesirable decision by means of its veto power in Brussels.
This now requires a transnationally coordinated campaign in several
countries. The incentive to undertake (supranational) lobbying in Brussels has also increased.
With majority voting in the Council, the possibility of determining
political accountability has been removed; the possibilities for individual
governments to justify decisions made in Brussels that have unpleasant
consequences for domestic politics have increased. There are reasons
one might describe the national governments and bureaucracies as in
fact intrastate winners in the integration process, rather than as losers,
although they are commonly characterized as losers, usually with reference to the supranationalization of policy areas. This effect is reinforced
by the fact that there is no comparable parliamentary control of the
Council at the European level. The former president of the European
Parliament called the integration process `an intrastate shifting of
authority': the national parliaments lost essential possibilities for in¯uence and initiative, while the national governments won the right to
create European legislation (HaÈnsch 1989: 218).
From the point of view of Europe's nation-states, European integration itself represents a complex process, one that includes the partial
replacement (supranationalization) of what are perceived as functions of
the national state, and the partial abolition, restriction and insidious
undermining of these functions or their gentle transformation through
incentives. In many respects, the process also represents the competitive
articulation of these functions with other levels and areas of government,
as well as with other mixed state±private sector committees or completely private organizations (see Ziltener 1999).
252
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
The underlying trend of this process is development in the direction
of what has been described as the `Schumpeterian workfare state'
( Jessop 1995) or the `competition state' (Wettbewerbsstaat, Hirsch
1995). In this sense, a process of convergence of state forms and
regulation is taking place in Europe. Convergence under these conditions, however, signi®es the implementation of the logic of spatial
competition, and consequently the fragmentation and differentiation of
spaces within the societal whole.
There is a great deal of evidence that national political elites use the
European level in the implementation of projects that are domestically
dif®cult or impossible to implement. In some of these efforts, argumentation based on the `practical constraint of Europe' can be constructed
without being conditioned on the particular case or interests involved.
However, there is often a traceable strategic calculation that in effect
incorporates the European level. This applies in particular to cases in
which national governments and/or big business pursuing their own
projects are confronted with strong, well-elaborated, balanced political
arrangements of a corporatist nature and/or with predominantly negative public opinion. Insofar as formal and/or actual regulatory authority
is removed from the national parliaments and interest mediation
systems (as a result of negotiations among national governments and
transnational and supranational actors), the resistance of interest groups
established in the previous systems of regulation is overcome at a
national level. The argument also applies to the case in which a certain
government ®nds itself in a situation in which it `must' contravene the
articulated interests of its own clientele.
Actors and alliances evaluated
A central ®nding of our analyses of the dynamic of European integration
in the 1980s is that the reality of the political processes at the European
level, despite the still dominant position of the Council, cannot be
reduced to an intergovernmentalist explanatory model. In some policy
areas, the central initiatives can be traced back to non-governmental
actors, while in others the number of actors involved expanded in the
course of or as a result of the thrust toward integration. In many areas,
non-governmental actors, especially the roundtables of high-ranking
representatives of large European ®rms, and the supranational bodies,
in particular the Commission, played an important role.
In what follows we take a somewhat broader view of these two groups
of actors, which were central for forging the European elite pact. The
fact that we concentrate on these does not mean that they were the only
European integration after the Single Act
253
important actors or that the integration thrust can be explained in toto
by looking at the interactions of these two alone. From our point of
view, this is justi®ed by the fact that these new forms of cooperation
constitute what is new and particular about this stage of integration.
The Delors Commission as political entrepreneur
The analyses in this volume unequivocally indicate that the Commission
was the most important supranational body in the integration relaunch.
This is not surprising if we compare the role of other supranational
institutions, such as the European Parliament, whose role we assess as
marginal, or the European Court of Justice, although its rulings were
very signi®cant for certain policy areas (e.g. the Cassis de Dijon decision
for the internal market project or the judgments regarding the social
dimension). It should be emphasized that here we can speak accurately
of an actual rebirth of the EC Commission as both a prerequisite for and
a consequence of the push for integration in the 1980s (chapter 2,
pp. 52ff ). The impact of the Commission on the process leading to the
Single Act and beyond ± especially with regard to initiating projects,
mediating and mobilizing actors ± has to be admitted even from a
neorealist point of view, as in Moravcsik's (1998) recent contribution.
All our interviewees emphasized the strength and leadership function
of the Delors Commission. The unanimous assessments of the Committee of Permanent Representatives (COREPER) members were especially informative in this regard, since they are independent of the
Commission but at the same time very directly affected by its activity.
The Delors Commission is often compared with the ®rst Commission
under Walter Hallstein (who held of®ce from 1958 to 1967). One of the
founding fathers of integration theory, Ernst B. Haas (1964: 87ff ),
de®ned three critical determinants of effective supranational leadership
in his account of its successful activity: (1) the de®nition of an `organizational ideology' (priority goals, strategy); (2) a bureaucracy that is
committed to this ideology (`cohesive and loyal staff'); and (3) supporting coalitions and alliances among individuals, groups and organizations in the members' national systems, organized around the ideology
and the speci®c action proposals of the supranational leadership.
The `Delorist leadership system' (Ross 1995a: 158ff ) successfully
connected these elements. In comparison with the Hallstein Commission, however, the Commission formed in 1984 was saddled with other
less favourable conditions at its inception. The Hallstein Commission
faced a newly formulated founding treaty with clearly de®ned roles for
the supranational organs. The Delors Commission, on the other hand,
254
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
had ®rst to recapture the space for its praxis (see Ehlermann 1988: 58)
while simultaneously partially reorganizing the bureaucracy. To put it
another way, the wheels of the train had to be changed while it was still
moving. The counter-argument ± that conditions also did not favour its
predecessor's construction of a bureaucracy ± is only partially right. The
available resources may have been fewer at the beginning, but the unity
of the bureaucracy and thus the possibilities for its instrumental use
were disproportionately greater.
The activity of the Delors Commission was overlaid by the `heritage'
of earlier years, which again and again hindered its initiative and
impeded the opening of new areas of activity. The budgetary problems
and the question of the member states' contributions are examples of
this, which were resolved in a compromise within the Delors Package
of 1988 (chapter 5, pp. 142f ) Nevertheless, the Commission was able
unequivocally to strengthen its position as `ruler of the process' in the
course of the 1980s, as shown in this volume for several policy areas. As
a consequence, a new, intensi®ed network relationship developed
between the Community organs.8
The Delors Commission, building on the activity of the previous
Commissions, demonstrated particular skill with respect to assembling
supporting coalitions and alliances. This pertains speci®cally to the
support of transnational interest groups, from the various roundtables of
industrial interests to the trade unions. We have reviewed how this
process (a mixture of push and pull elements) developed in certain
areas, and indicated how it may be understood theoretically in terms of
the supply of and demand for order (see chapter 1). In addition, one
must also keep in mind that the integration thrust would hardly have
been possible without the excellent relationships between the Delors
Commission and political actors at the national level and in the national
administrations.
The (continued) pact with the European transnational business elite
The area of research and technology policy was actually the ®rst in
which a qualitative breakthrough in forms of transnational cooperation
took place; this occurred some time prior to the Single Act and even
before the actual `take-off ' phase of the integration thrust in 1984.
The research ®ndings from the areas of information technology (and
biotechnology) presented in this volume con®rm the important role of
the Commission and how successfully it took the initiative.
8
See the particularly detailed and informative account by Engel and Borrmann (1991)
and the contributions in Engel and Wessels (1992).
European integration after the Single Act
255
The origins of the initiatives in the information technology area can
be traced to the late 1970s and are closely connected with the name of
Commissioner Etienne Davignon (chapters 1 and 4). The Esprit programme that was approved in 1984 not only was the ®rst result of these
efforts, but has also served decisively as the `¯agship' of the entire
European research and development policy since then (see Grande and
HaÈusler 1994). In particular, through this programme, cooperation
between the Commission and a roundtable ± the European Information
Technology Industry Roundtable (EITIRT) ± was institutionalized for
the ®rst time. This new form of cooperation proved very successful and
thus became the strategic model for many other projects of the Commission. With regard to the further development of this European technology corporatism, we must note that there are indications that the
former clearly dominant position of the EITIRT has rather weakened in
the course of the past ten years primarily owing to the proliferation of
voices in Brussels and the intent of the Commission to include more
interests (chapter 4). In general we can say that there has been a
perceptible expansion of these forms of cooperation.
In the area of biotechnology the Commission has also tried from the
beginning to channel interests by means of the formation of European
umbrella organizations. However, this proved to be dif®cult in light of
the low degree of centralization among the corresponding interest
groups and thus the absence of any `internal' method of interest mediation. Nevertheless, the lobbyists and technical experts of big business
successfully in¯uence policy formulation in the advisory bodies of the
Commission (chapter 8).
The European Roundtable of Industrialists (ERT), whose initiative
was the crucial weight behind the creation of a European Single Market
(chapter 3), is still one of the most in¯uential interest organizations at
European level, as also stressed by Green Cowles (1997: 131): `the most
powerful industrial coalition in Brussels.' It has successfully expanded its
base (numbers, range and reciprocal interconnection of the represented
businesses; chapter 7) and the scope of its activities and still has at its
disposal the most important avenues of in¯uence. Of particular importance is the newly created Competitiveness Advisory Group, whose
duties are connected with the argumentation regarding general industrial
policy and competitiveness in the `Europe 1990' paper (Dekker 1984,
1985b) and the White Paper of 1985 (CEC 1985). That said, we must
add that it is also true that, with the increased number of European actors
in the political landscape, the ERT's weight has also diminished somewhat in relative terms. The ERT as well as the other roundtables suffered
not so much a decrease in centrality but rather a loss in exclusiveness.
256
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
The increasing signi®cance of these more direct political interventions
on the part of big business, without taking the `detour' through the
corresponding umbrella organizations, is also detectable at the national
level. This is especially effective at the European level, since, with the
exception of some speci®c areas (agricultural policy), there are still no
strong umbrella organizations and no system for the mediation of interests that one could describe as corporatist (see Streeck and Schmitter
1991). At the same time, it is also true that lobbyists pro®t from the fact
that the comparatively weak resource base of the Brussels state
apparatus makes it dependent on external expertise. The large
European ®rms systematically and successfully take advantage of the
speci®cs of the supranational level within the European multi-level
system. In two policy areas ± information technology and biotechnology
± the efforts of the Commission are currently aimed at overcoming its all
too exclusive cooperation with the roundtables of leading European
®rms. It is dif®cult to judge to what extent this can be attributed to an
increasingly critical attitude of the public with respect to a one-sided
`Europe of big business' and thus can be described as a reaction by the
Commission to its legitimation problems. However, the thesis that these
new forms of cooperation might represent only a short-term and limited
transition phase on the road to an extensive corporatist European interest mediation system based on the model of the national political
systems of the postwar era seems to us implausible.
A new social compromise at European level?
A Commission without strong allies
The Commission did not have comparably strong allies at its disposal
when it came to certain projects beyond the realization of a single
market or European technology policy. Where there was no strong
economic and political `demand' for supranational regulations, the
Commission tried on its own to obtain these in the interest of the
enforcement of its overall integration project. The most obvious
example of this was social policy, when Delors tried to arouse the public
and possible allies in the summer of 1988. In areas of inferior `demand'
or relatively weak actors, the Commission was clearly less successful.
From the point of view of the Commission's project, the balance sheet
with respect to social policy and the coordination of economic policy is
mixed. The path to harmonization of political regulations at the
European level ran into too much resistance, except for a few areas such
as occupational health and safety.
European integration after the Single Act
257
Generally speaking, most of the integration research emphasizes
the predominance of market-creating as opposed to market-correcting
measures. In many areas, there is in fact a `competition of (national)
systems', which does not correspond to the concept of an espace europeÂen
organise as advanced by Delors at the beginning of 1985 (chapter 2,
pp. 54ff, chapter 6, pp. 163ff ).
From the point of view of the Commission, the balance sheet for the
second central dimension of the `cohesion target' that was envisioned
from the inception of the integration thrust ± the extension and
rebuilding of regional balance ± is clearly more positive. EC regional
policy was not only provided with more resources; it became elaborated
in the direction of a supranational mode of regulation. The functions of
the Commission were strengthened and a greater variety of actors were
drawn into the process.
On the one hand, the reasons for the varying degrees of success in
these two policy areas are due to their political nature (deep-seated
divergences of interests among the involved actors and differences with
respect to their ability to block the integration process). On the other
hand, they also have a deeper structural dimension, namely the divergences between the West European societies and nation-states as well as
the basic institutional structure of the EC. With respect to the latter, we
refer not only to the imbalance among the European institutions (for the
debate on the democracy de®cit, see chapter 10, pp. 266f ) but also to a
dramatic inequality among the political actors regarding the `utility' of
the European level for their projects.
Thus, the trade unions, for example, despite the efforts of the Delors
Commission to the contrary, are without a doubt still holding the short
straw. While the competitive articulation of national regulations promotes a deregulatory dynamic, pro-active efforts aimed at re-regulation
quickly come to a standstill in the face of polymorphous EC decisionmaking. The unions have much to fear from the `regulation gap'
between insuf®cient EU regulatory authority and the national governments, which are increasingly under pressure. In this light, actors who
are not interested in social policy integration can easily pursue a reactive
strategy.
But the weaknesses of the unions at European level can also be traced
back to `internal' problems resulting from variability in the traditional
con¯ict structures in the member states, patterns of social mobilization
and forms of internal mediation of interests. Furthermore, the varying
degrees to which industrial relations are regulated, the variety of trade
union and political party goals, alliances and resources of power in the
different member states also contribute to the resulting relative weakness
258
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
(see Ebbinghaus and Visser 1994). The same applies to social movements, which still ®nd the logic of in¯uence in Brussels heavy going.
Generally speaking, one can say that the new style of integration, as
developed from the integration thrust of the 1980s, favours the heavyweights, that is, the organizations of particular interests that are not
burdened by lengthy internal processes for mediating multiple interests.
The `slow' representative organizations and movement-based actors, as
well as diffuse general interests that are dif®cult to organize, are
discriminated against.
Legitimation without welfare?
For many theories of the state, the legitimacy of state order is connected
with the organization of social security and relative social balance
between the classes in society. In view of the far-reaching absence of
such elements at European level and the simultaneously relatively
successful construction of a European regional policy, the question is
posed: Is this a substitute for or indeed `the' social policy of the EU?
Only in a limited sense can regional policy be equated with social
policy. On the one hand, it contributes to the equalization of life
chances. However, it is not a substitute for regulatory harmonization,
nor does it provide claims to payments (entitlements based on citizenship) on the part of individuals or regions. Rather, regional policy is
concerned with the promotion of infrastructural investments and an
opening of regions, from which the entire European economic area
potentially pro®ts.
In one respect, there is an important `compensatory' connection
between the absence of harmonization and ®nancial balance. The
cohesion payments to countries with a low level of regulation have surely
contributed to the fact that these countries did not react to the intensi®ed competition from the core with a decrease in this level of regulation.
In this sense, the regional policy elements of the integration relaunch of
the 1980s have become the most signi®cant instruments for preempting any `race to the bottom' in labour standards and labour market
regulation. This made it possible, as Ross (1995b: 364) puts it, `to buy
backward EC regions into the ``European model of society'' '. Anderson
(1995b: 149) poses the question, `Why, at critical junctures in the
development of the EC, have member states and the Commission
selected this particular approach to uneven regional economic development over plausible entitlement-based social options?' and answers it
with three interrelated reasons. First, the structural funds insert themselves into the fundamental institutional characteristics and broader
European integration after the Single Act
259
aims of the EU, and, once in place, they have presented EU policymakers with pre-existing frameworks for interpretation and action.
Secondly, as a result, the costs of addressing the negative effects of
integration through the structural funds are lower in comparison with
new social policy approaches and programmes. Anderson ®nds a third
reason in the increasingly strong support networks at the national and
subnational levels, which support and even increase the demand for
such regional policy measures. The reasons named by Anderson correspond with our explanation of the differential success of the two policy
domains.
Whether regional policy payments will in fact prevent regulatory
competition in the long term is more than questionable. The middleand long-term effect of the fully realized internal market will reinforce
the temptations. What is more, it already appears that this competition
works even more strongly between the European core countries, for
example with business taxation. This fact, along with the monetary
union and the expansion of the EU to East Central Europe, will
inevitably raise anew the related questions about the basic regulatory
structure of the EU in the near future. The disputes over questions
regarding harmonization, competition and competitiveness will be
revived again, just as they were in 1987±8.
Will the EU itself at some point in the future become the institutional
centre of socially necessary welfare state functions in (Western) Europe?
Our research, like the vast majority of research on integration, suggests a
negative answer to this question.9 From this assessment, two evaluations
are possible: that the nation-state will continue to play the central role in
this area, or that this development points in the direction of a general
reduction of state functions in this area.
In the future, impulses toward the further development of the welfare
functions of the EU will also emanate from the Commission. Especially
important in this regard is its policy with respect to the expansion of the
circle of involved actors. In March 1996, about 1,000 representatives of
non-governmental organizations met for the ®rst time in Brussels with
the Commission. The `European Social Forum' aimed to broaden the
scope of interaction between the EU institutions and those actors
9
Streeck (1996) sketches the new form of governance under the concept of neovoluntarism: `Unlike neo-corporatism, where strong quasi-public organizations of social
groups are enabled by an interventionist public policy to negotiate and correct market
outcomes, neo-voluntarism returns allocational decisions to private actors in private
markets, with no possibility previously to readjust their political and organizational
resources' (Streeck 1996: 83; see also Lange 1992: 256). For Flora (1993) as well, a
European welfare state will be characterized by institutional fragmentation, subsidiarity
and parastatist organization.
260
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
involved at the grassroots level in the ®elds of economic and social
action and social cohesion (CEU 1996b). To what extent this policy will
be successful depends not only on the (momentary) constellation of
actors, but also quite pivotally on whether the contradictions that arise
from European integration itself are resolved in favour of the nationstate or in favour of `Europe'.
In this context, certain tendencies that result from a fully realized
internal market must be discussed. The increasing mobility of intraEuropean labour would have serious organizational consequences for
national welfare regimes (see Flora 1993; Guild 1999). Intensi®ed
locational competition forced by the internal market, displacements of
businesses on the basis of cost factors and regulatory competition will
not be readily accepted by the political publics in Europe: National
responses to these issues, however, would fragment the internal market
such that European solutions could conceivably appear as the cheaper
ones.
Much will also depend on the perception of the development of the
structure of social inequality. If in the future the distribution of the costs
and bene®ts of European integration is judged to be unequal, then
pressure will increase in favour of a European system as the guiding
mechanism of this distribution. The older neofunctionalist scholars
have already spoken on this matter;10 then as now the threat of the
alternative, namely a sudden shift to nationalist fragmentation, was not
suf®ciently taken into account.
These problems cannot be avoided, much less solved, through an
exclusive elite pact of the type previously described. Even if the initiatives always proceed from above ± `L'initiative vient toujours d'en haut!',
the conclusion reached by the politically sobered FreÂdeÂric Moreau in
Flaubert's Education sentimentale ± their results are sustainable in the
long term only if at the very least they do not destroy a minimum of
social cohesion.
The future of elite bargaining
In a certain sense, the situation in the mid-1980s was unique. The
surprisingly powerful capabilities of the alliance between transnational
companies and the Commission were based on a series of prerequisites:
10
See Schmitter's analysis of the tension-producing conditions of integration processes.
As `basic contradictions' he includes, among others, `uncertainty in regard to the
capacity to guarantee relative equality of perceived bene®ts once new productive and
distributive forces are unleashed (equity)' and `heightened sensitivity to the comparative performance of one's partners generated by higher transactions and available
information (envy)' (Schmitter 1971: 235f ).
European integration after the Single Act
261
(a) convergence of the policies of the national governments in Western
Europe after the failure of the ®nal attempt to revitalize the Keynesian
societal model; (b) the capacity for action of the political elites in the
context of the permissive consensus, that is, the widespread lack of
interest of the political publics in Western Europe in the negotiations at
European level; (c) the relative `shelteredness' of the European integration process with respect to world politics; and, last but not least, (d) the
coincidence of the integration thrust and a conjunctural economic
upswing phase.
These conditions have now changed extensively. First, the `shelteredness' of the elite bargain has for the most part dissolved. In the course of
the 1980s new economic and political actors whom the elite bargain had
largely bypassed now pushed their way into the negotiation system.
These included long-established Brussels business interest organizations, the European trade unions, the governments of the EFTA states
and subnational and non-governmental organizations. The inclusion of
these forces was welcomed, promoted and in some cases even initiated
by the Commission. However, in this way it was the Commission itself
that contributed to the undermining of the elite bargaining model that
was so successful in the 1980s.
That the national governments are still not ready to give up their
position as the strongest actors in the increasingly complex multi-level
political system is demonstrated by the negotiations at both the Maastricht and Amsterdam intergovernmental conferences. The Delors
Commission was increasingly restricted in its late phase, and the
approval of the successor to the Commission president was unambiguously intended to create a more `comfortable partner' for the national
governments.
The permissive consensus among the West European populations has
been eroded in the course of the post-Maastricht crisis. This is connected to the economic recession, and also to the fact that the populations were repeatedly asked to make adjustments that were justi®ed in
the name of `Europe'. Moreover, few have failed to notice that the
orientation of national policies toward the convergence criteria for
monetary union has deepened the economic recession. Widespread
opinion holds that the `fruits' of integration have thus far remained
elusive.
The external conditions have also changed. Throughout the 1980s,
the USA successfully exercised political pressure in alliance with the
traditionally free-trade-oriented European countries in such a way as
to connect the new integration thrust externally with steps toward
economic liberalization. The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
262
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
(GATT) negotiations continued parts of the Single Market liberalization
on a world scale. For many dossiers a close connection between these two
processes can be shown: a series of measures for the dismantling of nontariff and regulatory barriers to trade are to be found on both agendas.
In many cases the actions for completing the internal market served as
`test and laboratory cases for solving dif®cult liberalization tasks'
(Wegner 1991: 201, our translation) that existed in new areas such as
the liberalization of services, which were also being debated in GATT.
This strengthened the trend toward the completion of transatlantic
strategic alliances between companies, and, moreover, the inclusion of
Japanese ®rms in these alliances; the area of biotechnology illustrates
this. In this way, the meaning of the European level for transnational
business became relative.
As a result of the world political changes that accompanied the
collapse of the Soviet Union, new demands were placed on the
European institutions, which led to an obvious system overload. The
pressure for a rapid expansion of the European Union to the east was
increased by certain actors in order to hamper or at least slow down the
deepening of the integration process. In 1994, despite the accelerated
integration process, Delors noted in response to the question of the
basis for Europe's falling relatively behind: `The world has changed
more quickly than we.'11
The fact that the European elite pact, whose many facets we have
described in this volume, could come into effect only in the context of
speci®c historical conditions was clear to us from the outset. It was
never our intention to advance a general theory of integration that
would replace existing general theories. If we placed the elite pact
between transnational business and the supranational political entrepreneur at the centre of our analysis of the integration relaunch, this does
not signify that this alliance was also decisive for earlier (and later)
events in the long history of European integration. Although stressing
different conditions for successful political entrepreneurship, we agree
with Moravcsik (1998, 1999) that there was indeed a unique `window of
opportunity' for the alliance of supranational and transnational actors in
the 1980s. There are good arguments for his claim that `informal
entrepreneurs enjoy brief successes and long periods of failure'
(Moravcsik 1999: 285). Yet these `brief successes' can and did set the
course of economic and political trajectories.
For us, the point was to analyse what was qualitatively new in the
integration thrust of the 1980s and to show that this was the central
11
Delors in a TV interview, ARTE, 26 April 1994.
European integration after the Single Act
263
precondition for the integration relaunch and, therefore, for the development of a historically new multi-level political system in Europe. This
development is not complete, and the logic of the multi-level polity in
the 1990s was already quite different from that of the elite pact of the
1980s. The integration process provoked the transformation of the
relationship between politics and economics and of the meaning of
statehood in Europe, and continues to pose new theoretical questions.
Concluding remarks
The Amsterdam Treaty, the result of the intergovernmental conference
of 1996±7, is widely regarded as insuf®cient with respect to institutional
reform. It is plausible to think that the EU is heading for a situation in
which the gap between the de®ciencies of its ability to formulate policy
and the internal and external requirements for action becomes even
bigger.
There are a number of indications that the type of integration pursued
up to now has de®nitely reached its limit in view of new conditions; the
Amsterdam Treaty itself is evidence of this fact. A qualitatively new
dynamic can be expected only if the EU can be reshaped as a political
arena. But grand designs or even concrete projects aimed at the institutional reorganization of the EU are not on the agenda at the moment.
In any case, we think that there are good reasons to abandon the idea
of the EU as an `un®nished federal state', as it was seen by Hallstein
(1969), the ®rst Commission president. Moreover, some puzzling
elements of contemporary statehood at European level may be not of
a temporary nature but rather the central characteristics of a new
hegemonic form. As we suggest in chapter 10, this notion is based on a
new composition of tendencies in European history.
10
The state of the European Union
Volker Bornschier
What kind of state?
Having reassessed the integration thrust of the 1980s and the events that
it set in motion, we have summarized our ®ndings on the structure of
the policy areas that set the tone of the political economy of the Union.
We would now like to comment on the form of state that developed out
of this process. The curious nature of this state is widely acknowledged
by scholars; we would like to add that the puzzling nature of the
governance structures embodied in the institutions of the European
Union is due to a renewed compromise between two old European
processes ± nationalism and liberalism.
What exactly is `odd' about the form of state called the European
Union?
The European Union, which evolved from the renewed drive for
European integration in the mid-1980s and which of®cially assumed
this new name through the Treaty on European Union (agreed to at the
end of 1991 and in effect since the completion of its rati®cation in
1993), is something new in the recent history of European statebuilding. This new form of state remains, as we termed it in chapter 1, a
somewhat strange hermaphrodite ± something between a confederation
of states and a federal state. One important difference between the two
is that a federal state unites several states within the framework of a
single state in a single nation and is the exclusive subject of international
law. By contrast, a confederation of states does not constitute a subject
of international law on its own (Scholz 1995: 116f ). The latter is
formally the case of the EU insofar as its member states have remained
sovereign in terms of international law. But even de jure the status of the
EU is beyond a confederation, because the sovereignty that the member
states retain is substantially truncated by the self-binding treaties to
which they have agreed. Community law ± the acquis communautaire ± is
264
The state of the European Union
265
indeed supranational, binding all member states in the sense that the
regulation is directly applicable.
Yet, despite these ambiguities, the EU de facto represents a respected
and powerful actor on the international stage. For example, during the
renegotiations of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT),
which led to the foundation of the World Trade Organization (WTO),
the EU was an accepted party to the ®erce bargaining that took place
with the USA. Furthermore, the EU is regularly represented by the
president of the European Commission when the famous Group of
Seven gathers. Finally, `international politicians have added Brussels to
their itinerary when on world tours', as Beverly Springer (1996: 274)
puts it.
We used the metaphor of a hermaphrodite to indicate that conventional social science categories fail to come to terms with what the EU
actually is. This view is shared by scholars studying the nature of the
state in the European Union, regardless of their theoretical approach
(see, for example, MuÈnch 1993: 133±81). Klaus Dieter Wolf (1996: 3)
stated it concisely: `The governance structure embodied in the institutions of the European Union is of a puzzling nature, no matter which
theoretical perspective is applied to it.' Beverly Springer, re¯ecting
on the `March toward Monetary Integration', concluded that the EU
is neither an international organization nor a fully sovereign state:
`Attempts to compare it to a federal system, such as that of the United
States, are as ¯awed as attempts to compare it to the North American
Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA)' (1996: 274).
It was Raymond Vernon (1994, see Springer 1996: 273) who poetically decribed the European Union as `an historical aberration smuggled
into the family of nations'. Although poetic, this is an ultimately
inaccurate characterization. The European Union is indeed a strange
novelty when compared with other products of mainstream state formation, which culminated in the full establishment of nation-states in the
nineteenth century. But, in historical perspective, the EU represents
something that was rare but not uncommon in the history of European
state-building, and the EU has at least one very in¯uential and eminent
European forerunner, which we discuss below. However, in its present
form, the EU represents a reconciliation between two mighty European
forces that was seldom achieved in mainstream European development.
The compromise and its price
It is obvious that, for its member states, the EU restricts their sovereignty and preserves their jointly exercised sovereignty. Keohane and
266
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
Hoffmann (1991: 7f, 16f ) describe it aptly as the `pooling and sharing
of sovereignty' rather than the transfer of sovereignty to a higher level.
Indeed ± as all scholars of EU affairs acknowledge ± the Council of
Ministers and the European Council1 represent the real political power
in the EU. Member states wield ultimate authority through these
Councils: they negotiate and agree on treaties and their amendments,
extensions or modi®cations, which then become law in the European
Union.
In this context, Klaus Dieter Wolf (1996) has drawn our attention to
yet another puzzle. The member states ± normally very proud of the
democratic achievements and forms of political participation in their
respective nation-states ± obviously refuse to allow similarly strong
forms of democracy to develop at the level of the Union. They are the
only formally authorized actors who could jointly agree to let such forms
arise. Obviously, the nation-states do not want to do so or cannot do so
owing to restrictions placed upon them by their electorates.
This leads to what is commonly referred to as a de®cit of democracy
at the level of the EU (see, for example, Lepsius 1991; Bach 1999;
Buchmann 1999). Fully democratic procedures at the EU level would
certainly legitimate that supranational governance structure, which
would then gain power at the expense of the member states. Faced with
this prospect, the member states have preferred to supply the EU with
only indirect democratic legitimation since they ± as democratically
elected and controlled governments ± have the last say on treaty matters.
The so-called de®cit of democracy, although often referred to in both
public as well as academic discourse, is often not fully understood.
Several dimensions to this problem need to be distinguished. First,
democratic governance requires not only that majorities legitimately
decide on political action but that at the same time minorities are
protected against the arrogance of majorities. In the latter respect the
EU's track record is not bad, provided of course that the interests of
minorities ®nd a way to be represented by a nation-state.
Secondly, an important criterion of the degree of democratic governance is the equality of each individual vote. However, the quota system
1
The Council of Ministers consists of a representative of each member state at ministerial
level, authorized to commit the government of that member state (see the Treaty on
European Union, signed in Maastricht on 7 February 1992, Article 146). The European
Council brings together the heads of state or government of the member states and the
president of the Commission. They are assisted by the ministers of foreign affairs of the
member states and by a member of the Commission. The European Council meets at
least twice a year, under the chairmanship of the head of state or government of the
member state that holds the presidency of the Council. The European Council provides
the EU with the necessary impetus for its development and de®nes the general political
guidelines thereof (ibid., Article D).
The state of the European Union
267
through which the assembly of the European Parliament is constituted
poses a severe problem in this respect because it violates the principle of
equality in franchise (see also Scholz 1995: 120): the number of seats for
a country is not directly proportional to the size of its population. A vote
for a representative of the European Parliament in Ireland or Greece, for
example, has more impact on the distribution of seats in the assembly
than a vote in France or even more so in Germany.
Thirdly, the lack of separation of powers is also a serious drawback.
Since only the Council can create EU law by amending, extending and
renegotiating the treaties binding on all member states, this body
simultaneously also creates supranational law. In this way, the Council
forces the national parliaments automatically to ratify this change in EU
law, i.e. by incorporating it into their national laws. This, however,
clearly violates the democratic principle that only legitimized parliaments have the power to legislate (see also Vaubel 1995: 131).
Fourthly, the EU is characterized by a lack of democratically constituted control. The Commission wields de facto executive power
rather extensively in the sense that it transforms EU law into decrees
and speci®c regulations that affect the life of many if not all EU citizens
(see also Bach 1992), something that is, of course, the very intention of
the treaties. Under strictly democratic conditions, such executive power
should be responsible to parliamentary control and parliamentary investigating committees, which, as noted above, are not available in a
legitimized form at the EU level.
These are several relevant aspects of what is called the democracy
de®cit. Since the democratically constituted governments of the nationstates have reserved for themselves the right to legislate EU matters, the
trade-off between the sovereignty of member states and democracy at
the EU level has been resolved in favour of joint implementation of
national sovereignty at the expense of democracy at the highest level of
European statehood.
Nationalism meets liberalism
Despite the nationalist element present in the governance of the
European Union discussed above, liberalization in the form of deregulation of formerly quite heavily segmented national economies was
successfully implemented through the programme of `completing the
internal market'. This was the `Europe 92' initiative approved via the
Single European Act of the mid-1980s. The so-called four freedoms ±
capital, labour, trade and services ± and the establishment of a common
governance structure for economic matters through harmonization
268
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
and/or mutual recognition of regulations correspond to a liberal economic programme advocating the removal of barriers to trade and a
homogenized market as a basis for and bene®t to prosperity and growth.
There is no doubt that the transition of formerly nationally regulated
and thus quite substantially segmented markets into a single, common
market represents an important step in institutionalizing economic
liberalism throughout Europe. Indeed, it is the largest and most farreaching deregulation project in economic history.
We can thus conclude that the form of state in the European Union
represents a compromise between nationalism and liberalism. This
conclusion is hardly novel; Streeck (1996: 305) has already described
this state as an `alliance of nationalism and neoliberalism'. Nevertheless,
we would like to add that this compromise between divergent forces
present throughout European history should be acknowledged as a
reconciliation of forces that ± to the detriment of Europe ± has been
quite rare.
In chapter 1 we re¯ected brie¯y on state-building in Europe. Here we
would like to acknowledge the two key social forces that acted on this
process throughout European history. During the ®rst phase of modernity, i.e. until the beginning of the nineteenth century, European states
became more dissimilar. On the one hand, the absolutist state projects
accentuated war, while, on the other hand, decentralized social systems
emphasized trade. Important predecessors of the latter included Venice,
the Hanseatic League, the United Provinces of North Holland, and later
England and the United States. Over centuries, this polarization in
state-building was accompanied by a dramatic process of concentration,
reducing the number of states from about ®ve hundred to twenty-®ve
(Tilly 1975: 27).
The historical roots of contemporary processes
Which exactly were the forces acting on state formation over these
centuries? They consisted primarily of two quite contradictory forces
that emerged following the dissolution of the medieval world of Catholic
European society. Each represented a new `absolutism', albeit in ways
that were diametrically opposed to one another. One emphasized
collectivism, whereas the other promoted individualism (see also
Coleman 1974). The ®rst was expressed in the theory of the absolute
power of the state, the second through a theory of individualism in
which the individual is of paramount importance.
Absolute power of the state and individual pre-eminence clashed not
only with each other but also with the medieval idea of a ®xed position
The state of the European Union
269
for each social agent within the whole. Power exercised on the basis of
the absolutist claim of the state or the individual claim to pre-eminence
thus needed new justi®cations to convince the public that order beyond
collective and individual egoisms was possible. In collectivism the
exercise of power was legitimated over time through the claim that this
power was deployed `for the people'. This justi®cation remained inherently problematic since power exercised in favour of one group of people
easily clashed with the claims of other people, and thus engendered
belligerent competition between the emerging states of Europe. In the
end, attempts at creating order through mutual recognition of the
territorial power base of others and the promise of non-intervention in
the internal affairs of sovereign states were only a kind of temporary
truce.
In the case of individualism, the prescribed form of legitimation
seemed much more elegant. Adam Smith provided the well-known
justi®cation of individualism: while egoistically pursuing their own ends,
humans are led by an invisible hand in such a way as to promote an end
that was never part of their intentions. The mysterious alchemy of the
market thus transforms individual egoism into a social good ± if and
only if the market is given free rein. Thus, laissez-faire, i.e. restricting
the state to a minimal role, is an integral part of this alchemy. This
evolved into the doctrine of economic liberalism, which assumed ± just
as in case of the other absolutism ± a quasi-religious status.
Yet, liberalism has always been more than that. Although it is true that
the ideology of liberalism started to spread throughout Europe after the
French Revolution, the central ideas and social movements that became
liberalism are in fact much older. A very early example that demonstrates the roots of liberalism as a manifestation of individualism is the
preamble of a law promulgated in Florence in the year 1289 ± ®ve
hundred years (!) before the French Revolution ± which proclaimed:
`Because liberty as the basis of will cannot be conditional upon alien
criteria but must be based on self-determination; because personal
freedom derives from natural right ± the same that protects peoples from
oppression, that protects and elevates their rights ± we are determined to
preserve and enhance it' (quoted in Raith 1979: 29, our translation).
Thus, declarations of human rights came into being long before the
Dutch, English, American and French revolutions. They are manifestations of an old and powerful European social movement and theory ±
individualism ± that became elaborated in the European Enlightenment
with its programme of self-empowerment and nourished diverse forms
of liberalism.
The term `liberalism' as such, however, appeared late. It ®rst came
270
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
into use in the political sphere at the beginning of the nineteenth
century (i.e. los liberales in the Spanish Cortes) and signi®ed a plea for
the liberty of the individual and his/her right to self-expression.
Each of the two aforementioned `absolutisms' ± collectivism and
individualism ± became manifest in diverse and even con¯icting movements. With respect to individualism, we mention here only three of
the often con¯icting manifestations of individualism: economic, political and social liberalism. Collectivism was an emerging consequence
of the claim to absolute power by the state. The expansion of state
power in Europe ultimately created a very powerful ideology ± nationalism ± in order both to legitimate and to limit through democratization the exercise of this absolute power of the state. At the same time,
the territorial expansion of state power produced its own collective
enemy, based also on collective bonds, i.e. regionalism. Regionalism,
which can be seen as a lower-level nationalism, opposed the centralization implied by modern state-building, which abolished or restricted
older identities that included patriotism and the right to self-governance at the regional level. This opposition between regionalism and the
central state is a consequence of the key feature of European statebuilding, i.e. the aforementioned shrinking of ®ve hundred state-like
entities to only twenty-®ve over the past ®ve hundred years of
European history.
Socialism, although in theory an internationalist movement, is collectivist in orientation but also oriented toward a strong state. The
programme of revolutionary socialism was to conquer state power and
exercise a new and more just rule prior to the withering away of the
state. Even when the reformist, social democratic version of the movement triumphed, socialism was still interested in a strong state with an
extended role in economic and social matters whose purpose was to
improve the destiny of the people. In this respect socialism and nationalism had a common interest; although in severe con¯ict with each
other, they were both hostile towards liberalism.
The two con¯icting historical movements (collectivism and individualism) are still found today in rather different notions of the state
present in political science (Wolf 1996: 8). In the realist approach, the
state is mysti®ed as a single unitary rational actor trying to maximize
its autonomy within a system of states. By contrast, the liberal perspective on the state sees the state as a subsystem of national or international society, which re¯ects societal needs based on people's
preferences and which produces a public good. Here the state is seen
as the problem-solver instead of a mysti®ed, glorious and autonomous
actor.
The state of the European Union
271
Both currents of thought have been in¯uential in terms of political
practice as well as political theory. Thus, the two opposing theories
were also embedded as con¯icting principles in the Charter of the
United Nations, which establishes both the rights of nations (along
with a non-intervention clause) and the human rights of the individual.
Today, the clash between the principle of territoriality, established on
the basis of social groups within a certain area, and the capitalist logic
of the free use of economic opportunities in markets, which are
fundamentally trans-territorial, has become clearly evident. To some
observers this appears to be a new feature of global capitalism. But the
battle between these principles has been going on in Europe for
centuries. Unlike today, these forces were represented in con¯icting
state projects prior to the convergence that began in the nineteenth
century.
An early form of reconciling the two con¯icting forces was the United
Provinces of North Holland, which developed at the end of the sixteenth
century. This state was highly atypical for its time but seems very up-todate when we compare it with the European Union (see chapter 1). In
the provinces of North Holland, the most fully urbanized area at that
time, civilian rule had for the ®rst time in European history created a
state structure that was also able to dominate its territory, which became
the home of civil liberalism. The balance between the patriotic forces of
the sovereign provinces and the newly emerging liberalism sheds new
light on what has been called the curious form of state that is the
present-day European Union.
To conclude this section, let us make the following points. First, the
con¯ictive compromise between nationalist claims of sovereignty and
liberalism, which we observe in present-day Europe at the level of the
European Union, is not as new as it might seem. Even the democracy
de®cit can be found in its historical forerunner. Secondly, during the
process of reconciling nationalism and liberalism in the competitive
setting that was Europe, the modern state was ultimately more strongly
in¯uenced by the `trade and economic state' as a `contract of association' than by the colossal, rapacious states founded on domination and
military power that represent the European tradition of war. The
formation of the European Union is consistent with this trend toward
peace. This aspect of European cooperation is not simply a recent
occurrence, but was intended from the beginning, when, on the ®fth
anniversary of the end of the Second World War (9 May 1950), the
French minister of foreign affairs, Robert Schuman, proposed a
common organization in Europe.
272
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
Shifts in the composition of nationalism and liberalism
Compromise ± even if con¯ictive ± is not such a bad thing. More often
in European history, the supremacy of collectivism was imposed at the
expense of liberalism. To be sure, the forerunners of the capitalist
project in Europe, which over time were situated in very different places
(Venice, the Hanseatic League, North Holland and the United
Kingdom), were always more liberal than their historical counterparts.
But apart from this, the composition of nationalism and liberalism in
Europe as a whole shifted in considerable waves which mark distinct
phases.
In order to understand the different phases of nationalism and
liberalism in the twentieth century we must brie¯y turn to the previous
one. The nineteenth century started with an initial surge and ended
with a resurgence of nationalism. Nevertheless, it was also the century
in which liberalism triumphed for the ®rst time in large parts of
Western Europe. Liberalism then began to lose strength during the
1880s, both within as well as between countries (see Mommsen 1969).
The new nationalism after 1870 was an attempt at ideologically
mending societal ruptures without having to undertake more fundamental reforms. European imperialism from 1885 until the end of the
First World War can be seen as an extreme form of nationalist
thinking, not only in the continental countries but also under liberal
imperialism in England.
Extreme nationalism, popular arrogance and accompanying racism
and xenophobia were reactions to an insuf®cient compromise in the
class-polarized societal model around the turn of the century. Once
again, during the 1920s and the 1930s, such attitudes could be observed
in many European countries (and something similar, although much
weaker, took place during the 1980s and the 1990s). These ideologies
were used to divert attention from domestic con¯icts. In this respect
Hitler's race hatred and lust for conquest are directly related to this
imperialist phase.
The various Europes in the twentieth century
The ®rst phase of the composition of nationalism and liberalism in
Europe in the twentieth century is actually the continuation of the
resurgence of nationalism in the last third of the nineteenth century
which ended in the Thirty Years War of the twentieth century, 1914±45.
In the course of the second part of this phase, hyper-nationalism and
imperialism triggered the world wars of the twentieth century, in the
The state of the European Union
273
course of which dramatic changes in economic and political positions
within Western core society became evident. By the end of this phase,
Europe had lost its leadership position to the United States. After 1945,
in the second phase of the composition of nationalism and liberalism
in the twentieth century, Europe, under the hegemony of liberal
Keynesianism and US liberalism, recovered. But liberalism remained
restricted ± `The state is the solution' was the key phrase to characterize
the societal model ± and national alliances of the state, business and the
labouring classes for recovery and growth kept a tight rein on liberalism.
The third phase of the recomposition of nationalism and liberalism
started with the decay of the Keynesian societal model.
As the 1960s drew to a close, liberalism experienced a resurgence. In
one respect, this was obviously evidenced by the renewed absolutism of
neoliberalist doctrine, which became hegemonic during the 1970s. But
in important respects there was more to it than that. Political liberalism
was strengthened, as evidenced by the anti-authoritarian youth movements and the subsequent broad wave of progressive political and social
movements, which, in addition to their speci®c themes, had a strong
and common focus on basic democratic procedures. It was not only the
anti-authoritarian and autonomous movements that evidenced a fresh
and radical claim to freedom throughout the Western world; wider
segments of society were also increasingly affected. The greater desire of
citizens to assume responsibility for organizing their own lives was
clearly evident. These citizens demanded a society of multiple choices
that makes possible an individualized lifestyle. `Individualization' is the
term sociologists have created for this concept. Even those who do not
like the quasi-religious nature of economic neoliberalism have been
forced to admit that it is only part of a broad current of resurgent
individualism.
In sociology and political science this remarkable shift, which altered
both the themes of political discourse and the forms of interest articulation, has been labelled by Ronald Inglehart (1977) as The Silent Revolution. But this term does not tell the whole story. When institutionalized
value priorities and those manifest at the level of citizens begin to
diverge, society is on the move. Political potentials can be de®ned as
value priorities among citizens that ± given appropriate political opportunity structures and framing through theories ± feed oppositional
movements expressing discontent and opposition. The decay of the
Keynesian compromise, however, triggered not just one new political
potential (the so-called new social movements) but two. Since the
beginning of the 1970s, these two emerging political potentials have
become increasingly polarized in Western countries. This is shown by
274
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
the detailed empirical research of Stefan Sacchi (1998) covering the past
quarter of a century. Indeed the `silent revolution' represented both the
rebirth of oppositional (and universalist) liberalism and the rebirth of a
regressive and authoritarian political potential that nourished the
renewed identi®cation with forms of `nationalisms' at the regional and
nation-state level.
The move toward political union: did liberalism eventually beat
nationalism?
The modern push towards European integration, which started as early
as the beginning of the 1950s, persisted through two phases of Europe
in the twentieth century ± the Keynesian era and the resurgence of
liberalism. But it was only the revitalization of the European Community in the 1980s that changed the very nature of integration by
adding a considerably extended political dimension to it, one that was
continued but in no way fundamentally altered by the Treaty on
European Union, which came into effect in 1993.
In this volume we have argued that the European transnational
corporations were the decisive protagonists behind the move towards
the European Union. This could be falsely interpreted as a triumph of
deregulationist philosophy over the state, but this is in fact not the case.
Even for the European transnational corporations themselves, a compromise between protective nationalism and liberalism is evident. To be
sure, this new type of nationalism is a social force that transcends the
established nation-states. It seems less emotional and more instrumental
in kind, and its frame of reference is competition in the world system.
The European business elite and the political elite in Brussels were and
are the early, in¯uential spokespeople of this Euro-nationalism. Among
the latter, the political Euro-entrepreneur Jacques Delors has always
been a strong advocate of this new form of Euro-nationalism and one
willing to project European brilliance into the future. Therefore he used
to warn: `We must move quickly otherwise Europe will become an
archaeological excavation site, where Americans and Japanese seek for
lost ideas and ways of life' (Delors 1991).
But Euro-nationalism was in no way restricted to the elite who
managed the integration thrust of the mid-1980s. A signi®cant minority
of Community citizens belongs to this group, too. Unfortunately,
despite continuing efforts at monitoring European public opinion, we
cannot say whether this group has increased in size over time. At least
we know that in 1982 ± before the push for integration ± slightly more
than 20 per cent of the Community's citizens could be classi®ed as
The state of the European Union
275
Euro-nationalists, i.e. often self-identifying as `Europeans' and expressing mistrust of extra-European powers (Krummenacher 1997).
We now must acknowledge the varieties of `nationalism' in Europe. At
present, nationalism as a powerful historical manifestation of a collective
ideology assumes different and opposing forms: regionalism, nationalism and Euro-nationalism. Patriotism rooted in local or regional
bonds may easily reactivate resentments against the nation-state, since
the victory of that very nation-state originally put an end to their forms
of self-government. Therefore, this kind of nationalism is most often
opposed to classical nationalism, although it might well seek alliances
with Euro-nationalist forces against the nation-state in order to regain
more independence. Classical nationalism is rooted in historically constructed bonds that are based on entitlements, political and social rights
that became institutionalized at the level of the nation-state during the
past two centuries. It may regard regional bonds as forms of backwardness while at the same time perceiving Euro-nationalism as threatening established political and social rights. Euro-nationalism is
progressive in a historical sense in so far as it seeks protection at a level
beyond the nation-state, a collectivity large enough to provide competitive advantages in a world system in which smaller political units
increasingly feel the threat of falling behind.
Unfortunately, we have little empirical evidence on the shifts in size of
the different kinds of collective identities over time and on their exclusiveness. Even if we have little information on changes over time, we can
say that up to 30 per cent of EU citizens can be classi®ed as distinct
nationalists, and about 20 per cent can be termed marked Euronationalists in the above-mentioned sense (Krummenacher 1997).
Another ®nding for two time points at the beginning of the 1990s
suggests that about 55 per cent of EU citizens feel very attached to their
region (RothenbuÈhler 1997). The latter study suggests that nationalist
and regionalist identi®cation are of about the same size, whereas the
identi®cation with Europe or the EU is clearly lower and declined
between 1991 and 1995.
From recent research we can conclude that a distinct nationalist
orientation does not represent a serious threat to European integration.
The expression of national pride and support for European integration
are not mutually exclusive alternatives; in fact, there is a very small but
positive correlation between the two. Less spectacular is the ®nding that
Euro-nationalists on the average are more favourable toward integration
than the rest of the population and would regret it more if it failed
(Krummenacher 1997). In the 1990s, citizens of the EU seemed to be
increasingly attached to smaller units such as the region or city while the
276
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
corresponding ®gures for feelings of attachment to the European Union
fell. But there is no hint at all that identi®cation with one's own region is
affecting attitudes towards European integration (RothenbuÈhler 1997).
A compromise ± no victory of liberalism
Interpreting the form of the state in the European Union as a compromise between nationalism and liberalism must acknowledge not only the
tensions between the underlying forces of collectivism and individualism, but also the fact that the European reality is a bit more complex
than that. Indeed, in the case of different forms of nationalism, it is a
multi-level compromise. Modern-day liberalism quarrels with nationalism, but different forms of collective identity also quarrel among
themselves: regionalism, classical nationalism and Euro-nationalism.
The same is true for the various manifestations of liberalism, although
to a lesser extent. While economic liberalism is quite well established at
the Union level, the key claims of political liberalism are not ± as
evidenced by the democracy de®cit to which we have referred.
Looking back at European history, the various manifestations of
collective identity have changed considerably in terms of their impact.
Regionalism has always been opposed to the centralization implied by
state-building, which restricted or abolished older rights and forms of
self-government of smaller political units. Nationalism and the creation
of a nation became a strategy to legitimate the authority of the nationstate. This in turn triggered the extension of citizens' rights (see
Marshall [1950] 1965). At the EU level this process is repeated.
Nationalism now seems to be playing the role of an oppositional force
with respect to the Union project much as regionalism once did vis-aÁ-vis
the emerging nation-states. However ± and this is quite important ±
contemporary regionalism has not become weakened by the process of
European integration; quite the contrary. Thus regionalism and nationalism have become two distinct forces in opposition to the centralization
of authority, while at the same time both are in opposition to each other.
The European nation-state has thus come under pressure to compromise from two sides: from the quest for more regional autonomy, and
from being forced to give away regulatory authority to the supranational
body of the EU. The European nation-states reacted to these pressures
by maintaining ultimate control over the matters of the Union.
However, the binding nature of the EU treaty is at the same time
signi®cant and transfers considerable executive power from the nationstates to the new supranational European state. The price of this overall
compromise is the not insigni®cant de®cit of democracy in European
The state of the European Union
277
politics. Given the complicated forces behind the compromise, this
de®cit will not be easy to overcome.
Empirical evidence for the compromise is suggested by the mentioned
®ndings: contrary to general opinion, classical nationalism as well as
regionalism ± in their present forms at least ± are not endangering
European integration, although they do help to shape it.
Given the weight of the multi-level compromise of collective identities
embodied in the overall governance structures of European institutions,
one can hardly say that liberalism took over in Europe. Yet, it increased
its impact at the same time. Without question, the deregulation project
in Europe is of historic dimensions and was pushed by a forceful
ideology. We should not however make neoliberalism a comic ®gure.
This is only one aspect of the resurgence of liberalism, which has
become accepted by wider segments of the population in the realm of
politics (grassroots democracy, referenda) and everyday life (individualization). Thus we have to accept, even if we do not admire, that
European citizens have become more liberal and seek to democratize
their freedom. This is why opposition to economic liberalism has been
limited.
The European Union ± an untimely undertaking?
The political dimension of European integration developed during an
era of dramatic change in information technologies and intensi®ed
economic globalization. Many observers have contended that the state is
in decline or even that states are withering away precisely because of
these two factors. If this were true, the EU would indeed be an untimely
undertaking. However, we question the myth of the decline and/or
withering away of the state and suggest two arguments in support of our
view.
Our ®rst argument relates to the emerging era of telematics (the fusion
of telecommunications with information technologies under the aegis of
digitalization). Views of discontinuous technological development have
changed since the early 1980s. Whereas the original approach of Joseph
Schumpeter was to explain innovation thrusts by reference to changes in
the economic sphere alone, Carlota Perez and those who followed her
line suggested an important revision, to which we have already referred in
chapter 1. Both the technological style and the politico-economic regime
± the techno-economic and the socio-institutional subsystems ± need to
adjust to each other in order to make a long-term economic upswing
viable. Since the adjustment of the socio-institutional subsystem is a
necessary part of the evolution and diffusion of a new technological style,
278
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
the institutional infrastructure that is able to support a new technological
style is subject to a political logic. This needs to be de®ned, and new
institutions need to be created through political struggles, not only within
nation-states but also in the world market and the world polity.
We contend that the new political institutions that will be necessary in
the age of telematics imply that the state sphere is not becoming obsolete
but will be an indispensable element for making the new technological
style viable. The need for social and material infrastructure at the
national as well as at the international level will increase, especially with
regard to information technology. And with this comes an increasing
need for international cooperation. Although these developments will
alter the nature of state sovereignty, they will not make states and
leadership in the global community obsolete. Those states that take the
lead in providing the infrastructure for the global information system
will be in a position to exert dominance in setting the norms and
standards of the new infrastructures.
The EU as a supranational state is unique in meeting this present
challenge. In developing the infrastructure for the emerging technological style of the telematics era, the EU did something that no nationstate was willing or able to do on that scale. There may be debate about
how well it has performed in this regard (see Bornschier 1994; Mytelka
1995), but this is not the point here. What is important to note is that
the state sphere is not becoming obsolete in the era of the new
technological style.
Our second argument regarding economic globalization seems to
have invited considerable misunderstanding. In comparison with the
time prior to and following the turn of the nineteenth century, the
expansion of economic globalization that began in the 1980s is not so
exceptional, as we have already noted in chapter 1, and during this
earlier expansion the state survived quite well. This should make us
cautious about predicting the withering away of the state any time
within the twenty-®rst century. Beyond this historical analogy, wishes
for or fears of the withering away of the state in the world political
economy are not warranted.
In order to explain why, one has to consider that states and business
in the capitalist world political economy are inextricably interrelated.
States provide territorially bounded public goods which ± if of good
quality ± help economic enterprises to prosper. This applies not only to
the average ®rm that normally does business only within the framework
of a single state, but more importantly ± and this is a point neglected in
the recent debate on globalization ± to transnational corporations. In
order to compete successfully, these corporations, although economic-
The state of the European Union
279
ally active around the world, need a strong base of operations allowing
for economies of scale as well as shared economic regulation. They
prosper if backed by strong governments that protect their interests both
at home and abroad.
Even in an era of ¯ourishing free trade ideology, protective state
action continues to be important. One recent example is the EU
protecting European aerospace from the merger of two gigantic US
aerospace corporations, Boeing and McDonnell Douglas: an EU antitrust panel found that the US$15 billion merger would strengthen
Boeing's existing dominant position and therefore should be prohibited.
Under EU law, the European Commission can block mergers ± even of
non-European enterprises ± if it feels these will harm fair trade in the
Union. Yet, in completely blocking the merger the EU Commission
would have seriously collided with the US government, which had
already approved the deal between the two aircraft giants without
conditions. Eventually the case was settled by an agreement with conditions when it came to a decision in July 1997. Another example from the
competition in the triad is that `the EU will reintroduce minimum prices
on some computer chips exported by Japan and South Korea. The
antidumping move will be phased in over the next three months, a
slower pace than the European chip industry has sought' (Wall Street
Journal Europe, 11 March 1997, p. 1).
We can ®nd many other examples in favour of the proposition that
states regulating a huge market command considerable market power
and weight in the world political economy. The same relationship
between size and power applies, of course, also to currencies. Indeed,
this was the underlying rationale for the European monetary union
established through the Treaty on European Union. Ironically, the rigid
timetable and convergence criteria ultimately had the negative sideeffect of tying the hands of European governments (owing to limits on
public debt) when it came to overcoming sluggish growth and persistent
unemployment in the mid-1990s through anti-cyclical public spending.
States not `withering away' and state alliances in no way novel
The recent debate on globalization and telematics rests in our view on
fatally ¯awed premises in so far as it falsely suggests that the state is
withering away. This will certainly not be the case, since strong states
and big business go hand in hand in the world political economy. This is
a lesson perhaps lost on the authors of present-day economics textbooks
although not on students of history.
What seems true, however, is that political middleweights, such as the
280
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
old European powers, as well as political lightweights will increasingly
suffer a loss of impact in comparison with the Keynesian era. Strong and
± via measures to enhance solidarity ± solidly integrated states are very
likely to have a clear advantage in the twenty-®rst century in effectively
competing for shares in the world political economy.
As we have witnessed, since the 1980s several integration projects
have been launched ± the North American Free Trade Agreement
(NAFTA), the Asean Free Trade Area (AFTA) and Asia-Paci®c Economic Cooperation (APEC), to mention only those involving members
of the triad. European integration served as a trigger for these, although
thus far it remains unique. One might well argue that alliances aimed at
aggregating state power would not compare favourably to well-established nation-states; as units of power they are hardly as effective.
Although this seems a plausible argument, it neglects the role alliances
have played in the history of the world political economy.
Alliances between states are in no way novel. Just as ®rms can and do
merge, so it is with states; indeed states have done so in the past.
Consider, for example, the last three hegemons in the world political
economy following the ®rst Thirty Years War; all were in fact alliances of
states: the United Provinces of North Holland, the United Kingdom
of England, Scotland and Northern Ireland, and the United States of
America.
The EU and the other big players in the world political
economy
The role of the European Union in the world political economy is often
too narrowly analysed in terms of economic aggregates. This omits the
fact that economic competition is also intrinsically a form of competition
between institutional solutions. One complex set of such institutions
relevant to the topic of this volume is the state, an institutional set that,
as we have concluded, will surely not become obsolete in the near
future. Before addressing the competing forms of the state in the core of
the world system, let us begin by reciting some important economic
®gures.
We start with the year 1992, when the internal market project was
realized. In terms of share of world trade and world share of foreign
direct investment, the EU clearly leads Japan and the USA, the other
two nation-states making up the triad (see also chapter 1). Moreover,
the jurisdiction of the Union encompasses the largest ever single highincome market; the combined population of the EU's ®fteen members is
368 million, compared with a population of 255 million in the USA and
The state of the European Union
281
125 million in Japan. Even though per capita income (corrected for
purchasing power parities) in the EU ranks only third to its rivals in the
triad (USA: US$ 23,120; Japan: US$ 20,160; EU: US$ 17,424), total
market size is somewhat larger in the EU (US$ 6,417 billion) than in the
USA (US$ 5,898 billion), while Japan ranks a distant third (US$ 2,510
billion) (®gures computed from World Bank 1994: 201, 259).
Of course, a huge market like the one under EU jurisdiction cannot
be equated with a leading position in high-tech industries; here Europe
does not command positions commensurate with its market size. Yet,
one should not dismiss huge markets as an effective source of power in
itself. Here the EU is in a strong position, which it wants to consolidate through the new Euro-currency (a heavyweight in the world
economy), and anxieties about its decline seem premature if not farfetched.
Let us proceed to the second half of the 1990s. Two decades after the
time when, to many observers, the USA seemed to be in decline and
Japan's economic growth was actually challenging Europe's position, the
situation in the triad had changed very considerably. The revitalized
American position has become clearly evident. Without a doubt, the
new technological style of the telematics era has put both US ®rms and
US standards in leading positions. This pertains not only to information
technologies but also to biotechnology.
Japan, whose spectacular economic growth made it the big challenger of the 1970s and 1980s, featured in very different newspaper
headlines in the 1990s. The crisis in Japan has affected societal selfcon®dence and exposed the rotten pillars of its postwar order. The
years of extreme self-con®dence are over, and Japan has entered a
phase of deep self-doubt. Japan is moving from its position as a special
case in the postwar era to being a normal case of discontinuous
development in the core.
Western Europe, hit by worrisome levels of unemployment and fears
of further job losses, now shares with Japan the fate of being second to
the USA in terms of economic soundness. Yet, in contrast to Japan,
Western Europe has already carried out much of the task of deregulation, and despite the currently sluggish economy has produced a timely
vision. This vision is evidenced by the White Paper of December 1993
entitled Growth, Competitiveness, Employment ± The Challenges and Ways
Forward into the 21st Century. This report calls for a `new model of
European society' and for `sustainable development': `It is important to
develop a societal project for a higher quality of life in the Community,
which can motivate people and hence can generate the required human
energy' (EU 1993: 15, 150f ).
282
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
Leadership
The present economic ranking in the triad ± the United States as
number one, followed by the European Union, and both rather unchallenged by Japan in third place ± is also present in ideological leadership
in shaping global concerns.
Even if the United States is no longer the world's premier economic
power, as it was from the end of the Second World War until the 1960s,
its recent come-back is remarkable and it remains the ideological and
military leader. The European Union has undoubtedly gained stature in
economic policy circles. Together with the United States, the European
Union facilitated the agreement establishing the World Trade Organization (WTO), while Japan remained in the background. The United
States is frequently able to gain support for its positions in the WTO.
Although the United States is no longer the world's biggest exporter, it
does successfully export its values: America's passion for deregulation
and free trade. At the beginning of 1997, the United States brought
seventy countries to agreement on its position regarding the deregulation of telecommunications. The chief US negotiator immodestly stated
in press releases that this made the American style of competition the
norm. For telecommunications, the world's third-largest industry today,
and one which until recently was dominated by state monopolies (even
in the United States), this unleashes a revolution.
In other areas of global concern, the European Union is ideologically
the overall leader. Take, for example, protection of the atmosphere. At
the Rio conference as well as at the subsequent conferences of the
parties to specify the climate convention, the European Union was
showing leadership, while the United States was the biggest hindrance
among the developed countries (Missbach 1999). At the various preparatory meetings for the third conference of the parties in Kyoto at the
end of 1997 this became obvious from the EU proposal, which aimed to
®nd broad support among developing countries too. The European
Union proposed that industrialized countries should reduce their greenhouse gas emissions by 15 per cent by 2010 from 1990 levels while
developing countries were exempted from reductions. Notwithstanding
that the results of the Kyoto conference fell short of this initial EU
position, it is noteworthy that in the end the European Union succeeded
in pushing the United States and Japan to a ®rst binding agreement for
protecting the atmosphere from greenhouse gases.
There is another remarkable point to the EU initiative. A special
strength of the European Union lies in the fact that it can focus the
diverging positions of its ®fteen member countries beforehand, thus
The state of the European Union
283
increasing its odds of success at large international conferences. The
forging of a common position for external consumption is made possible
through internal compensation. In this respect the European Union
could be a model for the world. The EU environmental ministers
succeeded in creating an equitable system of internal compensation
between the rich and poor member states. The total reduction for the
Union is realized through an extremely unequal internal formula:
whereas the rich countries must reduce their production of greenhouse
gases, the poorer ones can even produce more greenhouse gases than in
the reference year of 1990.
The European state of nations ± a model for world society?
The heading above is not a product of arrogance or Euro-centrism; it is
quite obvious that previous European social innovations have been
models for the world. The cultural legacy of the Atlantic West ± the
roots of which lie in Europe ± shaped the institutions that incontrovertibly determine core status in world society: the market, social egalitarianism and the rule of law, along with the sharing of power and political
checks and balances, economic enterprise and modern schools. To be
sure, within that globally dominant social praxis Europe does not play
the role it once did. But it is far from being on the decline, as evidenced
by its revitalization since the 1980s and its proven ability to continue to
contribute innovatively to the future shape of world society ± the supranational state being the case in point here.
At present two quite different kinds of state alliances are preparing for
leadership in the twenty-®rst century: the United States of America as a
federal nation-state and the European state of nations. Even if different,
the two are actually not independent, a point made obvious by the
NATO alliance linking the Atlantic West under American leadership
and military might. Despite this joint leadership, which is facilitated by a
strong common cultural heritage, the differences in the two forms of
state are important and will not wither away in the course of time.
It has become clear from what we and others have already said (see,
for example, Lepsius 1991) that there will not be a United States of
Europe, since that would imply a melting pot of groups from different
nations ± although admittedly this was an admirable historical accomplishment in the case of the USA. In contrast to this, the European state
project rests, and needs to rest, on the acknowledgement of its constituent nations, which have developed in the course of its history. What
the Union contributes to this is an increasingly European identity ± not
as a replacement for, but as an addition to, national, regional and local
284
Conclusions beyond the Single European Act
bonds. Such an overarching European identity has existed for a long
time in Europe's history, albeit to varying degrees and restricted to
elites.
Does the speci®c type of alliance of state power that recently developed in Europe imply that the resulting state will be a comparatively
weak one? What is a strong state and what is a weak one? A strong state
is one that is able to institutionalize cohesion and social balancing ± an
obvious strength of postwar European state-building ± and can reconcile
the different forces (nationalism and liberalism) in a productive compromise that represents more than a stalemate. This does not seem
impossible in the case of the European Union ± for efforts see `target
cohesion' and `social and economic convergence' in chapters 5 and 6.
But will such a state con®guration also be successful in taking part in
peaceful world economic competition? This remains to be seen, but the
history of Europe suggests that pessimism is not appropriate. The
aforementioned example of the state of North Holland seems to be
relevant to the debate. Here we recall Braudel's question (see chapter
1): Can the United Provinces of North Holland be called a `state'? No
matter how that question is answered, there is no doubt that during its
time the novel system of governance in North Holland achieved preeminence in the emerging world economy for at least one century and
that this societal system was astonishingly liberal compared with its
contemporary rivals.
Thus, what has been termed the `odd nature' of the form of state
represented by the European Union and what has even been called `an
historical aberration' must be reinterpreted in a rather different light.
The present-day uniqueness of this European social innovation (which
follows that earlier European innovation, the nation-state) may become
a model to the world for reconciling the different manifestations of
nationalism and liberalism in a multi-level system of governance. We
hope that such an interpretation (see Bornschier 1996: 368; and
Therborn 1997: 586) does not seem too optimistic to the reader.
Appendix: List of interview partners
(1993±1996)
E U C O M M I S S I O N A N D D I R E C TO R AT E S G E N E R A L
Lord Cock®eld
E. Davignon
F. Braun
K. Schreiber
M. RuÈte
C. Savoini
P. Venturini
A. Klepsch
J.- P. Masson
R. HuÈber
Commission
Commission
DG/VEBA
DG III
DG IV
DG V
DG V
DG XII
COST/DG XII
DG XIII
C O M M I T T E E O F P E R M A N E N T R E P R E S E N TAT I V E S
(COREPER)
Two British senior of®cials
Two German senior of®cials
J. Vandamme
Counsellor of the Belgian COREPER delegation
E U R O P E A N PA R L I A M E N T
Chr. Tannert
J. Moreau
Socialist group
Former chairman of the Economic and Monetary
Affairs Committee; president of the Economic and
Social Committee
E M P L OY E R S , B U S I N E S S A S S O C I AT I O N S , R O U N D TA B L E S
OF INDUSTRIALISTS
W. Dekker
F. Braun
H. Maucher
Philips/European Roundtable of Industrialists
DG/VEBA
NestleÂ/European Roundtable of Industrialists
285
286
List of interview partners
H. Glatz
H. Kressler
S. Ryser
R .Verschueren
K. Vandendael
W. Wagner
J. Moritz
N. Hazewindus
J. Vanhumbeeck
Daimler-Benz
Unilever/European Roundtable of Industrialists
Hoffmann-La Roche, Senior Advisory Group Biotechnology
UNICE
EFPIA
European Information Technology Industry Roundtable
Siemens
Philips
Siemens, Liaison Of®ce to the European Union
TRADE UNIONS
F. Bisegna
T. Jenkins
W. Bergans
ICEF
TUC/ETUC, also Economic and Social Committee
ETUC
N O N - G OV E R N M E N TA L O R G A N I Z AT I O N S
J. Krazek
Friends of the Earth Europe, BUND
OT H E R I N F O R M A N T S
Prof. S. George
University of Shef®eld
Prof. M. Sharp
University of Sussex
Prof. J. Pelkmans Centre for European Policy Studies, Brussels
Bibliography
I . O F F I C I A L P U B L I C AT I O N S O F T H E C O M M I S S I O N O F
THE EC/EU
CEC 1970. Die Industriepolitik der Gemeinschaft. Memorandum der Kommission
an den Rat.
1981a. Communication from the Commission to the Council on the State of the
Internal Market. Strasbourg, 17 June 1981, COM (81) 313 ®nal.
1981b. A Policy for Industrial Innovation ± Strategic Outlines of a Community
Approach. COM (81) 620 ®nal.
1982a. Commission Communication to the Council on Re-Activating the European
Internal Market. Brussels, 15 November 1982, COM (82) 735 ®nal.
1982b. On Laying the Foundations for a European Strategic Programme of
Research and Development in Information Technology: The Pilot Phase. COM
(82) 486 ®nal/2.
1982c. Towards a European Strategic Programme for Research and Development
in Information Technologies. COM (82) 287 ®nal.
1983a. Biotechnologie: Die Aufgaben der Gemeinschaft. COM (83) 328 ®nal.
1983b. Biotechnologie in der Gemeinschaft. COM (83) 672 ®nal.
1984a. `Eurofutures: The challenges of innovation'. Futures (Special Edition).
1984b. Communication from the Commission to the Council: Consolidating the
Internal Market. Brussels, 13 June 1984, COM (84) 305 ®nal.
1985. Completing the Internal Market. White Paper from the Commission to the
European Council. June 1985, COM (85) 310 ®nal.
1991a. Informations- und Kommunikationstechnologien. Die Rolle Europas.
General Directorate XIII.
1991b. Promoting the Competitive Environment for the Industrial Activities Based
on Biotechnology within the Community. SEC (91) 629.
1991c. `FoÈrderung eines wettbewerbsorientierten Umfeldes fuÈr die industrielle Anwendung der Biotechnologie in der Gemeinschaft'. EC Bulletin,
Suppl. No. 3.
1992. Europe on the Move. The European Community in the 1990s. Booklet for
the Universal Exposition in Seville 1992. Publications Unit.
CEU 1993. White Paper: Growth, Competitiveness, Employment: The Challenges
and Ways Forward into the 21st Century. COM (93) 700 ®nal. Luxembourg:
Of®ce for Of®cial Publications.
1994. Biotechnologie und das Weissbuch uÈber Wachstum, WettbewerbsfaÈhigkeit
und BeschaÈftigung. Vorbereitung der naÈchsten Phase. COM (94) 219 ®nal.
287
288
Bibliography
1995a. `Der soziale Dialog in der Gemeinschaft 1995: eine Bestandesaufnahme'. Social Europe No. 2. Luxembourg: Of®ce for Of®cial Publications.
1995b. Intergovernmental Conference 1996. Commission Report for the Re¯ection
Group. Luxembourg: EUR±OP.
1996a. First Report on Economic and Social Cohesion. Luxembourg: Of®ce for
Of®cial Publications.
1996b. Die Weiterentwicklung der europaÈischen Sozialpolitik ± Bericht uÈber die
Arbeiten des Forums. Luxembourg: Of®ce for Of®cial Publications.
I I . OT H E R R E F E R E N C E S
Agnelli, Giovanni. 1989. `The Europe of 1992'. Foreign Affairs 68(4): 61±70.
Allen, David. 1992. `European Union, the Single European Act and the 1992
Programme'. In D. Swann (ed.), The Single European Market and Beyond. A
Study of the Wider Implications of the Single European Act. London and New
York: Routledge.
1996. `Cohesion and Structural Adjustment'. In H. Wallace and W. Wallace
(eds.), Policymaking in the European Union. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Alter, Karen J. 1996. `The European Court's Political Power'. West European
Politics 19(3).
1998. `Who are the ``Masters of the Treaty''? European Governments and the
European Court of Justice'. International Organization 52(19).
Alter, Karen J., and Sophie Meunier-Aitsahalia. 1994. `Judicial Politics in the
European Community. European Integration and the Pathbreaking Cassis
de Dijon Decision'. Comparative Political Studies 26(4).
Anderson, Jeffrey J. 1995a. `The State of the (European) Union: From the
Single Market to Maastricht, from Singular Events to General Theories'.
World Politics 47: 441±65.
1995b. `Structural Funds and the Social Dimension of EU Policy: Springboard or Stumbling Block?' In S. Leibfried and P. Pierson (eds.), European
Social Policy: Between Fragmentation and Integration. Washington DC:
Brookings.
Archibugi, Daniele. 1992. `Patenting as an Indicator of Technological Innovation: A Review'. Science and Public Policy 19: 357±68.
Armingeon, Klaus. 1994. `Die Regulierung der kollektiven Arbeitsbeziehungen
in der EuropaÈischen Union'. In W. Streeck (ed.), Staat und VerbaÈnde.
Special issue of Politische Vierteljahresschrift, No. 25. Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag.
Artis, M.J. 1992. `The Maastricht Road to Monetary Union'. Journal of Common
Market Studies 30(3).
Attali, Jacques. 1993. Verbatim. Tome 1: Chronique des anneÂes 1981±1986. Paris:
Fayard.
1995. Verbatim. Tome 2: Chronique des anneÂes 1986±1988. Paris: Fayard.
Bach, Maurizio. 1992. `Eine leise Revolution durch Verwaltungsverfahren.
BuÈrokratische Integrationsprozesse in der EuropaÈischen Gemeinschaft'.
Zeitschrift fuÈr Soziologie 21.
Bibliography
289
1993a. `Vom Zweckverband zum technokratischen Regime: Politische
Legitimation und institutionelle VerselbstaÈndigung in der EuropaÈischen
Gemeinschaft'. In H.A. Winkler and H. Kaelble (eds.), Nationalismus ±
NationalitaÈten ± SupranationalitaÈt. Stuttgart: Klett-Cotta.
1993b. `Integrationsprozesse in der EuropaÈischen Gemeinschaft: Vom Zweckverband zum technokratischen Regime?' In H. Meulemann and A. EltingCamus (eds.), 26. Deutscher Soziologentag. LebensverhaÈltnisse und soziale
Kon¯ikte im neuen Europa, Tagungsband II: Sektionen, Arbeits- und Ad hocGruppen. Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag.
1999. Die BuÈrokratisierung Europas. Verwaltungseliten, Experten und politische
Legitimation. Frankfurt/Main: Campus.
Bairoch, Paul. 1996. `Globalization Myths and Realities: One Century of
External Trade and Foreign Investment'. Pp. 173±92 in Robert Boyer and
Daniel Drache (eds.), States against Markets: The Limits of Globalization.
London and New York: Routledge.
Baumann, Hans. 1995. Von nationalstaatlichen zu europaÈischen Arbeitsbeziehungen? MoÈglichkeiten und Grenzen der sozialen Dimension in Europa nach
Maastricht: Das Beispiel der Bauwirtschaft. Basler Schriften zur europaÈischen
Integration No. 11, Basel: Europa Institut.
Begg, Ian, and David Mayes. 1993. `Cohesion, Convergence and Economic and
Monetary Union in Europe'. Regional Studies 27(2).
BerieÂ, Hermann. 1988. `Deutsche EG-PraÈsidentschaft: Erfolg fuÈr den europaÈischen Sozialraum'. Bundesarbeitsblatt 9.
1992. `Maastrichter BeschluÈsse / Auf dem Weg zur Sozialunion'. Zeitschrift fuÈr
Sozialreform 8.
Bieber, Roland, Jean-Paul Jacque and Joseph H.H. Weiler (eds.). 1985. L'Europe
de demain. Une Union sans cesse plus eÂtroite. Analyse critique du projet de traiteÂ
instituant l'Union europeÂenne. Brussels: Collection perspectives europeÂennes.
Bieber, Roland, J. Pantalis and J. Schoo. 1986. `Implications of the Single
European Act for the European Parliament'. Common Market Law Review
23.
Biehl, Dieter. 1988. `Ein substantielles, aber begrenztes Reformpaket ± Zum
BruÈsseler Reformgipfel'. Integration 2.
BoissieÁre, Jean-Baptiste, and Bertrand Warusfel. 1991. La nouvelle frontieÁre de la
technologie europeÂenne. Paris: Calman-Levy.
Bornschier, Volker. 1988. Westliche Gesellschaft im Wandel. Frankfurt/Main:
Campus.
1994. `The Rise of the European Community. Grasping towards Hegemony?
Or Therapy against National Decline?' Pp. 55±82 in Max Haller and
Rudolf Richter (eds.), Towards a European Nation. Political Trends in Europe.
New York: Sharpe.
1996. Western Society in Transition. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.
Bornschier, Volker, and Christopher Chase-Dunn. 1999. `Technological
Change, Globalization and Hegemonic Rivalry'. Chapter 14 in Volker
Bornschier and Christopher Chase-Dunn (eds.), The Future of Global
Con¯ict. London: Sage.
Bornschier, Volker, and Christian Suter. 1992. `Long Waves in the World
290
Bibliography
System'. Pp. 15±49 in Volker Bornschier and Peter Lengyel (eds.), Waves,
Formations, and Values in the World System. Vol. 2 of World Society Studies.
New Brunswick and London: Transaction Publishers.
Bornschier, Volker, and Patrick Ziltener. 1999. `The Revitalization of Western
Europe and the Politics of the ``Social Dimension'' '. In P. Boje, B. van
Steenbergen and S. Walby (eds.), European Societies: Fusion or Fission?
London: Routledge.
Braudel, Fernand. [1979] 1984. The Perspective of the World. Vol. 3 of Civilization
and Capitalism 15th-18th Century. New York: Harper & Row.
Buchanan, James M. 1965. `An Economic Theory of Clubs'. Economica 32:
1±14.
Buchmann, Marlis. 1999. `European Integration: Disparate Dynamics of Bureaucratic Control and Communicative Participation', In P. Boje, B. van
Steenbergen and S. Walby (eds.), European Societies: Fusion or Fission?
London: Routledge.
Bullmann, Udo. 1994. Die Politik der dritten Ebene. Regionen im Europa der Union.
Baden-Baden: Nomos.
Bulmer, Simon, and William Paterson. 1987. The Federal Republic of Germany
and the European Community. London: Allen & Unwin.
Burkhardt-Reich, Barbara, and Wolfgang Schumann. 1983. AgrarverbaÈnde in der
EG. Kehl-Strassburg: Engel.
Burt, Ronald S. 1992. Structural Holes. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University
Press.
Busch, Klaus. 1978. Die Krise der EuropaÈischen Gemeinschaft. Frankfurt/Main:
EuropaÈische Verlagsanstalt.
Butler, Michael. 1986. Europe ± More than a Continent. London: Heinemann.
Cameron, David. 1992. `The 1992 Initiative: Causes and Consequences'.
Pp. 23±74 in Alberta M. Sbragia (ed.), Euro-Politics: Institutions and Policymaking in the EC. Washington DC: Brookings Institution.
Cini, Michelle. 1996. The European Commission. Leadership, Organization and
Culture in the EU Administration. Manchester: Manchester University Press.
Cock®eld, Lord. 1990. `The Real Signi®cance of 1992'. In C. Crouch and
D. Marquand (eds.), The Politics of 1992. Beyond the Single European
Market. Oxford and Cambridge: Basil Blackwell.
1991. `From Genesis to Revelation: The Emergence of the Vision of a New
Europe'. In A. Clesse and R. Vernon (eds.), The European Community after
1992: A New Role in World Politics? Baden-Baden: Nomos.
1992. `1992 ± Bilan d'une renaissance. Le Programme 92: Objectifs et
meÂthodes'. Address by the Rt. Hon. The Lord Cock®eld at the SeÂance
Academique in Brussels on 17 December 1992. Reprinted in Lord Cock®eld, The European Union. Creating the Single Market. Chichester: Wiley
Chancery Law, 1994.
1994. The European Union. Creating the Single Market. Chichester: Wiley
Chancery Law.
Colchester, Nicholas, and David Buchan. 1990. Europower. The Essential Guide
to Europe's Economic Transformation in 1992. New York: Times Books and
Random House.
Bibliography
291
Coleman, James S. 1974. Power and the Structure of Society. New York: Norton.
1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, Mass.: Belknap Press.
Corbett, Richard. 1992. `The Intergovernmental Conference on Political
Union'. Journal of Common Market Studies 30(3).
Cox, Robert. 1993. `Structural Issues of Global Governance: Implications for
Europe'. Pp. 259±89 in Stephen Gill (ed.), Gramsci, Historical Materialism
and International Relations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Cutler, Tony, et al. 1989. 1992 ± The Struggle for Europe: A Critical Evaluation of
the European Community. New York: Berg.
Dahrendorf, Ralf (ed.). 1981. Trendwende: Europas Wirtschaft in der Krise.
Vienna: Molden.
1992. Der moderne soziale Kon¯ikt. Stuttgart: Deutsche Verlags-Anstalt (extended version of the English-language edition, The Modern Social Con¯ict,
1988).
DaÈubler, Wolfgang. 1989. `Sozialstaat EG? Notwendigkeit und Inhalt einer
EuropaÈischen Grundrechtsakte'. In Wolfgang DaÈubler (ed.), Sozialstaat
EG? Die andere Dimension des Binnenmarktes. GuÈtersloh: Bertelsmann Stiftung.
Davignon, Etienne. 1981. `Europa am Ende oder vor einem neuen Aufschwung'. Pp. 167±91 in Ralf Dahrendorf (ed.), 1981. Trendwende: Europas
Wirtschaft in der Krise. Vienna: Molden.
Dekker, Wisse. 1984. Europa 1990. Lecture at the Centre for European Policy
Studies in Brussels, 13 November 1984.
1985a. Die Zukunft einer EuropaÈischen Informationstechnologie im internationalen
Wettbewerb. Lecture at a conference of the `Statistisch-Volkswirtschaftliche
Gesellschaft' in Basel, 4 February 1985.
1985b. Europa 1990: Ein Massnahmen-Katalog ± Fortschritte und Fortsetzung.
Lecture to the `Deutsche Gesellschaft fuÈr AuswaÈrtige Politik e.V'. In Bonn,
9 October 1985.
1989. `The American Response to Europe 1992'. European Affairs No. 2:
105±10.
1996. Levenslang Philips. Amsterdam: Balans.
Delapierre, Michel, and Jean-BenoõÃt Zimmermann. 1994. `The Computer
Industry: Reshaping European Competitiveness in a Global Industry'. Pp.
217±36 in U. Muldur and R. Petrella (eds.), Directorate-General Science,
Research and Development. The European Community and the Globalization
of Technology and the Economy. Brussels: Commission of the European
Communities.
Delors, Jacques. 1981. `Frankreich zwischen Reform und Gegenreform'. In
R. Dahrendorf (ed.), Trendwende. Europas Wirtschaft in der Krise. Vienna:
Molden.
1988a. La France par l'Europe. Paris: ClistheÁne-Grasset (Our Europe. London:
Verso, 1991).
1988b. `FuÈr ein soziales Europa'. Bundesarbeitsblatt 11.
1988c. Preface to the Cecchini-Report, EUROPA '92. Der Vorteil des Binnenmarktes. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
1991. `Wir muÈssen Grossmacht werden'. Interview in Der Spiegel.
292
Bibliography
1992. Le Nouveau Concert EuropeÂen. Paris: Editions Odile Jacob.
1993. `Entwicklungsperspektiven der EuropaÈischen Gemeinschaft'. Aus
Politik und Zeitgeschichte 1.
Deppe, Frank, and Michael Felder. 1993. Zur Post-Maastricht-Krise der EuropaÈischen Gemeinschaft (EG). Arbeitspapier No. 10, Forschungsgruppe EuropaÈische Gemeinschaften (FEG) am Institut fuÈr Politikwissenschaft der
Philipps-UniversitaÈt Marburg, Marburg.
De Ruyt, Jean. 1989. L'Acte Unique EuropeÂen. Brussels: Editions de l'UniversiteÂ
de Bruxelles.
De Zwaan, J.W. 1986. `The Single European Act: Conclusion of a Unique
Document'. Common Market Law Review 23.
Doutriaux, Yves. 1992. Le Traite sur l'Union EuropeÂenne. Paris: Colin.
Dreyer, Marion. 1993. Akzeptanzmodelle der EG-Politik zur Bio- und Gentechnologie. Ein (soziologischer) Nachruf auf CUBE. Florence: EuropaÈisches
Hochschulinstitut.
Durant, John (ed.) 1992. Biotechnology in Public. A Review of Recent Research.
London: Science Museum.
Durant, John, Martin Bauer and George Gaskell. 1998. Biotechnology in the
Public Sphere: A European Source Book. London: Science Museum.
Ebbinghaus, Bernhard, and Jelle Visser. 1994. `Barrieren und Wege ``grenzenloser SolidaritaÈt'': Gewerkschaften und EuropaÈische Integration'. In
W. Streeck (ed.), Staat und VerbaÈnde. Special issue of Politische Vierteljahresschrift, No. 25. Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag.
Ehlermann, Claus-Dieter. 1987. `The Internal Market Following the Single
European Act'. Common Market Law Review 24.
1988. `Die BeschluÈsse des BruÈsseler Sondergipfels: Erfolg einer Gesamtstrategie der Delors-Kommission'. Integration 2.
Eichener, Volker, and Helmut Voelzkow. 1994. `EuropaÈische Regulierung im
È berraschungen aus BruÈssel und ein erster Versuch ihrer
Arbeitsschutz: U
ErklaÈrung'. In V. Eichener and H. Voelzkow (eds.), EuropaÈische Integration
und verbandliche Interessenvermittlung. Marburg: Metropolis.
EITIRT (European Information Technology Industry Roundtable). 1995.
Europe and the Global Information Society: Proposals for the Implementation of
Priority Applications by the European IT Industry. Brussels: EITIRT, January.
È ber den Prozess der Zivilization. Wandlungen der
Elias, Norbert. [1969] 1977. U
Gesellschaft. Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp, 3rd edition.
Endo, Ken. 1998. Political Leadership in the European Community: The Role of the
Commission Presidency under Jacques Delors, 1985±1995. New York: St.
Martin's Press.
Engel, Christian. 1991. `Regionen in der EuropaÈischen Gemeinschaft: Eine
integrationspolitische Rollensuche'. Integration 1.
Engel, Christian, and Christine Borrmann. 1991. Vom Konsens zur Mehrheitsentscheidung. EG-Entscheidungsverfahren und nationale Interessenpolitik nach
der Einheitlichen EuropaÈischen Akte. Bonn: Europa Union Verlag.
Engel, Christian, and Wolfgang Wessels (eds.). 1992. From Luxembourg to
Maastricht: Institutional Change in the European Community after the Single
European Act. Bonn: Europa Union.
Bibliography
293
Ernst & Young. 1994. Biotechnology's Economic Impact in Europe: A Survey of Its
Future Role in Competitiveness. Brussels: SAGB.
1995. Biotech 1995. Brussels: SAGB.
ERT (European Roundtable of Industrialists). 1984. `Missing Links: Upgrading
Europe's Transborder Ground Transport Infrastructure'. Brussels: ERT.
1985. `Changing Scales'. Brussels: ERT.
1986. `Making Europe Work'. Brussels: ERT.
1991a. `Missing Networks: A European Challenge'. Brussels: ERT.
1991b. `Reshaping Europe'. Brussels: ERT.
1992. `Rebuilding Con®dence. An Action Plan for Europe'. Brussels: ERT.
1994. `European Competitiveness. The Way to Growth and Jobs'. Brussels:
ERT.
1995. `Education for Europeans ± Towards the Learning Society'. Brussels:
ERT.
1997. `Investing in Knowledge ± The Integration of Technology in Europe'.
Brussels: ERT.
1998. `Job Creation and Competitiveness through Innovation'. Brussels:
ERT.
Esping-Andersen, GoÈsta. 1990. The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Esser, Josef. 1993. `Technologieentwicklung in der Triade. Folgen fuÈr die
europaÈische Technologiegemeinschaft'. Pp. 21±42 in Werner SuÈss and
Gerhard Becher (eds.), Politik und Technologieentwicklung in Europa. Berlin:
Duncker & Humblot.
ETUC (European Trade Union Confederation). 1988. Anhang zum TaÈtigkeitsbericht 85/87. Brussels.
1991. Anhang zum TaÈtigkeitsbericht 88/90. Brussels.
EUREKA. 1989. Annual Report. Brussels: EUREKA Secretariat.
1994. Annual Report. Brussels: EUREKA Secretariat.
EuropaBio. 1997. Benchmarking the Competitiveness of Biotechnology in Europe.
Brussels.
Everling, Ulrich. 1990. `Von der FreizuÈgigkeit der Arbeitnehmer zum EuropaÈischen BuÈrgerrecht?' in G. Nicolaysen and H.-J. Rabe (eds.), EuropaÈisches
Arbeits- und Sozialrecht. Europarecht-Beiheft 1. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
1993. `Die Entwicklung des europaÈischen Wirtschaftsrechts'. In H.A. Winkler
and H. Kaelble (eds.), Nationalismus ± NationalitaÈten ± SupranationalitaÈt.
Stuttgart: Klett-Cotta.
Falke, Josef. 1993. `Von der Implementation zur Selbstimplementation? Zur
Kontrolle der Anwendung des Gemeinschaftsrechts in den Mitgliedstaaten'. In H. Meulemann and A. Elting-Camus (eds.), 26. Deutscher
Soziologentag. LebensverhaÈltnisse und soziale Kon¯ikte im neuen Europa.
Tagungsband II: Sektionen, Arbeits- und Ad hoc-Gruppen. Opladen:
Westdeutscher Verlag.
Falkner, Gerda. 1994. SupranationalitaÈt trotz Einstimmigkeit: Entscheidungsmuster
der EU am Beispiel Sozialpolitik. Bonn: Europa Union.
FAST (Forecasting and Assessment in Science and Technology). 1984. Eurofutures: The Challenge of Innovation. London: Butterworths.
294
Bibliography
Fels, Gerhard. 1989. `Die Sozialcharta oÈkonomisch gesehen'. In W. DaÈubler
(ed.), Sozialstaat EG? Die andere Dimension des Binnenmarktes. GuÈtersloh:
Bertelsmann Stiftung.
Fennema, Meindert. 1982. International Networks of Banks and Industry. The
Hague: Nijhoff.
Fennema, Meindert, and Huibert Schijf. 1985 `The Transnational Network'.
Pp. 250±66 in Fram N. Stokman, Rolf Ziegler and John Scott, Networks of
Corporate Power. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Ferrera, Maurizio. 1993. EC Citizens and Social Protection. Main Results from a
Eurobarometer Survey. Brussels.
Fielder, Nicola. 1997. Western European Integration in the 1980s. The Origins of
the Single Market. Bern, Frankfurt, New York: Peter Lang.
Flora, Peter. 1993. `Europa als Sozialstaat'. In B. SchaÈfers (ed.), LebensverhaÈltnisse und soziale Kon¯ikte im neuen Europa. Verhandlungen des 26. Deutschen
Soziologentages in DuÈsseldorf 1992, Frankfurt/Main: Campus.
Franzmeyer, Fritz, Bernhard Seidel and Christian Weise. 1993. Die Reform der
EG-Strukturfonds von 1988. Konzeption, Umsetzung, Weiterentwicklung aus
deutscher Sicht. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.
Garrett, Geoffrey, and Barry R. Weingast. 1993. `Ideas, Interests, and Institutions: Constructing the European Community's Internal Market'. In
J. Goldstein and R.O. Keohane (eds.), Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs,
Institutions, and Political Change. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Gazzo, Marina (ed.). 1985. Towards European Union. From the `Crocodile' to the
European Council in Milan (28±29 June 1985). Brussels, Luxembourg:
Agence Europe.
1986. Towards European Union II. From the European Council in Milan to the
Signing of the European Single Act. Brussels, Luxembourg: Agence Europe.
Genscher, Hans-Dietrich. 1981. `Jetzt die EuropaÈische Union schaffen!' Speech
on 12 December 1981 to the XXVII Congress of the Europa-Union
Deutschland in Bremen. Bonn: Europa-Union Deutschland.
1995. Erinnerungen. Berlin: Siedler.
George, Stephen. 1990. An Awkward Partner. Britain in the European Community.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
1991. Politics and Policy in the European Community. Oxford: Oxford University
Press, 2nd Edition.
1992. `Intergovernmentalism, Supranationalism and the Future Development
of the European Community'. Paper presented to the Pan-European Conference on International Relations, Heidelberg, September.
1993. `Supranational Actors and Domestic Politics: Integration Theory
Reconsidered in the Light of the Single European Act and Maastricht'.
Paper presented to the Political Studies Association Annual Conference,
University of Leicester, April.
Gerbet, Pierre. 1995. La France et l'inteÂgration europeÂenne. Bern: Lang.
Gerlach, Michael. 1992. Alliance Capitalism. The Social Organization of Japanese
Business. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Gill, Stephen. 1991. American Hegemony and the Trilateral Commission. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Bibliography
295
Grande, Edgar, and JuÈrgen HaÈusler. 1994. Industrieforschung und Forschungspolitik. Staatliche Steuerungspotentiale in der Informationstechnik. Frankfurt/
Main: Campus.
1996. `Demokratische Legitimation und europaÈische Integration'. Leviathan
3: 339±59.
Grant, Charles. 1994. Delors. Inside the House that Jacques Built. London:
Nicholas Brealey Publishing.
Grant, Wyn. 1989. Government and Industry. A Comparative Analysis of the US,
Canada and the UK. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.
1990. `Industrial Policy'. Pp. 25±42 in James Simmie and Roger King (eds.),
The State in Action: Public Policy and Politics. London: Pinter Publishers.
Grant, Wyn, William Paterson, and Charles Whitson. 1989. Government and the
Chemical Industry. A Comparative Study of Britain and West Germany.
Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Green Cowles, Maria L. 1994. `The Politics of Big Business in the European
Community: Setting the Agenda for a New Europe'. Dissertation, American University, Washington DC.
1995. `Setting the Agenda for a New Europe: The ERT and EC 1992'. Journal
of Common Market Studies 33(4): 501±26.
1997. `Organizing Industrial Coalitions: A Challenge to the Future?'
Pp. 116±40 in Helen Wallace and Alasdair R. Young (eds.), Participation
and Policy-Making in the European Union. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Grosser, Alfred. 1989. Frankreich und seine Aussenpolitik. 1944 bis heute. Munich:
Deutscher Taschenbuch Verlag.
Grossmann, Susi, and Daniela Decurtins. 1993. `Die Bedeutung sozialer Vernetzung fuÈr die GruÈndung der ZuÈrcher Kantonalbank'. In Jakob Tanner
and Youssef Cassis (eds.), Banken und Kredit in der Schweiz (1850±1930).
Zurich: Chronos.
Grote, JuÈrgen-R. 1990. `Steuerungsprobleme in transnationalen BeratungsgreÈ ber soziale Kosten unkoordinierter Regulierung in der EG'. Jahrmien. U
buch fuÈr Staatswissenschaften 4: 227±56.
Guild, Elspeth (ed.). 1999. The Legal Framework and Social Consequences of Free
Movement of Persons in the European Union. The Hague: Kluwer Law International.
Gulman, Claus. 1987. `The Single European Act ± Some Remarks from a
Danish Perspective'. Common Market Law Review 24.
Haas, Ernst B. 1958. The Uniting of Europe. Political, Social, and Economic Forces
1950±1957. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.
1964. Beyond the Nation-State: Functionalism and International Organization.
Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.
Hagedoorn, John, and Jos Schakenraad. 1990. `Strategic Partnering and Technological Co-operation'. Pp. 171±91 in Ben Dankbaar, John Groenewegen
and Hans Schenk (eds.), Perspectives in Industrial Organization. Boston:
Kluwer.
Hagen, Kare. 1992. `The Social Dimension: A Quest for a European Welfare
State'. In Z. Ferge and J.E. Kolberg (eds.), Social Policy in a Changing
Europe. Frankfurt/Main and Boulder, Colo.: Campus and Westview.
296
Bibliography
Hallstein, Walter. 1969. Der unvollendete Bundesstaat. EuropaÈische Erfahrungen
und Erkenntnisse. DuÈsseldorf and Vienna: Econ.
HaÈnsch, Klaus. 1989. `Die auswaÈrtige Innenpolitik. Zum Demokratiede®zit der
EuropaÈischen Gemeinschaft'. In H. Elsenhans, G. Junne, G. Kiersch and
B. Pollmann (eds.), Frankreich ± Europa ± Weltpolitik. Festschrift fuÈr Gilbert
Ziebura. Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag.
Haywood, Elizabeth. 1993. `The European Policy of FrancËois Mitterrand'.
Journal of Common Market Studies 31(2).
Hirsch, Joachim. 1995. Der nationale Wettbewerbsstaat. Staat, Demokratie und
Politik im globalen Kapitalismus. Berlin: Edition ID-Archiv.
Hooghe, Liesbet (ed.). 1996. Cohesion Policy and European Integration: Building
Multi-level Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hort, Peter. 1988. `Eine Bilanz der deutschen EG-PraÈsidentschaft'. EuropaArchiv 15.
House of Lords Select Committee on the European Communities. 1984. Session
1984±5. 8th Report: Esprit. London: Her Majesty's Stationery Of®ce.
Howe, Geoffrey. 1984. `Grossbritannien und die Bundesrepublik Deutschland
als europaÈische Partner'. Europa-Archiv 21.
1985. `Europa ± unsere Zukunft'. Europa-Archiv 29.
1994. Con¯ict of Loyalty. London: Macmillan.
Hrbek, Rudolf. 1982. ```Relance EuropeÂenne'' 1981?' Integration 1.
1996. `Kommission'. Pp. 180±87 in Beate Kohler-Koch and Wichard Woyke
(eds.), Die EuropaÈische Union. Munich: Beck.
Inglehart, Ronald. 1977. The Silent Revolution: Changing Values and Political
Styles among Western Publics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Jachtenfuchs, Markus, and Beate Kohler-Koch. 1996. `Regieren im dynamischen Mehrebenensystem'. In M. Jachtenfuchs and B. Kohler-Koch
(eds.), EuropaÈische Integration. Opladen: Leske & Budrich.
Jessop, Bob. 1995. `Die Zukunft des Nationalstaats: Erosion oder ReorganizaÈ berlegungen zu Westeuropa'. In EuropaÈische Integration? GrundsaÈtzliche U
tion und politische Regulierung ± Aspekte, Dimensionen, Perspektiven, Study of
the Forschungsgruppe EuropaÈische Gemeinschaften (FEG), No. 5, University of Marburg, Marburg.
Jones, Erik. 1993. `Small Countries and the Franco-German Relationship'. In
P. McCarthy (ed.), France±Germany 1983±1993. New York: St. Martin's
Press.
Junne, Gerd. 1992. `Konfrontation zwischen Europa und Japan?' Pp. 287±98 in
Klaus W. Grewlich (ed.), Europa im Technologiewettlauf. Der Weltmarkt wird
zum Binnenmarkt. GuÈtersloh: Bertelsmann.
Kasakos, Panos. 1991. `Die neue EG-Agenda und die griechische EuropaPolitik'. Europa-Archiv 7.
Kaufmann-BuÈhler, Werner. 1994. `Deutsche Europapolitik nach dem Karlsruher Urteil: MoÈglichkeiten und Hemmnisse'. Integration 1.
Kennedy, Kevin. 1989. `Competitiveness and Technology Policy'. International
Journal of Technology Management 4(3).
Bibliography
297
Keohane, Robert O., and Stanley Hoffmann. 1991. `Institutional Change in
Europe in the 1980s'. Pp. 1±39 in R. Keohane and S. Hoffmann (eds.), The
New European Community. Decisionmaking and Institutional Change.
Boulder, Colo.: Westview.
Kleinhenz, Gerhard. 1990. `Die sozialpolitische Bedeutung der Verwirklichung
des Binnenmarktes'. In R. Birk (ed.), Die soziale Dimension des EuropaÈischen
Binnenmarktes. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
Kleinknecht, Alfred. 1987. Innovation Pattern in Crisis and Prosperity: Schumpeter's Long Cycle Reconsidered. New York: St. Martin's Press.
Kohler-Koch, Beate. 1992. `Interessen und Integration. Die Rolle organisierter
Interessen im westeuropaÈischen Integrationsprozeû'. In M. Kreile (ed.), Die
Integration Europas. Special issue of Politische Vierteljahresschrift, No. 23:
81±119.
Kohler-Koch, Beate, and Hans-Wolfgang Platzer. 1986. `Tripartismus ± Bedingungen und Perspektiven des sozialen Dialogs in der EG'. Integration 4.
KoÈnig, Thomas, Elmar Rieger and Hermann Schmitt (eds.). 1996. Das europaÈische Mehrebenensystem. Frankfurt/Main and New York: Campus.
Konstanty, Reinhold, and Bruno Zwingmann. 1989. `EuropaÈische Einigung
und Gesundheitsschutz in der Arbeitsumwelt'. WSI. Mitteilungen 10.
KraÈgenau Henry, and Wolfgang Wetter. 1993. EuropaÈische Wirtschafts- und
WaÈhrungsunion ± vom Werner-Plan zum Vertrag von Maastricht. EinfuÈhrung
und Dokumentation. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
1994. `EuropaÈische Wirtschafts- und WaÈhrungsunion (EWWU) ± Vom
Werner-Plan bis Maastricht'. In R. Caesar and H.-E. Scharrer (eds.),
Maastricht: KoÈnigsweg oder Irrweg zur Wirtschaft- und WaÈhrungsunion? Bonn:
Europa Union.
Kramer, Heinz. 1985. `Die EuropaÈische Gemeinschaft auf neuen Wegen?' EGMagazin 8.
Kreile, Michael (ed.). 1991. Europa 1992. Konzeptionen, Strategien, Auswirkungen. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
Krummenacher, Franz. 1997. `Nationalismus und europaÈische Einigung'. MA
thesis, University of Zurich, Sociological Institute.
Lange, Peter. 1992. `The Politics of the Social Dimension'. In A.M. Sbragia
(ed.), Europolitics. Institutions and Policymaking in the `New' European Community. Washington DC: Brookings Institution.
1993. `Maastricht and the Social Protocol: Why Did They Do It?' Politics and
Society 21(1).
Laursen, Finn, and Sophie Vanhoonacker (eds.). 1992. The Intergovernmental
Conference on Political Union. Institutional Reforms, New Policies and International Identity of the European Community. Maastricht: European Institute
of Public Administration.
1994. The Rati®cation of the Maastricht Treaty. Issues, Debates and Future
Implications. Maastricht: European Institute of Public Administration.
Lederman, Leonard. 1985. `Science and Technology in Europe: A Survey'.
Science and Technology Policy 12(3).
Leibfried, Stephan, and Paul Pierson (eds.). 1995a. European Social Policy:
Between Fragmentation and Integration. Washington DC: Brookings.
298
Bibliography
1995b. `Semi-Sovereign Welfare States: Social Policy in a Multi-Tiered
Europe'. In Stephan Leibfried and Paul Pierson (eds.), European Social
Policy: Between Fragmentation and Integration. Washington DC: Brookings.
1996. `Social Policy'. In H. Wallace and W. Wallace (eds.), Policymaking in the
European Union. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Lepsius, M. Rainer. 1991. `Nationalstaat oder NationalitaÈtenstaat als Modell fuÈr
die Weiterentwicklung der EuropaÈischen Gemeinschaft'. In R. Wildenmann
(ed.), Staatswerdung Europas? Optionen fuÈr eine EuropaÈische Union. BadenBaden: Nomos.
Lequesne, Christian. 1989. `Europapolitik unter Mitterrand: Die franzoÈsische
PraÈsidentschaft als Etappenziel'. Integration 4.
1993. Paris ± Bruxelles. Comment se fait la politique europeÂenne de la France.
Paris: Presses de la Fondation nationale des sciences politiques.
Lindberg, Leon N., and Stuart A. Scheingold. 1970. Europe's Would-Be Polity.
Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Lipp, Ernst-Moritz, and Horst Reichert. 1991. `Kon¯iktfelder auf dem Weg zur
EuropaÈischen WaÈhrungsunion'. In M. Weber (ed.), Europa auf dem Weg zur
WaÈhrungsunion. Darmstadt: Wissenschaftliche Buchgesellschaft.
Lodge, Juliet. 1985. `European Union: A Qualitative Leap Forward?' The World
Today, 41(11).
Louis, Jean-Victor, and Denis Waelbroeck (eds.). 1989. La Commission au coeur
du systeÁme institutionnel. Brussels: Editions de l'Universite de Bruxelles.
Lowe, Philip. 1988. `The Reform of the Community's Structural Funds'.
Common Market Law Review: 25.
Ludlow, Peter. 1982. The Making of the European Monetary System: A Case
Study of the Politics of the European Community. London: Butterworth
Scienti®c.
1991. `The European Commission'. In R. Keohane and S. Hoffmann (eds.),
The New European Community. Decisionmaking and Institutional Change.
Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press.
McAleavey, Paul, and James Mitchell. 1994. `Industrial Regions and Lobbying
in the Structural Funds Reform Process'. Journal of Common Market Studies
32(2).
McDonald, Robert. 1985. `Greece after Pasok's Victory'. The World Today
41(7).
Marks, Gary. 1992. `Structural Policy in the European Community'. In A.M.
Sbragia (ed.), Europolitics. Institutions and Policymaking in the `New'
European Community. Washington DC: Brookings Institution.
Marks, Gary, Fritz W. Scharpf, Philippe C. Schmitter and Wolfgang Streeck
(eds.). 1996. Governance in the European Union. London: Sage.
Marshall, Thomas H. [1950] 1965. Class, Citizenship and Social Development.
Garden City, NY: Anchor Books.
1975. Social Policy. London: Hutchinson.
Mayes, David G. (ed.). 1997. The Evolution of the Single Market. Cheltenham:
Edward Elgar.
Mertes, Alois. 1983. `Die Europapolitik der Bundesregierung ± KontinuitaÈt und
Aufbruch'. Integration 1.
Bibliography
299
Middlemas, Keith. 1995. Orchestrating Europe. The Informal Politics of the
European Union 1973±1995. London: Fontana Press.
Missbach, Andreas. 1999. Das Klima zwischen Nord und SuÈd. Eine regulationstheoretische Untersuchung des Nord-SuÈd-Kon¯ikts in der Klimapolitik der
Vereinten Nationen. MuÈnster: WestfaÈlisches Dampfboot.
Mùller, érstrùm J. 1988. `The Nordic Angle III: The Single European Act ± A
Danish View'. The World Today, November.
Mommsen, Wolfgang J. 1969. Das Zeitalter des Imperialismus. Frankfurt/Main:
Fischer.
Moravcsik, Andrew. 1991. `Negotiating the Single European Act: National
Interests and Conventional Statecraft in the European Community'. International Organization 45(1): 19±56.
1993. `Preferences and Power in the European Community: A Liberal Intergovernmentalist Approach'. Journal of Common Market Studies 31(4).
1998. The Choice for Europe. Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to
Maastricht. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
1999. `A New Statecraft? Supranational Entrepreneurs and International
Cooperation'. International Organization 53(2): 267±306.
Moreau, Jacques, and Michel Richonnier. 1983. Quelle strateÂgie europeÂenne pour
la France dans les anneÂes 80? Paris: La Documentation FrancËaise.
Mosley, Hugh G. 1990. `The Social Dimension of European Integration'. International Labour Review 129.
 lectroMoynot, Jean-Louis. 1987. `The Left, Industrial Policy and the FilieÁre E
nique'. Pp. 263±90 in George Ross, Stanley Hoffmann and Sylvia Malzacher, The Mitterrand Experiment. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Mueller, Frank, and John Purcell. 1992. `The Europeanization of Manufacturing and the Decentralization of Bargaining: Multinational Management
Strategies in the European Automobile Industry'. International Journal of
Human Resource Management 3(1).
MuÈller, Joachim. 1990. European Collaboration in Advanced Technology.
Amsterdam: Elsevier.
MuÈnch, Richard. 1993. Das Projekt Europa. Zwischen Nationalstaat, regionaler
Autonomie und Weltgesellschaft. Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp.
Mytelka Krieger, Lynn. 1993. `Strengthening the Relevance of European
Science and Technology Programmes to Industrial Competitiveness: The
Case of ESPRIT'. Pp. 56±63 in Marc Hubert (ed.), The Impact of Globalization on Europe's Firms and Industries. London: Pinter Publishers.
1995. `Dancing with Wolves: Global Oligopolies and Strategic Partnerships'.
Pp. 182±204 in John Hagedoorn (ed.), Technical Change and the World
Economy. Convergence and Divergence in Technology Strategies. Aldershot:
Edward Elgar.
Mytelka Krieger, Lynn, and Michel Delapierre. 1987. `The Alliance Strategies
of European Firms in the Information Technology Industry and the Role of
ESPRIT'. Journal of Common Market Studies 26(2): 231±53.
Narjes, Karl-Heinz. 1988. `Europe's Technological Challenge: A View from the
European Commission'. Science and Public Policy 15(6): 395±402.
Nicolaysen, Gert. 1991. Europarecht I. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
300
Bibliography
Niggli, Peter. 1989. `Auf den Tisch klopfen'. Bilanz No. 3: 164±8.
NoeÈl, Emil. 1987. `The European Community Today'. Government and Opposition 22(1).
È ber BedinNollert, Michael. 1992. Interessenvermittlung und sozialer Kon¯ikt. U
gungen und Folgen neokorporatistischer Kon¯iktregelung. Pfaffenweiler: Centaurus.
1996. `Verbandliche Interessenvertretung in der EuropaÈischen Union: Ein¯uûressourcen und faktische Ein¯uûnahme'. Zeitschrift fuÈr Politikwissenschaft 6(3): 647±67.
1997. `VerbaÈndelobbying in der EuropaÈischen Union ± EuropaÈische DachverbaÈnde im Vergleich'. Pp. 107±36 in Ulrich von Alemann and Bernhard
Wessels (eds.), VerbaÈnde in vergleichender Perspektive. Berlin: Sigma.
Nye, Joseph S. 1971. `Comparing Common Markets: A Revised Neo-Functionalist Model'. In L.N. Lindberg and S.A. Scheingold (eds.), Regional
Integration. Theory and Research. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University
Press.
Offe, Claus. 1969. `Politische Herrschaft und Klassenstrukturen. Zur Analyse
spaÈtkapitalistischer Gesellschaftssysteme'. Pp. 155±89 in Gisela Kress and
Dieter Senghaas (eds.), Politikwissenschaft. Eine EinfuÈhrung in ihre Probleme.
Frankfurt/Main: EuropaÈische Verlagsanstalt.
Offe, Claus, and Helmut Wiesenthal. 1980. `Two Logics of Collective Action.
Theoretical Notes on Social Class and Organizational Form'. Political Power
and Social Theory 1: 67±115.
Ohmae, Kenichi. 1985. Macht der Triade. Die neue Form des weltweiten Wettbewerbs. Wiesbaden: Gabler.
Olson, Mancur. 1968. Die Logik des kollektiven Handelns. KollektivguÈter und die
Theorie der Gruppen. TuÈbingen: Mohr.
Padoa-Schioppa, Tommaso. 1987. Ef®ciency, Stability, and Equity: A Strategy for
the Evolution of the Economic System of the European Community: A Report.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Perez, Carlota. 1983. `Structural Change and Assimilation of New Technology
in the Economic and Social Systems'. Futures 15(5): 357±75.
1985. `Microelectronics, Long Waves and World Structural Change: New
Perspectives for Developing Countries'. World Development 13(3): 441±63.
Pescatore, Pierre. 1986. `Die einheitliche EuropaÈische Akte. Eine ernste Gefahr
fuÈr den Gemeinsamen Markt'. Europa-Recht 2.
Peterson, John. 1991. `Technology Policy in Europe: Explaining the Framework
Programme and Eureka in Theory and Practice'. Journal of Common Market
Studies 29: 269±90.
Pierson, Paul. 1998. `The Path to European Integration: A Historical-Institutionalist Analysis'. In W. Sandholtz and A. Stone Sweet (eds.), European
Integration and Supranational Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Pierson, Paul, and Stephan Leibfried. 1995. `The Dynamics of Social Policy
Integration'. In S. Leibfried and P. Pierson (eds.), European Social Policy:
Between Fragmentation and Integration. Washington DC: Brookings.
Platzer, Hans-Wolfgang. 1994. `Sozialpolitik und soziale Integration in der
Bibliography
301
EuropaÈischen Union ± Bedingungen, Perspektiven und Grenzen im Spannungsfeld von Markt- und Politikintegration'. In B. Dietz, J. Bardelmann
and T. SchaÈfer (eds.), Die Soziale Zukunft Europas. Bedingungen und Perspektiven einer EuropaÈischen `Sozialen Integration'. Giessen: Focus.
Raith, Werner. 1979. Florenz vor der Renaissance. Der Weg einer Stadt aus dem
Mittelalter. Frankfurt/Main: Campus.
Ridinger, Rudolf. 1991. Technologiekooperation in Westeuropa. Die Suche nach
grenzuÈbergreifenden Antworten auf technologiepolitische Herausforderungen.
Hamburg: R. Kraemer.
Ringrose, Marjorie Anne. 1994. `The Bureaucratic Imperative: Esprit and the
Making of British Foreign Policy'. Thesis submitted for the PhD in International Relations, London School of Economics and Political Science,
University of London.
Robinson, Jeffrey J. 1995. `The State of the (European) Union. From the Single
Market to Maastricht, from Singular Events to General Theories'. World
Politics 47: 441±65.
Rokkan, Stein. 1975. `Dimensions of State Formation and Nation-Building'.
Pp. 562±600 in Charles Tilly (ed.), The Formation of National States in
Western Europe. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
1981. `Territories, Nations, Parties: Toward a Geoeconomic-Geopolitical
Model for the Explanation of Variations within Western Europe'.
Pp. 70±95 in Richard L. Merritt and Bruce Russett (eds.), From National
Development to Global Community. Essays in Honor of Karl W. Deutsch.
London: Allen & Unwin.
Ross, George. 1995a. Jacques Delors and European Integration. Cambridge: Polity
Press, and Oxford: Blackwell.
1995b. `Assessing the Delors Era and Social Policy'. In S. Leibfried and
P. Pierson (eds.), European Social Policy: Between Fragmentation and Integration. Washington DC: Brookings.
Ross, George, Stanley Hoffmann and Sylvia Malzacher (eds.). 1987. The
Mitterrand Experiment. Cambridge: Polity Press.
RothenbuÈhler, AndreÂ. 1997. `Regionale IdentitaÈt und europaÈische Integration'.
MA thesis, University of Zurich, Sociological Institute.
Sacchi, Stefan. 1998. Politische Potentiale in modernen Gesellschaften. Zur Formierung links-gruÈner und neokonservativer Bewegungen in Europa und den
USA. Frankfurt/Main and New York: Campus.
SAGB (Senior Advisory Group Biotechnology). 1990a. Community Policy for
Biotechnology: Priorities and Actions. Brussels.
1990b. Economic Bene®ts and European Competitiveness. Brussels.
1990c. Creation of a Community Task Force and Independent Consultative Body.
Brussels.
1994a. Biotechnology Policy in the European Union. Prescriptions for Growth,
Competitiveness and Employment. Brussels.
1994b. Biotechnology Policy in the European Union. Competitiveness, Investment
and the `Cycle of Innovation'. Brussels.
Sand, Stephanie. [1990] 1992. Das Europa der Konzerne. Munich: Heyne.
302
Bibliography
Sandholtz, Wayne. 1992. High-Tech Europe: The Politics of International Cooperation. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Sandholtz, Wayne, 1993. `Choosing Union: Monetary Politics and Maastricht'.
International Organization 47(1): 1±39.
Sandholtz, Wayne, and Alec Stone Sweet (eds.) 1998. European Integration and
Supranational Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Sandholtz, Wayne, and John Zysman. 1989. `1992 ± Recasting the European
Bargain'. World Politics. 42(1), October.
Savoini, Carlo. 1984. `Der soziale Dialog in der Gemeinschaft'. Soziales Europa
2.
Scharpf, Fritz. 1994. `Community and Autonomy: Multi-Level Policy-Making
in the European Union'. Journal of European Public Policy 1(2).
Schlecht, Otto. 1990. Grundlagen und Perspektiven der Sozialen Marktwirtschaft.
TuÈbingen: Mohr.
Schmid, Josef. 1995. Wohlfahrtsstaaten im Vergleich. Stand, Perspektiven und
Probleme der Organization und Finanzierung sozialer Sicherungssysteme.
Opladen: Leske & Budrich.
Schmidt, Susanne K. 1998. Liberalisierung in Europa. Die Rolle der EuropaÈischen
Kommission. Frankfurt/Main and New York: Campus.
Schmitter, Philippe C. 1971. `A Revised Theory of Regional Integration'. In
L.N. Lindberg and S.A. Scheingold (eds.), Regional Integration. Theory and
Research. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Schneider, Volker, and Raymund Werle. 1989. `Vom Regime zum korporativen
Akteur. Zur institutionellen Dynamik der EuropaÈischen Gemeinschaft'. In
B. Kohler-Koch (ed.), Regime in den internationalen Beziehungen. BadenBaden: Nomos.
Schnorpfeil, Willi. 1993. EuropaÈische Sozialpolitik und industrielle Beziehungen seit
der Einheitlichen EuropaÈischen Akte (EEA). Policies, Netzwerke und Entscheidungsverfahren. Mannheimer Zentrum fuÈr EuropaÈische Sozialforschung
(MZES), Arbeitspapier AB II/No. 1, Mannheim.
1994. Die EuropaÈisierung sozialpolitischer Teilbereiche in der EuropaÈischen Gemeinschaft. Mannheimer Zentrum fuÈr EuropaÈische Sozialforschung
(MZES), Arbeitspapier AB II/No. 4, Mannheim.
Scholz, Rupert. 1995. `EuropaÈische Union ± Voraussetzung einer institutionellen Verfassungsordnung'. Pp. 113±27 in LuÈder Gerken (ed.), Europa
zwischen Ordnungswettbewerb und Harmonisierung. Berlin: Springer.
Schulte, Bernd. 1993a. `Die Entwicklung der europaÈischen Sozialpolitik'. In
H.A. Winkler and H. Kaelble (eds.), Nationalismus ± NationalitaÈten ±
SupranationalitaÈt. Stuttgart: Klett-Cotta.
1993b. `EinfuÈhrung'. In Soziale Sicherheit in der EG. 2. Au¯age, Munich:
Beck.
Schumpeter, Joseph. 1939. Business Cycles, 2 vols. New York: McGraw Hill.
Scott, John. 1991. Social Network Analysis. A Handbook. Beverly Hills and
London: Sage.
SecreÂtariat d'Etat aupreÁs du Premier Ministre and Commissariat GeÂneÂral du
Plan. 1983. Quelle strateÂgie europeÂenne pour la France dans les anneÂes 80?
Rapport du groupe de travail sur l'Europe. Paris: La documentation
francËaise, April.
Bibliography
303
SecreÂtariat d'Etat au Plan. 1989. La France, l'Europe. Xe Plan 1989±1992. Paris:
La documentation francËaise.
Seifert, Franz, and Helge Torgersen. 1996. `Die Bewertung der Bio- und
È sterreich im EU-Vergleich'. SWS-Rundschau 36: 47±72.
Gentechnologie. O
Seitz, Konrad. 1985. `SDI ± Die technologische Herausforderung fuÈr Europa'.
Europa-Archiv 13.
1991. Die japanisch-amerikanische Herausforderung. Munich: Bonn Aktuell.
Senker, Jacqueline (ed.). 1998. Biotechnology and Competitive Advantage.
Europe's Firms and the US Challenge. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Servan-Schreiber, Jacques J. 1968. Die amerikanische Herausforderung. Hamburg:
Hoffmann & Campe.
Sharp, Margaret. 1986. `Biotechnology: Watching and Waiting'. Pp. 161±212 in
M. Sharp (ed.), Europe and the New Technologies. Ithaca, NY: Cornell
University Press.
1989. `The Community and the New Technologies'. Pp. 202±20 in Juliet
Lodge (ed.), The European Community and the Challenge of the future. New
York: St. Martin's Press.
Sharp, Margaret, and Keith Pavitt. 1993. `Technology Policy in the 1990s: Old
Trends and New Realities'. Journal of Common Market Studies 12(2):
129±51.
Sidjanski, Dusan. 1992. L'avenir feÂdeÂraliste de l'Europe. La Communaute europeÂenne, des origines au traite de Maastricht. Paris: Presses Universitaires de
France.
Siebert, Gerd. 1989. `EG-Binnenmarkt und Gewerkschaften'. In Gerd Siebert
(ed.), Wenn der Binnenmarkt kommt. Neue Anforderungen an gewerkschaftliche
Politik. Frankfurt/Main: Nachrichten.
Silvia, Stephen J. 1991. `The Social Charter of the European Community'.
Industrial and Labor Relations Review 44.
Springer, Beverly. 1992. The Social Dimension of 1992: Europe Faces a New EC.
New York: Greenwood Press.
1996. `The March toward Monetary Integration: Europe and the Maastricht
Treaty'. Pp. 272±87 in C. Roe Goddard, John T. PasseÂ-Smith and John G.
Conklin (eds.), International Political Economy. State-Market Relations in the
Changing Global Order. Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner.
Stadlmann, Heinz. 1984. `Die EuropaÈische Gemeinschaft nach der franzoÈsischen RatspraÈsidentschaft. Die Bedeutung der gemeinsamen Rolle Frankreichs und der Bundesrepublik Deutschlands'. Europa-Archiv 15.
Starbatty, Joachim, and Uwe Vetterlein. 1989. `Spitzentechnologie oder innere
KohaÈsion: Ein technologiepolitischer Zielkon¯ikt in der EuropaÈischen
Gemeinschaft'. Europa-Archiv 5: 145±54.
1990. Die Technologiepolitik in der Gemeinschaft. Entstehung, Praxis und ordnungspolitische KonformitaÈt. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
Stavenhagen, Lutz G. 1991. `Durchbruch zur Politischen Union ± Vor dem
Maastrichter Gipfel'. Integration 4.
Stokman, Frans, Rolf Ziegler and John Scott. 1985. Networks of Corporate Power.
Cambridge: Polity Press.
Stone Sweet, Alec, and Wayne Sandholtz. 1998. `Integration, Supranational
Governance, and the Institutionalization of the European Polity'. In
304
Bibliography
W. Sandholtz and A. Stone Sweet (ed.), European Integration and Supranational Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Streeck, Wolfgang. 1991. `Interest Heterogeneity and Organizing Capacity'.
Pp. 161±98 in Roland Czada and Adrienne Windhoff-HeÂritier (eds.),
Political Choice. Frankfurt/Main: Campus.
1993. `The Rise and Decline of Neocorporatism'. In L. Ulman, B. Eichengreen and W.T. Dickens (eds.), Labor and an Integrated Europe. Washington
DC: Brookings Institution.
1994. `Neo-Voluntarism: A New European Social Policy Regime?' Paper
presented at a Conference on European Law in Context: Constitutional
Dimensions of European Economic Integration, European University Institute, Law Department, Florence, 14±15 April 1994.
1995. `From Market Making to State Building? Re¯ections on the Political
Economy of European Social Policy'. In S. Leibfried and P. Pierson (eds.),
European Social Policy: Between Fragmentation and Integration. Washington
DC: Brookings.
1996. `Neo-Voluntarism: A New European Social Policy Regime?' In
G. Marks, F.W. Scharpf, P.C. Schmitter and W. Streeck (eds.), Governance
in the European Union. London: Sage.
Streeck, Wolfgang, and Philippe C. Schmitter. 1991. `From National Corporatism to Transnational Pluralism: Organized Interests in the Single
European Market'. Politics and Society 19: 133±64.
Streil, Jochen. 1986. `Der Beitrag des Gerichtshofes der EuropaÈischen
Gemeinschaften zur Entwicklung des Sozialrechts in der Gemeinschaft'. In
H. Lichtenberg (ed.), Sozialpolitik in der EG. Referate der Tagung des
Arbeitskreises EuropaÈische Integration e.V. In Augsburg vom 18. ± 20. Oktober
1984. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
Sturm, Roland. 1992. `Konkurrenz oder Synergie? Nationale und europaÈische
Industriepolitik'. Pp. 234±53 in Michael Kreile (ed.), Die Integration
Europas. Special issue of Politische Vierteljahresschrift, No. 23. Opladen:
Westdeutscher Verlag.
Sutcliffe, John B. 1995. `Theoretical Aspects of the Development of European
Community Regional Policy'. Schweizerische Zeitschrift fuÈr Politische Wissenschaft 1(2/3).
Swann, Dennis (ed.). 1992. The Single European Market and Beyond. A Study of
the Wider Implications of the Single European Act. London and New York:
Routledge.
1996. European Economic Integration. The Common Market, European Union,
and Beyond. Cheltenham: Elgar.
Taylor, Paul. 1989. `The New Dynamics of EC in the 1980s'. In J. Lodge (ed.),
The European Community and the Challenge of the Future. New York: St.
Martin's Press.
Teague, Paul. 1989. The European Community: The Social Dimension. Labour
Market Policies for 1992. London: Kogan Page.
Teasdale, Anthony L. 1993. `The Life and Death of the Luxembourg Compromise'. Journal of Common Market Studies 31(4).
Thatcher, Margaret. 1993. The Downing Street Years. London: HarperCollins.
Bibliography
305
Therborn, GoÈran. 1997. `Europas kuÈnftige Stellung ± Das Skandinavien der
Welt?' Pp. 573±600 in Stefan Hradil and Stefan Immerfall (eds.), Die
westeuropaÈischen Gesellschaften. Opladen: Leske & Budrich.
Thorn, Gaston. 1984. `Die EuropaÈische Gemeinschaft ± war es ein Irrtum?'
Europa-Archiv 8.
Tiedemann, W.A. 1989. `Comments'. In Lammy Betten (ed.), The Future of
European Social Policy. Deventer and Boston: Kluwer Law and Taxation
Publishers.
Tilly, Charles (ed.). 1975. The Formation of National States in Western Europe.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Timmermann, Heiner. 1995. `Das Europa der Regionen nach den Maastrichter
BeschluÈssen: Motive und Wirkungen'. In Heiner Timmermann (ed.), Die
Kontinentwerdung Europas, Festschrift fuÈr Helmut Wagner. Berlin: Duncker &
Humblot.
ToÈmmel, Ingeborg. 1994. Staatliche Regulierung und europaÈische Integration: Die
Regionalpolitik der EG und ihre Implementation. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
Toth, A.G. 1986. `The Legal Status of the Declarations Annexed to the Single
European Act'. Common Market Law Review 23.
Traxler, Franz, and Phillippe C. Schmitter. 1994. `Perspektiven europaÈischer
Integration, verbandlicher Interessenvermittlung und Politikformulierung'.
Pp. 45±70 in Volker Eichener and Helmut Voelzkow (eds.), EuropaÈische
Integration und verbandliche Interessenvermittlung. Marburg: Metropolis.
Tsoukalis, Loukas. 1993. The New European Community. The Politics and
Economics of Integration. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2nd revised
edition.
Tulder, Rob van, and Gerd Junne. 1986. European Multinationals in Core
Technologies. Chichester: Wiley.
Tyszkiewicz, Zygmunt. 1989a. `European Social Policy ± Striking the Right
Balance'. European Affairs 4.
1989b. `Trouver le bon niveau pour le dialogue social'. In Fondation Europe
et SocieÂteÂ, Cahiers de la Fondation No. 12±13, CoheÂsion sociale et dialogue
social europeÂen dans la construction du marche inteÂrieur. Paris.
Ulman, Lloyd, Barry Eichengreen and William T. Dickens (eds.). 1993. Labor
and an Integrated Europe. Washington DC: Brookings.
UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development). 1994.
World Investment Report 1994: Transnational Corporations, Employment and
the Workplace. New York and Geneva.
1996: Investment, Trade and International Policy Arrangements. New York
and Geneva.
Ungerer, Werner. 1983a. `Europa-Politik unter deutscher PraÈsidentschaft im
RuÈckblick'. Aussenpolitik, No. 1.
1983b. `Deutsche EG-PraÈsidentschaft im RuÈckblick'. Aussenpolitik, No. 4.
1984. `EuropaÈische Perspektiven nach Fontainbleau'. Aussenpolitik, No. 2.
United Nations. Transnational Corporations and Management Division. 1993.
From the Common Market to EC 92. Regional Economic Integration in the
European Community and Transnational Corporations. New York.
Useem, Michael. 1984. The Inner Circle. London: Oxford University Press.
306
Bibliography
Uterwedde, Henrik. 1988. Die Wirtschaftspolitik der Linken in Frankreich. Programme und Praxis 1974±1986. Frankfurt and New York: Campus.
Vandamme, Jacques (ed.). 1985. New Dimensions in European Social Policy.
London: Croom Helm.
Vaubel, Roland. 1995. `Diskussionsbeitrag'. Pp. 129±34 in LuÈder Gerken
(ed.), Europa zwischen Ordnungswettbewerb und Harmonisierung. Berlin:
Springer.
Á l'EÂlyseÂe 1981±1995.
VeÂdrine, Hubert. 1996. Les mondes de FrancËois Mitterrand. A
Paris: Fayard.
Venturini, Patrick. 1988. 1992. The Social Dimension. Luxembourg: Of®ce for
Of®cial Publications of the European Communities.
Vernon, Raymond. 1994. Speech to the Academy of International Business
Conference, Boston, 4 November 1994.
Vogel, Jean. 1991. `Analyse socio-politique'. In Eliane Vogel-Polsky and Jean
Vogel, L'Europe social 1993: Illusion, alibi ouÁ reÂaliteÂ? Brussels: Editions de
l'Universite de Bruxelles.
Vogel-Polsky, Eliane. 1991. Die Sozialpolitik im europaÈischen Integrationsprozess.
Ed. European Parliament. Luxembourg: Of®ce for Of®cial Publications.
1994. `Maastricht ou la voie eÂtroite du social'. In M. TeloÁ (ed.), Quelle Union
sociale europeÂenne? Acquis institutionnel, acteurs et de®s. Brussels: Editions de
l'Universite de Bruxelles.
Volle, Angelika. 1989a. `Der Wandel Grossbritanniens vom zoÈgernden Aussenseiter zum widerspenstigen Partner in der EuropaÈischen Gemeinschaft'.
Politik und Zeitgeschichte 3: 89.
1989b. Grossbritannien und der europaÈische Einigungsprozess. Forschungsinstitut
der Deutschen Gesellschaft fuÈr AuswaÈrtige Politik. Arbeitspapier zur Internationalen Politik No. 51, Bonn: Europa Union Verlag.
Wallace, Helen. 1988. `EuropaÈische Integration: Auf dem Weg nach 1992'.
Europa-Archiv 120.
1996a. `Politics and Policy in the EU: The Challenge of Governance'. In
H. Wallace and W. Wallace (eds.), Policymaking in the European Union.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
1996b. `The Institutions of the EU: Experience and Experiments'. In
H. Wallace and W. Wallace (eds.), Policymaking in the European Union.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Wallace, Helen, and William Wallace (eds.). 1996. Policymaking in the European
Union. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Wallace, William. 1996. `Government without Statehood: The Unstable Equilibrium'. In H. Wallace and W. Wallace (eds.), Policymaking in the European
Union. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Walsum-Stachowicz, Judith Margaretha van. 1994. `Corporate Diplomacy and
the European Community Information Technology Policies: The In¯uence
of Multinationals and Interest Groups, 1980±1993'. Thesis submitted for
PhD in International Relations, London School of Economics and Political
Science, University of London.
Ward, Hugh, and Geoffrey Edwards. 1990. `Chicken and Technology: The
Bibliography
307
Politics of the European Community's Budget for Research and Development'. Review of International Studies 16: 111±29.
Wasserman, Stanley, and Katherine Faust. 1994. Social Network Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Wegner, Manfred. 1991. Die Entdeckung Europas. Die Wirtschaftspolitik der
EuropaÈischen Gemeinschaft. Ein Grundriss. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
Weltwoche. 1997 `Die neue `SphaÈre' des Percy Barnevik'. No. 17, 24 April.
Wendling, Peter. 1991. Die Unfehlbaren. Zurich: Schweizer Verlagshaus.
Wessels, Wolfgang. 1984. `Der Vertragsentwurf des EuropaÈischen Parlaments
fuÈr eine EuropaÈische Union. Kristallisationspunkt einer neuen EuropaDebatte'. Europa-Archiv 8.
1991. `The EC Council: The Community's Decisionmaking Center'. In
R. Keohane and S. Hoffmann (eds.), The New European Community.
Decisionmaking and Institutional Change. Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press.
Wessels, Wolfgang, and Elfriede Regelsberger (eds.). 1988. The Federal Republic
of Germany and the European Community: The Presidency and Beyond. Bonn:
Europa-Union.
Windolf, Paul. 1993. `Codetermination and the Market for Corporate Control
in the European Union'. Economy and Society 22: 137±58.
Winkler, Heinrich August, and Hartmut Kaelble (eds.). 1993. Nationalismus ±
NationalitaÈten -SupranationalitaÈt. Stuttgart: Klett-Cotta.
WirtschaftsWoche. 1991. `Grenzenlose Kontrolle: AufsichtsraÈte ± die Machtver¯echtungen in Europa'. No 33, 9 August: 46±8.
1996. `Kleines KunststuÈck'. No. 46, 7 November.
Wolf, Klaus Dieter. 1996. `Defending State Autonomy. Intergovernmental
Governance in the European Union'. Working Paper No. 5, World Society
Research Group, University of Darmstadt and University of Frankfurt.
World Bank. 1994. World Development Report. Washington DC: IBRD.
Wurm, Clemens. 1993. `Die Integrations- und Europapolitik Frankreichs und
Grossbritanniens seit 1945 im Vergleich'. In H.A.Winkler and H. Kaelble
(eds.), Nationalismus ± NationalitaÈten ± SupranationalitaÈt. Stuttgart: KlettCotta.
Ysmal, Colette. 1993. `France'. European Journal of Political Research 24:
425±34.
Ziltener, Patrick. 1999. Strukturwandel der europaÈischen Integration. Die EuropaÈische Union und die VeraÈnderung von Staatlichkeit. MuÈnster: WestfaÈlisches
Dampfboot.
Index
absolutism, 268±70
acquis communautaire, 264
Ad Hoc Committee for Institutional
Affairs, see Dooge Committee
Adtranz, 204
Advanta, 232 n.5
AEG, 107
aeronautics industry, 214, 279
Agnelli, Giovanni, 79, 189±90
Agnelli, Umberto, 189, 198
Agreement on Social Policy, see Treaty on
European Union, Social Protocol
AgrEvo, 232 n.5
agricultural associations, 226, 227
agricultural policy, 138, 256
reform, 140, 143
agricultural sector, 144, 219
United Kingdom, 126
agricultural subsidies, 125, 126, 136,
140
agro-industrial technologies, 220
see also biotechnology
Airbus Industrie, 209 n.14
Akzo Nobel, 232, 241
America, see United States of America
American Chamber of Commerce, 114
Amigo Group, 56
Amorin, 204
Amsterdam Treaty, 263
Anderson, Jeffrey, 258±9
Andreotti, Giulio, 60 n.33
Andriessen, Frans, 139
anti-trust panel, 279
see also competition policy
Ares-Serono, 232 n.5
Asea AB, 189 n.5, 197
Asea Brown Boveri (ABB) Ltd., 190, 195,
201, 203±5, 207, 208
Asean Free Trade Area (AFTA), 280
Asia-Paci®c Economic Cooperation
(APEC), 280
308
Association of Microbial Food Enzyme
Producers in Western Europe
(AMFEP), 227 n.4, 228, 239
Association for Monetary Union, 247
Atlas Copco, 197
Attali, Jacques, 53
austerity, 41 n.5
Australia, transnational corporations, 25
Austria
and biotechnology, 223, 225
public opinion, 241
transnational corporations, 23
automotive industry, 17, 214
Badische Annilin- und Soda-Fabrik
(BASF) AG, 232 n.5
Bamelis, Pol, 232
Bangemann, Martin, 209
Bank for International Settlements (BIS),
247 n.4
banks, 199
Barnevik, Percy, 190, 201, 204, 208
barriers
to investment, 23
to trade, 23, 89, 268
see also non-tariff barriers to trade
Baxendell, Sir Peter, 189 n.5
Bayer AG, 197, 203±7, 232, 241
Beffa, Louis, 197±8
Belgium
big business, 188, 196±7, 202±4, 206±7,
208
and biotechnology, 223, 225
Council presidency, 138 n.22, 172, 173
n.34
currency policy, 44
and intergovernmental conference 1985,
66±7, 68, 157±8
and monetary union, 246
public opinion, 173
and regional policy, 144
Index
and social policy, 157±8
see also Benelux countries
Benedetti, Carlo de, 189 n.5, 196±7, 198,
202
Benelux countries, 43
and intergovernmental conference 1985,
61, 64, 66±7, 132
Beretta report, see Economic and Social
Committee
Bernhard, Prince of the Netherlands,
189
Bertelsmann, 205, 207
bilateral meetings, 51, 143
Bilderberg Club, 189±90, 201
Biogen, 213, 232 n.5
Biomolecular Engineering Programme,
218
Bioresearch Ireland, 232 n.5
biotechnology, 18, 103, 185, 210±43,
254±6, 262, 281
acceptance problems, 215±16, 222±5,
229, 241±3
de®nition, 211
ethical aspects, 215, 237
see also Group of Advisers on the
Ethical Implications of Biotechnology
Biotechnology Action Programme, 218
Biotechnology Clearinghouse, 233
Biotechnology Industry Organization
(BIO, United States), 229
Bodmer, Henry C., 202
Boehringer, 232 n.5
Boeing Corp., 279
BoeÈl, Yves, 206
Bosch, 189 n.5, 196, 197, 198, 204±7
Boyer, Herbert, 211±12
Braudel, Fernand, 13, 284
Braun, Fernand, 189, 199
Bretton Woods, see exchange rates
Britain, see United Kingdom
British American Tobacco (B.A.T.)
Industries, 205, 209 n.14
British Biotechnology, 232 n.5
British Cable & Wireless, 203±4
British Petroleum (BP), 205, 207, 209
British Steel, 205
British Telecom, 199, 209 n.14
Brittan, Sir Leon, 209
Browaldh, Tore, 203
BSN, 189 n.5, 196, 198, 203
Bund fuÈr Natur und Umwelt Deutschland
(BUND), 233
bureaucracy, 6, 251, 253±4
see also Directorates General; European
Commission
309
Bureau EuropeÂen des Unions des
Consommateurs (BEUC; Bureau of
European Consumers' Organizations),
233±4, 239
business elite, 193, 252
European transnational, 29, 32, 36, 78,
189, 192, 254
see also European Roundtable of
Industrialists
business organizations, 185
see also European Roundtable of
Industrialists; employer organizations
Canada
biotechnology, 229
transnational corporations, 23, 25
cancer mouse (EPO patent), 224
capital
cost reduction, 200
and labour, 15
market, 136
movement liberalization, 146
and state, 26, 93, 96
capitalism, 5, 7, 8, 271, 278
Cargill, 232 n.5
Carlsberg, 204
Catholic social doctrine, 55
Celltech, 232 n.5
Centocor, 232 n.5
Centre EuropeÂen des Entreprises
Publiques (CEEP), see European
Centre of Public Entreprises
CESPA, 204±5
Chaban-Delmas, Jacques, 55
Chandernagor, AndreÂ, 154
Chase Manhattan Bank, 189±90
chemical industry, 212, 221
see also biotechnology; European
Chemical Industry Council
CheveÁnement, Jean-Pierre, 103
Cheysson, Claude, 53
child protection, 177
Chirac, Jacques, 140, 163
Christian democratic governments, 150±1,
173
Christian democratic party, German, 173,
248
Christopherson, Henning, 139
Ciba-Geigy AG, 189 n.5, 192 n.9, 195±6,
241
CII, 105, 107
citizenship, 9
class, 122, 258, 272
climate convention (Rio 1992), 282
Clinton, Bill, 209
310
Index
clubs, 192±4
Cock®eld, Lord, 5, 11, 29, 69, 77, 79 n.1,
82, 83±4, 86±7, 89, 146, 165, 191
cohabitation (France), 163
Cohen, Stanley, 211±12
Cohesion Fund, 148
cohesion policy, 12, 63, 66, 133±5, 162
see also regional policy; social policy
cohesion regime, 74, 146
cohesion target, 122, 149, 171, 257, 284
Cokoladovny, 204
Coleman, James S., 268
collective bargaining, 158±9, 163, 164,
169
collectivism, 268±70, 276
Collomb, Bertrand, 190, 201
Colombo, Emilio, 45
Commerzbank, 203
Committee for the Monetary Union of
Europe, 247
Committee for Veterinary Medicine
Products, 222
Committee of Experts of Science and
Technology (CODEST), 240
Committee of Permanent Representatives,
see COREPER
Committee of the Regions, 148
see also Consultative Council of Regional
and Local Authorities
Communist Party, France, 50
Compagnie GeÂneÂrale des Eaux (CGE),
107, 198
competition
policy, 108, 201, 241
state, 252
competitive advantages, 99
competitiveness, 12, 31, 86, 109 n.7, 126,
148, 179, 180, 199±201, 259
and social policy, 155
technological, 102, 214, 217, 230±2
computer integrated manufacturing, 97
computers, 15
see also information technology
concertation, 54±5, 56, 164, 166
confederation, 13, 264
ConfeÂdeÂration francËaise et deÂmocratique
du travail (CFDT), 49, n.17, 55, 57
ConfeÂdeÂration geÂneÂrale du travail (CGT),
55
conservation of genetic resources, 219
conservative governments, 41
Conservative Party, United Kingdom, 172
Consultative Council of Regional and
Local Authorities (CCLRA), 145,
146
see also Committee of the Regions
consumer organizations, 168, 226, 233±4
consumer protection, 161 n.12
convergence, 40±2, 247, 252, 261, 284
criteria for monetary union, 261
of living standards, 131
see also regional policy
of social policy, 170
of social security systems, 156 n.7
Coordination EuropeÂenne des Amis de la
Terre (CEAT), see Friends of the
Earth
COREPER (Committee of Permanent
Representatives), 59, 76, 81, 85, 86,
90, 235, 253
corporate law, 202
COST (European Cooperation in the ®eld
of Scienti®c and Technical Research),
221
Council of Europe
bio-ethics convention, 222
European agreement for the protection
of animals employed in agriculture,
224
European agreement for the protection
of vertebrates used in testing and for
other scienti®c purposes, 224
Council of Ministers, 10, 36±7, 78, 86,
167±68, 234±5, 240, 252
and biotechnology, 212, 218, 223, 233
and capital movement liberalization, 146
environmental ministers, 283
and Esprit, 96±7, 110±12
and European Commission, 90
and information technology, 105, 218
industry ministers, 231
internal market (trade ministers), 82
lack of parliamentary control, 251
legislative power, 266±7
majority voting, 12, 42, 49, 58, 60, 65,
66, 76, 133±4, 156±7, 161, 162, 178,
249, 251
presidency, 42, 44, 58, 181
Belgium 1987, 138 n.22, 172, 173
n.34
Denmark 1987, 172
France 1984, 50±1, 53, 129, 155
France 1989, 176
Germany 1983, 45±6
Germany 1988, 142±3
Ireland 1984, 155
Italy 1985, 59±61
Luxembourg 1985, 59, 136
Netherlands 1991, 178
United Kingdom 1986, 139
and regional policy, 127, 133±4, 136,
137, 141, 144
Index
research ministers, 103, 110
social affairs ministers, 155, 175±6
and social policy, 155±6, 161±2, 175±7
unanimity principle, 40, 66±7, 127, 133,
136, 137, 178
craft workers' organizations, 168
Craxi, Bettino, 61, 158
creative destruction (Schumpeter), 16
Credit Suisse, 207
Crocodile Group, 46
Cromme, Gerhard, 197, 209
cultural policy, 67
Dahrendorf, Ralf, 13, 18, 212
Daimler-Benz AG, 199, 204±7, 209 n.14
Dankert, Piet, 56
Danone, 196, 198, 203±7, 232
Davignon, Etienne Vicomte, 5, 11, 18±19,
41 n.5, 53, 82, 83, 86, 87, 89, 91, 94,
101±2, 104, 106±10, 112, 113,
188±90, 192, 197, 199, 202±3, 206,
208±9, 210, 213
cabinet, 189
`The Telematics Revolution', 18±19
de®cit spending, 279
Defraigne, Pierre, 189
Dekalb Genetics, 232 n.5
Dekker, Wisse, 5, 11, 29, 82, 89, 189 n.5,
191, 198±99, 208
Delorism, Delorist project, see European
Commission, integration project
Delors, Jacques, 4±5, 10, 33, 41, 44, 49
n.17, 52 n.22, 53±8, 62, 65, 70, 71,
83±4, 86, 87, 132±3 n.14, 133±4,
136, 138, 139, 142, 153, 154, 157±8,
163, 164±6, 170, 171±2, 174, 175,
181, 191, 214, 216, 247, 256±7, 262,
274
cabinet, 57, 164 n.20, 172
preface to the Cecchini report, 166 n.22
speech at TUC Congress in Brighton
1988, 172
tour of the capitals 1987, 139±40
see also European Commission,
presidency
democracy, 9, 113
de®cit in EC / EU, 192, 194, 266±7, 271,
276
grassroots / direct, 277
see also social movements
Denmark, 45
big business, 204
and biotechnology, 223, 225
Council presidency, 172
and intergovernmental conference 1985,
59±60, 63±4, 66±7, 157±8
311
public opinion, 176, 241
referendum on Union Treaty, 179
and Single European Act, referendum
on, 70
and social policy, 49, 154, 157±8, 160±1
deregulation, 54, 165, 180, 195, 267±8,
282
in biotechnology, 216, 226±7, 231
winners and losers, 30
see also liberalization
Deutsche Bank AG, 190, 196, 203, 206±7,
247
Directives
70/457, 222
70/458, 222
70/524, 222
87/22, 222±3
90/219, 215, 222, 226, 228
90/220, 215, 222, 226, 228
90/679, 222, 227, 234
91/414, 222
93/39, 222
93/41, 223
93/114, 222
Directorates General, 57, 238, 242
DG I, 227
DG III, 81, 82, 83, 106, 108 n.5, 212,
224, 226, 236, 238±9
DG V, 227, 236
DG VI, 235, 239
DG XI, 226, 228, 232, 236, 239
DG XII, 98, 106, 108 n.5, 212, 226,
228, 236, 238±40
Concertation Unit of Biotechnology in
Europe (CUBE), 233, 236±7, 239
Department E, 238
Task Force on Vaccines and Viral
Diseases, 237, 239
DG XIII, 112, 114±15
see also Information Technology Task
Force
DG XV, 82, 227
DG XVI, 145
DG XXI, 82
division of labour, European, 151 n.40
dollar±gold parity, 32
Domeniconi, Reto, 209
Dompe Biotec, 232 n.5
Dondelinger Group, 62
Dooge Committee, 52, 61
®nal report (1985), 59, 67, 131, 154,
157
Dow AgroSciences, 232 n.5
Doyle, Peter, 228
Dresdner Bank AG, 203
Drews, JuÈrgen, 228, 232
312
Index
DSM-Gist, 232 n.5, 241
Dumas, Roland, 50
DuPont Inc., 232 n.5
Durant, John, 233
Durham, Kenneth, 189, 203
East±West con¯ict, 3
ECLAIR (European Collaborative Linkage
of Agriculture and Industry through
Research), 219
ecology movement, 226
see also environmental organisations
economic and monetary union (EMU), see
monetary union
economic and social cohesion, see cohesion
policy; regional policy; social policy
Economic and Social Committee, 49 n.17,
126, 128 n.5, 131, 141, 142, 145 n.29,
159, 166±8, 174, 175, 235, 240, 242
Beretta report, 162, 168, 173 n.34
economic competition among states, 26,
28
economic policy, 179
convergence of, 50
coordination, 256
economic recession (1990s), 179, 261
economies of common governance, 12
economies of scale, 5, 23±4, 25, 86, 99,
100, 118, 279
education, 200
Ekman, Bo, 189
Electrolux, 197, 204
electronics industry, 199
Elias, Norbert, 8
Eli Lilly, 222, 232 n.5
employer organizations, 155, 167, 169±70,
188, 192±5, 224, 243
see also Union of Industrial and
Employers' Confederations of Europe
(UNICE)
employment policy, 154, 159, 178, 200
energy
industry, 199
market liberalization, 200
enlargement of EC / EU, 200, 208
Eastern Europe, 259, 262
®rst round (1973), 126
second round (1981/1986), 117, 128
Enlightenment, 269
enterprise alliances, 240
environmental compatibility, 147 n.33
environmental organizations, 223, 225,
226, 233±4, 237, 243
see also biotechnology, acceptance
problems
environmental policy/ protection, 12, 59,
64, 67, 68, 161 n.12, 189, 200, 219,
225, 232, 233±4, 240, 282±3
E-Plus Mobilfunk, 204
equal opportunities, 170, 177, 178
Ericsson, 197, 204±5, 209
Ernst & Young
biotech reports, 216
Escher, Alfred, 193
Esprit (European Strategic Programme of
Research and Development in
Information Technology), 53, 66, 83,
103, 104, 114±21, 210, 243
Advisory Board, 112±13
genesis, 93±7, 107±12
Management Committee, 112±13
phase 1, 111
Steering Committee, 113
decision-making structure, 112±14
Ethical Advisory Group, see Group of
Advisers on the Ethical Implications of
Biotechnology
Eurawasser, 204
EUREKA, 42, 66, 110, 219, 221, 229
Eurobarometer surveys, 34, 36±7, 173,
175±6, 233
Euro-centrism, 283
Euro-nationalism, 274±6
see also federalism, European
EuropaBio, see European Secretariat of
National Biotechnology Associations;
Senior Advisory Group Biotechnology
European Agricultural Guidance and
Guarantee Fund (EAGGF), 125, 144
see also structural funds
European±American Business Council, 209
European Assembly, 125
European Biotechnology Coordination
Group (EBCG), 227±8, 236±7, 239
European central bank (project), 248
European Centre for Infrastructure Studies
(ECIS), 200
European Centre of Public Enterprises
(CEEP), 142, 164
European Chemical Industry Council
(ECIC), 226±8
European Coal and Steel Community
(ECSC) Treaty, 125
European Commission, 36, 102, 185±6,
194, 279
and biotechnology, 210±25, 236±43,
255
Biotechnology Coordination Committee,
231, 234, 238
Biotechnology Steering Committee, 236
Index
Communications to the Council
Biotechnology and the White Paper on
Growth, Competitiveness and
Employment (1994), 215
Biotechnology in the Community (1983),
213
Biotechnology: The Task of the
Community (1983), 212±13
Consolidating the Internal Market
(1984), 77±8, 80
on the State of the Internal Market
(1981), 78, 80
on Re-activating the European Internal
Market (1982), 78, 80
Promoting the Competitive Environment
for the Industrial Activities based on
Biotechnology within the Community
(1991), 214
Towards a European Strategic Programme
for Research and Development in
Information Technologies (1982), 110
cooperation with European Roundtable
of Industrialists, 1, 58, 73, 75, 84±92,
188±91, 194, 198±201, 255
cooperation with European Information
Technology Industry Roundtable, 73,
95, 107, 111±12, 113, 114±20, 121,
255
cooperation with transnational
corporations, 93±4, 106, 109, 254±6,
260, 262
and Council of Ministers, 90
decline of in¯uence in early 1980s, 46
decision-making process, 235, 242
and Esprit, 96±7, 110±12
executive power, 267
extension of competences, 146
and federalism, 149
and high-tech industry, 98±9, 105±6,
109±10
inception, 29
The Industrial Policy of the Community
(1970), 212
Industry Research and Development
Advisory Committee, 238, 240
integration project, 74, 91, 152, 154,
164±71, 174, 179±81
and intergovernmental conference
1985, 62±3, 66±7, 68, 70, 132±5,
156±8
leadership role in the Single Market
project, 83±7
monopoly on initiatives, 71, 84, 140,
234±5
presidency, 187
313
Delors, 10, 34, 40, 56±8, 83 n.3, 84,
132, 145, 149, 163, 253±4, 257,
261
Hallstein, 83 n.3, 84, 253
Jenkins, 52 n.22
Thorn, 52, 83 n.3, 91
Programme 1985, 80, 155
publicity campaign for Single Market,
173, 245
rebirth in 1980s, 39, 52±8, 253
and regional policy, 124±51, 156, 257
see also European Regional
Development Fund, reform of 1988
Report on Regional Policy (1965), 125
in Single European Act, 65, 67
and social policy, 139, 152±82, 256
standing committees, 235±6, 242
as supranational actor, 2, 90, 136±37,
145, 262
and triad competition, 240
Venturini report (1988), 133 n.15, 164,
166, 170, 173 n.34, 174
White Papers, 76
Completing the Internal Market (1985),
10, 11, 61, 76, 77, 79 n.1, 80±1, 82,
84, 92, 145, 153, 156, 169, 175,
180, 191, 246, 255
Growth, Competitiveness, Employment
(1993), 31, 200, 214, 216, 230±1,
246, 281
European Council (summit meetings), 10,
77±9, 124, 127, 146, 188, 266
1981 June, 80
1986 June, 138
Amsterdam 1997, 246
Athens 1983, 46
Brussels, March 1984, 46 n.12, 51
Brussels, March 1985, 81, 191
Brussels, February 1988, 142
Copenhagen 1982, 77, 80±1, 82
Corfu 1994, 216, 229
Dublin 1984, 77, 80±1
Fontainebleau 1984, 48, 52, 77, 80±1
Hanover 1988, 142±43, 173±4, 247
London 1986, 139
Luxembourg 1985, 2, 65, 128, 135, 158,
161, 191±2
Maastricht 1991, 54, 128, 147±8, 178±9
Madrid 1989, 176
Milan 1985, 60±2, 66±7, 81, 156, 191
Paris 1972, 126
resolution on industrial policy 1973,
212, 217
Strasbourg 1989, 176
Stuttgart 1983, 212, 236
314
Index
European Council (summit meetings) (cont.)
see also Solemn Declaration
summit meetings of 1987, 142
Versailles 1982, 97
European Court of Justice, 12, 37, 161,
249
Cassis de Dijon decision, 53, 253
directive on working hours, 162
and social policy, 168
European Economic Area (EEA), 245
European Economic Community (EEC)
Treaty, 11, 61, 85, 89, 166, 242
Art. 92, 125
Art. 152, 234
Art. 155, 234
Art. 175, 234
Art. 235 (general clause), 110, 124, 127
European Enterprise Group, 189
European Environmental Bureau, 239
European federal state, 122, 263
European federalism, see federalism,
European
European Federation of Animal Health
(FEDESA), 227±8, 239
European Federation of Biotechnology,
211, 213, 232, 239
European Federation of the Chemical
Unions (FESCID), 234
European Federation of Pharmaceutical
Industry Associations (EFPIA),
226±8, 239
European Free Trade Association (EFTA),
245, 261
European Group on Ethics in Sciences and
New Technologies, 237
European identity, see multi-level identities
European Information Technology
Industry Roundtable (EITIRT), 66
cooperation with European
Commission, 73, 95, 107, 111±12,
113, 114±20, 121, 255
decline of in¯uence, 114±20, 121
European industrial area, 58
European Investment Bank (EIB), 125
European Laboratories Without Walls, 218
European Medication Evaluation Agency
(EMEA), 223
European monetary fund (project), 247 n.3
European Monetary System, 138, 247
establishment, 127±8
in Single European Act, 12, 66
European Movement, 189
European norms and standards, 18
European Parliament, 9±10, 37, 175, 192,
235, 240
and biotechnology, 211, 223, 225
Boserup report, 242
budgetary authority, 12
Committee on
Economic and Monetary Affairs, 49,
n.17
Institutional Problems, 46
communist group, 225
draft treaty on European Union (1984),
47, 51 n.19, 60, 62, 167
and economic and social policy, 139
elections of 1989, 176
electoral system, 266±7
extension of competences, 58, 60, 67,
140, 248
green representatives, 225
legislative power(lessness), 12, 251
mediation committee, 223, 236
and regional policy, 127 n.3, 131, 141,
145 n.29
in Single European Act, 65, 69±70
socialist group, 49, 225
and social policy, 159, 162, 166±8, 171,
177
as supranational actor, 145 n.29, 253
veto power, 194
European Patent Convention, 223±4
European Patent Of®ce (EPO), 215, 224
European Regional Development Fund
(ERDF), 132 n.14
establishment, 126±7
at intergovernmental conference 1985,
132±4
reform of 1979, 127±8
reform of 1988, 123, 137±46
content, 144±5
regulation of 1984, 129
Art. 5, 129
in Single European Act, 136
see also structural funds
European Roundtable of Industrialists
(ERT), 1, 10, 32, 36, 74, 76, 81, 83,
96, 185±86, 187, 207±9, 232
Advisory Group for Social Relations and
Industrial Policy, 199
characteristics, 194±5
Competitiveness Advisory Group,
198±9, 255
cooperation with European
Commission, 58, 73, 75, 84±92,
188±91, 194, 198±201, 255
`Education for Europeans' (1995), 200
`Europe 1990: Agenda for Action'
(1984), 29, 82, 191, 255
`European Competitiveness: The Way
to Growth and Jobs' (1994), 198,
200
Index
founding, 48, 82, 87, 89, 188, 192,
207±8
`Foundations for the Future of European
Industry' (1983), 190
historical development, 89
`Investing in Knowledge' (1997), 200
`Job Creation and Competitiveness
through Innovation' (1998), 200
membership, 195±7, 202±7
`Missing Links: Upgrading Europe's
Transborder Infrastructure' (1984),
89, 191, 200
`Missing Networks' (1991), 200
Policy Memorandum (1983), 29±30, 88
`Rebuilding Con®dence: An Action Plan
for Europe' (1992), 199±200
`Reports on the Competition Policy of
the Commission', 201
`Reshaping Europe' (1991), 199
and Single Market, 66
European Secretariat of National
Biotechnology Associations (ESNBA),
228, 232, 238±9
European social area, 49, 58±9, 63, 66,
154±8, 160, 163±4, 167, 169, 172,
181
European Social Charter (Council of
Europe, 1965), 167, 173 n.34, 182
European Social Forum, 259
European Social Fund (ESF), 125 n.2,
144
see also structural funds
European societal model (modeÁle europeÂen
de socieÂte ), 5, 19, 34, 56, 164, 181
European standardization organization
(CEN / CENELEC), 162 n.16,
Committee 233, 236, 239
European Trade Union Confederation
(ETUC), 141, 142, 155, 164, 169±70,
182±3, 234
and intergovernmental conference 1985,
169
Social Charter draft, 175
Stockholm conference 1988, 171
see also trade unions
European Venture Capital Association, 89,
191
Europe Plus Thirty study group, 212
Euroscepticism, 97
Eurosclerosis, 1, 31, 75
Evotec BioSystems, 232 n.5
exchange rates
®xed, 32, 247
¯oating, 32
exemption regulations, 43
export controls, 200
315
Fabius, Laurent, 103
fair return, see juste retour principle
Falck family, 196
Farm Animal Industrial Platform (FAIP),
228, 239
farmers' organizations, 168
Faroux, Roger, 189 n.5
FAST (Forecasting and Assessment in
Science and Technology) group,
106±7, 212
®rst provisional report (Eurofutures: The
Challenge of Innovation, 1982 /4), 212
federalism
European, 44, 149, 250
failure of integration projects, 47
and Single European Act, 57 n.28, 69,
71
see also Euro-nationalism; European
Movement; Genscher±Colombo
initiative; supranationality
United States, 265, 283
see also regions
Ferruzi
family, 196
group, 228
Fiat, 79, 189, 196±7, 198, 201, 202±3,
205, 207, 247
®nancial jurisdiction, 10
Finland
big business, 204
and biotechnology, 223, 225
transnational corporations, 23
®scal crisis, 122
®sheries sector, 144, 219
FLAIR (Food Linked Agro-Industrial
Research), 219
¯anking measures, 54, 63, 133
see also regional policy; Single Market,
negative effects; social policy
Flaubert, Gustave, 38, 260
Florence, republic, 269
food industry, 199
see also biotechnology
Fordism, 31
see also societal model, Keynesian
foreign direct investment (FDI), 20±4,
245
inside EU, 23
foreign policy cooperation, 64, 67
foreign trade, 20
inside EU, 23
Forum for European Bioindustry
Coordination (FEBC), 227±9, 239
Fowler, Norman, 175±6
Framework Programmes, 217±21, 238
BRIDGE, 218±9, 236
316
Index
France, 35, 42, 45, 51, 75
and agricultural policy, 140
big business, 188, 195, 196±8, 202±4,
207, 208
and biotechnology, 217, 223, 225
Commissariat du Plan, 48, 55
Council presidency, 50±1, 53, 155,
176
DeuxieÁme Gauche, 55±6
employers' organization, 170
foreign ministry, 48
and Germany, 43, 52
see also French±German axis / tandem
and industrial decline, 144
integration project, 69
and intergovernmental conference 1985,
61, 64±5, 66±7, 68, 132, 134, 157±8
intergovernmentalist position, 51 n.19
Keynesianism, 48
Members of European Parliament, 47
memorandum for a European social
area, 49
and monetary union, 246, 250
as net payer, 145
political culture, 160
public opinion, 173, 176
referendum on Union Treaty, 179
and regional policy, 130, 134, 142, 144,
145, 151
revolution, 269
right-wing government, 140, 151, 163
science and technology policy, 102±4,
105
and Single Market project, 54
socialist government, 41, 173
and social policy, 154±55, 157±8, 163
state-owned industry, 105, 116
trade unions, 55, 57
transnational corporations, 189 n.5
free trade, see liberalization of trade
È ko-Institut
Freiburg Ecology Institute (O
Freiburg), 225
French±German axis / tandem, 41 n.5, 49,
64, 71, 126, 142
Friends of the Earth, 233, 238±9
functional integration, 9
Fusion Treaty, 10
Art. 15, 90
Gandois, Jean, 206
Gardini family, 196
Gaulle, Charles de, 38 n.1
GEC, 107
Genencor, 232 n.5
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
(GATT), 20, 261±2, 265
genetically modi®ed organisms
and food, 223, 233±4, 236
release in the environment, 215
see also biotechnology
genetic engineering, see biotechnology
Geneva International Management
Institute, 189
Genscher, Hans-Dietrich, 45±6, 50, 52,
104, 247 n.5
Genscher±Colombo initiative, 45, 62, 67
Genscher Memorandum, 248
Genset, 232 n.5
Genzyme, 232 n.5
George, Stephen, 85, 91
Germany, 35, 75
agricultural policy, 140
big business, 188, 193, 195, 196, 202±4,
207, 208
and biotechnology, 216, 217, 223, 225
central bank (Bundesbank), 248
Constitutional Court
(Bundesverfassungsgericht), 179
corporate law, 202
Council presidency, 45±6, 142±3
environmental organizations, 233
and Esprit, 111
and European Social Fund, 125 n.2
foreign policy, 250
and France, 43, 52
see also French±German axis / tandem
and industrial decline, 144
integration project, 146, 174
see also Genscher±Colombo initiative
and intergovernmental conference 1985,
59, 64±5, 66±7, 68, 132, 173
and Italy, 45
Members of European Parliament, 47
monetary policy, 246, 248
neocorporatism, 55
as net payer, 43 n.7, 146
public opinion, 173, 176, 241
and regional policy, 126, 143, 144
reuni®cation, 3, 148, 247
science and technology policy, 102, 104
and Single Market, 146
trade unions, 169
transnational corporations, 189 n.5
Gevaert, 197, 202, 203, 205±7, 247
Giscard d'Estaing, ValeÂry, 64, 155 n.4, 247
Glatz, Hannes, 199
globalization, 1, 5, 20±6, 277±9
Grant, Ulysses S., 193
Greece, 45, 46
and agricultural policy, 140, 249
big business, 204
and biotechnology, 225
Index
integration project, 131±2
and intergovernmental conference 1985,
59±60, 63, 66±7, 132±34
and regional policy, 128±34, 140, 144
and Single European Act, approval, 70
socialist government, 48, 130
trade balance, 150 n.40
and underdevelopment, 144
see also enlargement of EC, second
round; Mediterranean countries
Greenpeace, 225, 233, 238±9
Groupe Bruxelloise Lambert, 196
Group of Advisers on the Ethical
Implications of Biotechnology, 222±4,
237, 239
Group of Seven (G7), 265
Gut, Rainer, 207
Gyllenhammar, Pehr, 89, 188±91, 197,
198, 203±4, 208
Haas, Ernst B., 253
Hallstein, Walter, 83, 263
see also European Commission,
presidency
Hanon, Bernard, 189
Hanseatic League, 268, 272
Hansenne, Michel, 172
harmonization
biotechnology policies, 213
occupational health and safety, 179
regulation, 50, 156, 161, 256, 258±9,
267
social protection, 159, 164, 183
taxes, 44, 64
Harvey-Jones, John, 189 n.5
heads of state and government, 187, 191
see also European Council
health policy, 167
see also biotechnology; occupational
health and safety
hegemony, 21, 36
hegemonic transition, 4
non-hegemonic cooperation, 40
post-hegemonic competition, 1, 34
see also United States of America
Heineken, 192 n.9
Hinks-Edwards, Michael, 189
Hinterscheid, Mathias, 171 n.29
Hintze, Otto, 25
Hirsch, Joachim, 252
Hitler, Adolf, 272
Hobbes, Thomas, 13
Hoechst AG, 228, 232 n.5, 241
Hoffmann-La Roche AG, 201, 205, 207,
209 n.14, 228, 232
Holland, see Netherlands
317
Honeywell-Bull, 103, 105
see also CII
Hong Kong, transnational corporations,
23
Howe, Geoffrey, 51, 60, 69
HuÈber, Roland, 108
human rights, 271
Iberdrola, 204±5
IBM Corp., 105
ICL, 107
I®al, 203
Imperial Chemical Industries (ICI), 189
n.5, 196, 201, 204±5, 209 n.14, 228
imperialism, 272
India, biotechnology, 220
individualism, 268±70, 273, 276
Indosuez bank, 197
Industrial Biotechnology Association of
Canada (IBAC), 229
industrial change, 144
industrial decline, 144
industrial policy, 50, 188
see also technology policy
industrial relations, 165, 257
see also collective bargaining;
employer organizations; trade
unions
informal negotiations, 76
information society, 19, 119, 200
information technology (IT), 20, 83 n.3,
94, 96±121, 210±11, 214, 218, 221,
230, 243, 254±6, 277±8, 281
Big 12, 107±8, 110, 115
ethical aspects, 237
see also Esprit; European Information
Technology Industry Roundtable
Information Technology Task Force
(ITTF), 106±7, 112±13
Inglehart, Ronald, 273
Innogenetics, 232 n.5
insurance companies, 199
Integrated Mediterranean Programmes,
130, 141
integration blockade, 165, 257
integration crisis (1965±6), 126
integration project, 39±40, 44, 71, 123,
250±1
European Commission, 74, 91, 152,
154, 164±71, 174, 179±81
France, 48±50, 69
German±Italian, 47
see also Genscher±Colombo initiative
Germany, 146, 174
Greece, 131±2
United Kingdom, 60, 250
318
Index
integration relaunch / thrust, 6, 27, 38, 41,
48±50, 56, 72, 75, 122±3, 147, 148,
150, 152, 154, 163, 174, 181, 186, 187
n.1, 244, 254, 258, 262±3, 264, 274
integration theory, 245, 253, 257, 262
neofunctionalist, 27±8, 123, 149, 152,
174, 260
neorealist, 27±8, 123, 250, 253
network theory (S. George), 85
see also convergence; package deal;
political entrepreneurship; spillover
intellectual property rights, 213±15, 217,
223±5, 233, 237, 242±3
see also European Patent Of®ce
intergovernmental conferences, 1, 61, 71,
200
Amsterdam 1996±7, 246, 261, 264
Luxembourg 1985, 38, 62±70, 94, 182
preparation, 59±61
and regional policy, 132±5, 147, 156
and social policy, 153, 156, 158, 161,
163, 169, 173
Maastricht 1991, 123, 178, 248, 261
intergovernmentalism, 35, 123, 146 n.31,
148, 182, 244, 250, 252
internal logic of integration, 27
internal market, see Single Market
Internal Market Support Committee
(IMSC), 89, 187
International Bioindustry Forum (IBF),
229
International Labour Organization (ILO),
173 n.34
international law, 264
direct applicability, 265
international organizations, 265
international regime, 36
International Standardization Organization
(ISO), 20
International Telecommunications Union
(ITU), 20
interstate ®nancial transfer, 124
interstate negotiations, 123
Investor AB, 204
Ireland, 45
and agricultural policy, 140
big business, 204
and biotechnology, 223
Council presidency, 155
employers' organization, 170
and intergovernmental conference 1985,
59, 61, 63, 66±7, 132, 134
neutrality, 132
and regional policy, 126±8, 132, 134,
140±1, 144
and underdevelopment, 144
Italy
big business, 196
and biotechnology, 217 n.3, 223, 225
Council presidency, 59±61
and Germany, 45
and industrial decline, 144
and intergovernmental conference 1985,
63, 64, 66±7, 132
Members of European Parliament, 47
Mezzogiorno, 125, 143
public opinion, 176
and regional policy, 126±8, 130,
142±43, 144
and Single European Act, approval 70
state-owned industry, 196
transnational corporations, 189 n.5
and underdevelopment, 125, 144
see also Mediterranean countries
Japan, 4, 18, 78, 86, 190, 212, 279,
280±2
biotechnology, 210, 213±16, 219, 225,
229, 240±1, 243
elite clubs, 193
information technology, 96±7, 106, 107
market size, 88
Ministry of Trade and Industry (MITI),
101, 109, 215
rise as a trading power, 1, 21, 31, 281
technology corporatism, 94, 97, 101±2
transnational corporations, 22±5
Japan Bioindustry Association ( JBA), 229
Jefferson Smur®t, 204
Jenkins, Roy, 52 n.22
Jessop, Bob, 252
Joint European Submicron Silicon
Initiative ( JESSI), 115
juste retour principle, 127±8, 131, 132 n.14,
147
Kabivitrum, 241
Kant, Immanuel, 13
Kaske, Karl-Heinz, 198
Kissinger, Henry, 189
Kohl, Helmut, 64, 85, 143, 199
Kopper, Hilmar, 190, 202, 206
Kressler, Herwig, 199
Kriwet, Heinz, 209
Krupp, 197, 205±7, 209
KWS, 232 n.5
Kymmene OY, 201, 204
Laage de Meux, FrancËois, 202
labour market, 180
policy, 125 n.2, 169, 179, 258
Labour Party, United Kingdom, 42
Index
Lafarge-CoppeÂe, 189 n.5, 190, 196, 201,
205, 207
Lamfalussy, Alexandre, 247 n.4
Lamy, Pascal, 57
Lane, Frederic C., 25
Lecerf, Olivier, 189 n.5
Lederman, Leonard, 102
legitimacy, 26
Lenoir, NoeÈlle, 237
Leysen, AndreÂ, 197, 202, 206±7
liberalism, 186, 264, 267±8, 269±77, 284
see also societal model, liberal
liberalization, 267
of capital movement, 146
of energy markets, 200
of services, 262
of telecommunications markets, 200,
282
of trade, 132, 150 n.40, 209, 260±1
of transportation markets, 200
see also deregulation; Single Market
Limagrain, 232 n.5
lobbying, 192±4, 225, 242, 251
locational competition, 260
Luxembourg
and biotechnology, 225
Council presidency, 59, 62
see also intergovernmental conferences
employers' organization, 170
and intergovernmental conference, 66
see also Benelux countries
Luxembourg Compromise, 38 n.1, 45, 49,
127, 128, 248±9, 251
Lyonnaise des Eaux, 196±98, 203±7,
208±9
Maastricht, see European Council;
intergovernmental conferences; Treaty
on European Union
McDonnell Douglas Corp., 279
machinery industry, 199
majority voting, see Council of Ministers
market economy, 9, 56
market failure, 99
Marshall Plan, 147 n.32
Martens, Wilfried, 53
materials science, 103, 214
Maucher, Helmut, 187, 189 n.5, 198±9,
201, 202, 207, 208
Mauroy, Pierre, 41 n.5, 154
Mediterranean countries, 141
member states, legislative power, 13
mergers and acquisitions, 201, 245, 246
Merkle, Hans, 189 n.5, 198
Mestrallet, GeÂrard, 206, 209
metals industry, 199
319
micro-electronics, 15, 18
Middle Ages, 268
middle classes, enlargement, 15
Miert, Karel van, 200
migration, 260
of scienti®c specialists, 213
military integration, 209
Millennium Bug, 208
Mitterrand, FrancËois, 41 n.5, 50±3, 56, 64,
85, 103, 143, 155, 163
speech to the European Parliament
1984, 51
modeÁle europeÂen de socieÂteÂ, see European
societal model
Mùller, érstrùm J., 61
monetarism, 15, 31
monetary policy, 66, 68, 158, 246±7
monetary union (EMU), 44, 66, 126, 127
n.3, 128, 147, 185, 199, 244, 246±8,
250, 259, 261, 265, 279, 281
Monnet, Jean, 71, 166
Monnetist type of integration, 179
Monod, JeÂroÃme, 197, 198, 207, 209
monopoly, national, 29
Monsanto, 222, 228, 232 n.5
Monti, Mario, 190
Moravcsik, Andrew, 27, 35, 43, 68 n.37,
88, 159, 250, 253, 262
Moreau, Jacques, 49±50, 56
multi-level governance, 124 n.1, 149, 182,
186, 244, 261, 263, 284
multi-level identities, 276±7, 283±4
Narjes, Karl-Heinz, 41 n.5, 83, 191, 213
cabinet, 108 n.5
national interest, 27, 81, 250
see also sovereignty; veto
national markets, 30, 100
national parliaments, 251±2
national sovereignty, see sovereignty
nationalism, 186, 264, 267±8, 270±7, 284
nation-state, see state; state-building
negative integration, 150
neocorporatism, 14, 55, 259 n.9
neofunctionalism, see integration theory
neoliberalism, 15, 273, 277
see also liberalism; monetarism; supplyside economics
neorealism, see integration theory
neo-voluntarism, 259 n.9
Nestle SA, 187, 189 n.5, 195±6, 198, 201,
202, 204±5, 207, 208±9, 232
Netherlands
and agricultural policy, 140
big business, 202, 207
and biotechnology, 216, 217, 225
320
Index
Netherlands (cont.)
corporate law, 202
Council presidency, 178
currency policy, 44
and intergovernmental conference, 66±7
public opinion, 173, 176, 241
and regional policy, 126
revolution, 269
science and technology policy, 102
transnational corporations, 189 n.5, 196
see also Benelux countries; United
Provinces of North Holland
net-payer countries, 145, 148, 149
network theory, see integration theory
New Zealand, transnational corporations,
25
Nicolin, Curt, 189 n.5
Nixdorf, 107
NoeÈl, Emil, 52, 137, 248
Nokia OY, 209 n.14
non-governmental organizations (NGOs),
259, 261
see also consumer organizations;
environmental organizations; social
movements; trade unions
non-tariff barriers to trade, 12, 29, 49, 262
Norsk Hydro, 201, 204, 209 n.14
North American Free Trade Agreement
(NAFTA), 265, 280
North Atlantic Treaty Organisation
(NATO), 190, 209, 283
North±South cleavage inside EC, 242
North±South relations, 200
Norway
big business, 204
transnational corporations, 25
Novartis AG, 232 n.5
Novo Nordisk, 232 n.5
occupational health and safety, 64,
159±62, 169±70, 177, 179, 234, 256
occupational training, 155
Offe, Claus, 194
Olivetti, 107, 189 n.5, 196, 198, 202, 205
Olson, Mancur, 194±5
organizational capacity, 194±5
Ortoli, FrancËois-Xavier, 11, 55, 91
package deal, 40, 43±4, 70, 123, 124, 126,
128, 134, 136
Padoa-Schioppa, Tommaso, 138
Padoa-Schioppa report (1987), 138
Papandreou, Andreas, 46, 130
Papantoniou, Iannis, 131
parastatist organization, 259 n.9
Paribas, 196
patents, see European Patent Of®ce;
intellectual property rights
Pelkmans, Jacques, 53 n.23
PepsiCo, 232 n.5
Perez, Carlota, 16, 277
peripheral countries (in EC), 149, 150
n.40, 151
peripheral regions, 151 n.40
Permanent Representatives, see COREPER
Pescatore, Pierre, 249
Pesenti family, 196
Petro®na, 196, 203, 205±7
Pfeiffer, Alois, 169
pharmaceutical industry, see biotechnology;
chemical industry; European
Federation of Pharmaceutical Industry
Associations
Pharmacia, 232 n.5
Pharming, 232 n.5
Philippa, Wim, 192 n.9
Philips Electronics N.V., 5, 11, 82, 83, 89,
105, 107, 189 n.5, 191, 196±7, 198,
201, 205±7, 209, 247
Pierer, Heinrich von, 199
Pilkington, 202, 205±7
Pioneer Genetique, 232 n.5
Pirelli, 201, 202, 205, 209 n.14
Planta, Louis von, 189 n.5
Plant Genetic Systems (PGS), 220±1
Plessey, 107
Political Committee for `political
cooperation', 62
political culture(s), 160
political entrepreneurship, 4, 28, 40, 42±3,
58, 70, 74, 87, 92, 93, 96, 109, 136,
148, 151, 152; 211, 243, 253, 262
political participation, 6
political public, 261
political union, 1, 186, 248
Pompidou, Georges, 55
Portugal
and agricultural policy, 140
big business, 204
public opinion, 241
and regional policy, 132, 140, 144, 146
and social policy, 172
trade balance, 150 n.40
transnational corporations, 23
and underdevelopment, 144
see also enlargement of EC, second
round; Mediterranean countries
post-Fordism, 100
power, 8, 269
see also separation of powers
pre-competitive research, 108±10, 111,
210
Index
Procter & Gamble, 232 n.5
production technology, 103
productivity advance, 15
Pro®lo, 199, 202
property rights, 25±6
protection, 25±6, 278
standards, 68
Prudential Corporation, 196
public goods, 10, 12, 13, 278
Pury, David de, 190
racism, 272
Ramaer, J.C., 89
rationalization, 17, 137
Reagan, Ronald, 34
redistribution, 6, 137, 147 n.33
see also regional policy
Regional Fund, see European Regional
Development Fund
regionalism, 270, 275±7
regional policy, 2, 73±4, 117, 122±51, 154,
171, 182±3, 257, 258
at intergovernmental conference 1985,
132±5, 147, 156
internal reform dynamic, 137
see also European Regional Development
Fund
regions, 128 n.5, 135, 143, 145, 149, 259,
261
see also Committee of the Regions;
Consultative Council of Regional and
Local Authorities; regional policy
regulation, 41
economic, 5, 279
gap, 257
harmonization, 50, 156, 161, 256,
258±9, 267
interstate, 28, 36
labour market, 258
mutual recognition, 268
Regulation 2100 / 94, 222
Regulation 258 / 97, 223, 236
regulatory capacity of nation-states, 70,
72, 183 252
regulatory competition, 44, 138, 161,
165, 180±1, 259
see also social dumping
regulatory style, 161
Renault, 189, 196, 204
RENAVAL programme, 144
research and development (R&D), 12, 19,
53, 97, 99±102, 109, 111, 162, 231±2
see also biotechnology; Esprit;
information technology; technology
policy
research networks, 201
321
RESIDER programme, 144
Retinger, Joseph H., 189
RhoÃne-Poulenc SA, 228, 232, 241, 247
Riboud, Antoine, 189 n.5, 198
Richardson, Keith, 192
Ripa Di Meana, Carlo, 56, 138, 139
Rockefeller family, 190
Rokkan, Stein, 6, 8
Rothschild Asset Management, 232 n.5
Royal Dutch±Shell, 189, 196, 201, 205,
207, 241
rule of law, 283
Saint-Gobain, 189 n.5, 196±7, 203,
205±7, 209
Sandholtz, Wayne, 102, 104
Sandoz AG, 228
Santer, Jacques, 136
Schering, 232 n.5
Schmidheiny, Stephan, 189, 201
Schmidt, Helmut, 64, 247
Schuman, Robert, 271
Schumpeter, Joseph, 16
Schumpeterian workfare state, 252
Schweizerische Gesellschaft der
Chemischen Industrie, 226
science, 94, 213, 232±3
see also biotechnology; information
technology; technology policy
security cooperation, 59
Seelig, Wolfgang, 189 n.5, 203
Seitz, Konrad, 98, 104
Senior Advisory Group Biotechnology
(SAGE), 220, 228±32, 238±9
Benchmarking the Competitiveness of
Biotechnology in Europe (1997), 232
Biotechnology Policy in the European
Union: Competitiveness, Investment and
the Cycle of Innovation (1994), 231
Biotechnology Policy in the European
Union: Prescriptions for Growth,
Competitiveness and Employment
(1994), 230±1
Community Policy for Biotechnology:
Priorities and Actions (1990), 229±30
Creation of a Community Task Force and
an Independent Advisory Board (1990),
230
Economic Bene®ts and European
Competitiveness (1990), 230
Senn, Niklaus, 202
separation of powers, 267, 283
Sheehy, Patrick, 89
Shell, see Royal Dutch±Shell
Siemens AG, 105, 107, 117, 118, 189 n.5,
196, 198±9, 202±7, 209 n.14
322
Index
Singapore, transnational corporations, 23
Single European Act (SEA), 2, 3, 5±6, 9,
10, 33, 46 n.12, 66±7, 73±4, 85, 132,
145, 148, 185±6, 187±8, 198±9, 201,
208, 244, 248±9, 250, 254
adoption, 38, 70, 75, 192
Annex Declarations, 66±7
No. 7, 158
Arts. 6±12, 67
Art. 13, 66, 75
Arts. 14±19, 66
Arts. 20±24, 66
Arts. 21±22, 152, 157±9, 181
Art. 23, 135, 142
Art. 24, 104±5, 116
Art. 25, 67
Art. 30, 67
Commission's view, 133 n.15
content, 11±2, 65±70
Delors' view, 166
and democratization, 33
ETUC's view, 169
genesis, 36±7, 66±7, 164
role of industry, 89
in¯uence of big business on, 187±8,
192
negotiations, 58, 250
Preamble, 157±8
rati®cation, 172
and regional policy, 123, 135±6, 137,
147, 149
and Single Market, 88, 142, 250
and social policy, 152±3, 157±8, 168,
182
and technology policy, 93, 96, 104±5,
250
UNICE's view, 141
see also intergovernmental conferences,
Luxembourg; Single Market; Treaties
on the European Communities
Single Market / internal market, 3, 61, 66,
70±1, 73, 75±6, 83, 85±92, 110,
141±2, 145±6, 162, 185, 189, 201,
236, 244, 250, 256
and economies of scale, 100
and Esprit, 118
and harmonization of regulation, 161
negative effects, 63, 152, 180, 259±60
project / programme, 2, 12, 54, 57, 59,
78±81, 84, 93, 101, 122, 147, 165±6,
168, 180, 181±2, 208, 247, 255,
267±8
and regional policy goals, 135
safeguard clauses, 65
and social policy, 152, 155, 156 n.6,
171±4, 177
spatial effects, 150 n.38
and structural policy, 138, 150
Thatcher's view, 172 n.30
and trade liberalization on a world scale,
262
see also social dimension
small and medium-sized enterprises, 113,
114, 118, 119, 157±9, 228, 230±1
Smith, Adam, 269
SmithKline Beecham, 232 n.5
Social Charter of EC (Community Charter
of the Fundamental Social Rights of
Workers), 154, 173±4, 175±7
social compatibility, 147
social democracy / social democratic party,
270
Germany, 56, 248
Sweden, 56
see also socialism; socialist governments
social democratic governments, 150±1, 245
social dialogue, 59, 63, 154±5, 157±8,
163, 164, 167±71, 172, 178, 181
Val Duchesse talks, 164
social dimension, 34, 135, 141, 152, 155
n.4, 159, 165, 168, 169, 174, 177±8,
181, 245, 246
social dumping, 156, 169, 172±3, 180
social egalitarianism, 283
social inequality, 260
social movements, 258, 269, 273
social partners, see collective bargaining;
Economic and Social Committee;
employer organizations; industrial
relations; social dialogue; trade unions
social policy, 2, 44, 63±4, 66, 74, 117,
122±3, 133, 138, 149, 151, 154±83,
200, 256, 258±9
at intergovernmental conference 1985,
153, 156, 158, 161, 163
politicization of, 152
theoretical explanations for, 152±3, 160,
163, 171, 174, 179±83
social protection, 154±55, 178
Social Protocol, see Treaty on European
Union
social regression, 180, 183
social rights, 172
see also Social Charter of EC; Treaty on
European Union, Social Protocol
social security, 156 n.7, 159, 178, 258
socialism / socialist party, 176, 270
France, 42, 53, 56±7, 155 n.4
Greece (PASOK), 130
see also Labour Party; social democracy
socialist governments, 173, 245
societal consensus, 122
Index
societal model, 8, 31, 36, 94, 122
class-polarized, 272
Keynesian / neocorporatist, 4, 14±17,
21, 31±2, 41, 71, 261, 273, 274, 280
liberal, 14
Western, 31, 34
see also European societal model
SocieÂte GeÂneÂrale de Belgique, 82, 83, 189,
196±7, 199, 202±3, 205±7, 208±9,
247
socio-institutional subsystem, 16, 277
So®na, 196, 203, 205±7
Solemn Declaration (Stuttgart 1983),
45±6, 62, 79, 80±1
Solvay, 196, 202, 204±7, 232
South Korea, 279
transnational corporations, 23
sovereignty, 9, 27, 68 n.37, 72, 143, 166,
183, 250±1, 264±7, 278
see also integration theory, neorealist;
state
Soviet Union, dissolution, 3, 262
Spain
and agricultural policy, 140
big business, 204
and industrial decline, 144
liberalism, 270
public opinion, 176, 241
and regional policy, 132, 140, 143, 144,
146
and social policy, 172
trade balance, 150 n.40
transnational corporations, 23
and underdevelopment, 144
see also enlargement of EC, second
round; Mediterranean countries
Spethmann, Dieter, 189 n.5, 203
spillover, 27, 44, 149 n.37, 182
Spinelli, Altiero, 46
standardization, 6, 162 n.16
Standard Oil, 190
state
and capital, 26, 93, 96
competing forms of, 280
control over economy, 165
federal, 13, 264
legitimizing function, 93, 258
modern, 6±8, 13
nation-state, 284
establishment of, 265, 276
regulatory capacity, 70, 72, 183, 252
welfare functions, 259
see also nationalism
resource bases, 26
supranational, 278, 283
theory, 270±1
323
world, 7
see also confederation; multi±level
governance; parastatist organization;
regions; sovereignty
state-building, 8, 268±72, 284
in EC / EU, 6, 166, 186
United Kingdom, 268, 272, 280
United States of America, 268, 280
see also United Provinces of North
Holland
statehood, 9±10, 245, 263
European, 6
steel industry, 156 n.7
STET, 107
Stora Kopperberg, 197
Strategic Defense Initiative (SDI), 98
Streeck, Wolfgang, 180, 194±5, 259 n.9,
268
Strenger, Herrmann, 206
structural adjustment, 136, 245
Structural Biology Industrial Platform,
240
structural funds, 133±7, 139, 141, 142±4,
148, 149 n.37, 150, 258±9
see also European Agricultural Guidance
and Guarantee Fund; European
Regional Development Fund;
European Social Fund
structural policy, 74, 129, 133, 138, 144,
147
see also regional policy
subnational state bodies, see regions
subsidiarity principle, 138, 179, 259 n.9
subsidization, see agricultural subsidies;
biotechnology; European Regional
Development Fund; information
technology; structural funds
Suez (company), 196±8, 203, 206±7,
208±9
summit meetings, see European Council
supply-side economics, 31
supranationality, 9, 27, 35, 65, 123, 250,
251, 253, 265±6, 278, 283
regional policy, 127, 128, 132, 146, 151
social policy, 122
see also integration project; integration
relaunch
Sutherland, Peter D., 190, 209
Svanholm, Poul, 190
Sweden, 14
big business, 189 n.5, 195, 203±4
and biotechnology, 223, 225
model of wage-earner funds, 55
neocorporatism, 55
science and technology policy, 102
transnational corporations, 23
324
Index
Switzerland, 14, 223, 224
big business, 189 n.5, 195±6
chemical industry, 226
transnational corporations, 25
Tabaksblat, Morris, 190
Taiwan, transnational corporations, 23
Tarifautonomie, 157
tariffs, elimination, 12
Task Group on Public Perceptions of
Biotechnology, 232±3
taxes, 180
upon business, 200
harmonization, 44, 64
Taylorism, 17
techno-economic subsystem, 16, 277
technological innovation, 98
resistance to, 49, 215
technological revolution in 1970s, 98
technological style, 4, 14, 15±17, 31,
277±8, 281
technology, 189
corporatism, 18±19, 73, 93±7, 102, 112,
114, 119±20, 121, 185, 210±11, 225,
243, 250
de®nition, 94±5
and institutions, 17
policy, 5, 65, 66, 68, 70±1, 93±121, 122,
134, 216, 254, 256
politicization of, 116±17
see also biotechnology; Esprit;
information technology
telecommunications industry, 199, 277,
282
see also information technology
TelefoÂnica de EspanÄa, 204±5
textile industry, 156 n.7
Thatcher, Margaret, 48, 51, 53 n.24,
69 n.38, 82, 85, 87, 111, 130 n.10,
143, 161, 168 n.25, 176
speech in Bruges 1988, 172 n.30
Thatcherism, 42
Thirty Years War, 280
Thomson CSF, 103, 107, 116
Thorn, Gaston, 52±3, 212
see also European Commission,
presidency
Thyssen AG, 189 n.5, 196, 197, 203±7,
209
Tiedemann, W.A., 170
Titan, 204
Total SA, 196, 203, 205, 207, 247
trade unions, 17, 153, 165, 167, 171, 174,
176, 180, 181, 193, 194±5, 208, 237,
254, 257, 261
chemical workers, 226
see also European Federation of the
Chemical Unions
France, 55
Germany, 169
United Kingdom, 172, 182
see also European Trade Union
Confederation
Trades Union Congress (TUC, United
Kingdom), 172
Transatlantic Business Dialogue, 209
Transgene, 232 n.5
transnational corporations (TNC), 1,
20±5, 28, 88, 89, 93±4, 106, 109,
254±6, 260, 262, 274, 279
world's 100 largest, 24±5
see also European Roundtable of
Industrialists
transportation industry, 199
Treaties on the European Communities
Art. 8 a, 66, 75
Art. 8 b±c, 66
Art. 17, 158
Art. 57, 66
Art. 59, 66
Art. 70, 66
Art. 84, 66
Art. 99, 66
Art. 100a, 63, 66, 156
Art. 102a, 66
Art. 117, 157
Art. 118 a±b, 66, 152, 157±63, 170
Art. 130
a±e, 66, 104±5, 135
a, 135
c, 136
d, 137
Art. 130
f±q, 66, 116, 217
k, l, n, 237±8
Art. 130 r±t, 67
Art. 145, 67
cohesion target, 122
and regional policy, 124, 147
and social policy, 158, 168
Treaty on European Union, 3, 4, 9, 10, 35,
46 n.12, 154, 182, 244, 247, 264, 274,
279
Art. 46, 266 n.1
cohesion fund, 33, 148
German Constitutional Court ruling, 179
referenda in Denmark and France, 179
Social Protocol, 178, 182
triad competition, 4, 19, 49, 83, 86, 96,
100, 106, 118, 186, 210, 213, 240,
243, 274, 279, 280, 282
see also Japan; United States of America
Index
Trilateral Commission, 190, 201
Triumph-Adler, 197
Turkey, big business, 199, 202
Tyszkiewicz, Zygmunt, 170
unanimity principle, see Council of
Ministers
underdevelopment, 135, 144
Italy, 125
Mediterranean region, 130
unemployment, 35, 99, 125 n.2, 144, 156,
158, 173, 179, 279, 281
of youth, 144
see also employment policy; social policy
UNIDATA project, 105±6
Unilever, 189, 190, 196, 201, 203±5, 207,
209 n.14, 228, 232
Union of Industrial and Employers'
Confederations of Europe (UNICE),
81±2, 85, 91, 92, 141, 142, 155, 161,
163, 164, 169±70, 174, 175, 189,
192, 194±5, 198, 207
see also employer organizations
United Kingdom, 14, 35, 45, 75
and agricultural policy, 140
agricultural sector, 126
big business, 195±6, 208
and biotechnology, 216, 217, 223
conservative government, 48, 149 n.37,
151
see also Conservative Party;
Thatcherism
corporate law, 202
Council presidency, 139
desire for budgetary correctives, 50, 111,
126, 130, 140, 143, 151
economy, 100 n.2
elite clubs, 193±4
and Esprit, 111
Foreign Affairs Committee, 249
integration project, 60, 250
and intergovernmental conference 1985,
60, 63, 66±7, 68±9, 132, 156±8
Labour government, 126
see also Labour Party
as net payer, 43 n.7, 145
and regional policy, 126, 128, 142±3,
145, 150
revolution, 269
science and technology policy, 102±3,
104
and Single European Act, 249
and social dimension, 34
and social policy, 156±8, 161±3, 175±6,
182
and sovereignty, 250
325
state-building, 268, 272, 280
trade unions, 172, 182
transnational corporations, 189 n.5
United Nations Charter, 271
United Nations Educational, Scienti®c and
Cultural Organization (UNESCO),
International Bioethics Committee, 237
United Provinces of North Holland, 7, 13,
268, 271, 280, 284
United States of America, 4, 14, 78, 86,
101, 190, 209, 212, 261, 265, 273,
279, 280±2, 283
biotechnology, 210, 213±16, 219, 224,
225, 229, 230, 232, 240±1, 243, 281
decline of hegemony, 1, 21, 30±2
information technology, 96±7, 106, 281
market size, 88
passion for deregulation, 282
revolution, 269
state-building, 268, 280
transnational corporations, 23±5
see also North Atlantic Treaty
Organisation
Universal Exposition, Seville 1992, 3
Vallance, Iain, 199
Var®s, Georgis, 129, 139
variable geometry, 51
VEBA, 197, 199, 202±7, 209 n.14
VeÂdrine, Hubert, 41 n.5, 42±3
Venice, Republic, 7, 268, 272
Venturini, Patrick, 172 n.33
see also European Commission, Venturini
report
veto
culture of, 65, 244, 249, 251
European Parliament's power of, 194
national power of, 45, 251
see also Council of Ministers,
unanimity principle
Vogel, Dieter, 197
Volvo AB, 188±9, 197, 198, 201, 203±4
Wallenberg, Peter, 189, 197, 204
Weber, Max, 7, 25
welfare state, 6, 8, 17, 122, 125, 259
see also social policy
White Papers, see European Commission
workers' rights, 156
association, 178
information, consultation and
participation, 177, 178
strike, 178
see also Social Charter of EC; social
protection
working environment, 158±60, 162, 178
326
Index
working hours, reduction, 155
World Bank, 281
World Business Council for Sustainable
Development, 201
world economic crisis, 14, 21
World Economic Forum (WEF), 201
world market, 278
information technology, 100
for protection, 36
world society, 283
world system, 7, 274, 280
world trade, 21, 199, 280
World Trade Organization (WTO), 265,
282
World War (First and Second), 30, 272
Worldwide Fund for Nature (WWF), 233,
238
Worms, GeÂrard, 206
Zeneca, 228, 232 n.5