Foreign Aid and Corruption
FOREIGN AID AND CORRUPTION IN
POST-CONFLICT COUNTRIES
Gul M. KURTOGLU ESKISAR
PUBLICATIONS
ISTANBUL
2015
183
Kurtoglu Eskisar
WISE MEN CENTER
FOR STRATEGIC STUDIES
Mecidiyeköy Yolu Caddesi (by Trump Towers)
No:10 Celil Ağa İş Merkezi Floor: 9 Flat: 36-38
Mecidiyeköy / İstanbul / Türkiye
Tel: +90 212 217 65 91
Fax: +90 212 217 65 93
www.bilgesam.org
[email protected]
Atatürk Bulvarı Havuzlu Sok. No:4/6
A. Ayrancı / Çankaya / Ankara / Türkiye
Tel : +90 312 425 32 90
Fax: +90 312 425 32 90
Copyright © July 2015
All rights reserved
his publication cannot be reproduced in parts or in whole without consent and permission by Wise Men Center for Strategic Research
Author: Gul M. KURTOGLU ESKISAR
Cover and design: Sertaç DURMAZ
ISBN: 978-605-9963-14-5
Print: Gülmat Matbaacılık
Litros Yolu 2. Matbaacılar Sitesi 1NE 4 Zeytinburnu / İstanbul
0212 577 79 77
184
Foreign Aid and Corruption
FOREIGN AID AND CORRUPTION IN
POST-CONFLICT COUNTRIES
Gul M. Kurtoglu-eskısar
i
Kurtoglu Eskisar
For my parents Olcay and Halil Kurtoglu, with love and gratitude..
And for Tilda, who almost made it.
ii
Foreign Aid and Corruption
Gül M. Kurtoğlu Eskişar
Gul M. Kurtoglu Eskisar received her B.A. in International Relations from Bilkent University in 1995 as valedictorian. She continued her graduate studies in the USA as a Fulbright scholar, and
received both her M.A. degree in international relations in 1997 and
Ph.D. degree in political science at the University of Chicago in
2003. During her graduate studies, she was awarded several scholarships and grants, including those from the University of Chicago
and Andrew Mellon Foundation. Since 2010, Dr.Kurtoglu Eskisar
has served as an associate professor in the International Relations
department at Dokuz Eylul University. Some of her published works
include a co-edited book on political Islamist movements around
the world and several articles devoted to the same theme. She also
has publications on democratization, patronage and corruption in
English and Turkish.
Gül M. Kurtoğlu Eskişar Bilkent Üniversitesi Uluslararası İlişkiler
Bölümü’nden 1995 yılında birincilikle mezun oldu. Ardından Fulbright bursuyla gittiği ABD’de ilk olarak University of Chicago’da
1997 yılında uluslararası ilişkiler dalında M.A derecesini ve sonra yine aynı üniversitede 2003’de siyaset bilimi üzerine yaptığı
doktorasını tamamladı. Bu dönemde yaptığı çalışmalar nedeniyle
University of Chicago bursu ve Andrew Mellon doktora bitirme
bursu gibi pekçok ödül aldı. Kurtoğlu Eskişar 2010 yılından beri
İzmir Dokuz Eylül Üniversitesi İngilizce Uluslararası İlişkiler bölümünde doçent doktor olarak görev yapmaktadır. Kendisinin dünyadaki farklı siyasal İslam akımları üzerine ortak editör olarak hazırladığı derleme bir kitabı ve aynı konuda çeşitli makalelerinin yanısıra,
demokratikleşme, patronaj ve yolsuzluk gibi konularda İngilizce ve
Türkçe yayınları bulunmaktadır.
iii
Kurtoglu Eskisar
TABLE OF CONTENTS
1. Introduction.................................................................................1
1.1 The scope and goal of the book...............................................1
2 Deining Corruption and Foreign Aid.......................................9
2.1 Deining corruption..................................................................9
2.2 Corruption as a security problem.............................................10
2.3 Causes of corruption...............................................................11
2.4 Regime types and corruption................................................14
2.5 Effects of corruption on war torn countries.............................16
2.6 Corruption as an informal institution in post-conlict societies 17
2.7 Poverty as a cause of corruption..............................................19
2.8 Corruption, development and good governance......................20
2.9 Deining foreign aid..............................................................21
2.10 Forms of foreign aid............................................................22
2.11 Who are the donors?............................................................23
2.12 Explaining the causes of foreign aid: normative factors.......24
2.13 Explaining the causes of foreign aid as an extension of foreign
policy goals.................................................................................25
2.14 Political Realism and foreign aid.......................................26
iv
Foreign Aid and Corruption
2.15 Social constructivism and foreign aid.................................28
2.16 Liberalism and foreign aid..................................................29
2.17 Modernization theories, development and corruption..........30
2.18 Development, international organizations and foreign aid..31
2.19 Conclusion..........................................................................32
3 Corruption and aid: Changing Patterns................................33
3.1 Introduction: patterns of foreign aid......................................33
3.2 Neoliberalism, democratization and foreign aid objectives in
the post-Cold War era.................................................................34
3.3 Changing reactions to corruption.........................................35
3.4 The global rebirth of corruption as a crime..............................37
3.5 States as principal actors in forming and enforcing anticorruption laws...........................................................................38
3.6 Problems related with tracking corruption through global
indices....................................................................................................39
3.7 Critical approaches to global anti-corruption campaigns......39
3.8 Good governance debate.......................................................41
3.9 International aid and economic development.......................45
3.10 Now and forever? Deining the limits of foreign aid..........46
3.11 Foreign aid and corruption in divided societies..................47
v
Kurtoglu Eskisar
3.12 Foreign aid for peacebuilding and corruption.....................48
3.13 Peace settlements and corruption in post-conlict societies
....................................................................................................48
3.14 Organized crime networks, corruption and political elite in
post-conlict settings...................................................................49
3.15 Foreign aid as a rent source in post-conlict societies.........50
3.16 Foreign aid and social cohesion in post-conlict societies..50
3.17 Donor awareness of conditions in recipient countries........51
3.18 Corruption networks and inter-group conlict in post-conlict
societies......................................................................................52
3.19 Weak judiciary and corruption in post-conlict societies....52
3.20 Conclusion..........................................................................53
4 Afghanistan...............................................................................55
4.1 Foreign aid and Afghanistan during the Cold War................56
4.2 The effects of foreign aid to Afghanistan during the Cold War.57
4.3 Afghanistan War (2001-2014) and its impact on intra-ethnic
relations.......................................................................................57
4.4 Corruption in Afghanistan since 2001...................................63
4.5 Public perceptions of corruption...........................................64
4.6 Assessing the impact of foreign aid in Afghanistan...............66
vi
Foreign Aid and Corruption
4.7 Anticorruption efforts of Afghan government: the good the
bad and the ugly..........................................................................67
4.8 Corruption and criminal networks........................................69
4.9 Corruption and justice...........................................................70
4.10 The unexpected effects of foreign aid: some examples......72
4.11 The input of Afghans really matters....................................76
4.12 Conclusion: Afghanistan—a net gain or a net loss for
donors?........................................................................................78
5 Bosnia-Herzegovina:.................................................................80
5.1 Bosnia: a model for successful international aid?.................80
5.2 Corruption in Bosnia: is culture to blame?...........................86
5.3 Dayton Peace Agreement and its aftermath..........................87
5.4 Bosnian state and consociationalism....................................89
5.5 Bosnian administrative structure and economy.....................91
5.6 Foreign inancial aid to Bosnia: some igures.......................93
5.7 Taking the front seat: international community and the Bosnian
elite.............................................................................................96
5.8 The (unexpected) consequences of external led reforms......97
5.9 Bosnian elite and corruption...............................................100
5.10 Political parties and organized crime................................102
vii
Kurtoglu Eskisar
5.11 Conclusion........................................................................104
6 Iraq:..........................................................................................107
6.1 Introduction.........................................................................107
6.2 Corruption in Iraq since 2003: some anecdotes..................110
6.3 Corruption as a security problem in Iraq.............................111
6.4 A culture of corruption?.......................................................111
6.5 Foreign aid and corruption in Iraq before 2003..................114
6.6 Foreign inancial aid after Iraq War (2003): some igures..116
6.7 Statebuilding efforts in postwar Iraq: lack of postwar
planning.........................................................................................120
6.8 Lack of information, poor choices......................................122
6.9 Iraqis as decisionmakers: the missing link..........................124
6.10 De-Baathiication..............................................................126
6.11 Aftereffects of de-Baathiication: security crisis...............129
6.12 The institutionalization of corruption in Iraq?..................130
6.13 Conclusion........................................................................132
7 Conclusion: Quo Vadis Foreign Aid—and Corruption?......134
8 Bibliography............................................................................140
9 Appendices...............................................................................165
viii
Foreign Aid and Corruption
B. Foreign Direct Investment to Afghanistan in Years.................165
C. Foreign Direct Investment to Bosnia in Years........................166
D. Foreign Direct Investment to Iraq in Years.............................166
ix
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Acronyms:
AIA: Afghan Interim Administration
AID: The United States Agency for International Development
ATA: Afghan Transitional Authority
BiH: Bosnia and Herzegovina
CPA: Coalition Provisional Authority
CPI: Corruption Perceptions Index
DAC (DCD-DAC): Development Co-operation Directorate-Development Assistance Committee of OECD
EU: European Union
EULEX: European Union Rule of Law Mission
EUSR: European Union Special Representative
HRBH: High Representative for Bosnia and Herzegovina
IFOR: Implementation Force
ISAF: International Security Assistance Force
MCC: Millenium Challenge Corporation
MDG: Millenium Development Goals
NGO: Non Governmental Organization
ODA: Oficial Development Assistance (by OECD)
x
Foreign Aid and Corruption
OECD: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development
OHR: Ofice of the High Representative in Bosnia and Herzegovina
RS: Republika Srpska
SIGAR: Special Inspector General for Afghanistan Reconstruction
SIGIR: Special Inspector General for Iraq Reconstruction
SFOR: Stabilization Force
TI: Transparency International
UN: United Nations
UNSC: United Nations Security Council
WGI: Worldwide Governance Indicators
xi
Kurtoglu Eskisar
2
Foreign Aid and Corruption
CHAPTER 1
INTRODUCTION
1.1 The scope and goal of the book
This book explores the nexus between foreign aid1 and corruption in
post-conlict settings.2 It particularly focuses on the experiences of
some of the countries that have received foreign aid in order to initiate or accelerate their economic reconstruction and state building3
efforts after experiencing a violent conlict during the post-Cold
War period. Corruption is an oft-quoted factor by both international
donors and key nation-level actors to explain the setbacks that arise
during the statebuilding efforts in such countries. Moreover, corruption is commonly portrayed as a phenomenon with internal rather
than external roots; culture and domestic factors are often assumed
to play key roles in nurturing it.
1 As explained in further detail in the second chapter of this book, the term “foreign
aid” refers to both inancial and non-inancial support offered by international actors.
2 The term “post-conlict settings” throughout the book exclusively refers to those
conditions where violence broke out between the conlicting parties.
3 In reference to statebuilding, this study adopts the following description of
Heineman Jr. and Heimann (2006: 77): “state building ... consists of institutional
reforms designed to create a society of laws, not men, and to build a transparent,
accountable, and durable legal, economic, and political foundation.” For a general
overview of alternative (and sometimes contradictory) deinitions for statebuilding
in the literature, see Marquette (2011: 1873-1875).
1
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Similar to cultural approaches, neoliberal discussions on economic
development and governance also associate corruption with various domestic factors like inefficiency and bad governance, stressing
its detrimental effects on economic development. As this neoliberal
outlook has dominated policymaking circles worldwide since the
early 1990s, foreign aid lows have become increasingly dependent
on the level of corruption in the receiving country. Today, high levels
of corruption detected and reported by international organizations
like Transparency International (TI) and the World Bank (WB) can
seriously reduce the amount of aid received or altogether prevent it.
Notwithstanding the culturalist or neoliberal assumptions, however, the role of external factors like foreign aid on corruption in
post-conlict settings has not been adequately explored. This neglect
needs remediation, as the end of the Cold War marked the rise of
democratization as a key exogenous variable behind international
interventions (Belloni 2007: 25). In tandem with the democratization movements in the post-Cold War era and the rise of neoliberal
ideals on governance and economic development, both corruption
and foreign aid have received increasing attention from scholars and
policymakers alike (Maipose 2000: 94). This interest seems congruent with the exponentially increasing levels of corruption observed
throughout the world during 1990s (Johnson and Sharma 2004: 1).
The overall impact of foreign aid in world politics and economics
is hard to ignore. As Easterly (2008: 1) puts it, currently “[f]oreign
aid is in the headlines more than ever before in its sixty-year history, and it has big ambitions.” Indeed, when it comes to explaining
the pivotal role of foreign aid for both modern day international
economies and politics, numbers speak for themselves. The DAC
2
Foreign Aid and Corruption
members gave $80 billion in 2004 and $106 billion in 2005 as aid
to various countries around the world (Lancaster 2008: 39). Private
donations made through NGOs of the same countries amounted to
$6.9 billion in 2000 and over $11 billion in 2004 (ibid.: 44). During the same year, the United States Agency for International Development (USAID) alone distributed more than $26 billion in aid
and grants to various recipients. Approximately 30 percent of this
amount was received by Iraq and Afghanistan, which were trying
to reconstruct themselves in every possible sense following their
exposure to prolonged period of wars and conlicts (Taffet 2007: 1).
Meanwhile, Turkey has also been receiving increasing international
attention in recent years due to its steadily rising amount of foreign
aid worldwide. According to Turkish official sources, the amount
of ODA that has been made available has increased 30 fold during
the past decade, reaching $3.4bn in 2012.4 Although this dramatic
increase is to some degree attributable to the recent Syrian refugee
crisis and the following complications5, the steadily rising trend in
years is nonmistakeable. Similar to many of its Western counterparts, the majority of Turkish aid targets “social infrastructure and
services, notably education and health, as well as governance and
civil society.” (ibid)
While different forms of international aid exist, the type that is offered for nation-building is regarded as “the most ambitious form”
of its kind, and for a good reason: “in nationbuilding programs, ex4 http://kdk.gov.tr/sayilarla/turkiyenin-dis-yardimlari-2012/35 (accessed on 27
April 2015).
5 See, for instance, the OECD webpage on Turkish foreign aid at http://www.oecd.
org/dac/dac-global-relations/turkeys-oficial-development-assistanceoda.htm (accessed on 04 November 2014).
3
Kurtoglu Eskisar
ternal donors seek to create, reestablish, or strengthen the capacity
of the state to govern and also to support a policy framework that
will enable civil society to achieve political, economic, social, and
physical development.” (Rondinelli and Montgomery 2004: 225226) Many times, the aid offered by the international community
goes beyond finance and takes the form of building a nation or state
building from scratch in order to reconstruct what was destroyed
during the war. As Rondinelli and Montgomery (2004: 225-226)
point out, “[d]onors are compelled to practice nation-building when
war displaces an existing regime or when it can no longer function
effectively.”6 Since the end of the Cold War, a rising portion of the
foreign aid offered by the international community to post-conlict
societies has thus aimed for their reconstruction and development
along liberal principles, including the formation of a democratic government and a liberal economic market.
The ongoing liberalization efforts promoted by both domestic and
external actors in post-conlict regions, however, do not guarantee
the end of corrupt activities in a given setting (Roberts 2008: 548;
Ateljevic and Budak 2010: 379). Contrary to donor expectations, in
many of these settings, the inlow of foreign aid for state building
purposes was followed by high levels of corruption, and less than
optimum outcomes (Fearon and Laitin 2004). As a result, neoliberal
policies have received increasing levels of criticism in recent years.
6 According to Diamond (2006: 176), following a conlict, successful statebuilding
rests on fulilling the following four interacting conditions: 1) the formation or restoration of a state capable of functioning of its own, and widely recognized by citizens, 2) the restoration of state economy and infrastructure, including both physical
and social aspects (e.g. economic rules), 3) forming a functional civil society and
political culture, which supports democracy and counterweights state power and 4)
restoration of security. For a similar approach, see Doig and Tisne (2009: 374).
4
Foreign Aid and Corruption
Exploring the reasons behind this puzzling outcome therefore constitutes the main goal of this study. As discussed in further detail in
later chapters, although foreign aid can function as an exogenous
factor that can help establish or maintain peace, it can also become
a source of instability and cause humanitarian crises and security
problems both in the receiving country and abroad (Robb 2004:
29; Calderisi 2006: 153-156; Easterly 2008: 2). Ironically, and regardless of geographic location, in many conlict prone settings
“aid programs ignored signs of impending conlict or inadvertently
exacerbated the problems that led to violent confrontation” (Muscat
2004: 93).
While studying the links between foreign aid and corruption in postconlict societies undergoing reconstruction, three factors particularly stand out. First, formulaic adaptations of neoliberal principles
that are routinely employed for statebuilding in such environments
often seem to achieve the contrary results that they originally target. Emphasizing a minimalist state with carefully circumscribed
capabilities as favored by international donors tends to fall short of
addressing the needs of post-conlict societies and can inadvertently
promote such practices. Ironically, corruption in these settings can
become both a means for survival and an avenue for criminal networks to reinforce their income and increase their inluence over
the society.
Second, poor monitoring mechanisms due to lack of funding or
structural difficulties, exacerbated by the already limited capabilities of the newly established or reconstructed states, seem to play an
important role in the failure of foreign aid in reaching its original
targets. Worse, in such cases foreign aid often paradoxically ends
5
Kurtoglu Eskisar
up supporting corruption networks or individuals in post-conlict
societies. Complex administrative mechanisms are often originally
required or encouraged by donors to maintain the peace and protect
the interests of all members of the society. However these same
measures can gradually build and perpetuate corruption networks,
which prove surprisingly resistant to the adoption of anti-corruption
measures.
Third and possibly the greatest shortcoming of anti-corruption measures and campaigns promoted by international donors is the failure
to incorporate the nation-level elite in policy formulation and enforcement. Foreign actors’ disinclination to increase active participation by the local elite in establishing the rules of engagement in
anti-corruption campaigns, to some degree, is understandable. The
preoccupation of foreign actors to build a viable state and accompanying political structure as quickly as possible rises from the real
fear that the vacuum created in the absence of state is unbearable
by the local society. In such settings, security and the formation of
a predictable, safe environment become the primary goals, as such
elements are crucial to the reconstruction and maintenance of economy, as well as the reestablishment of political legitimacy (Diamond 2006: 176).
As a consequence, in post-conlict settings, security concerns often trump every other need, and time is of essence. Letting the local elite play an active role in setting the rules for anti-corruption
campaigns may lead to inadvertently bolstering the power of those
groups that initiated or prolonged hostilities during the war. These
individuals may use such measures as a convenient way to establish
their domination over other societal groups; additionally they may
hinder or even derail democratic structures that the new state hopes
6
Foreign Aid and Corruption
to install in the first place. However, ignoring or downplaying national input in favor of internationally dictated rules and measures
risks overlooking local nuances that can prove vital to long-term
efficacy and legitimacy.
Finally, in addition to discussing the above stated points in detail,
this study aims to review some of the outstanding arguments that
prevail in recent literature on corruption and foreign aid. Notwithstanding the large volume of studies dedicated to these subjects individually, there have been relatively few attempts to knit together a
seamless map of the terrain of current discussion. For scholars and
policy makers alike, this gap presents a disadvantage, as nuances on
corruption, foreign aid and their interaction are easy to miss when
viewed from a single perspective. This study therefore aims to provide a multi-layered outlook that can offer a more balanced view
of the subject, which, in turn, can help develop better methods to
address it.
Although this book mainly concentrates on the shortcomings of foreign aid toward corruption and statebuilding in post-conlict societies, it does not claim that the overall effects of such involvement are altogether useless or undesirable. Contrary to pessimist
approaches on the effects of foreign aid, some scholars claim that
it can succeed if supported by “progressive forces” who govern the
state (Goldsmith 2001: 127). Indeed, some of the earlier examples
of foreign aid with extensive goals have achieved impressive results. Countries that received aid after experiencing violent conlicts
(ranging from South Korea to Mozambique) or for economic development purposes (like Turkey and Taiwan or Thailand) are usually
counted among the successful cases, where the donors reached or
7
Kurtoglu Eskisar
even exceeded their initial goals (Muscat 2004: 93; Rondinelli and
Montgomery 2004: 225). Based on their findings concerning ODA
data and the outbreak of civil war, Savun and Tirone (2012) similarly conclude that foreign aid can help reduce the possibility of the
outbreak of a civil war in recipient countries experiencing economic shocks. While meager, the data in Annex E of this study also
suggest that international assistance for the purpose of increasing
transparency and fighting corruption can yield positive results in
some fields.
While a degree of generalization is useful for displaying repetitive
patterns across countries and regions and therby drawing the general
framework of debate, accounting for the nuances can help understand persistant and pervasive issues in many post-conlict societies
receiving foreign aid. In order to discuss these arguments in greater
depth, this book therefore discusses in detail three countries that to
date have received massive amounts of foreign aid: Afghanistan,
Bosnia-Herzegovina,7 and Iraq. In addition to these countries, this
text also offers occasional glimpses and anecdotal reference to other
countries that have received international aid in order to support the
main arguments and provide the reader with contextual information.
While not claiming to be representative of all available cases, the
countries discussed in some detail here offer both interesting and
important aspects of the links that seem to tie international aid, corruption and state building efforts.
Of the three countries being analyzed, Afghanistan has been the
longest recipient of foreign aid, with beginnings dating back to the
early years of the Cold War. Poor, underdeveloped and deeply tra7 Henceforth simply referred to as “Bosnia” in this study.
8
Foreign Aid and Corruption
umatized by decades of long invasion and violent internal conlict,
Afghanistan remains a quintessential example of a country in dire
need of foreign recovery assistance. Yet, as the chapter on Afghanistan aims to show, contrary to expectations, the impact of international aid within that country has remained shockingly limited
in effect. What is worse, it also seems to have fostered corruption
and made little progress in state building. A broad discussion of the
possible causes and consequences of this condition occupies the rest
of this chapter.
Compared to Afghanistan, Bosnia seems far better off as an aid recipient; however, it also has its own reasons for being regarded as
an ideal case for international aid. Bosnia was among the hardest hit
places in the world concerning the effects of the end of the Cold War
and the collapse of the communist bloc. Torn apart by the ethnic
and inter-communal war that also brought the end of Yugoslavia,
Bosnia came under the tutelage of international actors like NATO,
UN, USA and EU who aimed to rebuild and reintegrate this now
independent state. Unlike Afghanistan and Iraq, Bosnia was also
promised a much coveted EU membership upon satisfactory completion of expected reforms—including fighting rampant corruption.
Yet, as the violent protests against corruption in its various cities
during the winter of 2014 have shown, not all is well in the country.
The rest of this section is dedicated to finding out why this is so.
Iraq is the final country that this book investigates. Similar to Afghanistan and Bosnia-Herzegovina, Iraq has experienced foreign intervention followed by intense inter-communal and ethnic conlict.
Although the US-led international occupation of Iraq in early 2000s
promised to bring democracy and wealth and eradicate corruption
9
Kurtoglu Eskisar
to Iraqi citizens, none of these promises have been materialized to
date. Polarized by intense internal conlicts and left with little state
power to the central government (despite earlier foreign aid), Iraq
also remains riddled by massive corruption rates. While foreign aid
cannot be blamed for initiating corrupt practices in Iraq, there is
compelling reason to assume that it has exacerbated the volume and
strength of such conditions.
The rest of the book is organized as follows. Chapter 2 and Chapter
3 aim to provide the theoretical background of this study. Following the sections that define and discuss some of the key issues
concerning “corruption” and “foreign aid” in Chapter 2, Chapter 3
explains how foreign aid that aims to restore the central state power and promote liberal market economy in post-conlict settings
can generate or exacerbate corruption networks. Germane to these
definitions and discussions is their coverage in different bodies of
literature, including international relations and economics. Chapters 4, 5, and 6 discuss Afghanistan, Bosnia, and Iraq respectively.
Chapter 7 summarizes the presented arguments and offers concluding remarks.
10
Foreign Aid and Corruption
CHAPTER 2
DEFINING CORRUPTION
AND FOREIGN AID
2.1 Defining corruption
Due to its complex nature, defining corruption, its subtleties and
its effects has generated intense debates in academia in years (Underkufler 2009; Bracking 2007: 3-13; Johnson and Sharma 2004:
3). The key problem about the issue rises from the amorphous and
subjective nature of the phenomenon. Corruption can take many
forms;8 some of them more easily monitored than others (Johnson
and Sharma 2004: 2). As the following observation by Smith (2007:
34) on Nigerian approaches to corruption suggests, defining the
phenomenon remains a tricky task outside academia as well: “Nigerian notions of corruption encompass everything from government bribery and graft, rigged elections, and fraudulent business
deals, to the diabolical abuse of occult powers, medical quackery,
cheating in school, and even deceiving a lover.”
As a result, the term is often used interchangeably with clientelism,
political patronage and similar practices. Some scholars, however,
differentiate corruption from clientelism and its cousins, like po8 See, for instance, Kaufmann and Vicente (2005) for a discussion on “legal corruption.”
11
Kurtoglu Eskisar
litical patronage and pork barrel politics, as it “has no durability
of relationship, whereas patronage is characterized by stability of
relationship and reciprocity between a powerful person and a client,
both commanding unequal resources.” (Emizet 1999: 206) Notwithstanding these intricacies and possible pitfalls on reaching a universal deinition of corruption, internationally acclaimed scholars on
the subject, such as Susan Rose-Ackerman and Michael Johnston,
simply describe it as “the misuse of public power for private gain”
(Muno 2013: 34). This definition will be adopted for the purposes
of this book.
Some of the outstanding features of the existing literature on corruption include its generally normative tone as well as the tendency
to stress its negative effects on economic development and governance (e.g. Diamond 2008: 67; Debiel and Gawrich 2013: 3; Yeh
2011; Cockcroft 2010; Heineman Jr. and Heimann 2006). Displaying the strong normative undercurrents concerning the debates on
corruption, Rotberg (2009: 1) asserts that “[u]ntil avarice and ambition cease to be human traits, corruption will continue to lourish.”
While discussing the diversity of opinions on corruption, Underkufler (2009: 39) similarly concludes that it is ultimately tied to
moral issues:
“We are not outraged about corrupt politicians because their
existence in ofice proves a lack of eficiency or government
transparency; we are outraged because of the evil, the arrogance, the lagrant disregard of deeply entrenched social
norms that their tenure exhibits ... If governments or reformers
fail to respond to such popular emotions, their refusal can fuel
forces of social and governmental instability.”
12
Foreign Aid and Corruption
2.2 Corruption as a security problem
In addition to its various definitional intricacies, corruption is also
often regarded as a transnational security problem by both scholars
and policymakers alike (Chayes 2014). While discussing corruption
networks in the Balkans, for instance, Giatzidis (2007: 328) points
out that they are interlaced with crime networks, which, in extreme cases, not only weakens the state capacity but also legitimates
the act. Going beyond regional concerns, some scholars regard the
spread and persistence of corruption as serious contemporary global
security problems. Corruption has even been quoted in some cases
as a formal cause for international intervention, such as the US led
international occupation of Iraq in 2003 (Le Billon 2005: 685; Woods 2005).
The security-centric approach to corruption views it as a highly pervasive phenomenon. It can promote the accumulation of mass destruction weapons, encourage the spread of terrorism and other criminal practices, and hamper the “noble international efforts to improve
the health, educational attainments, welfare, prosperity, and human
rights of the inhabitants of the troubled planet.” (Rotberg 2009: 2)
Therefore, the same approach regards developing efficient measures to prevent and eliminate the phenomenon as a must, as failure
to do so can promote international terrorism and decrease global security. As Johnson and Jolyon (2008: 17) put it, “as long as western
governments continue to supply weapons to corrupt regimes that
oppress their people, terrorism will find recruits.” Some scholars
have gone even further, positing corruption as a cause of global nuclear proliferation (Bunn 2009). Finally, as this chapter discusses in
more detail further on, addressing corruption as a security problem
coincides with the increasing general tendency of international do13
Kurtoglu Eskisar
nors to channel counterterrorism related aid toward recipients since
September 11 attacks (Barratt 2008: 21).9
2.3 Causes of corruption
Similar to the plethora of arguments on defining corruption, its causes have also generated a lot of debates. Cultural factors in particular are commonly used to explain the existence and prevalence of
corruption in certain settings as opposed to others. Classic studies
often portray such activities as a primordial practice that would gradually fade away with modernization and economic development.
Even earlier, imperialist approaches considered corruption and economic underdevelopment as signs of “primitiveness” and lack of
civilization for states (Whyte 2007: 153). Today, the impact of culture on the growth and persistence of corruption is still debated. In a
cross-sectional study on the causes of corruption, Treisman (2000)
identifies at least six factors that can contribute to corrupt dealings
across the globe. According to Treisman, possessing a “Protestant
heritage” and exposure to British rule in its past decreases the likelihood of experiencing high corruption levels in a polity (ibid.).
Based on these arguments and related research, at a first glance,
there is a compelling reason to explain the level of corruption in a
society with its culture. Numerous surveys carried out in regions
like the Balkans, Latin America and elsewhere suggest that corruption, while not approved, is not universally condemned by people
either (World Bank 2000: 16; Irrera 2006: 9; Hislope 2011; USAID
2009: 8). Scholars like Whyte (2007: 154) further claim that it is
impossible to understand corruption outside the culture in which it
9 Some authors trace the link between development policies and security concerns
to nineteenth-century liberalism (Duffield 2010: 27).
14
Foreign Aid and Corruption
operates. Meanwhile according to Heineman and Heimann (2006:
77) fighting corruption also requires a cultural dimension, “which
involves transmitting positive values and norms that can strengthen
the enforcement, prevention, and state building measures.”
Contrary to such arguments, critiques of culturalist approaches to
corruption point out the pitfall of relegating such a complex phenomenon to a single and equally complex factor. On the one hand,
by lending ahistorical qualities to cultural traits, such approaches
tend to neglect how the term itself has evolved in time.10 The fact
is, many forms of actions that routinely took place in developed countries not so long ago would be dismissed as corrupt today. While
discussing different forms of foreign aid, Morgenthau (1962: 302)
mentions that bribery was an essential part of international diplomacy until early 19th century, and adds, “[n]o statesman hesitated
to acknowledge the general practice of giving and accepting bribes, however anxious he might be to hide a particular transaction.”
While discussing the evolution of the concept of corruption in developed societies, Huntington (1968: 63) similarly draws from the
British and US history, when the sale of ambassadorial or peer positions were regarded as perfectly permissible. While discussing the
evolution of the definition of what constitutes corruption in USA,
Johnson (2004: 23) argues that many former actions in US politics
would be defined as corrupt in current settings, with the latter one
primarily defined by changing public opinions.
Prevalent debates on corruption and development can be also profoundly misleading due to their cultural relativism and their inherent
10 As the later parts of this chapter discusses in further detail, neoliberal deinitions
of corruption similarly shares this ahistorical outlook. For a critical Marxist discussion on the latter subject, see Bedirhanoglu (2007: 1241).
15
Kurtoglu Eskisar
ties to the interests and strategies of donors. According to Bracking
(2007: 15), for instance, “more often than not, corruption is seen as
culturally relative (to the South), while expertise is given a universal
value (but principally resides in the North!).” Yet, as critiques of
the culturalist approach to such activities point out, elevated levels
of corruption or its acceptance within a society does not imply its
acceptance as a positive value by the perpetrators. Instead, it may
simply relect helplessness, “because there is no way out.” (Uslaner 2008: 6) While discussing the impact of corruption in Nigerian
culture, for instance, Smith (2007: 35) similarly points out that the
“culture of corruption” there persists simply because the involved
actors are unable to change or control the conditions that produce it
in the first place.
Some scholars have gone even further to claim that associating corruption with cultural practices has become a political act in and of
itself. According to Whyte (2007: 154), during the heyday of imperialism, its proponents routinely used terms like corruption “as an
ideological weapon in the struggle for the moral high ground as the
British Empire sought to triumph over its commercial competition.”
Ahistorical and universalistic in its outlook, the cultural perspectives toward corruption also coincides with the “good governance”
approach based on neoliberal principles, discussed later on in this
chapter. A major criticism directed against the good governance debate is its tendency to ignore the possibility of cultural relativism
and deny the rights of societies, which are instead imposed with
universal prescriptions to deal with the phenomenon (Barratt 2008:
21). Similar to the culturalist approach, the good governance approach has been labeled “one of the ways in which the North maintains
16
Foreign Aid and Corruption
and legitimizes its continued power and hegemony in the South.”
(Abrahamsen 2000: ix)
2.4 Regime types and corruption
Contradicting the cultural approaches to corruption and those that
rely on income level to explain its presence or absence in a country,
a closer examination reveals that corruption can be found in all parts
of the world. Unlike earlier assumptions, recent research relects that
corruption is not endemic to underdeveloped, poor or post-conlict
societies; rather, it can thrive in a variety of regime types (Rotberg
2009: 1-2). In fact, a growing number of studies relect that corruption may exist regardless of regime type and income level across
the globe. Contrary to intuition, for instance, corrupt activities can
and do take place in well-established democracies (e.g. Nelen 2014;
Bull and Newell 2003; Johnson 2004; Uslaner 2008: 1-2; Sun and
Johnston 2009). It is certainly misleading to assume that elections
are an antidote to corruption (Manzetti and Wilson 2007: 952). As
Mungiu-Pippidi (2013: 101) has pointed out, “[m]any of the countries that do a poor job of controlling corruption are electoral democracies. In fact, among the countries where corruption is prevalent,
those that hold free elections outnumber those that do not.”
Notwithstanding the ubiquity of corrupt practices worldwide, corruption that prevails in countries undergoing transition are often
worth further instrospection. While democracy is not immune to
hosting corrupt activities, in the absence of democratic consolidation, transitions into democracy themselves seem to carry a greater
risk for harboring corrupt activities. As Lancaster (2008: 35) has
pointed out, “it is far from clear that in the short or medium term democracy leads to improved governance. It is not proof against corruption and conlict—indeed, transitions from autocracy to democ17
Kurtoglu Eskisar
racy often intensify conlict.” In countries undergoing democratic
transition, weak parliaments may turn out to exacerbate corruption
due to their inability to shape the low of public funds or monitor
their effective spending (Carnahan et al 2004: 86). Finally, recent
findings suggest that there is no clear relation between holding regular elections and declining levels of corruption (Mungiu-Pippidi
2013: 102).
2.5 Effects of corruption on war torn countries
Corruption is assumed to have a particularly deleterious effect on
the reconstruction of war torn countries (Le Billon 2008; Phillips
2010:93; Rose-Ackerman 2009: 66). Such settings often quickly
turn into a hotbed of corrupt activities, as they frequently to encourage “extraordinarily high opportunities and low punitive risks.”
(Bolongaita 2005: 2) Furthermore, Johnston (2005: 1) explains the
negative impact of corruption as pervasive and argues that it affects
several fronts in state building process in countries with weak institutions: “[c]orruption benefits the few at the expense of the many;
it delays and distorts economic development, preempts basic rights
and due process, and diverts resources from basic services, international aid, and whole economies.”11 The economic conditions prevailing in a country in both pre- and post-conlict period can also
prove substantial to the existence, prevalence and type of corruption
links (Rose-Ackerman 2009: 70).
Since in post war countries administrative infrastructure and state
institutions that normally deliver basic public goods and services
11 For a more detailed discussion on the negative effects of corruption in such settings, see Ateljevic and Budak (2010: 377-378).
18
Foreign Aid and Corruption
are either completely absent or weak, the negative effects of corruption can quickly multiply in such settings (Damania et al. 2004).
Furthermore, peace settlements tend to include convoluted rules and
regulations, which often relect the complex dynamics of the often
fragile bargaining process that the negotiating sides experience. As
a result, they can contain what seems like endless details and regulations that are difficult to achieve and maintain in ordinary conditions by a regular state, much less in post-conlict settings (Johnson
and Jolyon 2008:16).
2.6 Corruption as an informal institution in post-conlict societies
In addition to the ever growing body of literature that is dedicated to
tracking and discussing the negative aspects of corruption, a number
of studies in recent years have been revisiting its unexpected—and
not always undesirable—side effects (e.g. Houston 2007).12 Most
of these studies start with the assumption that the role of corruption in transitioning societies in particular tends to be more complex
than often acknowledged. Some scholars further posit that in deeply
divided societies, corruption may function as a form of bargaining
between conlicting parties. Put differently, corrupt practices can
form a type of cohesion among divided societies, which is otherwise
not provided by the existing state institutions. “Corruption coalitions,” consisting of national elite of state, military, political, social
or economic origin in such settings can provide political stability
at the cost of preventing change (Johnston 2005: 89). In Kosovo,
for instance, Phillips (2010: 96) informs that crime networks have
12 For the debate between the revisionist approach to corruption in 1960s and
1970s and modernist approaches to development, see the “Modernization theories,
Development and Corruption” section in this book.
19
Kurtoglu Eskisar
helped to maintain peace in places like Mitrovica, which is “a potential lash point for the resumption of hostilities between Serbs
and Kosovar Albanians.”
Some of the recent studies on post-conlict societies receiving foreign aid therefore refute the earlier depiction of corruption as a nonpermanent form of relationship between actors. Instead, they argue
that it can assume institutional characteristics, if allowed to exist for
a prolonged period. As a result, some scholars have suggested studying corruption as a type of “informal institution.” (Muno 2013: 34)
Consider the case of Macedonia. In that country, corruption networks fostered by the coalition governments have led to the cooperation of opposing political elites representing different ethnic
groups (Muscat 2004: 108). While discussing Macedonian politics
following its independence, Hislope (2011: 150) noted the country’s
remarkable success in maintaining inter-ethnic peace despite its remarkably heterogeneous social composition and pressing problems
with its neighbors. According to Hislope (2011: 144), a significant
reason behind the Macedonian domestic peace during that period
may well have been a pragmatic alliance between its key ethnic
elites that heavily utilized corruption. Other studies have also revealed similar explanations (Ilievski 2007: 6). Ultimately, in a region
riddled by past conlicts, “[b]y promoting a policy of zero-tolerance
for corruption, the international community may in fact undermine
frail states by eliminating the only political mechanism that stands
between politics-as-bargaining and politics-as-war.” (Hislope 2011:
143)
The long-term positive effects of corruption, however, remain under suspect. A prevalent scholarly view is that unlike institutions
20
Foreign Aid and Corruption
that help to maintain and extend the longevity of a state and lend it
power to reinforce its legitimacy, corruption cannot limit or reverse
its long term negative effects, even despite the numerous pragmatic reasons that justify its existence (Rose-Ackerman 1999: 16-17;
Debiel and Gavrich 2013: 5). Indeed, in some settings, corruption
can become a self-justifying mechanism with destructive effects on
any attempts to create formal institutions and accompanying norms
(ibid.). In sub-Saharan Africa, for instance, practices dating back
to the colonial era have created their own institutions within the
state structure and have avoided intrusion or eradication efforts to
date (Yeh 2011: 630). After discussing the Macedonian experience
with corruption, Hislope (2011: 144) similarly acknowledges that
the short term benefits of corruption networks in Macedonia have
not stopped the involved elite from disrupting the status quo in favor
of what they perceived as a better equilibrium later.
Finally, some scholars have claimed that corruption can be used as
a mechanism of control for external parties, including international
donors. Based on the actions of the US-led coalition in Iraq following their occupation, Whyte (2007: 164), for instance, argues that
“corruption in complex state-corporate symbioses can equally be a
rational use or technique of power that is entirely consistent with the
overarching purpose of government.”
2.7 Poverty as a cause of corruption
Similar to culture, poverty is another frequently quoted factor behind corruption (Phillips 2010: 97). Academic discussions on the
issue notwithstanding, the following words of an Afghani policeman from 2003 summarize this proposition rather well: “I have four
children, they are all at school. Each child needs at least 1,000 Afg-
21
Kurtoglu Eskisar
hanis a month; tell me, how can I not be corrupt? We cannot live
on 1,500 Afghanis [US$30] a month – it is not possible.’” (Johnson
and Jolyon 2008: 194) This is a circular relationship, however, as
corruption is also regarded as a major factor behind global poverty
(Eigen 2009: 417).
Meanwhile, foreign aid has long been treated as manna for poverty.
This stance also resonates with the official claims of international
donors, who often assert that they offer aid to eradicate such conditions (Bracking 2007: 16). As Woods (2005: 394) has noted, since
1990s, but particularly after September 11, 2001 attacks, the international community has approached foreign aid as an effective tool
to fight poverty, which itself is regarded as a chief problem for security. Since poverty and corruption are generally assumed to share
a link, and foreign aid has been available to address both issues on a
global scale in recent years, it is useful to take a closer look at these
issues.
2.8 Corruption, development and good governance
Along with its assumed ties to morality, as pointed out earlier, many
observers also regard corruption to have tangible—and negative—
effects on development, social welfare and governance. Stapenhurst,
Ulrich and Strohal (2006:1), for instance, report that the Global Organization of Parliamentarians Against Corruption (GOPAC) regard
corruption as the most signiicant detrimental factor that leads to the
decline of the basic principles and institutions that form and support
democracies. A research study carried by Méon and Sekkat (2005:
71) similarly reached the conclusion that “corruption becomes even
more harmful when governance is poor.” Meanwhile, corruption is
similarly assumed to have a negative effect on foreign aid too:
22
Foreign Aid and Corruption
“Corruption ... slows down economic growth and development. Corrupt practices ... are costly to companies and thereby
reduce chances for corrupt states to attract necessary amounts
of foreign capital ... Therefore, it is legitimate to say that corrupt behavior of governments creates one of the most important obstacles to economic development. Corruption in developing states may also reduce the effectiveness and eficiency
of foreign aid.” (Schudel 2008: 507)
In order to understand the links between corruption and foreign aid
better, first it is necessary to define foreign aid, which the following
section aims to cover.
2.9 Defining foreign aid
Similar to corruption, the term foreign aid has a wide array of definitions in literature. “Official Development Assistance” (ODA),
which is a form of foreign aid is defined by Lancaster (2008: 39)
as “concessional public resource transfers from one government to
another (or to international or nongovernmental organizations) with
at least a 25 percent grant element, one purpose of which is furthering development in a poor country.”13 ODA has three general
forms: The first kind consists of grants that do not require repayment. The second type of ODA are “concessional loans.” Although
13 For ODA, Lancaster (2008: 39) further explains that
“[t]his deinition does not include export credits or trade
inancing, funding for cultural exchanges, remittances,
private charity, or funding for covert action by intelligence
agencies. It omits public resource transfers to countries not
classiied by the DAC [Development Assistance Committee
(DAC), which is a part of the Organisation for Economic
Co-operation and Development (OECD)] as ‘poor’ (such as
Russia or Israel).”
23
Kurtoglu Eskisar
they do require repayment, the receiving countries can stretch it
over time, and generally enjoy lower interest rates than those normally available on the market (Soubbotina 2004: 100 ). The final
type of ODA involves helping the international organizations that
promote global development, including the UN and the World Bank
(ibid). This study adopts the approach that foreign aid can occur in
the form of technical assistance or know-how that does not directly
involve pecuniary elements as well (Collier 2010: 214).
Just as it is important to understand what constitutes foreign aid, so
too it is necessary to identify aid recipients. Although it is not possible to determine the exact threshold after which a state is considered aid dependent, Goldsmith (2001: 125) explains that 10 percent
of gross national product (GNP) is a good starting point. Being a
member of the OECD or the DAC does not mean automatic exclusion from receiving aid. In fact, OECD reports that some of its members, including Turkey and Thailand have both been recipients of
aid (ODA) and donors (DAC) for a long time. However, the OECD
does remove those recipients that have been able to maintain a highincome per capita (based on the Gross National Income reports of
the World Bank) threshold for three consecutive years.14
2.10 Forms of foreign aid
Foreign aid can be between two countries—a donor and a recipient—or can be multilateral in nature. It can also be delivered in
many forms, some of them more prone to wastage than others, such
as those that are available through a program. In this type of aid,
donors allocate resources like money directly to the recipient government. Aware of the enticing lexibility that such a transfer al14 The conditions for ODA eligibility are available at http://www.oecd.org/development/stats/daclistofodarecipients.htm (accessed on 11 December 2014).
24
Foreign Aid and Corruption
lows the recipients, the donors often seek to monitor or control the
use of these funds “by accompanying it with conditionalities and an
increasing preference for enclave projects and parallel management
structures.” (Maipose 2000: 88; 95-96) Some of the common forms
of international aid include the following:
“development and poverty reduction, good governance (including democratization, elections and corruption), iscal
reform and management, security (including communism,
internal disturbances and terror), trade (including speciic
considerations regarding petroleum), Commonwealth or colonial history, aid effectiveness, humanitarian crises and rights.”
(Barratt 2008: 38)
In addition to regional specialists, economists, and foreign policy
specialists, IR theorists also offer their own types of foreign aid.
According to Morgenthau (1962: 301), there are six general forms
of foreign aid: “humanitarian foreign aid, subsistence foreign aid,
military foreign aid, bribery, prestige foreign aid, and foreign aid for
economic development.” Of these, he relects, only humanitarian
aid is non-political in nature, and even that form can have a political
function in a particular political setting (ibid.). Recently, Van der
Veen (2011: 10) distinguished seven general categories for foreign
aid goals, including “security, power and inluence, economic selfinterest (wealth), enlightened self-interest, self-affirmation and reputation, obligation and duty, and humanitarianism.”
25
Kurtoglu Eskisar
2.11 Who are the donors?
Foreign aid is available both through individual countries and international organizations. Regardless of whether action is independent
or collaboative, western donors offering foreign aid often pursue
similar goals (Akhand and Gupta 2002: 16-17). Until recently, notwithstanding exceptions, countries within the developed world, including Europe, North America and Japan, were leaders in offering
foreign aid. Following the relatively brief lapse that followed the
end of the Cold War during 1990s, this pattern seems to be changing
with the former Soviet Bloc re-entering the picture, to include Russia and Eastern Europe, China, and other regional actors like South
Korea and Turkey.15
2.12 Explaining the causes of foreign aid: normative factors
From a normative perspective, it is easy to grasp the logic behind
the foreign aid. According to Calderisi (2006: 156), the moral roots of foreign aid can be traced back to Judeo-Christian teachings:
“With two billion people in the world—a third of all humanity—
living on less than $2 a day, how can the afluent begrudge a portion of their wealth to help others?” Meanwhile, Hattori (2003:
230-231) traces the nonreligious roots of foreign aid to liberalism,
and summarizes them under three headings. The first line of that
argument follows a deontological16 approach and posits foreign aid
15 The reasons behind the eagerness of these “new” players to provide aid are
varied, and fall outside the scope of this book. While not thematically listed, the
following studies outline some of the prevailing discussions related to the subject
Woods (2008); Lancaster (2008: 40-43); Sörensen (2010); Woods (2008); Rowlands
(2008); Quadir (2013).
16 Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy explains deontology as follows:
“The word deontology derives from the Greek words for duty
26
Foreign Aid and Corruption
as a form of duty for developed countries to help provide for the
crucial human necessities—considered as a basic human right—of
their underdeveloped brethren. The second line of argument adopts
a more utilitarian17 approach and regards foreign aid as a remedy for
the technical failures and shortcomings of the receiving society or
country. In its general outlook, it resembles “a doctor-patient relationship, in which moral agency is attributed to (donor) doctors by
virtue of their technical capabilities and moral regard to (recipient)
patients because of the larger social benefit that can accrue from
their cure.” Hattori (2003: 230) The final perspective approaches
foreign aid from a humanitarian perspective, and seeks to justify
its presence and continuity through substantial amounts of public
support. (ibid.: 230-231).
2.13 Explaining the causes of foreign aid as an extension of
foreign policy goals
As the normative and security concerns given here suggest, giving
and receiving foreign aid is a serious business that defies solely economic concerns and explanations. While referring to the aid patterns
of the World Bank, Akhand and Gupta (2002: 17) assert that “[t]here
is a myth that the Bank makes its loan decisions entirely on the basis
(deon) and science (or study) of (logos) ... Deontology falls
within the domain of moral theories that guide and assess our
choices of what we ought to do (deontic theories), in contrast
to (aretaic [virtue] theories) that—fundamentally, at least—
guide and assess what kind of person (in terms of character
traits) we are and should be.” (http://seop.illc.uva.nl/entries/
ethics-deontological/, accessed on 10 December 2014).
17 According to Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, “utilitarianism is generally
held to be the view that the morally right action is the action that produces the most
good.” (http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/utilitarianism-history/, accessed on 11
December 2014)
27
Kurtoglu Eskisar
of economic factors, but ... such is simply not the case.” Their study
further concludes that contrary to the claims of donors that aid is
primarily to eradicate or reduce poverty, data does not support them
(ibid.: 35-36).
Aside from altruistic intentions, national interests can also motivate the basis and low of foreign aid.18 According to this viewpoint,
exceptions notwithstanding, countries or international organizations
take an active interest in the welfare of less fortunate countries when
it serves their interests (Bossin 2004: 75-76; Robb 2004: 29; Woods
2005: 394). As Taffet (2007: 2) argues, “[f]oreign aid is not, and
cannot be, divorced from foreign policy goals. Foreign aid is a tool
that policymakers use, and have used, to achieve their larger aims of
dominating, pacifying, protecting, strengthening, or changing certain countries.” Bearce and Tirone (2010: 837-838) further explain
that while factors like military interests or political gains significantly inluenced the amount of aid lowing from the Western world
throughout the Cold War years, other concerns have also been rising
to the forefront in recent years.19
18 While the focus here is on the factors that lead countries to become donors, it
is important to note that its absence, i.e., withholding foreign aid can also be an
important policy instrument. While explaining the withhold of the US foreign aid
toward Latin America during 1950s, Baldwin (1969: 432), for instance, makes the
following observation:
“Although strategic use of non-aid has been an important
means of inluencing developing states, its signiicance is
rarely recognized... Why should this be regarded as a ‘curious’ situation? It is precisely the kind of behavior we should
expect from a nation for which avoidance of competition
with private capital is one of the basic guiding principles of
its aid program. After we grow accustomed to thinking of
non-aid as a technique of statecraft, there is nothing at all
puzzling about the situation described.”
19 See, for instance, Radelet (2003).
28
Foreign Aid and Corruption
2.14 Political Realism and foreign aid
Since many scholars tend to approach foreign aid as a function of
foreign policy goals, it is useful to briely explore this relationship
from the perspective of leading IR theories. While discussing the
role of aid in foreign policy Hans Morgenthau (1962: 301), who
is one of the best known scholars of classical Realism, describes
the role of aid in foreign policy in those settings where the foreign
interests of a country cannot be solely addressed by military means
or diplomacy. Morgenthau (1962: 304) criticizes purely economic
approaches toward aid, “as though it were a self-sufficient technical
enterprise to be achieved with the instruments, and judged by the
standards, of pure economics.” Instead, he insists, “foreign aid ... is
not a science but an art.” (ibid.: 309)
Similar to classical realism, neorealism also considers states as both
rational and main actors in international relations. Furthermore,
neorealists consider anarchy as the main determinant of international structure, which both constrains and shapes state behavior. In
such an environment, there is little to no room for state preferences
that may be based on humanitarian or non-survival causes. However, unlike the classical realist approach, some neorealists have proposed studying economic factors in further detail to assess their role
in various security issues (Schraeder et al 1998: 311). The neorealist
interest in economic factors stems from the idea that economic capabilities can affect military strength and thereby also the impact the
overall state capabilities in any given international system.
As a result, similar to classical realists, neorealists quote economic
or strategic concerns of donors rather than humanitarian reasons as
main determinants of global foreign aid decisions. They view any
29
Kurtoglu Eskisar
foreign aid to have a potentially significant impact on constantly
shifting equilibria in global politics and security (Schraeder et al
1998: 298). While discussing the US motives behind being a donor
for Afghanistan, for instance, Stone (2010: 2) points out that “the
United States has compelling incentives to use its aid to promote
economic development in countries with friendly regimes that are
important to long-term U.S. strategies.” According to Schraeder et
al (1998: 311), the US foreign aid pattern towards Africa near the
end of the Cold War supports this view: “[S]everal of the top recipients of U.S. foreign aid during 1989, such as Nigeria, Ghana,
Senegal, and Kenya, were also those countries with which the U.S.
enjoyed important trade relationships relative to other countries in
Africa.”
2.15 Social constructivism and foreign aid:
Critics argue that neorealist approaches often fail to grasp all the
intricacies underlying the logic of foreign aid. The fact that it is
possible to explain literally any kind of foreign policy decision as a
result of security interests or strategic requirements of states further
diminishes the power of neorealist arguments on foreign aid (Palmer and Morgan 2006: 18-19). Furthermore, the realist explanations
tend to neglect or underestimate the equally strong—yet ultimately
clashing—coexisting undercurrents of foreign aid patterns of global
actors like USA from mid 1940s until 1980s , like fulfilling strategic
or political goals vs. developmental aid stemming from humanitarian sentiments (Rossiter [1985] cited in Akhand and Gupta 2002:1516).
30
Foreign Aid and Corruption
The proponents of social constructivist explanations for foreign aid
argue that instead of national interests or security concerns, ideas
that motivate the reasons and aims of foreign aid can also explain
why and how they occur (Van der Veen 2011: 2). According to the
social constructivist perspective, ideas form the basis of actor preferences, which ultimately generate from beliefs, and are variable.
Unlike realist and liberal explanations of foreign aid, constructivist
approaches can therefore explain how ideas can shape the goals behind foreign aid (Van der Veen 2011: 26). As Goldsmith (2001: 127)
points out, ideas as foreign aid matter, since “[p]olicy advice, and
training and education programs, can spread new ways of thinking
about governing and management.”
As a result, scholars like Van der Veen (2011) posit that while realist
explanations can explain the general tendencies of causes behind foreign aid toward corrupt countries, constructivist explanations may
uncover the underlying intricacies better. The view that the constructivist approach is superior to neorealist explanations of foreign
aid also dovetails with those recent findings, which conclude that
the causal factors indicating the aid decisions in the UNSC can be so
complex as to defy any general rules (Collier 2010: 83-84).
2.16 Liberalism and foreign aid:
The classic liberal view adopts a bottom-up perspective to explain why or how foreign aid occurs. Instead of external factors like
anarchy that shape the state behavior as explained by neorealism,
liberals posit that the society’s preferences based on the interactions of its members affect the state views and goals on foreign aid.
Nonetheless, liberal explanations do not clarify how society decides
on their preferences and neglects the role that perceptions and ideas
play in the process (Van der Veen 2011: 25).
31
Kurtoglu Eskisar
In order to understand the liberalist perspective toward foreign aid
better, an example from the US foreign policy is helpful. Travis
(2010: 799) explains that the US foreign aid patterns after mid1970s are often congruent with that country’s increasing interest in
democratization and observance of human rights in receiving countries. While the reason behind the US aid during these years could
generate from a real care for the welfare of the recipient countries, it
is also possible that the US emphasis on such conditions generated
from the goal of supporting other countries with similar values. If
the second argument holds, then foreign aid has acted both as a form
of prize for those countries that adopted such principles and as an
invitation for other potential recipient countries to do so (ibid.).
2.17 Modernization theories, development and corruption
Modernist theories, which rest on the utopian assumption that links
economic development and foreign aid while eradicating corruption, also need acknowledgement. The roots of modernist theories
can be traced both to antiquity as well as to the 20th century. On the
one hand, scholars like Easterly (2008: 4) argue that teleological
aspects of the modernist outlook date back to Aristotle, who considered economic development as a “Final Cause” that applies to
all polities, regardless of their differences. Modernization theories
and their approach to development played a key role in foreign aid
decisions for countries like USA during the Cold War. According
to Huntington (1970-1971: 164) it was during those years that “[i]
ndeed, ‘aid’ and ‘development’ came to be so closely linked as to be
almost interchangeable.”
Yet other scholars attribute the roots of modernization theory to the
Weberian concepts of rational authority and bureaucratic state or-
32
Foreign Aid and Corruption
ganization. According to this perspective, corruption is an anomaly
that is bound to become extinct in time with modernization. Later,
the critiques of the modernization theory during 1960s, refused to
treat the phenomenon as an aberration. Huntington (1968: 59), for
instance, wrote that contrary to the claims of the modernist approach, modernization intensifies corruption. This revisionist approach
treats corruption as a functional or utilitarian role for the societies
that heavily practice it (Chang and Chu 2006: 260).20
2.18 Development, international organizations and foreign aid
The debates that challenge or promote the necessity of good governance for state building is not only restricted to academic circles,
but remains a policy issue too (Marquette 2011: 1872). Many donor
countries continue to use modernization debates, which prevailed
policy making during 1960s, to justify their approach to development in transition countries. As a result, statebuilding theories borrow more from modernization theories than the good governance
debate (ibid.).
Interestingly, states are not the only actors that seek to maximize
their interests as international donors. More often than not, international organizations are not above pursuing their self-interests when
it comes to international aid. Calderisi (2006: 156), for instance,
argues that the establishment of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (the forefather of World Bank) after the
Second World War was not based on altruistic reasons, as idealism
would dictate, but rather on economic concerns propelled by selfinterest. Since then, not much has changed. As Duffield (2010: 26)
20 Some classic examples of the 1960s revisionist approach toward corruption
include Huntington (1968); Leff (1964) and Leys (1965).
33
Kurtoglu Eskisar
puts it, “[r]ather than a steady, experience-based refining and progression of policy ... every decade or two similar pronouncements
are repackaged by a new generation of policy-makers and presented
afresh as the way forward.” Le Billon (2005: 693) similarly contends that the oil-for-food program targeting Iraq during the Saddam
regime has been subject to intense manipulation by UN Security
Council members, who ruthlessly used the scheme to secure or improve their own political/economic goals. Another stark example of
foreign aid serving the donors rather than the recipient country can
be seen in the case of former Zaire. According to Maipose (2000:
94), due to foreign political interests, international aid continued to
low to Zaire during the Mobutu regime, even though the donors
were “fully aware of the abuses.” The results of this policy proved
devastating, as the country owed over US$10 billion due to foreign
debts in 1991:
“In this special case, aid was certainly abused and could not
have contributed to meaningful development due to a combination of wrong government policies, macroeconomic instability, economic misfortune, high debt-servicing obligations,
massive corruption and, equally important, light of capital.”
(Maipose 2000: 94)
2.19 Conclusion
As this chapter has tried to outline in detail, the definitions and causes of both foreign aid and corruption are diverse, and have been
subject to controversy among both scholars and policymakers alike. However, certain definitions and debates have found more favor than others in recent years, including the idea that corruption
is related to the use of public goods and services for private gains
and that maintaining good governance habits by governments can
34
Foreign Aid and Corruption
help overcome it. While linked with the modernization theory and
Weberian notions of public administration and efficiency, as well as
the more recent neoliberal approaches to the state-society relations,
this outlook has also received heavy criticism in both academic and
policymaking circles in recent years. Based on these debates, the
next chapter will overview the changing aid patterns, corruption definitions, and their impact on postconlict societies.
35
Kurtoglu Eskisar
36
Foreign Aid and Corruption
CHAPTER 3
CORRUPTION AND AID:
CHANGING PATTERNS
3.1 Introduction: Patterns of foreign aid
The development of the practice of international foreign aid as understood in contemporary times is frequently associated with the
US attempts after the Second World War (Akhand and Gupta 2002
citing Rossiter [1985] :15-16). Colonial powers like Britain, the
Netherlands and Belgium soon also developed aid programs for developing their own colonies during the same period, which were
gradually replaced by “development assistance programs.” (Van
der Veen 2011: 7) The following decade was similarly optimistic in
outlook, with the general idea being that newly independent postcolonial states could take the fast track to development by using
prescribed goals and methods (ibid.).
Although global foreign aid patterns are neither homogenous nor
universal, they seem to conform to the political and economic leitmotivs that prevail in various time periods. For instance, during the
Cold War, Bossin (2004: 86) concludes that the American and Soviet aid patterns remarkably differed from one another in Afghanistan.
The Soviet Union sought to replicate its economic development pattern during the 1930s, whereas United States aimed to provide the
country with widely used general methods or “know-how” skills.
Such methods would provide a wider application basis but no im37
Kurtoglu Eskisar
mediate tangible results. The Soviet strategy therefore focused on
offering a larger volume of credits with extended repayment dues
and reduced interest rates (ibid.).21
3.2 Neoliberalism, democratization and foreign aid objectives in
the post-Cold War era
After the Cold War, with the threat of communism no longer present, the foremost concern of the Western world was the spread of
democratic ideals and neoliberal teachings on liberal market economy worldwide. In this approach, democratization, in tandem
with the empowerment of the civil society, aims to act as the main
propeller of the transition into liberal market economy and politics.
The logic behind the aid for democratization is straightforward: giving voice to the public through elections can help to create more
responsive governments who will pay attention to remain efficient
and reliable (Goldsmith 2001: 136). The system is supposed to be
self-corrective, in that those governments that fail to do so will be
replaced through the ballot box. Among other gains, such reforms
also aim to eradicate corrupt practices or seriously weaken them in
favor of the private sector and civil society, which would gradually
gain the upper hand (Yeh 2011: 630).
US policy preferences during the first decade of the 2000’s confirms this change well. In 2005, USAID, which is the chief organization responsible for distributing US aid abroad expressed their
main goals as “(1) conlict resolution and state transformation, (2)
development of civil society, and (3) relief and development, both
21 Misdaq (2006: 84) similarly refers to the favorable inancial aid conditions offered by the former Soviet Union to Afghanistan during mid-1950s in an effort to
win over the Afghan ruling elite.
38
Foreign Aid and Corruption
social and economic.” (Picard and Groelsema 2008: 7) A year later,
Condoleezza Rice, the former US Secretary of State, officially declared the unification of USAID with the Department of State. US
priorities in providing aid were also redefined to include “regime
change, governance, and security issues” and a gradual exclusion of
developmental concerns (ibid.: 3). As of 2014, the official emphasis
on democratization and combating poverty worldwide to increase
US security and wealth remains intact.22
Discarding the state-led development models favored by communism and its variants and aiming to empower the individual vis-àvis the state, democratization reforms in many transition countries
have involved restricting state capacity and minimizing its direct
intrusion into market dynamics. The underlying idea here has been
that scaling back state involvement in economics and lending power
to the private sector would help increase transparency in governance. In addition to curbing any excessive leanings in governance, this
approach has also aimed to increase overall state efficiency.
3.3 Changing reactions to corruption
In tandem with the varying definitions of corruption discussed
earlier, global reactions to its existence have also changed in time
(Bracking 2007; Jakobi 2013; Manzetti and Wilson 2007: 950-951).
Whyte argues that (2007: 154) the tendency to regard corruption
as a deviant activity, which can be objectively measured, generates
from the classic liberal assumption on the division between the public and the private realm in a society. Liberalism regards the state as
22 USAID oficial site, located at http://www.usaid.gov/who-we-are/missionvision-values (accessed on 28 August 2014).
39
Kurtoglu Eskisar
the primary defender of public interests, while the market and the
economic activities are dominated by private actors. If these two realms contradict, it is due to the abnormal behavior of private actors,
who seek to increase their own payoffs or gain advantages in the
existing environment to the detriment of public interests (e.g. Eigen
2009: 424). This is “abnormal” (i.e., corrupt) behavior, in the sense
that such action transgresses what is supposed to be the “normal”
segregation between the two realms, as it also “normally involves
a conspiracy of elites.” (Whyte 2007: 155) According to this view,
then, corruption emerges as a major block against rational economic
development (ibid.).
Notwithstanding its traceable roots to classical liberalism, the global fight against corruption as an undesirable practice that needs
eradication at all costs is a relatively new development. Up until
1997, bribery of foreigners in business or other transactions was
a legally permissible act in Germany for export companies, which
could be officially used by them for tax deduction purposes (Jakobi
2013: 244; Eigen 2009: 419-420). Germany was not an isolated case
among the developed countries, either; many other Western countries also followed this pragmatic approach in their dealings with the
developing world.
The globalization of the fight against corruption dates back to 1970s,
when certain domestic reasons, such as the Watergate scandal, propelled the US to make new legal arrangements that outlawed the bribery of foreigners by US citizens (Jakobi 2013: 246; Warren 2006:
160-162). However, American companies soon found themselves
at a significant disadvantage over their Western competitors, which
40
Foreign Aid and Corruption
continued to manipulate corruption networks in various countries
“where bribes were accepted or even expected.” (Jakobi 2013: 247)
To address this imbalance, the US government began to increase
its efforts to spread its norms and regulations on corruption to international platforms like the OECD during 1980s (ibid.). Despite
initial resistance, Europe also followed suit, and gradually adopted
the US-led OECD convention in 1997, which declares bribery as a
criminal activity (ibid.: 248).23
3.4 The global rebirth of corruption as a crime
While initially limited to mainly economic and international business concerns, as a consequence of these efforts, international anti-corruption efforts have gradually spilled over to cover political
and administrative realms (ibid.: 245). They also changed their
tune: beginning with the Clinton period, international anti-corruption campaigns led by successive US administrations adopted an
increasingly moral tone (ibid.: 247). As an extension of neoliberal
approaches to economic development and governance, detecting
and eradicating corruption have thus become increasingly important global concerns.
Tracking corruption levels on a global level is a relatively recent
development. In tandem with the rising number of regime transitions to democracy since 1990s, statebuilding efforts have routinely
involved anti-corruption measures.24 International donors have also
23 OECD Convention on Combating Bribery of Foreign Public Oficials in International Business Transactions is available at http://www.oecd.org/corruption/oecdantibriberyconvention.htm (accessed on 11 August 2014).
24 For further discussion on this topic, see Heineman Jr. and Heimann (2006: 77).
41
Kurtoglu Eskisar
increasingly adopted the belief that any efforts to promote transparency and less state involvement would act as a dynamo for the selfdevelopment of recipient countries and democracy (Barratt 2008:
21). State building aid provided by international actors in postconlict societies has thus become tightly related to anti-corruption
campaigns and “good governance” approaches on a more general
level. Furthermore, fighting corruption has become important to
attract and maintain high levels of foreign investment to a country
(Donais 2005: 64).
3.5 States as principal actors in forming and enforcing anticorruption laws
Non-state actors have been indispensible helpers of states in further
empowering their efforts during anticorruption campaigns and spreading the associated norms (Jakobi 2013: 245-246). Here, “global
norm diffusion” refers to the condition where a particular policy that
is spread is attractive for normative reasons to other players (ibid.).
During this process, the input of some of the international organizations has been particularly important. The U.S. based MCC, for
instance, is an organization that tracks large amounts of aid low to
receiving countries based on their levels of corruption, among other
statistical indicators of good governance (Heller 2009: 47-50).
Notwithstanding the increasing involvement of international organizations on issues related to foreign aid in recent years, states remain pivotal for creating and enforcing international norms on corruption (Jakobi 2013: 245-246). More often than not, “governments
strategically promote their own norms on the international level as a
binding standard for all.” (ibid.) The impact of international norms
42
Foreign Aid and Corruption
is often contingent on their compatibility with the existing aid principles of a donor country (Van der Veen 2011: 17). A clear indication of the prevailing state power over international organizations
on foreign aid decisions can be seen in the historical evolution of
the World Bank. Although the World Bank today is internationally
reknowned for its efforts to promote global development and plays
a key role to combat poverty, these ideas were inculcated by the US
government (Ayres [1983] cited in Akhand and Gupta 2002: 16).
3.6 Problems related with tracking corruption through global
indices
Despite its widespread use and convenience, tracking corruption
through global indices like TI or WGI also carries significant risks
for both methodological and ethical reasons. Scholars like Apaza
(2009) and Bader et al (2013) point out the inherent conceptual
and methodological weaknesses of such aggregated data. While
evaluating corruption, adopting the same criteria indiscriminately
to evaluate both countries that operate on ideal democratic norms
and possess well-functioning liberal economies and those countries
that undergo transition can prove misleading. On a more general
level, aggregate data representing a country or a region can include
wide variances, and thus turn out to be misleading on a micro level. While not directly related to the measurement of corruption, the
following example is informative in this respect. When asked about their opinion of Afghani state’s progress (whether it is “moving
in the right direction or wrong direction”) 84% respondents in the
Helmand region of Afghanistan replied affirmatively, as opposed to
32% of the respondents in Nooristan (Asia Foundation 2013: 21).
The aggregate survey result for the whole country, however, has
43
Kurtoglu Eskisar
revealed that on average, 57% of the people believe that it is moving
in the right direction, and 38% believe that it is not (ibid.: 16).
3.7 Critical approaches to global anti-corruption campaigns
Relegating corruption to the realm of its legality or illicit nature,
however, can create more problems than solutions. On the one hand,
the increasing tendency to link corruption with illegality can help to
load “all of the safeguards that we associate with legal procedures
and legal rules into our treatment of this phenomenon.” (Underkuffler 2009: 29) On the other hand, the illegality concept depicted as
such can fail to fully cover the wide spectrum of corrupt actions,
or, contrastingly, prove far broader than the latter concept implies.
(ibid.) As Underkufler (2009: 34) has pointed out, while prevalent
among economic approaches to corruption, this view is problematic
in that it does not explain why the legal framework is superior to the
alternative path (act of corruption) adopted by the practitioners. In
fact, the proponents of this approach seem to miss that corruption
may result simply due to the unwanted aspects of the formal system
due to inefficiency or other laws.
Furthermore, scholars like Findlay (2014: 180) argue that treating
corruption as merely a criminal activity without examining the underlying economic and political power relations lends the defining
agents power. Anti-corruption measures adopted globally often not
only declare such behavior as criminal but also depict them as apolitical acts and tend to isolate them from surrounding economic or
political activities. Such an approach mostly focuses on the perpetrator of the “crime” instead of relecting on its founding dynamics,
thereby failing to identify and understand the full net of players involved in the act. By doing so, “the discourse and procedure of cri44
Foreign Aid and Corruption
minalization emphasizes pathology and illegality, rather than commercial and social utility.” (ibid.: 180) Such measures create the
illusion that corruption can be eradicated or kept in check through
prescribed institutions and applied definitions instead of identifying
and addressing the power relations that produce it in the first place
(ibid). The result is increased power to its evaluators that can prolong economic dependence (Bracking 2007: 15).
Finally, recent research on foreign aid patterns suggests that donor
reactions to corruption in recipient countries is not uniform, but rather depends on their own level of corruption. Schudel (2008: 508),
for instance, has found out that while those countries with a low
level of corruption are sensitive to the corruption levels of the recipient country and would tend to donate less amounts to them, their
more corrupt counterparts would have no such reservations. Schudel explains this discrepancy in donor behavior with the differing
relations of each donor government with their own society: the low
corruption governments care about the preferences of their public
and expect their aid to make a positive difference to the development of recipient country. In contrast, high corruption governments
value personal gains over public interests and make aid decisions
based on strategic calculations (ibid.).
3.8 Good governance debate
Due to the aforementioned issues, among others, an increasing
number of scholars have been requesting a more critical approach
to explaining corruption and development. Instead of taking development as a given, some scholars posit that its rationale requires
dismantling. Bracking (2007: 14), for instance, argues that if deve-
45
Kurtoglu Eskisar
lopment is taken as a concept that is constructed, rather than given,
corruption becomes another term where those that attribute criminal
characteristics to its definition seek to alter the perception of viewers, thus creating the illusion that it is an objective and universal fact. Furthermore, attributing universality and objectivity to the
definition of corruption through statistics and other mathematical
measurement techniques, as used by international organizations like
CPI, ultimately creates a timeless reading of the issue. This approach, however, is problematic at best, as it reinforces “dominant view
of reality, such that knowledge is created conditioned by the power
and positionality of those party to constructing the index.”(Bracking
2007: 14)25
Scholars like Khan (2004), Le Billon (2005: 686) and Barratt (2008:
21) similarly explain the tendency to attribute negative characteristics to corruption in the literature with the “good governance”
bias. According to Coles (2007: 240), “[d]emocracy promotion by
the humanitarian industrial complex less often features the popular
struggle for democracy and more often touts the transition to welldefined practices of good governance and efficacy.” Khan (2004)
similarly contends that the “good governance” approach attempts
to measure up the developing countries with an idealized notion of
a democratic state with a fully developed liberal free market economy. Any measurable discrepancies between the ideal and the
existing conditions are then taken as evidence of underdevelopment
or a failing/weak economy.
25 The tendency of international institutions to “standardize knowledge” is hardly
unique to corruption related issues. For a similar approach on democratization, see
Coles (2007: 240).
46
Foreign Aid and Corruption
Meanwhile, an increasing number of scholars point out that defining corruption and developing responses to it is not solely an
intellectual exercise particular to academic settings, but can have
immense political implications particularly for those countries that
receive foreign aid. Encouraging good governance while tracking
corruption levels in particular has a direct impact on the availability
and amount of foreign aid (Heller 2009: 47). The UN international
conference that led to Monterrey Consensus in 2002, for instance,
explicitly tied development with good governance and promised
increased availability of aid to those underdeveloped countries with
a good record on corruption (ibid.). The lessons gained from earlier
failures and problems concerning the transfer and consequences of
international aid have also had a substantial impact on the growing
efforts to increase public involvement in demanding the eradication
of corruption (Groves and Hinton 2004: 4). The message of these efforts was clear: the donors expected the recipient countries to make
a real effort to check and reduce corruption levels and implement
development programs associated with good governance to ensure
the low of aid.
The problem with the good governance argument, Khan (2004: 16)
argues, is that it contrasts with factual evidence from the past. Indeed, recent data from developing countries seems to indicate that
different corruption practices can lead to different effects, not all of
them negative (Khan 2006; Mironov 2005).26 Lancaster (2008: 49)
similarly argues that it is misleading to evaluate country performance by simply labeling them as “good” or “bad”, as many countries
would probably possess both forms at any given time. Furthermore,
26 Between these types exists yet another type, which Khan (2004: 20-21) refers to
as “quasi-legal rent-seeking,” exempliied by patronage and/or clientelist networks.
47
Kurtoglu Eskisar
examples like China and Indonesia suggest that significant amounts
of economic growth are possible despite remarkable levels of corruption and under institutionalized legal structure (ibid.). Meanwhile, Marjit and Mukherjee (2007: 19) warn that overemphasizing
labels like “good policy” or “corruption” can lead to a paradox: Selecting recipients based on such criteria may end up overlooking countries that desperately need assistance but remain under the radar
due to their sluggish development rates.
Some scholars have criticized the neoliberal tendency for minimal
state intervention as “state-lite” and their preoccupation with full
force market economy as an obsession (Sörensen 2010: 78). A critique has bluntly accused the neoliberal definitions of corruption as
being “ahistoric, biased, contradictory and politicised, and has been
induced by concerns over market competition rather than morality.”
(Bedirhanoglu 2007: 1239) However, for international donors, a
less inquired but nonetheless plausible explanation for adopting
neoliberal principles in making foreign aid decisions can involve
institutional factors. Although various ideological, strategic or moral causes are routinely offered for adopting neoliberal principles
in foreign aid and corruption, it is also possible that actors—states,
international organizations or other actors alike—also follow it due
to path dependency.
When international donors set good governance as their priority and
make administrative and institutional reforms based on universal
guidelines instead of paying attention to local nuances and existing
balances, they can worsen, not improve, the existing conditions in
receiving countries. Taken to its extreme, “good governance” can
resemble little more than a universal to-do list on achieving econo-
48
Foreign Aid and Corruption
mic efficiency, which can widen social inequalities as well as increase overall levels of instability (Barrett 2008: 21).
According to critics, the main problem with the neoliberal approaches that dominate the global aid patterns today is that they tend
to neglect the aftermath of development, and more importantly, the
distributional effects of sheer economic calculations (Esman 2004:
160). They also fail to explain the emergence and low of international aid in post-Cold War era.
What is deeply problematic with neoliberal approaches to economic
development and corruption is that they implicitly assume that such
cases can be objectively classified and evaluated without offering
convincing methodological or other justification (Bracking 2007:
15). Indeed, the followers of this approach themselves acknowledge the methodological shortcomings of “measuring” a phenomenon
like corruption, an act itself primarily subject to individual perception and reporting in the first place. Furthermore, over time, the measurement of concepts like corruption and good governance have
come to include a broad set of other hitherto excluded concepts,
such as “human rights, democracy, civil society, accountability,
business transparency, fiscal accountability, and the rule of law,”
without thoroughly justifying their use (Heller 2009: 54). Without
making such clarifications, any achieved results through such indices risk being meaningless (ibid.).
The greatest problem concerning the neoliberal approach toward
corruption, therefore may be its disinclination to explicitly acknowledge its limits. As Lancaster (2008: 49-50) has pointed out concerning US aid during the Bush administration in the US, sometimes
right policies may not suffice to reach intended goals. Since the
motivating factors behind foreign aid tend to be complex and its
49
Kurtoglu Eskisar
use and “efficiency” is not subject to objective factors, studies that
solely rely on statistical data analysis are likely to come up with
misleading conclusions (ibid.).
3.9 International aid and economic development
According to the research of Easterly, Levine and Roodman (2004),
there is no relationship between international aid and economic
growth, including those cases where the aid-receiving countries
follow the recipes prescribed by donors. Bearce and Tirone (2010:
838) argue that foreign aid can help economic development only if
the outcome results in little direct benefit for donors. They stress that
the opposite is not effective, as the “the strategic benefits” that the
donors expect to receive by their donation decrease their ability to
convince the receivers that they can enforce their conditions without
jeopardizing their gains. Johnson and Jolyon (2008: 203) similarly
claim that in countries like Afghanistan, much touted neoliberal
measures like privatization do not have any positive effects on an
already corrupt government.
The positive impact of foreign aid on helping to establish law and
order in recipient countries has also been subject to criticism. A common argument against foreign aid states that it encourages the recipient countries to decrease or not try to increase services commonly
associated with states, such as keeping law and order (Goldsmith
2001: 126). Goldsmith (2001: 124) uses the term “moral hazard” to
describe the negative effects of foreign aid on recipient countries.
These effects are a result of the rising tension between donors, who
press for political reforms, and recipients, who avoid them. In moral
hazard debate, local authorities are assumed to eschew the political
50
Foreign Aid and Corruption
responsibilities of the existing status quo due to receiving aid.27
3.10 Now and forever? Deining the limits of foreign aid
Aside from deciding on the form it takes, one of the most pressing
donor concerns about offering aid is timing. Agreeing on the starting and ending time of the aid can become a bitter subject of controversy both within the donor and recipient states. Meanwhile, for the
recipient countries that are heavily or exclusively reliant of foreign
aid, fulillment of aid pledges can become a matter of survival. After
the end of a violent conlict, donors often fail to follow up on their
aid promises or end up giving far less than what is initially pledged.
The negative effects of the failure to fulill the earlier promises of
aid are numerous. Statebuilding and related anticorruption efforts
rarely produce immediate and dramatic results. More importantly,
such projects often demand a lot of time and patience, which may
well exceed the attention span that donors are willing to offer due
to their own domestic constraints28 and other agendas. Since most
donors are interested in getting immediate results, they tend to focus
on offering humanitarian aid or physical reconstruction efforts rather than investing in time consuming and oftentimes invisible steps
that would bring long lasting results (Easterly 2008: 517; Maley
2006: 98).
27 Interestingly, Goldsmith (2001: 124) also likens moral hazard debate for foreign
aid to the opponents of social welfare in domestic politics, on the grounds that
“welfare supposedly reduces the work ethic.”
28 For a detailed overview of the literature on public opinion and foreign aid, see
Milner and Tingley (2013).
51
Kurtoglu Eskisar
3.11 Foreign aid and corruption in divided societies
Transition periods, which involve dramatic political or economic
changes, can often produce unintended byproducts (Le Billon 2005:
689). As Balkan countries (as well as the countries depicted by this
study) well exemplify, external assistance can unwillingly exacerbate the existing corrupt networks or play a role in the formation of
new ones (Kurtoglu Eskisar and Komsuoglu 2015). Financial aid
or political reform packages often attract existing local players who
are already involved with corrupt activities and wish to enrich themselves with the illicit spoils unwillingly offered by the donors. Fulfillment of rigid bureaucratic rules or regulations required by donors
in return for assistance can also encourage local actors to implement
superficial measures that lack longevity.
3.12 Foreign aid for peacebuilding and corruption
The formulaic outlook of neoliberal approaches toward foreign aid
already covered in the previous section neglects the nuances that
underline the existing forms of corruption in a given setting. For
instance, the type of conlict that a society went through can also
affect the type of corruption that it will experience later on (RoseAckerman 2009: 66). More often than not, the cause of conlict or
conditions that weaken a former state also persist in the post-war
state. (Doig and Tisne 2009: 374). External actors that are willing to
intervene to end the conlict—and often become donors following
the cessation of hostilities—find themselves in a dilemma: excluding the sides that played a key role in the eruption or sustenance
of conlicts initially risks the premature dissolution of peacekeeping
efforts and provoke further armed conlict (ibid.: 376).
52
Foreign Aid and Corruption
3.13 Peace settlements and corruption in post-conlict societies
Although attaining and maintaining peace is a much desired ending,
the particulars of the peace agreement can also have a serious impact
on the existence and type of corruption in a setting (Rose-Ackerman
2009: 68). Peace settlements that rely on inter-group cooperation
can also prove hazardous grounds for corruption:
“The division of state power allows more hands to reach into
the pot. Each group may feel pressure to provide beneits to its
supporters, thus exhausting the pool of rents. Furthermore, if
power-sharing means that those in government feel that their
tenure is shaky or incomplete, they may try to take what they
can for short-term gain.” (Rose-Ackerman 2009: 68)
A similar risk also exists during international assistance following a
conlict for peacebuilding purposes, which may have the unexpected effect of monopolizing and even institutionalizing corruption
networks to ensure “economic and political stability.” Practices,
particulary those that are loosely related with corruption, such as
“nepotism, fraud, over-invoicing, lack of transparency and accountability, and tax avoidance” during post-conlict foreign assistence
based on liberal principles, further challenge the validity and usefulness of such efforts (Le Billion 2008: 345).
3.14 Organized crime networks, corruption and political elite in
post-conlict settings
In some post-conlict settings, close ties between organized crime
networks and political elite, often built prior to or during the conflict, can also exacerbate the leanings toward corruption. Greenhill
53
Kurtoglu Eskisar
(2009: 97) refers to such relations as “kleptocratic interdependence”
and defines them as follows:
“a set of proit- and power-driven, self-reinforcing domestic
and international relationships between criminal groups and
government oficials. In its most basic form, criminals provide
inancial succor to receptive (would-be) political leaders, who,
once in power, in turn strive to protect those providing their
largesse. These activities concomitantly serve to strengthen
and enrich both the criminals and the corrupt politicians, helping them to consolidate their power while heightening their
mutual dependency.”
Such liaisons are particularly worrisome as they often prevent the
establishment or reinforcement of institutions that can monitor or
punish corruption (Rose-Ackerman 2009: 67).
Though unintentional, international aid can foster or reinforce corrupt networks between criminal gangs and political elite. International aid available after post-conlict to reconstruct the wasted infrastructure can be used by political elite and bureaucrats and their
cronies to line their pockets (ibid.). Lack of reliable statistical data
forms a serious problem for making accurate assessment of what is
available or needed in post-conlict regions (Bossin 2004: 89).
3.15 Foreign aid as a rent source in post-conlict societies
In post-conlict societies, using international aid as a form of rent
constitutes another problem (Rose-Ackerman 2009: 67). More often
than not foreign aid is used to delect an approaching or existing
emergency or crisis, and therefore lacks sufficient mechanisms to
monitor its expenditure, thus reinforcing corrupt habits (ibid.: 71).
54
Foreign Aid and Corruption
The disinclination of donors to require well defined rules that monitor the aid low under such conditions further exacerbate the problem (ibid.).
3.16 Foreign Aid and social cohesion in post-conlict societies
Yet another condition often ignored by international donors is the
disinclination of different or opposing groups to form state institutions that would represent the whole population in post-conlict
societies. A condition often ignored by western donors is that “in the
societies of the bottom billion, ethnic identity usually trumps national identity.” (Collier 2010: 51) Furthermore, democratization efforts in weak states with existing ethnic or other group divisions can
lead to centrifugal tendencies by strengthening ethnic or other group
identities (Belloni 2007: 26). A strong emphasis on group identity
in societies where it plays an important role in politics can increase
corruption. A recent research by Banerjee and Pande (2009:4) has
found out that emphasizing ethnic identity can encourage politicians
to get involved in corruption. Finally, Belloni (2007) argues that in
societies divided by ethnic or other identity based cleavages, neoliberal recipes are unlikely to succeed, as corruption in economic
and political realms adopts a predatory stance concerning state or
private owned goods. Furthermore, such quick paced reforms can
further destabilize the society by increasing inequality and increasing the likelihood of renewed conlict.
3.17 Donor awareness of conditions in recipient countries
International donors often remain oblivious to the nuances that underline the prevailing political and social conditions in a given setting, including ethnic and/or political conlicts, and cultural values
(Sörensen 2010: 100). Worse, they miss the fact that any aid made
55
Kurtoglu Eskisar
available in such a setting is likely to be used by one of the conlicting parties, to the exclusion or detriment of other groups (Picard
and Groelsema 2008: 13). In Kosovo, for instance, international aid
for democratization and building civil society has ended up serving
mostly ethnic Albanians, to the detriment of other ethnicities, and
ended up undermining the Serbian state there during 1990s (Sörensen 2010: 95).
In Bosnia and Herzegovina, the dysfunctionality of the central authority that is formed by the consensus of all formerly conlicting
groups has eased the path to corrupt activities (Divjak and Pugh
2008: 375). Economic conditions preceding the Bosnian war, followed by the war conditions later, also inluenced the approach of
people toward post war corruption opportunities (ibid.). While discussing corruption in Nigeria, Okojie and Momoh (2007: 113) similarly point out the difficulty of undertaking any meaningful action,
as any attempt to fight corruption among state employees is often
regarded as a political act with ethnic undertone.
3.18 Corruption networks and inter-group conlict in post
conlict societies
Although often presented as an outcome dependent on a variety
of factors, the above discussed points suggest that corruption can
also become a source of instability and induce inter-group conlict.
Corruption networks, which exclude certain groups in favor of others, combined with repression, can lead to the outbreak of violent
conlicts. International donors can use aid to promote inter-group
cooperation in a post-conlict setting. However, if earlier injustices
are not addressed, or aid distribution does not address the expectations of all players, instead of the expected benefits, it may have an
56
Foreign Aid and Corruption
adverse effect on long-term peace. Worse, donors themselves can
become accused of discriminating against specific actors or groups,
which can decrease the credibility of the goals set by the donor and
increase the likelihood of transgression.
3.19 Weak judiciary and corruption in post-conlict societies
Lack of institutions can exacerbate tendencies for corruption in
post-conlict societies (Rose-Ackerman 2009: 67). The lack of institutionalized rules and their universal implementation seriously
impedes the efforts to fight corruption on a decisive and long term
basis (Maipose 2000: 90). In some cases, like Afghanistan, the resistance of corruption networks to follow existing legal framework
has acquired a systematic nature, where the authorities in charge of
combating corruption actually foster such behavior (USAID 2009:
4). In order to eradicate rampant corruption in Kosovo, Phillips
(2010: 94) asserts that establishing the rule of law is a must, and it
needs to be reinforced by a legal system fully independent from the
executive.
Meanwhile, addressing corruption related problems does not only
concern taking administrative measures, but also requires serious
(re)arrangements in the judiciary for at least two reasons. First, people seem to be more sensitive to discrepancies in law enforcement
(e.g. selective law enforcement based on nepotism or patronage)
than the existence of corruption per se. Second, fighting corruption
with an institutionalized legal framework also promotes democratic
consolidation in the long run (Johnston 2005: 3).
57
Kurtoglu Eskisar
3.20 Conclusion
As this chapter discussed, the changing definitions of corruption
have had a significant inluence on foreign aid patterns in recent
years. Compared to the Cold War years, developing countries with
high levels of corruption in particular have found it increasingly
difficult to receive aid. The assumed link between corruption and
lack of good governance has also led international donors to encourage aid receiving countries into adopting neoliberal principles to
reshape their economies and politics. The donor tendency to push
for the adoption of similar practices in post-conlict societies, however, have generated a number of problems hitherto unexpected by
them. A major factor behind this unpredicted outcome is the level of
complexity of postconlict environments, which are often neglected
by donors.
The following chapters will now try to cover the particular examples that the theoretical debates raised in chapters 2 and 3.
58
Foreign Aid and Corruption
CHAPTER 4
AFGHANISTAN
“Mr. President, I urge you to undertake a sweeping, coordinated, and decisive counter-corruption campaign. Here time
is not on your side. Acknowledging that the US and West bear
some of the responsibility for the state of corruption in Afghanistan, the great challenge to Afghanistan’s future isn’t the
Taliban, or the Pakistani safe heavens, or even an incipiently
hostile Pakistan. The existential threat to the long term viability of modern Afghanistan is corruption. Indeed, across your
great country, the ideological insurgency, the criminal patronage networks, and the drug enterprise have formed an unholy
alliance, which relies for its success on the criminal capture of
your government functions at all levels.”
John R. Allen, General, Former Commander, NATO ISAF,
and U.S. Forces in Afghanistan (2014)
“The water is dirty from the source ... Governors and ministers, businessmen and bureaucrats — everyone is involved.”
Khan Jan Alokozai (Deputy Chairman of the Afghanistan
Chamber of Commerce and Industry, cited in Walsh [2014])
“You should cooperate with me on these reforms. You have
accused me of making deals. Yes, I have done so, but I had
reasons. And now I am changing this. I am bringing reform
from the inside…”
Hamid Karzai (President of Afghanistan [2004-2014]; cited in
Riechmann [2012])
59
Kurtoglu Eskisar
4.1 Foreign aid and Afghanistan during the Cold War
Afghanistan is no stranger to receiving foreign aid: the beginnings of
international aid low into the country dates back to the late 1940s.29
From the 1950s until the end of the 1970s, the Afghan state received
about $2 billion worth of foreign aid, which has comprised more
than 40% of its income since 1960s (Dorronsoro 2005: 63). During
those earlier decades of the 20th century, aid low to the country was
not dominated by a single donor or international agency. Rather,
most of it occurred in the form of bilateral agreements, led by the
USSR (54%) and USA (31%), respectively (ibid.). The prevalence
of aid from these two donors in particular was mostly related to their
rivalry throughout the Cold War, from which Afghanistan significantly benefited, especially during the earlier years (ibid.).
In tandem with global changes to foreign aid and the rising importance of international organizations in general, bilateral aid agreements were gradually replaced with multilateral patterns during
1970s throughout the world. In the meantime, funding from the US
and USSR receded. As these international organizations began to
offer more aid to Afghanistan, they also became more important
actors for the country (ibid.) The rise of international organizations
during the same period also marked the decline of direct US aid to
Afghanistan, even though the Soviet aid remained significant well
until the end of 1970s:
“At the time of the communist coup in 1978 ... US aid ... made
up merely 42 per cent of Russian aid, and consisted of loans
and grants for training, education, road building, and an agri-
29 For more information on the foreign aid low to Afghanistan before this period,
see Misdaq (2006: 66-69).
60
Foreign Aid and Corruption
cultural project near Kandahar. Soviet aid was actually greater
than the combined aid Afghanistan obtained from the US, the
different agencies of the UN, the World Bank and the NATO
countries combined.” (Misdaq 2006: 70)
4.2 The effects of foreign aid to Afghanistan during the Cold War
Foreign aid to Afghanistan in earlier decades did not achieve its
purported goals. Contrary to the arguments of the modernization
theory, instead of penetrating all segments of Afghan society and
promoting its rapid economic and political development as expressed by donors, it “succeeded only in creating modernized enclaves.”
(Dorronsoro 2005: 64) Moreover, in a country that was already fragmented by complex ethnic and sectarian differences, the ensuing social polarization turned out to cripple the efforts for a lasting peace.
Later, its effects on general governance and corruption levels during
the Cold War era were hardly any better. As Maley (2006: 52) has
boldly stated, “[t]he old state bureaucracy before 1978 was one of
the most corrupt in human history.” Country observers therefore often explain the Taliban’s success in controlling Afghanistan during
1990s and lasting appeal to the Afghan people by its local reputation
for being less corrupt than its predecessors (Ahmed 2015).
4.3 Afghanistan War (2001-2014)30 and its impact on
intraethnic relations
Since it falls outside the scope of this book to discuss in depth the
reasons and military dynamics of the War in Afghanistan that began
in 2001, this section will only highlight a few key points. Following
the terrorist attacks launched by the international Islamist terror or30 The years here mark the oficial beginning and end of the war operations in
Afghanistan by the US and UK. Furthermore, 2014 marks the transition of security
keeping from NATO forces to Afghan army.
61
Kurtoglu Eskisar
ganization named al-Qaeda in the USA on September 11, 2001, the
US launched a war campaign against Afghanistan in October 2001
to eradicate its leader and headquarters. The same campaign also
targeted the Taliban, another radical Islamist group that had maintained control over most parts of Afghanistan since 1994. Declaring
itself as the legitimate Afghan government after coming into power,
the Taliban was known to host al-Qaeda camps on Afghan soil prior
to and following the September 11 attacks and refused to hand its
leaders over to the US.
After the US-led invasion of Afghanistan began in late 2001, the
UNSC formed the ISAF31 by the end of that same year. The initial
goal of the ISAF was to ensure the general security in Kabul and its
immediate surrounding areas. However, the efforts to incrase international involvement on the ground, expand the newly established
state authority outside of the Kabul region, and provide security
throughout Afghanistan led to changes in the structural organization
and functions of the ISAF. Its operational area gradually expanded
to cover the whole country, and NATO assumed its leadership in
August 2003. NATO leadership over the ISAF lasted until the end
of 2014, when the responsibility of Afghanistan’s security officially
passed to the NATO trained Afghan army.
Following the Taliban’s fall from power, international efforts and aid
low to reconstruct Afghanistan gained velocity. However, the task
awaiting the international donors who were willing to get involved
in the reconstruction of Afghanistan was formidable. In 2006, the
31 For a brief overview of ISAF and its actions in Afghanistan, see NATO (2015),
ISAF’s mission in Afghanistan (2001-2014), http://www.nato.int/cps/en/natohq/topics_69366.htm (accessed on 29 January 2015).
62
Foreign Aid and Corruption
Afghan government officially announced its need for roughly US$4
billion each year for the next five years for its immediate recovery
plan (Maley 2006: 136).
As in other post-conlict settings, aside from the reconstruction of
the physical infrastructure, donors also regarded speed in statebuilding to be of essence, as it would help prevent any anti-democratic inclinations that may lourish in an atmosphere of desperation
(Diamond 2006). Therefore, soon after the start of the US-launched
war campaign, a UN led international meeting in Bonn at the end
of 2001 declared the establishment of the new government as “Interim Authority,” to be followed by a “Transitional Authority,” which
later became the “Transitional Islamic State of Afghanistan.” Afghan Interim Administration, which was established on 22 December
2001 lasted until 13 July 2002, and left its place to Afghan Transitional Authority, which functioned until 7 December 2004.
The US-led war campaign against al-Qaeda and Taliban not only
brought military results but also had a lasting impact on both ethnic
balances and the overall political panorama of Afghanistan (Rotberg
2007: 10). During the initial phase of the campaign, the lack of broad international involvement on the ground led the US to heavily
rely on the Afghan warlords to fight against al-Qaeda and the Taliban. While militarily effective, the prevalence of the Northern Coalition on the ground during the war brought the unintended byproduct of lending further power to these armed groups at the expense
of Kabul in the long run, which also balked at the later attempts for
state centralization (Weinbaum 2006: 139; Maley 2006: 39; Lister
and Wilder 2007: 244-245).
63
Kurtoglu Eskisar
As a result, a significant post-war outcome has been observed: incorporated factions have had a tendancy to carve off their own respectives niches at the expense of the center. The case of Abdul Rashid Dostum constitues a good example here. As the former leader
of the Uzbek fighters during the Soviet invasion of Afghanistan and
a part of the Northern Alliance that fought against the Taliban later,
Dostum is known to have de facto control over several provinces in
north Afghanistan (Johnson and Jolyon 2008: 8-9; Lister and Wilder 2007: 245). Despite his prominent place in Afghan politics and
proximity to the center, however, Dostum has also been accused of
getting involved in criminal acts, numerous human rights violations
and generally acting outside the existing legal framework on numerous occasions (ibid.).
The former Helmond Governor, Mohammad Gulab Mangal, constitutes another example. Similar to Dostum, Mangal played a crucial role in enabling the success of NATO in ousting Taliban and
reconstituting peace in Helmand during the early 2000s. Due to his
military successes on the field and his general ability to maintain
peace in his province, Helmand was able to remain its governor
from 2004 to 2012. During that period, he also kept close ties with
foreign donors, particularly with the British, who had sent troops to
his province to help maintain order and security there after 2001.
Notwithstanding his close Western relations which enabled him to
maintain his position for years, Mangal remained a controversial figure for some Afghans, who blamed him for diverting public funds
for his benefit and his generally failing to provide regional security
(Peter 2012; Ghanizada 2012).
64
Foreign Aid and Corruption
In retrospect, the resistance of the Northern Alliance and its supporters to become subservient to the newly reestablished central state
authority is an ironic outcome for the international community. Due
to the long history of conlicts that tore the country apart for years,
the donors that were directly involved in the statebuilding project
since 2001 considered separatism of any sort as the greatest threat
to the immediate existence of Afghanistan (Starr 2006: 111). While
international concerns helped to observe ethnic balances in the new
Afghan government and overall contributed to keeping a delicate
peace, it may have also also prevented national unification in the
long term (Jalali 2007: 30).
After winning the war, the Alliance and their supporters did not
want to share their newly gained power with groups left outside
their circle (ibid.: 29). Following their move to the capital, the Alliance therefore immediately took over the most coveted posts in
the government, in addition to controlling the national intelligence
services (Starr 2006: 111). The eagerness of the Northern Alliance
and its supporters to occupy the key spots in administration have
had both political and economic dimensions on a national scale, since all groups seeking positions in the government do not only covet
political benefits but also a portion of the foreign aid originally earmarked for development (Weinbaum 2006: 132). In a country where unemployment is the norm, the newly established government
backed by the international donors has played the pivotal role of
acting as the primary job and resources provider. Therefore, in such
an environment being an insider has meant a lot in both political and
economic sense for all Afghans.
65
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Aside from keeping ethnic tensions balanced and ensuring equitable representation for all groups in the country, international donors
have had two other main concerns: the establishment of a sovereign
state with intact borders (Starr 2006: 107). Both concerns stem from
harsh reality; for many years now the porous borders of Afghanistan have enabled the low of illegal traffic for terrorists, narcotics,
or arms and made the country a safe haven for all kinds of illicit
activities. Notwithstanding the series of measures undertaken by the
international community after the war, border control has remained
a serious problem for both security and corruption reasons (SIGAR
2014). Meanwhile the economic and political costs of the lack of
border controls remain high: experts guess that the exorbitant amounts of bribery at the customs cost the Afghan government around
$500 million dollars each year. Since customs revenue constitues
around a quarter of the Afghani state income, it represents a substantial loss for a state that is trying to rebuild itself on foreign assistance (Walsh 2014).
While not denying the importance of these issues for donors, the
most pressing issue for Afghans was the legitimacy of the new state,
which would also determine peoples’ overall willingness to obey
its rules and regulations (Starr 2006: 109-110). It mattered that the
new government had to convince all conlicting groups and factions
in the country that they would be represented in an equitable manner. However, the international community in Bonn mostly neglected these sensitivities, and implicitly accepted the existing status
quo—i.e., the domination of the Northern Alliance over the new
government (ibid.:112). This decision on the part of the international donors turned out to have significant future implications on
statebuilding process and corruption (ibid.: 110).
66
Foreign Aid and Corruption
In the meantime, a growing amount of data have become available
in recent years to assess the legitimacy of the post war Afghan states. Some of this collected data rests on the idea that people with
a high level of confidence in public institutions are more likely to
believe that their country is progressing as desired (Asia Foundation
2013: 21; Weinbaum 2006: 126). These findings, among other points, also seem to support the earlier concerns of the Afghan people.
The available data from 2013, for instance, suggest that over 50% of
the Afghan respondents (57% to be exact) believe that their country
is “moving in the right direction.” (Asia Foundation 2013: 16) While this response is encouraging for statebuilding purposes, it also
suggests that more efforts are required to achieve long-term results.
4.4 Corruption in Afghanistan since 2001
Despite years of foreign aid and state rebuilding efforts monitored
by the international community, the persistence of corruption in
Afghanistan has attracted increasing attention in recent years. The
Afghan case is interesting and important; Afghanistan is not only
among those countries where corruption is widespread but also
has assumed a systemic character. In fact, a remarkable aspect of
corruption in Afghanistan is not only its ubiquity but also its persistence. Despite the anticorruption measures of statebuilding aid
and good governance assistance from international organizations
and donors since 2001, corruption levels have hardly changed. In
fact, as the post-2001 CPI scores of the country given in Appendix
F in this book shows, Afghanistan remains among the most corrupt
countries in the world. As a report by USAID (2009: 4) has pointed
out, “corruption has become pervasive, entrenched, systemic and by
all accounts now unprecedented in scale and reach” in the country.
67
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Meanwhile, the sheer financial cost of corruption is staggering. It
is speculated that roughly US$103 billion in aid has been lost to
corrupt practices in Afghanistan since in 2001 (Swarts 2014). The
recent collapse of the biggest private bank in Afghanistan due to
corruption is another good example of its financial effects on that
country. The fact that over 90% of its disappearing funds (some
$395) were siphoned off by just 19 individuals adds a grim tone to
the already bleak picture (ibid.).
4.5 Public perceptions of corruption
In tandem with the recent surveys that track the perceived levels of
corruption in the country, more and more Afghans seem to conclude
the inevitability of corruption in nearly all aspects of their lives. The
UN surveys undertaken in 2009 and 2012 further support this possibility by relecting a sharp increase concerning the acceptance of
corruption among Afghan respondents in recent years. The UNODC
(2012: 27) report on the subject informs the following:
“a large share of civil servants across all sectors (between 38
and 69 per cent) consider some forms of administrative bribery ... acceptable. At the same time, an even higher percentage
of civil servants (between 53 and 75 per cent) consider nepotism or patronage in recruitment ... acceptable.”
Recent surveys conducted in Afghanistan also point out a significant rise in the number of respondents who consider the corruption
levels in the country (from 14% to 23% in one year) (Asia Foundation
2013: 21). As these numbers suggest, corruption has remained a
leading cause of concern for Afghan people after security problems.
However, while recent surveys reveal that a steadily increasing part
68
Foreign Aid and Corruption
of the population is willing to get involved in corrupt activities, such
as bribing an official, there is no clear indication that people consider such interactions as normal or desirable (Chayes 2014).
The figures in Table 1 can help to understand the stance of the Afghan people toward corruption better. According to a recent survey,
24% of the Afghan people feel insecure about the progress of their
country, followed by 23% of people, who are dismayed about the
prevalence of corruption (Asia Foundation 2013: 19). The same
survey has similarly revealed that following 30% of Afghan respondents who regard insecurity as the most serious problem, 26%
regard corruption as the second most serious problem (ibid.: 22).
Table 1: “In your view, what is the biggest problem facing Afghanistan as a whole?”32
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
%
Insecurity
27
46
36
36
37
38
28
30
Unemployment
32
27
31
35
28
23
27
25
Corruption
19
16
14
17
27
21
25
26
Poor Economy
24
19
17
20
11
10
11
10
Education
10
11
9
11
11
10
10
9
Poverty
13
5
8
11
10
12
9
9
Suicide attacks
-
-
-
4
5
4
5
9
Presence of
Taliban
6
13
13
8
8
4
8
7
32 The table and all its contents are taken from the survey of Asia Foundation
(2013: 23) survey on Afghanistan.
69
Kurtoglu Eskisar
As Table 1 suggests, while corruption ranked as the fourth most
important problem for Afghani respondents in 2006, it became their second biggest concern by 2013. While it is possible to explain
the Afghan people’s general dissatisfaction with the high levels of
corruption with the increased awareness of corruption in public due
to rising expectations, it may also be a result of the insufficiency or
failure of hitherto undertaken policies to deal with the phenomenon.
However, the fact that Afghanistan is the lowest ranking country in
corruption perception index in recent years coupled with the numerous anecdotes given below seriously weakens the probability of
this explanation.
4.6 Assessing the impact of foreign aid in Afghanistan
Many scholars and country experts agree that foreign aid remains
critical to the reconstruction of Afghanistan and eradicating corruption (Weinbaum 2006: 127). They also concur that the international
involvement in Afghanistan has brought lasting effects on the nature
of aid and corruption there in general. Yet, the net effects of the USled international presence in Afghanistan and the ensuing foreign
aid remain debated. On the one hand are the cautious optimists, who
argue that not all is doom and gloom after the invasion: “by mid2005, Afghanistan had a relatively liberal constitution, a president
chosen in a credible national election, and plans for a popularly chosen parliament later in the year.” (Weinbaum 2006: 125) This approach further argues that, notwithstanding many shortcomings, the
international community has left a “light footprint” on the overall
state reconstruction efforts in that country. Some Afghans also seem
to share this view and, as Table 1 in this chapter relects, display
70
Foreign Aid and Corruption
a cautious optimism that their country is being led in the correct
direction.
On the other hand, however, are the pessimists, who portray the past
decade as one of missed opportunities and worsening conditions—
particularly concerning corruption—in Afghanistan. Donor efforts
have been increasingly associated with the persistence of rampant
corruption in Afghanistan (SIGAR 2014: 4). Critiques of foreign
aid point out that the international efforts since 2001 have not fared
much better than their predecessors. They assert that the current
Afghan state is no closer to supporting itself and enforcing its rules
and institutions over its people than earlier decades. Due to the various problems and mistakes in these efforts, some observers further
claim that a valuable window of opportunity to unite Afghanistan
is missed:
“$4.5 billion raised by international sources for the irst three
years of the Karzai government has vanished without making
a cent’s worth of change to the lives of ordinary people ... The
opportunity to unite the country and form an integrated government after two and a half decades of war has been missed.”
(Misdaq 2006: 269)
The critiques also underline the irony that the international reform
efforts by organizations like the UN lack universal support from
the new regime (Dorronsoro 2005: 313). As a result of the general
misuse, incompetency, and lack of plan to spend the donor aid, it is
therefore no coincidence that currently “Afghanistan has schools
built so badly they are in danger of collapsing, clinics with no doctors or medical supplies, police and army barracks that are not fit
71
Kurtoglu Eskisar
to use, and roads that are disintegrating for lack of maintenance.”
(SIGAR 2014: 6).
4.7 Anticorruption efforts of Afghan government: the good the
bad and the ugly
Partially in an attempt to appease the donors and to supplement their
efforts, the Afghan government has also taken some steps to fight
corruption in Afghanistan in recent years. As a result, guided by
the international community, there has been some reasonable progress to build the necessary legal framework to curb corruption, to
reinforce any existing administrative institutions that would monitor any misdeeds, and to make much needed appointments to ill
the vacant staff in the judiciary. During these efforts, top ranking
Afghani officials like the former President Hamid Karzai have also
repeatedly underlined corruption as a major problem for the state and society and vowed to fight it (Mohseni 2012: 151-152). In
July 2012, Karzai officially announced a 23-page list of new rules
and regulations dedicated to attacking corruption related issues and
urged the judiciary to take the necessary steps to increase its efficiency in ongoing corruption related cases (Taylor and Harooni
2012). Later, he also removed several governors as a part of the
anticorruption efforts, including some of them who had close links
with donors (Peter 2012). His successor, President Ashraf Ghani
introduced additional anticorruption decrees targeting the judiciary
(Stancati and Totakhil 2014).
As data in Appendix E suggest, these efforts have not been all in
vain, as the state has made signiicant progress in increasing the
transparency of its budget and expenditures. Although the beginning score of Afghanistan in 2008 was a mere 8, in 2012 the coun72
Foreign Aid and Corruption
try received 59 (out of 100), compared to Bosnia, which received
50 and Iraq, which trailed far behind at 4. However, the Afghan
government’s fight against corruption has also remained cautious
in outlook and did not bring any radical changes (Weinbaum 2006:
133-134). Instead, more often than not, the government has sought
to co-opt or at least not alienate the circles involved in corrupt activities to prevent them from attacking the new state and dismantle its
modest gains. As a result, even in the absence of illicit trading activities, eschewing any formal monitoring, lexible funding available
to the minister of finance and the president has further provided
ample grounds for corruption in Afghanistan. Corruption, fostered
through the unholy alliance of politicians and criminals has become
a difficult trap to break up. Country experts point out that “a picture
emerges of such rampant bribery and extortion that corruption can
no longer be described as a cancer on the system: It is the system...
And it is deeply enmeshed with Afghan politics.” (Walsh 2014)
4.8 Corruption and criminal networks
One of the reasons behind the reticence of the Afghan government
to tackle corruption in earnest is its links with crime. The easy accessibility of aid funds to criminal gangs has rendered corruption
not only a political or an economic problem but also one of security (Carnahan et al 2014: 123). The involvement of many rich or
leading Afghanis in the highly lucrative yet illegal narcotics trade
also significantly complicates the issue and decreases the chances
of making meaningful progress in the fight against corruption (Morgan 2007: 148; Carnahan et al 2004: 123). The stakes for anyone to
fight against the low remain high: Afghanistan is reported as the
biggest (90%) producer of heroin in the world, which is estimated
73
Kurtoglu Eskisar
to generate as much as $2.8 billion annually (Mohseni 2012: 142).
As Maley (2006: 63) has put it, “some groups may have enough resources at their disposal to corrupt the embryonic policing and other
bureaucratic structures of an infant state.”
4.9 Corruption and justice
For international donors, corruption in some parts of the Afghan administrative structure constitutes a far greater and immediate threat
than others, such as the judiciary. Not so long ago, an international
organization monitoring Afghanistan has observed that the “justice
system is in a catastrophic state of disrepair.” (International Crisis
Group 2010: i) Aside from a general lack of functional institutions
that are crucial to state building and empowerment, distrust in the
existing legal framework and judiciary is widely assumed to stoke
corrupt behavior throughout the country. Most Afghans have expressed that they would prefer seeking justice in informal courts and
gatherings led by community leaders than relying on the existing
legal institutions (USAID 2009: 7). The increasing lack of faith of
Afghans in justice, which is more and more becoming regarded as
“a market commodity to be bought and sold” is worrisome (ibid.:
8). The inefficiency and corruption of the Afghan judiciary is also
frequently underlined by various country experts and high ranking
officials of international anticorruption agencies (Taylor and Harooni
2012; Latifi 2012). Meanwhile, the ubiquity of corruption among
the judiciary has led the locals to increasingly find ad hoc solutions
to their problems, including solving their conlicts within their respective community using local customs and sharia (Saltmarshe and
Medhi 2011: 2). However, in the absence of serious attempts to rebuild the national judicial system, there is no reason to assume that
74
Foreign Aid and Corruption
such practical measures can be maintained in the long term (ibid.:6).
Aside from its immediate systemic effects, observers also note that
high levels of corruption in the judiciary can seriously affect state legitimacy and security in the long run (Saltmarshe and Medhi
2011; Sarwary 2012; International Crisis Group 2010: 1). As the
following comments of an Afghan man relect, being fed up with the
shortcomings and failures of the existing system risks driving more
people into supporting the Taliban or other extremist groups at the
expense of the newly reestablished order:
“The Taliban courts were swift and strict ... A thief would
be given the death sentence after a short trial. But under Mr.
Karzai’s rule, it will take a century to prove a thief guilty and even then there is no guarantee that he will be punished.”
(quoted in Sarwary 2012)
A major problem with the donor efforts in Afghanistan arises from
the fact that they often do not match with the existing reality. Consequentially their offered solutions are not what Afghan people truly
need (International Crisis Group 2010: 10). Many donor attempts
have failed by their inability to pick up suitable international experts
who know the country well and are able to help the Afghan officials
in the real sense. The international attempts to reorganize and reconstruct the Afghan justice system in recent years remains a good
case in point. The international teams of experts who were selected
by donors to provide help and counsel the local people indeed fulfilled the criteria required by the donors for their particular subfield.
However, a country report also informs that some of these assigned foreign experts in the justice sector had no previous knowledge
of Afghan politics or its justice system, and others were not even
75
Kurtoglu Eskisar
directly related to the legal field itself (International Crisis Group
2010: 10). As a result, the overall assistance of these experts to the
local community of judicial personnel who really needed it turned
out to be minimal at best (ibid.; Latifi 2012).
4.10 The unexpected effects of foreign aid: some examples
Notwithstanding the already well demonstrated political and administrative shortcomings of the Afghan government since 2001,
it would be misleading to blame it for all of the failures that have
lead to the current state of affairs in that country, including corruption. Insufficient donor funding and ill-suited foreign assistance
also seem to have played a key role behind this disappointing outcome. Due to the above mentioned problems in the judicial sector,
for instance, the EU, which remains one of the biggest donors for
Afghanistan, has halted its financial aid. These funds, originally earmarked to undertake the desparately needed reforms to the Afghan
judiciary and its institutional infrastracture, were forfeited due to
insufficient progress in anticorruption efforts (Latifi 2012). The international aid for the reconstruction of the Afghan judicial system
has been often termed as “miserly,” and its initial targets far from
grasping the reality (International Crisis Group 2010: 1-2). Furthermore, while seeking to reconstruct the Afghan judicial structure,
the donors more often than not have sought for their establishment,
ignoring the Afghan views and input to follow their own preconceived notions of universal, standard or good rules. Perhaps the most
worrying aspect of corruption in Afghanistan is its general image as
being abetted or simply ignored by the Afghan society.
As earlier mentioned, international donors involved with the country are often oblivious to the opinions of the locals and retain their
76
Foreign Aid and Corruption
support for the local administrations despite their blatantly criminal
practices solely for the reason that they support the donors (Johnson
and Jolyon 2008: 10). Numerous times, the attempts by the Afghan
government to remove certain governors due to their controversial
reception by the locals in the past were vetoed by the key international donors like the U.K on the grounds of compatibility (Peter
2012). Yet recreating order and institutions in Afghanistan under foreign tutelage has also led to the unexpected outcome of disturbing
the local socio-political balances. Many Afghanis seem to remain
frustrated by their own elite who, despite all the havoc they created
during the civil war, have been able to maintain and even expand
their political and economic capabilities, mostly thanks to their ties
with the international community (Johnson and Jolyon 2008: 8; Peter 2012).
A closer look at the low of foreign aid and its results in Afghanistan
seems to confirm the following observation pointed out by Maley
(2006: 98) earlier: “The political reality ... was and is that donor
priorities and the Afghan government’s priorities do not necessarily
coincide.” Yet the Afghan government, mostly developed according
to donor assesed needs and monitored or directly controlled by donor sent or administered technical experts, “progressively lost control of its development programme.” (Dorronsoro 2005: 64) Giving
what they think or imagined that the country needed, international
donors thus failed for years to predict or delect the crises, such as
in agriculture that later occurred (ibid.).
Another problem concerning the statebuilding attempts in Afghanistan concerns the inconsistent or contradicting decisions of the
international community on different fields. (Weinbaum 2006: 131).
77
Kurtoglu Eskisar
International donors have often failed to coordinate their efforts,
which further limited the impact of their aid in the first place (Johnson and Jolyon 2008: 194). Ironically, instead of aiding and quickening the pace of state building and fighting corruption, certain
steps taken by the international community may have inadvertently
encouraged corrupt practices in Afghanistan. Approached from this
perspective, the following example is noteworthy:
“In the run-up to the Emergency Loya Jirga, the UN gave out
hundreds of expensive satellite phones. No one ever asked for
them back. In Kabul, ISAF has a contract for ten tankers of
fuel a day from, as it happens, a very close associate of a very
important minister. Often it takes only three tankers to reill
their tanks, the other seven get sold on the city streets. Stories
like this abound, the message is, it does not matter, money is
there to be wasted, accountability is just a word.” (ibid. 45)
Yet another controversial outcome of the international efforts for
statebuilding and fighting corruption is observable in its effects on
the current Afghan police force. Although corruption among the
police officers well predates the international intervention, it is disturbing for the locals to see that they “now wear uniforms, bear weapons and drive vehicles paid for by external assistance.” (ibid. 9)
Ironically, since the police officers have become annoyingly aggressive in their pursuit of bribery and other corrupt behavior, Afghans
mostly bypass them during times of need. Furthermore, this condition risks becoming a serious security problem in the forthcoming
years, as Afghan officials admit that it is common among policemen
and other security personnel to “sell their bullets and weapons in the
market to the highest bidder and that sometimes includes Taliban or
other insurgent groups.” (Sarwary 2012)
The cookie cutter approach of donors to statebuilding, economic
78
Foreign Aid and Corruption
development and corruption has worked at cross-purposes in Afghanistan, and sometimes even generated paradoxical outcomes, as
summarized below:
“Development in Afghanistan has for a large part been based
on the assumption that introducing a public administration and
democratic elections based on Western models would allow
Afghanistan to move forward as an autonomous and sovereign
state able to effectively manage its own affairs. This is not
what has happened. Insecurity has increased, as has corruption. The democratic process has been subject to massive vote
rigging, and abuses of power are widespread.” (Saltmarshe
and Medhi 2011: 9)
Consider the international zest to balance any tendency for accumulation of centralized power by empowering the periphery through
the support of local governance. These programs funded by donors
aim to encourage local communities to increase their political participation (Johnson and Jolyon 2008: 207). Foreign observers generally concur that developing local governance can significantly aid
the statebuilding efforts in the country and help to decrease corruption (Saltmarshe and Medhi 2011: 6). The following comments of
US General Allen further underline the idea that the impact of such
efforts can have a positive effect on both statebuilding and lowering
corruption levels in Afghanistan:
“[W]hat I observed when I was there ... was the importance
of district level and sometimes -- and village level leadership ... [W]hat we’re looking at for success is a model that
includes a strong government in Kabul where corruption is
brought down over time and it has resources that are able to
provide not just for its own protection, but provide in part an
79
Kurtoglu Eskisar
avenue of resources ... back down to the local levels, and at the
same time continue to build that from ... the grass roots, if you
will, at the village and district level, build strong governance.”
(Allen 2014: 27)
In the absence of international funding and resources available to
the center, however, such measures run the risk of worsening the
already high levels of corruption (Johnson and Jolyon 2008: 208).
Due to the lack of a functioning and legitimate national judicial
system, the current foreign efforts to strengthen the local councils
in an attempt to tie them to Kabul can also lead to the reinforcement
of informal institutions at the expense of formal ones and ultimately
play into the hands of Taliban (Ahmed 2015).
4.11 The input of Afghans really matters
As explained in the previous section, notwithstanding the impending threat, the current attitude on foreign aid to Afghanistan is not
much concerned about the Afghan peoples’ input in setting the goals
and strategies to achieve them. In fact, some observers have argued
that while the international community acting as a watchdog limits
the Afghani government’s overall capabilities, the foreign advisors
can ensure the optimal use of foreign aid (Morgan 2007: 148-149;
SIGAR 2014: 4). Many observers also argue that external monitoring and intervention is crucial to undertaking the intended reforms
required for statebuilding, combating corruption, and achieving the
results expected by the international community (Latifi 2012).
Notwithstanding the efforts to increase political participation among
local governance mentioned earlier, the international community has
consistently either limited or entirely overlooked Afghan views or
80
Foreign Aid and Corruption
preferences on numerous statebuilding measures based on good governance principles, including the privatization of public services,
such as healthcare. For instance, the post-2001 privatization scheme (e.g. health sector) in Afghanistan disregarded existing services,
dismantled them with possible adverse effects on people already
working in the sector, and generated the inclination to get involved
in corruption. More importantly, experts claim that the new health
system is unsustainable in the long run and can further weaken the
already emaciated state functions, thus ultimately detracting from
the legitimacy of the new state (Johnson and Jolyon 2008: 205-206).
However, it is far from clear that the Afghan people concur with this
approach. The following words of a member of the Afghan cabinet
are rather meaningful: “they say we can have whatever we want –as
long as it is what they’re offering.” (cited in Johnson and Jolyon
2008: 15) Moreover, the opinions of Afghans matter, as they are
crucial to creating social cohesion, promoting institutionalization,
and thus dealing with the leading causes of corruption in the long
run. Failure to do so certainly risks losing all gains that were aimed
through international aid, and more. Country specialists warn that,
if not dealt with, local frustration can lead to explosive, violent behavior in the long run (ibid. 2; Allen 2014: 13).
Reminiscent of earlier decades, a point that contemporary donors
seem to miss is that politics in Afghanistan is mostly “a ‘recurrent
process of fission and fusion’, where the integrating tendency of the
state is opposed to the centrifugal force of the tribes.” (Dorronsoro
2005: 7) Therefore, ignoring the impact of foreign aid on ethnic or
inter-group balances by donors is not only likely to render any efforts as useless or ineffective, but also unlikely to promote any long
81
Kurtoglu Eskisar
lasting peace in Afghanistan (Esman 2004: 160).
4.12 Conclusion: Afghanistan—a net gain or a net loss for donors?
As this chapter sought to underline, Afghanistan has had a long
history of receiving foreign aid. Despite the steady low of foreign funds to the country for many years, their total amount remains
far less than other postconlict countries, which also received aid
during the same time period (Weinbaum 2006: 131; Maley 2006:
137; Johnson and Jolyon 2008: 210-211). Furthermore, much of the
available foreign aid remains channeled to meeting humanitarian
needs instead of being invested in long term projects (Maley 2006:
98). Ad hoc or short term solutions, however, are likely to increase
the already elevated level of corruption in Afghanistan.
To make things worse, throughout the country, including its capital,
the lack of security remains a major problem. This problem leaves
donors seriously concerned and has a negative effect on the foreign
aid low. Yet leaving Afghanistan to its own devices may no longer work, either; along with fast declining levels of international
financial aid, country experts argue that the premature withdrawal
of international security forces can threaten the future of the Afghan statebuilding efforts and the hitherto taken measures to combat corruption (Saltmarshe and Medhi 2011: 9). Paradoxically, it
may also aggravate the very thing that the international donors are
desparately trying to eradicate in the first place. The persistence of
corruption in Afghanistan, even after the steady international efforts
that began in 2001, seems to be associated with the local belief that
it would be only transitory: The prevailing instinct for many Afghans, therefore, is to grab as much as possible while the foreign cash
continues to low in and foreign troops help maintain the security
82
Foreign Aid and Corruption
(Walsh 2014; Sarwary 2012).
While discussing the role of foreign aid in the reconstruction of Afghanistan and fighting corruption, some observers have pointed out
the moral obligations of the international community. According to
this view, after invading Afghanistan, the international community
holds a responsibility for its people, and it is obliged to help it get
back on its feet (Johnson and Jolyon 2008: 13). While this argument
is valuable and requires contemplation, it is nonetheless unlikely
to find a unified response from the donors. In the meantime, it is
reasonable to assume that the international donors are more likely
to fail than succeed in accomplishing both goals with their current
methods in Afghanistan in the foreseeable future.
83
Kurtoglu Eskisar
84
Foreign Aid and Corruption
CHAPTER 5
BOSNIA-HERZEGOVINA
“Europe, you owe us, do you remember 1992-1995?”
(Written on a protester’s sign during 2014 protests, cited in
Arsenijevic 2014)
“You have been stealing from us for 20 years”
(Written on a protester’s sign during 2014 protests, cited in
Giovanni 2014)
“My theory is that outsiders, the international community, cannot
impose a new positive system ... [But] [w]ithout them the changes
would not have happened. By ourselves we could have changed
some things, but there would have been other things that dragged us
back—people, traditions.”
(Nada Majinovic, Lawyer in Brčko district, cited in Pond 2006: 148)
5.1 Bosnia: a model for successful international aid?
Although the world is no stranger to statebuilding efforts in the postCold War era, few such endeavors are as impressive as those made
for Bosnia in its post-Dayton phase, for they have sought to achieve
several goals at once. The political institutions and economic frame-
85
Kurtoglu Eskisar
work outlined by the Dayton agreement that ended the Bosnian war
in 1995 not only promised peace but also aimed to bring together
a severely divided society through democratization and introduce
full scale economic reforms needed for a liberal market economy
(Donais 2005: 1). Another remarkable aspect of the Bosnian state building experience was the intense level of international donor
involvement. While foreign involvement in conlict resolution and
peace negotiations is hardly uncommon, as Chandler (2000: 43) has
emphasized,
“[t]he peace agreement signed at Dayton was unlike any other
peace treaty of modern times, not merely because it was imposed by powers external to the conlict, but because of the
far-reaching powers given to the international community
which extended well beyond military matters to cover the
most basic aspects of government and state.”
On a more general level, Chandler (2000: 34-36) has further commented that the signature of Dayton Treaty was a step that directly
challenged the hitherto internationally prevalent understanding of
sovereignity on the state level. The underlying reasons for foreign
involvement have similarly been debated, with some scholars interpreting the international efforts for democratization in that country after Dayton “as an early node in the professionalization and
standardization of democratic techne and democratic knowledge
as tools of foreign policy aims—that is, the liberal and neoliberal
transformation of regimes in the name of peace and security.” (Coles 2007: 237)
In addition to the leading factors that initiated international aid to
Bosnia and its significance, its long term effects on that country also
86
Foreign Aid and Corruption
remains debated. On the one hand is the argument that foreign aid
has been pivotal for all major achievements that have taken place in
post-Dayton phase. The idea is that without constant external monitoring provided by donors, Bosnians themselves could not have
achieved anything significant (Pond 2006: 142). According to this
viewpoint, the international donors originally aimed to transform
Bosnia into a model democracy with a well-functioning market that
is fully ready to become a member of the European Union (Dobbins
et al. 2003: 92).
The line of argument that emphasizes the role of foreign aid to explain the positive developments in Bosnia is not without its merits.
In retrospect, the resulting impact of international community on
achieving long-term peace and overall stability in Bosnia has been
considerable. Despite its highly bureaucratic and complex administrative structure, the country has managed to survive since the end
of the war. Moreover, once established, the sovereign status of Bosnia has remained intact, and with constant international assistance,
the new state has had a number of successes, including the following achievements:
“single license plates ... a single currency and passport system; a single customs system, with Bosniak, Serb, and Croat
oficials assigned to border crossings irrespective of the majority ethnicity of the neighboring district; a single army command; a single criminal intelligence agency ... and the return
of more than a million refugees. Moreover, in the RS they
have effected a managed transition from the de facto rule of a
still-triumphant Radovan Karadzic in 1996 to his ouster; and
in 2004, the irst public apology by the RS government for the
87
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Srebrenica massacre, and its delivery to prosecutors in 2005
of a list of 17,000 Serb perpetrators and abettors.” (Pond 2006:
141).
Some of the political and administrative reforms introduced by the
international community are also regarded as net gains for the new
state. According to Dominik Zaum (2007), the annulment of payment offices, which were remnants of the previous Yugoslav state is
a good case in point. Zaum (2007: 103-106) argues that while their
removal reduced direct state involvement over the economy, the
new administrative measures did not remove its control altogether
either, and offered some legitimacy to the new state in other aspects,
including tax collection. Begić (2014: 37) similarly points out that
the active involvement of the OHR has “enabled the functioning of
legal state.”
The overall positive depiction of the international community’s capabilities and functions over the Bosnian state since its inception
also requires counting in their favor. In other war settings like Afghanistan or Iraq, direct foreign involvement in statebuilding has
often drawn serious criticism from both national and international
actors alike. Unlike its counterparts, however, foreign aid to Bosnia
has generally been viewed under a more positive light by both Bosnians and the international community alike (McMahon and Western 2009).
On the other hand, notwithstanding these intense and generally
positively regarded donor efforts, many scholars argue that the
foreign-led statebuilding efforts since Dayton Agreement have brought mixed results at best. As a scholar has bluntly put it, “[t]hirteen
years after the Dayton Peace Agreement, and with a tremendous
88
Foreign Aid and Corruption
international engagement of aid, post-conlict reconstruction, statebuilding and support to civil society, there are still few signs of
reconciliation, multi-ethnic integration and democratisation.” (Sörensen 2010: 92) Other critiques similarly describe the failure of
international efforts to rebuild the country following the end of the
war as follows:
“Bosnia was once the poster child for international reconstruction efforts. It was routinely touted by U.S. and European
leaders as proof that under the right conditions the international community could successfully rebuild conlict-ridden
countries ... In the past three years, ethnic nationalist rhetoric
from leaders of the country’s three constituent ethnic groups
-- Muslims, Croats, and Serbs -- has intensiied, bringing reform to a standstill. The economy has stalled, unemployment
is over 27 percent, about 25 percent of the population lives in
poverty, and Bosnia remains near the bottom of World Bank
rankings for business development.” (McMahon and Western
2009)33
What is worse, despite the anticorruption campaigns funded and
supported by international donors for years, Bosnia has sported
surprisingly high levels of corruption, which has proven itself quite resilient to all efforts to eradicate it. Some observers estimate
that during mid to late 1990s alone, approximately 20 percent of
international aid money to the country—roughly over $1 billion in
worth—evaporated (McMahon and Western 2009). The overall levels of corruption in the country has not changed much in recent
years, either: According to CPI results, Bosnia ranked at 72 (out of
33 For a similar view, see also Judah (2014).
89
Kurtoglu Eskisar
175 countries) in 2013.34 While discussing the level of corruption in
Bosnia, Ateljevic and Budak (2010:386) have remarked that:
“[c]orruption is embedded into the entire fabric of the country’s socio-economic and political environment through theft
of public funds including the misuse of international donations, buying of state positions and court decisions, bribery,
payment of favours in customs, telecommunications, building
licenses and medical services and education.”
The public dissatisfaction with corruption finally reached a cataclysmic end in 2014, when a series of violent protests attended by thousands of Bosnians shook the country.35 Interestingly, this so-called
“citizen tsunami” caught most international observers and donors
by surprise, who had always feared the return of inter-ethnic hostilities instead (Giovanni 2014). Yet, during the protests, rather than
inter-ethnic woes, corrupt politicians and skewed income distribution proved to be at the core of the public complaints. Summarized
in the following words of an observer: “’There are so many valid
reasons to protest in Bosnia ... Nontransparent and criminal privatization of state-owned companies, widespread corruption, nepotism
and general misery - to name just a few.’” (ibid.)
Some observers explain these unexpected turn of events and the less
than ideal results concerning statebuilding efforts in Bosnia with
the overly self-interested approach of the international actors. While
34 The country ranked the same in 174 countries in the previous year (72/174 in
2012). For corruption scores of Bosnia as reported by CPI between 1995 and 2013,
see Appendix E in this book.
35 Although corruption is regarded as a universal problem for Bosnia, the RS
regions interestingly did not participate in the chain of protests that took place in
the rest of the country.
90
Foreign Aid and Corruption
discussing the anticorruption protests in 2014, Kurtović (2014:
101), for instance, has bitterly noted that the comments of international spectators
“reminded citizens of Bosnia and Herzegovina of something
they had learned long ago: that the International Community
is a self-serving, self-interested and alienated center of power
that never has been working in support of citizens’ own interests. The truth is, the ‘democratic transition’ which the International Community promoted was always supposed to be
limited, and done according to the terms of its own design.”
Regardless of the factors that motivated the international community to aid Bosnia in the irst place, foreign-led state building
strategies and related aid programs may have played a signiicant
role in both prolonging the state building efforts and persistence of
high levels of corruption in postwar Bosnia. As this chapter aims to
discuss, the Bosnian state built on democratic and neoliberal economic principles as envisioned by international donors after Dayton
Agreement originally targeted to overcome the societal fragmentation along ethnic lines, while promoting rapid accumulation of
economic wealth for the whole society. A wide array of measures,
ranging from ensuring equal ethnic representation at all administrative levels to the privatization of state enterprises were regarded as
the required handmaidens to achieve this outcome. Instead, various
congenital shortcomings associated with the post Dayton administrative and economic structure seems to have created a vicious
circle that has primarily beneited those actors who are involved in
the corruption networks. The rest of the chapter outlines some of the
reasons behind this unexpected outcome.
91
Kurtoglu Eskisar
5.2 Corruption in Bosnia: is culture to blame?
Before discussing the role of international aid on the Bosnian state
building and anticorruption efforts, the impact of culture as another
possible independent variable requires brief mention. Culture is
often counted as the chief factor behind the prevalence of corruption
in places like Bosnia and Herzegovina (Divjak and Pugh 2008: 373;
Pržulj and Kostadinović 2014: 474). International anticorruption
efforts, including foreign aid low to Bosnia in particular has routinely treated the subject as a primordial phenomenon with cultural
underpinnings that is solely intrinsic to the region, and is ‘curable’
by Western or foreign induced recipes (Kurtović 2014: 99).
While this assumption seems simple and compelling, it is not necessarily proven. On the one hand, a survey in that country by the
World Bank has revealed that “73 percent of the general public respondents and 71 percent of public officials agree with the statement
that in BiH ‘corruption is a part of culture and mentality.’” (World
Bank 2000: 16) The fact that corruption was also widespread especially during the later years of Yugoslavia, Bosnia’s predecessor,
also supports this view. On the other hand, however, the same World
Bank (2000) survey also revealed that over 50% of the respondents
would report any exposure to corruption to the authorities (ibid.).
Furthermore, the majority of respondents in the public service stated that if implemented, they would support anticorruption reforms
and that they would favor a system based on meritocracy (ibid.: 17).
It is therefore reasonable to assume that, instead of an ingrained and
permanent cultural trait, Bosnians regard corruption as a dynamic
phenomenon that is responsive to different settings and approaches.
92
Foreign Aid and Corruption
5.3 Dayton Peace Agreement and its aftermath
In order to understand the impact of Dayton Agreement on the current state of affairs in Bosnia, it is useful to sketch some of its key
points. Dayton Agreement, which effectively ended the Bosnian
war was finalized on 21 November 1995, and was signed three weeks later.36 Led by USA, it is a complex document, which draws
on the military results of the Bosnian war, and the ethnic and communal demands that produced it in the first place. The agreement
originated from the Vance-Owen plan developed in 1993, which
divided the land into two cantons with limited autonomy, the FBiH
and RS. Dayton also further divided the FBiH into ten cantons, each
with their own administrative units (including parliaments and ministries) (Divjak and Pugh 2008: 374). After a while, Brčko region
in the north became a separate administrative district, with its own
appointed international head, police and judiciary. All of these divisions effectively have become five different interconnected levels
of administration, including “state, entity, canton, city and municipality.” (International Crisis Group 2001: 2) Other inherent administrative characteristics of the new state also include its divided
military structure (each administration is granted their own forces),
and the central government’s lack of independent income. Yet, the
Bosnian state also happens to be subject to some very strict regulations (Donais 2005: 79).
In recent years, an increasing number of critiques have pointed out
that the existing over-complex and decentralized state structure int-
36 Discussing the factors behind the demise of Yugoslavia and the subsequent outbreak of war fall outside the scope of this study. For a brief summary of the events
that led to the Bosnian war, see Paris (2004: 97-98); Pond (2006: 144-145).
93
Kurtoglu Eskisar
roduced by Dayton Agreement not only detracts from state building
and democratization efforts, but also fosters corruption in the country (De Launey 2015; Juncos 2005: 90; Stubbs 2001: 100; Donais
2005: 78; Giatzidis 2007: 335; von der Brelie 2014; Pond 2006:
158; Reuters, 10 September 2014). According to this viewpoint,
the primary—or only—goal of Dayton Agreement was to end the
war and stop the bloodshed (Pond 2006: 151). The preoccupation
of the agreement with achieving peace, however, may have affected
its long-term viability as a state and its anti-corruption policies. As
McMahon and Western (2009) have pointed out, “[a]s successful as
Dayton was at ending the violence, it also sowed the seeds of instability by creating a decentralized political system that undermined
the state’s authority.”
Lending support to this argument is the existing ratio of administrators in the country to the population, which is staggering: “Each of
the thirteen political units has between six and twelve ministries, effectively amounting to at least 181 ministers for 3.7 million people.
If this ratio were applied to Germany, that country would have 4,240
ministers.” (International Crisis Group 2001: 2) The overcomplex
administrative structure of the country has also received criticism
from the Bosnians themselves. During the widespread anticorruption protests in 2014, a student, for instance, has frustratedly pointed out that “[i]n Bosnia-Herzegovina we have 13 regional governments, more than 130 ministries and ministers, and on the top of that
we have five presidents. We have a whole bunch of leaders but they
don’t lead.” (von der Brelie 2014).
94
Foreign Aid and Corruption
5.4 Bosnian state and consociationalism
Some scholars have pointed out that the Bosnian state established by
the Dayton Agreement displays many characteristics of consociationalism, including its positive aspects and pitfalls (Paris 2004: 193;
Donais 2005: 78). Consociationalism is the term initially introduced
by the political scientist Arend Lijphart to describe a particular form
of governance in democracies with segregated groups that provide
generous amounts of autonomy and veto rights to all major identity
groups. Paris (2004: 193) explains that in ideal settings, democracies built on consociationalist principles adhere to the following rules:
1) All major identity groups that form the society are represented in
all segments of the administration (including government), 2) The
appointment of these representatives need to be relective of their
size in population, 3) Decisions that involve the whole society need
to be taken together; with input and agreement from all groups, 4)
Decisions concerning in-group matters do not require approval or
intervention by other groups. As the earlier outlined highlights suggest, Bosnian administrative structure often followed these consociationalist principles, which has ensured equitable representation
of all major ethnic groups in the country, including the guarantee to
preserve their identity in democratic setting.
At the same time, however, consociational principles can also create
deadlocks for political cooperation between groups in the long run
(Donais 2005: 78). Another unexpected outcome of the consociational administrative framework is its negative effects on the institutionalization of state functions. As Begić (2014: 39) has pointed
out, under the auspices and dictation of international actors, any
important decision making process is restricted to private dealings
95
Kurtoglu Eskisar
among the elite of the leading ethnic parties, without ever being
brought up for public inspection.
Notwithstanding democratic representation for all ethnic groups, in
Bosnia the main dilemma ultimately seems to center on the vague
Bosnian state identity itself that was prescribed by Dayton Agreement (Dobbins et al. 2003: 90; Juncos 2005: 90). This vagueness
becomes a particular cause for concern, as it is directly linked with
high levels of corruption. Simply put, the ethnic enclaves that are
originally created to ensure fair representation of all groups have
gradually become hotbeds of corrosive clientelist networks and
encouraged wasteful behavior (McMahon and Western 2009). A
prime example of this condition is observable in Republika Srpska,
where the political elite has actively resisted any efforts to build
central state power, fearing that doing the opposite would divest
them of their near-independence and privileges guaranteed by the
Dayton Agreement (Donais 2005: 80).
To summarize, then, the consociationalist tendencies of Dayton Agrement to power sharing within the Bosnian society, seem
to have promoted (ethnic) group interests over societal interests
(Hajdarpašić 2014: 105), and ultimately eliminated its chances to
become a “normal state,” where
“reciprocity and sharing of risk in which all citizens have a
responsibility for raising revenues which are then disbursed,
on the basis of need. Instead, separate ethnicized claims and
loyalties are legitimated, leading to three separate welfare regimes underpinned by a social vision which limits reciprocal obligations on the basis of ethnicized belonging.” (Stubbs
2001: 101)
96
Foreign Aid and Corruption
5.5. Bosnian administrative structure and economy
In addition to its negative impact on governance, the administrative division of Bosnia, especially in terms of municipalities, is also
criticized for lacking an economic rationale and hindering economic
development (Divjak and Pugh 2008: 374; World Bank 2009: 1).
The ineficiency of the existing Bosnian administrative network in
terms of economic performance is well described in the following
excerpt:
“Any would-be foreign investor in Sarajevo, for example,
would have to deal with ive separate levels of government
in order to obtain the requisite licences to set up a company:
state, entity, canton, city, and municipality. Even if matters
proceeded smoothly at all ive levels, the multiplication of effort would still be wasteful and require several months.” (International Crisis Group 2001: 1)
As a consequence, public spending percentage in Bosnia is estimated as over three times more than the neighboring Hungary, which
is roughly 64% (Donais 2005: 71). Furthermore, while trying to appease all ethnic groups in state representation, administrative units
often work at cross-purposes, and further sap the already feeble
economic activities in the country (Donais 2005: 67; De Launey
2015). This administrative ineficiency, among its other effects, has
also negatively affected the unemployment levels among young
Bosnians, which already ranks among the highest in the world (De
Launey 2015).
The effects of economic stagnation have been almost circular: Economic inefficiency for Bosnia has not only meant a loss in revenue
97
Kurtoglu Eskisar
for the state, but also serious political repercussions, since, combined with the consociational administrative characteristics of the
Bosnian state, it renders political cooperation very difficult –if not
downright impossible—to achieve. More often than not, Bosnian
politicians avoid collaborating with each other in this winner-takeall environment, to avoid losing their gains (Donais 2005: 67). As
a result, the newly created institutions in Bosnia are not only frail
in economic terms, but they have also been accused of contributing
to the existing high levels of political polarization. Notwithstanding
the belief that the Bosnian state would respond to the various welfare needs of the Bosnians to increase social cohesion after the war,
its inherent structural deficiencies and economic frailty have also
prevented it from fulfilling these expectations, and thus may have
weakened the overall public faith in its long-term viability (Stubbs
2001: 101).
5.6 Foreign financial aid to Bosnia: some figures
In assessing the impact of external aid on statebuilding and corruption in Bosnia, along with the internationally drawn and monitored Dayton Agreement, international financial aid also requires
relection. While signing Dayton Agreement in 1995 was a great
achievement in terms of officially ending the war, the daunting task
of building a new state and ensuring social cohesion out of the ruins
of a bloody conlict that lasted for years remained. The Bosnian war
had cost the lives of 250,000 people; about half of the new country’s
population was forced to move due to ethnic cleansing, and well
over a million people led abroad as refugees. The physical effects
of the war were equally devastating: The war had taken its toll on
the infrastructure, by either completely destroying or heavily dama-
98
Foreign Aid and Corruption
ging schools, hospitals, homes or power lines alike (Dobbins et al.
2003: 92). Eighty percent of the people had to rely on international
aid for food (ibid.: 90).
Therefore, once the hostilities formally came to an end with the
Dayton Accord, and the Bosnian state was officially established, the
foreign involvement in the economic reconstruction of the country
also quickly picked up pace. According to OECD data, which are
available in Appendix A of this book, in 1995 alone Bosnia received US$733.99 million in aid, in comparison to US$106.05 million
disbursed to Afghanistan and US$238.95 million to Iraq during the
same year. As data in that chart indicate, the ODA low to Bosnia
also remained high in the following few years, and reached a peak
in 1999, when the country received US$702.77 million, compared
with US$104.16 million delivered to Afghanistan and US$79.07
million to Iraq.
The following paragraph similarly outlines the magnitude of foreign
aid and involvement in Bosnia during the initial years following
Dayton Agreement well:
“Soon after the war’s end, the country was looded with attention and over $14 billion in international aid, making it a
laboratory for what was arguably the most extensive and innovative democratization experiment in history. By the end
of 1996, 17 different foreign governments, 18 UN agencies,
27 intergovernmental organizations, and about 200 nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) -- not to mention tens of
thousands of troops from across the globe -- were involved in
reconstruction efforts. On a per capita basis, the reconstruction of Bosnia -- with less than four million citizens -- made
99
Kurtoglu Eskisar
the post-World War II rebuilding of Germany and Japan look
modest.” (McMahon and Western 2009)
During this time period, the leadership in international efforts to
aid Bosnia also gradually shifted. The events and negotiations that
eventually culminated with the signing of Dayton were almost exclusively dominated by USA (Chandler 2000: 36). In the post Dayton period, however, the US orchestrated efforts gradually left their
place to the EU, which took the front seat as the leading foreign
donor and supporter of Bosnia’s economic and political development (Juncos 2005: 88-89; Pond 2006: 140). The joint efforts of the
EU and World Bank culminated in the Priority Reconstruction and
Recovery Program for Bosnia, which spent more than US$4 billion
in the next four years with the goal to resuscitate its economy (Pond
2006: 142; Suhrke and Buckmaster 2006: 343-344).This amount
excluded other international projects and aid that came independent
of the aforesaid program.
In tandem with the changing leadership concerning international
aid to Bosnia, its amount that is offered by the leading donors has
also gradually changed. While the Kosovo crisis during late 1990s,
combined with the US-led war against terror in Afghanistan and
Iraq reduced the amount of financial aid low to the country, the
EU-led international efforts, including financial aid, to reconstruct
the country have continued to date. In December 2014, European
Commission announced its decision to spend 166 million euros
on Bosnia to help prepare the country to become eligible for EU
membership. With this aid, the Commission has aimed “to support
democracy and governance, rule of law, competitiveness, local development, education, employment and social policies” in Bosnia
(Reuters, 16 December 2014).
100
Foreign Aid and Corruption
The overall declining levels of foreign financial aid to Bosnia, however, has nonetheless remained a persistent trait. Notwithstanding
the EU efforts, since the peak aid low in 1999, Bosnia overall has
received gradually declining levels of financial aid from international donors. The following examples can help to frame this condition
clearer: According to OECD data in Appendix A, in 2002, for instance, the country received $292.35 million in aid in comparison to
$991.73 million to Afghanistan. While the following year brought
in a slight increase to the aid low, which was $335.45 million, it
still remained significantly lower than the aid low to Afghanistan,
which reached $1227.2 million, and $2178.2 million to Iraq. Interestingly, these declining levels of financial aid to the country have
also run parallel to the increasing tendency of the international community to adopt a policy of noninterference with Bosnian affairs,
which is explained later in the chapter.
5.7 Taking the front seat: international community and the
Bosnian elite
Aside from ensuring the low of significant amounts of financial aid
already mentioned, the novelty of Dayton Agreement and its responsibilities also meant making difficult administrative and economic
decisions for international donors. More precisely, the international
donors that were directly involved with Bosnia’s reconstruction on
the economic front faced a dilemma: While the need to build state
capacity through functional institutions for the Bosnians remained
a real need, the neoliberal norms that inluenced the international
aid patterns at the time also called for lean governments, and a fast
paced privatization of state-held entities (Zaum 2007).
101
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Cognizant of the economic factors that contributed to the Bosnian war in the first place, international donors therefore primarily
targeted economic efficiency and political legitimacy in their privatization efforts by adopting a developmental model earlier tried
in other transitioning countries. With these steps, the donors expected the country to have a viable market economy within the course
of several years, in pace with the ongoing democratization efforts.
Moreover, by urging the adoption of these measures by the Bosnian
state, the donors also expected to curb, or lessen corruption (Zaum
2007: 98-100).
During the same period, in order to speed up the reforms and
prevent what was perceived as fruitless debates and contentions
within the newly formed state at any administrative level, the international community also formalized its leadership in the rebuilding process of Bosnia. In 1997, the Office of the High Representative, which represented the international actors involved
in the country gained “the power to impose legislation directly,
giving the international community both executive and legislative control over the formally independent state.” (Chandler 2000:
65) The intensity of international involvement in Bosnia is also
traceable in the formal goals of the OHR, which are stated as follows:
“The High Representative is working with the people and
institutions of Bosnia and Herzegovina and the international
community to ensure that Bosnia and Herzegovina evolves
into a peaceful and viable democracy on course for integration
in Euro-Atlantic institutions. The OHR is working towards the
point where Bosnia and Herzegovina is able to take full responsibility for its own affairs.”37
37 Ofice of the High Representative, http://www.ohr.int/ohr-info/gen-info/default.
asp?content_id=38519 (accessed on 16 February 2015).
102
Foreign Aid and Corruption
5.8 The (unexpected) consequences of external led reforms
In the short run, taking the front seat in making decisions have ensured the donors that their preferences and priorities are observed in
the reconstruction process, and gave them direct control over their
initial implementation period. As earlier predicted, direct international involvement also quickened the overall decision making process. Furthermore, throughout the earlier phases of statebuilding,
the new rules based on neoliberal principles set by the international
donors were never seriously questioned (Chandler 2000: 35).
In the long run, however, the privatization efforts in the country
have generated few tangible results; certainly far less than the original targets of international donors, and their regional effects have
remained erratic (Bayliss 2005: 45). It is possible to explain the limited effect of neoliberal economic reforms on the Bosnian economy
with at least two main factors. First, privatization has attracted little
interest from outsiders, who have remained reluctant to make investments, due to the country’s violent past, its small economic scale
and excessive red tape (ibid.: 46). Second, some of the paradoxical
aspects of the Bosnian state mentioned earlier cast doubts on its
legitimacy as well its capability to promote and maintain social cohesion in the long-run. The Bosnian war and its devastating effects
required an administrative framework that would help to irmly establish its legitimacy both domestically and abroad, and help to lay
down the rule of law. Meanwhile, the same state was also expected
to fulill the neoliberal principles of limiting state capacity in favor
of expanding private sector involvement in economics and political
involvement on a grassroots level (Zaum 2007: 102-103). In the
absence of social cohesion, where political involvement primar-
103
Kurtoglu Eskisar
ily occurs through consociational outlets, privatization has taken a
much more different course than originally intended.
More specifically, the donor decision to adopt neoliberal principles for statebuilding purposes gradually culminated in “a strong
corporate governance structure” in Bosnia (Bayliss 2005: 38).
Reducing state power to achieve efficiency in neoliberal terms in
a setting where the new state lacked a well established infrastructure and the support of its national political elite in the first
place turned out to bring self-defeating results for donors. Begić
(2014: 36) argues that the original plan of the reformers, which
involved transforming the status of public property into state property gradually played into the hands of “the party elites, which
dictated the structure of state institutions,” leading, ultimately, to
their privatization.
While privatization was the primary goal of the international community from the start, the resulting ownership pattern, combined
with the unexpected strengthening of patronage networks fed on
corrupt practices came as an unexpected outcome. According to
Ibrišimović (2014: 27)
“[p]eople championing the nationalist parties ... support the
policy of destroying once strong state-owned firms, by devaluing them and burdening them with huge loans. The firms
that were thus led to bankruptcy were then bought, as private
companies, by those same people, or those close to them.”
Yet, in the end, many Bosnians were left with no choice but adopting themselves to clientelist practices and corruption, in hopes
104
Foreign Aid and Corruption
of finding employment or ensuring their job security (Kurtović
2014: 99).
Kurtović (2014: 98-99) similarly refers to the privatization process
in Bosnia as an example of “accumulation by disposition” and argues that it was the leading reason behind the 2014 protests in the
country. Observers who explain the spark in Tuzla that grew into
fierce antigovernment protests throughout Bosnia as a result of the
earlier “rip-off privatization” of some state companies in the region,
followed by increasing levels of corruption, and an overall lack of
new investments to the region (Deutsche Welle 06 February 2014;
Bayliss 2005: 45). Gordy (2014: 113) describes the region’s ruthless economic transition with the following words: “the industrial
infrastructure that provided the base for Tuzla’s labour activism was
... gradually dismantled, its capacity hit ... in greater measure by
asset-stripping, budget-skimming and credit-bouncing privatizations.” Unpaid for over a year, the former workers believed that “bad
privatization and the corruptness of political parties” effectively
demolished the existing institutions, and reacted to it by a series
of protests, which were also backed up by their supporters in other
cities (Giovanni 2014).
5.9 Bosnian elite and corruption
A further complicating factor to the above stated conditions were
the inefficient or poorly executed earlier attempts of help by the
international community. Notwithstanding the general willingness
of the international community to help Bosnia, there have been an
increasing number of accusations about earlier attempts as not necessarily being well planned, or executed (Pond 2006: 151). Furthermore, similar to other postwar settings like Afghanistan or Iraq,
105
Kurtoglu Eskisar
in the name of encouraging adherence to central authority, the international actors involved in Bosnia may have turned a blind eye to
the existing corrupt practices on the local level (Donais 2005: 80).
Critiques of the international community point out their paradoxical failure to see that the initiated reforms turned out to create more
problems for the people they aimed to aid in the irst place (Kurtović
2014: 99).
To complicate the existing state of affairs further, the international
domination of all state-related affairs in Bosnia lasted until 2006, at
which point the international community decided that it was time
the Bosnians themselves took the driver’s seat for decision making
from the OHR. One of the reasons behind this decision of noninterference stemmed from the growing desire of the international
community to exit from Bosnian politics and governance and encourage “local ownership.” (ibid. 98) Similar to the criticisms that
targeted the international community earlier for turning a deaf ear
to the demands and frustrations of the Bosnians and imposing their
blueprints for reforms earlier, this decision has also been predicted
to lead to negative results for the future of Bosnia (ibid.: 97-98;
Begić 2014: 38-39).38
The strategy of excluding national actors from making key decisions by international donors for many years following Dayton
Agreement effectively meant that the Bosnians had little chance
to officially intervene into the reforms initiated and monitored by
the international actors since the end of the war (Donais 2005: 71).
For international actors, it also meant undertaking some measures,
which were often strongly resisted by the local actors, and probably
38 A counterview, however, has pointed out that, in practice, the external control
over the Bosnian affairs has hardly abated since that time period (Chandler 2010;
Chandler 2006).
106
Foreign Aid and Corruption
had a role in the suboptimal results in installing law and order, and
negatively affect the survival capabilities of the new infrastructure
in the long run (Zaum 2007: 102-103). The resistance of national
elites to the international reform efforts in issues like corruption,
and the general failure of the newly brought changes to take root
within the Bosnian society later became important subjects that greatly diminished the effects of foreign leadership.
Worse, as discussed later, the same approach enabled the Bosnian
elite to pass the buck of responsibility to the international community at the first sign of dysfunction, shortcoming, or failure of the
new structure (Pond 2006: 155). The end result, as most observers
agree, is
“a weak state built upon a complex and highly unstable set
of compromises between unity and partition, between monoethnicity and multiethnicity, and between individual and collective rights. These compromises, rife with ambiguity and
contradiction, were aimed far more at stopping a war than at
establishing a solid foundation for a liberal democratic state,
and have resulted in a complex, fragmented, competitive, and
arguably unsustainable set of governing structures.” (Donais
2005: 78).
The dubious commitment of the national elite at the apex of the
Bosnian administration to the ideals lined up by the international
government based on “good governance” principles is already well
outlined by observers (ibid.: 79) Political parties representing the
main ethnic groups in Bosnia are often accused of directly benefiting
from the existing political system, and striving to maintain the status
quo, which enables them to enjoy unlimited access to state goods
and their revenues, at all costs (Belloni 2007: 32; Donais 2005: 67-
107
Kurtoglu Eskisar
75). The political and national elites have therefore strongly resisted
the reforms that effectively stripped their privileges (Donais 2005:
71; Zaum 2007: 103; Bayliss 2005: 46). As a result, instead of promoting economic efficiency and triggering development, privatization in Bosnia seems to have generated the transfer of public goods
to predatory national elite, who, as discussed later, have used the
opportunity to enrich themselves and their allies, or use it as a means to reinforce their existing status and power (Donais 2005: 75).
5.10 Political parties and organized crime
In addition to the growing problems of the Bosnian state, the institutionalization of corruption patterns in Bosnia that often goes hand in
hand with crime networks has also become a point of concern (ibid.:
67). There are increasing accusations on the alleged symbiotic ties
between the leading political parties of all ethnic groups and crime
groups (ibid.: 75). In the current state of affairs, these parties do not
only represent the political interests of their respective groups, but
also dominate the economic environment through their
“sweeping control of state-run enterprises, government jobs,
and the issuing of lucrative state contracts. These new political
elites now function as maia-like economic syndicates, tightly
controlling companies, cash, and jobs. That has stunted the
country’s economy and politics.” (Rohde 2014)
Begić (2014: 37) similarly argues that “[p]owerful party elites control absolutely everything,” including legal decisions, which are increasingly undertaken “to it the needs and desires of individuals
within the parties, all facilitated through a developed network of
party sympathizers within the institutions of government.” Some
observers claim that the arrest of several people in the country,
108
Foreign Aid and Corruption
including two ministers in September 2014 of on corruption and
organized crime charges remains a clear indicator of the power of
the leading political parties in the country (Reuters, 10 September
2014). Begić (2014: 39) further blames the international community
for tacitly encouraging the strong leadership patterns, at the expense
of debilitating the institutionalization process of the new state.
The roots of growing ties between illicit activities and political parties are often traced to the incomplete democratization process in
Bosnia. According to Donais (2005: 77) rules dating from Yugoslavia, maze-like administrative apparatuses and measures implemented by the national political elite to fulill their self-interests all
trump the post-Dayton liberal reforms. Instead of initiating the beginnings of a working parliamentary system, the first elections that
took place after Dayton were used by the leading ethnic political
parties as leverage for official approval (Pond 2006: 153-154). Later, the ability of political parties to control both political and economic relations in Bosnia has reinforced “neo-feudalist” tendencies
among leading political figures, and have promoted clientelism in
that country (Donais 2005: 72).
Concurring with the neo-feudal characteristics of the Bosnian state, Stubbs (2001:101) similarly describes them as the power accumulation in local administrations “based on patronage, inluence
peddling, and mafia-like elites.” This concern is similarly raised by
Begić (2014: 39), who points out that
“[e]very day we see prime ministers, assembly presidents, envoys and other senior public oficials appointing their closest
relatives as directors of public companies. We see the government giving grants from public funds to private irms run by
109
Kurtoglu Eskisar
the spouses of ministers who work in that same government,
or employing immediate family members in public institutions and companies.”
5.11 Conclusion
As in any other country with a violent past and riddled with a multitude of issues and problems, overviewing some of the leading factors behind persistent corruption in Bosnia remains a complex task.
Notwithstanding other contributing factors, however, the points
brought in the chapter attribute more importance to the overall role
of foreign aid in the final outcome than often assumed. Similar to
the Afghan experience outlined in the previous chapter, corruption
in Bosnia seems to have been largely dependent on the misappropriation of public goods for private purposes, including the foreign
aid proffered by the international community (Arsenijevic 2014).
Ultimately, despite the active involvement of the international community, the goals it had set earlier may have sown the seeds of their
its own hubris in the long run.
Aside from its presumed effects on economy, corruption in Bosnia
remains regarded as a threat against the accumulation of its social
capital, in the sense that it seems to promote vertical, rather than
horizontal ties. As Begić (2014: 39) argues, “[w]ith all this, arrogance “becomes the basic principle in communication with citizens.”
Arguably the internationally structure implemented by the Dayton
Agreement has aggravated corruption through its sheer complexity, and inability to build inter-group or individual-state cohesion, which is needed for statebuilding (Divjak and Pugh 2008: 374).
110
Foreign Aid and Corruption
The lack of a sound legal framework to encourage accountability, as
well as the tendency for over-regulation, which stiles the economic
and business environment has not improved the existing condition
either (Donais 2005: 75). The domination of political parties to the
detriment of existing laws has also played a role in gravitating politicians toward corrupt activities. Since the political elite profit from
the existing status quo, they also resist any significant changes that
would alter or end it, leaving the rest of the society to utilize corruption as a necessary means to stay aloat. (ibid.)
In some aspects, it is possible to conclude that the foreign aid to
Bosnia has acted much like a piece of amber, locking the combatting
sides and their spectators into a permanent status quo, and preventing the outbreak of inter-group violence at the expense of inducing
political, administrative and economic stagnation in the long-run.
111
Kurtoglu Eskisar
112
Foreign Aid and Corruption
CHAPTER 6
IRAQ
“[W]e were left dealing with what seemed like the ifth string…
Nobody who was left knew anything.”
(A US expert describing the state of Iraqi Ministry of Transportation
and Communications following the Coalition led de-Baathiication
process in Anderson (2004)
“Corruption is the second insurgency, and I use that metaphor to
underline the seriousness of this issue.”
(Stuart W. Bowen, the Special Inspector General for Iraq Reconstruction (SIGIR) in Borger and Pallister (2006)
“These guys, these units are demoralized. They are underpaid and
ripped off constantly by their commanding oficers, who steal their
allowances and use their commands as a way to build a personal
nest egg.”
(A former US oficer in Iraq explaining the defeat of the Iraqi army
by the Islamist ighters in Parker and Ryan (2014)
113
Kurtoglu Eskisar
6.1 Introduction
In March 2003, an international coalition39 led by USA entered Iraq
with the goal of removing its leader Saddam Hussein from power by
force and replace his authoritarian regime with democracy. Among
its other goals, the “Operation Iraqi Freedom” aimed to increase the
security both in Iraq and in the Middle East, and promote the spread
of democracy worldwide (Dobbins et al 2003: 167; Kaplan and
Kristol 2003; Anderson and Stansield 2004: 185-186). The US-led
international coalition also frequently brought up the corrupt nature
of the Saddam regime as a major factor that initiated the occupation,
sometimes stressed to the level of ignoring more important issues,
such as serious human rights violations of the same regime (Whyte
2007: 156).
Notwithstanding its estimated payoffs by the Coalition, however,
the invasion of Iraq divided the international community even before it occurred. While the UNSC permanent members like China,
France and Russia irmly opposed any military operations to Iraq,
USA and the UK supported it on the grounds of eliminating any security threats from Saddam Hussein’s regime to the region, particularly based on the claim that it possessed and could utilize Weapons
of Mass Distruction (ibid.). Differences of opinion among countries
39 It is not the purpose of this chapter to discuss the causes and the dynamics of
the war in Iraq in 2003 in detail, which has already formed its own substantive literature in years (e.g. Rogers 2006; Ricks 2006). A few important details, however,
requires pointing out: The coalition forces (referred to as “the Coalition” throughout
the chapter) that carried out the Operation Iraqi Freedom and the following war in
that country consisted of USA, UK, Australia and Poland. Despite the technically
international nature of the invasion, since the size of the US troops and their overall
involvement in the war and its aftermath far exceeded the other coalition members,
unless explicitly noted otherwise, the term Coalition throughout the chapter refers
to the US institutions established and led by USA to govern Iraq following the war.
114
Foreign Aid and Corruption
during any international intervention is hardly uncommon. However, the polarization of some of the leading international donors
regarding the occupation into opposite camps from the outset raised
questions concerning its legitimacy and the underlying motives of
the Coalition forces, particularly USA as their leader, that are involved in it (Diamond 2006: 185). These concerns, combined with a
series of unexpected problems following the war have turned out to
play a crucial role in limiting the effectiveness of the original plans
of the Coalition and its postwar statebuilding goals in Iraq.
Despite the international reactions against it, at the beginning the
Coalition members had some cause for cautious optimism for the
war to fulill its purported goals. It was no secret that Saddam Hussein was already disliked by many Iraqis who really wanted his removal from power. Furthermore, the war was over in a few weeks
and the freedom it brought seemed to be welcomed by the Iraqis
(Fontan 2009: 25). During the war and in its immediate aftermath,
the much feared sectarian differences in the country did not seem as
pronounced as earlier feared by the Coalition, either (ibid.).
Yet, merely acouple of months later, these factors were completely
reversed, and an increasing number of Iraqis seemed to resent the
foreign presence in their midst (ibid.: 26). As a former British oficer has pointed out, “[t]he British boasted to the Americans about
how they had fought successful guerrilla wars in Malaysia and
Northern Ireland, but in both those places we were backed by the
majority of the population. In Basra [Iraq] we had no allies.” (cited
in Cockburn 2015)
In fact, a considerable number of observers now regard the Iraqi experience of democratization and statebuilding attempts since 2003
115
Kurtoglu Eskisar
as the worst one of its kind when compared to places like Afghanistan, Bosnia, Cambodia or East Timor (Arato 2009: viii). A scholar
has remarked that “the failure in Iraq” was like “a car crash when
a drunken teenager gets behind the wheel of a dilapidated car on a
bad road in heavy trafic: each factor in itself may be suficient for
the accident.” (Byman 2008: 601) Whyte (2007: 159) has similarly
criticized the postwar statebuilding efforts of the Coalition in Iraq
as follows:
“[T]hose measures culminated in the ‘creative destruction’ of
the Iraqi economy, which fatally weakened indigenous industry and indigenous capital ... In the aftermath of the invasion,
the CPA regime acutely reduced the chances of a genuine resurgence of Iraq’s indigenous industries.”
6.2 Corruption in Iraq since 2003: some anecdotes
One of the most disappointing outcomes of the war in Iraq has been
its adverse impact on the corruption levels in the country, which,
according to the TI data, have remained among the highest in the
world. While corruption was already rampant during the prewar
period, postwar efforts to improve matters not only seem to have
backired, but ironically may have exacerbated the phenomenon.
Corruption in Iraq today remains ubiquituous and vast, spanning
almost all aspects of life, ranging from the military or administrative ofices to the judiciary (Bassem 2015). Indeed, a former Iraqi
statesman has gone so far as to describe the contemporary Iraqi state
as “an institutionalized kleptocracy.” (Cockburn 2013) While this
remark may seem excessive, it is to some extent backed up by data:
Recent research undertaken in 2011 has found out that 11.6 per cent
of the adult population was involved in bribery (UNODC 2013: 5).
116
Foreign Aid and Corruption
Yet another Iraqi, a political scientist, similarly summarizes the existing conditions on corruption as follows:
“The corruption is unbelievable ... You can’t get a job in the
army or the government unless you pay; you can’t even get
out of prison unless you pay. Maybe a judge sets you free but
you must pay for the paperwork, otherwise you stay there.
Even if you are free you may be captured by some oficer
who paid $10,000 to $50,000 for his job and needs to get the
money back.” (Cockburn 2013)
6.3 Corruption as a security problem in Iraq
Apart from its already well known effects on the Iraqi politics and
economy, corruption may well have also become a serious problem for its domestic security, and territorial integrity. Among other
incidents, the recent government efforts to crack down on corruption has revealed that it had been paying 50,000 soldiers who only
existed on paper, which roughly estimated to be worth US$300 million (Mohammed 2014). The devastating effects of corruption on
the Iraqi army recently also came under scrutiny during its defeat
by the radical Islamist ighters who seek to establish an Islamic state
known as the Islamic State of Iraq and the Levant (ISIL), sometimes
also referred to as the Islamic State of Iraq and ash-Sham (ISIS) by
carving out territory from several Middle Eastern countries, including Iraq (Hussein 2015). Due to the artiicially inlated numbers of
soldiers in the army, a high ranking Iraqi oficer estimated the actual
combat capability of the Iraqi troops against the Islamist ighters to
be roughly around 20% (“How Iraq’s ‘ghost soldiers’ helped ISIL,”
2014).
117
Kurtoglu Eskisar
6.4 A culture of corruption?
While discussing the factors that underline the corruption networks
in Iraq in recent years, some observers have referred to “a broader
culture of corruption that no one has been able to change, despite
government efforts enlisting international assistance.” (Bassem
2015) A closer look at the patterns of corruption and how it is perceived in Iraq, however, offers a quite complex picture. To begin
with, recent data on corruption patterns in Iraq gives a broad idea
about the level of general acceptance of corruption as a “normal”
behavior by Iraqis themselves:
“In almost four out of ive cases Iraqi citizens are prompted
to pay bribes, as opposed to offering bribes voluntarily themselves. Speciically, in about two-thirds (65 per cent) of cases
bribes are requested, either explicitly or implicitly, by the
civil servant taking the bribe, and in another 14 per cent a
third party requests the bribe on behalf of the bribe taker.”
(UNODC 2013: 6)
Furthermore, corruption levels in Iraq are not uniform, but show
variations across regions. It is remarkable that the Baghdad region
representing the central government boasts the foremost levels of
corruption, whereas the autonomous Kurdish region has far lower
levels (ibid.: 5). One possible explanation for this outcome would
be the existing (or absent) administrative infrastructure in different
regions in Iraq. Byman (2008: 608) describes those parts of the
country controlled by the Sunnis and Shia as a failed state, which
exacerbated the existing problems, including security. Another reason behind this diversity might be the disinclination of post-conlict
societies to unite around a central state structure. Foreign aid with
118
Foreign Aid and Corruption
neoliberal approaches toward state may exacerbate such tendencies (Sörensen 2010: 100). Although more research is needed for an
affirmative conclusion, it is possible to hypothesize that countries
where post-conlict national reconciliation is missing are likelier to
boast higher levels of corruption than countries where such reconciliation has been reached.
While discussing corruption in post-conlict societies, Rose-Ackerman
(2009: 68) argues that “[e]ven if a person wishes to report a corrupt
offer, there may be no effective way to do so that does not invite
harassment or worse.” Iraq constitutes an appropriate example to
this relection. Despite the high levels of corruption in the country,
Iraqi people have remained hesitant to bring up their experiences to
demand retribution or institutional change, mostly due to fear:
“Not all Iraqi oficials are corrupt. But all are vulnerable to
anti-corruption charges. This has a crippling impact. A US
businessman explained that he was dealing with a ministry
in which he thought only 10 per cent of oficials took bribes.
‘But the other 90 per cent know they might be targeted for
investigation and therefore the safest course for them is to take
their salaries and do nothing. The ministry is effectively paralysed.’” (Cockburn 2013)
Such anecdotes are further supported by systematic data gathered in
recent years. According to a recent UN report on Iraq, for instance,
“[t]wo thirds (66.3%) of civil servants would not feel adequately protected if they had to “blow the whistle” (report
an act of corruption) in their own ministry. Notably, 38.9% of
those who do not feel adequately protected are afraid of losing
their job and 22.8% fear physical harm.” (UNODC 2013: 11)
119
Kurtoglu Eskisar
As these arguments suggest, rather than being a primordial feature
of the Iraqi society, this “culture” of corruption attributed to the
Iraqi society may be supported by the extraordinary conditions that
the country has experienced for years. While discussing corruption
and its effects in postwar Iraq, Borger and Pallister (2006) underline
the contribution of foreign intervention in the outcome by stating
that “[a] culture of waste, incompetence and fraud may be one legacy the occupiers have passed on to Iraq’s new rulers more or less
intact.” Indeed, according to Cockburn (2009), “Iraqis resent paying
a bribe for almost everything, but do not see what they can do about
it.” As an Iraqi man on paying a bribe to get a job confessed; “[p]
eople know this is wrong, but there is no way round it.” (cited in
Cockburn 2009) The next section, which covers the pre-occupation
conditions in Iraq regarding corruption can help to grasp some of
these extraordinary conditions better.
6.5 Foreign aid and corruption in Iraq before 2003
Before discussing the impact of the foreign aid on the subsequent
Iraqi statebuilding and anti-corruption efforts since 2003, it is useful to take a brief look at the conditions that prevailed in the country in earlier years. To start with, it is important to remember that
Iraq has had a long history of corruption exacerbated by foreign
aid. As Cockburn (2009) explains, “Iraq was not always uniquely
corrupt. Its 1970s administration was probably more eficient and
honest than that in most oil-producing countries: the aftermath of
the invasion of Kuwait in 1990 criminalised Iraqi society.” Indeed,
prior to its US-led international occupation in 2003, most observers
concur that the UN sanctions had already exacerbated the already
high levels of corruption in the country, and strengthened a small
120
Foreign Aid and Corruption
but increasingly powerful elite who used them to enrich themselves
and their clans (Whyte 2007: 157).
The economic sanctions on Iraq began on 6 August 1990 with the
UN resolution 661, after the Iraqi invasion of Kuwait, which lasted
until another UN resolution (1483) replaced it on 22 May 2003. The
elevated levels of corruption during the sanctions period were not
primarily a result of Iraqi state ineficiency in economic terms, but
were more inluenced by its deteriorating public welfare functions
(Whyte 2007: 158). Shortage of basic public goods and services
during this period exacerbated corrupt behavior among civil servants, and promoted the emergence of black markets (ibid). Another
observer similarly concludes that
“the approach came at a heavy cost: massively depressed Iraqi
living-standards, a failure to satisfy Washington and some
others of Iraqi disarmament—eventually producing a second Western invasion in 2003, and massive corruption of the
sanctions regime that severely damaged UN credibility after
2003.” (Malone 2006: 17)
While scholars generally agree on the negative impact of economic
sanctions on corruption levels in Iraq during the Saddam era, they
disagree on their outcome as deliberate or unintended. On the one
hand are claims that climbing levels of corruption during these years
were either a deliberate and promoted result or the international
community turning a blind eye in the hopes to weaken Saddam’s
regime. Following the occupation, Whyte (2007: 159-160) argues
that the corruption rhetoric was used as an excuse to apply the neoliberal reforms to Iraqi economy, which ultimately led to their institutionalization in its new economic structure. On the other hand,
121
Kurtoglu Eskisar
however, it is possible to explain the same outcome with the inability of the sanction supporters to see that their proclivity for complex
administrative measures and overdependence “on agents—either
the staff of the UN, or the Member States themselves—who implemented, monitored, and enforced the rules it laid down. That created
the opportunity for those agents to corrupt, in a variety of ways, application of the regulatory regime.” (Malone 2006: 294) In support
of earlier claims, international investigations later discovered that
during the UN led Oil-for-Food Program, bribing became a common practice among foreign companies to get oil from the Saddam
administration, which was later sold at a much higher price abroad.
The US investigations similarly found out that while the US administration knew about these corrupt activities all along, its oficials
chose to ignore it (Whyte 2007: 158).
Following the end of the Iraqi war, the Coalition initially underlined the corrupt nature of the Saddam regime as an excuse for the
poor economic conditions and serious levels of mismanagement in
the country (ibid.: 157). This line of argument, however, has been
mostly discarded in recent years, mainly due to the following reasons. First, as already stated earlier, nothwithstanding the heavy
damage that the Saddam era did to the Iraqi economy and society,
it was not completely defunct, either (Byman 2008: 611). Second,
the problems and failures associated with the decisions taken during
the postwar period has been increasingly acknowledged in the oficial reports of the Coalition or by people who served in the region.
Today, country experts mostly concur that a string of ineficient or
wrong decisions taken following the occupation by the Coalition
has played an important role in the persistence of corruption in Iraq.
122
Foreign Aid and Corruption
6.6 Foreign financial aid after Iraq War (2003): some figures
Once the war was over, the Coalition quickly formed the Coalition
Provisional Authority in April 2003, which acted as the de facto
government for Iraq until its powers were transferred to the Iraqi
Interim Government in June 2004.40 The Iraqi Interim Government was later replaced by the Iraqi Transitional Government in
May 2005, which inally left the loor a year later in May 2006 after
the irst postwar general elections in Iraq for the irst permanent
Iraqi government. Consequently in December 2007 the US troops
began to exit the country, which was inally completed in December
2011.41
For many reasons, Iraq following the invasion resembled a minefield for the Coalition. A country already wrecked by war damages,
internal divisions, human rights abuses and sheer mismanagement,
among other factors, made the task of rebuilding the Iraqi state in
every sense—including fighting corruption—a daunting task at best
(Byman 2008: 602). Another unexpected outcome of the war was
the local resistance to the Coalition troops in its aftermath. Although
the invasion of Iraq was complete in roughly three weeks, in some
locations like Fallujah violence against the troops had begun even
earlier (Fontan 2009: 11).
The key to ending postwar violence in Iraq rested both on successfully undertaking the necessary military measures, and to adopt the
40 In other words, soon after the ighting ended, “[t]he CPA, which is to say the
United States, had become the de facto government of Iraq, responsible for all the
things people usually expect of their governments.” (Shimko 2010: 174)
41 Although the US troops did return to Iraq after three years in 2014, it was by the
invitation of the Iraqi government, and it aimed to aid the Iraqi army against the
rising threat by ISIL/ISIS (Garamone 2014).
123
Kurtoglu Eskisar
necessary means to quickly ensure a political representation system
that would obtain its legitimacy from the Iraqi society (Diamond
2006: 181). Meanwhile, the power vacuum that briely emerged
after toppling Saddam Hussein and his regime led to a fierce and
bloody fight for political domination among the contending groups in that country. The attacks, which were earlier restrained to
mostly Sunni parts of Iraq, but slowly gaining pace elsewhere later
on, forced the coalition powers to concentrate on peacekeeping, and
further slowed down or hampered their efforts on statebuilding, including those directed against corruption (Byman 2008: 604-605).
Furthermore, they also played a key role in determining the later
Sunni dominance over the Iraqi state (ibid.: 605). Many of the resisting people consisted of the former Iraqi administrative, military
or intelligence ranks, who did not seek to reestablish the prewar
state structure (ibid.: 604). Rather, they were “Iraqis (mainly Sunnis) who turned against the occupation because they believed it was
excluding them politically.” (Diamond 2006: 181)
As mentioned earlier, the international community was already
sharply divided before the Iraqi war. This disunion, followed by the
rising security problems in Iraq following the war further curtailed
the international involvement in the country, including assistance
on the ground and the UN relief work. Numerous terrorist attacks or
threats on capable foreign professionals experienced in peacebuilding processes proved particularly worrisome, and even affected the
future outlook of such organizations toward providing aid at conlict
prone zones (ibid.: 185-186). Therefore, security problems limited
the overall effects of the available international aid in Iraq in general
(SIGIR 2013: 9).
124
Foreign Aid and Corruption
As a result, following the end of the war, USA and Iraqis quickly
emerged as the primary inancial donors of the reconstruction efforts in the country (SIGIR 2013: 9). According to a US oficial
report, “[d]uring its existence, the CPA controlled over $23.4 billion
in Iraqi funds composed of $20.7 billion.” (ibid.: 9) Compared to the
US and Iraqi funds, the portion of direct international inancial aid
remained somewhat smaller, but still signiicant. Although the international community pledged to give over $13 billion to the country
a few months after the invasion, the amount that was actually sent
was smaller, and came in much later (ibid.: 10). Nevertheless, the
international community did also take some immediate steps to relieve the Iraqi economy and help its reconstruction, by cancelling a
signiicant portion of the country’s earlier debts in late 2003 (ibid).
The general trajectory of the international aid low to Iraq in years
can also be traced with a quick glance at the available ODA data.
The massive donor input into Iraq can also be better appeciated if
compared with some of the other aid receiving countries during the
same period.While the aid low from ODA to Iraq has widely luctuated in years, its overall amount has consistently remained higher
in the postwar period. As igures in Appendix A at the end of this
book point out, while the country received only US$85.39 million
of aid in 2002, this amount quickly rose to US$2178.2 billion in
2003. In comparison, during the same year Bosnia received only
US$335.45 million and Afghanistan US$1227.2 million, respectively. Consistently rising international aid low to Iraq inally peaked
at US$21983.36 million in 2005, meanwhile, Bosnia received only
US$268.51 million and Afghanistan received US$2184.96 million
during the same year. Since 2005, aid low to Iraq, however, has taken a steady downturn: The country received US$1113.79 million in
125
Kurtoglu Eskisar
2012; a much higher amount than the previous decade, but nonetheless signiicantly lower than the amount sent in 2005. Afghanistan,
however, received US$5660.93 million during the same year, which
becomes an even more impressive igure when compared to the aid
received by Bosnia at US$213.41.
Notwithstanding all these substantive amount of inancial aid from
foreign donors, various reports and investigations in recent years
have repeatedly pointed out at the misappropriation and abuse of
donor money that was supposed to be used for the reconstruction of
Iraq. The inal report of SIGIR (2013: 9), for instance, admits that
“[i]n 2003 and 2004, more than $10 billion in DFI cash was lown
to Baghdad on U.S. military aircraft in the form of massive shrinkwrapped bundles of $100 bills stored on large pallets. This money
was not managed particularly well, either by the CPA or its successors.” Many observers, including Iraqis themselves, also concur
with this view, and conclude that corruption levels got higher following the low of large amounts of inancial aid to the reconstruction efforts in the country after the war (Bassem 2013). Critiques
of foreign aid to Iraq further argue that, instead of producing the
intended positive results the low of inancial aid, it has helped to
create “a ‘triangle of political patronage’ among Iraq’s political parties, sectarian groups and government oficials that sparked corruption and terrorism.” (Wood 2013)
6.7 Statebuilding efforts in postwar Iraq: lack of postwar
planning
Notwithstanding its immense humanitarian and economic costs,
one of the foremost criticisms directed against the occupation of
Iraq has been the lack of afterwar planning by the US-led Coalition.
126
Foreign Aid and Corruption
Some critiques have even claimed it to be “the least well-planned
American military mission since Somalia in 1993, if not Lebanon
in 1983, and its consequences for the nation have been far worse
than any set of military mistakes since Vietnam.” (O’Hanlon 2004)
This lack of afterwar planning is not only given as a leading reason
behind its failure to restore order and democratize Iraq and curb
corruption, but also a key element in reducing its chances to realize
them for the foreseeable future, too (SIGIR 2013: 12).
While discussing the overall effects of the Iraqi war, scholars generally concur that the postwar plans of the Coalition were mostly
unrealistic (Diamond 2006: 174). In fact, once the war ended, a
leading shortcoming of the US-led Coalition reconstruction efforts
quickly emerged as the “poor American knowledge about what Iraq
needed.” (SIGIR 2013: 11) The people who made the decisions at
the CPA did not have suficient amount of people who could directly
communicate with the Iraqis, or had suficient knowledge of the
region or the Iraqi society (Diamond 2006: 181-182).
To begin with, the timing of the US investments in Iraq, when security was not completely restored, has received a lot of criticism
from the US oficers. The following example given by Wood (2013)
offers an idea about the cost of such neglect of the realities on the
ground:
“In 2004 ... the U.S. launched an ambitious project to build
a sewer and water system in Fallujah, a center of intense and
bloody sectarian ighting. Originally slated to cost $35 million
and take 18 months to complete, the project so far has cost
$195 million and is scheduled to be inished in 2014.” (Wood
2013)
127
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Furthermore, the US-led attempt for a massive rebuilding of the
country instead of concentrating on a few select projects complicated the donor efforts to get quick but politically meaningful results,
and left the country scattered instead with “hundreds of ill thoughtout projects and half baked ideas ... [which] marred the American
reconstruction efforts.” (Boyle 2013) As a former Iraqi minister has
complained,
“[w]ith all the money the U.S. has spent, you can go into any
city in Iraq and you cannot ind one building or project [built
by the U.S. government] ... You can ly in a helicopter around
Baghdad or other cities, but you cannot point a inger at a single project that was built and completed by the United States.”
(SIGIR 2013: 14)
As a result, numerous US-led reforms were also often resisted by the
regional elite and in those instances when the reforms went through,
the expected outcomes did not address the needs or expectations of
the Iraqi society (Le Billon 2005: 686; SIGIR 2013: 14).
6.8 Lack of information, poor choices
Another problem concerning the Coalition decisions was the lack of
transparency, competition and planning while making appointments
or distributing projects. Observers generally concur that loyalty and
personal networks instead of merit played a chief role in the appointment of senior level positions for administration or the distribution of reconstruction projects following the war (Whyte 2007:
160). As the leader and the primary force behind the Coalition, the
US and the Bush administration has particularly received criticism
for neglecting the importance of transparency:
128
Foreign Aid and Corruption
“[T]he US government ... split the economy into sectors and
shared them out among nine big US corporations. In most
cases the contracts were distributed without competition and
on a cost-plus basis. In other words the contractors were guaranteed a proit margin calculated as a percentage of their costs,
so the higher the costs, the higher the proits. In the rush to get
work started the contracts were signed early in 2004. In many
cases work did not get under way until the year was nearly
over. In the months between, the contractors racked up huge
bills on wages, hotel bills and restaurants.” (Borger and Pallister 2006)
As a result, inconsistent, even contradicting approaches of the coalition forces in their reconstruction efforts have further increased the
level of corruption in Iraq. Due to mismanagement, corrupt practices and the overall chaotic environment, which clouded the decisions
taken by the CPA, Iraq is estimated to have lost at least $8 billion of
its oil income during this relatively short period (Whyte 2007: 159).
Ironically, the end of the CPA era in 2004 did not improve matters for Iraq, either. Unlike the earlier period, when reconstruction
spending was poorly monitored or accounted for, this time the USsent funding became subject to over regulation and bureaucratic
measures (ibid.: 162). Although the increased concern for control
during this period may have aimed to reduce corruption caused by
lack of monitoring, it also effectively barred the Iraqi society, including entrepreneurs, from playing an active role in the reconstruction of their country. The following observations of Whyte (2007:
163) are remarkable in this regard:
“The second phase of reconstruction, structured around a U.S.
procurement system, with all of its attendant claims of pre129
Kurtoglu Eskisar
venting corruption, effectively established a system of structural advantage for U.S. irms, while retaining the formal appearance of equal access. It effectively establishes a system
of ‘clean corruption’ in the allocation of reconstruction funds.
The same prime contractors that reaped windfall proits during the CPA’s regime (without having to comply with U.S.
procurement standards) are well positioned to use their alliances with Iraqi partner irms to beneit from the structural
advantages the procurement system provides. Firms that are
not involved in those networks stand little chance of securing contracts unless they form partnerships with U.S. irms or
‘hire an American.’”
In tandem with this argument, the former Iraqi prime minister Nuri
al-Maliki conirmed in an interview that during the reconstruction
process, the U.S. personnel in charge more often than not “’depended on others’ (local subcontractors) who frequently turned out to be
illinformed or dishonest. Thus, ‘there was misspending of money.’”
(SIGIR 2013: 11) Another former Iraqi minister made a similar remark and expressed that the “U.S. rebuilding managers governed
‘in a vacuum, so they were responsible for everything,’ to the exclusion, in his view, of meaningful Iraqi input.” (ibid.: 13)
6.9 Iraqis as decisionmakers: the missing link
Another main reason behind the failure of foreign led efforts to
rebuild Iraq and fight corruption is the exclusion of Iraqis themselves from making crucial decisions for themselves. On the one
hand, some initial efforts of the Coalition are worth mentioning.
For instance, it took some steps to involve the Iraqis in the reform
and reconstruction process, including the formation of the Iraqi
130
Foreign Aid and Corruption
Governing Council (IGC). According to Shimko (2010: 176), the
driving force behind this quest was the idea that “[Paul] Bremer did
not want to be seen as the American dictator of Iraq and felt there
needed to be some move toward Iraqi self-government, no matter
how symbolic.” As a result of these efforts, in some regions, some
simple elections were conducted under the tutelage of the occupying forces.
On the other hand, despite the well intentions of the Coalition, such
measures were far from suficient to bring consistent and satisfactory results for Iraqis as they were excluded from making their future decisions for themselves. Indeed, according to the former chair
of the Iraqi Commission on Public Integrity, the greatest problem
that generated waste and corruption in Iraq was that the “Americans excluded Iraqis from the planning and prioritizing of projects.”
(Wood 2013) For instance, the prescribed function of the IGC was
merely consultative, and its decisions were nonbinding (Diamond
2006 184-185). It also had other shortcomings that severely limited its eficacy or legitimacy in the eyes of Iraqis, such as, many
of its members consisted of the former Iraqi exiles or expatriates,
who had little knowledge of the existing dynamics and conditions
that prevailed in Iraq. Since these people were outside the country
and constantly travelling, most of them hardly remained in contact
with their respective constitutents, or get involved in intensive and
long-term social cohesion building efforts (ibid.:185). The aforementioned electoral processes for local councils were not foolproof
either, as instead of the one-man one vote principle each household
voted as a single unit (ibid.: 184).
The greatest problem facing these councils, however, was not due to
131
Kurtoglu Eskisar
lack of efforts on the part of their participants, or the apathy of the
Iraqi society. Rather, it was “their evident powerlessness and lack
of resources—to the point that many of them had to wait for months
even to receive their salaries, and most of them felt frustrated by
their impotence.” (Diamond 2006: 184) This turned out to mar the
legitimacy claims of the Coalition further, and put a further strain on
the long-term efforts to democratize Iraq (ibid.)
Although the initial elections after the war could have encouraged
the emergence of new political elite with no past ties to the corrupt
networks or power cliques of the past era, the prevalence of political exiles from Saddam era in the IGC also removed this possibility
(Arato 2009: 22-23). While the latter group was not directly appointed to governing positions in the post war Iraq, they played a
major role in the de-Baathiication process, as well as the formation
of new patronage networks (ibid). An Iraqi doctor expressed the increasing dissatisfaction of Iraqis being excluded from all vital decisions as follows: “[w]e need to know what’s going to happen. There
is no transparency to the American role in Iraq, and this gives rise to
more rumors. We need to know more.” (Anderson 2004)
6.10 De-Baathification
While making plans for Iraq’s postwar reconstruction, instead of
focusing on what was present on the ield, the US administration
often drew on the experiences of Germany and Japan after the Second World War (Goldsmith 2007: 26; Fontan 2009: 6-7; Anderson
2004; Feldman 2004: 1). The impact of drawing on the postwar experiences of Germany to orchestrate the statebuilding efforts in Iraq
can be perhaps best seen in the de-Baathiication decision that the
Coalition adopted shortly after the occupation. The ad hoc nature of
132
Foreign Aid and Corruption
the de-Baathiication decision can be assessed from the following
comments of a foreign oficer in Iraq. When asked about the possibility of dissolving the Baath party in Iraq, “the French commander
of the Baghdad military sector demurred and noted that ‘we will
only remove a handful of Iraqis from power—no more than would
it on a deck of cards.’” (Byman 2008: 600) Briely after his arrival,
however, Paul Bremer III, who was appointed by the US President
George W. Bush to lead the CPA announced the ban on the Baath
Party, and ired its members from administrative ranks, regardless
of their rank or involvement with the excesses of the Saddam era,
which included “teachers, doctors, and mid-level civil servants.”
(Malone 2006: 203) Fontan (2009: 27) summarizes the underlying
logic of this decision as follows:
“Because Saddam Hussein’s rule represented a brutal dictatorship in the eyes of many Iraqis, any remnant of this former
regime had to be eliminated. This initiative stemmed from the
post–World War II Germany’s denaziication policies, which
were thought to have paved the way for the country’s successful reconstruction.”
Scrapping the administrative structure or informal networks dating
from Saddam era without understanding how they functioned for so
long, however, turned out to be a costly experiment for international
donors, and had an adverse effect on the fight against corruption
in the long run. To start with, the de-Baathification process involved the disbandment of the Iraqi Army, which meant that 500,000
people with military training and weapons suddenly became loose
(Malone 2006: 203).
On a wider scale, this decision also meant sacking a significant part
133
Kurtoglu Eskisar
of the existing state administration and the loss of jobs for more than
two million Iraqis (Diamond 2006: 182-183; SIGIR 2013: 12). Furthermore, while many of the purged individuals were officially party
members, many of their ties to their party stemmed from pragmatic, rather than ideological reasons, and were not directly involved
with the violent excesses of the Saddam regime (Fontan 2009: 29;
Anderson 2004). More importantly, they “filled jobs at every level
of society and anchored the middle class.” (Anderson 2004) However, since the expulsion criteria were mechanical and concentrated
on the ranks of individuals instead of their actual deeds, the whole
process was regarded as unfair and inefficient by most Iraqis, and
further stoked the sectarian divisions within the Iraqi society (Sissons and Al-Saiedi 2013: 32; Fontan 2009: 29).
The polarizing effect of the de-Baathification process and its impact on the subsequent Iraqi politics and anticorruption efforts are
better appreciated under the light of the heterogeneous nature of the
Iraqi society. During the early period following the occupation, the
leadership of the main groups in Iraq did not display similar characteristics: While the Shia community was led by religious networks,
the Sunnis mostly had nonreligious or traditional leaders (Byman
2008: 606). Furthermore, the support for the Coalition was not universal in Iraq, with Shia generally being more favorably disposed
to them than the Sunnis (ibid.: 607). As a result of these factors, the
coalition forces may have overestimated the sectarian rivalries in
the country prior to their invasion. As Fontan (2009: 26) has pointed
out:
“In the spring of 2003, while the Coalition sought to establish
its occupation of Iraq on the basis that its departure would trig-
134
Foreign Aid and Corruption
ger a civil war, most Iraqis I met deemed such a catastrophic
scenario laughable ... I was made to realize that, after all, both
Sunnis and Shiites took part in the war against Iran from 1980
to 1988. Divisions there were, but not along ethnic lines, at
least for Sunnis and Shiites.”
The US-led efforts to curb smuggling activities in Iraq following the
occupation constitute another example to the problem of eradicating
the existing albeit illegal practices without understanding their exact
functions or sufficient planning for the possible aftereffects of their
absence. In return for retaining a firm political grasp on the country,
the prewar regime of Saddam Hussein had earlier had turned a blind
eye to the illegal activities like smuggling by certain tribes in western Iraq. After the occupation, however the Coalition tried to put
an end to such activities without offering any incentives to those
people who are involved in such networks, thus gaining their ire,
and contributed to the ongoing instability in the country (Byman
2008: 610).
6.11 Aftereffects of de-Baathification: security crisis
Another unexpected but grave outcome of de-Baathiication turned
out to be the increase of looting and destroying the existing infrastructure with alarming frequency (Anderson 2004). Soon after the
entry of US-led international troops to Iraq, looting followed (Byman 2008: 603). As described by Shimko (2010: 175),
“Iraqis saw American soldiers perched on their tanks and
ighting vehicles watching looters haul off anything not bolted
down, apparently unable or unwilling to intervene. With only
two U.S. divisions in a city of ive million, it is not clear what
135
Kurtoglu Eskisar
they could have done even if they were inclined to act.”
The passivity of the Coalition troops to stop the street violence
turned out to bear an important and mostly negative effect on the
Iraqi perception of the war. In fact, one of the most serious barriers
against the success of the postwar statebuilding and anticorruption
efforts in Iraq has been the Iraqi perception of them. Unlike in other
conlict settings like Bosnia, except for the brief period at its beginning phase, many Iraqis did not regard the foreign intrusion to their
country as benign, or even tolerable. Rather, it was mostly seen as
“an invasion and occupation by Western, Christian, essentially Anglo-American powers that evoked powerful memories of previous
subjugation and of the nationalist struggles against Iraq’s former
overlords.” (Diamond 2006: 182) What made matters even worse
was the occupiers themselves seemed unaware of these sentiments,
until it was too late (ibid.: 181).
Despite the seriousness of the situation, not only the invading troops
remained passive to the ongoing destruction and havoc it created,
they also did not take action even after realizing that “the looting
was not a one-time breakdown of social order—that, in fact, an
elaborately organized, armed, and inanced resistance to the American occupation had emerged.” (ibid.: 175) Instead, such events were
mostly dismissed as transitory, or insigniicant, as the following
words of the former US Defense Secretary Donald Rumsfeld suggested: “Freedom’s untidy, and free people are free to make mistakes and commit crimes and do bad things ... They’re also free to
live their lives and do wonderful things. And that’s what’s going to
happen here.” (Loughlin 2003)
Aside from the extreme violence that surrounded all these events,
136
Foreign Aid and Corruption
what made them further problematic was their dubious contribution
to the increasing levels of “street crime,” which further limited social cohesion and hampered the long-term efforts for statebuilding
(O’Hanlon 2006). Meanwhile, from the perspective of corruption
and statebuilding, the impact of the violent conlicts that followed
the intervention in Iraq proved disastrous, as it had a seriously negative effect on the perceptions of the locals, who gradually came to
view “the United States standing by helpless or being a party to the
conlict.” (Byman 2008: 608)
6.12 The institutionalization of corruption in Iraq?
Ultimately the de-Baathification process did not open the path for a
new and well defined set of criteria to be followed for government
appointments either. This missing factor effectively meant that a
considerable amount of people who were sacked earlier for party
membership could get back into the various echelons of the state
without facing any serious setbacks (Sissons and Al-Saiedi 2013:
36). In fact, among its other effects, de-Baathification seems to have
also encouraged the growth of patronage networks:
“The law, along with weak governmental controls, rampant
patronage, and the effects of corruption and conlict, meant
that civil service personnel procedures slipped almost entirely
out of government control and into the hands of those with the
most extensive patronage networks.” (Sissons and Al-Saiedi
2013: 23)
De-Baathiication, followed by the growing polarization of sectarian factions supported by militias within the different parts of the
Iraqi administration not only further deteriorated its already fragile
foundations, but also decreased its overall eficiency and promoted
137
Kurtoglu Eskisar
the rise of corruption into a political goal in itself (SIGIR 2013: 13;
Kroft 2008: 2). During the period when the new Iraqi constitution
was written and general elections subsequently followed in 2005,
sectarian tensions reached new heights which, among its other side
effects, also led to the employment of an excess number of personnel based on patronage links (Sissons and Al-Saiedi 2013: 15).
While discussing the roots and effects of corruption in Iraq, observers remain pessimistic about its remediation in the foreseeable
future, mainly due to its systemic characteristics (Kroft 2008: 2).
Behind this doubt lies the observation that more often than not, the
misuse of funds in reconstruction efforts in Iraq are intimately interwoven with political corruption, and those who are involved in the
network keep each other’s secrets (Bassem 2015). As a result, “[t]
he system cannot be reformed by the government because it would
be striking at the very mechanism by which it rules. State institutions for combating corruption have been systematically defanged,
marginalised or intimidated.” (Cockburn 2013)
6.13 Conclusion
Similar to other postwar settings like Afghanistan and Bosnia that
are earlier covered in this book, despite some successes, attempts to
eradicate or at least weaken corruption in Iraq have largely proven
unsuccessful. The invasion of Iraq and its subsequent foreign-led reconstruction efforts have generally failed to achieve any signiicant
results. The overall lack of infrastructure or the serious shortcomings of what is already available in the country are also regarded as
a major reason behind the ubiquity of corruption in Iraq (UNODC
Iraq 2013: 12) In retrospect, it is possible to explain a considerable
amount of the economic failure of the Iraqi state and its consequent
138
Foreign Aid and Corruption
problems with security vulnerability, exacerbated by the administrative disarray due to the mismanaged de-Baathiication process,
crowned by the decisions undertaken by the CPA during the initial
period following the invasion (Arato 2009: 51).
Instead of helping the Iraqis as were their original claim, some
scholars contend that the true goal of international actors like USA
in rebuilding the Iraqi state and ighting corruption was to fulill
their national interests and foreign policy goals. Whyte (2007: 164),
for instance, claims that
“counter-corruption rhetoric has been a legitimating narrative
for the neoliberal transformation of the economy. The CPA
and interim Iraqi governments legitimized neoliberal reforms
as a means of breaking from an era of government theft and
patronage. They did nothing of the sort, but merely replaced
Saddam’s nepotism with a new structure of elites and a system
of patronage and favoritism.”
Whyte (2007: 159) has also drawn some similarities between the
economic reconstruction efforts in Iraq and the earlier neoliberal
reforms undertaken in places like Chile and Indonesia. In proof,
the radical measures implemented by the CPA are given, which removed all protectionist policies aimed at local producers and laborers, and aided the privatization of public resources (ibid.). Starting
reconstruction efforts without ensuring nationwide stability and
security, however, decreased eficiency and the legitimacy of the
new built state, and overall increased the gravitation towards corrupt activities.
Other observers, however, reject that all postwar statebuilding ef-
139
Kurtoglu Eskisar
forts in Iraq had an ulterior agenda. While discussing the transfer
of money to Iraq immediately after the invasion, some authors, for
instance, have also noted the good intentions of the Coalition: “The
money was meant to demonstrate the invaders’ good intentions and
boost the Iraqi economy ... But it also fuelled a cycle of corruption
left over from Saddam Hussein’s rule.” (Borger and Pallister 2006)
As the overall postwar reconstruction efforts in Iraq suggest, when
the donors are perceived to gain from their acts, their reform attempts are unlikely to produce the intended results. Following the
international coalition’s intervention, the job of rebuilding the war
damaged or destroyed structures were mostly given to a select few
US companies. This preference, combined with the general failure
to advance the living conditions of most of the Iraqi society later has
seriously weakened the credibility of the international community
in that country (Le Billon 2005: 686).
140
Foreign Aid and Corruption
CHAPTER 7
CONCLUSION: QUO VADIS FOREIGN
AID—AND CORRUPTION?
The ongoing debates on the causes and effects of corruption are
unlikely to end anytime soon. Aside from its theoretical implications, such a state of affairs is also significant news for regions that
are reported to harbor such activities. Notwithstanding the corrosive
effects of corruption on states and societies, Underkufler (2009:
41) argues that it is probably not the key or sole factor behind state
failure and related problems. A closer look at Afghanistan, Bosnia
and Iraq, as covered in this book, supports this conclusion.
Treating corruption as a merely cultural phenomenon or a technical
problem with uniform characteristics across the globe increases the
risk of overlooking its diverse functions under different settings.42
In fact, based on the arguments and country synopses covered in this
book, it is possible to conclude that the leading factors behind corruption in post-conlict societies cannot be explained only by cultural factors. As numerous examples (ranging from Afghanistan to
Bosnia) suggest, corruption can become a significant component of
governance, serving a variety of purposes for a large and diverse set
of actors. While discussing the leading factors that generated cor42 Smith (2007: 35), for instance, argues that the Nigerian culture is “as much a
‘culture against corruption’ as it is a ‘culture of corruption.’”
141
Kurtoglu Eskisar
rupt activities in the Balkans, Sioussiouras and Vavouras (2012:97)
boldly state that “[i]n an extreme but plausible scenario, what we
are dealing with is an administrative mechanism that does not work
unless one contributes the necessary ‘supplement.’” As Goodhand
(2008:419) argues in the case of Afghanistan, another land torn apart
by numerous conlicts and long-time recipient of foreign aid, labeling the fight against corruption as a “Western crusade” and tossing
it aside in post-conlict settings is likely to miss the cry rising from
these countires to eradicate it. At the same time, undertaking austere
campaigns without understanding the exact role of corrupt activities
in post-conlict politics or strengthening those institutions that form
the backbone of democracies is unlikely to generate results that will
satisfy all involved players in such regions in the long run.
While not covered in this book, the unexplored effects and functions
of corruption in the countries used as examples here are therefore worth further introspection. Given the paradoxes that riddle the
current administrations in Afghanistan, Bosnia and Iraq, dismissing
corruption as a merely criminal activity also neglects its function as
a survival mechanism for involved actors. In a World Bank survey,
for instance, Bosnian respondents admitted that not getting involved in a corrupt behavior like bribery can lead to isolation or even
mobbing (World Bank 2000: 20). Similar sentiments were echoed
by the Iraqi public servants, as mentioned in the previous chapter.
Furthermore, notwithstanding its negative effects, certain forms of
corruption in economics and politics also seemed to contribute to
building social ties in Bosnia (Divjak and Pugh 2008: 374).
Since the 1990’s, most western donors have been left facing a dilemma. The neoliberal teachings of development argue that privatization and reduction of state power, coupled with the adoption of free
142
Foreign Aid and Corruption
market economy, is needed for faster and more efficient economic
development. In these settings, a lean state with limited interfering
power over budding market economy is regarded as key. The idea is
that once economic efficiency is reached and development ensues,
corruption networks are likely to become redundant and eventually
dissipate. The neoliberal approach to corruption has taken further
strength from the fact that in many post-conlict settings—including
the three countries examined in this study—corruption was already
endemic prior to the start of hostilities, sometimes constituting a
source of conlict in and of itself.
While scholars disagree on the reasons that motivate aid in international relations—norms diffusion, altruism or self-interest—they
generally concur that its recipients often do not benefit from the
intended results. In order to empower the center, international aid
(following the neoliberal teachings) provides universal or generic prescriptions on how to build the institutions associated with
a functional state. Accepting little input from local actors while
prescribing numerous reforms, the donors often miss, neglect or
simply underestimate the distributional consequences of the new
institutions and regulations that accompany statebuilding efforts on
different portions of post-conlict societies. Worse, many times the
foreign dictated or recommended reforms exacerbate the already
existing imbalances between conlicting factions, which frequently
evokes the outbreak of hostilities earlier.
The problem is, many post-conlict societies either do not have
functioning states with centralized powers (e.g. Bosnia and Herzegovina) or posess weak poltical centers where capbilities are severely reduced (e.g. Afghanistan and Iraq). This is especially true in
the periphery or those portions of society which do not consider
143
Kurtoglu Eskisar
themselves as part of the center. The agreements that end the conflicts in these settings primarily focus on halting violence; as such
they tend to concentrate on wartime balances and other complex
factors, such as military capabilities and inter-group dynamics that
would pacify all involved parties.
A remarkable characteristic traced in all three cases discussed earlier is the international community’s insistence to stick to general
guidelines that were expected to work universally. Without making
an in-depth analysis of the pros and cons present in the existing
institutions, the international donors in all cases requested removal
and replacement of existing regimes with their own requested or
downright mandated administrative structures (e.g. the health organization in Afghanistan, the Bureau in Bosnia, and the references
to the post World War II statebuilding experiences of Germany and
Japan during the reconstruction of Iraq). To a certain level, in all of
these examples, the international community’s insistence on requiring its own brand of institutions makes sense. In all of these countries, time was considered to work against the respective societies;
peace was fragile. The donors were preoccupied with keeping the
peace at all costs, and thus regarded the in-depth assessment of existing institutions as hazardous to the perceived overall success of
their aid campaigns.
Meanwhile, the donors’ general lack of knowledge regarding the
recipient countries’ societies further exacerbated already existing
issues and problems,and misled the aid goals. Furthermore, in virtually all three cases, the state was either collapsed (e.g. Afghanistan),
nonexistent (e.g. Bosnia), or simply written off as illegitimate by the
international community (e.g. Iraq). Thus there was reason to sus144
Foreign Aid and Corruption
pect the health, viability, and impeccability (in terms of corruption)
of any existing institutions.
From the perspective of international actors, the existing infrastructure in all cases mostly represented a nest of ineficiency and corruption that needed to be replaced at all costs. It was thus logical to
conclude that starting with a clean slate, which would pay heed to
all segments of the respective society and comply with the existing
favored approach to development and governance (i.e. neoliberalism), was preferable to existing structures.
Disregarding existing local institutions in favor of the international
blueprints may have also worked better if more efforts had been
made to involve local actors. In all of these cases, however, the
international donors mostly ignored native participants and their
demands on the grounds of being nationalistic, secessionist, nonsecular and corrupt, among other things. In those cases where the
local elites were successfully incorporated, it often created more
problems than solutions: some were incorporated because they either played a signiicant role during the war era or their disinclusion
could prove hazardous to peacekeeping. Others were incorporated
to the new administration as they were seen to share the Western
ideals of statebuilding or economic development (or, at least not
stand directly against it). In many instances, the local elite, who
were known to be corrupt or otherwise inappropriate for the intended goals of the international community, were still left intact,
as disturbing the status quo was seen as too costly in terms of the
overall image of the donors.
Finally, the experiences of all three countries examined here suggest that successful state building and anticorruption campaigns rely
on extended involvement on behalf of the international community.
145
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Donor failure to fulill earlier aid pledges negatively affected the
locals and reduced their faith in the achievability or durability of the
preset goals. As Afghanistan exempliies, without reassurance that
the international community is committed to supporting the country
long-term, the local elite may engage in predatory behavior, lining
their pockets at the expense of local welfare and development.
In retrospect, the end results have proven ineficient at best and disastrous at worst (depending on the reader’s level of optimism) for
statebuilding and the eradication of corruption in the countries discussed above. Learning from the past mistakes of donors in these
countries will help increase the eficacy of future international aid.
146
Foreign Aid and Corruption
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Abrahamsen, Rita. (2000) Disciplining Democracy: Developm Discourse and Good Governance in Africa, London: Zed Books.
Ahmed, Azam. (31 January 2015) “Taliban Justice Gains Favor as
Oficial Afghan Courts Fail,” The New York Times, http://www.nytimes.com/2015/02/01/world/asia/taliban-justice-gains-favor-as-oficial-afghan-courts-fail.html?_r=0 (accessed on 03 February 2015)
Akhand, Haiz A. and Kanhayal Gupta. (2002) Foreign Aid in the
Twenty-First Century, New York: Springer Science and Business
Media.
Allen, John R. (30 April 2014). “Testimony,” A Transformation: Afghanistan Beyond 2014, Subcommittee on Near Eastern and South
and Central Asian Affairs, United States Senate Committee on Foreign Relations, http://www.foreign.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/Allen_Testimony.pdf. (accessed on 08 September 2014).
Anderson, John Lee. (15 November 2004) “Out on the Street,” The
New Yorker, http://www.newyorker.com/magazine/2004/11/15/outon-the-street (accessed on 18 April 2015).
Anderson, Liam and Gareth Stansield. (2004) The Future of Iraq:
Dictatorship, Democracy, or Division?, New York, N.Y.: Palgrave
Macmillan.
147
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Apaza, Carmen R. (January 2009) “Measuring Governance and
Corruption through the Worldwide Governance Indicators: Critiques, Responses, and Ongoing Scholarly Discussion,” PS: Political Science and Politics, v. 42, no. 1, pp. 139-143.
Arato, Andrew. (2009) Constitution Making Under Occupation:
The Politics of Imposed Revolution in Iraq, New York: Columbia
University Press.
Arsenijevic, Damir. (28 February 2014) “After 22 years of being
bullied Bosnians are desperate, and must protest,” The Guardian,
http://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2014/feb/28/bosniaprotest-citizens-change-corruption (accessed on 05 February 2015).
Bader, Florian, Patrick von Maravić, B. Guy Peters and Michael
Tauch. (December 2013) “Corruption, method choice, and constraints—exploring methodological pluralism in corruption research,” Zeitschrift für Vergleichende Politikwissenschaft/ Comparative Governance and Politics, volume 7, supplement 1, special
issue 3, pp.13–32.
Baldwin, David A. (April 1969) “Foreign Aid, Intervention, and Inluence,” World Politics, v. 21, no. 3, pp. 425-447.
Banerjee, Abhijit V. and Rohini Pande (2009). Parochial Politics:
Ethnic Preferences and Politician Corruption, http://economics.
mit.edu/iles/3872 (accessed on 09.03.2014).
Barratt, Bethany. (2008) Human Rights and Foreign Aid: For love
or money? London: Routledge.
148
Foreign Aid and Corruption
Bassem, Wassim. (25 February 2015) “Iraq’s corruption continues
unchecked,” (trans. Sami-Joe Abboud), Iraq Pulse http://www.almonitor.com/pulse/originals/2015/02/iraq-contracting-corruptionreconstruction-projects.html# (accessed on 12 April 2015).
Bayliss, Kate. (August 2005) Post-conlict Privatisation: A Review
of Developments in Serbia and Bosnia Herzegovina, ESAU Working Paper no.12, ile:///C:/Users/gul/Desktop/bayliss%20privatization%20in%20bosnia%20and%20servia.pdf (accessed on 16 February 2015).
Bearce, David H. and Daniel C. Tirone. (July 2010) “Foreign Aid
Effectiveness and the Strategic Goals of Donor Governments, The
Journal of Politics, v. 72, no. 3, pp. 837-851.
Bedirhanoglu, Pinar. (2007) “The Neoliberal Discourse on Corruption as a Means of Consent Building: Relections from Post-Crisis
Turkey,” Third World Quarterly, v. 28, no. 7, pp. 1239-1254.
Begić, Zlatan (2014). “War, Peace and the Protests,” Unbribable Bosnia and Herzegovina The Fight for the Commons, Damir
Arsenijević (ed.), Baden-Baden: Nomos, pp.35-45.
Belloni, Roberto. (2007) State Building and International Intervention in Bosnia, London: Routledge. Bolongaita, Emil.
(January 2005) Controlling Corruption In Post-Conlict Countries, Kroc Institute Occasional Paper, no.26: OP: 2, http://
www.google.com/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&frm=1&source
=web&cd=1&ved=0CDQQFjAA&url=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.
u4.no%2Frecommended-reading%2Fcontrolling-corruption-inpost-conlict-countries%2Fdownload&ei=_dxQUcnZJ4LmOvOz
gMAJ&usg=AFQjCNGFuDmoO3l7mh5tuRQYxl8H73gbBw accessed on 25.03.2013).
149
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Borger, Julian, and David Pallister. (02 December 2006) “Corruption: the ‘second insurgency’ costing $4bn a year,” The Guardian,
http://www.theguardian.com/world/2006/dec/02/usa.iraq (accessed
on 20 April 2015).
Boyle, Michael. (11 March 2013) “How the US public was defrauded by the hidden cost of the Iraq war,” The Guardian, http://www.
theguardian.com/commentisfree/2013/mar/11/us-public-defraudedhidden-cost-iraq-war (accessed on 19 April 2015).
Bracking, Sarah (ed.). (2007) Corruption and Development: The
Anti-Corruption Campaigns, Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.
Bull, Martin J. and James L. Newell. (2003) Corruption in Contemporary Politics, Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.
Bunn, Matthew. (2009) “Corruption and Nuclear Proliferation,”
Corruption, Global Security, and World Order, Robert I. Rotberg
(ed.), pp.124-166.
Byman, Daniel. (October-December 2008) “An Autopsy of the Iraq
Debacle: Policy Failure or Bridge Too Far?,” Security Studies, v.17,
no.4, pp.599-643.
Calderisi, Robert. (2006) The Trouble with Africa: Why Foreign Aid
Isn’t Working, New Haven: Yale University Press.
Carnahan, Michael, Nick Manning, Richard Bontjer, and Stéphane
Guimbert (eds.). (2004) Reforming Fiscal and Economic Management in Afghanistan, Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.
Chandler, David. (2010) “The EU and Southeastern Europe: the rise
of post-liberal governance,” Third World Quarterly, v. 31, no. 1, pp.
69–85.
150
Foreign Aid and Corruption
________. (Spring/Summer 2006) “State-Building in Bosnia: The
Limits of ‘Informal Trusteeship,’” International Journal of Peace
Studies, v.11, no.1, pp.17-38.
________. (2000) Bosnia: Faking Democracy After Dayton, 2nd edition, London: Pluto Press.
Chang, Eric C. C. and Yun-han Chu. (May 2006) “Corruption and
Trust: Exceptionalism in Asian Democracies?”, The Journal of Politics, v. 68, no. 2, pp. 259-271.
Chayes, Sarah. (6 April 2014) “The Military Must Hunt Corruption, Not Just Terrorists,” Defense One, http://www.defenseone.
com/ideas/2014/04/military-must-hunt-corruption-not-justterrorists/81973/?oref=d-river (accessed on 03 February 2015)
Cockburn, Patrick. (19 April 2015) “From Iraq to Libya and Syria: The wars that come back to haunt us,” The Independent, http://
www.independent.co.uk/voices/from-iraq-to-libya-and-syria-thewars-that-come-back-tohaunt-us-10187065.html (accessed on 19
April 2015).
________. (04 March 2013) “Iraq 10 years on: How Baghdad became a city of corruption,” The Independent, http://www.independent.co.uk/news/world/middle-east/iraq-10-years-on-how-baghdad-became-a-city-of-corruption-8520038.html (accessed on 19
April 2015).
________. (28 June 2009) “How bribery became a way of life in
Iraq,” The Independent, http://www.independent.co.uk/news/world/
middle-east/how-bribery-became-a-way-of-life-in-iraq-1722466.
html (accessed on 19 April 2015).
151
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Cockcroft, Laurence. (Spring 2010) “Global Corruption: An Untamed Hydra,” World Policy Journal, v.27, no.1, pp. 21-28.
Coles, Kimberley. (2007) Democratic Designs: International Intervention and Electoral Practices in Postwar Bosnia-Herzegovina,
Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.
Collier, Paul. (2010) Wars, Guns, and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places, Harper Collins e-books.
Cornell, Agnes. (2013) “Does regime type matter for the impact
of democracy aid on democracy?, Democratization, v. 20, no. 4,
pp.642–667.
Damania, Richard, Fredriksson, Per G, and Muthukumara Mani.
(2004) “The persistence of corruption and regulatory compliance
failures: Theory and evidence,” Public Choice, v.121, pp.363-390.
De Launey, Guy. (2 January 2015) “Bosnians look to dump bafling politics after protests,” http://www.bbc.com/news/world-europe-30599338 (accessed on 05 February 2015.
Diamond, Larry. (2008) “Foreign Aid in the National Interest: The
Importance of Democracy and Governance,” Foreign Aid and Foreign Policy Lessons for the Next Half-Century, Louis A. Picard,
Robert Groelsema and Terry F. Buss (eds.), pp.61-85.
__________. (2006) “What Went Wrong and Right in Iraq,” NationBuilding Beyond Afghanistan and Iraq, Francis Fukuyama (ed.),
Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.
152
Foreign Aid and Corruption
Divjak, Boris and Pugh, Boris. (June 2008) “The Political Economy
of Corruption in Bosnia and Herzegovina,” International Peacekeeping, v.15, no.3, pp.373–386.
Dobbins, James, John G. McGinn, Keith Crane et al. (2003) America’s Role in Nation-Building: From Germany to Iraq, Santa Monica:
Rand, available at http://www.rand.org/pubs/monograph_reports/
MR1753.html. (accessed on 30 September 2014)
Doig, Alan and Tisne, Martin. (2009) “A Candidate for Relegation?
Corruption, Governance Approaches and the (Re) Construction of
Post-War States,” Public Administration and Development, v.29,
pp.374-386.
Dorronsoro, Gilles. (2005) Revolution Unending Afghanistan: 1979
to the Present, John King (trans.), London: Hurst and Co.
Dufield, Mark. (2010) “The Development-Security Nexus in Historical Perspective: Governing the World of Peoples,” Challenging the Aid Paradigm: Western Currents and Asian Alternatives.
Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.
Easterly, William (ed.). (2008) Reinventing Foreign Aid, Cambridge: The MIT Press.
Eigen, Peter. (2009) “A Coalition to Combat Corruption: TI, EITI,
and Civil Society, (ed.). Corruption, Global Security, and World Order, Robert I. Rotberg (ed.), Cambridge: World Peace Foundation,
pp.416-429.
Esman, Milton J. (2004) Beyond Reconstruction in Afghanistan:
Lessons from Development Experience, John D. Montgomery
and Dennis A. Rondinelli (eds.), New York: Palgrave Macmillan,
pp.132-155.
153
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Ghanizada. (13 May 2012) “Anti-corruption protests erupt in Helmand and Takhar,” Khaama, http://www.khaama.com/anti-corruption-protests-erupt-in-helmand-and-takhar-247 (accessed on 02
February 2015).
Goodhand, Jonathan. (June 2008) “Corrupting or Consolidating the
Peace? The Drugs Economy and Post-conlict Peacebuilding in Afghanistan,” International Peacekeeping, v.15, no.3, pp.405–423.
Gordy, Eric. (2014) “From Antipolitics to Alterpolitics: Subverting
Ethnokleptocracy in Bosnia and Herzegovina,” Unbribable Bosnia
and Herzegovina: The Fight for the Commons, pp.111-118.
Fearon, James D. and David D. Laitin. (Spring 2004) “Neotrusteeship and the Problem of Weak States,” International Security, v.28,
no. 4, pp. 5-43.
Feldman, Noah. (2004) What We Owe Iraq. Princeton: Princeton
University Press.
Garamone, Jim. (31 October 2014) “DoD Authorizes War on Terror Award for Inherent Resolve Ops,” DoD News, http://www.defense.gov/news/newsarticle.aspx?id=123542 (accessed on 22 April
2015).
Giatzidis, Emil. (September 2007) “The Challenge of Organized
Crime in the Balkans and the Political and Economic Implications,”
Journal of Communist Studies and Transition Politics, v.23, no.3,
pp.327–351.
Giovanni, Janine Di. (13 February 2014) “Bosnia’s Corrupt Rulers
Hit by an Angry ‘Citizen Tsunami,’” Newsweek, (http://www.newsweek.com/2014/02/14/bosnias-corrupt-rulers-hit-angry-citizen-tsunami-245526.html) (accessed on 16 February 2015).
154
Foreign Aid and Corruption
Goldsmith, Arthur A. (2007) “Does nation building work? Reviewing the record,” Governance in Post-Conlict Societies: Rebuilding
fragile states, Derick W. Brinkerhoff (ed.), London: Routledge,
pp.25-44.
________. (Winter 2001), “Foreign Aid and Statehood in Africa,”
International Organization, v.55, no. 1, pp. 123-148.
Groves, Leslie and Rachel Hinton (ed.). (2004) Inclusive Aid:
Changing Power and Relationships in International Development,
London: Earthscan.
Heineman Jr., Ben W. and Fritz Heimann. (May - June 2006) “The
Long War against Corruption,” Foreign Affairs, v. 85, no. 3 pp. 7586.
Heller, Nathaniel. (2009) “Deining and Measuring Corruption:
Where Have We Come From, Where Are We Now, and What Matters For the Future?,” Corruption, Global Security, and World Order, Robert I. Rotberg, (ed.), Cambridge: World Peace Foundation.
Hislope, Robert. (2011) “Corrupt Exchange in Divided Societies,”
Transnational Actors in Central and East European Transitions,
Mitchell A. Orenstein, Stephen R. Bloom, and Nicole Lindstrom
(eds), Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh, Digital Research Library, pp.142-161. (http://digital.library.pitt.edu/cgi-bin/t/text/textidx?c=pittpress;cc=pittpress;q1=ambiguous;rgn=full%20text;view
=toc;idno=31735062135821) (accessed on 15 December 2014)
“How Iraq’s ‘ghost soldiers’ helped ISIL.” (11 December 2014) aljazeera.com, http://www.aljazeera.com/news/middleeast/2014/12/
how-iraq-ghost-soldiers-helped-isil-2014121072749979252.html
(accessed on 26 April 2015).
155
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Hussein, Ahmed. (7 January 2015) “Fighting corruption within
military institution must coincide with ighting ISIL, says MP,”
iraqinews.com, http://www.iraqinews.com/baghdad-politics/ighting-corruption-within-military-institution-must-coincide-withighting-isil-says-mp/, (accessed on 26 April 2015).
Ilievski, Zoran. (March 2007) Country Speciic Report on Actors
and Processes of Ethno-Mobilization, Violent Conlicts and Consequences: Macedonia, Sixth Framework Program, MIRICO: Human
and Minority Rights in the Life Cycle of Ethnic Conlicts, Bozen:
European Academy http://www.eurac.edu/en/research/autonomies/
minrig/Documents/Mirico/Macedonia%20Report.pdf (accessed on
5 May 2015).
International Budget Partnership. (2012) Open Budget Survey 2012,
http://internationalbudget.org/wp-content/uploads/OBI2012-Report-English.pdf. (accessed on 28 January 2015)
International Crisis Group. (17 November 2010) Reforming Afghanistan’s Broken Judiciary, Asia Report No.195, http://www.crisisgroup.org/~/media/Files/asia/south-asia/afghanistan/195%20Reforming%20Afghanistans%20Broken%20Judiciary.ashx (accessed
on 02 February 2015)
________. (7 August 2001) Bosnia’s Precarious Economy: Still Not
Open For Business, ICG Balkans Report, no.115, Sarajevo/Brussels, downloaded at http://www.crisisgroup.org/~/media/Files/europe/Bosnia%2041.pdf (accessed on 16 August 2014)
Hattori, Tomohisa. (April 2003) “The moral politics of foreign aid,
Review of International Studies, v.29, no.02, pp. 229 – 247.
156
Foreign Aid and Corruption
Houston, Douglas A. (Fall 2007) “Can Corruption Ever Improve An
Economy?” Cato Journal, v. 27, no. 3, pp.325-342.
Huntington, Samuel P. (Winter 1970-1971) “Foreign Aid for What
and for Whom,” Foreign Policy, no. 1, pp. 161-189.
________. (1968) Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Jakobi, Anja P. (December 2013) “The changing global norm of
anti-corruption: from bad business to bad government,” Zeitschrift
für Vergleichende Politikwissenschaft/ Comparative Governance
and Politics, volume 7, supplement 1, special issue 3, pp. 243-264.
Johnson, Roberta Ann (ed.) (2004) “The United States: In Search of
the Perfect Law,” The Struggle Against Corruption: A Comparative
Study, pp.21-52, New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Johnson, Roberta Ann (ed.) and Shalendra Sharma (2004) “About
Corruption,” The Struggle Against Corruption: A Comparative
Study, pp.1-20.
Johnson, Chris and Leslie Jolyon. (2008) Afghanistan: The mirage
of peace, London: Zed Books.
Johnston, Michael. (2005) Syndromes of Corruption: Wealth, Power, and Democracy, New York: Cambridge University Press.
Judah, Tim. (07 February 2014) “Bosnian protests: A Balkan
Spring?,” BBC News, http://www.bbc.com/news/world-europe-26093160, (accessed on 14 February 2015).
157
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Juncos, Ana E. (November 2005) “The EU’s post-Conlict Intervention in Bosnia and Herzegovina: (re)Integrating the Balkans and/or
(re)Inventing the EU?”, Southeast European Politics, v.6, no.2, pp.
88-108.
Kaplan, Lawrence F. and William Kristol. (2003) The War Over
Iraq: Saddam’s Tyranny and America’s Mission, San Francisco: Encounter Books.
Kaufmann, Daniel and Pedro C. Vicente. (October 2005) “Legal
Corruption,” (2nd Draft) unpublished paper available at http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTWBIGOVANTCOR/Resources/Legal_Corruption.pdf (accessed on 15 December 2014).
Khan, Mushtaq Husain. (2006) “Determinants of corruption in developing countries: the limits of conventional economic analysis,”
International handbook on the economics of corruption, Susan
Rose-Ackerman (ed.), Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd.,
pp.216-246.
Khan, Mushtaq Husain. (2004) “Evaluating the emerging Palestinian state: ‘Good governance’ versus ‘transformation potential,’”
Mushtaq Husain Khan, George Giacaman and Inge Amundsen
(eds.), State Formation in Palestine: Viability and governance during a social transformation, London: Routledge Curzon, pp.13-63.
Kroft, Steve. (11 April 2008) “Iraq: State of Corruption,”
cbsnews.com, http://www.cbsnews.com/news/iraq-state-of-corruption-11-04-2008/ (accessed on 18 April 2015).
Kurtoglu Eskisar, Gul M. and Aysegul Komsuoglu. (2015) “A Critical Assessment of the Transformative Power of EU Reforms on Reducing Corruption in the Balkans,” Journal of Southeast European
and Black Sea Studies, DOI:10.1080/14683857.2015.1015315,
158
Foreign Aid and Corruption
Lancaster, Carol (2008). George Bush’s Foreign Aid: Transformation or Chaos?, Washington, D.C: Center for Global Development.
Latii, Ali M. (16 November 2012) “EU halts Afghan judicial aid
over corruption,” Aljazeera, http://www.aljazeera.com/indepth/features/2012/11/2012111510557286862.html (accessed on 02 February 2015)
Le Billon, Philippe (ed.). (2005) The Geopolitics of Resource Wars:
Resource Dependence, Governance and Violence, London: Frank
Cass.
Leff, Nathaniel H. (November 1964) “Economic Development
through Bureaucratic Corruption,” American Behavioral Scientist,
v.8 no.3, pp.8-14.
Leys, Colin. (August 1965) “What is the Problem About Corruption?”, The Journal of Modern African Studies, v. 3, no. 2, pp. 215230.
Lister, Sarah, and Andrew Wilder. (2007) “Subnational administration and state building: lessons from Afghanistan,” Governance
in Post-Conlict Societies: Rebuilding fragile states, Derick W.
Brinkerhoff (ed.), London: Routledge, pp.241-257.
Loughlin, Sean. (12 April 2003) “Rumsfeld on looting in Iraq: ‘Stuff
happens’ Administration asking countries for help with security,”
CNN.com, http://edition.cnn.com/2003/US/04/11/sprj.irq.pentagon/
(accessed on 15 April 2015).
McMahon, Patrice C., and Jon Western. (September/October 2009)
“The Death of Dayton How to Stop Bosnia From Falling Apart,”
Foreign Affairs, http://www.foreignaffairs.com/print/65244 (accessed on 25 February 2015).
159
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Maipose, Gervase S. “Aid Abuse and Mismanagement in Africa:
Problems of Accountability, Transparency and Ethical Leadership,”
Corruption and Development in Africa: Lessons from Country
Case-Studies, Kempe Ronald Hope, Sr. and Bornwell C. Chikulo
(eds.), pp.87-103 pp.87-103, Houndmills: Macmillan.
Maley, William. (2006). Rescuing Afghanistan, Sydney: University
of New South Wales Press.
Malone, David M. (2006) The International Struggle Over Iraq:
Politics in the UN Security Council 1980–2005, New York: Oxford
University Press.
Manzetti, Luigi and Carole J. Wilson. (August 2007) “Why Do Corrupt Governments Maintain Public Support?, Comparative Political
Studies, v.40, no.8 pp.949-970.
Marjit, Sugata and Vivekananda Mukherjee. (2007) “Poverty, Utilization of Foreign Aid and Corruption: The Role of Redistributive
Politics,” Theory and Practice of Foreign Aid (Frontiers of Economics and Globalization, Volume 1), Sajal Lahiri (ed.), Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp.17 – 29.
Marquette, Heather. (2011) “Donors, State Building and Corruption: lessons from Afghanistan and the implications for aid policy,”
Third World Quarterly, v. 32, no. 10, 2011, pp.1871–1890.
Méon, Pierre-Guillaume and Khalid Sekkat (January 2005) “Does
Corruption Grease or Sand the Wheels of Growth?”, Public Choice,
v. 122, no. 1/2, pp. 69-97.
Milner, Helen, and Dustin Tingley. (2013) “Public Opinion and Foreign Aid: A Review Essay,” International Interactions, v.39, no.3,
pp.389-401.
160
Foreign Aid and Corruption
Mironov, Maxim. (14 November 2005) “Bad Corruption, Good
Corruption and Growth,” unpublished paper available at http://
www.mironov.fm/research/corruption.pdf (accessed on 11 November 2014).
Misdaq, Nabi. (2006) Afghanistan: Political frailty and external interference, London: Routledge.
Mohammed, Riyadh. (03 December 2014) “Iraq’s Two-headed War:
ISIS and Corruption,” The Fiscal Times, http://www.theiscaltimes.
com/2014/12/03/Iraq-s-Two-headed-War-ISIS-and-Corruption (accessed on 17 April 2015).
Mohseni, Nader. (March 2012) “Corruption in Afghanistan,” Resource Material Series No.86, Work Product of the 14th UNAFEI
UNCAC Training Program, http://www.unafei.or.jp/english/pdf/
RS_No86/No86_19PA_Mohseni.pdf
Morgan, Matthew J. (2007) A Democracy is Born: An Insider’s
Account of the Battle Against Terrorism in Afghanistan, Westport:
Praeger Security International.
Morgenthau, Hans. (June 1962) “A Political Theory of Foreign
Aid,” The American Political Science Review, v.56, no. 2, pp. 301309.
Mungiu-Pippidi, Alina. (January 2013) “Controlling Corruption
Through Collective Action,” Journal of Democracy, v.24, no.1,
pp.101-115.
161
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Muno, Wolfgang. (23 August 2010) “Conceptualizing and Measuring Clientelism,” Paper to be presented at the workshop “Neopatrimonialism in Various World Regions,” GIGA (http://www.
politik.uni-mainz.de/cms/Dateien/Clientelism__GIGA_paper_
neopat_workshop_Muno.pdf) (accessed on 11 December 2014)
Muscat, Robert J. (2004) “Lessons from Post-Conlict Aid Experience,” Beyond Reconstruction in Afghanistan: Lessons from Development Experience, John D. Montgomery and Dennis A. Rondinelli
(eds.), New York: Palgrave Macmillan, pp.93-112.
NATO, ISAF’s mission in Afghanistan (2001-2014). (2015) http://
www.nato.int/cps/en/natohq/topics_69366.htm (accessed on 29
January 2015).
Nelen, Hans. (2014) “Corruption Dutch Style,” Organized Crime,
Corruption and Crime Prevention: Essays in Honor of Ernesto U.
Savona, Stefano, Caneppele and Francesco Calderoni (eds.), Heidelberg: Springer, pp.159-168.
O’Hanlon, Michael E. (December 2004-January 2005) “Iraq Without a Plan,” Policy Review, http://www.hoover.org/research/iraqwithout-plan (accessed on 20 April 2015).
Palmer, Glenn and T. Clifton Morgan. (2006) A Theory of Foreign
Policy, Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Paris, Roland. (2004) At War’s End: Building Peace After Civil
Conlict, New York: Cambridge University Press.
Parker, Ned and Missy Ryan. (13 June 2014) “Iraqi military breakdown fueled by corruption, politics,” Reuters, http://www.reuters.
com/article/2014/06/13/us-iraq-security-military-analysis-idUSKBN0EO2FK20140613 (accessed on 20 April 2015).
162
Foreign Aid and Corruption
Peter, Tom. (20 September 2012) “Afghan president sacks Helmand governor,” The Guardian, http://www.theguardian.com/
world/2012/sep/20/afghan-president-sacks-helmand-governor (accessed on 02 February 2015)
Phillips, David L. (2010) “The Balkans’ Underbelly,” World Policy
Journal, pp.93-98.
Picard, Louis A., and Robert Groelsema. (2008) “U.S. Foreign Aid
Priorities: Goals for the Twenty-First Century,” Foreign Aid and
Foreign Policy Lessons for the Next Half-Century, Louis A. Picard,
Robert Groelsema and Terry F. Buss (eds.), Armonk, New York:
M.E. Sharpe.
Pond, Elizabeth. (2006) Endgame in the Balkans: Regime Change,
European Style, Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.
Pržulj, Živka and Svetolik Kostadinović. (September 2014) “Cultural Roots Of Corruption - The Case Of Western Balkans,” Mediterranean Journal of Social Sciences, vol.5, no.22, pp.467-478.
Quadir, Fahimul. (2013) “Rising donors and the New Narrative of
‘South-south’ Cooperation: What Prospects for Changing the Landscape of Development Assistance Programmes?, Third World Quarterly, v. 34. no, 2, pp. 321-338.
Radelet, Steven. (September-October 2003) “Bush and Foreign
Aid,” Foreign Affairs, 82: 5, pp. 104-117.
Reuters. (16 December 2014) “EU to aid Bosnia with $207 million in bid to spur reform,” Reuters, http://www.reuters.com/article/2014/12/16/us-bosnia-eu-idUSKBN0JU1XF20141216
(accessed on 24 February 2015)
163
Kurtoglu Eskisar
________. (10 September 2014) “Bosnian police arrest two ministers, 9 others on corruption charges,” Reuters, http://uk.reuters.
com/article/2014/09/10/uk-bosnia-arrest-minister-idUKKBN0H50UN20140910 (accessed on 08 February 2015)
Riechmann, Deb. (27 July 2012) “Afghanistan Corruption: Karzai
Issues Ambitious List Of Reforms To Battle Cronyism,” The World
Post, http://www.hufingtonpost.com/2012/07/27/afghan-presidentissues-decree-to-curb-corruption_n_1709734.html (accessed on 02
February 2012)
Ricks, Thomas E. (2006) Fiasco: The American Military Adventure
in Iraq, New York: The Penguin Press.
Robb, Caroline (2004). “Power Relations in the History of Aid,”
Inclusive Aid: Changing Power and Relationships in International
Development, Leslie Groves and Rachel Hinton (eds.), London:
Earthscan, pp.21-41.
Rogers, Paul. (2006) A War Too Far: Iraq, Iran and the New American Century, London: Pluto Press.
Rohde, David. (17 February 2014) “Has International Intervention Helped or Hurt Bosnia?”, The Atlantic, http://www.theatlantic.
com/international/archive/2014/02/has-international-interventionhelped-or-hurt-bosnia/283885/ (accessed on 08 February 2014)
Rose-Ackerman, Susan. (2009) “Corruption in the Wake of Domestic National Conlict,” Corruption, Global Security, and World Order, Robert Rotberg (ed.), Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution
Press, pp. 66-95.
164
Foreign Aid and Corruption
Rotberg, Robert I. (ed.). (2009) “How Corruption Compromises
World Peace and Stability,” Corruption, Global Security, and World
Order, pp.1-26.
________. (ed.). (2007) “Renewing the Afghan State,” Building A
New Afghanistan, pp.1-21, Cambridge: World Peace Organization.
Saltmarshe, Douglas, Dr. and Abhilash Medhi. (June 2011) Local
Governance in Afghanistan A View from the Ground, Afghanistan
Research and Evaluation Unit Synthesis Paper, http://www.areu.
org.af/Uploads/EditionPdfs/1114E%20Local%20Governance%20
in%20Afghanistan%20SP%202011.pdf (accessed on 06 February
2015)
Sarwary, Bilal. (2 February 2012) “Why Taliban are so strong
in Afghanistan,” BBC News, http://www.bbc.com/news/worldasia-16851949, (accessed on 29 January 2012)
Savun, Burcu and Daniel C. Tirone. (Summer 2012) “Exogenous
Shocks, Foreign Aid, and Civil War, International Organization,
v.66, pp. 363–393.
Schraeder, Peter J., Steven W. Hook and Bruce Taylor. (January
1998). “Clarifying the Foreign Aid Puzzle: A Comparison of American, Japanese, French, and Swedish Aid Flows,” World Politics,
v.50, no.2, pp. 294-323.
Shimko, Keith L. (2010) The Iraq Wars and America’s Military
Revolution, New York: Cambridge University Press.
Schudel, Carl Jan Willem. (August 2008) “Corruption and Bilateral
Aid: A Dyadic Approach Journal of Conlict Resolution, v.52, no.4,
pp.507-526.
165
Kurtoglu Eskisar
SIGIR. (March 2013) Learning from Iraq: A Final Report from the
Special Inspector Generalfor Iraq Reconstruction, http://www.globalsecurity.org/jhtml/jframe.html#http://www.globalsecurity.org/
military/library/report/2013/sigir-learning-from-iraq.pdf|||Learning
From Iraq: A Final Report from the Special Inspector General for
Iraq Reconstruction (accessed on 13 April 2015).
Sissons, Miranda and Abdulrazzaq Al-Saiedi. (March 2013) A Bitter
Legacy: Lessons of De-Baathii cation in Iraq, https://www.ictj.org/
sites/default/iles/ICTJ-Report-Iraq-De-Baathiication-2013-ENG.
pdf (accessed on 20 April 2015).
Smith, Daniel Jordan. (2007) A Culture of Corruption: Everyday
Deception and Popular Discontent in Nigeria, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Soubbotina, Tatyana P. (2004). Beyond Economic Growth: An Introduction to Sustainable Development (2nd Ed.), Washington, D.C:
The World Bank, http://www.worldbank.org/depweb/beyond/beyondco/beg_13.pdf (Accessed on 11 December 2014).
Sörensen, Jens Stilhoff (ed.). (2010) “Introduction: Reinventing
Development for the Twenty-First Century?,” Challenging the Aid
Paradigm: Western Currents and Asian Alternatives, Palgrave:
Macmillan, Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan, pp.1-24.
Special Inspector General for Afghanistan Reconstruction (SIGAR). (30 April 2014) Quarterly Report to Congress, http://www.
sigar.mil/pdf/quarterlyreports/2014-04-30qr.pdf (accessed on 02
February 2015)
166
Foreign Aid and Corruption
Stancati, Margherita and Habib Khan Totakhil. (02 October 2014)
“Afghan President Issues New Decree in Bank Fraud Case,” Wall
Street Journal, http://www.wsj.com/articles/afghan-president-issues-new-decree-in-bank-fraud-case-1412199021 (accessed on 02
February 2015)
Starr, S. Frederick. (2006) “Sovereignty and Legitimacy in Afghan
Nation-Building,” Nation-Building: Beyond Afghanistan and Iraq,
Francis Fukuyama (ed.), Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University
Press, pp.107-124.
Stone, Randall W. (January 2010) “Buying Inluence: Development
Aid between the Cold War and the War on Terror,” unpublished
working paper, http://www.rochester.edu/college/psc/stone/working_papers/buying_inluence.pdf (accessed on 03 February 2015)
Stubbs, Paul. (2001) Chapter 8, “’Social Sector’ or the Dimunition
of Social Policy? Regulating Welfare Regimes in Contemporary
Bosnia-Herzegovina,” International Support Policies to SouthEast European Countries: Lessons (Not) Learned in B-H, pp.95107, http://pdc.ceu.hu/archive/00002241/01/covered_ch_8.pdf (accessed on 10 March 2015).
Suhrke, Astri and Julia Buckmaster. (October 2006) “Aid, growth
and peace: a comparative analysis,” Conlict, Security and Development, v.6, no.3, pp.337-363.
Sun, Yan and Michael Johnston. (October 2009) “Does Democracy
Check Corruption? Insights from China and India,” Comparative
Politics, v.42, no.1, pp. 1-19.
167
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Swarts, Phillip (14 May 2014). “Afghanistan corruption still severe
problem, U.S. watchdog says,” The Washington Times, (http://www.
washingtontimes.com/news/2014/may/14/afghanistan-corruptionstill-severe-problem-us-wat/?page=all) (accessed on 05 September
2014)
Taffet, Jeffrey F. (2007) Foreign Aid as Foreign Policy: The Alliance for Progress in Latin America, New York: Routledge.
Taylor, Rob and Mirwais Harooni. (19 September 2012) “Afghanistan’s Karzai targets governors in anti-graft ight,” Reuters
(http://in.reuters.com/article/2012/09/19/afghanistan-corruptionidINDEE88I0CM20120919) accessed on 02 February 2015.
Travis, Rick. (2010) “Problems, Politics, and Policy Streams: A
Reconsideration US Foreign Aid Behavior toward Africa,” International Studies Quarterly, v.54, pp.797–821.
Treisman, Daniel, (2000) “The causes of corruption: a cross-national study,” Journal of Public Economics, v.76, no.3, pp.399 –457.
Stapenhurst, Rick, Martin Ulrich and Severin Strohal. (2006) “Introduction: Parliamentarians Fighting Corruption,” The Role of Parliament in Curbing Corruption, Rick Stapenhurst Niall Johnston and
Riccardo Pellizo, eds., Washington, DC: The World Bank, pp.1-10.
Underkufler, Laura S. (2009) “Deining Corruption: Implications
for Action,” Corruption, Global Security, and World Order, Robert
I. Rotberg (ed.), pp.27-46.
UNODC. (2013) Corruption and Integrity Challenges in the Public
Sector of Iraq: An Evidence-Based Study, http://www.unodc.org/
documents/publications/2013_Report_on_Corruption_and_Integrity_Iraq.pdf (accessed on 17 April 2015).
168
Foreign Aid and Corruption
UNODC. (December 2012) Corruption in Afghanistan: Recent
Patterns and Trends, http://www.unodc.org/documents/frontpage/
Corruption_in_Afghanistan_FINAL.pdf. (accessed on 27 January
2015)
USAID. (15 January 2009-1 March 2009) Assessment of Corruption in Afghanistan, http://pdf.usaid.gov/pdf_docs/PNADO248.pdf.
(accessed on 04 February 2015)
Uslaner, Eric M. (2008) Corruption, Inequality, and the Rule of
Law: The Bulging Pocket Makes the Easy Life, New York: Cambridge University Press.
Van der Veen, A. Maurits. (2011) Ideas, Interests and Foreign Aid,
New York: Cambridge University Press.
Von der Brelie, Hans. (28 February 2014) “Bosnia-Herzegovina:
corruption protests fuel a potential political spring,” Euronews, Special Reports, http://www.euronews.com/2014/02/28/bosnia-s-earlyspring/ (accessed on 07 February 2015)
Walsh, Declan. (11 November 2014) “At Afghan Border, Graft
Is Part of the Bargain,” New York Times, http://www.nytimes.
com/2014/11/12/world/asia/in-afghanistan-customs-system-corruption-is-part-of-the-bargain.html?_r=0 (accessed on 26 January
2015).
Warren, Mark E. (January 2006) “Democracy and Deceit: Regulating Appearances of Corruption,” American Journal of Political Science, v.50, no.1, pp. 160-174.
Weinbaum, Marvin G. (2006) “Rebuilding Afghanistan Impediments, Lessons, and Prospects,” Nation-Building: Beyond Afghanistan and Iraq, pp.125-144.
169
Kurtoglu Eskisar
Whyte, Dave. (2007) “Hire an American! Economic Tyranny and
Corruption in Iraq,” Social Justice, v.34, no.2, pp.153-168.
Wood, David. (03 June 2013) “Iraq Reconstruction Cost U.S.
$60 Billion, Left Behind Corruption And Waste,” Hufington
Post,
http://www.hufingtonpost.com/2013/03/06/iraqreconstruction_n_2819899.html (accessed on 12 April 2015).
Woods, Ngaire. (November 2008) “Whose Aid? Whose Inluence?
China, Emerging Donors and the Silent Revolution in Development
Aid,” International Affairs, v.84, no.6, pp.1205-1221.
Woods, Ngaire. (March 2005) “The Shifting Politics of Foreign Aid,
International Affairs (Royal Institute of International Affairs 1944), v.81, no.2, pp. 393-409.
World Bank. (15 April 2009) Country Partnership Strategy Progress Report for Bosnia and Herzegovina for the Period FY08-FY11,
Washington, D.C.: World Bank, http://www-wds.worldbank.org/
external/default/WDSContentServer/WDSP/IB/2009/07/20/00035
0881_20090720112528/Rendered/PDF/482290CAS0CORRIGEN
DUM0R20091010411.pdf, (accessed on 16 March 2015).
World Bank. (2000) Bosnia and Herzegovina Diagnostic Surveys
of Corruption, Washington, D.C.: World Bank, http://www-wds.
worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/WDSP/IB/200
5/08/17/000090341_20050817124341/Rendered/PDF/332550BiH
0Diag1Report0200001public1.pdf (accessed on 13 February 2015)
Yeh, Stuart S. (2011) “Ending corruption in Africa through United
Nations inspections,” International Affairs, v.87, no.3, pp.629–650.
Zaum, Dominik (2007). The Sovereignty Paradox: The Norms and
Politics of International Statebuilding, Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
170
Foreign Aid and Corruption
APPENDICES
A. Aid Disbursement from ODA to Afghanistan, Bosnia, and Iraq
(1995-2012)43:
1995
1996
1997 1998
Year
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011 2012
Country
Bosnia
733.99
602 521.56 602.03 702.77 453.33 377.61 292.35 335.45 300.12 268.51 335.6 299.11 327.41 283.65 249.36 281.59 213.41
Afghanistan
106.05
84.32 123.35 88.29 104.16 87.58 323.6 991.73 1227.2 1729.27 2184.96 2417.43 3013.65 4001.89 5123.79 5494.45 5949.55 5660.93
Iraq
238.95 284.48 180.32
74.8 79.07 84.16 101.07 85.39 2178.2 4481.56 21983.36 8557.19 9056.19 9764.54 2629.36 2007.51 1807.41 1113.79
Year
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
Value
0.03
1.22
1.26
3.54
4.32
3.37
2.16
0.89
0.62
1.34
0.43
B. Foreign Direct Investment to Afghanistan in Years:44
43 Data derived from the OECD statistics website, available at http://stats.oecd.org/
Index.aspx?datasetcode=TABLE2A#. (accessed 26 September 2014) All igures
are current prices in US Dollars (million).
44 Table based on information from indexmundi website, available at http://www.
indexmundi.com/facts/afghanistan/foreign-direct-investment. (accessed on 29
September 2014) The igures show the net inlow of FDI with regard to the % of
Afghan GDP.
171
Kurtoglu Eskisar
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
5,42
0,81
1,98
2,1
2004
7,08
11,81
2003
4,56
2006
2002
4,03
6,82
2001
2,06
2005
2000
2,65
5,7
1999
3,77
Value
1998
Year
1,62
C. Foreign Direct Investment to Bosnia in Years:45
Year
1990
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
Value
0,00
0,82
1,03
0,59
1,09
1,41
1,43
1,01
1,12
1,57
1,24
D. Foreign Direct Investment to Iraq in Years:46
45 Table based on information from indexmundi website, available at http://www.
indexmundi.com/facts/bosnia-and-herzegovina/foreign-direct-investment#BX.KLT.
DINV.WD.GD.ZS. (accessed on 29 September 2014) The earliest year available for
this country is 1998. The igures show the net inlow of FDI with regard to the % of
the Bosnian GDP.
46 Table based on information from indexmundi website, available at http://www.
indexmundi.com/facts/iraq/foreign-direct-investment#BX.KLT.DINV.WD.GD.
ZS. (accessed on 29 September 2014) The igures show the net inlow of FDI with
regard to the % of the Iraqi GDP.
172
Foreign Aid and Corruption
E. Budget Transparency in Afghanistan, Bosnia and Iraq:47
Country
Open Budget
Index 2006
Open Budget
Index 2008
Open Budget Index
2010
Open Budget
Index 2012
Afghanistan
--
8
21
59
Bosnia
--
44
44
50
Iraq
--
--
0
4
F. Corruption Scores for Afghanistan, Bosnia and Iraq:
47 Table data extracted from Annex B data in Open Budget Survey (International
Budget Partnership 2012: 50). Open Budget Index is formed by taking the simple
average of the coded responses to the survey questions prepared by International
Budget Partnership. The score ranges between 0 and 100, with 0 representing the
lowest possible score for budget transparency, and 100 representing the highest one
(ibid., 2). For more information on data collection and research methods of this
survey, see the organization’s website at http://internationalbudget.org/what-wedo/open-budget-survey/research-resources/methodology/ (accessed on 23 March
2015).
173