Haitian Emigration
In The Early Twentieth Century
Glenn Perusek
University of Chicago
Standard migration theories see receiving countries as the dynamic
agent which pull migrants to them. These theories, while useful for
explaining many cases, appear inadequate for the case of labor migration from Haiti to Cuba and the Dominican Republic in the early
twentieth century. This article examines this history and offers an
alternative theoretical framework for explaining this migration flow.
It is argued that the prime cause of migration from Haiti is factors in
the sending country.
Haiti has a long history as a country with a strong pattern of emigration.
This article seeks to present the case of Haitian emigration to Cuba and the
Dominican Republic during the first three decades of this century, and to
suggest the central elements of a comprehensive explanation of these
population movements. Examination of this history provides a useful case
against which standard views of migration can be measured.
Currently accepted approaches to the causes of migration focus on the
rationality of individual migrants. People move to find jobs, or to find
better jobs. They make a rational calculation of their interest in staying as
opposed to leaving. When the balance tips toward leaving, they go (Petersen,
1977). This approach is stated in different ways by different authors.
4 IMR Volume XVIII, No.1
HAITIAN EMIGRATION
5
According to Roseman,
If a high comparative place utility is put upon the present job of the
household head, and upon the climate and other local environmental
conditions, then the household is likely to remain... If the household
puts a higher comparative place utility upon environmental conditions,
a better job, or hope for a better job, in another general area, it may
decide to move. (Roseman, 1971:589)
Schwartz (1971:193) states simply, "we expect people to migrate from low
earning locations into high earning locations". He sees human migration as
a deliberate act, wherein the migrant attempts to increase his "lifetime
utility". For Eichenbaum (1975), who constructs a "matrix of human
movement" migrants are precisely those people who are free to make a
calculation about both place of origin and of destination. People who are
absolutely constrained by their environment at the place of origin are either
refugees or slaves, not migrants at all.
Lee's (1966) well-known theory of migration asserts that there are four
factors associated with migration:
1)
Factors associated with place of origin.
2)
Factors associated with place of destination.
3)
Intervening obstacles.
4)
Personal factors.
This theory allows for the fact that migrants have better information about
their home country than any possible destination, and that intervening
obstacles, like distance tend to discourage movement. In this theory migrants
make a rational calculation, but it must be overwhelmingly in favor of
leaving for movement to occur as there is a certain amount of inertia which
must be overcome.
This "rational actor" approach underlies even the Wallersteinian analysis
of the world labor market by Petras (1981). Her argument is that workers
seek the best wages and standard of living. "By migrating to sites where
prior contests over the labor-capital balance have already been won by
labor, workers are able to take advantage of those gains which have been
institutionalized into conditions of the local labor market and into the
general social structure".
All of these approaches share common features: first, migrants are
rational calculators, even though their rationality may be bounded, and
second, factors in both the sending and the receiving countries affect their
decision to move. In the language of migration theory, there' are 'push'
factors in the sending country and 'pull' factors in the receiving country
which determine migration.
6
INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION REVIEW
The underlying assumption to these approaches is that, for potential
migrants, there is some reckoning between conditions in the place of origin
and that of destination. If there is a great disparity between the two, migration
will increase. If conditions are not much different, the level of migration
will be lower. As a result it is predicted that migration will increase during
times of economic expansion. This is because economic expansion is uneven,
causing relatively more growth in advanced areas than the backward ones.
The greater disparities in turn cause greater migration levels. Economic
downturns, though, will inhibit .uigration. "During depressions... a leveling
of opportunities occurs and sheer familiarity with the place of residence
militates against moving to places where positive factors no longer so heavily
outweigh those at home" (Lee, 1966:53). The bias in these approaches is that,
between push and pull factors, it is pull factors, those associated with the
receiving country, which dominate. "The active agent seems to be the
evolution of the developed country and the forces emanating from it" (Piore,
1979:19).
Haitian emigration to Cuba and the Dominican Republic will be examined
in light of the theoretical approach outlined above. It will be argued that the
focus on migrants as rational economic actors is too narrow and that, in the
case of Haiti, it would be better to situate migration within the broader
economic, social and political context of the Caribbean. In the Haitian case
it appears that the reckoning between push and pull factors does not occur.
For instance, the standard approaches would predict that a drop in, the
demand for labor in receiving countries, constituting a leveling of conditions
between sending and receiving countries, would result in a decrease in
migration. It will be demonstrated that once established great changes in the
demand for labor in receiving countries have little or no effect on migration
patterns from Haiti.
Thus an alternative explanation must be found. This article presents
Haiti as a classic push case - factors in receiving countries do not determine
whether there will be migrants from Haiti. For the migration flows to Cuba
and the Dominican Republic it appears that receiving countries do playa
role in initiating migration flows. But changes in labor demand in the
receiving countries thereafter appear to have little effect in reducing flows.
The disparity between Haitian conditions and those in potential receiving
countries is so great at all times that changes, even drastic ones, in receiving
countries are not reflected in changes in the flow of migrants. Rather, it is
Haiti's position as the most backward country in the Western Hemisphere
that leads to immutable outflow from the country. The vast majority of the
population in Haiti lives always on the brink, with incomes at or even below
the subsistence level. A small change in prices on the international market,
or in weather conditions, or variations in the level of repression from the
current regime can easily trigger exodus. The reason changes in labor
HAITIAN EMIGRATION
7
demand in receiving countries play little or no part in determining the level
of migration from Haiti - once migration flows are established - stems
from the fact that the situation for most Haitians at home is not 'normal'.
This situation - absolute poverty - is the fundamental cause of migration
from Haiti.
In addition, the argument that labor demand in receiving countries
leads to migration fails to take into account the fact that labor demand is not
the extent of 'conditions in receiving countries'. There are also 'collective
goods' from which migrants cannot be excluded, such as certain services and
conditions. In the most recent migrations of boat people to the United
States, for example labor demand is an insufficient conception of 'conditions
in the receiving country'. Even if the migrant is imprisoned upon landing in
the U. S. he or she may be better off than remaining in Haiti.
This is not to argue that only surface modifications of the 'rational actor,
push-pull' explanation are needed. As Petersen (1958:263) has argued,
"when emigration has been set as a social pattern, it is no longer relevant to
inquire concerning individual motivations". Of course, individual migrants
make a calculation of whether to migrate or not. However, to focus on this
calculation is to fail to take into account the important social, political and
economic factors which determine broad patterns of migration.
THE LABOR MIGRATIONS TO CUBA AND THE
DOMINICAN REPUBLIC, EARLY20THCENTURY
Haiti gained independence at the beginning of the nineteenth century as a
result of the first and only successful slave revolt in history. Although what
was to become Haiti was the most valuable colony in the Western Hemisphere in the eighteenth century, economic prosperity did not accompany
independence. During the nineteenth century the economy was able to just
keep pace with the growth of the population. This is indicated, for example,
by the figures for exports per capita. When measured in constant 1914
prices, the exports per capita stagnated at just over $6.00 until the 1890s,
however, prices for coffee and logwood, Haiti's two main export products,
dropped dramatically. Simultaneously, the absolute quantity of coffee
exported dropped. By 1910-1914the value of exports per capita had fallen by
more than 25 percent compared to the early 1890s. This represented a
significant slashing of incomes for the Haitian peasantry, so that by the turn
of the century Haiti was primed to begin exporting labor.
Apparently some hesitant attempts to employ Haitians in nascent Cuban
8
INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION REVIEW
HAITI, EXPORTS PER
TABLE 1
CAPITA, IN 1910-1914
PRICES
Average Exports
(million dollars)
Population
(millions)
Exports Per
Capita
1821-25
3.596
.593
$6.06
1838-42
4. 775
.731
6.53
1859-62
5. 739
.935
6. 14
1888-92
8.208
1. 355
6.06
1910-14
8.217
1. 778
4.62
Year
Source: Rotberg, p. 97.
enterprises took place at the turn of the century. There is only indirect
evidence, of this, however. For instance, this note appeared in the Cuban
Financier and Havana Advertiser on August 4, 1900.
Recently at the demand of the press in Santiago, (Major) Tasker H.
Bliss asked officials there to stop the importation by local planters and
mining companies of contract labor from Haiti, Jamaica and Turks
Island, whence had come over a thousand Negroes since January,
1900. (Thomas, 1971:431)
It was only with the development of the sugar industry - mainly by American
capital - that the possibility for large scale importation of Haitian labor into
Cuba opened up. In 1900 more than 80 percent of Cuba was "unoccupied,
fertile and absurdly cheap" (Jenks, 1928:129). In 1900 a syndicate headed by
Andrew Preston, president of United Fruit, bought 174-190,000 acres on
Nipe Bay in Oriente province, the easternmost part of Cuba, at the price of
$2.00 per acre (Hoernel, 1976:229). Other Americans followed and by 1905
twenty-nine mills, producing 21 percent of Cuba's sugar, were owned by
Americans. In 1902, the Reciprocity Treaty between the U. S. and Cuba was
signed, making it possible for the U. S. to buy sugar from Cuba cheaper than
from anywhere in the world. "The preference guaranteed Cuba a chance to
expand her output of sugar until she supplied all that the U. S. needed from
abroad" (Jenks, 1928:139). A Cuban sugar boom ensued: between 1900 and
1904 production increased from 409,272 to 1,312,216 sacks (325 pounds
each) in Oriente alone (Hoernel, 1976:229). For all of Cuba the 1905 harvest
was the largest ever, and by 1914 double the 1905amount was being produced.
Still the immigration of nonwhites was forbidden in 1898 by American
military forces occupying the island and this policy was continued by the Ley
de Inmigracion y Colonizacion, passed in 1910. Contract labor was also
forbidden after 1898, but 150, 000 Spaniards and thousands of others entered
HAITIAN EMIGRATION
9
Cuba between 1899 and 1905 anyway. Cuban planters and industrialists
pushed through a special immigration bill in July 1906 which authorized the
Cuban executive to spend $11 million to attract Europeans to Cuba. But
since those who came, again mostly Spanish, could get higher wages in
industrial jobs, they seldom went further than Havana. Thus, while an
estimated 436,000 Spaniards entered Cuba between 1902 and 1919 (Hoernel,
1976:234), the perennial labor shortage in the ever-expanding sugar industry
remained unsolved.
In 1912 the United Fruit Company received special permission from
Cuban President Jose Gomez to import 1,400 Haitians for harvesting at their
operation in Oriente (Guerra y Sanchez, 1935: 201-202). Then, during the
next year, the new president, Raul Garcia Menocal, attempted to alleviate
the labor shortage in the sugar industry - without relying on black labor by
offering to pay a $5 bonus for every white person brought from Panama to
work in eastern Cuba. He expected 5, 000 new workers could be obtained
this way (Corbitt, 1942). The sugar companies themselves, though, were
"afraid to depend entirely on white immigrants" and several got permits for
importing a restricted number of black workers during 1913. These permits
always stipulated that the blacks were to be returned home after the harvest.
World War I upset this piecemeal arrangement, which in any case was
not wholly satisfactory for the needs of the sugar industry. Sugar profits
sky-rocketed during the war: $163 million in 1914, $202 million in 1915, $308
million in 1916. European beet production collapsed and Cuba regained its
position as the greatest sugar producer in the world. In 1917 Cuba entered
the war and in 1918 the entire sugar harvest was bought by the allies. The
increased sugar demand only intensified the labor shortage. Even though
large numbers of Haitians, Jamaicans and others were now entering the
country legally and illegally, the shortage of labor was reflected in a dramatic
rise in wages. A trade journal complained in 1917:
How serious the situation is, is indicated by reports from the eastern
provinces that wages have now reached the point where ordinary hoe
hands are receiving $3 per day and, in some instances, as much as $5.
(Neville, 1917)
President Menocal, himself a mill owner, was forced to act. Finally, on
August 3, 1917, he signed a law permitting importation of contract labor
until two years after the end of the war (Corbitt, 1942).
A group of millers and growers, the Association for the Furthering of
Immigration, swung into action. Each member pledged $1000 plus a margin
of their profits in order to send agents to Haiti, Jamaica and other emigration
centers to recruit laborers (Hoernel, 1976:235). This effort met with limited
success, for there remained something of a labor shortage until the slump of
1921.
10
INTERNATIONAL MIGRAnON REVIEW
A comparison of several sources gives an indication of the magnitude of
the labor migration to Cuba during this whole period. According to the 1919
Cuban census, 27,000 Haitians and' 23,000 Jamaicans entered Cuba from
1914 to 1918, inclusive, and in 1919 an additional 10,000 Haitians and
24,'000 Jamaicans entered, along with about 30,000 Spaniards (Thomas,
1971:540). The estimate of Carlos Trelles, presumably taking into account
undocumented as well as legal migration, is that between May, 1915 and
May, 1921some 81,000 Haitians and 75,000Jamaicans entered Cuba (Guerra
y Sanchez, 1935:201-202). Loveira (1929), writing in the late 1920s, says that
40,000 -50,000 immigrant workers came to Cuba 'in good season', half white
(mostly Spanish), the rest from Haiti and Jamaica. In bad seasons 20,000
migrants.would enter, from Haiti and Jamaica or from Haiti alone. These
figures are comparable to those provided by Castor (1971:84) for legal
migration of Haitians to Cuba during the 1920s (See, Table 2), but she
contends that illegal migration of between one-third and one-half the legal
level should be added for each year, at least during the 1920s.
TABLE 2
LEGAL MIGRATION OF HAITIANS TO CUBA,
1912-1929
Year
Entered
Departed
1912
1913
1914
1915
1916
1917
1918
1919
1920
1921
1922
1923
1924
1925
1926
1927
1928-9
209
1,512
117
2,490
4,878
10,241
11,268
7,329
30,722
12,567
10,152
20,117
21,517
22,970
21,619
14,098
5,500
328
498
25
470
980
1,977
4,427
6,143
12,651
4,267
Source: Balch, p. 77, Castor, p. 83.
These figures indicate a stable pattern of migration from Haiti to Cuba
from the mid-191Os through most of the 1920s. Millspaugh (1931:143) and
Balch (1927:77) both estimate that two-thirds of the Haitians who went to
Cuba during this period returned to Haiti. The 1928 annual report of the
United Fruit Company shows that of the 11, 000 Haitians employed in 1927,
HAITIAN EMIGRATION IN THE EARLY TWENTIETH CENTURY
11
the vast majority had traveled to Cuba previously, only 2,777 making their
first trip (Guerra and Pulpeiro, 1974:78).
It is very interesting to note the lack of effect the change in sugar prices in
the 1920shad on Haitian migration to Cuba. In 1920 the sugar boom reached
its peak, with sugar costing a phenomenal 22. 5 cents per pound for a time.
By the end of the year sugar had plummeted to 2 cents per pound. Cuban
banks closed, wages immediately dropped, and the labor shortage became a
surplus. Since so much of Oriente, by now the most economically dynamic
province of Cuba, was provisioned from the U. S., prices for food, clothing
and other necessities remained high (Hoernel, 1976:238). Nevertheless, the
pattern of migration from Haiti was uninterrupted: it appears to have been
little affected by the changed demand for labor. This may in part be due to
the fact, suggested by Loveira's commentary, that during years of labor
shortage workers would enter Cuba from Haiti, Jamaica and other Caribbean
islands as well as from Spain, but in years of surplus they would only come
from Haiti, or from there and Jamaica. Although wages fell to 40 cents per
day in Oriente after 1920 - that is, to a level below that of the 1890s for sugar
workers in Cuba - this did not diminish the flow of migrants from Haiti. A
standard explanation, seeking the causes of labor migration in the receiving
country, cannot explain this occurance. Once a pattern of migration was
established it was conditions facing Haitians in Haiti which resulted in its
continued stability. Once started, even the shock of a veritable depression
in the sugar industry in Cuba could not alter the pattern of migration from
Haiti.
In fact, the movement of Haitians to Cuba continued through the 1930s,
though it is unclear how large the movement was by then, and in spite of the
fact that by 1932sugar reached the rock bottom price of 112 cent per pound. It
was only in 1937, under pressure from Cuban labor unions which would not
work at the wages of the Haitians, that Batista deported thousands of
immigrant Haitians and closed the country to them (Leyburn, 1966:271).
Then in 1939 the Cuban immigration law was amended with strict new
provisions aimed at excluding black (i.e., Haitian) workers (Proudfoot,
1950:50).
The early twentieth century also saw the establishment of a strong pattern
of migration of Haitians to the Dominican Republic. Previously, in the late
nineteenth century, the border between the two countries which shared the
island of Hispaniola was ill-defined. The relatively greater concentration of
population in the Haitian half led to an osmosis - the spontaneous movement
of Haitians into what would later become clearly defined as the Dominican
Republic for farming (Moral, 1959). Today there are hundreds of thousands
of black Dominicans living in the western part of the Dominican Republic
who are descendents of these early migrants.
With the development of the sugar industry Haitian laborers migrated to
12
INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION REVIEW
the Dominican Republic far less haphazardly and in much larger numbers.
The use of Haitian labor apparently coincided with the involvement of
American capital in Dominican sugar. As of 1905 there was little American
interest in the Dominican Republic, but by 1924 sugar companies owned
about one-quarter of the agricultural land in the Dominican Republic. The
lion's share of this was American owned. The Central Romana Corporation
(today owned by Gulf Western, and still the largest sugar company in the
Dominican Republic) owned 144,000 acres of the total 438, 000 dedicated to
sugar. Unfortunately, estimates of the magnitude of the migration of Haitians
to work in the Dominican sugar industry are few. Castor (1971) considers the
movement to have been greater than that to Cuba, and other authors
(Lundahl, 1979:625) accept this opinion.
The size of these migrations does not mean the work Haitians found in
Cuba or the Dominican Republic was desirable by normal standards. It is
worth quoting Wingfield at length on these conditions of Haitians in the
Dominican sugar fields:
The life of a Haitian migrant worker in the Dominican Republic is
reminiscent of slavery days. Their work consists of cutting or carting
cane from dawn to dusk. The companies provide them with shacks and
hammocks but they have to shift for themselves for food. It is incredible
how they subsist on a meager diet of a little rice and beans which they
cook themselves on open fires with occasionally some bread and very
rarely some meat. They get their energy from the cane that they chew
all day long while working. .. The return trip is at the expense of the
worker and sometimes uses up half of his savings. Some actually walk
all the way back... since the majority are illiterate, they are occasionally
short-changed when converting their Dominican pesos into Haitian
gourdes... It is on the whole a shocking exploitation of people who are
educationally and economically deprived and defenseless (Wingfield,
1966:99).
Conditions in Cuba were much the same.
Since the U. S. occupied Haiti from 1915 to 1934 and the Dominican
Republic from 1912 to 1924, and since American business interests stood to
gain in Cuba and the Dominican Republic from the employment of Haitian
migrant labor, it might be suspected that the U. S. government, directly or
indirectly, induced migration from Haiti. In fact, the opposite is true. The
Haitian government (overseen by American forces) tried repeatedly in the
1920s to stem the flow of migrants from the country, but in vain.
In the name of rediscovered nationalism, the dangers of a rapidly
diminishing labor force were denounced. The government tried to
HAITIAN EMIGRATION
13
limit emigration by increasing passport fees (in 1923, CP), by regulating
the operations of hiring companies, and by controlling freelance
migration. Emigration was even legally prohibited in 1928. It was
fruitless (Millspaugh, 1931:143).
The 1928 emigration ban actually had to be revoked five months after it was
enacted because it went unheeded. The American military government of
the Dominican Republic put restrictions several times on the use of Haitian
labor, and in December 1919banned the employment of nonwhite immigrant
labor altogether (Hernandez, 1973:59). The first regulations ever on the
Dominican border were promulgated in the 1910sby the occupying American
forces.
Again in 1930 the Dominican border was closed, with no apparent effect
on the migration of Haitian labor. Only the massacre of up to 25, 000
Haitians by the dictator Trujillo in 1937 temporarily checked the flow into
the Dominican Republic.
Trujillo conceived of 'Operation Perejil", literally 'Operation Parsley'.
Creole-speaking Haitians were known to have difficulty pronouncing
the world parsley in Spanish and this was the only feature which
distinguished Haitian from Dominican. Thus Trujillo's troops, garbed
in peasant clothes, ranged up and down the border carrying sprigs of
parsley. "What is this?" they would ask of the peasant whose nationality
they were not sure of. If the reply was pelegil instead of perejit the man
was marked for death (Diederich and Burt, 1970:401).
Incredibly, despite the massacre, which rid the Dominican Republic of
thousands of Haitians living there, migration resumed in 1939.
What caused these significant out-migrations of the early twentieth
century? Surely without the expansion of the sugar industries in Cuba and
the Dominican Republic and the simultaneous lack of such development in
Haiti, the migration to these places would not have happened. Yet, if it
were a matter of Haitian labor being pulled to the sites of rapid capital
expansion, the migration patterns would not have continued after the price
of sugar on the world market dropped so drastically after 1920. The inertia
of the migration flows after the drop in labor demand in the receiving
~ ountries
is what needs to be explained.
In Haiti there was a great lack of employment opportunities in the towns.
Conditions in Port-au-Prince and other coastal communes were unattractive to families who could, if they remained at home, at least be
assured of a tiny plot of land in the mountains or, if they were fortunate,
in some reasonably fertile valley (Rotberg, 1971:150).
14
INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION REVIEW
TABLE 3
HAITIAN POPULATION DENSITY, 1820-1914
YEAR
POPULATION
DENSITY
(MILLIONS)
(PERSONS/SQUARE KM.)
1820
·593
21.4
1840
.73 1
26·3
1860
·935
18 0
1.355
33·7
48.8
1914
1.8 23
65·7
9
As the percentage of the rural population on marginal farming land
increased, the propensity for Haitians to migrate out of the country increased.
Between the early 1890s and 1914 the population density of Haiti increased
significantly - from 48.8 persons per square kilometer to 65.7 (Rotberg,
1971:97). In addition, as has already been noted, until the 1890s the value of
exports kept pace with the growth of the population. Then it dropped
significantly, so that by the 1910s the prospects for earning a living from
selling coffee or other agricultural products was far less encouraging.
Between the early 1890sand the 1910s the value of exports per capita actually
dropped by about 25 percent, while all during the nineteenth century they
had remained stable. This was not merely a matter of prices; the average
coffee exports, in quantities, illustrate the same trend. In the early 1890s
fifty-one pounds of coffee per person were exported, but in 1905-1914 the
figure had fallen to just 33. 2 pounds per person (See, Table 4). For Haitian
peasants, who had previously been living right around the minimum
subsistence level, such drops in export earnings and quantities exported did
not merely represent a diminishing of the standard of living. Many peasants
were driven below the minimum subsistence level. For them the alternative
was migrate or starve.
TABLE 4
AVERAGE QUANTITIES OF COFFEE EXPORTED, 1888-1914
Year
Million
Pounds
Population
Pounds
Per Person
1. 355
51. 0
1. 778
34. 1
1888-92
69. 12
1893-99
64.86
1905-1914
60.56
Source: Rotberg, Appendix B.
HAITIAN EMIGRATION
15
The stability of emigration patterns from Haiti, even in light of declining
labor demand in receiving countries, was bolstered by the fact that there was
no agent to transform the methods of agricultural production in order to
increase productivity. In other Caribbean countries productivity-increasing
modernization was achieved in this period as a result of the appearance of
American and, to a lesser extent, European interests in agriculture. In
Cuba and the Dominican Republic,American capital invested in large scale
agricultural undertakings which covered the countryside. Along with this
foreign capital came planting, growing, harvesting and other methods
which increased the productivity of land. No such influx of foreign capital
occurred in Haiti. This is in large part an historical accident: the American
occupation of Haiti, which would have been a propitious moment for
investment, occurred in 1915. Because of the First World War and the fact
that the first attempts at large scale agriculture by American interests (there
were two) failed, subsequent foreign investment was discouraged.
The peasantry themselves were not capable of saving anything toward
investment in improved techniques. Even if savings were somehow possible,
the size of the land-holdings made productivity-increasing investment highly
unlikely. Because the small Haitian peasant had no savings or surplus land
with which to take risks, no innovations occurred.
Under conditions where the countryside is not developing, and in the
absence of any foreign or domestic capital interest to centralize and modernize
agriculture, it is logical that the government would step in to make the
investment necessary to halt steadily falling agricultural productivity.
Indeed, any government which identifies its own survival with economic
development, however defined, and regardless of the original resource
endowment of a country, will apply itself to the problem of agriculture. In
Haiti, this is precisely the element that was missing; successive Haitian
governments (unfortunately right up to the present) have not identified the
security of their own position with economic development. As Lundahl
(1979:636) puts it:
The history of Haiti is the history of clique infighting for the spoils of
the presidential office. Economic development has never been a
political goal in Haiti. Instead, a never-ending stream of kleptocracies
who could think of little else than filling their pockets have squandered
the available funds in their attempts to gain or retain the presidency.
Since the middle of the nineteenth century, as capitalism spread over the
globe, noncapitalist regimes were faced, one after another, with the choice
of being subsumed by the far more productive capitalist system ortransforming their own mode of exploitation in imitation of the logic of capitalism.
Previously the exploitation of the population was determined by the
consumption needs of the rulers, as Marx said, "the exploitation of the serf
I
16
INTERNATIONAL MIGRAnON REVIEW
was determined by the walls of the lord's stomach". But under capitalism
competing units, be they entrepreneurs or entire states, are compelled to
continually expand production so as not to be overtaken. Crucially, the web
of international capitalism left a gap for Haiti. Being unchallenged by
capital, a series of nondeveloping regimes has been allowed to remain in
power. Haitian rulers have no interest in developing agriculture because
their consumption needs can be met without such development.
CONCLUSIONS
Standard migration theories see the receiving countries as the dynamic
agents which pull migrants to them. An increasing amount of labor is a
prerequisite for expanding capital, and as a result these theories predict
migration during times of economic growth.
These standard theories, while useful for analyzing many cases, seem to
be inadequate for the Haitian experience in the early twentieth century.
The migrations to Cuba and the Dominican Republic, to be sure, could not
have been initiated without the intrusion of (American) capital into the
Caribbean. But Haitians were not merely being 'pulled' to sites of rapid
capital expansion. Patterns of migration from Haiti to developing areas,
once established, appear to have had a good measure of stability - inertia which was relatively independent of the demand for labor in the receiving
country. Haitians continued to migrate to Cuba and the Dominican Republic
during the 1920s and 1930s, even after the international sugar market
collapsed. Pressure from Cuban labor unions led Batista to forcibly expatriate
thousands of Haitians in 1937 and General Trujillo massacred thousands of
Haitians in the Dominican Republic that same year, which was seventeen
years after the collapse of sugar prices. If it were that Haitian labor was
responding to labor demand in developing areas alone, these migration
patterns are difficult indeed to explain. This is especially so if Haitian
emigration is considered as a whole. There has been a steady stream of
migrants from Haiti ever since the beginning of the twentieth century.
Receiving countries determine where Haitian migrants go; that they will go
is determined by conditions in Haiti and by the relationship of Haiti, as the
most backward country in the Western Hemisphere, to the rest of the
Caribbean.
It is factors as they affect Haitians inside Haiti itself that are the causes of
out-migration. Haitians have historically had very few employment
opportunities at home. The mass of the population is rural peasants, living
near the subsistence level. They are extremely sensitive to changes in food
prices and to changes in export markets, especially that of coffee. When the
17
HAITIAN EMIGRATION
coffee crop collapses due to a drop in prices, as in Haiti during World War I,
thousands of Haitians are pushed beyond the brink. Many probably die;
others emigrate. In a country where, since the turn of the century, a portion
of the population has, at all times, been ripe for emigration, such catastrophes
must simply enlarge that portion.
REFERENCES
Balch, E. G., ed.
1927 Occupied Haiti. New York: Writers' Publishing Company.
Castor, S.
1971 La occupacion norteamericana de Haiti y sus consecuencias (1915-1934). Mexico City: Sieglo
Vientiuno Editors, S. A.
Corbitt, D.
1942 "Immigration in Cuba", Hispanic American Historical Review 2(22):280-307.
Diederich, B. and A. Burt
1970 Papa Doc: Haiti and its Dictator, London: Bodley
He~ d
Press.
Eichenbaum, J.
1971 "A Matrix of Human Movement", Journal of Human Resources, 6(2):193-205.
Gucrra, S. and R. Pulpeiro
1974 "Politica demografica de la United Fruit", Universidad de la Habana, 200:60-92.
Guerra y Sanchez, R.
1935 Azucar y Poblacion en las Antillas. Madrid: Cultural, S. A.
Hernandez, F. M.
1973 La inmigracion Haitiana. Santo Domingo, D. R. : Ediciones Sargazo.
Hoerncl, R. B.
1976 "Sugar and Social Change in Oriente, Cuba, 1898-1946", Journal of Latin American Studies,
8(2):215-249.
Jenks, L.
1928 Our Cuban Colony: A Study in Sugar. New York: Vanguard Press.
Leyburn, J. G.
1966 The Haitian People. New Haven: Yale University Press.
18
INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION REVIEW
Loveira, C.
1929 "Labor in the Cuban Sugar Industry", International Labor Review, 20:424-429.
Lundahl, M.
1979 Peasants and Poverty: A Study of Haiti. New York: St. Martin's Press.
Millspaugh, A. C.
1931 Haiti Under American Control, 1915-1930. Boston: World Peace Foundation.
Moral, Paul
1959 L 'economie haitienne. Port-au-Prince: Imprimerie de I'Etat,
Neville, H. O.
1917 "News of the Cuban Sugar Industry", Facts About Sugar. 5.
Petersen, W.
1977 "International Migration", Annual Review of Sociology, 4:533-575.
1958 "A General Typology of Migration", American Sociological Review, 23(2):256-266.
Petras, E.
1981 "The New Global Labor Market in the Modern World-Economy". In Global Trends in
Migration: Theory and Research on International Population Movements. Edited by M. Kritz
et al. New York: Center for Migration Studies.
Piori, M.
1979 Birds of Passage, Migrant Labor and Industrial Societies. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Proudfoot, M. J.
1950 Population Movement in the Caribbean. Port-of-Spain: Kent House.
Roseman, C. C.
1971 "Migration as a Spatial and Temporal Process", Annals of the Association of American
Geographers, 61(3):589-598.
Rotberg, R. 1.
1971 Haiti: The Politics of Squalor. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Schwartz, A.
1971 "On Efficiency of Migration", Journal of Human Resources, 6(2):193-205.
Thomas, H.
1971 Cuba - The Pursuit of Freedom. New York: Harper & Row.
Wingfield, R.
1966 "Haiti, A Case Study of an Underdeveloped Area". Unpublished PhD dissertation,
University of Louisiana, Baton Rouge.