This article was downloaded by: [Bailard, Catie Snow]
On: 4 August 2009
Access details: Access Details: [subscription number 913658677]
Publisher Routledge
Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House,
37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK
Political Communication
Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:
http://www.informaworld.com/smpp/title~content=t713774515
Mobile Phone Diffusion and Corruption in Africa
Catie Snow Bailard a
a
School of Media and Public Affairs, George Washington University,
Online Publication Date: 01 July 2009
To cite this Article Bailard, Catie Snow(2009)'Mobile Phone Diffusion and Corruption in Africa',Political Communication,26:3,333 — 353
To link to this Article: DOI: 10.1080/10584600903053684
URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10584600903053684
PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE
Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.informaworld.com/terms-and-conditions-of-access.pdf
This article may be used for research, teaching and private study purposes. Any substantial or
systematic reproduction, re-distribution, re-selling, loan or sub-licensing, systematic supply or
distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden.
The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contents
will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae and drug doses
should be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss,
actions, claims, proceedings, demand or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly
or indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.
Political Communication, 26:333–353, 2009
Copyright © Taylor & Francis Group, LLC
ISSN: 1058-4609 print / 1091-7675 online
DOI: 10.1080/10584600903053684
Mobile Phone Diffusion and Corruption in Africa
1091-7675
1058-4609
UPCP
Political
Communication,
Communication Vol. 26, No. 3, Jun 2009: pp. 0–0
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
Corruption
Catie
Snowin
Bailard
Africa
CATIE SNOW BAILARD
The explosion of mobile phones into a region that, until recently, was nearly devoid of
telecommunications infrastructure provides a valuable opportunity to explore the
potential effects of information and communication technology on various economic
and social outcomes. This article focuses specifically on the potential influence that
mobile phones will exert on corruption in Africa. Two distinct empirical analyses test
the hypothesis that mobile phones will reduce corruption in Africa, as a result of
decentralizing information and communication and thereby diminishing the opportunities available to engage in corruption as well as increasing the potential of detection
and punishment. The results of a fixed effects regression of panel data at the country
level reveal a significant negative correlation between a country’s degree of mobile
phone penetration and that country’s level of perceived corruption. In addition to this,
a multivariate regression of survey data reveals that the degree of mobile phone signal
coverage across 13 Namibian provinces is significantly associated with reduced
perceptions of corruption at the individual level.
Keywords corruption, Africa, mobile phones, ICT, information and communication
technologies
A woman provides for her family by selling the fish she catches from the river. She does
not own a freezer. So, if she can not find customers quickly enough, the fish putrefy and
an entire day of work is wasted. Then she buys a mobile phone. Customers can now call
her to tell her if they plan to buy her fish that day, which she keeps tethered in the river
until they arrive. Now she knows exactly how many fish she is likely to sell that day,
enabling her to provision her time and energy more efficiently (LaFraniere, 2005).
A 45-year-old farmer needs to know how much to sell her fruit for on a given day.
Some days she spends hours trudging around in pursuit of a working public pay phone to
call the markets and learn how to best price her fruit. Then the farmer buys a mobile phone.
Now, not only can she quickly learn the best price to maximize that day’s sales, but she can
also reliably and instantly connect with customers, brokers, and the market (Ngowi, 2005).
A man wants to open a bank account. Keeping money in his home makes his family a
target for robbery, and it is simply too difficult to amass any sort of savings that way. But
Catie Snow Bailard is Professor in the School of Media and Public Affairs at George Washington
University.
The work for this article was completed while I was a PhD candidate in the Political Science
Department at the University of California, Los Angeles. For feedback and guidance with the article
and/or beyond, I would like to thank Matt Baum, Tim Groeling, Jeff Lewis, James Lo, Dan Posner,
Phil Potter, Lynn Vavreck, and John Zaller. Of course, any shortcomings belonging to the article are
entirely my own.
Address correspondence to Catie Snow Bailard, School of Media and Public Affairs,
George Washington University, 805 21st St. NW, Suite 400, Washington, DC 20052. E-mail:
[email protected]
333
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
334
Catie Snow Bailard
there is no bank branch in his remote village. And, even if there were, he surely could not
afford the fees associated with a traditional account. Then the man gets a mobile phone.
Using his mobile phone and a government-issued identity number, the man calls into a
mobile phone banking system. Now it doesn’t matter that there is no bank branch for
many miles around. And, with no start-up fees or monthly charges (only a small fee per
transaction), the man can now afford to keep his money in a bank account. Not only is his
family’s safety and savings less vulnerable to would-be predators, but he can also buy groceries and conduct a number of other daily business transactions with a simple touch of a
button (Itano, 2005).
Mobile phones are changing daily life in Africa. Anecdotes are already pouring out of
the continent, highlighting the many ways that mobile phones have reconfigured and streamlined various daily activities—particularly those in the economic domain. As these real-life
examples attest, thanks to mobile phones, buyers and sellers can now connect more readily,
creating more efficient markets. Small business owners and individual vendors are also now
less dependent on middlemen, reducing their susceptibility to extortion or simply bad information (Ross 2004). And bank accounts via mobile phones render business transactions less
vulnerable to default by reducing the risk of nonpayment. As such, these anecdotes are substantiated by a number of recent studies, which have identified mobile phones as contributing to reduced price discrepancies (Aker, 2008), increased consumer and producer welfare
(Abraham, 2007; Jensen, 2007), improved productivity (Donner, 2005; Lane, Sweet, Lewin,
Sephton, & Petini, 2006; Moloney, 2005), and assistance in finding employment (Frost &
Sullivan, 2006; Samuel, Shah, & Hadingham, 2005).
Considering the abject poverty still suffered across the African continent, the full
range of avenues through which mobile phones may reform and energize African economies is a worthwhile consideration. Accordingly, this article focuses on the mobile
phone’s impact within a specific domain of economic activity: corruption. In the following sections, I review the growth of mobile phones and current state of corruption in
Africa, followed by a discussion of the impact that I hypothesize mobile phones will exert
on corruption in this region. In short, I argue that the net effect of the diffusion of mobile
phones in Africa will be to reduce corruption by decentralizing information and communication, thereby diminishing the opportunities available to engage in corruption as well as
increasing the potential of detection and punishment.
I then test this hypothesis by means of two distinct empirical analyses. First, I employ
a fixed effects regression of panel data to test whether the growth in mobile phone penetration across 46 African countries, from 1999 to 2006, is correlated with changes in these
countries’ perceived corruption scores.1 Next, in order to better address the endogeneity
and misspecification concerns that accompany such cross-country quantitative analyses,
I shift the level of analysis to the individual. To do so, I utilize Afrobarometer survey data
to determine whether moving along the spectrum from more to less mobile phone signal
coverage exerts a distinct and significantly more negative influence on corruption perceptions across the 13 different Namibian provinces in 2006 (when mobile phones were
present) compared to 1999 (before mobile phones were widely in use).
The findings produced by each of these analyses support the hypothesized negative
relationship between mobile phone diffusion and corruption in Africa. The fixed effects
regression of panel data reveals a significant negative correlation between a country’s
degree of mobile phone penetration and its level of perceived corruption. In addition, the
individual-level regression reveals a significantly greater negative correlation between the
degree of mobile signal coverage in a respondent’s province and that respondent’s perception of corruption in 2006 when compared to 1999.
Corruption in Africa
335
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
Mobile Telephones in Africa
As recently as 2000, less than 3% of Africans subscribed to fixed telephone land lines. As
a result, mobile telephone companies initially overlooked the African continent. Assuming
that, whether it be a result of financial limitations or simple lack of interest, the apparent
paucity of demand for land lines among Africans would extend to mobile telephones as
well. “We all misread the market,” admits the chief executive officer of a Kenyan mobile
service provider (Ngowi, 2005).
Despite the number of land-line telephone subscribers continuing to stagnate at less
than 4%, the number of mobile phone subscribers mushroomed from less than 2% in
2000 to nearly 30% in 2007 (International Telecommunications Union [ITU], 2008).
And, being that this indicator measures only subscribers—defined as prepaid and postpaid users of “portable phones subscribing to an automatic public mobile telephone service” (ITU, 2008, p. 125)—the number of individuals with access to mobile phones
likely reaches considerably higher once neighbors, friends, and family are taken into
account. Considering that some remote villages still communicate by beating drums,
while in other cases merely passing on a message often meant that “someone may have to
leave work, travel for days, spending much more money” (LaFraniere, 2005), this rapid
infusion of mobile phones into Africa suggests a revolution in communication and information diffusion.
As it turns out, the lack of land-line subscriptions was not at all a result of lack of
interest in telephonic communication. “The real reason for weak demand was that land
lines were expensive, subscribers had to wait for months get hooked up, and the lines
often went down because of poor maintenance, floods, and theft of copper cables”
(Ngowi, 2005). As such, once cash-strapped governments began to privatize their telecommunications industries in the mid-1990s, monopolies gave way to more competitive
industries that offered increasingly affordable and reliable mobile services. Considering
the myriad ways that mobile telephones have already demonstrably improved daily life on
the continent—from conducting simple business transactions, to calling a doctor when a
baby gets sick in the middle of the night, to being able to check in on loved ones living far
away or in war zones—experts do not expect demand to abate any time soon (Sullivan,
2006).
In fact, at the moment, it is the supply side that is struggling to keep pace. Mobile
towers cannot be erected quickly enough. In Nigeria, two providers had to suspend sales
of subscriber identity module (SIM) cards for a period of months to allow the companies
to strengthen their networks. In the Congo, unwilling to wait for the mobile company to
erect a nearby mobile tower, eager villagers built 50-foot-high treehouses to capture signals from remote towers (LaFraniere, 2005). However, villagers such as these may not
have to wait much longer: As of 2007, mobile phone signal coverage reached 64% of the
African population (ITU, 2008).
Moreover, as mobile subscriber rates near 100% in developed countries, although the
majority of future African subscribers are of low income, providers are nevertheless keen
to get them onboard. “Existing business models and strategies show that lower revenues
are compensated by masses of new subscribers. Also, studies have shown low-income
groups are prepared to spend proportionally more of their income on telecommunications”
(ITU, 2008, p. 6). As such, mobile providers are producing increasingly affordable mobile
handsets and selling airtime in cheaper and cheaper packets, with the majority of subscribers opting for prepaid plans that offer such features as per-second billing and low denomination airtime recharges (ITU, 2008).
336
Catie Snow Bailard
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
Corruption in Africa
Corruption is widely defined in the literature as behavior that “deviates from the formal duties
of a public role because of private-regarding (personal, close family, private clique) pecuniary
or status gains; or violates rules against the exercise of certain private-regarding behavior”
(Klitgaard, 1988, p. 23). Corruption is not unique to Africa, but the extent to which it has hamstrung good governance and economic development may be. As one scholar observes, corruption “is not markedly worse than in many other parts of the developing and former communist
world. . . . Yet corruption in Africa is universally perceived, by external observers and by local
reformers alike, as being ‘catastrophic’ in its impact on development” (Szetfel, 2000, p. 427).
In brief, scholars have identified corruption as contributing to fiscal deficits, income inequality,
market distortion, lack of investment, inefficient public services, low growth rates, authoritarianism, political instability, and state collapse (Tanzi, 1998; Mauro, 1995, 1997; Szetfel, 2000;
Azfar, Lee, & Swamy, 2001; Jackson & Rosberg, 1994).
In Africa, corrupt behavior often takes the form of rent-seeking, in which elites and
officials extract payments in return for special policy, administrative advantages, or other
political goods (LeVine, 1975). Aside from these payments, which Western society generally deems “bribes,” corruption also takes the more passive form of officials and local elites
siphoning away some portion of aid and welfare disbursements for their own private use.
For example, a study tracking the distribution of school capitation grants in Uganda found
that only 14% of the funds intended for the schools actually reached their targets (Reinikka
& Svensson, 2004). Similar studies reveal comparable levels of aid lost through misappropriation in Ghana (49%), Tanzania (57%), and Zambia (76%) (Ye & Canagarajah, 2002;
Price Waterhouse Coopers, 1999; Das, Habyarimana, & Krishnan, 2002; Reinikka &
Svensson, 2004).
In African nations, the funds derived from corruption frequently fuel clientelist politics
(Jackson & Rosberg, 1994; Reinikka & Svensson, 2004), which are defined as “the distribution of public goods—offices, public works projects, permits, tax breaks, and so on—in
return for loyalty” (Leonard & Scott, 2003, p. 2) On the ground level, clientelist politics
often also entail vote-buying, in which small monetary payments or staples are provided to
villagers in exchange for their vote commitment. However, portions of these misappropriated funds also ultimately line the pockets of officials and elites (Platteau & Gasspart, 2003).
While there tends to be scholarly consensus regarding the deleterious nature of
corruption,2 the primary causes of corruption in Africa remain much more debated. Some
scholars contend that corruption is an artifact of colonialism, in which African leaders of
newly independent states sought to replicate the material indulgences of their former colonial leaders (Greenstone, 1966). However, another line of reasoning contends that corruption derives primarily from precolonial notions of patrimonialism, in which leaders must
capture funds to satisfy the expectations of traditional kinship networks and ethnic obligations (Olivier de Sardan, 1999). Turning to more economic-based arguments, some argue
that integration into the global market is correlated with decreased corruption as a result of
exposing domestic businesses to international norms and increased demands for transparency (Sandholtz & Koetzel, 2000; Mauro, 1995). However, another school of thought
contends that increased participation in the global economy actually encourages corruption
by creating more situations in which companies seeking contracts will find the payment of
bribes to be highly lucrative (Tanzi, 1998). Moving to politics, one body of literature contends that more competitive political systems and democracy in general diminish corruption by increasing accountability and transparency (Rose-Ackerman, 1993; Rasmusen &
Ramseyer, 1994; Montinola & Jackman, 2002). Conversely, Szetfel (2000) worries that
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
Corruption in Africa
337
intense factional competition for political office could escalate political mobilization via
patronage politics, increasing the incentives for leaders to engage in corrupt activities.
Despite these very divergent arguments, which represent only the tip of the iceberg in
terms of the range of factors argued to contribute to corruption, there are two simple
logical premises that tend to underpin most theories regarding the causes of corruption.
First, corrupt behavior most often takes place in secrecy. Corruption prefers the shadows
and abhors transparency, so corruption will thrive in contexts where information and communication are centralized into a few, often elite, hands (Reinikka & Svensson, 2004,
2005; Schleifer & Vishny, 1993; Sandholtz & Koetzle, 2000). This preference for privacy
stems from the second logical premise, which posits that individuals will engage in a costbenefit analysis in the course of deciding whether to commit an act of corruption. In
essence, individuals weigh the likely benefit to be gained from the corrupt act against the
potential cost of committing the act—particularly, the likelihood of detection and punishment (Azfar et al., 2001; Schleifer & Vishny, 1993; Bardhan & Mookherjee, 2000;
Treisman, 2000). Taking these two premises into account, it is not surprising that corruption has proliferated on the African continent, where telecommunication technologies—
the very tools that promote transparency and strengthen oversight mechanisms—were,
until recently, nearly nonexistent among the general population.
Theory
Although a number of institutional reforms are necessary to effectively curb corruption,
transparency and accountability are consistently cited as integral components of anticorruption campaigns. Transparency and accountability combat corruption both by
decreasing the number of opportunities available to engage in corruption and increasing
the likelihood of detection and punishment. The historic dearth of telecommunications
infrastructure in Africa centralized information and communication into the hands of
elites, creating conditions conducive to the perpetration of corrupt behavior by severely
constraining the potential for transparency and accountability. As such, I argue that the net
effect of the rapid and massive diffusion of mobile phones in Africa will be the reduction
of corruption by decentralizing information and communication, thereby shrinking the
veil of secrecy that shields corrupt behavior as well as altering the cost-benefit calculus of
corrupt behavior by strengthening oversight and punishment mechanisms.
In order to engage in corrupt behavior, the opportunity to do so must first exist.
Therefore, it can be plausibly reasoned that the more opportunities that are available, the
more likely individuals will engage in corrupt behavior. Opportunities for corruption
increase when elites, officials, and other influential individuals enjoy some degree of
monopoly over information and communication. For example, local elites can capture aid
disbursements intended for schools or villages because they represent the exclusive channel for communication between aid agencies and the intended recipients—enabling local
elites to falsely report back to aid agencies as well as keep recipients in the dark regarding
the actual amount of intended aid (or the existence of such aid, at all) (Reinikka & Svensson, 2004, 2005). Bureaucrats and officials can extract bribes because they enjoy sole discretion over the supply of required services, permits, or licenses (Azfar et al., 2001).
Moreover, even in instances when officials do not officially possess monopoly discretion,
they can exploit villagers’ comparative lack of information regarding the appropriate costs
and full range of channels available to procure such services, permits, or licenses.
Mobile phones decrease the prevalence of opportunities for corruption by decentralizing information and communication. Thanks to mobile phones, local elites no longer
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
338
Catie Snow Bailard
necessarily serve as the exclusive channel for communication between aid agencies and
intended recipients. With mobile phones, aid agencies can directly contact schools and
villagers to ensure that aid was appropriately disbursed. In addition, mobile phones make
it easier for villagers to learn that they are entitled to receive a certain amount of aid,
increasing their capacity to demand that aid. Mobile phones also diminish the power of
local officials to extract bribes by better connecting individuals with alternative officials
or with villagers who can provide information regarding alternative channels, reducing a
given official’s sole discretion over the supply of services, permits, or licenses.
In support of the power of information diffusion to deter local capture, a recent study
revealed that simply posting a newspaper advertisement stating that aid was meant to be
dispersed to certain schools significantly reduced the amount of aid that was lost through
misappropriation (Reinikka & Svensson, 2005). Notably, this study also found that the
farther a school was geographically located from the closest newspaper outlet, the more
funding that school lost to local capture. Not only do mobile phones serve as an additional
channel for informing villagers regarding intended aid, adding mobile phones will further
strengthen newspaper public information campaigns against corruption by reducing the
constraining effect of geography and literacy.
In addition to these instances, mobile phones can also directly reduce the opportunities
for corruption as a result of the spread of affordable bank accounts via mobile phones. As
more Africans open bank accounts via mobile phones, aid agencies and governments are
beginning to transfer aid, pensions, and grants directly into the bank accounts of recipients
(Itano, 2005). As a result, some degree of aid disbursement will bypass local elites entirely,
meaning that the opportunity to capture these funds should diminish considerably.
Moving to the next stage, mobile phones also reduce corruption by increasing the likelihood of detection and punishment, thereby changing the cost-benefit calculus of corrupt behavior. In the past, the dearth of telecommunications infrastructure meant that aid agencies and
officials had to rely on local elites for assurances that aid was disbursed appropriately. If suspicious of the veracity of these reports, their only alternative often was embarking on the arduous
and timely endeavor of traveling to remote villages to verify in person. Accordingly, it was
often difficult to definitively determine whether corruption had occurred at all, let alone punish
it. In addition, although many African governments have instituted (often sincere) anti-corruption reforms, “experience has shown that these need to be backed up with effective enforcement abilities, especially the ability to track down violations” (Harsch, 1993, p. 46)—a rather
difficult endeavor when control over communication and information is tightly centralized
within the same small group of individuals that largely perpetrate the corruption.
Mobile phones reduce the monopoly over information and communication that officials have traditionally exploited to shield their own corrupt behavior. In addition to
enabling aid agencies to efficiently and directly follow up with intended aid recipients,
mobile phones better equip reformers to track down violations and monitor adherence to
anti-corruption campaigns. In support of this, a mobile service provider in Sierra Leone
launched a toll-free phone number that residents can call to report instances of suspected
corruption to the nation’s Anti-Corruption Commission (Ogendeji, 2008). Finally, mobile
phones also bolster the role that average citizens can play in the fight against corruption by
increasing the ease with which whistle-blowing citizens can contact reformers, government officials, and the news media. The recent conviction of the son of an Indian politician provides an example of how mobile phones can empower citizens in the fight against
corruption; in that instance, a massive mobile phone grassroots campaign forced prosecutors to retry a case in which a politician’s son had been previously acquitted despite shooting a bartender dead in front of several eyewitnesses (Rautray, 2006).
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
Corruption in Africa
339
Note, however, that I do not claim that mobile phones alone will act as a panacea for
corruption. Successful anti-corruption campaigns require a multidimensional approach in
which mobile phones can only play a partial role. Therefore, although the diffusion of
mobile phones into a region where telecommunications technology was nearly nonexistent
may serve to reduce corruption by decentralizing information and communication, there is
no reason to expect mobile phones alone to eradicate corruption. After all, there are a number of countries outside of Africa that boast a lot of phones and a lot of corruption.
Accordingly, in order for mobile phones to decrease corruption, it is necessary that
there be someone on the other end of the line committed to the fight against corruption.
If there are no concerned citizens, aid agency representatives, reformers, or journalists
“dialing in” in the fight against corruption, phones alone will likely make little difference.
Therefore, the presence of some combination of public awareness campaigns, responsible
and vigilant aid agencies, sincere reform efforts, and/or a vigilant and unfettered news
media seems necessary for mobile phones to exert a negative influence on corruption.
Lastly, there exist a number of instances in which the diffusion of mobile phones may actually enhance rather than inhibit corrupt behavior. These instances can be characterized as those
in which some segment of the masses are directly involved in and benefit from the corrupt act.
Two examples of this category of corrupt acts are vote-buying and ethnic kinship demands.
Villagers directly benefit from the foodstuffs and small monetary payments they receive in
exchange for pledging their vote to a given candidate. Mobile phones feasibly make it easier for
candidates and parties to contact these voters for the purposes of making arrangements for the
buying of votes. In addition, mobile phones increase the ease with which villagers can contact
their officials once elected into office. This will feasibly make it more efficient for villagers to
attempt to extract goods by pressuring their officials to honor traditional kinship ties.
Nevertheless, despite the conditional nature of the impact of mobile phone diffusion
on corruption and despite the likelihood that mobile phones will increase the feasibility of
specific types of corrupt acts, this article contends that mobile phone diffusion will inhibit
corrupt behavior more often than facilitate it. In other words, the diffusion of mobile
phones will improve the ability to avoid, detect, and/or punish corruption to a greater
extent than it will enhance the ability to collude, conceal, and/or execute corrupt acts. This
is because a large proportion of corrupt acts in Africa can be characterized as collusion
between elites to the detriment of the masses. And, long before the diffusion of mobile
phones, elites possessed the telephonic resources to orchestrate and commit those acts. As
a consequence, the diffusion of mobile phones should only minimally enhance the capacity
for these elites to collude for the purposes of corruption. On the other hand, the massive
diffusion of mobile phones into a region where telecommunications infrastructure was
nearly nonexistent among nonelites greatly decentralizes information and communication.
This weakens elites’ monopoly over communication and information, thereby strengthening the potential for transparency and accountability. This will decrease the number of
opportunities available to commit corrupt acts as well as augment the potential to detect
and punish corrupt behavior. Accordingly, the following sections test the hypothesis that
the net effect of mobile phone expansion will be to diminish corruption in African nations.
Country-Level Analysis
Methods
To test whether the diffusion of mobile telephones correlates with decreased perceived
corruption levels in African nations, I employ a fixed effects OLS multiple regression
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
340
Catie Snow Bailard
based on panel data spanning from 1999 to 2006. The dependent variable used in this analysis is Transparency International’s Corruption Perceptions Index (CPI), which is a composite measure based on surveys from 3 to 14 different sources of country analysts and
resident and nonresident businesspeople.3 The original CPI assigns a score of between 1
and 10 (to the 10th unit) to each nation; with lower numeric scores indicating greater
levels of corruption. However, for ease of interpretation, this article employs an inverted
version of the CPI score, also ranging from 1 to 10—so that higher numeric scores now
represent more corrupt nations. Accordingly, a negative correlation coefficient now
indicates that a variable is associated with a decrease in corruption levels, while a positive
coefficient represents a positive relationship between that variable and corruption.
Opting to use the subjective measure of perceived corruption rather than a more objective measure of actual corruption is motivated by two considerations. First, corruption is
culturally variable—for example, what some countries might consider bribes, others may
accept as a necessary cost of doing business—rendering it a very difficult concept to
define consistently and accurately across borders. Second, as the following example from
Transparency International (2007) illustrates, reliable and valid data measuring corruption
are difficult to obtain: “Comparing the number of prosecutions, for example, does not
reflect actual levels of corruption but the quality of prosecutors” (p. 2).
As one corruption scholar remarks, “If corruption could be measured, it could
probably be eliminated. In fact, conceptually it is not even clear what one would want to
measure”; however, “while there are no direct ways of measuring corruption, there are
several indirect ways of getting information about its prevalence in a country” (Tanzi,
1998, pp. 576–577). Accordingly, the preferred measure of corruption utilized by corruption scholars is Transparency International’s subjective CPI measure. CPI does not force
each nation to conform to the same cookie-cutter formula of corruption, trusting instead
that country experts and other individuals well acquainted with each country are best
equipped to determine the extent to which official behavior deviates from accepted
national norms. The high level of correlation between the 14 sources used to build the
2007 CPI scores substantiates the reliability of this index, which Pearson’s and Kendall’s
rank correlations place at .77 and .62, respectively (Transparency International, 2007).
I build the primary independent variable of mobile phone penetration from data provided by the International Telecommunications Union, an agency of the United Nations.
This variable measures the number of mobile phone subscribers per 100 persons for each
nation. Recall that this indicator only represents subscribers, meaning that the number of
individuals with access to mobile phones reaches much higher once the friends, family,
and neighbors of mobile subscribers are taken into account. In fact, in some villages individuals have begun using their own mobile phones to start small businesses, renting out
their mobile phone for a fee (LaFraneire, 2005).
Accordingly, the impact of mobile phone penetration in Africa is best operationalized
as the logged value of the percentage of mobile subscribers in each nation. First, as previously stated, since the ITU’s measure of mobile subscribers only gauges the number of
subscribers, the number of individuals who have access to these phones and therefore
benefit from them is certainly higher than this measure would indicate.4 Second, as network analysts contend, the “value of a telephone network increases with the square of the
number of users,” since the n + 1st user benefits from being able to communicate with all
n prior users, and each of them gains from being able to communicate with her or him
(Daly, 2000, p. 288). In other words, as a result of network externalities, the more people
who use mobile phones, the larger the number of people those individuals can communicate with using those phones, thereby exponentially increasing the value of mobile
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
Corruption in Africa
341
phones. Because of these two considerations, I operationalize the value of mobile phone
penetration as the logged value of the number of subscribers in a given country for this
analysis.
This model also controls for a handful of factors that are correlated with both mobile
phone penetration and corruption.5 First, scholars often cite poverty and low wages as
exerting causal influences on corruption, since individuals’ need and willingness to capture
funds via corrupt behavior increases the greater their level of deprivation (Sandholtz &
Koetzle, 2000). As discussed above, scholars also argue that corruption exerts a reciprocal
effect on poverty by limiting economic development. Since poverty is also feasibly correlated with mobile phone penetration, by reducing the number of individuals who can
afford mobile phone service, this model incorporates a variable measuring GDP per capita.
Second, researchers have in addition identified a correlation between democracy and
corruption, with corruption levels declining once nations reach the more complete level of
democratization (Montinola & Jackman, 2002; Sandholtz & Koetzle, 2000). A strong
positive correlation between democratization and the expansion of telecommunications
infrastructure also exists (Kedzie, 1997; Best & Wade, 2005). To account for the potentially confounding influence of democracy, this model includes a measure of the strength
of democratic practices available in a nation.6
Third, the degree of privatization of a nation’s telecommunications industry is correlated
with both mobile phone penetration and corruption. As the International Telecommunications Union (2008) reports, increased competition in the telecommunications industry has
been a primary catalyst in the reduction of mobile prices across Africa, contributing to
expanded networks, reduced tariffs, and more affordable service provision. Privatization
(or the lack thereof) is also correlated with corruption, since “when the state and its administrative apparatus exercise relatively greater control over the economy, public officials
make decisions that determine who will enjoy access to economic resources. . . . Thus
bribery, extortion, and kickbacks become viable means of influencing distribution of
wealth” (Sandholtz & Koetzle, 2000, p. 37). To control for the correlates of privatization,
I include a World Bank governance indicator measuring each nation’s regulatory quality.7
This composite variable captures the degree to which government institutions generally
protect and promote market-friendly economic competition by means of a number of
factors, including business regulations, tax policy, privatization, and protectionism.8
Finally, this analysis controls for fixed effects. The inclusion of year and country
variables offers several important advantages in the testing of panel data. First, it allows the
model to control for factors that do not change over time, reducing concern that the model
fails to account for influential country-specific factors that are either difficult to identify or
difficult to measure. Fixed effects also confine the analysis to within-country variation, as
opposed to across-country variation, which is a more valid means of determining the effect
of mobile phone penetration on corruption within a country by minimizing the acrosscountry characteristics that are plausibly correlated with corruption (Allison, 2005).
Results
As predicted, greater mobile phone penetration is associated with lower levels of perceived
corruption, reaching the .01 significance level (see Table 1). In substantive terms, Cameroon’s
increase in mobile penetration from under 1 subscriber in 1999 to 24 subscribers per 100
individuals in 2006 (an increase approximate to just under two standard deviations) predicts a decrease in that country’s perceived level of corruption of .7 points. Considering
that the CPI’s entire scale ranges from 1 to 10, this represents an 8-percentage-point
342
Catie Snow Bailard
Table 1
Country-level regression of mobile phone penetration on CPI scores
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
Slope
Log of mobile phone penetration
(base 10, mean = .53, SD = .82)
GDP per capita (US$, mean = 1,512,
SD = 2,084)
Strength of democratic practices
(percentile ranking, mean = 33,
SD = 21)
Regulatory quality (percentile
ranking, mean = 35, SD = 19)
Intercept
−.47
SE
0.1
95%
confidence
interval
−.68 to −.27
.00004 0.00006 −.0001 to .0001
Statistical
significance
.001***
.550
−.02
0.006
−.03 to −.006
.004***
−.004
0.006
−.02 to .008
.480
9.7
0.3
Note. Number of cases: 219; adjusted r2: 92%. The dependent variable is the inverted CPI score,
which is a discrete variable ranging from 1 (lowest possible level of corruption) to 10 (highest
possible level of corruption), to the 10th unit. It has a mean of 8 and standard deviation of 1.1.
Country and year fixed-effects variables are also included in this regression, the coefficients of
which are not included in the table for brevity’s sake. These can be obtained from the author upon
request. In this table *** indicates significance at the .01 level.
improvement in that country’s perceived level of corruption across the entire spectrum of
possible scores. Moreover, being that African nations consistently rank among the most
corrupt in the world, the countries constituting this analysis actually span a much more
narrow range, from 4.6 to 10. Therefore, a .7-point improvement in a country’s CPI score
represents an upgrading of 13 percentage points across the range of cases considered in
this analysis. Finally, to test the robustness of these results, I conducted several iterations
of the original regression by omitting various combinations of independent variables—the
results of each largely analogous to those attained in the primary regression (see Table 2).
Individual-Level Analysis
Methods
Although the country-level regression of panel data substantiates the hypothesized negative effect of mobile phone penetration on perceived corruption, an individual-level analysis
of this relationship will provide a more compelling empirical foundation for this analysis.
As is often the case for cross-national analyses, the country-level analysis alone cannot
adequately assuage a number of potential methodological concerns, particularly endogeneity (i.e., when the independent and dependent variables share a reciprocal relationship),
omitted variable bias (i.e., failing to include an independent variable that should be in the
model), and ecological fallacy (i.e., an error of inference caused by assuming that an
observed association between given variables at the aggregate level also exists at the individual level). Therefore, I employ Afrobarometer survey data and mobile phone signal
coverage rates across the 13 Namibian provinces to determine whether mobile phone penetration is also correlated with reductions in perceived corruption at the individual level.
Corruption in Africa
343
Table 2
Robustness check of country-level regression of mobile phone penetration on CPI scores
Log of mobile phone
penetration
GDP per capita
Regression 1
Regression 2
Regression 3
Regression 4
−.52
(SE = .09,
p ≤ .01***)
−.55
(SE = .1,
p ≤ .001***)
−.47
(SE = .09,
p ≤ .01***)
−.53
(SE = .09,
p ≤ .01***)
.00001
(SE = .00007,
p ≤ .88)
Strength of democratic
practices
−.02 (SE = .006,
p ≤ .01***)
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
Regulatory quality
Intercept
−.01
(SE = .01,
p ≤ .11)
9.0 (N = 277, 8.9 (N = 219,
adj. r2 = 91%) adj. r2 = 92%)
9.4 (N = 224,
adj. r2 = 92%)
9.3
(adj. r2 = 91%)
Note. The dependent variable is the inverted CPI score, which is a discrete variable ranging from
1 (lowest possible level of corruption) to 10 (highest possible level of corruption), to the 10th unit.
It has a mean of 8 and standard deviation of 1.1. Each of these regression models includes only the
variables for which a correlation coefficient is listed in the table. Country and year fixed-effects
variables are also included in each of these regressions, the coefficients of which are not included in
the table for brevity’s sake. These can be obtained from the author upon request. In this table ***
indicates significance at the .01 level.
Of the 12 countries surveyed in both 1999 and 2006, I selected Namibia for this analysis because it was the best fit for three crucial criteria. First, the surveys in 1999 and 2006
both included questions pertaining to corruption with reasonably similar wording. Second,
Namibia experienced neither too little nor too great mobile phone signal expansion during
this period, permitting adequate variation in the measure of mobile phone signal coverage
across the provinces. And, third, the geographical size of the provinces is not so small as
to invite concern regarding the pixel quality of the GSM map used to build the independent variable of mobile signal coverage.
Factors related to both mobile phone penetration and corruption also render Namibia
an attractive candidate for this analysis. First, the growth in mobile phone penetration in
Namibia during this period was sufficient to make any causal claims regarding the impact
of mobile phones on corruption plausible. In 1999 less than 2% of Namibians subscribed
to mobile phones, whereas by 2005 this number had reached nearly 25%. Moreover, the
presence of a relatively active Anti-Corruption Commission in Namibia means that this
country meets at least one of the conditionality criteria set forth in the theory section.9
I derive the dependent variables measuring corruption perceptions in Namibia from
questions asked in the 1999 and 2006 Afrobarometer surveys. The first question asks
respondents to indicate how corrupt they believe the president’s administration to be. The
second question asks respondents to rate the degree of corruption among local government
officials. The final question inquires whether the respondents have had to pay a bribe in
order to receive household services, such as water or electricity, over the past year (see
Table 3 for exact question wordings). As a whole, these questions paint a relatively inclusive picture of corruption perceptions by tapping into assessments of corruption at both the
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
Table 3
Wording of questions from 1999 and 2006 Afrobarometer surveys
Perception of
corruption in
presidential
administration
344
Perception of
corruption
among local
government
officials
Paid a bribe in the
past year
1999
2006
What about corruption? (Corruption is where those in
government and the civil service take money or gifts from
people and use it for themselves, or expect people to pay
them extra money or a gift for them to do their job.) How
many officials in the Nujoma administration do you think
are involved in corruption? (Answers: 1. None, almost none;
2. A few, some; 3. Most; 4. All, almost all; 5. Don’t know)
What about corruption? How many officials in your local
government do you think are involved in corruption?
(Answers: 1. None, almost none; 2. A few, some;
3. Most; 4. All, almost all; 5. Don’t know)
How many of the following people do you think are involved
in corruption, or haven’t you heard enough about them to
say: the president and officials in his office? (Answers:
1. None; 2. Some of them; 3. Most of them; 4. All of them;
5. Don’t know)
How many of the following people do you think are involved
in corruption, or haven’t you heard enough about them to
say: local government officials? (Answers: 1. None; 2. Some
of them; 3. Most of them; 4. All of them; 5. Don’t know)
In the past year, have you or anyone in your family had to pay
money to government officials (besides paying rates or
taxes), give them a gift, or do them a favor in order to get
the following: electricity or water? (Answers: 1. No; 2.
Once or twice; 3. A few times; 4. Often; 5. Don’t know)
In the past year, how often, if ever, have you had to pay a
bribe, give a gift, or do a favor to government officials in
order to get a household service (like piped water, electricity,
or phone)?a (Answers: 1. No experience with thisb/no;
2. Once or twice; 3. A few times; 4. Often; 5. Don’t know)
a
The difference in the wordings of the bribery questions is potentially problematic. Whereas the 1999 version references family members, the 2006 question does
not. The inclusion of family members could potentially bias this dependent variable in favor of my hypothesis, since taking into account more people increases the
chances of having paid a bribe. On the other hand, the 2006 question asks about bribes paid for water and electricity but also includes telephone service as an example, while the 1999 question asks exclusively about water and electricity. The inclusion of additional services could feasibly bias this variable in the opposite direction than that predicted by my hypothesis, since considering additional services increases the number of opportunities in which that individual may have been bribed.
In sum, then, these two opposing potential biases may ultimately counterbalance one another. Moreover, since this regression primarily seeks to determine whether
living in a province with greater signal coverage has a distinctly more negative relationship with corruption perceptions in 2006 than it does in 1999, these questions
are adequate to permit this analysis. Essentially, the matter of interest is whether moving along the spectrum of less signal coverage to more signal coverage
decreases the likelihood of being bribed more dramatically in 2006 (when cell phones were present) than in 1999 (when cell phones were not present).
b
The 2006 question provided an additional option of answering “No experience with this in past year,” while the 1999 question did not include this option. As
such, these answers were collapsed into the “no” category in the 2006 data, since “no” is what respondents in 1999 would plausibly answer if they did not have the
option of answering “No experience with this in the previous year.”
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
Corruption in Africa
345
national and local levels, as well as the respondents’ actual experience with a particular act
of corruption.
Since the Afrobarometer does not ask respondents specifically about their access to a
mobile phone, the primary independent variable in this model is a measure of the percentage of each Namibian province that was covered by a mobile phone signal in late 2005.10
This is based on the logical assumption that the likelihood an individual uses a mobile
phone is correlated with the likelihood that the geographic area in which he or she resides
receives a mobile phone signal. Using province-level mobile signal coverage as the
independent variable also enables this analysis to address endogeneity concerns that the
country-level regression could not resolve.
Endogeneity occurs when the independent and dependent variables in a regression
share a simultaneous relationship, which would be the case if mobile phones and corruption exert a reciprocal influence on one another. This is problematic for an OLS regression
because the regression coefficient becomes biased and inconsistent, making it difficult to
measure or validate the independent and direct influence of mobile phone diffusion on
perceived corruption. It is preferable, therefore, to identify an instrument that is correlated
with the independent variable of interest but uncorrelated with the dependent variable.
In this case, this factor should be correlated with mobile phone diffusion but not directly
correlated with corruption.
Mobile signal coverage arguably meets each of these criteria. First, as discussed
above, the logic connecting mobile phone penetration with mobile signal coverage is
evident. Second, the findings of a recent econometric analysis (Buys, Dasgupta, Thomas,
& Wheeler, 2008) conducted by the World Bank provide a strong basis for arguing that
mobile signal coverage at the province level is uncorrelated with corruption. This study
reveals that the factors that are most determinant of the presence of cell towers in a specific region include size of adjacent population, costs of maintaining and installing the
towers (i.e., accessibility), and the national competition policy. Of these factors, the variable that is most plausibly correlated with corruption is the nation’s competition policy,
since market competition and corruption tend to share a negative relationship. However,
being that Namibia’s competition policy is determined at the national level and, therefore,
applies uniformly to all of its provinces, the competitive climate of the telecommunications industry is likely constant across the provinces included in this analysis. This suggests that the degree of mobile signal coverage at the province level is most driven by
population density and accessibility factors, and therefore exogenous to the relationship
shared by competition policy and corruption.11
To construct the measure of mobile signal coverage, I overlaid a 50-by-50 grid per
10-degree latitude-longitude square over a 2005 map of mobile phone signal coverage
across the Namibian provinces.12 Using this map, I divide the number of grid squares
covered by mobile phone signals by the total number of grid squares that each province
encompasses. This produces a measure of the percentage of each province’s geographical
space in which it was possible to use a mobile phone in 2005. The average level of mobile
signal coverage across these 13 provinces is 42% (SD = 25%), with a minimum of 6% in
Okavango and a maximum of 85% in Khomas.
In order to test whether gaining access to mobile phones altered respondents’ perceptions of corruption in Namibia, I conducted an OLS multiple regression of this 2005
measure of mobile signal coverage on the respondents’ perceptions of corruption in 1999
and 2006. By including an interaction term representing mobile signal coverage in 2006
specifically, it is possible to test whether living in a state with a high degree of mobile
signal coverage was correlated with a greater decline in perceived corruption in 2006
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
346
Catie Snow Bailard
(when mobile phones were actually present) than in 1999 (when mobile phones were not
yet being widely used). Moreover, this interaction term enables the analysis to address
omitted bias concerns that there may be some factors unaccounted for at the province
level, which are really driving the proposed relationship shared by mobile phone signal
coverage and corruption perceptions. If this is the case, the analysis should reveal a similar
correlation between the degree of mobile signal coverage in a province and the level of
corruption perceived by its residents in both 1999 and 2006. On the other hand, if mobile
phones do exert an independent influence on corruption perceptions, the correlation
between mobile signal coverage and corruption perceptions should be distinct from and
significantly more negative in 2006 than in 1999.
Finally, this analysis includes several demographic variables to control for personal
characteristics that are plausibly correlated with both the likelihood of using a cell phone
and attitudes regarding corruption. These factors include gender, age, education, employment status, and whether the individual lives in an urban or rural area. Lastly, the model
includes dummy variables for each of the 13 Namibian provinces to control for difficult to
identify or difficult to measure province-level factors.
Results
In all three cases, living in a province with greater mobile signal coverage exhibited a
significantly more negative relationship with corruption perceptions in 2006 when compared
to 1999. In other words, moving along the spectrum of more to less mobile signal coverage
is associated with a more significant decline in corruption perceptions in 2006 (when mobile
phones were actually present) than in 1999 (before mobile phones were widely present).
Moreover, in each case, the distinct 2006 relationship shared by mobile signal coverage and
corruption perceptions reaches statistical significance at the .01 level (see Table 4).
In substantive terms, in 1999 residents of the province of Otjozundjupa (mobile signal
coverage: 60%) rated the presidential administration to be 3 percentage points less corrupt
than did residents of Hardap (mobile coverage: 40%). By 2006, residents of Otjozundjupa
rated the extent of corruption in the presidential administration to be nearly 10 percentage
points lower than did Hardap residents. The difference in the extent of corruption that
respondents assigned to their local governments followed a similar trajectory between
1999 and 2006. In 1999, the level of corruption that residents assigned to their own local
government was 4 percentage points lower in Otjozundjupa (mobile signal coverage:
60%) than in Karas (mobile signal coverage: 31%). In 2006, this difference expanded
three-fold, to 14 percentage points. Turning to the matter of bribery, individuals living in
the province of Oshikoto (mobile signal coverage: 83%) were 5 percentage points less
likely to pay a bribe for household services in 1999 than respondents living in the province
of Kavango (mobile signal coverage: 6%). By 2006, however, Oshikoto residents had
become 15 percentage points less likely to pay a bribe for household services than
Kavango residents.
In summary, in all three cases, the effect of moving along the spectrum from lower to
higher mobile signal coverage on corruption perceptions was significantly more negative in
2006 than in 1999 (see Figures 1, 2, and 3). When compared to 1999, residents living in provinces with a greater degree of mobile signal coverage were significantly less likely to have paid
a bribe for household services than individuals living in provinces with less mobile coverage in
2006. The effect of living in a province with higher signal coverage also diminished the level
of corruption that respondents assigned to the presidential administration and local government
to a greater extent in 2006 when compared to 1999. Taken collectively, these results provide a
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
Table 4
Individual-level regression of mobile phone signal coverage on perceptions of corruption
Corruption
in presidential
administrationa
347
Mobile signal coverage of province (0–1 range,
mean = .42, SD = .25)
Year 2006 (0–1 binary, mean .5, SD = .5)
Interaction of mobile signal coverage and
year 2006 (0–1 range, .22, SD = .29)
Male (0–1 range, mean = .49, SD = .5)
Age (0–1 range, mean =.25, SD = .29)
Education (0–1 range, mean = .36, SD = .29)
Employment status (0–1 range, mean = .34,
SD = .44)
Urban (0–1 range, mean = .37, SD = .48)
Intercept
Corruption among local
government officialsb
Had to pay bribe
in past year for
household servicesc
−.17 (SE = .15, p ≤ .26 )
−.13 (SE = .82, p ≤ .87)
−.07 (SE = .48, p ≤ .89)
.02 (SE = .03, p ≤ .41)
−.31 (SE = .05, p ≤ .001***)
.22 (SE = .03, p ≤ .001***)
−.34 (SE = .06, p ≤ .001***)
.11 (SE = .01, p ≤ .001***)
−.10 (SE = .03, p ≤ .005***)
.01 (SE = .01, p ≤ .29)
−.03 (SE = .03, p ≤ .23)
−.02 (SE = .03, p ≤ .49)
−.03 (SE = .02, p ≤ .07*)
.020 (SE = .01, p ≤ .27)
.002 (SE = .03, p ≤ .95)
.006 (SE = .03, p ≤ .83)
−.030 (SE = .02, p ≤ .06*)
.005 (SE = .007, p ≤ .47)
−.030 (SE = .01, p ≤ .03**)
−.040 (SE = .01, p ≤ .004***)
.020 (SE = .009, p ≤ .06*)
.04 (SE = .02, p ≤ .03**)
.57 (N = 1,810, adj. r2 = 13%)
.04 (SE = .01, p ≤ .08*)
.47 (N = 1,699, adj. r2 = 8%)
.008 (SE = .01, p ≤ .43)
.06 (N = 2,128, adj. r2 = 5%)
Note. For the sake of brevity, I am not reporting the coefficients of the province dummy variables, but these results can be obtained from the author. In this table
* indicates significance at the .1 level, ** indicates significance at the .05 level, and *** indicates significance at the .01 level.
a
The dependent variable is how many members of the presidential administration respondents believe are corrupt. It ranges from 0 (none) to 1 (all), with intermediate values at .33 (some) and .66 (most). It has a mean of .35 and standard deviation of .3.
b
The dependent variable is how many members of the local government that respondents believe are corrupt. It ranges from 0 (none) to 1 (all), with intermediate
values at .33 (some) and .66 (most). It has a mean of .38 and standard deviation of .3.
c
The dependent variable is whether the respondent was asked to pay a bribe for household services in the previous year. It ranges from 0 (no) to 1 (often), with
intermediate values at .33 (once or twice) and .66 (a few times). It has a mean of .05 and standard deviation of .17.
348
Catie Snow Bailard
Change in Average Perception of
Presidential Corruption
20%
0%
–20%
–40%
1999
2006
–60%
0%
20%
40%
60%
80%
100%
Percentage of Province Covered by Mobile Phone
Signal
Figure 1. Different relative effects of living in a province with greater mobile signal coverage
on perceptions of presidential corruption before and after diffusion of mobile phones.
20%
Change in Average Perception of
Local Government Corruption
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
–80%
0%
–20%
1999
2006
–40%
–60%
–80%
0%
20%
40%
60%
80%
100%
Percentage of Province Covered by Mobile Phone
Signal
Figure 2. Different relative effects of living in a province with greater mobile signal coverage on
perceptions of local government corruption before and after diffusion of mobile phones.
relatively broad empirical foundation supporting the hypothesized negative influence of
mobile phone diffusion on corruption perceptions, by encompassing corruption assessments at
both the national and local levels as well as experience with a particular act of corruption.
Discussion and Conclusion
This analysis substantiates the hypothesized negative influence of mobile telephone diffusion on corruption perceptions at both the country and individual levels. These findings
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
Change in Likelihood of Paying Bribe for
Water or Electricity
Corruption in Africa
349
10%
0%
–10%
1999
2006
–20%
–30%
–40%
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
Percentage of Province Covered by Mobile Phone
Signal
Figure 3. Different relative effects of living in a province with greater mobile signal coverage on
likelihood of paying bribe for water or electricity before and after diffusion of mobile phones.
independently and mutually support the prediction that mobile telephone diffusion
will decrease corruption in Africa by decentralizing control over information and
communication—thereby decreasing the opportunities available to commit corrupt acts as
well as increasing the threat of detection and punishment. Nevertheless, there remain
some potential caveats that should be considered.
To begin with, recall that the dependent variables in this analysis largely represent subjective measures of perceived corruption, as opposed to more objective measures of actual
corruption. Opting to focus on perceived corruption was motivated by two considerations.
First, corruption is a culturally variable concept, making it very difficult to define consistently
and accurately across borders. Second, reliable and valid data measuring “actual” corruption
are difficult to obtain. Although scholars generally accept perceived corruption as a valid and
reliable proxy measure of actual corruption, it is plausible that mobile phones reduced
perceptions of corruption without actually diminishing the incidence of actual corruption. For
example, perhaps people conflate cell phones and the ability to communicate with greater
transparency, thereby assuming that more cell phones equal less corruption. This suggests
that over time, once the gleam wears off, the negative correlation between mobile phone diffusion and corruption perceptions will cease. Or, it is possible that individuals are so pleased
that they can now afford to use mobile phones that a sort of halo effect is produced that causes
mobile phone users to view their government officials more positively in general.
Although these are important potential caveats, I contend that controlling for privatization and GDP per capita at the country level and employment and education status at the
individual level should largely control for these possible influences. For example,
people’s intellectual capacity to associate mobile phones with greater transparency and,
therefore, reduced corruption should be somewhat dependent on their level of education.
Second, if individuals are rewarding officials because they are pleased that they can now
afford mobile phone service, this potentially confounding influence should be somewhat
mitigated by the inclusion of the GDP per capita and privatization measures at the aggregate level, as well as the employment status variable at the individual level.
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
350
Catie Snow Bailard
Finally, future analyses should explore the conditionalities upon which I argue a negative relationship between mobile phones and corruption rests. For example, to what
degree is some combination of public information campaigns, a vigilant press, sincere
reform efforts, and/or responsible aid agencies a necessary requisite for mobile phones to
exert a negative net effect on corruption? Moreover, what is the relative influence of each
of these factors?
In addition, future analyses should also investigate my claim that the Internet will
actually increase the incidence of specific types of corrupt acts. I define these particular
types of acts as those the masses are directly involved in and gain some immediate benefit
from—such as vote-buying and kinship demands. Beyond this, also consider whether the
expansion of the telecommunications industry itself will create more opportunities for
corruption as the executives of these companies negotiate licenses and contracts with
government officials. (However, I would argue that the increase in corrupt behavior
within the telecommunications industry specifically would likely be offset by the
increased ease with which reformers and journalists could monitor and detect corruption
in already-extant industries.) Accordingly, these considerations raise the question of
whether mobile phones will instead have the net effect of actually increasing corruption in
nations without at least one of the conditions listed above.
In conclusion, the findings produced in both the country- and individual-level analyses support the hypothesized negative influence of mobile phone diffusion on corruption
in Africa—reaching the .01 significance level in each case. Drawing from 46 nations over
the period 1999 to 2006, a fixed effects regression of panel data reveals a significant negative correlation between a country’s degree of mobile phone penetration and its level of
perceived corruption. Based on Afrobarometer surveys conducted in Namibia in 1999 and
2006, individual-level regressions also reveal a significantly distinct negative correlation
between mobile signal coverage and respondents’ perceptions of corruption in 2006. In
more detail, when compared to 1999 (before mobile phones were widely used), living in a
province with greater mobile signal coverage in 2006 (when mobile phones were widely
in use) significantly reduced how corrupt respondents tended to rate their presidential
administration and local government relative to respondents living in provinces with
lower mobile signal penetration. Moving along the spectrum from lesser to greater mobile
signal coverage also created a more significant reduction in the likelihood of having to pay
a bribe for household services in 2006 than it did in 1999.
Notes
1. CPI scores and mobile phone penetration rates were not available for each of these countries
in each of these years. Therefore, this analysis includes all of the cases in which both measures were
available for a given country in a given year—equaling 219 cases in all. For a specific list of these
cases, please contact the author.
2. For exceptions to this view, see Huntington (1968) and Leff (1964).
3. For more details about the how this measure is constructed, please visit http://www.transparency.
org/ policy_research /surveys_ indices/cpi.
4. Although in some countries subscribers may own multiple SIM cards, potentially inflating
this measurement of mobile subscribers, this is unlikely to be the case in African nations. Considering
the dire poverty most African nations face, it is highly unlikely that a large number of the individuals
living in these countries will find it economically feasible or even possible to own multiple mobile
phone subscriptions.
5. Summary statistics for each of the variables used in this analysis are included in the relevant
regression tables.
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
Corruption in Africa
351
6. This measure is derived from the World Bank’s Voice and Accountability governance
indicator. This measure represents the percentile rank of the strength of democratic practices available
in that nation. For more information, please refer to http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/
index.htm.
7. For more information regarding how the World Bank constructs the Regulatory Quality
Index, please visit http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/index.htm.
8. The World Bank does not provide measures for the Voice and Accountability and Regulatory Quality indexes for the years 1999 and 2001. To address this, I calculate the average of the
years immediately preceding and following 1999 and 2001. For example, the 1999 value included in
this analysis is the average of each country’s 1998 and 2000 scores.
9. For a detailed timeline of anti-corruption activities in Namibia, please refer to http://
www.anticorruption.info/ corr_in_time.php.
10. Since the Afrobarometer survey was conducted in the first months of 2006 (February 14 to
March 7), it is reasonable to assume that the 2005 map of mobile signal coverage in Namibia is
representative of the degree of coverage present in early 2006 when the respondents were surveyed.
11. One could argue that population density is correlated with corruption. However, a Pearson
product-moment correlation of the percentage of a nation’s population that lives in an urban area and
each nation’s CPI reveals that these factors are uncorrelated (−.06). In regard to a possible correlation between accessibility and corruption, the most obvious determinant of accessibility is the roadway infrastructure extant in a province. Essentially, the more roads, the easier it will be for mobile
service providers to erect cell towers in a particular region. As to whether the degree of roadway
infrastructure is correlated with corruption levels at the national level, roadway density [total
roadways (km)/total land area (km2)] is uncorrelated with perceived corruption (Pearson productmoment correlation: .1). At the provincial level in Namibia, road density is only very weakly correlated with the average level of corruption that residents assigned to the following in 1999: local
government corruption (−.21 ), presidential corruption (−.22), and likelihood of paying bribe (−.33).
Moreover, the relationship that these three average perceptions of corruption share with road density
fails to reach statistical significance in all three cases.
12. This map was published in the Information Society and Development Conference’s The
Acacia Atlas 2005: Mapping African ICT Growth, based on information provided by the GSM
Association. For more details and to view the map, please visit http://www.idrc.ca/uploads/user-S/
11836495021Acacia_Atlas_ 2005.pdf.
References
Abraham, R. (2007). Mobile phones and economic development: Evidence from the fishing industry
in India. Information Technologies and International Development, 4(1), 5–17.
Aker, J. C. (2008). Does digital divide or provide? The impact of cell phones on grain markets in
Niger. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, University of California–Berkeley.
Allison, P. D. (2005). Fixed effects regression methods for longitudinal data using SAS. Cary, NC:
SAS Institute.
Azfar, O., Lee, Y., & Swamy, A. (2001). The causes and consequences of corruption. Annals of the
American Academy of Political and Social Science, 573, 42–56.
Bardhan, P., & Mookherjee, D. (2000). Capture and governance at local and national levels. American
Economic Review, 90, 135–139.
Best, M. L., & Wade, K. W. (2005). The Internet and democracy: Global catalyst or democratic
dud? Retrieved from http://cyber.law.harvard.edu/publications
Buys, P., Dasgupta, S., Thomas, T., & Wheeler, D. (2008). Determinants of a digital divide in SubSaharan Africa: A spatial-economteric analysis of cell phone coverage. (The World Bank policy research working paper no. WPS 4516). Washington, DC: The World Bank Sustainable
Rural and Urban Development Team, Development Research Group.
Daly, J. A. (2000). Studying the impacts of the Internet without assuming technological determinism.
Aslib Proceedings, 52, 285–300.
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
352
Catie Snow Bailard
Das, J., Dercon, S., Habyarimana, J., & Krishnan, P. (2002). Rules vs. discretion: Public and private
funding in Zambian basic education. Part 1: Funding equity. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Donner, J. (2005). The use of mobile phones by microentrepreneurs in Kigali, Rwanda. Changes to
Social and Business Networks Information Technology and International Development, 3(2),
3–19.
Frost & Sullivan. (2006). Social impact of mobile telephony in Latin America. Retrieved from the
GSM Latin America Association Web site: http://www.gsmlaa.org/files/content/0/94/
Social%20Impact%20of%20Mobile%20Telephony%20in%20Latin%20America.pdf
Greenstone, J. D. (1966). Corruption and self-interest in Kampala and Nairobi. Comparative Studies
in Society and History, 8, 199–210.
Harsch, E. (1993). Accumulators and democrats: Challenging state corruption in Africa. Journal of
Modern African Studies, 31, 31–48.
Huntington, S. P. (1968). Political order in changing societies. New Haven, CT: Yale University
Press.
International Telecommunications Union. (2008). African Telecommunication/ICT indicators 2008:
At a crossroads. Geneva, Switzerland: Author.
Itano, N. (2005). Africa’s cell phone boom creates a base for low-cost banking. Christian Science
Monitor. Retrieved from http://www.csmonitor.com/2005/0826/p07s01-woaf.html
Jackson, R. H., & Rosberg, C. G. (1994). The political economy of African personal rule. In
D. Apter & and C. Rosberg (Eds.), Political development and the new realism in sub-Saharan
Africa (pp. 291–322). Charlottesville, VA: University of Virginia Press.
Jensen, R. (2007). The digital provide: Information (technology), market performance and welfare
in the South Indian fisheries. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 3, 879–924
Kedzie, C. R., with Aragon, J. (1997). Coincident revolutions and the emergent dictator’s dilemma:
Thoughts on communication and democratization. In J. E. Allison (Ed.), Technology, development,
and democracy: International conflict and cooperation in the information age (pp. 105–130).
Albany, NY: State University of New York Press.
Klitgaard, R. (1988). Controlling corruption. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
LaFraniere, S. (2005). Cellphones catapult rural Africa to 21st century. New York Times. Retrieved
from http://www.nytimes.com/2005/08/25/international/africa/25africa.html?ex=1282622400&
en=32b49363eac57aae&ei=5090&partner=rssuserland&emc=rss
Lane, B., Sweet, S., Lewin, D., Sephton, J., & Petini, I. (2006). The economic and social benefits of
mobile services in Bangladesh: A case study for the GSM Association. Retrieved from http://
www.dirsi.net/english/files/Ovum%20Bangladesh%20Main%20report1f.pdf
Leff, N. (1964). Economic development through bureaucratic corruption. American Behavioral
Scientist, 8(3), 8–14.
Leonard, D. K., & Straus, S. (2003). Africa’s stalled development: International causes and cures.
Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
LeVine, V. T. (1975). Political corruption: The Ghana case. Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution
Press.
Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 681–712.
Mauro, P. (1997). The effects of corruption on growth, investment, and government expenditure:
A cross-country analysis. In K. A. Elliott (Ed.), Corruption in the global economy (pp. 83–107).
Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.
Molony, T. (2005). Food, carvings and shelter: The adoption and appropriation of information and
communication technologies in Tanzanian micro and small enterprises. Unpublished doctoral
dissertation, University of Edinburgh.
Montinola, G. R., & Jackman, R. W. (2002). Sources of corruption: A cross-country study. British
Journal of Political Science, 32, 147–170.
Ngowi, R. (2005). Africa’s cellphone explosion changes economics, society. USA Today. Retrieved
from http://www.usatoday.com/tech/products/gear/2005-10-16-africa-cellular_x.htm
Ogendeji, O. A. (2008). GSM operator supports fight against corruption. Network World. Retrieved from
http://www.networkworld.com/news/2008/061608-gsm-operator-supports-fight-against.html
Downloaded By: [Bailard, Catie Snow] At: 22:45 4 August 2009
Corruption in Africa
353
Olivier de Sardan, J. P. (1999). A moral economy of corruption? Journal of Modern African Studies,
37, 25–52.
Platteau, J.-P., & Gaspart, F. (2003). The risk of resource misappropriation in community-driven
development. World Development, 31, 1687–1703.
Price Waterhouse Coopers. (1999). Health and Education Financial Tracking Study. Report prepared for government of Tanzania.
Rasmusen, E., & Ramseyer, J. M. (1994). Cheap bribes and the corruption ban: A coordination
game among rational legislators. Public Choice, 78, 305–327.
Rautray, S. (2006). Indian politician’s son guilty of model’s murder. Free Republic. Retrieved from
http://www.freerepublic.com/focus/f-news/1755260/posts
Reinikka, R., & Svensson, J. (2004). Local capture evidence from a central government transfer
program in Uganda. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 679–706.
Reinikka, R., & Svensson, J. (2005). Fighting corruption to improve schooling: Evidence from a
newspaper campaign in Uganda. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2, 259–267.
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1993). Corruption: A study in political economy. New York: Academic Press.
Ross, W. (2004). Mobile markets deny middlemen. BBC News. Retrieved from http://news.
bbc.co.uk/go/em/fr/-/2/hi/africa/3321167.stm
Samuel, J., Shah, N., & Hadingham, W. (2005). Mobile communications in South Africa, Tanzania
and Egypt: Results from community and business surveys. Vodafone Policy Paper Series, 2,
44–52.
Sandholtz, W., & Koetzle, W. (2000). Accounting for corruption: Economic structure, democracy,
and trade. International Studies Quarterly, 44, 31–50.
Schleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1993). Corruption. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 599–617.
Sullivan, K. (2006, July 9). In war-torn Congo, going wireless to reach home: For poor, cellphones
bridge digital divide. Washington Post, p. A1.
Szetfel, M. (2000). Clientelism, corruption, & catastrophe. Review of African Political Economy, 27,
427–441.
Tanzi, V. (1998). Corruption around the world: Causes, consequences, scope, and cures. Staff
Papers of the International Monetary Fund, 45, 559–594.
Treisman, D. (2000). The causes of corruption: A cross-national study. Journal of Public Economics,
76, 399–457.
Ye, X., & Canagarajah, S. (2002). Efficiency of public expenditure distribution and beyond: A report
on Ghana’s 2000 Public Expenditure Tracking Survey of Primary Health and Education.
Washington DC: World Bank.