TRADE, INVESTMENT AND TAX
COOPERATION
Tax Competition
Lead author:
Christian von Haldenwang,
German Development Institute (DIE)
Tommaso Faccio, Independent Commission for the
Reform of International Corporate Taxation
Tobias Hentze, German Economic Institute
Thomas Mättig, Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung
Irma Johanna Mosquera Valderrama, Leiden University
Agustín Redonda, Council on Economic Policies
Gabriela Rigoni, Universidad Nacional de La Plata (UNLP)
- Universidad Nacional de Buenos Aires (UBA)
Jakob Schwab, German Development Institute (DIE)
Rob Vos, International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI)
www.t20argentina.org
/T20Solutions
@T20Solutions
/T20Solutions
Abstract
The world is facing a new round of international tax competition that may
result in a ruinous race to the bottom, undermining the fiscal capacity of
states to respond to global challenges and to implement the Agenda 2030.
G20 leaders must take action to strengthen multilateral and cooperative
approaches to taxation, curtail harmful tax competition and protect their own
tax base as well as that of developing countries.
Challenge
Tax competition may be an important tool to attract investment, but more
often than not it undermines the capacity of governments to mobilize
sufficient resources to finance public services - including those services that
are essential for sustainable development and economic growth. Particularly
harmful are tax competition practices that a) erode the tax bases of other
countries, thereby diminishing global welfare, b) deny other countries the
opportunity to adapt their tax regimes in response to unwanted spillovers,
due to a lack of transparency of the measures, or c) introduce market
distortions in favor of specific groups or actors by shifting the tax burden to
the disadvantage of other groups or actors, thereby undermining the fairness
and social acceptance of tax systems.
The US tax reform of December 2017 threatens to trigger another round of
worldwide tax competition, as other G20 governments may feel urged to
adjust their corporate tax regimes as well. We see the risk of a downward
spiral driven by three mechanisms:
•
First, race-to-the-bottom corporate tax competition may involve
lowering statutory tax rates as well as providing additional tax breaks
for specific types of economic activity. In particular the latter tend to
be harmful because they distort markets.
•
Second, preferential tax regimes, distorting investment incentives and
so-called anti-abuse rules as in the case of the US tax reform affect the
level playing field significantly. If other countries react with similar
measures, the resulting global tax structure could be even more
complex and mutually harmful.
•
Third, while tax cuts might boost economic growth in the short run,
growing budgetary deficits could be a hindrance to growth in the
medium term, as higher budget deficits would push up interest rates,
which would discourage investment. For instance, the US tax reform is
expected to cause an additional deficit of between USD 0.5 and 1.5
trillion over the coming decade, depending on the source of the
estimation. This limits the space for public policies in the future and
2
puts a strain on coming generations, especially against the background
of already high public debt rates in the US. If other governments would
follow suit, fiscal space would shrink globally and limit resource
availability for promoting balanced, sustainable and inclusive growth.
The consequences are likely to differ across countries:
•
First, industrialized countries could see their tax base affected by a new
round of corporate tax competition. By contrast, many developing
countries might be less directly affected by this type of tax competition
- either because they seek investments in sectors where market
barriers exist (for instance, extractive industries) or because they
already offer generous tax breaks in highly competitive sectors.
However, they are likely to suffer from indirect effects, as their
revenues from direct taxes are often heavily dependent on corporate
taxation, the lion's share of which is typically borne by a small number
of multinational corporations (MNCs). Developing countries could be
under pressure to raise indirect taxes, shifting the tax burden further
from corporations to consumers, particularly middle- and low-income
sectors.
•
Second, in addition, many measures already undertaken or foreseen by
G20 member countries (such as for instance certain tax incentives for
research and development) create additional competitive advantages
for large MNCs which might lead to new distortions in the economic
structure of countries worldwide, thereby affecting the capabilities of
national economies to innovate, create jobs and adapt to the
transformation of global production patterns, in particular to the
growing digitalization of the world economy.
Proposal
Abolishing and preventing economic distortions of the kind outlined above
should be a main goal of international tax policy. We ask G20 leaders to take
urgent and decisive action in two distinctive though interrelated topics: (a)
reverse the current tendency to engage in harmful tax competition and (b)
provide a level playing field for taxation and investment.
1. Reverse the current tendency to engage in harmful tax competition
G20 leaders should deepen cooperation with regard to the exchange of taxrelated information and the fight against Base Erosion and Profit Shifting
(BEPS)
Unilateral action by individual countries, as powerful as they may be, is not
an adequate response to the requirements of taxing a globalised economy.
Any gains arising from such action will be short-lived, as other countries are
3
likely to introduce compensatory measures and economic actors should be
expected to quickly adapt to the changing conditions.
A change of investment behaviour due to tax reforms is not necessarily
negative, but cooperation should take account of differences in capacities of
developed and developing countries to undertake appropriate action.
Research shows that countries are taking different approaches to the
implementation of BEPS Actions (IBFD 2018, Mosquera Valderrama 2018),
leading to peculiar and undesired forms of tax competition. We observe that
countries implementing BEPS are sometimes in disadvantage with respect to
countries that are not implementing BEPS. For instance, BEPS minimum
standard Action 6, which aims at "Preventing the Granting of Treaty Benefits
in Inappropriate Circumstances" foresees the inclusion of principal purpose
tests (PPT) in tax treaties. These tests create an extra requirement for
taxpayers who are investing in that country. Discretionary application of the
principal purpose test by tax administrations can introduce additional
distortions in the global competition for investments. In this sense, balancing
competition and BEPS implementation is needed to achieve a global model
of tax governance in which developed and developing countries compete on
a level playing field.
We ask the G20 leaders to promote regional cooperation in the
implementation of international standards, including BEPS. The G20 should
facilitate the creation of regional (or sub-regional) peer review and
consultancy mechanisms that would allow countries to set and revise their
own goals and targets for implementation, getting regular feedback from
neighbouring countries. The G20 should actively promote regional learning
processes: To give an example, the exchange of information (for instance, on
trade flows and taxation) between neighbouring countries could be used to
jointly implement technical platforms and standards and to build
administrative capacity. This would make countries fit for the exchange of
information on a broader international scale and allow them to better use that
information locally.
G20 leaders should agree on a minimum corporate tax rate
Tax competition has harmful consequences for the global provision of public
goods when effective tax rates of all countries end up below the level that
countries would have chosen if no measure to attract foreign tax bases was
introduced or if no reaction to other countries' measures was required. This
has distributional effects to the disadvantage of immobile factors and
impedes a fair sharing of the burden of financing sustainable development
between all economic actors. Currently, average statutory corporate tax
rates around the world are converging at around 25 per cent. Many tax
havens apply much lower rates. While the BEPS project tackles some of the
most pressing issues regarding corporate tax evasion and avoidance, it only
marginally addresses the problem of tax competition. Initiatives on tax
coordination between countries only exist at a regional level within the EU
4
and the West African Economic and Monetary Union (WAEMU). A practical
approach towards establishing a minimum level of tax coordination about
particularly harmful practices of corporate taxation would be to agree on a
minimum corporate tax rate.
G20 leaders should explore the possibility of introducing a minimum
corporate tax rate to be applied to the worldwide profits of private
companies. Such a common minimum corporate tax rate would stop
rewarding tax havens and prevent a race to the bottom, while keeping G20based multinational companies, as well as other companies and permanent
establishments operating in G20 countries, on a level-playing field with
competitors. Such a minimum tax rate should help limit both tax avoidance
and harmful tax competition. The determination of corporate tax rates above
the minimum level would remain subject to the national tax rules.
2. Provide a level playing field for taxation and investment
G20 leaders should Improve the transparency of tax instruments for the
attraction of investments
We ask G20 leaders to ensure that tax instruments used for the attraction of
investments are employed with a view on creating, rather than undermining
the level-playing field for investors. Clarity, simplicity and reliability are
relevant criteria in this context. Measures to improve the design and
transparency of tax incentives are presented in the T20 Policy Brief on "Tax
Expenditure and the Treatment of Tax Incentives for Investment".
G20 leaders should work towards a common corporate tax base and explore
ways to treat multinationals as single entities
Some progress has been made in addressing tax avoidance by multinational
corporations in recent years. Much remains to be done, however. We ask G20
leaders to engage in a strategic debate on a reform of tax systems to make
these fit for purpose in a globalised economy in which many companies
operate across borders, but are managed as one single entity. A first step in
this direction would be to broaden existing initiatives under the BEPS project,
especially regarding the digital economy, as the delay in the introduction of
tax measures to address the challenges of digitalization implies, in practice,
an underlying preferential tax regime.
A second step would be to agree on a common corporate tax base (CCTB),
applying harmonized nexus and profit allocation concepts in line with the
exigencies of digitalization. As a third, longer-term measure, introducing a
common consolidated corporate tax base (CCCTB) with broad international
applicability would be an adequate approach to taxing the globalized and
digitalized world economy. This approach would take into account assets
invested, human resources employed and sales generated/destined.
5
Consolidation in this context means that, rather than individual jurisdictions,
the overall distribution of the above-mentioned factors (capital, labour, sales)
would be taken into account to allocate the tax base. We see important
benefits of this approach with regard to the simplicity and certainty of
taxation, the lowering of compliance costs, the internalization of unwanted
spillover effects and a further facilitation of cross-border trade and
investment. As the European Union is moving in the direction of
implementing a CCTB and, subsequently, a CCCTB, we urge G20 leaders to
explore opportunities for the scaling-up of this initiative.
That the G20 promotes and facilitates: a) the organization of a Special Group
of countries (composed by Argentina, Australia, Brazil, Canada, New Zealand,
Thailand and USA, as net exporters; China, Korea, Japan, Russia and Saudi
Arabia as main net importers; and India as a top trader, b) that, within the
institutional space in WTO, a permanent Secretariat is established to convene
the Group for the purpose of dialogue, exchange of information and progress
in special trading arrangements to facilitate a freer global trade in food
among them and a greater market stability worldwide.
G20 leaders should promote the use of new technologies to fight trade
mispricing and misinvoicing
We ask G20 leaders to jointly promote the use of digital technologies, such
as blockchain technology, as an instrument to improve the transparency and
security of trade flows. This includes making tax and customs administrations
fit for such purpose and enabling them to exchange the necessary
information by means of public infrastructure investments and capacity
development. We further ask G20 leaders to provide the necessary means to
support low- and lower-middle-income countries in their own digitalization
agenda, in order to enable them to take part in the exchange of such
information and to benefit from a better control of trade flows.
Additional measures to tackle current challenges in the taxation of the digital
economy are presented in the T20 Policy Brief on "Digital Trade and Digital
Taxation".
6
References
Independent Commission for the Reform of International Corporate Taxation (ICRICT)
(2016):
Four
ways
to
tackle
tax
international
competition
https://static1.squarespace.com/static/5a0c602bf43b5594845abb81/t/5a25cdcbec212dbe
ed80d78c/1512426962658/ICRICT_Tax+Competition+Report_ENG_web+version+%281%29
.pdf
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) (2015): World Invstment
Report, Chapter 5: International Tax and Investment Policy Coherence. Geneve: UNCTAD
http://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2015_en.pdf
IBFD: BEPS in Latin America (Part I): A review of the implementation of minimum standards
and the peer review process. White paper Available at https://www.ibfd.org/IBFD-TaxPortal/White-Papers
Mosquera Valderrama I.J. (2018), Output Legitimacy Deficits and the Inclusive Framework of
the OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Initiative, Bulletin for International Taxation
72(3). https://openaccess.leidenuniv.nl/handle/1887/59348
European Economic and Social Committee. (2017). Opinion of the European Economic and
Social Committee - Proposal for a Council Directive on a Common Consolidated Corporate
Tax Base (CCCTB) - Proposal for a Council Directive on a Common Corporate Tax Base
(CCTB).
Brussels:
Council
of
the
European
Union
https://politx.de/documents/592905/europa/eu-dokumente/european-economic-and-socialcommittee-2017-12-19-opinion-of-the-european-economic-and-social-committee-on-theproposal-for-a-council-directive-on-a-common-consolidated-corporate-tax-base-ccctbcom2016-683-final-20160336-cns-and-on-the-proposal-for-a-council-directive-on-acommon-corporate-tax-base-com2016-685-final-20160337-cns
Tax Policy Center (2017): Analysis of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (27.12.2017):
http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/feature/analysis-tax-cuts-and-jobs-act
Tax Foundation (2017): Preliminary Details and Analysis of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act, Special
Report No. 241:
https://files.taxfoundation.org/20171220113959/TaxFoundation-SR241TCJA-3.pdf
7