27
ECONOMIC ISSUES
Tax Policy for
Developing Countries
Vito Tanzi
Howell Zee
I N T E R N A T I O N A L M O N E T A R Y
W A S H I N G T O N ,
F U N D
D . C .
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
©2001 International Monetary Fund
Series Editor
Jeremy Clift
IMF External Relations Department
Cover design and composition
Massoud Etemadi, Julio R. Prego, and
the IMF Graphics Section
ISBN 1-58906-020-2
ISSN 1020-5098
Published March 2001
To order IMF publications, please contact:
International Monetary Fund, Publication Services
700 19th Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20431, U.S.A.
Tel: (202) 623-7430
Telefax: (202) 623-7201
E-mail:
[email protected]
Internet: http://www.imf.org
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Preface
The Economic Issues series aims to make available to a broad
readership of nonspecialists some of the economic research being
produced on topical issues by IMF staff. The series draws mainly
from IMF Working Papers, which are technical papers produced by
IMF staff members and visiting scholars, as well as from policyrelated research papers.
This Economic Issue is based on IMF Working Paper 00/35 "Tax
Policy for Emerging Markets," by Vito Tanzi and Howell Zee.
Citations for the research referred to in this shortened version are
provided in the original paper which readers can purchase (at
$10.00 a copy) from the IMF Publication Services or download from
www.imf.org. David Driscoll prepared the text for this pamphlet.
iii
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
This page intentionally left blank
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Tax Policy for Developing
Countries
hy do we have taxes? The simple answer is that, until someone comes up with a better idea, taxation is the only practical
means of raising the revenue to finance government spending on the
goods and services that most of us demand. Setting up an efficient
and fair tax system is, however, far from simple, particularly for
developing countries that want to become integrated in the international economy. The ideal tax system in these countries should raise
essential revenue without excessive government borrowing, and
should do so without discouraging economic activity and without
deviating too much from tax systems in other countries.
Developing countries face formidable challenges when they
attempt to establish efficient tax systems. First, most workers in these
countries are typically employed in agriculture or in small, informal
enterprises. As they are seldom paid a regular, fixed wage, their earnings fluctuate, and many are paid in cash, "off the books." The base
for an income tax is therefore hard to calculate. Nor do workers in
these countries typically spend their earnings in large stores that keep
accurate records of sales and inventories. As a result, modern means
of raising revenue, such as income taxes and consumer taxes, play a
diminished role in these economies, and the possibility that the government will achieve high tax levels is virtually excluded.
Second, it is difficult to create an efficient tax administration without a well-educated and well-trained staff, when money is lacking to
pay good wages to tax officials and to computerize the operation (or
even to provide efficient telephone and mail services), and when
W
1
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
taxpayers have limited ability to keep accounts. As a result, governments often take the path of least resistance, developing tax systems
that allow them to exploit whatever options are available rather than
establishing rational, modern, and efficient tax systems.
Third, because of the informal structure of the economy in many
developing countries and because of financial limitations, statistical
and tax offices have difficulty in generating reliable statistics. This lack
of data prevents policymakers from assessing the potential impact of
major changes to the tax system. As a result, marginal changes are
often preferred over major structural changes, even when the latter
are clearly preferable. This perpetuates inefficient tax structures.
Fourth, income tends to be unevenly distributed within developing countries. Although raising high tax revenues in this situation
ideally calls for the rich to be taxed more heavily than the poor, the
economic and political power of rich taxpayers often allows them to
prevent fiscal reforms that would increase their tax burdens. This
explains in part why many developing countries have not fully
exploited personal income and property taxes and why their tax systems rarely achieve satisfactory progressivity (in other words, where
the rich pay proportionately more taxes).
In conclusion, in developing countries, tax policy is often the art
of the possible rather than the pursuit of the optimal. It is therefore
not surprising that economic theory and especially optimal taxation
literature have had relatively little impact on the design of tax systems in these countries. In discussing tax policy issues facing many
developing countries today, the authors of this pamphlet consequently draw on extensive practical, first-hand experience with the
IMF's provision of tax policy advice to those countries. They consider these issues from both the macroeconomic (the level and composition of tax revenue) and microeconomic (design aspects of
specific taxes) perspective.
2
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Level of Tax Revenue
What level of public spending is desirable for a developing country at a given level of national income? Should the government
spend one-tenth of national income? A third? Half? Only when this
question has been answered can the next question be addressed of
where to set the ideal level of tax revenue; determining the optimal
tax level is conceptually equivalent to determining the optimal level
of government spending. Unfortunately, the vast literature on optimal tax theory provides little practical guidance on how to integrate
the optimal level of tax revenue with the optimal level of government expenditure.
Nevertheless, an alternative, statistically based approach to assessing whether the overall tax level in a developing country is appropriate consists of comparing the tax level in a specific country to the
average tax burden of a representative group of both developing
and industrial countries, taking into account some of these countries' similarities and dissimilarities. This comparison indicates only
whether the country's tax level, relative to other countries and taking into account various characteristics, is above or below the average. This statistical approach has no theoretical basis and does not
indicate the "optimal" tax level for any country. The most recent
data show that the tax level in major industrialized countries (members of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development or OECD) is about double the tax level in a representative sample of developing countries (38 percent of GDP compared with 18 percent).
Economic development will often generate additional needs for
tax revenue to finance a rise in public spending, but at the same
time it increases the countries' ability to raise revenue to meet these
needs. More important than the level of taxation per se is how revenue is used. Given the complexity of the development process, it
is doubtful that the concept of an optimal level of taxation robustly
linked to different stages of economic development could ever be
meaningfully derived for any country.
3
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Composition of Tax Revenue
Turning to the composition of tax revenue, we find ourselves in
an area of conflicting theories. The issues involve the taxation of
income relative to that of consumption and under consumption, the
taxation of imports versus the taxation of domestic consumption.
Both efficiency (whether the tax enhances or diminishes the overall
welfare of those who are taxed) and equity (whether the tax is fair
to everybody) are central to the analysis.
The conventional belief that taxing income entails a higher welfare (efficiency) cost than taxing consumption is based in part on
the fact that income tax, which contains elements of both a labor tax
and a capital tax, reduces the taxpayer's ability to save. Doubt has
been cast on this belief, however, by considerations of the crucial
role of the length of the taxpayer's planning horizon and the cost of
human and physical capital accumulation. The upshot of these theoretical considerations renders the relative welfare costs of the two
taxes (income and consumption) uncertain.
Another concern in the choice between taxing income and taxing
consumption involves their relative impact on equity. Taxing consumption has traditionally been thought to be inherently more
regressive (that is, harder on the poor than the rich) than taxing
income. Doubt has been cast on this belief as well. Theoretical and
practical considerations suggest that the equity concerns about the
traditional form of taxing consumption are probably overstated and
that, for developing countries, attempts to address these concerns by
such initiatives as graduated consumption taxes would be ineffective and administratively impractical.
With regard to taxes on imports, lowering these taxes will lead to
more competition from foreign enterprises. While reducing protection of domestic industries from this foreign competition is an
inevitable consequence, or even the objective, of a trade liberalization program, reduced budgetary revenue would be an unwelcome
by-product of the program. Feasible compensatory revenue measures under the circumstances almost always involve increasing
domestic consumption taxes. Rarely would increasing income taxes
be considered a viable option on the grounds of both policy
4
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
(because of their perceived negative impact on investment) and
administration (because their revenue yield is less certain and less
timely than that from consumption tax changes).
Data from industrial and developing countries show that the ratio
of income to consumption taxes in industrial countries has consistently remained more than double the ratio in developing countries.
(That is, compared with developing countries, industrial countries
derive proportionally twice as much revenue from income tax than
from consumption tax.) The data also reveal a notable difference in
the ratio of corporate income tax to personal income tax. Industrial
countries raise about four times as much from personal income tax
than from corporate income tax. Differences between the two country groups in wage income, in the sophistication of the tax administration, and in the political power of the richest segment of the population are the primary contributors to this disparity. On the other
hand, revenue from trade taxes is significantly higher in developing
countries than in industrial countries.
While it is difficult to draw clear-cut normative policy prescriptions from international comparisons as regards the incomeconsumption tax mix, a compelling implication revealed by the
comparison is that economic development tends to lead to a relative shift in the composition of revenue from consumption to personal income taxes. At any given point of time, however, the important tax policy issue for developing countries is not so much to
determine the optimal tax mix as to spell out clearly the objectives
to be achieved by any contemplated shift in the mix, to assess the
economic consequences (for efficiency and equity) of such a shift,
and to implement compensatory measures if the poor are made
worse off by the shift.
5
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Selecting the Right Tax System
In developing countries where market forces are increasingly
important in allocating resources, the design of the tax system
should be as neutral as possible so as to minimize interference in
the allocation process. The system should also have simple and
transparent administrative procedures so that it is clear if the system
is not being enforced as designed.
Personal Income Tax
Any discussion of personal income tax in developing countries
must start with the observation that this tax has yielded relatively little revenue in most of these countries and that the number of individuals subject to this tax (especially at the highest marginal rate) is
small. The rate structure of the personal income tax is the most visible policy instrument available to most governments in developing
countries to underscore their commitment to social justice and
hence to gain political support for their policies. Countries frequently attach great importance to maintaining some degree of
nominal progressivity in this tax by applying many rate brackets,
and they are reluctant to adopt reforms that will reduce the number
of these brackets.
More often than not, however, the effectiveness of rate progressivity is severely undercut by high personal exemptions and the
plethora of other exemptions and deductions that benefit those with
high incomes (for example, the exemption of capital gains from tax,
generous deductions for medical and educational expenses, the low
taxation of financial income). Tax relief through deductions is particularly egregious because these deductions typically increase in
the higher tax brackets. Experience compellingly suggests that effective rate progressivity could be improved by reducing the degree of
nominal rate progressivity and the number of brackets and reducing exemptions and deductions. Indeed, any reasonable equity
objective would require no more than a few nominal rate brackets
in the personal income tax structure. If political constraints prevent
a meaningful restructuring of rates, a substantial improvement in
6
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
equity could still be achieved by replacing deductions with tax credits, which could deliver the same benefits to taxpayers in all tax
brackets.
The effectiveness of a high marginal tax rate is also much reduced
by its often being applied at such high levels of income (expressed
in shares of per capita GDP) that little income is subject to these
rates. In some developing countries, a taxpayer's income must be
hundreds of times the per capita income before it enters the highest
rate bracket.
Moreover, in some countries the top marginal personal income
tax rate exceeds the corporate income tax by a significant margin,
providing strong incentives for taxpayers to choose the corporate
form of doing business for purely tax reasons. Professionals and
small entrepreneurs can easily siphon off profits through expense
deductions over time and escape the highest personal income tax
permanently. A tax delayed is a tax evaded. Good tax policy, therefore, ensures that the top marginal personal income tax rate does
not differ materially from the corporate income tax rate.
In addition to the problem of exemptions and deductions tending
to narrow the tax base and to negate effective progressivity, the personal income tax structure in many developing countries is riddled
with serious violations of the two basic principles of good tax policy: symmetry and inclusiveness. (It goes without saying, of course,
that tax policy should also be guided by the general principles of
neutrality, equity, and simplicity.) The symmetry principle refers to
the identical treatment for tax purposes of gains and losses of any
given source of income. If the gains are taxable, then the losses
should be deductible. The inclusiveness principle relates to capturing an income stream in the tax net at some point along the path of
that stream. For example, if a payment is exempt from tax for a
payee, then it should not be a deductible expense for the payer.
Violating these principles generally leads to distortions and
inequities.
The tax treatment of financial income is problematic in all countries. Two issues dealing with the taxation of interest and dividends
in developing countries are relevant:
7
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
• In many developing countries, interest income, if taxed at all, is
taxed as a final withholding tax at a rate substantially below both
the top marginal personal and corporate income tax rate. For taxpayers with mainly wage income, this is an acceptable compromise between theoretical correctness and practical feasibility. For
those with business income, however, the low tax rate on interest income coupled with full deductibility of interest expenditure
implies that significant tax savings could be realized through fairly
straightforward arbitrage transactions. Hence it is important to target carefully the application of final withholding on interest
income: final withholding should not be applied if the taxpayer
has business income.
• The tax treatment of dividends raises the well-known double taxation issue. For administrative simplicity, most developing countries would be well advised either to exempt dividends from the
personal income tax altogether, or to tax them at a relatively low
rate, perhaps through a final withholding tax at the same rate as
that imposed on interest income.
Corporate Income Tax
Tax policy issues relating to corporate income tax are numerous
and complex, but particularly relevant for developing countries are
the issues of multiple rates based on sectoral differentiation and the
incoherent design of the depreciation system. Developing countries
are more prone to having multiple rates along sectoral lines (including the complete exemption from tax of certain sectors, especially
the parastatal sector) than industrial countries, possibly as a legacy
of past economic regimes that emphasized the state's role in
resource allocation. Such practices, however, are clearly detrimental
to the proper functioning of market forces (that is, the sectoral allocation of resources is distorted by differences in tax rates). They are
indefensible if a government's commitment to a market economy is
real. Unifying multiple corporate income tax rates should thus be a
priority.
8
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Allowable depreciation of physical assets for tax purposes is an
important structural element in determining the cost of capital and
the profitability of investment. The most common shortcomings
found in the depreciation systems in developing countries include
too many asset categories and depreciation rates, excessively low
depreciation rates, and a structure of depreciation rates that is not in
accordance with the relative obsolescence rates of different asset
categories. Rectifying these shortcomings should also receive a high
priority in tax policy deliberations in these countries.
In restructuring their depreciation systems, developing countries
could well benefit from certain guidelines:
• Classifying assets into three or four categories should be more
than sufficient—for example, grouping assets that last a long time,
such as buildings, at one end, and fast-depreciating assets, such
as computers, at the other with one or two categories of machinery and equipment in between.
• Only one depreciation rate should be assigned to each category.
• Depreciation rates should generally be set higher than the actual
physical lives of the underlying assets to compensate for the lack
of a comprehensive inflation-compensating mechanism in most
tax systems.
• On administrative grounds, the declining-balance method should
be preferred to the straight-line method. The declining-balance
method allows the pooling of all assets in the same asset category
and automatically accounts for capital gains and losses from asset
disposals, thus substantially simplifying bookkeeping requirements.
Value-Added Tax, Excises, and Import Tariffs
While VAT has been adopted in most developing countries, it frequently suffers from being incomplete in one aspect or another.
Many important sectors, most notably services and the wholesale
and retail sector, have been left out of the VAT net, or the credit
mechanism is excessively restrictive (that is, there are denials or
delays in providing proper credits for VAT on inputs), especially
9
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
when it comes to capital goods. As these features allow a substantial degree of cascading (increasing the tax burden for the final
user), they reduce the benefits from introducing the VAT in the first
place. Rectifying such limitations in the VAT design and administration should be given priority in developing countries.
Many developing countries (like many OECD countries) have
adopted two or more VAT rates. Multiple rates are politically attractive because they ostensibly—though not necessarily effectively—
serve an equity objective, but the administrative price for addressing
equity concerns through multiple VAT rates may be higher in developing than in industrial countries. The cost of a multiple-rate system
should be carefully scrutinized.
The most notable shortcoming of the excise systems found in
many developing countries is their inappropriately broad coverage
of products—often for revenue reasons. As is well known, the economic rationale for imposing excises is very different from that for
imposing a general consumption tax. While the latter should be
broadly based to maximize revenue with minimum distortion, the
former should be highly selective, narrowly targeting a few goods
mainly on the grounds that their consumption entails negative externalities on society (in other words, society at large pays a price for
their use by individuals). The goods typically deemed to be excisable (tobacco, alcohol, petroleum products, and motor vehicles, for
example) are few and usually inelastic in demand. A good excise
system is invariably one that generates revenue (as a by-product)
from a narrow base and with relatively low administrative costs.
Reducing import tariffs as part of an overall program of trade liberalization is a major policy challenge currently facing many developing countries. Two concerns should be carefully addressed. First,
tariff reduction should not lead to unintended changes in the relative rates of effective protection across sectors. One simple way of
ensuring that unintended consequences do not occur would be to
reduce all nominal tariff rates by the same proportion whenever
such rates need to be changed. Second, nominal tariff reductions are
likely to entail short-term revenue loss. This loss can be avoided
through a clear-cut strategy in which separate compensatory measures are considered in sequence: first reducing the scope of tariff
10
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
exemptions in the existing system, then compensating for the tariff
reductions on excisable imports by a commensurate increase in their
excise rates, and finally adjusting the rate of the general consumption tax (such as the VAT) to meet remaining revenue needs.
Tax Incentives
While granting tax incentives to promote investment is common
in countries around the world, evidence suggests that their effectiveness in attracting incremental investments—above and beyond
the level that would have been reached had no incentives been
granted—is often questionable. As tax incentives can be abused by
existing enterprises disguised as new ones through nominal reorganization, their revenue costs can be high. Moreover, foreign
investors, the primary target of most tax incentives, base their decision to enter a country on a whole host of factors (such as natural
resources, political stability, transparent regulatory systems, infrastructure, a skilled workforce), of which tax incentives are frequently far from being the most important one. Tax incentives could
also be of questionable value to a foreign investor because the true
beneficiary of the incentives may not be the investor, but rather the
treasury of his home country. This can come about when any
income spared from taxation in the host country is taxed by the
investor's home country.
Tax incentives can be justified if they address some form of market failure, most notably those involving externalities (economic
consequences beyond the specific beneficiary of the tax incentive).
For example, incentives targeted to promote high-technology industries that promise to confer significant positive externalities on the
rest of the economy are usually legitimate. By far the most compelling case for granting targeted incentives is for meeting regional
development needs of these countries. Nevertheless, not all incentives are equally suited for achieving such objectives and some are
less cost-effective than others. Unfortunately, the most prevalent
forms of incentives found in developing countries tend to be the
least meritorious.
11
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Tax Holidays
Of all the forms of tax incentives, tax holidays (exemptions from
paying tax for a certain period of time) are the most popular among
developing countries. Though simple to administer, they have
numerous shortcomings. First, by exempting profits irrespective of
their amount, tax holidays tend to benefit an investor who expects
high profits and would have made the investment even if this incentive were not offered. Second, tax holidays provide a strong incentive for tax avoidance, as taxed enterprises can enter into economic
relationships with exempt ones to shift their profits through transfer
pricing (for example, overpaying for goods from the other enterprise and receiving a kickback). Third, the duration of the tax holiday is prone to abuse and extension by investors through creative
redesignation of existing investment as new investment (for example, closing down and restarting the same project under a different
name but with the same ownership). Fourth, time-bound tax holidays tend to attract short-run projects, which are typically not so
beneficial to the economy as longer-term ones. Fifth, the revenue
cost of the tax holiday to the budget is seldom transparent, unless
enterprises enjoying the holiday are required to file tax forms. In this
case, the government must spend resources on tax administration
that yields no revenue and the enterprise loses the advantage of not
having to deal with tax authorities.
Tax Credits and Investment Allowances
Compared with tax holidays, tax credits and investment
allowances have a number of advantages. They are much better targeted than tax holidays for promoting particular types of investment
and their revenue cost is much more transparent and easier to control. A simple and effective way of administering a tax credit system
is to determine the amount of the credit to a qualified enterprise and
to "deposit" this amount into a special tax account in the form of a
bookkeeping entry. In all other respects the enterprise will be
treated like an ordinary taxpayer, subject to all applicable tax regulations, including the obligation to file tax returns. The only
12
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
difference would be that its income tax liabilities would be paid
from credits "withdrawn" from its tax account. In this way information is always available on the budget revenue forgone and on the
amount of tax credits still available to the enterprise. A system of
investment allowances could be administered in much the same way
as tax credits, achieving similar results.
There are two notable weaknesses associated with tax credits and
investment allowances. First, these incentives tend to distort choice
in favor of short-lived capital assets since further credit or allowance
becomes available each time an asset is replaced. Second, qualified
enterprises may attempt to abuse the system by selling and purchasing the same assets to claim multiple credits or allowances or
by acting as a purchasing agent for enterprises not qualified to
receive the incentive. Safeguards must be built into the system to
minimize these dangers.
Accelerated Depreciation
Providing tax incentives in the form of accelerated depreciation
has the least of the shortcomings associated with tax holidays and
all of the virtues of tax credits and investment allowances—and
overcomes the latter's weakness to boot. Since merely accelerating
the depreciation of an asset does not increase the depreciation of
the asset beyond its original cost, little distortion in favor of shortterm assets is generated. Moreover, accelerated depreciation has two
additional merits. First, it is generally least costly, as the forgone revenue (relative to no acceleration) in the early years is at least partially recovered in subsequent years of the asset's life. Second, if the
acceleration is made available only temporarily, it could induce a
significant short-run surge in investment.
Investment Subsidies
While investment subsidies (providing public funds for private
investments) have the advantage of easy targeting, they are generally quite problematic. They involve out-of-pocket expenditure by
the government up front and they benefit nonviable investments as
13
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
much as profitable ones. Hence, the use of investment subsidies is
seldom advisable.
Indirect Tax Incentives
Indirect tax incentives, such as exempting raw materials and capital goods from the VAT, are prone to abuse and are of doubtful utility. Exempting from import tariffs raw materials and capital goods
used to produce exports is somewhat more justifiable. The difficulty
with this exemption lies, of course, in ensuring that the exempted
purchases will in fact be used as intended by the incentive.
Establishing export production zones whose perimeters are secured
by customs controls is a useful, though not entirely foolproof, remedy for this abuse.
Triggering Mechanisms
The mechanism by which tax incentives can be triggered can be
either automatic or discretionary. An automatic triggering mechanism allows the investment to receive the incentives automatically
once it satisfies clearly specified objective qualifying criteria, such as
a minimum amount of investment in certain sectors of the economy.
The relevant authorities have merely to ensure that the qualifying
criteria are met. A discretionary triggering mechanism involves
approving or denying an application for incentives on the basis of
subjective value judgment by the incentive-granting authorities,
without formally stated qualifying criteria. A discretionary triggering
mechanism may be seen by the authorities as preferable to an automatic one because it provides them with more flexibility. This
advantage is likely to be outweighed, however, by a variety of problems associated with discretion, most notably a lack of transparency
in the decision-making process, which could in turn encourage corruption and rent-seeking activities. If the concern about having an
automatic triggering mechanism is the loss of discretion in handling
exceptional cases, the preferred safeguard would be to formulate
the qualifying criteria in as narrow and specific a fashion as possible, so that incentives are granted only to investments meeting the
14
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
highest objective and quantifiable standard of merit. On balance, it
is advisable to minimize the discretionary element in the incentivegranting process.
Summing Up
The cost-effectiveness of providing tax incentives to promote
investment is generally questionable. The best strategy for sustained
investment promotion is to provide a stable and transparent legal
and regulatory framework and to put in place a tax system in line
with international norms. Some objectives, such as those that
encourage regional development, are more justifiable than others as
a basis for granting tax incentives. Not all tax incentives are equally
effective. Accelerated depreciation has the most comparative merits,
followed by investment allowances or tax credits. Tax holidays and
investment subsidies are among the least meritorious. As a general
rule, indirect tax incentives should be avoided, and discretion in
granting incentives should be minimized.
Tax Policy Challenges Facing Developing Countries
Developing countries attempting to become fully integrated in the
world economy will probably need a higher tax level if they are to
pursue a government role closer to that of industrial countries,
which, on average, enjoy twice the tax revenue. Developing countries will need to reduce sharply their reliance on foreign trade
taxes, without at the same time creating economic disincentives,
especially in raising more revenue from personal income tax. To
meet these challenges, policymakers in these countries will have to
15
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
get their policy priorities right and have the political will to implement the necessary reforms. Tax administrations must be strengthened to accompany the needed policy changes.
As trade barriers come down and capital becomes more mobile,
the formulation of sound tax policy poses significant challenges for
developing countries. The need to replace foreign trade taxes with
domestic taxes will be accompanied by growing concerns about
profit diversion by foreign investors, which weak provisions against
tax abuse in the tax laws as well as inadequate technical training of
tax auditors in many developing countries are currently unable to
deter. A concerted effort to eliminate these deficiencies is therefore
of the utmost urgency.
Tax competition is another policy challenge in a world of liberalized capital movement. The effectiveness of tax incentives—in the
absence of other necessary fundamentals—is highly questionable. A
tax system that is riddled with such incentives will inevitably provide fertile grounds for rent-seeking activities. To allow their emerging markets to take proper root, developing countries would be well
advised to refrain from reliance on poorly targeted tax incentives as
the main vehicle for investment promotion.
Finally, personal income taxes have been contributing very little
to total tax revenue in many developing countries. Apart from structural, policy, and administrative considerations, the ease with which
income received by individuals can be invested abroad significantly
contributes to this outcome. Taxing this income is therefore a daunting challenge for developing countries. This has been particularly
problematic in several Latin American countries that have largely
stopped taxing financial income to encourage financial capital to
remain in the country.
16
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
The Economic Issues Series
1. Growth in East Asia: What We Can and What We Cannot Infer.
Michael Sarel. 1996.
2. Does the Exchange Rate Regime Matterfor Inflation and Growth?
Atish R. Ghosh, Anne-Marie Guide, Jonathan D. Ostry, and
Holger Wolf. 1996.
3. Confronting Budget Deficits. 1996.
4. Fiscal Reforms That Work. C. John McDermott and Robert F.
Wescott. 1996.
5. Transformations to Open Market Operations: Developing
Economies and Emerging Markets. Stephen H. Axilrod. 1996.
6. Why Worry About Corruption? Paolo Mauro. 1997.
7. Sterilizing Capital Inflows. Jang-Yung Lee. 1997.
8. Why Is China Growing So Fast? Zuliu Hu and Mohsin S. Khan.
1997.
9. Protecting Bank Deposits. Gillian G. Garcia. 1997.
10. Deindustrialization—Its Causes and Implications. Robert
Rowthorn and Ramana Ramaswamy. 1997.
11. Does Globalization lower Wages and Export fobs? Matthew J.
Slaughter and Phillip Swagel. 1997.
12. Roads to Nowhere: How Corruption in Public Investment Hurts
Growth. Vito Tanzi and Hamid Davoodi. 1998.
13. Fixed or Flexible? Getting the Exchange Rate Right in the 1990s.
Francesco Caramazza and Jahangir Aziz. 1998.
14. lessons from Systemic Bank Restructuring. Claudia Dziobek and
Ceyla Pazarbasioglu. 1998.
15. Inflation Targeting as a Framework for Monetary Policy. Guy
Debelle, Paul Masson, Miguel Savastano, and Sunil Sharma. 1998.
16. Should Equity Be a Goal of Economic Policy? IMF Fiscal Affairs
Department. 1998.
17
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
17. Liberalizing Capital Movements: Some Analytical Issues. Barry
Eichengreen, Michael Mussa, Giovanni Dell'Ariccia, Enrica
Detragiache, Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, and Andrew Tweedie. 1999.
18. Privatization in Transition Countries: Lessons of the First
Decade. Oleh Havrylyshyn and Donal McGettigan. 1999.
19. Hedge Funds: What Do We Really Know? Barry Eichengreen and
Donald Mathieson. 1999.
20. fob Creation: Why Some Countries Do Better. Pietro Garibaldi
and Paolo Mauro. 2000.
21. Improving Governance and Fighting Corruption in the Baltic
and CIS Countries: The Role of the IMF. Thomas Wolf and Emine
Gurgen. 2000.
22. The Challenge of Predicting Economic Crises. Andrew Berg and
Catherine Pattillo. 2000.
23. Promoting Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa: Learning What Works.
Anupam Basu, Evangelos A. Calamitsis, and Dhaneshwar Ghura.
2000.
24. Full Dollarization: The Pros and Cons. Andrew Berg and
Eduardo Borensztein. 2000.
25. Controlling Pollution Using Taxes and Tradable Permits. John
Norregaard and Valerie Reppelin-Hill. 2000.
26. Rural Poverty in Developing Countries: Implications for Public
Policy. Mahmood Hasan Khan. 2001.
27. Tax Policy for Developing Countries. Vito Tanzi and Howell Zee.
2001.
18
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
This page intentionally left blank
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution
Vito Tanzi was the Director of the Fiscal
Affairs Department of the IMF from 1981
to 2000. He retired from the IMF on
December 1, 2000. He holds a Ph.D. from
Harvard University and is the author of
many books and articles in professional
journals.
Howell Zee is the Chief of the Tax Policy
Division in the IMF's Fiscal Affairs
Department. He holds a Ph.D. from the
University of Maryland (College Park) and
is the author of many articles in professional journals.
©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution