The Nordic Model
Embracing globalization and sharing risks
Torben M. Andersen, Bengt Holmström, Seppo Honkapohja,
Sixten Korkman, Hans Tson Söderström, Juhana Vartiainen
THE NORDIC MODEL
Embracing globalization and sharing risks
Torben M. Andersen, Bengt Holmström, Seppo Honkapohja,
Sixten Korkman, Hans Tson Söderström, Juhana Vartiainen
The Research Institute of the Finnish Economy (ETLA)
Publisher: Taloustieto Oy
ETLA B232
ISBN 978-951-628-468-5
ISSN 0356-7443
Printed in Yliopistopaino, Helsinki, 2007
PREFACE
This report is a joint product of its authors. We had several discussions and out of these emerged a shared interpretation of the
essential features of the Nordic model and of the challenges it is
facing. The group is similarly in agreement on the need for reform
and on the main directions that reform should take.
The group is for me a “dream team”; all those who were approached joined the team. Seppo Honkapohja has acted as chairman. The participants are eminent economists and thoroughly
familiar with the policy issues confronting the Nordic countries.
This report should be of considerable interest to all those who want
to have a good understanding of the Nordic model.
Pasi Sorjonen and other staff from ETLA have assisted the
group in its work. The efficiency and speed of the editing by Kimmo
Aaltonen and Laila Riekkinen has been amazing. We are grateful
to a number of colleagues for their help and advice.
Financial support of the TT-foundation is gratefully acknowledged.
Helsinki 4 December 2007
Sixten Korkman
THE AUTHORS
Torben M. Andersen is Professor of Economics at the School of Economics and Management, Aarhus University in Denmark and affiliated to the
research centres CEPR (London), CESifo (Munich) and IZA (Bonn).
His research interests include the economics of the welfare state, labour
economics and macroeconomic policy. He has published widely on these
issues in international recognized journals. Torben M. Andersen has been
involved in policy advice in Denmark and a number of other countries.
He has among other things been chairman of the Danish Economic
Council and the Danish Welfare Commission. Currently he is member
of the Fiscal Board in Sweden.
Bengt Holmström is the Paul A. Samuelson Professor of Economics in
the Department of Economics at MIT. He has a joint appointment with
MIT’s Sloan School of Management. He has worked on the theory of the
firm, particularly in the areas of contracting and incentives. His recent
research has focused on corporate governance, as well corporate liquidity
management and the demand and supply of liquidity in financial markets.
Holmström is a fellow of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences,
the Econometric Society, the European Economic Association and the
European Corporate Governance Institute. He is a Research Associate
of the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) and a member
of the executive committee of the Center for Economic Policy Research
(CEPR). He has served on the board of Kuusakoski Oy (recycling) since
1989 and Nokia Oyj (mobile telecom) since 1999.
Seppo Honkapohja (D.Soc.Sc., University of Helsinki, 1979) has
been professor of economics at Turku School of Economics and Business Administratin in 1987–1991 and at the University of Helsinki in
1992–2003, and is currently professor of international macroeconomics
at the University of Cambridge. He has also served as Academy Professor in the Academy of Finland and has held visiting academic appointments in the US and other countries. In the beginning of 2008 he will
become Member of the Board of Governors of the Bank of Finland. He
is a member of Academia Europaea, of the Finnish Academy of Science
and Letters, a Fellow of the Econometric Society and a Fellow of the
European Economic Association. Honkapohja is an active participant in
economic policy discussions. In 1997 he was Member of Finnish Expert
Commission on EMU, and in 2002–2007 he served in the European
Economic Advisory Group at CESifo.
Sixten Korkman, pol.dr., is since 2005 managing director of the Research
Institute of the Finnish Economy (ETLA) and the Finnish Business and
Policy Forum EVA. He has previously served as Head of Office at the Bank
of Finland (1983–1988), as Director General in the Ministry of Finance
in Finland (1989–2005), and as Director General in the secretariat of
the Council of Ministers in the European Union (1995–2005). He has
written articles on macroeconomic policy issues and a book on economic
policies in the European Union.
Hans Tson Söderström was from 1970 until 1984 Research Fellow, Senior Fellow and finally Deputy Director at the Institute for International
Economic Studies at Stockholm University. Between 1985 and 2002 he
served as President and CEO of SNS – the Swedish Center for Business
and Policy Studies. Since 1992 Hans Tson Söderström has served part
time as Adjunct Professor of macroeconomic analysis and policy in the
Department of Economics at the Stockholm School of Economics (SSE).
In 2004 he returned full time to SSE to become President and CEO of
the school’s executive education branch. Professor Söderström’s main
area of research is macroeconomic policies in small open economies. He
has produced a number of scientific papers and textbooks in the area
and has also served widely as policy advisor. Beween 1985 and 1995 he
was chairman of the SNS Economic Policy Group with annual reports
on Swedish economic policy.
Juhana Vartiainen, pol.dr., leads the Research Division at the National
Institute for Economic Research (Konjunkturinstitutet), Stockholm and
is a part time associate professor (docent) at Åbo Akademi, Finland. In
2003–2005 he was the director and executive officer of the Trade Union
Foundation for Economic Research, Stockholm. Juhana Vartiainen has
been engaged in macroeconomic research, including the history of macroeconomic policy in Finland and Sweden, as well as microeconometric
studies of the labour market, the gender wage gap and the economics of
collective wage agreements in the Nordic countries.
CONTENTS
PREFACE
THE AUTHORS
1
INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY
1.1 A nordic model exists
1.2 The nordic model has performed well in the past
1.3 The nordic model has been conducive to good
economic performance
1.4 Major challenges to the nordic model give rise
to an urgent need for reform
1.5 Many proposed “solutions” are unworkable
1.6 An effective wage bargaining process is essential
1.7 Privatization and/or outsourcing of public services
can contribute to efficient provision
1.8 Our guidelines for reform
11
13
15
16
19
21
24
25
26
2
THE NORDIC MODEL: MYTH OR REALITY?
2.1 Free trade and the market mechanism
2.2 Collective mechanisms for risk sharing
Endnotes
31
32
37
44
3
THE PERFORMANCE OF THE NORDIC MODEL
3.1 Employment and productivity levels
3.2 Growth and technology
3.3 Social equality
Annex: Growth accounting
Endnotes
45
45
47
54
58
61
4
DEMOGRAPHICS: FROM TAIL-WIND TO
HEAD-WIND
4.1 The welfare state as a social contract
4.2 Ageing – the trend is turning
4.3 Ageing puts the public sector under financial
pressure
4.4 Fighting a trend
63
64
69
71
73
4.5 Easy fixes?
4.6 Save or adjust?
Endnotes
75
78
81
5
WELFARE SERVICES: RISING COSTS AND
INCREASING DEMAND
83
5.1 Services become more costly – the Baumol effect
83
5.2 More is expected – the Wagner effect
84
5.3 Preferences for leisure
87
5.4 An easy fix – bring services back to the family?
88
5.5 Combining the service and demographic challenges 89
5.6 Why not increase taxes?
93
5.7 The difficult road: what are the remedies to the
service challenge?
99
Endnotes
101
6
THE LABOUR MARKET: ENOUGH WORKERS
WORKING ENOUGH?
6.1 Make more people work – the extensive margin
counts!
6.2 Work more hours, not less!
6.3 Unemployment benefits, workfare and activation
Endnotes
7
8
WAGE BARGAINING WITH MORE FLEXIBILITY
7.1 Uniform pay increases: for and against
7.2 Coordination and decentralization of wage
formation
7.3 Wage formation and productivity
7.4 Taking stock – some conclusions
Endnotes
THE PROPER SCOPE OF THE PUBLIC SECTOR
8.1 The virtues of competition
8.2 External effects and private organization
8.3 The case for government provided services –
missions versus profit maximization
8.4 The costs of bureaucracy
103
106
110
113
118
119
120
122
126
128
131
133
136
138
140
142
9
8.5 The future of public services – leveraging the
private sector
8.6 Conclusion
Endnotes
145
154
156
GUIDELINES FOR REFORM
References
157
162
1
The Nordic model:
a benchmark and a
bumble bee
The model faces big
challenges – bold
reform is required
INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY
The Nordic model is widely regarded as a benchmark. A number
of comparative studies of economic and social performance have
ranked the Nordics high. A common finding of cross-country
comparisons is that the Nordics succeed better than other countries in combining economic efficiency and growth with a peaceful
labour market, a fair distribution of income and social cohesion.
The model is pointed to as a source of inspiration for other people
in their search for a better social and economic system.
On the other hand, many observers around the world are
amazed that “the bumble-bee can fly” – that the Nordic economies
can prosper and grow in spite of the presumably weak economic
incentives associated with high tax wedges, a generous social security system and an egalitarian distribution of income. Critics have
been looking for inner contradictions in the model and they have
questioned its sustainability. Some argue that the economic performance of the Nordic countries is simply a result of exceptional
and temporary advantages, bound to disappear over time.
This report deals with the Nordic model, the reasons why it
has worked in the past, and the challenges it is being subjected
to in the future. Present economic and social trends, including
globalization and demographic change, pose significant challenges to the model as we know it. The model will remain viable
and successful only if the challenges and the need for reform are
understood – and if action is taken.
Introduction and summary
·
11
Globalization is primarily an opportunity and not a threat. It
has been the very basis of the growth in productivity and living
standards that the Nordics have achieved. However, the continued trend of globalization will put the model under pressure.
The emerging economic giants in Asia and Latin America will
force us to restructure our economies at a rapid pace; relocation
of production and job losses need to be compensated for through
innovations and growth in new activities. Simultaneously, globalization may undermine the financial viability of the welfare state
by increasing international factor mobility and tax competition
between nations as well as by opening up the possibility of “social
tourism” for eligible groups.
Demographic change – in the form of an ageing population
– increases the size of the passive population (retirees), while
tending to decrease the size of the active population (workers).
The result is a dramatic rise in the dependency ratio and a strong
pressure towards increased social spending and higher tax rates.
The combination of ageing populations and high ambitions for
welfare services will strain public finances, even more so if globalization increases the mobility of jobs and labour. The sustainability
of present tax-transfer systems and public systems of care for the
elderly are being seriously put into question.
In responding to these challenges we regard a number of
proposed “solutions” as basically non-workable. For instance, the
financial dilemma of the welfare state cannot be resolved through
more rapid economic growth, higher taxes, increased fertility or
more immigration.
On the other hand, we believe it is essential to preserve one
central feature of the Nordic Model. The Nordics have been
embracing both globalization and the welfare state, and we argue
that the security offered by collective mechanisms for sharing
risks has been instrumental in enhancing a favourable attitude
to globalization and competition. This key characteristic of the
model must be preserved – in order to maintain an economic and
social climate which is conducive to future welfare and growth.
Collective risk sharing should continue to offer a safety net which
helps workers and their families to cope with risks and to adapt to
new requirements in times of change.
12
·
The Nordic Model
Globalization is beneficial, but it may undermine the financing
of the welfare state
Ageing populations
put heavy pressure on
welfare spending and
the sustainability of
public finances
The strength of the
Nordic model should
be maintained: risk
sharing and a safety
net to help workers
and their families
cope with risks and
change
The incentives and
the balance between
entitlements and
obligations must
support a high rate
of labour force
participation
In addition, we emphasize that a high rate of labour force
participation is an indispensible ingredient of the model. There
must be sufficient incentives – in the form of financial rewards
and/or workfare elements – to participate in the labour force and
to work. Lengthening working careers must go hand in hand with
increasing longevity. The “social contract”, including the public
pension system, should not be based on the assumption that the
tax burden can be passed on to future generations in the form of
rising tax rates.
There is also a need to define the core tasks of the welfare
state and to clarify the scope of the services that citizens are entitled to and should be able to expect. Higher productivity in the
provision of welfare services is imperative and can be enhanced by,
inter alia, privatization and outsourcing of public services, though
only in cases where difficult and important issues of governance
can be dealt with satisfactorily.
Finally, investment in human capital should not be the victim
of increasingly tight budget constraints; what is good for the young
is good for the future of society.
Our findings and conclusions are summarized in the sections
that follow. The reasoning behind them is then developed in the
ensuing chapters.
1.1 A NORDIC MODEL EXISTS
Shared attributes of
the Nordics include
a large welfare state,
a particular set of
labour market institutions and a high rate
of investment in
human capital
There is indeed a social and economic system that can usefully be
referred to as the Nordic model. Obviously, there are important
differences between the economies and policies of the Nordic
countries. (The Nordic group is in our case limited to Finland,
Denmark and Sweden, as Norway and Iceland would deserve
special treatment due to their non-membership of the EU and
their high reliance on oil and fishing respectively.) Yet, it is the
similarities that are more striking, some of the principal features
being the following:
· a comprehensive welfare state with an emphasis on
transfers to households and publicly provided social serv-
Introduction and summary
·
13
ices financed by taxes, which are high notably for wage
income and consumption;
· a lot of public and/or private spending on investment in
human capital, including child care and education as well
as research and development (R&D); and
· a set of labour market institutions that include strong labour unions and employer associations, significant elements of wage coordination, relatively generous unemployment benefits and a prominent role for active labour
market policies.
To the extent that these features can be measured, the similarities of the Nordics are supported by statistical data. The Nordic
countries tend to create a cluster of their own along many dimensions. Other European countries (notably the Netherlands and
Austria) are often similar in certain respects, but in no important
respect do we see an outlier among the Nordics.
While the similarities are important, they are not in themselves the essence of the Nordic model; its crucial characteristics
are more difficult to capture, they relate to intangible and systemic
features. We believe that the basis of the model is a combination
of collective risk sharing and openness to globalization. There is a
mutually supportive interaction between these two elements: collective risk sharing helps make globalization acceptable to citizens,
by facilitating adjustments that allow the economy to benefit from
changing markets and to raise productivity and incomes. While
having large public sectors, the Nordics are also embracing the
market economy and actions to foster competition. Underpinning
this virtuous interaction of security and flexibility is the widespread
feeling of trust – among citizens and in public institutions – and a
sense of fairness related to the egalitarian ambitions of the welfare
state (education, social policy).
14
·
The Nordic Model
The key feature of the
model is the mutually
supportive interaction
of risk sharing and
globalization
1.2 THE NORDIC MODEL HAS PERFORMED
WELL IN THE PAST
The Nordics have
achieved a satisfactory economic performance and high social
ambitions
Growth has been associated with rapid
technical progress and
structural change
The Nordic model offers a good business
climate
The Nordic countries have, according to many indicators, succeeded relatively well in fulfilling their social ambitions. Recently,
this has been combined with a satisfactory economic performance
in terms of employment and productivity levels as well as growth
of GDP per capita. Also, the macroeconomic balance is good and
public finances are strong. There is indeed a Nordic success story
in the sense of a favourable combination of economic efficiency
and social equality.
True, the Nordics went through a period of low productivity
growth in the 1970s (like most other OECD countries) as well as a
major financial and macroeconomic crisis with very high unemployment rates and large fiscal imbalances in the early 1990s (somewhat
earlier and less dramatically in the case of Denmark). But even so,
the Nordics have more or less managed to keep up with the US
in terms of PPP-adjusted GDP over the last 25–30 years, which is
more than can be said of most other EU15 countries. The longterm performance is mainly recorded as a high rate of total factor
productivity growth. This indicates that technical progress, notably
in the area of information and communication technology (IT),
has played in important role in growth. More importantly, it also
shows that the Nordics – contrary to popular belief – demonstrate
a high degree of economic flexibility and capacity of structural
change. The macroeconomic crises have helped the process by
inducing growth-enhancing changes in structural policies (and,
for a while, through the improvements of competitiveness caused
by large depreciations in the early 1990s).
The Nordic countries are now at the forefront with respect to
technological development and IT growth. Their financial markets
are open to the world, the Nordics have developed a reasonably
well-functioning system of corporate governance, and in the
corporate sphere they have produced a disproportionate number
of world leaders. The Danish economy is ranked by the World
Bank as number 5 in the world with respect to the ease of doing
business, with Finland and Sweden coming in at number 13 and
Introduction and summary
·
15
14, respectively, out of a total of 173 countries. In terms of ease
of “Trading across borders”, the three Nordics are among the six
top nations in the world (with Singapore, Hong Kong and Norway
also in this group). The Nordics are well ahead of the average for
the EU15 with respect to macroeconomic stability, in particular
fiscal consolidation and the net foreign asset position, but also
in combining price stability with a relatively low unemployment
rate. In the “World Competitiveness” rankings done by the World
Economic Forum the three Nordics are among the top six nations
out of 131 for 2007–2008. In a recent ranking of “innovation ability” (“Innovationsfähigkeit”) of leading industrial nations in 2007
by the German Institute for Economic Research, Sweden, Finland
and Denmark come among the top five out of 17 nations. One
should be careful in interpreting such rankings, but based on the
abundance of similar evidence it is hard to argue that the Nordic
model is not consistent with a good business climate.
1.3 THE NORDIC MODEL HAS BEEN CONDUCIVE
TO GOOD ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Professional economists have often been puzzled by the relatively
good economic performance of the Nordic model, given its high
taxes and its generous social protection systems as well as the
role of strong labour unions and wage coordination. Obviously,
there must be losses of economic efficiency caused by some of the
characteristics of the Nordic model, and many studies have been
devoted to the analysis of the economic costs of a large welfare
state. But, equally obviously, there are other factors which have
made up for such disadvantages.
The “other factors” can for the purpose of exposition be
divided into three categories. The first category includes factors that are entirely exogenous to the economic system, such as
geographic location, climate, natural resources, or religion. The
second category comprises institutional factors that are related to
the economic system, such as political freedom and absence of corruption, well-defined property rights and a reliable judicial system,
16
·
The Nordic Model
Economic performance reflects many
factors – economic
and non-economic
The Nordics are open
to globalization, and
state intervention in
the business sector is
comparatively limited,
as is regulation of
markets
High taxes are economically harmful, but
their negative effects
can be mitigated if
public spending supports employment
and growth and if entitlements in transfer
systems are linked to
labour market attachment
or good health and educational standards. The third category,
finally, are factors that are a direct result of economic policies, such
as openness to trade and factor mobility, a tax system favourable
to labour supply, accumulation and entrepreneurship, and a good
infrastructure for transport and communication.
While the Nordic success story could be partly explained by
factors belonging to the first and notably the second category,
we would for the purpose of this report like to focus on the final
category, i.e. growth-enhancing economic policies. For more than
a century the Nordics have been free-trading nations with a low
level of protection in commodity trade (excluding agricultural
products), leading to continuous structural change and a high
degree of specialization in areas of comparative advantage. The
Nordics have even longer been relatively open to migration, not
least immigration of specialists and entrepreneurs with specific
technical or commercial skills. A more recent development is that
free enterprise on the whole prevails and that state intervention
in the business sector is limited. The labour unions are politically
influential but have not gone against these policies, nor have
they resisted the introduction of new techniques or off-shoring
of activities which have led to productivity improvements and
displacement of labour.
One way of looking at the “bumble bee” feature of the Nordic
model is by pointing to some significant characteristics of public
spending. Much of it is on items like child care and education, the
infrastructure, research and active labour market policies. Such
spending may offset part of the negative effects of high taxes. Also,
there is often a link between entitlements and contributions in
transfer systems (notably pensions), which supports participation
in the labour force. Furthermore, the importance of a high level
of trust and absence of corruption must not be underrated – these
phenomena help maintain the public backing and therefore the
viability of a large public sector.
As already noted above, we argue that some of the key elements
of the Nordic model have been conducive to the implementation
and political acceptance of growth-enhancing policies. The argument is this: Economic growth is only to a limited extent achieved
via pure accumulation of factors of production. More important
Introduction and summary
·
17
are the effects of technical change and reallocation of factors in
response to changes in the international pattern of specialization.
International trade and technical progress can lead to increased
welfare only by way of structural change, a process with winners
and losers. New competition has the consequence that some work
places are closed down, jobs are lost and labour is displaced. The
economic argument in favour of free trade and open markets is
not that there are no losers, only that the winners have so much
to gain that they can – in principle – compensate the losers. Such
compensation, however, is not always achieved in practice. Thus,
potential losers in many countries have used political and union
power to create barriers to new competition by way of tight labour
market regulation with strict job protection, tariff and non-tariff
protectionism, government subsidies or public monopolies.
The Nordic model can be regarded as a way of generating
political support for growth-enhancing technical change, free trade
and open markets by creating a number of systems through which
the winners from structural transformation at least to some extent
compensate the losers. Solidaristic wage setting, active labour
market policies, redistribution of income via tax-transfer schemes,
comprehensive and generous unemployment insurance schemes
and other elements of social protection can all be regarded as ingredients in such compensation mechanisms. This is not to say that all
parts of such policies can be motivated by compensation arguments,
or that existing schemes are particularly efficient in compensating
the losers at the expense of the winners. In particular, a lot of public
transfers amounts to redistribution of resources over the lifetime
of a given individual rather than redistribution between different
individuals. Nevertheless, we believe that social and labour market
policies have been important in mobilizing political support in the
Nordic countries for openness to new technology in production,
free international trade and competition in domestic markets.
18
·
The Nordic Model
Many features of the
Nordic model amount
to mechanisms designed to give some
compensation to
those suffering from
negative effects of
structural change
1.4 MAJOR CHALLENGES TO THE NORDIC
MODEL GIVE RISE TO AN URGENT NEED
FOR REFORM
The Nordic welfare
state is vulnerable to
changes in employment and the age
structure of the
population
The demand for welfare services tends
to grow and the relative cost of producing them tends to
increase, which is why
spending on welfare
services rises faster
than GDP
Functional as it may have been in the past, we believe that the
Nordic model today is subject to a number of challenges that will
put it under serious pressure and call for fundamental reform in
order to make it sustainable.
The root of the challenges is inherent in the basic set-up of
the Nordic welfare state, which is based on tax-financed public
provision of a large number of social services: child care, basic and
advanced education, hospital care and health services, and care
for the elderly. This is an important aspect of the Nordic model, in
that it makes the access to such basic welfare services independent of income and employment status. But it is also a problematic
feature, which may in the long run lead to an impasse in public
finances. This is so for two reasons.
First, demand for (some) welfare services tends to increase
faster than income (a phenomenon known by economists as
“Wagner’s law”). Second, by their very nature, productivity in the
production of welfare services tends to increase at a lower rate,
if at all, than in the production of goods (or other services). Assuming equal wage developments across sectors, unit costs must
then increase faster in the production of welfare services than in
the economy as a whole (a phenomenon known by economists as
“Baumol’s law”).
The two phenomena taken together imply a tendency for
total spending on welfare services to rise faster than GDP over
time. As long as the production of these services remains in the
public domain, or as long as they are tax-financed, the tax burden
must also exhibit a tendency to rise continuously with GDP. This
is a problem of the welfare state that we have been living with for
decades now. However, starting from an already high tax burden,
the efficiency cost of further increases in tax wedges will at some
stage rise steeply, and high taxes will eventually cause serious harm
to employment and growth. It seems to us that we may be close to
a critical point where the deadweight losses due to high tax wedges
Introduction and summary
·
19
– and, particularly, their effect on labour force participation rates
– start to bite seriously. This is particularly so in view of some of
the consequences of globalization and demographic change.
Globalization is in general beneficial to economic growth as it
provides an opportunity to increase the returns to factors of production via international exchange of goods and services and/or via
international factor mobility. Nevertheless, increasing international
mobility of labour also poses, if it continues unabated for long, a
threat to the welfare state and the Nordic model. The entitlements
to education and retirement as well as to care or benefits in the
case of sickness, disability and unemployment belong to all citizens
as individuals in this model, while the cost of these entitlements
are born collectively and shared by all via the tax system.
With higher mobility of labour it becomes increasingly possible
to benefit from the entitlements without sharing the cost (paying
the taxes). There are many examples. Graduates from domestic taxfinanced universities increasingly make their careers (and pay their
taxes) abroad. Citizens who have spent most of their working lives
(and paid their taxes) abroad, return to their home country after
retirement to collect the benefits of free (or cheap) hospital care
and care for the elderly. Unemployment rates and the frequency of
disability pensions tend to be higher for certain immigrant groups
than for domestic citizens. With increasing claims on entitlements
due to “social tourism” and eroding tax bases due to factor mobility
and tax competition between nations, the long-run sustainability
of the Nordic model could be in serious jeopardy.
The most serious challenge to the Nordic model, however,
is caused by the changing demographics, given the extensive role
of the public sector in providing age-dependent social services
and transfers. The age composition of the population will in most
European countries change rather dramatically in coming decades.
The shift is driven by two factors: a temporary “baby boom effect”
as the large cohorts of the 1940s and 1950s reach retirement age,
and a permanent effect caused by a continued increase in life expectancy. As a consequence, the working age population in Finland
will decline from 66.5 per cent of the total today to 57.5 per cent
by 2040. The share of those over 65 will increase from 16 to 26 per
cent of the population, and the share of very old (above 85) will
20
·
The Nordic Model
Tax competition and
social tourism may
become an increasing
source of concern for
public finances
The dramatic shift in
the demographics is
the most important
force undermining the
financial sustainability
of the welfare state
Public finances are
presently recorded as
having a large surplus
– yet public finances
are under present policies unsustainable in
the long term
increase from just below 2 to over 6 per cent over the same time
period. Figures are broadly similar (though somewhat less alarming) for Denmark and Sweden. Accordingly, dependency ratios
will start increasing dramatically from around 2010.
Obviously, the balance between those contributing to and
those benefiting from the welfare state is shifting to such an extent
that these demographic trends are putting the financial sustainability of the system in danger. In the absence of corrective measures
Finland’s general government budget surplus will – according to
calculations made in the Ministry of Finance – turn into a growing deficit (and public debt could amount to 120 per cent of GDP
by 2050). The projection (which is no forecast) brings home the
message that public finances are unsustainable in the long run
when assessed in the light of current spending programmes and tax
rates. Somewhat paradoxically, the general government finances
are presently recorded as being in a large surplus, yet are deemed
to be unsustainable in the long run unless significant action (corresponding to at least 1–2 per cent of GDP) is undertaken to
improve the budget on a permanent basis.
1.5 MANY PROPOSED “SOLUTIONS” ARE
UNWORKABLE
More rapid growth
will not solve the sustainability problem of
public finances
In public discussion there have been a number of suggestions as
to how these challenges can be handled. Unfortunately, many of
those suggestions turn out to be non-workable on closer inspection. We will deal here with some of these not-so-helpful reform
proposals and explain why they do not work.
Economic growth. One of the most common proposals for
solving the fiscal sustainability problem of the Nordic model is to
undertake measures to raise the overall rate of GDP growth. The
suggestion appeals to common sense: by “baking a bigger pie” we
could get enough tax revenues and other resources to handle the
increasing demands on the welfare state. Yet a little reflection
reveals that economic growth per se does not solve the problem,
and might even aggravate it. It should be emphasized that we are
Introduction and summary
·
21
not contesting economic growth as the key to higher living standards in the future. But however desirable growth is, it is unlikely
to resolve the financial dilemma of the welfare state that we see
looming in coming decades.
Growth of GDP is mainly achieved via increased productivity
in the production of goods, while productivity change in the provision of many services is lagging behind. Nevertheless, higher private
sector productivity will raise real wages not only in the private
sector but in the whole economy, including in the public sector
(as a consequence of market forces and/or wage coordination by
unions). Though growth increases tax revenues, it also raises the
public sector wage bill. In addition, political pressure will normally
prevent public pensions and other transfer payments from falling
permanently behind general income developments. Finally, higher
incomes are likely to increase the demand for publicly provided
welfare services. The overall result may, therefore, be that more
growth leads to a deterioration rather than an improvement in
public finances. It can help public finances only under the dubious or unrealistic assumption that public sector wages and/or
transfers are allowed to fall permanently behind general income
developments.
Higher taxes. Technically, the fiscal sustainability problem can
be solved by sufficient increases in tax rates, either now (for “tax
smoothing” reasons) or later when deficits would otherwise start
to materialize. However, tax increases can solve the fiscal problem only under the assumption that they do not negatively affect
the size of tax bases – or at least that such effects are quite small.
We do not believe that this assumption is realistic in economies
which already have quite high tax rates and which operate in an
increasingly globalized environment. Higher tax wedges would
lead to further substitution away from taxed activities (like work
in the regular sector) to untaxed activities (like leisure, household
production and work in the “informal” sector). They can also
have detrimental effects on entrepreneurship, saving and capital
accumulation – and thereby on economic growth. In the longer
run, internationally mobile tax bases, like highly skilled labour,
will spend an increasing proportion of their activity in jurisdictions
with a lower tax burden.
22
·
The Nordic Model
Growth increases the
tax base and tax revenues – but also the
public sector wage bill
and transfers as well
as the demand for
welfare services
Higher overall tax
rates are no longer a
realistic option
More children may be
desirable – but will
not solve the problem
of public finances
More immigration
may be helpful – but
cannot realistically
solve the financing
problem
Therefore, we do not believe it is advisable in the present
Nordic context to attempt to increase tax revenue by raising further
the overall tax burden of the economy. This does not exclude, of
course, efficiency-enhancing tax reforms where certain taxes may
be raised – in particular, perhaps, “Pigouvian” taxes like emission
or congestion charges, or taxes on relatively immobile tax bases.
Higher fertility – more children. The demographic challenge arises from the trend towards an ageing population with more retirees
and fewer workers. Encouraging larger families with more children
may sound like a straightforward solution to the demographic
challenge, but as a matter of fact it is not. Increasing fertility today
would actually lead to an even sharper increase in the dependency
ratio over the next two decades. There would be more children to
support and educate at the same time that the baby-boomers go
into retirement and will become increasingly dependent on care for
the elderly. In the longer run, the extra new-borns will experience
the same increase in life expectancy and they will therefore not be
net contributors to the welfare systems in a lifetime perspective. So,
while higher fertility may be desirable for other reasons, it cannot
help resolve the fiscal sustainability problem of the welfare state,
particularly not over the next couple of decades.
Immigration. Migration is a natural part of globalization, and
flows of labour can support economic growth by, e.g., alleviating
specific skill shortages. Immigration could also bring a temporary
relief to the demographic challenge – but only under conditions
which we believe to be politically unacceptable or unrealistic for
other reasons. First, we must reserve the right to admit only young
immigrants who are ready to join the labour force quickly and to
accept the jobs offered. That puts high demands on the selection
of immigrants with respect to age, education, health and language
skills. Second, we must not admit dependents (children, parents,
relatives) to come with them unless they also fulfil these criteria.
Third, we need to ensure that the immigrants do not rely more on
the welfare systems than the resident population, i.e. they must not
have higher frequency of, for instance, sick absence, unemployment
or early retirement. Even if these politically unrealistic conditions
could be met, the positive effects of immigration would peter out
as immigrants reach retirement age.
Introduction and summary
·
23
1.6 AN EFFECTIVE WAGE BARGAINING PROCESS
IS ESSENTIAL
The parties on the labour market can contribute towards the
reforms needed to adapt the Nordic model to its challenges, particularly by introducing a more effective process of wage bargaining. Experiences from Denmark and Sweden demonstrate that a
continued role for collective agreements can go hand in hand with
quite individualized wage setting.
The role of collective agreements could be reduced to the
following tasks, which are of great importance: First, they should
continue to impose industrial peace, while leaving much of the
negotiations over pay to the local level. Second, central organizations need to agree on certain general conditions, notably those
concerning overall working times. Third, the organizations may
define rules or boundary conditions for local wage setting.
We believe that there are strong reasons for individualized
wage setting, which would deserve more attention also in the case
of Finland: The organization of production has changed in ways
which give a premium to incentives and flexibility, differently from
the days of Taylorist organization. Economic shocks are increasingly firm-specific rather than general, and they therefore call
for adjustment within firms. The need for flexible wage setting is
also related to the large possibilities for outsourcing of particular
functions and tasks. Experience in Sweden and Denmark suggests that decentralized wage formation increases wage dispersion
somewhat, while reducing wage drift. On balance we think that
macroeconomic stability and comprehensive social protection have
changed the environment of the labour market in ways which both
underline the importance of more decentralized wage setting and
ensure that its consequences should be less of a concern from the
point of view of workers.
24
·
The Nordic Model
Collective agreements
will remain important,
but labour market organizations should reconsider their role
The world has
changed in ways
which require and
justify a more decentralized wage setting
process – also in Finland
1.7 PRIVATIZATION AND/OR OUTSOURCING OF
PUBLIC SERVICES CAN CONTRIBUTE TO
EFFICIENT PROVISION
More privatization
and/or outsourcing of
public services may in
some cases help raise
efficiency, if difficult
and important issues
of governance can be
succesfully dealt with
While it is important that the public sector retains its organizing
and financing role for a number of core services, it is equally important to ensure that those tasks are performed in a cost-effective
manner. Productivity in the production of such services could be
enhanced by having them subjected to competition from other
public or private providers. Raising productivity in the provision of
public services is indeed essential for resolving the fiscal dilemma
described in this report.
But we need to caution against a too simplistic belief in this
solution to the fiscal challenges. Many proposals for privatization
and outsourcing are based on a false analogy between private and
public sector activities. Therefore, claims can be overly optimistic
or even entirely wrong-headed. Part of the output from the public
sector concerns truly public goods that cannot be individually
priced and subjected to market transactions. Obvious cases in
point are defence, law enforcement and public administration. Attempts to increase productivity in such areas by way of market-like
incentive systems carry with them risks of corruption and serious
problems of quality, which may ultimately infringe upon the legal
rights of individuals and the rule of law in general. What may look
like excessive bureaucracy in these areas may be entirely rational
and purposeful from this perspective.
Outsourcing and market solutions are feasible for other services of a more private nature, like education, hospital care and
care for the elderly. This may improve service quality by making
providers more responsive to client needs and staff more task-oriented. But outsourcing is also associated with important problems
of assignment. Handing over these activities to profit maximizing
private companies can lead to bad outcomes, since costs are easy
to measure but quality of output – in its many dimensions – is very
hard to monitor. This is not to say that privatization and outsourcing in the production of welfare services can never be successfully
implemented, only that this is a complicated procedure that had
Introduction and summary
·
25
better be tried in individual cases (with learning-by-doing) before
being implemented on a large scale.
1.8 OUR GUIDELINES FOR REFORM
The Nordic model faces serious challenges and many proposed
solutions do not stand up to scrutiny. Not surprisingly, there are no
easy solutions for maintaining a large redistributive welfare state
in an environment of ageing populations and intensified global
competition. Yet, in order to secure continued political support
for free trade and open markets we believe that the core of the
Nordic model can and should be preserved. By the core we refer
to the comprehensive and mostly mandatory systems for pooling
and sharing labour market and other risks. We are in this sense
not advocating radical change or an overhaul of the whole system.
However, we do see a need for significant reform, including actions
for which it may be difficult to get the required political backing.
Above we already underlined the importance of an effective wage
bargaining process and the potential for enhancing efficiency in
the provision of public services. Here we refer briefly to a number
of further elements where reconsideration and reform are called
for; all these issues are dealt with in the subsequent chapters.
The issues at stake have a bearing on “the social contract”, and
they can be illuminated by using the scheme set out in figure 1.1.
This figure can be read in two ways. One way is to think of it as
showing the net contribution to the public sector over the lifetime
of a representative citizen. This citizen will benefit from public (or
publicly subsidized) childcare and education when young, will pay
net taxes during the active years, and will then again become a net
recipient of public transfers and welfare services after retirement.
Another way of reading the figure is to think of it as showing the
aggregate or average relation between net contributions to the
public sector and the age of various cohorts at a certain point of
time.
The strains on public finances will depend importantly on both
the age profile in net spending as set out in figure 1.1 and on the
26
·
The Nordic Model
The model should be
reformed, building on
its strengths
The financing problem arises from the
combination of the
social contract and
the changing age
composition of the
population
Net contribution
to the public
sector
Net contribution to
the public sector of
those working
(average)
A
0
Public
spending on
children and
the young
B
C
Public spending
on pensions,
health and oldage care
Age
Figure 1.1
The social contract
Net contributions to the public sector over the life cycle or as a function of age.
People start to work
later, they often want
to retire earlier, and
they live longer
distribution of the population as between the different age cohorts.
Some of the challenges of the welfare state can now be rephrased as
follows: The “baby boom” phenomenon means that a lot of people
are presently or soon changing status from net contributors to net
recipients, thereby reducing the positive contribution to public
finances indicated by the area between A and B and increasing
the negative contribution from the area between B and C. Also,
working careers have tended to start later (point A shifting to the
right) and end earlier (point B shifting to the left), at the same
time that longevity has been increasing (point C shifting to the
right). All these changes have the consequence of reducing the
total amount of net contributions and increasing public spending
on the elderly. A further factor increasing public spending on the
elderly are the advances in medical science which continuously
bring forward new and more expensive medicines and treatments
of diseases (shifting the curve between B and C downwards).
Introduction and summary
·
27
The scheme of the social contract can also be used to explain the directions in which reforms must be sought and action
undertaken:
First, work careers could usefully start earlier. There is clearly
scope for better efficiency in education, notably in higher education. Also, we see no need for the state to subsidize the “consumption element” in education.
Second, the net taxes paid by those of working age would
increase on average if labour force participation were to be raised
and unemployment reduced. The Nordics will need to reconfirm the
importance that they have traditionally attached to participation
in working life and find means to reduce benefit dependency. This
calls for lower taxes on work, further modifications of social protection so as to alleviate “unemployment traps”, including better
use of workfare elements. Policymakers should abolish unnecessary
disincentives to work, such as “sabbatical years” and other schemes
that discourage active participation in the labour force.
High employment also calls for action to improve the matching
of demand and supply in the labour market and well-functioning wage
bargaining institutions. Here, the negotiating parties on the labour
market rather than the state have important roles to play.
Economic research has demonstrated that active labour
market policy measures have had a disappointingly weak effect
on total employment. At best such measures can have positive
effects on some subgroups, like e.g. youngsters who run the risk
of otherwise becoming marginalized. On the other hand, a reduction of unemployment calls for reform of unemployment insurance
schemes. There is a strong case for a decreasing time profile in
benefit payments as well as an expiry date for their duration. More
active monitoring of recipients’ search effort and conditionality of
benefits on training or activation schemes can also speed up the
transition from unemployment to work.
Third, the effective retirement age should be increased further,
including measures weakening the incentives for early retirement,
and pensioners should be encouraged to continue working. One
way to enhance this would be to give working pensioners more
generous tax allowances (referred to in Sweden and Finland as
“jobbavdrag” or “ansiotulovähennys” respectively). It would also
28
·
The Nordic Model
be important for public authorities to facilitate the provision of
work input by the elderly in the third sector.
Fourth, pension costs must not be allowed to become an excessive
burden for young age cohorts, and pension rules (benefit levels and
statutory retirement ages) should be adjusted in line with increasing
longevity. The latter is already the case in the Nordic countries
(though indexation of pension rules is done in different ways), but
total expenditure on public pensions is still projected to increase
significantly, notably in Finland. The outlook and risks attached to
projected pension developments could usefully be reviewed with
a view to capping the level of expenditure and the contribution
or tax rate that rising pension expenditures are allowed to lead to
(see Korkman et al. (2007)).
Fifth, the core activities of the public sector in the provision of
welfare services should be better defined and the scope of the responsibility for health and old-age care clarified. Given the projected
demographics, welfare services will not only absorb huge resources
but will also cause serious pressure on tax rates. In the end this
pressure can be alleviated only by capping the public provision
and/or tax-financed provision of welfare services in one way or
another. This is already what happens, as municipalities find
themselves financially squeezed and react by lowering quality
and/or rationing of, e.g., health and old-age care (thereby creating
queues). More transparency with regard to the level and scope of
services that citizens are entitled to and can expect would make
it easier for citizens to plan (and save) over their lifetime and for
complementary private services to develop.
Finally, raising productivity in the provision of welfare services is
crucial. There are great difficulties in increasing productivity in the
provision of face-to-face services. Nevertheless, such services are
always associated with administrative and other tasks which can be
rationalized significantly. As already noted above, there is scope in
this area for improving incentives and organizations as well as for
privatization and outsourcing. However, creating the right conditions for social goals to be enhanced through competitive provision
of welfare services call for many hurdles to be overcome.
At best, the Nordic model combines strong government with
effective markets. The aspiration to merge efficiency and solidarity
Introduction and summary
·
29
is worthy and realistic. But the demographic change will increasingly pose a dilemma for the welfare state. The ideal of universalism
in the sense of high-quality welfare services available to everybody
at no or low cost must be reassessed. Delineating and capping the
scope of the public responsibility for our welfare should not be seen
as an assault on the model but as a way to preserve its essentials
and viability in a world characterized by changing demographics
and increasing global competition. There is a need to re-emphasize
the importance of work and employment as well as of a proper
balance between entitlements and obligations of citizens for the
Nordic model to be viable in the future.
30
·
The Nordic Model
2
The Nordic model:
socialist experiment
or bumble bee?
THE NORDIC MODEL:
MYTH OR REALITY?
There exists a straw man version of the Nordic model. This is the
perception of the Nordic model as a socialist experiment with
stifling taxes and heavy-handed regulation where paternalistic
bureaucrats decide the fate of citizens from cradle to grave. Presumably such a model is neither efficient nor desirable on other
grounds. Yet, in this chapter we argue that the Nordic model does
indeed exist, and in the next chapter we demonstrate that it has
performed reasonable well in the past. The model thus seems to
have something in common with the bumble bee, which keeps flying even though it has been claimed that the laws of aerodynamics
prove this to be impossible.1 Clearly the straw man version of the
Nordic model needs to be amended.
Small and open economies are heavily dependent on international developments and need to cope with the process of
globalization. The global division of labour creates the potential
for big gains. However, these gains can be realized only through
a process of structural change, a process with winners and losers.
Increased openness, therefore, gives rise to fear among workers
as well as resistance by trade unions and political decision makers. It is remarkable that citizens and organizations in the Nordic
countries have, by and large, understood and endorsed the case
for free trade and the open economy. Our hypothesis is that the
key feature of the Nordic model is the beneficial and mutually
The Nordic model: myth or reality?
·
31
supportive interaction of openness and collective risk sharing. It
follows that the constitutive elements of the model – including
tax, transfer and spending policies as well as labour market institutions and labour force participation rates – cannot be evaluated
in isolation but have to be seen as part of a comprehensive and,
to some extent, coherent system.
This chapter first points to a number of shared attributes of
the Nordic countries. These cover areas such as labour market
institutions and performance, attitudes and policies with regard to
globalization and new technologies, and the design of the welfare
state and social policies. However, the focus is not on the visible
characteristics as such but on what we perceive as essential for
understanding the performance of the Nordic countries and the
way their policies have evolved over time. We emphasize two basic
and interrelated policy orientations that have played a fundamental
role for a long time and notably in the post war period: free trade
(in an increasingly broad sense) and collective mechanisms for risk
sharing. The Nordic countries have benefited from their openness
to globalization in the form of higher productivity and incomes.
The welfare state and labour market institutions have nevertheless given protection against the risks associated with economic
openness. We argue that collective risk sharing facilitates acceptance of globalization by reconciling the flexibility required by open
markets with the security that workers and citizens aspire to. This
has helped the Nordic countries to adapt institutions and policies,
though often only under the pressure of events, so as make it possible to benefit from and cope with the process of globalization.
Globalization allows
higher incomes but
requires structural
adjustments, a process with winners and
losers. Risk sharing
enhances safety and
makes globalization
more acceptable.
2.1 FREE TRADE AND THE MARKET MECHANISM
The Nordic countries are wedded to free trade and have, with some
sectoral exceptions, been in favour of free trade already for a very
long time. This policy orientation is easily understandable for any
small country. It is particularly rational for countries with a narrow resource base and peripheral location; access to international
markets is essential as a precondition for attaining high living stand-
32
·
The Nordic Model
Free trade is a must
for small countries
with a narrow resource base and
peripheral location
Governments used to
have a hands-on approach to managing
industry and the
economy
ards. Also, exports will in the long run have to grow fast enough
to finance the imports associated with an acceptable growth rate
of the economy, which in turn requires the economy to adjust to
changes in the external environment in one way or another. The
post-war history amply testifies to the importance that the Nordic
countries have attached to the maintenance of competitiveness
through moderate wage developments and currency devaluations
as well as various means of structural policies.
Commitment to free trade does not automatically go hand
in hand with a market-friendly attitude more generally. Like
most parts of Europe and the world, the Nordic countries were in
the first post-war decades highly regulated. Structural economic
policies were interventionist, while macroeconomic policies were
active and discretionary. The governments were heavily involved
in managing industry through, e.g., state companies and subsidized
investment.
Considerations of openness and competitiveness were in those
days largely restricted to exports of goods and the manufacturing
industry, at times supported by devaluations. For other parts of the
economy – such as housing, banking, insurance, the food industry,
retail trade, agriculture and energy – administrative regulation was
extensive and price setting by cartels common. Structural change
of the economy was slowed down by selective subsidies to large
firms and high taxes on profits in combination with significant tax
advantages for investment and retained profits, which tended to
lock in capital in firms with a profitable past but not necessarily
present.
Capital markets and international financial flows acquired
increasing importance in the 1980s. Their growth was stimulated
by technological developments in information technology (IT)
that substantially reduced the cost of cross-border information
flows. The ability to exploit the new financial opportunities and
access to international finance of domestic firms was increasingly
seen as necessary for their competitiveness. Also, the effectiveness
of financial regulation was undermined as a consequence of IT as
well as the internationalization of companies and their possibilities for evading regulations. These developments belatedly paved
the way for a re-evaluation of capital market controls and foreign
exchange market regulations.
The Nordic model: myth or reality?
·
33
The financial deregulations in the late 1980s were badly
handled in terms of timing, sequencing and supporting policies,
and they were associated with a severe banking crisis in the early
1990s in Sweden and Finland, preceded by a milder crisis a decade
earlier in Denmark. By the mid-1990s, Sweden and Finland had
experienced the most severe slump since the 1930s with recordhigh unemployment. Nevertheless, the liberalization of financial
markets must be seen as a key step in the development of the
market economy in the Nordic countries. It led to a rapid development of financial markets with interest rates determined by the
market rather than administrative regulation, improved liquidity,
a broad variety of financing alternatives and investment outlets,
and better possibilities for managing risk.
There were certainly other important forces in addition to the
financial market developments. The deep crisis of the economy and
the prospect of membership in the European Union were, for Sweden and Finland, instrumental in engineering a more general reassessment of regulatory and other policies. In these circumstances
the Nordic countries increasingly took action to deregulate and
foster competition in previously regulated sectors of the economy,
such as energy and communication. Tax reform was undertaken
to broaden the tax base while lowering tax rates, the dual income
tax system was introduced, and capital taxation was changed to
enhance its neutrality with regard to financing and investment
alternatives. Macroeconomic policies were reoriented away
from discretionary action targeted to cyclical objectives towards
“norm-based” policies. Monetary policy assumed responsibility for
safeguarding price stability in the medium term, and fiscal policy
was increasingly geared to the sustainability of public finances in
the long run. Benefit levels and other aspects of the welfare state
were also the object of reconsideration and action, as discussed
below. Even the labour market, not particularly tightly regulated
in the first place, underwent changes in the form of moves towards
more decentralized wage bargaining.
The political decision-makers in the Nordic countries did
not opt with any enthusiasm for the process of liberalization. It
was not as if they would suddenly have come to appreciate the
virtues of the market mechanism, though the academic criti-
34
·
The Nordic Model
Financial liberalization, the deep recession and EU membership engineered a
profound reorientation of the strategy
of economic policies,
though not of the
ultimate goals
More market-friendly
policies have helped
the Nordics to cope
with new technologies and globalization
cism of (interventionist) policy failures played some role. Rather,
regulatory and other policies were adjusted under the pressure of
events. What originally was a commitment to free trade, developed
– under the influence of the internal logic of globalization – into a
policy embracing the market. The increased prominence given to
market-friendly policies may in hindsight be seen as having contributed to the successful changes that have since taken place in
the Nordic economies, and which have helped them to cope with
the challenges of new technologies and new competitors. Also, in
the new environment the Nordic countries have reoriented their
policy concern about competitiveness towards policies that pay
more attention to the supply side of the economy and that support
R&D and innovation.
The claim that the Nordics are complying with and exploiting
market forces rather than suppressing them is supported by the
data reported in figure 2.1, which shows the OECD’s index of the
strictness of employment protection legislation (EPL, vertical axis)
and its index of the strictness of product market regulation (PMR,
4.0
Labour market, EPL
4.0
3.5
3.5
Por
Spa
3.0
Fra
Swe
2.5
Bel
Fin
2.0
Ger
Net
Aut
3.0
Gre
2.5
Ita
2.0
Den
1.5
1.5
Ire
UK
1.0
0.8
1.0
1
1.2
1.4
1.6
1.8
2
Product markets, PMR
Figure 2.1
Regulation in the EU15, 2003
EPL = Summary indicator of employment protection legislation.
PMR = Product market regulation.
Source: OECD Economic Surveys: Italy-OECD (2007).
The Nordic model: myth or reality?
·
35
horizontal axis). These indices are broadly based and systematically
compiled; they are the best available measures for international
comparisons of regulation in product and labour markets.
As is seen, the indices are strongly correlated, though regulation in Sweden is tilted towards the labour market and regulation
in Italy in favour of the product market. It also appears that the
EU15 countries fall rather neatly into four familiar categories. The
Anglo-Saxon countries are the most liberal, having the highest
ranks for EPL and PMR (except for Denmark). They are followed
by the Nordics, notably Denmark, and then by the Continental
countries, while the Mediterranean countries are the ones most
bent on regulation according to both indices.
While broadly based, the indices reported in figure 2.1 arguably do not suffice to characterize the attitude of member states
to the market mechanism. However, there is a wealth of other
information pointing in the same direction. The Nordic countries
rank very high in terms of the index for “Ease of Doing Business”
(EDB) produced by the World Bank Group. Denmark, Sweden
and Finland are all among the top 6 performers in the “Global
Competitiveness Index” published by the World Economic Forum.
The Nordic countries have a good track record with regard to
transposition of and compliance with Community legislation for
the internal market. In the area of banking, Denmark and Finland
nowadays have low regulatory barriers to competition and all the
Nordic countries have relatively light rules for prudential supervision (de Serres et al. (2006)). Turning to a wider perspective, there
is an extensive “economic freedom index” compiled by the Fraser
Institute, and a globalization index developed by a Swiss institute
(the “Konjunkturforschungsstelle” in Zurich). Both of these indices
give high ranks to the Nordic countries, and the ranking between
groups of countries is roughly the same as in figure 2.1. According
to Bergh (2006), the Nordic countries have in the past decades
improved their ranking significantly according to both indices. It
is also interesting to note that Denmark, Sweden and Finland are
among the six top nations in the world (with Singapore, Hong
Kong and Norway) in the subindex of the EDB measuring external
openness, that is, the “trading across borders”.
36
·
The Nordic Model
Markets in the Nordic countries are less
tightly regulated than
in Southern Europe
and the Continent
Openness to globalization and liberalization of markets have
contributed to a successful transformation
of the economy towards knowledgeintensive activities
To repeat, the argument of this section is the following: in
the 1980s and 1990s the Nordic countries accepted openness to
financial capital and factor movements as an extension of their
long-standing commitment to free trade in the new circumstances
created by the IT revolution and globalization. After the process
had started, the arguments for further liberalization turned out
to be strong and self-reinforcing. The perception of the Nordic
countries as being heavily regulated has no obvious justification,
certainly not if the EU15 is used as the reference.
In fact, the Nordics appear to be among the frontrunners in
liberalization. This has facilitated a successful transformation of
their economies in favour of knowledge-intensive activities, and
the Nordic countries have thereby been successful in adapting
to the on-going changes in the global allocation of labour. The
process, which has been remarkably swift notably in Finland, has
been supported by the existence of high-quality education for large
shares of young age cohorts and government support for research
and innovation. (These issues are discussed further in chapter
3.) As will be argued next, the process has also been facilitated
by the security provided through collective mechanisms for risk
sharing.
2.2 COLLECTIVE MECHANISMS FOR RISK
SHARING
Globalization is associated with risks and
people are risk averse
– there is a role for
mechanisms of collective risk sharing
Globalization is associated with big changes and entails risks: it can
be seen as offering beneficial opportunities or as posing threats.
Individuals are normally not able to insure themselves against the
risks of losing their job or finding their skills outdated. There is a
role for social insurance or, more generally, for risk sharing by collective means. The welfare state, in conjunction with labour market
institutions, plays a key role from this perspective. Governments
have over the years come to assume a wide range of functions in
the areas of redistribution and provision of services that go well
beyond the traditional (“nightwatch”) role of upholding law and
order and public administration. Much of what the public sector
The Nordic model: myth or reality?
·
37
does can nowadays be seen, in a broad sense, as entailing risk
sharing through collective mechanisms.
The Nordic countries are indeed well-known for their big
welfare states and high tax rates. Social insurance and protection
systems have a broad coverage and are highly inclusive or “universal” in the sense that all citizens have, as a matter of legal right,
certain entitlements in the case of eventualities like sickness, disability or unemployment. These entitlements are not conditional
on, say, ability to pay or previous tax payments by the individuals
concerned. Social protection provides for relatively generous income replacement in addition to flat-rate benefits, which are often
not means-tested.2 Financing is largely by taxes and the welfare
state is therefore associated with a lot of income redistribution
both between individuals and over the lifetime of individuals.
Public provision of social services, available to all citizens, is free
of charge or heavily subsidized. It meets relatively high standards
in the sense of corresponding to the needs or requirements of a
large fraction of the population.
The border line between insurance and redistribution is
not clear-cut, as social insurance is often associated with some
redistribution. Also, much of the tax-financed activities of the
public sector can in a broader sense be perceived as forming part
of collective risk sharing.3 The provision of welfare services and
transfers tends to reduce the incidence and the risk of poverty.
An egalitarian society with a strong role for the public sector in
areas such as child care, education, health and old-age care and
pensions may in a broad perspective appear as an attractive option,
given the risk aversion typically exhibited by individuals (Sandmo
(1998) and references therein).
The Nordic countries are egalitarian societies in the sense that
income and wealth differentials are smaller than elsewhere. One
might speculate that this is because citizens and decision-makers in these countries attach great importance to social equality.
However, it is difficult to believe that egalitarianism is in the genes:
why would there be a particular predisposition of people in the
North to value equality in relation to efficiency differently from
other human beings? A more promising line of argument, followed
here, is to stress that the preconditions for egalitarian policies to
38
·
The Nordic Model
The Nordic welfare
state entails universal
entitlements, comprehensive social protection, subsidized social
services – and very
high tax rates
The Nordics are egalitarian societies – but
egalitarianism is not
in the genes
Nordic egalitarian
ambitions have deep
roots in their history
and culture
be viable or to succeed have been exceptionally favourable in the
Nordic area.
In particular, the Nordic countries are small and ethnically
homogenous, and they were so notably at the time that the welfare
state developed. (Subsequently immigration has been substantial
and policies have not succeeded fully in integrating the immigrants
into the labour market and the society at large.) Ethnic homogeneity is conducive to the emergence of trust, the key ingredient in
“social capital”, which is widely believed to improve the efficiency
of society by facilitating coordinated action. In fact, the level of
trust is higher in the Nordic countries (and the Netherlands) than
elsewhere according to available indicators, such as the European
Values Survey, which typically measure trust by the share of people
who agree that “most people can be trusted”. A high level of trust
is also associated with low corruption, which is essential for confidence in authorities and the acceptability of redistributive policies.
Surveys suggest that the Nordic countries have an exceptionally
low level of corruption (Transparency International).
It has often been suggested that the high Nordic ambition
in the area of egalitarian policies has to be seen against the
background of both their ethnic and their religious homogeneity.
Reference has also been made to the long history of independent
farmers and the labour movement having influence in local and
national matters of policy.4 This has arguably fostered a high level
of trust of citizens and the emergence of a relatively incorrupt
and efficient public administration, capable of planning collective
mechanisms of risk sharing and executing the social programmes
of a large welfare state. The result has been visible not only in the
size and tasks of the public sector; some of the attitudes with regard
to macroeconomic policy and labour market institutions can also
be interpreted as aiming at risk sharing.
A main objective of macroeconomic policies is to maintain
full employment and an effective use of resources. However, macroeconomic policies can also be seen as a way of enhancing the
economic security of citizens and reducing risks in investment.
These ambitions were underneath the accommodating monetary
and fiscal policies that were long pursued in all the Nordic countries in the form of, inter alia, recurrent devaluations and steady
The Nordic model: myth or reality?
·
39
employment increases in the public sector acting as an “employer
of last resort”. While low and stable unemployment has remained
an important policy objective, the strategy and means of enhancing the achievement of the objective have changed markedly in
the past two decades.
The Nordic labour market institutions – high unionization,
highly coordinated wage bargaining geared to wage compression,
active labour market policies, and relatively generous unemployment benefits – can also be interpreted as reflecting the inclination towards collective risk sharing (see, e.g., Agell (2002)).
More specifically, the institutional system, based on coordinated
negotiations between strong partners and supporting policies
by the government, may be seen as a way of offering security to
workers without some of the drawbacks of tight legislative labour
market regulation.
The above-mentioned reasons may partly explain why a big
welfare state is or has been more viable in the Nordic countries
than in many other cultural and political contexts. Nevertheless,
the policies in the Nordic countries ran increasingly into excesses
in the 1970s and 1980s. In Sweden, for instance, public spending
exceeded 60 per cent of GDP in the late 1980s, and marginal tax
rates were about 70 per cent for most full-time employees. Labour
market regulation was tight and the goal of wage policy increasingly
became “equal pay for all work”, thus undermining incentives for
skill formation and labour mobility. Monetary and fiscal policies
were accommodating to an extent that was increasingly seen as
unsustainable.
As noted in the preceding section, a number of developments – such as financial liberalization, the deep crises, and EU
membership – triggered a reassessment of policies, paving the way
not only for further deregulation but also for a new approach to
macroeconomic policies and, to some extent, for acceptance of
more flexibility in the labour market. While the basic objectives
remained unchanged, the big budget deficits associated with the
crisis also led to a reconsideration of the public-sector and welfare-state policies. There was some retrenchment of the public
sector with cuts in benefit levels and subsequently in tax rates. A
number of reforms were introduced with a view to improving the
40
·
The Nordic Model
Macroeconomic policies and labour market institutions can
also be seen as mechanisms for collective
risk sharing
Excesses call for a reversal, all the Nordics
undertook significant
reforms
incentive effects of social security programmes, pension reforms
being an important case in point. The provision of public services
has been partly privatized or outsourced and it is increasingly being
exposed to the forces of competition. The timing and sequencing
differ somewhat between countries, but all Nordic countries have
in the past two decades undertaken significant reforms of their
public sectors and welfare policies.
As of now, the public sector in the Nordic countries is still
large by international comparison. It absorbs a share of total income
which is larger than in other countries, the tax burden is high,
and it extracts an amount of resources that is close to or exceeds
50 per cent of GDP (table 2.1, columns 1 and 2). Much of this
is social expenditure. However, social transfers are more heavily
taxed in the Nordic countries than elsewhere. Also, one should
take account of publicly mandated private expenditure or of social
benefits, which legislation forces employers to provide (Adema and
Ladaique (2005)). Making these adjustments, the Nordic countries
Table 2.1
Public sector and social spending
Denmark
Sweden
Finland
Germany
France
Austria
Belgium
Netherlands
Luxembourg
Italy
Spain
Greece
Portugal
United Kingdom
Ireland
a
b
c
d
e
f
g
Tax burden
in 2006,
% of GDP a
Total
expenditure
in 2006,
% of GDP b
Social
expenditure
in 2003,
% of GDP c
49.0
50.1
43.5
35.7
44.5
41.9
44.8
39.5
36.3
42.7
36.7
27.4
35.4
37.4
31.7
51.1
55.5
48.5
45.6
53.7
49.1
49.0
46.7
40.4
50.1
38.5
36.7
46.1
45.1
34.0
23.8
29.2
22.7
29.5
29.8
23.9
26.0
20.6
25.3
19.6
23.2
22.8
15.6
Child care
Average net
Gross
and early unemployment replacement
education
benefit
rate in
in 2003,
replacement
pensions f
% of GDP d
rate e
1.6
1.3
1.4
0.4
1.2
0.6
0.8
0.5
0.9
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.8
0.6
0.2
78
73
73
73
62
64
62
73
71
5
50
25
63
63
70
83.6
63.7
63.4
39.9
51.2
80.1
40.7
81.7
90.3
67.9
81.2
95.7
54.3
34.4
38.2
Progressivity
index of
pensions g
59.3
12.9
7.6
26.7
24.6
30.4
58.8
0.0
18.6
3.1
18.8
2.6
18.8
81.1
100.0
The sum of taxes on income and wealth, capital taxes, social security contributions and indirect taxes, from OECD Revenue
Statistics 1965–2006.
OECD Economic Outlook (2007), General government total outlays, Annex Table 25.
Net publicly mandated social expenditure, see Adema & Ladaique (2005).
OECD (2007), Social Expenditure database 1980–2003.
Average net replacement rates in per cent over a period of 60 months of unemployment in 2004, one earner at average wage,
married couple, with social assistance. OECD (2007), Benefits and Wages, Paris (www.oecd.org/els/social/workincentives).
OECD (2007), Pensions at a Glance.
OECD (2007), Pensions at a Glance.
The Nordic model: myth or reality?
·
41
are not at the top of the league, though Sweden ranks high in terms
of social expenditure relative to GDP (column 3).
A particular feature of Nordic social policies is the high share
of spending on child care and early education (column 4), and the
Nordics are also unique in spending as much as 3–4 per cent of
GDP on families in the form of cash and services. The replacement
rate is high in unemployment insurance (column 5), but it may be
added that eligibility for benefits in the Nordic countries is increasingly conditional on “effective” availability to the labour market,
that is, workfare elements. Replacement rates in pensions (column
6) are higher in the North than in the Anglo-Saxon countries
but lower than in the South, except for Denmark in some cases.
Also, pensions in the Nordic countries have a low “progressivity
index” (column 7), meaning that benefits are strongly related to
contributions and are therefore actuarially rather fair, again with
exception for Denmark that has a quite generous flat-rate pension
(“folkepensionen”). In sum, public spending in the Nordic countries is high but a significant part of it is geared towards supporting
a high rate of labour force participation.
Needless to say, it would be easy to point to significant differences between the Nordic countries. Yet, in an international
comparison it is the similarities that are striking. Comparing the
Nordics with other countries in Europe or elsewhere, one is impressed by the perception of a specific Nordic “cluster” in a number
of dimensions. It would indeed be easy to multiply the examples
of such similarities by covering in more detail areas such as labour
market institutions, the design of the welfare state, policies with
regard to new technologies and research and development or
environmental policies.5
However, it is not the number of similarities that is important but the systemic interrelations between the key institutions
and policies. To recapitulate, the argument of this chapter is that
the Nordics have in recent decades broadened their long-standing commitment to free trade and modernized their collective
mechanisms for risk sharing under the pressure of and in response
to globalization. Openness to globalization and emphasis on social
security are important not only in themselves but also because they
are interconnected and mutually supportive. Free trade and factor
42
·
The Nordic Model
The Nordic public
sector is big, but net
social spending is not
that much higher than
elsewhere
It would be easy to
multiply examples of
Nordic similarities
The key: Openness
creates the potential
for higher incomes,
but it entails risks and
increases the demand
for safety, which the
welfare state can help
provide
mobility are key factors in generating high productivity and rising
incomes. But some of the consequences of open competition on
global markets, including off-shoring of activities and layoffs of
workers, are politically more acceptable if their consequences for
workers and local communities are softened by social safety nets
and labour market policies.
Evidence indeed suggests that people in countries with extensive social security systems have a more favourable attitude to
free trade and globalization (Sanz and Coma (2007)). It is also
plausible that external openness increases the demand for the
insurance and security that the welfare state can offer, which is the
interpretation made by Rodrik (1998) of the positive correlation
between openness and the size of the public sector. The coexistence or combination of collective mechanisms for risk sharing
and openness to globalization is therefore no coincidence but a
key feature of what might be regarded as the “Nordic model”. It
amounts to a system of generalized “flexicurity”, the purpose of
which is to help the economy and society to cope with risks and
adapt to new requirements in times of rapid change.
The Nordic model: myth or reality?
·
43
ENDNOTES
1
Wikipedia refers to popular views, according to which “the laws of aerodynamics prove that
the bumble bee should be incapable of flight, as it does not have the capacity (in terms of wing
size or beat per second) to achieve flight with the degree of wing loading necessary”. There is an
interesting sequel to this, because Wikipedia also reports that the erroneous view is based on “a
simplified linear treatment of oscillating aerofoils”, while “more sophisticated aerodynamic analysis shows that the bumble bee can fly because its wings encounter dynamic stall in every oscillation cycle”. The analogy with the bumble bee obviously suggests that the Nordic model is something more than just high taxes and big government. On this analogy see also Thakur et al. (2003).
2
There are residual forms of social assistance which are means-tested also in the Nordic countries, and which therefore give rise to “poverty traps”. However, it remains the case that countries
with universal schemes in general have less means-testing and less severe poverty traps than
many other countries.
3
This is the case notably if one starts from a (“Rawlsian”) perspective of a hypothetical individual who does not know what his position in society may be or become (who is reflecting on social
choices from behind the “veil of ignorance”). The purpose for which Rawls employs this thought
experiment is to help make the theoretical case for certain basic principles of justice. Its practical
relevance is, needless to say, weakened by the fact that actual political discourse does not occur
in a vacuum but in a context where various actors have well-defined and often conflicting interests.
4
While now highly secular, the Nordic culture is strongly influenced by the Lutheran faith,
which gives prominence to a strong work ethic and solidarity between members of society (and
even conformist pressures). The long history of independent farmers and the tradition of local self
governance are other features worth noting. Scandinavian kings have shared some power not
only with the nobility and the church but also with the land-owning farmers for ages. The administration of the state was rather effectively organized in the Swedish kingdom as early as the 16th
century. The Nordic countries have never been class societies to the same extent as, say, France or
England. In the 1920s (at the latest), the labour movement and the Nordic Social Democratic parties abandoned the view that capitalism would collapse because of its inherent contradictions.
Instead, the reformist vision was that the socialist future should be built not on the ruins of capitalism but on a flourishing and growing economy. Increasingly, as the labour movement acquired
influence and power, it became an element of stability in society – though later in Finland than in
the other Nordic countries.
5
44
See, e.g., EEAG (2007), chapter 4.
·
The Nordic Model
3
This is a look into the
rear mirror – which
may be no guide for
the future
THE PERFORMANCE OF
THE NORDIC MODEL
As was noted in chapter 1, there is a general perception that the
Nordic countries have done well in a number of respects and
notably in terms of reconciling the requirements of economic
efficiency with a high degree of social equality. This chapter will
present some facts to help evaluate the justification of that perception. We will first examine aspects of economic efficiency in terms
of activity levels and growth performance, and then turn to social
considerations. It should be emphasized that we now look into
the rear mirror; this chapter provides a retrospective evaluation
of past performance. Needless to say, there is no strong reason to
presume that future developments will prolong past trends; many
countries and regions have experienced significant discontinuities
in their economic development. Subsequent chapters will set out
and assess some of the challenges that we think are of particular
importance in catering for the future.
3.1 EMPLOYMENT AND PRODUCTIVITY LEVELS
How should performance be measured, and with whom
should one compare?
There is no single measure of economic efficiency that could be
used for comparing Nordic performance to that of other areas
or countries. However, it may be argued that it makes sense to
The performance of the Nordic model
·
45
consider employment and productivity; the economic efficiency
of a country may be deemed satisfactory to the extent that there
is a high level of both employment and productivity. Productivity
needs to be considered not only in terms of its level but notably
in a dynamic perspective (which is done in the next section), as
productivity growth is by far the most important source of higher
living standards. One may also ask which countries the Nordics
should be compared to. Here we compare the Nordics mainly to
the EU15 and the US. One might object that a comparison with
the EU15 gives too rosy a picture of the Nordics because economic
growth in the reference group has been weak for many years.
Why not compare with the dynamic economies in the East? On
balance, however, we think the EU15 is a reasonable reference
because of similarities in the economic, institutional and cultural
background.
The performance of the Nordics, as compared to other European countries, is good in terms of the employment and productivity levels (figure 3.1). The level of employment is high, partly
Hours worked per population
105
105
100
100
95
USA
Spa
Por
95
Den
Fin
Swe
UK
Gre
90
85
Aut
80
Ger
75
Ita
Ire
85
Net
Bel
Fra
70
80
75
70
65
50
60
70
80
90
65
100
110
GDP per hour worked*
Figure 3.1
Employment (average hours worked) and productivity per hour
* In Purchasing Power Parity terms by the EKS method.
Source: The Conference Board and Groningen Growth and Development Centre.
46
90
·
The Nordic Model
The Nordics have high
employment rates
in combination with
decent productivity
levels
because of the high rate of labour force participation of women.
True enough, average hours worked (of the whole population)
are higher in Spain and Portugal, but productivity is low in these
countries. Also, the level of productivity is higher in many continental countries, but they tend to have low employment rates.
High employment and high productivity is achieved mainly by the
Anglo-Saxon and the Nordic countries. This also means that these
countries achieve a relatively high level of GDP per capita, which is
the product of hours worked and productivity. To show this, figure
3.1 also gives the “level curves” (or “isoquants”) going through the
points for Germany and Finland; the defining characteristic of the
level curves is that all points on these curves represent the same
level of GDP per capita as in Germany and Finland, respectively.
One may add, though, that disposable income and private consumption per capita are low in the Nordic countries, barely above
the level in Southern Europe, as the public sector absorbs a large
fraction of the income generated in the economy.1
3.2 GROWTH AND TECHNOLOGY
Much of European
growth differentials in
the past 4–5 decades
is explicable as a process of catching up of
the (initially) poorer
countries
Nordic growth in the
past decade or so has
been comparatively
favourable and has
benefited from the IT
revolution
We now turn to the dynamic perspective and examine the Nordic
growth performance. A first observation is that the Nordic growth
rate of GDP per capita since 1960 does not seem to deviate much
from what could be expected in a “catching up” framework (see
figure 3.2). Only Finland achieved, over the period 1960–2006, a
growth rate of GDP per capita somewhat above what could have
been expected assuming catching up and considering the level of
GDP per capita at the start of the period. Growth in Denmark and
Sweden was below the average in the EU15, but this seems broadly
explicable in view of their relatively high starting level. Ireland is
an obvious “outlier” with a rate of growth roughly one per cent
higher than could be expected on the basis of the average relation
between the level and rate of growth of GDP per capita.
More information on the recent growth performance is
provided by figure 3.3, which shows the development of GDP
per capita in purchasing power parity terms relative to the US
The performance of the Nordic model
·
47
from the mid-1980s. Finland has gradually been catching up with
Denmark and Sweden; the Nordics are now very close also in
this dimension. For Finland and Sweden the early 1990s were a
Average growth of GDP per capita
4.5
4.5
Ire
4.0
3.5
4.0
3.5
Por Gre
Spa
3.0
3.0
Fin
Ita
2.5
2.0
400
600
800
Bel
Fra
1000
Aut
Den
Net
2.5
W-Ger
UK Swe
2.0
1200
1400
GDP per capita in 1960
Figure 3.2
Growth of GDP per capita, EU15, 1960–2006
Source: Eurostat.
Ind
Denmark
Finland
Sweden
Euro area
95
90
95
90
85
85
80
80
75
75
70
70
65
65
1985
90
95
2000
Figure 3.3
Levels of PPP-adjusted GDP, USA=100, 1985–2006
Source: IMF.
48
Ind
·
The Nordic Model
05
The Annex to this
chapter contains calculations of the quantitative significance
of various sources of
growth, and notably
of the big importance
of IT and “total factor
productivity”
The Nordics have advanced more than
most on the path to
the knowledge-based
economy
particularly difficult period, as both countries experienced major
recessions.2 Since then, both countries have grown more rapidly
than both the euro area and the US. Overall, Denmark has also
kept pace with growth in the US, while growth in the euro area
has been quite weak.3
The growth performance of the Nordic economies has in
recent years been associated with an increased use of new technologies, reflecting the readiness of these countries to participate
in and benefit from information and communication technology
(IT) developments. In fact, these countries were early starters in
the use of IT and had high shares of IT capital relative to most
countries already in the mid-1990s, i.e. at the time that the IT
revolution really took off. In the Annex to this chapter we will
use growth accounting to assess the quantitative significance of
various sources of growth. It indeed turns out that the contribution
of IT capital to growth has been significant since the 1990s in the
Nordic countries (similar to that in the US) and typically bigger
than that of non-IT capital.
Data on the whole confirms that the Nordic countries do well
on indicators of IT diffusion, such as IT expenditure or personal
computers (PCs) per capita. Figure 3.4 shows the expenditure on
IT as a share of GDP and the number of computers per 1000 people. Sweden is at the top in both respects and also Finland scores
well above the average. Denmark is close to the EU average for
IT expenditure but scores very high in terms of the number of PCs
per population. According to the World Economic Forum, these
Nordic countries are at the top (with positions 1, 2 and 4) in a
global ranking measuring the environment for IT as well as the
readiness to use IT by various stakeholders.
It should be emphasized that these indicators measure the
diffusion or use of IT in the economy, while a different picture
emerges from looking at the production side.4 In fact, IT production
has a strong role notably in the Finnish and to some extent in the
Swedish economy: the share of IT in total industrial production in
2004 was some 11 and a bit over 7 per cent respectively, while its
role in Denmark and the EU15 is on average more modest.
Many important aspects of technology are not captured by
the amount of IT capital or IT diffusion. Notably for Finland and
The performance of the Nordic model
·
49
%
Units
IT expenditure, % of GDP (left scale)
PCs per 1000 people (right scale)
7
700
6
600
5
500
4
400
3
300
2
200
1
100
0
0
Spa Ire
Ita Por Gre Aut Bel Ger Den Fra Net Fin Swe UK
Figure 3.4
IT expenditure and diffusion in the EU15, 2003
Source: World Bank Development Indicators 2005.
Sweden, the computations in the Annex suggest that there has also
been an important growth contribution from general technological progress (referred to as growth in total factor productivity or
TFP), which cannot be assigned to any specific factor. A difficulty
with TFP growth is that it reflects factors which are not directly
measurable (with reasonable precision), such as structural change,
innovations, and improvements in the general knowledge and
organization of economic activities. Among such indirect factors
of growth, it is usually thought that a high quality of the education
system, strong competition and deregulation, and innovation and
entrepreneurship are of particular importance. We will next make
some remarks on these factors.
Education is often considered a key determinant of both TFP
growth and economic growth in general, though the measurement
of human capital and its formation is very difficult. Indicators such
as years of schooling or changes in the educational composition
of labour do not capture all the potential effects of investment in
human capital. In particular, labour quality improvements may be
complementary to technological progress by, for instance, facilitating the adoption of new technologies.5
50
·
The Nordic Model
The Nordics spend a
lot on education and
achieve rather good
results
The Nordic countries spend on average comparatively much
on education, and young people in these countries stay rather many
years in education. In fact, the median age of persons in tertiary
education is quite high in the Nordic countries (some 24–25 years),
much higher than in, for instance, the US or Ireland (20–21 years).
This may not only indicate something about investment in human
capital, but may also suggest that there is scope for improvements
in the efficiency of Nordic university systems. Needless to say,
tertiary education may be of particular importance for the diffusion of new technologies and economic growth prospects6; we
will return to this aspect in chapter 8. Here we will only make the
observation (figure 3.5) that the Nordic countries spend more on
educational expenditure, up until but not including tertiary education, than most other EU15 countries. The mean performance
of students in mathematics is better in high-spending countries,
including the Nordics, though the correlation between spending
and performance is weak.
a
560
PISA scores
560
540
Fin
Net
540
Bel
520
Ire
500
Ger
Aut
Fra
Den
520
Swe
500
Lux
Spa
480
480
Ita
460
Por
460
Gre
440
2
440
2.5
3
3.5
4
4.5
5
b
Educational expenditure
Figure 3.5
Educational expenditure and student performance
a
b
Mean score for student performance in mathematics according to the PISA 2003 evaluation.
Primary, secondary and post-secondary non-tertiary education in 2004, per cent of GDP.
Source: OECD (2007): Education at a Glance.
The performance of the Nordic model
·
51
As technological change is to a significant degree associated
with the emergence of new and more productive firms, the degree
of competition is potentially an important element behind TFP
growth. One way for public policy to influence competition is
through reform of regulatory policies – a less regulated economy
makes it easier to establish new firms and thereby enhance competition in the economy. The findings of Alesina et al. (2005) suggest
that regulatory reform also leads to increased investment of firms,
so that effects of competition can partly work through increased
capital accumulation and not only through TFP growth.
The strictness of regulation in the EU countries can be illustrated by the structural indicators on product market regulation
and legislative employment protection constructed by the OECD,
which were already presented in figure 2.1 in the preceding chapter. The UK and Ireland (as well as the US) are benchmark cases,
having little regulation in labour and product markets. As is seen
from the figure referred to, all the Nordics appear to be among
the countries with a particularly low degree of regulation. This is
important, because conventional sources of growth might be less
sensitive to regulatory intervention than sources of growth relying
on high-tech and new products7, where competition should be
particularly encouraged.
For labour markets, legislative employment protection in
Denmark is quite weak. It is somewhat more stringent in Finland
and notably in Sweden. However, both countries have in recent
years taken some steps towards lowering employment protection,
Finland with respect to regular employment and Sweden with
respect to temporary employment.
Promoting innovations and facilitating start-ups of new production activities is another possible policy tool for improving TFP
growth. It is, however, difficult to find accurate measures of innovative activities and start-ups of new production that are relevant
for long-term growth. Here we consider two indicators, venture
capital (VC) financing and investment in R&D, both of which are
measured as the ratio of spending to GDP.
As to venture capital financing, the statistical data distinguish
between “early stage” and “late stage” or “expansion” venture
finance. The US is a clear leader (table 3.1), but Finland and Swe-
52
·
The Nordic Model
Liberal regulatory
policies support competition and makes it
easier to set up new
firms
Table 3.1
Venture capital investment, relative to GDP, 2000–2003
Denmark
Finland
Sweden
EU
US
a
Early stage
Later stagea
0.057
0.085
0.088
0.041
0.115
0.065
0.104
0.147
0.089
0.260
Shares of high-tech
Communication
IT
Health/
bioscience
13.2
13.5
10.2
13.5
26.8
19.3
20.0
13.9
11.7
35.1
28.2
1.3
17.3
9.9
13.0
Expansion and replacement. All figures are averages for 2000–2003 relative to GDP.
Source: OECD.
Innovation and venture capital: The Nordics do well but not
well enough
den also do well in terms of both indicators. A further interesting
indicator for VC investment is the share of the investment that
goes into different forms of high-technology activities. Here the
picture is broadly similar: the Nordics are in this respect ahead of
EU on average but well behind the US.
The figures suggest that the Nordic countries are doing relatively well in venture capital undertakings. However, it should be
emphasized that this data shows only VC spending and not returns
to VC investments; these results may give too rosy a picture.8 Finally, it may be noted that R&D spending as a share of GDP, which
is another indicator of innovative activity that may be relevant for
general technological progress, is higher in the Nordics (at 2.5–3.5
per cent) than in the EU15 and the US (at some 2 per cent).
Thus, the Nordic countries are doing significantly better than
other EU countries as regards innovative activities, and they appear
to be comparable to or not very far behind the US in these areas.
More generally, this section and the Annex support the view that
the Nordics have been able to create institutions and policies (in
areas such as education, market regulation and innovation), which
have been conducive to a relatively favourable growth performance
notably since the mid-1990s.
The performance of the Nordic model
·
53
3.3 SOCIAL EQUALITY
Economic efficiency is important in its own right and as a precondition for the realization of other ambitions, but it is not in itself
the only or the most important goal of society. While it is unclear
how the ultimate objective should be defined, there is no doubt
that the Nordic political system attaches great importance to social
considerations and the achievement of social equality or “justice”.
This section will offer some brief observations on this vast topic.
A first observation is that the Nordic countries, again compared mainly to the EU15, are characterized by a rather low
degree of income inequality and a relatively high degree of social
mobility (figure 3.6). The degree of income inequality here refers
to the Gini coefficient of the distribution of income after taxes
and transfers. While income inequality is rather similar in most
countries before taxes and transfers (see Mahler and Jesuit (2006)),
income inequality after redistribution via taxes and cash benefits
differs considerably, and would most probably differ even more if
Current income inequality
0.38
a
0.38
USA
0.34
UK
Ita
Spa
0.30
0.34
0.30
Ger
0.26
Fin
0.22
0.1
Swe
Den
0.2
0.3
Fra
0.26
0.22
0.4
0.5
0.6
b
Intergenerational income elasticity
Figure 3.6
Income inequality
a
b
54
Gini coefficient, data from The Luxembourg Income Study (www.lisproject.org). Data refer to the year
2000 except for Denmark (2004), the Netherlands and the UK (1999).
A high elasticity value implies a high correlation between income levels of children and parents. Data
from OECD (2006): Society at a Glance and Corak (2006).
·
The Nordic Model
Social welfare and
equality are difficult
to measure, but many
indicators point in the
same direction
Social mobility is higher in the Nordic countries than in France,
the UK or the US
The Nordics rank high
on indicators of social
welfare but are not
the biggest spenders
There exists a Nordic
model and it has performed relatively well
also benefits in kind were included. Inequality is low in the Nordic
countries as well as in the Netherlands and Austria, while it is high
in the Anglo-Saxon and South-European countries.
Social mobility refers in this context to a measure of intergenerational income elasticity, i.e. a measure of the strength of the
relation between income levels of children and parents. There are
several possible reasons why children tend to “inherit” their parents’ socio-economic status (genes, wealth, transmission of learning
behaviour and attitudes from parents to children). Redistributive
family policies and particularly the educational system are probably some of the main forces working in the opposite direction and
contributing to intergenerational income mobility.
As is seen from figure 3.6, the intergenerational income
elasticity is lower, that is, social mobility is higher in the Nordic
countries than in France or the UK (or in the US). This may be
deemed noteworthy, as few people find it desirable that the socioeconomic status is strongly hereditary whatever the views held on
current income inequality.
A second observation is that the Nordic countries score well
in terms of indicators of social welfare. In figure 3.7 we show a
measure of social expenditure and the OECD’s “composite social
index”, which is a broad-based measure of social well-being that
aggregates a number of sub-indices covering “self-sufficiency”,
equity, health and social cohesion.9 The composite indicator gives
the highest ranks to Sweden, Denmark and Finland, while low
ranks are accorded to the countries in the South. This measure
is strongly correlated with GDP per capita, though the Nordic
countries get higher ranks for their social performance as compared
to their GDP per capita (contrary to, for instance, the US). As is
seen, the Nordics achieve comparatively good results without in
all cases being among the high spenders.10
The observations in this and the preceding chapter substantiate the claim that there exists a Nordic model in the sense of a
number of shared attributes that are economically, socially and
politically significant. What is the “bottom line” with regard to
the performance of this model? Employment and productivity
rates in the Nordic countries are relatively high, the former more
so than the latter. The growth rate of GDP per capita has been
The performance of the Nordic model
·
55
a
Composite index
0.9
0.9
Swe
0.8
Fin
0.7
0.7
Net
UK
0.6
Aut
Spa
0.5
18
20
0.8
Den
Por
22
24
Ita
Fra
Ger
0.6
0.5
26
28
30
b
Social spending, 2003
Figure 3.7
Social spending and welfare
a
b
Median of a composite index based on selected social indicators. OECD (2006): Society at a Glance.
Net mandated social expenditure as a per cent of GDP, see Adema & Ladaique (2005).
satisfactory, notably since the mid-1990s. (Also, price stability has
prevailed and the general government budget is in surplus.) The
Nordics have embraced globalization and are at the forefront in
adopting new technologies. With regard to the social area, the
Nordic countries are consistently at the top in terms of income
equality, social mobility over generations, and broad indicators of
social welfare. In all, the Nordics perform fairly well in economic
terms and they rank quite high according to social indicators.
On balance, these observations do not suggest that the Nordic countries have, in the recent past, been paying a heavy price
for their large public sectors in terms of economic distortions and
inefficiency caused by the high tax rates. This need not be seen as
surprising, as the effects of taxes and public expenditures are likely
to depend very much on their content and context. Public action
may obviously contribute to economic efficiency by correcting for
market failures, by allowing for an improved risk allocation through
social insurance, and by investing in infrastructures and human
capital (see, e.g., Lindbeck (2006)). Increased income security
and redistribution may also, up to a point, promote not only social
56
·
The Nordic Model
So far the bumble
bee has been flying
– but what about the
future?
stability but also economic growth (Alesina and Rodrik (1994)).
The design and implementation of policies has, by and large,
helped the economy to cope with the challenges of globalization
and new technologies. In other words, the interaction of policies
and markets has been such as to allow the “bumble bee” to fly.
This is comforting, but the real question is whether we can count
on this continuing to be the case in the future.
The performance of the Nordic model
·
57
ANNEX:
GROWTH ACCOUNTING
The Nordic countries have relied strongly on the IT revolution
for their economic growth success. The methodology of growth
accounting allows us to assess the quantitative importance of this
and other sources of growth, such as the growth of conventional
capital and labour input as well as general technological change
(referred to as total factor productivity or TFP).
Growth accounting tries to uncover the sources of economic
growth by considering the production side of the economy. The
growth of aggregate output is decomposed into contributions from
growth in different factor inputs (capital, labour and other factors)
and from general technological change. The method can be used
in a flexible way depending on the availability of data on inputs
of productive factors. It should be noted that it is not possible to
measure general technological change directly, so its effects are
shown by the residual in the growth accounting decomposition.
In this study, we have used the method to decompose overall GDP
growth into contributions from the growth of labour input, non-IT
capital input, IT capital input and general technological progress
(total factor productivity). The contribution of each productive
factor follows from its growth rate and its relative importance in
production. The decompositions are based on the formula:
GDP growth rate = contribution of labour + contribution of non-IT
capital + contribution of IT capital + residual contribution (TFP).
We now consider the three Nordic countries, using the growth
accounting technique, and we also compare developments to those
of the US and the EU15. Table 3.2 shows the results of the growth
accounting computations11 (first panel), the rate of accumulation of
IT and non-IT capital (second panel), the growth of labour input
(third panel), and technological progress or TFP (last panel).
Several observations can be made. First, information technology has played a fairly big role (first panel in table 3.2). The Nordics are much like the US in the sense that the contribution of IT
58
·
The Nordic Model
capital to GDP growth, since the mid-1990s, has been significant
– and typically larger than that of non-IT capital. In fact, these
countries were early starters in the use of IT and had high shares
of IT capital relative to most other countries already in the mid1990s, i.e. at the time that the IT revolution took off.
Second, general technological change (TFP) has been important for the US, for Finland and also, to an extent, for Sweden.
It seems to have played much less of a role in Denmark and the
EU15. TFP growth can be thought of as a measure of technological
progress, which is not embodied in the explicit factors of production, i.e. in labour and the various types of capital. The non-measurable factors in TFP include innovations and improvements in
general knowledge and the organization of production. However,
since TFP growth is measured as a residual, it also contains effects such as cyclical variations, pure changes in efficiency, and
measurement errors.12
Third, there is more variation in the growth rates for conventional capital. Denmark and Sweden have had positive growth in
conventional capital as well, whereas for Finland conventional
capital has played almost no role in the rapid growth in the second
half of the 1990s. Investment in conventional capital continued
to make a significant contribution to GDP growth in the US. The
Table 3.2
Growth accounting
Denmark
95–00 00–04
Sweden
95–00 00–04
Finland
95–00 00–04
USA
95–00 00–04
EU15
95–00 00–04
GDP growth
2.8
1.3
3.5
2.0
4.9
2.3
4.2
2.4
2.7
1.5
Growth contribution
Labour
IT capital
Non IT-capital
TFP
0.4
1.0
0.8
0.6
-0.1
0.5
0.9
0.3
0.7
1.1
0.4
1.3
-0.4
0.4
0.2
1.9
1.0
0.6
-0.1
3.3
-0.3
0.5
0.1
2.0
1.3
1.1
0.7
1.1
-0.3
0.5
0.4
1.7
0.6
0.6
0.6
0.9
0.3
0.3
0.5
0.4
Growth of capital services
IT capital
10.9
Non IT-capital
1.4
17.6
2.9
19.1
1.7
6.8
0.7
13.8
-0.2
10.8
0.2
17.9
9.1
2.8
1.8
-
-
Growth of labour input
Total hours
Hours of workers
Number of workers
-0.1
0.1
0.2
1.0
-0.4
0.8
-0.6
-0.5
0.4
1.6
-0.6
2.1
-0.5
-0.8
0.2
1.9
-0.5
1.4
-0.4
-0.3
0.7
0.9
-0.5
1.4
0.4
-0.3
0.7
0.6
-0.4
1.0
The performance of the Nordic model
·
59
sources of GDP growth in the EU15, which has been slower than
in the US or in the Nordics, have been different, as growth contributions are spread rather evenly between the different sources.13
After Finland, Sweden has the second lowest rate of accumulation
of conventional capital, while the Danish figures are comparable
to those of the US and many other European countries.
With regard to the growth rates of IT and non-IT capital
services14, it is seen (second panel) that both the Nordics and the
US invested heavily in IT capital in the boom period 1995–1999,
while in the period 2000–2004 IT capital growth slowed down.
The Nordics do not stand out according to IT capital growth,
even though they had significant contributions to growth from
this source. The explanation is instead that these countries – like
the US – already had accommodated a relatively high share of IT
capital before the mid-1990s (the average share of income imputed
to IT capital was around 5–6 per cent). As early users of IT capital,
these countries benefited from the high-tech boom of the 1990s.
A decomposition of changes in total hours worked into
changes in annual hours per worker (working time) and changes
in the total number of employed workers (employment) sheds some
additional light on the growth process (third panel). It indicates
that some countries have experienced negative contributions from
hours per worker as working times have progressively become
shorter. Yet, for many countries there have been substantial positive contributions from the total number of employed workers, so
that total labour input in terms of total hours has increased. In the
period 1995–2000, this increase has been significant not only for
the US but also for Finland and Sweden, which is largely explained
by increased labour utilization of labour as these two countries
recovered from their deep recessions. The increase in hours has
been much smaller for the second period 2000–2004, mainly due
to slow growth in the number of workers.
60
·
The Nordic Model
ENDNOTES
1
It is occasionally argued that the provision of child care and old age care by public authorities rather than within families implies a higher GDP, as it is measured, without “real” differences
in amount of work or services provided. The argument is correct as far as it goes. However, one
should not infer that the way care is organized does not matter, as complex efficiency and equity
arguments need to be considered. On the arguments for “home production” see chapter 4.
2
Honkapohja et al. (2008) and Jonung and Hagberg (2005) provide a description and analysis
of the Finnish and Swedish recessions of the early 1990s.
3
The data used in figures 3.1–3.3 are based on different sources which are not always mutually consistent. However, differences for individual countries have no bearing on the broad messages that those figures convey about the economic performance of the Nordics as compared to
other countries.
4
IT production is defined as the sum of current value-added in industries for optical and electrical equipment, postal and telecommunications, and computers and related activities.
5
Diffusion of new technologies such as IT involve learning costs that decrease over time with
the increasing number of users, and this process can be facilitated by a well-qualified labour
force. The evidence of high educational attainment in the Nordics supports this conclusion as
these countries are on the IT technology frontier.
6
An important question in education policies concerns the level of education at which improvements should be focused. The answer appears to depend on whether the country is close
or far from the technology frontier (see Aghion and Howitt (2005)). If a country is close to the
frontier, it should focus on improving the tertiary education systems. This is because high-technology innovations appear to require more advanced skills than lower-level innovations. It can
be noted that the US does not stand out in the quality of secondary education but it is obviously
well ahead of EU countries in the quality of its best universities. This is the part of the education
system that matters the most for economic growth of the advanced countries.
7
The effects of deregulation work via intensified competition, which in turn leads to increased
entry and exit. Recent evidence suggests that the growth effects of entry and exit depend on the
industry, more precisely on the distance of the industry from the technology frontier. Industries
that are close to the frontier can compete in the environment of intensified competition, whereas
industries or sectors that are far behind cannot cope with it. Correspondingly, the exit of less efficient firms and replacement of them by new ones tends to have positive effects on economic
growth.
8
A recent study by Dantas et al. (2006) has compared profitability of venture capital investment in Europe and in the US. Their findings are worrisome as European VC investments appear
to be far less profitable than corresponding investment in the US. The results for Europe have not
been decomposed by country, so that profitability of Nordic VC investment is not available separately. It would be important to analyze profitability of VC investment in the Nordic countries,
with benchmarking against the US.
9
More particularly, the sub-indices in the four areas cover: 1) self-sufficiency (total employment rates, people in jobless households, average years of schooling, mean student performance), 2) equity (income inequality, relative poverty rate, child poverty, gender wage gap), 3)
health (healthy life expectancy at birth, total life expectancy at birth, infant mortality, potential
years of life lost) and 4) social cohesion (volunteering, victimization rate, prisoners, suicide rate).
10
The composite indicator is an aggregate and its composition can be put in question on many
grounds. Other weighting schemes might give a different picture and a less favourable rating of
the Nordic countries. For instance, Finns have a relatively high death rate from alcohol abuse as
well as from homicide and suicide. It might indeed be argued that the OECD composite social indicator is just one possible measure rather than the definitive yardstick. However, there are many
social indicators produced by international organizations (OECD, EU, WB, UN), and scanning these
indicators of social equality and welfare (whether based on hard data or surveys) tends to confirm
the impression of a high ranking of the Nordics.
The performance of the Nordic model
·
61
11
These decompositions have been carried out on the basis of five-year averages and not annually; thus they are approximations. The data is from the Groningen Growth and Development
Centre, Total Economy Growth Accounting Database.
12
It can also partly reflect effects from improvements in labour and capital quality, since such
quality improvements are difficult to quantify and may not be fully incorporated into factor
shares and growth rates of the corresponding productive factors.
13
EEAG (2006), Chapter 3 provides a more detailed discussion of economic growth in the EU15
countries.
14
Capital services are measured using the methodology developed by Jorgenson and Griliches
(1967), in which growth rates of different types of capital are weighted using average shares of
each capital asset type in the value of the property compensation in terms of rental prices. See
Timmer, Ypma and van Ark (2003) for further details on the method of construction of the data.
62
·
The Nordic Model
4
The population is
greying and this will
have profound effects on both labour
markets and public
finances
DEMOGRAPHICS:
FROM TAIL-WIND TO HEAD-WIND
The Nordic welfare model will face substantial financial pressure
in the future, not least in the case of Finland. The main reason
is that the population is greying. The number of elderly citizens
is increasing at the same time as the work force is shrinking. The
balance between those working and those not working will thus
change dramatically, which in turn affects both labour markets
and public finances. Public expenditures are projected to outpace
revenues by a significant margin and this development raises serious
challenges for current welfare arrangements. In short, the financial
sustainability of the welfare state is at stake.
The worsening of public finances will take place automatically,
simply as a consequence of maintaining current arrangements.
Even relatively conservative estimates of future pressures on public
spending suggest that the tax burden (tax revenues/GDP) would
have to increase by several percentage points to close the sustainability gap in public finances. The magnitude of this challenge
implies that the status quo is not a policy option. Moreover, the tax
burden is already high and the tax system is under pressure from
globalization. The policy option of raising taxes is therefore not
appealing. Difficult policy choices have to be made to cut spending,
to reduce benefit dependency and/or to increase employment rates.
It is also worth stressing that the sooner reforms are undertaken,
the less drastic will they have to be!
Demographics: from tail-wind to head-wind
·
63
4.1 THE WELFARE STATE AS A SOCIAL
CONTRACT
It is a hallmark of the Nordic welfare model that it offers both an
elaborate social safety net as well as public services such as education and care (child and old age care, health care). Although
there are various rules determining entitlements to these welfare
provisions, it is a defining characteristic that ability to pay is not
a criterion; the right to these provisions is universal in the sense
that they are available to all citizens without being preconditioned
on prior payments or contributions (see also chapter 2). These arrangements are financed by various forms of taxation, and there is
no relation for the individual between tax payments and entitlements to services. (The same is not the case for most pensions and
part of unemployment benefits.) However, at the aggregate level
the tax revenues obviously have to cover expenses generated by
the welfare arrangements.
This way of structuring the welfare society has the important
consequence that benefits received and payments made by the
average citizen differ strongly according to his/her age. The reason
is simply that many arrangements of the welfare state serve to
improve conditions for children (care and education) and the old
(health care and pensions), while the contributions in the form
of tax payments primarily accrue from income earned in the active years. Figure 4.1 shows the age-dependent net contribution
of the average person to the public sector in Finland; that is, the
difference between tax payments (of various kinds) and the value
of transfers and individual services received.
The figure displays a clear pattern – the average person benefits from the welfare state in young and old age, and contributes
in the years during which he or she is active in the labour market.
It should be stressed that the figure shows only the average position
for different age groups. Within age groups there are large variations: some have high incomes and rarely use public provisions like
health care, while others have low income and poor health.
The relation depicted in the figure captures the “social contract” between generations, which is one of the backbones of the
64
·
The Nordic Model
The social contract
between generations
and the change in
demographics imply a
serious challenge for
the sustainability of
public finances
1000 EUR
1000 EUR
20
20
10
10
0
0
-10
-10
-20
-20
-30
-30
-40
-40
0-4
10-14
20-24
30-34
40-44
50-54
60-64
70-74
80-84
>90
Figure 4.1
Average net contributions depending on age
The figure shows the net contribution to public finances defined as all types of tax payments less transfers and individualized public consumption. The numbers are calculated
on the basis of data for 2004.
Source: Vaittinen and Vanne (2006).
welfare state. The essence of it is that those working finance, via
their tax payments, the welfare provisions of the young and the old
(and of other groups, such as the sick and unemployed). This can
be interpreted as reflecting solidarity of those of working age, who
contribute to the young and the old because they care about their
living conditions. Alternatively, the social contract is supported
by the perception of those of working age that they, if currently in
need or in due time as they grow old, will be able to benefit from
the same or similar welfare provisions. Expectations and trust are
essential; those currently active agree to pay taxes because they
trust that future active generations will do the same. The system
is based on social cohesion in the sense of a perception that we
are all, in one way or another, in the same boat.
The social contract has three key elements
1 Extent, coverage and quality of entitlements,
2 level and structure of tax payments,
3 labour force participation, including exit from and entry
into the labour market.
Demographics: from tail-wind to head-wind
·
65
The extent, coverage and quality of the entitlements depend
on the ambitions of society for, e.g., education and health care,
and with regard to when and how the social safety net should protect persons becoming unable to support themselves. The Nordic
welfare model is characterized by the aspiration to offer service
provisions that meet the requirements of most people; that is, the
public sector is not a residual supplier of last resort for those unable to provide for themselves but rather something used by the
majority of the population. All should have the same options for
education – depending on ability and motivation – and health
care – depending on need.
Likewise, the social safety net is supposed to offer a decent living
standard, and it is not acceptable that individuals without self-support only attain a living standard very much lower than that of other
groups. The ambition is to ensure equal opportunities irrespective of
the ability to pay. While difficult to achieve, this egalitarian objective
is a cornerstone of the Nordic welfare model.
Given the high ambitions with respect to the extent and quality of services and the social safety net, a large fraction of economic
resources is in the Nordic countries allocated and distributed via
the public sector. And since the welfare package is mainly financed
by taxes, the tax burden (the ratio of total tax revenues to GDP)
is high (see figure 4.2). This raises issues concerning the effects
of taxes on economic decision making, since taxes cause a wedge
between the social and private return to activities like education
and work.
A high rate of labour force participation – reflecting working
hours over the year as well as entry by the young and exit by the
old from the labour market – is crucial for the Nordic model. The
reason is straightforward: most outside the labour market are entitled to some form of transfer income, while only those with a job
are contributing to the financing of the welfare state. The financial
balance of the social contract is therefore undermined if too few
are active in the labour market. An extended tax-financed welfare
model necessarily has to rely on high employment. As already
noted in chapter 3, the Nordic countries have indeed managed
to achieve a high rate of labour force participation. In 2006, the
average participation rate for the age group 15–65 was higher in
66
·
The Nordic Model
The Nordic principle
of universality is ambitious – and costly
High tax rates are part
of the model
High employment
rates are one of the
preconditions for the
viability of the Nordic
model
Mexico
Korea
Japan*
Greece
Slovak Republic
Switzerland
Australia*
Ireland
Turkey
Canada
Poland*
Portugal
Germany
Luxembourg
New Zealand
Czech Republic
Spain
Hungary
United Kingdom
Netherlands
Iceland*
Austria
Italy
Finland
Norway
France
Belgium
Denmark
Sweden
0
10
20
30
40
50
60 %
Figure 4.2
Tax burden of OECD countries in 2006
* Figure is for 2005.
Source: OECD Revenue Statistics 2007.
Two main challenges: the changing demographics and the
provision of welfare
services
Denmark and Sweden (at 76.9 and 74.5 per cent, respectively)
than in any other country in the EU15. The rate in Finland (at
68.9 per cent) was lower than in the other members of the Nordic
family but higher than in other EU15 countries except for the
Netherlands and Austria. However, decomposing labour market
participation by age (figure 4.3), Finland stands out by having a very
high participation rate for prime age groups, but a low participation
rate for the young (which to a large extent can be explained by
education) and, in particular, for the elderly or those aged above
50 (due to early retirement in one form or another).
Two important challenges arise as a consequence of these
characteristics of the Nordic welfare state. The first is the demographic challenge in the form of the change in the age composition
Demographics: from tail-wind to head-wind
·
67
%
%
80
80
60
60
40
40
OECD max
Finland
OECD min
20
20
0
0
15-19 20-24 25-29 30-34 35-39 40-44 45-49 50-54 55-59 60-64 65-69
Figure 4.3
Labour force participation rate by age, 2003
Average participation rates for 5-year age groups, both sexes. The OECD max and OECD
min curves are composite indicators that depict, for each age group, the highest and lowest participation rate over all OECD countries.
Source: OECD Labour Force Statistics.
of the population resulting from a fall in fertility and an increase
in longevity. The second may be termed the service challenge.
The services provided by the public sector include a large share
of labour-intensive human care, for which it is difficult to increase
productivity without weakening quality. For instance, the quality
of old-age care is assessed by how much time the personnel has
available per old person. Moreover, needs and requirements tend
to increase alongside other developments in society. Technology opens up new possibilities, notably, through advances in life
sciences. Increases in material living standards give rise to new
aspiration levels; the perception of a satisfactory quality of public
provision of services is reassessed in the light of the development
of income and other spending in the society. Hence, the demand
for services may rise at the same time as they become more costly.
In the following, these two challenges are discussed in turn; in this
chapter we discuss the direct effects of demographic changes, and
in the next chapter we turn to the service challenge.
68
·
The Nordic Model
4.2 AGEING – THE TREND IS TURNING
The welfare state was
created in conditions
of favourable demographics
The demographics
are changing because
of the retiring babyboom generation and
increasing longevity
A straightforward implication of the social contract shown in figure
4.1 is that the financial balance of the welfare state depends critically on the age composition of the population. There is no problem
with the financial balance if there are few children and old relative
to the working age population – then many are net payers and few
are net recipients. Financial problems arise, however, if there are
many children and old relative to the working age population, or
few payers to support many recipients.
Historically, the welfare state expanded when there were
“many to support few” in the sense that working age population
was increasing relative to the number of children and the old.
In contrast, the perspective for the future is now one in which
“few will have to support many”. This may be illustrated by the
so-called demographic dependency ratio, defined as the young
(below age 15) and old (age above 65) relative to the age group
in between (figure 4.4). The dependency ratio is in coming years
going to increase significantly in the Nordic countries as well as
elsewhere. In Finland the ratio has declined from the 1950s to the
1990s, but it is now starting to increase rapidly towards a new and
much higher level. Most of the change reflects the increase is in
the number of people aged 65 or more and will take place already
within the next 10–20 years.
The age composition of the population is therefore going to
change dramatically. For instance, according to the latest forecast
from Statistics Finland, the proportion of persons older than 65
years will increase from the current 16 to 26 per cent by 2030. In
addition, there is a “double ageing” in the sense that not only will
the share of old people rise, but the share of the very old (those
above 85) will increase even more (from currently 1.8 to 6.1 per cent
in 2040). The share of young people below 15 will diminish from
about 17 to 15.5 per cent in 2040. As a consequence of these two
trends, the percentage of the working-age population (age between
15 and 65) will decrease from 66.5 to 57.5 per cent by 2040.
The demographic shifts are driven by two main factors. One
is the so-called baby-boom effect created by high fertility rates in
Demographics: from tail-wind to head-wind
·
69
%
%
Total
Old age
80
80
60
60
40
40
20
20
0
1940
0
50
60
70
80
90
2000
10
20
30
40
Figure 4.4
Total and old-age dependency ratios, 1940–2040
The demographic dependency ratio – total – is defined as the age groups below 15 and
above 64 relative to the age group 15–64, and the old-age dependency ratio is defined as
the above 64 relative to the age group 15–64. Actual data 1940–2006, and Statistics Finland demographic projection for the period 2007–2040.
Source: Statistics Finland.
4.0
4.0
3.5
3.5
3.0
3.0
2.5
2.5
2.0
2.0
1.5
1.5
1.0
1.0
0.5
0.5
0.0
1930
0.0
40
50
Figure 4.5
Fertility rate, 1930–2006
Source: Statistics Finland.
70
·
The Nordic Model
60
70
80
90
2000
the late 1940s and the 1950s and the subsequent fall in fertility, cf.
figures 4.5 and 4.6. As a consequence, large cohorts are approaching retirement while, at the same time, smaller generations are
entering the labour market. Another factor is increasing longevity.
Life expectancy has been on an upward trend, driven in recent
years by the fall in mortality rates. In short, people live longer: while
life expectancy for a newborn in 1970 was 70 years, it is today 79.4
years, and in 2040 it is expected to be 86.2 years.
Yrs
Yrs
78
78
76
76
74
74
72
72
70
70
68
1970
68
75
80
85
90
95
2000
05
Figure 4.6
Life expectancy 1971–2006
Source: Statistics Finland.
4.3 AGEING PUTS THE PUBLIC SECTOR UNDER
FINANCIAL PRESSURE
Combining the demographic trends with the social contract depicted in figure 4.1 yields a clear message. The balance between
those contributing to and those benefiting from the welfare state
is shifting to such an extent that the financial balance of the sys-
Demographics: from tail-wind to head-wind
·
71
tem is seriously affected. Today, there is roughly one person older
than 65 for 4 persons in the working age (or between 15 and 65),
but in 2040 there will be almost two above 65 for 4 persons in
the working age. That is, the old-age dependency ratio is almost
going to double.
The “official” assessment of the financial consequence of
these shifts is the one made by the Ministry of Finance (2006).
Age-related expenditures (pensions, health care, long-term care,
education and unemployment) are projected to increase by some
5 percentage points of GDP between now and 2050. Assuming
an unchanged overall tax rate, the general government primary
balance1 will deteriorate significantly, cf. figure 4.7. The projected
situation is one of systematic budget deficits, and the situation is
not sustainable (public debt would be growing to 120 per cent of
GDP by 2050).
The size of the “sustainability gap” is measured by the ministry
by the permanent improvement in the annual budget needed to
ensure that the debt level in 2050 is the same as today. It turns
out that the needed improvement of the general government financial balance corresponds to 1.5 per cent of GDP. The cyclically
adjusted budget surplus would thus have to be significantly bigger
than presently foreseen or projected. Achieving fiscal sustainability
in the long run (well beyond 2050) would require a permanent
strengthening of the budget more than twice of that size. Thus,
fiscal sustainability will require a substantial improvement of public
finances.
There are two important aspects to note about the message
of figure 4.7. First, the precise numbers are not very interesting in
themselves. Clearly there is uncertainty, and the more so the longer
into the future the projections are extended. The relevant point is
not the specific number but the proposition that systematic deficits
are likely to emerge – and this conclusion is robust to a number of
changes in the underlying assumptions of the calculations (see figure 4.7). Second, the calculations reported here are conservative:
they only illustrate the consequences of given welfare arrangements
and tax rates when the age compositon of the population changes.
It is implicitly assumed that there are no improvements in public
services in the future – which is hardly a realistic assumption.
72
·
The Nordic Model
Ageing populations
are a main factor leading to unsustainable
finances
The long-term financial outlook of the
public sector may be
worse than projected
% of GDP
% of GDP
1
1
0
0
-1
-1
-2
-2
-3
-3
-4
-4
-5
2010
-5
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
Figure 4.7
Primary balance projection for 2010–2050
Source: Ministry of Finance (2006): Stability Programme for Finland, 4b/2006.
We will return to this issue in the next chapter. In short, current
welfare arrangements are not financially sustainable, and figure
4.7 is interesting because it provides a frame for discussing some
of the issues policy makers will have to address.
4.4 FIGHTING A TREND
Ensuring a high employment rate is crucial for the financing of the
welfare state. This is particularly obvious for pay-as-you-go (PAYG)
pension systems, in which the active population is financing the
pensions of those retired out of contributions from current incomes.
Such a system works well when the dependency ratio is decreasing, but it is problematic when the dependency ratio is increasing.
Ageing poses an obvious financial threat, because more people live
longer and because the employment ratio is likely to fall. One way
of counteracting this would be for the retirement age to increase
in parallel with increases in longevity (implying that the shares
of life spent in and outside the labour market remain constant).
Demographics: from tail-wind to head-wind
·
73
Historically, however, the share of life spent in the labour market
has (until recently) been decreasing both due to later entry into
the labour market and due to earlier withdrawal from the labour
market, typically via early retirement schemes. This trend is sooner
or later bound to resume if retirement ages remain unchanged while
longevity is increasing. Preventing this from happening is clearly
one of the steps needed to ensure the financial sustainability of
the welfare state.
Much has been done in the Nordic countries to meet the
pension challenge. In particular, the Swedish pension reform,
introducing a “notionally defined contribution system”, is widely
considered a benchmark. It promises a system that will remain
financially sustainable without any increase in pension contributions from their present level. Denmark has recently taken steps
to increase statutory ages for early retirement and public pensions.
Once these changes have been implemented, the statutory ages
will be tied to longevity. These measures address a large part but
do not solve the sustainability problem driven by changing demographics. Finland is not as advanced in solving the problems;
notably the earnings-related pension system of the private sector
is unsustainable in the sense that it is likely to call for significant
increases in the contribution rate in coming decades.
In recent years Finland has undertaken some reforms that
affect pensions and retirement, though these reforms are not sufficient to solve the problems. The recent pension reform abolished
some early retirement schemes and improved the incentives for
prolonging work careers beyond the age of 63. It also introduced
an adjustment mechanism linking pensions to longevity to the
effect that pensions to be paid to a given age cohort are reduced if
longevity increases. The latter is very important and implies that an
increase in longevity combined with an unchanged retirement age
would leave the individual with a lower annual benefit. In other
words, the individual would have either to accept a lower (material) living standard or postpone retirement alongside the increase
in longevity. If the individual postpones retirement in parallel with
the increase in longevity, the benefits received will be unchanged.
Although this contributes towards solving the problems arising
from ageing, these measures are not sufficient. Moreover, from a
74
·
The Nordic Model
The Nordic countries
have done much to
meet the pension
challenge – but more
needs to be done, notably in Finland
Many people want to
retire early – but
should be encouraged
to prolong their working careers
long-run perspective it is an anomaly that the statutory retirement
ages (62, 63 and 68) are kept fixed while longevity increases.
There are several reasons why retirement may take place too
early as seen from the perspective of society. First, taxation (in
combination with various forms of means testing and supplements)
implies that the return for continued work and later retirement is
smaller for the individual than for the society even if the benefits
are actuarially fair. The reason is that the labour income earned
by postponing retirement is taxed (while leisure is not).
Second, even though indexation of benefits to longevity
provides incentives for individuals to retire later when longevity increases, the system does not automatically ensure that this
takes place. This is so since the statutory ages that apply to the
various schemes are not indexed, and because individuals may
underestimate longevity. Finally, with rising incomes there may
be a preference shift with an increasing focus on leisure in the
“third phase” of life.
Ageing is often perceived as an issue of pensions and retirement only. While these issues are important, one should stress
that there are other financing concerns related to ageing. These
include welfare provisions such as health and old age care. Financing the latter is also strongly dependent on the age composition
of the population. More people – both relatively and absolutely
(and particularly the very old) – will be in need of old age care
and health services in the future. While increasing longevity is
associated with more healthy ageing, there will nevertheless be
an increasing pressure on health and old-age care if the old are in
the future to have the same access to welfare services as currently.
This requires more resources and raises financing issues beyond
that of pensions.
4.5 EASY FIXES?
In the debate on the consequences of the ageing of society, it is
often claimed that there are some easy solutions. Let us consider
a few of these.
Demographics: from tail-wind to head-wind
·
75
More children. Since the problem is the increasing share of old
people in society, it is intuitively plausible that more children would
be a straightforward solution. However, there are two reasons why
this will not solve the problem. First, to eliminate the baby-boom
effect, fertility should have increased years back, cf. figure 4.5; it is
too late to rectify this problem now. Second, the newborns will also
benefit from increased longevity, and hence in a lifetime perspective they will not be net contributors if current retirement ages
remain unchanged. If the current system is not robust with respect
to increasing longevity, it does not help to increase the number
of newborns who will also enjoy increasing longevity. This is not
to deny that there are both economic and non-economic reasons
why more children and higher population growth are important
for the society. However, higher fertility is not a solution to the
financial problems arising from ageing.
Immigration. If it is too late to solve the problem by increasing
fertility, could it not be rectified swiftly by immigration? It is correct
that immigration of people in their 20s and 30s would contribute
to flattening the rise in the dependency ratio. However, this will
solve the economic problems only if the immigrants obtain a high
labour-market attachment; to put it a bit bluntly, we are not looking for young people per se, but for workers who can contribute to
financing our welfare system by paying taxes (rather than receiving
benefits). It is not obvious that a country like Finland can induce
immigration satisfying the latter condition on a very large scale.
The potential for solving the problem via immigration may also
been seen in light of the fact that in a medium-term perspective
there is no “population surplus” in Eastern Europe; these countries
are among the significantly ageing countries, and therefore large
migration flows from these regions should arguably not be expected,
cf. Carone (2005). The conclusion is again that more immigration
may be desirable for various reasons but is not realistically to be
perceived as a solution to the public finance problem at hand.
The others have a bigger problem. It is often argued that our
demographic problems are not that bad since other countries,
like those in Southern Europe, are facing even larger demographic
shifts. This is a strange argument: why would problems faced by
other countries contribute to solving the problems faced by the
76
·
The Nordic Model
More children are
desirable – but will
not solve the public
finance problem
More immigration
may well be desirable
– but will not solve
the public finance
problem
Economic growth is
important – but will
not solve the public
finance problem
Finnish welfare state? Actually the opposite may very well be the
case. If countries with large demographic problems are late in
reforming their systems, they may be a source of financial and economic instability with negative repercussions on other countries.
If anything, it is better to have trading partners that either have
smaller problems or are front-runners in reforms.
Growth. If the problem is that we have to support more old
people, could the problem not be solved by a growth-oriented
economic policy? In this way the pie would become larger, and
perhaps we could then ensure the financial viability of the welfare
system. Upon reflection, this turns out to be less obvious than it
sounds. True enough, more growth will imply higher wages and
incomes and thus also more tax revenues. This will indeed give
more leeway in the public budget. However, the expenditure side
will also be affected.
The public sector has basically two types of expenditures:
wages paid to employees hired for the supply of various welfare
services and transfers of one kind or another. Consider the following benchmark case in which we assume an unchanged supply of
welfare services and an unchanged distribution profile in society.
Under these two provisos, public expenditures will tend to grow
by the growth rate of the pie.
To see this, note that public sector wages will have to increase
by the same rate as wages in the private sector in order to maintain (in the medium term) the public-sector work force. Hence,
this expenditure component increases by the same growth rate.
Similarly, if recipients of transfers are going to gain from growth
to the same extent as other groups in society, transfer expenditure
will also grow at the same rate. Thus, more growth in the private
sector will (roughly) raise the growth rate of public revenues and
expenditures by equal magnitudes. It will not create any leeway in
the public budget – under the assumption of unchanged service
supply and distribution. Nothing is, of course, precluding a change
in either of these two conditions. The point is that growth per se
will not contribute to solving the financial problems unless policy
makers decide or accept a decline in public-sector wages and/or
transfers relative to private-sector wages.
Demographics: from tail-wind to head-wind
·
77
Actually higher growth may make the financial problems of
the welfare state worse. We return to discuss this paradoxical effect
in detail in the next chapter.
There are thus no easy fixes to the financial problems driven
by the demographic changes. This leaves basically three options:
increase taxes, cut expenditures or increase employment. The
option of increasing taxes is not only conditional on political support for such increases, but it also raises question about how tax
increases would affect economic performance. The tax burden is
already high and it is not clear that it is advisable to increase tax
rates further. Expenditure cuts imply a retrenchment of the welfare
state, and hence the sustainability problem of the welfare state is
solved by making it shrink. This meets with political opposition
and it would not qualify as a strategy for adjusting the welfare
state to the new challenges – unless it is based more on increased
efficiency than reduced entitlements. A further option could be
to reduce benefit dependency and increase employment. Since a
significant part of the problem is driven by increased longevity,
it is natural to focus on measures to ensure that the effective or
average retirement age increases.
Increase taxes, cut
spending or raise the
employment rate?
4.6 SAVE OR ADJUST?
The key challenge for the welfare state is that expenditures will
outpace revenues for unchanged welfare arrangements due to the
ageing of the population. However, although the demographic
changes are approaching rapidly, there is still some time before
they materialize fully. The issue of how to plan for the projected
financial problems is, therefore, important.
One strategy would be to consolidate public finances in advance; to run a budget surplus in order to bring down public debt
as soon as possible and eventually create a stock of public wealth,
which can be used to finance the expenditure rise. Fiscal policies
in recent years can be said to have followed this path, since the
budget has been in surplus and public debt has been reduced. It
makes sense to consolidate public finances when the debt level is
relatively large and financial pressures are projected.
78
·
The Nordic Model
Fiscal consolidation
is justified – to some
degree
Current budget surpluses are sizeable
but cannot solve the
future financing
problems
It is, however, neither advisable nor realistic to solve the entire
problem by consolidation. This is so since the needed consolidation is large – of the order of magnitude of a permanent annual
budget improvement of several per cent of GDP – and would thus
require policy makers to run very big surpluses for a long sequence
of years to cover expenditure rises in the very distant future. Figure
4.8 illustrates the implications of a consolidation strategy in which
large budget surpluses are assumed not only for the next few years
but continuing until around 2030 so as to ensure that (modest)
deficits beyond 2030 can be financed.2
This is not a politically realistic path. It is unlikely that policy
makers could pursue the tough fiscal policies required to raise the
present (already sizeable) budget surplus by amounts corresponding to several percentage points of GDP for such a long sequence
of years. The combination of the public sector building up a huge
fund while citizens are increasingly insisting on increased welfare
services would easily result in a political impasse. Moreover, it is
important to distinguish between increases in the demographic
%
%
Primary balance with fiscal consolidation
ensuring sustainability
Primary balance in baseline projection
4
4
2
2
0
0
-2
-2
-4
-4
-6
2010
-6
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
Figure 4.8
Budget change needed to ensure long-run sustainability: consolidation
strategy 2010–2050
Source: Own calculations based on data from figure 4.7. Growth corrected real rate of interest is assumed equal to 1 per cent.
Demographics: from tail-wind to head-wind
·
79
dependency ratio driven by the baby-boom effect and the increase
in longevity. For the former, some consolidation makes sense; the
possibility of redressing the change in fertility is bypassed and
consolidation will imply that the consequences of the change
in the dependency ratio are smoothened across generations. For
longevity the case is different, since pre-funding would imply that
current generations contribute to the financing of expenditure
for future generations enjoying higher longevity. It is not obvious
that this is fair. Hence, consolidation has to be combined with
reforms that take the trend out of the public budget balance. This
requires reforms that adapt the social contract to deal with the
consequences of ageing.
80
·
The Nordic Model
ENDNOTES
1
The general government primary balance is equal to the total balance less net revenues
from financial assets. As the pension funds are significantly bigger than government debt, the
general government financial balance deteriorates more slowly than the primary balance.
2
The graph uses the figures for the primary balance (baseline) as projected by the Ministry of
Finance (2006). That projection starts only in 2010, which is therefore the starting point also for
figure 4.8. Recent data suggest an upward revision of estimates for the general government surplus for this and possibly the next year. However, the long run projection is geared to the cyclically adjusted balance and should remain unaffected by recent and temporary developments.
Demographics: from tail-wind to head-wind
·
81
82
·
The Nordic Model
5
WELFARE SERVICES:
RISING COSTS AND INCREASING
DEMAND
The provision of services is an essential element of the welfare
state. The services include, inter alia, day-care, education (ranging from primary schooling to higher education), health care,
and old-age care. The Nordic welfare model has the ambition of
ensuring equal access to services for all according to need. The
services are therefore mainly tax-financed and the standards offered
should not only amount to a bare minimum but should meet the
requirements of most people.
It is a major challenge to maintain the extended provision of
tax-financed services in conditions of rising costs and increasing
demand. We consider these issues in turn.
5.1 SERVICES BECOME MORE COSTLY –
THE BAUMOL EFFECT
Productivity increases
rapidly in agriculture
and manufacturing –
but is much more difficult to raise in faceto-face services
Many forms of service production are special because of the crucial role of human interactions between the provider and user.
This applies in particular to child-care, old-age care, health care,
and education. Whereas productivity increases are possible and
significant in most types of economic activities, they are difficult
to achieve in face-to-face services. New techniques allow a farmer
Welfare services: rising costs and increasing demand
·
83
to handle much bigger fields today, as compared to farmers in the
past. Yet, the time it takes for a nurse to talk to the patient or for
the staff in day-care institutions to play with the children is the
same today as it was, say, 25 years ago. Time is essential for these
services and they can therefore not be rationalized and productivity cannot be increased to the same extent as for traditional
manufactured products.
As a rule of thumb, average productivity rises by about two
per cent a year due to more effective means of production or new
techniques and better machines. Real wages tend to grow over
time at the rate of productivity growth and material living standards increase accordingly. However, as those performing service
activities are to have the same wage increase as other groups and
since the productivity of this group remains broadly unchanged, it
follows that the relative price of producing these services goes up.
The main implication is that time/human-intensive services tend
to become more expensive over time (“Baumol’s law”).
The basic mechanism here is not dependent on whether
the service is provided by a private or public supplier – it is the
nature of the activity which is important. (This is not to deny
that incentives and organizational structures, which may differ as
between public and private provision, may also affect productivity,
see chapter 8.) While the price of, say, mobile phones has fallen
drastically due to technical advances, this has not happened for
hair cuts. In the same way, it has not become cheaper to produce
many public services – they are labour intensive and it is difficult
to increase productivity while maintaining the same quality of
the service. Rising costs will be reflected in higher prices paid by
the customer or higher taxes paid by the citizen. Since the public
sector is responsible for the provision of many such services, the
public sector is facing a major financing challenge.
Productivity rises less
than in the manufacturing sector but
wages as much – the
relative costs of welfare services increase
over time
5.2 MORE IS EXPECTED – THE WAGNER EFFECT
Productivity increases and improvements in material well-being
also release a demand effect. There is a tendency for the demand
for services to increase when incomes rise. Once basic needs (food,
84
·
The Nordic Model
At higher income
levels citizens want
more welfare services
and services of better
quality
clothes, shelter etc.) are provided for, more attention is given to
the satisfaction of other needs. Economists term this the “Wagner
effect”, referring to a shift in demand alongside improvements in
material living standards. The quality and extent of public service
provisions are not given once and for all but follow other trends in
society. Public services are expected to meet rising standards.
Again, the basic mechanism is present whether provision is private or public. Increases in demand are seen over a wide spectrum.
Standards have increased for many privately provided services, and
the same is happening for publicly provided services.1
Advances in medical
science make possible new and more
costly treatments and
medicines, which voters and politicians will
want to make widely
available
The costs for health
care and long-term
care will increase significantly as a share of
GDP – and could double by 2050
Health care – a particular challenge
Health care is an important part of the publicly provided services,
and an important area where the cost and demand effects outlined
above are having significant consequences. Equally important is the
fact that the opportunity frontier changes, thereby creating new
treatment possibilities and hence new demands. This is particularly the case for health care, where we fortunately see significant
advances in medical science. While these advances make some
forms of treatments much easier and thus cheaper, they also shift
the opportunity frontier and allow new and better treatments for
diseases for which no treatments were earlier available. These
advances bring important improvements in welfare, but they also
create pressure on the health system to make the new (and more
expensive) treatments and medicines widely accessible.
The effects of these tendencies are basically an empirical
question, and the outcome will reflect both technical and organizational/political mechanisms. One issue is the scope for actually
improving efficiency and productivity in the provision of welfare
services. Another important consideration relates to how increasing demands should be accommodated. In any case, the Baumol
and Wagner effects pose difficult challenges for the Nordic model,
given its ambition to provide welfare services at a level which meets
the needs and requirements of a large part of the population.
To illustrate this issue, table 5.1 reports the outcome from
a recent OECD study of the challenges facing the health care
systems in different countries, taking into account the effects discussed above. In the OECD analysis the new medical techniques
Welfare services: rising costs and increasing demand
·
85
Table 5.1
Projections of public health and long-term care spending as per cent of GDP,
2005 and 2050
2005
Denmark
Finland
Norway
Sweden
OECD
5.3
3.4
7.3
5.3
5.7
Health care
2050
2050
Cost
Cost
pressure containment
8.8
7.0
10.7
8.5
9.6
7.0
5.2
8.9
6.7
7.7
2005
2.6
2.9
2.6
3.3
1.1
Long-term care
2050
2050
Cost
Cost
pressure containment
4.1
5.2
4.3
4.3
3.3
3.3
4.2
3.5
3.4
2.4
2005
7.9
6.2
9.9
8.6
6.7
Total
2050
2050
Cost
Cost
pressure containment
12.9
12.2
15.0
12.9
12.8
10.3
10.3
12.4
10.1
10.1
Source: Projecting OECD Health and Long-term care expenditures: What are the main drivers, OECD Economics Department
Working Paper 477, 2006.
and treatments as well as the relative cost increases are in focus,
while the assumption on the income effect on service demand is
moderate.
The table present two scenarios: “cost pressure” refers to the
case where treatment costs rise more rapidly than income, while
in the “cost containment” case this rise is assumed to moderate
over time.2 The message of the table is clear. The rise of expenditure is significant for both health and long-term care even in the
optimistic scenario, in which cost containment is assumed. For
Finland there is an increase in spending from currently 6.2 per
cent of GDP to 10.3 per cent – and if costs cannot be contained
there will be a doubling.
The key point is that the service challenge for public finances
is caused by the combination of the cost (Baumol) and demand
(Wagner) effect. More is wanted of services at the same time as
they are becoming relatively more expensive to provide. The
reason why it is more difficult to address this problem for publicly
than for privately provided services is the difference in the way in
which demand and supply are brought into balance. For privately
produced services it is a matter for the individuals themselves to
decide whether they want to spend a larger share of their income
on these services or not. For public services the choice is much
less clear to the citizens since the services are provided free (or at
a heavily subsidized price), and hence policy makers are left with
86
·
The Nordic Model
the problem of how to define, provide and finance a “satisfactory”
level of public services.
5.3 PREFERENCES FOR LEISURE
People want to work
less as income levels increase – which
means that the tax
base shrinks
The challenges do not stop here. At the same time as the services
are straining public finances, we may actually choose to contribute
less to their financing. This may sound paradoxical, but there is
a simple explanation. With increasing material well-being it is
to be expected that the demand for the non-material aspects of
life will acquire an increased importance, that is, the demand for
leisure goes up (shorter working hours, longer vacations, earlier
retirement). This has happened in other countries and, historically,
it has also happened in Finland. Average annual working times
were 2005 hours in 1960 and 1624 hours in 2006 – people work
fewer hours because they can afford it. This trend is no surprise
– when material conditions improve, it is natural that people want
to expand non-material activities. The trend is a challenge for the
public sector since it tends to reduce the tax base – labour income
is taxed, leisure is not! While individuals do not think of a decision to work less as a decision to pay less tax, this is nevertheless
one of the consequences. When many people choose to have more
leisure the tax base shrinks (see also chapter 6).
We thus have what may be termed a growth paradox – more
growth may increase the demand for welfare services at the same
time as it raises the costs of providing services and shrinks the
base on which these activities are financed. The precise order of
magnitudes of future increases in the demand for both improved
and better welfare services as well as leisure are, of course, subject
to uncertainty. However, the effects of an increase in leisure can
easily be as large as the effects of the demographic shifts. Box 5.1
lays out in more detail why growth does not solve the financial
problems faced by the welfare state, and why it may even worsen
them.
Welfare services: rising costs and increasing demand
·
87
5.4 AN EASY FIX – BRING SERVICES BACK TO
THE FAMILY?
It is occasionally suggested that there is a straightforward solution
to the challenge of providing and financing the services: bring them
back to the family, i.e. let the children take care of their parents,
and let the parents stay home to look after the kids. The reasoning seems to be that shifting the provision away from the public
sector would eliminate the problem. This reasoning is erroneous
in overlooking two important considerations.
First, it is the nature of the services that is the basic source of
the problem, not the provider. Home production of services will
also face the problem that they become relatively more expensive
(the alternative is to work in the market, where the real wage is
increasing), and that the demand for services is increasing alongside developments in society. To counteract this, home production
would have to increase. But this would make both the labour supply
and the tax base shrink and it would thereby add to the financial
problem that the measure was intended to solve.
Second, for many services there are substantial economies of
scale. As an example, consider day-care. Compare the case where
four families each have one person staying at home to look after
one child, to the case where one parent stays home to look after
four children. In the latter case it is possible for three persons to
be at work in the market economy, adding to production and thus
material well-being. Exploiting this type of economies of scale is
precisely what kindergartens and old-age care institutions are doing. With the public sector offering good opportunities for care of
children and old people, it is possible to boost the labour supply, in
particular of women. This is an important reason why the Nordic
countries – despite their high tax rates – have achieved a high
labour force participation rate (in particular of women). Hence,
shifting care to private homes can have drastic implications for
public finances – and not only because home work is not taxed
while market work is.
This is not to deny that there is an important choice to be
made with regard to what should be provided by the welfare state
88
·
The Nordic Model
Shifting the burden
back to the family is
not a realistic proposal
Does the welfare state
undermine individual
and family responsibility?
and what should be left to individual responsibilities. Public arrangements may have the consequence that individuals provide
too little effort on their own part and have excessive expectations
concerning what society can or should do to solve their problems.
There is also a need to consider other aspects related to gender
equality, family values and the socialization process when pondering whether certain activities should be within the family, the
market or the public sector. The point here is only that the basic
financial problem related to public service provision is not solved
by shifting it back to the private sphere.
5.5 COMBINING THE SERVICE AND
DEMOGRAPHIC CHALLENGES
The two challenges that we have considered – demographics and
services – have different sources, but the problems are magnified
by the fact that they both appear simultaneously. To assess the
orders of magnitude of the overall challenge, let us return to the
projection of public finances set out in chapter 4 above (in figure
4.7, reproduced in figure 5.2). The baseline in figure 5.2 basically
shows the effects of changing demographics on public finances
(revenue less expenditures). Let us modify the baseline by two
additional scenarios:
(A) First, assume an increase in the overall growth in productivity by 0.5 percentage points per annum starting
in 2005 and continuing up until 2050. As in box 5.1, it
is assumed that the increase in productivity growth concerns only the private sector but not the provision of
welfare services (the “Baumol” hypothesis).
(B) Assume, in addition to the better productivity development, that the volume growth of welfare services is
0.25 percentage points higher. This reflects our version
of the “Wagner law”, according to which increasing
income raises demand also for welfare services.
The results of these two scenarios are set out in figure 5.2.
Scenario A is seen to make the budget deterioration less fast and
Welfare services: rising costs and increasing demand
·
89
Box 5.1
Growth and the welfare state
It is argued in chapter 4 that growth is not a solution to the demographic challenge and in this chapter that growth may actually worsen the financial problems. These points are crucial and they are often neglected or not understood in
policy debates. This box brings out the basic arguments underlying these statements.
Before explaining the effect of general growth (productivity increases) on public
finances it should be noted what we are not saying. We are not contesting the importance of achieving strong economic growth, which is indeed the key to higher
living standards in the future. Also, we are not discussing how the growth rate of
the economy could be raised – which is clearly a complicated issue (discussed in
chapter 3). Instead, we are just saying that economic growth, however desirable
it may be for other reasons, is unlikely to resolve the financial dilemma of the welfare state that we see looming in coming decades.
Consider a situation where growth is driven by a higher rate of growth of productivity in the production of goods, while productivity is unchanged in the provi-
Figure 5.1
The welfare state and the growth dilemma
Budgetary effects of an increase in the growth of private sector productivity
Rise in tax
revenues
A
B
Increase in
public wage bill
C
Increase in
public transfers
Increase in D
provision of
welfare services
Bigger tax
base
Rise in all
wages
Distributional
constraint
Higher incomes and
higher demands
0
Budget deterioration
90
·
The Nordic Model
Budget improvement
sion of welfare services. This is an assumption about technology (our version of
the “Baumol hypothesis”), that we discussed above. The effects of more growth
on the state of public finances can now be explained in simple terms with the
help of figure 5.1.
First, higher growth means more output and incomes and thereby it leads to a
bigger tax base and higher tax revenues (box A in figure 5.1). This is the effect that
people have in mind when they claim that we should solve the public finance
problem through more rapid economic growth.
Second, higher private sector productivity will raise real wages not only in the
private sector but in the whole economy, including in the public sector (as a consequence of market forces and/or wage coordination by unions). The rise in the
public sector wage bill increases public expenditure and absorbs part of the increase in tax revenues (box B in figure 5.1).
Third, public pensions and other transfers will fall relative to wages unless they
are protected through indexation (to wages) or increased by discretionary decisions. Political pressure will normally prevent transfers from falling permanently
behind general income developments. Assuming this distributional constraint to
hold, public spending on transfers will absorb the rest of the increased tax revenues (box C in figure 5.1). Invoking the “Baumol hypothesis” (or the “Baumol disease”) and the distributional constraint prevents more growth from improving
public finances.
Fourth, higher incomes are likely to increase the demand for services, including
the demand for publicly provided welfare services. The income elasticity of demand is normally positive and for some of these services, such as health services, it is likely to be quite high. Growing incomes will therefore be associated
with growing demand for welfare services and pressure on the government to increase their supply as well as to improve their quality. Again, more public spending is called for (box D in figure 5.1), though by now there remain no additional
tax resources to draw upon. The likely overall result is therefore that more growth
in itself leads to a deterioration rather than an improvement in public finances. It
may help public finances only if public sector wages and/or transfers are allowed
to fall behind general income developments.
A fifth consideration (not shown in the figure) is that higher incomes may increase the demand for leisure and reduce the amount of work supplied at a given
(net) wage rate. The supply of labour will diminish since the income elasticity of
demand for leisure is positive (and presumably sizeable), and the subsequent decline in employment will reduce the tax base.
To repeat, the preceding is not an argument against growth in itself. Growth is
indeed important for material well-being, and it is important that productivity should continue to increase if Finland is to remain a high income country.
The message of the box is rather that growth is not a solution to the financial
problems that the welfare state is facing. Or to put it differently, policies boosting growth will not have a double dividend by both improving material well-being and ensuring sound public finances. More difficult policy choices have to be
made to ensure the financial viability of the welfare state.
Welfare services: rising costs and increasing demand
·
91
it implies that the long-run deficit of the primary balance is “only”
about 3.5 per cent of GDP compared to 4.3 per cent in the base
scenario. This result may seem to contradict our statement above
that productivity growth is not a solution to the financial problems arising from ageing. However, the reduction in the deficit
in scenario A arises as a consequence of the index clause in the
Finnish system for earnings pensions, according to which pensions
are adjusted by 80 per cent of the rise in consumer prices and 20
per cent of the rise in wages. Thus, an increase in productivity,
which in the model is reflected in a corresponding increase in real
wage growth, leads over time to a decline in pensions relative to
wages.3 Real wages in this scenario therefore increase more than
the real value of pensions, and the income distribution will change
in favour of those in work. Hence, this scenario actually underlines
the conclusion made above, which is that increased productivity
growth is a solution to the financial problem of the welfare state
only if all people are not allowed to benefit from the increase in the
pie. This is a possible route for reducing the public deficit, though
Primary balance as a per cent of GDP
%
%
0
0
A
Baseline
B
-1
-2
-2
-3
-3
-4
-4
-5
-5
-6
2010
-6
15
20
25
30
35
Figure 5.2
Growth and public finances in Finland, 2010–2050
A = 0.5 % more productivity growth.
B = A + 0.25 % more welfare service growth.
Source: Ministry of Finance.
92
-1
·
The Nordic Model
40
45
50
More rapid growth increases the tax base
but also the public
wage bill and transfers
as well as demand for
welfare services and
leisure – growth will
not solve the problem
of public finances
it is debatable whether such a development could continue for long
without creating strong political pressure to restore a more “just”
or “reasonable” parity between pensions and wages.
Scenario B shows that the joint effect of 0.25 per cent more
volume growth in the provision of welfare services and 0.5 per
cent more rapid growth of productivity amounts to a worsening
of the primary balance, by an amount which is close to one per
cent of GDP in the long run. Thus, a rather small increase in the
growth rate for public services will have strong implications for
public finances and add considerably to the financial sustainability
problem. An increase in the volume growth of services of 0.5 per
cent is rather moderate from a historical perspective; this scenario
is by no means extreme but rather cautious in its assumption on the
underlying expenditure pressure (cf. endnote 1 in chapter 4).
In summary, provision of services poses a challenge to the
welfare state due to the combined effects of the rising costs of
producing welfare services and the increasing demand for them.
As noted above, the underlying forces do not depend on the way
in which services are provided (though their manifestation will be
different in the case of private as compare to public provision). The
reason they become a particular challenge for the Nordic welfare
state is that a large fraction of services are provided via the public
sector and are tax-financed. Not only will the Baumol and Wagner
effects as well as advances in medical services increase expenditure
pressure, but improvements in material well-being will tend to
undermine the financial basis for these services by reducing labour
supply (as a consequence of increasing demand for leisure).
5.6 WHY NOT INCREASE TAXES?
Are tax increases the solution to these financial problems? Raising taxes may seem like a straightforward solution to a problem
caused by an expenditure drift, itself driven by demographic shifts
and increased costs of and higher demand for services. However,
increasing taxes to solve the problem may, for several reasons, be
a more problematic route than many people think.
Welfare services: rising costs and increasing demand
·
93
The level of taxation is already high at the outset. Taxation
is not only a question of whether the money should go to private
or public pockets. Taxes affect incentives: economic agents must
in most situations be expected to react to the reward for work
that they receive after taxes and the prices they pay, including
the tax components of these prices. This is the reason why some
taxes – say environmental taxes – can be used to steer decisions
in a direction which is considered favourable to the society. But
it is also the reason why many economic decisions are likely to be
adversely affected or distorted by taxes. In particular, the direct and
indirect taxes levied on labour income will reduce labour supply;
individual workers are induced to choose more leisure relative to
consumption (and work), though it might well in the interest of
society at large that people should work more.
The most relevant metric for understanding how taxes affect
the labour market is the so-called tax wedge. The tax wedge is the
difference that taxes make between what labour costs to employers, and what employees get in return for their work. To see this,
consider a setting where an employer and employee have agreed
on a given wage. The total cost to the employer is the wage plus
eventual social security contributions (paid by the employer). The
reward to the employee is the wage less eventual social security
contributions (paid by the employee), direct taxes and indirect
taxes. Both direct and indirect taxes have to be taken into account
since they determine how much consumption the employee can
get for the work effort – and consumption in its many forms (today
or in the future) is the main motive to work. Hence, the total tax
wedge is made up of social security contributions, direct income
taxes and indirect income taxes. Figure 5.3 shows the tax wedge for
different countries computed for a worker with average income.
For Finland the tax wedge is nearly 60 per cent (57.5 per cent),
which is at the higher end in the OECD. To see why the tax wedge
is a barrier to employment, consider a worker willing to work for a
reward in terms of consumption equal to 100 units. The value of
the production to an employer has to be at least 160 units, because
it must cover both the compensation to the worker and the tax
wedge. Consider an activity that yields an output of only 140 units,
which is well above the compensation demanded by the worker.
94
·
The Nordic Model
Raising taxes is not
the straightforward
solution – because tax
rates are already high
and their economic
costs considerable
Large tax wedges reduce the scope and
incentives for work
and other economic
activities
USA
Ireland
United Kingdom
Portugal
Greece
Spain
Luxembourg
Italy
Norway
Netherlands
Austria
Finland
France
Sweden
Denmark
Germany
Belgium
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70 %
Figure 5.3
Total tax wedge on labour in selected countries, 2003
Source: Ministry of Taxation, Denmark (2004) .
In general, it would be worthwhile to undertake the activity, and
without taxes this would take place; the employer would earn a
profit of 40 and the worker would get a compensation of 100 (or
they could share the surplus of 40 in some other way). But with a
tax wedge of 60 per cent, the activity is either unprofitable for the
employer or insufficiently rewarding for the employee (or both).
The tax wedge prevents some activities from being undertaken
(that would be worthwhile in the absence of taxation). The larger
the tax wedge, the larger this effect is – increasing the tax wedge to,
say, 65 per cent would imply that all activities yielding an output
between 160 and 165 are no longer worthwhile.
Actually, an increase in the tax wedge from 60 to 65 per cent
harms economic activity more than an increase from 40 to 45
per cent.4 The important message here is that taxation of income
does not leave economic activity and total income unchanged
– the greater the tax, the smaller the total income generated in
the economy. Moreover, this effect is stronger the higher the level
of taxation at the outset. This implies a difficult policy dilemma:
incomes are taxed to finance the welfare state, but higher taxes
make the cake shrink.
Welfare services: rising costs and increasing demand
·
95
One may ask why this problem arises. If we all understand that
taxes are needed to finance the welfare state we support, why is
there a problem? The reason is that individual tax payments have
no direct effect on the services the tax payer can access. This is
precisely one of the defining characteristics of the Nordic model,
namely that entitlements are unrelated to tax payment. Another
way of expressing this is that the effect of one individual contributing a little more or less in taxes is negligible as it is shared with 5
million other inhabitants. However, when the whole population
contributes less it adds up and has significant implications for
total finances.
The effect of taxes on distortions therefore implies that it is
not costless to levy taxes. The cost of raising one euro of public
revenue is effectively larger than one euro. This is so since the cost
includes both the direct effect of the euro going to the public sector,
and the cost in terms of the economic activity squeezed out due to
the tax. If a tax of one euro reduces incomes by, say, 20 cent, then
the true cost of raising one euro to the public sector is euro 1.20;
namely, the one euro paid directly and the indirect income loss
of 20 cent. Available estimates are highly uncertain but suggest
that the (marginal) cost of public funds for Finland and the other
Nordic countries may indeed be much higher than the direct costs
because of the increase in efficiency losses.5
A problematic aspect of taxation is that it makes the price
of leisure lower to individuals than it is to society. An individual
considering the option of enjoying more leisure (shorter working
hours, more vacation, earlier retirement) will lose the net income
after all taxes, or the consumption that the net wage would buy.
To society the cost of leisure is the total income lost, including
the tax revenue of the public sector. Hence, the tax wedge causes
a difference between the cost of leisure to the individual and to
society; leisure is less costly to the individual deciding on his or
her leisure than it is to the society at large.
The above may seem to leave a puzzle for understanding the
Nordic countries: if taxes are potentially so harmful, how come
overall labour force participation is high, and how can these
countries be among the richest countries in the world? There are
many explanations for this (and yet the issue may not be fully
understood).
96
·
The Nordic Model
There is a “common
pool” problem in that
the individual does
not factor in the consequences of his/her
decision for the society at large
The costs to the economy of collecting 1
euro in taxes is significantly larger than
1 euro
Taxes on labour makes
leisure unduly attractive relative to work
How can the Nordic
economies do reasonably well at these tax
rates?
A rise in tax rates will
increase the efficiency
loss – more than proportionally
International tax competition will magnify
the distortionary effects of high tax rates
One important reason is that tax distortions cannot be assessed independently of how the public money is spent. The money
may contribute to expand incomes if it is spent on, say, education
or day-care facilities, whereas this effect is smaller or absent if the
money is spent on, say, cultural activities (even though there can
be other good reasons to spend money on culture). Another issue
is the role of institutions. Labour markets are or have been highly
centralized and therefore key decisions on wages and working hours
have not been taken by individuals but rather by central actors,
who may well have taken into account that the price of leisure
is higher to society than it is to the individual. (We will return to
this issue in the next chapter.) Moreover, many policies have been
designed so as to support the “work line”; various elements of the
social safety net are conditional on the individual actively looking
for a job, and workfare policies have the same aim.
As noted above, the costs or efficiency losses of taxes are
an increasing function of their level. This has one very important implication. Even though it has been possible in the past to
counteract some of the distortionary effects of taxation, it will be
increasingly difficult to do so if the tax rates are raised. Hence, one
cannot assess the effects of increasing taxes by simple looking at
how taxes in the past have affected economic activity. Moreover,
labour markets are also becoming more decentralized, and hence
one of the important counteracting forces to the distortionary
effects of taxes is becoming weaker.
Last but not least, globalization may also affect both the scope
for taxation and the distortions. Tax-base mobility is increasing and
may erode certain tax bases. (A partial response to this is to shift
taxes to other less mobile tax bases, like real estate.) Second, even
if people are not becoming more mobile, it is a fact that production
and thus employment may more easily relocate than before. This
implies that the negative consequences for economic activity of a
high tax burden on labour are going to increase.
Needless to say, it is difficult to assess with any precision the
consequences of higher taxes. However, the distortionary effects
of taxes are almost certainly larger, the higher the tax rate. It is
becoming increasingly difficult to counteract these distortions
via labour market policies and centralized wage bargaining. And
Welfare services: rising costs and increasing demand
·
97
globalization may contribute to both a direct revenue drag and an
increase in tax distortions. Hence, relying on tax increases to solve
financial problems in a situation where taxes are already high seems
to be a very risky and potentially quite costly strategy.
The financial problems discussed here are those of a “mature”
welfare state. In earlier decades the welfare state was expanded
against a background of a demographic tail-wind (declining dependency ratio), initially low tax rates and a large potential for
expanding the labour supply by bringing women into the labour
market. The expansion of the welfare state has been made possible
by expanding the tax base and increasing the tax burden. Figure 5.4
shows that the tax burden in Finland is today roughly the double
of what it was 50 years ago. The tax base has been enlarged by
increasing the labour force participation rate of women to a level
very close to that of men, cf. figure 5.5. Since the late 1980s, the
participation rates for the two sexes have moved closely in tandem.
While one can discuss the options of reallocating the tax burden, it
is difficult to avoid the assessment that the route of higher overall
tax burdens no longer offers a realistic way of solving the future
%
%
40
40
30
30
20
20
10
10
0
1955
0
60
65
70
75
80
85
90
95
2000
05
Figure 5.4
Tax burden, per cent of GDP, Finland 1955–2005
Data exists only for 1955, 1960 and 1965, and values for years in between are found by extrapolation.
Source: OECD.
98
·
The Nordic Model
The Nordic welfare
state was created in
very different circumstances, in which the
demographics were
favourable
%
%
Men
Women
85
85
80
80
75
75
70
70
65
65
60
60
55
1960
55
65
70
75
80
85
90
95
2000
Figure 5.5
Labour force participation rates, Finland 1963–2004
Source: OECD.
financing problems. The policy choices are thus more difficult – as
demographics have turned into a head-wind with an increasing
dependency ratio and already high tax rates.
5.7 THE DIFFICULT ROAD: WHAT ARE THE
REMEDIES TO THE SERVICE CHALLENGE?
Politicians find it hard
to square the circle:
keeping welfare
spending in check
while meeting the
aspirations of voters
The level and extent of public services are politically decided. It
may therefore seem that the answer is political control; that is,
politicians have to be tough and avoid accommodating demands
to expand the level and quality of public services. It is an open
question whether this is a tenable solution, even disregarding the
question of whether such policy makers would ever be elected.
Strict control will imply an increasing gap between the level and
quality of services desired and those provided, and the public sector
will soon be considered “old” and of “deficient standards”. This
will violate the ambition of the welfare state to provide services
meeting the requirements of most, and it is likely to induce those
Welfare services: rising costs and increasing demand
·
99
able to pay to seek private solutions and many citizens to ask what
they get in return for the taxes they pay. This may undermine the
support for the welfare state.
One reason why the service dilemma arises is that the kind
of services to be provided as well as their volume and quality are a
matter of political decision making. There is no “natural” constraint
on the desires and demands that citizens will formulate concerning
their need for services – as these are offered free of charge (or at
heavily subsidized prices) to the users. Introducing user payments
is one means of providing policy makers with a tool to control and
curtail demand. User payments are not a new thing in Finland;
they already exist for child care and parts of old-age and health
care. (However, user fees financed only 7.5 per cent of the social
expenditure of local authorities in 2006 and this share has been on
a declining trend.) There is scope for considering the possibilities of
using this instrument more effectively or consistently. Nevertheless,
user payments cannot be a major mode of financing if the ability to
pay is not to become a main criterion determining eligibility.
There is the key issue of deciding which activities are to be
included in the “public welfare package”, and which are to be left
to individuals to cater for by themselves. One way of addressing
the service challenge is to focus public provision on some core
activities and ensure that they meet high requirements, and then
leave other activities out of the package. That would mean that
the public sector does less but ensures that the quality and availability of the core services meet the requirements of most people,
leaving other matters for private solutions. This route will require
strong political leadership.
Finally, the difficulties of increasing productivity for certain
human-intensive types of services do not apply to all services. There
are important cases of a lack of efficiency due to the way service
provision is organized. There is significant scope for enhancing
efficiency by improving incentives and organizational solutions.
We will come back to this in chapter 8.
100
·
The Nordic Model
User fees for public
services may have to
play a bigger role
The key issue is to define the core activities
of the welfare state
Raising productivity in
the provision of public
services is essential
ENDNOTES
1
As an example, public expenditure on health and old-age care in Finland increased annually
in the period 1993–2004 by 1.9 per cent on average. It has been estimated that 0.8 per cent was
due to changes in the structure of the population (age and sex), while 1.1 per cent reflected enhanced quality. For the period 2000–2004 the corresponding figures were 3.5 per cent and 0.8 per
cent, implying that the main part was not due to the change in the structure of the population
but due to other factors. On this see Hujanen et al. (2006).
2
In its “cost-pressure” scenario the OECD assumes that expenditure, for a given demography,
increases by 1 per cent more than income (which corresponds to the trend in the past two decades). In its “cost-containment” scenario it is assumed that policy can gradually eliminate this “extra” growth.
3
Increased growth could improve the public balance much more if it were assumed that
other public transfers are given in nominal terms or are permanently indexed to consumer prices
only (as is formally the case for, say, the flat rate basic pensions). However, historical experience
suggests that transfers are increased by discretionary political decisions in a way which roughly
corresponds to the outcome which would emerge with formal indexation to the development of
wages. As suggested above, this may in the end hold also for the earnings pension system, but
in the simulation it was assumed that the agreed (20/80) pension indexation formula is used permanently. Another element contributing to the reduced deficit is the fact that accrued pension
rights in Finland are indexed with an (80/20) formula: 80 per cent based on wage developments,
20 per cent based on consumer prices. The simulations were done with the general equilibrium
model (“FOG”) maintained at ETLA.
4
It is a familiar result of the theory of taxation that the efficiency costs caused by taxes are a
non-linear (approximately quadratic) function of the tax wedge.
5
See, for instance, Kleven and Kreiner (2006).
Welfare services: rising costs and increasing demand
·
101
102
·
The Nordic Model
6
Nordic labour markets
pool risks and embrace free trade
Policies support a
high participation rate
of women
THE LABOUR MARKET:
ENOUGH WORKERS WORKING
ENOUGH?
We argue that risk sharing and openness to globalization are two
mutually reinforcing key strengths of the Nordic economies. Many
attributes of the Nordic labour market can also be understood
as forming part of a strategy of pooling risks while exploiting the
opportunities of the global economy. For example, general industry-wide pay increases were a reasonably effective instrument for
creating real wage flexibility in an era of “Taylorist” organization of
industries, while at the same time promoting productivity growth
via high investments and a process of Schumpeterian creative
destruction. It is noteworthy that the main labour market organizations in the Nordic countries have embraced not only high
employment but also technical progress and free trade. While
powerful labour organizations have at times employed an antimarket rhetoric, they have not seriously jeopardized the objective
of exploiting the global division of labour.1 Protectionism has been
rejected by both labour market parties.
Nordic societies have been influenced by a strong “Weberian” work ethic. Their efforts in favour of gender equality have
encouraged female labour supply with the help of, e.g., child care
facilities and relatively generous child-related benefits. This has
made it possible to combine work careers and childbearing also
for women, which in turn has boosted labour supply and thereby
employment and production. Furthermore, it is thanks to the fam-
The labour market: enough workers working enough?
·
103
ily policies that Nordic demographic projections look better than
those of Southern European countries (in which childrearing at
home has been more prevalent).
We thus see a lot of strengths in the Nordic labour market.
However, many of the labour market institutions and policies that
we currently observe were designed in the 1950s and 1960s, in an
era when the welfare state, the productive technologies as well
as the rules of the global economy were very different from what
they are today. We believe that some of these institutions and policies, perhaps notably in Finland, are not in conformity anymore
with what is required to achieve the basic “Nordic” objectives.
Therefore, and in tune with our overall argument, our thesis is
that the Nordic labour market model can remain successful only
if it is thoroughly reformed.
A well functioning labour market is, needless to say, an indispensable precondition for favourable economic developments.
Given the demographic transformation discussed in chapters 4
and 5 above, the labour force and employment constitute the key
resource constraints of the economy. It is essential for the viability
of the Nordic model that the amount of productive employment
in the economy be high enough to meet the manpower demand
of a large public service sector as well as to generate the tax base
and revenues needed to pay for its expenditures, including the
welfare services and pensions.
High employment requires well designed stabilization policies
as well as structures and institutions that are conducive to low
unemployment. The Nordic countries have traditionally been
associated with ambitious employment policies, but their performance since the 1990s has been more ambivalent. For example,
the labour markets in Sweden and Finland were subject to severe
macroeconomic shocks in the 1970s and notably in the 1990s,
and unemployment rates have not returned to the low levels of
the 1950s and 1960s. The very low unemployment rates in those
decades are probably partly to be seen as a consequence of the
continuous expansion of the public sector.
A high level of employment and labour input requires:
1 a high aggregate supply of labour or a high rate of labour
force participation;
104
·
The Nordic Model
Historical strengths
are not enough –
there is need for
reform
High employment
rates are a sine quo
non of the Nordic
model
2 a sufficient amount of average hours worked per employed
person; and
3 a low rate of (structural) unemployment.
We will deal with these issues separately in subsequent sections.
Box 6.1
What are Nordic labour markets made of?
Rate of unionization. The rate of union membership, though it has recently declined somewhat, is higher in the Nordic countries than elsewhere. Negotiations
between organizations have a significant influence on wage formation and working conditions.
Uniform pay increases within industries. Nordic pay bargaining was for a long time
after WWII characterized by collectively agreed uniform pay increases – all members of a union would receive the same wage increase in relative (per cent) or absolute (units of money) terms.
Inter-industry coordination. The economy-wide rate of pay increase has often been
determined in bargaining or consultations between central trade union federations and employer organizations. This has made it easier for unions to take into
account the negative consequences of high wage claims for the economy as a
whole (to “internalize” the “externalities”). It may also have made it more difficult
to introduce flexible pay at the workplace, since national bargaining tends to focus on the size of wage increase as such and to neglect more sophisticated contract designs.
Mutual consultation and interplay with macroeconomic policy. The economy-wide
coordination of pay bargaining has been facilitated by the government. Political decisionmakers have encouraged pay moderation by making tax adjustments
conditional on the pace of contractual wage increases, particularly in Finland. In
Sweden, however, government involvement in the wage bargaining has normally been rejected. In the period of high inflation – up until the 1980s – the consequences of comprehensive pay settlements, when undermining competitiveness, were often mitigated through soft exchange rate policies (devaluations).
This way of supporting high employment was obviously unsustainable in the
long run.
“Solidaristic” pay bargaining. The uniform wage increases in Sweden were originally motivated by the need to control inflation and limit local wage drift while
enhancing productivity. The concern of the so called “Rehn–Meidner” model,
launched in the 1950s, was to contain the excessive wage claims of workers in
firms with above average profitability. A uniform pay increase was advocated as
a solution, also on the grounds that it would promote productivity growth by
enhancing the investment possibilities of firms with above average profitability
(this was a time of credit rationing). A stronger form of solidarism was attempted in Sweden in the 1970s, when low wages were systematically raised more in
The labour market: enough workers working enough?
·
105
absolute and relative terms than high wages. This redistributive solidarism was
subsequently abandoned, as it led to a revolt of businesses and professional employees and, finally, to the collapse of national coordination of wage bargaining
in the 1980s.
Generous unemployment insurance schemes. In Sweden, Finland and Denmark,
unions have assumed responsibility for operating unemployment insurance
schemes, aided by tax-financed subsidies. This “Ghent system” has strengthened
the unions, since access to unemployment insurance has been linked to union
membership. In Norway, the Ghent system was never introduced and unemployment insurance has been undertaken by the state, which explains the lower Norwegian unionization rate. In Finland, after the introduction of unemployment
insurance funds decoupled from the unions, the rate of unionization promptly
shrank from about 85 per cent to about 70 per cent2. The average net unemployment benefit replacement rate in the Nordic countries is about 10 percentage
points higher than in the euro area countries and about 20 percentage points
higher than in the Anglo-Saxon countries (cf. table 2.1 in chapter 2).
Employment protection legislation. The Nordic countries differ with regard to the
strictness of their employment protection legislation. On average, employment
protection is less strict in the Nordic countries than on the Continent or in Southern Europe (cf. figure 2.1 in chapter 2). Sweden has probably the most restrictive
labour laws, but that has not hindered Sweden from achieving an employment
rate of about 80 per cent in 2007. Employment protection measures that make
it harder for firms to dismiss employees have during the last two decades been
relaxed in Finland.
Active labour market policy. The Nordic countries spend more than others on active labour market policies in the form of job intermediation as well as training
and subsidized employment. One element of the Rehn–Meidner model of uniform wage increases was the idea of helping dislocated people to find new jobs
and move to new regions and occupations, and Sweden has been the country
with the largest expenditures on active labour markets policy measures. Active
labour market policies in the form of workfare, i.e. a more stringent conditioning
of benefits on job search or training, have gained popularity in recent years.
6.1 MAKE MORE PEOPLE WORK –
THE EXTENSIVE MARGIN COUNTS!
Labour supply involves two important dimensions: the labour market participation rate of the different age groups and the average
working hours of those who are employed. The former is referred
to as the extensive margin (“what determines the choice of participating or not participating in the labour force?”) and the latter as
the intensive margin (“how many hours does an employed person
106
·
The Nordic Model
The most important
policy question is
“how many are working?” rather than “how
many hours does an
employed person on
average work?”
Prime age males do
not work much more
at lower marginal tax
rates – but the labour
supply of the young,
the old and those with
low incomes may be
significantly affected
by the average tax
rate
work?”). Both margins are important, but there is an emerging
consensus among researchers that the “extensive” margin is more
important for policy purposes.
In other words, the effect of tax and social security parameters
on the decision “shall I participate in the labour market?” is more
important than the effects on the decision “how many hours shall
I work, provided I have a job?”. The extensive margin is closely
related to the age profile of individuals as well as their net contribution to the public sector. In terms of our figure 1.1 in chapter
1, the key policy issues become: how to encourage the inflow of
young people into the labour force and how to contain the outflow
of elderly people into retirement?
The importance of the extensive margin has only recently
been appreciated in the scholarly literature and policy debate3.
Traditional labour supply analysis has been mainly concerned with
the labour supply elasticity of those working, and found it to be
low.4 The new strand of analysis, focussing on the extensive margin,
is associated with significantly higher estimates of labour supply
elasticities. This also leads to a different assessment of the role
of taxes in inhibiting the supply of market work. The traditional
textbook analysis of the choice of leisure versus work assumes that
only the marginal tax rate (not the average tax rate) affects working
hours. The new theoretical paradigm5, by contrast, emphasizes the
connection between average taxes and labour supply (taking also
into account the possible withdrawal of social benefits). It turns out
that the importance of the extensive margin gives rise to a much
more significant distortion in the choice between leisure and work
than most economists have hitherto assumed. These conclusions
are reinforced by recent empirical research emphasizing the large
participation response of certain subgroups of the population. In
particular, the labour supply decisions of people at the lower end
of the earnings distribution and of the young and the old (as well
as of intersections of these groups, the low-skilled old and lowskilled young) may be influenced quite a lot by the design of tax,
social protection and pensions systems6.
Comparative data on participation rates suggest that a large
part of the US-Europe gap in life cycle working hours is accounted
for by different choices along the extensive margin, i.e. differences
The labour market: enough workers working enough?
·
107
in the participation decision of the young and the old as well as
of women.7 Similarly, Kleven and Kreiner (2006) emphasize the
extensive margin in their analysis of the efficiency losses associated with high tax rates. They find the negative effects on labour
market participation (in the sense of “unemployment traps”) to
be significant for the Nordic countries. The effects are large notably at the bottom of the productivity distribution, as a result of
generous out-of-work benefits in combination with high tax rates
on earned income.
On the other hand, labour force participation is high in the
Nordic countries in spite of their large tax wedges. This suggests
that other factors, such as labour market policies or high female
employment rates, may counter the effects of high tax rates. To
draw the conclusion that a large welfare state is incompatible with
proper incentives for work may thus be premature. In our view, an
equally plausible policy conclusion is that other means and policy
instruments have to be used to compensate for the distortions
caused by taxes. For example, a stronger “workfare” conditionality
of social security benefits could be introduced. The entitlement
to unemployment benefits can be made conditional on having
worked full time and for a sufficient number of months or years.
Also, the authorities might cancel benefits if the unemployed individual is not willing to consider job offers in other occupations
or geographical areas.
Choices along these lines may seem politically unattractive in
the Nordic political culture. However, we believe this is the direction that policy makers ultimately have to choose if the Nordic
combination of high taxes and high employment is to be sustained.
Indeed, such conditionality is not new in itself: there are already
links between work and benefits and these probably partly explain
the high supply of labour in the Nordic countries. However, we
believe it is essential that policy makers should focus even more
sharply on reducing the “thresholds” for work by those with a fragile
attachment to the labour market. Particular attention should be
directed to the participation decisions of the young, the elderly and
those with low incomes. In Sweden, the government has recently
introduced an earned income tax credit that reduced the marginal
tax rates for workers with very low incomes significantly, while the
108
·
The Nordic Model
Public spending on
family policies and
“workfare” conditionality of social benefits
support high employment
High taxes conflict
with high employment – notably if policies cannot lower the
threshold to work for
groups with otherwise
weak labour market
attachment
replacement rates of unemployment benefits were cut at the same
time. Together, those reforms are expected to increase potential
employment by about 1–1.5 percentage points8.
The effects of public policies – such as the tax and transfer
system, the education system and the pension system – on the
labour force participation decision of individuals is necessarily
very complex. For example, the retirement policies of firms adjust
in the course of time to the pension system. The important point,
though, is that economic actors respond to incentives and labour
market participation rates are influenced by tax and transfer
schemes. Needless to say, incentives affect both employers and
employees.9 In all, we believe that increasing the labour market
participation rates, in particular for the young and the elderly, is
of primordial importance.
The achievements in Finland leave much to be desired in this
respect. In particular, the activity rates and employment rates of
older individuals (in age brackets 55 to 64 years) are lower than
those of Sweden and Denmark (see tables 6.1 and 6.2 and also figure 4.3 in chapter 4). For the young (15 to 24 years), both Sweden
and Finland perform poorly in comparison with Denmark. This
poor record of activating and employing the young and the old
is clearly one main reason for Finland’s relatively lacklustre (by
Nordic standards) aggregate employment rate.
Table 6.1
The employment rate, aggregate and by age groups, 2006
Employment rate (15 to 64 years)
Employment rate (15 to 24 years)
Employment rate (25 to 54 years)
Employment rate (55 to 64 years)
Denmark
Finland
Sweden
77.4
64.6
86.1
60.7
69.3
42.1
82.4
54.5
73.1
40.3
84.7
69.6
Employment rate = employed persons as a percentage of same age total population.
Source: Eurostat.
The labour market: enough workers working enough?
·
109
Table 6.2
The activity rate, aggregate and by age groups, 2006
Activity rate (15 to 64 years)
Activity rate (15 to 24 years)
Activity rate (25 to 54 years)
Activity rate (55 to 64 years)
Denmark
Finland
Sweden
80.6
69.9
88.9
63.2
75.2
51.8
87.8
58.5
78.8
51.3
89.4
72.8
The activity rate = persons in the labour force as a percentage of same age total population.
Source: Eurostat.
6.2 WORK MORE HOURS, NOT LESS!
We have emphasized the key role of the “extensive margin”, i.e. of
the decision of the individual to participate or not in the labour
market. Needless to say, this does not mean that the intensive
margin is irrelevant; it is also important that proper incentives be
in place for people to work many hours. Policy makers are in this
respect confronted with a challenge, since the historical evolution of working hours has displayed (until very recently) a clear
downward trend.10 Conventional economics suggests that this is
not surprising, since it is only to be expected that the demand for
leisure increases along with rising income levels. After all, many
consumer goods deliver their utility only if the consumer has at
his/her disposal a sufficient amount of leisure.
It is not our purpose to preach some stringent moral responsibility of every individual to work hard. However, we believe that
the basic challenge of sustaining work incentives has not really been
understood by the Nordic electorates (or politicians). There is no
problem with individuals deciding freely on how much to work
and how many hours of leisure to enjoy – if the price of leisure for
the individual, in the form of foregone earnings, reflects the “full”
cost of leisure. Yet, as we have argued, the very fabric of Nordic
welfare societies is likely to distort this choice in favour of leisure.
It thereby creates a potential inconsistency and a problem of (lack
110
·
The Nordic Model
The preference for
leisure increases
along with rising income levels – which
tends to reduce hours
worked
High taxes and many
public policies tilt the
decisions of individuals and unions away
from hours worked
and in favour of more
leisure – without due
regard to the economy-wide consequences
Policy makers should
encourage more work
rather than more
leisure
There is a case for
centralization or coordination of labour
market decisions on
overall working hours
of) sustainability, in particular when the demographic structure
becomes less advantageous.
Many institutions and policies in the Nordic countries distort the work-leisure choice of their citizens. There is a relatively
good level of social security, protection of the environment, and
a well-developed urban infrastructure. Also, there are generous
government subsidies for, inter alia, public transport, housing, arts
and culture. These public goods or heavily subsidized services are
combined with high taxes on income from work, which tilts the
choice of individuals in favour of (untaxed) leisure. The large scope
of collective action and public goods means that life in the Nordic
societies can be relatively “pleasant” even when the individual’s
market income is low. This is not just a by-product of the Nordic
policy package but reflects the very aim of social and other policies: extensive provision of public goods and social security are
the means of insuring citizens against risks and avoiding extreme
poverty.
In short, individuals are induced to work less than is desirable
from a wider (societal) perspective. As taxes and some of the other
causes of the distortions cannot be done away with, policy makers
should use other instruments to compensate for these distortions
(or to “distort” the labour supply choices of individuals in the opposite direction). Also, it should hardly be part of Nordic policy
to subsidize programmes encouraging leisure-intensive careers for
individuals that have already enjoyed a publicly subsidized education. Thus, policy makers should abolish unnecessary disincentives
to work, such as “free years” or other schemes that discourage
working.11
Another aspect of this externality has to do with collective
agreements on shorter working hours. It is sometimes quite attractive for unions and employers in particular industries to agree on
shorter working hours instead of higher wages and salaries. That
may seem like a good idea for both the union and its counterpart.
However, it should be appreciated that the agreement on shorter
working hours has consequences for other workers, who go on
working longer hours and pay more taxes to finance services consumed by all (the “common pool” problem).
The labour market: enough workers working enough?
·
111
Thus, responsible unions should resist shorter working hours in
the name of worker solidarity. We argue below that decentralized
and even individual pay bargaining is appropriate in a world of modern production techniques and globalization. Yet, working hours is
an issue in which there is a strong case for coordination, and overall
working hours should probably be dealt with and agreed mainly at
a fairly centralized union-employer organizational level. Otherwise
individual unions may have incentives to agree on shorter working hours without due regard to the social costs. As centralized or
coordinated decision making is part of the Nordic labour markets
setting, the framework exists to ensure that decisions on working
hours take into account their wider implications.
It is a noteworthy fact that the Nordics have been able to
sustain a rather high supply of working hours even though their
tax rates are quite high. This is illustrated in figure 6.1, which
shows average working hours in the EU15 and the size of total
tax wedges (including income taxes, social security contributions and indirect taxes). Not surprisingly, there appears to be a
65
Tax wedge
65
Bel
Ger
60
Swe
Fra
55
Net
Ita
Aut
60
Den
Fin
55
50
50
Gre
45
Spa
Ire
40
Por
UK
35
USA
30
900
1000
1100
* Average hours worked by the working-aged population.
Source: OECD.
·
The Nordic Model
40
35
30
1200
1300
1400
Average hours worked in 2003*
Figure 6.1
Tax wedge and hours worked in EU15
112
45
All2 w/o Nordics
R = 0.62
The Nordics work
more hours, as an
average for the total population, than
would be expected
given the size of the
tax wedge
negative (and statistically significant) correlation between the tax
wedge and hours worked. However, the relation is much weaker
(and no longer statistically significant) when also the Nordics are
considered. These countries appear as “outliers”; their amount of
hours worked is higher than would be expected, given the high tax
wedges. One plausible explanation for this observation is precisely
the role that central labour market organizations have played for
agreements on working hours, countervailing the individual disincentive to work. Another likely important factor is the role of
family policies and women.
6.3 UNEMPLOYMENT BENEFITS, WORKFARE AND
ACTIVATION
The design of unemployment insurance
matters!
Unemployment benefits are economically
and socially useful –
but they should facilitate re-employment,
not promote benefit
dependency
Good employment performance requires well designed labour
market institutions and a well working system of wage bargaining.
The next chapter will focus on the latter issue, here we discuss
unemployment insurance and the role of labour market policies
and activation schemes.
Insuring the individual against unemployment spells is an
important part of the Nordic philosophy of risk sharing, and
unemployment benefit schemes are accordingly relatively generous. Extensive theoretical and empirical research has in the last
decades been devoted to the analysis of unemployment insurance schemes. Nothing in these research efforts suggests that it
is fundamentally infeasible or inefficient to use unemployment
insurance and thereby improve the well being of wage earners.
However, the research also comes with a strong message: the devil
is in the details, the detailed design of unemployment insurance
schemes matters a lot.
The basic dilemma of unemployment insurance is the same
as in all insurance systems: the existence of insurance affects the
behaviour of the clients. Unemployment insurance may reduce
job search efforts of the unemployed and raise the wage claims
of those at work. These potential effects are an important issue
in the Nordic countries, in which very large number of individu-
The labour market: enough workers working enough?
·
113
als take part in various unemployment insurance and activation
schemes.
The main policy conclusions that emerge from the research
literature are12:
· A generous unemployment insurance scheme is not infeasible per se; unemployment spells need not imply poverty.
· However, there is a strong case for a decreasing time profile
in benefit payments as well as an expiry date for their
duration. In other words, insurance levels can initially be
high, but they must shrink markedly as the unemployment
spell is prolonged. A large amount of theoretical and empirical research suggests that the search effort of the
individual intensifies as the time limit approaches and the
benefit level shrinks. A fairly high initial benefit level can
be compatible with efficiency, but it must also be preceded
by a “self-insured” no-benefit period at the very beginning
of an unemployment spell, so that transitions to unemployment in general and abuse of the insurance system in
particular is discouraged.
· There is a strong case for active monitoring of the recipient’s search effort. Monitoring is costly, but stringent
monitoring can sustain a more generous insurance system.
Needless to say, the cost of monitoring can be kept down
if the sanctions of getting caught are sufficiently severe.
· Similarly, the effects of workfare elements, in the sense of
conditionality of benefits on training or activation schemes,
can also be strong. Even if the productivity and direct
return on activation schemes is poor, such schemes can
act as a useful deterrent and selection device – an activation scheme or a training course makes unemployment
a less attractive option for those not strongly engaged in
job search.
With structural unemployment stuck at 6–7 per cent in Sweden and Finland, one clearly has to ask whether the unemployment
insurance system is appropriate at present.
The introduction of uniform pay increases in Sweden in the
1950s went hand in hand with an active labour market policy in-
114
·
The Nordic Model
Unemployment benefits can be generous
if they are time limited
and conditional – a
review of the rules is
called for
Active labour market
policy: poor return on
a lot of money spent
Danish experiences
seem more positive,
which may be due to
the role of “workfare”
tended to help displaced workers find new jobs in expanding sectors
of the economy. However, most of the large scale measures of active
labour market policy since then have been ineffective and clearly
a source of disappointment, particularly in Sweden. The policy
measures may also have been subject to electoral cycles, since it is
attractive for governments to hide a part of open unemployment
temporarily into various training programmes and subsidized employment. In the 1990s, when Sweden was confronted with mass
unemployment, active labour market policy measures increased
hugely in volume13.
By and large, econometric evidence suggests that the labour
market policy measures have had a disappointingly weak effect on
unemployment.14 Training programmes and subsidized employment
do have some effects that reduce open unemployment. The net
effect on unemployment is weak or non-existent, however, because
of direct crowding out effects and second round effects on wage
claims. Direct crowding out occurs if the employer substitutes
subsidized employment for their ordinary employees. Second
round effects work via the wage formation process. An increase in
labour market programmes will increase the wage claims of unions,
thereby increasing structural unemployment. This will happen
notably if it is attractive for a potentially unemployed individual
to participate in a programme and the trade unions take this into
account in their wage claims. It is then less painful for unions to
push for higher wages, as part of the newly unemployed will be
absorbed by the programmes.15
While the empirical evidence is somewhat inconclusive, the
general result is that the effects of labour market policies on unemployment are quite weak. And when positive, the effects are at
the expense of ordinary employment. Some studies have also found
a positive effect on wage claims. The overall picture is therefore
bleak.16 The Danish experience suggests, however, that labour
market policy may play quite an important role in conjunction with
other policies. In particular, labour market policy administration
can encourage and even compel the individual to active job seeking. This seems to be one important aspect of the famous Danish
“flexicurity model” (see the box 6.2), and the Swedish labour
market administration has recently moved in that direction.
The labour market: enough workers working enough?
·
115
Box 6.2
What is the Danish “flexicurity model”?
It is often argued that Denmark has been able to sustain high employment and
keep unemployment low thanks to a combination of weak employment protection legislation and generous unemployment insurance. Andersen and Svarer
(2007) demonstrate that this common perception is to some extent a myth. The
combination of employment policy legislation and unemployment insurance
was already in the 1980s quite similar to that of today, yet Denmark experienced
high unemployment at that time. Furthermore, employment protection does not
appear to be all that weak in international comparison, and the unemployment
insurance scheme is in fact quite generous for the less skilled. What seems to
have made the difference, really, is a general shift from income maintenance to
ensuring job search and employment. For example, participation in activation
measures does not anymore guarantee renewed eligibility for unemployment
benefits. The effective duration of benefits has also been cut. Furthermore, the
“workfare” element has been strengthened by the introduction of new measures
that compel the individual to a more active job search, even at the threat of losing
his/her benefits. Such workfare policies imply that the public employment service can ask the unemployed to accept a given employment opportunity. If the unemployed does not comply with the requirements, his/her unemployment insurance fund is notified and the fund can choose to sanction the individual in question by cancelling the benefit payment for a while.17 Although such sanctioning
is not very often implemented in practice, Andersen and Svarer argue that the introduction of such workfare policies have made a difference. They also point out,
however, that sanctions are quite costly to administer and that they affect different groups of individuals in different ways.
Although the overall return of active labour market policy
investment is low, it may be high for some subgroups. In particular,
any activation measures that have a positive effect on young groups
can potentially be very productive, in particular if work histories
exhibit strong path dependence. Preventing a young person from
being marginalized can cost a lot and still be economically efficient.
This consideration is particularly relevant for Finland, which
among the Nordic countries has the lowest rate of labour force
participation of the young.
More generally, the labour market performance of Finland
leaves a lot to be desired in important respects. The mediocre
employment performance (in a Nordic comparison) is arguably
associated with a lack of political prioritization of the issue of high
employment. The need to increase labour supply in response to
the demographic challenge has not really penetrated the minds
116
·
The Nordic Model
Even expensive activation measures may be
efficient and justified,
if they help avoid marginalization of young
individuals
Do voters and politicians in Finland give
sufficient weight to
high employment?
of politicians nor those of the voters. For instance, the debate
leading to the parliamentary election of 2007 did never focus on
that issue (in contrast to the political debate in the 2006 Swedish electoral campaign). Instead, the main electoral themes were
purely redistributive ones. Yet, the demographic transition is going
to be much faster in Finland than in Sweden and Denmark, and,
as noted, labour force participation rates in Finland for the young
and the elderly are clearly lower than Nordic averages.
The labour market: enough workers working enough?
·
117
ENDNOTES
1
In his history of the economic policy initiatives of the Swedish trade unions, Villy Bergström
(2007) shows how committed the Swedish trade union federation LO was from the outset to technical progress and economic openness.
2
See Böckerman and Uusitalo (2006).
3
See Kleven and Kreiner (2006), a longer version of which is available as CEPR Working Paper
5594, April 2006.
4
Estimates of microeconomic labour supply normally imply low elasticities for individuals of
prime working age who are already working. Intuitively, changes in the tax schedule change the
slope of the individual’s budget line marginally, and the individual therefore adjusts his/her labour-leisure choice only marginally. In fact, hours-of-work elasticities, conditional on the person
already working, turn out in many studies to be close to zero for prime age male individuals. It is
well known that the labour supply of women is more elastic, but even in the case of women it is
crucial for policy makers to affect the participation decision and not only the hours decision.
5
Theoretical modelling of th e choice at the extensive margin typically assumes that there are
significant fixed costs of participating in the labour market. This makes intuitive sense, since it is
for many individuals quite impractical and costly to carry out a little amount of work only – for example, the individual has to travel to the workplace, it takes time to learn a new job, and the employer has to incur administrative costs also for part-time employees.
6
See Kleven and Kreiner (2006), who use micro data on taxes and benefits for the EU15 countries, Eissa and Liebman (1996), and Blundell and MaCurdy (1999).
7
Some calibrated theoretical models start to make sense of the large hours gap between Europe and the United States; see, in particular the calibrated model of labour supply over the life
cycle by Rogerson and Wallenius (2007). The focus of their analysis is precisely on the life cycle
pattern of labour supply: at which age will an individual start his/her productive career, and at
which age is the individual likely to retire?
8
As estimated by the National Institute of Economic Research (Konjunkturinstitutet), Stock
holm, (“The Swedish Economy”, December 2006).
9
For example, Uusitalo and Hakola (2001) show how the flow into early retirement in Finland
depends on the incentive of both the employer and the employee to initiate such a move.
10
See table 1.5 in Cahuc and Zylberberg (2004), partly based on Maddison (1995).
11
In Finland, there is a programme giving tax incentives for taking a year off work or a sabbatical year (“vuorotteluvapaa”). In Sweden a similar scheme (“friår”) has been used, though it was recently abolished by the Reinfeldt government.
12
See Peter Fredriksson and Bertil Holmlund (2006).
13
Sweden has established a research institute (IFAU, Institut för arbetsmarknadspolitisk utvärdering) that carries out sophisticated evaluations of active labour market policy programmes.
14
See Forslund and Holmlund (2003).
15
However, there is also an effect in the opposite direction by these programmes: participation
may improve the individual’s attachment to the labour market and strengthen his/her individual
competitiveness as an employee – because of, say, newly acquired skills. This could modify the
wage claims of unions, as they know that any newly unemployed member will encounter harder
competition from part of those currently unemployed. It may also be noted that some studies
have used data on individual labour market careers to analyse the effects of programme participation on the probability of getting a job. Even those effects turn out to be very weak or even of
the wrong sign. For example, Fredriksson and Johansson (2003) find that the participation in job
creation or training programmes reduces the individual’s chance of finding a job.
16
See Forslund and Holmlund (2003).
17
See also Fredriksson and Holmlund (2003, 2006) who argue that the case for imposing a penalty on less active job search is theoretically solid.
118
·
The Nordic Model
7
Wages need to be
compatible with macroeconomic balance
and full employment
There is a case for centralization or coordination of bargaining
in highly unionized
economies
WAGE BARGAINING WITH MORE
FLEXIBILITY
Equilibrium unemployment depends, in heavily unionized economies, on both the demand for labour by employers and the level of
the wage claims of unions.1 Powerful unions can have significant
effects on wage claims and hence unemployment; they are in a position to extract wage settlements that disrupt the macroeconomic
balance. It is a constant challenge to enhance or impose wage
moderation in order to keep wage claims at a level compatible with
low unemployment. This is an important point, since some of the
negative consequences of rigid labour market institutions may be
limited if wage demands of unions are sufficiently moderate.
In the late 1980s, co-ordination of wage bargaining became
the subject of a large body of theoretical models, starting with
the well known contribution of Calmfors and Driffill (1988).2
One conclusion was that centralized pay bargaining is conducive
to high employment and low unemployment in heavily unionized economies. Nationally coordinated pay settlements are an
advantage because they make it possible to take into account the
negative consequences of high wage claims of individual unions
and to contain union rivalry. This discussion reinforced the legitimacy of centralized pay bargaining and underlined the challenge
of achieving wage moderation.
Achieving full employment may indeed necessitate some kind
or degree of cooperation between unions. This requirement is
Wage bargaining with more flexibility
·
119
particularly noteworthy in a euro area member state like Finland,
since there is no national monetary authority reacting to the wage
setting behaviour of the unions. In Sweden, for instance, large
unions know that high pay increases will be met by high interest
rates. In a small euro area member state, by contrast, there is no
central bank fulfilling that role, which means that inter-union
coordination may be desirable as a means of achieving some moderation of wage claims3.
7.1 UNIFORM PAY INCREASES: FOR AND
AGAINST
We do not contest the need for macroeconomic pay moderation in
unionized economies, nor do we question the potential usefulness
of collective agreements. Collective pay increases may function as
a crude mechanism for creating some wage flexibility in a small and
open economy vulnerable to external shocks (such as fluctuations
in the foreign demand for exports). Instead of requiring wages to be
renegotiated separately in every firm, the Nordic labour market parties have sought to enhance the necessary process by establishing a
collective adjustment mechanism. Also, investment incentives are
better if the firm can expect that the profits arising from enhanced
local productivity – achieved with the help of, for example, new
machinery – will not be expropriated by the local union. This is
precisely what Nordic collective agreements traditionally achieve:
they always prohibit local strikes or lockouts, and they externalize the pay increase decision to higher level organizations. They
thereby prevent local rent seeking and strengthen the incentives
for investment.
Furthermore, the union and employer association representatives can adjust the collectively agreed pay increase to the business cycle position of the industry as a whole and thereby allow
downturns to be met with lower pay growth (and upturns with a
higher one).4 In Finland, which has an industrial structure less
diversified than Denmark and Sweden, such an “incomes policy”
system with nationally coordinated and uniform pay increases
120
·
The Nordic Model
There was a point with
uniform pay increases;
they may be appropriate if shocks are macroeconomic, or affect
the whole economy
in the same way, and
if “Taylorist” organization of production is
predominant
Decentralization of
pay bargaining is appropriate if shocks
and risks are increasingly specific, if there
are ample options
for outsourcing, and
if individual incentives matter more for
productive efficiency
than Taylorist control
and monitoring
worked reasonably well for a long time. The large increase in both
output and productivity in the electronics industry from the mid1990s onwards was enhanced by a Rehn–Meidner type of incomes
policy, which supported investment and expansion in high tech
firms with good profitability.
We suspect that the need for industry-wide adjustment
mechanisms is far weaker today than it was in the early post-WWII
decades. The system of uniform and moderate pay increases may
well have suited volatile export industries in small countries in
the era of a Taylorist organization of production (into many rather
similar tasks). In the global economy of today, by contrast, shocks
and structural transformations are increasingly firm-specific or
even task-specific – not national or sectoral. Firms can outsource
many parts of their production, and outsourcing of tasks is increasingly a vital competitive instrument. A general pay agreement for
an entire industry is too blunt a tool for controlling costs in such
circumstances. If a particular operation is threatened by outsourcing, it does not make sense to cut all the wages in the entire firm or
industry – in the way it once made sense to moderate all costs of
paper mills if the price of paper declined. Successful Nordic firms
must be able to seek productivity increases via outsourcing and
reorganization of production.5 Inevitably, global firms will need to
operate their own pay and personnel policies with due regard to
the increasingly global market.
Moreover, production techniques have evolved in ways that
increase the importance of individual incentives as compared to
direct control and monitoring. In Taylorist industrial production it
made sense to tie pay to particular tasks and to do that in collective agreements. In the Taylorist era, there were many similar tasks
within firms and it was easier than it is now to monitor and measure
the performance of employees. In modern production conditions,
the performance of individuals and groups is often harder to assess.
Remuneration should be based on a variety of performance indicators, and remuneration schemes should be tailored with regard
to the tasks and the personnel at hand. It makes far less sense to
regulate final wage outcomes in collective agreements.
Wage bargaining with more flexibility
·
121
7.2 COORDINATION AND DECENTRALIZATION
OF WAGE FORMATION
Our view is that macroeconomic moderation of wages should in
no way preclude a more decentralized or individual wage setting.
Indeed, this is the trend that has been observed in Denmark
and to some extent also in Sweden. Starting from a tradition of
uniform pay increases, pay bargaining has been comprehensively
individualized in large parts of the Swedish and Danish labour
markets. This has not implied a rejection of collective agreements.
Individualization has taken place within the framework of collective agreements: many Swedish and almost all Danish collective
agreements avoid imposing a general pay increase on all firms and
individuals. Instead, they just impose industrial peace and rules
stating that wages should be decided upon in local discussions,
possibly with some (low) guaranteed individual increase.
The model with general and undifferentiated pay increases,
the level of which is subject to national co-ordination, has been
quite long-lived in Finland. Central coordination may have been
enhanced politically by Finland’s membership in the euro area,
since wage moderation has in these conditions to be achieved
without a national monetary authority that would discipline wage
setters. Many Finnish unions strive for similar pay increases for
their members, and this implies that relative wage differentials are
rigid. Overall wage dispersion as well as wage dispersion within
tasks is accordingly low.6 However, the need for macroeconomic
control of wage developments has been unnecessarily interpreted
as an argument against pay differentiation. Changing technologies
strengthen the case for reconsidering pay policies. Employers have
indeed become increasingly unwilling to go on with pay settlements that do not leave room for firm-specific pay outcomes and
individually differentiated pay increases7.
Developments in Finland contrast with those in Sweden,
where central bargaining of pay increases was abolished after the
ambitious solidarism in the 1960s and 1970s had undermined the
willingness of employers and professional employees to cooperate
with the LO. From the mid-1990s onwards, a new pay bargaining
122
·
The Nordic Model
Combine individual
flexibility with macroeconomic responsibility
Finland in the laggard’s
role?
Most of pay is in Denmark and Sweden negotiated at the level of
the workplace or the
individual – subject to
a collectively agreed
peace clause
routine emerged, relying on informal coordination of pay claims
by sectoral bargaining cartels. Co-ordination is facilitated by a
new government authority, the National Mediation Office, which
provides the labour markets organizations with wage statistics and
descriptions of current collective agreements. White collar and professional unions have become increasingly willing to conclude pay
agreements that leave the final determination of pay to individual
negotiations at the workplace. At most, such contracts set a low
minimum level of pay increases. Only a minority of employees in
both the business and the public sector are covered by collective
and general pay increases, and almost all professional employees
conduct completely individual wage discussions with their employers. There is a great variety of contractual forms; some collective
agreements just stipulate a peace clause or at most an “individual
guarantee” of a minimum pay increase, remaining completely silent
on the distribution of pay increases between individuals.
The contrast is even starker between Finland and Denmark,
where the role of collective agreements has increasingly been confined to the regulation of working hours, pensions, sickness and
vacation issues. Thus, most private sector employees in Denmark
now negotiate their pay directly with their employer, subject to a
peace clause.
The decentralization of pay bargaining in Sweden and Denmark has broadly coincided with increasing wage differentials
between firms, in particular among white collar employees. In
other words, the individual’s level of pay depends less and less on
his/her observable characteristics and more and more on the firm or
establishment where he/she works.8 This is a general trend, which
is visible also in Finnish earnings data, but the changes are more
significant in Denmark and Sweden9. As expected, the dispersion
of wage changes across individuals is in Finland and Sweden clearly
lower than in Denmark (the dispersion also in Denmark remaining
clearly smaller than in, say, the US).
The change in firm-specific pay differentials can be related
to institutional changes. In a recent report on Swedish wage formation, a clear correlation is reported between more individual
contracts and changes in wage and salary distributions for many
industrial sectors.10 However, the evolution of pay differentials
Wage bargaining with more flexibility
·
123
also depends on the business cycle. In general, salary differentials
increase in booms if collective contracts allow it. In recessions,
by contrast, the earnings distribution is stable. Thus, it seems
that firms reward some of their key employees in periods of high
growth.
At the same time, wage drift has been quite low in Sweden.
The Swedish experience suggests strongly that it is possible to establish wage moderation in a strongly unionized economy without
imposing uniform pay increases for all individuals. In fact, more
individual pay bargaining has probably limited the rate of general
wage drift, since individual wage determination makes it possible
for employers to adjust relative wages with lower aggregate pay increases, as a part of the regular bargaining process. If the collective
agreements leave a lot of room for relative wage adjustments at the
local level, it is less likely that wage drift in excess of collectively
agreed increases will emerge. There need thus be no contradiction between macroeconomic objectives and more individual and
firm-specific pay bargaining.
Opposition to more individual wage settlements in Finland
often stems from a fear of an explosive increase in wage differentials. It is apparently assumed that the labour market institutions
in the Nordic countries keep pay differentials (artificially) low.
This conventional perception may be true to some extent, but we
would not expect a very large increase in wage differentials even
if pay bargaining were further individualized. There are several
reasons for this. First, it is doubtful whether collective regulation
could in the long term sustain a distribution of individual wages
that deviates dramatically from the competitive wage structure.
Second, the Nordic countries are well known for the equality of
their educational opportunities and the absence of educational
tracking in primary school. Thus, the relatively small wage differentials also reflect a relatively even distribution of productive
abilities11.
Empirical evidence for Sweden suggests that the effect of
individualization of pay bargaining on earnings differentials is
rather gentle. Most groups of salaried white-collar employees in
Sweden moved into individual pay determination around the years
1997–1999. This was reflected in an increase in wage dispersion,
124
·
The Nordic Model
Decentralization of
wage formation has
increased pay differentials somewhat
– and has reduced
wage drift
A further decentralization or individualization of wage bargaining is unlikely to lead
to a big increase in
wage dispersion
Percentile ratios
Percentile ratios
2.6
2.6
P90/P10
P90/P50
P50/P10
2.4
2.2
2.4
2.2
2.0
2.0
1.8
1.8
1.6
1.6
1.4
1.4
1.2
1968
1.2
72
76
80
84
88
92
96
2000
04
Figure 7.1
The evolution of wage differentials in Sweden,1968–2004
Measures of wage dispersion (P90/P10, P90/P50, P50/P10) for all wage earners.
Source: National Institute of Economic Research, Wage Formation Report (Lönebildningsrapporten
2006).
Percentile ratios
Percentile ratios
3.5
3.5
Blue collar workers
Salaried employees
3.0
3.0
2.5
2.5
2.0
2.0
1.5
1.5
1.0
1.0
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2004
Figure 7.2
The evolution of wage differentials in Sweden,1970–2004
Dispersion measure P90/P10 for blue collar workers and salaried employees.
Source: National Institute of Economic Research, Wage Formation Report (Lönebildningsrapporten
2006).
Wage bargaining with more flexibility
·
125
but not in any dramatic way (cf. figure 7.1). In particular, if the
pay structures were initially very compressed, one would expect a
large increase in the wage dispersion of salaried employees. Such
an increase is discernible (see figure 7.2) but it is rather modest,
in particular when compared to the large decrease in wage differentials that took place in the 1970s.
Finally, and as pointed out above, the Swedish experience
also suggests that more individual pay bargaining leads to higher
earnings for key employees in periods of high economic growth,
without leading to any general downward bidding of wages (in
good or bad times).
7.3 WAGE FORMATION AND PRODUCTIVITY
The role of decentralized wage formation for economic developments should not be exaggerated. It is unlikely to boost growth
significantly or resolve the difficulties of the welfare state. However, individualized pay formation can still contribute to both a
better allocation of resources in the economy as a whole and to
more efficiency in the provision of services. In particular, it may
enhance productivity in the public sector and thereby alleviate
somewhat one of the key problems highlighted in this report (cf.
chapters 5 and 8).
Since public sector productivity measures are poor, there is not
much data to test this hypothesis. There are econometric results,
however, that lend support to the idea that labour productivity
responds positively to individual incentives, at least in the business sector. Some recent studies have investigated the relationship
between pay individualization and productivity growth in Sweden,
exploiting the fact that an encompassing individualization of pay
bargaining took place from the late 1990s onwards. The evidence
is scarce so far, but it suggests that the shift to more individual wage
bargaining has been associated with higher labour productivity
growth.12 If available results can be generalized to public sector
employment – and this is not an implausible conjecture – they
provide an important argument for reforming public sector wage
determination.
126
·
The Nordic Model
A link between pay
dispersion and (public
sector) productivity
outcomes?
Decentralized wage
formation is arguably associated with
improved individual
incentives and more
rapid productivity
growth
Insufficient wage flexibility in Finland?
It should be also pointed out that productivity growth in the
business sector has in recent years been quite high in both Sweden
and Finland (see chapter 3). In Finland this is very much driven
by the IT sector, in which collective agreements have since the
1980s allowed for an evaluation of individual performance as the
basis of wage and salary determination.
With the prevalence of uniform pay increases in Finland,
and to some extent in other Nordic countries, we would expect
econometric analyses to indicate high wage rigidity (particularly
in Finland). International comparisons of wage flexibility indeed
support the view that Finland – and also Sweden, though it has
gone further in liberalising its wage bargaining system – may suffer
from excessive wage rigidity.
Flexibility and rigidity of wages involve many dimensions. Real
wage flexibility at the macroeconomic level refers to the interaction
between unemployment and average real wages. Full employment
can be restored quickly if the labour market is flexible, since an
increase in unemployment then exerts strong downward pressure
on the level or rate of change of real wages. Relative wage flexibility
refers to the ability of the economy to generate adjustments in relative wages when needed. For example, as new industries emerge
and old ones disappear, changes in relative wages may help the
reallocation of labour and provide proper incentives for individuals
to change jobs. The internal pay policies of firms and incentive
schemes may also require changes in relative wages between groups
and individuals. Finally, nominal wage flexibility refers to the ability
of the economy to generate nominal pay cuts when needed in some
firms or in exceptional circumstances.
Nominal and real wage flexibility has in recent years been
highlighted in a number of comparative international studies.13 In
general, all countries exhibit some rigidity, and nominal and real
wage rigidity should not only be attributed to collective regulations14. There is also considerable uncertainty as to how correctly
individual pay changes are measured, since most data sets contain
some errors. However, it is noteworthy that Finland and Sweden
stand out in one major study as the two countries with the highest degree of real wage rigidity and with nominal wage rigidity
well above the average (though it may also be noted that the US
Wage bargaining with more flexibility
·
127
displays higher nominal rigidity than both Sweden and Finland).
The rigidity measures for Denmark, by contrast, are amongst the
lowest in the entire comparative data set15. Measurement errors
notwithstanding, Finnish and Swedish collective agreements seem
to be particularly effective in protecting the real earnings of workers who stay with their current employer16.
7.4 TAKING STOCK – SOME CONCLUSIONS
As we have seen, the Nordic labour market experiences are a
mixed bag. When compared with the lacklustre EU labour market
performance, the Nordic countries stand out rather positively. It
is also positive that labour market parties have been able to learn
from experience and reform their practices. In Denmark, wage settlements have become almost completely individualized. In Sweden
as well, individual pay bargaining has proceeded quite far. Dead
end policies like a redistributive solidaristic wage system have been
abandoned, and the political system has reacted to the need for
boosting employment and the labour supply. As noted in chapter
6, this is the case for Denmark and Sweden, less so for Finland.
As to pay bargaining, we believe there is an unnecessarily stark
opposition in Finland to more individual wage settlements. The
Swedish experience, as well as basic economic reasoning, suggests
that there are many ways of combining flexible wage determination
with both (some degree of) income security and macroeconomic
objectives. Wage determination in the Nordic countries could in
our view be quite market-driven, as there are many other mechanisms in place to compensate for economic risks. And as noted,
both Denmark and Sweden have already proceeded quite far in
the direction of individualization of wage bargaining.
The transition in Sweden, which is otherwise known for its
political sensitivity vis-à-vis earnings differentials, is noteworthy. It
probably reflects the fact that there is now in place a fully fledged
welfare state to protect the worker against the most severe economic risks, thereby reducing the uncertainties that wage earners
have to face. In such circumstances it is much less threatening to
128
·
The Nordic Model
The welfare state –
social security and
redistribution – has
alleviated the fear of
market forces
Both the welfare state
and macroeconomic
stability have contributed to the acceptability of local and
individual wage
negotiations
Demands for flexibility
are no assault on the
Nordic model
allow market forces and the personnel policy of firms to influence
individual pay. Furthermore, inasmuch as voters desire redistribution (as they clearly do in all Nordic countries), the welfare state
now operates a large redistributive mechanism. It thus makes less
sense to try to use the system of wage formation for redistributive
purposes.
Also, and as compared to the 1950s when collective pay
bargaining was established, the macroeconomic framework is now
much more stable. When the macroeconomic environment is stable and inflation is low, the individual worker may feel much less
need to ensure a decent pay increase by collective action. Compare
this state of affairs to the 1970s when inflation was around 10 per
cent – in those circumstances it might have seemed a good idea
to ask the union to ensure that unanticipated inflation is matched
by corresponding pay increases.
In summary, we believe that a successful political reform
programme should build on the strengths of the Nordic model. It
is because of sound macroeconomics policies and social insurance
that Nordic labour markets can do without stringent employment
protection legislation and cope with individual pay bargaining. By
the same token, a successful political reform programme should
acknowledge the basic strengths of the Nordic model and not try
to reform all things at once. Opposition in trade unions is easily
triggered by the suspicions that reformers want to abolish everything: unemployment benefits, pensions, public services, collective
agreements.
Incremental reforms make sense in our view. It should be
possible to design wage bargaining systems that allow firms to
operate flexible wage policies, also in Finland. It should be possible to sustain social insurance and tax systems that alleviate
individual economic uncertainty, while keeping work incentives
sufficiently strong. If economic reform in countries like Finland
and Sweden is to gather political support, voters and unions must
be persuaded that the goal of reform is not to dismantle the entire
edifice of Nordic institutions, but rather to design schemes that
reduce deadweight losses. The Nordic labour market model and
collective agreements are not the issue: the challenge is more of a
political nature. Many characteristics of the Nordic labour market
Wage bargaining with more flexibility
·
129
model stem from an age in which the political mobilization of the
workers sought to generate a collective will of the working class to
overcome powerful opponents and notably the owners of capital.
Today, the main challenge arises from the need to control internal
free riding. This calls for another kind of political discourse, much
less adversarial in nature.
While there is need for further reform, we believe that the
Nordic societies should exploit the strengths of their own model.
We do have strong trade unions – they could help coordinate agreements on working hours with a view to keeping them sufficiently
high? We have progressive taxation as well as comprehensive
social security and generous unemployment insurance – why not
liberalize employment protection legislation further and allow
wage settlements to better reflect market forces? We appreciate
hard work and regard high employment as a precondition for the
attainment of economic and social objectives – why not establish a
stronger workfare? These are the questions that Nordic electorates
and decision makers should and must address in coming years, and
it is not a service to anybody to pretend that hard choices do not
exist or can be avoided.
130
·
The Nordic Model
There are promising
avenues for further
reform
ENDNOTES
1
The modern theory of equilibrium unemployment makes unemployment a function of the
wage claims of unions: there is a mapping from the level of employment to the desired level of
wages, and it is the position of this “wage claim curve” that determines the NAIRU, i.e. the level of
unemployment that is compatible with stable inflation.
2
Calmfors and Driffill (1988).
3
Holden (2005) fledges out the theoretical argument.
4
Hartog and Teulings (1998) present a sophisticated analysis of Dutch pay bargaining from
this perspective, but their analysis fits the Nordic countries’ labour markets equally well.
5
The paper by Baldwin (2006) is an elaboration of this new paradigm of industrial organiza-
tion.
6
To compensate for this, profit sharing schemes and performance pay schemes have become
increasingly popular among white collar employees.
7
In 2007, the Finnish metal and technology employer associations and some of their wage
earner counterparts broke new ground by concluding agreements that leave a large part of pay
increases to firm-level negotiations.
8
For Sweden, this is reported by Edin, Holmlund and Skans (2007), and for Denmark, by Westergaard-Nielsen and Tor Eriksson (2007). Similar trends are reported for Finnish white collar employees by Uusitalo and Vartiainen (2007), although overall salary differentials are lower in Finland.
9
See Uusitalo and Vartiainen (2007).
10
Lönebildningsrapporten 2007, Konjunkturinstitutet november 2007.
11
In general, though, economic theory suggests that the distribution of market pay displays a
higher variance than the distribution of productive abilities. An early demonstration of this was
provided by the celebrated Roy model, see Sattinger (1993).
12
In a study exploiting a large data set of individuals matched with information on the firms
in which the individuals were employed, Per Lundborg (2005) was able show that productivity
(value added per employee) had increased more rapidly in those firms within which intra-occupational pay dispersion had increased the most. In another study with a similar matched data set,
Fredrik Heyman (2005) showed that profits are enhanced by increased wage dispersion within
the group of highly paid salaried employees.
13
The International Wage Flexibility Project (see Dickens & et al., 2006) compared large data sets
of individual wages for “job stayers” – i.e. individuals who do not change employers – between
two consecutive years. The research strategy was to look for nominal wage rigidity by analysing
the shape of the statistical distribution of individual wage changes in particular countries and
particular years. If the statistical distribution of pay changes contains a lot of observations just
around or above a zero increase, that would be interpreted as evidence for nominal rigidity, because a large amount of nominal pay cuts would then in all likelihood have been prevented by
some rigidity mechanism. If there were a large concentration of observations just around the rate
of inflation, that would be evidence of real rigidity, since a number of real wage cuts would in all
likelihood have been prevented.
14
There are many reasons for wage rigidity emerging even without any collective regulations.
For example, most wage contracts are written in nominal terms and many are quite long term.
Many workers resist pay cuts, and managers are rightly concerned about the effect of pay cuts on
motivation, morale and hence productivity.
15
See figure 3 in Dickens & et al. (2006). The countries investigated were Ireland, Denmark,
France, Belgium, UK, Switzerland, Austria, Germany, Italy, Netherlands, Finland, Norway, Greece,
Sweden, US, and Portugal. The list ranks them according to increasing nominal wage rigidity.
Norway was not part of the study. The data covered different time periods for different countries,
Wage bargaining with more flexibility
·
131
mostly in the years 1980–2000. For Sweden the years 1995–2003 were covered. Thus, the Swedish
bargaining reforms starting in the late 1990s may not be fully reflected in the results.
16
We do not want to paint an all black picture, and other studies on wage flexibility yield more
nuanced results on Finland and Sweden. Holden and Wulfsberg (2007) compare the distributions
of average wage changes over sectors in particular countries and particular years. Their research
strategy is based on the dynamics of average wages in a large number of industries and a large
number of countries. It thus provides another statistical look at wage rigidity/flexibility. For example, an important channel of wage flexibility may work through new recruits and job changes,
something that may not be captured by the analysis of individual job stayers. Interestingly, the
Nordic countries do not stand out as particularly rigid in this analysis. In the light of Finnish experiences, this discrepancy between the International Wage Flexibility Project and the Holden
– Wulfsberg results makes some sense. Finland experienced a dramatic structural transformation
from the mid-1990s onwards, with high productivity growth and big flows of individuals between
firms and establishments. Thus, although pay cuts of incumbents were not frequent, average
wage costs in industry exhibited a fair amount of flexibility.
132
·
The Nordic Model
8
Raise taxes or broaden
the tax base – or
revisit the scope and
organization of public
services
THE PROPER SCOPE OF
THE PUBLIC SECTOR
There are three ways to deal with the impending fiscal imbalances
that we forecast to be so significant due to demographic changes.
We can raise tax rates. We can broaden the tax base by encouraging
higher employment. And we can revisit the scope and organization
of government provided services. The third option is the subject
of this chapter.
Table 8.1 shows the 2005 breakdown of government expenditures by function for Denmark, Finland, Sweden, EU15 and the
U.S. The Nordic countries have public sectors that all exceed 50
per cent of GDP, which is larger than the EU average and much
larger than the U.S. The main deviation does not come from the
basic “nightwatch” services (defense, public security, fire, emergency, government offices, etc), but rather from a larger welfare
state. Expenditures on education are somewhat higher than in
the EU, but the biggest difference comes from the extent of social
protections. Further analysis reveals that transfers and especially
public services are big.
It is evident that adjusting the scope and increasing the efficiency of public services can play an important part in avoiding
future fiscal shortfalls.
The public sector has of course adjusted to changed circumstances all along, usually in response to fiscal constraints and the
macroeconomic environment. The big sell-off of government
The proper scope of the public sector
·
133
Table 8.1
Government expenditure by function, 2005
Total
Nightwatch state*
Welfare state, of which
- Health
- Education
- Social protection
Other**
EU15
Denmark
Finland
Sweden
U.S.
47.2
10.0
30.8
6.6
5.2
19.0
6.4
53.1
9.3
37.4
6.9
7.9
22.6
6.4
50.5
9.9
34.1
6.8
6.1
21.2
6.5
56.4
10.7
38.1
7.0
7.3
23.8
7.6
34.2
10.8
20.7
7.8
5.3
7.6
2.7
General government expenditure 2005 as a percentage of GDP.
* Defined as the sum of government spending on general public services, defence, and public order and safety.
** Defined as the sum of government spending on economic affairs, environmental protection, and housing and community
amenities.
Sources: Eurostat and Bureau of Economic Analysis.
owned corporate assets throughout the EU in the 1980s and 1990s
was largely triggered by the need to cover fiscal deficits. On the
other hand, privatization has continued in the Nordic countries
even in times of fiscal surpluses, indicating that economic efficiency
has become an important objective as well.
It is estimated that the private sector’s share of government
financed services in the EU has increased by 30 per cent over the
past ten years. We have seen increased reliance on outsourcing and
the birth of new hybrid forms of organization, such as the Public
and Private Partnerships (PPPs). The inspiration for these experiments has come from similar trends in the private sector.
We endorse the general direction of these developments. It is
a good time to reconsider the boundary between the private and
the public sector. Financial markets have developed enormously,
which together with technological advances, especially in the information and communication sectors, has led to new, successful
business models, which the public sector should try to emulate and
exploit. Exposing selected parts of the public sector to competition
can have big efficiency payoffs.
Opinions about public versus private sector services become
easily polarized. At one end is the liberal view that, with appropriately defined property rights, one should be able to privatize all but
134
·
The Nordic Model
Should welfare services be publicly or
privately provided?
Private enterprise is
all about profits – the
public sector has to
deal with much fuzzier objectives
The public sector ends
up with tasks that the
private sector handles
poorly
the most basic government infrastructure and leave efficiency to
market forces alone. At the other end is the extreme public interest
view stating that any service that serves the public at large should
be provided by the public sector.
Our goal is to offer a balanced view based on insights from
organizational economics as well as evidence on how a heavier
reliance on private services have worked out in public sectors
around the world.
The basic premise must be that privately supplied and publicly supplied services each have their comparative advantages.
They shift over time, which is why boundary questions have to
be revisited continuously. The great strength of the private sector
is its single-minded pursuit of profits – a clearly defined, easily
measured objective that is very effective in providing incentives
for efficient production and innovation. But profit maximization
can also become a liability in environments where it is too narrow
an objective.1
The public sector’s comparative advantages are just the opposite. It has the capacity to consider broader objectives than
profit maximization, but the imprecise nature of its objectives,
translated into missions for its agencies and bureaus, makes it a
much more challenging organization to run. To coordinate and direct its work force to achieve objectives that are much fuzzier than
profit maximization, the public sector is forced to employ a much
heavier layer of bureaucracy than private organizations (which
can be quite bureaucratic, too). Also, the government’s need for
public legitimacy and trust calls for procedures and rules that are
unnecessary in the private sector, thanks to competition.
Excessive bureaucracy and inertia are often seen as public
sector diseases, but they appear more purposeful through the lens
of organizational economics. Bureaucracy is a rational response to
organizational problems that are more challenging for the public
sector, because it operates without the performance feedback from
competition and consumer choice.
The differences in performance between the private and the
public sector are also exacerbated by the way tasks get allocated
between the two. The public sector tends to be handed tasks that
the private sector does poorly, namely tasks that are hard-to-meas-
The proper scope of the public sector
·
135
ure. This selection bias alone will make public agencies appear
operationally less efficient than private enterprises.
These observations should not be taken as excuses for all inefficiencies in the public sector. The purpose is to caution against
the belief that the public sector could be made internally more
efficient simply by using stronger performance incentives and less
bureaucracy. The ability to commit to weak performance incentives
is often essential for handling some of the tasks that the public
sector is charged with.
The upshot is that the public sector is an expensive form of
organization (measured by cost) and should be used only where
its unique qualities – the ability to serve broader social goals – are
especially valued. Consequently, the best route towards higher
productivity of public services will much of the time come from
leveraging the private sector using outsourcing, Private-PublicPartnerships (PPPs) and other hybrid forms of organization that
exploit the benefits of competition without losing sight of the
broader mission that is the rationale of having public services in
the first place.
Finding the right hybrids is not easy and will require trial and
error – and patience. The discussion of the Danish Flexicurity
model in Chapter 6 illustrates the point. It took a long time before
the missing piece was found that made Flexicurity effective in
reducing unemployment. Experimentation is a challenge for the
government, because it does not have the competitive urge to
innovate. In the public sector errors tend to get punished, while
successes are less noticed. Understandably, there is also a lot of
resistance within the public sector to reforms. To break these barriers requires political action and administrative initiative at the
highest levels.
The public sector is
an expensive, but at
times indispensable
form of organization
8.1 THE VIRTUES OF COMPETITION
It is useful to start by reviewing the virtues of competitive markets and the circumstances in which profit maximization leads to
desirable social outcomes. Publicly provided services need to be
considered only when competition does not work well.
136
·
The Nordic Model
Free competition ensures that all mutually
advantageous trades
are carried out and no
others, under the right
conditions
The option to exit
drives competition
Consider a single service, say, a cup of coffee. Suppose there
are several coffee shops right next to each other, all offering an
identical cup of coffee. Consumers know that the coffee is identical
so unless the coffee shops collude, they will all end up charging
the same price in equilibrium. In what sense does this outcome
maximize social welfare? The precise answer is this: When supply
equals demand, the price is such that all mutually advantageous
trades are carried out and no others. The reason is simple. Everyone who decides to buy coffee must value it higher than the
going price while everyone who decides not to buy coffee must
value it lower. Therefore, when supply equals demand, there is
no alternative allocation of coffee and money that makes all the
customers as well as the shop owners better off. (Economists call
this state Pareto optimal).
The magic of competition is that the customers’ welfare will
be taken care of by profit maximizing shop owners, merely because
customers can walk out – or exit in Albert O. Hirschman’s famous
language – if they are dissatisfied with the price that a coffee shop
offers. Voluntary trade paired with competition will provide enough
information about customer preferences to allocate services efficiently.
The efficiency of a competitive equilibrium holds much more
generally. Shops could invest in capacity or, when customers have
different preferences, choose what types of services to offer. As they
maximize profits, shop owners will optimally trade off the benefits
and costs of customers, too. They will also seek the best way to
organize the coffee shop: the number of workers to employ, the
training they have, the hours they work, how much to pay them
and what fringe benefits to provide them. Loosely speaking, as
long as all direct stakeholders – the customers, workers and suppliers – have competitive alternatives to choose from, the resulting
market outcome will maximize social welfare in the Pareto sense
describe above. Shop owners will receive a market determined
return on their time and investment, but not more, while the
stakeholders will be at least as well off as they would with their
best alternatives.
Competition and Pareto optimality do not guarantee any
particular distribution of income or utility. All it guarantees is
The proper scope of the public sector
·
137
that everyone gets their worth as measured by the value that the
market puts on their contributions. Distributional issues have to
be dealt with through taxation, social security and other government policies and, of course, through informal arrangements within
families and communities.
Distributional concerns underlie many public services, such as
schooling and public health. A big reason why the public sectors
in the Nordic countries are so large has to do with the perceived
need for collective risk sharing, as we discussed earlier. The question that we will address here, however, is whether some of the
services could be offered more cheaply through the private sector,
even when the public sector finances them (partly or fully). This
leads us to consider reasons for having publicly produced, not just
publicly financed services.
Competition enhances efficiency, distributional issues are a
separate matter
8.2 EXTERNAL EFFECTS AND PRIVATE
ORGANIZATION
In assessing the efficiency of coffee service, we only considered the
value created for the shop owners and their customers. This is fine
as long as the coffee business does not harm or benefit anyone else.
If the coffee shops disturb the neighborhood at night, or if they
bring more shoppers to the neighborhood during the day, profit
maximization will not take into account all social benefits and
costs. There would be external effects, or externalities.
In economic textbooks, externalities are always paired with
government intervention of some kind. It could involve corrective
taxes as in the case of congestion, or new property rights such as
tradable “pollution rights,” that force the firms to bear the external
costs and benefits that they cause. Other externalities can rationalize publicly provided services, as we will discuss shortly. But it is
important to note first that firms can “internalize” many externalities on their own, without the need of government. Indeed, the very
existence of firms and the determination of the lines of business
that they pursue are in large part driven by the value of internal
coordination of activities that decentralized market trades would
138
·
The Nordic Model
Governments and
firms are both designed to deal with
externalities – but of
very different kinds
Exit options are the
crucial difference between competitively
supplied private services and non-competitively supplied public
services
handle poorly because of externalities. Firms greatly extend the
scope of market efficiency, because they can do what the markets
cannot. Thus, the division of labor between public agencies and
private firms comes down to which types of externalities firms can
handle better than the government.
To give a concrete illustration of how firms internalize externalities, consider the organization of shopping malls. A shopping
mall is typically owned and operated by a separate firm. The firm’s
objective is to bring under the same roof a constellation of shops
that make the mall as attractive as possible to buyers as well as
shop owners. The firm considers carefully the contribution each
shop can make to the overall value of the mall. Rental rates will
reflect not just the size and location of a store, but also its ability
to draw customers, which benefit everyone. The mall owners also
put a lot of thought into the lease contracts, spelling out operating rules and constraints (such as store hours) that are designed
to maximize the aggregate surplus for everyone setting up shop in
the mall. If the shops were not coordinated in this fashion, but
instead set up along a street like the coffee shops discussed earlier,
positive and negative externalities from proximity would not be
priced and would lead to inefficiencies. The popularity and ubiquity
of shopping malls show that there is plenty of money to be made
by internalizing externalities from proximity.
Metaphorically speaking, firms are rather like shopping malls,
assembling different types of activities within one organization.
Subject to public laws and regulations, firms are free to set the
rules of conduct, design employee incentives, define jobs, allocate
authority, select businesses to pursue and strategies to employ.
Firms are far from democratic – nor do they need to be.2 A profit
maximizing firm will take into account stakeholder interests as
long as they have good exit options. Exit options are the essence
of competition and the crucial difference between privately and
publicly supplied services.
The proper scope of the public sector
·
139
8.3 THE CASE FOR GOVERNMENT PROVIDED
SERVICES – MISSIONS VERSUS PROFIT
MAXIMIZATION
So, why do we need government services? Because the government
has one thing profit maximizing firms do not have: the ability not
to maximize profits and instead consider broader social objectives.
Firms will not internalize externalities that they cannot profit from.3
In such cases, it can be more efficient both for private firms and
for society to let the government deal with the externalities. We
turn to some illustrative contexts where publicly provided services
often are used.
Public goods (or bads). National defense is a classic public good.
Citizens want a strong national defense, but when asked individually to contribute to defense they would have little incentive to
do so. The problem is that every euro spent to protect one citizen
protects everyone. Private financing of defense suffers from a massive free-rider problem – a large scale externality.
The same holds true for many of the basic services needed
in a functioning nation. The court system, the administration
of political offices, the collection of taxes, the police, the fire
department, all are public goods that are best put in the hands of
the government. It need not be the central government. When
the externality does not extend beyond a particular jurisdiction,
it can be dealt with by the local government. Zoning rights for a
city are best handled by the city government, which has the local
knowledge and, thanks to recurring elections, the incentive to
further the interests of its citizens.
Note that the zoning problem shares many of the features of
the shopping mall: there are external effects, positive and negative, and a heterogeneous clientele that needs to be satisfied. So,
why not have a private firm handle zoning? Because there is one
crucial element missing: the citizens do not have good exit rights.
Property owners would be captive to a private zoning office, which
as a monopoly could extract much of their surplus. Real estate is
an area prone to corruption precisely for this reason.
140
·
The Nordic Model
The virtue of government is its ability to
consider broader objectives than profit
The free-rider problem is the reason why
public goods are supplied by government
Adverse selection
problems explain why,
e.g., comprehensive
health insurance cannot be provided by
competitive markets
Consumers can have
difficulties in making
informed decisions,
and the information
required can sometimes be acquired better by public agencies
Asymmetric information causes contractual externalities, which
competitive markets often have problems with. A case in point
is the market for health insurance, which suffers from an adverse
selection problem. Adverse selection occurs when people know
their own health risks better than the insurance company and
purchase insurance based on their private information. Insurance
companies would like to know the health risks, too, but they may
have to infer the risks (imperfectly) from individual purchasing
behavior. Those who want to buy comprehensive coverage are
suspected to have relatively poor health, forcing the price for
comprehensive insurance higher than it would be if insurance were
mandatory. As the price of comprehensive coverage rises, even
less healthy will drop out of the pool. The process may not end
until everyone, except the very sick, have been discouraged to buy
comprehensive insurance. In that case a competitive market will
be unable to provide full insurance.4 For this reason, mandatory
health insurance is widely regarded as desirable.5 Even the U.S.
is on the verge of adopting general health insurance, though the
public sector will play a lesser role in the U.S. system.
Public oversight. Market efficiency rests on the assumption that
consumers can make informed decisions. In some cases information can be more cheaply acquired by an agency than by each
individual separately. The safety of products is a case in point.
Firms may be able to certify their products using a private agency,
but given the firms’ bias towards profit, people may not trust their
choice of agency. The credibility of the government often beats the
credibility of a private agency. The safety of medicines, toys and
vehicles are illustrative. When consumers can rely on minimum
standards assured by government, their monitoring costs can be
significantly reduced.
More complex issues arise when services are provided to
people incapable of making decisions. Nursery homes are a topical
example. Family members and friends can act as trustees, but they
are not always perfect substitutes for the real consumer: the person
in need of the nursing home. Government provided or subsidized
nursing homes are a possible solution.
Poor quality. Nursing homes, health care and primary schools
bring up another potential advantage of public service supply. Profit
The proper scope of the public sector
·
141
maximizing firms tend to focus excessively on reducing cost at the
expense of quality and other hard-to-measure consumer benefits.6
Teaching elementary school students, for instance, entails much
more than reading and writing. The school is supposed to impart
social skills as well. Motivating teachers through high-powered
performance incentives can be counter-productive, if it emphasizes
what can be measured rather than the overall value of what is
taught.7 Low-powered performance incentives enhance the selfmotivation and sense of duty of teachers.
Of course, concerns for reputation may reduce quality shading
and bridge the gap between narrow incentives and broader goals.
Problems arise, when consumer feedback is slow or non-existent.
Apparently this was an important rationale for letting a government agency take responsibility for all airport security in the U.S.
after 9/11. When incentives for cost-saving and responsiveness to
consumer (passenger) complaints are weak, as they tend to be in
government agencies, the attention to safety is likely to be higher,
particularly when complemented with procedural governance.
The common feature in all the examples above is that profit
maximization is misaligned with social value maximization, because
profit maximization does not consider all the external effects. In
such instances, public service provision is potentially better than
private provision. But there is no guarantee that the public sector
will do a better job, because it faces its own set of challenges. We
turn to these next.
8.4 THE COSTS OF BUREAUCRACY
Not many good things are said about bureaucracy. The very word
“bureaucracy” has a negative connotation, conjuring up images
of slow and unresponsive public offices, wading in red-tape and
lacking initiative.
There are two reasons why the public sector is so bureaucratic.
The first reason relates to a problem that has been addressed
by many great political scholars: A government that is powerful
enough to protect the rights of its citizens is also powerful enough to
142
·
The Nordic Model
High-powered performance incentives
can be counter-productive, if they emphasize what can be
measured rather than
what really matters for
valuable outcomes
Public service provision is potentially better than private provision – but faces its
own challenges
The government has
exceptional rights and
powers – and the citizen has few options
to exit
The tasks handed
to the public sector
serve complex social
objectives
take these rights away. Because government has exceptional rights
it has to be exceptionally careful not to abuse these rights. Trust
and credibility are invaluable for the government. Without rules
and constraints government officials could cause unspeakable damage to credibility. A firm, conscious of its reputation, encounters
similar problems, more so the larger the firm is. This is one reason
large firms become more bureaucratic. Yet, there is a big difference
between the government and firms: Citizens have few options to
exit, while the power of firms is held in check by voluntary trade.
As a result, firms are much freer to use subjective judgment and
exercise its powers and authority in a discretionary manner. The
government has to fetter the hands of its bureaus and agencies to
a much larger extent, because of concerns for legitimacy.
The first problem is compounded by a second problem: the
fact that the public sector tends to get assigned tasks which the
competitive market has difficulties handling.8 When profit maximization is misaligned with social welfare maximization, it usually
means that performance measures reflecting the full social value
of a service are missing. The government, when it takes over such
services, will therefore have to deal with a much fuzzier set of
objectives and poorer accountability. Government agencies are
hard to govern, because they are guided by missions, the success
of which is difficult to measure.9
There are two responses to lack of good performance measures.
One is to use weak incentives and rely on employees’ intrinsic
motivations as just discussed. Relying on intrinsic motivation is
not enough, however, because private motivations do not necessarily align with the public interest in every dimension. Passionate
teachers are usually not passionate about saving costs. The second
response is to use bureaucratic procedures to guide behavior.
Line-item budgets for public agencies are a manifestation of this
principle. It may seem bizarre that an agency cannot spend excess
funds in one account, say office supplies, for something useful
like buying better teaching equipment. Line-item budgeting appears very wasteful since it foregoes opportunities to improve a
service. But in an environment where it is very difficult to judge
how much money is needed for various activities, making funds
less fungible and using incremental budgeting procedures (rather
The proper scope of the public sector
·
143
than zero based budgeting) are imperfect ways of acquiring such
information over time.
Consumers of a public service often have no other choice, either because no private service is available (as in the case of primary
education in Finland) or because private services are expensive (as
in the case of private health care). The alternative is to use voice
when one is dissatisfied. But complaints often get a tepid response.
There is a rational reason for this, too. Unlike exit, where one has
to give up something, voice is cheap and prone to be overused,
especially when the service is free. Red-tape limits excessive use
of voice.10 It reduces illegitimate claims, but unfortunately also
legitimate claims. As a result, public agencies have a harder time
responding to consumer needs and react to new concerns as well
as opportunities.
We have spent time on the problems of public bureaucracy
because it is essential to understand the reasons why the public
sector operates under very different incentives than the private
sector. Any reforms of the public sector, including increased reliance on private sector services, will have to take into consideration
the special nature of public sector accountability. Those who think
one can readily make the internal workings of the public sector
more efficient by strengthening employee incentives, giving them
more authority and slashing bureaucracy, are likely to be disappointed with the results. One can certainly do better, but the fact
that public bureaucracy is driven by missions and a deep concern
for public legitimacy, without direct parallels in the private sector,
suggests that a different approach is needed and that the gains will
be more limited.
To illustrate this point, consider the use of information technology. As reported in chapter 3, IT has been the main driver
behind the large increases in private sector productivity over the
past fifteen years, especially in the U.S. and the Nordic countries.
Even the service sector, which traditionally has experienced slow
productivity growth, has been enjoying a remarkable resurgence.
New business models have created highly efficient chains like WalMart, which today employs close to two million workers globally.
Controlling the logistics and the labour force in a firm of this size
would be unthinkable without IT.11
144
·
The Nordic Model
Unlike exit, voice is
cheap and prone to
be overused
The public sector operates under very different incentives and
requirements than
the private sector, and
this should be taken
into account when assessing the scope for
potential efficiency increases
With this kind of productivity growth in the private sector, the
prospects for similar gains in the public sector would seem good.
However, investments in IT alone are far from enough. IT is merely
a technological enabler. To improve productivity, firms have to
make complementary investments in human capital and changed
work practices of the order of three to five times the investments
in IT.12 What is especially troublesome from the public sector’s
perspective is that the changes in work practices that are essential include higher work autonomy and more powerful financial
incentives (usually for teams of workers). Given the problems of
accountability in the public sector and the bureaucracy built to deal
with them, it is going to be hard to change the whole system. Yet,
if these complementary investments are not made, the evidence
from the private sector shows that returns from IT investments
are often minimal, even negative.13
8.5 THE FUTURE OF PUBLIC SERVICES –
LEVERAGING THE PRIVATE SECTOR
Increase the reliance
on privately supplied
services, but keep
control of the “core”
activities of the public
sector
The private sector
is already providing
a significant part of
the services financed
by the public sector,
and the private sector
could do more
Because of the inevitable burdens of public bureaucracy, the best
way to raise public sector productivity is often to look for ways to
“leverage” the private sector without compromising the government’s broader social objectives. This means increasing the reliance on privately supplied services, while keeping “core activities”
under government control. The strategy is similar to outsourcing
within the private sector and some of the lessons learned there
can be useful. But as always, one should be careful about imitating private business models without checking how well their logic
fits the public context. The core activities of the public sector are
obviously very different from those in the private sector.
Many OECD countries, including the Nordic countries, are
already relying heavily on the private sector for part of government financed services. Figure 8.1 shows the central governments’
purchases of all goods and services from outside vendors as a
proportion of total expenditures, excluding transfers and interest
payments. The Nordic countries, with their large government
The proper scope of the public sector
·
145
sectors, place at or above the median of the sample, which reveals
considerable variation across countries. Unfortunately, the figure
does not include local government expenditures. The role of private sector services has grown especially fast in local government
where budget pressures have been most acute.
The purpose of engaging the private sector is to bring in more
competition. The hoped for benefits from competition include better allocation of resources, lower cost of service, higher quality of
service, more innovation and new business models – in short, all the
virtues of competition we discussed earlier. However, these benefits
will necessarily be limited by the government’s need to retain control so that its broader missions can be achieved and its legitimacy
preserved. Many bureaucratic rules will continue to apply in the
relationship between the private sector and the government. For
instance, while a firm is free to choose whichever private service
provider it wants based on whatever criteria it chooses, including
very subjective ones, the government has to rely on transparent,
Portugal
Italy
France
Spain
Ireland
Belgium
Luxembourg
Austria
Denmark
Canada
Germany
Iceland
Netherlands
Finland
Australia
New Zealand
Sweden
Switzerland
Norway
United States
United Kingdom
0
10
20
30
Figure 8.1
Outsourcing of government services, 2001
Purchase of goods and services vs. in-house provision.
Source: OECD Secretariat calculations based on GFS Data.
146
·
The Nordic Model
40
50
60
70
80 %
There are a lot of potential benefits from
competition, but
these will be limited
by the government’s
need to retain control
of its broader mission
objective, egalitarian criteria when it selects suppliers. Equal access
to services is often imposed as well. This means that the cost of
government services will be higher than in the private sector even
when the government employs private vendors.14
There are four main ways in which the government can use
the private sector: (a) Outsourcing, (b) Private-Public Partnerships
(PPPs), (c) Privatization (with regulation) and (d) Vouchers. The
categories overlap somewhat. For instance, PPPs are a variant of
outsourcing and may simply be classified as such. The order in
the classification above reflects roughly decreasing government
control. In outsourcing the government retains the most control,
while privatization and voucher systems give private enterprises
significantly more freedom.
We will not take up regulation here. It is a large subject in its
own right and leads to somewhat different considerations, since it
usually deals with monopoly problems. Instead, we want to make
some observations about the three other forms of private sector
engagement, where the idea is to make use of competition.
Outsourcing of government services is
important and increasing fast
a. Outsourcing
In outsourcing, one or more service suppliers are selected through
competitive bidding, which is repeated when the contract comes
to an end. Bidding is essential, because of the special demands for
government accountability. For the same reason, the bid price is
almost exclusively used to choose the winner – concerns about
service quality and other requirements have to be dealt with
through detailed contract terms. Subjective information regarding vendor performance cannot be used much, which reduces the
vendor’s incentive to invest in reputation and further increases the
need for explicit requirements. Contract terms often spell out not
just what should be produced, but also how it should be produced.
The bureaucratic hand of government is very much present even
when a service is outsourced.
Outsourcing has been the fastest growing category for government spending on private goods and services. A very rough estimate
of the size of central government outsourcing can be obtained by
reducing the numbers in figure 8.1, by 10–15 percentage points.
Outsourcing is clearly the largest private expenditure category.
The proper scope of the public sector
·
147
The demands for objectivity limit what the government can
efficiently outsource. Yet, all sorts of outsourcing services have
been tried by now. It is useful to distinguish between two sub-categories: (i) Maintenance and administrative services that do not
directly involve consumers, ranging from cleaning and security to
IT administration and other back-office support; (ii) Consumer
services, ranging from garbage collection to complex services such
as health and elderly care. Apart for protests by affected workers,
the maintenance and administrative services raise few controversies, because they are non-core government activities. Outsourcing
of consumer services faces harder trade-offs, because this is where
private and public interests will conflict.
The collective evidence, which by now is extensive, indicates
that outsourcing leads to significant efficiency gains on average.
The estimates in individual studies vary widely, depending on how
narrow the studies are and also on the biases of those reporting.
The clearest and most significant evidence concerns cost savings.
In a study of over 2000 outsourcing initiatives in the U.S., the
average cost savings were above 30 per cent; UK and Australian
studies show cost savings in the 15–20 per cent range; Sweden’s
highway agency saw procurement costs drop by 25 per cent thanks
to competitive bidding; in Finland outsourcing of the public
transportation system in Helsinki saved around 30 per cent.15 It is
likely that these estimates overstate the savings, because the studies rarely include the transition and transactions costs associated
with outsourcing. On the other hand, few if any studies appear
to consider the increased efficiency of government services that
remain in-house but feel the competitive pressures of the private
sector indirectly. Irrespective of the balance between the omitted
benefits and costs, it is clear that the overall cost savings from
outsourcing have been large.
Weakening of quality, which is a potential concern with private
services, has been less of a problem than one might have expected.
The general experience is that the quality of service stays the same
or improves under outsourcing. Nevertheless, there have also been
major problems. In the U.S. sub-standard service at nursing homes
has made headlines. Recently, The New York Times conducted a
major study that showed that when private equity owners merged
148
·
The Nordic Model
The possibilities for
and the potential benefits of outsourcing
of services differ from
case to case
While challenging,
outsourcing makes it
possible to enhance
efficiency significantly
Quality is a source of
concern but is, on balance, not undermined
by outsourcing
Competition is key,
specifics of services
are essential, and outsourcing should be
accompanied by clear
goals and performance measures
small nursing homes into large chains, profits went up at the expense of much lower service. On virtually all indicators of service,
the chains performed below the national average and in some cases
were in gross violation of legal standards.
Health care services seem to be less prone to quality shading.
In a large study of British emergency hospitals strong performance incentives caused dramatic improvements in waiting times
without any noticeable adverse effects on treatment.16 In Finland,
local governments have rapidly outsourced ambulatory physician
services to private companies. The private firms can take advantage of economies of scale by servicing large areas covering many
local governments. So far, both cost and quality have improved
at MedOne, the largest of the private suppliers, with throughput
per euro increasing an estimated 20 per cent and patient as well
as worker satisfaction ratings up.17
What lessons can be drawn from the outsourcing experiences
to date?
The biggest lesson is that competition is the key to improved
performance. It does not necessarily matter whether the bidding
for a service is won by a private firm or a public agency. This was
the finding in a study of outsourced garbage collection, where both
private and public sector vendors got contracts.18 A vendor that
has a captive client is not going to be efficiently run. A vendor
facing competition will be pressed to lower prices and mostly to
higher quality as well.
In evaluating the evidence on quality, it has to be kept in mind
that the choice of outsourced services is not random. The choices
have been made considering the potential for the net benefits.
Initially, non-core services and the more mundane core services
were outsourced. As the outsourcing movement has gathered pace
and expanded deeper into the core activities of the government
– public security, emergency services, schools, even prisons and
military combat – the experiences have tended to become more
variable.
A second lesson, not illustrated by this quick review, but evident in the many case accounts, is that every outsourcing case has
unique features requiring great attention to detail. For instance, the
length of the service contract involves trade-offs that need to be
The proper scope of the public sector
·
149
assessed case by case. The importance of design details is corroborated by experience from incentive designs both in the private and
the public sector. It is impossible to foresee all future contingencies
and the many ways in which creative, profit driven parties can
exploit omissions and mistakes in contracts. Moreover, there is a
fundamental imbalance between the weak financial incentives of
government agents and the strong financial incentives of private
firms, which is always going to warrant consideration.
The third lesson is that outsourcing does require clearly
defined goals and carefully chosen performance measures. Investments in better auditing systems, especially by independent
parties, can have high payoffs. It is conceivable that accounting
practices within some sectors of government could be changed to
serve the specific requirements of outsourcing and other kinds of
private sector engagements. With better performance measures
one can rely less on how a service is carried out and more on what
the results are. This will increase the autonomy and initiative of
the service provider.
b. Public and Private sector Partnerships
Public and Private sector Partnerships (PPPs) are a more recent
phenomenon. They got started in earnest after Prime Minister John
Major’s Public Finance Initiative in the U.K. in 1992. The PPP
label may suggest a variety of jointly arranged services between
the government and the private sector, but the label refers to a
particular variant of outsourcing. PPPs are governance structures
where a consortium of private investors sets up a company to finance, plan, build, maintain and operate a piece of infrastructure
such as a hospital, a school, an airport, a highway, or a railroad.
The company does not deal with the patients in the hospital or
teach the students in the school. The sole purpose is to handle the
infrastructure. The hope is that by putting all the stages of a big
infrastructure project under the responsibility of the same entity,
better incentives are created for coordinating the various stages of
the project and undertaking each in a way that takes into account
both short and long-run effects. Also, by moving the financial
responsibility of the project to private investors, the thought is
that risk will be carried by the parties that are in the best position
to monitor and manage those risks.
150
·
The Nordic Model
PPPs amount to a
particular variant of
outsourcing to the
private sector, used
notably in the area of
infrastructures
PPPs are not a panacea – the contractual
challenges are big and
many have failed
PPPs have received disproportionate attention in the press.
They are not that widely used yet. Even in the U.K., which has
the most extensive experience, PPPs only count for 10 per cent of
government spending on outside services. PPPs are not meant for
small or ongoing services that are regularly put up for bid. They are
tailored for large scale projects that have a long duration – typically around 20 years – with assets expected to be turned back to
the government at the end of the term. Because they are one-off
projects, even more thought has to go into performance clauses
and rules for termination.
Some of the projects have fared badly and caused public
uproar. The privatization of the U.K. railway infrastructure assets
is the most noted failure. In 1994, an investor owned company,
Railtrack, took control of all government owned railway infrastructure assets in the U.K. In 2002 after a tormented relationship
with the government and the public, Railtrack was forced into
liquidation. A string of accidents, some fatal, appeared to be the
result of insufficient investments in maintenance at the same time
as generous dividend payments were made to the shareholders; a
prime example of quality shading.
Interestingly, the assets were subsequently sold to another
private company, Network Rail Infrastructure, a “not for dividend”
company similar to a mutual company. It is run expressly in the
interest of its stakeholders: the government, the regional railroad
operators, and the communities that it serves. The structure is
complicated, but the new entity is enjoying a much higher credibility with the public and better operating performance.
There are also many successful PPP implementations. In Denmark, the community Solröd used a PPP structure to build a string
of new schools (financed by public money, presumably because
of uncertainty about revenues). The Norwegian government has
employed PPPs for large highway projects, using tolls and rental
payments from the government as a stable income stream. Success
again seems to rest on careful planning to ensure cooperation between the public and private parties including arbitration schemes
to prevent problems from getting out of hands. Failure versus success seems to hinge critically on having realistic expectations and
foreseeing potential trouble spots in advance. This may explain
why PPPs have not been employed more extensively.
The proper scope of the public sector
·
151
c. Vouchers
Vouchers are issued by a central or a local government to consumers so that they can pay for a service that the government
wants to subsidize. A voucher is a generic term that covers all
types of subsidies channeled directly or indirectly through the
consumer. Vouchers are always issued for a specific purpose. They
are non-tradable and may be means-tested or cover only part of
the service cost.
The purpose of vouchers is to give consumers a choice among
various service options, that is, free them from being captive by
giving them an exit option. Vouchers combine a concern for equity with the allocational and productive efficiencies that come
from letting consumers express their own preferences and having
service providers compete for their business. For some services
it makes less sense to let consumers choose, because they are
in a poor position to judge which service provider is best. For
instance, in garbage collection or local transportation it may be
efficient to have one service supplier, in which case having the
government ensure competition by putting the service up for bid
makes more sense.
Vouchers are extensively used in the OECD to subsidize consumer driven services like health care, child care, elderly care and
schooling. In the Nordic countries, vouchers play a smaller role,
because so many services are government supplied. The health care
sector is probably the heaviest user of vouchers, though people do
not recognize the subsidies under that name. The Nordic health
care systems are a complicated mix of public and private supply
with physicians often working for both sectors. In Finland, basic
health services are essentially free, but private services are also
heavily subsidized. Screening via differentiated subsidies is also
practiced by private health insurers, for instance in the U.S. It can
be rationalized as an efficient way to regulate the consumption of
services and to steer people towards cheaper services where appropriate. Those who want more or better health services have to
prove it through a higher co-payment.
Vouchers are also used in the care for the elderly, but not in
a major way. The fraction of private nursing homes in Finland is
the lowest within OECD. The rest of the Nordics are also at the
152
·
The Nordic Model
Vouchers reconcile
choice and competition with social
objectives
There is scope for
more private supply
and vouchers in the
area of care
tail end. Vouchers are allowed to be used for expenses incurred by
a family that cares for its own and for private attendants. Both are
laudable options, because they give consumers a choice.
We do not have statistics for child care, but anecdotal evidence suggests that the same pattern prevails. Private childcare is
available, but since the 1970s the public sector (mainly through
local governments) has established a very dominant position. This
might be efficient if there were concerns about quality or if parents
could not be trusted to choose proper care. Since there seems to
be little evidence that this is the case, childcare but also elderly
care are areas in which there is scope for substantially increased
private sector involvement.
Economists like vouchers, because they have good efficiency
properties both in terms of determining individual levels of service
consumption as well as the allocation of services across providers.
For the same reason, they like fees for publicly provided services.
A service that is free will be over-consumed or be inefficiently paid
through rationing and queues. However, the public is much more
accepting of co-payments for private services than they are of fees
for publicly provided services. There may be a presumption that
private services can cost money, but public services should be free,
because they have already been paid for through taxes. A more
sinister interpretation is that low fees foster higher use of public
services at the expense of private services. The benevolent interpretation is that some services should be available for everybody
at no cost, because it is equitable – service provision is part of the
collective insurance system. This is a defensible position if one is
careful about which services deserve such heavy subsidies. Health
care and primary schooling are good candidates, because they are
essential for all. But providing higher education for free seems like
a very costly, even unfair subsidy, in a case where consumers clearly
have very different preferences. A public good argument also works
much better for primary than tertiary schooling.
Our intention is not to argue strongly for or against fees for
particular services. Our point is simply that low or no fees for
public services, in an economy where half of GDP is spent on the
public sector are unlikely to be optimal or easy to defend on equity
grounds. This is an issue that should not be shunned or treated
The proper scope of the public sector
·
153
mechanically in the political debate over the proper scope of
government. The Nordic countries will almost surely have to restructure parts of their social safety net to make room for expected
increases in expenditures induced by changed demographics. In
preparation for this, it is good to begin to review the fee structure
for public services already now.
8.6 CONCLUSION
In this chapter we have provided an economic framework for
thinking about the proper scope of government that should help
in assessing some of the main trade-offs involved in deciding what
the public sector should be involved in and how it should adjust
to changed circumstances. The chapter is short on specific advice,
partly because decisions are complicated and require more detailed
analysis and partly because they involve value judgments. But there
are some important messages nevertheless.
· The public sectors in the Nordic countries are large because of the high share of publicly provided services and
the extensive use of transfer schemes. Increasing the efficiency of public services is an essential element in alleviating expected future fiscal pressures.
· Efficiency gains can be obtained by streamlining internal
work processes, changing organizational structures, making
better use of new technologies and retraining public servants. But there are limits to how much can be achieved
this way, because public bureaucracy is to a large extent
purposeful rather than the result of poor design, inattention or indifference. Trying to emulate the strong incentives for initiative and innovation that characterize vibrant competitive markets would not only be impossible,
but also misguided. Low-powered incentives fit the particular tasks that the public sector should handle – activities where the pursuit of profit is sufficiently misaligned
with the pursuit of social welfare (including important
equity goals).
154
·
The Nordic Model
·
·
·
Because the public sector is charged to deal with diffuse and difficult tasks, it is expensive. Where possible, the
public sector should exploit the allocational and productive efficiencies inherent in private organizations. Given
the size of the Nordic public sector services, this is where
the greatest opportunities for raising the productivity of
the public sector lies.
The experiences from outsourcing, privatization, the use of
vouchers and various other forms of public and private
sector cooperation have been mostly positive. Significant
cost savings with the same level or higher service quality
have been achieved. The most important driver of value
is the introduction of competition, because it gives consumers and procurement officers new choices.
The Nordic countries do not appear to benefit less or more
from outsourcing public services than other countries. One
might have speculated that the high quality of the public
labor force in the Nordic countries would be especially
well suited for outsourcing, resulting in higher returns
than elsewhere. Or one might have thought that the
quality of public services is already so high that outsourcing
gains would be small. The empirical evidence does not
seem to show any consistent patterns one way or the other,
though the evidence we have seen is very limited.
The proper scope of the public sector
·
155
ENDNOTES
1
The private sector includes of course non-profit maximizing enterprises such as cooperatives
and not-for-profits, but the bulk of private sector activity occurs within profit maximizing enterprises.
2
See Holmström (1999) for more on this perspective on the firm.
3
In the modern theory of the firm, the main reason why a division within a firm may be spun
out into a separate firm is that as an independent firm, the division will have stronger incentives
to pursue profit. The cost is that this will forego from coordination, because the independent division will have a narrower objective. See Hart (1995).
4
See Rotschild and Stiglitz (1976).
5
The government does not appear to have an advantage in handling moral hazard problems,
another manifestation of asymmetric information.
6
See Hart et al (1997) and Holmstrom and Milgrom (1991).
7
There is evidence showing that U.S. primary school teachers that are rewarded based on
how their students perform on standardized tests, tend to bias their teaching and some of them
will even resort to cheating.
8
Prendergast (2003).
9
Tirole (1994) emphasis and provides further discussion on the role of missions. See also Dixit
(1996) on low-powered incentives in bureaucracies.
10
Prendergast (2003).
11
Wal-Mart’s share of the U.S. retail sector’s productivity gains, directly and indirectly, has been
estimated to be around 25 per cent.
12
Brynjolfsson and Hitt (2000).
13
Finland has just embarked on an ambitious and important initiative to reform its higher education system. Universities will become free-standing foundations rather than government bureaus. Each will have an outside board of trustees that will guarantee university presidents and
their administrations much more autonomy to raise and spend funds. Many governance details
remain to be decided. One of the most important ones is to introduce a new strong evaluation
system, which will provide reliable, independent information about the quality of research and
teaching. The U.K. introduced such a system some years back and it has had a strong effect on the
allocation of government funds across universities as well as fields and spurred healthy competition that had been missing.
This example illustrates that with decisive action on the highest political and administrative levels, the government can reorganize itself also internally by strengthening incentives and reducing
bureaucracy.
14
However, the government’s benefits from moving a service to a private provider may be
higher or lower depending on circumstances. It is surprising that few comparisons between private and public sector savings from outsourcing have been done.
15
See OECD (2005), Sjöström et al. (2006) and Jensen and Stonecash (2005) for more details on
the evidence.
16
Kelman and Friedman (2007).
17
Interview with Anssi Soila, director of MedOne.
18
Jensen and Stonecash (2005).
156
·
The Nordic Model
9
Our purpose is to
identify challenges,
discuss trade-offs, reject false solutions
and indicate directions for reform
GUIDELINES FOR REFORM
The purpose of this report is not to praise the Nordic model, even
though we find that it has important strengths and has performed
reasonably well. Nor is the purpose to preach doom and gloom
unless a specific set of policy recommendations is implemented.
The ambition is more modest but no less useful:
· to identify and explain the nature of some main challenges
faced by the Nordic countries (along with other countries)
and to shed light on the trade-offs involved;
· to explain why many of the “solutions” suggested in public
debate are based on erroneous reasoning or are unrealistic;
and
· to indicate directions or areas in which new thinking and
policy reforms are called for in the Nordic countries, and
notably in Finland.
In other words, the report assesses the need and directions
for reform so as to safeguard the key features of the Nordic model
in the face of new challenges – notably those of the demographic
transition. By the key features we refer to openness to globalization
and risk sharing. Broadly stated, we believe that reform should
build on the strengths of the model and focus on proposals that
improve work incentives while maintaining the essential elements
of collective risk sharing.
Guidelines for reform
·
157
The biggest hurdle to overcome for policy reform is neither the
lack of options for addressing the problems, nor some intrinsic fault
of the Nordic model itself. The biggest difficulty is our complacency
– understandable enough in the light of past successes. Economic
developments have been favourable for many years. Also, the
problems associated with ageing populations will materialize fully
only after a time interval measured in decades rather than years.
It is extremely difficult to engineer the political will for courageous
actions that address problems which are not acute, but far in the
future – and yet, one generation is a short time span for society
and its welfare policies.
The virtue of the Nordic model is its ability to reconcile risks
and uncertainties with openness and the market economy. This
unique “third way” of the Nordics has two tracks: an open and
well-functioning market economy, combined with a large public
sector that has wide ranging responsibilities. However, globalization, a rapidly ageing population and the Nordic welfare state is a
challenging triangle. What has worked well in the past, is unlikely
to be good enough in the future.
There are at least three areas that call for new thinking and
decisive reforms.
First, the changing demographics underline the need to reduce
benefit dependency and raise employment rates:
· the young should start their working careers earlier; the
average time spent in tertiary education is excessively long
(e.g., tuition fees might be helpful);
· changes in labour demand require educational institutions
to adjust and call for an enhanced role for employers in designing on-the-job training schemes; also, specific programmes and effective workfare elements can be used to
prevent e.g. school dropouts and immigrants from becoming marginalized;
· pension and tax policies should encourage the elderly to
prolong their working careers through weaker incentives
for early retirement, by indexing the pension system to
longevity, and by offering a more favourable treatment for
the wage income of working pensioners;
158
·
The Nordic Model
The biggest hurdle to
reform is complacency
The Nordics have their
own version of the
“third way”
Globalization, an ageing population and a
large welfare state: a
demanding triangle
Reduce benefit
dependency and
work more
there is a case for discarding arrangements that de facto
subsidize leisure at the expense of work (such as the sabbatical leave in Finland);
· there is a need to match better the demand and supply of
labour regionally and occupationally; labor mobility can be
supported by more stringent limits on unemployment benefits (duration, workfare elements) and financial incentives to relocate;
· decentralized wage formation may improve matching
and the functioning of the labour market in general as
well as contribute to a better personnel policy (an area in
which Finland could emulate “best practices” in Sweden
and Denmark); and
· immigration policy should take into account the needs of
the economy with the aim to achieve a high rate of labour
market attachment of immigrants.
Second, the impending spending pressure calls for actions that
define the core activities of the welfare state, set limits for what the
government is responsible for and enhance the efficiency of public
services:
· a ceiling on overall pension contributions (moving decisively towards a defined contribution system) could usefully be specified and measures enacted to ensure that
pension costs allow the ceiling to be respected;
· the efficiency of public services can be enhanced by introducing competition via selective outsourcing of services
and use of vouchers and customer fees.
· one should clarify the scope and need for complementary
private solutions, so that citizens have a clear understanding of what they can expect in the areas of publicly provided health and old-age care.
Third, and this is an overarching principle, society should
have high ambitions with regard to investment in human capital and
skills of the young. Changing demographics will increasingly lead to
conflicts of interest between the old and the young, for instance,
when central and local budgets are decided. There is a risk that
the many (the old) will outvote the few (the young), which could
imply policies that do not cater for the future appropriately. Invest·
Cap the welfare state
and enhance efficiency
Give priority to the
young and investment
in the future
Guidelines for reform
·
159
ment has a higher return when spent on the young. A society can
remain healthy and vital only if it ensures that the young generation
is well-educated and prepared to take on future challenges. This
broad principle should guide policy choices in a number of areas:
· we should invest more in education, particularly at the
university level (both education and research);
· social protection should pay due attention to the needs
of families with children (safeguarding good quality day
care facilities and parental leaves); and
· the relative tax burden of the young could be eased by
shifting the tax structure from taxes on wage income
towards consumption and real estate taxes (which is also
in tune with the requirements of globalization).
The bottom line
Institutions should be reassessed, while some values underlying the
Nordic model need to be reiterated. For instance, the rationale for
legislative protection of employment is certainly much weaker in
today’s era of comprehensive social security and unemployment
benefits. Similarly, collective wage bargaining made sense when
inflation rates were high and uncertain and macroeconomic policies lacked credibility, but we now live in a very different world.
The Nordic model will in coming years be facing the most
stringent political test of its lifetime. It was established in favourable
demographic circumstances. When the first welfare services were
introduced and the first pension systems established, the reforms
created many more winners than losers. The political mobilisation for the welfare state, in particular within the powerful Nordic
labour movement, has accordingly been articulated as a win-win
struggle for the “rights” of workers and all citizens. Such a political
discourse continues to permeate today’s electoral debates, in which
it is far easier for candidates to promise further entitlements than
to remind the electorate of the dynamic budget constraints or of
the looming demographic challenge.
Given the worrying demographic prospects, many of the reforms will create both winners and losers. Responsible politicians
will have to understand and acknowledge that it is largely the same
people who enjoy the benefits of entitlements and who finance
160
·
The Nordic Model
A time for reassessment of institutions
and reiteration of
values
We will have to work
more
their increasing costs. There is no unused reserve of resources
that can be tapped – nor is there some unexploited tax base that
could generate significant financial leeway. The resources that are
needed will have to be generated through productive activity; we
cannot afford free-riders.
People have to work more – start their working careers earlier,
work more hours on average, and retire later. The Nordic countries are not doomed to stagnation, financial deficits or rising tax
rates. The Nordic model can be defended and upheld – but only
through reforming its institutions and policies while reiterating its
commitment to a proper balance between the entitlements and
responsibilities of its citizens.
Guidelines for reform
·
161
REFERENCES
Adema, W. and Ladaique, M. (2005): Net Social Expenditures, 2005 Edition, More Comprehensive
Measures of Social Support, OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Paper 29, Paris.
Agell, J. (2002): On the Determinants of Labour Market Institutions: Rent Seeking vs Social Insurance, German Economic Review 3(2), pp. 107–135.
Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (2005): “Appropriate Growth Policy: A Unifying Framework”, mimeographed, Harvard University.
Alesina, A., Ardagna, S., Nicoletti, G. and Sciantarelli, F. (2005): Regulation and Investment, Journal
of European Economic Association, 3, pp. 791–825.
Alesina, A. and Rodrik, D. (1994): Distributive Politics and Economic Growth, The Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 109, pp. 405–490.
Andersen, T.M. and Pedersen, L.H. (2006): Financial Restraint in a mature welfare state – the case
of Denmark, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 22(3), pp. 313–329.
Andersen, T.M. and Svarer, M. (2007): Flexicurity – Labour Market Performance in Denmark, CESifo
Working Paper Series No. 2108.
Baldwin, R. (2006): Globalisation: the great unbundling(s), Prime Minister’s Office, Economic Council of Finland, Helsinki.
Bergh, A. (2006): Explaining Welfare State Survival: The Role of Economic Freedom and Globalization, Ratio Working Papers No. 101.
Bergström, V. (2007): Rättvisa, solidaritet och anpassning. Landsorganisationens ekonomiska politik under fem årtionden. Atlas.
Blundell, R.W. and MaCurdy, T. (1999): Labor Supply: A Review of Alternative Approaches, in Ashenfelter, O. and Card, D. (eds.): Handbook of Labor Economics, vol 3A, Elsevier Science, Amsterdam.
Brynjolfsson, E. and Hitt, L. (2000): Beyond Computation: Information Technology, Organizational
Transformation and Business Performance, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 14, No. 4, pp.
23–48.
Böckerman, P. and Uusitalo, R. (2006): Erosion of the Ghent System and Union Membership Decline: Lessons from Finland. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 44:2, pp. 283–303, June 2006.
Cahuc, P. and Zylberberg, A. (2004): Labor Economics. The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Calmfors, L. and Driffill, J. (1988): Bargaining Structure, Corporatism and Macroeconomic Performance, Economic Policy 6, pp. 13–61.
Carone, G. (2005): Long-Term Labour Force Projections for the 25 EU Member States: A Set of Data
for Assessing the Economic Impact of Ageing, European Commission, Economic Paper No. 235.
The Conference Board and Groningen Growth and Development Centre, Total Economy Database, 2007, January.
Conway, P., Janod, V. and Nicoletti, G. (2005): Product Market Regulation in OECD Countries 1998
to 2003, OECD Economics Department Working Paper, no. 419.
Corak, M. (2006): Do Poor Children Become Poor Adults? Lessons from a Cross Country Comparison of Generational Earnings Mobility, Research on Economic Inequality, 13 (1), pp. 143–188.
Dantas, C., Rosa, M. and Raade, K. (2006): Profitability of Venture Capital Investment in Europe and
the United States, European Commission, Economic Paper No 245.
de Serres, A., Kobayakawa, S., Slök, T. and Vartia, L. (2006): Regulation of financial systems and economic growth, Economics Department Working Papers No. 506.
162
·
The Nordic Model
Dickens, W.T., Götte, L., Groshen, E.L., Holden, S., Messina, J., Schwitzer, M.E., Turunen, J. and
Ward, M.E. (2006): “How wages change? – micro evidence from the international wage flexibility
project”, European Central Bank Working Paper 697, November 2006.
Dixit, A. (1996): The Making of Economic Policy: A Transactions Cost Politics Perspective. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Edin, P.-A., Holmlund, B. and Skans, O. (2007): Wage Dispersion Between and Within Plants, NBER
Working Paper 13021, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
EEAG (2006): The EEAG Report on the European Economy 2006, European Economic Advisory
Group at CESifo.
EEAG (2007): The EEAG Report on the European Economy 2007, European Economic Advisory
Group at CESifo.
Eissa, N. and Liebman, J. (1996): Labor Supply Response to the Earned Income Tax Credit. Quarterly Journal of Economics 61 (1996), pp. 605–637.
European Commission (2006): The long-term sustainability of public finances in the European Union, European Economy, no 4.
Forslund, A. and Holmlund, B. (2003): Arbetslöshet och arbetsmarknadspolitik. IFAU (Institutet för
Arbetsmarknadspolitisk Utvärdering), Rapport 2003:6.
Fredriksson, P. and Holmlund, B. (2006): Improving Incentives in Unemployment Insurance: A Review of Recent Research, Journal of Economic Surveys 20:3, pp. 357–386.
Fredriksson, P. and Johansson, P. (2003): Employment, Mobility and Active Labor Market Programs.
IFAU – Institute for Labour Market Policy Evaluation Working Paper 2003:3.
Hart, O. (1995): Firms, Contracts and Financial Structure. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hart, O., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1997): The Proper Scope of Government: Theory and Application to Prisons, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112: pp. 1127–1161.
Hartog, J. and Teulings, C. (1998): Corporatism or Competition? Cambridge University Press.
Heyman, F. (2005): Pay inequality and Firm Performance: Evidence from Matched Employer-Employee Data, FIEF Working Paper 186, Stockholm.
Hirschman, A.O. (1970): Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and
States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Holden, S. (2005): Monetary regimes and the co-ordination of wage setting”. European Economic
Review 49, pp. 833–843.
Holden, S. and Wulfsberg, F. (2007): How strong is the macroeconomic case for downward real
wage rigidity? Manuscript, 22 October 2007 (http://folk.uio.no/sholden/DRWR.pdf ).
Holmström, B. and Milgrom, P. (1991): Multitask Principal Agent Analysis, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 7: pp. 24–52.
Holmström, B. (1999): The Firm as a Subeconomy, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization,
15 (1), pp. 74–102.
Honkapohja, S., Koskela, E., Leibfritz, W. and Uusitalo, R. (2008): Economic Prosperity Recaptured:
The Finnish Path from Crisis to Fast Growth, MIT Press, forthcoming.
Hujanen, T., Pekurinen, M. and Häkkinen, U. (2006): Terveydenhuollon ja vanhustenhuollon alueellinen tarve ja menot 1993–2004, Työpapereita 11/2006, Stakes.
Jensen, P.H and Stonecash, R.E. (2005): Incentives and the Efficiency of Public Sector – Outsourcing Contracts, Journal of Economic Surveys, 19 (5), pp. 767–787.
Guidelines for reform
·
163
Jonung, L. and Hagberg, T. (2005): How Costly Was the Crisis of the 1990s? A Comparative Analysis
of the Deepest Crises in Finland and Sweden over the Last 130 Years, European Commission Economic Papers, No. 224, March 2005.
Jorgenson, D. and Griliches, Z. (1967): The Explanation of Productivity Change, Review of Economic Studies, 34, pp. 249–283.
Kelman, S. and Friedman, J.N. (2007): Performance Improvement and Performance Dysfunction:
An Empirical Examination of Impacts of the Emergency Room Wait-Time Target in the English National Health Service, RWP07-034, Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University.
Kleven, H.J. and Kreiner, C.T. (2006): The marginal cost of public funds: hours of work versus labour
force participation, CEPR Discussion Paper Series No. 5594.
Konjunkturinstitutet: Konjunkturläget, December 2006.
Konjunkturinstitutet: Lönebildningsrapporten 2006.
Konjunkturinstitutet: Lönebildningsrapporten 2007.
Korkman, S., Lassila, J., Määttänen, N. and Valkonen, T. (2007): Hyvinvointivaltion rahoitus – Riittävätkö rahat, kuka maksaa? Elinkeinoelämän Tutkimuslaitos, B230, Taloustieto Oy.
Lindbeck, A. (2006): The Welfare State – Background, Achievements, Problems, Research Institute
of Industrial Economics, Working paper No. 662, Stockholm.
Lundborg, P. (2005): Individual Wage Setting, Efficiency Wages and Productivity in Sweden, FIEF
Working Paper 205, Stockholm.
Maddison, A. (1995): The World Economy, 1820–1992. OECD, Paris.
Mahler, V. and Jesuit, D. (2006) : Fiscal redistribution in the developed countries: new insights from
the Luxembourg Income Study, Socio-economic Review, pp. 483–511.
Ministry of Finance (2006): Stability programme for Finland, Economic and Policy Surveys
4b/2006.
OECD (2004): Employment Outlook, OECD, Paris.
OECD (2005): Modernizing Government – The Way Forward.
OECD (2006): Economic Outlook 79, Paris.
OECD (2006): Finland – Economics Surveys, 2006/5, Paris.
OECD (2006): Projecting OECD Health and Long-term care expenditures: What are the main drivers, OECD Economics Department Working Paper 477.
OECD (2007): Benefits and Wages, www.oecd.org/els/social/workincentives.
OECD (2007): Economic Outlook No. 81, May 2007-11-15.
OECD (2007): Pensions at a Glance.
OECD (2007): Revenue Statistics 1965–2006.
OECD (2007): Social Expenditure Database 1980–2003.
Prendergast, C. (2003): The Limits of Bureaucratic Efficiency, Journal of Political Economy, 111 (5):
pp. 929–958.
Rodrik, D. (1998): Why Do More Open Economies Have Bigger Governments?, Journal of Political
Economy 105(6), October 1998, pp. 997–1032.
Rogerson, R. and Wallenius, J. (2007): Micro and Macro elasticities in a Life Cycle Model With Taxes.
NBER Working Paper 13017, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
164
·
The Nordic Model
Rothschild, M. and Stiglitz, J. (1976): Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on
the Economics of Imperfect Information, Quarterly Journal of Economics.
Sandmo, A. (1998): The Welfare State: a theoretical framework for justification and criticism, Swedish Economic Policy Review, Vol. 5 Nr 1, spring 1998, pp. 11–33.
Sanz, I. and Coma, F. (2007): Support for Globalisation and the Welfare State, translated from
Spanish, http://www.realinstitutoelcano.org/analisis/1103.asp.
Sattinger, M. (1993): Assignment models of the distribution of earnings. Journal of Economic Literature 31:2, pp. 831–880.
Sjöström, A.-K., Eriksson, I., Eklund, N. and Selin, J. (2006): Effektivare statlig verksamhet med private medverkan, ESV:15, Ekonomistyrningsverket, Stockholm.
Thakur, S., Keen, M., Horvath, B. and Cerra, V. (2003): Sweden’s Welfare State. Can the Bumblebee
Keep Flying?, IMF.
Timmer, M.P., O’Mahony, M. and van Ark, B. (2007): EU KLEMS Growth and Productivity Accounts:
An Overview, mimeo, available at www.euklems.net.
Timmer, M.P., Ypma, G., and van Ark, B. (2003): IT in the European Union: Driving Productivity Divergence?, GGDC Research Memorandum GD-67, October.
Tirole, J. (1994): The Internal Organization of Government, Oxford Economic Papers, 46: pp. 1–29.
Uusitalo, R. and Hakola, T. (2001): Let’s Make a Deal – the Impact of Social Security Provisions and
Firm Liabilities on Early Retirement. VATT Discussion Papers 260.
Uusitalo, R. and Vartiainen, J. (2007): Firm factors in wages and wage changes. In Lazear, E. and
Shaw, K. (eds.): Wage Structure, Raises and Mobility: International Comparisons of the Structure of
Wages Within and Across Firms, University of Chicago Press, forthcoming.
Vaittinen, R. and Vanne, R. (2006): Government Finances by Age in Finland, Finnish Centre for Pensions, Working Paper 3/2006.
Westergaard-Nielsen, N. and Eriksson, T. (2007): Wage and Labor Mobility in Denmark, 1980–2000,
NBER Working Paper 13064, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Guidelines for reform
·
165
Is there a Nordic model? What are the main characteristics of the Nordics? What challenges are they facing? Is the Nordic welfare state viable
in conditions of globalization and ageing populations? What reforms
are needed?
The Nordic countries have attracted much international attention in recent years. The school system in Finland has repeatedly been ranked
the best in the world. The Swedish pension reform is a benchmark in
the international debate. Danish “flexicurity” figures prominently on the
policy agenda in the EU and the OECD.
The economic performance of the Nordic countries has been impressive
in comparative terms: rapid growth, high employment, price stability,
healthy surpluses in government finances. The Nordics have embraced
globalization and new technologies. Cross-country comparisons support the view that the Nordics have been successful in reconciling economic efficiency with social equality.
While successful in the past, the Nordic model is facing increasingly
serious challenges in the future. Globalization and the demographic
transformation have major consequences for labour markets and the
public sector. The viability of the Nordic welfare state as it exists today
is put into question.
This report offers an in-depth analysis of the Nordic model, explaining
its key features and evaluating its performance as well as setting out its
challenges. It examines many of the “quick fixes” put forward in public
debate and explains why they are unrealistic or based on erroneous reasoning. The report also outlines the main elements of policy that reform
of the Nordic model should focus on.
ISBN 978-951-628-468-5