IPPG Programme Office, IDPM,
School of Environment & Development
University of Manchester
Harold Hankin Building, Precinct Centre
Oxford Road, Manchester M13 9PL
Telephone 0161 306 6438
Fax 0161 273 8829
www.ippg.org.uk
The Socio-Political Matrix and Economic Development
in ChileA
Manuel a. Garretón M.
Discussion PaPer series nuMber FiFteen a
october 2007
A
This document was prepared in colaboration with Daniel Grimaldi, and draws on material from work done with other authors,
in particular Malca Espinosa (see bibliography).
Paper prepared for the DFID-funded Research Programme, Institutions and Pro-Poor Growth (IPPG). The authors are grateful to
DFID for the funding that made this research possible. The views expressed in this paper are entirely those of the author and in no
way represent either the official policy of DFID or the policy of any other part of the UK Government.
Material published by the IPPG may be reproduced free of charge in any format or medium provided it is reproduced faithfully,
not used in a misleading context and properly attributed to the author(s). Copyright exists in all other original material published
by members of the Programme and may belong to the author or to the University of Manchester depending on the circumstances
of publication. Enquiries should be sent to the editor at the above address.
iPPG
contents
1. Approach to the question
2. The foundations of Chile’s socioeconomic system at mid-century
3. The Statist-National, Popular-Democratic, Party-Orientated Matrix
3.1 The classic matrix
4. The Neoliberal Authoritarian Thrust
5. Democracy and a Hybrid Matrix
6. Summary and Conclusions
Bibliography
PaGe
4
4
6
6
12
14
20
23
3
iPPG
1. aPProach
to the question
This paper examines the evolution of Chile as a nation and society from the middle of the twentieth
century. Any thorough grasp of this period requires an understanding of the relationships among the
players, the gestation and development of their relationships, and the conditions under which their
interactions occurred, as well as the rules of the game governing the entire scenario. Two useful tools
can be profitably combined for the purpose: the concept of a socio-political matrix, and neo-institutional
analysis.
The concept of the socio-political matrix is based on the assumption that a society can be defined in
terms of the pattern of relationships that link (i) the State, (ii) the political regime and political parties
and (iii) civil society or grassroots. Thus, the socio-political matrix is the relational matrix of elements that
make up a society, including the State (a society’s moment of unity and direction), a system of political
parties or other mechanisms of political representation (the moment of aggregation of the people’s and
players’ political and other claims) and a socioeconomic and cultural base (the moment of participation
and diversity of civil society). The institutions that mediate among these elements constitute what we
call the political regime. Thus, the matrix approach focuses on the players, how they are constituted as
players, and their interactions.
A socio-political matrix is a way of seeing a society as it functions under given norms or ‘rules of the
game,’ which are determined to a great extent by the political regime. Thus, matrices evolve hand in hand
with changes in the rules of the game. As these realities change, different results are evidenced.
The theory of institutional change looks at economic, social and political change from a different
point of view, focusing on the relationships among different organizations and institutions, and the
transactions costs involved in those relations. The main ‘organisation’ here is the State, and what we call
‘institutions’ include all the rules of the game, both formal and informal. From this point of view, though
organizations are created by the evolution of institutions, the influence flows in the other direction as well,
for organizations affect institutions through actions and relationships that necessarily include a mixture of
limited rationality and non-rational elements.
Our basic hypothesis is that what we designate as the statist-national, popular-democratic, partyoriented matrix has disintegrated in Chile in the last decades. Thus, with the democratic rule of law
partially re-established today, a new fundamental question arises: What remains of the Chile that has
been, and how can a vision of the nation-state be reformulated in today’s globalized world? We must
consider that the future state will probably be multi-national, with indigenous peoples playing a role,
and that its highly diverse and polyvalent protagonist is a people that organizes itself and determines its
destiny democratically. Without a driving idea or an effective vision of itself as a nation-state, a country
ceases to be a country, and disintegrates into scattered fragments that are subordinate to the global
sum of transnational and national de facto powers—an immense, unintegrated mass of people who are
relegated to the role of mere extras on the world stage.
2. the
FounDations oF
chile’s
socioeconoMic systeM at MiD-century
In the early twentieth century, Chile began to develop what we call the classic Latin American sociopolitical matrix. In Chile’s case, the form this took was statist, national, popular, democratic, and politicalparty-oriented. The economic and social model up to that time was an outward-oriented free-market
system based on the most traditional free-trade paradigm. This orthodox economic model was combined
with an oligarchic system of limited democracy, in which major segments of the population were politically
and socially excluded. The State’s minimal role during this period facilitated the country’s capitalistic urban
expansion, which was driven by industrial activity and mining. As industry drew great flows of migrants
from rural areas, acute social problems arose, pointing clearly toward a crisis of the oligarchic model,
which collapsed definitively in the wake of the global crisis of 1929. With the collapse of the oligarchic
model, Chile was forced to seek a new development strategy, and a period began in which the State for
the first time took an active role in development.
The so-called ‘social question’ of the 1920s was the issue of the marginalized new proletariat. The
situation was not sustainable, and a climate favourable to major social change developed. Politically
progressive middle-class groups had begun to emerge as early as 1880, along with an increasingly
organized workers’ movement that had paved the way for the creation of the Communist Party by the
early 1920s. Though progressive groups before the 1920s hardly had enthusiastic electoral support,
they did put new issues on the social agenda. Important advances were made in this sense during the
presidential campaign of the liberal candidate Arturo Alessandri Palma, who took office as president in
1920.
The Alessandri government oversaw the writing of a new Constitution (1925) that heavily reflected
the predominant social and constitutional doctrines of the twentieth century, which had previously found
expression in the landmark Mexican Constitution of 1917 and that of the Soviet Union in 1918. Chile’s
1925 Constitution enshrined the principle of minimum wellbeing for all citizens, and included explicit
protections for labour and industry, as well as social welfare provisions (Heise 1977). The institutional
structure created by the Constitution led to the creation of the Labour Code in 1931, as well as a Health
4
iPPG
Code. The Constitution established a democratic presidentialist system as a reaction to the institutional
crises of the late nineteenth century. It also created a new electoral framework, in which proportionality
was the guiding principle for representation in Congress. Absolute separation between Church and State
was mandated, the Central Bank was created, and new banking and budget laws were put in place. The
Contraloría General de la República (an autonomous government agency that monitors the legality of the
behaviour of governmental entities and personnel) was also established.
The 1925 Constitution provided the institutional framework for later social processes that, as we shall
see, helped to create the classic socio-political matrix, which was based on relatively modern institutions,
political democratization, social protections, a pro-active role for the State, and secularism. All of this
progress, however was rather precarious in nature, and steps backward not unknown, for until the 1970s
the peasantry and poor urban sectors were excluded, there were oligarchical and other economic enclaves
(e.g., foreign ownership of large-scale mining, and land-owning sectors that effectively resisted change),
and stable political coalitions were lacking between the centre (broadly speaking, representing the middle
class) and the left (largely representing the working class).
The Great Depression that began in 1929 affected Chile more drastically (see Table 1) than it did many
other Latin American countries, or countries in other parts of the world, because of Chile’s dependence
on nitrate and copper exports, which fell precipitously, reducing both fiscal revenue and international
reserves, and leading to the country’s defaulting on its foreign debt in the early 1930s. The strategy
adopted to deal with the crisis was import substitution industrialization (ISI). This involved reducing
imports while stimulating domestic demand and controlling the exchange rate. The gold standard was
abandoned and anti-cyclical monetary and fiscal policies were put in place. Quotas and tariffs were
implemented to discourage importation of consumer goods, while measures were taken to strengthen
domestic production and demand (Corbo 1988).
Table 1: Impact of the Great Depression on the Chilean Economy (percentage)
1932
Change from
1929a
1927–29b
1938
Change from
1929a
1927–29b
GDP
-45.8
-38.3
-7.3
+.
Exports
-81.4
-78.3
-38.4
-28.2
International nitrate prices
-59.0
-61.1
-45.2
-48.0
Nitrate export volume
-78.5
-74.0
-56.8
-47.7
International copper prices
-69.3
-63.4
-44.8
-34.3
Copper export volume
-71.4
-68.6
-10.1
-1.2
Imports
-86.8
-83.5
-68.7
-60.7
Per capita GDP
-48.2
-42.0
-16.1
-6.0
Source: Sáez (1989), quoted in Meller (1996:49).
Note: The figures represent change as a percentage with respect to a baseline. For example, the ‘-45.8%’ figure for GDP means that
1932 GDP dropped 45.8% from the 1929 baseline.
a: (1929=100).
b: (average 1927–29=100).
The result of ISI was naturally the development of domestic industry stimulated and protected by the
State through institutions such as the Corporación de Fomento de la Producción (CORFO). Created in 1939,
CORFO generated a symbiotic relationship between the enterprise State and its highly subsidized private
sector. The foundations of the capitalistic system remained untouched until the 1950s (only circumstantial
adjustments being made to deal with the 1929 crisis) when Latin America created its version of the
‘welfare state’ – which never, however, became a consolidated reality in Chile.
iPPG
Table 2: Industry’s share of GDP, selected countries, 1929, 1945 and 1955
Country
1929
1945
1955
Argentina
22.8
25.0
25.0
Brazil
11.7
17.0
23.0
Chile
7.9
23.0
23.0
Colombia
6.0
11.0
15.0
Guatemala
n.d.
13.0
11.0
Honduras
n.d.
7.0
12.0
14.2
19.0
19.0
Peru
n.d.
13.0
15.0
Uruguay
n.d.
18.0
23.0
Mexico
Source: Furtado, Celso. La Economía Latinoamericana desde la Conquista Ibérica hasta la Revolución Cubana. Santiago, Editorial
Universitaria, 1969, p. 107. Quoted in Del Pozo, José, Historia de América Latina y El Caribe 1825-2001. Santiago, Editorial LOM,
2002, p. 118.
These measures were at first no more than a natural, rational response to the crisis. No viable
alternative was in sight, given the international financial situation (and, not much later, the Second World
War). Toward the end of World War II, however, the pursuit of these measures was intensified as a Latin
American ideology emerged based on the theory of development and structural approach put forth by
ECLAC in the mid-1940s.
3. the statist-national, PoPular-DeMocratic, Party-orientateD Matrix
3.1 The classic matrix
Chile’s dominant social model, or socio-political matrix, in the twentieth century may be designated
as statist-national, popular-democratic and party-oriented. It was characterised by the intertwining of
politics and civil society (including the economy), a system in which political actors or political parties
played a dominant and articulating role vis-à-vis the State.
Thus, the model supported a national identity that was in the process of being constructed through
the work and struggles of the nation’s representatives in the political arena. This represented an effort
at broad-based social inclusion, and an attempt to resolve conflicts in an institutional framework, rather
than by force or exclusion.
The political sphere always provided the main expression of the statist-national, popular-democratic,
party-oriented idea as it was enshrined in the 1925 Constitution, and concomitantly in institutions
that sought to assure respect for the law and liberty while enforcing the State’s accountability to, and
responsibility for serving, the public. The period’s social legislation (enacted from 1920 on) provided
for universal suffrage and for mass political participation. This was the basis for the programmes of the
Radical Party and the parties on the left that made up the Frente Popular (which aimed to bring together
the middle and working classes), for the Patria Joven and Revolución en Libertad, which were a part of the
Christian Democratic thrust of the 1960s, and for the Chilean Road to Socialism led by the Unidad Popular
and President Allende between 1970 and 1973. Socioeconomically, the situation featured industrialization
with the State in a directing role, free public education and universities with national coverage, land
reform, and eventually nationalization of healthcare (the National Health Service), among many other
important landmarks. At one time, even military service played a role in national integration.
The Frente Popular governments of 1938 to 1952 marked the beginning of a period of solid social
reforms and industrial growth, with policies designed to create an infrastructure base for production, and
a system of social protections for the working and middle classes. Between 1940 and 1953, industry grew
an average of 7.5% yearly, rising from 7.9% of GDP in 1929 to 23.0% by 1955 (see Table 2).
6
iPPG
Table 3: Summary of principal reforms of 1938-1952 under the import substitution
model
Infrastructure
investment
• New hydroelectric plants: Ovalle, La Serena, Copiapó, El Salado, Tocopilla
• Construction of the Sauzal plant on the Cachapoal River
• Abanico plant
• Pilmaiquén plant
Creation of new
enterpriz
• Corporación de Formento a la Producción, or CORFO (National Corporation
for Productive Development) 1939
• Empresa Nacional de Electricidad S.A., or ENDESA (National Electricity
Company) 1944
• Discovery of Manantiales reserves in Magallanes, and creation of ENAP
(National Petroleum Company) 1950
• Compañia de Acero del Pacifico S.A. or CAP (Steel Company of the Pacific,
a mixed public-private enterprise) 1946
• Huachipate steel plant
• Industria Azucarera Nacional S.A. or IANSA (National Sugar Company)
1952
Social coverage
• Increase in social spending from 10% in 1935 to 26.9% in 1945 and
28.5% in 1955
• Creation of the Servicio Nacional de Salud or SNS (National Health
Service)
• Increase in number of primary school students from 500,000 in 1925 ti
797,600 by 1950
• Increase in number of secondary school students from 63,500 in 1925 to
148,000 by 1950
• Increase in number of university students from 6,200 in 1925 to 11,000
by mid-century
• Creation of the Junta Nacional de Auxillo Escolar (National Student Aid
Board)
Source: Based on Sofía Correa et al., Historia del siglo XX chileno. Editorial Sudamericana 2001.
The hard data reflect the fact that over more than 40 years, independent of the political or ideological
orientation of particular governments, there was a basic political and social consensus regarding
industrialisation and the essential role of the State in the development process (through such institutions
as CORFO, for example, which controlled 30% of all capital goods investment, 25% of public investment
and 18% of gross investment.1 However, despite general consensus about the role of the State, there was
dissent from the right regarding economic and political issues, as well as dissent from the centre-left or
middle- and working-class sector regarding approach to social issues. Industrialisation policy and foreign
trade disincentives, meanwhile, were implicitly in conflict with the workers’ movement that was imbedded
in the political structure of the State and the parties. Workers’ groups established alliances with the new
industrial business sector, to the detriment of the more export-oriented land-owning agricultural sector
(Corbo, 1988). This was to become a point of conflict when the ISI model faced its crisis.
It was in the late 1950s that the model began to collapse. Though standards of living and access
to services continued to improve, protectionism created severe problems, including high inflation and
unemployment, which augured badly for the future. The conservative government of Carlos Ibáñez
del Campo, elected in 1952, had attempted unsuccessfully to reform the CEPAL model, following the
recommendations of the American Klein-Saks economic mission (1955) by restricting the money supply
and public spending. Recessionary effects made it impossible to pursue this course, however (FfrenchDavis 2004).
1.
Vuskovic, quoted in Moss (1973), quoted in Meller, Patricio (1996) Un Siglo de economía política chilena (1890–1990).
Editorial Andrés Bello, pp. 59. Santiago.
7
iPPG
Chart 1: Annual price fluctuation 1945–1965 (percentages)
Gráfico 1
Variación Anual de Precios 1945 - 1965
90
84
80
70
60
55
%
50
33
30
20
Precio
44
40
28
20.4
23
21
20.4
19
10
10
0
1945
1947
1949
1951
1953
1955
1957
1959
1961
1963
1965
años
Source: Braun, Juan et al (2002) ‘Economía chilena 1810–1995: Estadísticas Históricas’. Documento de Trabajo no. 187, Instituto
de Economía, Universidad Católica de Chile, pp. 102.
The import substitution model did not meet expectations, and was criticised for the oversized and
inefficient bureaucracy that was created to sustain an infrastructure of social benefits, and for its support of
inefficient social productive sectors. Meanwhile, the independence of the foreign sector remained no more
than a desire, for dependence on imported capital goods and raw materials for domestic production rose,
prices were distorted by subsidies, and competition was lacking, with rising prices and unemployment as
consequences. Thus, the model was called seriously into question, aggravating the ideological confrontation
between defenders of the CEPAL model and the champions of neoliberal modernization.
In 1958, conservative Jorge Alessandri Rodríguez became president, and a modernistic capitalistic
reform ensued. There was an attempt to make the private sector the engine of growth, but in a framework
of active Keynesian fiscal policy. The reforms were well conceived, but the establishment of a nominal
exchange rate as a way of stabilizing prices and the support provided by foreign borrowing (Ffrench-Davis
2004) were not sufficient either to sustain productive growth or to control prices, since there was an
inconsistency in the medium term between the modernizing strategy and the adjustment measures. Also,
as Chart 1 shows, the Alessandri price control measures had but a fleeting effect. To make matters worse,
the measures enjoyed neither a substantial political majority nor the support of the business sector.
The Christian Democratic government of Eduardo Frei Montalva (1964) began a process of reform
under a plan called Revolución en Libertad. The strategy included gradual, non-recessionary stabilization
of the exchange rate; land reform and strong support for rural workers’ unions; industrial modernization,
with the State playing a major role in growing the telecommunications and petrochemicals industries; and
the beginning of the process of nationalizing the country’s copper industry – which the Unidad Popular
government would later complete.
The reforms took shape progressively between 1965 and 1973, and were based on increasing the
economic, political and social integration of the poorest working-class sectors in both agricultural and
urban areas. The process was gradual under Eduardo Frei, but took a radical strategic turn – basically in
terms of economic and social organization – with the Allende government. Except for extending effective
citizenship to a larger segment of the population, no reforms in the political/institutional system were
undertaken by the reformist governments.
The main economic reforms (land reform and nationalization of the copper industry) addressed ownership
patterns in sectors considered to be of strategic importance for development. Reforms designed to extend
democracy focused on social organization and electoral mechanisms to involve young people and the
illiterate. These governments oversaw legislation for the unionization of rural workers, which contributed
to bringing the rural sector – whose social and political rights had been long deferred– into the country’s
political life. Suffrage was extended to the illiterate, and the voting age was lowered from 21 to 18. Both
governments showed absolute respect for the Constitution, took care to protect the regular functioning of
democratic institutions, supported the full reign of individual liberties, and upheld the rule of law.
The political spectrum underwent a double process. On one hand, it broadened, as new parties were
formed by groups breaking off from the Christian Democrats. On the other, there was a phenomenon of
polarization and increasing rigidity. The right unified in a nationalistic political party of authoritarian bent
(the Partido Nacional); the autonomy of the more ideologically centrist Christian Democratic Party was
8
iPPG
promoted by a platform that reflected its specific views; and the left grouped around the Marxist-Leninist
matrix in a more radically anti-capitalistic orientation.
From the crisis of 1929 to 1973, the State played a central role not only in guiding development and
in organizing economic and social agents under a common pro-development model, but also as the
social and political articulator par excellence. Successive governments (whether of the right, centre or
left) maintained protectionist measures for industry, subsidized economic agents (e.g., via low interest
rates), and redistributed income systematically and progressively. These governments took an active
role in regulating wages and prices, while increasing social services in education, health and housing
through budgetary allocations. Indeed, the consequences of this social investment are recognized even
today as one of the lasting effects of the pro-development policy, for without them the growth of the
Chilean economy that we see today would have been impossible. The economic data for the period show
moderate but sustained growth, low unemployment and reasonable investment rates (though with high
inflation), a situation that points up the political nature of the fall of democracy in 1973.
Table 4: Annual sectoral growth rates by period
1920–1930
1930–1940
1940–1950
1950–1960
1960–1970
1970–1980
1980–1990
Producto
Agricola
Producto
Minero
Producto
Manufacturero
Servicios
Gubernativos
Resto
3.26%
0.86%
2.16%
1.64%
1.93%
2.24%
6.02%
1.89%
0.60%
0.33%
-0.73%
2.57%
3.44%
3.74%
1.89%
4.76%
8.12%
4.45%
5.32%
1.14%
2.59%
-2.47%
9.07%
7.84%
4.32%
2.54%
1.87%
-0.23%
1.48%
3.76%
2.22%
4.96%
4.58%
3.10%
2.85%
Source: Braun, Juan et al (2002) ‘Economía chilena 1810–1995: Estadísticas Históricas’. Documento de Trabajo no. 187, Instituto
de Economía, Universidad Católica de Chile.
Table 5: Main economic indicators under the Alessandri and Frei Montalva governmentsa
Economic
Growth
(%GDP)
Alessandri
(1958–64)
Frei
(1964–70)
Annual
Inflation
(%)
Unemployment
(%)B
Real Annual Exports
Wage
(% GDP)
Increase (%)
International
Reserves
(months of
imports)C
3.7
25.8
7.5
1.8
14.5
2.2
3.9
26.2
5.5
8.0
15.4
4.9
Source: Central Bank, INE, in Meller 1996.
A.
Annual average for presidential term.
B.
1960–64 period for Alessandri government.
C.
Value for last year of the period.
The principal feature of the classic matrix is the central role of politics not only in economic processes,
but in constituting the society’s cast of players and in shaping cultural orientations (notwithstanding the
fact that cultural sphere has its own degree of autonomy). There were cultural orientations that valued
education, equality, solidarity, a collective national vision, and that emphasized the importance of the
middle class. However, meritocratic criteria were lacking, and classist and oligarchical factors played an
important role, given the culture of rural life and of the hacienda. Meanwhile, the national identity and
the process of constructing collective identities within it were organized around politics – in a sense much
broader than simply government and governmental decision-making. It was the particular way in which
the society and its way of life constituted themselves that was so important. Politics was the principle
area in which the quest for meaning took shape, and institutions were the main instrument through which
answers were generated, creating a perpetual ambiguity or hypocrisy in which norms were accepted while
their intrinsic value was doubted.
The particularity of Chilean politics was that it was more party-based than populist or personality-based,
unlike other Latin American countries. There was a wide spectrum of political parties and ideologies, even
before the masses were brought into the political process. Politics was centre-stage and highly ideological,
paving the way for the radicalization of the 1970s, which translated abstract ideology into concrete
claims.
9
iPPG
Table 6: Results of parliamentary elections, 1925–1969
Election
Right
Centre
Left
1925
52.2
21.4
0.0
1932
32.7
18.2
5.7
1937
42.0
28.1
15.3
1941
31.2
32.1
28.5
1945
43.7
27.9
23.0
1949
42.0
46.7
9.4
1953
25.3
43.0
14.2
1957
33.0
44.3
10.7
1961
30.4
43.7
22.1
1965
12.5
49.0
29.4
1969
20.0
36.3
34.6
Source: Borón (1971) and Valenzuela (1978). Quoted in Meller (1996:102).
Note: The ‘right’ includes the Liberal and Conservative parties; the ‘centre’ the Radical, Agrario Laborista (Agrarian Workers) and
Christian Democratic parties; and the ‘left’ the Socialist and Communist parties. Starting in 1965, half of the Radical votes are
counted as belonging to the left and the other half to the centre. The sum of the percentages is not 100%, since some minor parties
and independent candidates are not included.
Despite its achievements, the statist-national, popular-democratic, political-party-oriented model
whose general features we have sketched here suffered from major contradictions and constraints. The
rural population, the urban poor, women and regional interests were marginalized, subordinated and
only tardily incorporated. Cultural forms and identities outside the mainstream as defined by the de facto
powers (in particular, the cultures of indigenous peoples) were kept in a subordinate position and excluded
from political expression. Parochial thinking reigned, and the national-popular idea was appropriated and
identified with particular social, political or cultural sectors, excluding the rest of the society, a dynamic
that segregated the country rather than promoting integration. The culture did not encourage individual
creativity or the expression of diversity, but promoted an apparent homogeneousness behind which lay
mediocrity, discrimination, classism and hypocrisy. Finally, the technical aspects of economic policy were
excessively dependent on politics.
It was precisely these contradictions, and the difficulty of overcoming them, that created the crisis
conditions that were taken advantage of by the economy’s dominant sectors and the armed forces as a
way of implementing their own socioeconomic and political project, which was completely foreign to the
principles of the model that had reigned up to that time. In 1970, the capitalistic development model, with
its social consequences, suffered a legitimacy crisis, but not so the democratic regime. During the 19701973 period, on the other hand, there was a crisis of democratic legitimacy that triggered the downfall
of the entire political system.
The Unidad Popular and the economic and political crisis
The parties of the left, grouped together in the Unidad Popular under the leadership of Salvador
Allende, shared with Chile’s political forces across the political spectrum the revolutionary aspiration of
radical, comprehensive social change. On the left, this aspiration took socialistic forms, looking to supplant
capitalistic society (though, unlike most Latin American countries, a democratic context was assumed).
In terms of content – the transformation of the capitalistic model and the beginning of a transition to
socialism – the project paid the price of the predominant views of the time: the economic determinism of
social and political life, ideological expressions that reflected rather monolithic systems of thinking, and,
most important, the absence of models for the left apart from the revolutionary Marxist-Leninist matrix
and the historical cases that it had generated.
Despite these obstacles, the Chilean left did succeed in tentatively formulating its own vision, the
‘Chilean road to socialism.’ The doctrine is best expressed in President Salvador Allende’s first address
to Congress in 1971, in which he stressed the relationship between political democracy and economic
and social democracy. The platform of the Unidad Popular was based on certain goals and strategic
formulations, with specific measures based essentially on redistribution as a way of meeting the basic
needs of the majority of the population. The linchpin was the expropriation of the monopolies, which
would give the State the surplus needed to reorient the productive apparatus to the people’s needs.
Eminently anti-capitalistic in spirit, the ideal of the Unidad Popular’s economic programme was economic
democracy. Redistribution was to be achieved through changes in ownership structures, nationalising
the country’s large-scale copper, nitrate, iodine, iron and coal mining operations, and dismantling the
country’s banking, foreign-trade and strategic monopolies. Action was also taken on private distribution
enterprises that were considered to be of strategic importance, while other firms were arbitrarily seized
by workers’ organizations – as were many farms not affected by previous land reform (see Table 8). Fees
10
iPPG
for public services were reduced, and wages were raised by issuing money. This triggered heavy inflation
– 293% in 1973 (see Table 9).
Table 7: Land reform under presidents Frei and Allende
Expropriations
Seizures by workers
(number of farms)
Number of farms
Area (thousands
of hectares)
E. Frei Montalva
government (1964–1970)
1,400
3,557
Salvador Allende
(1971–1973)
4,409
6,409
1,379
2,189
836
2,027
3,013
833
1971
1972
1973
241*
1,278
1,228
n.d.
Source: Martner (1988) and Kay (1992) in Meller (1996:143).
For seizures, the breakdown by year is: 1965: 13; 1967: 9; 1968: 26; 1969: 148; 1970: 456.
*Includes figures for 1965–1969.
Table 8: Comparison of key macroeconomic variables, 1959–1973a
Variable
GDP growth (%)B
Export growth (%)
C
Inflation
D
Umemployment
Alessandri
1959–64
Frei
1965–70
Allende
1971–73
3.7
4.0
1.2
6.2
2.3
-4.1
26.6
26.3
293.8
5.2
5.9
4.7
Real wages (1970 =
100)
62.2
84.2
89.7
Gross fixed
investment (% of
GDP) in 1977 pesos
20.7
19.3
15.9
National government
surplus (% of GDP)
-4.7
-2.5
-11.5
Source: Central Bank of Chile and DIPRES, Jadresic (1986, 1990); Marcel and Meller (1986); Larraín (1991). Quoted in FfrenchDavis (2004) (extract of complete table, covering through 2003).
A
Annual cumulative GDP and export growth; average annual inflation and unemployment.
B
In 1977 pesos.
C
In 1977 pesos.
D
December to December.
Beyond the fact of the Unidad Popular’s theoretical and policy inadequacies, and a discourse that
over-emphasized the worker as the agent of social change, which led to exclusionary and confrontational
attitudes and action, what it aspired to was, in effect, to square the circle: to conduct a revolution by
non-revolutionary, democratic methods – and without the institutional majority that, in Chile, could only
be built through political parties. The great lesson of this period is that a majority-building strategy is
of the essence in Chile. Indeed, the absence of such a strategy is a part of its past that the Christian
Democratic Party has yet to come to terms with. No doubt, the coalition (Concertación de Partidos por
la Democracia) that succeeded the military government in 1990 emerged not only because of the need
to fight the military dictatorship, but because that lesson had been absorbed to a significant degree. In
any case, to see the 1970–1973 period and its culmination in the military coup of 1973 solely as a due to
the weakness or unviability of the Unidad Popular’s aims and strategy would be misguided. Those three
years were marked by a political struggle in which a sector opposed to the Unidad Popular and the Allende
government attempted, from the beginning, to bring it down –an objective shared by the United States
government.
11
iPPG
4. the neoliberal authoritarian thrust
Between 1973 and 1989, the democratic regime was interrupted by a de facto military government led
by Augusto Pinochet.2 A coup d’état ended the institutional stability that the country had enjoyed, with few
interruptions, over more than 150 years of republican life. Congress was dissolved, the legislative function
was taken over by the executive, political parties were prohibited, electoral mechanisms were suspended,
and individual liberties were practically abolished. There was massive, systematic repression of those
considered supporters of the previous government or opponents of the new. The judicial branch was
subordinated to the de facto executive. The authoritarian regime’s institutional model was consolidated
in the 1980 Constitution, which was approved in a fraudulent plebiscite. The Constitution enshrined the
authoritarian institutional structure, which was to lead straight to the 1988 plebiscite.
Here, then, we see a counter-revolutionary project. The Chilean military regime from 1973 to 1981
or 1982 engaged in a double process. One aspect was the repression and disempowerment of existing
players on the national scene. Given the nature and origin of these players’ roles, that meant suppressing
party activity, which first reappeared under the umbrella of the Church. The other aspect of the process
was personalization, for General Pinochet represented a mixture of institutional regime and personal
dictatorship, political power and military power. A hegemonic nucleus was formed that combined this
personalized political power with the socioeconomic management of the State by a technocratic team
known as the ‘Chicago Boys,’ which very quickly aligned itself with financial capitalism.
The content of the Pinochet regime’s civil and military programme was twofold. First, it aimed to reverse
the relationship between the economy and the State, reducing the State’s integrative and redistributive
role to a bare minimum, along with its role as a referent for collective action, while continuing to make use
of its coercive functions and employing it as an instrument for implementing the model itself. Second, it
aimed to generate a set of social and institutional changes subsumed under the rubric of ‘modernization,’
which principally meant atomizing social relations, reducing social relationships to market mechanisms,
and cutting off links between social relationships and political action.
The authoritarian/neoliberal proposition was presented as a radical step beyond preceding formulas
(traditional capitalism, the mixed formula of the 1960s and the socialist orientation of the Unidad
Popular). By suppressing political activity, the military regime was able to carry out the changes that its
technocratic nucleus deemed necessary. The State was able to impose these changes without having to
face countervailing social forces. The social costs of this have been analyzed at length, and their effects
on today’s and tomorrow’s society are undoubtedly long-term. The neoliberal formula produced not only
a restructuring of the economy but a restructuring of the political sphere (since the regime enshrined its
institutional model lastingly in the 1980 Constitution), and a social reordering in which the entrepreneur
assumed the leading role, in which the working class was dissolved as a social agent, and in which the
cultural orientations of the social and political players were transformed.
The military government’s plan for stabilising the economy and placing it on a new foundation was
based on dismantling Chile’s version of the welfare state and the classic socio-political matrix, and on
creating the groundwork for the neoliberal matrix to which we have referred. First of all, policies were
put in place to control macroeconomic imbalances. Priority was placed on controlling hyperinflation, and
this was followed by unilateral and indiscriminate trade deregulation, price deregulation and deregulation
of the financial market. Thus began the dismantling of the governmental apparatus, which included the
dissolution of the entire state enterprise system through privatization, even in some areas by long tradition
within the purview of government, such as the pension and healthcare systems. Foreign borrowing was a
fundamental element in implementing the new economic reforms, but it proved to be a two-edged sword
that bounced back with the world debt crisis of 1982 to throw the Chilean banking system into default.
2.
Of note in this connection, among the abundant literature on the Pinochet military regime is C. Hunneus (2000) El régimen
de Pinochet. Santiago: Editorial Sudamericana. On economic issues see R. Ffrench Davis (2004) Entre el neo-liberalismo y el
crecimiento con equidad.
12
iPPG
Table 9: Comparison of the economic situation before the political crisis and after the
coup
1972–73
Post-1973
Privatization
State business controls over 400
businesses and banks
In 1980, the public sector includes
45 firms (including one bank)
Prices
General price controls
Unregulated prices (excluding
wages and exchange rate)
Trade Regime
Multiple exchange rate; prohibitions
and quotas; high tariffs (average
94%, maximum 220%)
Single exchange rate; acrossthe-board 10% tariff (excluding
automobiles); no other trade
barriers
Fiscal Regime
Cascading tax on purchase/sale
transactions; high rate of public
employment; high public deficit
Value-added tax (20%); reduction
of public payroll; government
surpluses (1979–81)
Domestic capital
market
Interest rate controls; nationalized
banking; controls on credit
Unregulated interest rates;
reprivatization of banking;
deregulation of capital market
Capital account
Total control of capital flows;
government is main foreign
borrower
Gradual deregulation of capital
flows; private sector is main
foreign borrower
Labour regime
Powerful unions with great
negotiating power; legislation
preventing dismissal of workers;
mandatory wage readjustments;
high non-wage labour costs (40%
of wages)
Atomization of unions, which lose
all bargaining power; employees
easily fired; drastic drop in real
wages; low non-wage labour costs
(3% of wages)
Source: Meller (1996)
Along with introducing radical changes in the economy (deregulation, privatisation, and dismantling
barriers to international trade), the military government changed social policy in six main ways:
1. by drastically reducing resources, affecting housing, health and education with particular intensity
(the major cuts being in investment and salaries in those sectors);
2. by transferring executive functions and services to the private sector, and implementing geographical
deconcentration of ministries and services;
3. by introducing market mechanisms into the allocation of public funds (demand subsidies);
4. by specific measures designed to virtually eliminate programmes with universal coverage, targeting
public spending on the poorest segments of the population;
5. by creating compensatory social programmes to be applied in situations of extreme poverty;
6. by weakening the power of workers and unions through tight control over collective expression of
social demands.
Despite the lack of a coherent ‘package’ of administrative reforms as such, the military government,
from its very first policy adjustment in 1975, implemented a series of measures that profoundly changed
the apparatus of the State. Among these was the massive privatization of public enterprises, including those
providing public services – social security pre-eminently – though the privatization of certain firms was
left pending, and large-scale copper mining was exempted. The functions of public services were shifted,
as were municipal fiscal deficits in education and health; the number of public employees was drastically
reduced, and entire government entities were eliminated; the ‘social’ ministries were restructured and
weakened, and ministries in the economic area were modernized; the country was divided into regions in
military fashion; administrative legislation created increasing instability; and a new Constitution was put
in place that was designed so as to be extremely difficult to change.
Thus, despite some initial measures in the area of financial and administrative streamlining, in practice
there was a marked deterioration of public administration, since the military regime’s economic authorities
considered the State inefficient by definition. Unremitting arbitrariness, authoritarianism and deprecation
of public functions devastated the morale of the bureaucracy. Salaries were reduced disproportionately in
fiscal adjustments. Obsessed with privatization, the Pinochet government abandoned public employees
to their fate (Marcel, 1994).
Thus, an extremely negative notion of the State’s role was promoted, and modernization and
administrative efficiency were identified with the private sector. The dominant political thinking associated
the public sector with bureaucratic and antiquated, not to say anachronistic, ideas and images. As a
result, all public servants were deemed inefficient. This prejudicial view, which rejected the functions and
13
iPPG
dismissed the effectiveness of public policy, continued among groups on the right and business sectors
during the succeeding democratic governments. Behind these arguments was, on one hand, an interest
in preventing the creation of regulatory strategies, and on the other an interest in privatizing all available
public capital and services (Díaz, 1988). But this approach had a major political motivation as well,
which was to punish a sector considered to bear responsibility for the 1973 crisis, and to eliminate State
intervention, which was construed as the principal cause of the politicization of society. Stressing the
ineffectiveness of governmental action, and its supposedly harmful effects on economic growth, neoliberals
and neoconservatives put a powerful brake on the endogenous modernization of public administration,
opposing various reform initiatives put forward by the democratic governments (Oyarce, 1997).
In 1981 and 1982, the debt crisis produced a crisis of the economic model, which led to the eruption
of protests and public expressions by the opposition. Starting in 1986, the regime partially repaired its
economic model to set the stage for the plebiscite in 1988, in which the opposition agreed to participate
with a view to turning it from a mechanism for the propagation of the regime into a mechanism for
dénouement, an end to dictatorship, and a transition to democracy.
Table 10: Results of the military regime’s ‘economic miracle’
1973
1980
1981
Annual inflation
CPI (revised)
WPI
Economic Growth (GDP)
606.1
31.2
9.5
1,147.10
28.1
-3.9
-4.3
7.8
.
1,309
4,705
3,836
14
1,821
1,411
167
4,074
3,775
21
-5.5
-2.9
-25.3
8.6
9
Exports (millions of USD)
Total exports
Non-traditional exports
International reserves
(millions of USD)
Budget deficit
(percentage of GDP
Annual increase in real wages (%)
Source: Central Bank, Ministry of Finance, in Meller (1996).
It is true that the military regime succeeded in imposing a new development model, but this was after
a resounding fiasco in 1981–1982, which entailed regressive growth for a period of time (though a partial
recovery began in 1986 – not including social indicators, none of which recovered to near their 1970s
levels).3 It is nonsense, then, to speak of a Chilean economic miracle.
In short, the military dictatorship and its neoliberal model produced a change in Chile’s socio-political
matrix, but since it created no new matrix, what it did in essence was in essence simply to dismantle the
old one.
. DeMocracy
anD a
hybriD Matrix
The political transition in Chile began with the 1988 plebiscite. Despite the clearly non-democratic civil
and military intentions of Pinochet and his collaborators, a return to authoritarianism became impossible
at that point. The transitional period ended when the first democratic government took office in March
of 1990. Since then, the country has been governed by four successive centre/left governments of the
Concertación de Partidos por la Democracia, a coalition comprising the Christian Democratic Party, the
Socialist Party, the Partido por la Democracia (Party for Democracy, or PPD) and, of less weight, the
3.
To mention only one, a long-range view of the economic history summarized in the present paper shows that, for the Chilean
population, the regressive redistribution of income that occurred under the military regime meant not a ‘lost decade’, as averred
in assessments of Latin America in the 1980s, but four lost decades. In the 1950s, the percentage of families living in poverty was
approximately 40% the same proportion as at the beginning of the 1990s. For a complete review of the economic policies of the
dictatorship and the pertinant indicators, see R. Ffrench Davis, op. cit.
14
iPPG
Partido Radical Social Demócrata (Social Democratic Radical Party). Two of the presidents have been
Christian Democrats (Patricio Aylwin, 1990–1994, and Eduardo Frei, 1994–2000) and two Socialist-PPD
(Ricardo Lagos, 2000–2006, and Michelle Bachelet, 2006–2010). Thus was resolved one of the major
problems that Chilean society confronted in the twentieth century. For though the imbrications of social
actors in the party system had been evident in the country’s progressive democratic parties individually,
it had not taken the form of a progressive democratic coalition uniting centre and left except during the
time of the Frente Popular in the late 1930s – and then only partially, because the configuration of social
actors had changed in such a way that they could no longer be fully represented by the party system.
The first democratic government, led by Patricio Aylwin, defined the national task in terms of a ‘transition
to democracy,’ putting forth the emblematic idea of ‘growth with equity’ while maintaining macroeconomic
balances and seeking to correct the social effects of the economic model. It also defined a method of
negotiation and specific agreements designated ‘democracy by consensus.’ In fact, no transition was still
in progress, nor were there, as we have said, true consensuses. But whatever criticisms one may lay at
the door of this government for partial or insufficient definitions, one must acknowledge that there were
goals and direction, and that in the terms it had set itself the government advanced.
During the second Concertación government, however, despite excellent economic performance up to
1997, and major progress in terms of public works and reform of the judicial and educational systems, the
country was basically adrift without a vision, a collectively-defined direction or a political leader. In place
of goals capable of mobilising social and cultural energies, there was a vacuum. Presidential leadership
‘was recovered in the Lagos government, when national objectives were given definition again in terms
of the goal of becoming a developed country before the conclusion of Chile’s second century of existence
as an independent nation. Despite enormous progress in infrastructure, social reform and international
insertion, the goal remains distant – nor does it seem at this point that the country’s social and political
actors are focused on a clearly defined joint objective.
The Bachelet campaign and the first 10 months of the Bachelet government (the first gender-balanced
government run by a woman in Latin America – in office for only a four-year term, pursuant to the
Constitutional reforms of 2005) has emphasized the idea of a new style, the ‘citizen’ style. Though there
are agendas consisting of specific measures, a political vision or ultimate goal that might give meaning to
governmental action as a whole is lacking, except for the generic proposition of social protections in the
form of pension reform (announced in late 2006). In the absence of a guiding direction, the government
has been beset by problems that were not on its agenda, the most significant of which has been that the
secondary-student protest movement.
Conclusion of the ‘transition’ to democracy does not mean that with fully democratic governments the
political regime and society had reached democracy properly speaking. For this was an incomplete transition
that gave rise to limited democracy of low quality, and one riddled with enclaves of authoritarianism. The
unfulfilled task at the end of the transition was neither to extend the transition nor to consolidate the new
post-authoritarian regime – which was already consolidated in the sense that no return to authoritarianism
was possible. The challenge was to profoundly reform the regime and create a new authentic political
democracy where de facto powers or political minorities would not set limits on the will and sovereignty
of the people. In other words, the transition left problems that have not been resolved.
The relative success of Chile’s political democratization occurred at a cost that may be seen in the
major problems left unsolved, failures due not to the nature of the process, but to the political way in
which it was handled.
Much has been made of the consensual character of the Chilean transition. The truth is that the transition
was characterised primarily by an absence of debate on the great issues that define a society and provide
the foundations of democracy. The illusion of consensus has been no more than a compensation for this
failure. The only consensus that really existed was consensus on ending dictatorship. What occurred in
this context was circumstantial and specific agreements between the government and the opposition. But
no one anywhere else in the world would have presumed to call this ‘consensus-based democracy.’ The
absence of true consensus on the basic issues of reconstructing a post-dictatorial society is due, on one
hand, to the veto power of the minority and de facto powers (business organizations and the economic
groups that control the media, the armed forces, the judiciary to some extent, and the electoral minority
of the right that has a virtual veto under the present electoral system). The crucial issues have either
received no debate, or the debate has been drowned in demands for economic or political stability. And
finally, there is a remaining trauma around conflict and confrontation, processes that are demonized
and seen as pathological, though debate and conflict are essential if true societal consensus is to be
reached.
Thus, debate has been limited, or nil, and totally unproductive of consensus on central issues such as
the problem of justice for violation of human rights under the dictatorship, regional reform, the Mapuche
problem, equality and redistribution, reproductive and cohabitation issues that are generally vetoed by the
Church, the constitutional model, and reformulation of the development model in the face of globalization.
It is worth pointing out, on the other hand, that there has been a certain consensus regarding placing
priority on education. This led to educational reform under the Frei government, but the limits of the
reforms were apparent in the student movement of 2006, which created new debate and led once again
to partial and precarious consensus. A fight on poverty was launched by the National Commission Against
15
iPPG
Poverty, but the central question of redistribution was omitted. Finally, one must acknowledge that the
modernization of the judicial system and the reform of the penal code, with the creation of the Ministerio
Publico (the ranking entity ultimately responsible for criminal investigations) and the institution of oral
judicial proceedings, are undoubtedly important advances.
Chile’s political democratization was certainly successful in the sense that it displaced the dictatorship,
kept the society from falling apart by controlling macroeconomic variables, and ensured a government
formed by a democratic coalition that represented a majority. However, one can hardly speak of an
‘exemplary’ or ‘successful’ transition, considering the products and quality of the democratic process
under this new regime, which is characterised by precarious institutions, de facto powers, and weak
representation due to tensions in the society and among its political players. Another factor is the fragility
of the transition’s cultural underpinnings, in that basic consensus and societal unity and direction are
lacking as a result of the fracturing of governmental power.4
Chile’s transition to democracy was happily free of something that occurred in many similar cases,
where economic crisis tore the relationship of pro-democracy forces asunder, and created opportunities
for destabilization or delegitimation by de facto powers, or distanced middle- and working-class sectors
from the new government’s policies. Chile’s initial democratic governments had not inherited a crisis that
would force them to take measures detrimental to working-class sectors or regressive in nature. What
had been inherited was not a crisis, but a model – a much more serious structural problem that called for
rectification, if not, indeed, replacement.
However, the resulting opportunity to concentrate on the truly political issues involved in completing
the transition and eliminating the remaining enclaves of authoritarianism was unfortunately not taken
advantage of, and the absolute priority placed on economic stability discouraged the creation of social
movements and actors, and was harmful to existing players’ relationship to politics and parties.
It is true that Chile has stood out in the last decade among its Latin American counterparts as a
notable emerging economy, and that its income, growth and poverty statistics, as reflected in human
development indices, are the best in the region. Nevertheless, as we shall see, problems permeate the
socioeconomic model, and they may end up not only acting as a brake on further growth at some point,
but actually jeopardizing progress already made, and threatening the very existence of the country as a
social community. This concern has triggered debate about correcting or changing the economic model.
The dissent was expressed principally from left of the Concertación in the 2005 presidential campaign.
The first problem has to do with the pace, type and goals of economic development. The proposed goal
is to become a developed country by 2010. This will not be possible, either in terms of per capita income
or in terms of a ‘developed’ distribution of the fruits of growth. Here, then, is the basic dilemma. The
world’s growth model, based on a leading role for transnational market forces and what has been called
the ‘new economy,’ has ceased to be a development model. Growth and development no longer go hand in
hand. The structural problem of employment is the best illustration of this, for it requires direct economic
intervention by State and society. Though international economic agreements of enormous significance
have been signed, and there have been socioeconomic reforms such as Plan Auge in healthcare and
Chile Solidario in poverty reduction, these are clearly insufficient. Discussion of the essential nature of a
development model based on exports without high valued added – and with a level of unemployment that
is apparently structural – is barely sparked before it gets smothered, for it seems that the only voices that
have influence (and indeed set the agenda for public bodies) are those of large business organizations and
associations, and the communications media that they control.
This is precisely the second major problem left unsolved by the Chilean development model—the
problem of the actors in the development process. On one hand, the country has experienced a cyclical
climate of government-business relations, which move from verbal guerrilla warfare with recriminations
by the government and threats from business, to declarations of full trust and mutual support – the latter
primarily when economic policy produces good results. In fact, despite some significant exceptions, the
extent to which ideology and a general unrestrained interest in profit at all costs have come to dominate
the economic arena means that Chile lacks one of the essential engines of economic development in
today’s world economic model: a business class with a sense of responsibility, one that is not intent
on profit at any cost, or addicted to extra-economic caprices, but feels a commitment to the national
wellbeing. This requires thinking in terms of the nation, and reflecting on the one’s role as an agent of
development in permanent cooperation and relation with the State.
Meanwhile, a critical or timid attitude subsists regarding a more active role for the State in its directing
and mobilizing capacity. It is true that in a highly globalized economy like Chile’s, it is much more difficult
to design aggressive economic policy than it is, for example, for the main Mercosur countries. But it is also
true that in its role as a regulator and provider of incentives, social protector, redistributor of resources
and wealth and generator of equality, as well as promoter of activities in areas such as research and the
environment, the Chilean State is still backward, and captive to the limitations that neoliberal ideology
4.
On the process of democratization in Chile, see, among other sources, E. Boeninger (1993) Democracia en Chile. Lecciones
para la gobernabilidad, in P. Drake & P. Jaksic, eds., El dificil camino hacia la democracia en Chile 1982–1990 (Santiago: FLACSO),
which includes coverage of the second half of the military regime; M.A. Garretón (1995) Hacia una nueva era politica. Estudio sobre
las deomcratizaciones (Santiago: Fondo de Cultura Económica); and, for a more recent review, A. Menéndez and A. Joignant, eds.
(1999) La Caja de Pandora. El retorno de la transición chilena (Santiago: Planeta/Ariel).
16
iPPG
has imposed in the guise of common sense. Modernization of the State has produced beneficial advances
in government in terms of computerization, user-friendliness and service. However, the process has
fallen into the trap of measuring its progress with indicators proper to the private sector and the market.
Reassuming the directing, regulating and protecting role continues to be a priority without which the
problems of inequality we have mentioned will not be resolved. It should be recalled that portion of the
national output represented by the State is very low, and that there is ample margin for moving from a
liberal model to a social-democratic one without jeopardizing growth.
The third problem has to do with the consequences of the economic situation in the social sphere
– namely, relative stagnation, especially in terms of jobs, socioeconomic equality and the capacity for
action on the part of the social groups and sectors most affected.
As regards jobs, though there has been undeniable progress in areas such as unemployment insurance
and the creation of new jobs by the State, and though unemployment has dropped in the last year with
a significant rate of job creation, the basic question remains. For today, growth is no longer equivalent
to development, social integration and, as the ILO puts it, a decent job for everyone. Hence, the growth
model must be changed, or additional measures taken – and these changes or additions may be in
contradiction to the model’s premises, since the whole thrust of the changes would be to again link
development and growth.
The fact is that socioeconomic inequality is the Achilles’ heel of Chilean society, though poverty, at
least statistically, has been reduced significantly, as mentioned above, largely as a result of growth and
effective social policy. In the 2005-2006 presidential campaign, the issue of inequality as the main problem
in Chilean society re-emerged and penetrated the discourse of all the candidates, including those on the
right. However, the major generator of greater equality – redistribution, one of whose indispensable
elements is tax reform – has been absent from the programs of the opposition on the right as well as in
the rhetoric and policies of the Concertación. The only important measure taken has been to increase the
VAT, a pre-eminently regressive step.
Thus, just as the previous model of development, which was based on industrialization and the State,
had certain intrinsic defects that needed to be corrected from outside it, the current model has perverse
aspects that are a part of its nature. Today’s economic model, unlike the model of earlier decades, based
on industrialisation and a pro-active State, does not promote the creation of a material and institutional
soil in which social actors can arise. It provides no stable foundation on which they can organise put
forth new demands, express themselves, or negotiate with representatives of the political sphere, i.e.,
representatives of political parties. When the bases for collective action are dismantled, the corporate
dimension associated with economic power is left in a uniquely privileged position, and social action
is reduced to sporadic defensive manoeuvres. Furthermore, institutions that can provide and enforce
standards and regulations are lacking, and the State is ill-equipped to process conflicts and demands.
This deficiency is reflected in the scandals triggered by complaints of bribery and fraud in the government
in 2002 and 2003, which led to an agenda of important but partial reforms, which hardly changed the
structure of the State itself, or its relation to the society.
The lack of balancing forces between the most powerful economic actors (the de facto powers) and
the nation’s social organizations, especially those in the most vulnerable sectors, appears not only not to
have diminished, but to have actually been aggravated. The thus weakened social actors are consequently
forced to focus on their own problems, and to emphasize their particular collective demands, neglecting
the great national issues. This phenomenon is reinforced by the absence of a party system in which social
sectors feel themselves heard and included by the political class, as they have been at other historical
periods. The only sectors that are so heard and incorporated are those of the right, which directly and
exclusively represent the business and military interests, and the Communist Party, which, with the
little political weight it has, expresses the remaining sectors’ dissatisfaction with the governments of the
Concertación.
If the Chilean model has been successful somewhere, it is in positioning the country in the globalization
process. Clearly, the Chilean economy has been impacted by globalization more strongly than others on
the continent, in part because of its historical dependence on foreign phenomena of all kinds, but also
because of the nature of its economy, which is more open than the others, partly because the process of
deregulation and adjustment was carried out before globalization became the central phenomenon of the
late twentieth century. Economically, over 50% of Chile’s GDP is linked with the foreign sector.
The following tables show how socioeconomic indicators have fared since the first democratic government
took office.
5.
Reforms in 2003 addressed issues of probity and public administration. They placed caps on confidential funds in some
ministries and provided for public financing of electoral campaigns, in the wake of scandals involving bribery, extra pay for employees
of some government entities, and irregular use of public funds – problems that led to an accord between President Lagos and the
parties of the Concertación, on one hand, and the opposition led by UDI President Pablo Longueira, on the other.
17
iPPG
Table 11: Comparison of the performance of the democratic governments as reflected
in key macroeconomic variables: 1974–2005
Variable
Pinochet
1974–89
Concertación
1990–2005
Government
Aylwin
1990–93
2.9
5.6
7.7
5.4
4.3
Export growth (%)a
10.7
8.5
9.6
9.7
6.5
Inflation
79.9
7.8
17.7
6.1
2.9
Unemployment
18.1
8.3
7.3
7.4
10.0D
Real Wages (1970=100)
81.9
122.3D
99.8
123.4
138.9D
Gross fixed investment
(% of GDP)E
15.3
23.8
21.0
25.4
24.5
0.3
0.8D
1.6
1.1
0.0D
0.7D
0.4
0.8
0.8D
GDP growth (%)a
B
C
National government
surplus (% of GDP)
Structural surplus (% of
GDP)
D
Frei R.-T.
1994–99
Lagos
2000–05
Sources: Taken from Ffrench-Davis (2003, table I.1) and updatings of Ffrench-Davis. Based on Banco Central de Chile and DIPRES.
The 2005 figures are very provisional. Quoted by Huneeus, C. Party coalitions. ‘¿Un nuevo escenario para el sistema partidista
chileno?’ Revista Política. Santiago, vol. 45, spring 2005.
A
Annual cumulative GDP and export growth rates; average annual inflation and unemployment rates.
B
December to December.
C
Included as unemployed are workers in special job programs, without whom the figures are 13.3% in 1974–89, 7.3% in
1994–99 and 9.0% in 2000–04.
D
Figures as of 2004.
E
In 1996 pesos.
Table 12: Poor and indigent population, 1990–2006
Indigencia
Pobreza no indigente
Total pobreza
1990
2006
1,674,736
3,293,566
4,968,302
516,738
1,692,199
2,208,937
Variación porcentual
-69.1
-48.6
-55.5
Source: 2006 CASEN Survey
Chart 2: Poverty and Indigence over time, 1990–2006 (%)
Source: 2006 CASEN survey
18
iPPG
Table13: Economic growth and poverty
Variaciones
Elasticidades
Años
PIB
%
Pobreza
%
Indigencia
%
Pobreza
Indigencia
1992/90
21.1
-11.2
-27.5
-0.53
-1.30
1994/92
13.1
-13.5
-13.9
-1.03
-1.06
1996/94
18.8
-13.0
-21.3
-0.69
-1.13
1998/96
10.0
-4.6
1.5
-0.45
-0.15
2000/98
3.7
-4.6
1.5
-1.23
-0.41
2003/00
9.8
-4.4
-13.3
-0.45
-1.36
2006/03
16.51
-24.9
-28.9
-1.45
-1.75
Puntos porcentuales
Table 14: Income distribution in Chile
Indice 20/20
Indice 10/40
Coeficiente de Gini
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
14.0
3.5
0.58
13.2
3.3
0.57
14.3
3.5
0.58
14.6
3.5
0.57
15.5
3.5
0.58
15.3
3.6
0.58
* Se excluye al servicio doméstico puertas adentro y su núcleo familiar.
Fuente: MIDEPLAN, Encuestas CASEN 1990–2000.
Table 15: Autonomous income, distributive gap and Gini coefficient, 1990–2006
Años
Indice 20/20
Coeficiente de Gini
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2003
2006
13.98
13.17
14.01
14.83
15.57
14.41
14.51
13.10
0.57
0.56
0.57
0.57
0.58
0.58
0.57
0.54
*Personas
Source: 2006 CASEN survey.
As far as poverty is concerned, the governments of the Concertación have, among other measures,
implemented a sustained increase in social spending, created special agencies such as FOSIS under the
Ministry of Planning and Cooperation (MIDEPLAN) to deal with projects initiated by the actors themselves,
a national commission to address poverty, and the Chile Solidario and Puente programmes, which provide
very significant direct assistance for which all indigent families are eligible. In addition, recent social
policy goes beyond these specific targets to promote and ensure respect for welfare-state entitlements.
Examples are the Plan Auge healthcare programme, the expansion of preschool education and the
projected pension reform.
It is worthy of note that the latest CASEN survey data, released in June 2007 and reflected in the
above tables, show an improvement in terms of poverty and indigence as a result of the government’s
principles and programmes. However, two reservations must be noted. First, there is debate on the way in
which poverty is calculated, since poverty would be roughly double what CASEN shows if the value of the
market basket of basic goods were recalculated in today’s terms.6 This is not to deny the positive trend.
However, it is important to see the statistics in light of this constraint. Second, it is clear that however it is
calculated, the ‘poverty line’ remains no more than a statistical reality, not a sociological one, for people
may be above the line and yet lack the structural conditions for sustainability and be quite vulnerable to
falling below the line. In other words, a person or family may be above the poverty line at a given time,
but continue to be poor sociologically speaking.
As far as income distribution is concerned, only recently has a certain degree of improvement occurred.
However, even this is more apparent than real, if distribution is considered in terms of deciles or percentiles.7
Also, the distribution of autonomous income improves considerably in favor of the poorest when the State
intervenes through aid and subsidies.
6.
7.
Felipe Larraín, El Mercurio (1 July 2007). Hugo Fazio, Carta Económica (17 June 2007) Santiago.
H. Fazio, op. cit.
19
iPPG
6. suMMary
anD
conclusions
The classic Chilean socio-political matrix favoured the articulation and intertwining of social forces and
political parties. It was they – centre and left in concert in the 1930s, and separately in the 1960s – that
constituted the ‘redistribution coalition,’8 expressing the central role of government policy in defining and
managing development.
The military regime and the socio-economic changes that it implemented marked the advent of a new
development model, and had a significance beyond the mere disarticulation of the society as it existed
until the 1970s, which the military regime attempted to replace by something that, in its pure form, was
a neoliberal utopian vision that went beyond simply releasing the economy from all political control, to
actually subordinating politics to the economy. Market mechanisms were posited as the new ‘backbone’
of essential social actors that would replace representation by political parties as the State’s central point
of reference.
The military regime was successful at dismantling the previous matrix. However, it did not achieve
the goal of replacing it with a neoliberal one. Though the old socioeconomic model was thrown out, the
neoliberal model was not consistently applied where growth strategy was not concerned, at least from
the time a democratic regime (of low quality though it may be) came in. Though the previous model was
dismantled, elements of it remain alongside features of the neoliberal model, and other features that
belong to neither of the two models.
Thus, post-transition Chile presents the opposite of Aníbal Pinto’s classic description of the classic
matrix,9 which points to the basic contradiction between an atrophied economy and a developed political,
institutional and cultural system. From this weakness of the economic system emerged the idea of making
the economy autonomous of its political ties. Today, the problem is precisely the reverse. The economy is
taking off (or at least has been, with the exception of the period between the mid-1990s and 2005), but
what it has primarily ‘taken off’ from is the country and its society. Meanwhile, back on the ground, we
face an atrophied political, institutional and cultural system, as the extant enclaves of authoritarianism10
make clear—namely the country’s Constitution and institutional structure, a climate of impunity vis-àvis human right violations under the dictatorship, merely partial solution of the problems of the judicial
system, the presence of non-democratic Pinochet-oriented actors in the political system, the weaknesses
of the decentralization and regionalization process, the crisis of the educational system and collapse of
higher education, the enormous weakness of social actors, especially where they must negotiate with
economic power, the barely overcome backwardness of institutions dealing with the family,11 and the
difficulty of defining a new directing and protecting role for the State. Though the democratic regime has
certainly progressed in a number of these areas, the advances are inevitably partial, because they remain
circumscribed by the inherited institutional framework. Meanwhile, the nature of the socioeconomic model
has blocked access to the institutional resources needed to confront economic crises such as those of
1998 and 1999.
We would seem, then, to be facing a socio-political matrix or society that is a hybridized version of the
twentieth-century matrix. There are some features of continuity, and others that are in sharp contradiction
to the past model, while yet other, emerging, features must be defined on their own terms.12
The discontinuity consists in the fact that the economy has achieved its autonomy from politics, and
has apparently been surrendered to its own development dynamic, which the State may place constraints
on, but not define the direction of. Now, this does not mean that the economy is organized in such a way
as to optimize national development. For while it the economy is now autonomous of politics and the
State, it is subordinate to, or dependent on, transnational market forces. The central fact is perhaps, as
we mentioned above, that the socioeconomic growth model is no longer a development model. To put
it another way, the economy by itself cannot ensure social integration, as the employment dilemma, for
example, clearly illustrates.
The social conflicts would seem to reflect the contradictions of a country that deals fairly well with its
short-term economic problems, but that has left pending, or dealt poorly with, its institutional, political
and cultural problems, not to mention the issue of a long-term socially-sustainable development model
– i.e., one in which the central problem of social inequality is addressed. The response of the democratic
governments to the development formulas followed before and during the military dictatorship has been
a strategy defined as ‘development with equity.’ However, despite success in economic growth (up to the
8.
S. Wiggins, A. Schejtman and G. Gray (2006) ‘Bolivia case study; an interpretative summary’. IPPG Working Paper.
9.
See A. Pinto (2001).
10.
M.A. Garretón (1995) Hacia una nueva era politica. Estudio sobre las democratizaciones. Fondo de Cultura Económica.
11.
Recall that until the beginning of the present decade, Chile was the only western country without legal divorce. On the
other hand, there has been important progress in such areas as paternity and children’s parental origin and dependency, domestic
violence, child custody and gender discrimination.
12.
On the changes in Chilean society in the last decades, see Various authors (2003) Cuánto y cómo cambiamos los chilenos.
Balance de una década. Santiago: Cuadernos del Bicenterario.
20
iPPG
1997-98 crisis), poverty reduction and social spending, socioeconomic inequality persists (see Tables 14
and 15), and has even become worse in some cases.13
It is clear that Chile’s central problem can no longer be defined as ‘the transition to democracy and a
market economy,’ as was maintained a decade ago, in the early 1990s. If we have achieved democracy, but
it the democracy is weak, we are no longer in transition, but in need of deep political reform. Meanwhile,
the neoliberal market economy, or ‘privatization,’ model has exhausted itself as a basis for integral, selfsustaining national development – not only in Chile, but around the world. Caught between globalisation
and the need to turn the helm back over to the Nation State and its alliances, the world shifts uneasily
today.
Since the clock cannot be turned back to ‘put the economy in its place’ as subordinate to the political
sphere, we must conceive new alternatives that give the State and supra-national blocs a new guiding
role in development. We must establish frameworks to regulate market forces, and to ensure citizens’
control over both the frameworks and the forces. In other words, recognizing politics and economis as
distinct and autonomous, we must introduce the ethnical principles of democracy in the functioning of
markets.
Put another way: What is at stake in the coming years is the existence of the country as a community
with a collective meaning that reflects its plurality and diversity. The national vision, the nation’s living
together peacefully, the identities that make the nation up, and their autonomous insertion in the globalized
world – these are the essence of politics today.
Thus, the fundamental problems of post-transition Chile have to do with the organization of the polis,
the ability to create direction, the challenge of making the political process respond to the country’s cultural
and social problems, and the need to link the economy with the general development of the society. This
means that there is no present crisis of political legitimacy as such, even among young people.14 The crisis
that we face has to do with the political capacity and activity needed to create awareness of the political
sphere, and to prevent it from simply turning about itself. Thus, though we have no crisis of legitimacy at
present, such a crisis is a long-term risk.
Today, the freezing of the political/institutional dimension to an economic base that is dependent on
the transnational economy is a result of two factors. The first is the presence of institutional enclaves of
authoritarianism defended by the right which is the heir of the military regime. The second is the absence
of alternative models and proposals of a political/cultural nature. One of the reasons for this is the very
success of the Concertación governments. In the absence of such models or proposals, the ‘natural forces’
of the transnational economy dominate the scene.
It would seem to be very early to answer the question of whether we are looking at an emerging matrix
of relations between the State and society, or whether we are witnessing a transition to some other model
as yet unknown. The questions posed by the world economic situation and the future of globalization and
economic integration accentuate the uncertainty.
In any case, the future of Chilean society lies in its ability to construct a social-political system that
restores the idea of a national community that is something more than a market or a set of instruments
and techniques. What the country needs is no longer an ‘economic miracle,’ but a great leap forward in
the political, institutional and cultural dimensions.
13.
MIDEPLAN (2006) Distribución del Ingreso e Impacto Distributivo del Gasto Social, 2006 Serie análisis de resultados de la
Encuesta de Caracterización socioeconómica nacional Nº 2
14.
This does not mean that young people are not structurally distanced from politics, or that the distance has not affected the
legitimacy of politics. M.A. Garretón and V. Villanueva (1999) Política u jóvenes en Chile. Una reformulación. Santiago: Participa and
Fundación F. Ebert.
21
iPPG
Table 16: Summary
Period
Socio-political
matrix and social
actors
Politicalinstitutional
context
Economic reforms
Results/social
effects (poverty)
1930–
1973
Statist-national,
popular,
political-partyorientated
Economic crisis
and replanning
for active State
role in the
economy
Social and
productive
infrastructure
created through
State action; import
substitution model
implemented
Living conditions
improve
momentarily,
thanks to State
support, but
the system
subsequently
collapses
Coup d’état,
elimination
of Congress,
prohibition
of political
parties, violent
dictatorship
State apparatus
dismantled,
economic activity
privatised,
neo-liberalism
established
Macro-economic
indicators
stabilized, jobs and
social programmes
sacrificed.
Return to
democracy, with
adjustments to
the dictatorship’s
neoliberal
model; gradual
democratization,
with subsisting
legacies from
the dictatorship
Modernization
of the State,
deregulation of
markets, increased
social spending,
privatization
In 16 years,
poverty is reduced
nearly 50%, but
inequality remains
at one of the
highest levels in
the world.
State, parties,
workers
1973–
1990
Dismantling of
socio-political
matrix
State (armed
forces), business
1990–
2007
Hybrid matrix:
corrected
neoliberal model
plus social
democratic
elements
Business, State,
parties
22
iPPG
biblioGraPhy
Angell, Alan (1993) ‘Chile Since 1958’ in Leslie Bethell, ed., Chile Since Independence. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Banco Central de Chile (1995) ‘Modernización de la gestión pública en Chile. Antecedentes, orientaciones
actuales y avances’. Paper presented at Seminario Experiencias Internacionales de la Gestión Pública y su
Relevancia para Chile, Santiago, March.
Boeninger, Edgardo (1997) Democracia en Chile. Lecciones para la gobernabilidad. Santiago: Editorial
Andrés Bello.
Braun Juan et al. (2002) ‘Economía chilena 1810–1995: Estadísticas Históricas’. Working document no.
187, Instituto de Economía, Universidad Católica de Chile.
Bulmer-Thomas, Víctor (1998) La historia económica de América Latina desde la independencia. Mexico
City: Fondo de Cultura Económica.
Corbo, Vitorio (1988) ‘Problemas, teorías del desarrollo y estrategias en América Latina’. Estudios
Públicos, no. 32.
Correa S., Sofía et al. (2001) Historia del siglo XX chileno: balance paradojal. Santiago: Editorial
Sudamericana.
Cunill, Nuria (1997) Repensando lo público a través de la sociedad. Nuevas formar de gestión pública
y representación social. Caracas: Nueva Sociedad.
Del Pozo, José (2002) Historia de América Latina y el Caribe 1825–2001. Santiago: LOM.
Díaz, Álvaro (1994) ‘Tendencias de la reestructuración económica y social en Latinoamérica.’ Revista
Mexicana de Sociología, no. 14 (October-December).
Drake, Paul (1993) ‘Chile 1930–1958’ in Leslie Bethell, ed., Chile Since Independence. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Drake, Paul and Iván Jaksic, eds. (1999) El modelo chileno: democracia y desarrollo en los noventa.
Santiago: LOM Ediciones.
Evans, Peter. (1995) Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Ffrench-Davis, Ricardo (1973) Políticas Económicas en Chile 1957–1970. Santiago: CIEPLAN - Catholic
University of Chile.
Ffrench-Davis, Ricardo (1990) ‘Desarrollo económico, inestabilidad y desequilibrios políticos en Chile.
1950–1989’. Colección Estudios, no. 28, Santiago: CIEPLAN.
Ffrench-Davis, Ricardo (2004) Entre neoliberalismo y crecimiento con equidad. Tres décadas de política
económica en Chile. Siglo XXI Editores: Buenos Aires.
Ffrench-Davis, Ricardo and Dagmar Raczynski (1990) ‘The Impact of Global Recession and National
Policies on Living Standards: Chile 1973–1989’. Notas Técnicas, no. 97 (November), Santiago: CIEPLAN.
Flisfisch, Angel (1993) ‘Los desafíos del Estado chileno en la década de los noventa’ in Klaus Bodemer,
ed., La reforma del Estado: más allá de la privatización. Montevideo: FESUR.
Fuenzalida, L. (1987) ‘Ocupación, desigualdades y pobreza. aspectos crónicos y política económica de
largo plazo’. Estudios Públicos, no. 28’.
Fundación Nacional para la Superación de la Pobreza (FNSP) (1996) ‘La pobreza en Chile’. Un desafío
de equidad e integración social, 1: 52. Santiago: FNSP.
Ghai, Yash P., Robin Luckham and Francis G. Snyder, eds. (1988) The Political Economy of Law: A
Third- World Reader. Delhi and New York: Oxford University Press.
23
iPPG
Garretón, Manuel Antonio (1994) ‘New Relations between State and Society in Latin America’ Colin
Bradford, ed., in Redefining the State in Latin America. Paris: OECD.
Garretón, Manuel Antonio (1995) Hacia una nueva era política. Estudio sobre las democratizaciones.
Santiago: Fondo de Cultura Económica.
Garretón, Manuel Antonio (1996) ‘Transformación del Estado en América Latina.’ Espacios Revista
Centroamericana de Cultura Política, no. 6, October-December.
Garretón, Manuel Antonio (1999) ‘Balance y perspectivas de la democratización política chilena’
in Amparo Menéndez-Carrión and Alfredo Joignant Rondón, eds. La caja de Pandora. El retorno de la
transición chilena. Santiago: Planeta/Ariel.
Garretón, Manuel Antonio (2000a) La sociedad en que vivi(re)mos. Introducción sociológica al fin de
siglo. Santiago: LOM Editores.
Garretón, Manuel Antonio (2000b) Política y sociedad entre dos épocas: América Latina en el cambio
de siglo. Rosario, Argentina: Ediciones Horno Sapiens.
Garretón, Manuel Antonio (2003?) ‘La (in)conducción política del segundo gobierno democrático’ in
compilation on Frei government, currently being prepared. Santiago: FLACSO.
Garretón, Manuel Antonio and Malva Espinosa (1992) ‘Reforma del Estado o cambio en la matriz sociopolítica.’ Perfiles Latinoamericanos. Mexico City.
Garretón, Manuel Antonio and Malva Espinosa (1994) ‘From the Adjustment Policies to the New Relations
between the State and Society.’ Paris: Independent Commission for Population and Quality of Life.
Garretón, Manuel Antonio and Malva Espinosa (1995) ‘Tendencias de cambio en la matriz socio-política
chilena. Una aproximación empírica’. Final report, Fondecyt project. Santiago (March).
Gomez Sergio and Jorge Echenique (1998) La agricultura Chilena. Las dos caras de la modernización.
Santiago: FLACSO Chile
Góngora, Mario (1986) Ensayo histórico sobre la noción de Estado en Chile en los siglos XIX y XX.
Santiago: Editorial Universitaria.
Hachette, Dominique (2000) ‘Privatizaciones: Reforma estructural pero inconclusa’ in Felipe Larraín
and Rodrigo Vergara, eds., La transformación económica. Santiago: CEP.
Heise, Julio (1977) ‘150 años de evolución institucional’. Editorial Andrés Bello, Santiago.
Lagos, Ricardo (2000) Presidential address of 21 May 2000. Santiago: Ministerio Secretaría General
de Gobierno.
Lagos, Ricardo (2001) Presidential address of 21 May 2000. Santiago: Ministerio Secretaría General
de Gobierno.
Larraín, Felipe and Rodrigo Vergara, eds. (2000) La transformación económica de Chile. Santiago:
CEP.
Marcel, Mario (1989) ‘Privatización y finanzas públicas.’ Colección Estudios, no. 26. Santiago:
CIEPLAN.
Marcel, Mario and Carolina Tohá (1998) ‘Reforma del Estado y la gestión pública’ in René Cortazar and
Joaquín Vial, eds., Construyendo Opciones. Propuestas Económicas y Sociales para el Cambio de Siglo.
Santiago: CIEPLAN-DOMEN.
Martner, Gonzalo (1988) ‘El gobierno del presidente Salvador Allende, 1970–1973: una evaluación’.
Concepción, Chile: Programa de Estudios del Desarrollo Nacional: Ediciones Literatura Americana
Reunida.
Meller, Patricio (1996) Un siglo de economía política chilena. 1880–1990. Santiago: Editorial Andrés
Bello.
24
iPPG
Menéndez-Carrión, Amparo and Alfredo Joignant Rondón (1999) La caja de Pandora. El retorno de la
transición chilena. Santiago: Editorial Planeta/Ariel.
Moulián, Tomás (1982) ‘Desarrollo político en Chile’. Colección de Estudios, no. 18. Santiago:
CIEPLAN.
Moulián, Tomás (1997) Chile actual. Anatomía de un mito. Santiago: Ediciones LOM.
Muñoz, Oscar (1998) ‘Estado, mercado y política. Chile en los años noventa’ in René Cortazar and
Joaquín Vial, eds., Construyendo Opciones. Propuestas Económicas y Sociales para el Cambio de Siglo.
Santiago: CIEPLAN-DOMEN.
North Douglass C. (2000) ‘La evolución histórica de las formas de gobierno.’ Revista de Economía
Institucional, Colombia.
Oyarce, Héctor (1997) ‘Los procesos de modernización, el Estado y la política.’ Santiago. Manuscript.
Pinto, Anibal (1971) Tres ensayos sobre América Latina y Chile. Buenos Aires: Solar-Hachette.
United Nations Development Programme (UNPD) (1994) Human Development Report. New York.
Raczynski, Dagmar (1994) ‘Políticas sociales y programas de combate a la pobreza en Chile: balance
y desafíos’. Colección de Estudios, no. 39. Santiago: CIEPLAN.
Riveros, Luis (1985) ‘Desempleo distribución del ingreso y política social.’ Revista CEP, no. 20.
Smith, William C., Carlos H. Acuña and Eduardo A. Gamarra, eds. (1994) Latin American Political
Economy in the Age of Neoliberal Reform: Theoretical and Comparative Perspectives for the 1990s. Coral
Gables, Fla.: North-South Centre, University of Miami Press.
Suárez, Christian (1990) ‘Reseña del Gobierno de Chile.’ Selección de Documentos Clave 7, Caracas:
CLAD.
Toloza, Cristián and Eugenio Lahera (1998) Chile en los noventa. Santiago: Dolmen Ediciones.
Various authors (2003) Cuánto y cómo cambiamos los chilenos. Balance de una década. Santiago:
Cuadernos del Bicentenario.
Vergara, Pilar (1985) Auge y caída del neo liberalismo en Chile. Santiago: FLACSO.
Wiggins, S., A. Shejtman and G. Gray (2006) ‘Bolivia case study: an interpretative summary’. IPPG
Working Paper Series.
25