ECN-C--04-094
ENERGY TRENDS FOR EUROPE IN A
GLOBAL PERSPECTIVE
Baseline projections by twelve E3-models in the
CASCADE MINTS project
M.A. Uyterlinde (ed.)
G.H. Martinus (ed.)
E. van Thuijl (ed.)
K. Akimoto
M. Blesl
C. Böhringer
I. Ellersdorfer
T. Homma
I. Keppo
N. Kouvaritakis
A.S. Kydes
S. Kypreos
A. Löschel
L. Mantzos
P. Le Mouël
V. Panos
P. Rafaj
K. Riahi
P. Russ
F. Sano
L. Szabo
T. Tomoda
G. Totschnig
M. Zeka-Paschou
The CASCADE MINTS project is funded by the EU
under the Scientific Support to Policies priority
of the Sixth RTD Framework Programme
DECEMBER 2004
Preface
The CASCADE MINTS project on ‘CAse Study Comparisons And Development of Energy
Models for INtegrated Technology Systems’ is partially funded by the EU under the Scientific
Support to Policies priority of the Sixth RTD Framework Programme. More information on the
project can be found on www.e3mlab.ntua.gr/cascade.html.
The following partners are involved in Part 2 of the Cascade Mints project:
• Energy research Centre of the Netherlands (ECN) (The Netherlands); coordination/MARKAL model.
• ICSS/NTUA - E3MLAB (Greece); PRIMES and PROMETHEUS models.
• The International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA) (Austria); MESSAGE
model
• IPTS (Institute for Prospective Technological Studies), Joint Research Centre, EC (Spain);
POLES model.
• Paul Scherrer Institute (PSI) (Switzerland); GMM model.
• The Centre for European Economic Research GmbH (ZEW) (Germany); PACE model.
• The Institute for Energy Economics and the Rational Use of Energy (IER) (Germany);
TIMES-EE and NEWAGE-W models.
• ERASME-Équipe de Recherche en Analyse des Systèmes et Modélisation Économiques,
University of Paris (France); NEMESIS model.
• International Energy Agency (France); ETP model.
• U.S. DOE/EIA Energy Information Administration of the U.S. Department of Energy
(USA); NEMS model.
• Research Institute of Innovative Technology for the Earth (Japan); DNE21+ model.
• National Institute for Environmental Studies (Japan); AIM model.
• Natural Resources Canada (Canada); MAPLE model.
The authors wish to thank Ian Hayhow (Natural Resources Canada) for providing constructive
comments, and Cees Volkers (ECN) for developing the analysis tool.
For more information, please contact:
Ms. Martine A. Uyterlinde,
[email protected]
Energy research Centre of the Netherlands, Policy Studies department
Abstract
In the coming decades, Europe’s energy system is facing a number of challenges. Some of
these, such as the enhanced greenhouse effect and depletion of fossil fuel resources have a
worldwide dimension. Consequently, the strategies for tackling these issues must be designed
taking worldwide developments into account. Alternative energy sources and new technologies
will have to play a key role. In the analysis of the potential impact of new technologies and the
evaluation of possible policy options, energy - economy - environment (E3) models can provide
useful insights. In the CASCADE MINTS project, these E3 models have been used to evaluate
possible developments of the world energy system and the implications for Europe.
The objectives of this report are first to document the baseline assumptions and results in the
project as a basis for analysis of policy cases. Secondly the report aims at providing information
to policy makers, based on a scientific consensus among modellers, on possible developments in
a world with moderate GDP and population growth, with no additional policies in place. The
variety of technological and other assumptions in the different models causes a range in the results that reflects the uncertainty inherent to any projection of future developments.
2
ECN-C--04-094
CONTENTS
LIST OF TABLES
5
LIST OF FIGURES
5
POLICY BRIEF
8
1.
INTRODUCTION
1.1 The CASCADE MINTS project
1.2 Report overview
16
16
17
2.
ENERGY MODELS IN CASCADE MINTS PART 2
2.1 Classifying different types of energy models
2.1.1 Top down models
2.1.2 Bottom-up models
2.1.3 Classification summary
18
18
19
19
20
3.
KEY ASSUMPTIONS FOR HARMONISATION
3.1 Introduction
3.2 Choice of baseline scenario
3.3 Initial conditions to be harmonised
3.4 GDP and population
3.5 Energy prices
3.6 Policies
3.6.1 General guidelines
3.6.2 Primary energy sources
3.6.3 End-use of energy carriers
3.6.4 Emissions
3.6.5 Regional assumptions
21
21
22
23
24
26
27
27
27
28
30
32
4.
BASELINE GLOBAL ENERGY OUTLOOK
4.1 Introduction
4.2 World primary energy
4.2.1 Primary energy consumption more than doubles
4.2.2 Fossil fuels remain dominant
4.2.3 Security of supply will become a world wide issue
4.2.4 Coal production grows faster than oil and gas production
4.3 Improvements in energy intensity
4.4 World final energy and electricity consumption
4.4.1 Consensus on the growth of final energy demand, but not on the level
4.5 World electricity and hydrogen production
4.5.1 Electricity increasingly important
4.5.2 Much uncertainty on the future of renewables and nuclear power
4.5.3 Hydrogen plays a modest role, at best
4.6 Energy-related CO2 emissions
4.6.1 CO2 emissions are directly related to the primary energy mix
4.6.2 Varying developments for CO2 emission indicators
4.7 Other GHG emissions
4.8 NOx emissions
4.9 SOx emissions
33
33
33
33
34
35
38
40
42
42
43
43
45
46
47
47
48
50
50
51
5.
52
52
BASELINE OUTLOOK FOR EUROPE
5.1 Introduction
5.2 Primary energy consumption in Europe grows less than world energy
consumption
5.3 Primary consumption grows less than GDP, but faster than population
5.4 Primary consumption is still dominated by fossil fuels
ECN-C--04-094
53
53
55
3
5.5
5.6
5.7
5.8
5.9
6.
Import dependency will increase significantly
5.5.1 Diversity in the European primary fuel mix relatively constant
5.5.2 Highest dependency for oil - up to 85%
5.5.3 Sources of oil imports
5.5.4 A dash for gas
5.5.5 The European response to natural gas demand
Final energy demand in Western Europe grows less than GDP
5.6.1 No major change in sectoral structure of final demand
5.6.2 Final consumption of electricity
Technologies for power generation in Europe
Energy-related CO2 emissions
5.8.1 CO2 emissions grow along with primary energy consumption
5.8.2 Large variety in CO2 emissions projections power sector
5.8.3 Strong decline in carbon intensity of GDP but constant CO2 emissions
per GJ
5.8.4 Relatively high increase of CO2 emissions from transport sector
CH4 emission reduction important to mitigating the greenhouse effect
57
58
59
60
61
61
62
63
64
65
67
67
69
69
72
73
KEY MESSAGES
74
6.1 Twelve models use one baseline scenario to provide a comprehensive outlook
on future developments
74
6.2 World energy trends until 2050
74
6.3 Europe in a global context
75
6.4 Challenge: Security of supply
76
6.5 Challenge: Climate change
77
6.6 Strategies and directions
78
REFERENCES
APPENDIX A
79
KEY CHARACTERISTICS OF THE ENERGY MODELS
80
APPENDIX B
IMPLEMENTATION OF HARMONISED BASELINE ASSUMPTIONS
IN MODELS
B.1 PRIMES
B.2 PROMETHEUS
B.3 MARKAL
B.4 MESSAGE
B.5 POLES
B.6 GMM
B.7 PACE
B.8 NEWAGE-W
B.9 TIMES-EE
B.10 NEMESIS
B.11 DNE21+
B.12 NEMS
4
84
84
86
89
89
90
91
92
93
94
95
97
98
ECN-C--04-094
LIST OF TABLES
Table 2.1
Table 3.1
Table 3.2
Table 3.3
Table 3.4
Table 3.5
Table 3.6
Table 5.1
General overview of the models used in CASCADE MINTS Part 2
World growth rate of GDP, for Market Exchange Rate (MER) and Purchasing
Power Parity metrics
Proposed upper bounds for total capacity of nuclear power plants in the EU15
in the baseline scenario (WEPP, 2003)
Activity levels of renewable energy systems from the ADMIRE-REBUS model,
under the assumption of unchanged policies until 2010
Capacity level of renewable energy systems from the ADMIRE-REBUS model,
under the assumption of unchanged policies until 2010
CO2 emission targets for ACEA, JAMA and KAMA for passenger cars
Assumptions on energy-related SO2 emissions in the B2 scenario (IIASA-B2)
Regional coverage in European models
18
25
28
29
30
31
32
52
LIST OF FIGURES
Figure P.1 Development of GDP per region and share of these regions in world GDP
Figure P 2 Development of primary energy consumption by regions
Figure P.3 Fuel mix of primary energy consumption in the world and Western Europe,
2050
Figure P.4 Europe’s energy intensity of GDP compared to other world regions
Figure P.5 Shares of production and imports of oil and natural gas (Western Europe)
Figure P.6 Range among models in average energy related CO2 emissions projections
Figure P.7 Range among models in average energy related CO2 emissions projections in
Western Europe
9
10
Figure 1.1
Figure 2.1
Figure 3.1
Figure 3.2
16
20
21
Overview of the CASCADE MINTS project
Classification summary
Level of harmonisation of initial conditions in CASCADE MINTS
Four IPCC/SRES scenario families and their general characteristics (IPCC,
2000)
Figure 4.1 Total global primary energy consumption for the various models
Figure 4.2 Mix of primary energy use in various models, where we distinguish between
major categories: fossil, nuclear, renewables, and other; in the year 2030
Figure 4.3 Percentage of the total world oil production that is produced in the region
encompassing the Middle East
Figure 4.4 The probability distribution for the ratio of Middle East oil production to total
World oil production (mean: 0.59, standard deviation: 0.084)
Figure 4.5 Probability distribution of the maximal increase in oil price in any three-year
period between 2000 and 2030 (mean: 15.9, standard deviation: 5.904)
Figure 4.6 World oil production for the various models
Figure 4.7 World coal production per region, according to GMM
Figure 4.8 World gas production for the various models
Figure 4.9 Probability distribution of the ratio of the gas to oil price in 2030 (mean: 0.67,
standard deviation: 0.17)
Figure 4.10 Energy intensity as function of the gross energy consumption per capita for the
various regions in GMM and NEMS (USA). The Other OECD region includes
Europe. Other models show similar trends for the various regions.
ECN-C--04-094
10
11
12
13
14
23
34
35
36
37
37
38
38
39
40
41
5
Figure 4.11 Gross inland consumption per unit of GDP as function of the GDP per capita
for the various regions in GMM, and for the USA according to NEMS. Other
models show similar trends
Figure 4.12 Total final energy consumption for the various world models
Figure 4.13 Electricity demand in the world models show very similar trends
Figure 4.14 Contribution of electricity to the final energy demand in the five world regions
distinguished in GMM, and in the world as a whole
Figure 4.15 Contribution from renewable energy sources (RES), nuclear energy, gas, and
coal in the power sector as percentage of total electricity generated generally
shows widely varying trend, reflecting uncertainty on the future electricity
system
Figure 4.16 Contribution from renewable energy sources to the power sector: percentage
of total electricity generated, for the regions in GMM.
Figure 4.17 Contribution from nuclear energy to the power sector: percentage of total
electricity generated, for the regions in GMM.
Figure 4.18 Total production of hydrogen in three world models shows a large variation,
both in the level and in the time of uptake. Note the logarithmic scale
Figure 4.19 Energy-related CO2 emissions on global level; total and power sector only for
2000-2050
Figure 4.20 Development of CO2 emissions per capita in the period 2000-2050
Figure 4.21 Development of CO2 emissions per unit of GDP in the period 2000-2050
Figure 4.22 Development of CO2 emissions per unit of gross inland energy consumption in
the period 2000-2050
Figure 5.1 Total primary energy consumption
Figure 5.2 Primary energy intensity (Gross inland consumption/GDP) compared for
Western Europe, the new Member States, the US and the world. Other models
show similar trends
Figure 5.3 Gross inland consumption/capita compared for Western Europe, the new
Member States, the US and the world. Other models show similar trends
Figure 5.4 Primary consumption by fuel in Western Europe in the year 2000; total 68,771
PJ 55
Figure 5.5 Primary energy consumption by fuel in Western Europe in 2030
Figure 5.6 Primary consumption by fuel in the new Member States in the year 2000; total
8,380 PJ
Figure 5.7 Net imports as share of gross inland consumption
Figure 5.8 Import dependency and diversity indices in Western Europe
Figure 5.9 Oil production and imports in Western and Central Europe
Figure 5.10 World oil reserves
Figure 5.11 Natural gas production and net imports to Western Europe by region of origin
Figure 5.12 Share of imports in gross primary consumption of natural gas in 2030
Figure 5.13 Final energy demand in different European regions
Figure 5.14 Final energy intensity for Western Europe compared to the world, the US and
the new Member States; other models show similar trends
Figure 5.15 Final energy demand in Western Europe by sector in 2000 and 2030; Total:
45.7 EJ in 2000 and 57.3 EJ in 2030
Figure 5.16 Contribution of electricity to the final energy demand
Figure 5.17 Final electricity demand by sector in the EU-30
Figure 5.18 Net electricity generation by fuel in Western Europe in 2000 (total 2698 TWh)
Figure 5.19 Net electricity generation by fuel in Europe in 2030
Figure 5.20 Energy-related CO2 emissions for Europe (WEU/EU-30) for 2000-2030
Figure 5.21 CO2 emissions from the power sector for Europe (WEU/EU-30) for 2000-2030
Figure 5.22 CO2 emissions per capita for WEU/EU-30/NMS/US for 2000-2030
Figure 5.23 Carbon intensity of GDP for WEU/EU-30/NMS/US for 2000-2030
Figure 5.24 CO2 emissions per GJ for WEU/EU-30/NMS/US for 2000-2030
Figure 5.25 CO2 emissions per kWh for WEU/EU-30/NMS/US for 2000-2030
6
42
43
44
44
45
46
46
47
48
49
49
50
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
60
61
62
62
63
64
65
65
66
67
68
69
70
70
71
72
ECN-C--04-094
Figure 5.26 Contributions of end-use sectors to total energy related CO2 emissions for
Western Europe and EU-30 for 2030 and 2050
Figure 5.27 Development of total CO2, CH4, N2O and Greenhouse Gas (GHG) emissions
(MARKAL)
Figure B 1 Distributions in 2030
ECN-C--04-094
72
73
88
7
POLICY BRIEF
In the coming decades, Europe’s energy system is facing a number of challenges. Some of
these, such as the enhanced greenhouse effect and depletion of fossil fuel resources have a
worldwide dimension. Consequently, the strategies for tackling these issues must be designed
taking worldwide developments into account. Alternative energy sources and new technologies
will have to play a key role. In the analysis of the potential impact of new technologies and the
evaluation of possible policy options, energy - economy - environment (E3) models can provide
useful insights. In the CASCADE MINTS project, twelve of these E3 models have been used to
evaluate possible developments of the world energy system and the implications for Europe.
This policy research comes right at a time when the EU has started a reflection on the actions on
climate change for the post-2012 period1, especially considering the benefits and costs and taking into account both environmental and competitiveness concerns.
The policy brief provides an outlook on global and European energy developments towards
2050, summarising the main results generated by these models. It reflects the scientific consensus among modellers concerning the baseline presented and the main policy messages included
in this brief. Although all models confirm the major trends, there are sometimes significant differences among individual model results, reflecting the different dynamics and assumptions and
indicating the impact of uncertainties in the future energy system. The graphs, presented in this
policy brief, show projections from different models, and should be regarded as illustrative of
the discussed trends, by no means the only possible paths. The models used in the baseline projections are: PRIMES, PROMETHEUS, MARKAL, MESSAGE, POLES, GMM, PACE, TIMES-EE,
NEWAGE-W, NEMESIS, NEMS and DNE21+.
Developments against a background of moderate economic growth
The outlook is based on a common, harmonised baseline scenario. The baseline will serve as a
benchmark against which policy scenarios will be compared in later stages of the project. It is
based on the B2 scenario from the IPCC Special Report on Emissions Scenarios, because this
scenario is characterised by a moderate economic and demographic growth. Some assumptions
of major importance in this scenario are listed below.
1
See http://europa.eu.int/comm/environment/climat/future_action.htm.
8
ECN-C--04-094
[bln Euro]
160,000
Middle East, Latin
America, Africa
100%
90%
140,000
Asia
120,000
80%
70%
Eastern Europe
and Former
Soviet Union
100,000
80,000
Pacific OECD
60%
50%
40%
60,000
Western Europe
40,000
30%
20%
20,000
North America
0
1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050
Figure P.1
10%
0%
1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050
Development of GDP per region and share of these regions in world GDP
In all regions of the world, the average GDP growth in the period 1990-2050 is lower than in
1950-1990. Asia shows by far the highest growth, while the economies in Western Europe,
North America, Japan and Australia grow at a lower pace than the other world regions. This increasing dominance of the developing countries has a direct impact on energy consumption and
greenhouse gas emissions. Despite the economic ‘catch up’, income differences between industrialised and developing countries remain significant.
Population growth is in line with current population trends and based on the UN median population projections from 1998. Global population increases to about 9.4 billion people by 2050.
Population growth is highest in the developing countries in Africa, Latin America, and the Middle East. It is significantly lower in Asia and North America, whereas the population of both
Europe and the Former Soviet Union remains almost constant until 2050.
Oil prices reflect assumptions of low to moderate resource availability. In the period 2000-2050,
the world oil price is projected to increase from 4.2 to 6.2 Euro2000/GJ, which is equivalent to a
range of ca. 26 to 38 US$95/barrel. Obviously there is a great deal of uncertainty to this assumption.
Only instrumented policies in force or approved on December 31st 2003 have been included in
the baseline scenario. Moreover, some representation of climate policy or emission trading for
the region of Europe has been included. This is reflected in a generic carbon tax of 10
Euro2000/tonne CO2 as from the year 2012.
A continuing worldwide reliance on fossil fuels
World primary energy consumption is expected to more than double in 2000-2050. This is a
consequence of the assumptions regarding moderate economic and population growth, implying
that a larger growth would also be possible. In line with the assumptions, Asia grows fastest,
and quadruples its energy consumption by 2050.
ECN-C--04-094
9
[EJ]
1.200
1.000
800
600
400
200
0
2000
Asia
2010
2020
Eastern Europe and Former Soviet Union
2030
Latin America and Africa
2040
North America
2050
Europe, Japan, Oceania
Figure P 2 Development of primary energy consumption by regions
All models indicate that fossil fuels are expected to remain dominant in the world fuel mix by
supplying 65-80% of primary energy use (Figure P.3). Combined with the growth in primary
energy consumption, this will result in an even faster depletion of the global natural resources
than today. Although Europe’s primary energy consumption shows a much slower growth than
the world average - some 20% until 2030 -its reliance on fossil fuels (70-75% of the primary
energy mix, depending on the model), is comparable to the rest of the world.
2050
World
21%
18%
Fossil fuels
4%
6%
Western
Europe
Nuclear
Renewables
76%
75%
Figure P.3 Fuel mix of primary energy consumption in the world and Western Europe, 2050
Although the models show a consistent picture of the share of fossil and non-fossil fuels in future primary energy mix, they deviate on the contributions of individual fuels. In Europe, particularly the prospects of solid fuels and nuclear energy differ, due to different assumptions on
technological development and costs. The power generation sector plays a key role in these fuel
and technology choices. Coal consumption is expected to stabilise or grow. Some models expect
nuclear energy to be phased out, due to high costs. There is a certain consensus on Europe’s
consumption of natural gas for power production, which is expected to increase significantly,
and on the moderately increasing consumption of oil, mainly in the transport sector. Developments of energy prices may play a key role here.
10
ECN-C--04-094
On world level, a similar variation in projections exists. One of the models includes constraints
on sulphur emissions, which induce a smaller share of particularly solids, and a substitution
with nuclear and renewables.
These observations have the following implications for Europe.
• Europe will encounter more competition on increasingly scarce fossil resources. Given
the limited domestic resource base, the growing dependency on imported fuels, particularly oil and natural gas, will bring about more risks of high prices and supply disruptions.
• The differences in projections of the primary energy mix indicate that there is room for
fuel switch, particularly in the power sector. The results indicate that the future
development of use of energy sources may substantially be influenced by policies,
such as emissions regulations and stimulating non-fossil fuels. Moreover, high oil and
gas prices might accelerate changes in Europe’s energy mix.
Energy savings increasingly important
Europe’s energy intensity is among the lowest in the world. In the current baseline projections,
Europe is expected to maintain this leading role. However, as illustrated in Figure P.4, the scope
for further efficiency improvements is more limited than in other world regions. On the other
hand, Europe’s energy consumption per capita is more than twice the world average, and keeps
increasing. The increasing trend is in line with developments in other world regions.
[PJ/bln€ ]
25
20
15
10
5
0
2000
US
2010
New Member States
World
2020
Western Europe
2030
Figure P.4 Europe’s energy intensity of GDP compared to other world regions
•
Recognising that Europe’s energy consumption is substantial but relatively efficient,
policy measures should focus on stimulating energy savings in order to slow down
the steady growth in energy consumption of the average European citizen.
Security of supply becomes a key issue
Given the continuing global reliance on fossil fuels, an important issue in the years to come will
be the increasing dependence on oil from the Middle East. Although the models show different
projections of the evolvement of oil production, they agree that the contribution from the Middle East region grows, and becomes substantially larger. Given the large uncertainty on future
oil price developments, confirmed by one of the models indicating that there is a substantial
ECN-C--04-094
11
probability of sudden increases in the oil price, this may lead to increased concerns about the
security of oil supply on the longer term, particularly in view of the present uncertain political
situation in the Middle East.
For Europe, trends are in line with the global developments. Europe’s oil consumption is expected to stabilise at about a third of its primary energy consumption in 2030. Domestic production however is expected to decrease due to limited reserves and high production costs, thereby
introducing a greater reliance on imports up to 85% (Figure P.5).
[%]
[%]
100
100
80
80
60
60
40
40
20
20
0
2000
0
2000
2010
Oil
d
i
2020
2030
2010
2020
2030
Imports (Russia and FSU)
Oil
Imports (Africa, Latin America, Middle East)
i
Natural gas production (Western Europe)
Figure P.5 Shares of production and imports of oil and natural gas (Western Europe)
For natural gas, Europe’s external dependency will also grow in the next decades. A continuing
growth in gas consumption combined with a decrease of gas production in the UK, the Netherlands and Norway, will lead to a higher share of imports from the two main suppliers Russia
and Algeria. Additionally, the accession of the new Member States and their heavy reliance on
supplies from Russia increases the risks related to gas supply security.
There is another dimension to security of supply than dependency on imported fuels. The level
of diversification is inversely related to the dependence on a few primary fuels, and is related to
the correlation between the fuels in terms of costs and availability. The level of diversification
may further influence the sensitivity of Europe to fuel supply disruptions.
•
•
12
Europe’s dependence on oil from the Middle East is expected to increase significantly in
the next decades. Given the prospect that other world regions will also increasingly rely
on oil from this region, this may indeed lead to further oil price increases, which will affect all economic sectors.
An increase in diversification – for instance a growing contribution from renewables –
may to a certain extent alleviate the increase in external dependence for oil and gas. In
the current analysis, the models show large differences in their projections of Europe’s
future fuel mix, and thus in the expected level of diversification. This suggests that new
policies may be required to stimulate an increased uptake of renewables or other
sources.
ECN-C--04-094
The challenge of climate change remains
It is highly likely that global warming is attributable to human activities, in particular to emissions of greenhouse gases. All models project a continuing growth of these emissions, of which
CO2 is the most important one. Overall, the CO2 emissions in 2030 are expected to be approximately twice the level of 1990, the base year of the Kyoto protocol. The largest growth is expected to occur in the developing world, in particular in Asia. There is a large variation in emissions projections between models, related to the differences in the primary energy mix, particularly the share of fossil fuels. These differences are due to different assumptions on technological development and the associated technology costs.
[Gton]
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
2000
2010
2020
2030
2040
2050
Figure P.6 Range among models in average energy related CO2 emissions projections
In Europe, CO2 emissions grow moderately, when compared to trends at world level (Figure
P.7). Still, Western Europe is not on track towards the targets agreed under the Kyoto Protocol.
Western Europe is committed to achieving an 8% reduction of CO2 emissions by 2008-2012, as
compared to the level in 1990. This means that in this period, the level of total CO2 emissions
(including non-energy uses) should not exceed approximately 3100 Mton per year. However, all
models indicate that the energy-related CO2 emissions alone are already expected to exceed this
level. The carbon tax of 10 euro/(ton CO2), included from 2012 onwards to reflect the assumption that some type of climate policies will be implemented, does not suffice to curb the growing trend in greenhouse gas emissions.
ECN-C--04-094
13
[Mton]
4500
4000
3500
3000
2500
2000
1500
1000
500
0
2000
2010
2020
Figure P.7 Range among models in average energy related CO2 emissions projections in
Western Europe
•
•
The results clearly indicate that under current policies, Europe will have severe difficulties achieving its Kyoto target. Therefore, additional instruments, such as emissions
trading with countries outside Europe (Annex A), based on the JI and CDM instruments, may have to play a key role in meeting Kyoto commitments.
Beyond 2012, a moderate carbon tax appears to be insufficient for curbing the trends in
Europe, as emissions are expected to continue their growth with some 0.4% annually. In
the rest of the world - in the absence of international incentives or regulation for mitigation - carbon emissions are expected to increase at a much higher pace, particularly in
the developing countries. Therefore post-Kyoto policies will need to be developed.
Given the large inertia in the energy system, short-term action is needed to foster the introduction of advanced and cleaner technologies, in order to enable these technologies
to play a significant role in the long term.
Outlook: strategies and directions
The analysis presented in this report has identified some major challenges that the world is facing today. The findings are in line with the Commission WETO report2 and the IEA World Energy Outlook 2004 (IEA, 2004). In the next phases of the CASCADE MINTS project, several
strategies will be explored that may help to counter these developments.
Renewables are indigenous and CO2 neutral, and therefore may improve diversification, and
avoid greenhouse gas emissions. However these technologies still face financial and other barriers, and will have to be stimulated ‘down the learning curve’. Questions to be explored include
the amount of support necessary and the potential of these sources.
Similarly, nuclear power is an energy supply option that may help mitigating the greenhouse
effect, but comes with other problems, such as the waste issue and the lack of political consensus.
2
See http://europa.eu.int/comm/research/energy/gp/gp_pu/article_1257_en.htm.
14
ECN-C--04-094
CO2 capture and storage is an alternative way to combat climate change while continuing the
use of fossil fuels, but many technical and institutional issues still need to be solved. The project
will evaluate the conditions and policy instruments that are required to make CO2 capture and
sequestration in old gas and oil fields or in aquifers become environmentally and economically
feasible.
Finally, the project will explore the prospect of a hydrogen economy, which may potentially
transform the complete energy system. The project will evaluate the costs, required R&D efforts, and policy measures in an integrated analysis.
ECN-C--04-094
15
1.
INTRODUCTION
1.1
The CASCADE MINTS project
The current report presents results of Part 2 of the CASCADE MINTS project (CMP2). This
project involves the development and use of energy and energy/economy models with special
emphasis on analysing technological developments. The CASCADE MINTS project is split into
two distinct parts:
• Part 1 focuses on modelling, scenario evaluation and detailed analysis of the prospects of the
hydrogen economy. It involves extensive development and use of detailed energy models
that have received assistance from previous framework Programmes of DG Research. The
ultimate aim of this part of the project is to enable perspective analysis of the conditions under which a transition to an energy system dominated by hydrogen is possible.
• Part 2 does not involve significant model development. Its main aim instead is to use a wide
range of existing operational energy and energy/economy models in order to build analytical
consensus (to the extent that this is possible) concerning the impacts of policies aimed at
sustainable energy systems. This part builds on the experience obtained in the ACROPOLIS
project (Das et al, 2003), funded by DG Research within the 5th Framework Programme and
involves common exercises carried out using a wide variety of models. This part involves
modelling teams from both inside and outside the EU. The emphasis is placed on evaluating
the effects of policies influencing technological developments.
This policy research comes right at a time when the EU has started a reflection on the actions on
climate change for the post-2012 period, especially considering the benefits and costs and taking into account both environmental and competitiveness concerns.
PART 1
PART 2
Modelling possible
configurations of a
hydrogen economy and
using models to study its
prospects
Joint case studies
on policy issues
with
operational
energy models
Coordinator : NTUA
Coordinator : ECN
Administrative Coordinator : NTUA
Figure 1.1 Overview of the CASCADE MINTS project
Part 2 of the project consists of six work packages. Five of these involve modelling work, and
one work package is devoted to reporting and dissemination. This report presents results of the
first work package on harmonisation of initial assumptions and evaluating a common baseline
projection. In each of the next four work packages a set of common case studies will be analysed with the participating modelling teams. These work packages are briefly summarised below.
16
ECN-C--04-094
Renewable energy (WP 2.2)
Renewable energy sources have the potential to play a much larger role than they presently do.
However, targets for steadily increasing the share of renewables prove difficult to achieve. What
are the consequences of different targets in 2020? What is an optimal share for renewables under different CO2 mitigation and import dependency constraints? Under what conditions and by
means of which policy instruments can the 2020 target of a 20% renewable energy share (of
primary resources) be reached? What is the related impact on GHG emission reduction and import dependency in 2020 and 2050? What mix of renewable technologies (solar, wind, biomass,
geothermal) will be applied in which sectors?
Nuclear energy (WP 2.3)
Nuclear power currently accounts for approximately one-third of the electricity generating capacity in the EU and is therefore a main topic in the current debate concerning security of energy supplies in the EU and the reduction of GHG emissions. Replacement of existing nuclear
power plants puts even more stress on both policy issues. Important issues which will shape the
future trends in the nuclear sector, are the problems of managing nuclear waste, the economic
viability of the new generation of nuclear power plants, the safety of reactors in eastern Europe,
in particular Candidate Countries and the policies to combat climate change and improve the
security of supply. The main research question that will be addressed is under what conditions
and by means of which policy instruments will new nuclear power plants become environmentally and economically feasible? What will be the potential impact of nuclear energy in terms of
GHG emission reduction and improving of supply security in 2020 and 2050?
CO2 capture/storage (WP 2.4)
CO2 capture and sequestration will always come with an additional cost to any power generation
plant. This is true both for the conversion to electricity and the conversion to hydrogen, if hydrogen is used as an energy carrier. CO2 capture and sequestration will therefore only be applied
if future specific or general policies provide the necessary financial incentive. Under what conditions and by means of which policy instruments will CO2 capture and storage in old gas and
oil fields as well as aquifers become environmentally and economically feasible? Considering
different possible policy strategies to intervene and to stimulate CO2 capture and storage becoming a mature technology, what is the potential impact of CO2 capture and storage in terms of
GHG emission reduction in 2020 and 2050?
Trade offs and synergies (WP 2.5)
The final work package forms the link between Part 1 and Part 2 of the project. It integrates WP
2.2 (renewable energy), WP 2.3 (nuclear energy), WP 2.4 (CO2 capture/storage) and WP 1.2
(hydrogen).
1.2
Report overview
The objectives of this report are first to document the baseline assumptions and results in the
project as a basis for analysis of policy cases. Secondly the report aims at providing information
to policy makers on possible developments in a world with moderate GDP and population
growth, with no additional policies in place. The variety of technological and other assumptions
in the different models causes a range in the results that reflects the uncertainty inherent to any
projection of future developments.
The report is structured as follows. Chapter 2 introduces all models involved in the project and
classifies and clusters these in order to provide a framework for interpreting their results. Chapter 3 documents the assumptions, which the modelling teams agreed to harmonise. Next, Chapters 4 and 5 provide the main results of the baseline projections for the world and Europe, respectively. Finally, Chapter 6 presents the key messages formulated on the basis of previous
chapters.
ECN-C--04-094
17
2.
ENERGY MODELS IN CASCADE MINTS PART 2
2.1
Classifying different types of energy models
In the CASCADE MINTS Part 2 (CMP2) project, 15 different models will be used to help understand the policy questions related to climate change and security of supply. The models are
representative of the variety of analytical approaches used in current energy and climate policy
analysis. Generally, different studies use different models, or only a limited set of models,
which may cause difficulty in interpreting the differences in outcomes. Hence, the project aims
at starting off with a comparison of various models, providing a background for understanding
possible different outcomes when using different models. Building on this comparison, the
CMP2 project will provide the specific outcomes from each of the 15 models and synthesise the
results. Each model will provide different insights to energy policy issues because of its design;
therefore a range of policy effectiveness may be determined. This chapter will provide an overview of the different models participating in the CMP2 project, and classify and cluster these in
order to provide a framework for analysing their results. Table 2.1 lists all models by coverage
and affiliation.
Table 2.1 General overview of the models used in CASCADE MINTS Part 2
No. of Affiliation
Model
Geographical
Participating in
coverage
Region
work packages
s
Global, US, Canada
AIM
DNE 21+
ETP
World
World
World
21
77
15
GMM
MESSAGE
NEWAGE
POLES
PROMETHEUS
NEMS
MAPLE
World
World
World
World
World
USA
Canada
5
5
13
38
3
5-32
NIES, Japan
RITE, Japan
IEA, France
PSI, Switzerland
IIASA, Austria
IER, Germany
IPTS, Spain
NTUA, Greece
EIA, USA
NRCan, Canada
Baseline, renewables
All
From fall 2004 ready
to participate
All
All except Nuclear
All
All
All except CCS
All
All
ECN, Netherlands
ERASME, France
ZEW, Germany
NTUA, Greece
IER, Germany
All
All
All except CCS
All except CCS
All
Europe
MARKAL
NEMESIS
PACE
PRIMES
TIMES-EE
Western Europe
Europe
World
EU-25 countries
Europe
1
16
9
25
19
Three of these models have not participated in the current phase, for various reasons. The ETL
model of the IEA, and the MAPLE model of Natural Resources Canada are still under development. The AIM/CGE model of NIES in Japan is currently being upgraded and was for this
reason not available. These three institutes participate in the CASCADE MINTS project without
EU funding.
Annex A provides a summary overview of model characteristics as provided by the respective
institutes, used for the classification. Generally, a distinction is made between ‘bottom-up engineering models’ which provide a detailed representation of the energy system and satisfy a
18
ECN-C--04-094
given energy demand with least cost supply, and ‘top down energy economy models’ which describe the interaction between the economy as a whole and the energy sector but lack technological detail. Presently, most energy models are hybrids that attempt to compensate the drawbacks of the two approaches. The classification draws on the taxonomy of energy models provided by (IPPC-TAR, 2001).
2.1.1 Top down models
Top-down models usually describe the entire economy in aggregate terms, drawing on analysis
of historical trends and relationships to predict large-scale interactions between the energy sector and the rest of the economy. They incorporate relatively little detail on energy use and technological development. Top down modelling approaches are further classified into two groups.
• Macro-economic models. These models are usually simulation models, describing investment and consumption patterns in various sectors. They implicitly reflect past behaviour in
that the driving equations are estimated using econometric techniques on time-series data. In
the CMP2 project, only the NEMESIS model, a Neo-Keynesian macro econometric model
with detailed energy/environment module for Western Europe, falls into this category.
• Computable General Equilibrium Models. CGE models construct the behaviour of economic agents based on microeconomic principles. The models typically simulate markets
for factors of production (e.g., labour, capital, energy), products, and foreign exchange, with
equations that specify supply and demand behaviour. The models are solved for a set of
wages, prices, and exchange rates to bring all of the markets into equilibrium. CGE models
examine the economy in different states of equilibrium and so are not able to provide insight
into the adjustment process. The parameters in CGE models are partly calibrated and partly
statistically or econometrically determined. In the CMP2 project, three CGE models will be
used. AIM/CGE, PACE and NEWAGE are global models. PACE provides a detailed representation of the power sector.
2.1.2 Bottom-up models
Typically, a bottom-up engineering model incorporates detailed data on costs and efficiencies of
a wide range of available and new technologies, and describes energy use in great detail. Based
on these data, the model determines a (least cost) strategy for satisfying exogenously determined final or useful demand for energy services. These models incorporate relatively little detail on non-energy consumer behaviour and interactions with other sectors of the economy.
They tend to provide results in which technological progress plays a key role, because they disregard market thresholds and non-technical barriers. Bottom-up approaches can be further classified into two categories.
• Dynamic Energy System Optimisation Models. These technology-oriented models minimize
the total costs of the energy system, including all end-use sectors, over a time horizon of
several decades and thus compute a partial equilibrium for the energy markets. Recent versions allow demand to respond to prices. Some models link aggregate macroeconomic demand and energy demand. Technology learning is endogenous in some models. This class of
models is well represented in the CMP2 project. DNE21+, GMM, ETP and MESSAGE are
global models. The models differ in their regional and technological coverage and their incorporation of technology learning. For Europe, MARKAL describes the Western European
energy system as a whole, while TIMES-EE describes the electricity production sector in
the EU-15 plus Norway, Switzerland, Poland and Czech Republic.
• Integrated Energy-System Simulation Models. Integrated energy-system simulation models
are bottom-up models that include a detailed representation of energy demand and supply
technologies, which include end-use, conversion, and production technologies. Demand and
technology development are driven by exogenous scenario assumptions often linked to
technology vintage models and econometric forecasts. The demand sectors are generally
disaggregated for industrial sub-sectors and processes, residential and service categories,
ECN-C--04-094
19
transport modes, etc. In this category, the largest variation of methodologies can be found.
POLES is characterised as a recursive simulation model of the world energy market, while
PRIMES, NEMS and MAPLE have in common a ‘generalised equilibrium’ structure, meaning that they formulate the behavioural conditions for economic agents in a variety of formulations for separate sub models, which are solved by a market clearing algorithm.
Finally, one model remains to be classified. The PROMETHEUS model is a stochastic model of
the world energy system. It could be regarded a bottom-up model without fitting in one of the
categories listed above.
2.1.3 Classification summary
Summarising, the models participating in CMP2 provide a variety of methodologies giving
complementary information. Not surprisingly, more energy sector models are involved in the
CMP2 analysis than macro economic ones. Still, it should be stressed that no classification does
justice to the richness of approaches. Many of the models have ‘hybrid’ characteristics reflecting the attempts that modellers have made to adjust for specific drawbacks of a given approach.
Top down
Bottom up
Geographical Macro-economic
coverage
CGE
Energy System
Optimisation
Integrated Energy
System simulation
Global
AIM
NEWAGE
PACE
DNE21+
ETP
GMM
MESSAGE
POLES
PROMETHEUS
US,
Canada
Europe
NEMS
MAPLE
NEMESIS
MARKAL Europe
TIMES-EE
PRIMES
Figure 2.1 Classification summary
World
As illustrated in Figure 2.1, eight different models will provide projections of global energy sector developments. Three of these are top down (CGE) models, which will study macroeconomic feedbacks on energy policies. Four of the others are energy system optimisation models that will provide the bottom-up technology rich perspective. Furthermore, one stochastic
model will shed more light on the role of uncertainties and one integrated energy system simulation model is available. Moreover, two integrated energy system simulation models describe the
US and Canada energy systems.
Europe
When it comes to modelling policy cases within Europe, four different models are available,
whereas most of the global models distinguish enough regions to be able to focus on Europe as
well. One of the ‘European’ models (NEMESIS) provides the macro economic point of view,
two energy systems optimisation models (MARKAL and TIMES-EE) provide the bottom-up
perspective using different regional classifications, while one integrated energy-system simulation model (PRIMES) also pays attention to behavioural aspects.
20
ECN-C--04-094
3.
KEY ASSUMPTIONS FOR HARMONISATION
3.1
Introduction
In modelling, the effects of policies are analysed by comparing a situation in which the policy is
implemented to a situation in which no action is taken. Thus, when considering the impact of
policies, an image of the world has to be constructed in which none of the policies that are under
scrutiny are included. As such an image serves as the baseline against which scenarios will be
compared, it is generally called the baseline scenario.
The models used in the CASCADE MINTS project are too diverse to define a truly common
baseline scenario. Therefore, instead of attempting to define a common baseline scenario, an
approach is followed where a set of basic assumptions are harmonised. Thus, a baseline scenario
is defined for each model separately, subject to the requirement that some of the initial conditions have to be harmonised. The objective of this harmonisation is to allow for a common basis
for comparing baseline results and policy cases. This provides more insight in the range of results supplied by the different models. Moreover, it enables a better identification of the sources
of discrepancies among the results.
Different levels of harmonisation may be chosen for the baseline, depending on the desirability
and feasibility of these levels. Factors that must be taken into account are, for example, the desired ‘richness’ of the baseline results provided by the models, the variety of types of models
(bottom-up or top-down approach), the type of baseline variables (exogenous or endogenous),
and the available amount of time and budget. Figure 3.1 shows various possible levels of harmonisation. The lowest level of harmonisation concerns the harmonisation of qualitative assumptions based on a scenario storyline. The highest level of harmonisation refers to the harmonisation of quantitative assumptions on variables such as GDP, population, international energy prices, etc. combined with harmonisation of input data on technologies. For CASCADE
MINTS a moderate level of harmonisation is chosen. This means that only a small number of
quantitative assumptions (key economic parameters) will be harmonised, whereas technologyspecific assumptions will not be harmonised. This level of harmonisation brings the baseline results of the various models more into line, while preserving the ‘richness’ of the baseline results
due to the different modelling approaches and model structures. Before discussing the initial
conditions that are to be harmonised in the CASCADE MINTS project, the choice of baseline
scenario will be outlined first in the next section.
Low
Cascade
Mints
Qualitative assumptions based
on storyline
Quantitative assumptions
(GDP, population, etc.)
Technology data
High
Model methodology
Figure 3.1 Level of harmonisation of initial conditions in CASCADE MINTS
ECN-C--04-094
21
3.2
Choice of baseline scenario
As a starting point for the development of a baseline scenario, the IPCC/SRES ‘B2 marker scenario’ has been chosen, which is derived from the Special Report on Emission Scenarios by the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC, 2000). This B2 marker scenario represents
a group of scenarios that have similar characteristics and fit within the same qualitative storyline
(B2). This scenario is used in CASCADE MINTS to provide a common and consistent basis for
harmonisation of initial conditions in the baseline scenario. The objective of this project is not
to reproduce the outputs provided by the models for the B2 scenario in IPCC (2000) by a different set of models. Because the harmonisation is only done for a minimum set of initial conditions and not for all assumptions used by the models, each model defines and uses its own baseline scenario. Therefore, the set of baselines used in CASCADE MINTS is probably broader
than the B2 group of scenarios but the added value of these variations is that they reflect uncertainty about future developments. Moreover, the diversity of the models will provide different
views on the effectiveness of the policy approaches.
Regarding the timescale (up to 2100) and geographical scale (global), the four IPCC/SRES scenarios are suitable as a baseline for CASCADE MINTS. All four storylines, i.e. A1, A2, B1 and
B2, represent different directions of future developments and are considered equally plausible.
They only cover gradual changes in these different directions and do not include ‘catastrophic
futures’ or ‘surprises’. Although none of them can be treated as a ‘business as usual’ scenario,
they can be considered relatively ‘neutral’ in terms of policy assumptions. They do not include
explicit climate change or renewable energy policies. The storylines of these scenarios can be
used to develop and evaluate policies by assuming additional policies and measures, which also
makes them suitable as baseline scenarios for CASCADE MINTS.
From these four scenarios, the B2 scenario is chosen as a baseline scenario for CASCADE
MINTS because this scenario shows more gradual changes and less extreme developments than
the other three scenarios in all respects, including geopolitics, demographics, productivity
growth, and technological dynamics. The other three scenarios may show moderate developments as well for some of the characteristics mentioned above, but in general they are more ‘extreme’ than B2, assuming, for example, ‘low’ or ‘(very) high’ economic and population growth
rates, or technological improvement rates. In this respect, the B2 scenario can be considered the
closest approximation to a ‘dynamics as usual’ scenario.
Figure 3.2 shows the four scenario families and their general characteristics, categorised according to two dimensions, i.e. a global-regional and an economic-environmental orientation. More
details on the storylines and quantitative characteristics of the scenarios can be found in IPCC
(2000).
22
ECN-C--04-094
Economic
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
A1
Very rapid economic growth
Low population growth
Rapid introduction of new and more
efficient technologies
Convergence among regions
Capacity building
Increased cultural and social interactions
Reduced regional differences in per capita
income
•
•
•
•
•
A2
Very heterogeneous world
Economic development primarily
regionally oriented
High population growth
Self-reliance and preservation oflocal
identities
Per capita economic growth and
technological change more fragmented
and slower than in other storylines
Regional
Global
B2
B1
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
Convergent world
Low population growth
Changes in economic structures toward a
service & information economy
Reductions in material intensity
Introduction of clean and resource-efficient
technologies
Global solutions to economic, social
environmental sustainability
Improved equity
•
•
•
•
•
Intermediate levels of economic
development
Moderate population growth
Emphasis on local solutions to economic,
social, and environmental sustainability
Less rapid and more diverse technological
change (compared to B1 and A1)
Environmental protection and social
equity, focusing on local and regional
levels.
Environmental
Figure 3.2 Four IPCC/SRES scenario families and their general characteristics (IPCC, 2000)
Two important features of the B2 storyline are the high priority given to environmental issues
and the trend toward local self-reliance and stronger communities. These characteristics are not
explicitly harmonised in the models used for CASCADE MINTS. The reason for this is that the
B2 scenario is only used as a common and consistent basis for harmonisation of initial conditions and not to achieve complete reproduction of the outputs for the B2 scenario as described in
IPCC (2000). However, some of the models may have incorporated storyline characteristics of
the B2 scenario in other assumptions apart from the minimum set of assumptions to be harmonised within CASCADE MINTS, which will be discussed in the next section.
3.3
Initial conditions to be harmonised
The harmonisation of initial conditions is restricted to a number of key parameters, assuming
differences in other input variables reflect the uncertainties present or specific local conditions.
The variables to be harmonised may be either endogenous or exogenous, depending on the type
of model. Only those parameters that are exogenous in the models have to be harmonised.
ECN-C--04-094
23
The minimum set of initial conditions that must be harmonised, if exogenous, consists of the
following variables3:
• GDP
• Population
• Energy prices (oil and optionally coal)
• Overall discount rate
• Policy.
For GDP and population, the harmonisation is based on quantitative information from the
IPCC/SRES B2 marker scenario. More details on the assumptions for GDP and population will
be presented in Section 3.4.
Assumptions for energy prices of oil and, in some models, coal only concern the international
oil and coal prices. The prices of natural gas are not to be harmonised since they are regional,
they may be determined endogenously and/or they may be coupled to the oil prices. The oil and
coal prices that are used for harmonisation are based on results of the POLES model since the
B2 marker scenario did not provide information on international market prices (only on marginal costs). The assumptions on international oil and coal prices will be presented in Section
3.5.
The overall discount rate denotes the rate used for discounting future investments and prices to
the reference year 2000. The overall discount rate has been derived from the discount rates that
are currently used in the participating models. Based on this information, a value of 5% has
been chosen for the overall discount rate.
The harmonisation of policy assumptions is one of the most difficult tasks, since policy schemes
may be very complex and they may vary substantially among countries and regions included in
the models. The general guidelines for harmonisation of policy assumptions in the baseline scenario are described in Section 3.6. This section also presents the assumptions for specific policy
fields that are to be harmonised.
3.4
GDP and population
For the harmonisation of GDP and population quantitative information from the IPCC/SRES B2
marker scenario is used. IPCC (2000) provides information about the development of GDP and
population on global level as well as for different regions. Modelling teams use the assumptions
on GDP and population for the regions that are included in their models and, if necessary, they
make their own assumptions for sub-regions in accordance with the assumptions on regional
level. Here, only the assumptions for world region (based on GMM) and Europe (based on
MARKAL) are presented since CASCADE MINTS focuses on these regions. Figure 3.3 shows
the assumptions for the world and European population for the period 2000-2050. The average
annual growth rate of the world population is ca. 0.9%, whereas the population of Europe remains almost constant until 2050.
3
Given the differences in sectoral and/or regional aggregation and different nesting assumptions in the models,
harmonisation of substitution elasticities in CGE models is not feasible. A similar remark applies to the harmonisation of final energy demand in bottom-up models.
24
ECN-C--04-094
[M capita]
10000
9000
8000
7000
6000
5000
4000
3000
2000
1000
0
2000
2010
2020
Population (GMM World)
2030
2040
2050
Population (Markal WEU)
Figure 3.3 Harmonisation of population for world (GMM) and Europe (MARKAL) for 20002050
Figure 3.4 presents the assumptions on world and European GDP in the period 2000-2050. The
GDP of the European region is expected to grow by ca. 70% in the period 2000-2050 (ca. 1.1%
per year), whereas the world GDP is projected to almost quadruple in this period, which corresponds to an average annual growth rate of ca. 2.7%. This large difference is mainly due to the
strong economic growth that is expected in Asia, Latin America, and, to a lesser extent, in Eastern Europe and the states of the former Soviet Union.
The GDP growth in the figure is defined in terms of Market Exchange Rates (MER), as it is the
metric used in most of the models involved in the present study. However, some of the models,
such as PROMETHEUS, use Purchasing Power Parity to define GDP and hence also GDP
growth. The growth rates in these two metrics differ substantially, as can be seen from Table
3.1, where we give growth rates for world GDP in both metrics. For further information on the
use of the two different metrics in energy-economic scenarios see (Gruebler et al., 2004) or
(Manne and Richels, 2003).
Table 3.1 World growth rate of GDP, for Market Exchange Rate (MER) and Purchasing
Power Parity metrics
1990-2000 2000-2010 2010-2020 2020-2030 2030-2040 2040-2050
MER
3.1
3.2
2.8
2.7
2.6
2.5
PPP
3.1
3.0
2.5
2.3
2.1
2.0
ECN-C--04-094
25
[bln € ]
160000
140000
120000
100000
80000
60000
40000
20000
0
2000
2010
2020
GDP (GMM World)
2030
2040
2050
GDP (Markal WEU)
Figure 3.4 Harmonisation of GDP for world (GMM) and Europe (MARKAL) for 2000-2050
3.5
Energy prices
In CASCADE MINTS Part 2, only the international prices of oil and, in certain cases, coal are
harmonised. The assumptions on these prices are based on results of the POLES model. It
should be noted that for coal prices, modelling teams do not necessarily have to use the prices
provided by POLES but their assumptions should be in line with the B2 storyline. The reason
for this is that coal is regionally available and coal prices may be regionally determined. Figure
3.5 presents the international oil and coal prices for the period 2000-2030 from POLES. It also
shows an example, based on MARKAL, of the extrapolation for the international oil price beyond 2030. In the POLES model, the coal price for Europe is set equal to the international coal
price. Figure 3.5 presents an example, based on MARKAL, of a regional coal price for Europe
that deviates somewhat from the international coal price derived from POLES.
[€/GJ]
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
2000
2010
2020
Oil/liquids (Poles World)
Oil/liquids (Markal WEU)
2030
2040
2050
Coal/solids (Poles World)
Coal/solids (Markal WEU)
Figure 3.5 Oil and coal prices for the world (POLES) and Europe (MARKAL) for 20002030/2050
26
ECN-C--04-094
3.6
Policies
3.6.1 General guidelines
For the harmonisation of policies in the baseline scenario, some general guidelines are used.
First of all, only policies in force or approved on December 31st 2003 may be included in the
baseline scenario. This means that policies for which the exact implementation is not clear at
this date should be excluded. The baseline scenario should only contain instrumented policies so
this implies that policy targets (e.g. EU targets for renewable electricity or biofuels consumption) should be excluded. The reason for this is that it should not be assumed in the baseline
scenario that such policy targets would, in any case, be achieved. Financial incentives that are
included in the baseline scenario will be continued up to the year 2012 and then phased out. Assumptions on the following specific policy fields will be discussed further in the next sections:
• Primary energy sources: nuclear energy, oil, natural gas, and coal.
• End-use of energy carriers: end-use subsidies and taxes, electricity market, renewable electricity, and biofuels.
• Emissions: climate change and emission trading, standards and industry-negotiated agreements on emissions and energy-efficiency for vehicles, and sulphur control policies.
3.6.2 Primary energy sources
Nuclear energy
The contribution of nuclear energy in electricity generation is an area par excellence where
policies play a decisive role. The political and public attitude towards electricity from nuclear
fission differs substantially across the EU Member States. Whereas politicians in a number of
countries have decided to phase out the use of fission power plants (e.g. Germany, Belgium)
other countries are intent on maintaining or extending existing capacity (e.g. France, Finland).
In yet other countries, no policy is formulated.4
As becomes clear from a summary by the IEA (IEA, 2001), 8 Members States of the EU15 are
rejecting nuclear power as an option. However, in terms of nuclear capacity, these countries correspond to only about 30% of total capacity. On the other hand, due to the lack of competitiveness, the generating capacity in the UK should also be expected to gradually phase out. Thus, on
the longer term about 40% of nuclear power generating capacity will be replaced by other options. Most countries advocating a phase out are planning a gradual replacement ending in 2025.
The proposal for harmonisation of nuclear capacity is to use the data in Table 3.2 as an upper
bound (maximum installed capacity) for the EU15 region. For the New Member States, a continued use of nuclear power is likely, and it is therefore proposed to use the current capacity
level, i.e. 11.9 GW (WEPP, 2003), as upper bound in the baseline scenario (in a policy case in
which the future of nuclear power will be investigated, these assumptions will be relaxed). For
the rest of the world, no explicit assumption seems necessary in the base case.
4
Assuming the market situation in the UK proves to be exemplary for the European Union, nuclear can be expected
to undergo a 'voluntary' phase-out. In the UK, nuclear power plants are expected to remain non-competitive, even
in comparison to gas-fired power plants (IEA, 2002).
ECN-C--04-094
27
Table 3.2 Proposed upper bounds for total capacity of nuclear power plants in the EU15 in
the baseline scenario (WEPP, 2003)
Year
2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Capacity [GW]
123.9
113.8
103.7
93.5
83.4
2025
and later
73.3
Oil
No specific policies are given so policies regarding oil are not harmonised.
Natural gas
Gas market reforms are to be implemented in EU Member States, including the New Member
States. This influences the market model, and is expected to result in lower gas market prices,
but if this is indeed the case, and if so to what extent, is uncertain. No specific numbers can be
deduced from such policy measures. Therefore, modelling teams are free to make their own decisions on the specific translation of current and approved gas market policies in their models.
Coal
Traditionally, the mining industry has received substantial government support in the European
Union due to social considerations. Recently, such support schemes have been focussed on the
reduction of non-competing production capacity in a socially acceptable way. The support is
provided by the country governments, in particular by France, Germany, Spain, and the United
Kingdom. For none of these countries the production is truly commercial, resulting in a subsidised production of approximately 85 Mton per annum. Support schemes are partially advocated
as being useful in security of supply issues.
France is expected to end production by 2005, while Spain and Germany show no intention to
decrease state support. In the latter two countries, production costs are about three times the
world market prices. In the UK, a two-year state aid package of up to ca. 160 million Euro in
place since 2002, in spite of production costs being close to market prices. No proposal has been
made for the harmonisation of coal policies. Therefore, modelling teams are free to make their
own decisions on the inclusion of current and approved coal policies.
3.6.3 End-use of energy carriers
End-use subsidies and taxes
Most policies regarding the use of energy carriers in the European Union, and indeed in much of
the rest of the world, are put into concrete form by means of taxes, or tax exemptions. These are
levied on many levels in the energy system: on primary energy carriers, intermediate energy
products (such as gasoline) or final energy carriers (like electricity).
The prices of energy carriers in energy system models covering a single country or region, such
as MARKAL, are generally specified as world market prices, or resulting from costs of technologies used to extract and/or produce the energy carriers. Taxes and subsidies are mostly excluded from the description in global models, in part because these models describe composite
regions, for which it is hard to include the county-specific taxes in a simple way. A secondary
reason is that a full quantitative review for all taxes and subsidies for all countries in the world
is not at hand. Therefore, subsidies and taxes are not harmonised in CASCADE MINTS.
28
ECN-C--04-094
Electricity market
Electricity market reforms are to be implemented in the EU Member States, including the New
Member States. This influences the market model, and is expected to influence electricity market prices. However, as in recent years it has become clear that liberalisation does not necessarily result in lower prices, the effect on electricity market prices is unclear. Some recent developments have even raised concerns over market failures, leading to proposed policies for security of supply. However, no specific numbers can be deduced from these policy measures.
Therefore, modelling teams are free to make their own decisions on the specific translation of
current and approved electricity market policies in their models.
Renewable electricity
Renewable energy appears to be the area where most concrete measures are in place. The EU
Renewable Electricity Directive has set indicative targets for the share of renewable electricity
in 2010, and all EU Member States have some type of financial support scheme in place. An inventory of policy measures for renewable electricity can be found in ECN (2003).
Aside from this overview, in the ADMIRE REBUS project a simulation model has been developed for the European market for renewable electricity production (ECN, 2003). A specific policy case studied using this model is the case where present national support policies in the EU15
(such as feed-in tariffs) are continued unmodified up until 2010. These results in approximately
18% share of renewables in the European gross electricity consumption, compared to a 22%
target, a finding which is comparable to several other studies.
Given the fact that most policies are implemented via fiscal measures, which are countryspecific and therefore hard to parameterise as a direct effect on prices in an aggregate model, the
proposal for harmonisation of renewable electricity policies is to use the outcome of the ADMIRE-REBUS study with the extrapolation of current policies up until 2010 as lower bounds
for technologies. The results from this study can be regarded an aggregate representation of the
effect of the variety of current and approved support policies, and are therefore suitable as lower
limits for the renewable electricity production in Europe, up until 2010. This would imply the
bounds as given in Table 3.3 should be implemented in the models5. It should be noted that the
numbers given are activity levels, which is the logical limitation given that many of the fiscal
measures are stimulating production, rather than installation of capacity.
Table 3.3 Activity levels of renewable energy systems from the ADMIRE-REBUS model, under
the assumption of unchanged policies until 2010
2000
2005
2010
[GWh]
Biomass
26,773
60,075
99,751
Geothermal electricity
4,303
5,337
5,827
Large Hydro (>10 MW)
265,208
272,585
276,942
Small & Medium Hydro (<10 MW)
38,341
43,596
46,186
Photovoltaics
98
884
1,632
Tidal
580
580
580
Wind, off-shore
108
1,254
3,085
Wind, on-shore
16,812
61,043
108,777
From the activity levels capacity levels can be deduced, and the values from the ADMIREREBUS study are given in Table 3.4. As the study primarily calculates activity levels, these capacities should be considered as indicative levels, rather than actual bounding levels.
5
The data can be given in more detail: both in years (annual data) as well as in countries.
ECN-C--04-094
29
Table 3.4 Capacity level of renewable energy systems from the ADMIRE-REBUS model, under
the assumption of unchanged policies until 2010
2000
2005
2010
[MW]
Biomass
4,039
8,749
14,474
Geothermal electricity
756
937
1023
Large Hydro (>10 MW)
85,364
87,946
89,471
Small & Medium Hydro (<10 MW)
9,766
11,158
11,799
Photovoltaics
83
753
1,320
Tidal
255
255
255
Wind, off-shore
35
399
1,062
Wind, on-shore
8,610
28,001
49,143
The harmonisation proposal of renewable electricity policy assumes that current incentive policies will be continued until 2010, but not thereafter. In stead, from 2010 onwards, a generic carbon tax of 10 €/tCO2 is introduced for the EU (see Section 1.6.4). It may turn out that after 2010
electricity production using renewable options is not competitive, but given the activity in 2010,
a total abandonment of these options is unlikely. In such cases, it is left to the discretion of the
modelling teams to decide whether bounds should be used from 2010 onwards to simulate consistent behaviour of producers. As the assumption is that explicit investment subsidies are
phased out after this year, one may assume that from 2010 onwards the commercial viability
will determine installation of new capacity.
Biofuels
A particular source of renewable energy is the application of biomass. As a result of the broad
variety of possible applications for biomass (particularly in the electricity, transport, petrochemical sectors), an equally broad range of policy frameworks is relevant for biomass. In a
current EU-project a list of policies relevant for application of biomass is compiled (VIEWLS,
2004). From a first inventory of biofuel policies, there appear to be few specific instruments
aiming at large scale introduction of biofuels. Whenever such instruments are in place, they
generally take the form of tax exemptions for transport fuels, and hence are not to be included in
the baseline scenario (in compliance with earlier remarks on taxes as policy instruments). Therefore, biofuels policies are not harmonised in CASCADE MINTS.
3.6.4 Emissions
Climate change and emission trading
The policy assumptions include some expectations regarding climate change policy. Since climate change policy is considered an important issue and is not treated as a separate policy case
in Part II of the CASCADE MINTS project, some representation of climate policy/emission
trading for the region of Europe should be included in the baseline scenario. Therefore we propose to assume a generic carbon tax of 10 Euro2000/tonne CO2 as from the year 2012 (constant
value over time). This applies to the region of Europe (including Central and Eastern European
Countries).
In the US, there are no viable proposals on constraining carbon emissions except for the voluntary target reduction rate of carbon intensity announced by the President a few years ago. Therefore the US baseline will not include any additional climate policies.
For other regions/countries, the Kyoto Protocol status of ratification is used as a reference.6 This
means that for e.g. Japan and New Zealand, who have ratified/accepted the Kyoto Protocol, climate policy is also assumed in the baseline scenario. However, for Australia this assumption is
not made. Canada has ratified and should be with the ratifying countries, when using world
6
See http://unfccc.int/resource/kpstats.pdf (status March 17, 2004).
30
ECN-C--04-094
models. However, mostly Canada is treated as part of the North American region, and cannot be
separated from the US.
Standards and industry negotiated agreements on emissions and energy-efficiency for
vehicles
Standards and industry negotiated agreements that are in force or approved on December 31st
2003, such as the car industry negotiated agreements on CO2 emissions, are to be included in the
baseline scenario. This section will discuss the automobile industry negotiated agreements and
European standards on CO2 and other emissions, and energy-efficiency in further detail.
The associations of European, Japanese and Korean automobile manufacturers, ACEA, JAMA,
and KAMA respectively, have committed themselves to achieving substantial reductions in CO2
emissions from passenger cars. The CO2 emission targets, as stated in the Recommendations of
the European Commission, will be included in the policies that will be harmonised. Table 3.5
lists the targets for each association. These targets apply to the average of new cars sold by the
members of the associations in the EU, including vehicles replacing conventional cars and passenger cars not producing CO2 emissions or using alternative fuels. It should be noted that the
intermediate target ranges for 2003/2004 are indicative.
Individual members of ACEA should place on the market models emitting 120 g/km CO2 or
less, by the year 2000. For members of JAMA and KAMA, these models should be introduced
by the earliest possible date after the year 2000. The overall objective of the Community strategy is to attain a CO2 emission target of 120 g/km CO2 on average for newly registered passenger cars by 2005, and at the latest 2010. This objective is to be achieved by these three agreements with the automobile industry, combined with research activities. Fiscal measures regarding passenger cars are to be implemented as well to make cars more CO2 efficient.
Table 3.5 CO2 emission targets for ACEA, JAMA and KAMA for passenger cars
Intermediate target Intermediate target
Final target
Final target
[g/km CO2]
2003
2004
2008
2009
ACEA
165-170
140
JAMA
165-1757
140
KAMA
165-170
140
In the United States, the Corporate Average Fuel Economy (CAFE) standards for passenger cars
and light trucks were established in 1975 to improve the fuel economy of new vehicles. More
information on these CAFE standards can be found on the website of the Office of Automotive
Affairs of the US International Trade Administration.8
The European Union has established emission regulations for CO, HC, NOx and PM emissions
for new light-duty vehicles (cars and light commercial vehicles) and for heavy-duty diesel engines, and diesel and gas engines. More information on these emission regulations can be found
on the website of Dieselnet.9
Sulphur control policies
The B2 scenario includes implicit sulphur control policies. Only the MESSAGE model includes
assumptions on these policies. Table 3.6 shows the assumptions on energy-related SO2 emis7
8
9
The Official Journal sets an upper bound for the intermediate target of 170 g/km CO2, whereas monitoring reports
of the JAMA commitment states an upper bound for the intermediate target of 175 g/km CO2.
www.ita.doc.gov/td/auto/cafe.html
www.dieselnet.com/standards/eu/ld.html (Light-duty Vehicles) and www.dieselnet.com/standards/eu/hd.html
(Heavy-Duty diesel engines, diesel and gas engines).
ECN-C--04-094
31
sions derived from the B2 scenario that may be included in the baseline scenario, for various
regions. These assumptions are based on results from IIASA (source IPCC (2000)).
Table 3.6 Assumptions on energy-related SO2 emissions in the B2 scenario (IIASA-B2)
[MtS]
OECD
REF
ROW
ASIA
WORLD
21.48
16.16
5.82
16.02
59.48
1990
14.37
12.72
8.03
23.47
58.59
2000
9.08
8.39
6.84
27.50
51.80
2010
3.09
4.22
6.18
26.39
39.88
2020
1.85
2.06
5.29
23.66
32.86
2030
1.40
1.38
3.94
20.47
27.19
2040
1.06
2.78
3.02
13.73
20.59
2050
0.86
2.66
2.81
10.43
16.76
2060
0.70
2.59
2.44
7.79
13.52
2070
0.68
2.67
2.01
6.74
12.10
2080
0.72
2.74
1.89
6.60
11.95
2090
0.67
2.76
1.92
6.13
11.48
2100
3.6.5 Regional assumptions
Due to large variety of the models and the regions and countries included in them, it will not be
possible to harmonise on such a detailed level within the CASCADE MINTS project. Therefore,
only a few general guidelines will be given regarding regional assumptions:
• EU candidate countries will gradually implement EU policies (completed in 2020).
• Norway and Switzerland will follow overall trends of EU policies.
In order to realise as much harmonisation of policy assumptions as possible, it is important for
models dealing with the same region(s) to make sure that their policy assumptions are similar.
32
ECN-C--04-094
4.
BASELINE GLOBAL ENERGY OUTLOOK
4.1
Introduction
The developments of the energy system of Western Europe, and more in particular of the European Union, cannot be considered independent of global trends. In particular, the success or
failure of policies aimed at addressing global issues such as increased atmospheric
CO2 concentration levels, security of supply, and proliferation will be highly dependent on what
happens in the rest of the world. Therefore, in the case studies performed in the Cascade-Mints
project, a number of models have been included that address developments in other regions of
the world. In some cases these models specifically address a separate region, for example in the
case of the NEMS model, while in other cases the models describe a regionalised version of the
world, as was described in Chapter 2.
Below, an overview of the outcome of various models under baseline conditions will be given.
First, a number of global trends will be discussed, that may serve as a background against which
the developments of the European Union may be gauged. For the most striking results, the developments in the North American energy system will be reviewed. In particular, some issues of
interest such as the development of carbon intensity and security of supply will be addressed.
In the discussion below, the PROMETHEUS models stands out, and will not be directly included in the various discussions. The model provides the only stochastic description, which
makes it particularly suited for addressing issues where chance plays an important role, such as
the likelihood that a certain event (such as a 100% increase in CO2 concentration) will occur.
4.2
World primary energy
The total primary energy consumption to a large extent is determined by the driving forces that
were subject to harmonization of the baseline assumptions. However, as the various models offer different descriptions of the world, the levels will differ, in some cases substantially. Instead
of viewing the different outcomes as a handicap for consistent analysis and robust conclusions,
it should be thought of as a bonus, because the different descriptions reflect different views in
the way in which the world could develop, even if basic economic developments and energy
policy parameter are harmonised.
4.2.1 Primary energy consumption more than doubles
The different projections are shown in Figure 4.1for five world models. There are clear similarities in the outcomes of four of the models, as they project a steady growth leading to a more
than doubling of primary energy consumption in 2050 compared to the 2000 level. The lower
level of one of these five models (DNE21+) can largely be explained by the exclusion of nonmarketed energy use (biomass) by the model. Similarly, the difference between the results presented here and those of the SRES study (SRES, 2000) can be largely explained by the way in
which contributions from renewable and nuclear energy sources are accounted for. In the SRES
results a direct equivalence methodology was used, according to which the primary energy use
was equalized to the input for these sources. In the present study, these renewable and nuclear
energy sources are accounted for using substitution equivalents, by introducing efficiency factors of 3 for electricity generation.
Although the trends in most models are similar, the final outcomes differ substantially as the
growth rate in the models show large variations. The average annual growth rates of the three
ECN-C--04-094
33
bottom-up energy system models vary between a little under 1.7% per annum to over 1.9% per
annum. These differences are a reflection of the different dynamics in each of the models, and
can be regarded as indicative for the impact of uncertainties in the future energy system.
[EJ]
1400
1200
1000
800
600
400
200
0
2000
2010
2020
Message
GMM
2030
Poles
DNE21+
2040
2050
PACE
Figure 4.1 Total global primary energy consumption for the various models
In Figure 4.1, the model outcomes for PACE differ substantially from those of the other bottomup energy system models. The main reason is that PACE, in the version used for the current
simulation exercise, does not provide an explicit representation of primary energy from renewables and nuclear power. Shifts in primary energy supply away from fossil-fuel based production are represented in a top-down fashion by continuous substitution of fossil fuel inputs
through non-energy inputs, in particular capital. Also, there are some effects from using the
GTAP database of 1997 as proxy for 2000 economic data. However, a comparison of trends between the bottom-up models and the top-down model may be still meaningful, although given
the remark above one should be careful in interpreting differences. From such a comparison, it
is clear that until 2020 the results of PACE in this way are very similar to that of the other models, but that from this year onwards the trend as projected by PACE differs substantially, resulting in a demand level in 2050 that is almost half as small as the level projected by the other
models.
4.2.2 Fossil fuels remain dominant
Policies in general will not primarily be aimed at reducing energy consumption, but rather at
mitigating the results of energy use, such as increasing CO2-concentrations, or decreasing security of supply. Therefore, some policies will have an impact on the mix of energy sources, rather
than influence the overall primary energy use. From the policy perspective, it thus may be interesting to compare the mix of primary energy sources used. On the global scale, this is illustrated
in Figure 4.2, where the outcome of various bottom-up models is shown.
34
ECN-C--04-094
[EJ]
1000
800
600
400
200
0
DNE21+
GMM
Fossil
Nuclear
Message
Other
Poles
Renewable
Figure 4.2 Mix of primary energy use in various models, where we distinguish between major
categories: fossil, nuclear, renewables, and other; in the year 2030
It is clear that although the overall energy consumption can be of the same order of magnitude,
the contributions of the various fuel types may differ substantially10. Several factors can contribute to these differences in primary energy demand.
• As compared to the other models, MESSAGE has a larger contribution from non-fossil fuels. This is due to more optimistic assumptions concerning technological improvements and
deployment of renewable technologies. Another reason is the inclusion in MESSAGE of
constraints on sulphur emissions (see also Section 3.6.4).
• The time horizon assumed (2000/2050 or 1990/2100), which is important for models with a
perfect foresight.
• The application of endogenous learning or the (exogenous) assumptions on development of
technology costs. For example in GMM, the learning performance of the fossil technologies
like IGCC and NGCC is significant in the baseline, therefore the fraction of fossil fuels in
the primary energy mix is rather high.
This shows that policy measures and RTD support may be of substantial influence, and that the
future development of use of energy sources may substantially be influenced by policies, something that will be illustrated for selected topics in due course of this project.
4.2.3 Security of supply will become a world wide issue
An important issue in the years to come will be the increasing dependence on oil from the Middle East. In Figure 4.3 we show the percentage of the total world oil production that is produced
in the region of which the Middle East is part. The regional specification differs between the
five models shown11, resulting in somewhat different contributions in 2000, ranging from 50%
10
11
Note that the class ‘other’ in the POLES results includes the renewable options.
As four out of five models aggregate the Middle East with Latin America, we have decided to use a similar aggregation for the fifth model (DNE21+) that does provide separate numbers for the Middle East region.
ECN-C--04-094
35
to 58%. Although the five models show a different behaviour of the evolvement of the production, in all models the contribution from the Middle East region grows, and becomes substantially larger in most models. This indicates that the world as a whole becomes more and more
dependent on the resources of one specific region. This raises the question whether under these
conditions the security of supply can be safeguarded.
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
2000
2010
2020
Message
GMM
2030
Poles
DNE21+
2040
2050
PACE
Figure 4.3 Percentage of the total world oil production that is produced in the region
encompassing the Middle East
Some refinements are in place with respect to the regional dependence of oil production. On the
one hand, the dependence on the Middle East is less severe as one might think at first, as the regions used in Figure 4.3 include some other important oil producing countries. On the other
hand, the increase in dependence may be stronger than presented in the figure, as the relative
contribution from the Middle East in the region used for the comparison may grow. For the one
model, DNE21+, for which we have more detailed information at hand, this is indeed the case,
as the contribution from the Middle East and North Africa grows from 35% in 2000 to some
55% in 2030. It decreases again after this period, to a little over forty % in 2050, which is in line
with the expectation that a steep rise in oil production should in the long run be accompanied by
a decline, as the overall reserves dictate the possible cumulative production.
Given the recent interest in Security of Supply issues, it is clear that a more detailed analysis of
the issue would be welcome. Such an analysis should not only encompass a more detailed regional representation of oil production, but would also benefit much from an analysis of trade
flows. For example, the rise of economies in the Far East, such as India and China at the one
hand put more pressure on scarce resources, but on the other hand may lead to a more diverse
import mix for Europe and the USA, as unconventional resources may become more attractive.
The stochastic model PROMETHEUS is particularly suited for analyses of the security of supply, as it can give insight in the likelihood that this security is disrupted. Under the assumptions
set out in Chapter 3, the probability that by 2030 the Middle East produces more than half of the
annual oil consumption is over 85%, as illustrated in Source: PROMETHEUS
Figure 4.4. Stated otherwise, it is quite unlikely that the importance of the Middle East in the
world oil consumption decreases.
36
ECN-C--04-094
160
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
0.2
0.3
0.5
0.4
0.6
0.8
0.7
Ratio of oil productions
Source: PROMETHEUS
Figure 4.4 The probability distribution for the ratio of Middle East oil production to total
World oil production (mean: 0.59, standard deviation: 0.084)
Given that this (at present) rather unstable region tends to remain dominating in the oil production, it comes as no surprise that there is a substantial probability that a sudden price hike in the
oil price will occur. As can be deduced from the results shown in Figure 4.5, the probability that
a price hike of more than 15 US$ will occur, is almost 50%. For comparison, our oil price scenario (see Section 3.5) assumes that in the period 2000-2050, the oil prices are in the range of
4.2 and 6.2 €/GJ, which is equivalent to a range of ca. 26 to 38 US$/barrel12. Considering this
oil price range, a 15 US$ price hike would mean an increase of ca. 40-60% within a three-year
period.
200
160
120
80
40
0
10
20
30
40
$95/bl
Source: PROMETHEUS
Figure 4.5 Probability distribution of the maximal increase in oil price in any three-year period
between 2000 and 2030 (mean: 15.9, standard deviation: 5.904)
12
The energy content of one barrel of oil is 6.12 GJ.
ECN-C--04-094
37
4.2.4 Coal production grows faster than oil and gas production
In
Figure 4.6 the world oil production is shown for the five world models considered here. Most
models show similar trends, in that production continues to grow, although the rate differs.
Models that project a faster initial growth tend to slow down towards 2050. In general, the oil
production grows less than primary energy demand.
[EJ]
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
2000
2010
2020
Message
GMM
2030
Poles
DNE21+
2040
2050
PACE
Figure 4.6 World oil production for the various models
In
Figure 4.7 the world production of coal is shown, as calculated using GMM, chosen to represent
the trends in most world models. Of particular importance is that the main growth of production
takes place in Africa and Asia, as well as in the EEFSU (Eastern Europe and Former Soviet Union) region. Moreover, there is a doubling of production from 2000 to 2030 in the models under
consideration. MESSAGE again provides the exception, due to its sulphur constraints.
[EJ]
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
2000
2010
2020
Asia
Latin America, Africa and Middle East
Other OECD
2030
2040
2050
Eastern Europe and Former Soviet Union
North America
Figure 4.7 World coal production per region, according to GMM
38
ECN-C--04-094
The role of gas will be substantial in the future energy system, even in the present case where
only limited action is taken to reduce the carbon content of the system.13The different models
predict different levels of consumption, ranging from a little over 200 EJ up to some 360 EJ, by
in 2050. The largest deviation is exhibited by DNE21+, and primarily seems due to a later onset
of gas demand. This notwithstanding, the growth in gas consumption for all models is roughly
in line with the growth in total energy consumption, i.e. the relative contribution of gas does not
change significantly on the global scale.
[EJ]
400
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
2000
2010
2020
Message
GMM
2030
Poles
DNE21+
2040
2050
PACE
Figure 4.8 World gas production for the various models
For gas consumption, again the stochastic model PROMETHEUS may provide additional insights. For the potential role of gas, its relative price as compared to the oil price is highly relevant. In most models presented here, the gas price remains higher than the oil price. However, in
principle the chance that the international gas price becomes lower than the international oil
price is substantial, and an analysis using PROMETHEUS results shows that this chance is approximately 95%, as can be seen from Figure 4.9. This rather high probability may be due to the
increasing dependence on oil from the Middle East, noted in Section 4.2.3. If this is indeed the
underlying reason, the high probability is an indication that Security of Supply is likely to be a
more severe issue for oil than for gas - which would be furthermore in line with the status of reserves.
13
Different world models have dealt differently with the 10 €/tCO2 carbon tax in Europe from 2012 onwards, due to
their differing regional aggregations. Most models have applied it to the (larger) region containing Europe, with
the exception of MESSAGE, because it would be too strong an assumption to apply it to the complete OECD region.
ECN-C--04-094
39
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
1.6
Price ratios
Source: PROMETHEUS
Figure 4.9 Probability distribution of the ratio of the gas to oil price in 2030 (mean: 0.67,
standard deviation: 0.17)
4.3
Improvements in energy intensity
At present, the gross inland consumption of energy per capita shows a large divergence between
the developed world, most noticeably North America, Japan, and Western Europe, and the developing countries. A similar statement holds for the distribution of energy intensities over the
world. In line with the assumptions of the harmonised B2 scenario (see Paragraph 3.4), income
differences are expected to remain large. On the other hand, the assumption of relatively homogenous technological developments over the world induces a converging trend for energy
intensities.
The representation in Figure 4.10 aims at illustrating these points. The figure shows the growth
in consumption per capita as a function of the energy intensity14, from GMM, chosen to represent the trends observed in all models15. In the baseline, reflecting a world where no additional
action is taken to increase equity, differences remain in the levels of the indicators, but the
trends are similar. The per capita consumption increases in all regions in the world. At the same
time, the energy intensities tend to move towards lower values, indicating a more effective use
of energy for generating GDP worldwide.
14
15
Energy intensity is defined as (primary) energy consumption over gross domestic product.
Which is only partially the case, as the regional specification may yield different views on the interregional differences. Particularly, aggregating over all OECD will yield substantially different conclusions.
40
ECN-C--04-094
[PJ/bln € ]
50
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
350
400
450
500
[PJ/capita]
Asia
Eastern Europe and Former Soviet Union
Latin America, Africa and Middle East
North America
Other OECD
USA (NEMS)
Figure 4.10 Energy intensity as function of the gross energy consumption per capita for the
various regions in GMM and NEMS (USA). The Other OECD region includes
Europe. Other models show similar trends for the various regions.
One should be careful in interpreting effects in energy intensity, in particular on the level of individual countries. As developing countries industrialize, the use of energy initially increases. In
particular, a shift from non-marketed to marketed energy will occur, and thus if non-commercial
energy is excluded from the model the substitution will enhance this effect, leading to even
higher (and actually non-existing) rises in energy intensity. In later stages of development, the
decrease as depicted in Figure 4.10 occurs. That such increases are not observed in the figure is
due to the regional aggregation level, which we use as the interest of the project lays mainly in
European and regional trends, rather than on the behaviour of individual (developing) countries.
A more speculative conclusion from the figure would be that there appear to be roughly two
tracks along which economies can evolve. This is even clearer from Figure 4.11, where the energy intensity is shown as function of the gross domestic product (GDP), on a double logarithmic scale. One path seems to be defined by the combination of EEFSU (mainly former Soviet
Union) and NAME (mainly USA), and is characterized by relatively high GDP, but also high
energy intensities. The other path is defined by the three other regions, and combines low energy intensity with relatively low GDP. The improvement in energy intensity seems to be
roughly independent of the path, except for the region OOECD when the apparent minimal
value of 5 PJ/G€ is reached.
ECN-C--04-094
41
[PJ/bln € ]
100
10
1
1000
10000
100000
[EUR/capita] Eastern Europe and Former Soviet Union
Asia
Latin America, Africa and Middle East
North America
Other OECD
USA (NEMS)
Figure 4.11 Gross inland consumption per unit of GDP as function of the GDP per capita for
the various regions in GMM, and for the USA according to NEMS. Other models
show similar trends
4.4
World final energy and electricity consumption
In the previous sections, developments in the primary energy consumption were shown. As was
seen, this may provide insight into a number of global developments and trends, such as
CO2 emissions and security of supply issues. However, some of the developments will not directly be reflected in such a parameter; for example, the shift in or towards ‘secondary fuels’,
such as electricity or hydrogen, will not be captured in an analysis focussing only on primary
energy use.
4.4.1 Consensus on the growth of final energy demand, but not on the level
A more appropriate variable for such issues as what shifts in demand may occur, is the final energy demand. This also provides insight into the sectoral distribution of energy use. The final
global energy use summed over all sectors in the various models, is shown in Figure 4.12.
42
ECN-C--04-094
[EJ]
800
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
2000
2010
2020
Message
2030
GMM
Poles
2040
2050
DNE21+
Figure 4.12 Total final energy consumption for the various world models
The total final energy use shows only small deviations among models, albeit that DNE21+ starts
at a lower value. This is due to the fact that non-commercial energy is not included in this
model. The similarity in result is to be expected, as the final energy demand is driven by variables that were harmonized, such as the population, GDP and world oil prices. Note that as
compared to the figures on primary energy use, the PACE model is left out, because this (hybrid) model does not provide data on final energy demand.
4.5
World electricity and hydrogen production
The power sector is expected to play an increasingly important role in the energy systems of the
world. In the industrialised world, the sector already plays a significant role, and this will increasingly be the case. Moreover, on a global scale growth is expected to be considerable for a
second reason. As the standards of living in more and more countries is raised to a level comparable to that of the OECD, the energy system will tend to move to become a reflection of the
present system of the industrialised countries. Both the increasing importance of the power sector, and the fertile grounds it may provide for policies regarding renewable energy systems,
make it a sector of prime interest when considering the future developments of the energy system.
Aside from electricity, hydrogen could in principle play a significant role in the energy system
as secondary energy carrier. Its nature as physical energy carrier gives it advantages over electricity, in particular when storage plays a role. This is the case when supply and demand does
not match, either temporal or regional, and in mobile applications such as transport. Compared
to derivatives of primary energy sources (fossil fuels or biomass) it has the advantage that no
local or global pollution need be caused. For these reasons, the expectations with respect to the
role of hydrogen in the energy system will be highlighted below.
4.5.1 Electricity increasingly important
As indicated in the introduction to this section, the power sector will play a significant role in
the world energy system. As can be seen in Figure 4.13, the world models considered here all
ECN-C--04-094
43
show very similar trends for the expected growth of energy demand. Certainly, the difference
between the various models is maximally around 7% from the average value, both in 2030
(POLES), and in 2050 (GMM). Such differences are substantially smaller than the difference in
some other outcomes discussed in the preceding paragraphs, such as the primary energy consumption. This is related to the assumptions on the end-use demands for electricity consuming
sectors (usually given exogenously in the baseline). Note however that these assumptions have
not been harmonised in the CASCADE MINTS project, although some models are using the
same end-use demands as defined for the SRES-B2 scenario.
[EJ]
250
200
150
100
50
0
2000
2010
2020
Message
2030
GMM
Poles
2040
2050
DNE21+
Figure 4.13 Electricity demand in the world models show very similar trends
At present, there is a large regional variation in the importance of the power sector in satisfying
the final energy demand. Whereas in the industrialised world (OECD), it currently contributes
as much as one-fifth of the final energy demand, in the rest of the world its contribution ranges
between a mere 11 to 13%, as can be seen from Figure 4.14 below. The trends in growth furthermore seem to be roughly the same worldwide, leading to a similar proportion in 2050 between the OECD-region and the other regions. The levels are substantially higher, with almost
40% of the demand in the OOECD region being supplied by electricity.
40%
35%
30%
25%
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%
2000
2010
2020
Asia
Latin America, Africa and Middle East
Other OECD
2030
2040
2050
Eastern Europe and Former Soviet Union
North America
World
Figure 4.14 Contribution of electricity to the final energy demand in the five world regions
distinguished in GMM, and in the world as a whole
44
ECN-C--04-094
4.5.2 Much uncertainty on the future of renewables and nuclear power
While there is little controversy over the consumption of electricity, there is huge uncertainty
over which technologies will be the dominant ones in 2050. Most of the models however seem
to agree that gas and coal technologies will play a significant role by 2050, with only one
marked exception16. The agreement is completely lost when considering renewable energy
sources, where contribution from these sources to the total electricity demand ranges from 10%
to a quarter, and nuclear power, where it varies between 0-20%.
RES
Nuclear
60%
60%
50%
50%
40%
40%
30%
30%
20%
10%
0%
1990
2000
GMM
2010
2020
MESSAGE
2030
2040
POLES
2050
2060
20%
10%
0%
1990
2000
GMM
DNE21+
2010
MESSAGE
Gas
60%
50%
40%
50%
40%
30%
30%
20%
20%
10%
2000
GMM
2010
2020
MESSAGE
2030
2040
POLES
2050
2060
DNE21+
Coal
60%
0%
1990
2020
2030
2040
POLES
2050
2060
DNE21+
10%
0%
1990
2000
GMM
2010
2020
MESSAGE
2030
2040
POLES
2050
2060
DNE21+
Figure 4.15 Contribution from renewable energy sources (RES), nuclear energy, gas, and coal
in the power sector as percentage of total electricity generated generally shows
widely varying trend, reflecting uncertainty on the future electricity system
Based on the results presented here, both for renewables and for nuclear the results of GMM can
be used as some average value. We therefore use this model to investigate the role of renewables and nuclear on a more local scale. In Source: GMM
Figure 4.16 and Source: GMM
Figure 4.17 the regional contribution from renewables and nuclear, respectively, are shown for
the regions in GMM. A remarkable feature for the relative contributions from renewables is
that, although the world levels are practically constant, there are large changes on a local level.
Thus, the regional variations serve to show that global trends in some cases may be misleading,
or at the very least disguise changes in the underlying systems.
The changes in the contribution from renewable energy systems (RES) are such that an apparent shift from the LAFM region (Latin America, Africa and Middle East) to the OOECD (EU,
Japan, Australia, and New Zealand) occurs. In reality such a shift does not exist, as there is no
relation between the energy systems of the regions that could cause such a shift. In stead, the
demand for electricity in the LAFM region grows too fast for renewables to keep up with this
growth, and large hydropower, with limited growth potential, is the dominating renewable option. For these reasons, the relative contribution of renewables in the power sector is expected to
16
The exception again being the results from MESSAGE, due to the sulphur policies and the larger role of biomass
ethanol.
ECN-C--04-094
45
diminish. At the same time, the policies in the OOECD region are such that an increased importance of RES is the result.
45%
40%
35%
30%
25%
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%
2000
2010
2020
Asia
Latin America, Africa and Middle East
Other OECD
2030
2040
2050
Eastern Europe and Former Soviet Union
North America
World
Source: GMM
Figure 4.16 Contribution from renewable energy sources to the power sector: percentage
of total electricity generated, for the regions in GMM.
35%
30%
25%
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%
2000
2010
2020
Asia
Latin America, Africa and Middle East
Other OECD
2030
2040
2050
Eastern Europe and Former Soviet Union
North America
World
Source: GMM
Figure 4.17 Contribution from nuclear energy to the power sector: percentage of total electricity generated, for the regions in GMM.
4.5.3 Hydrogen plays a modest role, at best
As mentioned, hydrogen may develop as an alternative to electricity and combustible fuels due
to its unique character as transportable clean energy vector. However, in a baseline scenario one
would not expect hydrogen to fulfil its full potential, as the conditions needed for successful
penetration of hydrogen are absent. Main reason why hydrogen would play a modest role at best
46
ECN-C--04-094
is that the production costs are high. Figure 4.18 shows the projected production levels of hydrogen in three world models, currently including hydrogen production. The figure confirms the
expectations, in that the contribution of hydrogen remains relatively small. This holds even in
the most promising case, where the contribution amounts to roughly 3% of total demand in
2050, which indeed is modest when compared to for example the contribution of electricity, being of the order of 30%. The figure also illustrates that there is a huge uncertainty in the future
role of hydrogen, as the production of hydrogen differs by orders of magnitude in 2050, for the
three models.
[EJ]
100
10
1
0.1
0.01
2000
2010
2020
Message
2030
GMM
2040
2050
DNE21+
Figure 4.18 Total production of hydrogen in three world models shows a large variation, both
in the level and in the time of uptake. Note the logarithmic scale
Part 1 of the CASCADE MINTS project will be to provide a more extensive and consistent description of the hydrogen into the models, via the introduction of a more detailed technological
description. It is expected that such modifications will enable a more extensive analysis of the
role hydrogen may play in the transition towards a sustainable energy system. From this first
analysis, we may conclude that there will be some room for hydrogen; in the course of the project, this will be up for further investigations.
4.6
Energy-related CO2 emissions
4.6.1 CO2 emissions are directly related to the primary energy mix
In this section the results of the MESSAGE, GMM, and DNE21+ models are discussed. The
POLES model does also provide the required emission results (only up to 2030), but these are
mostly in line with results from GMM and only discussed separately if they show a different
trend.
Energy-related CO2 emissions are expected to increase by ca. 65-100% in the period 2000-2030
(1.7-2.4% per year) and even by ca. 85-170% in the period 2000-2050. This is in line with results from the PROMETHEUS model indicating a nearly 85% probability that energy related
CO2 emissions worldwide more than double between 1990 and 2030. Although the primary energy use projected by MESSAGE is 20% higher than that of DNE21+ in 2050, the CO2 emisECN-C--04-094
47
sions are ca. 25% lower. The level of CO2 emissions of GMM and DNE21+ is similar in 2050,
although the primary energy use of GMM is ca. 10% higher. These variations can be explained
from differences in the primary energy mix. For example, in 2030, the use of non-fossil energy
sources is almost twice as high in the MESSAGE model, as compared to the GMM model. This
is amongst others the result of the constraints on sulphur emissions included in MESSAGE, but
also due to more optimistic assumptions regarding technological improvements. The relatively
high CO2 emissions in the DNE21+ model are due to a decline of nuclear capacity and its replacement mainly by coal.
[Mton]
70000
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
2000
2010
Message World
Figure 4.19
2020
2030
Message World (power sector only)
2040
GMM World
2050
DNE21+ World
Energy-related CO2 emissions on global level; total and power sector only for
2000-2050
The MESSAGE model is the only model, from which CO2 emission results for the power sector
are available. On average, the CO2 emissions from the power sector show a similar trend as
compared to the total energy-related CO2 emissions up to 2030. Beyond 2030, the CO2 emissions from the power sector increase faster than the total CO2 emissions, which results in a doubling of CO2 emissions in the period 2000-2050.
4.6.2 Varying developments for CO2 emission indicators
Several indicators can be used to gain more insight into the drivers for the development of CO2
emissions over time. First, the indicator ‘CO2 emissions per capita’ provides insight into the relationship between CO2-emissions and population size. Using this indicator, the development of
CO2 emissions can be decoupled from population growth. Since the population growth is harmonised in CASCADE MINTS, CO2 emissions per capita mainly depend on differences in CO2
emissions.
In 2030, the CO2 emissions per capita are ca. 20-50% higher as compared to the base year 2000.
Beyond 2020, the models show diverging trends. For MESSAGE, the model with the highest
share of non-fossil energy sources and the slowest growth of the use of fossil fuels, the level of
CO2 emissions per capita remains almost constant in the period 2030-2050, about 20% higher
than the level in 2000. In the case when the use of fossil fuels increases substantially and the use
of non-fossil energy sources remains reasonably modest, the CO2 emissions per capita increase
much more, by approximately 70% in the period 2000-2050. The increase of the global level of
the CO2 emissions per capita is mainly due to a strong increase of this indicator in Eastern
Europe and the former Soviet Union.
48
ECN-C--04-094
[Ton CO2/capita]
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
2000
2010
2020
2030
Message World
GMM World
2040
2050
DNE21+ World
Figure 4.20 Development of CO2 emissions per capita in the period 2000-2050
The indicator ‘CO2 emissions per unit of GDP’ refers to the CO2 that is emitted for the production of one unit of GDP. Figure 4.21 shows that the carbon intensity of GDP is expected to decline over time. Since world GDP is harmonised in CASCADE MINTS, variations between
models regarding carbon intensity of GDP mainly depend on variations in CO2 emissions and
differences in regional aggregation. The downward trend in carbon intensity of GDP is due to a
higher economic growth as compared to the increase of CO2 emissions. The MESSAGE models
projects the strongest decline i.e. a 50% lower carbon intensity of GDP in 2050 as compared to
2000, whereas the results of the other models show a decrease of 30% in 50 years’ time. POLES
projects a relatively strong decline in the first 20 years but reaches the same level of carbon intensity of GDP in 2030 as MESSAGE. The main contributors to the decrease of the global level
of carbon intensity of GDP are Asia, Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union.
[Ton CO2/1000 EUR]
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
2000
2010
Message World
2020
GMM World
2030
Poles World
2040
2050
DNE21+ World
Figure 4.21 Development of CO2 emissions per unit of GDP in the period 2000-2050
ECN-C--04-094
49
CO2 emissions are strongly related to primary energy consumption, which is captured in the indicator ‘CO2 emissions per GJ primary energy use’. For example, in case the fuel mix remains
constant, the CO2 emission per GJ energy consumption would also remain roughly constant, and
so would the indicator. As can be seen in Figure 4.22, the models considered here show different trends for this indicator. Whereas GMM and POLES predict a slow increase of the indicator,
MESSAGE shows a considerable decline with 30% in the period 2000-2050. The trend displayed in MESSAGE is mainly driven by the shift towards CO2 free energy sources (or sources
low in CO2). The DNE21+ model projects the highest CO2 emissions per GJ, which is due to the
very small shares of renewable energy sources and nuclear energy in the primary energy mix.
[Ton CO2/GJ]
0.08
0.07
0.06
0.05
0.04
0.03
0.02
0.01
0.00
2000
2010
Message World
2020
GMM World
2030
Poles World
2040
2050
DNE21+ World
Figure 4.22 Development of CO2 emissions per unit of gross inland energy consumption in the
period 2000-2050
The indicator ‘CO2 emissions per kWh’ enables more insight into the development of
CO2 emissions from the power sector, independent of the growth of electricity production. This
indicator is provided only by MESSAGE. In 2000, this CO2 emission factor is ca. 0.50 kg
CO2/kWh. Due to the increased use of low-CO2 or CO2 free energy sources for electricity production, the CO2 emissions decline by almost 35% up to 0.33 kg CO2/kWh in 2030. In the period 2000-2050 the emission factor decreases by almost 50%, up to 0.25 kg CO2/kWh in 2050.
4.7
Other GHG emissions
None of the models reports separately on the development of N2O emissions. Only MESSAGE
provides information on the development of (energy-related) CH4 emissions. The growth of
CH4 shows a similar trend as compared to the CO2 emissions for this model, and so do the total
GHG emissions. The total CH4 emissions are ca. 77 Mton in 2000, rising to ca. 140 Mton in
2050. Between 2000 and 2020 the model projects the strongest growth of CH4 emissions.
4.8
NOx emissions
GMM only provides results on the NOx emissions from the power sector and can therefore not
be compared to the results from MESSAGE. According to MESSAGE, the NOx emissions decrease by almost 35% in the period 2000-2050, which is due to the increasing use of cleaner
50
ECN-C--04-094
primary energy sources that cause no or low NOx emissions. In the power sector, reported upon
by GMM, the combustion of fossil fuels remains more important, which leads to increasing NOx
emissions. In 2050, NOx emissions are twice as high as compared to the base year 2000.
4.9
SOx emissions
For energy-related SOx emissions results are presented for the energy system as a whole (MESSAGE) as well as for the power sector individually (GMM). Here, again, results from the two
models are difficult to compare. MESSAGE shows a strong decreasing trend for total SO2 emissions, i.e. almost a 50% decrease in the period 2000-2050. This is the result of sulphur control
policies that are included in the MESSAGE baseline.
On the global level, the power sector currently has a share of around 45% in total energy-related
SO2 emissions. The relatively high SO2 emissions from the power sector and the increasing
trend over the period 2000-2040 projected by GMM are due to the high share of coal in the energy mix for electricity generation, i.e. ca. 65% of the fuel input.
ECN-C--04-094
51
5.
BASELINE OUTLOOK FOR EUROPE
5.1
Introduction
In this chapter on baseline developments in Europe, the following models are considered:
PRIMES, POLES, MARKAL, NEMESIS, TIMES-EE, PACE and DNE21+. Sometimes the
European situation will be compared to the US, based on results from the NEMS model. For
other models results were not available at the time of writing. Moreover, not all models generate
results at the same level of detail, and therefore most graphs are based on results of a selection
of models. Most of the models that focus on Europe currently have a time horizon towards
2030, with the exception of MARKAL, DNE21+ and PACE. For reasons of cross-model comparability, the scope of this chapter is limited to the period up until 2030. Since most of the
models intend to extend their time horizon in the course of the CASCADE MINTS project,
more extended baseline results will become available later.
The starting point for the analysis is the region Western Europe (WEU) since this is the most
commonly used region in the models under consideration, as summarised in Table 5.1. Western
Europe is generally defined as the EU-15, Norway, Switzerland and Iceland. However, there are
small differences in the definition of this region in the various models. In the PRIMES model,
the region WEU excludes Iceland. For NEMESIS the WEU region refers to the EU-15 plus
Norway, while PACE and NEWAGE include Turkey in the WEU region. Differences in region
definition may partly explain differences in results. Wherever relevant, the PRIMES results for
the EU30 region, which is defined as Western Europe (excl. Iceland), the 10 new EU Member
States, Bulgaria, Romania and Turkey, will be taken into account in the discussion of baseline
results. Some models also distinguish a region ‘Central Europe’ which corresponds to the New
Member States in this region plus the countries of former Yugoslavia, but excludes the Baltic
States. It is noteworthy that the regional coverage of most models does not correspond with the
borders of the European Union. The present EU-25 is covered by only one model - PRIMES.
This is particularly important when issues related to security of supply are being considered.
Table 5.1 Regional coverage in European models
PRIMES POLES MARKAL NEMESIS TIMES- EE PACE NEWAGE-W DNE21+
3
3
3
3
• EU-15
3
3
3
3
3
3
3
3
• Western Europe (WEU)
excl.
excl.
incl. incl. Turkey incl. Malta
− EU-15
Iceland
Switzerland
Turkey
− Norway
Iceland
− Switzerland
− Iceland
• New EU Member
States
• Central Europe:
− Eastern Europe
− former YUG
• EU25
• EU30:
− EU25
− Norway
− Switzerland
− Bulgaria
− Romania
− Turkey
52
3
3
3
3
3
3
3
incl
Croatia,
Ukraine,
excl
Cyprus
ECN-C--04-094
5.2
Primary energy consumption in Europe grows less than world energy
consumption
As shown in Figure 5.1 the primary energy consumption projections of the different models
show only a very moderate increase, except for PACE and NEMESIS which project a decrease.
For NEMESIS this decrease can be attributed to the effect of the carbon tax. In addition to the
impacts of the carbon tax, the decrease in primary energy consumption in PACE can be attributed to the fact that PACE only takes into account primary energy consumption from fossil fuels
while primary energy consumption from nuclear and renewables are not explicitly accounted
for. Finally, NEWAGE-W shows a trend comparable to most other models, but the absolute
value is much lower, because only three types of fossil fuels are distinguished, and renewables
and nuclear are not accounted for. On average, European energy demand is projected to increase
by at most 0.5% per year between 2000 and 2030, whereas world energy consumption grows
with some 1.7% (based on POLES). For the EU-30 the projections are comparable to the trend
for Western Europe. Energy consumption growth is expected to be slightly higher in the new
EU Member States than in Western Europe.
[PJ]
120,000
100,000
80,000
60,000
40,000
20,000
0
2000
Primes WEU
DNE21+ EU-30
2010
Primes EU-30
NEMESIS EU+NO
2020
Poles WEU
NEWAGE-W WEU
2030
Markal WEU
PACE WEU (scaled)
Figure 5.1 Total primary energy consumption
5.3
Primary consumption grows less than GDP, but faster than population
The primary energy intensity relates the total amount of energy used in a region to the GDP. It
measures the amount of primary energy required to generate one unit of GDP. Changes in this
indicator reflect both efficiency changes in the transformation sector and at the level of final
consumers. Figure 5.2 illustrates the general expectation that in the next 30 years, the combined
effect of energy price increases, changes in the sectoral structure of the economy, and technical
efficiency improvements indicate that less primary energy is needed to create one unit of GDP.
As can be seen from the PRIMES results, this effect is stronger in the new Member States. The
high level of the energy intensity in the base year indicates that there is a lot of room for efficiency improvements. As is shown by the steep decrease in intensity for this region, this potential for improvement is to a large extent exploited: while for 2000 the intensity for the NMS region is roughly three times that of Western Europe, in 2030 the fraction has diminished to approximately a factor two, and the level is comparable to that of the world as a whole. In the US,
primary energy intensity is some 30% higher than in Western Europe, and is decreasing at a rate
ECN-C--04-094
53
similar to Europe; therefore not much change in regional differences is expected in the next two
decades.
[PJ/bln €]
25
20
15
10
5
0
2000
2010
US (NEMS)
2020
NMS (Primes)
World (Message)
2030
WEU (Markal)
Figure 5.2 Primary energy intensity (Gross inland consumption/GDP) compared for Western
Europe, the new Member States, the US and the world. Other models show similar
trends
On the other hand, the indicator that compares the growth of primary energy consumption to
population growth (Figure 5.3) shows an increasing trend. This implies that the energy needs of
the average European citizen are still increasing steadily. These observations hold not only in
Western Europe but also in the rest of the world. However, there are large differences in the
level of this indicator. American residents use approximately twice as much energy as western
Europeans, and no structural change is expected. On the other hand, in the new Member States,
energy consumption per capita starts at a lower level, but, according the PRIMES model, shows
the highest rate of increase.
54
ECN-C--04-094
[PJ/mln capita]
450
400
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
2000
2010
World (Message)
2020
US (NEMS)
NMS (Primes)
2030
WEU (Markal)
Figure 5.3 Gross inland consumption/capita compared for Western Europe, the new Member
States, the US and the world. Other models show similar trends
5.4
Primary consumption is still dominated by fossil fuels
As illustrated in Figure 5.4, Western Europe’s primary energy consumption in 2000 was dominated by fossil fuels, particularly oil and natural gas, which together accounted for almost two
thirds of total consumption.
Biomass and waste
4%
Other
Other renewables
1%
1%
Hydro
8%
Gas
21%
Nuclear
14%
Coal/solids
13%
Oil/liquids
38%
Source: Primes.
Figure 5.4 Primary consumption by fuel in Western Europe in the year 2000; total 68,771 PJ
No major change is expected in the baseline scenario. All projections indicate that by 2030, fossil fuels will still have some 70-75% share in the primary energy mix, although models show
different contributions of the different fossil fuels. Figure 5.5 illustrates the 2030 fuel mix in
Western Europe as projected by several models. Europe will still primarily rely on oil, but the
share of natural gas will significantly increase. The growth of gas demand is expected by all
ECN-C--04-094
55
models, and analysed further in Section 5.5.4. Oil consumption is expected to stabilise or to decrease slightly towards 2030 (MARKAL and DNE21+). Coal consumption is more or less stable according to Primes and Poles, while MARKAL and DNE21+ project a significant increase
in 2030 compared to the 2000 level. Not surprisingly, there is hardly any hydrogen in the baseline, and only beyond 2030.
[PJ]
90,000
80,000
70,000
60,000
50,000
40,000
30,000
20,000
10,000
0
Primes
Gas
Poles
Oil/liquids
Coal/solids
Markal
Nuclear
Renewables
DNE21+
Other
Figure 5.5 Primary energy consumption by fuel in Western Europe in 203017
Remarkable is that MARKAL and DNE21+ expect nuclear energy to be phased out in the baseline, although no explicit phasing out policies have been included (see Section 3.6). This reflects
that costs for nuclear power are in these models too high to be competitive. Thus, the different
projections on the share of nuclear in the future energy system reflect some uncertainty on the
role it may play under present circumstances.
The Primes model projects a 16% share of renewables18, whereas most other models expect
some 10-12% share in the primary energy mix. Apart from a steady contribution of hydropower,
wind power shows a significant growth.
Comparing the present fuel mix of primary energy consumption in Western Europe to that in the
new Member States (Source: Primes.
Figure 5.6), it is clear that the dominance of fossil fuels is even larger with a share of almost
90%. Particularly the share of coal is much larger in new Member States. The share of nuclear
and renewables is smaller in the new Member States than in Western Europe, and the contribution of wind and solar energy is negligible. Of course it should be noted that the size of total
primary energy consumption in the new Member States is small compared to that in Western
Europe; 8.4 EJ and 68.8 EJ respectively in the year 2000.
17
18
Results of the other models could not be included for various reasons. NEMESIS has a time horizon until 2020,
PACE and NEWAGE-W only distinguish three energy carriers: gas, oil and coal.
Measured according to the substitution principle. If the Eurostat convention was used, the share would be lower.
56
ECN-C--04-094
Hydro
2% Biomass and waste
3%
Nuclear
Gas
7%
19%
Coal/solids
45%
Oil/liquids
24%
Other renewables 0%
Other 0%
Source: Primes.
Figure 5.6 Primary consumption by fuel in the new Member States in the year 2000; total
8,380 PJ
In the next decades the energy system of the New Member States is expected to move towards
the energy system of the EU15. Consequently, the relative importance of coal will diminish, as
new, additional generation capacity will be covered mainly by natural gas and renewables. This
will probably be due to the carbon tax in the baseline scenario. The Primes model projects the
growth of energy consumption in the new Member States to be slightly higher than that in
Western Europe after 2010. Given the relatively small size of the energy consumption in the
new Member States compared to Western Europe, the fuel mix of the EU30 will not be dramatically different from that in Western Europe. The share of fossil fuels is projected to be 70-75%,
to which coal contributes some 9%.
5.5
Import dependency will increase significantly
In the year 2000 the import share in primary energy consumption ranges from 35-50% in different models. All models project this indicator to increase significantly; 2030 values range from
50-75% and a further increase is expected towards the year 2050. Differences between these
import shares may be explained by:
• Differences in assumptions on the availability of indigenous resources.
• Timing of use of indigenous sources.
• Use of renewables in different models.
• Use of coal, and origin of coal used.
• A methodological issue: the Primes results show lower import dependency because they do
not include the effect of imported nuclear fissile material.
In the next sections we will examine the background of these developments for oil and natural
gas respectively.
ECN-C--04-094
57
[%]
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Poles
Primes
Markal
Western Europe
Primes
EU-30
2000
2030
Figure 5.7 Net imports as share of gross inland consumption
5.5.1 Diversity in the European primary fuel mix relatively constant
Security of supply is not only reflected in the dependency on imports, although this is an important issue. Other factors to be considered are the level of diversification, inversely related to the
dependence on a few primary fuels, and the correlation between these fuels in terms of costs and
availability. Several attempts have been made to design indicators that capture these considerations in a compact way.
The Shannon diversity index reflects the variety and the balance in Europe’s portfolio of
sources for primary energy consumption.
• Variety refers to the number of fuels available for primary energy consumption. The greater
the variety of a system, the greater the diversity.
• Balance refers to the pattern in the spread or the relative importance of each fuel category;
the more even the spread; the greater the diversity.
In (Jansen et al, 2004) the mathematical definition and elaboration of this index for measuring
portfolio diversity is given. For this report, it suffices to explain that a decreasing diversity index is to be interpreted as a situation in which there is an increasing reliance on only a few energy sources.
The diversity index can be adjusted for the effect of import dependency in the primary fuel mix
of a given region. The resulting ‘diversity & dependence’ indicator, presented in Figure 5.8,
combines the information given by the straightforward domestic production share and the Shannon diversity index. The decreasing trend shows that for Western Europe, the supply security is
worsened. However, in the period until 2030 the decrease in indigenous production is partly offset by the increased diversification. For Primes, these indicators show comparable trends, although the levels of these indicators are higher, implying less external dependence and more diversity. This is mainly due to the higher share of renewables in the Primes baseline, which
makes diversity showing a slight increase towards 2030. It should be noted that the different
models show large differences in their projections of Europe’s future fuel mix, see Figure 5.4,
and thus in their expected level of diversification. Therefore conclusions on these issues can
hardly be supported from the baseline projections.
58
ECN-C--04-094
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
2000
2010
2020
2030
2040
2050
Share of domestic production
Diversity index
Diversity & dependence index
Source: MARKAL
Figure 5.8 Import dependency and diversity indices in Western Europe
The policy cases in the CASCADE MINTS project will be used to examine the effect of e.g. a
larger share of renewables to improve the overall supply security, as approximated by this indicator.
5.5.2 Highest dependency for oil - up to 85%
As shown in the previous sections, Europe’s oil consumption is expected to stabilise at about a
third of its primary energy consumption in 2030. Domestic production however is expected to
decrease due to limited reserves and high production costs, thereby introducing a greater reliance on imports from notably the Middle East. Source: Poles.
Figure 5.9 illustrates how the import share is expected to increase from 50% to 84% in 2030, as
projected by the POLES model for Western and Central Europe together. Other models show a
similar trend.
ECN-C--04-094
59
[PJ]
35000
30000
25000
20000
15000
10000
5000
0
2000
2010
Western and Central Europe - Oil production
2020
2030
Western and Central Europe - Oil imports
Source: Poles.
Figure 5.9 Oil production and imports in Western and Central Europe
5.5.3 Sources of oil imports
In 1999, 51% of oil imports to the EU-15 came from OPEC countries, of which Saudi Arabia,
Libya and Iran were largest suppliers. Large non-OPEC suppliers were Norway (21%) and the
former Soviet Union (18%) (European Union, 2000). As shown in the graph below, the largest
reserves are in the Middle East. As was seen in Chapter 4, the increased dependency on oil from
the Middle East one might expect from this build-up of reserves indeed occurs. This may lead to
increased concerns about the security of supply on the longer term, particularly given the present uncertain political situation in that region.
Source: BP.
Figure 5.10 World oil reserves
60
ECN-C--04-094
5.5.4 A dash for gas
As described in Chapter 4, the world gas consumption is projected to triple between 2000 and
2050. The gas consumption of Western Europe grows at a slower pace, and different models
show different growth rates. The growth is largely due to the increased production of natural gas
for power production (see Section 5.7). The share of Western and Central Europe in the world
gas consumption is some 22-24%.
5.5.5 The European response to natural gas demand
The three main natural gas producers within Western Europe are the United Kingdom, the
Netherlands and Norway, while Russia and Algeria are the main gas suppliers outside Europe.
Source: Poles
Figure 5.11 illustrates that in the period towards 2030, domestic gas production is expected to
decrease slightly, while imports from Russia will grow, thereby increasing the external dependency for natural gas.
[PJ]
25.000
20.000
15.000
10.000
5.000
0
2000
2010
2020
2030
Production in Western
Imports from Russia and
Imports from Africa, Latin America,
Source: Poles
Figure 5.11 Natural gas production and net imports to Western Europe by region of origin
In line with this, all models project an increase of the external dependence for gas. Figure 5.12
shows this for different regions and models, illustrating that other models expect an even
stronger increase of the import dependency than Poles. Gas supplies from Norway are regarded
‘domestic’ in these analyses, implying that import shares for the EU-15 are still higher. Nevertheless, Norway is already an established and politically stable supplier, so the actual security of
gas supply is not affected. However, the accession of the new Member States and their heavy
reliance on a single supplier - Russia - does increase the risks related to gas supply security. On
the other hand, enlargement is expected to reduce the risks associated with transit of gas across
the New Member States towards EU-15 countries (Van Oostvoorn et al., 2003).
ECN-C--04-094
61
[%]
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Poles
Primes
Markal
Western Europe
Poles
Primes
Western &
Central
Europe
DNE 21+
EU-30
Figure 5.12 Share of imports in gross primary consumption of natural gas in 2030
5.6
Final energy demand in Western Europe grows less than GDP
Final energy demand in Western Europe grows with on average 0.5-0.8% per year, which is less
than a third of the growth in world final energy demand. In the new Member States, final demand grows faster, at a rate of 1% per year. There is a significant difference in the projections
for the EU-30 by Primes and DNE21+. The latter model projects a much more moderate growth
after 2010. In Primes and MARKAL, final energy demand grows faster than primary consumption. This implies that the transformation sector will become more efficient.
[PJ]
80000
70000
60000
50000
40000
30000
20000
10000
0
2000
2010
Primes WEU
Primes EU30
Poles WEU
2020
Markal WEU
DNE21+ EU-30
2030
NEMESIS EU+NO
Figure 5.13 Final energy demand in different European regions
Final energy demand in Western Europe grows less than GDP, and therefore all models project
the final energy intensity to decrease with some 1.5% annually on average. Figure 5.14 shows
that, according to the Primes model, the New Member States start with a more energy intensive
situation in the year 2000. However, their energy intensity decreases faster, at the rate of 2.4%,
showing a convergence towards the year 2030. Given the small size of the final energy con62
ECN-C--04-094
sumption in the new Member States compared to their Western European counterparts, the energy intensity for the EU-30 is only slightly higher than that for Western Europe. In the US, final energy intensity is almost twice the level of that in Western Europe, and decreasing at the
same rate.
[PJ/bln EUR]
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
2000
2010
World (Message)
2020
USA (NEMS)
NMS (Primes)
2030
WEU (Markal)
Figure 5.14 Final energy intensity for Western Europe compared to the world, the US and the
new Member States; other models show similar trends
5.6.1 No major change in sectoral structure of final demand
Figure 5.15 illustrates the sectoral composition of final energy demand in the year 2000. The
transport sector has the largest contribution to the final energy demand, mainly consisting of oil
products, followed by the industrial sector. This sectoral structure of energy demand is not expected to change in the period towards 2030, implying that energy demand in the different enduse sectors shows comparable growth rates. The largest growth in final energy demand is found
in the commercial sector with 1.1% per year on average, followed by the transport sector with
0.9% annually, and industry with 0.8% annually.
ECN-C--04-094
63
Non-energy uses
2030
Agriculture
2%
8%
Industry
26%
9%
26%
2%
Transport
30%
2000
29%
Commercial
11%
12%
23%
22%
Households
Source: Primes.
Figure 5.15 Final energy demand in Western Europe by sector in 2000 and 2030; Total: 45.7
EJ in 2000 and 57.3 EJ in 2030
5.6.2 Final consumption of electricity
In the year 2000, final electricity demand was approximately 18% of total final demand. As illustrated in, most models expect this share to increase slightly to some 22%; MARKAL and
DNE21+ providing a lower and an upper estimate respectively. This growth is the continuation
of a trend that has been visible in the last years, when the growth of the service sector, and an
increase of disposable income in the residential sector caused an increased penetration of electrical appliances in most European countries.
There are differences in expected growth rates of electricity demand. The MARKAL model projects a much more moderate growth rate than the others; and NEMESIS and DNE21+ project a
stabilisation beyond 2010 and 2020 respectively. In the new Member States, demand for electricity grows relatively fast at an annual rate of 2.2%, compared to a rate of 1.2 – 1.4% annually
for Western Europe. All models indicate that final demand for electricity increases faster than
total final energy demand.
64
ECN-C--04-094
30%
25%
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%
2000
2010
Primes WEU
Primes EU30
2020
Poles WEU
Markal WEU
2030
DNE21+ EU-30
NEMESIS EU+NO
Figure 5.16 Contribution of electricity to the final energy demand
The sectoral structure of final electricity demand does not significantly change over time, as illustrated in
Figure 5.17 for PRIMES. There are some indications that the electricity demand of the commercial sector increases faster than that in other sectors. Other models confirm this pattern.
[TWh]
1800
1600
1400
1200
1000
800
600
400
200
0
Industry
2000
Commercial
Households
Transport
Agriculture
2030
Non-energy uses
Source: Primes.
Figure 5.17 Final electricity demand by sector in the EU-30
5.7
Technologies for power generation in Europe
In Figure 5.18 the composition of the fuels used for electricity production in Western Europe is
illustrated. Notable is the large share of nuclear, followed by coal. Renewables have a share of
over 20% in the year 2000, including a significant contribution of large hydropower in Norway19. In the EU-15 this share is somewhat lower (Norway production 113 TWh).
19
Of total hydropower capacity in Western Europe, approximately 21% is installed in Norway (Lako et al., 2003).
ECN-C--04-094
65
Wind Biomass
1%
2%
Hydro
20%
Gas
16%
Oil/liquids
6%
Nuclear
30%
Coal/solids
25%
Geothermal 0%
Solar 0%
Source: TIMES-EE.
Figure 5.18 Net electricity generation by fuel in Western Europe in 2000 (total 2698 TWh)
Expectations on future developments in the fuels and technologies used for power generation
differ largely among models, as shown in Figure 5.1920. This is due to differences in assumptions on the costs and efficiencies of power production technologies and availability of natural
gas resources. In addition, the future of nuclear power largely depends on nuclear policies, and
different models deal with this in different ways. It should also be kept in mind that the total
amount of electricity production differs substantially among models, see Section 5.6.2.
All models project an increase of the share of natural gas, ranging from 16% (TIMES and
MARKAL), 20% (POLES and DNE21+) to 43% (Primes) in 2030. This variation is mainly due
to different assumptions on availability and costs of indigenous gas production in Europe.
Likewise, all models project a decrease of the share of oil and oil products in power generation
to some 1-3%, compared to 6% in 2000. DNE21+ is the exception with a projected share of
17%.
The largest range is observed in the prospects for coal technologies and nuclear power production. Primes projects coal-based power generation to decrease from the current 25% to some
15% while the other models expect (considerable) growth in this sector, possibly to compensate
for the moderate shares of natural gas. The share of nuclear is expected to decrease in all models
to approximately 20% of the European power generation mix. The exceptions are MARKAL
and DNE21+, which project a 3-8% share due to high costs of nuclear power. Finally, the projections for biomass agree in their direction of growth in all models, TIMES and Primes being
the most optimistic ones. Whenever a distinction between biomass residues and energy crops is
made, the share of the energy crops is larger.
20
Results from NEMESIS are not shown here, because they are only available for 1990-2020; the trend is however
similar to the one projected by Primes.
66
ECN-C--04-094
[TWh]
6000
5000
4000
3000
2000
1000
0
Primes
Poles
Gas
Markal
Western Europe
Oil/liquids Coal/solids
Times
Nuclear
Hydro
Primes
DNE21+
EU30
Other renewables
Figure 5.19 Net electricity generation by fuel in Europe in 2030
5.8
Energy-related CO2 emissions
5.8.1 CO2 emissions grow along with primary energy consumption
Figure 5.20 shows the development of energy-related CO2 emissions for the European models,
except TIMES-EE, since this model only calculates emissions for the power sector. CO2 emissions from the power sector will be discussed later on in this section. On average, the CO2 emissions are ca. 12% higher as compared in 2030 to the base year 2000, for Western Europe. This
means that, on average, the CO2 emissions grow by approximately 0.4% per year. Beyond 2030,
growth of CO2 emissions becomes less rapid, and even a decrease is observed between 2040 and
2050 (based on MARKAL and DNE21+).
ECN-C--04-094
67
[Mton]
7000
6000
5000
4000
3000
2000
1000
0
2000
Primes WEU
2010
Primes EU30
Poles WEU
2020
Markal WEU
DNE21+ EU-30
2030
NEMESIS EU+NO
Figure 5.20 Energy-related CO2 emissions for Europe (WEU/EU-30) for 2000-203021
Variations in projected CO2 emissions can partly be clarified from slight differences in primary
energy consumption, regional aggregations and fuel mix, which also explains the difference in
the base year 2000. However, for most models for the Western European region, CO2 emissions
grow at similar rates (9-13%).
NEMESIS is the only model that expects a decline of CO2 emissions i.e. an 8% decrease in CO2
emissions in the period 2000-2020. In this model, the primary energy consumption is expected
to decline as well, as a result of the carbon tax (see Section 3.6.4), whereas the other models
project rising primary energy consumption. In addition to this, coal has a relatively small share
in the primary energy mix (based on results for 2020).
A comparison of the emission results from PRIMES for the WEU and EU30 region shows that
CO2 emissions are expected to grow somewhat faster when the new EU Member States and potential future accession countries are included. In the new Member States the CO2 emissions increase less rapidly as compared to Western Europe in the period 2000-2030, 4% and 9%, respectively. In contrast to this result, the DNE21+ model projects a much faster increase for the
CO2 emissions in the EU30 in the period 2000-2030, partly due to a different regional specification.
There is a striking difference with the projections of global energy-related CO2 emissions. Here,
annual growth rates of ca. 2% per year are observed. This means that in the rest of the world the
CO2 emissions are expected to rise much more rapid as compared to Western Europe. This also
means that Europe’s share in global CO2 emissions will decline over time.
Under the Kyoto Protocol, Western Europe is committed to achieving an 8% reduction of CO2
emissions by 2008-2012, as compared to the level in 1990. For the EU15, Norway, Switzerland,
and Iceland together, the total emissions of CO2 amounted to approximately 3400 Mton in
199022. This means that in the period 2008-2012, the level of total CO2 emissions (including
21
22
68
The PACE and NEWAGE models are not considered in this section, since these models only takes into account
the primary energy categories gas, oil/liquids, and coal/solids.
Based on CO2 emission level for individual countries for 1990 derived from ww.climnet.org/resources/kpeng.pdf.
ECN-C--04-094
non-energy uses) should not exceed a level of approximately 3100 Mton per year. However,
Figure 5.20 shows that the energy-related CO2 emissions alone are already expected to exceed
this level, indicating that it will be very difficult to achieve the Kyoto target.
5.8.2 Large variety in CO2 emissions projections power sector
The growth rates for CO2 emissions from the power sector vary much more among the models
as compared to the total energy-related CO2 emissions, i.e. a 14-32% growth in the period 20002030. This corresponds to an annual increase of 0.4-0.9%, which is faster than the growth rate
of total energy-related CO2 emissions. MARKAL projects the highest growth of CO2 emissions
from the power sector, which is due to the higher carbon content of the fuel mix for electricity
generation, i.e. the smaller share of natural gas and larger share of coal, as compared to
PRIMES and, to a lesser extent, TIMES-EE (see Paragraph 5.6.2).
The results from the PRIMES model for the WEU and EU30 region show similar growth rates,
but the growth rate for the New Member States and potential future accession countries is
somewhat lower. The declining trend that is observed for NEMESIS is not surprising considering the projections for total energy-related CO2 emissions and primary energy consumption.
[Mton]
1800
1600
1400
1200
1000
800
600
400
200
0
2000
2010
Primes WEU
Primes EU30
2020
Markal WEU
TIMES WEU
2030
NEMESIS EU+NO
Figure 5.21 CO2 emissions from the power sector for Europe (WEU/EU-30) for 2000-2030
5.8.3 Strong decline in carbon intensity of GDP but constant CO2 emissions per GJ
The results for the CO2 emissions per capita show that this indicator is expected to increase by
8-17% in the period 2000-2030 for Western Europe, see Figure 5.22. This implies that the CO2
emissions grow faster than the population in Western Europe. Beyond 2030, this growth will
continue but as of 2040, both MARKAL and DNE21 expect a decline of CO2 emissions per
capita.
Figure 5.22 also shows results for the CO2 emissions per capita for the new Member States.
These are expected to grow somewhat faster in the new Member States as compared to Western
Europe. CO2 emissions per capita for Western Europe are ca. twice as high as compared to the
range of the global average. For the US, the CO2 emissions per capita increase by similar rates
as compared to Western Europe, but the absolute value of this indicator is twice as high, or even
four times as high as the global average.
ECN-C--04-094
69
[Ton CO2/capita]
25
20
15
10
5
0
2000
2010
NEMS (US)
Poles WEU
Primes WEU
Markal WEU
2020
Primes EU30
DNE21+ EU-30
2030
Primes NMS
NEMESIS EU+NO
Figure 5.22 CO2 emissions per capita for WEU/EU-30/NMS/US for 2000-2030
For Western Europe the carbon intensity of GDP is expected to decline by 30-45% in the period
2000-2030. Results from the MARKAL model show that beyond 2030 the carbon intensity of
GDP decreases even further. Since the CO2 emissions increase over time, the downward trend in
carbon intensity of GDP is due to a higher economic growth as compared to the increase of CO2
emissions. The absolute level of the carbon intensity of GDP is in the range 0.21-0.26 tons CO2
per 1000 Euro in 2030. The global average in the same year is almost twice as high. In 2050, the
global average will have approached the 2000 level of carbon intensity of GDP in Western
Europe.
[Ton CO2/1000 EUR]
1.6
1.4
1.2
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
2000
2010
NEMS US
Poles WEU
Primes WEU
Markal WEU
2020
Primes EU30
DNE21+ EU-30
2030
Primes NMS
NEMESIS EU+NO
Figure 5.23 Carbon intensity of GDP for WEU/EU-30/NMS/US for 2000-2030
70
ECN-C--04-094
The new Member States currently have a carbon intensity of GDP of ca. 1.4 ton CO2 per 1000
Euro (PRIMES). This level is expected to decrease very quickly by ca. 2% per year to a level of
approximately 0.52 ton CO2 per 1000 Euro in 2030, which is still twice as high as compared to
Western Europe. In the US, the current carbon intensity of GDP is about 0.54 ton CO2 per 1000
Euro (NEMS). Since the development of this indicator for the US shows a similar trend as compared to Western Europe, the absolute level of carbon intensity of GDP will remain higher for
the US on the long term as well.
The carbon intensity of energy use is indicated by the CO2 emissions per GJ. For Western
Europe, most models show a constant trend or a slight decrease in the period 2000-2030. The
same conclusion holds for the US. In the new Member States, a decline of 15% is observed.
Only MARKAL expects a slight increase of CO2 emissions per GJ. The average CO2 emissions
per GJ are much lower for Western Europe as compared to the levels for the new Member
States and the US, and the global level. For the EU-30, PRIMES and DNE21 project different
developments, i.e. a 10-% decrease and a 25-% increase, respectively.
[Ton CO2/GJ]
0.07
0.06
0.05
0.04
0.03
0.02
0.01
0.00
2000
2010
NEMS (US)
Poles WEU
2020
Primes WEU
Markal WEU
Primes EU30
DNE21+ EU-30
2030
Primes NMS
NEMESIS EU+NO
Figure 5.24 CO2 emissions per GJ for WEU/EU-30/NMS/US for 2000-2030
The general expectation for Western Europe is that the specific CO2 emissions from the power
sector will decline in the period 2000-2030, which will mostly be achieved in the first ten years.
For this indicator most models show a decrease ranging from 10-28% by 2020 as compared to
the base year 2000, which is continued beyond 2020. Only the MARKAL model shows a different trend. After an initial decline of CO2 emissions from the power sector, the model expects the
emissions to rise again beyond 2010. The relatively high CO2 emissions per kWh are due to the
very large share of coal and the relatively small shares of gas and nuclear energy in electricity
generation. In 2000, the absolute level of CO2 emissions per kWh in Western Europe is about
30% lower as compared to the global average. However, in 2030, this difference no longer exists. For the new Member States the decrease is much higher as compared to Western Europe in
the next 25 years, ca. 36% (PRIMES). For the US, the CO2 emissions are expected to decline as
well, but at a much slower rate, ca. 6% in the next 15 years.
ECN-C--04-094
71
[Kg CO2/kWh]
0.90
0.80
0.70
0.60
0.50
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
2000
2010
NEMS
Markal WEU
2020
Primes WEU
TIMES WEU
Primes EU30
NEMESIS EU+NO
2030
Primes NMS
Figure 5.25 CO2 emissions per kWh for WEU/EU-30/NMS/US for 2000-2030
5.8.4 Relatively high increase of CO2 emissions from transport sector
Figure 5.26 shows the CO2 emissions of final energy use split into end-use sectors for 2030 and
2050, for the WEU and EU30 region. If the new Member States are included, the share of the
transport sector is slightly larger in 2030 (PRIMES). The results also show that for Western
Europe the share of the transport sector in total CO2 emissions is expected to increase mainly at
the expense of the industrial sector.
[Mton]
5000
4500
4000
3500
3000
2500
2000
1500
1000
500
0
PRIMES
PRIMES
2030
MARKAL
2030
EU-30
Industry
MARKAL
2050
Western Europe
Transport
Residential, commercial
Agriculture
Power sector
Other conversion
Figure 5.26 Contributions of end-use sectors to total energy related CO2 emissions for
Western Europe and EU-30 for 2030 and 2050
72
ECN-C--04-094
5.9
CH4 emission reduction important to mitigating the greenhouse effect
Among the European models, only MARKAL provides results on the development of other
greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions such as CH4 and N2O. Figure 5.27 shows the development of
these emissions in the period 2000-2050, compared to the development of total energy-related
CO2 emissions and total GHG emissions (which are calculated in Mton CO2 equivalents). The
CO2 emissions as well as the N2O emissions increase over time. The level of N2O emissions, for
which the use of fertilisers in agriculture is the principle source, is about 620 kton in 2000. This
is projected to increase up to ca. 690 kton in 2050. In contrast to this, the development of total
GHG emissions shows a decreasing trend, which means that the increase of CO2 and N2O emissions is entirely compensated by a decrease in CH4 emissions. The level of CH4 emissions is ca.
31 Mton per year in 2000. This is expected to decline rather quickly between 2010 and 2020
towards a level of ca. 19 Mton per year, which remains almost constant as from 2020. This decrease is mainly due to reduced methane emissions from disposal sites, as a result of increased
recovery of methane. Another possibility is to combust the methane, and possibly utilise the
produced heat. This reduces the methane emissions but produces CO2 emissions, which have a
less strong greenhouse effect. Figure 5.27 clearly shows the importance of reducing CH4 emissions in mitigating the greenhouse effect.
[2000=100]
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
2000
2010
CO2 total, from energy only
Figure 5.27
2020
CH4 total
N2O total
2030
Total GHG
Development of total CO2, CH4, N2O and Greenhouse Gas (GHG) emissions
(MARKAL)
ECN-C--04-094
73
6.
KEY MESSAGES
6.1
Twelve models use one baseline scenario to provide a comprehensive outlook on future developments
This report has presented the results of an effort by ten renowned modelling teams in Europe,
the US and Japan to provide an outlook to possible developments in Europe and at global level.
This outlook was based on a common, harmonised baseline scenario, and will serve as a
benchmark against which policy scenarios will be compared in later stages of the project.
Given the diversity of the models, a moderate level of harmonisation was chosen. A number of
quantitative assumptions – economic and demographic developments, oil prices and current
policies – have been harmonised, whereas technology-specific assumptions have not been harmonised. A consistent basis for harmonisation of a baseline scenario was provided by the SRES
‘B2 marker scenario’ (IPCC, 2000). The B2 scenario shows more gradual changes and less extreme developments than other SRES scenarios and can be considered the closest approximation
to a ‘dynamics as usual’ scenario, with moderate GDP and population growth.
Because other important driving forces, such as technological change and average improvement
of energy efficiency, were not harmonised, the set of baseline results from CASCADE MINTS
is broader than the B2 group of scenarios. The added value of these variations is that they reflect
uncertainty about future developments. Moreover, the diversity of the models will provide different views on the effectiveness of the policy approaches. It should be noted that all observations fall within the boundaries of the harmonised baseline. The main driving forces - GDP,
population and energy prices - have been harmonised, and conclusions that directly rely on implications of these assumptions are beyond the scope of the project.
Notwithstanding the fact that the baseline scenario provides a starting point for further analyses
in the CASCADE MINTS Part 2 project, the results of this modelling work, based on a scientific consensus among modellers, already provide a first image of a future world under moderate
GDP and population growth, thereby giving first answers to questions such as:
• What are the challenges and weaknesses of current energy supply in Europe, and in the rest
of the world?
• In what sense do Europe’s energy supply and consumption differ from other world regions?
• Are current policies sufficient for achieving set targets?
• What are the perspectives regarding global warming?
The timing of this policy research is appropriate, as the European Commission has started a reflection on the actions on climate change for the post-2012 period, especially considering the
benefits and costs and taking into account both environmental and competitiveness concerns.
In the next sections an overview is given of the key messages derived from the CASCADE
MINTS Part 2 baseline scenario.
6.2
World energy trends until 2050
Primary consumption more than doubles
•
74
World primary energy consumption is expected to more than double in 2000-2050, in line
with the assumptions regarding moderate economic and population growth. Asia is the fastest grower and quadruples its energy consumption in 2050.
ECN-C--04-094
•
•
•
Fossil fuels are expected to remain dominant in the world fuel mix by supplying 65-80% of
primary energy use. Combined with the growth in primary energy use, this results in an ever
increasing speed of depletion of natural resources.
The worldwide production of coal grows faster than oil and gas production. The main
growth of coal production takes place in Africa and Asia, as well as in the Eastern Europe
and Former Soviet Union region.
The growth in gas consumption is roughly in line with the growth in total energy consumption, i.e. the relative contribution of gas does not change significantly on the global scale.
Regional differences remain large
•
•
At present, the gross inland consumption of energy per capita shows a large divergence between the industrialised world, North America, Japan, and Western Europe on the one hand,
and the developing countries on the other hand. Although the per capita consumption increases in all regions in the world, the differences remain large, which is a reflection of our
assumption that no additional action is taken to increase equity.
The present distribution of primary energy intensities, the indicator measuring the average
amount of energy needed for the production of one unit GDP, shows a large dichotomy between the developed countries and the developing countries. Energy intensities improve in
all regions and their levels converge. This is for a large part the result of the global trend
towards increased efficiency in energy consumption. In the developing countries, such improvements may temporarily be offset by the shift from un-marketed energy towards commercial energy, which occurs due to industrialization.
Electricity increasingly important
•
•
The importance of electricity in satisfying the final energy demand increases in all world
regions, leading to an average global contribution of 32% electricity in final energy demand
in 2050. However, the present large regional variations, ranging from some 12% in the developing world to 20% in the industrialised world, tends to remain, as the trends in growth
seem to be roughly the same world-wide.
While there is little controversy over the increase in consumption of electricity, there is
huge uncertainty over which technologies will be dominant in 2050. Most of the models
however seem to agree that gas and coal technologies will play a significant role by 2050.
The agreement is completely lost when considering renewable energy sources, where contribution from these sources to the total electricity demand ranges from 10% to a quarter,
and nuclear power, where it varies between 0-20%.
Hydrogen plays a modest role, at best
•
6.3
Hydrogen may develop as an alternative to electricity and combustible fuels due to its
unique character as transportable clean energy vector. However, in a baseline scenario, the
conditions needed for successful penetration of hydrogen are absent, and therefore the contribution of hydrogen remains relatively small. There is a huge uncertainty in the future role
of hydrogen, as the production of hydrogen differs by orders of magnitude in 2050 among
models.
Europe in a global context
Europe in 2030 - what can we expect?
•
In Europe, the primary energy consumption increases by some 20% in 2000-2030, which is
a much slower growth than the world average. The reliance on fossil fuels, with a 70-75%
contribution to the primary energy mix, is comparable to the rest of the world. Europe’s
consumption of natural gas is expected to increase significantly, largely due to the increased
use of natural gas for power production.
ECN-C--04-094
75
•
•
Less consensus exists on the prospects of oil, coal and nuclear energy. The expectations on
consumption of oil vary from stable to a slight decrease. The perspectives of solid fuels and
nuclear energy mainly depend on the development of the European fuel mix for power generation. Coal consumption is expected to stabilise or grow. Some models expect nuclear energy to be phased out in the baseline, although no explicit phasing out policies have been
included. This reflects that these models assume higher costs for nuclear power.
Europe’s 10 New Member States presently have a 45% share of coal in their primary fuel
mix, a great deal larger than in their Western European counterparts. This is balanced by a
much smaller share of nuclear and renewables. In the next decades the energy system of the
New Member States is expected to move towards the energy system of the EU-15. Consequently, the relative importance of coal will diminish, as new, additional generation capacity will be covered mainly by natural gas and renewables.
Europe uses a lot of energy but does so efficiently
•
•
6.4
Energy intensities can be used for comparing Europe’s energy consumption to that in the
rest of the world. European residents use 2,3 times as much energy as the world average,
and the energy consumption per capita shows an increasing trend, implying that the energy
needs of the average European citizen are still increasing steadily. American residents use
approximately twice as much energy as western Europeans, and no structural change is expected. On the other hand, in the New Member States, energy consumption per capita starts
at a lower level but shows the highest rate of increase.
Europe’s energy intensity, measured as the amount of primary energy required to generate
one unit of GDP, is among the lowest in the world. An exception is the situation in Europe’s
10 New Member States. The high level of the energy intensity in the base year indicates that
there is a lot of room for efficiency improvements. A steep decrease in intensity for this region shows that this potential for improvement is to a large extent exploited: while for 2000
the intensity for the New Member States region is roughly three times that of Western
Europe, in 2030 the fraction has diminished to approximately a factor two, and the level is
comparable to that of the world as a whole.
Challenge: Security of supply
Security of Supply will become a worldwide issue
•
•
Recognising the continuing global reliance on fossil fuels, an important issue in the years to
come will be the increasing dependence on oil from the Middle East. Although the models
show different projections of the evolvement of oil production, in all models the contribution from the Middle East region grows, and becomes substantially larger. This is confirmed
by the results of a stochastic model yielding a more than 85% probability that by 2030 the
Middle East produces more than half of the annual oil consumption. This indicates that the
world as a whole becomes more and more dependent on the resources of one specific region.
Given that this (at present) rather unstable region tends to remain dominating in the oil production, it comes as no surprise that there is a substantial probability of sudden increases in
the oil price of some 40-60%. Also, one of the models suggests that Security of Supply is
likely to be a more severe issue for oil than for gas - which would be in line with the status
of reserves.
Europe’s import dependency will increase significantly
•
76
For Europe, the observations made for the world have significant implications. Europe’s
dependence on oil from the Middle East is expected to increase up to 85%. If other world
regions also increasingly rely on oil from this region, this may indeed lead to further oil
price increases, which will particularly affect the transport sector.
ECN-C--04-094
•
•
6.5
For natural gas, external dependency will also grow in the next decades. A continuing
growth in gas consumption combined with a decrease of gas production in the UK, the
Netherlands and Norway, will lead to a higher share of imports from the two main suppliers
Russia and Algeria. Additionally, the accession of the new Member States and their heavy
reliance on supplies from Russia increases the risks related to gas supply security. On the
other hand, enlargement is expected to reduce the risks associated with transit of gas across
the New Member States towards EU-15 countries.
There is another dimension to security of supply than dependency on imported fuels. The
level of diversification, inversely related to the dependence on a few primary fuels, and the
correlation between these fuels in terms of costs and availability may further influence the
sensitivity of Europe to fuel supply disruptions. Preliminary analysis of these issues indicates that an increase in diversification – for instance a growing contribution from renewables – may alleviate the increase in external dependence for oil and gas. It should be noted
however that the models show large differences in their projections of Europe’s future fuel
mix, and thus in the expected level of diversification.
Challenge: Climate change
Global CO2 emissions to double until 2030
•
•
•
It is likely that global warming is attributable to human activities, in particular to emissions
of greenhouse gases, including emissions of CO2. All models project a continuing growth of
these emissions. Overall, the CO2 emissions in 2030 are expected to be approximately twice
the level of 1990, the base year of the Kyoto protocol. The largest growth of these emissions
is expected to occur in the developing world, in particular Asia.
There is a large variation in emissions projections between models, related to the differences in the primary energy mix, particularly the share of fossil fuels. This illustrates the
uncertainty of developments within the boundaries of the harmonised baseline scenario.
The carbon intensity of the world economy is projected to decrease with 30-50%. The main
contributors to this decrease are Asia, Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union, where
the growth in emissions is compensated with a higher GDP growth. The region encompassing Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union remains the most carbon intensive one.
Western Europe will have severe difficulties complying to the Kyoto protocol
•
•
•
Although CO2 emissions in Western Europe show moderate growth as compared to the
global trend, it is not on track towards the target agreed under the Kyoto Protocol. Western
Europe is committed to achieving an 8% reduction of CO2 emissions by 2008-2012, as
compared to the level in 1990. This means that in this period, the level of total CO2 emissions (including non-energy uses) in Western Europe should not exceed approximately
3100 Mton per year. However, all models indicate that the energy-related CO2 emissions
alone are already expected to exceed this level. Therefore additional instruments to those in
place by the end of 2003, such as emissions trading with regions outside Annex 1 Europe,
based on the JI and CDM instruments, will have to play a key role in meeting Kyoto commitments.
Beyond 2012, assuming that some type of climate policy is in place in Europe, reflected in a
moderate carbon tax of 10 euro/ton CO2, emissions are expected to continue their growth
with ca. 0.4% per year.
CH4 emissions reductions might become important in mitigating the enhanced greenhouse
effect. According to one of the models, the increase in emissions of CO2, N2O, is compensated by a decrease in CH4 emissions. As a consequence, the overall development of greenhouse gas emissions (in Mton CO2 equivalents), also shows a decrease. The decline in CH4
emissions is mainly due to reduced methane emissions from disposal sites, as a result of increased recovery of methane. Another possibility is to combust the methane, and possibly
utilise the produced heat. This reduces the methane emissions but produces CO2 emissions,
which have a less strong greenhouse effect.
ECN-C--04-094
77
6.6
Strategies and directions
The analysis presented in this report has identified some major challenges that the world is facing today. The findings are in line with the Commission WETO report23 and the IEA World Energy Outlook 2004 (IEA, 2004). In the next phases of the CASCADE MINTS Part 2 project,
several strategies will be explored that may help to counter these developments. These strategies
rely on technologies based on renewable energy, nuclear power, CO2 capture and storage, and
hydrogen. All of these have their own characteristics, costs, advantages and consequences, and
will be further assessed within the project.
23
See http://europa.eu.int/comm/research/energy/gp/gp_pu/article_1257_en.htm
78
ECN-C--04-094
REFERENCES
Das, A., P. Russ, U. Fahla and A Voss (2003): Assessing Climate Response Options: POLIcy
Simulations - Insights from using national and international models - ACROPOLIS.
Publishable report, Stuttgart, September 2003.
ECN (2003): Renewable electricity policies in Europe: Country fact sheets 2003.
http://www.renewable-energy-policy.info.
European Union (2000): Towards a European strategy for the security of energy supply. Green
Paper, COM(2000)769, Brussels, November 2000.
Grübler, A., N. Nakicenovic, J. Alcamo, G. Davis, J. Fenhann, B. Hare, S. Mori, B. Pepper, H.
Pitcher, K. Riahi, H.H. Rogner, E. L. La Rovere, A. Sankovski, M. Schlesinger, R.P.
Shukla, R. Swart, N. Victor and T.Y. Jung (2004): Emissions Scenarios: A Final
Response. Energy & Environment, Vol. 15, No. 1, 2004, p. 11-24.
IEA (2001): Nuclear Power in the OECD. IEA, Paris, France.
IEA (2002): Energy Policies of IEA Countries. The United Kingdom 2002, Review. IEA, Paris,
France.
IEA (2003): Energy Policies of IEA Countries; 2003. Review. IEA, Paris, France.
IEA (2004): World Energy Outlook 2004. IEA, Paris, France.
IPCC (2000): Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (2000). Special Report on Emission
Scenarios. http://www.grida.no/climate/ipcc/emission/index.htm.
IPCC TAR (2001): Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Climate Change 2001:
Mitigation. http://www.grida.no/climate/ipcc_tar/wg3/index.htm
Jansen, J.C., W.G. van Arkel and M.G. Boots (2004): Designing indicators of long-term energy
supply security. ECN-C--04-007, January 2004.
Lako, P., M. de Noord, H. Eder and H. Reisinger (2003): Hydropower development with a focus
on Asia and Western Europe: Overview in the framework of VLEEM 2. ECN-C--03027, July 2003.
Manne, A. and R. Richels (2003): Market Exchange Rates or Purchasing Power Parity: Does
the Choice Make a Difference to the Climate Debate?
http://www.stanford.edu/group/MERGE/marketEx.pdf
Official Journal of the European Communities (1999): Commission recommendation of 5
February 1999 on the reduction of CO2 emissions from passenger cars. 1999/125/EC.
Official Journal of the European Communities (2000): Commission recommendation of 13 April
2000 on the reduction of CO2 emissions from passenger cars (KAMA). 2000/303/EC.
Official Journal of the European Communities (2000): Commission recommendation of 13 April
2000 on the reduction of CO2 emissions from passenger cars (JAMA). 2000/304/EC.
Oostvoorn, F. van (ed.) et al. (2003): Long-term gas supply security in an enlarged Europe:
Final Report ENGAGED Project. ECN-C--03-122, December 2003.
Uyterlinde, M.A. et al. (2003): Renewable electricity market developments in the European
Union, Final Report of the ADMIRE REBUS project. ECN-C--03-082, November 2003.
www.ecn.nl/library/reports/2003/c03082.html.
VIEWLS (2004): http://www.viewls.org.
World Energy Power Plants database (2003): www.platts.com.
ECN-C--04-094
79
APPENDIX A
KEY CHARACTERISTICS OF THE ENERGY MODELS
Table A.1 Models by type
Model
System
Top down/ Endogenous
boundaries bottom up technology
learning
Objective
Type
Distinguishing features
The AIM model assesses policy
options for reducing greenhouse gas
emissions and avoiding impacts of
climate change, particularly in the
Asia-Pacific region. It can also be
used for analysis at the global level.
A recursive dynamic equilibrium
model of the world economy.
•
Global models, US, Canada
AIM
Asian Pacific
Integrated Model
Macro
economic
Top down
DNE 21+
Dynamic New Earth
21+
Energy
sector
Bottom up
ETP
Energy
Bottom up
Energy Technology
sector
Perspectives
GMM
Energy sector Bottom up
Global Markal Macro
MAPLE (Canada)
ECN-C--04-094
Energy sector Bottom up
No, exogenous The model seeks the trajectory of
optimal global energy systems to
mitigate global warming.
Global energy systems model, bottom- •
up type, dynamic optimisation.
•
(under
Supporting the development of WEO
development) 2004 alternative Policy Scenario
(which will be a global scenario).
Yes
To provide a broad platform for
analysis of technological progress
and related policy insights.
Dynamic Energy System
Optimisation.
Yes
Family of models.
77-Region world model.
Time horizon is 2000 to 2100.
DNE21+ has a simple relationship
between the energy price and the
demand using the long term price
elasticity.
A dynamic linear programming
‘bottom-up’ model. Technologyoriented model allowing a rich
representation of both supply and
demand technologies.
•
•
•
•
•
•
To undertake analysis of technology, Energy-economy equilibrium with
•
environmental issues and regulations imperfect foresight. Each market is
related to energy policies.
modelled according to the way
consumers make decisions, e.g.,
•
refinery and utility markets are energy
Global 15-regional MARKAL-model.
Time horizon: 2050.
Linked to IEA WEO scenarios.
Multi-regional model.
Partial equilibrium (MARKAL-ED)
using elastic demands.
Time horizon 2000-2050.
MAPLE is a technology-rich model
which solves annually for energy
economy equilibrium.
The baseline assumes current
regulations and policies extend into
80
Model
System
Top down/ Endogenous
boundaries bottom up technology
learning
Objective
Type
Distinguishing features
the future; continual progress is
assumed in the menu of technologies
available for future choices based on
historical trend. Actual progress is
determined endogenously through
consumer choices and endogenous
technology improvements.
cost minimizers while residential car
choices are based on multiple
attributes (logit functions). It is
derived from the US model NEMS.
MESSAGE
Energy sector Bottom up
Model for Energy
Supply Strategy
Alternatives and their
General
Environmental Impact
Yes (optional) Medium- to long-term energy system Dynamic systems-engineering
•
planning, energy policy analysis, and optimisation model. The model
provides a framework to represent an •
scenario development.
energy system with all its flows and
dependencies. It can be used to
compute a least cost solution based on
exogenous energy demand.
•
NEMS (US)
National Energy
Modeling System
ECN-C--04-094
Energy sector Bottom up
To develop Annual Energy Outlook
Yes (for
electric power and to do analysis of technology,
technologies environmental or regulatory energy
and all other policies.
relatively new
infant
technologies in
the building
sector)
Energy-economy equilibrium with
•
imperfect foresight. Each market is
modelled according to the way
consumers make decisions, e.g.,
•
refinery and utility markets are energy
cost minimizers while residential car
choices are based on multiple
attributes (logit functions).
Technology-rich model with a time
frame of 1990-2100.
All technologies in the energy system
are associated with a number of
characteristics such as energy inputs
and outputs, capital and operational
costs, facility lifetimes, emissions of
various types per unit activity,
maximum possible penetration rates
and start year.
Technological change is represented
in two ways: either exogenously in
the form of predefined learning rates
for different technologies over time
as well as endogenously, where costs
are reduced as a function of
increasing cumulative capacities.
NEMS is a technology-rich model
which solves annually for energy
economy equilibrium.
The baseline assumes current laws,
regulations and policies extend into
the future; continual progress is
assumed in the menu of technologies
available for future choices based on
historical trend.
Actual progress is determined
81
Model
System
Top down/ Endogenous
boundaries bottom up technology
learning
Objective
Type
Distinguishing features
endogenously through consumer
choices and endogenous technology
improvements.
NEWAGE-W
Macro
economic
POLES
Energy sector Bottom up
PROMETHEUS
Top down
Energy sector Bottom up
No
Analysis of the macroeconomic
Computable General Equilibrium
Model (CGE)
effects of climate change policies
(e.g. CO2 reduction) on a global level.
Yes (optional) World energy market model. The
model structure corresponds to a
hierarchical system of interconnected
modules and involves three levels of
analysis: international energy
markets, regional energy balances
and national models on energy
demand.
Yes
•
•
ECN-C--04-094
Provides strategic and analytical
information on risks and
probabilities regarding the
variables incorporated in the
model or any pre-determined
function involving them: energy
supply and demand, emissions,
international fuel prices, power
plant capacities, electricity
generation by plant, reserves for
oil and gas.
Provides stochastic input
(variances, co-variances) to
decision tools designed to
incorporate risks.
•
•
•
It is a recursive simulation model, in •
which energy markets responds with
different lag structures to international •
price variations. Behavioural
•
equations take into account the price
effects, techno-economic constraints •
and trends.
•
Stochastic
•
•
•
Intertemporal.
33 regions.
4 sectors.
38 world regions (being extended to
46).
15 energy demand sectors.
12 large-scale power generation
technologies.
12 new and renewable energy
technologies.
Endogenous oil, gas and coal prices.
A self-contained energy model
consisting of a set of stochastic
equations.
All exogenous variables, parameters
and error terms in the model are
stochastic with explicit representation
of their distribution including on
many cases terms of co-variance. It
follows that all endogenous variables
as a result are also stochastic.
It contains stochastic relations
describing technology improvement
dynamics (both learning by research
and experience).
82
Model
System
Top down/ Endogenous
boundaries bottom up technology
learning
Objective
Type
Distinguishing features
European models
MARKAL
Energy sector Bottom up
Yes
To perform prospective analysis of
long-term energy balances under
different scenarios.
Dynamic Energy System
Optimisation.
•
•
•
Price elastic demand.
Endogenous technology learning.
System cost minimisation.
NEMESIS
Macro
economic
No
Assess for sectoral and macroeconomic impacts of European
policies in the area of Energy,
Environment and R&D.
Neokeynesian macro econometric
model with detailed energy/environment module for EU-15 countries +
Norway.
•
•
30 production sectors.
Endogenous taxes and tradable
permits for 3 greenhouse gases.
Endogenous R&D decisions of firms.
Multi-sector, multi-region dynamic
computable general equilibrium
(CGE) model.
•
•
Bottom-up foundation of power
sector.
Rational expectations.
•
EU-25, Norway and Switzerland.
•
•
Detailed power generation sector.
Detailed electricity exchange
balances.
Consideration of CHP and electricity
saving options.
EU-15, Norway, Switzerland, Poland
and Czech Republic.
PACE
Macro
economic
Top down
Top down
Endogenous Assessment of economic and
TC (under
environmental impacts of climate
development) change policies (cost-efficiency
analysis).
PRIMES
Energy sector Bottom up
Forecasting, scenario construction and Partial equilibrium model of the EU
energy system; hybrid model
policy impact analysis.
combining engineering orientation
with economic market driven
representations.
TIMES-EE
Energy sector Bottom up
Technology assessment and
evaluation of climate mitigation
strategies in the European electricity
sector.
Energy System Optimisation, main
focus on the electricity market.
•
•
•
ECN-C--04-094
83
APPENDIX B
B.1
IMPLEMENTATION OF HARMONISED BASELINE
ASSUMPTIONS IN MODELS
PRIMES
Input
Source
Remarks on if and how the translation was made
GDP
IPCC SRES B2
The GDP projections for EU-25 Member States are based on
Economic and Financial Affairs DG forecasts of April 2002 for the
short term (2001-2003);24 and on macroeconomic forecasts from
WEFA,25 adjusted to reflect recent developments, for the horizon
to 2030. Furthermore, for the EU-15 additional inputs were taken
into account from Member States’ stability programmes and longterm projections, stakeholders’ consultation,26 and the results of
GEM-E3 model.27
Population
IPCC SRES B2
Population data from the B2 scenario family are based on the UN
median 1998 population projections.
Energy prices (oil POLES
and optionally coal)
The values for the oil and coal prices provided by POLES were
used.
Overall discount
rate
Not used in PRIMES.
Three rates are currently used within the model. The first, used
mostly for large utilities, is set at 8%; the second, used for large
industrial and commercial entities, is set at 12%; the third, used for
households in determining their spending on transportation and
household equipment, is set at 17.5%.
Proposal ECN
Policy assumptions
Subsidies and taxes (not harmonised,
please indicate if
included)
The Baseline scenario includes existing trends and the effects of
policies in place and/or in the process of being implemented by the
end of 2001; whereas tax rates reflect the situation of July 2002 in
the EU-15 Member States.
Coal
Proposal ECN
All new coal plants have all Sulfur dioxide, NOx scrubbers as
required by law.
Nuclear
Proposal ECN
Differences in current policies of all States as regards nuclear
capacity, taking into account policy decisions as regards nuclear
phase out in Belgium, Germany, and Sweden and plans concerning
nuclear plant refurbishment/closure, as already agreed or under
negotiation with the European Commission for the rest countries.28
24
25
26
27
28
European Commission Economic forecasts, Spring 2002 (EUROPEAN ECONOMY. No. 2. 2002. Office for Official Publications of the EC. ISBN92-894-3357-4; ISSN0379-0991). Also available at:
http://europa.eu.int/comm/economy_finance/publications/europeaneconomy_en.htm.
WEFA (now integrated into DRI-WEFA) is an economic consultancy company which, in the context of the Long
Run Energy Modelling framework contract, was subcontracted by NTUA to deliver a consistent macro-economic
and sectoral forecast over the horizon to 2020 for the EU-15 Member States and, at a more aggregate level, for
candidate countries and EU neighbouring countries (Norway and Switzerland). This projection was delivered in
March 2001 and has been used as a benchmark in the context of this study.
Workshop on ‘Business-as-usual in energy intensive sectors beyond 2010’, organised by Commission services
(DG-ENV and DG-TREN), March 2001.
The GEM-E3 model has been constructed under the co-ordination of NTUA within collaborative projects supported by DG-RESEARCH involving CES-KULeuven and ZEW.
Nuclear policy assumptions of Central and Eastern European countries were drawn from the information contained in the 2001 Regular Reports from the Commission on Progress towards Accession, 13 November 2001
(http://europa.eu.int/comm/enlargement/report2001/index.htm).
84
ECN-C--04-094
Renewable
electricity
Proposal ECN
Energy policies that aim at promoting renewable energy (wind,
small hydro, solar energy, biomass and waste) and co-generation
are assumed to continue, involving subsidies on capital costs and
preferential electricity selling prices. Rather than imposing the
indicative targets of the EC renewables electricity Directive29 for
each Member State, the Baseline includes the policy measures in
view of such targets in each individual country.
Sulphur policies
IPCC SRES B2
It is assumed that stringent regulation for acid rain pollutants
continues, especially for large combustion plants. Similarly, other
clean air policies are assumed to continue.
Climate policies
Proposal ECN on
Carbon value
For the purposes of the study it is assumed that a carbon tax of 10
Euro2000/tonne CO2 as from the year 2012 (constant value over
time) was implemented in all States.
The effects from the voluntary agreement that was reached
between the European Commission and the European automobile
industry (followed in 1999 by similar agreements with Korean and
Japanese car manufacturers).
Efficiency standards
for cars
Concerning the use of biofuels in transportation, it was assumed
that all countries would follow EU rules30 sooner or later. The
impact of blending gasoline and diesel with biofuels on final
consumer prices was assumed to be negligible, since higher fuel
production costs will probably be offset by tax reductions
scheduled to be implemented on these fuel blends.
Other
29
30
31
Efficiency
Technological progress, induced both by economic growth and by
improvement in all modernisation of installations in all sectors of the economy,
sectors.
thereby improving the efficiency of the energy system.
Energy intensity
improvement
The restructuring of the sectoral pattern of economic growth,
which gradually shifts away from traditional energy intensive
sectors and concentrates on high value added activities, thereby
improving energy intensity.
Market
liberalisation
The effects from restructuring of markets through the liberalisation
of electricity and gas in the EU-15, which proceeds in line with EC
directives; liberalisation is assumed to be fully implemented in the
period to 2010.31 Liberalisation of electricity and gas markets is
also assumed to take place in New Member States, Bulgaria,
Norway, Romania, Turkey and Switzerland to attain compliance
with EC directives in the medium term.
Restructuring of
power and steam
generation
The restructuring in power and steam generation, which is enabled
by mature gas-based power generation technologies that are
efficient, involve low capital costs and are flexible regarding plant
size, co-generation and independent power production.
European Commission Directive 2001/77/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council on the Promotion of
Electricity Produced from Renewable Energy Sources in the Internal Electricity Market. Brussels, 27 September
2001.
European Commission Communication COM (2001) 547 of the European Commission of 07/11/01 on an action
plan and two proposals for Directives to foster the use of alternative fuels for transport, starting with the regulatory
and fiscal promotion of biofuels. Also at http://europa.eu.int/comm/energy/library/comm2001-547-en.pdf.
This country-by-country modelling has focused on the dynamics of the energy system within a country, while considering trade in fuels between countries. An in-depth study of trade developments in electricity and gas would necessitate further work on the PRIMES model, which goes beyond the scope of this study.
ECN-C--04-094
85
Are the results in line with your ‘usual’ baseline?
• In our ‘usual’ baseline, it is assumed that no specific new policies and measures aimed at
meeting Kyoto targets in 2008-2012, and possible more severe ones in the future, are implemented over the next 25 years. Therefore, the implementation of the carbon tax leads the
energy system to a different solution.
Your judgement of robustness or an indication of sensitivities for specific assumptions:
• Different energy prices as well as different macroeconomic assumptions can have a strong
impact on the future evolution.
• Policy towards energy efficiency and the promotion of renewable energy sources could
change dramatically carbon emissions and improve security of supply.
• Large uncertainties in the power sector concerning nuclear policies.
Possible biases due to model mechanism or inputs:
• In PRIMES model, consumer behaviour does not change easily.
Policy messages:
• The EU-30 energy system will need to deal with a number of major challenges over the next
30 years, including issues related to security of supply, tightening environmental pressures,
competitive energy prices and significant investment decisions. Even with a carbon tax of 10
Euro2000/tonne CO2, CO2 emissions in EU-15 remain 4.9% above 1990 levels in 2010.
B.2
PROMETHEUS
Input
GDP
Source
IPCC SRES B2
Population
Energy prices (oil and
optionally coal)
Overall discount rate
IPCC SRES B2
POLES
Proposal ECN
Remarks on if and how the translation was made
IPCC SRES B2 scenario growth rates were used
(GDP is expressed in ppp).
UN middle scenario projections were used.
Prices are endogenous in PROMETHEUS. However the mean values
for oil and coal were calibrated to POLES.
Not applicable.
Policy assumptions
Subsidies and taxes
Coal
Nuclear
Renewable electricity
Sulphur policies
Climate policies
Efficiency standards for cars
Other
86
(not harmonised,
please indicate if
included)
Proposal ECN
Proposal ECN
Proposal ECN
IPCC SRES B2
Proposal ECN on
Carbon value
Continuation of present used in real terms.
No specific policy.
As in ECN proposal.
As in ECN proposal.
Not applicable.
For the period 2005-2010:
• EU: a carbon tax was assumed (Mean: 8.02 Euro/tonne CO2
standard deviation: 6.08 Euro/tonne CO2)
• Rest of OECD: a carbon tax was assumed (Mean: 1.6 Euro/tonne
CO2 standard deviation: 3.2 Euro/tonne CO2)
For the period 2011-2030:
• EU: (Mean: 10.3 Euro/tonne CO2 standard deviation: 5.0
Euro/tonne CO2)
• Rest of OECD: a carbon tax was assumed (Mean: 7.2 Euro/tonne
CO2 standard deviation:
5.2 Euro/tonne CO2)
• Rest of the World: a carbon tax was assumed
(Mean: 1.6 Euro/tonne CO2 standard deviation:
3.1 Euro/tonne CO2)
Not applicable.
ECN-C--04-094
240
Ratio
Ratio of
of
GDP
(OECD)
GDP per
per Capita
Capita (OECD)
to
to
GDP
GDP per
per Capita
Capita (RoW)
(RoW )
200
160
Mean
Mean
Median
Median
Maximum
Maximum
Minimum
Minimum
Std.
Dev.
Std. Dev.
Skewness
Skewness
Kurtosis
Kurtosis
Jarque-Bera
Probability
Jarque-Bera
Probability
120
80
40
0
3
4
5
6
160
4.523613
4.523613
4.490695
4.490695
6.500750
6.500750
2.582848
2.582848
0.535623
0.535623
0.161591
0.161591
3.250657
3.250657
6.865255
0.032302
6.865255
0.032302
Ratio of
ofMiddle
MiddleEEast
roduction
il PProduction
ast OOil
Ratio
to
to
World Oil
Oil Pro
Production
duction
World
140
120
Mean
Mean
Median
Median
Maximum
Maximum
Minimum
Minimum
Std. Dev.
Std.
Dev.
Skewness
Skewness
Kurtosis
Kurtosis
Jarque-Bera
Jarque-Bera
Probability
Probability
100
80
60
40
20
0
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.590278
0.590278
0.597440
0.597440
0.808676
0.808676
0.213393
0.213393
0.083965
0.083965
-0.484350
-0.484350
3.584455
3.584455
52.53201
52.53201
0.000000
0.000000
0.8
200
Maximum
increase
in
il P rice
Maximum
n OPrice
in creasin
e iOil
any
3-years
riod ($ 9 5 / bl)
ars p e[$95/bl]
in any
3-yeperiod
160
Mean
Mean
Median
Median
Maximum
Maximum
Minimum
Minimum
Std.
Dev.
Skewness
Std. Dev.
Kurtosis
Skewness
Kurtosis
Jarque-Bera
Probability
Jarque-Bera
Probability
120
80
40
15.90246
15.90246
15.01488
15.01488
43.26549
43.26549
3.321730
3.321730
5.904048
1.020350
5.904048
4.591114
1.020350
4.591114
274.8189
0.000000
274.8189
0.000000
0
10
ECN-C--04-094
20
30
40
87
140
Ratio of Gas Price to
Ratio
of Gas
Price to
Oil Price
in 2030
Oil Price in 2030
120
Mean
Median
Mean
Maximum
Median
Minimum
Maximu
Std. Dev.
Minimu
Skewness
Std.
Dev.
Kurtosis
Skewness
Jarque-Bera
Kurtosis
100
80
60
40
Probability
0.667806
0.641660
1.588703
0.307478
0.170278
1.065430
5.091589
365.8991
0.000000
JarqueProbabilit
20
0
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
1.6
Figure B.1 Distributions in 2030
The probability:
• That GDP per capita in the Developing world will be more than one third of OECD GDP
per capita in 2030 (currently it is less than one sixth) is slightly higher than 0.3%.
• That the Middle East produces more than half of total world oil production in 2030 is
slightly more than 85%.
• That in the next 25 years there will be a price hike (over a short period) of more than (95)$
15 per barrel is nearly 50%.
• That the international gas price is lower than the international oil price is around 95%.
• That energy related CO2 emissions worldwide more than double between 1990 and 2030 is
nearly 85%.
• That there is on average de-carbonisation of world GIC between the present and 2030 is
nearly 35%.
The correlations of the main world energy economy aggregates are predominantly positive suggesting a certain dominance of an axis: higher economic growth, higher consumption and higher
energy prices.
Are the results in line with your ‘usual’ baseline?
• Main deviations from our usual baseline comes from higher growth in developing countries
and lower in industrialised ones retained for CASCADE MINTS.
Your judgement of robustness or an indication of sensitivities for specific assumptions:
• PROMETHEUS results are based on a wide spectrum of possible outcomes by design.
Possible biases due to model mechanism or inputs:
• Could be due to the relative simplicity of model specification. The main source of bias could
be due to possible biases in the basic common assumptions retained in CASCADE MINTS.
88
ECN-C--04-094
B.3
MARKAL
Input
Source
Remarks on if and how the translation was made
GDP
IPCC SRES B2
Fully harmonized (exogenous input to the model).
Population
IPCC SRES B2
Fully harmonized (exogenous input to the model).
Energy prices (oil
POLES
and optionally coal)
Fully harmonized world oil, gas and coal prices.
Overall discount rate Proposal ECN
5%, consistent with ECN proposal.
Policy assumptions
Subsidies and taxes
(not harmonised,
please indicate if
included)
No taxes were included.
Coal
Proposal ECN
Dynamic limit on phase-out of coal (relaxed over time).
Nuclear
Proposal ECN
No limitations (capacity limits will be introduced in the new
calibrated baseline).
Renewable electricity Proposal ECN
Lower limit of 18% renewables in electricity for Europe
(constraints on electricity per fuel will be introduced during the
ongoing calibration).
Sulphur policies
None
No policies were included.
Climate policies
Proposal ECN on €10 per ton CO2 included for all sources of CO2.
Carbon value
Efficiency standards
for cars
B.4
Accounted implicitly due to assumptions on energy intensity
improvements in the mobility sector.
MESSAGE
Input
Source
Remarks on if and how the translation was made
GDP
IPCC SRES B2
Fully harmonized (exogenous input to the model).
Population
IPCC SRES B2
Fully harmonized (exogenous input to the model).
Energy prices (oil
POLES
and optionally coal)
Endogenous.
Overall discount rate Proposal ECN
5%, consistent with ECN proposal.
Policy assumptions
Subsidies and taxes (not harmonised,
please indicate if
included)
No taxes were included.
Coal
Proposal ECN
Dynamic limit on phase-out of coal (relaxed over time).
Nuclear
Proposal ECN
No limitations (capacity limits will be introduced in the new
calibrated baseline).
Renewable electricity Proposal ECN
Lower limit of 18% renewables in electricity for Europe
(constraints on electricity per fuel will be introduced during the
ongoing calibration).
Sulphur policies
IPCC SRES B2
Included as emissions constraints.
Climate policies
Proposal ECN on
Carbon value
We are operating with an aggregated OECD region, hence no
carbon tax for Europe could be implemented.
Efficiency standards
for cars
Other
ECN-C--04-094
Accounted implicitly due to assumptions on energy intensity
improvements in the mobility sector.
89
Are the results in line with your ‘usual’ baseline?
• This is our central, dynamics-as-usual baseline scenario, which corresponds to the long-term
median of the scenario literature for the most important driving forces and scenario results.
Your judgement of robustness or an indication of sensitivities for specific assumptions:
• Uncertainty with respect to the dynamics and pace of technological change, economic
growth, and demographic change can lead to considerably different outcomes (particularly
in the long term). For a quantification of the uncertainty range see alternative projections illustrated in IPCC-SRES, 2000.
• Climate policies would change the results significantly.
Possible biases due to model mechanism or inputs:
• Perfect foresight.
Policy messages:
• Global carbon emissions are going to increase considerably, if there is no international incentive (regulation) for mitigation.
• Most of the growth in emissions is expected to occur in the developing world.
• There is large inertia in the energy system. Hence, short-term action (technology transfer/creation of niche markets) is needed to foster the introduction of advanced and cleaner
technologies, in order to enable that these technologies play a significant role in the long
term.
For more details see Riahi and Roehrl, 2000.
B.5
Input
GDP
POLES
Source
IPCC SRES B2
Population
IPCC SRES B2
Energy prices (oil POLES
and optionally coal)
Overall discount rateProposal ECN
Policy assumptions
Subsidies and taxes (not harmonised,
please indicate if
included)
Coal
Proposal ECN
Nuclear
Proposal ECN
Proposal ECN
Renewable
electricity
Sulphur policies
IPCC SRES B2
Climate policies
Proposal ECN on
Carbon value
Efficiency standards
for cars
Other
90
Remarks on if and how the translation was made
The GDP is in pppEUR00, and it was not reconciliated with the
SRES B2, as that is given in market prices. Comparison was made to
the CMP2 baseline assumption pppGDP data, on the basis of the
growth rates. Average differences are in the range of 0.2-0.4%
amongst the given regions. (Considering that the CMP2 baseline
assumptions are in 1990USD, the comparison is not straightforward).
Same as UN reference case.
Not used in POLES, discount rates by technology.
Subsidies are assumed to diminish in long term, so all prices will at
least cover costs.
No limit on available resources.
Future restrictions are not included.
The existing subsidies in place are considered in prices and costs.
The target share of the EU (2001/77EC) is not included.
The 10 Euro CV is in place for the EU 27 regions.
Renewable energy: assumed domestic energy sources , Nuclear
energy: fuel assumed all imported, Household energy demand
values are included in the commercial sector, Biomass is in one
category (no distinction is made for energy crops and residues).
The regional exchange file cannot be filled - POLES has world pool
for oil, three markets for gas - so the origin cannot be set.
The NMS region cannot be created with the present POLES, instead
our CEUR region is given as the closest (see remark in the file).
ECN-C--04-094
Possible biases due to model mechanism or inputs:
• Generally POLES baselines are coal intensive baselines, resulting in relatively higher carbon
emissions.
B.6
GMM
Input
Source
Remarks on if and how the translation was made
GDP
IPCC SRES B2
Same as IPCC SRES B2
Population
IPCC SRES B2
Same as IPCC SRES B2
Energy prices (oil POLES
and optionally coal)
Overall discount
rate
Proposal ECN
Energy prices are endogenous to the model.
5%
Policy
assumptions
Subsidies and taxes (not harmonised,
please indicate if
included)
Not included
Coal
Proposal ECN
Not included
Nuclear
Proposal ECN
It is assumed, that in 2050 the minimum nuclear power generation
will remain at current global levels.
Renewable
electricity
Proposal ECN
Penetration of renewable technologies is bounded by their regional
technological potential.
Sulphur policies
IPCC SRES B2
Not explicitly modelled.
Climate policies
Proposal ECN on
Carbon value
Carbon tax of 10€/tCO2 applied in the OOECD region.
Efficiency standards
for cars
Not included
Other
Are the results in line with your ‘usual’ baseline?
• The underlying storyline for the reference development refers to the SRES-IIASA B2 ‘dynamics-as-usual’ case. The baseline end-use demands and renewable-energy potentials are
directly taken from B2 scenario. However, no attempt has been undertaken to calibrate the
baseline scenario to match the results of the SRES-B2 scenario. In this respect, the reference
development corresponds to a PSI scenario, since the allocation of resources is based on an
optimisation performed under conditions of perfect foresight with ‘learning-by-doing’ considerations (LBD). The baseline is updated to reflect IEA statistics for the base year (2000).
Cost specification of some technologies has been revised (e.g. nuclear- and hydro-power,
hydrogen production). Additionally, carbon tax for OOECD region has been included in the
Baseline. The results are comparable to our previous reference scenario.
Your judgement of robustness or an indication of sensitivities for specific assumptions:
• Since the ETL approach is applied in the power sector, the results regarding technology and
fuel mix for electricity generation is highly dependant on the assumptions, particularly on
progress ratios and growth rates for the different technologies.
• The reference development for the power sector is coal-intensive. Thus, implementation of
explicit sulphur policies might influence significantly results of baseline.
ECN-C--04-094
91
Possible biases due to model mechanism or inputs:
• There is a full global spillover of experience and knowledge transfer across regions assumed
in the model. The limitation of ‘learning’ spillovers for selected technologies might change
results of baseline.
• Conservation measures are not explicitly modelled.
Policy messages:
• The baseline scenario remains in the median range of assumptions concerning socioeconomic and technological developments for mankind and is able to serve as basis for
studying policies of interest for the CASCADE-MINTS project. The global primary energy
consumption experiences a significant increase and is largely dominated by fossil fuels.
Both coal and natural gas experience a substantial growth, with clean coal technology and
gas becoming the predominant source by the end of the horizon. Growth of oil remains
modest, but it continues to hold a significant contribution. Non-fossil resources slowly gain
market share. At the global level, electricity generation experiences a vigorous growth with
the bulk of this growth driven by developing regions. On the demand-side it is assumed that
the historical shift from non-commercial to commercial fuels and towards more clean and
flexible, grid-transported energy carriers at the final-energy level continue in the future.
• Cumulative learning processes constitute important mechanisms of technological change
and play a significant role in the diffusion of technologies.
B.7
PACE
Input
Source
Remarks on if and how the translation was made
GDP
IPCC SRES B2
Adjustments to convex growth profiles
Population
IPCC SRES B2
Yes
Energy prices (oil and POLES
optionally coal)
Yes
Overall discount rate Proposal ECN
Yes
Policy assumptions
Subsidies and taxes
(not harmonised, As of GTAP 5.4
please indicate if
included)
Coal
Proposal ECN
No explicit policy
Nuclear
Proposal ECN
No explicit policy
Renewable electricity Proposal ECN
No explicit policy
Sulphur policies
IPCC SRES B2
No explicit policy
Climate policies
Proposal ECN on Yes
Carbon value
Efficiency standards
for cars
No explicit policy
Other
The calibration of our intertemporal multi-sector, multi-region CGE model is based on the
GTAP5.4 benchmark year 1997. We take this year to be the year 2000 and do a dynamic calibration in 10-year periods. Due to the differences between 1997 values and 2000 values the absolute level values of the model baseline may substantially differ from the MESSAGE reference
baseline (based on the empirical values for 2000) although we employ the same growth rates.
92
ECN-C--04-094
B.8
NEWAGE-W
Input
Source
Remarks on if and how the translation was made
GDP
IPCC SRES B2
Transformation of MESSAGE GDP from 1990 till 2030 into
growth-rates for NEWAGE-W.
Remark1: NEWAGE-W is calculating in $1997. For converting
into €2000, it makes a difference, if you first inflate Dollar and than
exchange it to Euro or the other way round. E.g. GDP for WEU in
the year 2000 is 11730 GEUR2000 (Source: MESSAGE) but is
9180 GEUR2000 (Source: PRIMES). The difference could be a
result of that problem. After all I used the conversion factor from
the deflator.xls you sent us. This issue could cause some confusion.
Remark2: The assumptions for overall COAL Use/Production
seems to be a little pessimistic.
Remark3: Due to the COAL production projection, the world CO2
emissions in 2030 are much lower than e.g. in POLES. This effect
is intensified by smaller overall GDP growth-rates (compared to
POLES).
Remark4: Total CO2 emissions in 1990/2000 seem to be very high,
concerning the given Primary Energy consumption in MESSAGE.
Population
IPCC SRES B2
Population is not an input parameter for NEWAGE-W.
Energy prices (oil POLES
and optionally coal)
Included
Overall discount rate Proposal ECN
5%
Policy assumptions
Subsidies and taxes (not harmonised,
please indicate if
included)
-
Coal
Proposal ECN
-
Nuclear
Proposal ECN
-
Renewable
electricity
Proposal ECN
-
Sulphur policies
IPCC SRES B2
-
Climate policies
Proposal ECN on
Carbon value
-
Efficiency standards
for cars
-
Other
-
ECN-C--04-094
93
B.9
TIMES-EE
Input
Source
Remarks on if and how the translation was made
GDP
PRIMES / IEA
Fully harmonized (exogenous input to the model)
Population
PRIMES / IEA
Fully harmonized (exogenous input to the model)
Energy prices (oil Proposal ECN
and optionally coal)
Fully harmonized (exogenous input to the model)
Overall discount
rate
5%, consistent with ECN proposal
Proposal ECN
Policy assumptions
Subsidies and taxes (not harmonised,
please indicate if
included)
Country-specific taxes (level of 2000) are included.
Coal
National coal policies are reflected.
Nuclear
National nuclear policies are reflected.
Renewable
electricity
National policies on renewables are reflected considering lower
limit of different renewables in electricity per country.
Sulphur policies
Included in technology description.
Climate policies
Efficiency standards
for cars
Proposal ECN on
Carbon value
Carbon tax for Europe is implemented.
Only electricity sector is considered.
Other
Are the results in line with your ‘usual’ baseline?
• This is our central baseline scenario, which corresponds to other projections like IEA or
European Energy and Transport Trends to 2030.
Your judgement of robustness or an indication of sensitivities for specific assumptions:
• Uncertainty with respect to the dynamics and pace of technological change, economic
growth, and demographic change can lead to considerably different outcomes (particularly
in the long term).
• Climate policies or variations in energy policy assumptions would change the results significantly.
Possible biases due to model mechanism or inputs:
• Perfect foresight
• Competitive markets.
Policy messages:
• Carbon emissions of the electricity sector in Europe are going to increase considerably, if
there is no strong international or european incentive (regulation) for mitigation.
• Most of the growth in emissions is expected to occur in the electricity sector of Southern
Europe and of Germany and the Netherlands.
94
ECN-C--04-094
B.10 NEMESIS
Input
Source
GDP
IIASA B2 Scenario for
Western Europe
Population
For European area:
growth of 0.34% for
2000/1990, 0.16% for
2010/2000 and 0,04% for
2020/2010
Remarks on if and how the translation was made
POLES
Energy prices (oil
and optionally coal)
Overall discount rate 5%
Policy assumptions
Subsidies and taxes (not harmonised)
Climate policies
ECN’s proposal on
climate policy, by
assuming a carbon tax of
10Euro2000/tonne CO2
from 2012 onwards.
Efficiency standards Effects from volontary
for cars
agreements between
European Commission
and the automobile
industry
ACEA/JAMA/KAMA)
are incorporated.
Other
The guidelines for baseline harmonisation were introduced in the bottom-up module of NEMESIS (NEMESIS-EnergyEnvironmentModule, NEEM).
This Energy/environment module is rather detailed (see baseline results sheet A_base), but with
the following limitations:
1. It does not distinguish biomass energy corps and residues; instead we have a global category
biomass. Biomass consumption and production are model results.
2. NEMESIS EEM does not include a precise CHP representation and only approximations can
be provided. However the fuel for power generation includes the fuels consumed in CHP
plants.
3. Hydrogen economy is not yet modelled, thus no hydrogen production can be reported.
4. Shadow prices for gas, oil and coal cannot be reported by NEMESIS EEM (There are no
constraints in the model for oil, gas and coal production).
5. Also total system cost cannot be provided. Only investment cost in the power generation
sector.
6. Finally regional exchanges are not modelled.
NEMESIS EEM takes as major inputs GDP, sectoral productions, households’ final consumption, long term interest rates projections, from the top-down economic model (sheet B_TD). The
economic model baseline is currently being actualised, and the baseline results displayed on
sheets A_base and B_TD will be modified during the project; they are thus at this stage only indicative on the kind of outputs NEMESIS could provide.
ECN-C--04-094
95
The current economic baseline was built in 2002/2003 using the following assumptions:
• External trade: The world economy was expected to recover after 2003, with sustained
growth of China supposed to increase its imports following its entry in WTO.. Asian new
developing countries and India were supposed to benefit as well of rising sources of economic growth. In the OPEC, structural reform was expected to give increasing support to
growth making these countries more attractive to foreign investors. For NAFTA, Mexico
was supposed to continue stimulate the economic activity in this area and besides, United
States and Canada were expected to reinforce strongly there growth. For Japan, banking and
structural problems were supposed to continue to limit growth potentials during the decade.
Sustained growth perspective were expected as well for accessing countries and rest eastern
European countries.
• World prices: they were supposed to grow about 2% per annum, with constant exchange
rates after 2002.
• Demographic assumptions: In European area, in coherency with World Bank projections,
population was forecasted to stay relatively stable, implying a potential drop of working
population
• Technical progress: Rates are differentiated by country and production sectors, and driven
by R&D expenditures of firms, which were supposed to increase slightly their research effort in reaction to international competition and the limitation of labour supply.
• Interest rates: Nominal rates are still exogenous in the model, and supposed to stay constant
at 5%.
• Government Consumption and production of non market services: European states were
supposed to continue to reduce their government consumption, and to limit the progression
of social expenditures, which were supposed to progress less quickly than GDP after 2010.
The baseline scenario exhibits a strong growth until 2010, pulled-up by extra-European exports
(not reported in sheet B_td) as result of global world economic recovery. In relation with demographic assumptions and economic growth, expected decrease of unemployment leads to a sustained growth of real wages and final consumption, despite the relatively slow rise of total employment. For energy, final intensity was supposed to decrease in response to R&D activities
despite a negative (price) substitution effect; for intermediate energy consumption, no gains
were expected. Finally, intra-European trade was supposed to continue to reinforce.
For the rest of the period (after 2010), extra European trade was supposed to reduce progressively its growth rate, while World economies are supposed to evolve from strong growth to potential growth rates, and the gap between growth rates of world regions to reduce equally progressively.
At a sectoral level, equipment goods industries were supposed to accompany growth expansion
while transportation and market services continue to increase their contribution to overall economic activity, and continued declining contributions of agriculture and intermediate industries,
at the exception of chemistry (which includes also pharmacy).
96
ECN-C--04-094
B.11 DNE21+
Input
Source
Remarks on if and how the translation was made
GDP
IPCC SRES B2
Growth rate of GDP/capita from SRES B2 is used to obtain
GDP/capita data for the four regions, and then the GDP/capita is
multiplied with the national population to obtain GDP for each
nation.
Population
IPCC SRES B2
Population data by nation of TGCIA(Task Group on Scenarios for
Climate Assessment ) are used.
Energy prices (oil
and optionally coal)
Production cost curves are assumed for fossil fuels according to
Rogner, 1997. Their prices are determined endogenously.
Overall discount
rate
5%/year
Policy assumptions
Subsidies and taxes
Not included
Coal
Not included
Nuclear
Not included
Renewable
electricity
Proposal ECN
Sulphur policies
Climate policies
Lower bounds of renewable electricity generation for the EU are
adopted according to ADMIRE-REBUS until 2010 and not
thereafter.
Not included
Proposal ECN on
Carbon value
10 Euro/tonne CO2 is adopted for the EU after 2010.
Efficiency standards
for cars
Not applicable
Other
Change rate in hydro power generation is limited within ± 5%/y
for every region.
Which results are in your opinion worth highlighting?
• The DNE21+ is a 77 region global model of optimization type, a developed version of the
DNE21 model. The DNE21+ distinguishes 54 countries and energy-environment policies of
these countries are evaluated consistently and on the same basis; interregional energy trade
is allowed including coal, crude oil, natural gas, methanol, hydrogen and electricity.
Are the results in line with your ‘usual’ baseline?
• The results are new but very similar at world level to those of the DNE21 which is reliable
in our view.
Your judgement of robustness or an indication of sensitivities for specific assumptions.
• FC vehicles are treated in a tricky way to see how and when the hydrogen substitutes for
gasoline. The assumption of their cost reduction affects the results pretty much.
Possible biases due to model mechanism or inputs.
• The model seeks for the future normative in the perfect foresight.
Policy messages
• Nuclear should phase out in no climate policy. Nuclear decreases and then disappears in our
baseline results.
ECN-C--04-094
97
B.12 NEMS
Input
Source
Remarks on if and how the translation was made
GDP
IPCC SRES B2
GDP is based on the US DOE/EIA baseline input assumptions as
provided by the Global Insight ‘mid’ case; definition is based on
US government published statistics. The resulting GDP results
from the ‘mid-growth’GDP case of Global Insight and used in the
US DOE revised reference case of April 24, 2004. Since the
resulting GDP is adjusted slightly by the feedback with the US
energy market, GDP is partly a derived result. That white paper
suggested that the two measures of GDP (one used by the EU and
the one used by the US government) are different and
reconciliation may not be reasonably possible.
Population
IPCC SRES B2
Same as UN reference case.
Energy prices (oil
POLES
and optionally coal)
Energy prices in NEMS are internal to the model with partial
exception of world oil prices.
Overall discount rate Proposal ECN
Not used in NEMS – discount rates set by technology, end-use
customer class.
Policy assumptions
Subsidies and taxes (not harmonised,
please indicate if
included)
All existing US federal and state taxes and incentive policies have
been implemented for the US.
Coal
Proposal ECN
NA - all new coal plants have all Sulfur dioxide, NOx scrubbers as
required by law.
Nuclear
Proposal ECN
NA – allowed to compete but does not penetrate market.
Renewable electricity Proposal ECN
Used all existing State and Federal incentives.
Sulphur policies
IPCC SRES B2
Existing Clean Air Act Regulations as enacted.
Climate policies
Proposal ECN on
Carbon value
NA
Efficiency standards
for cars
Other
Use existing CAFÉ standards for new cars and light trucks.
Electricity pricing Deregulated/regulated Electricity markets as currently represented
and regulation
by individual state policies/laws.
Are the results in line with your ‘usual’ baseline?
• This is our usual but updated baseline, since we agreed that anything endogenous would be
left alone.
Your judgement of robustness or an indication of sensitivities for specific assumptions
• Assumed natural gas resource base in the US is an important uncertainty as is the ability of
OPEC to stay cohesive. Also, since WOP are determined more by political factors than production cost, actual WOP’s are uncertain, based on availability of alternative (unconventional supplies from non-OPEC) and alternative technologies, (Coal to liquids and gas to
liquids).
• Carbon policy could dramatically change results of baseline.
• New efficiency standards or CAFÉ standards could dramatically change carbon emissions.
Possible biases due to model mechanism or inputs
• Model assumes consumer behaviour does not change easily (i.e., effective hurdle rates and
basis for decisions remain unchanged in the forecast period)
Policy messages
• Voluntary programs don’t do very well in most of US markets.
98
ECN-C--04-094