NREE Chapter - 4
NREE Chapter - 4
NREE Chapter - 4
Natural Resources
Introduction
Classification of natural resources
• Given a finite stock of non- renewable resources, at what rate should that
resource be depleted?
Figure, 4.1. the non-renewable resource demand function for the two-
period model
• However, the gross benefit obtained by consumers is not identical to the net
social benefit of the resource because resource extraction involves costs.
• Accordingly, let’s assume that the marginal cost of extraction is c and total
extraction costs, Ct, for the extracted quantity Rt units will be Ct = cRt
• Therefore, the total net social benefit is;
NSB = Bt- Ct
• where NSB denotes the total net social benefit and B is the
gross social benefit of resource extraction and use. Hence
• NSBt=
= aRt – b/2 Rt2 –CRt
• A socially optimal extraction policy requires that; the extraction
program maximizes social welfare.
• let, two things should be existed to determine this program.
– There should be social welfare function, and
– there should be statement of technical possibilities and constraints
available at any point in time.
• The general two period social welfare functions is given by;
U1
• W=W(U0, U1) takes the particular form; W U
1
0
• where ρ is the social utility discount rate, reflecting society’s time preference.
• Thus, the utility in each period as being equal to the net social benefit in each
period.
NSB1
W NSB0
1
• Only one relevant technical constraint exists in this case: there is a fixed initial
stock of the non-renewable resource, S.
• We assume that society wishes to have none of this resource stock left at the
end of the second period.
• Then the quantities extracted in the two periods, R0 and R1, must satisfy
the constraint: R0+R1=S
• Subject to R0+R1=S
• There are several ways of obtaining solutions to constrained optimization
problems of this form.
• We can use the Lagrange multiplier method. First step is to form the
Lagrangian function, L
L W ( S R0 R1 )
NSB1
NSB0 S R0 R1
1
b 2
b 2 aR1 R 1 cR1
aR0 R 0 cR0 2 ( S R0 R1 )
2 1
• Where, λ is a ‘Lagrange multiplier’. Remembering that R0 and R1 are choice
variables (variables whose value must be selected to maximize social
welfare)
• The necessary conditions includes: L a bR0 c 0
R0
L a bR c
0
R1 1
• Since the right-hand side terms of the above equations both equal to zero,
implies that, a bR1 c
a bR0 c
1
• Using the demand function Pt =a−bRt, the above equation can be written as,
P1 c
P0 c
1
• where P0 and P1 arePgross ) Pand
0 c (1 prices 1 c P0 −c and
P1 −c are net prices. A
resource’s net price is also known as the resource rent or resource royalty.
Rearranging this expression, we obtain
( P1 c) ( P0 c)
P0 c
• If we change the notation used for time periods so that P0 =Pt−1,
P1 =Pt and c=ct=ct−1, we then obtain Hotelling rule.
Pt Ct ( Pt 1 Ct 1
Pt 1 Ct 1
MUt
MU1 = P1
C1 Ct
• A market economy will probably not deliver an efficient and optimal
allocation of non-renewable resources because:
• The existence of Monopoly which makes depletion too slow.
• Social costs of resource depletion not considered. (e.g. pollution
externalities).
• Private (market) interest rate above the social discount rate.
• There may be other forms of market failure:
– Presence of public goods
– Absence of well-defined and enforceable property rights
– Incomplete information
– And some of the agents’ functions may depend upon
environmental quality:
– Utility depends on environmental quality
– Quantity depends on environmental quality
Renewable resources
• Environmental resources are described as renewable when they have a
capacity for reproduction and growth.
• These share with biological stock resources the property that current
harnessing of the flow does not mean that the total magnitude of the
future flow will necessarily be smaller.
• It is important to distinguish between stocks and flows of the renewable
resource.
• The stock is a measure of the quantity of the resource existing at a point in time,
measured either as the aggregate mass of the biological material (the biomass) in
question (such as the total weight of fish of particular age classes or the cubic
metres of standing timber), or in terms of population numbers.
• This is the proportional rate at which the fish stock would grow when
its size is small relative to the carrying capacity of the fishery, and so
the fish face no significant environmental constraints on their
reproduction and survival.
• But as we want to use the notation dS/dt net effect of natural changes and
human predation, we shall use the alternative symbol G to refer to amount of
biological growth.
• (More completely, we shall use the notation G(S) to make it clear that G
S
g 1 this change
G ( SS)) With
depends on S the logistic biological growth function is given
by: Smax
Steady-state harvests of fish
• Consider a period of time in which the amount of the stock
being harvested (H) is equal to the amount of net natural
growth of the resource (G).
resource stock,
S
with = G−H, it follows that in steady-state
harvesting =0 and so the resource stock remains constant
over time.
• There is one particular stock size (SMSY) at which the quantity of
net natural growth is at a maximum (GMSY)
• If at a stock of SMSY harvest is set at the constant rate HMSY, we
obtain a maximum sustainable yield(MSY) steady state.
• Indeed, Figure below shows that any harvest level between zero
and HMSY is a feasible steady-state harvest, and that any stock
between zero and SMAX can support steady-state harvesting.
Figure below shows Steady state harvest
Which of these two stock sizes would be more appropriate for attaining a
harvest level of H1.
An open-access fishery Model
• The open-access fishery model shares two of the characteristics of the
standard perfect competition model.
• Second, there are no barrier to entry into and exit from the fishery.
• But the free entry assumption has an additional implication in the open-
access fishery, one which is not present in the standard perfect competition
model.
• Economic sub-model
• Many factors determine the size of the harvest, H, in any given period.
• These include the number of boats deployed and their efficiency, the
number of days when fishing is undertaken and so on.
• For simplicity, assume that all the different dimensions of harvesting activity
can be aggregated into one magnitude called effort, E
• Hence, other determinants of harvest size, including random influences, we
may take harvest to depend upon the effort applied and the stock size. That
is: H=H(E, S)
• This relationship can take a variety of particular forms. H=eES
• where e is a constant number, often called the catch coefficient.
H
• Dividing each side by E, we have eS
E
• which says that the quantity harvested per unit effort is equal to some
multiple (e) of the stock size.
• Assuming that fish are sold in a competitive market, each firm takes the
market price P as given and so the revenue obtained from a harvest H is
given by B=PH.
• Therefore, fishing profit is given by; NB =B−C
• A crucial role is played here by the level of economic profit prevailing in the
fishery.
• Economic profit is the difference between the total revenue from the sale
of harvested resources and the total cost incurred in resource harvesting.
• Given that there is no method of excluding new firm into the
industry, nor is there any way in which existing firms can be
prevented from changing their level of harvesting effort,
• and effort applied will continue to increase as long as it is
possible to earn positive economic profit.
• We close our model with two equilibrium conditions that must be satisfied jointly.
• Biological equilibrium occurs where the resource stock is constant through time
(that is, it is in a steady state).
• This requires that the amount being harvested equals the amount of net natural
growth: G=H
• Such an equilibrium is only possible in open-access fisheries when rents have been
driven to zero, so that there is no longer an incentive for entry into or exit from
the industry, nor for the fishing effort on the part of existing fishermen to change.
• We express this by the equation; NB =B−C=0
• The above Equations constitutes two unknowns (H and E); these can
be solved for the equilibrium values of the two unknowns as
functions of the parameters alone.
•Three rays emanating from the origin portray the harvest– stock relationships (from the
function H=eES) for three different levels of effort.
•If effort were at the constant level E1, then the unique intersection of the harvest–stock
relationship and biological growth function determines a steady-state harvest level H1 at
stock S1.
•The lower effort level E2 determines a second steady-state equilibrium (the pair {H2,
S2}).
• The particular point on this yield–effort curve that corresponds to an open-
access equilibrium will be the one that generates zero economic profit.
• For given values of P and w, this plots as a ray from the origin with slope w/P
in Figure ‘’b’’.
• The inverted U-shape curve here shows the steady state harvests that
correspond to each possible effort level, describes the fishery’s yield–effort
relationship.
For given values of P & w, this plots as a ray from the origin with slope w/P in figure ‘b’. The
intersection of this ray with the yield–effort curve locates the unique open-access
equilibrium outcome.
Alternatively, multiplying both functions in Figure ‘’b’’ by the market price of fish, P, we find
that the intersection point corresponds to PH=wE.
This is, of course, the zero profit condition, and confirms that {EOA, HOA} is the open-access
effort–yield equilibrium.
Open access and species extinction
• The extinction of renewable resource stocks is a possibility in conditions of
open access, but open access does not necessarily result in extinction of
species.
• There are many reasons why human behaviour may cause species
extinction. These include:
• Trees typically exhibit very long lags between the date at which they are
planted and the date at which they attain biological maturity. The length of
time between planting and harvesting is usually at least 25 years, and can be
as large as 100 years. This is considerably longer than for most species of
fish.
• Unlike fisheries, tree harvesting does not involve a regular cut of
the incremental growth. Forests, or parts of forests, are usually
felled in their entirety.
• Once felled, the forest will not be replanted. So only one cycle or
rotation plant, grow, cut is considered.
• Looking from the point of view of the forest owner (landowner), what is the
optimum time at which to fell the trees?
• The answer is obtained by choosing the age at which the present
value of profits from the stand of timber is maximized.
• Profits from felling the stand at a particular age of trees are given by
the value of felled timber less the planting and harvesting costs.
• Notice that because we are assuming the land has no other uses, the
opportunity cost of the land is zero and so does not enter this
calculation.
• If the forest is clear-cut at age T, then the present value of profit is;
P C ST eiT K pST eiT K
• Where; ST= is the volume of timber available for harvest at time T
p= is is the net price of the harvested timber
i= is the private consumption discount rate (which is equal to
the opportunity cost of capital to the forestry firm).
• The present value of profits is maximized at that value of T
which gives the highest value for pST e iT K
iT S e iT
pe pST
T T
S
pe iT ipST e iT 0
T
S
pe iT ipST e iT
T
S
p ipST
T
S
i / ST
T
• The above equation states that the present value of profits is
maximized when the rate of growth of the (undiscounted) net
value of the resource stock is equal to the private discount rate.
• Note that when i =0, present values are identical to
undiscounted values.