CH 17
CH 17
CH 17
CAPITAL MARKETS
Capital
The capital stock of an economy is the
sum total of machines, buildings, and
other reproducible resources in existence
at a point in time
these assets represent some part of the
economys past output that was not
consumed, but was instead set aside for
future production
2
Rate of Return
At period t1, a decision is made to hold s from
current consumption for one period
Consumption
x
c0
Consumption returns to
its long-run level (c0) in
period t3
t1
t2
t3
Time
Rate of Return
The single period rate of return (r1) on
an investment is the extra consumption
provided in period 2 as a fraction of the
consumption forgone in period 1
x s x
r1
1
s
s
Rate of Return
At period t1, a decision is made to hold s from
current consumption for one period
Consumption
c0
t1
t2
t3
Time
Rate of Return
The perpetual rate of return (r) is the
permanent increment to future
consumption expressed as a fraction of
the initial consumption foregone
y
r
s
Rate of Return
When economists speak of the rate of
return to capital accumulation, they have
in mind something between these two
extremes
a measure of the terms at which
consumption today may be turned into
consumption tomorrow
Rewriting, we get
c0
1
c1 1 r
c1 1 r
Utility Maximization
c0
w = c0 + p1c1
w/p1
c1 *
U1
U0
c0*
c1
11
Utility Maximization
The individual consumes c0* in the
present period and chooses to save w
- c0* to consume next period
This future consumption can be found
from the budget constraint
p1c1* = w - c0*
c1* = (w - c0*)/p1
c1* = (w - c0*)(1 + r)
12
Intertemporal Impatience
Individuals utility-maximizing choices
over time will depend on how they feel
about waiting for future consumption
Assume that an individuals utility
function for consumption [U(c)] is the
same for both periods but period 1s
utility is discounted by a rate of time
preference of 1/(1+) (where >0)
13
Intertemporal Impatience
This means that
1
U (c0 , c1 ) U (c0 )
U (c1 )
1
c1
L U (c0 , c1 ) w c0
14
Intertemporal Impatience
The first-order conditions for a maximum are
L
U ' (c 0 ) 0
c0
L
1
U ' (c1 )
0
c1 1
1 r
L
c1
w c0
0
1 r
15
Intertemporal Impatience
Dividing the first and second conditions
and rearranging, we find
1 r
U ' (c 0 )
U ' (c1 )
1
Therefore,
if r = , c0 = c1
if r < , c0 > c1
if r > , c0 < c1
16
Effects of Changes in r
If r rises (and p1 falls), both income and
substitution effects will cause more c1 to
be demanded
unless c1 is inferior (unlikely)
Effects of Changes in r
The sign of c0/p1 is ambiguous
the substitution and income effects work in
opposite directions
19
Equilibrium Price of
Future Goods
Equilibrium occurs at p1*
and c1*
p1
S
p1*
D
c1*
c1
20
Equilibrium Price of
Future Goods
We expect that p1 < 1
individuals require some reward for waiting
capital accumulation is productive
sacrificing one good today will yield more than
one good in the future
21
1 R (1 r )(1 pe )
23
1 R 1 r pe r pe
R r pe
24
25
Determinants of Market
Rental Rates
Consider a firm that rents machines to
other firms
The owner faces two types of costs:
depreciation on the machine
assumed to be a constant % (d) of the machines
market price (p)
26
Determinants of Market
Rental Rates
The total costs to the machine owner for
one period are given by
pd + pr = p(r + d)
Nondepreciating Machines
If a machine does not depreciate, d = 0
and
v/p = r
Ownership of Machines
Firms commonly own the machines they
use
A firm uses capital services to produce
output
these services are a flow magnitude
Ownership of Machines
A profit-maximizing firm facing a
perfectly competitive rental market for
capital will hire additional capital up to
the point at which the MRPk is equal to
v
under perfect competition, v will reflect
both depreciation costs and the opportunity
costs of alternative investments
MRPk = v = p(r+d)
30
Theory of Investment
If a firm decides it needs more capital
services that it currently has, it has two
options:
hire more machines in the rental market
purchase new machinery
called investment
31
...
2
1 r (1 r )
(1 r )n
...
2
1 r (1 r )
(1 r )n
34
Simple Case
Suppose that machines are infinitely
long-lived and the MRP (Ri) is the same
in every year
Ri = v in a competitive market
Therefore, the PDV from machine
ownership is
v
v
v
PDV
...
...
2
n
1 r (1 r )
(1 r )
35
Simple Case
This reduces to
1
1
1
PDV v
...
...
2
n
(1 r )
1 r (1 r )
1 r
PDV v
1
r
1
PDV v
r
36
Simple Case
In equilibrium P = PDV so
1
P v
r
or
v
r
P
37
General Case
We can generate similar results for the
more general case in which the rental
rate on machines is not constant over
time and in which there is some
depreciation
Suppose that the rental rate for a new
machine at any time s is given by v(s)
The machine depreciates at a rate of d
38
General Case
The net rental rate of the machine will
decline over time
In year s the net rental rate of an old
machine bought in a previous year (t)
would be
v(s)e -d(s-t)
39
General Case
If the firm is considering the purchase of
the machine when it is new in year t, it
should discount all of these net rental
amounts back to that date
The present value of the net rental in
year s discounted back to year t is
e -r(s-t)v(s)e -d(s-t) = e(r+d)tv(s)e -(r+d)s
40
General Case
The present discounted value of a
machine bought in year t is therefore the
sum (integral) of these present values
PDV (t ) e ( r d )t v (s )e ( r d )s ds
t
p(t ) e ( r d )t v (s )e ( r d )s ds
t
41
General Case
Rewriting, we get
p(t ) e ( r d )t v (s )e ( r d )s ds
t
dp(t )
(r d )e ( r d )t v (s )e ( r d )s ds e ( r d )t v (t )e ( r d )t
dt
t
dp(t )
(r d )p(t ) v (t )
dt
42
General Case
This means that
dp(t )
v (t ) (r d )p(t )
dt
43
Therefore,
f ' (t )
r
f (t )
f ' ( t ) 0 .2
f (t )
t
If r = 0.04, then t* = 25
If r rises to 0.05, then t* falls to 16
47
Optimal Resource
Allocation Over Time
Two variables are of primary interest for
the problem of allocating resources
over time
the stock being allocated (k)
the capital stock
Optimal Resource
Allocation Over Time
Choices of k and c will yield benefits
over time to the economic agents
involved
these will be denoted U(k,c,t)
U (k, c, t )dt
0
Optimal Resource
Allocation Over Time
There are two types of constraints in this
problem
the rules by which k changes over time
dk
k f ( k , c, t )
dt
initial and terminal values for k
k(0) = k0
k(T) = kT
50
Optimal Resource
Allocation Over Time
To find a solution, we will convert this
dynamic problem into a single-period
problem and then show how the solution
for any arbitrary point in time solves the
dynamic problem as well
we will introduce a Lagrangian multiplier (t)
the marginal change in future benefits brought
about by a one-unit change in k
the marginal value of k at the current time t
51
A Mathematical Development
The total value of the stock of k at any
time t is given by (t)k
The rate of change in this variable is
d(t )k
dk
d
K
k k
dt
dt
dt
H U (k , c, t ) k k
52
A Mathematical Development
The first-order condition for choosing c
to maximize H is
H U (k, c, t )
k
0
c
c
c
Rewriting, we get
U
k
0
c
c
53
A Mathematical Development
For c to be optimally chosen:
the marginal increase in U from increasing
c is exactly balanced by any effect such an
increase has on decreasing the change in
the stock of k
54
A Mathematical Development
Now we want to see how the marginal
valuation of k changes over time
need to ask what level of k would maximize
H
H U (k , c, t )
k
0
k
k
k
55
A Mathematical Development
Rewriting, we get
U
k
k
k
A Mathematical Development
Bringing together the two optimal
conditions, we have
H U
k
0
c
c
c
H U
k
0
k
k
k
Exhaustible Resources
Suppose the inverse demand function
for a resource is
p = p(c)
U (c ) p( x )dx
0
58
Exhaustible Resources
If the rate of time preference is r, the
optimal pattern of resource usage will
be the one that maximizes
T
rt
e
U (c )dt
0
59
Exhaustible Resources
The constraints in this problem are of
two types:
the stock is reduced each period by the
level of consumption
k c
end point constraints
k(0) = k0
k(T) = kT
60
Exhaustible Resources
Setting up the Hamiltonian
H e rt (U ) k k e rt (U ) c k
61
Exhaustible Resources
Since U/c = p(c),
e-rtp(c) =
62
63
65
66
67