Encyclopedia of Nobel Laureates in Economic Sciences
Encyclopedia of Nobel Laureates in Economic Sciences
Encyclopedia of Nobel Laureates in Economic Sciences
Of
Nobel Laureates
ECONOMIC SCIENCES
ENCYCLOPEDIA
OF
NOBEL LAUREATES
IN ECONOMIC SCIENCES
Published by :
Panther
Publishers
ENCYCLOPEDIA
OF
NOBEL LAUREATES
IN ECONOMIC SCIENCES
P.T. RAJASEKHARAN
SOPHIE VARMA
Printed by:
Colours Imprint
47,6th Cross. Wilson Garden, Bangalore 560 027
ISBN 81-87350-21-0
INTRODUCTION
Nobel Foundation
The main objective of the foundation, since the beginning, has
been to administer the Nobel inheritance and to ensure that the
prize winners, according to the wishes of its patron, should receive
substantial prizes. One of the major reasons for the continual
high regard for the prize is the Foundations’ strong economic
base and hence the absolute independence and freedom from
external influence and interest.
The initial capital of 31.3 million kronor, have, over the years
grown substantially. Its market value, for example, as on 1985
was 711 million kronor. The Foundation’s income for 1985
amounted to 36 million kronor, including 21.5 million in interest,
6 million on share dividends and nearly 8 million for estate assets.
With a total expense of 5.6 million a year, the profit of the
Foundation was 30.5 million that year compared to the 28.5
million, the previous year. The appreciation, in fact, would have
been double the amount, had the Foundation not been so highly
taxed during the first five decades. Since 1946, however, it is
exempt from state income tax, although there are other local
levies and government taxes it has to bear. The Foundation also
has been relieved of its old restrictions of investing only in
government bonds since 1953. By judiciously using this
opportunity, to invest freely, the initial capital of the trust has
substantially recovered and the value of the prize has appreciated
since then.
Prize Amounts Through Years
Year in Swedish Year in Swedish
Kronor Kronor
1901 150,800 1978 725,000
1910 140,700 1979 800,000
1920 134,100 1980 880,000
1923 (lowest amount) 115,000 1981 1,000,000
1930 172,900 1982 1,150,000
1940 138,600 1983 1,500,000
1946 121,000 1984 1,650,000
1950 164,300 1985 1,800,000
1953 175,300 1987 2,340,000
1960 226,000 1989 3,000,000
1969 (including Prize in 375,000 1990 4,000,000
Economic Sciences)
1970 400,000 1991 6,000,000
1971 450,000 1992 6,500,000
1972 480,000 1993 6,700,000
1973 510,000 1994 7,000,000
1974 550,000 1995 7,200,000
1975 630,000 1996 7,400,000
1976 681,000 1997 7,500,000
1977 700,000 1998 7,600,000
The prize money is taxed in accordance with the laws of the
country of the recipient.
The Prize
The Nobel prize consists of a medal, a diploma and a cash award.
The Nobel medals, first minted in 1902 (1901 winners received
their medals late), are of 23 carat gold, about two and a half inches
across, and weigh nearly half a pound. Swedish sculptor Erik
Lindberg, whose bas-relief of Nobel in profile is considered to
be one of the finest likenesses ever made of the founder, designed
these medals.
The obverse side of each medal has a bust of Alfred Nobel. The
Chemistry and Physics medals have identical reverse sides. The
reverse side of each of the other medals is different.
The Nobel diploma is individually designed and hand-painted for
each winner in a style resembling that of medieval illuminated
manuscripts. The designs have never been repeated excepting
once in the case of the father and son team of Braggs who shared
the 1915 Physics prize.
ALFRED NOBEL
PHYSICS AND CHEMISTRY
PEACE
LITERATURE
PHYSIOLOGY OR MEDICINE
ECONOMIC SCIENCES
I A* !*<* hw« W>
«-4utA? uro»>,A «f *v
<xttoCfci»<KS*MA
»» <-m wwiww rwwr?
I »KV<MtfU'Kg Wn.'^SKA? nu.
ALFRED NOBELS M’NINE
Hit
HERBERT A.SIMON
f iW HAM MXW' VAWr* ♦CStSfcAWf
■ *• KMUWmXKMCN tN'CM
t Ki-tWMISAA <WA MSA1«w
W.T.
K—iau.—
xxii
The Nobel Phenomenon
Since the first award was given in 1901, Nobel prize has always
been regarded by laymen, scholars and scientists alike as the
ultimate symbol of excellence in achievements. The Nobelists,
undoubtedly, occupy the topmost hierarchy in their area of work
and are considered as peers. In the late 19lh century when Nobel
contemplated the awards, there was no substantial support for
scholars or researchers. As an inventor and scientist with over
350 patents under his belt, Nobel was aware that the costs of
most research, though modest, were beyond an independent
scientist’s means. For example, even as late as 1920, the research
grant for the entire Cavendish Laboratory was only about ten
thousand dollars or two thousand pounds for a year. One of the
major prizes available at that time, the Royal Society’s Rumford
medal, by comparison, carried an honorarium of approximately
$ 150. The first year Nobel awards in 1901 was $ 42,000 each.
For the general public and the laureates themselves, Nobel’s
princely sum constituted a symbolic message asserting, in a way,
that these people really mattered.
The value of the prize has varied between $ 30,000 to $ 100,0000
over the years. The division of Nobel prizes into two or three
portions further diminishes its monetary value. The prize money
of 1998 is $ 978,000 compared to the $ 42,000 of 1901.
Although the purchase value (adjusted after inflation) still lags
behind the original sum given in 1901 and no longer provides
anything like the liberating endowment that Nobel envisaged, for
independent research, the prestige of the award has increased
incomparably in ninety years of its evolution. The extraordinarily
deserving roster of recipients is the most distinctive aspect of
this prize.
The exclusion of certain branches of science, and more especially
that of mathematics, from the award list has caused a great deal
of heart-burns. One story, apocryphal though, traces this to the
rivalry between Nobel and the Swedish mathematician, Gosta
Mittag-Leffler, for the hand of an unidentified lady. Nobel, the
story goes, being the unsuccessful suitor had his revenge by
making sure that Mittage-Liffler would never get one of his prizes.
The general attitude of the Nobel Foundation, however, as its
member Stig Romel concludes, is that Nobel wanted to benefit
mankind in a concrete, rather than an abstract way, and thus
excluded mathematics from his purview.
There are other prizes as rich as the Nobel prize. The John and
Alice Taylor Ecology Award, for example, had an honorarium of
$ 175,000 in 1975. The Robert A. Welch award in Chemistry
carried with it $ 100,000 and Prix Balyan $ 52,000. But, the
Nobel prize is, in effect, the most prestigious international award,
and the fact that persons of over 40 nations have received the
prize attests to its international character and greatly extends its
viability. The international media attention it receives and the
feverish competition that preludes the awards ensure that the
Nobel prize is an ecumenical symbol of literary and scientific
accomplishments.
Historically, the Nobel awards in literature and peace have been
controversial. By virtue of the very scope of these specialised areas,
the prize is normally given at the fag end of the laureate’s career.
The average age of a Nobelist in this area is far higher than that of
his colleagues from sciences and the evaluation in these subjects
is almost based on one’s life work. The personality of the laureate,
invariably, is an aspect of consideration in these two areas. In
sciences, on the other hand, it is the work and only the work that
matters. In terms of criticism, it is in fact necessary to remember
that the Nobel prize in sciences is given as a recognition to a
particular discovery or achievement and not to the individual
per se or his life-time's work.
Nationalities do not count in the exploration and understanding
of nature and its beings, but certain institutions do have a profound
influence on the standard of work and the opportunities they offer.
The Universities of Harvard and Washington, for example, have
dominated awards in life sciences, whereas Columbia has led in
physics and Berkeley in chemistry. Similarly, certain specialist
areas, as for example, biochemistry have dominated the prizes.
As a consequence, scientists who work in a special area stand a
better chance of being noticed and recognised. Nobel Committee
has also favoured discoveries in fundamental sciences than in
technological innovations. This, despite the explicit will of Nobel,
that inventions and improvements should be included within the
purview of the prizes.
One significant point to note, while understanding the Nobel
phenomenon, is the tremendous influence the atmosphere provides
to a scholar in science. Association with laureates and
apprenticeship under them involves not merely education and
training as is ordinarily understood, but also the acquisition of
the norms and standards, the values and attitudes as well as the
knowledge, skills and behavioural patterns associated with
particular statures and roles. As a laureate himself put it: “ I knew
the technique of research. I knew a lot of physics. I had the words,
the libretto, but not quite the music. In other words, I had not
been in contact with men who were deeply embedded in the
tradition of physics: men of high quality. This was my first real
contact with first rate minds at the high point of their power”.
Hans Krebs, the 1953 Nobel laureate in Physiology or Medicine
and a student of the 1931 laureate Otto Warburg explains thus:
“If I ask myself how it came about that one day I found myself in
Stockholm, I have not the slightest doubt that I owe this good
fortune to the circumstance, that I had an outstanding teacher at
the critical stage in my scientific career... Otto Warburgh set an
example in the methods and quality of first rate research. Without
him, I am sure I would never have reached the standards which
are prerequisites for being considered by the Nobel Committees”.
The standard of excellence demanded by some of the masters
even when they were independent were so exacting that Gunther
Stent, a former Junior Colleague of‘phage group’ leader and 1969
laureate Max Delbriick, said: “Max Delbriick managed to become
a kind of Gandhi of biology, who, without possessing any temporal
power at all, was an ever-present and sometimes irksome spiritual
force. ‘What will Max think of it?’ became the central question
of the molecular biological psyche”.
As science advanced, the narrow lines that bordered specialized
areas seem to have become thinner. The interrelationship between
different branches became so dependent that a greatmaster’s
school often produced laureates from different areas.
The Nobel dream, however, could often be elusive or the wait
agonising. Polish born Andrew Schally and French emigre Rogre
Guillemin, each clearly dreamt of a Nobel as they made their
major breakthrough in 1969, after a 21 year battle to be the first
to discover how the brain’s hormones regulate the body’s growth
and other functions. Schally later confessed: “I was tense every
October”. But not until 1977 did the long awaited phone call came
from the Swedish capital to both of them. For the venerable old
virologist, Francis Peyton Rous, it was a different kind of wait.
He had to wait 50 years, until he was 87, to be honoured with the
prize in 1966. Von Frisch, the ethologist was 86 when he won the
award, but then his subject itself had taken decades to come under
the purview of the Nobel list. Over 30 scientists have won the
prize after their seventies, in spite of the official reluctance to
award the prize as ‘pensions’. In fact the trend has been an increase
in the average age of the winners as the years go by. This is
attributable to the increase in the time gap between the actual
work and award. The backlog of scientific giants partly contributes
to this trend, and the application and through that reemergence
of an earlier work after a time gap, accounts for the remaining.
An award of this magnitude cannot also be completely error-free.
There have been occasions, very rare though, of an awardee not
being actually deserving of the honour. Johannes Fibiger, the 1926
winner, for example, is regarded as one of the least meritorious
of laureates because his work on the propagation of malignant
tumours was altogether mistaken. The Nobel Committee for
medicine was so embarrassed over the error that it declined to
give a prize for cancer research for almost forty years. The
selection of J. J. R. Macleod (1923) was another error. When
Banting and Best isolated insulin and studied its therapeutic use
in human diabetes, Macleod was not even present at the laboratory.
The Committee honoured Macleod along with Banting; still worst,
Best was ignored. Macleod’s only role was, as a Director of the
laboratory, to facilitate the work. Another unfortunate oversight
involving the same award was that the Committee had failed to
note the Rumanian scientist N. Paulesco who had also come to
similar conclusion as that of Banting and Best, six months before
the actual awardees.
There are also obvious kinds of anomalies. Einstein, for example,
won the award in 1921 for discovery of the photoelectric effect.
His phenomenal and monumental work on the special theory of
relativity and the theory of Brownian motion done in 1905 or the
work on the general theory of relativity done in 1916 were not
mentioned in the prize citation. Edward C. Kendall, whose
research on thyroxine (between 1914 and 1926) was proposed
and judged prizeworthy, however did not win his prize for the
thyroxine investigations for unknown reasons. His studies on the
biochemistry of Cortisones and its use in treating chronic
rheumatoid arthritis finally brought him the award. The case study
of Frederic Soddy is even more fascinating. He was not nominated
to share the 1904 chemistry prize with William Ramsey even
though he was a close, indispensable collaborator with Ramsey
in his work.'Soddy again missed out 4 years later when the prize
went to Ernest Rutherford. This was despite the emphatic
statement of Rutherford that Soddy has been a full collaborator
on the research cited for the award. In 1921, Soddy finally
received his own prize for his investigations of isotopes, thus
demonstrating his persistence and scientific acumen and putting
to rest the questions that had been raised about the wisdom of
the Chemistry Committee’s earlier decisions.
In the past 98 years, 694 individuals and institutions have won
the Nobel prize, 157 in physics, 130 in chemistry, 168 in
physiology or medicine, 95 in literature, 101 in peace including
11 institutions, and 43 in economic sciences. The study of the
Nobelists, their work, and the tremendous commitment they
have to society at large and their area of work is revealing.
Economics, the baby of the Nobel Prizes since it was incepted
only in 1968, has travelled far from the days of the ‘study of how
goods and services get produced and how they are distributed’ to
a study of a behavioural science in seeking to understand the
responses which individuals, a group of people or countries
make in a given set of circumstances. Economists today
investigate and explain the patterns of behaviour they observe
and are concerned with what is and not what ought to be. The
scientific approach to economics, in fact, had started in the late
1800s and early 1900s. As early as the 1600s, the English
economist Sir William Petty stressed the use of mathematics
and statistics in economics. In France, Leon Walras prepared a
mathematical statement to show how each part of an economy
is related to all the other parts and thus laid the foundation for
econometrics with his mathematical description of the market
economy. The American, Wesley Clain Mitchell, who also
studied booms and depressions, was a pioneer in stressing the
need for using statistics in testing theories.
The great depression of the 1930s brought the applicability of
economics into proper perspective. John Maynard Keynes, the
British economist led the way by attacking free market and
propagating that the government could help end depression by
increasing its own spending. Ragnar Frisch, Simon Kuznets,
Gunnar Myrdal, Haavelmo, Allais among others, developed
methods of measuring gross national product, national income
and other economic factors. The 1960s and 1970s saw the
emergence of the monetarists, led by the American Milton
Friedman, who urged that governments increase the money
supply at a constant rate to stabilise prices and economic growth.
Econometrics, with its emphasis on mathematics and statistics,
by the 1960s, was as much a science affecting human welfare as
any and it is a tribute to the subject that the ‘closed doors’ of the
Nobel Foundation were opened in its seven decades of history
only once to sneak in the infant science of all.
1990s have seen the Nobelists in Economics being socially
active pioneers and influential opinion makers who have dared
to delve into transaction costs for the institutional structure
(Coase 1990) through transforming macroeconomic analysis
and deepening our understanding of economic policy (Lucas,
1995) to the phenomenal works of Amartya Sen on welfare
economics (1998).
Nobel Foundation has been rejecting proposals, often supported
by promises of large donations, to offer new prizes. These
include mathematics, astronomy, music, environmental
conservation and architecture, to name a few. The Nobel
Foundation has been of the view that addition of more categories
would result in inflation of the Nobel Prize values. The
Economics Prize is hence the exception that confirms the rules
- no new Nobel Prizes beyond the five prizes stipulated by Nobel
himself in his will, directly reflective of his own interests and
activities.
The Economic Prize, called “the Alfred Nobel Memorial Prize
in Economic Sciences”, initiated in 1968 is endorsed by the
Bank of Sweden, and is awarded by the Academy of Sciences.
The donation was made as a gesture to celebrate the bank’s 300lh
anniversary. The history of Nobel Prizes and its prestige and
durability suggest that it is a prudent association and investment
by the Bank of Sweden.
1969
FRISCH TINBERGEN
FRISCH, RAGNAR KITTIL ANTON
Nationality: Norwegian
b.-March 5,1895, Oslo, Norway; d.- January 31,1973,
Oslo.
TINBERGEN, JAN
Nationality: Dutch
b.- April 12, 1903, The Hague, Netherlands; d.- June
9, 1994, Netherlands.
1970
1972
ARROW HICKS
ARROW, KENNETH JOSEPH
Nationality: American
b.- August 23, 1921, New York City.
1973
LEONTIEF, WASSILY W,
Nationality: American
b.- August 5, 1906, St. Petersburg, now Leningrad,
Russia.
1974
1975
KANTOROVICH KOOPMANS
KANTOROVICH, LEONID VITAL EVICH
Nationality: Russian
b.- January 19, 1912, St. Petersburg, Russia; d.- April
9, 1986, Moscow.
1976
FRIEDMAN, MILTON
Nationality: American
b.- July 31, 1912, Brooklyn, New York.
1977
MEADE OHLIN
MEADE, JAMES EDWARD
Nationality: British
b.- June 23, 1907, Swanage, Dorset, England;
d.-December 22, 1995.
20
b.- April 23, 1899, Klippan, Sweden; d.- August 3,
1979, Northern Sweden.
1979
LEWIS, SIR WILLIAM ARTHUR
Nationality: British
b.- January 23, 1915, St. Lucia, British West Indies;
d.- June 15, 1991, Barbados, Princeton, New Jersey.
LEWIS SCHULTZ
1980
KLEIN, LAWRENCE ROBERT
Nationality: American
b.- September 14, 1920, Omaha, Nebraska.
1981
TOBIN
TOBIN, JAMES
Nationality: American
b.- March 5, 1918, Champaign, Illinois.
1982
DEBREU, GERARD
Nationality: American
b.- July 4, 1921,Calais, France.
1984
STONE, SIR JOHN RICHARD NICHOLAS
Nationality: British
b.-August 30, 1913, London; d.-1991.
STONE
, For having made fundamental contributions to the
development ofsystems ofnational accounts and hence
greatly improved the basis of empirical economic
analysis
1985
MODIGLIANI, FRANCO
Nationality: American
b.- June 18, 1918, Rome, Italy.
1986
SOLOW, ROBERT
Nationality: American
b.- August 23, 1924, Brooklyn, New York.
1988
ALLAIS, MAURICE
Nationality: French
b.- May 31, 1911, Paris.
For his pioneering contributions to the theory of
markets and efficient utilization of resources
1989
HAAVELMO, TRYGVE
Nationality: Norwegian
b.- December 13, 1911, Skedsmo, Norway.
MARKOWITZ SHARPE
MILLER
MARKOWITZ, HARRY
Nationality: American
b.- 1927, Chicago.
MILLER, MERTON
Nationality: American
b.- May 16,1923, Massachusetts, Boston.
SHARPE, WILLIAM
Nationality: American
b.- June 16,1934, Massachusetts, Boston.
1991
COASE, RONALD. H
Nationality: British
b.- December 29,1910, Willesden, London.
1992
BECKER, GARY. S
Nationality: American
b.- December 2, 1930, Pottsville, Pennsylvania.
1993
FOGEL NORTH
FOGEL, ROBERT. W
Nationality: American
b.- 1926, New York City.
NORTH, DOUGLASS. C
Nationality: American
b.- Novembers, 1920,Cambridge,Massachusetts.
1994
HARSANYI, JOHN. C
Nationality: American
b.- May 29, 1920, Budapest, Hungary.
NASH, JOHN. F
Nationality: American
b.- June 13, 1928, Bluefield, West Virginia.
HARSANYI NASH
SELTEN
SELTEN, REINHARD
Nationality: German
b.- October 10, 1930, Breslau, Germany.
1995
LUCAS, ROBERT JR. E
Nationality: American
b.- September 15,1937, Yakima, Washington.
LUCAS
For having developed and applied the hypothesis
of rational expectations, and thereby having
transformed macro economic analysis and deepened
our understanding of economic policy
1996
MIRRLEES, JAMES. A
Nationality: British
b.- July 5, 1936, Minnigaff, Scotland.
VICKREY, WILLIAM
Nationality: American
b.- 1914, Victoria, British Columbia, Canada;
d.- October 11,1996, Columbia.
MIRRLEES VICKREY
1997
MERTON, ROBERT. C
Nationality: American
b.- July 31,1944, New York City, USA.
MERTON SCHOLES
SCHOLES, MYRON. S
Nationality: American
b.- July 1, 1941, Ontario, Canada.
1998
SEN, AMARTYA
Nationality: Indian
b.- November 3, 1933, Shantiniketan, Bengal, India.
For his contributions to welfare economics
ISBN 81-87350-21-0