Unit 06
Unit 06
Unit 06
Governance, role of the state, market and civil society are crucial factors
in every economy. This unit covers the concepts related to governance in
lesson-1, role of state and market in lesson-2 and the role of the civil
society in lesson-3.
School of Business
Blank Page
Unit-6 Page-294
Bangladesh Open University
Lesson 1: Governance1
Objectives:
After studying this lesson, you will be able to:
Understand theoretical concepts related to governance.
Analysis the market and Government.
Describe the economic performance.
Introduction
The concept of governance is not easy to define. In case of an institution,
it may be said that the term refers to processes through which an
organisation is governed. When it is linked to a country the term relates
to processes having complex historical, cultural, social and political
determinants. It deals with the science of government behaviour and
performance. Economic theories emphasise efficiency in explaining the
role of institutions in development, while political and sociological
theories emphasise the role of authority, beliefs and ideology.
1
The section draws on J. J. Dethier: Governance and Economic Performance: A
Survey, ZEF Discussion Papers on Development Policy No. 5, Center for
Development Research, Bonn, April, 1999.
2
Se Note 1.
Unit-6 Page-296
Bangladesh Open University
Unit-6 Page-298
Bangladesh Open University
of an externality does not imply that there is a prima facie case for public
intervention. The Coase solution is to solve the problem without state
intervention, apart from fixing property rights, but this is not always
practicable. It does not generally work for education or health.
Bardhan (1997) points out, this calls for a more detailed theory of the
state than is usually available from the old “market vs. state” debate. On
the one hand, it is necessary to recognize the limitations of the state as an
economic governance structure, arising from its lack of access to local
information, its lack of local accountability and its vulnerability to
wasteful rent-seeking processes. On the other hand, especially in poor
countries, it is often desirable that the state play an active role, catalysing
the mobilisation of people in participatory development and providing
supra-local support of a financial and technical nature. In situations of
high economic and political inequality where elites dominate local
governance structures, benefits are not likely to percolate easily to the
poorer (and weaker) segments of the population.
Should public goods be provided by the government or by the private
sector? To what extent are market mechanisms better guarantors of
efficiency and/or social welfare than political processes or deliberative
government interventions? Theory provides guidelines, but the answers
to these questions have to be given on a case-by-case basis. Hart, Shleifer
and Vishny (1997) develop a model based on incomplete contracts to
assess the provision of public goods by private or public firms. Private
providers have stronger incentives to improve the quality of service and
reduce costs than do public providers. However, private providers’
incentives to cut costs are too strong because they can ignore the adverse
impact on quality. Hart, Shleifer and Vishny apply their theory to the
private management of prisons, a controversial trend which, according to
critics, has been driven entirely by ideology and politics and yields low
economic benefits (Schlosser 1998).
political costs to India’s leaders, who thus have a greater incentive than
the Chinese leadership to adopt policies to combat hunger (Dreze and
Sen, 1982).
A sizeable cross-country empirical literature, critically reviewed in
Przeworski and Limongi (1993), examines the relationship between
regime type and economic performance. Results are mixed, with the
most recent and sophisticated analyses concluding that democracies are
no more or less likely than non-democracies to grow rapidly.
Persson and Tabellini (1994) formalise this intuition in a growth model,
and claim to have found supporting evidence in the cross-country data:
income inequality is associated with slower growth among democracies,
but not among non-democracies, where the median voter theories do not
apply. However, other researchers using somewhat different data sources
on inequality, and on regime types, have found that income inequality
affects growth equally in democracies and non-democracies (e.g.,
Alesina and Rodrik, 1994). Knack and Keefer (1997) replicate the
Persson and Tabellini findings, but show that when reasonable
corrections are made for mis-measurement in their income inequality and
regime type data, the impact of inequality on growth is just as strong or
non-democracies as for democracies. Coupled with other evidence
suggesting that non-democracies also face pressures to redistribute from
rich to poor (e.g., through political violence; see Alesina and Perotti
(1996), it remains an open question whether insecurities in property
rights associated with majority-rule voting counteract some of the
governance advantages of democratic regimes.
A second possible reason for the failure of democracies to systematically
outperform autocracies is related to interest group pressures on the state.
The political openness characteristic of democracy may also allow freer
rein for the growth-slowing rent-seeking activities of special interest
organisations (Olson, 1982).
Conclusion
An overwhelming body of accumulating evidence indicates that good
governance and economic freedoms are crucial for attaining rapid
increases in the living standards of the broad mass of people in a
developing economy. Transparent, predictable governmental institutions
and policies are conducive not only to rising per capita incomes but also
to declines in absolute poverty.
Note
Many economists are trying to understand institutional causality. New
developments in the economics of organisation, information and
incentives have led to a major reformulation of welfare issues, both in
microeconomics and macro-economics. Basic references are Williamson
(1985), Tirole (1989), Laffont and Tirole (1993) Persson and Tabellini
(1990). Hirshleifer and Riley 1992 and Salanie 1997 are theoretical
overviews that are more accessible. As discussed by Tirole 1994,
extending this theoretical framework to include governments as
Unit-6 Page-300
Bangladesh Open University
Further Readings
1. Alesina, Alberto and Enrico Spolaore (1997), ”On the Number and
Size of Nations,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, p.1027-1056
2. Alesina, Alberto and Nouriel Roubini (1997). Political Cycles and
the Macroeconomy. Cam-bridge: The MIT Press.
3. Alesina, Alberto, Sule Özler, Nouriel Roubini and Phillip Swagel
(1996), “Political Instability and Economic Growth,” Journal of
Economic Growth, vol.1, p.189-211.
4. Alesina, Alberto and Allen Drazen (1991), “Why are Stabilisations
Delayed?” American Economic Review, vol.81, p.1170-1188.
5. Allen, Carleton Kemp (1964), Law in the Making, 7 th edition,
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
6. Arrow, Kenneth (1951, revised 1963), Social Choice and
Individual Values, New York: Wiley.
7. Asian Development Bank (1995). Governance. Working Paper
1/95 for the Board of Directors, 15 March.
8. Åslund, Anders, Peter Boone and Simon Johnson (1996), “How to
Stabilize: Lessons from Post-Communist Countries,” Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1996, p. 217-313.
9. Baird, Douglas, Robert Gertner and Randal Picker (1995). Game
Theory and the Law. Cam-bridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
10. Bardhan, Pranab (1990), “Symposium on the State and Economic
Development,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol.4, No.3,
p.3-7.
11. Bardhan, Pranab (1996), ”Efficiency, Equity and Poverty
Alleviation: Policy Issues in Less Developed Countries", The
Economic Journal, vol.106, p.1344-1356.
12. Bardhan, Pranab (1997a). The Role of Governance in Economic
Development. A Political Economy Approach. Paris: OECD
Development Center.
13. Bardhan, Pranab (1997b), “Corruption and Development. A
Review of Issues,” Journal of Economic Literature, vol.35,
p.1320-1346.
Unit-6 Page-302
Bangladesh Open University
Unit-6 Page-304
Bangladesh Open University
Unit-6 Page-306
Bangladesh Open University
Unit-6 Page-308
Bangladesh Open University
Unit-6 Page-310
Bangladesh Open University
Unit-6 Page-312
Bangladesh Open University
Introduction3
The discussion of the role of government is vital for improving
development strategy. There is a growing consensus that governments
can play a vital role in successful development efforts, but wrong kind of
government intervention can be highly detrimental. The re has been
recognition that the key issue is the scope and effectiveness of
government activities, rather than simply the size of the government's
budget or personnel.
Competition for rent seeking tended to dissipate the rents, but the
rent dissipation simply added to the waste.
While there is plenty of evidence to suggest that rent seeking was
important, these propositions do not seem to adequately describe the
process. Stiglitz (1998) provides three reasons for his view. First, there is
a curious intellectual inconsistency: while many conservatives seemed to
argue that Coase's theorem (or what might more appropriately be called
Coase's conjecture) worked well in the private sector, it seemed to have
no sway in the public. Inefficiencies within that sector did not seem to
get "bargained out." Second, it was simply assumed that there was
perfect competition in rent seeking. In reality, however, competition in
rent seeking was every bit as imperfect as competition elsewhere in the
economy. There are quite general theorems which established that if
there were even epsilon sunk costs, even strong potential competition
was not enough for the dissipation of imperfect competition rents.
4
Stiglitz, J.E. 1994. Whither Socialism?. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Unit-6 Page-314
Bangladesh Open University
5
Stiglitz, J.E. 1987. "Technological Change, Sunk Costs, and Competition," Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, 3, 1987. (Special issue of Microeconomics, M.N. Baily and C. Winston (eds.),
1988, pp. 883-947.)
6
This is a slightly revised version of the paper presented by the author at the International
Conference on "Institutions and Economic Development - Towards a Comparative Perspective on
State Reform", November 12-14, 1997, Rio de Janeiro, Brazil. This is forthcoming in L. Burlamaqui,
A. Castro & H-J. Chang (eds.), Institutions and the Role of the State, Edward Elgar). The paper is
reproduced with the permission of the author.
Unit-6 Page-316
Bangladesh Open University
1991; Evans, 1995; Chang & Rowthorn, 1995b).1 And following the
institutionalist criticisms, even some proponents of Neo-Liberal doctrine
have recently come to admit (but without necessarily recognising the
contributions from their critics) the importance of institutional factors in
understanding the role of the state (North, 1994, and World Bank, 1997,
are good examples of such change). Having achieved that important, if
unfairly unacknowledged, victory over the Neo-Liberals, however, I
think it is fair to say that the institutionalists still lack a full-blown
political economy that can replace the Neo-Liberal political economy. In
this paper, I will make some suggestions as to what I think should be the
building blocks of what may be called an institutionalist political
economy. For this purpose, I will dissect the Neo-Liberal research
agenda on the role of the state from an explicitly institutionalist
perspective and identify what I think are the fundamental flaws in it, and
in that process suggest what should be the elements in the institutionalist
theory of state intervention that can overcome these flaws.
2. Disentangling the Neo-Liberal Agenda
The Messianic convictions with which many proponents of Neo-
Liberalism have delivered their messages have created the impression
that it is a very coherent doctrine with clear conclusions. However,
contrary to this popular belief, the Neo-Liberal doctrine is in fact a very
heterogeneous and internally inconsistent intellectual edifice. So before
going into the detailed criticisms of this doctrine, it will be useful to
delineate the basic fault lines in the Neo-Liberal intellectual agenda and
reveal some of its obvious weaknesses.
welfare economics but then not to extend it beyond the set of "politically
acceptable" areas. So, for example, the externality argument is often
applied to politically less controversial areas such as the environment or
education, but is rarely applied to such politically more controversial
areas as "selective" industrial policy a la East Asia, which can be
justified by the same logic equally well. Given that there is no theoretical
way in Neoclassical economics to determine what is the "correct"
boundary for state intervention, it becomes necessary to argue that
market failures exist as logical possibilities, but rarely occur in reality -
naturally without providing much evidence (Friedman, 1962, is a good
example).3 2 This point is best illustrated by the experiences during the
early days of "reform" in the former Communist countries. What
captured people's imagination in those days was the Austrian-Libertarian
languages of freedom and entrepreneurship, and not the arid Neoclassical
languages of Pareto Optimality and General Equilibrium. However,
when the post-Communist governments in these countries chose their
foreign economic advisers, it was according, largely, to how high a
standing they had in the Western academic "hierarchy", which was
determined by how good they were in handling the concepts and the
tools of Neoclassical economics. Friedman's list of legitimate functions
of the state is as follows: maintenance of law and order; definition of
property rights; service as a means whereby people modify property
rights and other rules of the economic game; adjudication of disputes
about the.6 The second method of suppressing the interventionist instinct
of Neoclassical economics is to separate, partly deliberately and partly
subconsciously, the "serious" academic discourse from the "popular"
policy discourse and compartmentalise them. So Neoclassical economists
in universities may be doing researches justifying stringent anti-trust
policy, but the "lax" anti-trust policy by the government may be justified
in terms of some other logic which has no place in Neoclassical
economics - say, by citing the need "not to discourage entrepreneurship",
etc.. The recent "reform" experiences in the former Communist countries
that we just talked about is a most poignant example of such practice.
The last method of suppression is to fully accept the logic of market
failure and build models that may have strong interventionist
conclusions, but later dismiss them on the ground that "real life" states
cannot possibly be entrusted with such policies that are technically
difficult (due to informational asymmetry) and politically dangerous (due
to the possibility of bureaucratic abuse and/or interest group capture).
Various writings by the American trade economist Krugman provide the
best example, where frequently a few paragraphs, at the end of an article,
of "pop political economy" analysis dismissing the integrity of the state
would be used to discredit his own elaborate "strategic trade theory"
model endorsing state intervention that went on in the rest of the article.
To put it bluntly, the name of the game is that, a Neoclassical economist
may build a model that interpretation of the rules; enforcement of
contracts; promotion of competition; provision of a monetary framework;
engagement in activities to counter technical monopolies and to
overcome "neighbourhood effects" [his term for externality] widely
regarded as sufficiently important to justify government intervention;
supplementation of private charity and the private family in protecting
Unit-6 Page-318
Bangladesh Open University
Unit-6 Page-320
Bangladesh Open University
ownership has been, since the abolition of slavery), they are not a matter
of policy debate (i.e., there is no debate on whether the ban on child
labour is "efficient" in some sense). In contrast, in the developing
countries (of today and yesterday), such rights of children are not so
totally accepted, and therefore state action regarding child labour is
considered an "intervention", whose impact on "efficiency" is still a
legitimate subject of policy debate. For another example, many
environmental standards, which were widely criticised as unwarranted
intrusion on business and personal freedom (e.g., automobile emission
standards) when they were first introduced in the OECD countries not so
long ago, are these days rarely regarded as "interventions". Therefore
there would be few people in the OECD countries who would say that
their country's automobile market is not a "free" market because of these
regulations. In contrast, some developing country exporters who do not
accept such stringent environmental standard as "legitimate" may
consider them as "invisible trade barriers" that "distort" the market. Still
for another example, many Neoclassical economists who criticise
minimum wages and "excessively" high labour standards in the advanced
countries as unwarranted state interventions that "artificially" set up entry
barrier into the labour market do not even regard the heavy restrictions
on immigration that exist in these countries as a state intervention (not to
speak of supporting it), although immigration control sets up an
"artificial" entry barrier into the labour market as much as the above-
mentioned “interventions” do. This contradictory attitude is possible only
because these economists believe in the right of the existing citizens of a
country to dictate the terms of the non-citizens' participation in "their"
labour market, without explicitly stating their "political" position on this
matter. The examples can go on, but point is that, depending on which
rights and obligations are regarded as "legitimate" by the members of the
society, the same action could be considered an "intervention" in one
society and not in another. And once something is not even considered to
be an "intervention" in a particular society at a given time (e.g., ban on
child labour or slavery in the OECD countries), debating their
"efficiency" becomes politically unacceptable - although here is no God-
given reason why this should be the case. The corollary is that,
depending on the rights-obligations structure, the same market with the
same state "intervention" in the same area – for example, regarding child
labour - can be seen as "free" (from state intervention) in one society and
not in another. So, therefore, if we want to decide whether a particular
market is “free” or not, we need to understand the underlying institutions
which define the rights-obligations structure for the participants in the
relevant market (and indeed certain non-participants, when it involves
"externalities"). The institutions that need to be understood in this
context will include, among other things: (i) the formal and informal
rules that govern the ay in which interests are organised and exercised
(e.g., rules on political associations, rules on incorporation, rules on
lobbying); (ii) the formal and informal "ideologies" relating to the
notions such as "fairness" and "natural rights" that prevail in the society
(e.g., rights for everyone to self-ownership, rights for children to
education); (iii) the formal and informal institutions that determine how
the rights-obligations structure could be changed (e.g., procedures for
legal changes, social customs about when and how some de facto
rights/obligations can become "legitimate", if not necessarily legalised).
Thus, the apparently simple exercise of defining what is a "free" market
(and what constitutes "state intervention") is not so obvious any more -
and this is, to repeat, even before we can discuss whether some markets
are "failing" and therefore state intervention may make them "more
efficient”. From the institutionalist perspective, we may even say that
defining a free market is at the deepest level a pointless exercise, because
no market.12 is in the end “free”, as all markets have some state
regulations on who can participate in which markets and in what terms. It
is only because some regulations (and the rights and the obligations that
they are creating) can be so totally accepted (by those who are making
the observation as well as by the participants in the market) that some
markets appear to have no “intervention” and therefore be “free”. 3.1.2.
How do We Measure State Intervention and Why does It Matter? For the
purpose of international and historical comparison, people have used
some quantitative measures of state intervention. At one level, this seems
a straightforward exercise. However, how good a measure of state
intervention is depends on the theory (of state intervention) that
underpins it. Therefore, we need to look beyond the "numbers" that are
supposed to measure the extent of state intervention and analyse the
theories that lie behind those umbers. Let us explain what we mean by
this. Traditionally, the most popular measures of the degree of state
intervention have been the total government budget as a ratio of GDP
and the share of the public enterprise (PE) sector in GDP (or total
investment). It may be true that these measures give us as good an idea
of how "big" the state sector is but it is not true that they are good
indicators of the degree of state intervention. This is because a "big"
government is not necessarily a more "interventionist" government. The
point is very well illustrated by the East Asian countries of Japan, Korea,
and Taiwan. On the basis of these traditional measures, until recently
many people believed that we could "objectively" establish that the East
Asian countries are "non-interventionist" (e.g., World Bank, 1991, p. 40,
Box 2.2.). And except for the (conveniently ignored) fact that Taiwan has
one of the largest PE sectors in the non-socialist, non-oil-producing
world, this observation does not seem to be too far from the truth - that
is, as far as we accept that the "vision" of the role of the state that lies
behind these measures correctly reflects the actual role of state
intervention in these countries. However, the mode of state intervention
in East Asia has been quite different from what is envisaged in the
"vision" that lies behind these traditional measures, and thus they
"wrongly" measure the extent of state intervention in East Asia. In the
"traditional" vision, the state exercises its control basically through the
ownership of the means of production, which is (wrongly) equated with
the control over its use, and the reallocation of resources via taxes and
subsidies, for example, in the manner prescribed in welfare economics.
However, state intervention in East Asia has. The ratio of government
expenditure to GDP for Japan in 1985 was 33%, far lower than those in
other industrial nations except the US (37%). Corresponding figures
include 47% for Germany, 48% for the UK, 52% for France, and 65%
for Sweden (World Bank, 1991, p. 139, Table 7.4). In the case of Korea,
Unit-6 Page-322
Bangladesh Open University
3.2. What does Market Failure Mean and How Much does It
Matter?: "Rival Views of Market Society"
3.2.1. When does the Market Fail?
The term, "market failure", refers to a situation when the market does not
work like what is expected of the "ideal" market. But what is the ideal
market supposed to do? Given the current domination of Neoclassical
economics, the ideal market is usually equated with the "perfectly
competitive market" in Neoclassical economics. However, the
Neoclassical theory of the market is only one of the many legitimate
theories of how the market works (and therefore what we can expect
from the ideal market and therefore when we can say a market has
"failed") - and not a particularly good one at that. In other words, there
are, to borrow Hirschman's phrase, many different "rival views of market
society" (Hirschman, 1982a). And therefore the same market could be
seen as "failing" by some people while others regard it as "normal" or
even "succeeding", depending on their respective theories of the market.
Let us illustrate this point with some examples. For example, many
people think that on of the biggest "failures" of the market is to generate
"unacceptable" level of inequality (whatever the criteria for
"acceptability" may be). However, in Neoclassical economics, this is not
a market "failure", because the "ideal" Neoclassical market is not
assumed to generate equitable income distribution in the first place. This
is not to deny that many well-intentioned Neoclassical economists may
dislike the income distribution prevailing in, say, Brazil, and may
support some "non-distortionary" lump-sum income transfers, but to
point out that even they would.argue that an equitable income
distribution is simply not something that the market should be expected
to generate and therefore the issue is beyond economic '"science". For
another example, a "non-competitive" market is one of the most obvious
example of a "failing" market for Neoclassical economics, while the
Schumpeterian theory (and before it the Marxian theory) argues that the
existence of "non-competitive" (in the Neoclassical sense) markets is an
inevitable, if a secondary, feature of a dynamic economy driven by
technological innovation. Thus, a classic example of market failure in the
Neoclassical framework, namely, the non-competitive market, is
regarded as an inevitable feature of a "successful" dynamic economy,
according to the Schumpeterian perspective or to put it differently, a
market which is "perfect" in the Neoclassical sense (e.g., no participant
in the market has any market power) may look like an absolute "failure"
Unit-6 Page-324
Bangladesh Open University
Unit-6 Page-326
Bangladesh Open University
industry protection (Freeman, 1989), and was indeed the most heavily
protected economy among the industrial countries for around a century
until the Second World War (see World Bank, 1991, p. 97, Box Table
5.2; Kozul-Wright, 1995, p. 97, Table 4.8). Moving beyond the UK and
the US, we realise that there is virtually no country, except Hong Kong,
which achieved the status of an industrialised country without at least
some periods of heavy state involvement in the developmental effort.
The exact forms of intervention varied - "pre-emptive" welfare state in
Bismarckian Germany, postwar French industrial policy, early Swedish
state support of research and development, transformation of the
Austrian manufacturing sector since World War Two And he continues:
"Administrators had to be constantly on the watch to ensure the free
working of the system. Thus even those who wished most ardently to
free the state from all unnecessary duties, and whose whole philosophy
demanded the restriction of state activities, could not but entrust the self-
same state with the new powers, organs, and instruments required for the
establishment of laissez-faire [italics original]" (p. 140) During this
period, few countries had tariff autonomy either because of outright
colonial rule or because of "unequal treaties" - for example, Japan got
tariff autonomy only in 1899 when all its unequal treaties expired. Of the
cuntries with tariff autonomy, the US had by far the highest tariff rates.
Its average tariff rates since the 1820s was never below 25%, and usually
around 40%, when those in other countries for which the data are
available, such as Austria, Belgium, France, Italy, and Sweden, were
rarely over 20%. For detailed figures, see World Bank (1991, p. 97, Box
5.2.) public enterprise sector, the well-known state-led developments of
the East Asian countries - but the fact remains that all successful
developmental efforts involved substantial state intervention. So if
virtually all now-advanced countries, with the possible exceptions of
Britain at certain phases and Hong Kong, developed in some "unnatural"
way which involved heavy state intervention, it seems questionable
whether there is any point in calling the market a "natural" phenomenon.
What we have just discussed is not simply of historical interest. Whether
or not we accord primacy to the market institution makes a critical
difference on how we design developmental policies. For example, the
severe economic crises that many former Communist countries which
have opted for a "big bang" reform have experienced during the last
several years is one striking example which shows how the establishment
of a well-functioning market economy is impossible without a well-
functioning state (see Chang & Nolan, 1995, whose Spanish translation
appears as Chang & Nolan, 1996). In fact, if the markets evolve so
"naturally" as the Neoclassical economists believe, these countries would
not be in such trouble now. Likewise, the developmental crises that many
developing countries have gone through during the last two decades or so
also show how dangerous it is to assume the primacy of market
institutions and believe that it will naturally develop as far as the state
does not "interfere" with its evolution. The assumption of market
primacy has a lot more serious implications than it first appears to have.
Unit-6 Page-328
Bangladesh Open University
Unit-6 Page-330
Bangladesh Open University
we should remember that there are more than one views of what the
"ideal" market can do, and that the Neoclassical view is only one of
many plausible views I have attempted to develop this theory in a
number of my previous works. See Chang (1994), Chang (1995), Chang
& Rowthorn (1995b), and Chang (1997)..28 - and not a particularly good
one at that. Accordingly, it becomes possible that the same market may
be seen as failing by some with one "theory of the market" and as
succeeding by others with another theory. Only when an economist
makes his/her own theory of the market explicit, we will be able to judge
the merit of his/her view that the market is "failing" (or not) and thus to
accept or reject the "solution" to the problem, whether it is some kind of
state intervention or the establishment of some non-market institutions
and/or organisations. Thirdly, we need to realise that the Neoclassical
theory is essentially a theory of the market (and a very schematic and
misleading one at that). However, capitalism, as a socio-economic
system, is more than a collection of markets, and is made up of many
institutions, including, among others, the firms as institutions of
production, the marketsas institutions of exchange, the state as an
institution of politically addressing collective interests, and various
producer and consumer groupings (e.g., conglomeration of firms,
producer associations, trade unions, purchasing cooperatives,
subcontracting networks). Thus seen, market failure becomes, somewhat
paradoxically, less of a problem in the institutionalist framework than in
the Neoclassical framework, because in the former framework even
widespread and severe market failures would not necessarily suggest that
the whole "economy" is failing, whereas the latter framework would see
it as just that. Fourthly, we need to understand that the market is a
fundamentally political construction. A market cannot be defined except
with reference to the specific rights/obligations structure that underpins
it. And since these rights and obligations are determined through a
political process, and not by any "scientific" or "natural" law as
Neoclassical (and other Neo-Liberal) commentators want us to believe,
all markets have a fundamentally "political" origin. Therefore, it is
impossible to decide whether a market is "free" or not, without
specifying the position of the person(s) making that statement regarding
the legitimacy of the current rights/obligations structure. Added to this
are the more explicit administrations of prices that are found in many
markets through price caps, price ceilings, state setting of certain prices,
and quantity controls. While some prices may be more politically
administered than others in a given context, ultimately no price is free
from politics. This brings us to our fifth element in the institutionalist
theory on the role of the state, namely, the need to build a theory of
politics which takes a much more broad, balanced, and sophisticated
view of politics than what is offered by Neo-Liberalism. Neo-Liberal
thinkers see politics as a market-like process, where material benefits are
exchanged for political supports, but as a process that ultimately corrupts
the "rationality" of the market, because of the discretionary powers that it
confers to those who can make and/or influence political decisions.
However, this is a fundamentally jaundiced view of politics. The main
problem with this view is that the "rationality" that it want to preserve
through "de-politicisation of the economy", which is in fact an
Unit-6 Page-332
Bangladesh Open University
Bibliography
1. Albert, M. 1991. Capitalism vs. Capitalism, New York, Four Wall
Eight Windows.
2. Arrow, K. 1974. The Limits of Organisation, New York and London,
W. W. Norton and Company.
3. Baumol, W. 1965. Welfare Economics and the Theory of the State,
2nd ed., London, London School of Economics.
4. Berger, S. & Dore, R. (eds.) 1996. National Diversity and Global
Capitalism, Ithaca and London, Cornell University Press.
5. Bobbio, N. 1990. Liberalism and Democracy, London, Verso.
6. Buchanan, J. 1986. Contractarianism and Democracy in J. Buchanan,
Liberty, Market and State, Brighton, Wheatsheaf Books Ltd..
7. Chang, H-J. 1994a. The Political Economy of Industrial Policy,
London and Basingstoke, Macmillan.
8. Chang, H-J. 1994b. State, Institutions, and Structural Change,
Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, vol. 5, no. 2.
9. Chang, H-J. 1995. Explaining 'Flexible Rigidities' in East Asia in T.
Killick (ed.), The Flexible Economy, London, Routledge.
10. Chang, H-J. 1996. El Papel del Estado en el Cambio Económico,
Mexico City, Editorial Planeta Mexicana.
11. Chang, H-J. 1997. Markets, Madness, and Many Middle Ways:
Some Reflections on the Institutional Diversity of Capitalism in P.
Arestis, G. Palma & M. Sawyer (eds.), Essays in Hour of Geoff
Harcourt - Volume 2: Markets, Unemployment, and Economic
Policy, London, Routledge.
12. Chang, H-J. & Nolan, P. 1995. Europe versus Asia - Contrasting
Paths to the Reform of Centrally Planned Systems of Political
Economy in H-J. Chang & P. Nolan (eds.),.32 The Transformation of
the Communist Economies - Against the Mainstream,London,
Macmillan
13. Chang, H-J. & Nolan, P. 1996. La Transición en Europa oriental y en
Asia: Caminos Contrapuestos, Políticas Económicas Diferentes,
Revista de Estudios Asiaticos, no. 3.
14. Chang, H-J. & Rowthorn, R. 1995a. Introduction in H-J. Chang & R.
Rowthorn (eds.), Role of the State in Economic Change, Oxford,
Oxford University Press.
15. Chang, H-J. & Rowthorn, R. 1995b. Role of the State in Economic
Change –Entrepreneurship and Conflict Management in H-J. Chang
& R. Rowthorn (eds.), Role of the State in Economic Change,
Oxford, Oxford University Press.
16. Coase, R. 1992. The Institutional Structure of Production, American
Economic Review, vol. 82, no. 4.
Unit-6 Page-334
Bangladesh Open University
17. Deane, P. 1989. The State and the Economic System, Oxford, Oxford
University Press.
18. Elster, J. 1983. Sour Grapes, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press.
19. Evans, P., Rueschemeyer, D. & Skocpol, T. (eds.) 1985. Bringing the
State Back In, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
20. Evans, P. 1995. Embedded Autonomy - States and Industrial
Transformation, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
21. Freeman, C. 1989. New Technology and Catching-up, European
Journal of DevelopmentResearch, vol. 1, no. 1.
22. Friedman, M. 1962. Capitalism and Freedom, Chicago and London,
The University of Chicago Press.
23. Gamble, A. 1988. The Free Economy and the Strong State: The
Politics of Thatcherism, London and Basingstoke, Macmillan.
24. Hall, P. (ed.) 1989. The Political Power of Economic Ideas:
Keynesianism across Nations, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
25. Hayek, F. 1949.Individualism and Economic Order, London,
Routledge & Kegan Paul.Hirschman, A. 1958. The Strategy of
Economic Development, New Haven, Yale University Press
26. Hirschman, A. 1982a. Rival Views of Market Society, Journal of
Economic Literature, vol. 48, no. 4.
27. Hirschman, A. 1982b. Shifting Involvements, Princeton, Princeton
University Press.
28. Johnson, C. 1982. MITI and the Japanese Miracle, Stanford,
Stanford University Press.
29. King, D. 1987. The New Right: Politics, Markets and Citizenship,
London and Basingstoke, Macmillan.
30. Kozul-Wright, R. 1995. The Myth of Anglo-Saxon Capitalism:
Reconstructing the History of the American State, in H-J. Chang &
R. Rowthorn (eds.), Role of the State in Economic Change, Oxford,
Oxford University Press.
31. Krueger, A. 1990. Government Failure in Economic Development,
Journal of Economic Perspective, vol. 4, no. 3.
32. Lavoie, D. 1985. Rivalry and Central Planning, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press.
33. Lazonick, W. 1991. Business Organisation and the Myth of the
Market Economy, NewYork, Cambridge University Press.
34. Lucas, R. 1990. Review of Trade Policy and Market Structure by E.
Helpman & P.Krugman (1989, Cambridge, Massachusetts, MIT
Press), Journal of Political Economy, vol. 98, no. 3.
35. Marglin, S. & Schor, J. (eds.) 1990. The Golden Age of Capitalism,
Oxford, Clarendon Press.
Unit-6 Page-336
Bangladesh Open University
Review Questions
1. “The state is no more assumed to be an impartial, omnipotent social
guardian and is now analysed either as a “predator” or as a vehicle
for politically powerful groups,” – place your own observation on the
statement.
2. Do you agree with the statement that “the Neo-Liberal doctrine is in
fact a very heterogeneous and internally inconsistent intellectual
edifice?”
3. What is a free Market? How do we measure state intervention and
Why does It Matter?
4. What does market failure mean and how much does it matter?
5. “Can we rid the market of politics?” – analyse.
6. Do you agree with view that “all prices are political"?
7. Write a criticism of “institutionalist political economy.”
Introduction
The idea of 'civil society' has achieved prominence in political and
developmental discourse over the past two decades. Civil society,
particularly by the development partners, has been widely seen as an
increasingly crucial agent for limiting authoritarian government,
strengthening popular empowerment, reducing the socially atomizing
and unsettling effects of market forces, enforcing political accountability,
and improving the quality and inclusiveness of governance. With the
end of the Cold War and the ideological rationale for aid, donor
enthusiasm for civil society has been reflected in a growing number of
programmes and projects aimed both at creating and strengthening an
intermediary stratum of non-governmental organisations and in fostering
partnerships between such organisations, government and business.
Whilst the market seemed to hold its sway, the concept of civil society
began to enter academic discourse to conceptualise effective challenges
to oppressive state systems.
Definitions of 'civil society' are diverse and often rooted in alternative
social and political philosophies. The recent conception of civil society
can be traced to that of an intermediate associational realm situated
between the state on the one side and the basic building blocks of society
on the other (individuals, families and firms). The contribution of civil
society to good governance may has been summarised in Manor (1998) 7
under four headings: public policy and decision making; enhancing state
performance; transparency and information; and social justice and the
rule of law.
Public Policy and Decision Making: Civil society organizations can play
a role in mobilizing particular constituencies to participate more fully in
politics and public affairs. Wealthy and socially dominant groups are
better able to organize themselves by virtue of superior resources while
poor and socially disadvantaged groups -- marginal peasants,
7
The section draws on Manor, James, “Civil Society and Governance: A Concept Paper,”
presented as the basis for a research project on civil society and governance, funded by the Ford
Foundation, and coordinated by and held at the Institute of Development Studies, University of
Sussex, England, June 1998.
Unit-6 Page-338
Bangladesh Open University
8
The section draws on Manor, James, “Civil Society and Governance: A Concept Paper,”
presented as the basis for a research project on civil society and governance, funded by the Ford
Foundation, and coordinated by and held at the Institute of Development Studies, University of
Sussex, England, June 1998.
9
Sobhan, R “Building a Responsible Civil Society: Challenges and Prospects,” in Rounaq Jahan
(ed) Bangladesh: Promise and Performance, Dhaka: University Press Limited, 2000. The essay is
reproduced with the permission of the author and editor.
10
The present introduction is an excerpt of Rounaq Jahan, “Introduction: Bangladesh: Promise and
Performance,” in Rounaq Jahan (ed) Bangladesh: Promise and Performance, Dhaka: University
Press Limited, 2000.
Unit-6 Page-340
Bangladesh Open University
Democracy
Bangladesh’s political assets
Every major political event in the history of Bangladesh over the last 60
years originated in a process of democratic mobilisation. The liberation
of Bangladesh and the more recent overthrow of the Ershad autocracy
were sustained by such a process. There was therefore every expectation
that the Bangladesh polity would be grounded in a working democracy
underwritten by the hunger for democracy of its citizens. Today few
people would have reason to feel optimistic about the state of democratic
governance in Bangladesh. After a decade of democratic renewal in the
1990s which succeeded 16 years of cantonment raj our politics is
becoming increasing dysfunctional. The very institutions of democracy,
elections, parliament, political parties show signs of degeneration in their
practises. The culture of intolerance which permeates our polity holds the
nation hostage to a confrontational style of politics which is gradually
making the democratic process unworkable.
Ironically this process of confrontational politics originates in what
should have been the most positive asset for sustaining a democratic
system in Bangladesh. Since 1991 Bangladesh has witnessed the
consolidation of a viable two party system. This system is anchored by
the Awami League elected to power in 1996 and the Bangladesh
Nationalist Party (BNP) which was elected to office in 1991 and held
office till 1996. Each party operates with a national support base and
retains a credible prospect of capturing state power through the electoral
process. The amendment to our constitution in 1996 has institutionalised
the preconditions for holding such free and fair elections under a non-
partisan, caretaker government which leaves the two parties with equal
opportunities to solicit the support of the voters. During the election
campaigns of 1991 and 1996 it was difficult to predict which party would
capture state power. The two elections were recognised to be more free
and fair than any election in the last 50 years and was seen by outside
observers to compare favourably with elections in our neighbouring
countries.
Bangladesh’s two party system should have minimised the scope for
political instability in contrast to India, Pakistan, Nepal, even some of
our South East Asian neighbours. Most of our neighbours either have to
cope with the uncertainties associated with a multiplicity of parties
sharing state power or remain exposed to the authoritarianism associated
with a single party dominated polity. As we read in the papers of ethnic
and communal conflicts in India, Pakistan, Sri Lanka, Mynmar,
Indonesia or Philippines, Bangladeshis can better appreciate our political
good fortune in inheriting a relatively homogenous language and culture
which has minimised the scope for identity politics. Whilst we have a
large religious minority and a small ethnic minority of tribal people, the
unifying legacy of the liberation war and the original commitment to
secularism ensured that religious vote banks would not emerge as a
factor in national politics. However, the constitutional assault on
secularism as well as the failure to recognise the legitimate rights of
tribal minorities marked a departure from the secular premise of
Bangladesh’s national politics. The subsequent reinduction of overtly
communal forces into national politics revived the tendency of some
parties to project fundamentalist ideas into the national political
discourse.
This erosion of Bangladesh’s secular tradition has contributed to the
suppression of minority identities and diminished opportunities for their
political participation. The 1997 Peace Agreement with the Jumma or
hill people of the Chittagong Hill Tracts (CHT) could have emerged as a
move to reaffirm Bangladesh’s non-communal tradition. But the treaty
has been used as a vehicle by opposition political parties to activate
communal forces in the polity by focussing on the communal divide
between tribals and Bangali settlers in the CHT. This intrusion of
communalism could open up fissures in our political landscape which
Unit-6 Page-342
Bangladesh Open University
Unit-6 Page-344
Bangladesh Open University
Unit-6 Page-346
Bangladesh Open University
Nationalism
Coping with globalisation
In this day and age of globalisation an exclusively national agenda is no
longer meaningful. Whether we like it or not Bangladesh will have to
participate in the process of globalisation and will have to interact more
closely with our neighbours in order to better equip ourselves to cope
with this process. Bangladesh, over the last two decades has already been
exposed to a process of external dependence because of the dominant
role of aid donors in underwriting our development finance and
influencing our policy agendas. Donors are, today, much more assertive
as a price for committing their aid to Bangladesh. Not only have donors
sought to use aid conditionality so as to impose policy reforms on
Bangladesh but they are now becoming more exigent in their demands
for better governance. This tendency of the donors to intrude from the
economic to the political domain in their attempt to influence
Bangladesh’s policy agendas indicates that two decades of donor driven
policy reform have yielded only modest returns.
In contrast to the increasing trend by donors to influence both policy and
governance the share of aid as a resource for development has declined
from around 10% of GDP in the early 1980s to 2 or 3% at the end of this
century. This decline in aid dependence in Bangladesh reflects both an
improved capacity for domestic resource mobilisaiton as well as an
expansion in our export earnings over the last decade. At the same time
the 1990s witnessed an absolute stagnation and decline in the share of aid
resources in total pubic expenditure. The tendency for donors to seek to
influence our national policy agendas appears to have risen inversely to
their contribution to our public finances, as a result their ability to
exercise leverage over our public finances today compared to a decade
ago has also weakened. The emerging policy vacuum in Bangladesh has
not been readily filled by the government of Bangladesh who still look to
our aid donors to set the policy agenda.
This decline in the importance of aid in Bangladesh is part of a changing
global scenario where donors are limiting their aid commitments and
countries such as Bangladesh are being propelled by their donors to seek
foreign direct investment (FDI). In this process Bangladesh is being
asked to use FDI to underwrite the development of its infrastructure in
areas where aid was once the dominant source of finance. Investment in
energy development, power, telecommunications, even highways and
bridges, once the core of the aid programme, are today viewed by donors
as part of the domain of FDI. Over the decade of the 90’s neither the
World Bank nor the Asian Development Bank committed any loans for
expansion or even upgradation of Bangladesh’s public sector power
generation facilities. Any funds on offer in this area by these agencies is
to be used as risk guarantee funds for prospective private power
producers. Bangladesh, therefore, has to not only make itself receptive
to donor advice but to make itself attractive to prospective private
foreign investors. In contrast to aid where access originates in the
specific relationship of Bangladesh with its aid donors, to attract FDI
Unit-6 Page-348
Bangladesh Open University
Unit-6 Page-350
Bangladesh Open University
Unit-6 Page-352
Bangladesh Open University
Unit-6 Page-354
Bangladesh Open University
Bangladesh thus needs a system of quality care for the deprived which
builds upon the comparative successes of the immunisation and family
planning programme. Such a system needs to ensure the effective
implementation of the new health care policy based on community
participation, prioritisation of preventative care and improved
governance of the system of curative care. This requires bigger
investments in public health as well as effective management.
The test of the new system at the village level will be measured by
whether the poor in rural Bangladesh are kept waiting long hours by the
doctor, can expect to be treated with respect in the local primary health
care centre, are not made to pay rents for realising health services; if
admitted to a upazilla hospital such patients should expect to sleep on
clean sheets, eat decent food and use clean toilets.
An upgraded health care system needs to be backed up by a system of
health insurance which provides both security and choice for the entire
population in Bangladesh. The development of a contributory health care
system based on insurance will serve to provide some stake to the users
in the operation of the system whilst reducing the fiscal claims on the
public exchequer. The insurance system pioneered by Gono Shasto
Kendro and other such insurance systems may be studied with a view to
designing a national system.
Unit-6 Page-356
Bangladesh Open University
External relations
In building a sustainable domestic order our leaders will have to also
build a workable pattern of relations with our neighbours through the
framework of SAARC. Both geography and history have linked
Bangladesh’s prosperity and security to the nature of its relations with its
neighbours. Bangladesh’s future agricultural development, depends in
considerable measure on the enhancement of water resources inputs and
in its capacity to cope with floods. This degree of water security can, in
the long run, only be realised through cooperation with India and Nepal
from where our principal rivers originate. Our energy needs will also
demand an integrated solution which links the energy production
capacity of Bangladesh with its immediate neighbours and even beyond
to the energy resources of West and Central Asia through a shared
distribution network. Furthermore, Bangladesh’s transport system will
need to be integrated not just with our South Asia neighbours but with
South East Asia and China through the Asian Highway and Railway
network. In order to enhance and develop Bangladesh’s production
potential we will need to have access to the wider South Asian market
particularly to India, through the mechanism of the South Asian Free
Trade Area (SAFTA). At the same time we will have to equip ourselves
to cope with the gradual integration of our economy into a South Asian
economic community.
Bangladesh’s principal external policy challenge will therefore be to
develop our relations with our neighbours, particularly India, into an area
of opportunity rather than conflict, on the basis of mutual self interest.
Such an agenda will be immeasurabily facilitated by a dynamic well-
Conclusion
Building upon our assets
This paper is designed to demonstrate that Bangladesh does indeed
command the potential to build a sustainable development process and
democratic order for the 21st century. In identifying possibilities for the
new millennium the approach was to focus on the art of the possible.
Thus in each area of discussion I have attempted to anchor the
opportunities for change on assets or initiatives already in place to which
some value addition was deemed possible. The prospects for the
consolidation of democratic and secular politics derive from the
objective reality of a two-party system located in a relatively
homogenous society. Scope for a reassertion of nationalism derive from
our visible strengths in export growth and domestic resource
mobilization which have contributed to the decline in aid dependence.
The new opportunities offered by the globalization process, are likely to
sustain our export growth. The quest for social justice is grounded in the
positive gains registered in micro-credit, widening of educational
opportunities, the successes of the immunization as well as the family
planning programs but above all in the resilience, industry and enterprise
of the common people of Bangladesh. The visible production potential as
well as credit worthiness of the deprived, the contribution of rural
women to the dynamism of the RMG sector and the emergence of a
number of globally recognized institutions targeting the deprived
demonstrates both institutional commitment as well as capacity to
mobilise these constituencies of the underprivileged.
In seeking to build our future upon our revealed capacities and
experience we need to take account of the possibility that such gains can
also be undone mostly on account of Bangladesh’s dysfunctional
political processes, persistent malgovernance and increasingly unjust
social order. The prevailing political practises appear to emphasise
private and party needs over the public interest, as a result the machinery
of state is becoming increasingly anarchic and predatory. The
progressive degeneration in the social commitment of the state has led to
a configuration of social power which has elevated a small, affluent elite
into positions of political influence which has empowered them to
monopolise resources and remain immune from both the laws of the land
as well as of the market.
Unit-6 Page-358
Bangladesh Open University
Unit-6 Page-360
Bangladesh Open University
Unit-6 Page-362
Bangladesh Open University
This paper has argued that the new millennium holds out enormous
promise for Bangladesh. But to realise this promise will demand
structural adjustment not just for the economy but in our politics and
society. Such a process of structural change is beyond the capacity of any
donor and will have to be an indigenous exercise. In seeking such
political change civil society will have to play a much more active role
than before and will have to move beyond social issues to address
political concerns. In playing a more pro-active role in the polity civil
society will have to increasingly demonstrate its commitment to
prioritise societal over personal concerns. Over the years Bangladesh has
paid a heavy price for the privatisation of our sense of public purpose. If
Bangladesh is to establish itself as a dynamic and just nation state in the
next decade a restoration of a sense of public purpose within civil society
remains indispensable.
Review Questions
Unit-6 Page-364