Rethinking Regulation
Rethinking Regulation
Rethinking Regulation
A more inclusive economy depends on an inclusive political process. Regulatory agencies are central institutions in
economic policymaking, yet regulators remain vulnerable to undue political influence from established business
and industry interests. How then can we reinvent regulation to be more accountable and responsive to the public at
large? This white paper provides a progressive framework for addressing the problem of regulatory reform. The
paper argues that instead of seeking to undo regulations or further insulate regulators, we must instead pursue
reforms that expand participation and representation for a more inclusive set of stakeholders within the regulatory
process itself.
The paper begins with a brief history of different attempts at reforms to ensure regulation serves the public
interest, from the New Deals faith in expertise to the rise of procedural statutory requirements for regulation to
the attempts by both left and right to respond to the charges of capture in the later 20th century. The paper then
highlights two particular episodes of democratizing reform efforts: the War on Poverty in the 1960s and 1970s, and
more recent innovations in participatory governance in the U.S. and internationally. These episodes suggest some
ways in which governance can harness democratic participation and representation to improve accountability and
responsiveness.
The paper then offers specific policy recommendations for reinventing progressive regulation by incorporating
these democratizing strategies. In particular, the paper calls for reforms that: (1) institutionalize stakeholder
representation within regulatory agencies; (2) empower grassroots citizens to drive monitoring and enforcement
of rules; (3) update the procedural and presidential oversight requirements for agencies to enable greater
participation; and (4) expand and rethink the staffing, resources, and structure of agencies to facilitate
participation.
Introduction
Contemporary economic policy has failed to address the pervasive and growing crises of inequality,
underemployment, and declining opportunity that have been escalating in recent decades. Recent research
highlights that economic inequality is not a product of natural market forces, but of deeper structural disparities
in political power and voice. As a result, policies themselves are skewed, structuring markets in ways that produce
severe economic imbalances. As the political clout of business and economic elites increases, economic policies tilt
in their favor, to the detriment of ordinary Americans.1 A more inclusive economy therefore depends to a great
degree on a more inclusive political process. Nowhere is this basic mechanism of disempowermentor the need for
greater political accountability and responsivenessmore apparent than in the day-to-day functioning of the
modern regulatory state.
Regulatory institutionsfrom the SEC to the Federal Reserve to the EPAbear the primary responsibility for
actually drafting and implementing most public policy. Regulatory agencies are charged with the granular work of
CO P YR IG HT 20 1 6 B Y T H E R O O SE V E LT IN ST IT U TE . A LL R IG HT S R E SE R V E D.
making markets function, setting and enforcing the basic rules of the game on everything from insider trading and
financial regulation to labor and environmental standards. This responsibility is magnified in an era where,
whether owing to political gridlock or posturing, legislatures increasingly tend to produce broadly framed statutes
(if they pass a bill at all), leaving regulators to fill in many of the details of actual policy.
But just as legislative policy tends to favor the interests of economic and business elites, so too are regulatory
agencies prone to such special-interest capture. Big finance has been extraordinarily successful in using the
regulatory process to water down the impact of Dodd-Frank financial reform. The same story can be seen in labor
regulation, environmental regulation, and elsewhere.2 This kind of industry and elite influence sometimes
operates as a direct function of greater organization and political pressure on the part of business and elite
interests. But more subtle mechanisms are at work in this skewed regulatory regime as well. As policymakers share
social and economic backgrounds with economic elites to a greater degree, their own assessments of economic
conditions and policies become skewed away from working-class and middle-class interests.3 Policymakers
increasing reliance on industry members for data, information, and cooperation in devising policies creates
another vulnerability exploitable by sophisticated interest groups.4
These disparities in political power skew public policy in ways that further marginalize racial minorities, women,
and poorer citizens. This problem of capturethe ability of particular interest groups to skew public policy in
their favorhas been a long running concern for critics of the modern regulatory state. But where conventionally
the charge of capture has been used to motivate calls for deregulation by conservatives, or efforts to further
insulate regulatory experts from outside influence by liberals, this paper suggests a different response. Regulatory
capture and elite influence can be counteracted by reforms that expand the countervailing power of communities
to advocate for their views, bringing it to a level closer to that of more established and sophisticated interest
groups.
Achieving a more equitable economy therefore requires that we also reinvent the institutions charged with the
day-to-day task of writing, enforcing, and revising regulations. Just as we seek political equality in elections,
campaign finance, and legislatures, so too must we develop mechanisms to achieve a more equitable and inclusive
political process within the regulatory state. Conventionally, we might think about regulation as a top-down,
expert-driven process insulated from ordinary democratic politics. But instead, regulation might offer a process
through which affected constituencies can gain a greater sayand in so doing, help push the substance of
regulatory policy in more equality-promoting directions.
Regulatory reform offers an opportunity to do more than merely mitigate pathologies of capture and specialinterest influence. Done right, the regulatory process can be transformed into a dynamic, constructive arena that
actually expands democratic participation and inclusion. By institutionalizing stakeholder representation and
countervailing power, the regulatory process can be a major force for addressing disparities in political power and
promoting democratic participation and inclusion, thereby helping drive more equitable economic policies.
This white paper provides a brief history of attempts to ensure regulation serves the public interest (Part I),
addresses the ways that the experience of the War on Poverty and recent experiments in participatory governance
might inform regulatory reform today (Part II), and offers some policy recommendations for democratizing
CO P YR IG HT 20 1 6 B Y T H E R O O SE V E LT IN ST IT U TE . A LL R IG HT S R E SE R V E D.
CO P YR IG HT 20 1 6 B Y T H E R O O SE V E LT IN ST IT U TE . A LL R IG HT S R E SE R V E D.
CO P YR IG HT 20 1 6 B Y T H E R O O SE V E LT IN ST IT U TE . A LL R IG HT S R E SE R V E D.
claimed, regulation should instead take the form of permissive partnerships with private industry, allowing for
greater self-regulation.
This trajectory shapes contemporary discussions of regulatory reform. On the one hand, the specter of this
deregulatory critique looms large: the fear that agencies are too ineffectual, too prone to capture. On the other
hand, prior efforts to bind agencies to the public good, whether through increasingly convoluted and lengthy
procedures or through greater interest representation, have had mixed results. The challengeand opportunity
for regulatory reform today is to develop an alternative model of regulation that creates more room for genuine
democratic inclusion and participation, and in so doing can help drive a more equitable policy agenda.
CO P YR IG HT 20 1 6 B Y T H E R O O SE V E LT IN ST IT U TE . A LL R IG HT S R E SE R V E D.
How can we institutionalize this idea of democratic regulationof institutionalizing countervailing power within
the regulatory state? We can find some clues for future reform in the history of the War on Poverty, and in more
recent global experiences in participatory governance.
Democratic regulation 1.0: The experience of the War on Poverty Community Action
Program
Though often dismissed as a failure, this participatory strategy in the War on Poverty actually created some very
real avenues for empowering African-Americans, the urban poor, and other stakeholder groups, in turn enabling
the accountability of economic and political elites (albeit briefly). Understanding the exact lessons learned from
the War on Poverty can help us pioneer a more modern, and ultimately effective, strategy of participatory
regulation.10
While the bulk of the 1964 Economic Opportunity Act (EOA) focused on new entitlement programs for job
training, work-study, and access to legal services, the real radical innovation in the War on Poverty was its
commitment to grassroots participation as a way to mobilize community leaders to hold the bureaucracy itself
accountable to its poverty-reduction mandate. Formally, the EOA created community action programs, providing
funding for community groups to become mobilized in two main ways: first by creating local boards consisting of
local government officials and representatives from business, local community groups, and minority and lowincome stakeholders; and second, by involving community organizations in the implementing and service-delivery
aspects of operating poverty-reduction programs such as training centers and legal services clinics.
This approach of maximum feasible participation was rooted in a conviction that poverty was itself a matter of
political disempowerment, not just of insufficient income, and that therefore the only way to combat poverty was
to empower poor people with direct voice in the shaping, governing, and implementing of poverty programs. Only
through such direct empowerment could the poor hold the bureaucracy accountableand redress the traditional
disparities of political influence in local government.
In many ways this political strategy for reducing poverty proved effective. By creating institutionalized sources of
political power and leverage, the community action approach inspired many local community organizations to
channel funds toward expanding membership, providing services, and mobilizing constituencies as a political force
in defense of poverty-reducing policies. Even where local groups were denied representation on community action
boards by local elites, the institutional commitment to representation created a potent foundation for exerting
political pressure on policymakers.11
In some programs, these institutionalized avenues for direct participation dramatically changed the dynamics of
the policies themselves, making them more effective at promoting economic equity. The Community
Reinvestment Act (CRA) of 1977 offers a compelling example. Primarily focused on reducing lender discrimination
against minority borrowers, the CRA owed much of its success to an enforcement regime that borrowed from the
experience of community action. Under the CRA, federal agencies examine financial institutions on the basis of
their success in meeting local and minority credit needs. These rankings, in addition to public comments on the
CRA activities of these firms, were then considered when financial regulatory agencies examined merger
CO P YR IG HT 20 1 6 B Y T H E R O O SE V E LT IN ST IT U TE . A LL R IG HT S R E SE R V E D.
applications and requests by these firms to open and close new branches. A critical component of this review
process involved community members themselves: Local groups could ask to review a firms CRA records,
comment on its CRA activities, and file challenges requesting federal inspections for firms that failed to meet
community credit needs. Because firms needed a good CRA score in order to get regulatory approvals for mergers,
these community challenges were surprisingly powerful in incentivizing firms to respond.
The evidence suggests that banks have, as a result of the CRA, changed their behavior, forming multibank
Community Development Corporations, investing in locally based Community Development Financial
Institutions, and dedicating special units to focus on meeting the needs of local low- and moderate-income
borrowers within the geographic area of the bank orders or branch. This economic impact is partly the result of
increased participation in enforcing the CRA mandate. The CRA bolstered local community involvement both by
incentivizing banks to lend to local businesses, and by empowering community-based organizations as local
brokers who could match worthy borrowers with willing banks. In a number of cities, the CRAs provision allowing
community groups to invoke federal regulatory involvement helped catalyze a broader effort among community
organizations to organize and expand their engagement with local banks. The background threat of federal
regulatory enforcement incentivized banks themselves to engage with these community groups and negotiate for
mutually agreeable community lending programs.
The failures of the War on Poverty Community Action Program are rooted in political conflict over the very goals of
participation and community action in the first place. As community action programs catalyzed the mobilization of
grassroots constituencies to advocate for more accountable and equitable economic policies, the backlash from
local power elitesfrom the political establishment to business interestsled to systematic efforts to defund and
dismantle community action.12 Ultimately, the problem was a lack of alignment over the importance of community
action itself. Federal officials saw participation as a more surface-level strategy to generate cooperation and
consensus among stakeholders, whereas the civil rights and welfare rights movements saw it as a mechanism for
reclaiming greater political power over economic policymaking. State and local governments, meanwhile, saw the
directive for formal representation of the poor as a categorical threat to their own authority and control of
patronage networks.13 Even the founders of the program in the Johnson administration often operated under
vastly different motivations and visions for how significantly the program should invest in poor peoples political
power, as opposed to merely providing welfare services.14 As a result of these tensions, while more than 1,600
community action boards were established by 1968, covering two-thirds of the nations counties, by 1974 most of
the funding for the most active programs had been withdrawn, with new restraints from Congress and the
dismantling of the Office of Economic Opportunity, the federal office charged with creating and coordinating
community action across the country.15
The War on Poverty thus suggests some important elements for how to harness the potential of democratic
participation as a form of countervailing power to hold regulators accountable to a wider range of stakeholders and
to help drive more equitable economic policies. First, there is a value to creating institutionalized forms of
representation for the poor, minorities, and other underrepresented interests. Second, where civil society actors
can play a constructive role, for example in monitoring and enforcing standards, they can be a part of making
regulation both more accountable and more efficacious.
CO P YR IG HT 20 1 6 B Y T H E R O O SE V E LT IN ST IT U TE . A LL R IG HT S R E SE R V E D.
Indeed, this strategy of leveraging community participation in monitoring the degree to which regulators and
businesses alike follow and enforce existing standards has become a more widespread tool for empowering
communities and holding policymakers accountable in a variety of contexts. The global community and advocacy
group Slumdwellers International, for example, uses such participatory monitoring and audits as critical
mobilization and advocacy tools, empowering urban slum communities to monitor public officials, track progress
on promises for addressing basic infrastructure needs, and assert property rights of slumdwellers who would
otherwise be uprooted to make room for urban development projects.16 In the U.S. context, similar participatory
monitoring strategies are being employed to track developer and city commitments to local hire and community
development promises around large-scale urban redevelopment projects.17
The critical challenge for these models to work, however, is to secure the buy-in and cooperation both from
government officials and from community groups. As the War on Povertys failure indicates, where officials
themselves reject the core premise of participation, it is difficult to sustain these procedures. Similarly, where
communities are not organized and mobilized through advocacy and membership-based organizations, there is no
countervailing voice that can exert this kind of pressure and credibly claim to speak on behalf of these communities
when policies are made.
CO P YR IG HT 20 1 6 B Y T H E R O O SE V E LT IN ST IT U TE . A LL R IG HT S R E SE R V E D.
and then vote for representatives to the budgeting committee. The policy committees recommendations are then
sent back to the residents of the district for approval by referendum.20
Both of these approaches are increasingly being used in the United States. Groups such as the Participatory
Budgeting Project are working with governments and local stakeholders to implement participatory budgeting in
cities across the country. Local governments from New York to Chicago have started to use participatory budgeting
to allocate discretionary funds at the ward or city council level. Other cities are starting to use participatory
budgeting more directly to decide core budgetary issues.21 Similarly, micropublics are becoming a more common
strategy for policymakers to engage stakeholders in the early stages of policymaking. In a model similar to that of
other regulatory agencies, the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau convenes stakeholders through its online
RegulationRoom platform to help formulate focus areas for future regulations and to source ideas for how to help
key constituencies.22
These participatory processes share a common focus on engaging citizens in solving concrete problemsfor
example, the crafting of a budget, or the formulation of a particular policy issueoften in areas with which the
participants themselves have direct experience and interest. In formulating responses to these problems,
participants work in tandem with experts and decision-makers, who can offer advice and relevant information.23
The principle is that for participatory governance to work well, participants must (1) be empowered to make actual
decisions; (2) be situated alongside other stakeholders and policy experts to highlight a wider range of issues and
implications; and (3) be placed in a curated and structured context and process that facilitate deliberation and
concrete policy judgments.
CO P YR IG HT 20 1 6 B Y T H E R O O SE V E LT IN ST IT U TE . A LL R IG HT S R E SE R V E D.
10
1
government bodies that address important policy issues. Such an approach could consist of four elements.
CO P YR IG HT 20 1 6 B Y T H E R O O SE V E LT IN ST IT U TE . A LL R IG HT S R E SE R V E D.
11
1
as neutral experts, but as representatives of a particular social interest, identifying and channeling its concerns
within the broader ecology of regulatory agencies and the policymaking process. Such an agency could help
underrepresented social groups participate in and put pressure on regulatory policy debates on an equal level with
more sophisticated insider-interest groups.
CO P YR IG HT 20 1 6 B Y T H E R O O SE V E LT IN ST IT U TE . A LL R IG HT S R E SE R V E D.
12
1
guidelines of Executive Orders 12866 (issued by President Clinton) and 13563 (issued by President Obama). An
alternative structure for regulatory review might require more of agencies at the initial policymaking stage in
terms of participatory engagement and consultations, while tasking OIRA with reviewing not just the technocratic
policy analysis but also whether agencies have adequately complied with such participatory requirements.
Executive Order 13563, the latest on Executive branch standards and procedures for regulation, includes language
on the importance of participation in the regulatory process but does not specify either substantive standards for
such participation nor explicit forms of review and monitoring by OIRA. A new Executive Order could, for example,
establish baseline procedures and standards to systematize ad hoc agency practices of citizen participation and
stakeholder consultation by, for example, instituting formal requirements for agencies to convene such forums,
and requiring that these forums be comprised of representatives from specified constituencies.32
IV. Conclusion
These proposals can help make regulation more inclusive and democratic. The imperative to do so is not just
because of the intrinsic value of democratic participation; rather, it is an urgent necessity to address both economic
and political inequality. Regulatory policies are essential to making the economy work in an equitable way. But for
these regulations themselves to serve the public interest, the regulatory process must also be inclusive of all
affected constituencies. Reinventing regulation through greater democratic participation and engagement offers
one way of addressing these structural inequities.
CO P YR IG HT 20 1 6 B Y T H E R O O SE V E LT IN ST IT U TE . A LL R IG HT S R E SE R V E D.
13
1
Endnotes
1
See, e.g., Bartels, Larry, 2010, Unequal Democracy: The Political Economy of the New Gilded Age NJ: Princeton University Press; Hacker, Jacob and Paul
Pierson, 2011, Winner-Take-All Politics: How Washington Made the Rich Richerand Turned Its Back on the Middle Class New York: Simon & Schuster;
Gilens, Martin, 2014, Affluence and Influence: Economic Inequality and Political Power in America NJ: Princeton University Press; Gilens, Martin and
Benjamin Page, 2014, Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Interest Groups, and Average Citizens Perspectives on Politics 12:3.
See, e.g., Carpenter, Daniel and David Moss, eds., 2013, Preventing Regulatory Capture: Special Interest Influence and How to Limit It UK: Cambridge
University Press.
See, e.g., Carnes, Nicholas, 2013, White Collar Government: The Hidden Role of Class in Economic Policy-Making IL: University of Chicago Press.
See, e.g., Kwak, James, Cultural Capture and the Financial Crisis, and McCarty, Nolan, Complexity, Capacity, and Capture, in Carpenter and Moss, eds.,
Preventing Regulatory Capture.
Landis, James. 1938. The Administrative Process. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Brinkley, Alan. 1989. The New Deal and the Idea of the State. Pp. 85-121 in The Rise and Fall of the New Deal Order, 1930-1980, edited by Steve Fraser
and Gary Gerstle. NJ: Princeton University Press.
Stewart, Richard. 1975. The Reformation of American Administrative Law. Harvard Law Review 88:8.
See, e.g., Sunstein, Cass, 2013, The Real World of Cost-Benefit Analysis: Thirty-Six Questions (And Almost As Many Answers), Harvard Public Law Working
Paper 13-11, available online at papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2199112.
See, e.g., Kagan, Elena, 2001, Presidential Administration, Harvard Law Review 114.
10
For several recent analyses of the positive political effects of the War on Poverty and their implications for today, see, e.g., Melish, Tara, 2010, Maximum
Feasible Participation of the Poor: New Governance, New Accountability, and a 21st Century War on the Sources of Poverty, Yale Human Rights and
Development Law Journal 13; Cazenave, Noel, 2007, Impossible Democracy: The Unlikely Success of the War on Poverty Community Action Programs,
Albany, NY: SUNY Press.
11
See, e.g., Orleck, Annelise and Lisa Hazirjian, 2001, The War on Poverty: A New Grassroots History, 1940-1980, Athens, GA: University of Georgia Press.
12
Id.
13
14
See, e.g., Gillette, Michael, 2011, Launching the War on Poverty: An Oral History, UK: Oxford University Press.
15
16
See Xavier de Souza Briggs, 2008, Democracy as Problem Solving: Civic Capacity in Communities Across the Globe, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
17
See, for example, the Oakland Army Base redevelopment agreement and its use of community organizations to monitor compliance with local hiring and
community investment objectives.
18
See generally, Fishkin, James, 2011, When the People Speak: Deliberative Democracy and Public Consultation, UK: Oxford University Press; Goodin, Robert
and John Dryzek, 2006, Deliberative Impacts: The Macro-Political Uptake of Mini-Publics, Politics and Society 34; Goodin, Robert, 2008, Innovating
Democracy: Democratic Theory and Practice After the Deliberative Turn UK: Oxford University Press.
19
20
21
Russon Gillman, Hollie. 2016, Democracy Reinvented: Participatory Budgeting and Civic Innovation in America. Washington, DC: Brookings / Cambridge:
Ash Center for Democratic Governance, Harvard University.
CO P YR IG HT 20 1 6 B Y T H E R O O SE V E LT IN ST IT U TE . A LL R IG HT S R E SE R V E D.
14
1
22
Farina, Cynthia, Hoi Kong, Cheryl Blake, Mary Newhart, and Nik Luka. 2013. Democratic Deliberation in the Wild: The McGill Online Design Studio and the
RegulationRoom Project. Fordham Urban Law Journal 41(5):1527-80
23
Fung, Archon and Erik Olin Wright. 2013. Thinking About Empowered Participatory Governance. Pp. 15-23 in Deepening Democracy: Institutional
Innovations in Empowered Participatory Governance, edited by Fung and Wright. London and New York: Verso.
24
25
Omarova, Saule. 2011. Bankers, Bureaucrats, and Guardians: Toward Tripartism in Financial Services Regulation. Journal of Corporate Law 37(3):621-74
26
See, e.g., Daniel Schwarcz, Preventing Capture Through Consumer Empowerment Programs: Some Evidence from Insurance Regulation, in Carpenter
and Moss, eds., Preventing Capture (examining case studies of how proxy advocacy and tripartism has helped mitigate the risk of capture in state-level
insurance regulation).
27
See, e.g., Dodd-Frank Act 901-911 (to be codified at 15 U.S.C. 78) (creating an Investor Advisory Committee, which is tasked with advising the Financial
Stability Oversight Council (FSOC) on regulatory reforms to protect investors comprised of a mix of representatives of various stakeholder interests,
such as state governments, senior citizens, and pension funds, in addition to relevant expertsincluding an Investor Advocate, who is explicitly
empowered to head an advocacy unit within the network of financial regulatory agencies); Dodd-Frank Act 915 (to be codified at 15 U.S.C. 80b-11
note) (empowering the Investor Advocate to lobby the SEC for policies favorable to investor interests); Dodd-Frank Act 919D (to be codified at 15
U.S.C. 78d) (creating a forum for individual investors to lodge complaints and report lapses in financial regulations); Dodd-Frank Act 973-976 (to be
codified at 15 U.S.C. 78) (establishing a Municipal Securities Rulemaking Board, comprised of experts and representatives of brokers, investors, and
the general public, to set standards for municipal securities advisors).
28
See Mariano-Florentino Cuellar, 2005, Rethinking Regulatory Democracy, Administrative Law Review 57.
29
There are a number of new community organizations that focus on empowering citizens by enabling them to monitor government service delivery for
economic development, post-conflict reconstruction, and natural disaster relief projects. See, e.g., Ushahidi (ushahidi.com) and Development Seed
(developmentseed.org/about). Other groups focus on monitoring of government performance by, for example, enabling citizens to monitor bribery and
corruption. See, e.g., I Paid A Bribe (ipaidabribe.com).
30
31
Id.
32
Bingham, Lisa. 2010. The Next Generation of Administrative Law: Building the Legal Infrastructure for Collaborative Governance. Wisconsin Law Review
350-6 (proposing language for a new executive order).
33
Sabel, Charles, and William Simon. 2011. Minimalism and Experimentalism in the Administrative State. Unpublished manuscript, on file with author, Pp. 2730; also Cuellar, Rethinking Regulatory Democracy 491-97.
CO P YR IG HT 20 1 6 B Y T H E R O O SE V E LT IN ST IT U TE . A LL R IG HT S R E SE R V E D.
15
1