Governance and Institutions
Governance and Institutions
Governance and Institutions
Course
Reform
2016/2023
Introduction of the course
enables the students to know the reform initiatives and reforms taken place in
institution, institutionalism,
state-building, entrepreneurial-state,
market reform.
It also includes:
framework and issues of global institutions (e.g., UN, World Bank, IMF,
etc.)
Citizens links.
carried out in Ethiopia as well as other world (i.e., the science of it) and
One can distinguish a neutral definition of governance from its normative definition,
although these two sometimes overlap. The neutral and broader notion of governance is
Participants of the governance process, in this view, include not only government
(political and administrative) institutions, but also private and societal institutions that
Governance thus connotes the idea that the government is no longer the
issues such as corruption, security, human rights, and the role of formal and
informal institutions.
The emergence of this term reflects the changes in and the dynamics among the means
devolution as well as economic liberalization and the reduction of the role of welfare
state. These changes created new opportunities and incentives, and altered previously
2
ranging from local communities to relationships of global scale, thus affecting the
This distinction between government and governance and the new role of government in
the current context is very important here. Government is the term conventionally used
Governance is used to refer to the changing processes and practices of governing which
the emergence of self- governing networks and the development of new governmental
The previous emphasis on government was also weakened with the realization that more
self- governance through decentralization and participation can enhance efficiency and
industrial democracies under global and domestic pressures from international capital
markets, supranational organizations, the private sector, and strengthened civil society
and that reform need to account for this reality. This, at a minimum, means that
changing economic or political institutions alone will not be sustainable unless public
The narrower and more normative definition of governance is commonly used by major
It refers to what governments should do. For example, the World Bank defined
3
governance as:
The exercise of authority through formal and informal traditions and institutions for
Thus encompassing:
(2) the capacity to formulate and implement sound policies and deliver public services, and
(3) the respect of citizens and the state for the institutions that govern economic and social
The UN Committee of Experts included in governance ―public administration and civil service,
rule of law, human rights, macroeconomic policies and regulatory frameworks and transparent
and participatory decision-making processes. The normative definition overlaps with the term
good governance. Good governance refers to a set of idealized principles and guidelines for
reforms that IDA draw from best practices of the OECD countries‘ experiences and their own
o formal checks and balances, competition within civil service and among other
o rule of law, efficiency and accountability of the public sector, and tackling corruption
o policy making and allocation of resources based on consensus in society that accounts
o democratic accountability, fundamental freedoms, service delivery for all, due process
transparency.
4
The World Banks
Instrument to measure the quality of governance by the following six parameters more or less
government effectiveness,
control of corruption.
From this standpoint the purpose of institutional reforms, which are sometimes called
governance reforms, is to establish the way of governing that follows good governance
principles. Developing countries are advised to reform their institutions to exercise good
governance aligned with these principles and, as a result, secure economic, political, and social
It is important to note here that two major definitions of governance have gained currency in
In the most popular one, used by the World Bank and most other United Nations
leadership—the manner in which political (state) leaders manage, use, or misuse power—
to promote social and economic development or to pursue agendas that undermine such
goals.
rule of law,
accountability,
5
participation,
transparency, and
human and civil rights. These elements are indistinguishable from governance elements
A second approach to defining governance focuses on sharing authority for public management
between state and non-state organizations. Jan Kooimans (1993:2) and other European
actors do not act separately but in conjunction, together, in combination, that is to say, co-
arrangements.
The school therefore views governance as forms of multi-organizational action rather than
exclusively state actions. An important difference from the first approach is that governance
is judged as good or bad by both processes as well as by outcomes: the use of state and non-
This approach is also referred to as the partnership approach to governance. For many others
Governance is approached, as it has always been understood in the political science literature,
as the fundamental rules that regulate the relationships between rulers and the ruled, the
rules-in-use, or constitutive choice rules and operating at deeper levels of analysis than
collective and operational choice rules. The legal community refers to these constitutional
rules as ground-norms.
generic term that can be applied to all forms of human organizations— economic, cultural,
religious, or military.
The advantage of this third approach is that it enables us to suspend judgment on whether or
A process-only approach seems to equate democratic change to good governance. But we know
that governance might actually decline in some important respects under democratization—
especially if the crucial institutions supposed to perform specific functions are weak or
lacking. Process and outcomes are important in this approach, but from a process perspective
6
governance can be classified in terms of the quality of the fundamental rules of the political
game. While democratic governance promotes rules that ensure the fundamental equality
between rulers and the ruled, autocratic forms assume and reify inequality between them.
But the primary criteria for distinguishing between good and bad governance is the outcomes
of policies promoted by public organs. Good governance results from the activities of public
sector institutions as they work with other societal organizations to formulate public policies
and programs, which are implemented to improve the people‘s welfare, reduce poverty, and
B. Governance Indicators
development objective in itself has created demand for indicators to measure the quality of
governance and by one recent estimate there are now some 140 user-accessible sets of
governance indicators, comprising literally thousands of individual indicators. This has in turn
Commonly, these guides distinguish between governance indicators that are constructed from
International investors, donors and decision makers generally tend to rely mainly on
This is partly due to the fact that the data required to construct facts-based indicators are
often lacking for developing countries, and partly because the numbers that exist for those
Furthermore, the data that are used to construct facts- based indicators often only reflect
on formal de jure realities, and not the very different de facto realities on the ground.
A.The European bank for reconstruction and development (EBRD)-World Bank Business
Environment and Enterprise Performance Survey compiles the experiences of more than
10,000 firm managers in 1999 and 2002. The managers were asked to estimate the share of
7
annual sales ‗firms like yours‘ typically pay in unofficial payments to public officials.
B.The International Crime Victim Survey (ICVS) is designed to produce comparable data on
countries. Since 1989, more than 150 surveys have been done in over 80 different countries.
The ICVSs only provide information on the incidence of corruption from a household
perspective.
The most widely used perception-based governance indicators, which cover a large number of
countries, are:
A. The International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) provides ratings for 140 countries based on
financial and economic risk assessments, and assessments of political risk. It also offers one-
year and five-year assessments with projections in best case‘ and worst case‘ scenarios.
B. Freedom House provides annual ratings of political rights and civil liberties in 192 countries.
It rates both a country‘s political rights and its civil liberties on a scale from 1 (best‘) to 7
(lowest‘).
The 2007 index includes 180 countries. The CPI assesses the degree to which public officials
and politicians are believed to accept bribes, take illicit payment in public procurement,
embezzle public funds, and commit similar offences. The index ranks countries on a scale from
corruption-related data from expert and business surveys carried out by a variety of
independent institutions.
D.The Country Policy and Institutions Assessment (CPIA) is produced annually by the World
Bank‘s country teams. The purpose is to assess the quality of the borrowing countries‘ policy
and institutional frameworks for fostering poverty reduction, sustainable growth and
effective use of development assistance. These assessments have been used since 1977 to
8
help guiding the allocation of interest-free loans and grants by the Bank‘s IDA to the poorest
countries.
The Bank‘s country team gives a score of 1 to 6 to a country for each of in total 16 criteria. To
enhance consistency of ratings across countries, the Bank now provides the assessment teams
with detailed questions and definitions for each of the six rating-levels. Moreover, before the
country ratings are finalized, an extensive Bank wide benchmarking and vetting process is used
to avoid bias and to counterbalance the natural tendency of country teams to make their
E.The Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI) produced by the World Bank Institute since
1996 (often referred to as the KKZ Indicators named after their creators). Alongside with
Transparency International‘s CPI, the WGI have played a leading role in putting governance
and corruption on the agenda in developing countries. Due to the large number of sources used
to developing the WGI, the country coverage is very large (212 countries and territories in
2007).
A glance at the literature on institutions and institutional reform reveals the existence of a
variety of definitions given by individual scholars who introduced their own ways of specifying
As mentioned above, economist-historian Douglas North is one of the most influential scholars
in institutional studies across the social sciences. He defined institutions as rules, as opposed
to more commonly used definition that combined both rules and organizations.
9
Ostrom defined institution: as shared concepts used by humans in repetitive situations
In this definition rules mean shared prescriptions (must, must not, or may) that are mutually
Strategies are ―regularized plans that individuals make within the structure of incentives
produced by rules, norms, and expectations of the likely behavior of others in a situation
To date, the prominent sociologist Richard Scotts work (2007) embodies the most
divergent schools and disciplines over time. His synthesis led Scott to propose the following
Institutions are social structures that have attained a high degree of flexibility.
that, together with associated activities and resources, provide stability and meaning to
social life.
Institutions by definition connote stability but are subject to change processes, both
10
Approaches to the Definition of Institutions
At least three types of definitions of institutions have been used in practice and
academia. While institutions are generally understood as the phenomena that structure
organizations‘ role in structuring human behavior. The most commonly used definition
Institutions as Rules/Norms
The rule-centered definition focused on formally and informally enforced rules. It was
advanced by some early institutionalists in sociology, and has been revived since the
early 1990s. For example, Parsons referred to institutions as a system of norms ―that
Institutions are the rules of the game of a society, or, more formally, are the
humanly devised constraints that structure human interactions. They are composed
bodies (political parties, the senate, a city council, a regulatory agency); economic
bodies (firms, trade unions, family farms, cooperatives); social bodies (churches,
training centers)
He defined institutions as formal and informal rules of the game in a society, or more
formally, are the humanly devised constraints that structure human interaction.
11
work North used a metaphor of a game to distinguish institutions from organizations,
by referring to the distinction between rules and players. This definition of institutions
has been widely used in academia, especially among economists united under the New
Institutional Economics (NIE) movement and political scientists in the rational choice
Institutions as Organizations
The organization-centered definition emphasizes the functional fields and human collectivities
within which rules structure human interaction and which enforce those rules. This version was
For example, Sumner defined institutions as a concept (an idea, notion, doctrine, interest)
instrumentalities (a means) through which the concept is translated into action. The structure
here embodies the idea of institution. This definition mostly refers to organizational fields,
and organization as an adaptive organic system (a value). The former becomes institutionalized
when its goals or procedures become infused with values of the members of the organization,
that organizations are organic systems that structure behavior through normative processes.
Even if initially created as mechanistic instruments for certain ends, over time through
adaptation under the influence of characteristics of its members and its environment,
organizations become institutions to the extent that they serve as a source of norms and rules
12
Early institutionalists introduced the broad definition of institutions. It encompasses both
rules/norms and organizations through which those rules are enforced. Among economists, for
example, Commons saw institutions as solutions, mechanisms and rules of conduct generated to
reconcile past conflicts. Specifically, institutions for Commons consisted of a set of rights and
duties, an authority for enforcing them, and some degree of adherence to collective norms in
In sociology, Hughes also identified that the essential elements of institutions as including:
A set of mores (custom) or formal rules, or both, which can be fulfilled only by
(organization).
The first element represents rules and the second organization. Woodrow Wilson, a father of
American public administration, also leaned towards a similar definition emphasizing both legal
To sum up, early institutionalists‘ more encompassing definition of institutions that included
both rules/norms and organizations had been split into two directions in new institutionalism
schools. While both understand institutions to be social phenomena that structure human
interaction, the new institutionalism in economics and political science tends to focus more on
rules and norms which are used by actors (individuals and organizations) to pursue their
contexts that structure behavior of actors. A more encompassing definition that includes both
rules/norms and organizations is commonly used among practitioners who often go back and
what is often called first generation reforms of the 1960‘s, tended to refer to institutions as
organizations (e.g. political parties or specific agencies) or their systems that include
organizational entities as well as the principles of their organization (e.g. bureaucracy). In the
13
institutional reforms borrowed the sociologist Talcott Parsons‘ (1949) definition of
formal organization. The World Bank expert on public sector reforms similarly equated
improving an institutions ability to make effective use of the human and financial resources
available.
Since the early 1990s, the influence of North’s definition on practitioners changed this
and sometimes a combination of both definitions even within the same document. More
recently, donors have been moving towards a broader definition of institutions that
This lack of one definition and understanding of what specifically goes into it added to
the confusion and ambiguity, and also seems to have hindered the synthesis and
different ways.
The sources, consequences, and potential solutions to this definitional ambiguity are
discussed above. For the purposes of this course, institutions refer to rules and
Institutional Reform:
Institutional reform, which is much broader than PAR and PSR, refers to the artificially
or deliberately induced changes in rules and organizations. From this standpoint the purpose of
institutional reforms, which are sometimes called governance reforms, is to establish the way
of governing that follows good governance principles. Developing countries are advised to
reform their institutions to exercise good governance aligned with the principles of good
governance and, as a result, secure economic, political, and social development. As mentioned
above, in this wave of institutional reforms, good governance is treated both as the means and
14
ends of development.
The following are some of the numerous definitions given for the public sector:
the government.
The public sector refers to that part of the economy made up of central
References to the public sector are frequent in economic analysis and policy making.
However, it is not always obvious what it comprises. The concept of the public sector
consists of many different levels which have to be properly identified in order to obtain
15
According to the United Nations, ―general government comprises:
cultural, recreational and other social services, furnished but usually not sold to
the public.
by government.
o Government enterprises that are highly integrated with the public authorities;
supplying goods and services to other units of government, but also include
agencies that sell goods mainly to the public but operate on a small scale.
o Public saving and lending bodies which are financially integrated with the
Total public sector comprises general government plus public enterprises (also called
state- owned enterprises or parastatals), which are bodies that produce goods or
services and sell them to the public, whose ownership or control rests with public
authorities.
Despite the existence of a common definition of the public sector, and of each of the
concepts involved, it is not always clear how fully different countries apply the
definition. Another major problem is that some concepts appear to have different
meanings in different countries, and it is not always made clear exactly what is covered
16
The public sector, therefore, is a part of the state that deals with the production,
delivery and allocation of goods and services by and for the government or its citizens,
with ―government.
It is generally associated with the executive branch at national, central and local levels.
Viewed this way, the public sector is made up mainly of government departments and
agencies that are staffed by public servants. The activities of the public sector range
from delivering security; administering urban planning and organizing national defense
Traditionally, the public sector is concerned with the provision of certain goods and
services that all citizens value – defense, diplomacy, law and order, property rights,
parks, street lighting, public sanitation, pest control, public health, to name a few –
which the private sector, on its own, would either under-provide or not provide at
A public good can be used by one person without reducing the amount available for
others to use. This is known as shared consumption. An example of a public good that
has this characteristic is a spraying or fogging program to kill mosquitoes. The spraying
reduces the number of mosquitoes for all of the people who live in an area, not just for
one person or family. The opposite occurs in the consumption of private goods. When
one person consumes a private good, other people cannot use the product. This is known
as rival consumption. A good example of rival consumption is bread. If someone else eats
The second key characteristic of public goods is called the non-exclusion principle. It is
not possible to prevent people from using a public good, regardless of whether they
have paid for it. For example, a visitor to a town who does not pay taxes in that
17
community will still benefit from the town‘s mosquito-spraying program. With private
goods, like bread, when you pay for the bread, you get to eat it or decide who does.
Someone who does not pay does not get the bread.
Because many people can benefit from the same public goods and share in their
consumption, and because those who do not pay for these goods still get to use them, it
impossible to produce enough in private markets to reach the efficient level of output.
That happens because some people will try to consume the goods without paying for
As a result, the government must usually take over the decision about how much of
these products to produce. In some cases, the government actually produces the good;
in other cases it pays private firms to make these products. The classic example of a
public good is national defense. It is not a rival consumption product, since protecting
one person from an invading army or missile attack does not reduce the amount of
protection provided to others in the country. The non-exclusion principle also applies to
national defense. It is not possible to protect only the people who pay for national
defense while letting bombs or bullets hit those who do not pay. Instead, the
government imposes broad-based taxes to pay for national defense and other public
good.
controversial questions about the economic and social role of the public sector. Opinions
are (and always will be) divided on how active and influential the public sector should be
in a country‘s economic and social life. How much industrial output should be produced
by the public sector? How should the government regulate the private sector? How
should it address economic inequality? How should it pursue a range of issues related to
social justice, environmental protection, etc? The way countries deal with these
questions determines the nature, role, extent and structure of the public sector.
18
Hence, apart from the provision of public goods, consensus is lacking as to the proper
role of the public sector. This makes it difficult to come up with an exhaustive list of
activities to be carried out by the public sector. However, in both developing and
developed countries, the public sector designs and implements policies and programs
that aims to fulfill the government‘s broad economic and social objectives. This includes
The public sector makes and enforces policies that cover virtually everything the
government does. Policies developed by the public sector serve the government of the
Policies are realized through the design and delivery of public programs involving
goals.
Raises Revenue
Government must raise money in order to implement its programs. The public sector collects
taxes and user fees that are levied on citizens and companies. Governments also use tax policy
as a means to pursue social and economic goals. E.g., governments may pursue social goals by
providing tax breaks to certain segments of the population. They may also use tax provisions
Manages Accountability
Citizens demand accountability in return for the powers granted to government to raise and
spend revenue. The public sector responds by enforcing internal accountability measures, and
by reporting to citizens on how money is spent and on the successes (and failures) of public
19
programs. Governments typically create and sustain independent public institutions of
accountability that are empowered to oversee the government‘s actions and demand
explanations. This may include auditor‘s general, public ombudsmen, the judiciary, the
In parliamentary systems, the entire public sector reports ultimately to the head of state,
although its day-to-day operation is normally the responsibility of the head of government. In
presidential systems, the heads of state and government are combined in one office (e.g. the
President of the United States). In other countries, the two positions are distinct, with the
head of state limited to a ceremonial role (e.g. in Canada where the Prime Minister is head of
government and the Governor General is the ceremonial head of state). In still other
countries– France and its former colonies, for example – both the head of state (President)
and head of government (Prime Minister) play substantive political and policy roles.
The head of government governs with the advice of his cabinet, which is made up, for the most
Cabinet has both political and a policy/managerial function. Cabinet is the country‘s most
powerful political institution – a forum where the country‘s top political leaders solve, away
from public scrutiny, matters related to advancing the government‘s political agenda, managing
political opposition, etc. It also serves a more technical, policy/managerial function because
cabinet ministers are also the heads of government departments. Cabinet is therefore a forum
for addressing major policy issues that arise in particular government portfolios.
The public sector is divided into organizational units, each with a particular functional
Broadly, there are two major types of organizational units: central agencies and line
departments. There are also various types of specialized agencies, and state-owned
enterprises. Line departments are specialized around programs and policies that relate to a
particular economic or social sector, e.g. Department of Industry, Department of Health, etc.
20
Each department is headed by a high-ranking political officer – a ―Minister‖ or a ―Secretary‖.
Central agencies are specialized around functions that affect the entire government. For
example, a budget office manages the annual budget-making process; a cabinet office manages
the flow of policy and program proposals from all departments into the cabinet for decision;
the Department of Finance sets budget allocation levels that affect resources available for
Recently there has been an increasing tendency for governments to take certain well-defined
functions out of line departments and place them in specialized agencies. Customs and revenue
agencies are a good example of this trend in the developing world. Specialized agencies often
have greater flexibility to manage their human and financial resources than do line
Specialized agencies may report to the departmental bureaucracy or directly to the Minister.
The organization of the public sector (public ownership) takes several forms, including:
Direct administration funded through taxation; the delivering organization generally has
enterprises"); which differ from direct administration in that they have greater
commercial freedoms and are expected to operate according to commercial criteria, and
production decisions are not generally taken by government (although goals may be set
Partial outsourcing (of the scale many businesses do, e.g. for IT services), is considered
the entire service on behalf of government. This may be considered a mixture of private
sector operations with public ownership of assets, although in some forms the private
21
sector's control and/or risk is so great that the service may no longer be considered
As we have mentioned earlier, the field of development theory and practice, at least in
the post- war years, has been peculiarly susceptible to all manner of fads and fashions
with respect to both the ends and the means of development. Various schools of
thought have come in and come out of favor since the official launching of the project
of development in the post second world war period. Another trend has developed
Beginning in the 1990s, based on the assumption that 'institutions matter,' there has been a
countries. The idea that institutions matter for development is based on the assumption,
developed by Douglass North and other new institutional economists, that institutional
North, the specific institutional constraints dictate the margins at which organizations
operate and hence make intelligible the interplay between the rules of the game and the
behavior of the actors. If organizations – firms, trade unions, farm groups, political parties,
and congressional committees to name a few – devote their efforts to unproductive activity,
the institutional constraints have provided the incentive structure for such activity. Third
World countries are poor because the institutional constraints define a set of advantages to
However, donors‘ ―Institutions Matter‖ Policy that emphasizes public sector reforms is not
new. The Institutions matter policy, which stresses the need to reform government
institutions to build and strengthen their capacity, reemerged as a new idea in donor circles in
the second half of 1990s. Donors have been explicitly or implicitly promoting such institutional
22
reforms in developing countries, with the focus on strengthening public sector institutions, at
least since the emergence of official development assistance at the end of the WWII. In this
regard three waves of institutional reforms, which will be discussed in greater detail in the
Institution building was the main focus of the reforms promoted in developing countries by
donors during the first wave of official development assistance led at that time by the United
States. The 1949 ―Point Four Program of U.S. President Harry Truman called for mobilization
postcolonial countries, launching the major wave of institution building (IB) reforms.
Institutional reform during this time was largely confined to the organizational level changes
concerned with improving the managerial capacity of the administrative system and specific
organizations. But the attempts by experts to help developing countries build government
institutions by modeling them after those of the West did not deliver the expected results.
Disillusioned with such outcomes, donors pushed institutional development to the backseat
between the end of the 1960s and the mid-1990s even when donors moved away from explicit
reliance on institution building and switched their attention to other kinds of inputs to
building of infrastructure projects all have been complemented with technical assistance
Even in the 1980s and early 1990s – referred to as the second wave of donor-promoted
reforms when the most influential donors, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the
World Bank urged recipient countries to downsize their public administration systems, to free
markets from government control and make the latter perform like businesses, institutional
While this wave of reforms was concerned with downsizing public sector institutions,
23
downsizing was not simple elimination, but a complex process that required transformation of
In the late 1990s, institutional reform regained attention in development circles. The current
consensus among donors is that ―high quality institutions enable a better economic and
investment climate, foster better governance and accountability, encourage trust, reinforce
property rights, and avoid the exclusion of sections of the population. The experiences with
failed structural adjustment reforms in many developing and transitioning countries from the
1980s to the 1990s, combined with the new developments in research, among other factors,
made it clear to donors the important role that strong and effective public sector institutions
play in development. Donors realized that externally supplied policy advice and other inputs
In this third wave, donor institutional reform has become even more complex and has a much
as they came to realize that institutions are interdependent and that reforms need to account
for this reality. This means that economic, political, and societal institutions should be changed
along with public administration systems for the reforms to have sustained effect.
Thus, the current wave of institutional reform, sometimes referred to as governance reform –
to ensure that governments, in partnership with NGOs and the private sector, work towards
good governance, economic growth, and poverty reduction. In practice, however, most donors
are cautious of intervening in the political aspects of reforms and believe that economic
development hinges on the quality of the regulatory environment. This puts even more
The concept of administrative reform does not lend itself to a clear-cut definition.
However, the definition, which is commonly used because of its comprehensiveness and
24
scope, is the one offered by Gerald Caiden (1969).
It is usually undertaken to change the status quo for the better. It aims at
that is, injection of new ideas and new people in a new combination of tasks and
A set value with which the existing bureaucratic arrangements, public personnel
The concern by politicians and the general public that the existing bureaucratic
This definition of administrative reform was further modified and expanded by Quah to
include attitudinal aspect, on top of structural one, as: a deliberate attempt to change
25
both
(1) The structure and procedures of the public bureaucracy (i.e., reorganization of the
(2) The attitudes and behavior of the public bureaucrats involved (i.e. the attitudinal
development goals.
structures, personnel, etc.) funded by the state budget and in charge of the
management and direction of the affairs of the executive government, and its
environment.
Public Administration Reform can be very comprehensive and include process changes in
Public administration reform has been traditionally viewed by many donors more as a
organizations, and its political context and dimensions have been downplayed. But, this
administration system is not only a function of how civil service operates; it is also
shaped by economic, social, political, and cultural factors. Indeed, public administration
reforms include not only transformations in civil service, but also reforms of the policy
dynamics in the society. In this last sense, public administration reform could be largely
In the 1980‘s Public Administration reform is gradually being replaced by public sector
While there have been different views and definitions of PSR, many people and
That is why Schacter (2000) defines PSR as the strengthening the way the public
sector is managed‘. The presupposition is that things are not properly managed in the
public sector. So, changes from the old way of doing things must take place.
To this end, there has emerged a deliberate policy as well as action to change
government administrative machinery for performance at optimal level. The overall goal
defects in a system; and as the public sector can be understood to be the key apparatus
for the execution of the functions of the state or government‘, then PSR is the total
effectiveness, efficiency, hard-core competence and financial prudence into the running
of the public sector. This rebranding of the public sector is targeted to meet the
A better understanding of PSR, however, can be achieved if one captures the context
under which PSR came to be seen as panacea for the crises of development in the third
world from 1980s onwards. Specially, mention has to be made to the role played by
27
PSR was initiated against the background that governments required a departure from
the traditional methods of administration and the urgent need for a renewed public
sector to propel government in its quest for sustainable socio-economic, political and
technological development. So, there was a need for structural re-engineering of the
responsiveness and a focused sense of mission for maximum efficiency in the economy.
Based on the above, the main objectives of PSR as far as the IDAs are concerned, are
as follows:
To achieve better delivery of the basic public services that affect living
1997:103).
better meet its societal objectives of good governance as well (Mhone 2003:10).
From the above, we see that PSR aims at institutional restructuring of the public
sector, with the application of principles obtainable in the private sector as a basis for
enhancing the efficiency and effectiveness of public sector institutions. Arising from
this notion of how the public sector should be run and managed is that government is
PSR is carried out with the mindset of seeing government as a profit-making enterprise
rather than in service to the people. In fact, that is why we see African leaders talking
about a bloated civil service, which needs to be downsized, and the uncontrollable craze
to privatize and commercialize all government enterprises. It must be pointed out here
that, PSR is broader than PAR in that it includes not only the reform of the machinery
28
Institutional reforms /Governance reforms or institutional capacity building
reforms/
The overview provided above indicates that there is a fair amount of overlap between
public sector reform, governance reform, and capacity building. The overview also shows
that these terms are also used liberally by different stakeholders to refer to a wide
range of phenomena. Still, different donors prefer using different terms. The United
etc.) funded by the state budget and in charge of the management and direction of the
affairs of the executive government, and its interaction with other stakeholders in the
state, society and external environment and. OECD prefers to focus on capacity
development. The World Bank uses public sector reform and governance reform to
refer to reforms involving the transformation of all institutions of governance. For the
World Bank, the focus of contemporary institutional reform is not a single institution,
Public administration reform is seen as central to, and the entry point for,
transforming the whole governance system. Public administrative reform is seen as the
pillar of the current development agenda and to the evolving and all-encompassing
growth are slim without public goods provided by government, such as infrastructure,
basic educational institutions, and law and order. The government is expected to secure
and maintain a favorable policy and institutional environment for other players and
assumption underlying current public administration reforms is that the latter would
In donor literature institutions and institutional reforms mostly refer to public sector
29
institutions and reforms of public sector institutions, even though the term institutions
by definition are not confined public sector alone. The opposite is also true: Although
Whatever the name donors and researchers use, the focus of institutions and public
the term institutions by definition are not confined public sector alone from now on
we use the terms institutional reforms and public sector reforms to refer to these
governance process and system. Hereafter, institutional reforms will primarily refer
30
UNIT TWO
Unit Introduction
Welcome to the second unit of the course Governance and Institutional Reforms.
The focus in this unit, therefore, is to enable you understand the nature and
significance of this waves of reforms with special emphasis on the policy context
and the influential schools of thought in each wave. This unit reviews the
theoretical knowledge and ideas that informed these waves of reforms, what
specific reforms were implanted, how the reforms evolved and were carried out,
and what lessons were learned by placing all this in the policy context of the time.
Accordingly, the unit is divided in to three broad sections. In the first section,
we will discuss the first wave which was largely confined to the organizational
devoted to the second wave or what is often called the era of market
Unit Objectives
Explain the policy context and the influential schools of thoughts that
Identify and appreciate the content and approaches to the reforms in each phase
Evaluate the difference and similarity between the three waves of reforms
Identify and explain the dominant actors in each of the three phases and
31
Section One: The First Wave (1950s-1960s): Modernization of
Administrative Institutions
Section Overview
was launched with Truman‘s 1949 inaugural speech in which he presented his Point 4
Program modeled after the Marshall Plan. This section reviews the theoretical
knowledge and ideas that informed these reforms, how the reforms evolved and were
carried out, and what lessons were learned by placing all this in the policy context of
this time.
Section Objectives
Dear distance learner, by the end of this section you should be able to:
o Identify and explain the main themes and approaches to the first wave of
reform
o Identify and explain the policy context and the influential school of thought in
this wave
A. Policy Context
During this wave of reforms, the United States emerged as the leading nation
shaping development reforms in the developing world. The United States Agency
for International Development (USAID) and the Ford Foundation were the key
period.
The design and approach to the reforms promoted in developing countries through
development assistance projects in this decade closely followed the popular ideas
about development and governance in the United States, thus shaping international
32
development policy at that time.
In this era, development was associated with improved social and economic
effects of the Great Depression in the United States in the 1930s, in managing
the war economy of the 1940s, and helping to produce a recovering economy in the
European states through the Marshall Plan in the 1950s shaped the idea of how
The idea that desirable results could be obtained through the creation and building
The economic thought of that time also favored consolidated government effort:
big push theory, balanced growth, take-off into sustained growth, and critical
minimum effort thesis all saw economies of scale in basic industries and
Rationality,
modernization, and
The 1950s was a time of faith – faith in the developmental power of administrative
This wave of reforms, characterized with a great deal of optimism in the power of
quickest way to bring the dream of development into reality was through the
mechanism of public administration. The net result of all this enthusiastic action was
33
that in the 1950s public administration was a magic term and public administration
The view that humans can determine and build their future using reason and rationally
designed mechanisms, technologies and institutions, instead of relying on fate was the
management theories that saw organizations as closed systems (the view that
organizations are not affected by their socio political environment) and emphasized
modern institutions against traditional social institutions, favor the former over the
developing countries despite any opposition from pre- existing institutions that soon
would be sidelined.
this stage.
One of them is the belief in the universality and inevitability of the spread of
individualism, and science-based enlightenment in all the areas and people of the
earth.
The other is its elitist bias, an assumption that the agents of modernization
to transforming their societies along Western lines for benefit of all through the
34
state bureaucracy.
Scientific management embodied the ideas of both modernization and elitism. Its main tenet
that one best way could be identified for any job was highly influential in American public
administration at that time and directly shaped the approach to institutional development.
The implicit assumption [underlying development administration] was that there was one form
countries was possible and desirable through the power of knowledge and technical
assistance.
Poor and disadvantaged nations would develop by adopting rational practices and importing
modern institutions, organizations, technologies and values of advanced societies that were
scholars from the American universities of Pittsburgh, Michigan State, Indiana, and
Syracuse. They hoped to provide solid research knowledge about the process of
This group then modified this abstracted norm-based definition into an organization-
organization. This shift can be explained by the group‘s desire to make the definition of
35
institutions applicable for practitioners by focusing on the more tangible framework
(organization) within which those norms were to grow and take root.
The goals and the end state of institution building were to create a ripple effect
foster, and protect new normative relationships and action patterns, and (c)
The key elements of this institution building model were categorized under institutional
36
relevant to the doctrine and program of the institutions), and
The group engaged in studying the linkages between these elements and in drawing
researchers found this model of institution building useful and relevant as it brought
together important, although not new, elements. But this model was not extensively
used. In part, the model was abandoned as the interest in and funding for institution
The model was also criticized as being a-priori (vs. drawn from observations), un-
testable (i.e., did not qualify as a theory), static (did not tell how the various elements
were interrelated), and prescriptive, based on wishful thinking rather than testable
Practitioners also noted that it was too abstract and failed to stress important factors
in order to be useful.
The group of scholars that challenged the Inter-University Research Program in Institution
Building approach emerged under Fred Riggs‘ leadership. Riggs summarized his view as follows:
The first had evolved in traditional empires and kingdoms where pre-industrial
the second was a product of modernity following the industrial revolution and the
I rejected the escalator model of the new modernization literature in which traditional
changes that would, sooner or later, bring them into the new world of opportunity. It
struck me that most societies would adhere tenaciously to many of their most valued
37
ancient traditions and cultural norms while simultaneously importing and accepting a
façade of practices and patterns that would, hopefully, enable them to maintain their
distinctive cultures while benefitting from the autonomy and material goods offered by
the outside world. Instead, curious amalgams would be formed in which “agrarian” and
white light of undifferentiated social systems would mingle with the rainbow hues of
The CAG scholars‘ intent, in contrast to the orthodox American public administration,
was to study bureaucracy and public administrative systems across countries based on
their unique underlying sociopolitical and cultural trends and conditions. This process
Riggs‘ call for a clear understanding of the forces which lead to administrative
The CAG scholars, many of whom had been engaged in development assistance and
institution building also intended to correct what Riggs called the fundamental
ignorance.
awareness or ignorance of the unique contextual - cultural and historical factors that
Unfortunately, the CAG did not get to fulfill its ambitions. The interest in their subject
matter significantly faded over time due to a number of constraints. Insiders mention
among the main obstacles the competing agendas of the development administration and
comparative administration and the different expectations of the funders. The Ford
Foundation that provided funding for this group was interested in a prescriptive
development administrative (how to) approach, whereas the CAG was more interested in
38
scientific inquiry and synthesis of their observations based on in-depth empirical
evidence. Still, the CAG approach left an important trace by paving the way for the
The reforms in developing countries promoted by donors primarily by USAID and the
Ford Foundation in the United States focused on building and strengthening the
number of newly independent post-colonial states in Africa, the Middle East, and South
East Asia.
these developing countries. It was generally presumed that the laws, policies,
indigenous and developing countries because of their greater rationality, efficiency, and
relationship to democratic ideals. Their diffusion and adoption was considered both
39
In part, the donors and their consultants assumed that bureaucracies in developing
countries were as autonomous as was perceived in the United States. They believed
that the spillover from the changes in specific bureaucratic organizations would
gradually trigger the transformation of the whole system. Reformers justified their
by the fact that the donors wished to abide by self-imposed concerns of political
neutrality.
administrative reform such as POSDCORB. These models were what the consultants
themselves knew well and they lacked knowledge of the institutions and of the
organization as a closed rational system and the neglect of its environment as well as
the informal and emotional behaviors which influenced organizations, were exposed with
First, the reforms were fragmented. It was believed that by transforming individual
broader institutional environment. This proved not to be the case. Furthermore, the
design and implementation of the reforms overlooked not only local government
institutions, but also the broader context of these organizations (or their ecology, in
Riggs‘ language).
Second, the reforms were determined externally, with little input from the
beneficiaries. In other words, the reforms were supply-driven and used the same models
borrowed from the West with the assumption that those models were universal and
40
Third, the reforms were carried out without a clear understanding of what institutions
are (overall and in specific contexts) and how to change them. Many oversees experts
did not study in depth the history and institutional context of the local societies, did
not fully understand the local people, and were not adequately prepared to provide the
expected assistance. Rather, they were perceived as ignorant and resented by locals,
yet tolerated and accepted since they brought resources with them.
Fourth, reforms were crafted with the assumption that formal Western organizational
models would fit and work in any environment. But the design of the interventions did
not account for the actual realities and needs of the recipients. Fifth, the reformers
institutions are not neutral instruments, but are embedded within a political
Sixth, donors tended to focus more on inputs, neglecting the actual outcomes of the
reforms and assuming, without evidence, that the reforms would generate the expected
outcomes. Little thought was given as to what kind of unintended consequences the
and judicial institutions. The law and development movement was also funded by USAID
It engaged professors from leading law schools in the United States. The dominant
assumption underlying this initiative was that the reform of the legal and judicial
systems, just as the reform of the administrative systems for the development
countries.
41
Both movements shared a similar approach to institutional reforms based on the
external agencies via adopting or modifying formal laws and organizational structures.
Second, modeling them after Western institutions would work without regard to the
local context, because the knowledge about the existing institutions is lacking and/or
countries observed that the institution building which focused on building and
they facilitated the use of government resources and foreign aid by unpopular
regimes and post-colonial political leaders to promote and serve their personal and
when new, rationalized capabilities are produced with the help of foreign technical
assistance, they can be used to enhance regime objectives, which few observers would
define as developmental.
Those state institutions that had been getting technical assistance, instead of
induced industrialization, modernization and even economic growth. But this occurred
42
at a great cost in the welfare of the rural and urban poor and substantial erosion
These changes rendered the centralized and elitist social engineering approach to
development of the 1950s increasingly irrelevant; and along with that, development
administration and comparative public administration lost their appeal. By the mid-
1970s, the focus of the reforms promoted by the United States started to shift away
from government institutions. Policy makers, disillusioned with the outcomes of the
and corrupt governments and the ascendance of the neoclassical economic paradigm also
The first wave of reforms made it clear that reformers could not transform the
organizations. Overall, this wave of reforms challenged all the assumptions that
The period from the 1960s to the 1970s was a time of reflection and of a search for
difficult process; it often challenges the status quo and faces resistance from
resources that many developing countries cannot always afford, and it is hard to
A series of conferences in the United States and elsewhere that brought together
43
administrative reforms arrived at the following conclusions. Three major points could be
specific: the universal formula for administrative reform, based on foreign (i.e.,
Western) models, concepts, and ideas, is unlikely to work in developing countries, unless
only with organizational performance per se but with improving the performance of the
whole public sector. Thus, administrative reform is a broader process that has to
account for its ecology (in Riggs‘ words) – i.e., its political and social context and the
dynamics among these forces, in order to accomplish its purpose. The third point that
emerged from the experiments that administrative reform requires changing not only
formal laws, organizations, and procedures, but also attitudes, mindsets, and the
The problems in the first wave of institutional reforms also have resulted from a
approaches failed to involve local stakeholders in the process and account for the
political aspects of the reform. In addition, little attention was paid to promoting
organizations.
The experiences with the first wave of institutional reforms identified at least two
Another on the nature of the very institutions that reformers were trying to
transform.
44
Both practitioners and researchers learned that they did not understand how
administration experts and scholars admitted that they had tried to help developing
Practitioners and researchers also found that they had a poor understanding of the
local contexts and of the very institutions they were trying to change. In developing
countries, it was much easier to adopt laws and formal organizational structures than to
entities often served as façades, while the actual behavior remained a latent function
of other institutions and other contextual (historical, cultural, and like) factors, which
All of these factors combined to contribute to the loss of this movements momentum.
The experiences taught a sobering lesson that the experts sent to help
―underdeveloped areas did not have the knowledge and the skill to relieve the suffering
of these people but the lesson was wasted. Both practitioners and researchers chose a
tactic of hiding their heads under the sand, until these lessons came to haunt them a
few decades later. Practitioners decided that focusing on more tangible projects had
better payoffs. The mainstream policy sciences chose to live with the false assumptions
about the universal applicability of Western knowledge, and marginalized those who
Section Two: The Second Wave of Reforms (1980s and Early 1990s): The
Driver of Development
Section Overview
The period between the 1980s and the early 1990s was the height of the second wave
government institutions, this one was concerned with cutting and downsizing
45
government institutions and capitalizing on the energy of market institutions to bring
about development. How did this wave come about and how was it carried out? What
theories and ideas informed the content and approach to reforms? How did it play out
in practice? What lessons were learned and to what extent were lessons incorporated
from the previous wave of reforms? This chapter addresses these questions. In order
to address the public sector reforms of this wave the section is divided in to three
broad sub-sections. The first part is devoted the discussion of the policy and political
context of the reforms. In the second part we will discuss the content of reforms
The Second Wave of Reforms (1980s and Early 1990s): The Market as the
In this period the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank (WB) emerged
as the most influential IDA shaping this wave of public sector reforms. During this time,
the reforms promoted by these IDA in developing countries were dedicated to freeing
markets from governments regulatory grip. It was believed that unleashing the private
sector creative energy would induce growth. During this wave of reforms, development
was primarily measured by the level of economic growth driven by the private sector
This wave of public sector reforms which were curtailed as part of the broader
government bureaucracy on the economy and adopt principles and practices from
private sector management. The expected outcome of these reforms was to secure a
Among the main factors that contributed to this shift were the rise of neo-liberalism
and the changing role of the state in the West. At the peak of the Cold War,
governments had greatly expanded. They were increasingly criticized for being overly
46
centralized, bloated (big), inefficient, and unresponsive to the demands of the changing
markets are more flexible and superior to government institutions in producing social
welfare. The pro-market leadership in the United States and the United Kingdom (i.e.
the Reagan and Thatcher administrations) and the weakening and eventual dissolution
of the Soviet Union emboldened those advocating for the virtues of the minimalist
state. The failures of the previous development initiatives also lent support for this
shift. These earlier initiatives were seen as solely government-driven and their failure
was believed by the neo-liberals to have come as a direct result of too much
government.
In contrast to the 1950s, this time around the public sector reforms were heavily influenced
less by public administration experts and specialists, but by economists who have populated
and influenced the leading development agencies at this time. During this wave neo-classical
economics established itself as the most influential discipline in the development community.
The theories aligned with the prevailing political sentiments at this time have been bolstered
at the expense of those who presented divergent views on the role of the state.
Modernization came under attack, as did Keynesian economics, while the Chicago schools‘ (the
intellectual basis of the neoliberal ideology) influence on policy makers increased. The
influence of the schools advocating the invisible hand of market forces as the driver of
economic development ascended across the social sciences disciplines, including in public
administration. The growing dissatisfaction with the actual embodiment of the Weberian
bureaucratic model in Western institutions also fueled the growing anti-government and anti-
bureaucratic sentiments.
Public choice theory has exerted prevailing influence on public administration since the 1970s.
Rational choice theories (RCT) assume that people are rational actors with clear and consistent
preferences, and that they act on their economic self-interests. The theories holding this
assumption are criticized for neglecting the competing and unclear preferences people hold, as
47
well as their other motives – besides economic self-interests – including those based on their
Public choice literature is concerned with the problems of the free riders who take advantage
rational choice theory, bureaucracy came under particular attack as a self-serving category
problem). The researchers of this school inferred that cutting down bureaucracy and
subjecting it to greater external checks and control is needed. The donors came to promote
this recipe, assuming that exposing government organizations to pressures and competition
Most of the public sector reform programs that have taken place in developing
countries during this wave were introduced as part of the ―Washington consensus which
informed the Structural Adjustment Programmes (SAPs) of the World Bank in the
1980s.
The content of the reforms projected the main tenets of the Washington Consensus
and the New Public Management (NPM). While the language of IDA emphasized
institutions so as to support those reforms, especially in the countries that did not have
market economies; this is where the NPM came in. In this manner, institutional
The key principles underlying this wave of reforms were captured in the so-called and
much discussed Washington Consensus, a term coined in the early 1990s by economist
and Presidents Administration, and the technocratic Washington embodied by the IMF,
48
World Bank, and the think tanks, converged which policies should be promoted in
foreign direct investment, Privatize state owned enterprises, Deregulate market entry
reforms strategy.
The latter consisted of (1) liberalization of prices and elimination of trade barriers;
(2) Macroeconomic stabilization - the process through which inflation is brought under
(3) Restructuring and privatization – the processes of creating a viable financial sector
and reforming the enterprises in these economies to render them capable of producing
goods for free markets and of transferring their ownership into private hands, and
(4) Legal and institutional reforms, needed to redefine the role of the state in the
The IMF emerged as the chief authority on macroeconomic policy reforms, while the
World Bank initially assumed the greater role in promoting institutional reforms.
Between them, they set the tone in the development field, owing to their extensive
funding and their expanding in-house expertise. Backed by the U.S. presidential
Administration and the U.S. Treasury, the IMF was especially forceful in promoting the
tenets of the Washington Consensus through its conditionality loans. The IMFs role
became even more prominent with the fall of the Berlin Wall as the bankrupted
countries one after the other turned to the IMF for loans. The vastness of this task
strained even the IMFs financial resources, which is why the World Bank was brought in
to support the IMFs mission. Not surprisingly, this wave of reforms affected a large
49
number of countries in Africa, Asia and Latin America.
The reform of government institutions was given minimal attention; they were
government. The attention paid to public sector reforms was also minimal in view of the
perceived urgency of the political and economic reforms and the growing anti-
bureaucratic sentiments.
The most important reason why the reforms paid minimal attention to public sector
reforms is that donors naively assumed that effective institutions would fill in the
institutional vacuum once the macroeconomic reforms were implemented. This is not
surprising because this wave of reforms was shaped under the influence of the laissez
faire doctrine which holds that unleashing market forces would institutionalize the new
types of behavior and lead to more efficient institutions and more economic growth. In
sum, administrative reform was subsumed under this new market-oriented paradigm
during this wave of institutional reforms. The leading IDA argued that development is
best achieved not through government which, it was believed, actually hinders
development but through market forces that need to be freed from the grip of
The reform of the bureaucracy (public administration) during this wave was narrower in
scope than traditional administrative reform. The civil service system was the main
target of these initiatives; pay and employment, and within those, reducing numbers
performance and ethos, while cutting its rules, regulations, and bureaucracy’s role in
Although the ultimate goal of the reforms was to improve the institutions and
50
management capacity of the civil service by inducing principles and practices from the
private sector (the NPM), in practice the reforms have been largely limited to
downsizing through short-term cost containment measures such as employment cuts and
wage reforms.
At the same time, the broader term public sector reforms began to replace the
previously used administrative reforms. The former was more convenient and provided
more room for including reforms to public enterprises that did not comfortably fit
institutional public sector reforms expanded to encompass the private and, indirectly,
structural reforms. These changes affected the context of the bureaucracy and the
The core paradigm which can be discerned as influential in the development of public
sector reforms in the 1980s and 1990s was that public sector provision was inefficient
and often ineffective; that it led neither to cost containment nor to quality
improvement. With the problems so defined, the paradigm extended to a belief that
the public and private sectors did not have to be organized and managed in
fundamentally different ways. Indeed that it would be better for the public services if
they could be organized and managed as much like the private sector as possible. The
focus of the NPM movement therefore, was on creating institutional and organizational
contexts which are to mirror what is seen as critical aspects of private sector modes of
organizing and managing. Public sector reforms taking place in Africa today build on
previous programs. However, they also fundamentally question the role and institutional
In the literature on public sector and institutional reform, the NPM has been variously
called:
51
Managerialism,
entrepreneurial government,
administration reform agenda of most OECD countries from the late 1970s. It captures
most of the structural, organizational and managerial changes taking place in the public
services of these countries, and a bundle of management approaches and techniques borrowed
from the private sector. The goal of the NPM is to implement the 3Es‘: efficiency, economy
and effectiveness David Osborne and Gaebler, in their book entitled Reinventing Government
(1992) identified ten defining characteristics of what they call Entrepreneurial Government
(EG), namely:
inputs
preventing problems rather than cure them after they blew out
Focusing on catalyzing all sectors- public, private and voluntary-in to action, not
52
simply on providing public services, to solve societal problems.
Osborne and Gaebler‘s, EG, which is driven by the NPM and the New institutional economics
and minimize cost( e.g.: competition among public schools to improve quality of education)
and framing flexible rules to free public servants to pursue goals without being enslaved
by rules
5. Customer driven Government: spending is tied to results and for this purposes
minimum cost
decisions of the private sector, Government can accomplish more what it can do by
The notion of reinventing government, by Osborne and Gaebler was one of the most popular
works in the NPM movement, a perspective that underpinned the ideology of the anti-
better Governance. Governance is the act of collectively solving our problems. Government is
the instrument we use. The instrument is outdated, and it is time to make it.
Although different interpretations exist as to what constitutes the core of NPM, the common
claim among proponents of NPM is the call for using the insights and principles that worked
well in the private sector such as competition, decentralization, flexibility, and pay for
performance to induce efficiency, economy, and effectiveness in the public sector. Their
major argument in favor of their approach is that traditional public administration institutions
are deficient.
It is said to be a global phenomenon. The NPM was first popularized in the United States, the
United Kingdom, Canada and New Zealand and spread its influence over public administration
reforms in other countries around the world, especially in the Commonwealth countries. OECD,
disseminating best practices informed by NPM. The relative success of NPM in these
countries can be partly explained by the fact that it was launched on the basis of already solid
governing institutions. In these countries, constitutional democracy and the rule of law was
already firmly established. In addition, there has been a fair amount of adaptation of NPM
principles to realities of OECD countries that have adapted them as evident in the variation in
contrast, in many of the developing countries where these conditions did not exist, NPM‗s
From the forgone discussion, it seems apparent; the overall emphasis of the NPM is changing
achieving targets and results. With NPM, reduction in the size of Government, reducing the
functional load of the bureaucracies, speed, results, and accountability soon become the
buzzwords. Historically bureaucracy has always been under attack as power grabbers,
secretive, rule bound, inward looking, and the like. In this respect, the criticism of
bureaucracy by the NPM does not seem something new. However, the contemporary objection
54
to bureaucracy by the NPM is unique in that, it represents a savage onslaught on bureaucracy
as the main source of mal-governance and the various social evils afflicting humanity at the
The key components of NPM may be put into two broad categories – those that emphasize
managerial improvement and organizational restructuring, and those that emphasize markets
and competition. The basic foundation of the NPM movement, however, is the drive for
efficiency and the use of the economic market as a model for political and administrative
In addition, the institutional aspects of NPM derive from the ―new institutional
economics movement, which has a theoretical foundation in public choice, transaction cost and
principal- agent theories. These generated public sector reforms themes are based on ideas of
of giving more choice and voice to service users and promoting efficiency in public service
delivery.
The NPM has several interrelated components that cut across the traditional ways of
organizing governments. The first relates to the delivery of high quality services to citizens
customers, not just passive recipients. Hence, serious attempts are being made to find out
what customers expect. In this regard, public sector organizations, for instance, in UK and
Singapore have set performance targets and attempted to measure performance and publicize
results for the wider public. The most dramatic of such initiatives is citizens ‘charter in
Improved efficiency is now the overriding aim of public sector reforms in most African
countries. It is thought that the State‘s capability, its ability to promote and undertake
competition in service provision, both with the private sector and in the public sector
concentrate their efforts less on direct intervention and more on enabling others to be
productive by providing ―core‖ functions such as safeguarding law and order; protecting
property rights; managing the macro-economy to promote and regulate the market;
providing basic social services and infrastructure; and protecting the vulnerable and
destitute.
Despite the move to reduce the role of the public sector, there is broad agreement
about the need to increase the capacity of the State. To do this, varieties of NPM-
inspired measures are used. These includes: the refocusing of public-sector functions
‗hiving off‘ central government functions to local governments or the private sector;
While the content of the public sector reforms had changed since the first wave, the
approach to the public sector reforms did not depart much from the accustomed
practices. In the same way as with the overarching macroeconomic reforms, public
sector institutional reforms, when they received attention, were limited mainly to
importing best practices and policies, and changing formal organizational and internal
rules and regulations with the help of external consultants paid by the donors. The
donors still assumed that the same set of policies would benefit every country
56
The key macroeconomic and political decisions were made by the donors with little
consultation with the beneficiaries. While the loan conditions constituted the new
element in the approach to the reforms promoted by IDA during this wave of reforms,
they were accompanied by technical assistance (TA) projects, which employed the same
approach to reforms as did the experts in the first wave of reforms. In addition, the
Since institutional reforms were focused mainly on changing formal institutional and
organizational frameworks and modeling them after those borrowed from the West,
copying and passing laws without regard to their institutionalization prevailed. Little
attention was paid to the human and organizational factors that should give meaning to
those laws. During this wave, donors still showed little regard for understanding
beneficiaries‘ needs; the reform agenda was externally determined. In fact, this
aspect has become even more pronounced during this wave of reform as the donors
influence grew along with the countries‘ need for external assistance. Beneficiaries still
did not have much input in selecting the content of the reforms in part because those
reforms came for free and was a condition for receiving the much-needed loans from
the donors. Despite the change in terminology from administrative to public sector
reforms, the fragmented and technical approach to reforms was still evident in the
piecemeal focus on the aspects of the changes that were easiest to implement in short
time frames. Pay and employment reforms in the civil service and the privatization of
public enterprises were carried out without a clear strategy to account for the broader
institutional context.
The increased use of conditionality to promote macroeconomic reforms, and along with
that the downsizing of the public sector, contributed to the deepening of these
problematic approaches to the public sector reforms. In addition, the other problems
beneficiaries existing institutions and how institutions change overall, as well as the
ignorance and ethnocentrism of the donors – combined with the recipients desire to
57
secure external legitimacy by adopting influential donors models and frameworks and
the desperation of their officials to find ways out from their crises, contributed to
58
Assessment of the Outcomes of the Reforms
The leading donors and independent observers agreed that overall this wave of reforms,
despite some successes, had failed to live up to its promises. The overall consensus
among observers of these reforms was that despite some bright spots, donors‘ aid
at times encouraged incompetence, corruption, and misguided policies. With the lack of
viable government or other alternative institutions to provide the rule of law and
enforce policies, the macroeconomic and public sector reforms created opportunities
for a few vested interests – the new entrepreneurs who emerged from former
government elites and their allies – to concentrate government assets in their hands,
and even tailor the new government regulations for their own benefit. These processes
closely tied newly emerging business sector and government elites together in illicit
informal networks.
Among the many critics of the IDA policies, former chief economist at the World Bank
Joseph Stiglitz (2000) faulted both the content and approach of the reforms
prescribed by the IMF for contributing to and furthering financial crises in developing
countries that followed its advice. He argued that the content of the reforms was
informed by outdated and simplistic economic models. They were also misguided because
they did not account for the peculiarities of each country. Moreover, the IMF‗s
approach to policy making furthered these problems and prevented it from adjusting
even when the mistakes became obvious. Other critics emphasized the contrast
between the IDAs macroeconomic policy outcomes with the approach that led to the
Asian miracle. East Asia‘s fast-growing economies owed their success in part to stable
government institutions and the active intervention of the state in promoting economic
development.
The outcomes of the reforms specifically targeting the inner working of the public
administration system, not surprisingly, also were not encouraging. As mentioned above,
the World Bank mainly focused on downsizing civil service and paid little attention to
59
institutional and capacity building aspects of the reforms. As a result, the failures and
Thus, those donors were forced to reconsider the assumptions informing their
development interventions.
most of which, not surprisingly, were not new; they painfully rediscovered the lessons
from the first wave of institutional reforms. Out of these the lessons which were taken
The donors underscored that without strong and capable government institutions,
governments in many developing countries did not have the skills, capacity, and
properly and make effective use of aid. They also noted that in corrupt environments,
countries, have been further derailed to serve private interests, which undermined the
Moreover, government institutions were also found essential for dealing with social
issues such as poverty and education that topped the donors and world leaders‘ agenda
in the last decade of the 20th century. The IMF, for example, recommended that the
Washington consensus) and at the same time build the institutions required to underpin
a market economy.
60
2. One Size Does Not Fit All:
to be emphasized. The IDA learned that the reforms need to be tailored to a specific
context; and even that best practice in institutional development is a flawed concept.
The reformers also noted the importance of beneficiaries‘ involvement in the design
sustain. Thus, instead of a supply of experts and equipment from abroad, reformers
started looking at the ways to improve local capacity by increasing the involvement of
the beneficiaries.
Good Governance
A. Policy Context
institutional reforms. One of the main contributors to this shift was the increasing amount of
Contrary to donors‘ prescriptions, not all the countries that followed the Washington
If anything, evidence from the Asian crisis, the experiences of transition from command to
market economy, and situation in much of the underdeveloped world provided examples of
The problems IDAs are facing in their own governing institutions further increased the
focus on institutional reforms. The OECD countries, similarly, had been experimenting
of the welfare state. These reforms directly and indirectly influence the content and
A set of other factors further highlighted the emphasis on the quality of governance
institutions. One of them is the growing concern with aid effectiveness. The donors
noted that the governments with better institutions made more effective use of
development aid, while in countries with poorly functioning government institutions aid
did not make much positive impact. The worldwide social issues and humanitarian
institutions. The widening income gap between countries and individuals, especially in the
poorer countries, and other pressing social issues such as education and health also
played a role in shaping the new content and approach to this new wave of reforms. The
necessitated sustainable development strategies that would take into account not only
economic growth, but also the social and political dimensions of development.
reforms is that the major IDA involved in promoting institutional reforms are
assistance. From the late 1970s until the late 1990s, the World Bank, IMF, and USAID
favored neo-liberal policies, while other IDA such as the UNDP and European
Commission (EC) tended to favor a more balanced approach accounting for both
several steps.
In sum, since 1997 the new consensus that emerged among IDA is that development
interventions need to secure good governance to generate political, economic, and social
62
Another important but subtle change took place in this wave in the vocabulary of
donors. Most donors started talking more about capacity building and capacity
Who do you think the most influential IDA in public sector reforms during this
wave?
In this wave, the World Bank and the United Nations consider themselves the leading
among the IDA supporting public sector institutional reforms. Most other donors
involved in institutional reform, including the European Union (EU), Asian Development
Bank (ADB), United States Agency for International Development (USAID), UK‘s
Development Cooperation Agency (SIDA), have either a regional or bilateral focus and
narrower program scope, while the World Bank and UNDP have worldwide reach and a
The World Bank emerged as the most influential think-tank and donor in institutional
and governance reform since the late 1990s. The World Banks public sector reform
agenda has been evolving over a period of time and became more focused since the late
1990s. Since then, the World Bank has changed its aim to align it with its mission of
reducing poverty as it was becoming increasingly apparent that its previous market-
oriented focus was not well-suited for promoting this mission. The World Bank exerts
greater influence on the actions and policies of developing countries and other donors
owing to its large grants and loans along with its extensive knowledge-generating
research network.
administration in its core support areas. Institutional development (ID) the process of
planned reforms undertaken to artificially change the existing and/or devise new
institutions has been tacitly accepted as a major effort [for UN] in promoting
63
since the emergence of the official development assistance field at the end of WWII.
In the last decade, when the institutional development movement reemerged, the UN
also re-established itself as the chief authority in public sector reforms among donors.
Within the United Nations, the Division for Public Administration and Development
Management of the Department of Economic and Social Affairs of the United Nations
(DESA) focuses on analytical work and policy setting reforms. UNDP, an important arm
because it has a mandate to design programs with the highest long-term impact on the
poor and disadvantaged. Public administration is seen as most suitable tool for pursuing
administration is a central part of democratic governance and the basic means through
Two schools of thought that share similar assumptions influenced donors‘ public sector
reforms during this period more than other schools. One of them is New Institutional
Economics (NIE). It shaped the overall direction and rhetoric of leading donors‘ reform
policies. Another is New Public Management (NPM), which informed the specific details of the
By the 1990s, traditional theories of economic growth focused on labor, physical and
explaining the differences in economic growth among nations. At around the same time,
among donors.
The NIE movement, sometimes referred to as new political economy, has had significant
influence in social sciences for the last few decades. The NIE emerged from extensive
64
economics and rational choice theory (RCT) to apply to research in political science,
(c) recognition that coordination of market activity is a matter of not only markets, but
NIE influenced the leading donors‘ development policies through two sets of findings:
2. The other one on the links between institutions and economic growth.
First, this school‘s claim that more equal distribution of income and wealth is conducive
to growth- run counter to the neoclassical economics which held that unequal income was
a prerequisite to growth. This finding, along with Amartya Sen‘s capability approach,
reinforced the poverty reduction and human development policies of the leading donors
NIEs claims that development depends on the quality of institutions also caught donors‘
attention just when donors needed it following the backlash of its previous wave of
reforms. Students of NIE argue that institutions present that missing link, which
For example, North (1990) described the role of institutions as follows: Third World
countries are poor because the institutional constraints define a set of payoffs to
political/economic activities that do not encourage productive activity. They also hold
that efficient institutions are those which provide the right incentives to individuals.
65
The World Bank’s key policy documents that set the stage for the new wave of
institutional reforms draws predominantly from this strand of research. The research
used in World Bank‘s policy documents found that certain features of institutions -
with the long-term growth and poverty reduction. While there is agreement that good
quality institutions are necessary not only for economic development but also on other
grounds such as provision of human rights and democratic governance, and NIEs
contribution for the improved understanding of institutions has been notable, NIEs
research on institutions has been challenged for not being able to specify the nature
and causal relationships among the quality of institutions, functions of institutions, the
The public sector is still expected to become leaner and perform more effectively in
fulfilling its core functions. The IDA‘s emphasis on incentives and competition following
the NIE scholars further reinforced the assumption that public sector institutions
changing incentives (rules of the game) that expose them to greater competition from
the private sector and demand from citizen-customers. In sum, the principles according
to which the private sector institutions operate, when applied to public sector
The New Public Management (NPM) movement in public administration and development
similarly has not been able to specify the nature and causal relationships among the
outcomes of reforms.
Lacking clear understanding of causal relations, NPM draws from the institutional
66
models and practices of OECD countries that serve as benchmarks for practitioners,
management reform, leavened with the strategies and tools associated with core
Interesting, NPM approach goes against donors‘ rhetoric (discourse) to tailor reforms
integrated agenda that reflects a set of causal relationships. There are ongoing
debates around necessary and sufficient conditions, linkages, sequencing, and impacts.
nuanced, by "empirical studies covering diverse countries and regions, longer time
impacts". Given the tendency toward idealized thinking about development management
factors that influence outcomes and impacts. In sum, the research informing donor
policies has been criticized as being partial and poorly suited for understanding, let
alone informing, the design and implementation of institutional reforms. While the key
problems on the way towards creating effective institutions involve intangibles such as
values and trust issues, the research informing donors‘ institutional reforms, namely
NIE and NPM movements, has been based on the set of assumptions on human behavior
67
1. The Content of and Approach to the Reforms
This wave of reforms is distinct from the previous ones in a number of ways: donors
changed not only the content of its reforms, but also are attempting to change the
content of the IDA‘s reforms shifted away from the market to promoting good
system. Unlike the reforms in 1950s, this time the state and government institutions
are seen not as direct providers of goods and services, but more as facilitators of
economic growth. The IDA now argue that the government‘s main responsibility is to
create the right conditions and incentives for the private sector and civil society, which
are seen as complementary players in the broader governance process along with the
government.
The IDAs new approach to institutional reforms, at least in policy documents, also
became more aligned with what they prescribe the recipient governments should do
towards their own citizens. The IDA are now trying to make their interventions more
participatory, beneficiary- driven, and tailored to each specific context, and they seek
institutional reforms. It is assumed that this new approach will positively affect the
outcomes of the development interventions. Below, a brief overview of the key and
shared elements in the content and approach of the key IDAs public sector reforms.
Figure 1: The Vision for Public Sector Reforms in the Third Wave 140
68
Content of Public Sector Reforms
This wave of institutional reform differs from the previous ones in several aspects.
The previous reforms paid attention to both changing rules and promoting the
The current reforms tend to emphasize rule change over the development of
In contrast, the previous ones focused more on [meso-level] organizational rules and
resources.
Second, the current reforms intend to change not only administrative or judicial
institutions, but also economic, political, and societal institutions that together make
up governance institutions.
those components have been disjointed, and since the 1970s subsumed under other
priority policies. Policy-makers in IDA are finally acknowledging that institutions are
This, at a minimum, means that changing economic or political policies and even
institutions alone will not be sustainable unless public administration systems are
also reformed.
Today’s institutional reforms focus not on a single institution, but the whole
69
governance system.
countries with the weakest government capacity. For example, public sector reform is
now in the heart of the World Bank‘s overarching agenda of improving governance,
which falls into three broad areas rule-based operation of the government itself to
improve the supply of public goods, voice and accountability for citizens to demand
better public services, and more efficient and effective regulation of the private
Similarly, the UNDP treats public administration reforms as central part of its
The redefinition of development as a matter of high quality rules of the game resulted
in a confluence of administrative changes with the rule of law reforms, both in terms of
content and methods. Rule of law is the continuation of the previously tried and
abandoned rule and development field concerned with improving the capacity of the
judiciary. Now rule of law is a part of the broader public sector reforms. Moreover, this
field of practice regained greater influence among donors. If law and development was
promoted mainly by the US aid community, this time rule of law is deemed as an
essential component of institutional reforms by almost all IDA. Rule of law is appealing
In sum, in terms of the content of reforms, this time donors are trying to focus on a
large set of institutional transformations under the governance agenda that emphasizes
IDA‘s approach to institutional reforms shows a radical departure from the old approach, but
mainly in policy rather than in practice. This change in approach is reflected in the following
70
areas.
In contrast to the previous wave of public sector reforms, this time donors are
attempting to focus not only on the general idea of cutting government‘s size and role
and infusing more competition through privatization, but also on specific features of
These elements are promoted in the place of inputs, process, and public service
In other words, projects and programs of the donors are to be evaluated against their
impact on the overall governance environment. The recipients are therefore required to
develop long-term country level institutional development strategies and link donor
projects to them, instead of simply relying on ad-hoc supply-driven aid. Example of such
Meanwhile, IDA has been increasingly emphasizing the need to adjust reforms to the
specifics of each country thorough better understanding the recipients‘ needs. This
lesson has been vividly highlighted owing in part to the failures that followed the one-
decade earlier.
The realization that best practices may not work if not tailored to the local context and
the importance of a clear understanding of the problems and desired outcomes prior to
interventions have influenced the IDA‘s approach. For the first time OECD countries,
similar to what developing countries have been undergoing for a few decades, also
budgeting and NPM reforms popularized through New Zealand‘s successful example
have been tried in many countries, but led to different and not always desirable
71
outcomes even in OECD countries.
Furthermore, IDA has been trying to re-orient their policies to make the institutional
reforms more demand-driven. It is assumed that fostering local participation, voice, and
ownership will improve not only the beneficiaries‘ aid effectiveness, but also will
authorities. Although the World Bank still intends not to interfere in political matters
of the recipient states, this new approach implicitly and indirectly embraces the
political nature of the reforms and the need to change the existing distribution of
power for the public sector reforms to succeed. The World Bank, however, has
monetary and aggregate fiscal). It perceives that participation in these areas can be
easily captured by special interests, and are best carried out by organization [by
qualified experts with technical expertise] insular from the exigencies of everyday
politics.
falling out of favor, at least in policy rhetoric. Instead, the IDA came to recognize that
to make aid effective they need to tailor the reforms to beneficiaries‘ specific needs
and make lending support locally-driven and owned. The current consensus is that IDA
should help developing countries build government institutions capable of making sound
policies themselves without relying on external advisors, only through such institution-
building will countries be able to achieve the ultimate goals of poverty reduction,
72
UNIT THREE
Unit Introduction
Dear students, welcome to Unit three. In this unit you will be introduced about
reforms such as United Nations systems reforms and Bretton woods institutional
reforms. It also explains about some regional institutional reforms such as African
Unit Objectives
With the successful completion of this unit, you will be able to;
Explain the nature and scope of Global institutional architecture and reforms
Describe United Nations systems reforms, African union and European Union
system.
Global Governance
The idea or concept of global governance has gone from the ranks of the unknown to
one of the central orienting themes in the practice and study of international affairs
Sometimes the term global governance has been used as just a synonym for
and dynamism of the many collective efforts by states and an increasing variety of
non-state actors to identify, understand, and address various issues and problems in
73
international cooperation were called for by global changes following the Cold War‘s
end.
The commission defined governance as ―the sum of the many ways individuals and
With regard to the relationship between governance and government, the two
concepts are not identical. As James Rosenau (1992: 4) put it: Both refer to
suggests activities that are backed by formal authority, by police powers to insure
activities backed by shared goals that may or may not derive from legal and formally
and organizations within its purview move ahead, satisfy their needs, and fulfill their
wants.
Thus, global governance is not global government; it is not a single world order; there
Based on reviewing the evolution of the concept, Thomas Weiss and Rorden Wilkinson
(2014) conclude, ―We understand global governance as the sum of the informal and
formal ideas, values, norms, procedures, and institutions that help all actors states,
IGOs, civil society, and TNCs identify, understand, and address trans-boundary
74
problems.
by states, but goes well beyond them, because today‘s world is far more complex and
far less state-centric, with a wide variety of actors and governance mechanisms.
processes, norms, formal agreements, and informal mechanisms that regulate action
transnational, and regional levels and refers to activities in the public and private
cooperative action is based on rights and rules that are enforced through a
elements and methods from both the public and private sectors.
In other words, the concept global governance is the way that it enables us to look at
The concept of global governance has ancient roots, but contemporary conceptions
are very much a product of developments since the Cold War‘s end. Who governs the
globe? Is an essential question to answer, as are also the questions of who get what,
―who benefits, and with what consequences (Avant, Fennimore, and Sell 2010b).
Because global governance is also dynamic, the study of it is the study of how changes
have occurred in efforts to deal with shared trans- boundary problems, how changes
are occurring, and even how changes could or should occur in the future.
75
Rationales for the Need of Global Governance
The emergence of the concept of global governance in the 1990s accompanied the
growing awareness of the rapid pace of a number of systemic changes taking place in
the world, as well as the rapid proliferation of issues and actors and the inadequacy
changes include globalization, technological advances, the Cold War‘s end, and the
altered global politics at the same time that they have contributed to the increased
Globalization
Since the late 1980s, what had initially appeared to be simply growing
interdependence among states and peoples has become something much more
change. Particularly noticeable is the rapid pace of change, the compression of time
and space, and the scale and scope of interconnectedness. More broadly, however,
or transformation in the spatial scale of human social organization that links distant
communities and expands the reach of power relations across regions and continents.
economic markets, cultures, peoples, and states have become linked, thanks to
ideas, goods, news, capital, technology, and people, and to deregulation and
organizations (NGOs) and financial markets, linking like-minded people and investors,
as well as the unwelcome, often illegal actors terrorists and drug traffickers. It has
contributed to the homogenization of culture with the global spread of ideas and
76
popular culture. It has also contributed to heterogeneity, with the reassertion of
ethnicity and nationalism in many parts of the world in reaction to globalization. Civil
wars and conflicts in some of the world‘s poorest regions, such as Somalia and Mali,
ripple outward through the flows of asylum seekers and illegal migrants to richer
countries.
The effects of globalization change the significance of the borders of states and the
very nature of world politics. They mean that states no longer have a monopoly on
power and authority. They increase the recognition of transnational problems that
require global regulation in some form. The consequence has been a huge growth in
transnational, regional, and global forms of public and private rulemaking and
regulation since the early 1990s. This includes expanded jurisdiction of existing
IGOs like the Inter- national Maritime Organization, networks of cooperation among
government agencies such as the Financial Action Task Force that link government
technological, environmental, and political not all peoples or areas of the world are
equally affected. Some critics charge that globalization has deepened global
inequality between the haves and have-nots, especially those living on less than a
dollar a day. Undoubtedly, globalization has created winners and losers between
countries and also within countries. Given both the detrimental and the beneficial
not inevitable. Globalization has both coincided with and contributed to the growth
of transnationalism and the deregulation and privatization shift, all of which can be
Technological Changes
Globalization would not have been possible without major technological changes in
77
both transport and communications that permit the movement of people and goods
rapidly over great distances and move information, images, written words, and sound
Today‘s container ships and tankers carry many times the tonnage faster and at lower
cost than ever before. The ease and lower cost of contemporary jet travel have
Moving people and goods more cheaply and easily is facilitated by the technological
communications, faxing, cell phones, the Internet, e-mail, and social media, the
advances have had an enormous impact on global politics and governance. The
communications allow citizens all over the world to exchange ideas and information
and to mobilize like-minded people in support of a particular cause in virtual real time.
The cascade of events from Tunisia to Egypt to Yemen, Jordan, Bahrain, Morocco,
Libya, and Syria during the Arab Spring in 2011 owed much to people‘s use of
Internet-based social media such as Facebook and Twitter and the inability of
authoritarian governments to block the flow of images and information. Both the
transportation revolution and the communications revolution have aided the formation
networks.
The end of the Cold War was brought about by the collapse of Soviet- supported
communist governments in Central Europe, symbolized by the fall of the Berlin Wall in
1989, and the disintegration two years later of the Soviet Union itself into fifteen
separate, independent states. The fax machine and television were important in
transmitting images and information across the Iron Curtain into Poland,
78
Czechoslovakia, Hungary, East Germany, and other countries. The Cold War‘s end
marked the ending of one historical era and the beginning of another. The
Although the Cold War‘s end contributed to the so-called third wave of
removed the support of one or the other superpower from many weak states in Asia
and Africa, unleashing a long string of deadly conflicts in the former Yugoslavia,
Somalia, Afghanistan, and elsewhere. At the same time, it opened new political space
for states and non-state actors—space for pursuing new types of cooperation in
ending those very conflicts, expanding the scope and reach of human rights norms,
and reducing barriers to trade and investment. In short, it produced a series of new
governance.
Expanding Transnationalism
Contributing to the Cold War‘s end and benefiting from increased democratization,
accelerating globalization and the advances in technology and transport is the growth
non-state actors work together across state borders. It is exhibited in the activities
social movements.
The spread of democracy has bolstered the growth of civil society in countries where
restrictions on citizens‘ groups have been lifted. Civil society groups communicate
with each other domestically and cross-nationally, creating new coalitions from the
local to the global. These transnational civil society groups permeate numerous issue
areas, including the environment, human rights, economic development, and security.
incorporate non state actors into global governance. Systemic changes inevitably have
a variety of consequences for states and for state sovereignty. The increased need
as well as the importance of leadership and different strategies used by states and
non-state actors. Knowing global needs is rarely enough to explain how and why a
particular governance outcome was chosen. Accordingly in the next in the coming sub
titles of this unit, we are going to discuss about reason and factors instigating
UN replaces the League of Nation, which was formed at 1919 after W.W I. The
President Franklin Delano Roosevelt of the United States and PM Winston Churchill
of Britain. Therefore, after W.WII- 50 countries met at San Francisco and signed
the United Charter. UN officially existed in 24, Oct 1945. United Nations (UN),
cooperation. The UN was founded after World War II ended in 1945. Its mission is
cooperation in solving the world‘s problems, and encourage respect for human rights.
brings together countries that are rich and poor, large and small, and have different
social and political systems. Member nations pledge to settle their disputes
peacefully, to refrain from using force or the threat of force against other
countries, and to refuse help to any country that opposes UN actions. The UN is the
to unite and punish any nation that committed an act of aggression. This type of union
collective security. Kant also felt that the federation would protect the rights of
small nations that often become pawns in power struggles between larger countries.
Despite this failure, the idea of a league did not die. The first commitment to create
a new organization came in 1941, when U.S. president Franklin D. Roosevelt and British
Prime Minister Winston Churchill announced the Atlantic Charter, in which they
pledged to work toward a more effective system to keep world peace and promote
accepting the principles of the Atlantic Charter. The declaration included the first
formal use of the term United Nations, a name coined by President Roosevelt. A year
later, four of the Allies—the United States, the United Kingdom, the Soviet Union,
Since World War II, the United Nations has been the center-piece of global
governance. It is the only IGO with global scope and nearly universal membership, and
its agenda encompasses the broadest range of governance issues. The UN is, in fact,
a complex system with many pieces. Among its functions are the creation of
international law, norms, and principles; it has created other IGOs within the UN
committees and programs; it has sponsored global conferences and summits. It serves
also as a catalyst for global policy networks and partnerships with other actors. The
UN, in short, is the central site for multilateral diplomacy, and the UN General
Assembly is center stage. The establishment of the United Nations in the closing
days of WWII was an affirmation of the desire of war-weary nations for a general
international organization that could help them avoid future conflicts and promote
international economic and social cooperation. The UN Charter and the core principles
81
that it incorporates as well as the principal organs were patterned after those of the
International Court of Justice. The UN Charter remedied a major gap in the League
Covenant by creating the Economic and Social Council (ECOSOC) and it carried the
The UN is a complex system with many parts and many functions, making it the
centerpiece of global governance since its inception, despite its many weaknesses.
Other IGOs have been created within the UN system, such as the UN Conference on
Trade and Development, and the International Atomic Energy Agency, as well as
summits; it serves as a catalyst for global policy networks and partner- ships with
no state actors. Among the core elements of the UN system are nineteen specialized
agencies, including the first two public international unions: the ITU and UPU. The
number and nature of such specialized and functional organizations has greatly
expanded over the course of the past century and many are not linked to the UN
system.
economics, trade, labor issues, and environmental threats mirrors a pattern carried
over from national governments. Over time, other organizations have been created to
address still more specialized problems in response to the emergence of new issues
and unmet needs. Thus the numbers of functional and specialized IGOs have
Staying above politics, however, is not always possible, since the issues such IGOs
deal with are not merely technical, but can touch at the core of state sovereignty and
they retain their functional, specialized character and are important elements of
would play key roles in activities aimed at economic and social advancement.
Therefore, Articles 57 and 63 of the UN Charter call for the affiliation with the
economics, health, food, educational, and cultural fields. Today, the nineteen
ECOSOC and the General Assembly, like the UN itself, have global rather than
secretariats as well as their own interests and constituencies. There are also a
significant number of functional organizations within the UN system that are not
classified as specialized agencies, as they have been established by the UN itself and
report to the Security Council or General Assembly. And there are a wide variety of
other specialized, functional organizations. Some are regional in scope; others have
83
Specialized Functional Other Regional
United Nations
l Internatio on of Mekong
84
Internatio UN High
nal Commissione
maritime r for
organizatio Refugees
ns (IMO) (UNHCR),
Internation Universal
al Postal
telecommun Union
ic ation (UPU),
United Health
nations Organizatio
educational, n (WHO),
scientific World
organization al
(UNESCO) Organization
United (WMO).
nation
Industrial
Developmen
Organizatio
ns (UNDO)
etc.
85
Persistent Organizational Problems and the Need for Reform
Over the UN‘s seven-decade history, there have been many efforts at reform.
Indeed, one longtime observer has called this ―a constant refrain never finished,
never perfected‖ (Luck 2007: 653). In the 1970s, the focus was on improving
coordination of economic and social programs in the UN system; in the 1980s, calls
for financial reforms dominated the agenda; since the early 1990s, managerial
operations, and Security Council reform have been among the major issues. The UN is
policies, lack of accountability and transparency, limited resources, and the inability
to meet the needs of a changing world. There is some rationality for necessity of UN
reform:
Security Council
The key ingredients for serious UN reform, as a former UN official notes, ―will
require major concessions from powerful and weak countries alike‖ and a willingness
to ―rise above their own current sense of entrenched rights and privileges and find a
grand bargain‖ (Brown 2008: 6,8). Structural Reform of the Security Council Virtually
everyone agrees that more states should be added to the Security Council. The
overrepresented at the expense of Latin America, Africa, and Asia; China is the only
third world and Asian country among the permanent members; both Germany and
Japan contribute more financially than do Russia, China, the UK, and France, yet have
normative value placed on diversity, equity, and representation today than in 1945.
to halting the loss of, the legitimacy of the Council and of its resolutions.
Thus the first key issue is the size and composition of the Council‘s membership. Yet
86
if its size is increased to enhance its representativeness, it must still be small enough
question of whether new permanent members will have veto power. Some proposals
would give no veto power to the new permanent members; others would limit veto
There are three likely African candidates, for example (Nigeria, Egypt, and South
Africa). Countries such as Italy and Pakistan that know a rival is more likely to
seats. Some observers have even suggested that any new Security Council members
not be states at all but rather regional bodies. This could mean replacing France and
Britain with a rotating EU seat (something the European Parliament has already
endorsed) and including the African Union and other bodies. In short, there is no
important.
87
Table 3.2: The Debate over Security Council Reform
a For
debat
alternatively, Give to
permanent seats
88
Coordination and Management
The problem of multiple agencies engaged in similar tasks with no coordination has
plagued the UN system almost from the beginning, in part because the founders
―It is not designed as a matrix at all but as a set of deeply rooted columns
connected only by thin and tenuous rows. Nothing that has transpired since 1945 has
issues no longer fit into clear sectorial or regional boundaries. A major step toward
coordination among the many UN entities that deal with economic and social
Coordination and management issues have also plagued UN efforts to deal with
humanitarian crises since the early 1990s. Typically, there is a functional division of
responsibilities: the UNHCR manages refugee camps, UNICEF handles water and
sanitation, the WFP is responsible for food supplies, and the WHO handles the health
safeguard relief workers and supplies. The presence of large numbers of NGOs often
complicates the task of coordination. Donor countries pushed the General Assembly in
remedy the problems, but neither was given power over other agencies, nor over
The increasing involvement of NGOs and private businesses with UN programs and
activities demonstrates another area of needed reform: how to better integrate non
state actors into the UN system. Today, regionalism and globalism coexist with
minimal friction outside the security area, and regional organizations have
proliferated even more rapidly than global ones. They have become increasingly
important pieces of the global governance puzzle. Its participants resolved to create
89
a global civil society forum to deal with UN institutions, member states, and other
institutions (Alger 2007). Non state actors now play a substantial role in
participation by no state actors is a persistent issue for the UN. The lesson was
amplified by the realization in 1944–1945 that recovery and rebuilding after World
War II would require more capital than war-ravaged countries alone could expect to
rise. The decolonization process and the tripling of the number of states in the 1950s
and 1960s would make development assistance the major priority for the World Bank
Recognizing the importance of reducing barriers to the flow of goods and capital and
the value of international economic cooperation for its own well-being, the United
establish institutions, and the money to assist others. Henry Dexter White, chief
international economist at the US Treasury from 1942 to 1944, and British economist
Keynes proposed a world central bank capable of regulating the flow of credit; he also
experiencing liquidity problems. White argued for a weaker agency that would
promote the growth of international trade but preserve the central role of the US
The newly formed International Monetary Fund (IMF) would not be a world central
bank, but would promote economic growth by providing financial stability for
international trade. Over time, the US view about conditionality for assistance would
Ideas about how governance of trade should proceed likewise differed. At the
90
Bretton Woods meetings, a comprehensive body, the International Trade
Organization (ITO), was proposed to provide a general framework for trade rules and
a venue for ongoing trade discussions. Trade governance in the ITO negotiations
arrangement. Despite its lack of organizational character, GATT became the major
venue for trade negotiations from 1949 to 1995, with an interim committee for
The World Trade Organization succeeded GATT in 1995 as the world‘s comprehensive
trade organization, with infrastructure for dispute settlement that goes far beyond
The three Bretton Woods institutions were designed to address systemic weaknesses
in economic governance and promote a liberal economic order. The World Bank and
IMF are UN specialized agencies, but until the late 1990s they operated largely
independent of the UN system. The WTO has not become a specialized agency, but
Executives Board—the entity for coordinating the disparate agencies within the UN
system.
During the 1950s the World Bank shifted its focus from postwar reconstruction in
Europe to development in Latin America, Asia, and later Africa, lending funds with
generates these funds from member-state contributions and from borrowing in inter-
national financial markets. The loans are designed to complement private capital by
funding projects that private banks would not support, such as infrastructure (dams,
restructuring. Unlike private banks, the World Bank attaches conditions to its loans in
the form of policy changes it would like to see states make to promote economic
Finance Corporation (IFC) was created in 1956, the first of four subsidiary
organizations of the World Bank Group. The IFC provides loans to promote the growth
than 25 percent of the total estimated costs. Working with over 750 financial
institutions, its 184 members provide about a third of the financing provided by
international institutions to the private sector. Another Bank family member, the
currency restrictions, and losses stemming from civil war or ethnic conflict. In 1960,
of fifty years.
Today, about eighty countries are eligible for this concessional lending based upon
GNP per. IDA funds have to be continually replenished or added to by major donor
countries. Currently, the World Bank‘s 188 members together with its affiliates such
as the IDA provide over $30 billion annually to 100 countries for more than 300
projects. Since the 1950s, there have been major shifts in development strategies
transportation, or education. At times the World Bank, the IMF, and the UN itself
have been at the forefront of articulating new strategies, and at other times they
have responded to changes initiated by both the bilateral donor community and NGOs.
During the 1950s and 1960s, the World Bank emphasized large infrastructure
In the 1970s, the Bank shifted to a basic needs orientation, funding projects in
health, education, and housing geared to improve the economic needs of the
masses. During the 1980s, the mantra became private sector involvement, followed by
92
sustainable economic development. In the 1990s, the focus shifted to good
governance. Of these various changes, two trends have had the most profound
impact.
First is the reorientation toward support of the private sector in the 1980s.
investment, the Bank was prohibited from making loans without government
guarantees until the IFC was established. The Bank now strongly supports private
expectation that growth will trickle down and everyone will eventually benefit. Second
are the changes consistent with the sustainable development goals. The Bank became
more open to involving NGOs in planning and executing projects in the 1990s in order
to change individual lives. And the Bank began to recognize that sustainable
development, whether through public or private funds, requires good governance. But
in the early 1990s, the term governance was left purposefully vague or defined
very narrowly because of fear that the Bank‘s neutrality and a political mandate would
development. When the staff framed the issue in economic terms that corruption had
negative effects on development they were able to establish their case. But
developing good governance and rooting out systemic corruption require a long-term
commitment that the Bank has had difficulty sustaining, since it has a history of
making disbursements even when there is evidence of corruption in its own projects
(Weaver 2008: 108–113). Thus the World Bank has increasingly addressed political
Originally, the IMF‘s purpose was to lend money to countries to meet short-term fluctuations
in currency exchange rates, thus enabling member states to establish free convertibility
among their currencies and maintain stable exchange rates. Funds to meet temporary
93
Members contributed to the Fund according to quotas negotiated every five years.
These were paid both in gold and in local currency (later, so-called special drawing
rights provided added liquidity). Members could withdraw funds according to the
each transaction plus a charge based on length of time the money was borrowed.
These arrangements were typically for twelve to eighteen months. While quota
restrictions have been relaxed, the IMF still meets this need through ―standby‖
arrangements. From the beginning, the IMF‘s Executive Board allowed countries with
greater involvement in international finance and larger quota shares to also wield
more votes. The result is that the five largest vote-holders can shape IMF policy, not
only in terms of overall policy direction but also with respect to particular loans.
Beginning with the 1982 Mexican debt crisis, the IMF took on the role of
involved in bailouts and structural adjustment lending. It took the 1998 Asian
financial to demonstrate that all crises are not alike and that the IMF‘s prescriptions
were not always correct. Still, through the 1980s and 1990s, the IMF requirements
liberalization and private sector involvement. In other words, the diverse range of
suggested policies all which are compatible with liberal economic norms.
IMF Reform
In the wake of the 1997 crisis, the IMF set up systems to improve monitoring of the
meltdowns. It also set up a credit line to provide another account from which
countries in trouble could draw, despite some opposition by Germany and other ―tight
money European countries. As part of the negotiation on the credit line, the IMF put
94
in place a system whereby governments would be expected to divulge details of their
national accounts that had previously been confidential. For those more eager to
trade on global capital markets, even more information was expected. However, the
IMF has resisted providing specific credit scores on countries, although enough
information is now available to draw fairly specific inferences. Following the 2008
financial crisis and the elevation of the G-20 as a key part of global economic
governance, proposals were put forward to significantly increase the quotas, and
hence the votes, of G-20 members that were considered underrepresented on the
IMF Executive Board. Specifically, reforms agreed to in 2010 will double the quotas,
With that realignment, China would become the third largest member country in the
IMF, and Brazil, China, India, and Russia would be among the ten largest shareholders
in the Fund. At the same time, the quotas and voting share of the poorest member
countries would be preserved. Despite acceptance in March 2015 by 147 IMF member
states, representing 77 percent of voting shares, however, the reforms had yet to be
approved by the US Congress, leaving in doubt whether the quotas will be realigned in
The third part of the Bretton Woods system was the stillborn International Trade
Organization. The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade took its place in 1948; its
members (called contracting parties) were initially the largest developed countries,
excluding the Eastern bloc and the Soviet Union as well as most less developed
countries. With the accession of China and Russia and others in this century, WTO
membership has reached 160. In 1995, the WTO replaced GATT as the arbiter of
trade rules, providing a formal organization for trade for the first time. It
Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) and the General Agreement
on Trade in Services (GATS). In all, WTO trade rules include over sixty agreements
and decisions.
With a wide range of goods and services under its jurisdiction and strengthened
dispute settlement mechanisms, the WTO has become a lightning rod for groups from
both developed and developing countries who see the organization as the culprit in the
domestic interests and favoring the interests of major developed countries over poor
countries. Even though each WTO member has a voice through the consensus
procedure, decisions often involve ―unequally matched states against one another in
chaotic bouts of negotiating which has seen developed countries secure more of the
economic opportunities they already have while offering developing countries very
Still others point out that although some developing states participate in the WTO‘s
dispute settlement system, the vast majority do not, because of the considerable
cost of proving injury from the trade policies of another country and the reluctance
more general level, many are critical of the effects of reducing barriers to trade and
making the world more ―globalized.‖ Scholars‘ some-times question whether the world
is globalizing and even more so whether it should be (Veseth 2010). Among activists,
anti- globalization NGOs are major opponents of WTO activity, charging that the
WTO‘s power to make regulations that have consequences and settle disputes with
96
In addition, there is a widely held perception that the organization is captive to
the demands of rich governments and big MNCs. To other NGOs, the WTO‘s
adherence to the interests of free trade undermines the application of labor and
joined the opposition, believing that the WTO privileges economic liberalization over
social values. The environmental groups argue that the trade rules need to be more
before WTO accords are passed. In 1996, the WTO rejected negotiations with labor
groups, referring the promotion of labor standards to the ILO instead, where
compliance procedures are generally loosely enforced. In contrast, labor groups from
the developed world have lobbied for the WTO to take up the labor-friendly agenda,
since the WTO has the power to institute trade sanctions for labor violations.
politics. Hence the study of international organizations and global governance includes
the many regional and sub-regional organizations in Europe, Asia, Africa, the Middle
East, and the Americas; their efforts to address security, economic, environmental,
and human rights issues; and the interactions between and among global and regional
organizations. For the purpose of this course, this module only focuses only on the
The OAU, placed in a longer term of historical current, is a manifestation of the Pan-
African movement which originated in the USA during the late 19th century. In the
USA, thousands of blacks, with African origins found it intolerable to bear the
leaders, namely WEB Du Bois (1868- 1963) and Marcus Garvey (1885-1940) raised a
flag of revolt against the then prevailing injustice and chose to speak for the entire
black race which was leading a dehumanized existence. They subordinated the
97
immediate problems of American blacks to a grand and enlarged vision of Pan-
Africanism, which, in essence, stood for the unity and dignity of the black race.
participants issued the Declaration to the Colonial Peoples, supporting the right of
political freedom and self-government. In the late 1950s, under the initiative of
continental unity. Prior to the birth of the OAU, there was an inter-state politics in
Africa which was characterized by growing rivalry between the Casablanca and
the top of this, they were sympathetic towards the Soviet Union due to concrete
soviet support their activities. Moreover, this group had a radical approach involving
the creation of the federation African states with joint institutions with a joint
military command. In the other hand, Monrovia group, was constituted by the
Brazzaville group like most moderate Francophone states such as ivory coast, Gabon,
Senegal etc. in the meantime, there were neutrals members like Ethiopia, Liberia and
Somalia which were neutrals towards rivalry of Casablanca and Brazzaville group. It
However, these groups had a lot in common. These commonalties were backed by the
mediatory efforts of uncommitted states like Ethiopia gave birth to the organization
of African unity (OAU) in Addis Ababa, Ethiopia in May 1963. Accordingly, the leaders
whose resolutions would carry moral rather than legal obligations. Three overriding
98
principles guided the organization. First, all states were sovereign equals. Each state
would have an equal say, with no greater weight given to larger or more powerful
states. Second, states agreed not to interfere in the domestic affairs of fellow
members. Third, territorial borders were sacrosanct, with no room for alteration in
the status quo. No longer did states want to be dominated by outsiders, risk border
changes that would unleash ethnic rivalries and invite outside intervention, or cause
So at the outset, the OAU was designed as a voluntary organization limited by its
founding principles. Over time, each of these principles has been compromised.
Although all states are legally equal, there was implicit recognition that some states
Egypt, or South Africa. The principle of noninterference in domestic affairs was also
violated, most often during the 1990s, when human rights violations were condemned
by other states. On a few occasions the OAU also supported changes in state
Designed as a weak intergovernmental forum, the OAU did enjoy some notable
forum for mediating disputes among states. The OAU sponsored for the first time an
ad hoc, all-African military force to help establish law and order in Chad in 1981. At
regional military forces for a specific action. The OAU played a significant role in at
least nine cases of securing troop withdrawals, using its diplomatic pressure to
influence both African states and outside powers. The liberation of South Africa
from white minority rule, a central OAU goal, was achieved in1994.
On economic and development issues, however, the OAU was largely silent, essentially
deferring to the UN‘s Economic Commission on Africa. Since the conditions under
which the OAU was founded had changed and the organization‘s weakness contributed
99
to Africa‘s marginalization in international politics, the OAU was replaced by the
African Union in 2002, following two years of negotiations. Although unity remains an
The AU carried over some of the OAU‘s overarching principles, including sovereign
equality of states and respect for existing territorial borders. Additional principles
found in its constitutive act strengthen the organization to respond more effectively
to Africa‘s problems.
circumstances, namely war crimes, genocide and crimes against humanity.‖ This is a
radical departure from the OAU, although the vague language is open to varying
good governance, democratic principles, and respect for human rights, explicitly
OAU, the AU can suspend or expel illegitimate governments and has done so,
reinstating states when the governments are stabilized—a provision analogous to the
Third, resolving disputes peacefully and prohibiting use of force are a key principle.
The AU Constitutive Act also links this peace and security principle with economic
development, noting that the latter depends on the security of states and people.
The principles behind the AU, then, are more progressive than those of the
former OAU. Leaders pledge to hold free elections and to allow opposition parties
while these objectives and pledges have been favorably received, their application
100
has been uneven. Some scholars explain these new principles ―have been
internalized unevenly by the AU‘s member states‖ and the move from
indifference has been slow. That shift (states care and may act) has made it
and governance agenda. In 2003 the African Peer Review Mechanism was created, a
voluntary group of experts who work alongside governments and civil society groups
rule of law. Following an investigation and a report, the expert panel makes
recommendations for improvement. While states are not legally bound to implement
the suggestions, and many states may not have the resources to do so, the process
for those participating carries moral authority and signals commitment by African
states to the new agenda, with over a third of the AU‘s members participating. That
commitment was reinforced in the AU Commission‘s 2009– 2012 strategic plan and
the 2011 summit, which emphasized Africans‘ ―shared values.‖ In addition, the
Charter on Democracy, Elections and Governance entered into force in 2012, bringing
Modern slavery, conflicts, terrorism, resource contestations and localized strife including
those associated with herdsmen versus farmers over grazing land, rising inequality and poverty
are some of the most notable manifestations of Africa‘s governance, development and peace
varied global players, over its roles, impact and reflectivity in international discourse. The AU
is in charge for move on a united continental agenda and has settled an aspiring plan equally
integrated, prosperous and peaceful Africa, driven by its citizens and representing a dynamic
101
force in the international arena‘. However, the continental body has lingered weak for
resolution for the reason that of insufficient political will, a mismatch between its ambition
and realistic technical capacities; and overwhelming dependence on voluntary donor support for
the implementation of its decisions, programs and overall mandate. Such, is the circumstance
of the conclusion on the Institutional Reform of the AU that was embraced in the course of
the 27th Ordinary Session of Assembly of Heads of States held from 17 to 18 July in Kigali,
Rwanda.
essentially jointly strengthening aspects to the reform, which from time to time make
it challenging to coherent consistently. The 2017 report by the President Paul Kagame
The first side of the reform is to realign AU‘s institutions. Presently, the AU
that there are currently eight Commission directorates, 31 departments and offices
audit of institutional bottlenecks and inefficiencies as well as re-evaluates the size and
capabilities of AU Commission structures. Moreover, AU organs, and agencies such as the New
Partnership for African Development, the African Peer Review Mechanism (APRM), the Pan-
102
African Parliament, Peace and Security Council and judicial institutions are to be reviewed and
strengthened. Except for NEPAD and APRM, the current reforms are entirely communicative
development agency accountable for providing the development way out to Africa‘s
governance, peace and security challenges. The catastrophe to success- fully monitor
the execution of strategic decisions made by AU Heads of State and Government residues a
serious gap in realizing structural efficiency. Consequently, the APRM will be held
together to pathway an enactment and supervise checking and assessment in vital governance
areas on the continent. The second vital of the reform is to reduce and deepen the focus of
the AU to key priorities with a continental scope. Thus, the institutional reform program
suggests that the AU should focus on four main strategic priorities, namely political affairs,
peace and security, economic integration and Africa‘s global representation and voice.
proceed the principal in the seven ambitious goals delimited in the Agenda 2063, namely
continent, politically united and based on the ideals of pan-Africanism and the vision of
Africa‘s renaissance; an African of good governance, democracy, respect for human rights,
justice and the rule of law; a peaceful and secure Africa; Africa with a strong cultural
identity, common heritage, shared values and ethics; Africa whose development is people-
driven, relying on the potential of African people, especially its women and youth, and caring
for children; and Africa as a strong, united and influential global player and partner. Despite
the fact these ambitious goals are significant to the continent; the AU can unable to have the
reasonable benefit to attain the goals on its own effectively. The continental organization has,
for instance, fought to answer to humanitarian emergencies, enforces long- term post-conflict
reconstruction and development or in fact promotes a blue economy through the development
implementing the AU priorities, thus, is the basic to endorse, improve and endure partnerships.
103
RECs/RMs, member States, research institutions, civil society and other continental
institutions, are further- more crucial to reprioritization of the AU‘s focus in line with the
institutions, bilateral partners possibly will moreover show indispensable and basic roles. Yet,
AU‘s leadership and clarity of desire and needs will be vibrant in connecting the assets of
these different actors in completing the progression of its central four priorities under the
reform plan, however correspondingly, in meeting those that transcends them but are
The third primacy of the AU institutional reform plan is the imperative of relating
women and youth quotas in the recruitments, electoral processes and appointment
across the AU system. It also contains inspiring the involvement of the private sector
to support the AU vigorously. Other enlightened plan has been projected, intended at
endorsing continent-wide public goods and services such as rolling out of the African
The fourth primacy connects to the need to manage the business of the AU
with the RECs. Furthermore, the role of the embarrassment of allies will endure to be
mandatory in realizing AU‘s ambitious goals. But, there is a political consent between
AU member States that the roles of partners would need to be better coordinated,
limited and more aligned with AU‘s needs. At the functioning level, the interior
Commissioners pre-dates the current reform. Unquestionably, there are several other
104
encouraging organizational cultures regarded as by some extremely proficient,
overreached and under- remunerated staff within the AU Commission. Yet, the total
system residues pathetic in its bureaucracy, experiences inadequate staffing and has
been criticized by its member States for deficient performance across all levels of
the Commission.
The fifth and the greatest imperative priority is the journey for endorsing the
financial autonomy of the AU. The ambition for expectable and amplified funding to
the AU from its member States was a precarious driver to the comprehensive
The variety of Africa‘s challenges implies that the AU alone may not continuously
have the financial resources to address them exclusively. Nevertheless, the over-
responsibility to its member States, is a wide opening to the deviating and sometimes
inconsistent interests from donor States/partners, and possibly will have made the
institution defenseless to the risk of negative consequences including but not limited
to possible espionage.
decision on financing the Union. AU member States fixed to institute a 0.2% levy on
all eligible imported goods into the continent. The conclusion was heralded by, inter
alia, a Summit decision in January 2015, where member States promised to give 100%
of the Union‘s budget; 75% of the Union‘s programme budget and 25% of the Union‘s
budget towards peace support operations.33 The AU Summits of July 2015 and
January 2016, respectively, also reiterated this decision on the financing of the
Union. It looks the space of the unending reform is to structurally transform the AU
105
finance most of its activities. Especially, the institution will be projected to reach
The EU is a unique entity that has become deeply institutionalized and involves far more
commitment than any other regional organization. Whereas the initial steps involved only six
Western European states, today twenty-eight states are full members. The EU‘s development
embodies a process of integration, where steps taken in one area have spilled over into others
over time. It encompasses aspects of both supra nationalism (sometimes also referred to as
federalism) and inter-governmentalism. European Union development has involved both the
widening of membership and the deepening of ties among the member states, integrating
economies and societies more closely, and expanding the authority of community institutions
over the member states. Much of the policymaking in Europe today is common or EU policy,
The EU affects the daily lives of its more than 500 million citizens, most of who can
now move freely between member states and carry EU passports. The EU commands
18 percent of world GDP, and citizens in nineteen member countries use the euro,
to voting in the World Trade Organization; with its own legal system, parliament,
bureaucracy, currency, and court, its complex institutions resemble those of nation-
effort by European leaders to find ways to overcome the national rivalries that had
led to two devastating world wars in the first half of the twentieth century. The
United States was committed to promoting democracy and a more open international
106
other policies that had marked the rivalries among European powers (and excluded US
did internal threats from strong communist parties in France and Italy. A desire to
enmesh the Germans in international agreements that would prevent them from posing
future threats to European security was another motivating factor. The United
States added incentives through post– World War II Marshall Plan requirements that
the European governments cooperate in developing a plan for utilizing aid, formulate a
joint effort rather than submit a series of national requests, and create an
So, too, did economic interests of powerful sectors, particularly in the French and
German economies (notably heavy industry and agriculture), along with trends in the
post–World War II international economy (notably rising trade and capital flows
among the industrialized countries), which led governments to look for ways to
The European Coal and Steel Community: The birth of European integration occurred in May
1950 with a proposal by then–French foreign minister Robert Schuman to place Franco-
German coal and steel production under a common ―high authority. This meant accepting
recently defeated Germany as an economic equal and handing over authority for both
countries‘ key coal and steel industries to a supranational authority. The result was the
European Coal and Steel Community, established in 1951 with six member states (France,
Germany, Italy, Belgium, Luxembourg, and the Nether-lands). Great Britain rejected an
invitation to join, because of strong sentiments in both major political parties against loss of
sovereignty and national control over coal and steel. The ECSC was successful enough in
boosting coal and steel production that the six member states agreed in 1958 to expand their
cooperation under the European Atomic Energy, Community and the European Economic
Community. The founding documents of these three organizations form the constitutional
107
basis of the European Union. The governing institutions of the three have been merged.
The Treaties of Rome represented recognition that the community could not develop the coal
and steel sectors in isolation from other economic sectors. One treaty committed members to
creating a common market over a period of twelve years through removal of all restrictions on
internal trade; a common external tariff; reduction of barriers to free movement of people,
services, and capital; the development of common agricultural and transport policies; and the
The second treaty created Euratom to establish a common market for atomic energy.
In 1962, the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) came into existence, with a single market for
farm products and guaranteed prices for farmers. In 1968, two years ahead of schedule, they
completed an industrial customs union and had removed enough internal barriers to trade to
agree on a common external tariff with nonmember countries and to form a single negotiating
party in international trade talks. In 1969, governments agreed on the principles of economic
and monetary union, both of which were regarded as essential to achieving political union,
although the sovereignty that would be lost with monetary union was particularly difficult for
them to contemplate at the time. Despite disagreement over whether economic or monetary
union should come first, they did agree to begin efforts toward controlling exchange-rate
Enlargement: Slow economic growth in the 1970s stalled any deepening of European
integration, but there was movement on another front. In 1973, the community‘s first
enlargement took place with the accession of Great Britain, Ireland, and Denmark (Norwegian
voters rejected the accession agreement their government had signed). Later in the 1970s, a
strong desire to bolster the new democracies in Greece, Spain, and Portugal provided political
impetus for their accession. In 1994, the decision was made to admit Finland, Sweden, and
Austria. Then, in anticipation of further enlargements to former Soviet- bloc states in Eastern
Europe, the European Council delineated conditions for new members, including respect for
democracy, rule of law, and human rights, protection of minorities, a functioning market
108
economy, and a demonstrated capacity to implement past and future EU rules and legislation.
These so-called Copenhagen conditions have provided benchmarks for candidate countries as
well as incentives for making the requisite changes in their economies, political systems, and
laws. Three further enlargements, in 2004, 2007, and 2013, brought in eleven Eastern
European and two Mediterranean countries. The EU now encompasses much of the continent
Deepening integration:
The process of deepening European integration has entailed completing the creation
of a single market, expanding the range of common policies, the establishment of the
European Union itself, and the monetary union and single currency. It has involved
In 1987, European Community members took their most important step since the
Treaty of Rome with their adoption of the Single European Act (SEA), which
established the goal of completing a single market by the end of 1992. This meant a
complicated process of removing all remaining physical, fiscal, and technical barriers
standards, varying levels of indirect taxation such as value-added taxes, and removing
The changes, however, allowed banks and companies to do business throughout the
community; allowed EC residents to live, work, and draw pensions anywhere in the EC;
and ended monopolies in sectors such as electricity and telecommunications. They also
included a number of important institutional changes such as greater power for the
European Parliament (EP). Even before the SEA‘s 1992 deadline for completing the
single market, the twelve members signed the Maastricht Treaty on European Union,
calling for ―an ever closer union among the peoples of Europe.‖ The original European
The second pillar comprises Common Foreign and Security Policy (CFSP), while the third
109
includes justice and home affairs—new areas of common policy. Both the second and third
pillars, however, remain largely matters for individual governments or, at best,
intergovernmental agreement. Maastricht also gave impetus to European monetary union with
agreement to institute a single European currency in 1999, and created a nascent European
citizenship with a common passport and rights to live and vote wherever citizens liked. It
Ratification of the Maastricht Treaty encountered problems when Danish voters rejected it in
Following agreement that Denmark could opt out of certain provisions in the treaty, Danish
voters passed a second referendum. This, however, was a wake-up call to EU leaders that
deepening integration was not accepted by all of Europe‘s citizens and prompted debate about
the democratic deficit‖ within the EU, whereby most decisions have been made
Three additional treaties have dealt with enlargement and institutional reform.
The Treaty of Amsterdam, which was signed in 1997 and came into force in 1999,
gave a green light to further enlargement and dealt with issues such as social policy,
immigration, asylum, the environment, and consumer protection. In 2003, the Treaty
of Nice entered into force, bringing changes important to an enlarged and more
modifying the weights in the EU‘s system of qualified majority voting, and limiting the
2002–2003 to address more of the structural problems anticipated with the 2004
The 2007 Lisbon Treaty incorporates many of the draft constitution‘s provisions
designed to improve the efficiency of institutions and make them more democratic. It
also provides the EU with international legal status, enabling it to sign international
treaties or be a member of other IGOs, and made the EU Charter of Rights legally
110
binding on members. The Lisbon Treaty was rejected by Ireland‘s voters in 2008
(supranational, executive, and bureaucratic body of the EU), Council of the European Union
(make decisions on law and policy), Council of Ministers (key body for major EU initiatives such
as concluding the single market, monetary union, enlargement, foreign policy issues,
constitutional reform, and the European debt crisis), Parliament (the voice of EU citizens
which is directly elected by voters in the member states) and European Court of Justice
(power to rule on the constitutionality of all EU law). There is different European Union
specialized and agencies that have been created over the years as the scope of European
integration and needs have required. These include the European Police Office, or Europol, to
facilitate police cooperation since the opening of borders between member states; the
European Central Bank, created in 1998 in conjunction with the creation of the single currency
and catapulted to greater visibility with the Eurozone crisis after 2008 and the European
Investment Bank, set up in 1958 to provide long-term finance for capital development
projects.
EU common policies: Beginning with trade and agriculture, the EU has moved progressively into
more and more areas of policy, ranging from fisheries and food safety to transport,
competition, social policy, regional development, monetary policy and common currency,
environment, justice and home affairs, external relations, and human rights. Three different
approaches have been used to advance common policies: mutual recognition of different
harmonization of standards (the most difficult, since this requires agreeing on a new common
set of standards).
111
CHAPTER FOUR
Unit Introduction
In the previous units you were introduced to the evolution of public sector institutional
since the official launching of the project of development since 1950s. The previous
units, have given you a perspective as to the nature and evolution of institutional
reforms.
In this unit, the focus will be on specific reforms that are implemented in the second
and third wave of the reform and the specific details of the first wave reform are
omitted for the want of space. However, it must be pointed out that it is impossible to
make a clear cut distinction between the specific reforms carried out in this waves of
reforms as most of the issues involved in the reform are cross cutting and often same
set of reforms were introduced in different waves, albeit with a different focus.
However, no matter the wave a particular reform introduced and whatever the emphasis
laid in different waves, the reform of public sector institutions can be divided into four
main areas: Civil service reform, which is concerned with human resources in the public
sector such as capacity, wages and conditions; Reforming the machinery of government
which is concerned with the rules, institutions, and structure of the administration
necessary to carry out government policy; Reforming the public sector revenue and
these areas of reforms, the first three are aimed at transforming public administration
while the fourth one is broader in scope and amounts to a body politic reform. The first
three, which are largely influenced by the NPM movement, will be discussed in this
chapter and the last one (integrated governance reforms) discussed in the last
chapter. Accordingly, the unit is divided in to three broad sections. In the first section
discuss civil service reforms. The second section devoted to the reforms intended to
112
transform of the machinery of government and the last section focus on public sector
Unit Objectives
Dear distance learner, by the end of this unit you should be able to:
Define the civil service and explain experiences of Civil service reform in
developing countries
Explain the context and the specifics of public sector financial management
reforms
Civil service is differentiated from public service and indeed, in every case found in
the literature the civil service is defined as a subset of persons employed to provide
the term.
The differences arise in two respects. One concerns the composition of that subset,
that is, the categories of public service employees that are considered civil servants.
113
Thus, military personnel are generally excluded, but many categories of civilian
employment are also excluded, such as those in local government, state enterprises,
In addition, most authors choose to exclude elected officials, and, though rarely
employees, including administrative personnel in the military and social services sectors.
Often, however, authors fail to specify which public service workers are included in
their discussion.
A second source of definitional variation arises when the term ―civil service is applied
In practice, public service can be carried out under a variety of contractual and
administrative arrangements, but many authors reserve the term ―civil service
Such laws differ not only from private labor legislation but also from a variety of
contractual arrangements used for particular public services. Under that institutional
definition, the principal subject of analysis is the functioning of the legally defined
civil service regime, paid out of tax revenues in the form of budgeted posts, rather
than the broader human resource management problem of the public sector since the
latter can include a variety of employment regimes with a variety of sources of finance.
In most cases public employment under a formal employment even within the more
In examining the experience with civil service reform, it is important to first touch on
There is an immediate challenge in identifying who is a member of the civil service. In addition,
there are at least three key organizational features of those employment regimes, namely
114
their organizational principles, forms, and specific arrangements that help define the civil
service as an institution.
Scholars agree that civil services of developed and developing countries have been
organized following common principles that, taken together, have made the civil service
Merit,
Competence,
Continuity,
Accountability, and They underlie the traditional or basic model of the civil service.
Merit-based system:
Means seeking out the most talented citizens in a fair and open competition.
criteria for selection as defined in a civil service law. Once appointed, civil
servants are granted job security with many legal and administrative
115
civil servants. Since civil servants are not always committed to the public‘s
discretion to monitor and control civil servants, to uphold the legality and
This basic model characterizes the nature of public service as different from private
holder accountable to a set of formal rules that can be observed and regulated
rather than to the informal and unregulated rules governing patron-client relations in
The interpretation of job security‘ has evolved over the years. What was once equated
with absolute tenure is now more commonly considered to mean protection from
arbitrary dismissal. In this sense, job security‘ does not protect staff that are
incompetent or otherwise not meeting job requirements. But making such distinctions
has often proven to be difficult in weak institutional settings that do not have a merit-
Understanding and pursuing civil service reform begins with a broader vision of an effective
public sector. Schneider and Heredia see civil service reform as a sub-class of three major
models of public sector reform, each defined according to its main objectives and measures.
These are:
Weberian reforms,
accountability reforms,
Managerial Reforms.
116
In their view, Weberian reforms were historically a first step towards better
particularism and politicization in the bureaucracy and to counter the spoils system
administration.
The accountability reforms, designed to make the bureaucracy more accountable and
Managerial Reforms, which aimed to make the bureaucracy more efficient and
customer oriented.
Nunberg and Kaufman recognize the usefulness of this historical distinction, but see it
as more applicable to OECD experience, and point out that the more fundamental nature
of civil service problems in developing countries often has required a combination of the
three approaches.
Although these broader models of public administration have in turn lead to different
around the core values of a good‘ civil service as noted above: merit, competence,
greater, however, with regard to what the civil service should be doing differently to
Civil service reform (CSR), which implies developing the capacity of the civil service to
fulfill its mandate, defined to include issues of recruitment and promotion, pay, number
In the 1980‘s CSR focused on the need to contain the costs of public sector employment
through retrenchment and restructuring, but has broadened towards focusing on the
longer-term goal of creating a government workforce of the right size and skills-mix,
and with the right motivation, professional ethos, client focus, and accountability.
117
The overall cost of the civil service remains a valid concern, of course. Addressing the
causes of and reversing the increasing civil service wage bill experienced by many
countries in the 1970s and 1980s remains a primary concern. More recently, added to
these problems, a number of others have been better understood that relate more to
the quality of the civil service and their motivation, such as:
Recruitment and promotion systems that poorly reflect the realities of the
country, are often overly concerned with formal education, and fail to attract or
The following are the main issues that are commonly considered in designing CSR
programmes.
Mission
the statement itself is part of the process, as is the dissemination and articulation of
the mission internally and externally. While by no means anything more than a first
step, having a mission orientation can help establish a clear sense of direction and
commitment within the organization, either for the organization as a whole and for
Helping managers clarify in their own minds what the business of the organization is
Providing the focus for managers and other staff in meeting organizational goals
objectives
118
Providing a clear articulation for the public of the organization‘s reason for being.
Training
and training is a central feature of almost all PAR programmes. Interventions range
from specialist technical training to general educational and management skills. The big
issues in training are: a) the appropriateness of the training; b) selecting the candidates
for training; and c) retaining trained employees once they have been trained. While
there are a number of types of training that could be chosen, in-service training remains
the most common. For more junior personnel these could include training at a local
training college, or deployment, while for mid-level and senior personnel, specialized
training has proven helpful. Study trips abroad are generally popular, and can bring
All training provides a form of perk, and scrupulous transparency is required in the
servants unless there is a program to improve employment conditions. The fear that
newly trained civil servants will be wooed away to the private sector is often overblown
(since civil servants rarely choose to relinquish their benefits), but the danger of
Merit based public employment systems can be broadly divided into career systems and
position-based systems. A career system is ‗closed‘ in the sense that entry is usually
to the lower ranks and more senior positions are filled from within the ranks. In
119
position-based systems (also called job-in-rank systems), on the other hand, the
emphasis is placed on selecting the right candidate for the position to be filled. The
career system is most often associated with civil code traditions and the position-based
Choosing the appropriate system is the responsibility of the government and must
result from consultation and deliberation among the technical staff involved and
relevant policy makers. Because so many of the recent advances in thinking in public
administration have taken place within the Anglo-Saxon tradition, there is a tendency
to favor features of the position system. Each system has its merits and disadvantages.
Where the position-based system can bring new talent into the civil service where it is
needed, and tends to free managers to focus on results, a career system is better at
providing incentives for good performance and at ensuring that investments in training
Almost all developed country systems are increasingly hybridising and adopting aspects
of both a position and a career system. Thus, countries with a civil code tradition can
find useful examples of a position structure in developments in the French model over
the last decades, for example, without having to rely simply on variations of the Anglo-
Saxon tradition.
There are usually two main types of management arrangements for the personnel
function: the Anglo-Saxon type Public (or Civil) Service Commission (PSC) and its
an executive office under the Prime Minister or a Cabinet Minister in charge of the
Civil Service which is usually found in the countries under civil law. In addition to these
there is usually also a financial control organ in the Ministry of Finance, in charge of
120
The second choice that needs to be made is between a centralized and decentralized
leaving the centre with the responsibility of defining broad policy guidelines, issuing
executive positions are kept under direct control of the central agency.
Modern bureaucracies are founded on the premise that individuals who work in them
serve the public good as opposed to catering to personal interests. This presupposes a
basic income that will allow public servants to carry out their duties without succumbing
efficiency and accountability. The fiscal objective often implies pay reductions, for
instance by reducing the wage bill. However, other objectives, including those of
efficiency, may imply pay increases in the attempts to increase real wages for lower-
Poor pay and compensation regimes due, among other things, to overstaffing lead to low
motivation, corruption, loss of qualified staff, poor services in remote areas, and
undermine investments in training. There are four main issues with pay and
compensation, all of which derive in large part from efforts to contain the overall wage
Wages are too low – public sector staff in developing countries often face pay
scales that at best are barely sufficient to live off; are not competitive with
Wages are compressed – wages of senior personnel do not reflect their skills,
alternative rewards systems taken over, but these create opaque and arbitrary
systems of compensation that make wage bills difficult to monitor, manage and
contain.
Owing to this, pay and grading reform measures have been at the forefront of pay
and employment measures. Pay and grading reforms generally has five objectives:
The World Bank and other agencies have tried to link the policy of wage decompression
smaller number of public employees who will remain in the service, as well as offer
attractive salaries to senior officials. Bangura (2000) has reported how this policy has
been pursued in a few African countries, including Ghana and Uganda. In these
countries, government has made a strong commitment to get out of the low wage-
corruption, low morale-low performance-trap that has bedeviled their public services.
Massive retrenchments have been carried out and compensation and redundancy
There are reports that many countries, including the Gambia and Guinea, have made
122
considerable progress in simplifying their grading structures. This, in turn, has acted as
a magnet to attract and motivate some top professionals including those with scarce
skills such as physicians and accountants. The reality in Africa, however, is that even in
countries that have made tremendous efforts to restore living wages in their public
services, there remains the problem of paying competitive wages that will retain or
attract the best staff. Despite reforms, salaries are still much too low in many
African public services to retain professional staff, which has contributed to the
―brain drain‖ that Africa has been experiencing since independence. Significant
increases in salaries to attract and retain well-skilled staff may affect resources for
other service delivery inputs. How to improve public sector pay and the quantity of
other inputs that are essential for efficient service delivery is a challenge that low-
rewards for good performers. In practice, almost all performance management systems
More recent approaches have stressed focusing on results rather than personal traits,
test competence, and contribute towards a climate of open discussion within the public
service.
of the accountability problems in the civil service. In pursuit of the goal of performance
i.e. vesting the public manager with the power and authority s/he needs to serve the
citizen, and strengthen the links between government and its diverse clientele in civil
society. Underlying the empowerment premise is the assumption that the power or
123
authority that is ―delegated‖ to the average manager would not only be shared with the
subordinates, but would also be exercised for the public good (Hope, 2001). This is
assumed to increase efficiency, based on the notion that public sector managers are
hampered by rules and regulations, and have few incentives to take risks and to be
perform, make it easier to establish the basis for managerial accountability and to
political accountability by making it easier for managers to match targets with political
priorities. Politicians can, in turn, hold managers accountable for their performance, and
targets are further steps toward better democratic control and accountability of the
organizations at large, and allows for the development of indicators against which
contracting are to clarify the objectives of service organizations and their relationship
conformity with bureaucratic rules and regulations. The setting of specific performance
targets, in a format that can be monitored, is intended to provide a basis for evaluating
124
illustrates the shift in emphasis from the input and procedure-oriented controls of
In line with the new institutionalist perspective in PSM reforms, as reflected in public
choice theories, and in the policy prescriptions based on them, performance contracting
instrument for restructuring PEs and for managing the Government-PE interface.
Underlying performance contracting, and in line with NPM, is the belief that while
for performance.
In little more than a decade, Ghana has transformed the structure and strategy of its
rural water supply sector. By 2000, district assemblies and communities played a
significant role in planning supplies. The new policy and structure has attracted extra
funds, and accelerated the work. This reform process started with an extended
dialogue with the major stakeholders in the sector, out of which a new rural water and
sanitation policy was developed. The policy was then implemented in several large pilot
projects, supported by a number of external agencies, and finally the lessons from
those projects were incorporated into the national programme itself. The success of
this approach was due to the fact that national and international NGOs were contracted
to build the capacity of local-level NGOs and CSOs. The Community Water Supply
and lean, below 200 staff, and highly decentralized to its ten regional offices.
Whilst there have been some constraints on the capacity to implement performance
contracting in public enterprises in Africa, the World Bank has approved performance
contracts as one of the principal measures of reform for PEs, and the system has been
adopted in a number of African countries including Nigeria, Ghana and the Gambia.
125
Politicization and Patronage
Civil service reform efforts around the world, to various extents, have all stressed the
need for increased de-politicization of the civil service, promoting the ideal of a neutral
and merit-based civil service. Evidence shows however that pure merit-based systems
are the exception and that political appointments are common in most civil services.
Those in favor of a patronage system argue that it allows for the establishment of a
cadre of loyal and efficient civil servants. It also enhances democracy, as it enables the
regular rotation of senior staff in accordance with the will of the people. Those in favor
of the merit system argue that it complies better with a rights- based approach to civil
A more realistic policy line takes into consideration the pros and cons of both the merit
system and the patronage system, in a given political and socio-economic context. In
and balances that limit the discretionary powers of politicians over recruitments and
effective system of checks and balances. The following elements ensure that this is
achieved:
selection process and inclusion of formal checks and balances and appeals in
panel)
A code of conduct that stresses the political neutrality and loyalty of the civil
126
servants (i.e. they commit to execute and support the policies of the
government in place).
Constitutional and legal guarantees (Civil Service Act) stressing the right of
There are few studies that compare developing and transition country
Causes of Reform
Most authors agree that the factors that have driven reform in developing countries include
Declining confidence in government and citizens demands for changes in the government,
127
Studies of transition countries confirm the obvious pressure for reform created by the
collapse of authoritarian regimes starting in 1989. External pressures from donors, especially
in Africa, European Union, in the case of transition countries, should be added to the list of
causal agents.
In view of the diversity of factors and the many differences among countries in this
importance of each of these reasons across countries and regions. At the same time, it
is evident that many of the above-mentioned factors, whether once-over (like changes
the growing power of public opinion), are exogenous sources of pressure for reform
Some of these developing and transition countries have attempted to introduce various
elements of NPM over the last number of years, while others have pursued a mixed
strategy in which there are elements of the basic model (Weberian) and NPM. As noted
become increasingly important for the design of reform, expectations and performance
measures, diagnosis, and the package of specific reform proposals all differ to quite a
degree as a result.
The introduction of NPM has been urged, in many cases, by international organizations.
There are some critics regarding the role of these organizations in influencing the
reform agenda of these countries. For some authors, like Ingraham, there has been
Scholars agree that CSR reform efforts in developing and transition countries over the
last 20 years have been difficult to implement and sustain over time, and that those
128
difficulties probably explain the high incidence of failure. But there are differing
explanations on the reasons behind these difficulties. Some reasons are related to the
threatens the status quo and alters the balance of power within society. It creates
winners and losers within and outside the civil service. As Schneider and Heredia point
out ―CSR appears to be the one [public sector reform] most difficult to implement and
institutionalize‖. The difficulty arises from the loss of power and influence politicians
face as they move from discretionary to merit-based management. But this difficulty is
technical and managerial capacity within the civil service to manage that system and
Other scholars argue that implementation difficulties and lack of sustainability of CSR
reform interventions in developing countries arise from CSR reform designs. Designs
that either use a single template to address highly heterogeneous institutional settings
or introduce recent OECD managerial models that may not be suitable. This opens the
question on how much of the OECD recent managerial reform experience could be
applicability and suitability, for developing countries. Some scholars caution against
risks of misdiagnosing the problem. In countries where patronage and informality still
Spanning over a decade, Ethiopia‘s transformation agenda has evolved over three phases
(1992, 1996-2000 and 2001 onwards) in response to a growing awareness that pervasive
129
deficits in capacity have hampered the ability of the state to secure the fundamentals
However, the first reforms phase in the early days of EPRDF rule was politically
motivated by aiming to root out an entrenched but articulate section of the national
Following the consolidation of power, the Government also acknowledged the deep
regulation. Core public management systems at the federal and regional levels were
hampered by outdated civil service legislation and working systems; the absence of a
medium term planning and budgeting framework; ineffective financial and personnel
management controls; inadequate civil service wages and inappropriate grading systems;
poor capacity for strategic and cabinet-level decision- making; and insufficient focus on
Service Reform Program (CSRP) in 1996, marking the second reform phase. Indicative
of Ethiopia‘s first generation capacity building efforts, the CSRP sought to build
a fair, transparent, efficient, effective, and ethical civil service primarily by creating
enabling legislation, developing operating systems, and training staff in five key areas:
(v) Ethics.
Successful efforts (for example, budgeting, planning, and accounting reforms) at the
federal level were intended to provide prototypes for regional authorities. The CSRP
was also influenced by the international New Public Management trend and reforms in
130
New Zealand in particular.
The CSRP also faced some delays due to the Ethio-Eritrea border conflict 1998- 2000.
However, some achievements which may pave the way for full implementation of the
CSRP were witnessed. Among other things, the development of new legislation (for
systems for budgeting, procurement, and some aspects of personnel management such
The most recent reform phase began in September 2001, with the launch of the Public
Sector Capacity Building Support Program (PSCAP), which also revived the CSRP. The
Government has moved quickly to prepare the CSRP for its ―full implementation‖
across all regions and levels of government. Pilot studies and special programs on
These include;
tiers of government;
PSIP, along with other reform programme areas, have promoted Business Process
interface directly with the private sector. However, recently the perception is that the
CSRP in general is losing momentum, and following an appraisal of PSCAP, the following
131
poor incentives and a lack of strategic or performance orientation across all levels of
government. Therefore, in the light of the CSRP and other reform programs included
in the package of SAPs, the Ministry of Capacity Building reformulated the following
To shake off basic weaknesses ingrained in the existing Civil Service inherited
To build the capacity of the Civil Service so that it will execute the
To facilitate the Civil Service to provide efficient and fair services to the
public
To build a Civil Service that stands for gender and ethnic equality and rights
Although these objectives enjoy broad support in the country, the challenge is whether
the government is capable of bringing about the envisaged changed in the system. There
are doubts about the environmental readiness, political commitment, and that the
Ethiopia‘s CSR is an ambitious programme that would tax the capabilities of any
impressive blueprint for broad transformation. Whether the reform is too ambitious
Ethiopia.
According to Gebriel (2002), of the 300,000- plus civil servants, less than 17% held a
college diploma and the majority of these were concentrated in major cities such as
Addis Ababa. The creation of an enabling environment for the reform is one of the
132
demanding tasks of acquiring the resources to build the technical capabilities and to
donors, coordinated by the World Bank, have extended loans to finance the PSCAP,
development; and
2004: 8).
Clearly, to attain these objectives requires changes in bureaucratic values. The current
The machinery of government‘ refers to the allocation and reallocation of functions between
departments and includes changes in the internal structure of departments, the allocation of
functions within departments, and increasingly, the allocation of functions to bodies other
than ministerial departments, with the creation of executive agencies and privatization of
government bodies.
Structural reform of the machinery of government has its origins in the technical assistance
to the public administration offered in the early 1960s but has re-emerged in recent years as
a key element in institutional reform. Decentralization is, of course, the most commonly
referred to reform to the structure of government. In addition, new tools, notably those
coordinating the different branches of government better, and for forging a more direct link
133
Reform of the Machinery of Government
Decentralization
Dear learner you have a great deal of clue about decentralization since you grasped the
concept through other modules. However, in this Part the discussion will focus on
In lieu of this, the section specifically focuses on the objectives of decentralization and
One of the central elements in the changing role of the public sector and the construct
making, planning, management, or resource allocation from the central government to its
Highly centralized forms of governance have been blamed for the generation of
According to Borins 1994, Hope 2002, and Silverman 1992, within the context of the
134
Increasing managerial autonomy, particularly by reducing central
administrative controls;
performance;
performance targets;
part of an effort to ―de bureaucratize‖ and ―delayer‖ the hierarchies within the public
service. The key concern is to give managers the freedom to manage their units in order
(agentification):
The first and key trend is that, traditionally, monolithic public bureaucracies are
downsizing, contracting out functions and breaking up into more autonomous business
Downsizing arises from the concern for the size and cost of public-sector employment,
which has not only contributed to the growing fiscal crisis and budget deficits, but also
depressed real wages and maintenance in capital budgets. Like in the private sector,
135
governments around the world have responded by putting limits on the size and cost of
the public sector. Ghana and Uganda, for example, have experienced massive cuts in
the size of their civil services, in the case of the former by almost half, and the latter
by almost 40 per cent since 1987. The Zimbabwean civil service has also been cut by
about 12 per cent since the commencement of civil service reform in 1991.
through which they are held responsible through performance targets. In principle,
these agencies have greater managerial flexibility in the allocation of human resources
(including the right to hire and fire) in return for greater accountability for results. In
Ghana and Uganda, the Customs and Excise, and Internal Revenue Departments were
hived off from the civil service to form separate agencies in the 1980s. The aim was to
separate executive functions from policy-making and free managers from civil service
rules and conditions as well as offering them better incentives linked to performance.
3. Development of quasi-markets:
ones for public contracts, and require a separation of production and provisioning
functions of departments, i.e. the central policy units may be entrusted with the
provisioning and the executive agencies with production. The objective of this
of public services.
and financial) between defining the need for paying for public services and actually
disenfranchised field-based staff and allowed some autonomy for each protected area
136
in terms of the development of management plans, the disbursement of funds against
annual operating plan and the evaluation of the revenue generating potential of each
risks. Project experience, as well as various Quality Assurance Group reviews, showed
corporate governance and the board of director‘s model, which aims to reduce the
management.
sectors and represents a major element in the reconstruction of the public sector and
the construct of the NPM. Indeed, decentralization falls neatly into the neo-liberal
logic of divesting the central state of many of its responsibilities and encouraging the
demands for restructuring the African State along more distributional lines. It has
been used especially in countries that have been troubled by ethnic conflicts – such as
Ethiopia, Mali, Nigeria, Senegal and Uganda. Since decentralization is seen as a basic
intervening in this area than in democratization or other governance reforms that are
Subsidiarity is the principle of devolving political decisions to the lowest practical level.
for more efficiency in the production and management of resources and services.
rests with the smaller, lower and more regional entities, and is delegated ―upwards‖
137
at the discretion of the latter, and not at the discretion of the central authority. It
implies a kind of reverse delegation, namely a delegation of power from the outside to
the centre.
Benin‘s national agricultural research was re-organized so that decisions would be made
at the regional level. Since 1997, the regional program‘s priority setting for
local level to the regional, national and sub-regional (West Africa). The subsidiarity
and a national committee) and it facilitates dialogue between research, various users
and clients. In order for subsidiarity to succeed the interfaces must be effective and
sustainable. Using this bottom-up approach, Benin‘s agricultural research has made
implementation.
Privatization
Privatization, or the transfer of State assets to the private sector, is a central component of
downsizing. It refers to the transfer of control and responsibilities for government functions
and services to the private sector – private voluntary organizations or private enterprises.
and imposing hard budget constraints on the economic decisions of managers. Also, the
revenue derived from selling state enterprises to the public can help governments close
Commercialization
Despite the growing interest in privatization, it is clear that Public Enterprises will
autonomy and authority for managers at the level of the firm, particularly in relation to
pricing, procurement, staffing, performance management, and marketing; and from the
State‘s unwillingness to create owners who can protect the capital employed. By using
the market- based solution, PEs becomes more like private enterprises by placing a
empowered with greater managerial flexibility in resources management, better pay and
following measures to shift power away from State bureaus to the portfolio
• Assigning enterprise management the power to hire and fire workers and
evaluate their performance, set product prices, and decide on product lines and
output.
Contracting Out
Contracting out refers to the out-sourcing or buying in of goods and services from
The responsibility of the public organization is to specify what is wanted and let the
private or voluntary sector provide it. Contracting out, it is assumed, leads to cost
savings from inefficient public bureaucracies that are more intent on satisfying the
In Africa, there have been considerable efforts, in recent years, to extend the scope
of its application to a wider range of public organizations and activities than before.
Hope (2002) reports how in Botswana, parastatals have contracted out a number of
and billing are contracted out, while clinical services are contracted out on a limited
scale.
times through the production and sales chain or service-provision process. It also
effort, and curtailing overlaps of roles and responsibilities. The Key issues in TQM
are:
One solution that has been proffered for the problems of inadequate resources and
the increasing demand for effective services, low levels of public trust, and increasing
agreement on program goals and strategies for achieving these goals. Managers should
organizations and program and also for providing feedback to key stakeholders on
improved performance.
organizational levels
Customer-Driven Government
In applying TQM, the organization should focus on what the population (customers)
want, not what administration thinks they need. To improve efficiency, productivity and
integrity in the public service, efforts should be primarily focused on creating a culture
141
of commitment to identifying and meeting customer requirements throughout
organizations and within available resources. It follows that serving the customer is
This strategy has been the main focus of reforms in Malaysia, Namibia, Singapore and
the United Kingdom. The Malaysian Government has emphasized throughout the public
service that the customer is paramount. The Citizens Charter (United Kingdom)
provides specific targets such as hospital waiting times and train delays. Customer-
driven government became formal policy in the USA in 1993 through the National
Performance Review (NPR) report. The Clinton Administration used the NPR report to
set a goal of ―providing customer services equal to the best in business‖. Mauritius also
main objective was to devise and disseminate a document with guidelines that individuals
can follow to prevent corruption and promote integrity. The Charter also attempts to
inform and advise the general public on the nature and forms of corruption. Central to
the premise of the Charter is the imperative of making the general populace aware of
Public sector management reforms would be incomplete without addressing the issue of
the quality of products delivered to the consumers. The private sector, as the engine of
growth, cannot provide satisfactory services and products without the active
recognized quality, standards, metrology and testing organization that supports the
national effort towards economic development and social progress. The Authority has a
quality policy, which is committed to continuously satisfying the needs and expectations
142
of its customers in a process of continuous improvement.
improve customer service, cut operational costs, and become world-class competitors. A
key stimulus for reengineering has been the continuing development and deployment of
services and speed. Their claim was simple: most of the work being done does not add
any value for customers, and this work should be removed, not accelerated through
customer value, while minimizing the consumption of resources required for delivering
model:
1. Develop the business vision and process objectives: The BPR method is
2. Identify the business processes to be redesigned: most firms use the 'high
impact' approach that focuses on the most important processes or those that
conflict most with the business vision. A lesser number of firms use the
143
5. Design and build a prototype of the new process: the actual design should
not be viewed as the end of the BPR process. Rather, it should be viewed as a
As soon as the current government came to power, it started rigorous reforms (first
phase reforms from 1991 to 1995) in three fronts: Economic reform – from central
planning to market economy; Political reform – federalism, and power and fiscal
question was whether Ethiopia has a bureaucracy that is capable of doing these reforms
or not. The government employed private domestic and foreign consultants to study the
that Ethiopian bureaucracy is characterized by: very hierarchical with many non-value
and corruption; lack of leadership capacity; and input based and not output based – i.e.
Building‖ with the mandate of undertaking reforms in all public institutions (esp.
education and the civil service) was established. Also ―Anti-corruption Commission‖
Over time it was believed that an important condition to undertake the reforms was to
implement BPR. It was identified that to solve the problems of hierarchical bureaucracy
144
implemented in all public institutions gradually. The reason why the Ethiopian
government adopted BPR is that the current system has to be completely changed and
Services delivered by the public institutions are characterized by long time taking,
costly (high transaction cost), incompetence (not up to the needs of customers), not
response), not dynamic (the world is changing but our public institutions are stagnant).
People have choices when they buy products from private firms. However, government
services are one (no choice). At the same time people have the right to get appropriate
BPR, painful practices in each public office were identified, and many non-value adding
works/positions are avoided. For example, it was found that deputy head departments
So far BPR is implemented in public offices and publicly owned big institutions such
Corporation‖ and government banks. However, private firms have not adopted it yet in
Ethiopia. The experiences of the Ministry of Trade and Industry (MOTI), the Ethiopian
Investment Commission, and the Ethiopian Customs Authority are instructive examples
These three public institutions were taken as good examples in the IMF Country Report
No. 06/27 for Ethiopia (2006). By way of highlighting the major achievements of the
implementation of the Civil Service Reform Program, the following are worth noting:
now after the conduct of Business Process Reengineering (BPR) by the Commission it
only takes an individual 4 steps and 2 days to get his/her investment license. The
same service used to take 39 steps and 108 days for a company whereas now (after
145
BPR) it only takes 4 steps and 2 days. Securing main registration certificates used
to take 18 steps and 28 days for an individual businessperson before the BPR
whereas now it only takes 4 steps and 2 days. The same service used to take 39
steps and 96 days for a company, whereas now it takes the steps and time as the
b) The Ministry of Trade and Industry (MOTI): It used to take 14 working steps
(processes) and two and a half days to secure a trade license for an individual
business person whereas now (after the Ministry conducted BPR), it now only takes
a business person 6 work steps and 34 minutes to get a trade license. This same
service used to take a company 26 working steps and 35 days. After the conduct of
the BPR, it only takes the same work steps and time as an individual business (6 work
c) The Ethiopian Custom Authority: Securing loading permits from Djibouti used to
take 43 work steps (processes) and 2 days whereas after the Authority has been re-
organized and undertook BPR, it only takes 6 steps 15 minutes to get the service.
Checking and fixing a container with a customer seal used to take 8 steps and two
days before the BPR, whereas now it only takes 3 steps and 40 minutes to get the
items and distribution of declaration used to take 8 steps and 2 to 15 days, whereas
now it only takes three steps and 26 minutes to get same service for a business
entity.
throughout the country since 2008. While the reform is very much in vogue, it remains
146
3.6.1. E-government Reforms
Information technology (IT) has been included as one of the key strategies for public service
management information systems have risen rapidly in many countries and now represent major
The creation of new information and communication systems are seen as an essential
that decision and its outcomes must flow to all those to whom the decision maker is
accountable and without such an information flow, and without the information system
to carry that flow, there can be no accountability because there can be no knowledge of
the basic ingredient. Therefore, there is great potential for these trends of
been, and still remains, the single largest collector, user, holder and producer of
information. Information is a central resource for all staff levels and for all activities.
The work of government is thus very information-intensive and four main types of
staff for personnel management, and information about budgets and accounts for
financial management. Like the other three types of information, it can be used
information that records the details of the main entities‘: people, business
papers, details of policies, laws and regulations, and details of benefits and
entitlements.
part of all reform initiatives in Africa, and changes in information technology will have a
great potential in efficiency and effectiveness gains in the public sector. In theory,
everything that IT can do could be done by some other means. However, in practice, its
ability to increase the speed and/or reduce the cost of information tasks means it can
The key innovation is computer networks and the three domains are
e-Administration,
e-Society.
There are a growing number of e-government projects in Africa, some of which are
contributing to public sector reform and delivering efficiency gains in service delivery.
E-Citizens and Services, for example, deal particularly with the relationship between
government and citizens: either as voters/stakeholders from whom the African public
sector should derive its legitimacy, or as customers who consume public services.
The key aims in this domain include providing citizens with details of public sector
148
activities; increasing the input of citizens into public sector decisions and actions; and
improving the services delivered to members of the public along dimensions such as
For example, following difficulties in the 1994 elections, South Africa‘s independent
Electoral Commission was charged with making sure that the country‘s second
democratic elections in 1999 were free and fair. This election was vitally important
for the stability of the South African political climate and for ensuring that
information, education and communication (IEC) was able to ensure that all South
African citizens could have their voices heard. The effort included the creation of a
used to register 18.4 million voters in just nine days; a geographic information system
used to create voting districts; a national common voters‘ role; a sophisticated election
results centre for managing the process; and the training of 300,000 people. The
massive program was completed in less than two years, in time for the vote. For this,
the IEC received the 2000 Computer World Smithsonian Award for most outstanding
Africa has been slow. It is a fact that African governments have fewer e-government
initiatives than industrialized countries; make less use of ICTs in their work than
countries. A major explanation is financial. However, there are also strategic challenges
African countries.
149
Cost Recovery: User Fees and Charges
One of the major developments in the provision of public services has been the
represent an attempt to diversify financing for public services and reshape public
especially in Africa, in the 1980s, as governments faced slower economic growth and
rising deficits that made public expenditure levels unsustainable. User fees have been
introduced at different levels of education in Ghana, Kenya, Malawi and Uganda, and in
In comparison to other developing regions, user fee reforms have been most extensive
in sub- Saharan Africa. This is because the gap between resources and needs, and the
influence of international donors, has perhaps been greatest in Africa. The key
rationale of the introduction of user fees in Africa, therefore, has been to raise
additional revenue in the face of increasing demand for services. User fees also serve
apart from improving quality and fostering responsiveness to the needs of consumers.
The objective of introducing user fees is cost sharing. Implementing such a policy is
supposed to help the poor because it mobilizes more resources from better-off groups
that could then be used to provide services for poorer groups. In Guinea-Bissau, for
example, user fees in health care have consistently contributed between 30 and 45 per
cent of the operating costs of health services. However, user fees are not without
complement such a policy. There has been some evidence that the introduction of user
fees has made access to social services more difficult for the poor, especially in the
initial years of the scheme. Therefore, exemption systems and safety nets need to be
designed so that user fees fall mainly on services consumed by the non-poor. Such
systems include ensuring that information about incomes (on which to base exemption
150
decisions) is collected in an effective manner, especially for large numbers of people in
Public Reporting
financial and managerial performance of public departments that enables the public to
The International Monetary Fund (IMF) and other international bodies have developed
a number of codes and standards that set out ―good practices‖ in the areas of policy
public reporting, the IMF has identified the following codes and standards:
• The public availability of information – the public should be provided with full
should specify fiscal policy objectives, the macroeconomics framework, the policy
• Budget data should be classified and presented in a way that facilitates policy
The Office of the Auditor-General also provides a critical link in the chain of public
accountability, a role that is both unique and vital to the democratic process of
and advice about, government accountability and performance. Reports should provide
151
assessments and also highlight issues requiring the attention of the legislature or
government, and should also contain recommendations that could assist government
Citizens Charter
A key feature of the NPM is the concept of perceiving the citizen as a ―customer‖ of
public services. In the context of public sector reform, efforts to make public service
agencies more accountable to the public have included the adoption of Citizens Charters.
Citizens should be consulted about the level and quality of public services and, whenever
possible, be given the choice of services. Citizens should also be informed about the level and
quality of services they will receive, and they should have equal access to the services to
which they are entitled. Moreover, they should be informed about how national departments
and provincial administration are run, how much they cost and who is in charge.
In 1991, the British government launched the Citizens Charter. It was designed to raise
the standard of public services and make them more responsive to their users and to
encourage public servants to think about what they do in relation to how it affects
their customers. The Charter spells out a number of key principles that every citizen is
• The setting and publication of explicit standards for services and the
• The efficient and economical delivery of services within the resources the
In this regard, the Charter for the Public Service in Africa was adopted at the third
Pan African Conference of Ministers responsible for the Civil Service, in Windhoek,
Namibia, in 2001. The Charter highlights the need to adapt the different public
accompany the profound changes that African countries are experiencing. It also takes
152
into account the prevailing socio-economic conditions, including globalization, and the
need to create an enabling environment for private sector growth. The Charter also
defines a framework to guide the public services in Africa in taking such legislative,
regulatory, technical and practical measures as may be required to create the conditions
for the proper functioning of the public service and improve the quality of its services.
(i) Principle of Equality of Treatment: All public services shall recognize the
equality of citizens before the law and will not be discriminated against based on
the place of origin, race, gender, religion, ethnic group, philosophical or political
(ii) Principle of Neutrality: The public service that serves the interest of the
public shall not discriminate against its employees because of their personal
traits. The public service shall remain neutral in respect to the government of
the day and this fundamental principle will be respected by all administrations.
(iv) Principle of Continuity: Public service shall be provided on an ongoing basis and
in all its component parts, in accordance with the rules governing its operation.
Failure to comply with the principle of continuity may incur the liability of the
administration in respect of any person who might have suffered harm on account
of such failure.
Citizens Charters exist in both South Africa and Zimbabwe. In Tanzania there are plans
for Ministries to publish ―social pacts‖ setting out the standard of services that
the public can expect. Launched in 1997, the Batho Pele-People First initiative in
South Africa is based on a set of national principles for public service. Ghana and
Uganda have also shown good practices in customer-oriented public service. In Ghana,
the public service reform program is a sub- component of the country‘s National
Institutional Renewal Program and, amongst other areas, focuses on the development of
153
customer- service orientation, promotion of cost and time consciousness in the civil
service, and improvement of records and information management systems. The public
service reform program in Uganda has focused mainly on the transformation of public
and resources have been delegated to lower-level service delivery agents and also
The role of Civil Society Organizations (CSOs) and NGOs in the delivery of services to
the public is on the increase worldwide. In July 1999, African countries at the
professional organizations and women‘s groups, make a case for greater cooperation
between their activities and those of government and advocates for mutual acceptance
of legitimacy and strengths and weaknesses. NGOs and CSOs worldwide have been
known to be able to reach poor communities with social services, including health and
education.
While it is appreciated that governments must value the energy and creativity that
CSOs and NGOs bring to the development arena, NGOs and CSOs on the other hand,
organizations will reduce the mutual suspicion of each other‘s motives. It is also
suggested that joint policies should be developed to define sectors of society, the
economy, and the environment in which civil society activity, either independently or in
cooperation with government, are encouraged. Paying more attention to CSOs may
sustainable development and the problems associated with the development of social
154
capital. There is no doubt that the cooperation between government and civil society
would promote and implement people centered and sustainable public service delivery
reforms.
Section Overview
Public financial management concerns the taxing and spending of government, which in
turn influences resource allocation and income distribution. The spending portion
covers the budget cycle, including budget preparation, internal controls, accounting,
internal and external audit, procurement, and monitoring and reporting arrangements.
The revenue part concerns with taxation and income derived from different
sources. This section introduces you with some of the issues involved in public
Starting in the 1950s, the financial management advice most sought by developing countries
was how to raise more revenue to finance the capital investments governments were seeking to
make. Much of the discussion focused on how to raise investment needed to achieve a target
growth rate building on the dominant thinking of the time of state-led development. On the
expenditure side, a host of challenges gained attention largely following the oil price shocks,
where fiscal deficits of developing countries increased from 3.5 percent to 6.3 percent of GNP
during 1972-85. These challenges included weak public expenditure and resource planning (e.g.
weak priorities and linkage with macroeconomic framework), inconsistent budget structures
(e.g. inconsistencies and weak links between capital and recurrent budgets), budget
implementation (e.g. weak cash management) and accounting and reporting (e.g. absence of
Toward the end of the 80s, there was a belief that centralized financial controls
155
introduced during the crisis needed to be replaced in many cases with decentralized
controls at the spending unit level, with greater integration of policy and financial
considerations. This also linked with greater citizen demand for improved service
delivery and greater accountability for results through contractual and other
mechanisms. Countries also sought to reduce high, progressive income taxes, import
duties and export taxes and replace them, for example, with a value added tax (VAT)
that would help facilitate market directed allocation of resources, while being broadly
These demands from the developing world were a response in part to the recent
thinking in OECD countries on how to adapt new tools to carry out deliberate
changes in the structure and processes of the public sector to get them to run
better. Development agencies also changed their views over this period, increasingly
realizing that deficient PFM systems can undermine their development assistance.
They realized that even though aid projects may have good financial controls, they
could result in government resources being freed up to fund other things; if PFM
systems were deficient, the development results from these resources were likely to
be less than desired. Donors became increasingly aware that the distinction between
development and recurrent spending was less important than once thought: teachers‘
salaries were just as important as school construction for achieving education. They
realized that project-centered aid could not succeed with poor macroeconomic and
fiscal policies, and that economic development required not only physical investment,
but also good public sector management. There was increasing awareness that PFM
outcomes depend on the nature of budgetary institutions, and that sound PFM
requires not only a strong budgetary authority, but also capable a legislature, in some
cases supported by civil society budget groups. There is some evidence of recent
increasing work by multilateral donors in these areas. At the same time, there is
evidence that countries with rules that establish limits on deficits, that prevent sub-
national and decentralized agencies to incur in debt financing, that have medium term
156
fiscal frameworks and reserve funds in place, and by more hierarchical procedures,
that establish restrictions on the legislature and on the bargaining power of ministers
and provides the executive with discretion to cash manage expenditures, tend to
The next section will sketch out three broad debates carried out over the last two
decades relevant to these changes: first, the degree to which developed country
public management tools are transferable to developing countries; second, the role of
governance assessment in the transfer process; and third, the search for analytical
frameworks for public financial management. A final section will sketch out ongoing
Transferability of Ideas
and developed countries require that public financial management tools be used
selectively, and adapted to local conditions. Some of the key differences in context
between developed and developing countries are: First, the pace and nature of
reforms in developed countries are designed and carried out by the respective
reforms in developing countries are often designed by international agencies, and not
carried out by bureaucratic and political elites with the intent of preserving their
common reform packages designed to address fiscal crises in developed countries are
Confucian meritocracies. Many of these developing countries have much deeper fiscal
crises and sharper declines in public service than developed countries, yet programs
often used OECD country designs as models. Where programs vary, the reason is
157
often more failure to meet negotiated conditions, rather than differences in design.
the-pen reforms often moving quickly, while necessary structural changes move slowly
countries hinder reform effectiveness. For example, rivalries between planning and
finance ministries lead to conflicts over fiscal goals, poor communication, and
among developing countries, even within the same region. In countries with weak
capacity, centralized management models provide the best starting point, since
these occur in both developed and developing countries, they are larger in developing
countries because potential rents are larger, and the proportion of informed voters in
the electorate is lower. There are also very different interpretations of words like
languages, even among people with common historical and cultural traditions. Some
keywords from the reform toolkit, such as accountability, have no equivalent in other
developing countries, and the informal budgeting that actually takes place, responding
transfers of Western models, drawing the language, practices, and values from
Aside from broad debates on transferability of ideas there are specific debates on
158
evidence of success in developing countries with fiscal decentralization, providing
also higher in countries with large populations, and in transition countries. The
average because, inter alia, central governments want to hold on to major revenue
among regions, and officials from central ministries lobby for keeping the status quo.
In another example, as developing countries draw from the menu of OECD accounting
reforms, there are differing views on the results. Improved cash accounting in
Uganda and Zambia gave better information on expenditures where capacity was too
limited for a commitment based system. But the restriction on cash wasn't enough to
solve the problem of excessive commitments without the active involvement of the
President (Uganda) and the IMF (Zambia). Mongolia's attempt to adopt full accrual
budgeting and accounting, output budgeting, devolution of hiring to agency heads, and
performance contracts wasn't based on careful diagnosis, and had to be scaled back
Accrual accounting supplements cash accounting systems to ensure that the financial
These reforms aim to hold management responsible for outcomes and outputs whilst
responsible for all costs associated with the outputs produced, not only the
immediate outlays. Accruals allow for the capture of these full costs, thereby
this reform, to help achieve greater certainty on future funding. Despite concerns
evident in developed countries in making effective use of this tool, and the many
are central features of the Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper (PRSPs) and Poverty
Reduction Support Credit (PRSCs) prepared in recent years. Craig and Porter (2003)
point out that aside from technical problems of using this tool effectively, its use for
upward accountability to central ministries and donors can undermine local political
legitimacy and accountability, sideline the role of legislatures, and cut off important
sources of local knowledge on what works and doesn't work in poverty reduction.
adopted in some cases when there is sufficient commitment, capacity, and resources
as part of a broad and appropriately phased reform program. If conditions are right,
Korea, Brazil and Philippines has reportedly improved efficiency and transparency,
reduced acquisition cost, and may have reduced corruption. Malaysia‘s e-Perolehan
private company.
160
In some parts of Africa, the principal benefit from IT may be ensure more
parallel to IT-based systems and more relied on by finance staff. Successful IT-
based financial systems reforms are commonly iterative and modular rather than
integrated, built around scarce, high quality public managers wherever they may be
working. On the other hand, in both developing and developed countries, the expected
Delays in IT adoption by governments stem from the nature of public sector financing
awarding contracts. To prevent undue influence by any one official, many decisions
along the way are made by committees, which can lead to compromises and an unclear
focus. In addition, when acquisitions are finally made, the technology has often moved
far beyond where it was when the project was first conceived; thus governments
often install outdated systems. They also pay excessive prices, since new products
may have come into the market during this period that can deliver the same ICT
power for much less money. The difference between the outdated tender price and
the market price is also an arbitrage opportunity for corrupt officials. Capacity-
practices often very different from what may be indicated in formal rules and
regulations.
Developing countries have in many areas followed the OECD example of introducing
separate policy making from implementation, and to enhance incentives for the latter.
Debate on the effectiveness of such reforms continues, with analysts finding some
161
cases leading to increased revenue collection, and others leading to increased
financial resources, and unclear authority relationships between principals and agents.
Cross-Cutting Debates
transparency and governance, there are two cross-cutting questions that can be
raised: First, does more aid weaken governance? Second, what should be the scope of
reforms?
taxes; thus they have less need to provide a conducive business climate, and to
international donors). Aid can divert scarce skills from government, encourage
corruption and conflicts over control of aid funds, and reduce citizen demand for
reform. Aid can also weaken administrative effectiveness through high transaction
costs, the fragmentation and weak coordination of donor projects, the lack of
integration in the budget process, moral hazard, soft budget constraints, and
Using International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) governance data, Brautigam and Knack
(2004) found that aid dependence was linked with an increase in corruption, and
worsening bureaucratic quality and rule of law. They find a modest reduction in the
162
negative effect of aid on governance in Africa between the 1980s and 1990s, but the
methodology in analyzing ICRG data to argue that more aid may be associated with
less corruption, perhaps because donor rules constrain recipient government officials,
Ear (2007) uses pooled, time series cross-sectional (panel data) analysis drawing on
data in Kaufmann et al. (2005) to confirm a negative effect of aid dependence on rule
of law; but, unlike Knack and others, he finds no significant negative effect on other
cooperation) and on voice and accountability (positive effect from proportion of grant
scope, taking a ―big bang‖ approach, or incremental and opportunistic. Some stress
take advantage of narrow windows of opportunity. Thus Werlin (1992: 204), citing the
persuasive and manipulative (rather than coercive and corrupting) forms of power.
Rodrik (1996) cites Polish macroeconomic reforms beginning in 1989 among others
1984 and 1990 (Pallot 1991) and in Canada in 1994 are cited as examples of
typical:―The single most important point about institutional change, which must be
grasped if we are to begin to get a handle on the subject, is that institutional change
163
is overwhelmingly incremental‖. Esman (1991:138-139) advocates a "bottom up"
approach. He claims that system-wide reforms disrupt familiar routines and threaten
vital agencies.
Anti-Corruption Reforms
A. Defining Corruption
Corruption is an important aspect of poor governance, and often defined as the abuse of
public office for private gain. This is a widely used definition applied by the World Bank
among others. This definition includes various forms of interaction between public
sector officials and other agents. Money is often involved, such as in bribery or
kickbacks for public procurement contracts. In other cases, however, the private gain
acts where there is no interaction with external agents or external agents are not
Corruption can also take place among private sector parties. Hence, an alternative
entrusted power for private gain. In contrast to the former definition which includes
only acts involving public sector officials, TI‘s definition also includes similar acts in the
private sector. For example, a subcontractor that bribes an official of another company
164
public sector corruption, the latter definition thus includes private-private corruption.
This type of corruption is understudied, despite the fact that it may reduce private
The definition of corruption as abuse of public office has been criticized as being (i)
excessively legalistic and (ii) based on a Western ideal of separation of the public and
private which does not fit the cultural context of many developing countries. As for the
first criticism, the idea of abuse of office certainly implies deviation from some
standard. It does not follow from the definition itself that the standard is a legal one,
however. The standard could just as well be a moral one, where the proper role of
office holders is derived from fundamental ethical principles. The definition therefore
does not in itself depend on legal rules that may be incomplete or incidental. The
criticism of a basis in Western ideals is a matter of application, although the way the
definition is sometimes applied by donors has been informed by a Western idea of public
office. However, the definition does not in itself refer to a specific idea of public
office. In general, any well-functioning society must have some productive allocation of
Corruption and rent-seeking are not the same, though the two are often used
terms of monopoly rents or rents from natural resources. There is a degree of overlap,
where some acts of rent-seeking would also qualify as corruption. However, rent-seeking
does not necessarily entail misuse of position or power. In some borderline cases, these
available rents. Corruption in this sense can thus be viewed as a violation of the basic
Various typologies of corruption have been suggested. The commonly used distinction is
corruption takes place at the highest levels of political authority. It involves politicians,
165
government ministers, senior civil servants and other elected, nominated or appointed
senior public office holders. In other words, political corruption is abuse of office by
those who make the rules of the game, e.g. decide on laws and regulations, and the
allocation of resources in a society. These types of acts may include tailoring laws and
regulations to the advantage of private sector agents in exchange for bribes, granting
large public contracts to specific firms, or embezzling funds from the treasury. The
term grand corruption if often used to describe these types of acts, and reflects the
Most bureaucratic corruption takes place at the implementation end of public policies,
although it may in some cases have its roots in the planning and budgeting stages that
staff at the central or sub-national levels. In simple terms, it comprises corrupt acts
among those who implement the rules made by top officials. This includes interaction
with private agents, such as demanding extra payment for providing government
actions that violate rules and regulations. It also includes interaction within the public
which reflects the small payments often involved, though in specific cases and in
Political and bureaucratic corruption are clearly interrelated. Corruption at the top of
And corruption in high places is contagious to lower-level officials, as these will follow
the predatory examples of, or even take instructions from, their principals. However,
there are also distinctions in the causes and consequences of political and bureaucratic
corruption. The priorities and means by which to approach the two may therefore be
different.
166
B. Entry Points for Governance Reform
Governance is often defined as the manner in which public officials and public
institutions acquire and exercise the authority to provide public goods and services,
including the delivery of basic services, infrastructure, and a sound investment climate.
The various entry points can be viewed in relation to the three dimensions of
legitimate claim and the agents or agencies responsible for fulfilling or respecting
that right. The most basic accountability relationship is that between a person or
agency entrusted with a particular task or certain powers or resources, on the one
hand, and the principal‘ on whose behalf the task is undertaken, on the other.
This duty can be discharged in different ways, but the literature suggests that
criteria:
Transparency requires that decisions and actions are taken openly and that
sufficient information is available so that other agencies and the general public
can assess whether the relevant procedures are followed, consonant with the
given mandate.
decisions that runs counter to given mandates and procedures. This is often
Vertical accountability refers to the methods by which the state is (or is not) held to
account by non-state agents through the relationship between citizens and their
channels relates largely to the electoral (or political) accountability and secondly,
downward societal accountability to civil society and the media that monitor and address
between the legislature, the executive and the judiciary and between different sub-
entities of the executive, including Cabinet, line ministries and lower level
oversight functions, this includes special institutions of restraint such as the auditor
and sanction other government agencies are related to the centre box of public sector
international entities, including the World Bank and bilateral donors. To a large extent,
commissions, audit institutions, and so on. The effect of these types of interventions in
168
focused on creating and improving institutions of horizontal accountability, such as
anticorruption commissions, audit institutions, and so on. The effect of these types of
implement reforms that reduce their own opportunities for enrichment. Case in point is
number of countries. Outside of Hong Kong and Singapore, these have rarely been a
to improve horizontal accountability, the World Bank and bilateral donors have begun to
institutional reforms, and reforms of the incentive schemes in the public administration.
Policy measures, however, cannot be addressed properly without including the larger
question of the nature of the state that is supposed to implement the anti-corruption
scientists (Blundo & Olivier de Sardan 2006; Bayart et al 1999; Chabal & Daloz 1999)
implementing reforms.
dominant elites‘ extraction and rent seeking practices. Because neo-patrimonial elites
are the main profiteers of widespread corruption, they have limited will for reform.
169
Thus, any lasting effects of institutional and administrative reforms may be doubtful.
In this context, such reforms may even be aimed at securing the political and economic
To assume that all states and political leaders are predatory‘, however, as in the
literature referred to above and also in much of the public choice literature in the
context of developing countries, does not help in understanding why corruption is more
extensive in some countries than in others, in spite of fairly similar extent of state
interventions. Neither does it explain why countries with seemingly similar aggregate
Bardhan (1997) argues that some African states in recent history have become
predatory in their rent extraction not because they are strong, but because they are
weak. The state cannot enforce the laws and property rights that provide the minimum
officials.
In sharp contrast stand the strong East Asian states with their centralized rent
seeking machinery and their encompassing network with business interests, although
and the importance of predictability, getting rid of many of the public dysfunctional
regulations remains a major first step in anti-corruption policy, whatever the nature of
the state. Furthermore, both economists and political scientists seem to emphasize the
levels of the government. However, it is important to recognize that some conditions are
The general message of the anti-corruption reformers, until recently, has been that
corrupt countries should replicate the institutions of clean countries. Thus, many
countries have adopted various Western institutions. The ombudsman, for example, is
a Scandinavian institution that has been reproduced in many developing countries, often
with limited success. There is now a growing consensus between researchers and
country context. These insights imply that there is no best practice‘ anti-corruption
reform that could be uniformly applied to all countries, and that there is no single
factors that must be taken into consideration when designing and implementing anti-
corruption reforms.
(2004) the answer lies in taking an indirect approach and starting with the root causes.
To understand why, they suggest a model that divides developing countries into high‘,
medium‘, and low‘incidences of corruption. They assume that countries with high‘
corruption have a low‘ quality of governance, those with medium‘ corruption have fair‘
171
Because corruption is itself a symptom of governance failure, the higher the incidence
of corruption, the less an anticorruption strategy should include tactics that are
narrowly targeted at corrupt behavior and the more it should focus on the broad
anticorruption agencies and public awareness campaigns are likely to have limited
deeply flawed. In such environments anticorruption agencies are prone to being misused
as tools of political victimization. Such interventions are, according to Shah & Schacter,
more appropriate in a low‘ corruption setting, where the governance fundamentals are
is high and the quality of governance is correspondingly low, it makes more sense to
focus on the underlying drivers of malfeasance in the public sector – for example, by
institutions of restraint such as the auditor general. In societies where the level of
corruption lies somewhere in between the high and low cases, Shah & Schacter suggest
capacity - such as trying to make civil servants more accountable for results, bringing
administrative procedures, and reducing discretion for simple government tasks such as
low corrupt is too broad and does not capture the large differences between countries
within each category. This critique might be accommodated by further fine tuning the
model suggested by Shah & Schacter, as illustrated in the next section. Their main
message, however, is that context matters, and that anti-corruption reforms must be
Why do so many anti-corruption initiatives fail? Shah & Schacter (2004: 40) argue that
the lack of significant progress in fighting corruption can be attributed to the fact
that many anti- corruption programs are ‗simply folk remedies or one-size fits all
(2006: 91) who argues that ‗[t]he problem is that both the assessment instruments
toolbox‘ or textbook‘ solutions. There seems to have been an assumption that corruption and
its solutions could be fully specified in advance, and the required measures implemented on a
predictable timetable, over a fixed period. The technocratic approach, however, has
overlooked the fact that anti-corruption reform, though it has important technical aspects,
also is a social and political phenomenon driven by human behavior and local circumstances.
Many anti- corruption initiatives fail because they are non-political in nature, while most of
what is labeled corruption in these countries may not be the same phenomenon as corruption in
developed countries. In the latter, the term corruption usually designates individual cases of
infringement of the norm of integrity. In the former, corruption often means a mode of social
organization characterized by the regular distribution of public goods that mirrors the
173
distribution of power within such societies. Few anti-corruption campaigns dare to attack the
roots of corruption in such societies as these roots lie in the distribution of power itself.
Instead, anti-corruption strategies are adopted and implemented in cooperation with the very
predators who control the government and, in some cases also the anti-corruption instruments.
Historically, it has been the political opposition, civil society, or even enlightened
despots who have promoted the greatest strides forward. When are circumstances ripe
for civil disobedience against political corruption and state capture? In situations where
most people are content with existing arrangements and do not feel that they
personally have anything to lose by corruption, one simply cannot fight state capture.
This also applies to situations where people feel powerless to change the system and do
not want to get hurt trying. Thus, it is best to attack such systems during economic
crises or other periods of societal stress. Great political turning points can also provide
a favorable environment. Civil society is potentially a more effective auditor and a more
Capacity Building
solve problems, and set and achieve objectives in a sustainable manner. Capacity
Development (CD) is, therefore, the process through which the abilities to do so are
its mandated functions. Within the public service, typical aspects of capacity are the
In the context of this definition, institutional capacity building can be defined as the
174
provision of technical or material assistance designed to strengthen one or more
service delivery. At the national level, institutional capacity is often used as shorthand
the making and enforcement of rules and laws, including judicial reforms;
the ability to effectively plan government expenditure and the delivery of public
the ability to collect the statistical information needed for effective policy
implementation;
work force; to the promotion of knowledge and skills that are required by a society to
resource development can be perceived as both a process and a goal since it can be an
end in itself as it results in the realization of human potential and the development of
individual self-reliance.
CD is defined by the UNDP as the process through which individuals, organizations and
societies obtain, strengthen and maintain the capabilities to set and achieve their own
include policies, legislation, power relations and social norms that shape interactions
among organizations.
The World Bank’s Strategy for Reforming Public Institutions and Strengthening
and emphasizes its importance as the core of the World Banks activity.
As mentioned in the first unit, capacity development is used along with capacity
frequently to mean the same thing. For example, capacity development is understood as
While this term is not new to the development assistance field, the currently
emphasized focus/scope and the means of improving capacity reflects the broader shift
individual- and organizational-level to broader societal and governance level. In the past,
technical capacity building with emphasis on individuals and organizations received more
North to South. Donors did not pay as much attention to the broader context of their
interventions.
development; i.e., building, developing, and transforming the very governance system and
its institutions that structure the behavior of individuals and organizations. Donors
176
learned that the past focus on inputs, such as developing organizational capacity
through training and technology transfers and policy advice was not adequate when
institutions rules of the game that converted those inputs into desirable outputs
within a given governance system remained the same. In this sense, institutional
development.
that: the heart of the problem in ―poor societies‖ is not the lack of funding or
technical know-how (the traditional components of aid), but a matter of governance and
the resulting inability to make good use of existing institutions and capacities. Thus, the
leading IDA now intend to focus more on helping developing countries to set up proper
incentive structures via institutional reforms that would in turn improve government
capacity.
Capacity development is now about strengthening the capability of government and the
internal demand for improved governance through strengthening the capacity of civil
society organizations and the private sector, although public sector reforms still are
The challenge of capacity building for effective service delivery has preoccupied most
African countries since independence. There are a number of institutional and resource
177
meaningfully design and implement developmental interventions. Increasingly, there is
mounting recognition among African leaders that capacity development is at the centre
of development and that, without it, even past achievements could be reversed.
Similarly, there is growing self-examination in the West regarding the degree to which
countries. In the light of the above, many African countries have implemented various
Effort to develop institutional and human resource capacity for improved public sector
Important among these are three: one relates to the concern for improved
procedures of work and more effective management of human resources. Another is the
process of change required within the government sector to sustain efficient economies
in the emerging context of globalization. The third is the increasing concern for
The achievement of the ideal system described above calls for a comprehensive
approach in which several parallel initiatives are undertaken at different points in the
for incentives and rewards for civil servants through proactive personnel management
as well as strong executive leadership development. In the light of this, many countries
and organizations have undertaken administrative reform. A sample of some of the most
178
179