IPCC AR6 WGIII FinalDraft Chapter01
IPCC AR6 WGIII FinalDraft Chapter01
IPCC AR6 WGIII FinalDraft Chapter01
CHAPTER 1
Document Page Line Detailed information on correction to make
(Chapter, (Based on
Annex, the final
Supp. pdf FGD
Material) version)
Chapter 1 Front page Contributing Alexandre Koberle is a LA, also listed as CA, needs to be removed
Authors from CA list. And CA list needs to be in alphabetical order.
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
S
12 America), Jonathan Köhler (Germany), Jeremy Webb (New Zealand), Kate Ricke (the United States of
IT
13 America)
AL N
14 Review Editors: Ismail Elgizouli Idris (the Sudan), Jason Lowe (United Kingdom)
ED
N IO
15 Chapter Scientists: Lilia Caiado Couto (Brazil), Ben Hinder (United Kingdom), Vimla Kanhye
16 (Mauritius)
FI S
17 Date of Draft: 27/11/2021
R
18
TO E
T DV
EC TE
BJ P
E
SU C
AC
1 Table of Contents
2
3 Chapter 1 Introduction and Framing .................................................................................................... 1-1
4 Executive Summary ......................................................................................................................... 1-4
5 1.1 Introduction .......................................................................................................................... 1-6
6 1.2 Previous Assessments .......................................................................................................... 1-7
7 1.2.1 Key findings from Previous Assessment Reports ........................................................ 1-7
8 1.2.2 Developments in Climate Science, Impacts and Risk .................................................. 1-9
9 1.3 The Multilateral Context, Emission Trends and Key Developments................................. 1-10
10 1.3.1 The 2015 Agreements ................................................................................................ 1-10
S
11 1.3.2 Global and regional emissions ................................................................................... 1-13
IT
12 1.3.3 Some Other Key Trends and Developments .............................................................. 1-17
AL N
ED
13 Cross-chapter Box 1: The COVID-19 crisis: lessons, risks and opportunities for mitigation ... 1-17
N IO
14 1.4 Drivers and Constraints of Climate Mitigation and System Transitions/Transformation.. 1-22
FI S
15 1.4.1 Services, sectors and urbanisation.............................................................................. 1-22
16 1.4.2 Trade, consumption and leakage ................................................................................ 1-23
R
17 1.4.3 Technology ................................................................................................................ 1-24
TO E
25 1.5 Emissions Scenarios and Illustrative Mitigation Pathways (IMPs) ................................... 1-34
26 1.6 Achieving mitigation in the context of sustainable development ...................................... 1-38
AC
1 1.8.2 Illustrations of multi-dimensional assessment: lock-in, policies and Just Transition 1-57
2 1.9 Governing climate change ................................................................................................. 1-59
3 1.10 Conclusions ........................................................................................................................ 1-61
4 1.11 Knowledge gaps ................................................................................................................. 1-62
5 1.12 Roadmap to the Report ...................................................................................................... 1-63
6 Frequently Asked Questions (FAQs) ............................................................................................. 1-64
7 References ...................................................................................................................................... 1-66
8
9
10
S
11
IT
AL N
ED
N IO
FI S
R
TO E
T DV
EC TE
BJ P
E
SU C
AC
1 Executive Summary
2 Global greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions continued to rise to 2019: the aggregate reductions
3 implied by current Nationally Determined Contributions (NDCs) to 2030 would still make it
4 impossible to limit warming to 1.5°C with no or limited overshoot, and would only be compatible
5 with likely limiting warming below 2°C if followed by much steeper decline, hence limiting
6 warming to either level implies accelerated mitigation actions at all scales (robust evidence, high
7 agreement). Since the IPCC’s Fifth Assessment Report (AR5), important changes that have emerged
8 include the specific objectives established in the Paris Agreement of 2015 (for temperature, adaptation
9 and finance), rising climate impacts, and higher levels of societal awareness and support for climate
10 action. The growth of global GHG emissions has slowed over the past decade, and delivering the
11 updated NDCs to 2030 would turn this into decline, but the implied global emissions by 2030 exceed
12 pathways consistent with 1.5°C by a large margin, and are near the upper end of the range of modelled
13 pathways which keep temperatures likely below 2°C. Continuing investments in carbon-intensive
S
14 activities at scale will heighten the multitude of risks associated with climate change and impede societal
IT
15 and industrial transformation towards low carbon development. Meeting the long-term temperature
AL N
16 objective in the Paris Agreement therefore implies a rapid turn to an accelerating decline of GHG
ED
17 emissions towards ‘net zero’, which is implausible without urgent and ambitious action at all scales.
N IO
18 The unprecedented COVID-19 pandemic has had far-reaching impacts on the global economic and
19 social system, and recovery will present both challenges and opportunities for climate mitigation. {1.2,
FI S
20 1.3, 1.5, 1.6, Chapters 3 and 4}.
R
21 While there are some trade-offs, effective and equitable climate policies are largely compatible
TO E
22 with the broader goal of sustainable development and efforts to eradicate poverty as enshrined in
23 the 17 Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) (robust evidence, high agreement). Climate mitigation
T DV
24 is one of many goals that societies pursue in the context of sustainable development, as evidenced by
25 the wide range of the SDGs. Climate mitigation has synergies and/or trade-offs with many other SDGs.
26 There has been a strong relationship between development and GHG emissions, as historically both per
EC TE
27 capita and absolute emissions have risen with industrialisation. However, recent evidence shows
28 countries can grow their economies while reducing emissions. Countries have different priorities in
29 achieving the SDGs and reducing emissions as informed by their respective national conditions and
BJ P
30 capabilities. Given the differences in GHG emissions contributions, degree of vulnerabilities and
31 impacts, as well as capacities within and between nations, equity and justice are important
E
32 considerations for effective climate policy and for securing national and international support for deep
SU C
33 decarbonisation. Achieving sustainable global development and eradicating poverty as enshrined in the
34 17 SDGS would involve effective and equitable climate policies at all levels from local to global scale.
AC
35 Failure to address questions of equity and justice over time can undermine social cohesion and stability.
36 International co-operation can enhance efforts to achieve ambitious global climate mitigation in the
37 context of sustainable development. {1.4, 1.6, Chapters 2, 3, 4, 5, 13 and 17}.
38 The transition to a low carbon economy depends on a wide range of closely intertwined drivers
39 and constraints, including policies and technologies where notable advances over the past decade
40 have opened up new and large-scale opportunities for deep decarbonisation, and for alternative
41 development pathways which could deliver multiple social and developmental goals (robust
42 evidence, medium agreement). Drivers for and constraints against low carbon societal transition
43 comprise economic and technological factors (the means by which services such as food, heating and
44 shelter are provided and for whom, the emissions intensity of traded products, finance, and investment),
45 socio-political issues (political economy, equity and fairness, social innovation and behaviour change),
46 and institutional factors (legal framework and institutions, and the quality of international cooperation).
47 In addition to being deeply intertwined all the factors matter to varying degrees, depending on prevailing
1 social, economic, cultural and political context. They often exert both push and pull forces at the same
2 time, within and across different scales. The development and deployment of innovative technologies
3 and systems at scale are important for achieving deep decarbonisation. In recent years, the cost of
4 several low carbon technologies has declined sharply, alongside rapid deployment. Over twenty
5 countries have also sustained emission reductions, and many more have accelerated energy efficiency
6 and/or land-use improvements. Overall, however the global contribution is so far modest, at a few
7 billion tonnes (tCO2e) of avoided emissions annually. {1.3, 1.4, Chapters 2, 4,13,14}.
8 Accelerating mitigation to prevent dangerous anthropogenic interference within the climate
9 system will require the integration of broadened assessment frameworks and tools that combine
10 multiple perspectives, applied in a context of multi-level governance (robust evidence, medium
11 agreement). Analysing a challenge on the scale of fully decarbonising our economies entails integration
12 of multiple analytic frameworks. Approaches to risk assessment and resilience, established across IPCC
13 Working Groups, are complemented by frameworks for probing the challenges in implementing
S
14 mitigation. Aggregate Frameworks include cost-effectiveness analysis towards given objectives, and
15 cost-benefit analysis, both of which have been developing to take fuller account of advances in
IT
16 understanding risks and innovation, the dynamics of emitting systems and of climate impacts, and
AL N
17 welfare economic theory including growing consensus on long-term discounting. Ethical frameworks
ED
N IO
18 consider the fairness of processes and outcomes which can help ameliorate distributional impacts across
19 income groups, countries and generations. Transition and transformation frameworks explain and
20 evaluate the dynamics of transitions to low-carbon systems arising from interactions amongst levels,
FI S
21 with inevitable resistance from established socio-technical structures. Psychological, behavioural and
R
22 political frameworks outline the constraints (and opportunities) arising from human psychology and the
23 power of incumbent interests. A comprehensive understanding of climate mitigation must combine
TO E
24 these multiple frameworks. Together with established risk frameworks, collectively these help to
T DV
25 explain potential synergies and trade-offs in mitigation, imply a need for a wide portfolio of policies
26 attuned to different actors and levels of decision-making, and underpin ‘just transition’ strategies in
27 diverse contexts. {1.2.2, 1.7, 1.8}.
EC TE
28 The speed, direction and depth of any transition will be determined by choices in the,
29 environmental, technological, economic, socio-cultural and institutional realms (robust evidence,
30 high agreement). Transitions in specific systems can be gradual or rapid and disruptive. The pace of a
BJ P
31 transition can be impeded by ‘lock-in’ generated by existing physical capital, institutions, and social
E
32 norms. The interaction between power, politics and economy is central in explaining why broad
33 commitments do not always translate to urgent action. At the same time, attention to and support for
SU C
34 climate policies and low carbon societal transition has generally increased, as the impacts have become
AC
35 more salient. Both public and private financing and financial structures strongly affect the scale and
36 balance of high and low carbon investments. COVID-19 has strained public finances, and integrating
37 climate finance into ongoing recovery strategies, nationally and internationally, can accelerate the
38 diffusion of low carbon technologies and also help poorer countries to minimise future stranded assets.
39 Societal & behavioural norms, regulations and institutions are essential conditions to accelerate low
40 carbon transitions in multiple sectors, whilst addressing distributional concerns endemic to any major
41 transition. {1.3.3, Cross-Chapter Box 1 in this chapter, 1.4, 1.8, Chapters 2-4 and 15}.
42 Achieving the global transition to a low-carbon, climate-resilient and sustainable world requires
43 purposeful and increasingly coordinated planning and decisions at many scales of governance
44 including local, subnational, national and global levels (robust evidence, high agreement).
45 Accelerating mitigation globally would imply strengthening policies adopted to date, expanding the
46 effort across options, sectors, and countries, and broadening responses to include more diverse actors
47 and societal processes at multiple – including international – levels. Effective governance of climate
48 change entails strong action across multiple jurisdictions and decision-making levels, including regular
1 evaluation and learning. Choices that cause climate change as well as the processes for making and
2 implementing relevant decisions involve a range of non-nation state actors such as cities, businesses,
3 and civil society organisations. At global, national and subnational levels, climate change actions are
4 interwoven with and embedded in the context of much broader social, economic and political goals.
5 Therefore, the governance required to address climate change has to navigate power, political,
6 economic, and social dynamics at all levels of decision making. Effective climate-governing
7 institutions, and openness to experimentation on a variety of institutional arrangements, policies and
8 programmes can play a vital role in engaging stakeholders and building momentum for effective climate
9 action. {1.4, 1.9, Chapters 8, 15, 17}.
10
11 1.1 Introduction
12 This Report (WGIII) aims to assess new literature on climate mitigation including implications for
S
13 global sustainable development. In this Sixth Assessment Cycle the IPCC has also published three
IT
14 Special Reports1 all of which emphasise the rising threat of climate change and the implications for
AL N
15 more ambitious mitigation efforts at all scales. At the same time, the Paris Agreement (PA) and the UN
ED
16 2030 Agenda for Sustainable Development with its 17 Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs), both
N IO
17 adopted in 2015, set out a globally agreed agenda within which climate mitigation efforts must be
18 located. Along with a better understanding of the physical science basis of climate change (AR6 WGI),
FI S
19 and vulnerabilities, impacts, and adaptation (AR6 WGII), the landscape of climate mitigation has
R
20 evolved substantially since Fifth Assessment Report (AR5).
21 Since AR5, (IPCC 2014a) climate mitigation policies around the world have grown in both number
TO E
22 and shape (Chapter 13). However, while the average rate of annual increase of CO2 emissions has
T DV
23 declined (Section 1.3.2) GHG emissions globally continued to rise, underlining the urgency of the
24 mitigation challenge (Chapters 2, 3). Over twenty countries have cut absolute emissions alongside
25 sustained economic growth, but the scale of mitigation action across countries remains varied and
26 generally much slower than the pace required to meet the goals of the Paris Agreement (Section 1.3.2
EC TE
27 in this chapter and Section 2.7.2 in Chapter 2). Per-capita GHG emissions between countries even at
28 similar stages of economic development (based on GDP per capita) vary by a factor of three (Figure
BJ P
29 1.6) and by more than two on consumption basis (Section 2.3 in Chapter 2).
E
30 The Special Report on 1.5oC underlined that humanity is now living with the “unifying lens of the
31 Anthropocene” (SR 1.5 IPCC 2018a, 52 & 53), that requires a sharpened focus on the impact of human
SU C
32 activity on the climate system and the planet more broadly given ‘planetary boundaries’ (Steffen et al.
AC
33 2015) including interdependencies of climate change and biodiversity (Dasgupta 2021). Recent
34 literature assessed by WGs I and II of this AR6 underlines the urgency of climate action as cumulative
35 CO2 emissions, along with other greenhouses gases, drives the temperature change. Across AR6, global
36 temperature changes are defined relative to the period 1850-1900, as in SR1.5 and collaboration with
37 WGI enabled the use of AR6-calibrated emulators to assure consistency across the three Working
38 Groups. The remaining ‘carbon budgets’ (see Annex I) associated with 1.5°C and 2°C temperature
39 targets equate to about one (for 1.5°C) to three (for 2°C) decades of current emissions, as from 2020,
40 but with significant variation depending on multiple factors including other gases (Figure 2.7 in Chapter
FOOTNOTE1 These are the ‘Special Report on the impacts of global warming of 1.5°C above pre-industrial levels
and related global greenhouse gas emission pathways, in the context of strengthening the global response to the
threat of climate change, sustainable development, and efforts to eradicate poverty’ (hereafter SR1.5, 2018) (IPCC
2018b); the ‘Special Report on Climate Change and Land’ (SRCCL) (IPCC 2019c); and the ‘Special Report on
the Ocean and Cryosphere in a Changing Climate’ (SROCC) (IPCC 2019b).
1 2; Cross-Working Group Box 1 in Chapter 3). For an outline of the WGIII approach to mitigation
2 scenarios, emission pathways implied by the Paris goals, and timing of peak and ‘net zero’ (Annex I
3 and FAQ 1.3), see Section 1.5, and Chapter 3.
4 Strong differences remain in responsibilities for, and capabilities to, take climate action within and
5 between countries. These differences, as well as differences in the impact of climate change, point to
6 the role of collective action in achieving urgent and ambitious global climate mitigation in the context
7 of sustainable development, with attention to issues of equity and fairness as highlighted in several
8 chapters of the report (Chapters 4, 5, 14, 15, 17).
9 Innovation and industrial development of key technologies in several relevant sectors have transformed
10 prospects for mitigation at much lower cost than previously assessed (Chapters 2 and 6–12). Large
11 reductions in the cost of widely-available renewable energy technologies, along with energy efficient
12 technologies and behavioural changes (Chapters 5 and 9–11), can enable societies to provide services
13 with much lower emissions. However, there are still significant differences in the ability to access and
S
14 utilise low carbon technologies across the world (Chapter 4, 15, 16). New actors, including cities,
IT
15 businesses, and numerous non-state transnational alliances have emerged as important players in the
AL N
16 global effort to tackle climate change (Chapters 13–16).
ED
17 Along with continued development of concepts, models and technologies, there have been numerous
18
19
N IO
insights from both the successes and failures of mitigation action that can inform future policy design
and climate action. However, to date, policies and investments are still clearly inadequate to put the
FI S
20 world in line with the PA’s aims (Chapters 13, 15).
R
21 The greater the inertia in emission trends and carbon-intensive investments, the more that CO2 will
TO E
22 continue to accumulate (Hilaire et al. 2019; IPCC 2019a). Overall, the literature points to the need for
23 a more dynamic consideration of intertwined challenges concerning the transformation of key GHG
T DV
24 emitting systems: to minimise the trade-offs, and maximise the synergies, of delivering deep
25 decarbonisation whilst enhancing sustainable development.
26 This Chapter introduces readers to the AR6 WGIII Report and provides an overview of progress and
EC TE
27 challenges, in three parts. Part A, introduces the climate mitigation challenge, provides key findings
28 and developments since previous assessment, and reviews the main drivers for, and constraints against
29 accelerated climate action. Part B provides an assessment of the key frameworks for understanding the
BJ P
30 climate mitigation challenge covering broad approaches like sustainable development and more specific
E
31 economic, political and ethical framings. Part C briefly highlights the role of governance for steering
SU C
32 and coordinating efforts to accelerate globally effective and equitable climate mitigation, notes the gaps
33 in knowledge that have been identified in the process of assessment and provides a road map to the rest
AC
34 of the Report.
35
1 population and economic growth, resulting in global mean surface temperature increases in 2100 from
2 3.7°C to 4.8°C compared to pre-industrial levels. AR5 noted that mitigation effort and the costs
3 associated with ambitious mitigation differ significantly across countries, and in ‘globally cost-
4 effective’ scenarios, the biggest reductions (relative to projections) occur in the countries with the
5 highest future emissions in the baseline scenarios (IPCC 2014b, p. 17). Since most physical capital (e.g.
6 power plants, buildings, transport infrastructure) involved in GHG emissions is long-lived, the timing
7 of the shift in investments and strategies will be crucial (IPCC 2014b, p. 18).
8 A key message from recent Special Reports is the urgency to mitigate GHG emissions in order to avoid
9 rapid and potentially irreversible changes in natural and human systems (IPCC 2019b, 2018b, 2019a).
10 Successive IPCC reports have drawn upon increasing sophistication of modelling tools to project
11 emissions in the absence of ambitious decarbonisation action, as well as the emission pathways that
12 meet long term temperature targets. The SR1.5 examined pathways limiting warming to 1.5°C,
13 compared to historical baseline of 1850-1900, finding that “in pathways with no or limited overshoot
S
14 of 1.5°C, global net anthropogenic CO2 emissions decline by about 45% from 2010 levels by 2030,
15 reaching net zero around 2050” (2045–2055 interquartile range); with ‘overshoot’ referring to higher
IT
16 temperatures, then brought down by 2100 through ‘net negative’ emissions. It found this would require
AL N
17 rapid and far-reaching transitions in energy, land, urban and infrastructure (including transport and
ED
N IO
18 buildings), and industrial systems (high confidence) (IPCC 2018b).
19 SR1.5 found that the Nationally Determined Contributions (NDCs) as declared under the Paris
FI S
20 Agreement (PA) would not limit warming to 1.5 C; despite significant updates to NDCs in 2020/21,
21 this remains the case though delivery of these more ambition NDCs would somewhat enhance the
R
22 prospects for staying below 2°C (Section 1.3.3).
TO E
23 AR5 WGIII and the Special Reports analysed economic costs associated with climate action. The
T DV
24 estimates vary widely depending on the assumptions made as to how ordered the transition is,
25 temperature target, technology availability, the metric or model used, among others (Chapter 6).
26 Modelled direct mitigation costs of pathways to 1.5°C, with no/limited overshoot, span a wide range,
27 but were typically 3-4 times higher than in pathways to 2°C (high confidence), before taking account
EC TE
28 of benefits, including significant reduction in loss of life and livelihoods, and avoided climate impacts
29 (IPCC 2018b).
BJ P
30 Successive IPCC Reports highlight a strong connection between climate mitigation and sustainable
E
31 development. Climate mitigation and adaptation goals have synergies and trade-offs with efforts to
32 achieve sustainable development, including poverty eradication. A comprehensive assessment of
SU C
33 climate policy therefore involves going beyond a narrow focus on specific mitigation and adaptation
AC
34 options to incorporate climate issues into the design of comprehensive strategies for equitable
35 sustainable development. At the same time, some climate mitigation policies can run counter to
36 sustainable development and eradicating poverty, which highlights the need to consider trade-offs
37 alongside benefits. Examples include synergies between climate policy and improved air quality,
38 reducing premature deaths and morbidity (IPCC 2014b Fig SPM.6; AR6 WG1 sections 6.6.3 and 6.7.3),
39 but there would be trade-offs if policy raises net energy bills, with distributional implications. The
40 Special Report on Climate Change and Land (SRCCL) also emphasises important synergies and trade-
41 offs, bringing new light on the link between healthy and sustainable food consumption and emissions
42 caused by the agricultural sector. Land-related responses that contribute to climate change adaptation
43 and mitigation can also combat desertification and land degradation and enhance food security (IPCC
44 2019a).
45 Previous ARs have detailed the contribution of various sectors and activities to global GHG emissions.
46 When indirect emissions (mainly from electricity, heat and other energy conversions) are included, the
47 four main consumption (end-use) drivers are industry, AFOLU, buildings and transport (Chapter 2,
1 Figure 2.14), though the magnitude of these emissions can vary widely between countries. These –
2 together with the energy and urban systems which feed and shape end-use sectors – define the sectoral
3 chapters in this AR6 WGIII report.
4 Estimates of emissions associated with production and transport of internationally traded goods were
5 first presented in AR5 WGIII, which estimated the ‘embodied emission transfers’ from upper-middle-
6 income countries to industrialised countries through trade at about 10 percent of CO2 emissions in each
7 of these groups (IPCC 2014a Fig TS.5). The literature on this and discussion on their accounting has
8 grown substantially since then (Chapters 2 & 8).
9 The atmosphere is a shared global resource and an integral part of the “global commons”. In the
10 depletion/restoration of this resource, myriad actors at various scales are involved, for instance,
11 individuals, communities, firms and states. Inter alia, international cooperation to tackle ozone
12 depletion and acid rain offer useful examples. AR5 noted that greater cooperation would ensue if
13 policies are perceived as fair and equitable by all countries along the spectrum of economic
S
14 development–implying a need for equitable sharing of the effort. A key takeaway from AR5 is that
climate policy involves value judgement and ethics. (IPCC 2014a Box TS.1 “People and countries have
IT
15
AL N
16 rights and owe duties towards each other. These are matters of justice, equity, or fairness. They fall
ED
17 within the subject matter of moral and political philosophy, jurisprudence, and economics.” p. 37).
N IO
18 International cooperation and collective action on climate change alongside local, national, regional and
19 global policies will be crucial to solve the problem, and this report notes cooperative approaches beyond
FI S
20 simple ‘global commons’ framings (Chapters 13, 14).
R
21 AR5 (all Working Group Reports) also underlined that climate policy inherently involves risk and
22 uncertainty (in nature, economy, society and individuals). To help evaluate responses, there exists a rich
TO E
23 suite of analytical tools, for example, cost-benefit analysis, cost-effectiveness analysis, multi-criteria
T DV
24 analysis, expected utility theory and catastrophe and risk models. All have pros and cons, and have been
25 further developed in subsequent literature and AR6 (next section).
26 Recent Assessments (IPCC 2014a, 2018b) began to consider the role of individual behavioural choices
EC TE
27 and cultural norms in driving energy and food patterns. Notably, SR1.5 (Section 4.4.3 in Chapter 4)
28 outlined emerging evidence on the potential for changes in behaviour, lifestyle and culture to contribute
29 to decarbonisation (and lower the cost); for the first time, AR6 devotes a whole chapter (Chapter 5) to
BJ P
30 consider these and other underlying drivers of energy demand, food choices and social aspects.
E
32 The assessment of the Physical Science Basis (IPCC WGI AR6) documents sustained and widespread
33 changes in the atmosphere, cryosphere, biosphere and ocean, providing unequivocal evidence of a world
AC
34 that has warmed, associated with rising atmospheric CO2 concentrations reaching levels not experienced
35 in at least the last 2 million years. Aside from temperature, other clearly discernible, human-induced
36 changes beyond natural variations include declines in Arctic Sea ice and glaciers, thawing of
37 permafrost, and a strengthening of the global water cycle (WG1 SPM A.2, B.3 and B.4). Oceanic
38 changes include rising sea level, acidification, deoxygenation, and changing salinity (WG1 SPM B.3).
39 Over land, in recent decades, both frequency and severity have increased for hot extremes but decreased
40 for cold extremes; intensification of heavy precipitation is observed in parallel with a decrease in
41 available water in dry seasons, along with an increased occurrence of weather conditions that promote
42 wildfires.
43 In defining the objective of international climate negotiations as being to ‘prevent dangerous
44 anthropogenic interference’ (Article 2 UNFCCC 1992), the UNFCCC underlines the centrality of risk
45 framing in considering the threats of climate change and potential response measures. Against the
46 background of ‘unequivocal’ (AR4) evidence of human-induced climate change, and the growing
1 experience of direct impacts, the IPCC has sought to systematise a robust approach to risk and risk
2 management.
3 In AR6 the IPCC employs a common risk framing across all three working groups and provides
4 guidance for more consistent and transparent usage (AR6 WGI Cross-Chapter Box 3 in Chapter 1; AR6
5 WGII 1.4.1; IPCC risk guidance). AR6 defines risk as “the potential for adverse consequences for
6 human or ecological systems, recognising the diversity of values and objectives associated with such
7 systems” (Annex I), encompassing risks from both potential impacts of climate change and human
8 responses to it (Reisinger et al. 2020). The risk framing includes steps for identifying, evaluating, and
9 prioritising current and future risks; for understanding the interactions among different sources of risk;
10 for distributing effort and equitable sharing of risks; for monitoring and adjusting actions over time
11 while continuing to assess changing circumstances; and for communications among analysts, decision-
12 makers, and the public.
13 Climate change risk assessments face challenges including a tendency to mis-characterise risks and pay
S
14 insufficient attention to the potential for surprises (Weitzman 2011; Aven and Renn 2015; Stoerk et al.
15 2018). Concepts of resilience and vulnerability provide overlapping, alternative entry points to
IT
16 understanding and addressing the societal challenges caused and exacerbated by climate change (AR6,
AL N
17 WGII, Chapter 1.2.1).
ED
N IO
18 AR6 WGII devotes a full chapter (17) to ‘Decision-Making Options for Managing Risk’, detailing the
19 analytic approaches and drawing upon the Cynefin classification of Known, Knowable, Complex and
FI S
20 Chaotic systems (17.3.1). With deep uncertainty, risk management often aims to identify specific
21 combinations of response actions and enabling institutions that increase the potential for favourable
R
22 outcomes despite irreducible uncertainties (AR6 WGII Chapter 17 Cross-Chapter Box DEEP; also
TO E
24 Literature trying to quantify the cost of climate damages has continued to develop. Different
25 methodologies systematically affect outcomes, with recent estimates based on empirical approaches –
26 econometric measurements based on actual impacts – ‘categorically higher than estimates from other
27 approaches’ (Cross-Working Group Box ECONOMIC in WGII Chapter 16, Section 16.6.2). This, along
EC TE
28 with other developments strengthen foundations for calculating a ‘social cost of carbon’. This informs
29 a common metric for comparing different risks and estimating benefits compared to the costs of GHG
30 reductions and other risk-reducing options (Section 1.7.1); emissions mitigation itself also involves
BJ P
31 multiple uncertainties, which alongside risks can also involve potential opportunities (Section 1.7.3).
E
33 assessment and management (e.g., representative key risks in WGII Chapter 16), which may or may
34 not correlate with any single estimate of economic value (AR6 WGII 1.4.1; IPCC risk guidance). Given
AC
35 the deep uncertainties and risks, the goals established (notably in the Paris Agreement and SDGs) reflect
36 negotiated outcomes informed by the scientific assessment of risks.
37
39 Since AR5, there have been notable multilateral efforts which help determine the context for current
40 and future climate action. This section summarises key features of this evolving context.
1 Change (UNFCCC), the UN agreements on Disaster Risk Reduction (Sendai) and Finance for
2 Development (Addis Ababa), and the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs).
3 The Paris Agreement (PA). The Paris Agreement aims to “hold the increase in the global average
4 temperature to well below 2°C above pre-industrial levels and pursuing efforts to limit the temperature
5 increase to 1.5°C above pre-industrial levels” (UNFCCC 2015), alongside goals for adaptation (IPCC
6 WGII), and ‘aligning financial flows’ (below) , so as “to strengthen the global response to the threat of
7 climate change, in the context of sustainable development and efforts to eradicate poverty.”
8 The Paris Agreement is predicated on encouraging progressively ambitious climate action from all
9 countries on the basis of Nationally Determined Contributions (Rajamani 2016; Clémençon 2016). The
10 NDC approach requires countries to set their own level of ambitions for climate change mitigation but
11 within a collaborative and legally binding process to foster ambition towards the agreed goals (Falkner
12 2016a; Bodansky 2016). The PA entered into force in November 2016 and as of February 2021 it has
13 190 Parties (out of 197 Parties to the UNFCCC).
S
14 The PA also underlines “the principle of common but differentiated responsibilities and respective
IT
15 capabilities, in the light of different national circumstances” (PA Article 2 para 2), and correspondingly
AL N
16 that “developed country Parties should continue taking the lead by undertaking economy-wide absolute
ED
17 emission reductions”. It states that developing country Parties should continue enhancing their
18
19
N IO
mitigation efforts, and are encouraged to move over time towards economy-wide emission reduction or
limitation targets in the light of different national circumstances.
FI S
20 The Paris Agreement’s mitigation goal implies “to achieve a balance between anthropogenic emissions
R
21 by sources and removals by sinks of greenhouse gases in the second half of this century” (PA Article 4
TO E
22 para 1). The Paris Agreement provides for 5-yearly stocktakes in which Parties have to take collective
23 stock on progress towards achieving its purposes and its long-term goal in the light of equity and
T DV
24 available best science (PA Article 14). The first global stocktake is scheduled for 2023. (PA Article 14
25 para 3).
26 The Paris Agreement aims to make ‘finance flows consistent with a pathway towards low greenhouse
EC TE
27 gas emissions and climate-resilient development’ (PA Article 2.1C). In keeping with the acknowledged
28 context of global sustainable development and poverty eradication, and the corresponding aims of
29 aligning finance and agreed differentiating principles as indicated above, “…the developed country
BJ P
30 parties are to assist developing country parties with financial resources” (PA Article 9). The Green
E
31 Climate Fund (GCF), an operating entity of the UNFCCC Financial Mechanism to finance mitigation
SU C
32 and adaptation efforts in developing countries (GCF 2020), was given an important role in serving the
33 Agreement and supporting PA goals.. The GCF gathered pledges worth USD 10.3 billion, from
AC
34 developed and developing countries, regions, and one city (Paris) (Antimiani et al. 2017; Bowman and
35 Minas 2019). Financing has since increased but remains short of the goal to mobilise USD100 billion
36 by 2020 (Chapter 15).
37 Initiatives contributing to the Paris Agreement goals include the Non-State Actor Zone for Climate
38 Action (NAZCA or now renamed as Global Climate Action) portal, launched at COP20 (December
39 2014) in Lima, Peru, to support city-based actions for mitigating climate change (Mead 2015) and
40 Marrakech Partnership for Global Climate Action which is a UNFCCC-backed series of events intended
41 to facilitate collaboration between governments and the cities, regions, businesses and investors that
42 must act on climate change.
43 Details of the Paris Agreement, evaluation of the Kyoto Protocol, and other key multilateral
44 developments since AR5 relevant to climate mitigation including the CORSIA aviation agreement
45 adopted under ICAO, the IMO shipping strategy, and the Kigali Amendment to the Montreal Protocol
46 on HFCs, are discussed in Chapter 14.
1 SDGs. In September 2015, the UN endorsed a universal agenda – ‘Transforming our World: the 2030
2 Agenda for Sustainable Development’. The agenda adopted 17 non-legally-binding SDGs and 169
3 targets to support people, peace, prosperity, partnerships and the planet. While climate change is
4 explicitly listed as SDG13, the pursuit of the implementation of the UNFCCC is relevant for a number
5 of other goals including SDG 7 (clean energy for all), 9 (sustainable industry), and 11 (sustainable
6 cities), 12 (responsible consumption and production) as well as those relating to life below water (14)
7 and on land (15) (Biermann et al. 2017). Mitigation actions could have multiple synergies and trade-
8 offs across the SDGs (Chapter 17; Pradhan et al. 2017) and their net effects depend on the pace and
9 magnitude of changes, the specific mitigation choices and the management of the transition. This
10 suggests that mitigation must be pursued in the broader context of sustainable development as explained
11 in Section 1.6
12 Finance. The Paris Agreement’s finance goal (above) reflects a broadened focus, beyond the costs of
13 climate adaptation and mitigation, to recognising that a structural shift towards low carbon climate-
S
14 resilient development pathways requires large scale investments that engage the wider financial system
15 (15.1 and 15.2.4). The SR1.5C report estimated that 1.5oC pathways would require increased investment
IT
16 of 0.5-1% of global GDP between now and 2050, which is up to 2.5% of global savings / investment
AL N
17 over the period. For low- and middle-income countries, SDG-compatible infrastructure investments in
ED
the most relevant sectors are estimated to be around 4-5% of their GDP, and ‘infrastructure investment
N IO
18
19 paths compatible with full decarbonisation in the second half of the century need not cost more than
20 more-polluting alternatives’ (Rozenberg and Fay 2019).
FI S
21 The parallel 2015 UN Addis Ababa Conference on Finance for Development, and its resulting Action
R
22 Agenda, aims to ‘address the challenge of financing … to end poverty and hunger, and to achieve
TO E
23 sustainable development in its three dimensions through promoting inclusive economic growth,
24 protecting the environment, and promoting social inclusion.’ The Conference recognises the significant
T DV
25 potential of regional co-operation and provides a forum for discussing the solutions to common
26 challenges faced by developing countries (15.6.4).
27 Alongside this, private and blended climate finance is increasing but is still short of projected
EC TE
28 requirements consistent with Paris Agreement goals (15.3.2.1). The financing gap is particularly acute
29 for adaptation projects, especially in vulnerable developing countries. From a macro-regulatory
BJ P
30 perspective, there is growing recognition that substantial financial value may be at risk from changing
31 regulation and technology in a low-carbon transition, with potential implications for global financial
E
32 stability (15.6.3). To date, the most significant governance development is the Financial Stability
Board’s Task Force on Climate-related Financial Disclosure (TCFD) and its recommendations that
SU C
33
34 investors and companies consider climate change risks in their strategies and capital allocation, so
AC
35 investors can make informed decisions (TCFD 2018), welcomed by over 500 financial institutions and
36 companies as signatories, albeit with patchy implementation (1.4. 4; 15.6.3).
37 Talanoa Dialogue and Just Transition. As mandated at Paris COP21 and launched at COP23, the
38 ‘Talanoa Dialogue’ (UNFCCC 2018a) emphasised holistic approaches across multiple economic
39 sectors for climate change mitigation. At COP24 also, the Just Transition Silesia Declaration, focusing
40 on the need to consider social aspects in designing policies for climate change mitigation was signed
41 by 56 heads of state (UNFCCC 2018b). This underlined the importance of aiming for a ‘just transition’
42 in terms of reducing emissions, at the same time preserving livelihoods and managing economic risks
43 for countries and communities that rely heavily on emissions-intensive technologies for domestic
44 growth (Markkanen and Anger-Kraavi 2019), and for maintaining ecosystem integrity through nature-
45 based solutions.
S
14 CO2 (GHG) emissions per-capita, at about 5tCO2/person (/7tCO2e/person) respectively.
IT
AL N
ED
N IO
FI S
R
TO E
T DV
EC TE
BJ P
E
SU C
AC
S
IT
AL N
ED
N IO
FI S
R
TO E
T DV
EC TE
BJ P
E
SU C
1
AC
2 Figure 1.1: Global emission trends since 2000 by groups of gases: absolute, per-capita, and intensity
3 Note: Shows CO2 from fossil fuel combustion and industrial processes (FFI); CO 2 from Agriculture, Forestry and Other Land use (AFOLU); methane (CH4); nitrous oxide
4 (N2O); fluorinated gases (F-gases). Gases reported in Gt CO2eq converted based on AR6 global warming potentials with 100-year time horizon (GWP-100).
1 Due to its much shorter lifetime, methane has disproportionate impact on near-term temperature, and is
2 estimated to account for almost a third of the warming observed to date (AR6 WG1 SPM; WG-III Chapter
3 2, Figure 2.4). Methane reductions could be particularly important in relation to near- and medium-term
4 temperatures, including through counteracting the impact of reducing short-lived aerosol pollutants which
5 have an average cooling effect.2
6 The land-use component of CO2 emissions has different drivers and particularly large uncertainties (Chapter
7 2, Figures 2.2, 2.5), hence is shown separately. Also, compared to AR5, new evidence showed that the
8 AFOLU CO2 estimates by the global models assessed in this report are not necessarily comparable with
9 national GHG inventories, due to different approaches to estimate the 'anthropogenic' CO2 sink. Possible
10 ways to reconcile these discrepancies are discussed in Chapter 7.
S
IT
11 Regional trends have varied. Emissions from most countries continued to grow, but in absolute terms, 32
AL N
12 countries reduced energy-and-industry-CO2 emissions for at least a decade, and 24 reduced overall GHG
ED
13 (CO2-eq) emissions over the same period, but only half of them by more than 10% over the period in each
N IO
14 case (Chapter 2).3 In total, developed country emissions barely changed from 2010, whilst those from the
15 rest of the world grew.
16
17
FI S
Figure 1.2 shows the distribution of regional CO2 (GHG emissions) (a) per capita and (b) per GDP based
R
on purchasing power parity (GDPppp) of different country groupings in 2019. Plotted against population and
TO E
18 GDP respectively, the area of each block is proportional to the region’s emissions. Compared to the
19 equivalent presentations in 2004 (AR4, SPM.3) and 2010 (AR5, Figure 1.8), East Asia now forms
T DV
20 substantially the biggest group, whilst at about 8(/10tCO2eq) per person, its emissions per-capita remain
21 about half that of north America. In contrast, a third of the world’s population, in southern Asia and Africa,
22 emit on average under 2 (2.5tCO2eq) per person, little more than in the previous Assessments. Particularly
EC TE
23 for these regions there continue to be substantial differences in the GDP, life expectancy and other measures
24 of wellbeing (see Figure 1.6).
BJ EP
SU C
FOOTNOTE2 Indeed, cooling effects of anthropogenic aerosols (organic carbon, black carbon, sulphates, nitrates),
AC
which are also important components of local air pollution (Myhre et al. 2013; WGI SPM D1.7) may in global average
be of similar magnitude to warming from methane at present. Mitigation which reduces such aerosol masking could
thereby increase global temperatures, and reducing methane emissions would offset this much more rapidly than
reducing CO2 because of its relatively short lifetime, with the combined effects which could counterbalance each other
(WGI SPM D1.7). Methane is thus particularly important in determining whether or when 1.5C is reached for
example.
FOOTNOTE 3 With some exclusions for countries which were very small or undergoing economic collapse: Energy-
and Industry-CO2 emissions in 2018 were below 2010 levels in 32 developed countries, but only in 24 when including
other GHGs. Reductions were by less than 10% in half these countries. Data from Chapter 2: see (2.2.3) and Figure
2.11 for panel of countries that have sustained territorial emission reductions longer than 10 years, as analysed in
Lamb et al. (2021), and decomposition analysis of national trends in Xia et al. (2021). The previously rising trend of
‘outsourced/embodied emissions’ associated with goods imported into developed countries peaked in 2006, but
detailed data on this are only available EEI-CO2, to 2018 (Section 2.3 in Chapter 2). See Chapter 3 for reduction rates
associated with 1.5 and 2°C.
1 Emissions per unit GDP are much less diverse than per-capita, and have also converged significantly.
2 Poorer countries tend to show higher energy/ emissions per unit GDP partly because of higher reliance on
3 basic industries, and this remains the case, though in general their energy/GDP has declined faster.
4 Many developed country regions are net importers of energy-intensive goods, and emissions are affected
5 by the accounting of such ‘embodied emissions’. Panels (c) and (d) show results (only available for CO2,
6 to 2018) on the basis of consumption-footprints which include emissions embodied in traded goods. This
7 makes modest changes to the relative position of different regions (for further discussion see Chapter 2).
S
IT
AL N
ED
N IO
FI S
R
TO E
T DV
EC TE
BJ EP
8
SU C
9 Figure 1.1: Distribution of regional GHG emissions for 10 broad global regions according to territorial
10
AC
accounting (panels a & b, GHG emissions) and consumption-based accounting (panels c & d, CO2-FFI
11 emissions only).
12 GHG emissions are categorised into: Fossil fuel and industry (CO 2-FFI), Land use, land use change, forestry
13 (CO2-LULUCF) and other greenhouse gases (methane, nitrous oxide, Fgas - converted to 100-year global
14 warming potentials). Per-capita GHGs for territorial (panel a) and CO2-FFI emissions vs population for
15 consumption-based accounting (panel c). Panels b & d: GHG emissions per unit GDPppp vs GDPppp,
16 weighted with purchasing power parity for territorial accounting (panel b), CO2-FFI emissions per unit
17 GDPppp for consumption-based accounting (panel d). The area of the rectangles refers to the total emissions
18 for each regional category, with the height capturing per-capita emissions (panels a and c) or emissions per
19 unit GDPppp (panels b and d), and the width proportional to the population of the regions and GDPppp.
20 Emissions from international aviation and shipping (2.4% of the total GHG emissions) are not included.
1 While extreme poverty has fallen in more than half of the world’s economies in recent years, nearly one-
2 fifth of countries faced poverty rates above 30% in 2015 (below USD1.90 a day), reflecting large income
3 inequality (Laborde Debucquet and Martin 2017; Rozenberg and Fay 2019). Diffenbaugh and Burke (2019)
4 find that global warming already has increased global economic inequality, even if between-country
5 inequalities have decreased over recent decade. The distributional implications between regional groups
6 of different in the ‘shared socioeconomic pathways (SSPs)’ diverge according to the scenario (Frame et al.
7 2019).
8 An important recent development has been commitments by many countries, now covering a large majority
9 of global emissions, to reach net zero CO2 or greenhouse gas emissions (Chapter 3).4 Furthermore, globally,
10 net zero targets (whether CO2 or GHG) have been adopted by about 823 cities and 101 regions (Chapter 8).
S
11 1.3.3 Some Other Key Trends and Developments
IT
12 The COVID-19 pandemic profoundly impacted economy and human society, globally and within
AL N
13 countries. As detailed in Cross-Chapter Box 1, some of its impacts will be long lasting, permanent even,
ED
N IO
14 and there are also lessons relevant to climate change. The direct impact on emissions projected for rest of
15 this decade are modest, but the necessity for economic recovery packages creates a central role for
16 government-led investment, and may change the economic fundamentals involved for some years to come.
17
18
FI S
The COVID-19 aftermath consequently also changes the economic context for mitigation (Sections 15.2
R
and 15.4 in Chapter 15). Many traditional forms of economic analysis (expressed as general equilibrium)
TO E
19 assume that available economic resources are fully employed, with limited scope for beneficial economic
20 ‘multiplier effects’ of government-led investment. After COVID-19 however, no country is in this state.
T DV
21 Very low interest rates amplify opportunities for large-scale investments which could bring ‘economic
22 multiplier’ benefits, especially if they help to build the industries and infrastructures for further clean
23 growth (Hepburn et al. 2020). However, the capability to mobilise low interest finance vary markedly across
EC TE
24 countries and large public debts - including bringing some developing countries close to default - undermine
25 both the political appetite and feasibility of large-scale clean investments. In practice the current orientation
26 of COVID-19 recovery packages is very varied, pointing to a very mixed picture about whether or not
BJ EP
30 Cross-chapter Box 1 The COVID-19 crisis: lessons, risks and opportunities for mitigation
31 Authors: Diana Ürge-Vorsatz (Hungary), Lilia Caiado Couto (Brazil), Felix Creutzig (Germany), Dipak
32 Dasgupta (India), Michael Grubb (United Kingdom), Kirsten Halsnaes (Denmark), Siir Kilkis (Turkey),
33 Alexandre Koberle (Brazil), Silvia Kreibiehl (Germany), Jan Minx (Germany), Peter Newman (Australia),
34 Chukwumerije Okereke (Nigeria/ United Kingdom)
35 The COVID-19 pandemic triggered the deepest global economic contraction as well as CO2 emission
36 reductions since the Second World War (Section 2.2.2.1 in Chapter 2; AR6 WGI Box 6.1 in Chapter 6) (Le
37 Quéré et al. 2020b;). While emissions and most economies are expected to rebound in 2021-2022 (IEA
38 2021), some impacts of the pandemic (eg. aspects of economy, finance and transport-related emission
1 drivers) may last far longer. COVID-19 pushed more than 100 million people back into extreme poverty,
2 and reversed progress towards some other SDGs including health, life expectancy and child literacy (UN
3 DESA 2021). Health impacts and the consequences of deep economy-wide shocks may last many years
4 even without significant future recurrence (Section 15.6.3 in Chapter 15). These changes, as well as the
5 pandemic response actions, bring both important risks as well as opportunities for accelerating mitigation
6 (Chapters 1, 5, 10 and 15).
7 Lessons. Important lessons can be drawn from the pandemic to climate change including the value of
8 forward-looking risk management, the role of scientific assessment, preparatory action and international
9 process and institutions (1.3, Chapter 5). There had been long-standing warnings of pandemic risks, and
10 precursors – with both pandemic and climate risks being identified by social scientists as ‘uncomfortable
11 knowledge’, or ‘unknown knowns’ which tend to be marginalised in practical policy (Rayner 2012;
S
12 Sarewitz 2020). This echoes long-standing climate literature on potential ‘high impact’ events, including
13 those perceived as low probability (Dietz 2011; Weitzman 2011). The costs of preparatory action, mainly
IT
14 in those countries that had suffered from earlier pandemics were negligible in comparison, suggesting the
AL N
15 importance not just of knowledge but its effective communication and embodiment in society (Chapter 5).
ED
N IO
16 (Klenert et al. 2020) offer five early lessons for climate policy, concerning: the cost of delay; the bias in
17 human judgement; the inequality of impacts; the need for multiple forms of international cooperation; and
18 finally, ‘transparency in value judgements at the science-policy interface’.
19
20
FI S
Emissions and behavioural changes. Overall, global CO2 FFI emissions declined by about 5.8% (5.1% to
R
6.3%) from 2019 to 2020, or about 2.2 (1.8-2.4) GtCO2 in total (Section 2.2.2 in Chapter 2). Analysis from
TO E
21 previous economic crises suggest significant rebound in emissions without policy-induced structural shifts
22 (2.2.2.1; Figure 2.5) (Jaeger et al. 2020). Initial projections suggest the COVID aftermath may reduce
T DV
23 emissions by 4-5% over 2025 - 2030 (Shan and Et.al 2020; Reilly et al. 2021), below a ‘no-pandemic’
24 baseline The long-term impacts on behaviour, technology and associated emissions remain to be seen, but
25 may be particularly significant in transport - lockdowns reduced mobility-related emissions, alongside two
EC TE
26 major growth areas: electronic communications replacing many work and personal travel requirements
27 (Section 4.4.3.4 in Chapter 4 and Chapter 10); and, revitalised local active transport and e-micromobility
28 (Earley and Newman 2021). Temporary ‘clear skies’ may also have raised awareness of the potential
BJ EP
29 environment and health co-benefits of reduced fossil fuel use particularly in urban areas (Section 8.7 in
30 Chapter 8), with evidence also indicating that air pollution itself amplified vulnerability to COVID-19 (Wu
31 et al. 2020; Gudka et al. 2020). The significant impacts on passenger aviation are projected to extend not
SU C
32 just through behavioural changes, but also fleet changes from retiring older planes, and reduced new orders
33 indicating expectations of reduced demand and associated GHG emissions until 2030 (Section 5.1.2 in
AC
34 Chapter 5 and Section 10.5 in Chapter 10; AR6 WGI Box 6.1 in Chapter 6). However, air cargo has
35 recovered more rapidly (IATA 2020), possibly enhanced by online ordering.
36 Fiscal, growth and inequality impacts. Aspects of the global and regional economic crises from COVID-
37 19 may prevail much longer than the crisis itself, potentially compromising mitigation. Most countries have
38 undertaken unprecedented levels of short-term public expenditures. The IMF projects sovereign debt to
39 GDP to have increased by 20% in advanced economies and 10% in emerging economies by the end of 2021
40 (IMF 2020). This is likely to slow economic growth, and may squeeze financial resources for mitigation
41 and relevant investments for many years to come (15.2.3, 15.6.3). COVID-19 further lowered interest rates
42 which should facilitate low carbon investment, but pandemic responses have increased sovereign debt
43 across countries in all income bands (IMF 2021), and particularly in some developing economies and
44 regions has caused debt distress (Bulow et al. 2021) widening the gap in developing countries’ access to
1 capital (Hourcade et al. 2021b) (Section 15.6.3 in Chapter 15). After decades of global progress in reducing
2 poverty, COVID-19 has pushed hundreds of millions of people below poverty thresholds and raises the
3 spectre of intersecting health and climate crises that are devastating for the most vulnerable (5.1.2 Box 5.1).
4 Like those of climate change, pandemic impacts fall heavily on disadvantaged groups, exacerbate the
5 uneven distribution of future benefits, amplify existing inequities, and introduce new ones. Increased
6 poverty also hinders efforts towards sustainable low-carbon transitions (1.6).
7 Impacts on profitability and investment. COVID-19-induced demand reduction in electricity
8 disproportionally affected coal power plants, whilst transport reduction most affected oil (IEA 2020a). This
9 accelerated pre-existing decline in the relative profitability of most fossil fuel industries (Ameli et al. 2021)
10 Renewables were the only energy sector to increase output (IEA 2020a). Within the context of a wider
11 overall reduction in energy investment this prompted a substantial relative shift towards low carbon
S
12 investment particularly by the private sector (IEA 2020b; Rosembloom and Markard 2020; 15.2.1, 15.3.1,
13 15.6.1).
IT
AL N
14 Post-pandemic recovery pathways provide an opportunity to attract finance into accelerated and
ED
15 transformative low-carbon public investment (15.2, 15.6.3). In most countries, COVID-19 has increased
N IO
16 unemployment and/or state-supported employment. There is a profound difference between short-term
17 ‘bail-outs’ to stem unemployment, and the orientation of new public investment. The public debt is mirrored
18
19
20
FI S
by large pools of private capital. During deep crises like that of the COVID-19, economic multipliers of
stimulus packages can be high (Hepburn et al., 2020), so much so that fiscal injections can then generate
R
multipliers from 1.5 to 2.5, weakening the alleged crowding-out effect of public stimulus (Auerbach and
TO E
21 Gorodnichenko 2012; Blanchard and Leigh 2013; Section 15.2.3 in Chapter 15).
T DV
22 Recovery packages are motivated by assessments that investing in can boost the macroeconomic
23 effectiveness (‘multipliers’) of public spending, crowd-in and revive private investment (Hepburn et al.
24 2020). There are clear reasons why a low-carbon response can create more enduring jobs, better aligned to
25 future growth sectors: by also crowding-in and reviving private investment (e.g. from capital markets and
EC TE
26 institutional investors, including the growing profile of Environment and Social Governance (ESG) and
27 green bond markets (15.6)), this can boost the effectiveness of public spending (IMF 2020). Stern and
28 Valero (Stern and Valero 2021) argue that investment in low-carbon innovation and its diffusion,
BJ EP
32 poorer economies.
AC
33 A study with a global general equilibrium model (Liu et al. 2021)finds that because the COVID-19
34 economic aftermath combines negative impacts on employment and consumption, a shift from employment
35 and consumption taxes to carbon or other resource- related taxes would enhance GDP by 1.7% in 2021
36 relative to ‘no policy’, in addition to reducing CO2 and other pollutants. A post-Keynesian model of wider
37 ‘green recovery’ policies (Pollitt et al. 2021) finds a short-run benefit of around 3.5% GDP (compared to
38 ‘no policy’), and even c. 1% above a recovery boosted by cuts in consumption taxes, the latter benefit
39 sustained through 2030 - outperforming an equivalent conventional stimulus package while reducing global
40 CO2 emissions by 12%.
41 Orientation of recovery packages. The large public spending on supporting or stimulating economies,
42 exceeding USD12tn by October 2020, dwarfs clean energy investment needs and hence could either help
43 to solve the combined crises, or result in high-carbon lock-in (Andrijevic et al. 2020). The short-term ‘bail-
1 outs’ to date do not foster climate resilient long-term investments and have not been much linked to climate
2 action, (Sections 15.2.3 and 15.6.3 in Chapter 15): in the G20 counties, 40% of energy-related support
3 spending went to the fossil fuel industry compared to 37% on low-carbon energy (EPT 2020). Recovery
4 packages are also at risk of being ‘colourless’ (Hepburn et al., 2020) though some countries and regions
5 have prioritised green stimulus expenditures for example as part of ‘Green New Deal’ (Rochedo et al. 2021;
6 Section 13.9.6 in Chapter 13 and Section 15.6.3 in Chapter 15).
7 Integrating analyses. The response to COVID-19 also reflects the relevance of combining multiple
8 analytic frameworks spanning economic efficiency, ethics and equity, transformation dynamics, and
9 psychological and political analyses (Section 1.7). As with climate impacts, not only has the global burden
10 of disease been distributed unevenly, but capabilities to prevent and treat disease were asymmetrical and
11 those in greatest vulnerability often had the least access to human, physical, and financial resources (Ruger
S
12 and Horton 2020). ‘Green’ versus ‘brown’ recovery has corresponding distributional consequences
13 between these and ‘green’ producers, suggesting need for differentiated policies with international
IT
14 coordination (Le Billon et al. 2021). This illustrates the role of ‘just transition’ approaches to global
AL N
15 responses including the value of integrated, multi-level governance (Section 1.7 in this Chapter, Section
ED
N IO
16 4.5 in Chapter 4 and Section 17.1 in Chapter 17).
17 Crises and opportunities: the wider context for mitigation and transformation. The impacts of
18
19
20
FI S
COVID-19 have been devastating in many ways, in many countries, and may distract political and financial
capacity away from efforts to mitigate climate change. Yet, studies of previous post-shock periods suggest
R
that waves of innovation that are ready to emerge can be accelerated by crises, which may prompt new
TO E
21 behaviours, weaken incumbent (‘meso-level’) systems, and prompt rapid reforms (Section 1.6.5; Roberts
22 and Geels 2019a). Lessons from the collective effort to 'flatten the curve’ during the pandemic, illustrating
T DV
23 aspects of science-society interactions for public health in many countries, may carry over to climate
24 mitigation, and open new opportunities (Section 5.1.2 in Chapter 5). COVID-19 appears to have accelerated
25 the emergence of renewable power, electromobility and digitalisation (Newman 2020; Sectiopn 5.1.2 in
EC TE
26 Chapter 5, Section 6.3 in Chapter 6, Section 10.2 in Chapter 10). Institutional change is often very slow but
27 major economic dislocation can create significant opportunities for new ways of financing and enabling
28 ‘leapfrogging’ investment to happen (Section 10.8 in Chapter 10). Given the unambiguous risks of climate
BJ EP
29 change, and consequent stranded asset risks from new fossil fuel investments (Box 6.11), the most robust
30 recoveries are likely to be those which emerge on lower carbon and resilient pathways (Obergassel et al.
31 2020). Noting the critical global post-COVID-19 challenge as the double-impact of heightened credit risk
SU C
32 in developing countries, along with indebtedness in developed countries, (Hourcade et al. 2021a) estimate
33 that a ‘multilateral’ sovereign guarantee structure to underwrite low carbon investments could leverage
AC
34 projects up to 15 times its value, contributing to shifting development pathways consistent with the SDGs
35 and Paris goals.
36 COVID- 19 can thus be taken as a reminder of the urgency of addressing climate change, a warning of the
37 risk of future stranded assets (Rempel and Gupta 2021; and Chapter 17), but also an opportunity for a
38 cleaner recovery.
39 END CROSS-CHAPTER BOX 1 HERE
40
41 In addition to developments in climate science, emissions, the international agreements in 2015, and the
42 recent impact of COVID-19, a few other key developments have strong implications for climate mitigation.
1 Cheaper Renewable Energy Technologies: Most striking, the cost of solar PV has fallen by a factor of 5-
2 10 in the decade since the IPCC Special Report on Renewable Energy (IPCC 2011a) and other data inputting
3 to the AR5 assessments, The SR1.5 reported major cost reductions, the IEA (2020) World Energy Outlook
4 described PV as now ‘the cheapest electricity in history’ for projects that ‘tap low cost finance and high
5 quality resources.’ Costs and deployment both vary widely between different countries (chapter 6, 9, 12)
6 but costs are still projected to continue falling (Vartiainen et al. 2020). Rapid technological developments
7 have occurred in many other low-carbon technologies including batteries and electric vehicles (see 1.4.3),
8 IT and related control systems, with progress also where electrification is not possible (Chapters 2, 6, 11)
9 Civil society pressures for stronger action. Civic engagement increased leading up to the Paris Agreement
10 (Bäckstrand and Lövbrand 2019) and after. Youth movements in several countries show young people’s
11 awareness about climate change, evidenced by the school strikes for the climate (Hagedorn et al. 2019;
S
12 Buettner 2020; Walker 2020; Thackeray et al. 2020). Senior figures across many religions (Francis 2015;
13 IFEES 2015) stressed the duty of humanity to protect future generations and the natural world, and warned
IT
14 about the inequities of climate change. Growing awareness of local environmental problems such as air
AL N
15 pollution in Asia and Africa (Karlsson et al. 2020), and the threat to indigenous people rights and existence
ED
N IO
16 has also fuelled climate activism (Etchart 2017). Grass-root movements (Cheon and Urpelainen 2018;
17 Fisher et al. 2019), build political pressure for accelerating climate change mitigation, as does increasing
18 climate litigation (Setzer and Vanhala 2019; Chapters 13 and 14).
19
20
FI S
Climate policies also encounter resistance. However there are multiple sources of resistance to climate
R
action in practice. Corporations and trade associations often lobby against measures they deem detrimental
TO E
21 (Section 1.4.6). The emblematic ‘yellow vest’ movement in France was triggered by higher fuel cost as a
22 result of CO2 tax hike (Lianos 2019; Driscoll 2021), though it had broader aspect of income inequality and
T DV
23 other social issues. There is often mismatch between concerns on climate change and people’s willingness
24 to pay for mitigation. For example, whilst most Americans believe climate change is happening, 68% said
25 in a survey they would oppose climate policies that added just USD10/month to electricity bills (EPIC et
EC TE
26 al. 2019), and worry about energy costs can eclipse those about climate change elsewhere (Poortinga et al.
27 2018; Chapter 13).
28 Global trends contrary to multilateral cooperation. State-centred politics and geopolitical/geo-economic
BJ EP
29 tensions seem to have become more prominent across many countries and issues (WEF 2019). In some
30 cases, multilateral cooperation could be threatened by trends such as rising populism, nationalism,
31 authoritarianism and growing protectionism (Abrahamsen et al. 2019), making it more difficult to tackle
SU C
32 global challenges including protecting the environment (Schreurs 2016; Parker et al. 2017; WEF 2019).
AC
33 Transnational alliances. Partly countering this trend, cities, businesses, a wide range of other non-state
34 actors also have emerged with important international networks to foster mitigation. City-based examples
35 include the Cities Alliance in addressing climate change, Carbon Neutral Cities Alliance, the Covenant of
36 Mayors (chapter 8); there are numerous other alliances and networks such as those in finance (chapter 15),
37 technology (chapter 16), amongst many others (chapters 13, 14).
38 Finally, under the Paris Agreement process, during 2020/21, many countries strengthened their Nationally
39 Determined Contributions (NDCs). Including updates until October 2021, these would imply global GHG
40 emissions declining by 2030 to between 1-4% below 2019 levels (unconditional NDCs), or 4-10% (for
41 NDCs conditional on international support), See Table 4.3 in Chapter 4 ).This is a significant change but
42 would still not be compatible with 1.5°C pathways, and even if delivered in full, to likely stay below 2°C,
43 emissions would have to fall very rapidly after 2030 (Section 3.2.5).
1 Thus, developments since AR5 highlight the complexity of the mitigation challenge. There is no far-sighted,
2 globally optimising decision-maker and indeed climate policymaking at all levels is subject to conflicting
3 pressures in multiple ways. The next section overviews the drivers and constraints.
4
S
10 social innovation and equity and fairness; and (iii) Institutional factors, which comprise policy, legal
11 frameworks and international co-operation.
IT
AR 5 introduced six “enabling conditions” for shifting development pathways which are presented in
AL N
12
ED
13 Chapter 4 of this report and some of which overlap with the drivers reviewed here. However, the
N IO
14 terminology of drivers and constraints have been chosen here to reflect the fact that each of these factors
15 can serve as an enabling condition or a constraint to ambitious climate action depending on the context and
16
17
18
FI S
how they are deployed. Often one sees the factors exerting both push and pull forces at the same time in
the same and across different scales. For example, finance and investments can serve as a barrier or an
R
enabler to climate action (Battiston et al. 2021). Similarly, political economy factors can align in favour of
TO E
19 ambitious climate action or act in ways that inhibit strong co-operation and low carbon transition. The other
20 key insight from the assessment of the system drivers and constraints undertaken below is that none of the
T DV
21 factors or conditions by themselves is more or less important than the others. In addition to being deeply
22 intertwined all the factors matter in different measures with each exacting more or less force depending on
23 prevailing social, economic, cultural and political context. Often achieving accelerated mitigation would
24 require effort to bring several of the factors in alignment in and across multiple levels of political or
EC TE
25 governance scales.
26 1.4.1 Services, sectors and urbanisation
BJ EP
27 Human activities drive emissions primarily through the demand for a wide range of services such as food,
28 shelter, heating/cooling, goods, travel, communication, and entertainment. This demand is fulfilled by
SU C
29 various activities often grouped into sectors such as agriculture, industry and commerce. The literature
30 uses a wide range of sectoral definitions to organize data and analysis (Chapter 2). Energy sectors are
AC
31 typically organised into primary energy producers, energy transformation processes (such as power
32 generation, fuel refining), and major energy users such as buildings, industry, transport (Chapters 2, 5).
33 Other research (Chapter 8) organizes data around interacting urban and rural human activities. Land-based
34 activities can be organized into agriculture, forestry, and other land use (AFOLU), or land use, land use
35 change and forestry (LULUCF) (Chapter 7). Each set of sectoral definitions and analysis offers its own
36 insights.
37 Sectoral perspectives help to identify and understand the drivers of emissions, opportunities for emissions
38 mitigation, and interactions with resources, other goals and other sectors, including the co-evolution of
39 systems across scales (Moss et al. 2016; Kyle et al. 2016; Mori et al. 2017; IPBES 2019). Interactions
40 between sectors and agents pursuing multiple goals is a major theme pervading this assessment.
1 The ‘nexus’ between energy, water, and land – all key contributors to human well-being – also helps to
2 provide, regulate and support ecosystem and cultural services (Bazilian et al. 2011; Ringler et al. 2013;
3 Smajgl et al. 2016; Albrecht et al. 2018; D’Odorico et al. 2018; Brouwer et al. 2018; Van Vuuren et al.
4 2019), with important implications for cities in managing new systems of transformation (Chapter 8;
5 Thornbush et al. 2013; Wolfram et al. 2016) . Other important nexus’ shaping our planet’s future (Fajardy
6 et al. 2018) include agriculture, forestry, land use and ecosystem services (Chazdon 2008; Keesstra et al.
7 2018; Nesshöver et al. 2017; Torralba et al. 2016; Settele et al. 2016).
8 Historically, energy-related GHG emissions were considered a by-product of the increasing scale of human
9 activity, driven by population size, economic activity and technology. That simple notion has evolved
10 greatly over time to become much more complex and diverse, with increasing focus on the provision of
11 energy services (Garrett et al. 2020; Bardi et al. 2019; Cullen and Allwood 2010; Brockway et al. 2019))
S
12 The demand for agricultural products has historically driven conversion of natural lands (land use change).
13 AFOLU along with food processing account for 21-37% of total net anthropogenic GHG emissions
IT
14 (SRCCL SPM A3).5
AL N
ED
15 Continued growth in population and income are expected to continue driving up demand for goods and
N IO
16 services (Chapters 2, 3 & 5), with an important role for urbanisation which is proceeding at an
17 unprecedented speed and scale. In the last decade, the urban population grew by 70 million people each
18
19
20
FI S
year, or about 1.3 million people per week, with urban area expanding by about 102 km2 per day (Chapter
8). Urban areas account for most (45-87%) of the global carbon footprint (8.1) and the strong and positive
R
correlation between urbanisation and incomes means higher consumption from urban lifestyles will
TO E
21 continue driving direct and indirect GHG emissions. Cities provide conduit to many of the services such as
22 transportation, housing, water, food, medical care, recreation and other services and urban carbon emissions
T DV
23 are driven not only by population and income but also by form and structure of urban areas (8.1, 8.3, 8.4,
24 8.5, 8.6). This creates opportunities for decarbonization through urban planning and purposeful
25 “experimentation” (Newman et al. 2017 Chapter 8).
EC TE
26 Human needs and wants evolve over time making the transition toward climate and sustainable
27 development goals either more or less difficult. For example, changes in the composition of goods
28 consumed, such as, shifting diets toward a more vegetarian balance, can reduce land-use emissions without
BJ EP
29 compromising the quality of life (Stehfest et al. 2009; van Vuuren et al. 2018; van den Berg et al. 2019;
30 Hargreaves et al. 2021; Gough 2017; SRCCL SPM B2.3).
SU C
31 Human behavior and choices, including joint achievement of wider social goals, will play an important part
32 in enabling or hindering climate mitigation and sustainable development (Shi et al. 2016), for example
AC
33 shifting passenger transportation preferences in ways that combine climate, health and sustainable
34 development goals (Romanello et al. 2021).
35 1.4.2 Trade, consumption and leakage
36 Emissions associated with international trade account for 20-33 % of global emissions, as calculated using
37 multi-regional input-output analysis (Wiedmann and Lenzen 2018). Whether international trade drives
38 increase or decrease in global GHG emissions depends on emissions intensity of traded products as well as
39 the influence of trade on relocation of production, with studies reaching diverse conclusions about the net
40 effect of trade openness on CO2 emissions (Section 2.4.5). Tariff reduction of low carbon technologies
FOOTNOTE5 AFOLU accounted for about 13% of CO2, 44% of CH4 and 82% of N2O global anthropogenic GHG
emissions in 2007-2016 (SRCCL SPM A3).
1 could facilitate effective mitigation (de Melo and Vijil 2014; WTO 2016; Ertugrul et al. 2016; Islam et al.
2 2016).
3 The magnitude of carbon leakage (Annex I) caused by unilateral mitigation in a fragmented climate policy
4 world depends on trade and substitution patterns of fossil fuels and the design of policies (see Box 5.4.
5 AR5), but its potential significance in trade-exposed energy-intensive sectors (Naegele and Zaklan 2019;
6 Carbone and Rivers 2017; Bauer et al. 2013) can make it an important constraint on policy. See Section
7 13.6.6.1 in Chapter 13 for channels and evidence. Akimoto et al. (2018) argue that differences in marginal
8 abatement cost of NDCs could cause carbon leakage in energy-intensive, trade-exposed sectors, and could
9 weaken effective global mitigation.
10 Policy responses to cope with carbon leakage include border carbon adjustment (BCAs) and differentiated
11 carbon taxes (Liu et al. 2020). Some BCA options focusing on levelling the cost of carbon paid by
S
12 consumers on products could be designed in line with WTO (Ismer et al. 2016) while others may not be
IT
13 (Mehling et al. 2019). All proposals could involve difficulty of tracing and verifying the carbon content of
AL N
14 inputs (Onder 2012; Denis-Ryan et al. 2016). An international consensus and certification practice on the
ED
15 carbon content would help to overcome WTO compatibility (Holzer 2014). See chapter 13, and (Mehling
N IO
16 et al. 2019) on context of trade law and the PA.
17 Official inventories report territorial emissions, which do not consider the impacts embodied in imports of
18
19
FI S
goods. Global supply chains undoubtedly lead to a growth in trade volumes (Federico and Tena-Junguito
R
2017), alternative methods have been suggested to account for emissions associated with international trade,
20 such as shared responsibility (Lenzen et al. 2007), technology adjusted consumption based accounting
TO E
21 (Kander et al. 2015), value added-based responsibility (Piñero et al. 2019) and exergy-based responsibility
T DV
26 environmental impacts (Malik et al. 2019; Wiedmann and Lenzen 2018). chapter 2.3).
27 Increasing international trade has resulted in a general shifting of fossil-fuel driven emissions-intensive
BJ EP
28 production from developed to developing countries (Arto and Dietzenbacher 2014; Malik and Lan 2016),
29 and between developing countries (Zhang et al. 2019). High-income developed countries thus tend to be
30 net importers of emissions, whereas low/middle income developing countries net-exporters (Peters et al.
SU C
31 2011; Figure 1.2c, d).This trend is shifting, with a growth in trade between non-OECD countries (Meng et
32 al. 2018; Zhang et al. 2019), and a decline in emissions intensity of traded goods (Wood et al. 2020b).
AC
33 The Paris Agreement primarily deals with national commitments relating to domestic emissions and
34 removals, hence emissions from international aviation and shipping are not covered. Aviation and shipping
35 accounted for approximately 2.7% of greenhouse gas emissions in 2019 (before COVID-19); see Chapter
36 10.5.2 for discussion. In addition to CO2 emissions, aircraft-produced contrail cirrus clouds and emissions
37 of black carbon and short-lived aerosols (e.g. sulphates) from shipping are especially harmful for the Arctic
38 (10.8, Box 10.6).
39 1.4.3 Technology
40 The rapid developments in technology over the past decade enhance potential for transformative changes,
41 in particular to help deliver climate goals simultaneously with other SDGs.
1 The fall in renewable energy costs alongside rapid growth in capacity (Figure 1.3; Figure X in Chapter 2)
2 has been accompanied by varied progress in many other technology areas such electric vehicles, fuel cells
3 for both stationary and mobile applications (Dodds 2019), thermal energy (chapter 6) and battery and other
4 storage technologies (Chapters 6, 9, 12; Freeman et al. 2017). Nuclear contributions may be enhanced by
5 new generations of reactors, e.g., Generation III, and small modular reactors (Knapp and Pevec 2018; see
6 also Chapter 6).
7
S
IT
AL N
ED
N IO
8
9
FI S
R
Figure 1.2: Cost reductions and adoption in solar PV and wind energy
10 Source: (IRENA 2020a,b), with fossil fuel LCOE indicated as shaded blue at USD 50-177/MWh (IRENA 2020b)
TO E
11 Large-scale hydrogen developments could provide a complementary energy channel with long-term
T DV
12 storage. Like electricity, hydrogen (H2) is an energy vector with multiple potential applications, including
13 in industrial processes such as steel and non-metallic materials production (Chapter 11), for long-range
14 transportation (Chapter 10), and low-temperature heating in buildings (Chapter 9). Emissions depend on
15 how it is produced, and deploying H2 delivery infrastructure economically is a challenge when the future
EC TE
16 scale of hydrogen demand is so uncertain (Chapter 6). H2 from natural gas with CO2 capture and storage
17 (CCS) may help to kick-start the H2 economy (Sunny et al. 2020).
BJ EP
18 CO2-based fuels and feedstocks such as synthetic methane, methanol, diesel, jet fuel and other
19 hydrocarbons, potentially from carbon capture and utilisation (CCU), represent drop-in solutions with
20 limited new infrastructure needs (Artz et al. 2018; Bobeck et al. 2019; Yugo and Soler 2019); Chapter 10.
SU C
21 Deployment and development of CCS technologies (with large-scale storage of captured CO2) have been
AC
22 much slower than projected in previous Assessments (Page et al. 2019; IEA 2019b; see also Chapter 11).
23 Potential constraints on new energy technologies may include their material requirements, notably rare
24 earth materials for electronics or lithium for batteries (Wanger 2011; Flexer et al. 2018), stressing the
25 importance of recycling (Rosendahl and Rubiano 2019; IPCC 2011b). Innovation is enabling greater
26 recycling and re-use of energy-intensive materials (Shemi et al. 2018) and introducing radically new and
27 more environmentally friendly materials, however, still not all materials can be recycled (Allwood 2014).
28 By sequestering carbon in biomass and soils, soil carbon management, and other terrestrial strategies could
29 offset hard-to-reduce emissions in other sectors. However, large-scale bioenergy deployment could increase
30 risks of desertification, land degradation, and food insecurity (IPCC 2019a), and higher water withdrawals
31 (Hasegawa et al. 2018; Fuhrman et al. 2020), though this may be at least partially offset by innovation in
32 agriculture, diet shifts and plant-based proteins contributing to meeting demand for food, feed, fibre and,
33 bioenergy (or BECCS with CCS) (Chapters 5, 7; Köberle et al. 2020; Havlik et al. 2014; Popp et al. 2017).
1 A broad class of more speculative technologies propose to counteract effects of climate change by removing
2 CO2 from the atmosphere (CDR), or directly modify the Earth’s energy balance at a large scale (SRM).
3 CDR technologies include ocean iron fertilisation, enhanced weathering and ocean alkalinisation (Council
4 2015a), along with Direct Air Capture with Carbon Storage (DACCS). They could potentially draw down
5 atmospheric CO2 much faster than the Earth’s natural carbon cycle, and reduce reliance on biomass-based
6 removal (Realmonte et al. 2019; Köberle 2019), but some present novel risks to the environment and
7 DACCS is currently more expensive than most other forms of mitigation (Fuss et al. 2018; Cross-chapter
8 box 8 in Chapter 12). Solar radiation modification (SRM) could potentially cool the planet rapidly at low
9 estimated direct costs by reflecting incoming sunlight (Council 2015b), but entails uncertain side effects
10 and thorny international equity and governance challenges (Netra et al. 2018; Florin et al. 2020; National
11 Academies of Sciences 2021) (Chapter 14). Understanding the climate response to SRM remains subject
12 to large uncertainties (AR6 WG1). Some literature uses the term “geoengineering” for both CDR or SRM
S
13 when applied at a planetary scale (Shepherd 2009; GESAMP 2019). In this report, CDR and SRM are
IT
14 discussed separately reflecting their very different geophysical characteristics.
AL N
15 Large improvements in information storage, processing, and communication technologies, including
ED
N IO
16 artificial intelligence, will affect emissions. They can enhance energy-efficient control, reduce transaction
17 cost for energy production and distribution, improve demand-side management (Raza and Khosravi 2015),
18 and reduce the need for physical transport (Smidfelt Rosqvist and Winslott Hiselius 2016; see Chapters 5,
19
20
FI S
6, 9-11). However, data centres and related IT systems (including blockchain), are electricity-intensive and
R
will raise demand for energy (Avgerinou et al. 2017) - cryptocurrencies may be a major global source of
21 CO2 if the electricity production is not decarbonised (Mora et al. 2018) – and there is also a concern that
TO E
22 information technologies can compound and exacerbate current inequalities (Chapter 16; Box 2). IT may
T DV
23 affect broader patterns of work and leisure (Boppart and Krusell 2020), and the emissions intensity of how
24 people spend their leisure time will become more important (see Chapters 5, 9). Because higher efficiency
25 tends to reduces costs, it often involves some ‘rebound’ offsetting at least some of the emission savings
26 (Belkhir and Elmeligi 2018; Sudbury and Hutchinson 2016; Cohen and Cavoli 2019).
EC TE
27 Technology can enable both emissions reductions and/or increased emissions (Chapter 16). Governments
28 play an important role in most major innovations, in both ‘technology-push’ (Mazzucato 2013) and induced
BJ EP
29 by ‘demand-pull’ (Grubb et al. 2021a), so policy is important in determining its pace, direction, and
30 utilisation (Roberts and Geels 2019a; Sections 1.7.1, 1.7.3). Overall, the challenge will be to enhance the
31 synergies and minimise the trade-offs and rebounds, including taking account of ethical and distributional
SU C
1 risks and opportunities for the financial sector. The risks include physical risks related to the impacts of
2 climate change itself; transition risks related to the exposure to policy, technology and behavioural changes
3 in line with a low-carbon transition; and liability risks from litigation for climate-related damages (Box
4 15.2). These could potentially lead to stranded assets (the loss of economic value of existing assets before
5 the end of their useful lifetimes (Bos and Gupta 2019; Section 6.7 in Chapter 6, Section 15.6.3 in Chapter
6 15). Such risks continue to be underestimated by financial institutions (Section 15.6.1 in Chapter 15). The
7 continuing expansion of fossil fuel infrastructure and insufficient transparency on how these are valued
8 raises concerns that systemic risk may be accumulating in the financial sector in relation to a potential low-
9 carbon transition that may already be under way (Battiston et al. 2017; Section 15.6.3 in Chapter 15). The
10 Financial Stability Board’s TCFD recommendations on transparency aim to ensure that investors and
11 companies consider climate change risks in their strategies and capital allocation (TCFD 2018). This is
12 helping "investors to reassess core assumptions” and may lead to “significant” capital reallocation (Fink
S
13 2020). However, metrics and indicators of assets risk exposure are inadequate (Campiglio et al. 2018;
IT
14 Monasterolo 2017) and transparency alone is insufficient to drive the required asset reallocation in the
15 absence of clear regulatory frameworks (Chenet et al. 2021; Ameli et al. 2020). A coalition of Central Banks
AL N
16 have formed the Network for Greening the Financial Sector, to support and advance the transformation of
ED
N IO
17 the financial system (Allen et al. 2020; NGFS 2020), with some of them conducting Climate-related
18 institutional stress tests
19
20
21
FI S
Governments cannot singlehandedly fund the transition (Section 15.6.7 in Chapter 15), least of all in low-
income developing countries with large sovereign debt and poor access to global financial markets. Long-
R
term sources of private capital are required to close the financing gap across sectors and geographies
TO E
22 (Section 15.6.7 in Chapter 15). Future investment needs are greatest in emerging and developing economies
23 (Section 15.5.2 In Chapter 15) which already face higher cost of capital, hindering capacity to finance a
T DV
24 transition (Buhr et al. 2018; Ameli et al. 2020). Requisite North-South financial flows are impeded by both
25 geographic and technological risk premiums (Iyer et al. 2015), and the Covid-19 pandemic has further
26 compromised the ability of developing and emerging economies to finance development activities or attract
27 additional climate finance from developed countries (Cross-Chapter Box 1 in this chapter; Section 15.6.3
EC TE
28 in Chapter 15). Climate-related investments in developing countries also suffer from structural barriers
29 such as sovereign risk and exchange rate volatility (Farooquee and Shrimali 2016; Guzman et al. 2018)
BJ EP
30 which affect not only climate-related investment but investment in general (Yamahaki et al. 2020) including
31 in needed infrastructure development (Gray and Irwin 2003). A GCF report notes the paradox that USD14
32 trillion of negative-yielding debt in OECD countries might be expected to flow to much larger low-carbon,
climate-resilient investment opportunities in developing countries, but “this is not happening” (Hourcade
SU C
33
34 et al. 2021b).
AC
35 There is often a disconnect between stated national climate ambition and finance flows, and overseas direct
36 investment (ODI) from donor countries may be at odds with national climate pledges such as NDCs. One
37 report found funds supported by foreign State-Owned Enterprises into 56 recipient countries in Asia and
38 Africa in 2014-2017 went mostly to fossil fuel-based projects not strongly aligned with low-carbon
39 priorities of recipient countries’ NDCs (Zhou et al. 2018). Similarly, Steffen and Schmidt (2019) found that
40 even within Multilateral Development Banks, ‘public- and private-sector branches differ considerably’,
41 with public-sector lending used mainly in non-renewable and hydropower projects. Political leadership is
42 therefore essential to steer financial flows to support low carbon transition (15.6). Voituriez er al. (2019)
43 identify significant mitigation potential if financing countries simply applied their own environmental
44 standards to their overseas investments.
45
S
12 in daily life (Malm 2015; Huber 2012; Di Muzio 2015; Newell and Paterson 2010).
IT
13 The economic centrality of fossil fuels raises obvious questions regarding the possibility of decarbonisation.
AL N
14 Economically, this is well understood as a problem of decoupling. But the constraint is also political, in
ED
15 terms of the power of incumbent fossil fuel interests to block initiatives towards decarbonisation (Newell
N IO
16 and Paterson 2010; Geels 2014; Jones and Levy 2009). The effects of climate policy are key considerations
17 in deciding the level of policy ambition and direction and strategies of states (Alam et al. 2013; Ibikunle
18
19
20
FI S
and Okereke 2014; Lo 2010), regions (Goldthau and Sitter 2015); and business actors (Wittneben et al.
2012) and there is a widespread cultural assumption that continued fossil fuel use is central to this (Strambo
R
and Espinosa 2020). Decarbonisation strategies are often centred around projects to develop new sources
TO E
21 of economic activity: carbon markets creating new commodities to trade profit from (Newell and Paterson
22 2010); the investment generated in new urban infrastructure (Whitehead 2013); innovations in a range of
T DV
23 new energy technologies (Fankhauser et al. 2013; Lachapelle et al. 2017; Meckling and Nahm 2018).
24 One factor limiting the ambition of climate policy has been the ability of incumbent industries to shape
25 government action on climate change (Newell and Paterson 1998; Breetz et al. 2018; Jones and Levy 2009;
EC TE
26 Geels 2014). Incumbent industries are often more concentrated than those benefiting from climate policy
27 and lobby more effectively to prevent losses than those who would gain (Meng and Rode 2019). Drawing
28 upon wider networks (Brulle 2014), campaigns by oil and coal companies against climate action in the US
BJ EP
29 and Australia are perhaps the most well-known and largely successful of these (Brulle et al. 2020; Stokes
30 2020; Mildenberger 2020; Pearse 2017) although similar dynamics have been demonstrated for example in
31 Brazil and South Africa (Hochstetler 2020), Canada (Harrison 2018), Norway , or Germany (Fitzgerald et
SU C
32 al. 2019). In other contexts, resistance by incumbent companies is more subtle but nevertheless has
AC
33 weakened policy design on emissions trading systems (Rosembloom and Markard 2020), and limited the
34 development of alternative fuelled automobiles (Wells and Nieuwenhuis 2012; Levy and Egan 2003).
35 The interaction of politics, power and economics is central in explaining why countries with higher per-
36 capita emissions, which logically have more opportunities to reduce emissions, in practice often take the
37 opposite stance, and conversely, why some low-emitting countries may find it easier to pursue climate
38 action because they have fewer vested interests in high-carbon economies. These dynamics can arise from
39 the vested interest of State-owned Enterprises (Polman 2015; Wright and Nyberg 2017; Wittneben et al.
40 2012), the alignment and coalitions of countries in climate negotiations (Gupta 2016; Okereke and Coventry
41 2016), and the patterns of opposition to or support for climate policy among citizens (Swilling et al. 2016;
42 Ransan-Cooper et al. 2018; Turhan et al. 2019; Baker 2015; Heffron and McCauley 2018).
S
12 considered unfair may be hard to implement (Liu et al. 2017; Klinsky et al. 2017). Lessons from
13 experimental economics show that people may not accept a distribution that is considered unfair, even if
IT
14 there is a cost of not accepting (Gampfer 2014). As equity issues are important for reaching deep
AL N
15 decarbonisation, the transition towards a sustainable development (Okereke 2018; Evans and Phelan 2016;
ED
N IO
16 Heffron and McCauley 2018) depends on taking equity seriously in climate policies and international
17 negotiations (Martinez et al. 2019; Okereke and Coventry 2016; Klinsky et al. 2017).
18
19
20
FI S
Climate change and climate policies affect countries and people differently Low-income countries tend to
be more dependent on primary industries (agriculture, fisheries, etc.) than richer countries, and their
R
infrastructure may be less robust to tackle more severe weather conditions. Within a country, the burdens
TO E
21 may not be equally distributed either, due to policy measures implemented and from differences in
22 vulnerability and adaptive capacity following from e.g. income and wealth distribution, race and gender.
T DV
23 For instance, unequal social structures can result in women being more vulnerable to the effects of climate
24 change compared to men, especially in poor countries (Jost et al. 2016; Rao et al. 2019; Arora-Jonsson
25 2011). Costs of mitigation also differ across countries. Studies show there are large disparities of economic
EC TE
26 impacts of NDCs across regions, and also between relatively similar countries when it comes to the level
27 of development, due to large differences in marginal abatement cost for the emission reduction goal of
28 NDCs (Akimoto et al. 2018; Fujimori et al. 2016; Edmonds et al. 2019; Hof et al. 2017). Equalizing the
BJ EP
29 burdens from climate policies may give more support for mitigation policies (Maestre-Andrés et al. 2019).
30 Taking equity into account in designing an international climate agreement is complicated as there is no
31 single universally accepted equity criterion, and countries may strategically choose a criterion that favours
SU C
32 them (Lange et al. 2007, 2010). Still, several studies analyse the consequences of different social
AC
33 preferences in designing climate agreements, such as for instance inequality aversion, sovereignty and
34 altruism (Anthoff et al. 2010; Kverndokk et al. 2014).
35 International transfers from rich to poor countries to support mitigation and adaptation activities may help
36 equalizing burdens, as agreed upon in the UNFCCC (1992; Chapters 14 and 15) such that they may be
37 motivated by strategic as well as equity reasons (Kverndokk 2018; see also 1.4.4).
38 1.4.7 Social innovation and behaviour change
39 Social and psychological factors affect both perceptions and behaviour (Whitmarsh et al. 2021; Weber
40 2015). Religion, values, culture, gender, identity, social status and habits strongly influence individual
41 behaviours and choices and therefore, sustainable consumption (Section 1.6.3.1 in this chapter and Section
42 5.2 in Chapter 5). Identities can provide powerful attachments to consumption activities and objects that
43 inhibit shifts away from them (Stoll-Kleemann and Schmidt 2017; Ruby et al. 2020; Brekke et al. 2003;
1 Bénabou and Tirole 2011). Consumption is a habit-driven and social practice rather than simply a set of
2 individual decisions, making shifts in consumption harder to pursue (Evans et al. 2012; Shove and Spurling
3 2013; Kurz et al. 2015; Warde 2017; Verplanken and Whitmarsh 2021). Finally, shifts towards low-carbon
4 behaviour are also inhibited by social-psychological and political dynamics that cause individuals to ignore
5 the connections from daily consumption practices to climate change impacts (Norgaard 2011; Brulle and
6 Norgaard 2019).
7 As a notable example, plant-based alternatives to meat could reduce emissions from diets (Willett et al.
8 2019; Eshel et al. 2019) however, diets are deeply entrenched in cultures and identities and hard to change
9 (Fresco 2015; Mylan 2018). Changing diets also raises cross-cultural ethical issues, in addition to meat’s
10 role in providing nutrition (Plumwood 2004). Henceforth, some behaviours that are harder to change will
11 only be transformed by the transition itself: triggered by policies, the transition will bring about
S
12 technologies that, in turn, will entrench new sustainable behaviours.
IT
13 Behaviour can be influenced through a number of mechanisms besides economic policy and regulation,
AL N
14 such as information campaigns, advertising and ‘nudging’. Innovations and infrastructure also impact
ED
15 behaviour, as with bicycle lanes to reduce road traffic. Wider social innovations also have indirect impacts.
N IO
16 Education is increasing across the world, and higher education will have impacts on fertility, consumption
17 and the attitude towards the environment (Osili and Long 2008; McCrary and Royer 2011; Hamilton 2011).
18
19
20
FI S
Reducing poverty and improvements in health and reproductive choice will also have implications for
fertility, energy use and consumption globally. Finally, social capital and the ability to work collectively
R
may have large consequences for mitigation and the ability to adapt to climate change (Adger 2009; Section
TO E
21 4.3.5 in IPCC 2014a).
T DV
25 central role in in land-related systems (Chapter 7), urban development (Chapter 8), improving energy
26 efficiency in buildings (Chapter 9) and transport / mobility (Chapter 10), and decarbonising industrial
27 systems (Chapter 11).
BJ EP
28 Policy has been and will be central not only because greenhouse gas emissions are almost universally under-
29 priced in market economies (Stern and Stiglitz 2017; World Bank 2019), and because of inadequate
30 economic incentives to innovation (Jaffe et al. 2005) but also due to various delay mechanisms (Karlsson
SU C
31 and Gilek 2020) and multiple sources of path-dependence and lock-in to existing systems (Section 1.8.2),
including “Infrastructure developments and long-lived products that lock societies into GHG-intensive
AC
32
33 emissions pathways may be difficult or very costly to change, reinforcing the importance of early action
34 for ambitious mitigation (robust evidence, high agreement).” (AR5 p.18).
35 Many hundreds of policies have been introduced explicitly to mitigate GHG emissions, improve energy
36 efficiency or land use, or to foster low carbon industries and innovation, with demonstrable impact. The
37 role of policy to date has been most evident in energy efficiency (Sections 5.4 and 5.6 in Chapter 5) and
38 electricity (Chapter 6). The IPCC Special Report on Renewable Energy already found that “Government
39 policies play a crucial role in accelerating the deployment of RE technologies”, (IPCC 2011a, p. 24). Policy
40 packages since then have driven rapid expansion in renewables capacity and cost reductions (eg. through
41 the German Energiewende), and emission reductions from electricity (most dramatically with the halving
42 of CO2 emissions from UK power sector, driven by multiple policy instruments and regulatory changes),
43 as detailed in Chapter 6 (Section 6.7.5).
1 Chapter 13 charts the international evolution of policies and many of the lessons drawn. Attributing the
2 overall impact on emissions is complex, but an emerging literature of several hundred papers indicates
3 impacts on multiple drivers of emissions. Collectively, policies are likely to have curtailed global emissions
4 growth by several GtCO2e annually already by the mid-2010s (see Cross-Chapter Box 10 in Chapter 14).
5 This suggests initial evidence that policy has driven some decoupling (e.g. Figure 1.1d) and started to ‘bend
6 the curve’ of global emissions, but more specific attribution to observed trends is not as yet possible.6
7 However, some policies (e.g. subsidies to fossil fuel production or consumption), increase emissions; whilst
8 others (e.g. investment protection) may constrain efforts at mitigation. Also, wider economic and
9 developmental policies have important direct and indirect impacts on emissions. Policy is thus both a driver
10 and a constraint on mitigation.
11 Synergies and trade-offs arise partly because of the nexus of GHG emissions with other adverse impacts
S
12 (e.g. local air pollution) and critical resources (e.g. water and food) (Conway et al. 2015; Andrews-Speed
IT
13 and Dalin 2017), which also imply interacting policy domains.
AL N
14 The literature shows increasing emphasis on policy packages, including those spanning the different levels
ED
N IO
15 of niche/behaviour; existing regimes governing markets and public actors; and strategic and landscape
16 levels (Section 1.7.3). Chapters 13, 16, and 17 appraise policies for transformation in the context of
17 sustainable development, indicating the importance of policy as a driver at multiple levels and across many
18
19
FI S
actors, with potential for benefits as well as costs at many levels.
R
National-level legislation may be particularly important to the credibility and long-term stability of policy
TO E
20 to reduce the risks, and hence cost, of finance (Chapters 13, 15) and for encouraging private sector
21 innovation at scale (Chapter 16), for example if it offers greater stability and mid-term predictability for
T DV
22 carbon prices; Nash and Steurer (2019) find that seven national Climate Change Acts in European countries
23 all act as ‘living policy processes, though to varying extents’.
24 The importance of policy at multiple levels does not lessen the importance of international policy, for
EC TE
25 reasons including long-term stability, equity, and scope, but examples of effective implementation policy
26 at international levels remain fewer and governance weaker (Chapter 14).
1.4.9 Legal framework and institutions
BJ EP
27
28 Institutions are rules and norms held in common by social actors that guide, constrain and shape human
29 interaction (IPCC 2018b). Institutions can be formal, such as laws and policies, or informal, such as norms
SU C
30 and conventions. Institutions can both facilitate or constrain climate policy-making and implementation in
31 multiple ways. Institutions set the economic incentives for action or inaction on climate change at national,
AC
32 regional and individual levels (Dorsch and Flachsland 2017; Sullivan 2017).
FOOTNOTE 6 Linking estimated policy impacts to trends is complex, and as yet very tentative. An important factor
is that many mitigation policies involve investments in low carbon or energy efficient technology, the savings from
which persist. As a purely illustrative example: the annual increase in global emissions during 2000-2010 averaged
around 1GtCO2e yr-1, but with large fluctuations. If policies by 2010 reduced the annual increase in that year by
100MtCO2e (0.1GtC02e) below what it would otherwise have been, this is hard to discern. But if these savings sustain,
and in each subsequent year, policies cut another 100MtCO2e off the annual increase compared to the previous year,
global emissions after a decade would be around 5GtCO2e yr-1 below what they would have been without any such
policies, and on average close to stabilising. However each step would be difficult to discern in the noise of annual
fluctuations.
1 Institutions entrench specific political decision-making processes, often empowering some interests over
2 others, including powerful interest groups who have vested interest in maintaining the current high carbon
3 economic structures (Engau et al. 2017; Okereke and Russel 2010; Wilhite 2016); see also 1.4.6 and Chapter
4 13 on the sub national and national governance challenges including coordination, mediating politics and
5 strategy setting.
6 Some suggest that societal transformation towards low a carbon future requires new politics that involves
7 thinking in intergenerational time horizons, as well as new forms of partnerships between private and public
8 actors (Westman and Broto 2018), and associated institutions and social innovations to increase
9 involvement of non-state actors in climate governance (Fuhr et al. 2018). However literature is divided as
10 to how much democratisation of climate politics, with greater emphasis on equity and community
11 participation, would advance societal transformation in the face of climate change (Stehr 2005), or may
S
12 actually hinder radical climate action in some circumstances (Povitkina 2018).
IT
13 Since 2016, the number of climate litigation cases has increased rapidly. UN Environment’s “Global
AL N
14 Climate Litigation Report: 2020 Status Review” (UNEP 2020) noted that between March 2017 and 1 July
ED
15 2020, the number of cases nearly doubled with at least 1,550 climate cases filed in 8 countries. Several
N IO
16 important cases such as Urgenda Foundation v. The State of the Netherlands (“Urgenda”) and Juliana et al
17 v. United States (“Juliana”) have had ripple effects, inspiring other similar cases (Lin and Kysar 2020).
18
19
FI S
Numerous international climate governance initiatives engage national and subnational governments,
R
NGOs and private corporations, constituting a “regime complex” (Keohane and Victor 2011; Raustiala and
20 Victor 2004). They may have longer-run and second-order effects if commitments are more precise and
TO E
21 binding (Kahler 2017). However, without targets, incentives, defined baseline or monitoring, reporting, and
T DV
22 verification, they are not likely to fill the “mitigation gap” (Michaelowa and Michaelowa 2017).
23 1.4.10 International cooperation
24 Tackling climate change is often mentioned as an important reason for strong international co-operation in
EC TE
25 the 21st century (Bodansky et al. 2017; Cramton et al. 2017b; Keohane and Victor 2016; Falkner 2016).
26 Mitigation costs are borne by countries taking action, while the benefits of reduced climate change are not
27 limited to them, being in economic terms “global and non-excludable”. Hence anthropogenic climate
BJ EP
28 change is typically seen as a global commons problem (Wapner and Elver 2017; Falkner 2016). Moreover,
29 the belief that mitigation will raise energy cost and may adversely affect competitiveness creates incentives
30 for free riding, where states avoid taking their fair share of action (Barrett 2005; Keohane and Victor 2016).
SU C
31 International cooperation has the potential to address these challenges through collective action (Tulkens,
AC
32 2019) and international institutions offer opportunity for actors to engage in meaningful communication,
33 and exchange of ideas about potential solutions (Cole 2015). International cooperation is also vital for the
34 creation and diffusion of norms and the framework for stabilising expectations among actors (Pettenger
35 2016).
36 Some key roles of the UNFCCC have been detailed by its former heads (Kinley et al. 2021). In addition to
37 specific agreements (most recently the PA) it has enhanced transparency through reporting and data, and
38 generated or reinforced several important norms for global climate action including the principles of equity,
39 common but differentiated responsibility and respective capabilities, and the precautionary principles for
40 maintaining global cooperation among states with unevenly distributed emissions sources, climate impacts,
41 and varying mitigation cost across countries (Keohane and Victor, 2016). In addition to formal negotiations,
42 the annual Conference of Parties have increased awareness, and motivated more ambitious actions,
43 sometimes through for example the formation of ‘coalitions of the willing’. It provides a structure for
1 measuring and monitoring action towards a global goal (Milkoreit and Haapala 2019). International
2 cooperation (including the UNFCCC) can also promote technology development and transfer and capacity
3 building; mobilise finance for mitigation and adaptation, and help address concerns on climate justice (Chan
4 et al. 2018; Okereke and Coventry 2016; see Chapters 14-16).
5 A common criticism of international institutions is their limited (if any) powers to enforce compliance
6 (Zahar 2017). As a global legal institution, the PA has little enforcement mechanism (Sindico 2015), but
7 enforcement is not a necessary condition for an instrument to be legally binding (Bodansky 2016; Rajamani
8 2016). In reality implementation of specific commitments tends to be high once countries have ratified and
9 a Treaty or an Agreement is in force (Bodansky 2016; Rajamani 2016). Often, the problem is not so much
10 of 'power to enforce compliance or sanction non-compliance', but the level of ambition (Chapter 14).
11 However, whilst in most respects a driver, international cooperation has also been characterised as
S
12 ‘organised hypocrisy’ where proclamations are not matched with corresponding action (Egnell 2010).
IT
13 Various reasons for inadequate progress after 30 years of climate negotiations, have been identified
AL N
14 (Stoddard et al. 2021). International cooperation can also seem to be a barrier to ambitious action when
ED
15 negotiation is trapped in ‘relative-gains’ calculus, seek to game the regime or gain leverage over one
N IO
16 another (Purdon 2017), or where states lower ambition to the ‘least common dominator’ to accommodate
17 participation of the least ambitious states (Falkner 2016). Geden (2016) and Dubash (2020) offer more
18
19
FI S
nuanced assessments.
R
International collaboration works best if an agreement can be made self-reinforcing with incentives for
20 mutual gains and joint action (Keohane and Victor 2016; Barrett 2016), but the structure of the climate
TO E
21 challenge makes this hard to achieve. The evidence from the Montreal Protocol on ozone depleting
T DV
22 substances and from the Kyoto Protocol on GHGs, is that legally binding targets have been effective in that
23 participating Parties complied with them (Albrecht and Parker 2019; Shishlov et al. 2016), and (for Kyoto)
24 these account for most of the countries that have sustained emission reductions for at least the past 10-15
25 years (Section 1.3.2; Section 2.2 in Chapter 2). However, such binding commitments may deter
EC TE
26 participation if there are no clear incentives to sustain participation and especially if other growing emitters
27 are omitted by design, as with the Kyoto Protocol. Consequently the US refused to ratify (and Canada
28 withdrew), particularly on the grounds that developing countries had no targets; with participation in
BJ EP
29 Kyoto’s second period commitments declining further, the net result was limited global progress in
30 emissions under Kyoto (Scavenius and Rayner 2018; Bodansky 2016; Okereke and Coventry 2016) despite
31 full legal compliance in both commitment periods (chapter 14).
SU C
32 The negotiation of the Paris Agreement was thus done in the context of serious questions about how best
AC
33 to structure international climate cooperation to achieve better results. This new agreement is designed to
34 side-step the fractious bargaining which characterised international climate cooperation (Marcu 2017). It
35 contains a mix of hard, soft and non-obligations, the boundaries between which are blurred, but each of
36 which plays a distinct and valuable role (Rajamani 2016). The provisions of the PA could encourage flexible
37 responses to changing conditions, but limit assurances of ambitious national commitments and their
38 fulfilment (Pickering et al. 2018). The extent to which this new arrangement will drive ambitious climate
39 policy in the long run remains to be seen (Chapter 14).
40 Whilst the PA abandoned common accounting systems and timeframes, outside the UNFCCC many other
41 platforms and metrics for comparing mitigation efforts have emerged (Aldy 2015). Countries may assess
42 others’ efforts in determining their actions through multiple platforms including Climate Change
43 Cooperation Index (C3-I), Climate Change Performance Index (CCPI) ‘Climate Laws, Institutions and
1 Measures Index’ (CLIMI) (Bernauer and Böhmelt 2013) and Energy Transition Index (Singh et al. 2019).
2 International cooperative initiatives between and among non-state (e.g., business, investors, civil society)
3 and subnational (e.g., city, state) actors have also been emerging, taking the forms of public-private
4 partnerships, private sector governance initiatives, NGO transnational initiatives, and subnational
5 transnational initiatives (Bulkeley and Schroeder 2012; Hsu et al. 2018). Literature is mostly positive about
6 the role of these transnational initiatives in facilitating climate action across scales although criticism and
7 caution about their accountability and effectiveness remain (Chan et al. 2016; Roger et al. 2017; Widerberg
8 and Pattberg 2017; Michaelowa and Michaelowa 2017; Chapter 14).
9
S
11 Scenarios are a powerful tool for exploring an uncertain future world against the background of alternative
IT
12 choices and development. Scenarios can be constructed using both narrative and quantitative methods.
AL N
13 When these two methods are combined they provide complementary information and insights. Quantitative
ED
14 and narrative models are frequently used to represent scenarios to explore choices and challenges. The
N IO
15 IPCC has a long history of assessing scenarios (Nakicenovic et al. 2000; van Vuuren et al. 2011, 2014; see
16 also section 1.6 of AR6 WGI for a history of scenarios within the IPCC). This WGIII assessment employs
17
18
19
FI S
a wide range of qualitative and quantitative scenarios including quantitative scenarios developed through a
wide and heterogeneous set of tools ranging from spreadsheets to complex computational models (Annex
R
III provides further discussion and examples of computational models).
TO E
20 The concept of an illustrative pathway (IP) was introduced in IPCC Special Report on 1.5 (IPCC 2018b)
T DV
21 to highlight a subset of the quantitative scenarios, drawn from a larger pool of published literature, with
22 specific characteristics that would help represent some of the key findings emerging from the assessment
23 in terms of different strategies, ambitions and options available to achieve the Paris goals.
EC TE
24 Integrated Assessment Models (IAMs) are the primary tools for quantitatively evaluating the technological
25 and macro-economic implications of decarbonisation, particularly for global long-term pathways. They
26 broadly divide into ‘stylized aggregate benefit-cost models’, and more complex, ‘detailed process’ IAMs
BJ EP
27 (Weyant 2017), often mirroring the benefit-cost and cost-effective approaches outlined in 1.7.1, with more
28 detailed classification in eg. Nikas et al. (2019). IAMs embody a number of structural and socio-
29 demographic assumptions and include multiple modelling approaches, ranging from economic optimising
SU C
30 behaviour to simulation (See Annex III). Detailed process models can include energy system models used
31 to analyse decarbonisation and ‘net zero’ scenarios by international agencies (eg. IEA 2020a).
AC
32 Calculating cost-effective trajectories towards given goals typically involves detailed process IAMs. Often
33 these calculate the dynamic portfolio of technologies consistent with a given climate target. Some track
34 records of technology forecasting in IAMs are outlined in Chapters 2.5.4, and Box 16.1. Climate targets
35 may be imposed in models in a variety of ways that include, but are not limited to, constraints on emissions
36 or cumulated emissions (carbon budgets), and the pricing of emissions. The time-path of mitigation costs
37 calculated through these models may be translated into ‘shadow prices’ that (like the social-cost-of-carbon)
38 offer a benchmark to assess the cost-effectiveness of investments, as used by some governments and
39 companies (1.8.2).
40 Scenarios in the IPCC and AR6. For AR6, WG III received submissions of more than 2500 model-based
41 scenarios published in the scientific literature. Such scenarios, which explore different possible evolutions
42 of future energy and land use (with or without climate policy) and associated emissions, are made available
1 through an interactive AR6 scenario database. The main characteristics of pathways in relation to ‘net zero’
2 emissions and remaining ‘carbon budgets’ are summarised in Box 3.5 in Chapter 3. The warming
3 contribution of CO2 is very closely related to cumulative CO2 emissions, but the remaining ‘carbon budget’
4 for a given warming depends strongly inter alia on emissions of other GHGs; for targets below 2°C this
5 may affect the corresponding ‘carbon budget’ by c. +/- 220GtCO2, compared to central estimates of around
6 500GtCO2 (for 1.5°C) and 1350GtCO2 (for 2°C) (AR6 WGI, Table SPM.2; Cross-Working Group Box 1
7 in Chapter 3).
8 Pathways and ‘net zero’. The date at which the world needs aggregate emissions to reach net zero for Paris-
9 consistent temperature goals depends both on progress in reducing non-CO2 GHG emissions and near-term
10 progress in reducing CO2 emissions. Faster progress in the near term extends the date at which net zero
11 must be reached, while conversely, slower near-term progress brings the date even closer to the present.
S
12 Some of the modelled 1.5°C pathways with limited overshoot cut global CO2 emissions in half until 2030,
13 which allows for a more gradual decline thereafter, reaching net zero CO2 after 2050; also, net zero GHGs
IT
14 occurs later, with remaining emissions of some non-CO2 GHGs compensated by ‘net negative’ CO2 (see
AL N
15 Annex I and FAQ 1.3, and Cross-Chapter Box 3 in Chapter 3).
ED
N IO
16 Drawing from the scenarios database, five Illustrative Mitigation Pathways’ (IMPs) were defined for this
17 report (Figure 3.5 in Chapter 3 and Table 1.1). These are introduced here, with a more complete description
18
19
20
FI S
and discussion provided in Section 3.2.5 of Chapter 3. These IMPs were chosen to illustrate key themes
with respect to mitigation strategies across the entire WG III assessment. The IMPs embody both a storyline,
R
which describes in narrative form the key socio-economic characteristics of that scenario, and a quantitative
TO E
21 illustration providing numerical values that are internally consistent and comparable across chapters of this
22 report. Quantitative IMPs can be associated directly with specific human activities and provide a
T DV
23 quantitative point of reference that links activities in different parts of socioeconomic systems. Some parts
24 of the report draw on these quantitative scenarios, whilst others use only the narratives. No assessment of
25 the likelihood of each IMP has been made (as they reflect both human choice and deep uncertainty).
EC TE
26
BJ EP
SU C
AC
27
1 Figure 1.3 Illustrative Mitigation Pathways (IMPs) used in AR6 – illustration of key features and levels of
2 ambition
3
4 The IMPs are organized around two dimensions: the level of ambition consistent with meeting Paris goals
5 and the scenario features (Figure 1.4). The IMPs explore different pathways potentially consistent with
6 meeting the long-term temperature goals of the Paris Agreement. As detailed in Section 3.2.5 of Chapter 3
7 and Chapter 4, a pathway of Gradual Strengthening of current policies (IMP-GS) to 2030, if followed by
8 very fast reductions, may stay below 2C. The IMP-NEG pathway, with somewhat deeper emission
9 cutbacks to 2030, might enable 1.5C to be reached but only after significant overshoot, through the
10 subsequent extensive use of CDR in the energy and the industry sectors to achieve net negative global
11 emissions, as discussed in Chapters 3, 12, 7, 6, and 10.
S
12 Three other IMPs illustrate different features of technology scenarios with more short term rapid emission
IT
13 reductions, which could deliver outcomes compatible with the temperature range in the Paris agreement
AL N
14 without large overshoot. Based on the assessment in Section 5.3.3 of Chapter 5, one key mitigation strategy
ED
15 would be to rely on the opportunities for reducing demand (IMP-LD). Chapter 6 and the Chapter 7-11 show
N IO
16 how energy systems based on accelerated deep renewable energy penetration and electrification can also
17 provide a pathway to deep mitigation (IMP-REN). Chapter 4, 17 and 3 provide insights how shifting
18
19 (IMP-SP).
FI S
development pathways can lead to deep emission reductions and achieve sustainable development goals
R
20 These pathways can be implemented with different levels of ambition, that can be measured through the
TO E
21 classes (C) of temperature levels from the scenarios database, see Chapter 3 (Table 3.2). In the IMP
T DV
22 framework, Section 3.2.5 in Chapter 3 presents and explores quantitative scenarios that can limit warming
23 to 1.5 °C (with a probability of 50% or greater, i.e., C1 for the illustrated quantification of LD, SP and REN,
24 and C2 for NEG scenario), along with others GS pathway which keeps warming below 2 oC with a
25 probability of 67% or greater (C3). In addition to these primary IMPs, the full scenario database contains
EC TE
28 policies and pledges. Current Policies (CurPol) explores the consequences of continuing along the path of
29 implemented climate policies in 2020 and only a gradual strengthening after that, drawing on numerous
30 such scenarios in the literature. Moderate Action (ModAct) explores the impact of implementing NDCs to
SU C
31 2030, but without further strengthening; both results in global mean temperature above 2oC. They provide
32 benchmarks against which to compare the IMPs.
AC
33 Table 1.1 summarises the main storyline elements of the reference scenarios and each IMP.
34
S
CurPol Current Implementation of current climate policies (mostly as reported in NDCs), neglecting stated
Policies subsequent goals and objectives (e.g. for 2030); only gradual strengthening after 2030; Grey
IT
Covid recovery.
AL N
ModAct Moderate Implementation of current policies and achievement of 2030 NDCs, with further strengthening
ED
N IO
Action post-2030. Similarly to the situation implied by the diversity of NDCs (both policies and pledge),
a fragmented policy landscape remains; mixed Covid recovery.
FI S
GS Gradual Until 2030, primarily current NDCs are implemented; after that a strong, universal regime leads
Strengthening to coordinated and rapid decarbonisation actions.
R
Neg Net Negative Successful international climate policy regime reduces emissions below ModAct or GS to 2030,
TO E
Emissions but with a focus on the long-term temperature goal, negative emissions kick in at growing scales
T DV
thereafter, so that mitigation in all sectors also includes a growing and ultimately large reliance
on negative emissions, with large ‘net global negative’ after 2050 to meet 1.5C after significant
overshoot
Ren Renewables Successful international climate policy regime with immediate action particularly policies and
EC TE
IMPs
1.5/< incentives (including international finance) favouring renewable energy; Less emphasis on
2 negative-emission technologies. Rapid deployment and innovation of renewables and systems;
electrification of all end-use.
BJ P
LD Low Demand Successful international climate policy regime with immediate action on the demand side; policies
E
and financial incentives favouring reduced demand that in turn leads to early emission reductions;
SU C
SP Shifting Successful international climate policy regime with a focus on additional SDG policies aiming,
Pathways for example, at poverty reduction and broader environmental protection. Major transformations
shift development towards sustainability and reduced inequality, including deep GHG emissions
reduction.
1 What the IMPs do and don’t do. The IMPs are, as their name implies, a set of scenarios meant to
2 illustrate some important themes that run through the entire WGIII assessment. They illustrate that the
3 climate outcomes that the individuals and society will face in the century ahead depend on individual
4 and societal choices In addition, they illustrate that there are multiple ways to successful achievement
5 of Paris long-term temperature goals.
6 IMPs are not intended to be comprehensive. They are not intended to illustrate all possible themes in
7 this report. They do not, for example attempt to illustrate the range of alternative socioeconomic
8 pathways against which efforts to implement Paris goals may be set, or to reflect variations in potential
9 regional development pathways. They do not explore issues around income distribution or
10 environmental justice, but assume implicitly that where and how action occurs can be separated from
11 who pays, in ways to adequately address such issues. They are essentially pathways of technological
12 evolution and demand shifts reflecting broad global trends in social choice. The IMPs do not directly
13 assess issues of realization linked to the “drivers and constraints” summarized in our previous section,
14 and the quantifications use, for the most part, models that are grounded mainly in the Aggregate
S
15 Economics Frameworks (section 7.1). As such they reflect primarily the geophysical, economic and
IT
16 technological Dimensions of Assessment, but can be assessed in relation to the full set of Feasibility
AL N
17 criteria (section 1.8.1).
ED
N IO
18 Together the IMPs provide illustrations of potential future developments that can be shaped by human
19 choices, including: Where are current policies and pledges leading? What is needed to reach specific
FI S
20 temperature goals under varying assumptions? What are the consequences of different strategies to meet
21 climate targets (i.e. demand-side strategy, a renewable energy strategy or a strategy with a role for net
R
22 negative emissions)? What are the consequences of delay? What are the implications for other SDGs of
TO E
24
26 This chapter now sets out approaches to understanding the mitigation challenge, working from its broad
27 location in the context of wider aspirations for sustainable development, then identifying specific
28 analytic approaches, before summarising the corresponding main dimensions used for assessment of
BJ P
31 Climate change mitigation is one of many goals that societies pursue in the context of sustainable
32 development, as evidenced by the wide range of the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs). Climate
AC
33 change and sustainable development as well as development more broadly, are interwoven along
34 multiple and complex lines of relationship (Fankhauser 2016; Gomez-Echeverri 2018a; Okereke and
35 Massaquoi 2017; Okereke et al. 2009), as highlighted in several previous IPCC reports (IPCC 2007,
36 2019a, 2018b, 2011a, 2014a). With its significant negative impact on natural systems, food security and
37 infrastructure, loss of lives and territories, species extinction, conflict health, among several other risks,
38 climate change poses a serious threat to development and wellbeing in both rich and poor countries
39 (IPCC 2019b, 2018b, 2007, 2011a, 2014a). Without serious efforts at mitigation and adaptation, climate
40 change could push millions further into poverty and limit the opportunities for economic development
41 (Chapter 4 and 17). It follows that ambitious climate mitigation is necessary to secure a safe climate
42 within which development and wellbeing can be pursued and sustained.
43 At the same time, rapid and largescale economic development (which has in the past driven climate
44 change through land use change and dependence on fossil fuels), is widely seen as needed to improve
45 global wellbeing and lift millions especially in low- and middle-income countries out of poverty
46 (Baarsch et al. 2020; Lu et al. 2019; Mugambiwa and Tirivangasi 2017; Chen et al. 2017; See Figure
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-38 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 1.6). This strand of literature emphasises the importance of economic growth including for tackling
2 climate change itself, pointing to the relationship between economic development and climate resilience
3 as well as the role of industry-powered technologies such as electric vehicles in reducing GHG levels
4 and promoting wellbeing (Heinrichs et al. 2014; Kasztelan 2017). Yet, others argue that the character
5 of social and economic development produced by the nature of capitalist society (Pelling and Manuel-
6 Navarrete 2011; Koch 2012; Malm 2016) is ultimately unsustainable.
7 There are at least two major implications of the very close link between climate change and
8 development as outlined above. The first is that the choice of development paths made by countries and
9 regions have significant consequences for GHG emissions and efforts to combat climate change (see
10 Chapters 2, 3, 4, 5, and 14). The second is that climate mitigation at local, national and global level
11 cannot be effectively achieved by a narrow focus on ‘climate-specific’ sectors, actors and policies; but
12 rather through a much broader attention to the mix of development choices and the resulting
13 development paths and trajectories (see Chapter 4, 6, 10; O’Neill et al. 2014).
S
14 As a key staple of IPCC reports and global climate policy landscape (Gidden et al. 2019; Quilcaille et
15 al. 2019; van Vuuren et al. 2017; IPCC 2014b, 2007; see also Chapter 2), integrated assessment models
IT
16 and global scenarios (such as the “Shared Socio-Economic Pathways” – SSPs) highlight the interaction
AL N
17 between development paths, climate change and emission stabilisation (see Section 3.6 in Chapter 3).
ED
N IO
18 The close links are also recognised in the PA (section 1.3.1).
19 The impact of climate change in limiting wellbeing is most acutely felt by the world’s poorest people,
FI S
20 communities, and nations, who have the smallest carbon footprint, constrained capacity to respond and
R
21 limited voice in important decision-making circles (Okereke and Ehresman 2015; Tosam and Mbih
22 2015; Mugambiwa and Tirivangasi 2017). The wide variation in the contribution to, and impact of
TO E
23 climate change within and across countries makes equity, inequality, justice, and poverty eradication,
T DV
24 inescapable aspects of the relationship between sustainable development and climate change (Reckien
25 et al. 2017; Okereke and Coventry 2016; Bos and Gupta 2019; Klinsky et al. 2017; Baarsch et al. 2020;
26 Kayal et al. 2019; Diffenbaugh and Burke 2019). This underpins the conclusion as commonly expressed
27 that climate action needs to be pursued in the context of sustainable development, equity and poverty
EC TE
28 eradication (Burton et al. 2001; Smit et al. 2001; Klinsky and Winkler 2014; Tschakert and Olsson
29 2005; IPCC 2014a, 2018b).
BJ P
30 1.6.2 Concepts and frameworks for integrating climate mitigation and development:
E
31 At one level, sustainable development can be seen as a meta framework for integrating climate action
32 with other global sustainability goals (Antal and Van Den Bergh 2016; Casadio Tarabusi and Guarini
SU C
33 2013). Fundamentally, the concept of sustainable development underscores the interlinkages and
AC
34 interdependence of human and natural systems and the need to balance economic, social, and
35 environmental (including climate pollution) aspects in development planning and processes (Nunan
36 2017; Gomez-Echeverri 2018b; Zhenmin and Espinosa 2019).
37 Despite the appeal of the concept, tensions remain over the interpretation and practical application, with
38 acute disagreements regarding what the balancing entails in real life, how to measure wellbeing, which
39 goals to set, and the means through which such goals might be pursued (Michelsen et al. 2016; Shang
40 et al. 2019; Okereke and Massaquoi 2017; UNEP 2018b; Arrow et al. 2011; Dasgupta et al. 2015;
41 Sugiawan et al. 2019; Haberl et al. 2019).
42 Moreover, countries differ enormously in their respective situation regarding their development path –
43 a condition which affects their capability, goals, priorities and approach to the pursuit of sustainability
44 (Ramos-Mejía et al. 2018; Okereke et al. 2019; Shi et al. 2016). Most of the literature recognises that
45 despite its limitations, sustainable development with its emphasis on integrating social, economic and
46 environmental goals, provides a more comprehensive approach to the pursuit of planetary health and
1 human wellbeing. Sustainable development is then not a static objective but a dynamic framework for
2 measuring human progress (Costanza et al. 2016; Fotis and Polemis 2018), relevant for all countries
3 even if different groups of nations experience the challenge of sustainability in different ways.
4 Much like sustainable development, concepts like low-carbon development (Mulugetta and Urban
5 2010; Yuan et al. 2011; Wang et al. 2017; Tian et al. 2019), climate-compatible development (CCD)
6 (Mitchell and Maxwell 2010; Tompkins et al. 2013; Stringer et al. 2014; Bickersteth et al. 2017) and
7 more recently climate-resilient development (CRD) (Fankhauser and McDermott 2015; Henly-Shepard
8 et al. 2018) (see IPCC SR 1.5 2018b) have all emerged as ideas, tools and frameworks, intended to
9 bring together the goals of climate mitigation and the SDGs, as well as development more broadly.
10 Figure 1.5 suggests that the prospects for realizing a climate-resilient and equitable world is enhanced
11 by a process of transformation and development trajectories that seek to limit global warming while
12 also achieving the SDGS. The SDGs represent medium-term goals, and long-term sustainability
13 requires continued effort to keep the world along a climate resilient development path. A key feature of
14 development or transformation pathways that achieve a climate resilient world is that they maximise
S
15 the synergies and minimise the trade-offs between climate mitigation and other sustainable development
IT
16 goals (Dagnachew et al. 2018; Fuso Nerini et al. 2018; Thornton and Comberti 2017; Wüstemann et al.
AL N
17 2017; Mainali et al. 2018; Klausbruckner et al. 2016). Crucially, the nature of trade-offs and timing of
ED
18 related decisions will vary across countries depending on circumstances including the level of
N IO
19 development, capability and access to resources (see Cross-chapter Box 5, Shifting Development Paths
20 to increase Sustainability, in Chapter 4).
FI S
21
R
TO E
T DV
EC TE
BJ P
E
SU C
AC
22
23 Figure 1.4: A climate-resilient and equitable world requires limiting global warming while achieving the
24 SDGS.
25 Source: IPCC 2018b
26
27 Other concepts such as “Doughnut Economics” (Raworth 2018), ecological modernisation, and
28 mainstreaming are also used to convey ideals of development pathways that take sustainability, climate
29 mitigation, and environmental limits seriously (Dale et al. 2015a). Mainstreaming focuses on
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-40 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 incorporating climate change into national development activities, such as the building of infrastructure
2 (Wamsler and Pauleit 2016; Runhaar et al. 2018). The ‘green economy’ and green growth – growth
3 without undermining ecological systems, partly by gaining economic value from cleaner technologies
4 and systems and is inclusive and equitable in its outcomes - has gained popularity in both developed
5 and developing countries as an approach for harnessing economic growth to address environmental
6 issues (Bina 2013; Georgeson et al. 2017; Capasso et al. 2019; Song et al. 2020; Hao et al. 2021). Critics
7 however argue that green economy ultimately emphasises economic growth to the detriment of other
8 important aspects of human welfare such as social justice (Adelman 2015; Death 2014; Kamuti 2015),
9 and challenge the central idea that it is possible to decouple economic activity and growth (measured
10 as GDP increment) from increasing use of biophysical resources (raw materials, energy) (Jackson and
11 Victor 2019; Parrique et al. 2019; Hickel and Kallis 2020; Haberl et al. 2020; Vadén et al. 2020).
12 Literature on degrowth, post growth, and post development questions the sustainability and imperative
13 of more growth especially in already industrialised countries and argues that prosperity and the ‘Good
14 Life’ are not immutably tied to economic growth (Escobar 2015; Asara et al. 2015; Kallis 2019;
S
15 Latouche 2018; see also Section 5.2.1 in Chapter 5). The concept of ‘just transition’ also stresses the
IT
16 need to integrate justice concerns so as to not impose hardship on already marginalised populations
AL N
17 within and between countries (Goddard and Farrelly 2018; Smith, Jackie and Patterson 2018;
ED
18 McCauley and Heffron 2018; Evans and Phelan 2016; Heffron and McCauley 2018; see section 1.7.2).
N IO
19 The key insight is that pursuing climate goals in the context of sustainable development requires holistic
20 thinking including on how to measure well-being, serious consideration of the notion of ecological
FI S
21 limits, at least some level of decoupling and certainly choices and decision-making approaches that
R
22 exploit and maximise the synergy and minimises the trade-off between climate mitigation and other
23 sustainable development goals. It also requires consideration of equity and justice within and between
TO E
24 countries. However, ideas of a synergistic relationship between development and climate mitigation
T DV
25 can sometimes offer limited practical guidelines for reconciling the tensions that are often present in
26 practical policy making (Dale et al. 2015b; Ferguson et al. 2014; Kasztelan 2017; Kotzé 2018).
27 1.6.3 Climate Mitigation, Equity and the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs)
EC TE
28 Climate action can be conceptualised as both a stand-alone and cross-cutting issue in the 2030 SDGs
29 (Makomere and Liti Mbeva 2018), given that several of the other goals such as ending poverty (Goal
30 1), zero hunger (Goal 2), good health and wellbeing (Goal 3), affordable and clean energy (Goal 7)
BJ P
31 among many others are related to climate change (see Figure 3.39 in Chapter 3).
E
32 In addition to galvanising global collective action, the SDGs provide concrete themes, targets and
SU C
33 indicators for measuring human progress to sustainability (Kanie and Biermann 2017). The SDGs also
34 provide a basis for exploring the synergies and trade-offs between sustainable development and climate
AC
35 change mitigation (Makomere and Liti Mbeva 2018; Mainali et al. 2018; Fuso Nerini et al. 2018;
36 Pradhan et al. 2017). Progress to date (Sachs et al. 2016) shows fulfilling SDGs is a challenge for all
37 groups of countries – developed and developing – even though the challenge differs between countries
38 and regions (Pradhan et al. 2017).
39 Historically, the industrialisation associated with economic development has involved a strong
40 relationship with GHG emissions (see Section 5.2.1 in Chapter 5). Figure 1.6 shows per capita GHG
41 emissions on the vertical axis and Historical Index of Human Development (HIHD) levels (Prados de
42 la Escosura 2015) on the horizontal axis.7 The grey line shows historic global average GHG emissions
FOOTNOTE7 The Historical Index of Human Development (HIHD) emulates the widely used Human
Development Index (HDI) as they both summarise in indexes, key human development dimensions consisting of
a healthy life, knowledge and a decent standard of living. HDI is based on: life expectancy, expected years of
1 per capita and levels of human development over time, from 1870 to 2014. The current position of
2 different regions are shown by bubbles, with sizes representing total GHG emissions. Figure 1.6 also
3 shows the estimated position of the SDGs zone for the year 2030, and a “sustainable development
4 corridor” as countries reach towards higher HDI and lower emissions. To fulfil the SDGs, including
5 SDG 13 climate action, the historic relationship needs to change.
6 The top of the SDG zone is situated around the global per capita GHG emissions level of 5 tonnes
7 CO2eq required for the world to be path towards fulfilling the Paris Agreement.8 The horizontal position
8 of the SDG zone is estimated based on the HIHD levels (Prados de la Escosura 2015) of countries that
9 have been shown to either have achieved, or have some challenges, when it comes to SDG 3, SDG 4
10 and SDG 8 (Sachs et al. 2016); as these SDGs are related to the constituent parts of the HIHD. Beyond
11 2030, the sustainable development corridor allows for increasing levels of human development while
12 lowering per capita GHG emissions.
13 Figure 1.6 shows that at present, regions with HIHD levels of around 0.5 all have emissions at or above
S
14 about 5tCO2eq per-capita (even more so on a consumption footprint basis, see Figure 1.1c,d), but there
15 are wide variations within this. Indeed, there are regions with HIHD levels above 0.8 which have GHG
IT
16 per-capita emissions lower than several with HIHD levels of around 0.5. The mitigation challenge
AL N
17 involves countries at many different stages of development seeking paths towards higher welfare with
ED
N IO
18 low emissions.
19 From Figure 1.6, there are two distinct dimensions to sustainable development pathways for fulfilling
FI S
20 the SDGs. In terms of per-capita GHG emissions (the vertical), some regions have such low levels that
R
21 they could increase and still be below the global average required in 2030 for the world to be on path
22 to fulfil the Paris Agreement. Meanwhile other regions with high per capita GHG emissions would
TO E
23 require a rapid transformation in technologies and practices. It is against this background that Dubash
T DV
24 (2019) emphasises placing the need for urgent action on climate change in the context of domestic
25 political priorities and the institutions within which national frameworks are crystallised.
26 Concerns over equity in the context of growing global inequality and very tight remaining global carbon
27 budgets have motivated an emphasis on equitable access to sustainable development (Peters et al. 2015;
EC TE
28 Kartha et al. 2018b; Matthews et al. 2019; van den Berg et al. 2019). This literature emphasises the
29 need for less developed countries to have sufficient room for development while addressing climate
BJ P
30 change (Pan et al. 2014; Winkler et al. 2013; Gajevic Sayegh 2017; Warlenius 2018; Robinson and
31 Shine 2018). Meanwhile, many countries reliant on fossil fuels, related technologies and economic
E
32 activities are eager to ensure tax revenues are maintained, workers and industries have income and
SU C
33 justice is embedded in the economic transformations required to limit GHG emissions (Cronin et al.
34 2021).
AC
schooling of children, the mean years of schooling of the adult population, and GNI per capita adjusted for
purchasing power; the HIHD is based on: life expectancy at birth, adult literacy rates, educational enrolment rates,
and GDP per capita, and is used in Figure 1.6 because it is available for a longer time series (Prados de la Escosura
2015).
FOOTNOTE8 Based on global population projections of between 8 and 8.5 billion people in 2030, and GHG
emissions levels from the C1, C2 and C3 categories of scenarios in Table 3.2 and Box 3.7 in Chapter 3.
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-42 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
S
IT
AL N
ED
N IO
FI S
R
TO E
T DV
1
EC TE
5 (grey line). The bubbles on the graph show regional per capita GHG emissions and human development
E
6 levels in the year 2015, illustrating large disparities. Pathways towards fulfilling the Paris Agreement
7 (and SDG 13) involve global average per capita GHG emissions below about 5 tCO2e by 2030. Likewise,
SU C
8 to fulfil SDGs 3, 4 and 8, HIHD levels (see footnote 7) need to be at least 0.5 or greater. This suggests a
‘sustainable development zone’ for year 2030 (in green); the in-figure text also suggests a sustainable
AC
9
10 development corridor, where countries limit per capita GHG emissions while improving levels of human
11 development over time. The emphasis of pathways into the sustainable development zone differ (green
12 arrows) but in each case transformations are needed in how human development is attained while
13 limiting GHG emissions.
1 Correlation between CO2 emission intensity, or absolute emission and gross domestic product growth,
2 is not rigid, unambiguous and deterministic (Ojekunle et al. 2015), but the extent to which SDGs and
3 economic growth expectations can be fulfilled while decoupling GHG emissions remains a concern
4 (Hickel and Kallis 2020; Haberl et al. 2020). Below some thresholds of absolute poverty, more
5 consumption is necessary for development to lead to well-being (see Section 5.2.1.1 in Chapter 5),
6 which may not be the case at higher levels of consumption (Steinberger et al. 2020; Lamb and
7 Steinberger 2017; Section 1.7.2).
8 In conclusion, achieving climate stabilisation in the context of sustainable development and efforts to
9 eradicate poverty requires collective action and exploiting synergies between climate action and
10 sustainable development, while minimising the impact of trade-offs (Najam 2005; Makomere and Liti
11 Mbeva 2018; Okereke and Massaquoi 2017; Dooley et al. 2021). It also requires a focus on equity
12 considerations to avoid climate induced harm, as well as unfairness that can result from urgent actions
13 to cut emissions (Kartha et al. 2018a; Robiou du Pont et al. 2017; Pan et al. 2014). This is ever more
S
14 important as the diminishing carbon budget has intensified debates on which countries should have the
15 greatest claim to the ‘remaining space’ for emissions (Raupach et al. 2014) or production (McGlade
IT
16 and Ekins 2015),amplified by persistent concerns over the insufficiency of support for means of
AL N
17 implementation, to support ambitious mitigation efforts (Pickering et al. 2015; Weikmans and Roberts
ED
N IO
18 2019).
19
FI S
20 1.7 Four Analytic Frameworks for understanding mitigation response
R
21 strategies
TO E
22 Climate change is unprecedented in its scope (sectors, actors and countries), depth (major
T DV
23 transformations) and timescales (over generations). As such, it creates unique challenges for analysis.
24 It has been called “the greatest market failure in history” (Stern 2007); the Perfect Moral Storm
25 (Gardiner 2006) and a “super wicked problem” (Lazarus 2009; Levin et al. 2012) - one which appears
EC TE
26 difficult to solve through the traditional tools and assumptions of social organisation and analysis.
27 To complement the extensive literature on risks and decision-making under uncertainty reviewed in
28 AR6-WGII (notably, Chapter 19), this section summarises insights and developments in key analytic
BJ P
29 frameworks and tools particularly relevant to understanding specific mitigation strategies, policies and
E
30 other actions, including explaining the observed if limited progress to date. Organised partly as reflected
31 in the quotes above, these include aggregated (principally, economic) frameworks to evaluate system-
SU C
32 level choices; ethical perspectives on values and equity including stages of development and
AC
33 distributional concerns; and transition frameworks which focus on the processes and actors involved in
34 major technological and social transitions. These need to be complemented by a fourth set of approaches
35 which shine more light on psychological/behavioural and political factors. All these frameworks are
36 relevant, and together they point to the multiple perspectives and actions required if the positive drivers
37 of emission reduction summarised in section 4 are to outweigh the barriers and overcome the
38 constraints.
39 1.7.1 Aggregated approaches: economic efficiency and global dynamics of mitigation
40 Some of the most established and influential approaches to understand aggregate causes and
41 consequences of climate change and mitigation across societies, draw upon economic theories and
42 modelling to generate global emission pathways in the absence of climate policies (a reference) and to
43 study alternative mitigation pathways (described in detail in Section 3.2.5 in Chapter 3). The underlying
44 economic concepts aggregate wealth or other measures of welfare based on utilitarian ethical
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-44 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 foundations, and in most applications, a number of additional assumptions detailed in AR5 (Chapters 2
2 and 3).
3 1.7.1.1 Cost-benefit and cost-effectiveness analysis
4 Such global aggregate economic studies coalesce around two main questions. One, as pioneered by
5 Nordhaus (1992; 2008) attempts to monetize overall climate damages and mitigation costs so as to
6 strike a ‘cost-benefit optimum’ pathway. More detailed and empirically-grounded ‘cost-effectiveness
7 analysis’ explores pathways that would minimise mitigation costs (IPCC 2014a section 2.5; Ekholm
8 2014; Weyant 2017) for given targets (e.g. as agreed in international negotiations, see Section 3.2 in
9 Chapter 3). Both approaches recognise that resources are limited, and climate change competes with
10 other priorities in government policymaking, and are generally examined with some form of Integrated
11 Assessment Model (IAMs: see 1.5, and Appendix C). Depending on the regional disaggregation of the
12 modelling tools used and on the scope of the analyses, these studies may or may not address
13 distributional aspects within and across nations associated with climate policies (Bauer et al. 2020).
S
14 For at least 10-15 years after the first computed global cost-benefit estimate (Nordhaus 1992), the
IT
15 dominant conclusions from these different approaches seemed to yield very different recommendations,
AL N
16 with cost-benefit studies suggesting lenient mitigation compared to the climate targets typically
ED
17 recommended from scientific risk assessments (Weyant 2017). Over the past 10-15 years, literature has
18
19
N IO
made important strides towards reconciling these two approaches, both in the analytic methods and the
conclusions arising.
FI S
20 Damages and risks Incorporating impacts which may be extremely severe but are uncertain (known as
R
21 “fat tails” (Weitzman 2009, 2011), strengthens the economic case for ambitious action to avoid risks of
TO E
22 extreme climate impacts (Ackerman et al. 2010; Dietz and Stern 2015; Fankhauser et al. 2013). The
23 salience of risks has also been amplified by improved understanding of climate ‘tipping points’
T DV
24 (Lontzek et al. 2015; Lenton et al. 2019); valuations should reflect that cutting emissions reduces not
25 only average expected damages, but also the risk of catastrophic events (IWG 2021).
26 Discounting. The role of time-discounting, in weighting future climate change impacts against today’s
EC TE
27 costs of mitigating emissions, has been long recognised (Weitzman 1994, 2001; Nordhaus 2007;
28 Dasgupta 2008; Stern 2007). Its importance is underlined in analytical Integrated Assessment Models
29 (IAMs) (Golosov et al. 2014; van der Ploeg and Rezai 2019; van den Bijgaart et al. 2016); also Annex
BJ P
30 III. Economic literature suggests applying risk-free, public, and long-term interest rates when evaluating
E
31 overall climate strategy (Arrow et al. 2013; Groom and Hepburn 2017; Weitzman 2001; Dasgupta
SU C
32 2008). Expert elicitations indicate values around 2% (majority) to 3% (Drupp et al. 2018). This is lower
33 than in many of the studies reviewed in earlier IPCC Assessments, and many IAM studies since, and
AC
34 by increasing the weight accorded to the future would increase current ‘optimal effort’. The U.S.
35 Interagency Working Group on the Social Cost of Carbon used 3% as its central value (IAWG 2016;
36 Li and Pizer 2018; Adler et al. 2017). Individual projects may require specific risk adjustments.
37 Distribution of impacts. The economic damages from climate change at the nationally aggregated and
38 subnational level are very diverse (Moore et al. 2017; Ricke et al. 2018; Carleton et al. 2020). A 'global
39 damage function’ necessarily implies aggregating impacts across people and countries with different
40 levels of income, and over generations, a process which obscures the strategic considerations that drive
41 climate policy making (Keohane and Oppenheimer 2016). Economics acknowledges there is no single,
42 objectively-defined such ‘social welfare function’ (IPCC 1995, 2014a). This applies also to distribution
43 of responses; both underline the relevance of equity (next section) and global negotiations to determine
44 national and collective objectives.
1 Obvious limitations arise from these multiple difficulties in assessing an objective, globally-acceptable
2 single estimate of climate change damages (e.g. Pindyck 2013; Arrow et al. 2013; Auffhammer 2018;
3 Stern et al. 2021), with some arguing that agreement on a specific value can never be expected (Rosen
4 and Guenther 2015; Pezzey 2018). A new generation of cost-benefits analysis, based on projections of
5 actual observed damages, result in stronger mitigation efforts as optimal (Glanemann et al. 2020; Hänsel
6 et al. 2020). Overall the combination of improved damage functions with the wider consensus on low
7 discount rates (as well as lower mitigation costs due to innovation) has increasingly yielded ‘optimal’
8 results from benefit-cost studies in line with the range established in the Paris Agreement (see Cross-
9 Working-Group Box 1 in Chapter 3).
10 Hybrid cost-benefit approaches that extend the objective of the optimisation beyond traditional
11 welfare, adding some form of temperature targets as in (Llavador et al. 2015; Held 2019) also represent
12 a step in bridging the gap between the two approaches and result in proposed strategies much more in
13 line with those coming from the cost-effectiveness literature. Approaching from the opposite side, cost-
S
14 effectiveness studies have looked into incorporating benefits from avoided climate damages, to improve
15 the assessment of net costs (Drouet et al. 2021).
IT
Cost-benefit IAMs utilise damage functions to derive a social cost of CO2 emissions’ (SCC - the
AL N
16
ED
17 additional cost to society of a pulse of CO2 emissions). One review considered “the best estimate” of
N IO
18 the optimal [near-term] level “still ranges from a few tens to a few hundreds of dollars per ton of carbon
19 (Tol 2018)”, with various recent studies in the hundreds, taking account of risks (Taconet et al. 2019),
FI S
20 learning (Ekholm 2018) and distribution (Ricke et al. 2018). In addition to the importance of
21 uncertainty/risk, aggregation, and realistic damage functions as noted, on which some progress has been
R
22 made, some reviews additionally critique how IAMs represent abatement costs in terms of energy
TO E
23 efficiency and innovation (e.g. Rosen and Guenther 2015; Farmer et al. 2015; Keen 2021); see also
24 1.7.3 and 1.7.4. IAMs may better reflect associated ‘rebound’ at system level (Saunders et al. 2021),
T DV
25 and inefficient implementation would raise mitigation costs (Homma et al. 2019); conversely, co-
26 benefits – most extensively estimated for air-quality, valued at a few tens of USD/tCO2 across sixteen
27 studies (Karlsson et al. 2020) - complement global with additional local benefits (see alsoTable 1.2).
EC TE
28 Whereas many of these factors affect primarily cost-benefit evaluation, discounting also determines the
29 cost-effective trajectory: Emmerling et al. (2019) find that, for a remaining budget of 1000GtCO2,
reducing the discount rate from 5% to 2% would more than double current efforts, limit ‘overshoot’,
BJ P
30
31 greatly reduce a late rush to negative emissions, and improve intergenerational justice by more evenly
E
34 Care is required to clarify what is optimised (Dietz and Venmans 2019). Optimising a path towards a
35 given temperature goal by a fixed date (e.g. 2100) gives time-inconsistent results backloaded to large,
36 last-minute investment in carbon dioxide removal. ‘Cost-effective’ optimisations generate less initial
37 effort than equivalent cost-benefit models (Gollier 2021; Dietz and Venmans 2019) as they do not
38 incorporate benefits of reducing impacts earlier.
39 ‘Efficient pathways’ are affected by inertia and innovation. Inertia implies amplifying action on long-
40 lived investments and infrastructure that could otherwise lock in emissions for many decades (Vogt-
41 Schilb et al. 2018; Baldwin et al. 2020). Chapter 3 (section 3.5) discusses interactions between near,
42 medium and long-term actions in global pathways, particularly vis-à-vis inertia. Also, to the extent that
43 early action induces low carbon innovation, it ‘multiplies’ the optimal effort (for given damage
44 assumptions), because it facilitates subsequent cheaper abatement. For example, a ‘learning-by-doing'
1 analysis concludes that early deployment of expensive PV was of net global economic benefit, due to
2 induced innovation (Newbery 2018).
3 Research thus increasingly emphasises the need to understand climate transformation in terms of
4 dynamic, rather than static, efficiency (Gillingham and Stock 2018). This means taking account of
5 inertia, learning and various additional sources of ‘path-dependence’. Including induced innovation in
6 stylised IAMs can radically change the outlook (Acemoglu et al. 2012, 2016), albeit with limitations
7 (Pottier et al. 2014); many more detailed-process IAMs now do include endogenous technical change
8 (as reviewed in Yang et al. (2018) and Grubb et al. (2021b); also Annex III).
9 These dynamic and uncertainty effects typically justify greater up-front effort (Kalkuhl et al. 2012;
10 Bertram et al. 2015), including accelerated international diffusion (Schultes et al. 2018), and strengthen
11 optimal initial effort in cost-benefit models (Grubb et al. 2021b; Baldwin et al. 2020). Approaches to
12 risk premia common in finance would similarly amplify the initial mitigation effort, declining as
13 uncertainties reduce (Daniel et al. 2019).
S
14 1.7.1.3 Disequilibrium, complex systems and evolutionary approaches
IT
15 Other approaches to aggregate evaluation draw on various branches of intrinsically non-equilibrium
AL N
ED
16 theories (e.g. Chang 2014). These including long-standing theories from the 1930s (e.g. Schumpeter
N IO
17 1934a; Keynes 1936) to understand situations of structurally under-employed resources, potential
18 financial instabilities (Minsky 1986), and related economic approaches which emphasise time
FI S
19 dimensions (e.g. recent reviews in Legrand and Hagemann 2017; Stern 2018). More recently
20 developing have been formal economic theories of endogenous growth building on eg. Romer (1986),
R
21 and developments of Schumpeterian creative destruction (Aghion et al. 2021) and evolutionary
TO E
22 economic theories which abandon any notion of full or stable resource utilisation even as a reference
23 concept (Nelson and Winter 1982; Freeman and Perez 1988; Carlsson and Stankiewicz 1991; Perez
T DV
27 as continually evolving systems with continuously unfolding and path-dependent properties, and
28 emphasise uncertainty in contrast to any predictable or default optimality. Such approaches have been
29 variously applied in policy evaluation (Walton 2014; Moore et al. 2018), and specifically for global
BJ P
30 decarbonisation (e.g. Barker and Crawford-Brown 2014) using global simulation models. Because these
E
31 have no natural reference ‘least lost’ trajectory, they illustrate varied and divergent pathways and tend
SU C
32 to emphasise the diversity of possibilities and relevant policies, particularly linked to innovation and
33 potentially ‘sensitive intervention points’ (Farmer et al. 2019; see also section 1.7.3). They also illustrate
AC
34 that different representations of innovation and financial markets together can explain why estimated
35 impacts of mitigation on GDP can differ very widely (potentially even in sign), between different model
36 types (Chapter 15, Section 15.6.3 and Box 15.7).
37 1.7.2 Ethical approaches
38 Gardiner's (2011) description of climate change as ”The Perfect Moral Storm” identified three
39 ‘tempests’. Its global dimension, in a world of sovereign states which have only fragmentary
40 responsibility and control, makes it ‘difficult to generate the moral consideration and necessary political
41 will’. Its impacts are intergenerational but future generations have no voice in contemporary affairs,
42 the usual mechanism for addressing distributional injustices, amplified by the intrinsic inequity of
43 wealthy big emitters impacting particularly poorer victims. He argues that these are exacerbated by a
44 third, theoretical failure to acknowledge a central need for ‘moral sensitivity, compassion, transnational
45 and transgenerational care, and other forms of ethical concern to rise to the surface’ to help guide
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-47 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 effective climate action. As noted in section 1.4.6, however, equity and ethics are both a driver of and
2 constraint on mitigation.
3 1.7.2.1 Ethics and values
4 A large body of literature examines the critical role of values, ethics, attitudes, and behaviours as
5 foundational frames for understanding and assessing climate action, sustainable development and
6 societal transformation (IPCC WGIII IPCC 2014a chapter 3). Most of this work is offered as a counter
7 point or critique to mainstream literature’s focus on safe-guarding of economic growth of nations,
8 corporations and individuals (Castree 2017; Gunster 2017). These perspectives highlight the dominance
9 of economic utilitarianism in western philosophical thought as a key driver for unsustainable
10 consumption and global environmental change (Hoeing et al. 2015; Popescu 2016).
11 Entrenching alternative values that promote deep decarbonisation, environmental conservation and
12 protection across all levels of society is then viewed as foundational component of climate resilient and
13 sustainable development and for achieving human rights, and a safe climate world (Jolly et al. 2015;
S
14 Evensen 2015; Popescu 2016; Tàbara et al. 2019). The UN Human Rights Office of the High
IT
15 Commissioner has highlighted the potentially crucial role of human rights in relation to climate change
AL N
16 (UNHCR 2018). While acknowledging the role of policy, technology, and finance, the ‘managerialist’
ED
17 approaches that emphasise ‘technical governance’ and fail to challenge the deeper values that underpin
18
19
N IO
societies may not secure the deep change required to avert dangerous climate change and other
environmental challenges (Hartzell-Nichols 2014; Steinberger et al. 2020).
FI S
20 Social justice perspectives emphasise the distribution of responsibilities, rights, and mutual obligations
R
21 between nations in navigating societal transformations (Patterson et al. 2018; Gawel and Kuhlicke 2017;
TO E
22 Leach et al. 2018). Current approaches to climate action may fail to match what is required by science
23 because they tend to circumvent constraints on human behaviour, especially constraints on economic
T DV
24 interest and activity. Related literature explores governance models that are centred on environmental
25 limits, planetary boundaries and the moral imperative to prioritise the poor in earth systems governance
26 (Carley and Konisky 2020; Kashwan et al. 2020), with emphasis on trust and solidarity as foundations
EC TE
27 for global co-operation on climate change (Jolly et al. 2015). A key obstacle is that the economic
28 interests of states tend to be stronger than the drivers for urgent climate action (Bain 2017).
29 Short-term interests of stakeholders is acknowledged to impede the reflection and deliberation needed
BJ P
30 for climate mitigation and adaptation planning (Hackmann 2016; Herrick 2018; Sussman et al. 2016;
E
31 Schlosberg et al. 2017). Situationally appropriate mitigation and adaptation policies at both national
SU C
32 and international level may require more ethical self-reflection (Herrick 2018), including self-
33 transcendent values such as universalism and benevolence, and moderation which are positively related
AC
34 to pro-environmental behaviours (Howell and Allen 2017; Jonsson and Nilsson 2014; Katz-Gerro et al.
35 2015; Braito et al. 2017).
36 Another strong theme in the literature concerns recognition of interdependence including the intimate
37 relationship between humans and the non-human world (Hannis 2016; Gupta and Racherla 2018;
38 Howell and Allen 2017), with such ecological interdependence offered as an organising principle for
39 enduring transformation to sustainability. A key policy implication of this is moving away from valuing
40 nature only in market and monetary terms to strongly incorporating existential and non-material value
41 of nature in natural resource accounting (Neuteleers and Engelen 2015; Himes-Cornell et al. 2018;
42 Shackleton et al. 2017). There has been increasing attention on ways to design climate policy
43 frameworks to help reconcile ecological virtue (with its emphasis on the collective) with and individual
44 freedoms and personal autonomy (Kasperbauer 2016; Nash et al. 2017; Xiang et al. 2019). In such a
45 framework, moderation, fairness, and stewardship are all understood and promoted as directly
1 contributing to the ‘Good Life’. Such approaches are deemed vital to counteract tendencies to ‘free
2 ride’, and to achieve behavioural changes often associated with tackling climate change (Section 5.2.1
3 in Chapter 5).
4 Some literature suggests that attention to emotions, especially with regards to climate communication,
5 could help societies and individuals act in ways that focus less on monetary gain and more on climate
6 and environmental sustainability (Bryck and Ellis 2016; Chapman et al. 2017; Nabi et al. 2018; Zummo
7 et al. 2020).
8 1.7.2.2 Equity and representation: international public choice across time and space
9 Equity perspectives highlight three asymmetries relevant for climate change (Okereke 2017; Okereke
10 and Coventry 2016; 1.4.6). Asymmetry in contribution highlights different contributions to climate
11 change both in historical and current terms, and apply both within and between states as well as between
12 generations (Caney 2016; Heyward and Roser 2016). Asymmetry in impacts highlight the fact that the
13 damages will be borne disproportionately across countries, regions, communities, individuals and
S
14 gender; moreover, it is often those that have contributed the least that stand to bear the greatest impact
IT
15 of climate change (Shi et al. 2016; IPCC 2014a). Asymmetry in capacity highlights differences of power
AL N
16 between groups and nations to participate in climate decision and governance, including capacity to
ED
17 implement mitigation and adaptation measures.
18
N IO
If attention is not paid to equity, efforts designed to tackle climate change may end up exacerbating
FI S
19 inequities among communities and between countries (Heffron and McCauley 2018). The implication
20 is that to be sustainable in the long run, mitigation involves a central place for consideration of justice,
R
21 both within and between countries (Chapters 4, 14). Arguments that the injustices following from
TO E
22 climate change are symptomatic of a more fundamental structural injustice in social relations, are taken
23 to imply a need to address the deeper inequities within societies (Routledge et al. 2018).
T DV
24 Climate change and climate policies affect countries and people differently, with the poor likely to be
25 more affected (1.6.1). Ideas of ‘just transition’ (outlined in 1.8.2.) often have a national focus in the
26 literature, but also imply that mitigation should not increase the asymmetries between rich and poor
EC TE
27 countries, implying a desire for transitions which seek reduce (or at least avoid adverse) distributional
28 affects. Thus, it comes into play in the timing of zero emissions (chapter 3 and 14). International climate
29 finance in which rich countries finance mitigation and adaptation in poor countries is also essential for
BJ P
30 reducing the asymmetries between rich and poor countries (1.6.3 and chapter 15).
E
31 Equity across generations also matters, i.e., the distribution between the present and future generations.
SU C
32 One aspect is discounting (1.7.1). Another approach has been to study the burdens on each generation
33 following from the transition to low-carbon economies (IPCC 2014a chapter 3, Cross Working Group
AC
34 Box 3 in Chapter 12). Suggestions include shifting more investments into ‘natural capital’, so that future
35 generations will inherit less physical capital but a better environment, or financing mitigation efforts
36 today using governmental debt redeemed by future generations (Broome 2012; Heijdra et al. 2006; Karp
37 and Rezai 2014; Hoel et al. 2019).
38 1.7.3 Transition and transformation processes
39 This report uses the term transition as the process, and transformation as the overall change or outcome,
40 of large-scale shifts in technological, economic and social systems, called socio-technical systems in
41 the innovation literature. Typically, new technologies, ideas and associated systems initially grow
42 slowly in absolute terms, but may then ‘take-off’ in a phase of exponential growth as they emerge from
43 a position of niche into mainstream diffusion, as indicated by the ‘S-curve’ growth in Figure 1.7 (lower
44 panel). These dynamics arise from interactions between innovation (in technologies, companies and
1 other organisations), markets, infrastructure and institutions, at multiple levels (Geels et al. 2017;
2 Kramer 2018). Consequently, interdisciplinary perspectives are needed (Turnheim et al. 2015; Geels et
3 al. 2016; Hof et al. 2020). Beyond aggregated economic perspectives on dynamics (1.7.1.2), these
4 emphasise the multiple actors and processes involved.
5
S
IT
AL N
ED
N IO
FI S
R
TO E
T DV
EC TE
BJ P
E
SU C
AC
6
7 Figure 1.6: Transition dynamics: levels, policies and processes
8 Note: The lower panel illustrates growth of innovative technologies or practices, which if successful
9 emerge from niches into an S-shape dynamic of exponential growth. The diffusion stage often involves
10 new infrastructure and reconfiguration of existing market and regulatory structures (known in the
11 literature as the “socio-technical regime”). During the phase of more widespread diffusion; growth levels
12 off to linear, then slows as the industry and market matures. The processes displace incumbent
13 technologies/practices which decline, initially slowly but then at an accelerating pace. Many related
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-50 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 literatures identify three main levels with different characteristics, most generally termed micro, meso
2 and macro. Transitions can be accelerated by policies appropriately targeted, which may be similarly
3 grouped and sequenced (upper panel) in terms of corresponding three pillars of policy (Section 1.7.3);
4 generally all are relevant, but their relative importance differs according to stage of the transition.
5
6 Technological Innovation Systems (TIS) frameworks (chapter 16.4) focus on processes and policies of
7 early innovation and ‘emergence’, which combine experimentation and commercialisation, involving
8 Strategic Niche Management (Rip and Kemp 1998; Geels and Raven 2006). Literatures on the wider
9 processes of transition highlight different stages (eg. Cross-Chapter box 12 in Chapter 16) and scales
10 across three main levels, most generally termed micro, meso and macro (Rotmans et al. 2001).
11 The widely-used ‘Multi-Level Perspective’ or MLP (Geels 2002) identifies the meso-level as the
12 established ‘socio-technical (ST) regime’, an set of interrelated sub-systems which define rules and
13 regulatory structures around existing technologies and practices. The micro level is an ecosystem of
S
14 varied niche alternatives, and overlaying the ST regime is a macro ‘landscape’ level. Transitions often
IT
15 start with niche alternatives (Köhler et al. 2019; Grin et al. 2010), which may break through to wider
AL N
16 diffusion (second stage in Figure 1.8), especially if external landscape developments ‘create pressures
ED
17 on the regime that lead to cracks, tensions and windows of opportunity’ (Geels 2010; Rotmans et al.
N IO
18 2001); an example is climate change putting sustained pressure on current regimes of energy production
19 and consumption (Kuzemko et al. 2016). There are continual interactions between landscape, regime
FI S
20 and niches, with varied implications for Transition Management (Loorbach 2010; Rotmans et al. 2001).
R
21 In contrast to standard economic metrics of marginal or smooth change (e.g. elasticities), transition
22 theories emphasise interdisciplinary approaches and the non-linear dynamics, social, economic and
TO E
23 environmental aspects of transitions to sustainability (Köhler et al. 2018; Cherp et al. 2018). This may
T DV
24 explain persistent tendencies to underestimate the exponential pace of change now being observed in
25 renewable electricity (Chapters 2, 6) and emerging in mobility (Chapter 10).
26 Recent decades have seen parallel broadening of economic perspectives and theories. Building also on
EC TE
27 the New Institutional Economics literatures (Williamson 2000), Grubb et al. (2015) classify these into
28 three ‘domains of economic decision-making’ associated with different branches of economic theory,
29 respectively (1) behavioural and organisational; (2) neoclassical and welfare, and (3) evolutionary and
BJ P
30 institutional. Like MLP, these are related to different social and temporal scales, as applied also in
E
31 studying the ‘adaptive finance’ in UK electricity transition (Hall et al. 2017). There are significant
32 differences but these approaches all point to understanding the characteristics of different actors,
SU C
33 notably, individuals/local actors; larger corporate organisations (public or private); and (mainly) public
AC
1 There is usually a social dimension to such transitions. Key elements include capacity to transform
2 (Folke et al. 2010), planning, and interdisciplinarity (Woiwode 2013). The Second World War
3 demonstrated the extent to which crises can motivate (sometimes positive) change across complex
4 social and technical systems, including industry, and agriculture which then doubled its productivity
5 over 15 years (Roberts and Geels 2019b). In practice, climate change may involve a combination of
6 (reactive) transformational adaptation, and (proactive) societal transformation (Feola 2015), the latter
7 seen as reorientation (including values and norms) in a sustainable direction (Section 5.4 in Chapter 5),
8 including eg. ‘democratisation’ in energy systems (Sorman et al. 2020). Business change management
9 principles could be relevant to support positive social change (Stephan et al. 2016). Overall, effective
10 transitions rest on appropriate enabling conditions, which can also link socio-technical transitions to
11 broader development pathways (Cross-Chapter Box 12 in Chapter 16).
12 Transition theories tend to come from very different disciplines and approaches compared to either
13 economics or other social sciences, with less quantification, notwithstanding evolutionary and complex
system models (1.7.1.3). However, a few distinct types of quantitative models of ‘socio-technical
S
14
15 energy transition’ (Li et al. 2015) have emerged. For policy evaluation, transitions can be viewed as
IT
16 processes in which dynamic efficiency (1.7.2) dominates over static allocative efficiency, with potential
AL N
17 ‘positive intervention points’ (Farmer et al. 2019). Given inherent uncertainties, there are obvious risks
ED
N IO
18 (e.g. Alic and Sarewitz 2016). All this may make an evaluation framework of risks and opportunities
19 more appropriate than traditional cost-benefit (Mercure et al. 2021), and (drawing on lessons from
20 renewables and electric vehicles), create foundations for sector-based international ‘positive sum
FI S
21 cooperation’ in climate mitigation (Sharpe and Lenton 2021).
R
22 1.7.4 Approaches from psychology and politics of changing course
TO E
23 The continued increase in global emissions to 2019, despite three decades of scientific warnings of ever-
T DV
24 greater clarity and urgency, motivates growing attention in the literature to the psychological ‘faults of
25 our rationality’ (Bryck and Ellis 2016), and the political nature of climate mitigation.
26 1.7.4.1 Psychological and behavioural dimensions
EC TE
27 AR5 emphasised that decision processes often include both deliberate (‘calculate the costs and
28 benefits’) and intuitive thinking, the latter utilising emotion- and rule-based responses that are
29 conditioned by personal past experience, social context, and cultural factors (e.g. Kahneman 2003), and
BJ P
30 that laypersons tend to judge risks differently than experts - for example, ‘intuitive’ reactions are often
E
31 characterised by biases to status quo and aversion to perceived risks and ambiguity (Kahneman and
Tversky 1979). Many of these features of human reasoning create ‘psychological distance’ from climate
SU C
32
33 change (Spence et al. 2012; Marshall 2014). These can impede adequate personal responses, in addition
AC
34 to the collective nature of the problem, where such problems can take the form of ‘uncomfortable
35 knowledge’, neglected and so becoming ‘Unknown knowns’ (Sarewitz 2020).These decision processes,
36 and the perceptions that shape them, have been studied through different lenses from psychology
37 (Weber 2016) to sociology (Guilbeault et al. 2018), and media studies (Boykoff 2011). Karlsson and
38 Gilek (2020) identify science denialism and ‘decision thresholds’ as key mechanisms of delay.
39 Experimental economics (Allcott 2011) also helps explain why cost-effective energy efficiency
40 measures or other mitigation technologies are not taken up as fast or as widely as the benefits might
41 suggest, including procrastination and inattention, as “we often resist actions with clear long-term
42 benefits if they are unpleasant in the short run.” (Allcott and Mullainathan 2010). Incorporating
43 behavioural and social dynamics in models is required particularly to better represent the demand side
44 (Nikas et al. 2020), eg. Safarzyńska (2018) demonstrates how behavioural factors change responses to
45 carbon pricing relative to other instruments. A key perspective is to eschew ‘either/or’ between
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-52 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 economic and behavioural frameworks, as the greatest effects often involve combining behavioural
2 dimensions (e.g. norms, social influence networks, convenience and quality assurance) with financial
3 incentives and information (Stern et al. 2010). Randomised, controlled field trials can help predict the
4 effects of behavioural interventions (Levitt and List 2009; McRae and Meeks 2016; Gillan 2017).
5 Chapter 5 explores both positive and negative dimensions of behaivour in more depth, including the
6 development of norms and interactions with the wider social context, with emphasis upon the services
7 associated with human wellbeing, rather than the economic activities per se.
8 1.7.4.2 Socio-political and institutional approaches
9 Political and institutional dynamics shape climate change responses in important ways, not least because
10 incumbent actors have frequently blocked climate policy (1.4.5). Institutional perspectives probe
11 networks of opposition (Brulle 2019) and emphasise that their ability to block - as well as the ability
12 of others to foster low carbon transitions - are structured by specific institutional forms across countries
13 (Lamb and Minx 2020). National institutions have widely been developed to promote traditionally
S
14 fossil-fuel based sectors like electricity and transport as key to economic development, contributing to
IT
15 carbon lock-in (Seto et al. 2016) and inertia (Rosenschöld et al. 2014).
AL N
16 The influence of interest groups on policy-making varies across countries. Comparative political
ED
17 economy approaches tend to find that countries where interests are closely coordinated by governments
18
19
N IO
(‘coordinated market economies’) have been able to generate transformative change more than those
with a more arms-length, even combative relationship between interest groups and governments
FI S
20 (‘liberal market economies’) (Lachapelle and Paterson 2013; Meckling 2018; Ćetković and Buzogány
R
21 2016; Zou et al. 2016). ‘Developmental states’ often have the capacity for strong intervention but any
22 low-carbon interventions may be overwhelmed by other pressures and very rapid economic growth
TO E
24 Institutional features affecting climate policy include levels and types of democracy (Povitkina 2018),
25 electoral systems, or levels of institutional centralisation (federal vs unitary states, presidential vs
26 parliamentary systems) (Steurer and Clar 2018; Clulow 2019; Lachapelle and Paterson 2013). Countries
EC TE
27 that have constructed an overarching architecture of climate governance institutions (e.g. cross-
28 department and multilevel coordination, and semi-autonomous climate agencies), are more able to
29 develop strategic approaches to climate governance needed to foster transformative change (Dubash
BJ P
30 2021).
E
31 Access of non-governmental organisations (NGOs) to policy processes enables new ideas to be adopted,
SU C
32 but too close an NGO-government relation may stifle innovation and transformative action (Dryzek et
33 al. 2003). NGO campaigns on fracking (Neville et al. 2019) or divestment (Mangat et al. 2018) have
AC
34 raised attention to ideas such as ‘stranded assets’ in policy arenas (Piggot 2018; Newell et al. 2020;
35 Paterson 2021; Green 2018). Attempts to depoliticise climate change may narrow the space for
36 democratic participation and contestation, thus impacting policy responses (Swyngedouw 2010, 2011;
37 Kenis and Lievens 2014). Some institutional innovations have more directly targeted enhanced public
38 deliberation and participation, notably in citizens’ climate assemblies (Howarth et al. 2020) and in the
39 use of legal institutions to litigate against those opposing climate action (Peel and Osofksy 2020). This
40 literature shows that transformative pathways are possible within a variety of institutional settings,
41 although institutional innovation will be necessary everywhere to pursue zero carbon transitions; see
42 also Chapters 4 (Section 4) and 13.
43 Balancing the forces outlined in Section 4.6 in Chapter 4 typically involves building coalitions of actors
44 who benefit economically from climate policy (Levin et al. 2012). Policy stability is critical to enabling
45 long-term investments in decarbonisation (Rietig and Laing 2017; Rosenbloom et al. 2018). Policy
1 design can encourage coalitions to form, that sustain momentum by supporting further policy
2 development to accelerate decarbonisation (Roberts et al. 2018), for example by generating
3 concentrated benefits to coalition members (Millar et al. 2020; Bernstein and Hoffmann 2018; Meckling
4 2019), as with renewable feed-in-tariffs (FiTs) in Germany (Michaelowa et al. 2018). Coalitions may
5 also be sustained by overarching framings, especially to involve actors (e.g. NGOs) for whom the
6 benefits of climate policy are not narrowly economic. However policy design can also provoke
7 coalitions to oppose climate policy, as in the FiT programme in Ontario (Stokes 2013; Raymond 2020)
8 or the yellow vest protests against carbon taxation in France (Berry and Laurent 2019). The ‘just
9 transitions’ frame can thus also be understood in terms of coalition-building, as well as ethics, as the
10 pursuit of low carbon transitions which spread the economic benefits broadly, through ‘green jobs’, and
11 the redistributive policies embedded in them both nationally and globally (Healy and Barry 2017;
12 Winkler 2020). Appropriate policy design will be different at different stages of the transition process
13 (Meckling et al. 2017; Breetz et al. 2018).
Integration. Politics is ultimately the way in which societies make decisions – which in turn, reflect
S
14
15 diverse forces and assumed frameworks. Effective policy requires understandings which combine
IT
16 economic efficiency, ethics and equity, the dynamics and processes of large-scale transitions, and the
AL N
17 role of psychology and politics. No one framework is adequate to such a broad-ranging goal, nor are
ED
single tools. Chapter 13 (Figure 13.6) presents a ‘framing’ table for policy instruments depending on
N IO
18
19 the extent to which they focus on mitigation per se or wider socio-economic development, and whether
20 they aim to shift marginal incentives or drive larger transitions. Holistic analysis needs to bridge
FI S
21 modelling, qualitative transition theories illuminated by case studies, and practice-based action research
R
22 (Geels et al. 2016).
TO E
23 These analytic frameworks also point to arenas of potential synergies and trade-offs (when broadly
24 known), and opportunities and risks (when uncertainties are greater), associated with mitigation. This
T DV
25 offers theoretical foundations for mitigation strategies which can also generate co-benefits. Climate
26 policy may help to motivate policies with beneficial synergies (such as the consumer cost savings from
27 energy efficiency, better forest management, transitions to cleaner vehicles) and opportunities (such as
EC TE
28 stimulating innovation), by focusing on options for which the positives outweigh the negatives, or can
29 be made to through smart policy (e.g. Karlsson et al. 2020). More broadly, climate concerns may help
30 to attract international investment, and help overcoming bureaucratic or political obstacles to better
BJ P
31 policy, to support synergies between mitigation, adaptation, and other SDGs, a foundation for shifting
E
1 Table 1.2: Potential for net co-benefits arising from synergies and trade-offs, opportunities and risks
2
Positives Negatives
Broadly known (e.g. air Synergies Trade-offs
pollution, distributional)
Deep uncertainties (e.g. radical Opportunities Risks
innovations)
Select options with maximum Ameliorate trade-offs (e.g.
synergies, and foster and revenue redistribution), and
exploit opportunities minimize or allocate risks
appropriately
S
↑ ↑ ↑ ↑ ↑ ↑ ↑ ↑ ↑ ↑ ↑
IT
Net co-benefits from appropriate mitigation choices
AL N
3
ED
N IO
4
5
FI S
6 1.8 Feasibility and multi-dimensional assessment of mitigation
R
TO E
7 1.8.1 Building on the SR1.5 assessment framework: feasibility and enabling conditions
T DV
8 While previous ARs dealt with the definition of alternative mitigation pathways mostly exploring the
9 technological potentials, latest research focused on what kind of mitigation pathways are feasible in a
10 broader sense, underlining the multi-dimensional nature of the mitigation challenge. Building on
11 frameworks introduced by Majone (1975) and Gilabert and Lawford-Smith (2012), SR1.5 introduced
EC TE
12 multi-dimensional approaches to analysing ‘feasibility’ and ‘enabling conditions’, which AR6 develops
13 and applies broadly in relation to six ‘dimensions of feasibility assessment’ (Figure 1.7). Two reflect
BJ P
15 Geophysical, not only the global risks from climate change but also, for technology assessment, the
16 global availability of critical resources;
SU C
17 • Environmental & ecological, including local environmental constraints and co-benefits of different
AC
1 AR6 emphasises that all pathways involve different challenges and require choices to be made.
2 Continuing ‘business as usual’ is still a choice, which in addition to the obvious geophysical risks,
3 involves not making best use of new technologies, risks of future stranded assets, greater local pollution,
4 and multiple other environmental threats.
5 The dimensions as listed provide a basis for this assessment both in the sectoral chapters (6-11),
6 providing a common framework for cross-sectoral assessment detailed further in chapter 12, and in the
7 evaluation of global pathways (Section 3.2 in Chapter 3). More specific indicators under each of these
8 dimensions offer consistency in assessing the challenges, choices, and enabling requirements facing
9 different aspects of mitigating climate change.
10
S
IT
AL N
ED
N IO
FI S
R
TO E
T DV
EC TE
11
12 Figure 1.7: Feasibility and related dimensions of assessment
BJ P
13
E
14 Figure 1.7 also illustrates variants on these dimensions appropriate for evaluating domestic and
SU C
15 international policies (Chapters 13 and 14). The SR1.5 (Section 4.4 in Chapter 4) also introduced a
framework of ‘Enabling Conditions for systemic change’, which as illustrated also has key dimensions
AC
16
17 in common with those of our feasibility assessment. In AR6 these enabling conditions are applied
18 particularly in the context of shifting developments pathways (Chapter 4.4).
19 Some fundamental criteria may span across several dimensions. Most obviously, issues of ethics and
20 equity are intrinsic to the economic, socio-cultural (values, including intergenerational justice) and
21 institutional (e.g., procedural justice) dimensions. Geopolitical issues could also clearly involve several
22 dimensions, e.g., concerning the politics of international trade, finance and resource distribution
23 (economic dimension); international vs nationalistic identity (socio-cultural); and multilateral
24 governance (institutional).
25 In this report, chapters with a strong demand-side dimension also suggest a simple policy hierarchy,
26 reflecting that avoiding wastage – demands superfluous to human needs and wants – can carry benefits
27 across multiple indicators. Consequently, chapters 5 and 10 organise key actions in a hierarchy of Avoid
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-56 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 (unnecessary demand) – Shift (to less resource-intensive modes) - Improve (technologies for existing
2 modes), with a closely-related policy hierarchy in Chapter 9 (buildings).
3 1.8.2 Illustrations of multi-dimensional assessment: lock-in, policies and ‘just
4 transition’
5 The rest of this section illustrates briefly how such multi-dimensional assessment, utilising the
6 associated analytic frameworks, can shed light on a few key issues which arise across many chapters of
7 this assessment.
8 ‘Carbon Lock-in’. The continued rise of global emissions reflects in part the strongly path-dependent
9 nature of socio-economic systems, which implies a historic tendency to ‘carbon lock-in’ (Unruh 2000).
10 An interdisciplinary review (Seto et al. 2016) identifies a dozen main components organised into four
11 types, across the relevant Dimensions of Assessment as summarised in Table 1.3.
S
12 Table 1.3: Carbon lock-in – types and key characteristics
IT
13 Source: Adapted from (Seto et al. 2016)
AL N
ED
Lock-in type Key characteristics
Economic
N IO - Large investments with long lead-times and sunk costs, made on basis of anticipated use of
resources, capital, and equipment to pay back the investment and generate profits
FI S
- Initial choices account for private but not social costs and benefits
R
Socio-cultural, - Lock-in through social structure (e.g., norms and social processes)
TO E
equity and - Lock-in through individual decision making (e.g., psychological processes)
behaviour - Single, calculated choices become a long string of non-calculated and self-reinforcing habits
T DV
which are- Interrupting habits is difficult but possible (e.g., family size, thermostat setting) to
change
- Individuals and communities become dependent on fossil-fuel economy, meaning that change
may have adverse distributional impacts
EC TE
Technology - Learning-by-doing and scale effects, including cumulative nature of innovation, reinforces
and established technologies
infrastructure - Interaction of technologies and networks (physical, organisational, financial) on which they
BJ P
depend
E
- Random, unintentional events including network and learning effect final outcomes (e.g.,
Lock-in to the QWERTY keyboard)
SU C
Institutional & - Powerful economic, social, and political actors seek to reinforce status quo that favours their
AC
political interests
- Laws and Institutions, including regulatory structures, are designed to stabilise and lock -in
also to provide long-term predictability (socio-technical regimes in transition theories)
- Beneficial and intended outcomes for some actors
- Not random chance but intentional choice (e.g., support for renewable electricity in
Germany) can develop political consistencies that reinforce a direction of travel
14
15 Along with the long lifetime of various physical assets detailed in AR5, AR6 underlines the exceptional
16 degree of path-dependence in urban systems (Chapter 8) and associated buildings (9) and transport (10)
17 sectors, but it is a feature across almost all the major emitting sectors. The (typically -expected)
18 operating lifetimes of existing carbon-emitting assets would involve anticipated emissions (often but
19 inaccurately called ‘committed’ emissions in the literature), substantially exceeding the remaining
1 carbon budgets associated with 1.5C pathways (Chapter 2.7). Ongoing GHG-intensive investments,
2 including those from basic industrialisation in poorer countries, are adding to this.
3 The fact that investors anticipate a level of fossil fuel use that is not compatible with severe climate
4 constraints creates a clear risk of ‘stranded assets’ facing these investors (Box 6.2), and others who
5 depend on them, which itself raises issues of equity. A multi-dimensional / multi-framework assessment
6 helps to explain why such investments have continued, even in rich countries, and the consequent risks,
7 and the complexity of shifting such investments in all countries. It may also inform approaches that
8 could exploit path-dependence in clean energy systems, if there is sufficient investment in building up
9 the low-GHG industries, infrastructures and networks required.
10 Carbon pricing. Appraisal of policy instruments also requires such multi-dimensional assessment.
11 Stern’s (2007) reference to climate change as “the greatest market failure in history” highlights that
12 damages inflicted by climate change are not properly costed in most economic decision-making.
13 Economic perspectives emphasise the value of removing fossil-fuel subsidies, and pricing emissions to
S
14 ‘internalise’ in economic decision-making the ‘external’ damages imposed by GHG emissions, and/or
IT
15 to meet agreed goals. Aggregate economic frameworks generally indicate carbon pricing (on principles
AL N
16 which extend to other gases) as the most cost-effective way to reduce emissions, notwithstanding
ED
17 various market failures which complicate this logic.9 The High Level Commission on carbon pricing
N IO
18 (Stern and Stiglitz 2017) estimated an appropriate range as USD40-80/tCO2 in 2020, rising steadily
19 thereafter. In practice the extent and level of carbon pricing implemented to date is far lower than this
FI S
20 or than most economic analyses now recommend (Section 3.6.1 in Chapter 3), and nowhere is carbon
21 pricing the only instrument deployed.
R
22 A socio-cultural and equity perspective emphasises that the faith in and role of markets varies widely
TO E
23 between countries – many energy systems do no in fact operate on a basis of competitive markets – and
T DV
24 that because market-based carbon pricing involves large revenues transfers, it must also contend with
25 major distributional effects and political viability (Klenert et al. 2018; Prinn et al. 2017), both domestic
26 (Chapter 13) and international (Chapter14). A major review (Maestre-Andrés et al. 2019) finds
27 persistent distributional concerns (rich incumbents have also been vocal in using arguments about
EC TE
28 impacts on the poor (Rennkamp 2019), but suggests these may be addressed by combining
29 redistribution of revenues with support for low carbon innovation. Measures could include
BJ P
30 redistributing the tax revenue to favour of low-income groups or differentiated carbon taxes (Metcalf
31 2009; Klenert and Mattauch 2016; Stiglitz 2019), including ‘dual track’ approaches (van den Bergh et
E
32 al. 2020). To an extent though, all these depend on levels of trust, and institutional capacity.
SU C
33 Technological and transitions perspectives in turn find carbon pricing incentives may only stimulate
AC
34 incremental improvements, but other instruments may be much more effective for driving deeper
35 innovation and transitions (Chapters 14, 15, 16), whilst psychological and behavioural studies
36 emphasise many factors beyond only pricing (Sections 5.4.1 and 5.4.2 in Chapter 5). In practice, a wide
37 range of policy instruments are used (Chapter 13).
38 Finally, in economic theory, negotiations on a common carbon price (or other common policies) may
39 have large benefits (less subject to ‘free riding’) compared to a focus on negotiating national targets
40 (Cramton et al. 2017a). The fact that this has never even been seriously considered (outside some efforts
41 in the EU) may reflect the exceptional sovereignty sensitivities around taxation and cultural differences
42 around the role of markets. However, carbon pricing concepts can be important outside of the traditional
FOOTNOTE9 Beyond GHG externalities, Stern (2015) lists such market failures as; inadequate R&D; failures in
risk/capital markets; network effects creating coordination failures; wider information failures; and co-benefits.
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-58 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 market (‘tax or trading’) applications. A ’social cost of carbon’ can be used to evaluate government and
2 regulatory decisions, to compensate for inadequate carbon prices in actual markets, and by companies
3 to reflect the external damage of their emissions and strategic risks of future carbon controls (Zhou and
4 Wen 2020). An agreed ‘social value of mitigation activities’ could form a basic index for underwriting
5 risks in low carbon investments internationally (Hourcade et al. 2021a).
6 Thus, practical assessment of carbon pricing inherently needs multi-dimensional analysis. The realities
7 of political economy and lobbying have to date severely limited the implementation of carbon pricing
8 (Mildenberger 2020), leading some social scientists to ask ‘Can we price carbon?’ (Rabe 2018). Slowly
9 growing adoption (World Bank 2019) suggests “yes”, but only through complex evolution of efforts: a
10 study of 66 implemented carbon pricing policies show important effects of regional clustering,
11 international processes, and seizing political windows of opportunity (Skovgaard et al. 2019).
12 Just Transitions. Finally, whilst ‘transition’ frameworks may explain potential dynamics that could
13 transform systems, a multi-dimensional/multi-framework assessment underlines the motivation for ‘just
S
14 transitions’ (see subsection 1.6.2.3 in this chapter and section 4.5 in Chapter 4). This can be defined as
IT
15 a transition from a high-carbon to a low-carbon economy which is considered sufficiently equitable for
AL N
16 the affected individuals, workers, communities, sectors, regions and countries (Jasanoff 2018; Newell
ED
17 and Mulvaney 2013). As noted, sufficient equity is not only an ethical issue but an enabler of deeper
N IO
18 ambition for accelerated mitigation (Hoegh-Guldberg et al. 2019; Klinsky and Winkler 2018;
19 Urpelainen and Van de Graaf 2018). Perception of fairness influences the effectiveness of cooperative
FI S
20 action (Winkler et al. 2018), and this can apply to affected individuals, workers, communities, sectors,
21 regions and countries (Newell and Mulvaney 2013; Jasanoff 2018).
R
22 A ‘just transitions’ framing can also enable coalitions which integrate low carbon transformations with
TO E
23 concerns for climate adaptation (Patterson et al. 2018). All this explains the emergence of ‘just transition
T DV
24 Commissions’ in several of the more ambitious developed countries and complex social packages for
25 coal phase-out in Europe (Section 4.5 in Chapter 4; Sovacool et al. 2019; Green and Gambhir 2020), as
26 well as reference to the concept in the PA and its emphasis in the Talanoa dialogue and Silesia
27 declaration (1.2.2).
EC TE
28 Whilst the broad concepts of ‘just transition’ have roots going back decades, its specific realisation in
29 relation to climate change is of course complex: Section 5 in Chapter 4 identifies at least eight distinct
BJ P
30 elements proposed in the literature, even before considering the international dimensions.
E
31
SU C
33 Previous sections have highlighted the multiple factors that drive and constrain climate action, the
34 complex interconnection between climate mitigation and other societal objectives, and the diversity of
35 analytical frames for interpreting these connections. Despite the complexities, there are signs of
36 progress including increased societal awareness, change in social attitudes, policy commitments by a
37 broad range of actors and sustained emission reductions in some jurisdictions. Nevertheless, emission
38 trends at the global level remains incompatible with the goals agreed in the Paris Agreement.
39 Fundamentally, the challenge of how best to urgently scale up and speed-up the climate mitigation effort
40 at all scales –from local to global – to the pace needed to address the climate challenge is that of
41 governance understood as ‘modes and mechanisms to steer society’ (Jordan et al. 2015). The concept
42 of governance encompasses the ability to plan and create the organisations needed to achieve a desired
43 goal (Güney 2017) and the process of interaction among actors involved in a common problem for
44 making and implementing decisions (Hufty 2012; Kooiman 2003).
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-59 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 Climate change governance has been projected as conscious transformation at unprecedented scale and
2 speed involving a contest of ideas and experimentation across scales of authority and jurisdiction
3 (Hildén et al. 2017; Laakso et al. 2017; Gordon 2018; van der Heijden 2018; Kivimaa et al. 2017). Yet,
4 there remains a sense that achieving the urgent transition to a low carbon, climate resilient and
5 sustainable world requires significant innovation in governance (Hoffmann 2011; Stevenson and
6 Dryzek 2013; Aykut 2016).
7 Starting from an initial focus on multilateral agreements, climate change governance has long evolved
8 into a complex polycentric structure that spans from the global to national and sub-national levels, with
9 “multiple parallel initiatives involving a range of actors at different levels of governance” (Okereke et
10 al. 2009) and relying on both formal and informal networks and policy channels channels (Bulkeley et
11 al. 2014; Jordan et al. 2015). At the international level, implementation of the Paris Agreement and the
12 UNFCCC more broadly is proceeding in parallel with other activities in an increasingly diverse
13 landscape of loosely coordinated institutions, constituting ’regime complex’ (Keohane and Victor
S
14 2011), and new cooperative efforts demonstrate an evolution in the shifting authority given to actors at
15 different level of governance (Chan et al. 2018).
IT
AL N
16 Multi-level governance has been used to highlight the notion that the processes involved in making and
ED
17 implementing decisions on climate change is no longer the exclusive preserve of government actors but
N IO
18 rather involve a range of non-nation state actors such as cities, businesses, and civil society
19 organisations (Bäckstrand et al. 2017; Jordan et al. 2018; IPCC 2014a Chapter 13, 13.3.1 and 13.5.2).
FI S
20 Increased multi-level participation of subnational actors, along with a diversity of other transnational
21 and non-state actors have helped to facilitate increased awareness, experimentation, innovation,
R
22 learning and achieving benefits at multiple scales. Multi-level participation in governance systems can
TO E
23 help to build coalitions to support climate change mitigation policies (Roberts et al. 2018) and
24 fragmentation has the potential to take cooperative and even synergistic forms (Biermann et al. 2009)
T DV
25 However, there is no guarantee that multilevel governance can successfully deal with complex human-
26 ecological systems (Biermann et al. 2017; York et al. 2005; Di Gregorio et al. 2019). Multi-level
27 governance can contribute to an extremely polarised discussion and policy blockage rather than
EC TE
28 enabling policy innovation (Fisher and Leifeld 2019). Fragmented governance landscape may lead to
29 coordination and legitimacy gaps undermining the regime (Nasiritousi and Bäckstrand 2019).
Nevertheless, the realities of the ‘drivers and constraints’ detailed in Section 4 the “glocal” nature of
BJ P
30
31 climate change, the divided authority in world politics, diverse preferences of public and private entities
E
32 across the spectrum, and pervasive suspicions of free riding, implying the challenge as how to
SU C
33 incrementally deepen cooperation in a polycentric global system, rather than seeking a single, integrated
34 governance (Keohane and Victor 2016).
AC
35 Crucially, climate governance takes place in the context of embedded power relations, operating at
36 global, national and local context. Effective rules and institutions to govern climate change are more
37 likely to emerge when where power structures and interests favour action. However widespread and
38 enduring co-operation can only be expected to when the benefits outweigh the cost of cooperation and
39 when the interest of key actors are sufficiently aligned (Barrett 1994; Victor 2011; Finus and Rübbelke
40 2008; Tulkens 2019; Mainali et al. 2018). Investigating the distribution and role of hard and soft power
41 resources, capacities and power relations within and across different jurisdictional levels is therefore
42 important to uncover hindrances to effective climate governance (Marquardt 2017). Institutions at
43 international and national levels as also critical as they have the ability to mediate power and interest of
44 actors and sustain cooperation based on equity and fair rules and outcomes. Governance, in fact, helps
45 to align and moderate the interests of actors as well as to shift perceptions, including the negative,
46 burden-sharing narratives that often accompany discussion about climate action especially in
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-60 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 international negotiations. It is also useful for engaging the wider public and international networks in
2 imagining low carbon societies (e.g. Levy and Spicer 2013; Milkoreit 2017; Nikoleris et al. 2017;
3 Wapner and Elver 2017; Bengtsson Sonesson et al. 2019; Fatemi et al. 2020). Experimentation also
4 represents an important source of governance innovation and capability-formation, linked to global
5 knowledge and technology flows, which could reshape emergent socio-technical regimes and so
6 contribute to alternative development pathways (Berkhout et al. 2010; Roberts et al. 2018; Turnheim et
7 al. 2018; Lo and Castán Broto 2019).
8
9 1.10 Conclusions
10 Global conditions have changed substantially since the IPCCs Fifth Assessment in 2014. The Paris
11 Agreement and the SDGs provided a new international context, but global intergovernmental
12 cooperation has been under intense stress. Growing direct impacts of climate change are unambiguous
S
13 and movements of protest and activism – in countries and transnational organisations at many levels –
IT
14 have grown. Global emissions growth had slowed but not stopped up to 2018/19, albeit with more
AL N
15 diverse national trends. Growing numbers of countries have adopted ‘net zero’ CO2 and/or GHG
ED
16 emission goals and decarbonisation or low carbon growth strategies, but the current NDCs to 2030
N IO
17 collectively would barely reduce global emissions below present levels (1.3.3).. An unfolding
18 technology revolution is making significant contributions in some countries, but as yet its global impact
FI S
19 is limited. Global climate change can only be tackled within, and if integrated with, the wider context
20 of sustainable development, and related social goals including equity concerns. Countries and their
R
21 populations have many conflicting priorities. Developing countries in particular have multiple urgent
TO E
22 needs associated with earlier stages of sustainable development as reflected in the non-climate SDGs.
T DV
23 Developed countries are amongst the most unsustainable in terms of overall consumption, but also face
24 social constraints particularly arising from distributional impacts of climate policies.
25 The assessment of the key drivers for, and barriers against mitigation undertaken in this chapter
26 underscore the complexity and multidimensional nature of climate mitigation. Historically, much of the
EC TE
27 academic analysis of mitigating climate change, particularly global approaches, has focused on
28 modelling costs and pathways, and discussion about ‘optimal’ policy instruments. Developments since
BJ P
29 AR5 have continued to highlight the role of a wide range of factors intersecting the political, economic,
30 social and institutional domains. Yet despite such complexities, there are signs of progress emerging
E
31 from years of policy effort in terms of technology, social attitudes, emission reductions in some
SU C
32 countries, with tentative signs of impact on the trajectory of global emissions. The challenge remains
33 how best to urgently scale up and speed-up the climate mitigation effort at all scales –from local to
AC
34 global – to achieve the level of mitigation needed to address the problem as indicated by climate science.
35 A related challenge is how to ensure that mitigation effort and any associated benefits of action are
36 distributed fairly within and between countries and aligned to the overarching objective of global
37 sustainable development. Lastly, globally effective and efficient mitigation will require international
38 co-operation especially in the realms of finance, and technology.
39 Multiple frameworks of analytic assessment, adapted to the realities of climate change mitigation, are
40 therefore required. We identified four main groups. Aggregate economic frameworks – including
41 environmental costs or goals, and with due attention to implied behavioural, distributional and dynamic
42 assumptions - can provide insights about trade-offs, cost-effectiveness and policies for delivering
43 agreed goals. Ethical frameworks are equally essential to inform both international and domestic
44 discourse and decisions, including the relationship with international (and intergenerational)
45 responsibilities, related financial systems, and domestic policy design in all countries. Explicit
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-61 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 frameworks for analysing transition and transformation across multiple sectors need to draw on both
2 socio-technical transition literatures, and those on social transformation. Finally, literatures on
3 psychology, behaviour and political sciences can illuminate obstacles that have impeded progress to
4 date, and suggest ways to overcome them.
5 No single analytical framework, or single discipline, on its own can offer a comprehensive assessment
6 of climate change mitigation. Together they point to the relevance of growing literatures and discourses
7 on ‘just transitions’, and the role of governance at multiple levels. Ultimately all these frameworks are
8 needed to inform the decisions required to deepen and connect the scattered elements of progress to
9 date, and hence accelerate progress towards agreed goals and multiple dimensions of climate change
10 mitigation in the context of sustainable development.
11
S
13 Despite huge expansion in the literature (Callaghan et al. 2020), knowledge gaps remain. Modeling still
IT
14 struggles to bring together detailed physical and economic climate impacts and mitigation, with limited
AL N
15 representation of financial and distributional dynamics. There are few interdisciplinary tools which
ED
N IO
16 apply theories of transition and transformation to questions of economic and social impacts,
17 compounded by remaining uncertainties concerning the role of new technological sets, international
18 instruments, policy and political evaluation.
FI S
19 One scan of future research needs suggests three priority areas (Roberts et al. 2020); 1. Human welfare
R
20 focused development (e.g. reducing inequality), 2. How the historic position of states within
TO E
21 international power relations conditions their ability to respond to climate change, 3. Transition
22 dynamics and the flexibility of institutions to drive towards low carbon development pathways. There
T DV
23 remain gaps in understanding how international dynamics and agreements filter down to affect
24 constituencies and local implementation. Literature on the potential for supply side agreements, in
25 which producers agree to restrict the supply of fossil fuels (e.g. Asheim et al. 2019) is limited but gaining
EC TE
28 2019). Climate policies could increase the pressure on land and oceans (see IPCC 2019c,b), with
29 insufficient attention to relationships between biodiversity and climate agreements and associated
E
30 policies. IPBES aims to coordinate with the IPCC more directly, but literature will be required to
SU C
32 Compounding these gaps is the fact that socially oriented, agriculture-related options, where human and
33 non-human systems intersect most obviously, remain under-researched (e.g. Balasubramanya and Stifel
34 2020). Efforts to engage with policies here, especially framed around ecosystem services, have often
35 neglected their “practical fitness” in favor of focusing on their “institutional fitness”, which needs to be
36 addressed in future research (Stevenson et al. 2021).
37 The relative roles of short-term mitigation policies and long-term investments, including government
38 and financial decision-making tools, remains inadequately explored. Strategic investments may include
39 city planning, public transport, EV charging networks, and CCU/CCS. Understanding how international
40 treaties can increase incentives to make such investments is all the more salient in the aftermath of
41 COVID-19, on which research is necessarily young but rapidly growing. Finally, the economic,
42 institutional and political strategies to close the gap between NDCs, actual implementation, and
43 mitigation goals– informed by the PA and the UNFCCC Global Stocktake – require much further
44 research.
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-62 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
S
IT
AL N
ED
N IO
FI S
R
TO E
T DV
EC TE
BJ P
E
SU C
AC
6
7 Figure 1.8: The Structure of AR6 Mitigation Report
8 Chapters 2-5 cover the big picture trends, drivers and projections at national and global levels. (2)
9 analyses emission trends and drivers to date. (3) presents long-term global scenarios, including the
10 projected economic and other characteristics of mitigation through to balancing of sources and sinks
11 through the second half this century, and the implications for global temperature change and risks. (4)
12 explores the shorter-term prospects including NDCs, and the possibilities for accelerating mitigation
13 out to 2050 in the context of sustainable development at the national, regional and international scales.
1 (5), a new chapter for IPCC Assessments, focuses upon the role of services and derived demand for
2 energy and land use, and the social dimensions.
3 Chapters 6-12 examine sectoral contributions and possibilities for mitigation. (6) summarises
4 characteristics and trends in the energy sector, specifically supply, including the remarkable changes in
5 the cost of some key technologies since AR5; (7) examines the roles of AFOLU, drawing upon and
6 updating the recent Special Report, including the potential tensions between the multiple uses of land;
7 (8) presents a holistic view of the trends and pressures of urban systems, as both a challenge and an
8 opportunity for mitigation; Chapters 9 and 10 then examine two sectors which entwine with, but go
9 well beyond, urban systems: buildings (9) including construction materials and zero carbon buildings;
10 and transport (10), including shipping and aviation and a wider look at mobility as a general service;
11 (11) explores the contribution of industry, including supply chain developments, resource
12 efficiency/circular economy, and the cross-system implications of decarbonisation for industrial
13 systems; finally (12) takes a cross-sectoral perspective and explores cross-cutting issues like the
S
14 interactions of biomass energy, food and land, and carbon dioxide removal.
IT
15 Four chapters then review thematic issues in implementation and governance of mitigation. (13)
AL N
16 explores national and sub-national policies and institutions, bringing together lessons of policies
ED
17 examined in the sectoral chapters, as well as insights from service and demand-side perspectives (5),
N IO
18 along with governance approaches and capacity-building, and the role and relationships of sub-national
19 actors. (14) then considers the roles and status of international cooperation, including the UNFCCC
FI S
20 agreements and international institutions, sectoral agreements and multiple forms of international
21 partnerships, and the ethics and governance challenges of Solar Radiation Modification. (15) explores
R
22 investment and finance, including current trends, the investment needs for deep decarbonisation, and
TO E
23 the complementary roles of public and private finance. This includes climate-related investment
24 opportunities and risks (e.g. ‘stranded assets’), linkages between finance and investments in adaptation
T DV
25 and mitigation; and the impact of COVID-19. A new chapter on innovation (16) looks at technology
26 development, accelerated deployment and global diffusion as systemic issues that hold potential for
27 transformative changes, and the challenges of managing such changes at multiple levels including the
EC TE
30 practical pathways for joint responses to climate change and sustainable development challenges. This
31 includes major regional perspectives, mitigation-adaptation interlinkages, and enabling conditions
E
32 including the roles of technology, finance and cooperation for sustainable development.
SU C
33
AC
S
14 CO2), with additional emissions from industrial processes (mainly CO2, N2O and F-gases), and
IT
15 municipal waste and wastewater (mainly CH4) (2). In addition to these emissions, black carbon – an
AL N
16 aerosol that is, for example, emitted during incomplete combustion of fossil fuels – contributes to
ED
17 warming of the Earth’s atmosphere, whilst some other short-lived pollutants temporarily cool the
18
N IO
surface (IPCC WG1 Chapter 6.5.4.3).
FAQ 1.3 What is the difference between “net zero emissions” and “carbon neutrality”?
FI S
19
Annex I states that “carbon neutrality and net zero CO2 emissions are overlapping concepts” which
R
20
21 “can be applied at the global or sub-global scales (e.g., regional, national and sub-national)”. At the
TO E
22 global scale the terms are equivalent. At sub-global scales, net-zero CO2 typically applies to emissions
T DV
23 under direct control or territorial responsibility of the entity reporting them (e.g. a country, district or
24 sector); while carbon neutrality is also applied to firms, commodities and activities (e.g. a service or an
25 event) and generally includes emissions and removals beyond the entity’s direct control or territorial
26 responsibility, termed ‘Scope 3’ or ‘value chain emissions’ (Bhatia et al. 2011).
EC TE
27 This means the emissions and removals that should be included are wider for ‘neutrality’ than for net-
28 zero goals, but also that offset mechanisms could be employed to help achieve neutrality through
BJ P
29 abatement beyond what is possible under the direct control of the entity. Rules and environmental
30 integrity criteria are intended to ensure additionality and avoid double counting of offsets consistent
E
31 with “neutrality” claims (see Annex I definitions of “Carbon neutrality” and “Offset” for detail and a
SU C
32 list of criteria).
AC
33 While the term ‘carbon’ neutrality in this report is defined as referring specifically to CO2 neutrality,
34 use of this term in practice can be ambiguous, as some users apply it to neutrality of all GHG emissions.
35 GHG neutrality means an entity’s gross emissions of all GHG must be balanced by the removal of an
36 equivalent amount of CO2 from the atmosphere. This requires the selection of a suitable metric that
37 aggregates emissions from non-CO2 gases, such as the commonly used GWP100 metric (for a
38 discussion of GHG metrics, see AR6 WG1 Box 1.3 and Cross-Chapter Box 2 in Chapter 2 of this
39 report).
40
1 References
2 Abrahamsen, R., L. R. Andersen, and O. J. Sending, 2019: Introduction: Making liberal internationalism
3 great again? Int. J. Canada’s J. Glob. Policy Anal., 74(1), 5–14, doi:10.1177/0020702019827050.
4 Acemoglu, D., P. Aghion, L. Bursztyn, and D. Hemous, 2012: The environment and directed technical
5 change. Am. Econ. Rev., 102(1), 131–166, doi:10.1257/aer.102.1.131.
6 Acemoglu, D., U. Akcigit, D. Hanley, and W. Kerr, 2016: Transition to Clean Technology. J. Polit.
7 Econ., 124(1), 52–104, doi:10.1086/684511.
8 Ackerman, F., E. A. Stanton, and R. Bueno, 2010: Fat tails, exponents, extreme uncertainty: Simulating
9 catastrophe in DICE. Ecol. Econ., 69(8), 1657–1665, doi:10.1016/J.ECOLECON.2010.03.013.
10 Adelman, S., 2015: Tropical forests and climate change: a critique of green governmentality. Int. J. Law
11 Context, 11(2), 195–212, doi:10.1017/s1744552315000075.
S
12 Adger, W. N., 2009: Social Capital, Collective Action, and Adaptation to Climate Change. Econ.
13 Geogr., 79(4), 387–404, doi:10.1111/j.1944-8287.2003.tb00220.x.
IT
14 Adler, M. et al., 2017: Priority for the worse-off and the social cost of carbon. Nat. Clim. Chang., 7(6),
AL N
15 443–449, doi:10.1038/nclimate3298.
ED
N IO
16 Afionis, S., M. Sakai, K. Scott, J. Barrett, and A. Gouldson, 2017: Consumption-based carbon
17 accounting: does it have a future? Wiley Interdiscip. Rev. Clim. Chang., 8(1), e438,
FI S
18 doi:10.1002/wcc.438.
R
19 Aghion, P., C. Antonin, and S. Bunel, 2021: The Power of Creative Destruction. Power Creat. Destr.,
20 , Harvard University Press, Cambridge, New York, 400 pp., doi:10.4159/9780674258686/XML.
TO E
21 Akimoto, K., F. Sano, and T. Tomoda, 2018: GHG emission pathways until 2300 for the 1.5 °C
T DV
22 temperature rise target and the mitigation costs achieving the pathways. Mitig. Adapt. Strateg.
23 Glob. Chang., 23(6), 839–852, doi:10.1007/s11027-017-9762-z.
24 Alam, K. et al., 2013: Planning “Exceptionalism”? Political Economy of Climate Resilient
25 Development in Bangladesh. Springer, Tokyo, 387–417 pp.
EC TE
26 Albrecht, F., and C. F. Parker, 2019: Healing the Ozone Layer. In: Great Policy Successes, Oxford
27 University Press, Oxford, UK, pp. 304–322.
BJ P
28 Albrecht, T. R., A. Crootof, and C. A. Scott, 2018: The Water-Energy-Food Nexus: A systematic review
E
30 Aldy, J. E., 2015: Pricing climate risk mitigation. Nat. Clim. Chang., 5(5), 396–398,
31 doi:10.1038/nclimate2540.
AC
32 Alic, J. A., and D. Sarewitz, 2016: Rethinking innovation for decarbonizing energy systems. Energy
33 Res. Soc. Sci., 21, 212–221, doi:10.1016/j.erss.2016.08.005.
34 Allcott, H., 2011: Social norms and energy conservation. J. Public Econ., 95(9–10), 1082–1095,
35 doi:10.1016/J.JPUBECO.2011.03.003.
36 Allcott, H., and S. Mullainathan, 2010: Behavior and Energy Policy. Science , 327(5970), 1204–1205,
37 doi:10.1126/science.1180775.
38 Allen, T. et al., 2020: Climate-Related Scenarios for Financial Stability Assessment: An Application to
39 France. SSRN Electron. J., , doi:10.2139/ssrn.3653131.
40 Allwood, J. M., 2014: Squaring the Circular Economy: The Role of Recycling within a Hierarchy of
41 Material Management Strategies. In: Handbook of Recycling, Elsevier, pp. 445–477,
42 doi:10.1016/B978-0-12-396459-5.00030-1.
1 Ameli, N., P. Drummond, A. Bisaro, M. Grubb, and H. Chenet, 2020: Climate finance and disclosure
2 for institutional investors: why transparency is not enough. Clim. Change, 160(4), 565–589,
3 doi:10.1007/s10584-019-02542-2.
4 Ameli, N., S. Kothari, and M. Grubb, 2021: Misplaced expectations from climate disclosure initiatives.
5 Nat. Clim. Chang., 11(11), 917–924, doi:10.1038/s41558-021-01174-8.
6 Andrews-Speed, P., and C. Dalin, 2017: Elements of the water–energy–food nexus in China. In:
7 Routledge Handbook of the Resource Nexus [Bleischwitz, R., H. Hoff, C. Spataru, E. Van der
8 Voet, and S.D. VanDeveer, (eds.)], Routledge, Abingdon-on-Thames, UK.
9 Andrijevic, M., C.-F. Schleussner, M. J. Gidden, D. L. McCollum, and J. Rogelj, 2020: COVID-19
10 recovery funds dwarf clean energy investment needs. Science , 370(6514), 298–300,
11 doi:10.1126/science.abc9697.
12 Antal, M., and J. C. J. M. Van Den Bergh, 2016: Green growth and climate change: conceptual and
13 empirical considerations. Clim. Policy, 16(2), 165–177, doi:10.1080/14693062.2014.992003.
S
14 Anthoff, D., and R. S. J. Tol, 2010: On international equity weights and national decision making on
IT
15 climate change. J. Environ. Econ. Manage., 60(1), 14–20, doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2010.04.002.
AL N
16 Antimiani, A., V. Costantini, A. Markandya, E. Paglialunga, and G. Sforna, 2017: The Green Climate
ED
17 Fund as an effective compensatory mechanism in global climate negotiations. Environ. Sci.
N IO
18 Policy, 77(July), 49–68, doi:10.1016/j.envsci.2017.07.015.
19 Arora-Jonsson, S., 2011: Virtue and vulnerability: Discourses on women, gender and climate change.
FI S
20 Glob. Environ. Chang., 21(2), 744–751, doi:10.1016/J.GLOENVCHA.2011.01.005.
R
21 Arrow, K. et al., 2013: Determining benefits and costs for future generations. Science., 341(6144), 349–
22 350, doi:10.1126/science.1235665.
TO E
23 Arrow, K. J., A. Sen, and K. Suzumura, 2011: Handbook of Social Choice and Welfare Volume 2.
T DV
27 Arthur, W. B., 1999: Complexity and the Economy. Science , 284(5411), 107–109,
28 doi:10.1126/science.284.5411.107.
BJ P
29 Arto, I., and E. Dietzenbacher, 2014: Drivers of the growth in global greenhouse gas emissions.
30 Environ. Sci. Technol., 48(10), 5388–5394, doi:10.1021/es5005347.
E
31 Artz, J. et al., 2018: Sustainable Conversion of Carbon Dioxide: An Integrated Review of Catalysis and
SU C
33 Asara, V., I. Otero, F. Demaria, and E. Corbera, 2015: Socially sustainable degrowth as a social–
34 ecological transformation: repoliticizing sustainability. Sustain. Sci., 10(3), 375–384,
35 doi:10.1007/s11625-015-0321-9.
36 Asheim, G. B. et al., 2019: The case for a supply-side climate treaty. Science ., 365(6451), 325–327,
37 doi:10.1126/science.aax5011.
38 Auerbach, A. J., and Y. Gorodnichenko, 2012: Measuring the Output Responses to Fiscal Policy. Am.
39 Econ. J. Econ. Policy, 4(2), 1–27, doi:10.1257/pol.4.2.1.
40 Auffhammer, M., 2018: Quantifying Economic Damages from Climate Change. J. Econ. Perspect.,
41 32(4), 33–52, doi:10.1257/JEP.32.4.33.
42 Austen-Smith, D., W. Dziuda, B. Harstad, and A. Loeper, 2019: Gridlock and inefficient policy
43 instruments. Theor. Econ., 14(4), 1483–1534, doi:10.3982/TE3329.
44 Aven, T., and O. Renn, 2015: An evaluation of the treatment of risk and uncertainties in the IPCC
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-67 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
S
14 doi:10.1080/09644016.2017.1327485.
IT
15 Bain, C., 2017: The greening of self-interest: why is China standing firm on its climate commitments
AL N
16 despite US regression? University of British Columbia, .
ED
N IO
17 Baker, L., 2015: Renewable energy in South Africa’s minerals-energy complex: a ‘low carbon’’
18 transition?’ Rev. Afr. Polit. Econ., 42(144), 245–261, doi:10.1080/03056244.2014.953471.
FI S
19 Balasubramanya, S., and D. Stifel, 2020: Viewpoint: Water, agriculture & poverty in an era of climate
20 change: Why do we know so little? Food Policy, 93, 101905,
R
21 doi:10.1016/J.FOODPOL.2020.101905.
TO E
22 Baldwin, E., Y. Cai, and K. Kuralbayeva, 2020: To build or not to build? Capital stocks and climate
23 policy∗. J. Environ. Econ. Manage., 100, 102235, doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2019.05.001.
T DV
24 Bardi, U., S. Falsini, and I. Perissi, 2019: Toward a General Theory of Societal Collapse: A Biophysical
25 Examination of Tainter’s Model of the Diminishing Returns of Complexity. Biophys. Econ.
26 Resour. Qual., 4(1), 3, doi:10.1007/s41247-018-0049-0.
EC TE
27 Barker, T., and D. Crawford-Brown, 2014: Decarbonising the world’s economy: Assessing the
28 feasibility of policies to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. Decarbonising World’s Econ. Assess.
29 Feasibility Policies to Reduce Greenh. Gas Emiss., , 1–361, doi:10.1142/P955.
BJ P
30 Barrett, S., 1994: Self-Enforcing International Environmental Agreements. Oxf. Econ. Pap., 46(0), 878–
E
31 894.
SU C
32 Barrett, S., 2005: Chapter 28 The theory of international environmental agreements. Handb. Environ.
AC
1 Bauer, N. et al., 2013: CO2 emission mitigation and fossil fuel markets : Dynamic and international
2 aspects of climate policies. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change, 90.
3 Bauer, N. et al., 2020: Quantification of an efficiency-sovereignty trade-off in climate policy. Nature,
4 588(7837), 261–266, doi:10.1038/S41586-020-2982-5.
5 Bazilian, M. et al., 2011: Considering the energy, water and food nexus: Towards an integrated
6 modelling approach. Energy Policy, 39(12), 7896–7906, doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2011.09.039.
7 Beinhocker, E. D., 2007: The origin of wealth : evolution, complexity, and the radical remaking of
8 economics. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA, 526 pp.
9 Belkhir, L., and A. Elmeligi, 2018: Assessing ICT global emissions footprint: Trends to 2040 &
10 recommendations. J. Clean. Prod., 177, 448–463, doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.12.239.
11 Bénabou, R., and J. Tirole, 2011: Identity, morals, and taboos: Beliefs as assets. Q. J. Econ., 126(2),
12 805–855, doi:10.1093/qje/qjr002.
S
13 Bengtsson Sonesson, L. et al., 2019: Carbon Ruins: An exhibition of the fossil age. Climaginaries,.
14 https://www.climaginaries.org/carbonruins.
IT
15 Berkhout, F. et al., 2010: Sustainability experiments in Asia: Innovations shaping alternative
AL N
16 development pathways? Environ. Sci. Policy, 13(4), 261–271, doi:10.1016/j.envsci.2010.03.010.
ED
N IO
17 Bernauer, T., and T. Böhmelt, 2013: National climate policies in international comparison: The Climate
18 Change Cooperation Index. Environ. Sci. Policy, 25, 196–206, doi:10.1016/j.envsci.2012.09.007.
FI S
19 Bernstein, S., and M. Hoffmann, 2018: The politics of decarbonization and the catalytic impact of
R
20 subnational climate experiments. Policy Sci., 51(2), 189–211, doi:10.1007/s11077-018-9314-8.
21 Berry, A., and É. Laurent, 2019: Taxe carbone, le retour, à quelles conditions? , Paris, France,.
TO E
22 Bertram, C. et al., 2015: Carbon lock-in through capital stock inertia associated with weak near-term
T DV
26 https://cdkn.org/wp-content/uploads/2017/08/Mainstreaming-climate-compatible-development-
27 web-final.pdf.
28 Biermann, F., P. Pattberg, H. van Asselt, and F. Zelli, 2009: The Fragmentation of Global Governance
BJ P
30 doi:10.1162/glep.2009.9.4.14.
SU C
31 Biermann, F., N. Kanie, and R. E. Kim, 2017: Global governance by goal-setting: the novel approach
32 of the UN Sustainable Development Goals. Curr. Opin. Environ. Sustain., 26–27, 26–31,
AC
33 doi:10.1016/j.cosust.2017.01.010.
34 Bina, O., 2013: The Green Economy and Sustainable Development: An Uneasy Balance? Environ.
35 Plan. C Gov. Policy, 31(6), 1023–1047, doi:10.1068/c1310j.
36 Blanchard, O., and D. Leigh, 2013: Growth Forecast Errors and Fiscal Multipliers. IMF Work. Pap.,
37 13(1), 1, doi:10.5089/9781475576443.001.
38 Bobeck, J., J. Peace, F. M. Ahmad, and R. Munson, 2019: Carbon Utilization - A Vital and Effective
39 Pathway for Decarbonization. Cent. Clim. Energy Solut., (August 2019).
40 Bodansky, D., 2016: The Legal Character of the Paris Agreement. Rev. Eur. Comp. Int. Environ. Law,
41 25(2), 142–150, doi:10.1111/reel.12154.
42 Bodansky, D., J. Brunnée, and L. Rajamani, 2017: International Climate Change Law. Oxford
43 University Press, Oxford UK,.
1 Boppart, T., and P. Krusell, 2020: Labor Supply in the Past, Present, and Future: A Balanced-Growth
2 Perspective. J. Polit. Econ., 128(1), 118–157, doi:10.1086/704071.
3 Bos, K., and J. Gupta, 2019: Stranded assets and stranded resources: Implications for climate change
4 mitigation and global sustainable development. Energy Res. Soc. Sci., 56, 101215,
5 doi:10.1016/j.erss.2019.05.025.
6 Bowman, M., and S. Minas, 2019: Resilience through interlinkage: the green climate fund and climate
7 finance governance. Clim. Policy, 19(3), 342–353, doi:10.1080/14693062.2018.1513358.
8 Boykoff, M. T., 2011: Who Speaks for the Climate?: Making Sense of Media Reporting on Climate
9 Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge UK,.
10 Braito, M. T. et al., 2017: Human-nature relationships and linkages to environmental behaviour.
11 Environ. Values, 26(3), 365–389, doi:10.3197/096327117X14913285800706.
12 Breetz, H., M. Mildenberger, and L. Stokes, 2018: The political logics of clean energy transitions. Bus.
13 Polit., 20(4), 492–522, doi:10.1017/bap.2018.14.
S
14 Brekke, K. A., S. Kverndokk, and K. Nyborg, 2003: An economic model of moral motivation. J. Public
IT
15 Econ., 87(9–10), 1967–1983, doi:10.1016/S0047-2727(01)00222-5.
AL N
16 Brockway, P. E., A. Owen, L. I. Brand-Correa, and L. Hardt, 2019: Estimation of global final-stage
ED
N IO
17 energy-return-on-investment for fossil fuels with comparison to renewable energy sources. Nat.
18 Energy, 4(7), 612–621.
FI S
19 Broome, J., 2012: Climate matters : ethics in a warming world. W.W. Norton & Co., New York ;
20 London,.
R
21 Brouwer, F. et al., 2018: Energy modelling and the Nexus concept. Energy Strateg. Rev., 19, 1–6,
TO E
22 doi:10.1016/j.esr.2017.10.005.
T DV
23 Brulle, R. J., 2014: Institutionalizing delay: foundation funding and the creation of U.S. climate change
24 counter-movement organizations. Clim. Change, 122(4), 681–694, doi:10.1007/s10584-013-
25 1018-7.
26 Brulle, R. J., 2019: Networks of Opposition: A Structural Analysis of U.S. Climate Change
EC TE
30 Brulle, R. J., M. Aronczyk, and J. Carmichael, 2020: Corporate promotion and climate change: an
31 analysis of key variables affecting advertising spending by major oil corporations, 1986–2015.
SU C
33 Bryck, K., and N. Ellis, 2016: An Engineering Approach to Sustainable Decision Making. Environ.
34 Values, 25(6), 639–662, doi:10.3197/096327116X14736981715580.
35 Buettner, A., 2020: ‘Imagine what we could do’— the school strikes for climate and reclaiming citizen
36 empowerment. Continuum (N. Y)., 34(6), 828–839, doi:10.1080/10304312.2020.1842123.
37 Buhr, B. et al., 2018: Climate Change and the Cost of Capital in Developing Countries. , London, UK,
38 https://imperialcollegelondon.app.box.com/s/e8x6t16y9bajb85inazbk5mdrqtvxfzd.
39 Bulkeley, H., and H. Schroeder, 2012: Beyond state/non-state divides: Global cities and the governing
40 of climate change. Eur. J. Int. Relations, 18(4), 743–766, doi:10.1177/1354066111413308.
41 Bulkeley, H. et al., 2014: Transnational Climate Change Governance. Cambridge University Press,
42 Cambridge, UK,.
43 Bulow, J., C. Reinhart, K. Rogoff, and C. Trebesch, 2021: The debt pandemic: new steps are needed to
44 improve sovereign debt workouts. IMF Financ. Dev.,.
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-70 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2020/09/debt-pandemic-reinhart-rogoff-bulow-
2 trebesch.htm.
3 Burton, I. et al., 2001: Adaptation to climate change and variability in the context of sustainable
4 development. In: Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation, and Vulnerability [McCarthy, J., O.
5 Canziani, N. Leary, D. Dokken, and K. White, (eds.)], Cambridge University Press, Cambridge,
6 UK.
7 Callaghan, M. W., J. C. Minx, and P. M. Forster, 2020: A topography of climate change research. Nat.
8 Clim. Chang., 10(2), 118–123, doi:10.1038/s41558-019-0684-5.
9 Campiglio, E. et al., 2018: Climate change challenges for central banks and financial regulators. Nat.
10 Clim. Chang., 8(6), 462–468, doi:10.1038/s41558-018-0175-0.
11 Caney, S., 2016: The Struggle for Climate Justice in a Non-Ideal World. Midwest Stud. Philos., 40(1),
12 9–26, doi:10.1111/misp.12044.
13 Capasso, M., T. Hansen, J. Heiberg, A. Klitkou, and M. Steen, 2019: Green growth – A synthesis of
S
14 scientific findings. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change, 146, 390–402,
IT
15 doi:10.1016/j.techfore.2019.06.013.
AL N
16 Carbone, J. C., and N. Rivers, 2017: The Impacts of Unilateral Climate Policy on Competitiveness:
ED
17 Evidence From Computable General Equilibrium Models. Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy, 11(1), 24–
N IO
18 42, doi:10.1093/reep/rew025.
19 Carleton, T. et al., 2020: Valuing the Global Mortality Consequences of Climate Change Accounting
FI S
20 for Adaptation Costs and Benefits. , Cambridge, MA,.
R
21 Carley, S., and D. M. Konisky, 2020: The justice and equity implications of the clean energy transition.
22 Nat. Energy, 5(8), 569–577, doi:10.1038/s41560-020-0641-6.
TO E
23 Carlsson, B., and R. Stankiewicz, 1991: On the nature, function and composition of technological
T DV
27 Castree, N., 2017: Unfree Radicals: Geoscientists, the Anthropocene, and Left Politics. Antipode, 49,
28 52–74, doi:10.1111/anti.12187.
BJ P
29 Ćetković, S., and A. Buzogány, 2016: Varieties of capitalism and clean energy transitions in the
30 European Union: When renewable energy hits different economic logics. Clim. Policy, 16(5),
E
31 642–657, doi:10.1080/14693062.2015.1135778.
SU C
32 Chan, S., C. Brandi, and S. Bauer, 2016: Aligning Transnational Climate Action with International
AC
33 Climate Governance: The Road from Paris. Rev. Eur. Comp. Int. Environ. Law, 25(2), 238–247,
34 doi:10.1111/reel.12168.
35 Chan, S., R. Falkner, M. Goldberg, and H. van Asselt, 2018: Effective and geographically balanced?
36 An output-based assessment of non-state climate actions. Clim. Policy, 18(1), 24–35,
37 doi:10.1080/14693062.2016.1248343.
38 Chang, H.-J., 2014: Economics: The User’s Giude. 1st ed. Pelican, New Orleans, USA, 1–502 pp.
39 Chapman, D. A., B. Lickel, and E. M. Markowitz, 2017: Reassessing emotion in climate change
40 communication. Nat. Clim. Chang., 7(12), 850–852, doi:10.1038/s41558-017-0021-9.
41 Chazdon, R., 2008: Beyond deforestation: restoring forests and ecosystem services on degraded lands.
42 Science , 320(5882), 1458–1460.
43 Chen, K. et al., 2017: Impact of climate change on heat-related mortality in Jiangsu Province, China.
44 Environ. Pollut., 224, 317–325, doi:10.1016/j.envpol.2017.02.011.
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-71 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 Chenet, H., J. Ryan-Collins, and F. van Lerven, 2021: Finance, climate-change and radical uncertainty:
2 Towards a precautionary approach to financial policy. Ecol. Econ., 183, 106957,
3 doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2021.106957.
4 Cheon, A., and J. Urpelainen, 2018: Activism and the fossil fuel industry. 1st ed. Routledge, Abingdon-
5 on-Thames, UK, 242 pp.
6 Cherp, A., V. Vinichenko, J. Jewell, E. Brutschin, and B. Sovacool, 2018: Integrating techno-economic,
7 socio-technical and political perspectives on national energy transitions: A meta-theoretical
8 framework. Energy Res. Soc. Sci., 37, 175–190, doi:10.1016/j.erss.2017.09.015.
9 Clapp, J., P. Newell, and Z. W. Brent, 2018: The global political economy of climate change, agriculture
10 and food systems. J. Peasant Stud., 45(1), 80–88, doi:10.1080/03066150.2017.1381602.
11 Clémençon, R., 2016: The Two Sides of the Paris Climate Agreement: Dismal Failure or Historic
12 Breakthrough? J. Environ. Dev., 25(1), 3–24, doi:10.1177/1070496516631362.
13 Clulow, Z., 2019: Democracy, electoral systems and emissions: explaining when and why
S
14 democratization promotes mitigation. Clim. Policy, 19(2), 244–257,
IT
15 doi:10.1080/14693062.2018.1497938.
AL N
16 Cohen, T., and C. Cavoli, 2019: Automated vehicles: exploring possible consequences of government
ED
17 (non)intervention for congestion and accessibility. Transp. Rev., 39(1), 129–151,
N IO
18 doi:10.1080/01441647.2018.1524401.
19 Cole, D. H., 2015: Advantages of a polycentric approach to climate change policy. Nat. Clim. Chang.,
FI S
20 5(2), 114–118, doi:10.1038/nclimate2490.
R
21 Conway, D. et al., 2015: Climate and southern Africa’s water–energy–food nexus. Nat. Clim. Chang.,
22 5(9), 837–846, doi:10.1038/nclimate2735.
TO E
23 Costanza, R., L. Fioramonti, and I. Kubiszewski, 2016: The UN Sustainable Development Goals and
T DV
27 National Research Council, 2015b: Climate Intervention: Reflecting Sunlight to Cool Earth. The
28 National Academies Press, Washington,.
BJ P
29 Cramton, P., D. J. C. MacKay, A. Ockenfels, and S. (eds) Stoft, 2017a: Global Carbon Pricing: the
30 path to climate cooperation. [Cramton, P., D.J. MacKay, A. Ockenfels, and S. Stoft, (eds.)]. MIT
E
32 Cramton, P., A. Ockenfels, and J. Tirole, 2017b: Policy Brief—Translating the Collective Climate Goal
AC
33 Into a Common Climate Commitment. Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy, 11(1), 165–171,
34 doi:10.1093/reep/rew015.
35 Cronin, J. et al., 2021: Embedding justice in the 1.5°C transition: A transdisciplinary research agenda.
36 Renew. Sustain. Energy Transit., 1, 100001, doi:10.1016/j.rset.2021.100001.
37 Cui, L., and Y. Huang, 2018: Exploring the Schemes for Green Climate Fund Financing: International
38 Lessons. World Dev., 101, 173–187, doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2017.08.009.
39 Cullen, J. M., and J. M. Allwood, 2010: The efficient use of energy: Tracing the global flow of energy
40 from fuel to service. Energy Policy, 38(1), 75–81, doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2009.08.054.
41 D’Odorico, P. et al., 2018: The Global Food-Energy-Water Nexus. Rev. Geophys., 56(3), 456–531,
42 doi:10.1029/2017RG000591.
43 Dagnachew, A. G., P. L. Lucas, A. F. Hof, and D. P. van Vuuren, 2018: Trade-offs and synergies
44 between universal electricity access and climate change mitigation in Sub-Saharan Africa. Energy
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-72 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
S
13 science to address high-end climate change. Reg. Environ. Chang., 19(3), 807–818,
14 doi:10.1007/s10113-018-1288-8.
IT
15 de Melo, J., and M. Vijil, 2014: Barriers to Trade in Environmental Goods and Environmental Services:
AL N
16 How Important are They? How Much Progress at Reducing Them? , Milano, ES,.
ED
N IO
17 Death, C., 2014: The Green Economy in South Africa: Global Discourses and Local Politics. Politikon,
18 41(1), 1–22, doi:10.1080/02589346.2014.885668.
FI S
19 Denis-Ryan, A., C. Bataille, and F. Jotzo, 2016: Managing carbon-intensive materials in a
R
20 decarbonizing world without a global price on carbon. Clim. Policy, 16(sup1), S110--S128,
21 doi:10.1080/14693062.2016.1176008.
TO E
22 Di Gregorio, M. et al., 2019: Multi-level governance and power in climate change policy networks.
T DV
29 doi:10.1111/ecoj.12188.
E
30 Dietz, S., and F. Venmans, 2019: Cumulative carbon emissions and economic policy: In search of
SU C
1 Drouet, L. et al., 2021: Net zero emission pathways reduce the physical and economic risks of climate
2 change. Nat. Clim. Chang., doi:10.1038/s41558-021-01218-z.
3 Drupp, M. A., M. C. Freeman, B. Groom, and F. Nesje, 2018: Discounting disentangled. Am. Econ. J.
4 Econ. Policy, 10(4), 109–134, doi:10.1257/pol.20160240.
5 Dryzek, J., D. Downes, C. Hunold, D. Schlosberg, and H. K. Hernes, 2003: Green States and Social
6 Movements. Oxford University Press, Oxford,.
7 Dubash, N., 2019: An Introduction to India’s Evolving Climate Change Debate: From Diplomatic
8 Insulation to Policy Integration. In: India in a Warming World: Integrating Climate Change and
9 Development [Dubash, N.K., (ed.)], Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK.
10 Dubash, N. K., 2020: Revisiting climate ambition: The case for prioritizing current action over future
11 intent. WIREs Clim. Chang., 11(1), doi:10.1002/wcc.622.
12 Dubash, N. K., 2021: Varieties of climate governance: the emergence and functioning of climate
13 institutions. Env. Polit., 30(sup1), 1–25, doi:10.1080/09644016.2021.1979775.
S
14 Earley, R., and P. Newman, 2021: Transport in the Aftermath of COVID-19: Lessons Learned and
IT
15 Future Directions. J. Transp. Technol., 11(02), 109–127, doi:10.4236/jtts.2021.112007.
AL N
16 Edmonds, J., E. Al, and I. Review, 2019: Article 6 Could Make or Break the Paris Agreement to Limit
ED
N IO
17 Climate Change. Carbon Brief, https://www.carbonbrief.org/in-depth-q-and-a-how-article-6-
18 carbon-markets-could-make-or-break-the-paris-agreement.
FI S
19 Egnell, R., 2010: The organised hypocrisy of international state-building. Conflict, Secur. Dev., 10(4),
20 465–491, doi:10.1080/14678802.2010.500523.
R
21 Ekholm, T., 2014: Hedging the climate sensitivity risks of a temperature target. Clim. Change, 127(2),
TO E
22 153–167, doi:10.1007/s10584-014-1243-8.
T DV
23 Ekholm, T., 2018: Climatic Cost-benefit Analysis Under Uncertainty and Learning on Climate
24 Sensitivity and Damages. Ecol. Econ., 154, 99–106, doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2018.07.024.
25 Emmerling, J. et al., 2019: The role of the discount rate for emission pathways and negative emissions.
26 Environ. Res. Lett., 14(10), 104008, doi:10.1088/1748-9326/ab3cc9.
EC TE
27 Engau, C., D. C. Sprengel, and V. H. Hoffmann, 2017: Fasten your seatbelts: European airline responses
28 to climate change turbulence. In: Corporate Responses to Climate Change, Routledge, Abingdon-
BJ P
30 EPIC, 2019: Is the Public Willing to Pay to Help Fix Climate Change? , Chicago, MA, 1–12 pp.
SU C
31 EPT, 2020: Track funds for energy in recovery packages. Energy Policy Tracker,.
32 https://www.energypolicytracker.org/.
AC
33 Ertugrul, H. M., M. Cetin, F. Seker, and E. Dogan, 2016: The impact of trade openness on global carbon
34 dioxide emissions: Evidence from the top ten emitters among developing countries. Ecol. Indic.,
35 67, 543–555, doi:10.1016/j.ecolind.2016.03.027.
36 Escobar, A., 2015: Degrowth, postdevelopment, and transitions: a preliminary conversation. Sustain.
37 Sci., 10(3), 451–462, doi:10.1007/s11625-015-0297-5.
38 Eshel, G., P. Stainier, A. Shepon, and A. Swaminathan, 2019: Environmentally Optimal, Nutritionally
39 Sound, Protein and Energy Conserving Plant Based Alternatives to U.S. Meat. Sci. Rep., 9(1),
40 doi:10.1038/s41598-019-46590-1.
41 Etchart, L., 2017: The role of indigenous peoples in combating climate change. Palgrave Commun.,
42 3(1), 17085, doi:10.1057/palcomms.2017.85.
43 Evans, D., A. McMeekin, and D. Southerton, 2012: Sustainable Consumption, Behaviour Change
44 Policies and Theories of Practice. Collegium, 12, 113–129.
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-74 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 Evans, G., and L. Phelan, 2016: Transition to a post-carbon society: Linking environmental justice and
2 just transition discourses. Energy Policy, 99, 329–339, doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2016.05.003.
3 Evensen, D. T., 2015: Policy Decisions on Shale Gas Development ('Fracking’): The Insufficiency of
4 Science and Necessity of Moral Thought. Environ. Values, 24(4), 511–534,
5 doi:10.3197/096327115X14345368709989.
6 Fajardy, M., S. Chiquier, and N. Mac Dowell, 2018: Investigating the BECCS resource nexus:
7 delivering sustainable negative emissions. Energy Environ. Sci., 11(12), 3408–3430,
8 doi:10.1039/C8EE01676C.
9 Falkner, R., 2016: The Paris Agreement and the new logic of international climate politics. Int. Aff.,
10 92(5), 1107–1125, doi:10.1111/1468-2346.12708.
11 Fankhauser, S., 2016: Climate-resilient development: an introduction. In: The Economics of Climate-
12 Resilient Development, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, UK.
13 Fankhauser, S., and T. K. J. McDermott, 2015: Climate-resilient development: an introduction. Econ.
S
14 Clim. Dev., , 1–12.
IT
15 Fankhauser, S. et al., 2013: Who will win the green race? In search of environmental competitiveness
AL N
16 and innovation. Glob. Environ. Chang., 23(5), 902–913, doi:10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2013.05.007.
ED
N IO
17 Farmer, J. D., C. Hepburn, P. Mealy, and A. Teytelboym, 2015: A Third Wave in the Economics of
18 Climate Change. Environ. Resour. Econ., 62(2), 329–357, doi:10.1007/s10640-015-9965-2.
FI S
19 Farmer, J. D. et al., 2019: Sensitive intervention points in the post-carbon transition. Science, 364(6436),
20 132-134, doi:10.1126/science.aaw7287.
R
21 Farooquee, A. A., and G. Shrimali, 2016: Making renewable energy competitive in India: Reducing
TO E
22 financing costs via a government-sponsored hedging facility. Energy Policy, 95, 518–528,
23 doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2016.02.005.
T DV
24 Fatemi, M. N., S. A. Okyere, S. K. Diko, and M. Kita, 2020: Multi-Level Climate Governance in
25 Bangladesh via Climate Change Mainstreaming: Lessons for Local Climate Action in Dhaka City.
26 Urban Sci., 4(2), 24, doi:10.3390/urbansci4020024.
EC TE
27 Federico, G., and A. Tena-Junguito, 2017: A tale of two globalizations: gains from trade and openness
28 1800–2010. Rev. World Econ., 153(3), 601–626, doi:10.1007/s10290-017-0279-z.
BJ P
29 Feola, G., 2015: Societal transformation in response to global environmental change: A review of
30 emerging concepts. Ambio, 44(5), 376–390, doi:10.1007/s13280-014-0582-z.
E
31 Ferguson, D. B., J. Rice, and C. A. Woodhouse, 2014: Linking Environmental Research and Practice:
SU C
32 Lessons From The Integration of Climate Science and Water Management in the Western United
AC
33 States. https://climas.arizona.edu/publication/report/linking-environmental-research-and-
34 practice.
35 Fink, L., 2020: A Fundamental Reshaping of Finance. BlackRock Lett. to CEOs,.
36 https://www.blackrock.com/us/individual/larry-fink-ceo-letter (Accessed August 3, 2021).
37 Finus, M., and D. T. G. Rübbelke, 2008: Coalition Formation and the Ancillary Benefits of Climate
38 Policy. SSRN Electron. J., , doi:10.2139/ssrn.1259699.
39 Fisher, D. R., and P. Leifeld, 2019: The polycentricity of climate policy blockage. Clim. Change,
40 155(4), 469–487, doi:10.1007/s10584-019-02481-y.
41 Fisher, D. R. et al., 2019: The science of contemporary street protest: New efforts in the United States.
42 Sci. Adv., 5(10), doi:10.1126/sciadv.aaw5461.
43 Fitzgerald, L. M., I. Braunger, and H. Brauers, 2019: Destabilisation of Sustainable Energy
44 Transformations: Analysing Natural Gas Lock-in in the Case of Germany. , Brighton, UK,.
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-75 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 Flexer, V., C. F. Baspineiro, and C. I. Galli, 2018: Lithium recovery from brines: A vital raw material
2 for green energies with a potential environmental impact in its mining and processing. Sci. Total
3 Environ., 639, 1188–1204, doi:10.1016/j.scitotenv.2018.05.223.
4 Florin, M.-V., P. Rouse, A.-M. Hubert, M. Honegger, and J. Reynolds, 2020: lnternational governance
5 issues on climate engineering Information for policymakers. EPFL International Risk Governance
6 Center, Lausanne,.
7 Folke, C. et al., 2010: Resilience Thinking: Integrating Resilience, Adaptability and Transformability.
8 Ecol. Soc., 15(4).
9 Forster, P. M. et al., 2020: Current and future global climate impacts resulting from COVID-19. Nat.
10 Clim. Chang., 10(10), 913–919, doi:10.1038/s41558-020-0883-0.
11 Fotis, P., and M. Polemis, 2018: Sustainable development, environmental policy and renewable energy
12 use: A dynamic panel data approach. Sustain. Dev., 26(6), 726–740, doi:10.1002/sd.1742.
13 Frame, D. J. et al., 2019: Emissions and emergence: A new index comparing relative contributions to
S
14 climate change with relative climatic consequences. Environ. Res. Lett., 14(8), 84009,
IT
15 doi:10.1088/1748-9326/ab27fc.
AL N
16 Francis, 2015: Laudato Si’ of the Holy Father Francis on Care for Our Common Home. Vatican Press,
ED
17 Rome, IT,.
18
19 N IO
Freeman, C., and C. L. B.-F. Perez, 1988: Structural crises of adjustment: business cycles. In: Technical
Change and Economic Theory [Dosi, G., C. Freeman, R. Nelson, G. Silverberg, and L. Soete,
FI S
20 (eds.)], Pinter Publishers, London, UK.
R
21 Freeman, C., and F. Louçã, 2002: As Time Goes By. Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK,.
TO E
22 Freeman, G. M., T. E. Drennen, and A. D. White, 2017: Can parked cars and carbon taxes create a
23 profit? The economics of vehicle-to-grid energy storage for peak reduction. Energy Policy, 106,
T DV
24 183–190, doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2017.03.052.
25 Fresco, L., 2015: Hamburgers in Paradise: The Stories behind the Food We Eat. Princeton University
26 Press, Princeton, NJ, 560 pp.
EC TE
27 Fuhr, H., T. Hickmann, and K. Kern, 2018: The role of cities in multi-level climate governance: local
28 climate policies and the 1.5°C target. Curr. Opin. Environ. Sustain., 30, 1–6,
29 doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cosust.2017.10.006.
BJ P
32 Fujimori, S. et al., 2016: Will international emissions trading help achieve the objectives of the Paris
AC
1 Gardiner, S. M., 2011: A Perfect Moral Storm: The Ethical Tragedy of Climate Change. Oxford
2 University Press, 1–512 pp.
3 Garrett, T. J., M. Grasselli, and S. Keen, 2020: Past world economic production constrains current
4 energy demands: Persistent scaling with implications for economic growth and climate change
5 mitigation. PLoS One, 15(8), e0237672, doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0237672.
6 Gawel, E., and C. Kuhlicke, 2017: Efficiency–Equity–Trade–Off as a Challenge for Shaping Urban
7 Transformations. In: Urban Transformations, Springer, Cambridge, pp. 45–60.
8 GCF, 2020: Green Climate Fund Website. Green Clim. Fund,. https://www.greenclimate.fund/about
9 (Accessed October 1, 2020).
10 Geden, O., 2016: The Paris Agreement and the inherent inconsistency of climate policymaking. WIREs
11 Clim. Chang., 7(6), 790–797, doi:10.1002/wcc.427.
12 Geels, B. F. W., B. Sovacool, T. Schwanen, and S. Sorrell, 2017: Accelerating innovation is as
13 important as climate policy. Science , 357(6357), 1242–1244.
S
14 Geels, F., and R. Raven, 2006: Non-linearity and Expectations in Niche-Development Trajectories: Ups
IT
15 and Downs in Dutch Biogas Development (1973–2003). Technol. Anal. Strateg. Manag., 18(3–
AL N
16 4), 375–392, doi:10.1080/09537320600777143.
ED
N IO
17 Geels, F. W., 2002: Technological transitions as evolutionary reconfiguration processes: a multi-level
18 perspective and a case-study. Res. Policy, 31(8–9), 1257–1274, doi:10.1016/S0048-
19 7333(02)00062-8.
FI S
20 Geels, F. W., 2010: Ontologies, socio-technical transitions (to sustainability), and the multi-level
R
21 perspective. Res. Policy, 39(4), 495–510, doi:10.1016/j.respol.2010.01.022.
TO E
22 Geels, F. W., 2014: Regime Resistance against Low-Carbon Transitions: Introducing Politics and
23 Power into the Multi-Level Perspective. Theory, Cult. Soc., 31(5), 21–40,
T DV
24 doi:10.1177/0263276414531627.
25 Geels, F. W., F. Berkhout, and D. P. van Vuuren, 2016: Bridging analytical approaches for low-carbon
26 transitions. Nat. Clim. Chang., 6(6), 576–583, doi:10.1038/nclimate2980.
EC TE
27 Georgeson, L., M. Maslin, and M. Poessinouw, 2017: The global green economy: a review of concepts,
28 definitions, measurement methodologies and their interactions. Geo Geogr. Environ., 4(1),
29 e00036, doi:10.1002/geo2.36.
BJ P
30 GESAMP, 2019: High Level Review of a Wide Range of Proposed Marine Geoengineering Techniques.
E
31 [Boyd, P.W. and C.M.G. Vivian, (eds.)]. International Mariritime Organisation, London, UK,.
SU C
32 Gheorghe H., P., and F. C. Ciurlau, 2016: Can environmental sustainability be attained by incorporating
AC
33 nature within the capitalist economy? Econ. Manag. Financ. Mark., 11(4).
34 Gidden, M. J. et al., 2019: Global emissions pathways under different socioeconomic scenarios for use
35 in CMIP6: a dataset of harmonized emissions trajectories through the end of the century. Geosci.
36 Model Dev., 12(4), 1443–1475, doi:10.5194/gmd-12-1443-2019.
37 Gilabert, P., and H. Lawford-Smith, 2012: Political Feasibility: A Conceptual Exploration. Polit. Stud.,
38 60(4), 809–825, doi:10.1111/j.1467-9248.2011.00936.x.
39 Gillan, J. M., 2017: Dynamic Pricing, Attention, and Automation: Evidence from a Field Experiment in
40 Electricity Consumption. , Berkeley, CA,.
41 Gillingham, K., and J. H. Stock, 2018: The Cost of Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions. J. Econ.
42 Perspect., 32(4), 53–72, doi:10.1257/jep.32.4.53.
43 Glanemann, N., S. N. Willner, and A. Levermann, 2020: Paris Climate Agreement passes the cost-
44 benefit test. Nat. Commun., 11(1), 110, doi:10.1038/s41467-019-13961-1.
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-77 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 Goddard, G., and M. A. Farrelly, 2018: Just transition management: Balancing just outcomes with just
2 processes in Australian renewable energy transitions. Appl. Energy, 225, 110–123,
3 doi:10.1016/j.apenergy.2018.05.025.
4 Goldthau, A., and N. Sitter, 2015: A Liberal Actor in a Realist World. Oxford University Press, Oxford,
5 UK,.
6 Gollier, C., 2021: The cost-efficiency carbon pricing puzzle. CEPR Discuss. Pap. No. DP15919, , 1–
7 33.
8 Golosov, M., J. Hassler, P. Krusell, and A. Tsyvinski, 2014: Optimal Taxes on Fossil Fuel in General
9 Equilibrium. Econometrica, 82(1), 41–88, doi:10.3982/ECTA10217.
10 Gomez-Echeverri, L., 2018a: Climate and development: enhancing impact through stronger linkages in
11 the implementation of the Paris Agreement and the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs).
12 Philos. Trans. R. Soc. A Math. Phys. Eng. Sci., 376(2119), doi:10.1098/rsta.2016.0444.
13 Gomez-Echeverri, L., 2018b: Climate and development: enhancing impact through stronger linkages in
S
14 the implementation of the Paris Agreement and the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs).
IT
15 Philos. Trans. R. Soc. A Math. Phys. Eng. Sci., 376(2119), 20160444, doi:10.1098/rsta.2016.0444.
AL N
16 Gonella, F. et al., 2019: Is technology optimism justified? A discussion towards a comprehensive
ED
17 narrative. J. Clean. Prod., 223, 456–465, doi:10.1016/J.JCLEPRO.2019.03.126.
18
19 N IO
Gordon, D. J., 2018: Global urban climate governance in three and a half parts: Experimentation,
coordination, integration (and contestation). WIREs Clim. Chang., 9(6), e546,
FI S
20 doi:10.1002/wcc.546.
R
21 Gough, I., 2017: Recomposing consumption: defining necessities for sustainable and equitable well-
22 being. Philos. Trans. R. Soc. A Math. Phys. Eng. Sci., 375(2095), 20160379,
TO E
23 doi:10.1098/rsta.2016.0379.
T DV
24 Gray, P., and T. Irwin, 2003: Exchange Rate Risk Allocating Exchange Rate Risk in Private
25 Infrastructure Projects. , Washington, DC: The World Bank,
26 https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/11286.
EC TE
27 Green, F., 2018: Anti-fossil fuel norms. Clim. Change, 150(1), 103–116, doi:10.1007/s10584-017-
28 2134-6.
29 Green, F., and A. Gambhir, 2020: Transitional assistance policies for just, equitable and smooth low-
BJ P
30 carbon transitions: who, what and how? Clim. Policy, 20(8), 902–921,
E
31 doi:10.1080/14693062.2019.1657379.
SU C
32 Grin, J., J. Rotmans, and J. Schot, 2010: Transitions to Sustainable Development: New Directions in
33 the Study of Long Term Transformative Change. Routledge, Abingdon-on-Thames, UK,.
AC
34 Groom, B., and C. Hepburn, 2017: Looking back at social discounting policy: The influence of papers,
35 presentations, political preconditions, and personalities. Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy, 11(2), 336–
36 356, doi:10.1093/reep/rex015.
37 Grubb, M., J.-C. Hourcade, and K. Neuhoff, 2014: Planetary Economics: Energy, climate change and
38 the three domains of sustainable development. 1st ed. Routledge, Abingdon-on-Thames, UK, 520
39 pp.
40 Grubb, M., J.-C. Hourcade, and K. Neuhoff, 2015: The Three Domains structure of energy-climate
41 transitions. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change, 98, 290–302, doi:10.1016/j.techfore.2015.05.009.
42 Grubb, M. et al., 2021a: Induced innovation in energy technologies and systems: A review of evidence
43 and potential implications for CO2 mitigation. Environ. Res. Lett., 16(4), 43007,
44 doi:10.1088/1748-9326/abde07.
45 Grubb, M., C. Wieners, and P. Yang, 2021b: Modelling Myths: on DICE and dynamic realism in
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-78 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 integrated assessment models of climate change mitigation. Wiley Interdiscip. Rev. Clim. Chang.,
2 12(3), doi:https://doi.org/10.1002/wcc.698.
3 Gudka, S., N. Armstrong, and P. Newman, 2020: Cutting diesel exhaust could lessen Covid spread in
4 cities,. Sci. Am., (12 November).
5 Guilbeault, D., J. Becker, and D. Centola, 2018: Social learning and partisan bias in the interpretation
6 of climate trends. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U. S. A., 115(39), 9714–9719,
7 doi:https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1722664115.
8 Güney, T., 2017: Governance and sustainable development: How effective is governance? J. Int. Trade
9 Econ. Dev., 26(3), 316–335, doi:10.1080/09638199.2016.1249391.
10 Gunster, S., 2017: This changes everything: capitalism vs the climate. Environ. Commun., 11(1), 136–
11 138, doi:10.1080/17524032.2016.1196534.
12 Gupta, J., 2016: The Paris Climate Change Agreement: China and India. Clim. Law, 6(1–2), 171–181,
13 doi:10.1163/18786561-00601012.
S
14 Gupta, S. K., and U. S. Racherla, 2018: Interdependence among dimensions of sustainability: Evidence
IT
15 from the Indian leather industry. Manag. Environ. Qual. An Int. J., 29(3), 406–415,
AL N
16 doi:10.1108/MEQ-06-2017-0051.
ED
N IO
17 Guzman, M., J. A. Ocampo, and J. E. Stiglitz, 2018: Real exchange rate policies for economic
18 development. World Dev., 110, 51–62, doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2018.05.017.
FI S
19 Haberl, H. et al., 2019: Contributions of sociometabolic research to sustainability science. Nat. Sustain.,
20 2(3), 173–184, doi:10.1038/s41893-019-0225-2.
R
21 Haberl, H. et al., 2020: A systematic review of the evidence on decoupling of GDP, resource use and
TO E
22 GHG emissions, part II: synthesizing the insights. Environ. Res. Lett., 15(6), 065003,
23 doi:10.1088/1748-9326/ab842a.
T DV
24 Hackmann, B., 2016: Regime Learning in Global Environmental Governance. Environ. Values, 25(6),
25 663–686, doi:10.3197/096327116X14736981715625.
26 Hagedorn, G. et al., 2019: Concerns of young protesters are justified. Science , 364(6436), 139–140,
EC TE
27 doi:10.1126/science.aax3807.
28 Hall, S., T. J. Foxon, and R. Bolton, 2017: Investing in low-carbon transitions: energy finance as an
BJ P
30 Hamilton, L. C., 2011: Education, politics and opinions about climate change evidence for interaction
31 effects. Clim. Change, 104(2), 231–242, doi:10.1007/s10584-010-9957-8.
SU C
32 Hannis, M., 2016: Freedom and environment: Autonomy, human flourishing and the political
AC
1 Harstad, B., 2007: Harmonization and Side Payments in Political Cooperation. Am. Econ. Rev., 97(3),
2 871–889, doi:10.1257/AER.97.3.871.
3 Hartzell-Nichols, L., 2014: The Price of Precaution and the Ethics of Risk. Ethics, Policy Environ.,
4 17(1), 116–118, doi:10.1080/21550085.2014.885183.
5 Hasegawa, T. et al., 2018: Risk of increased food insecurity under stringent global climate change
6 mitigation policy. Nat. Clim. Chang., 8(8), 699–703, doi:10.1038/s41558-018-0230-x.
7 Havlik, P. et al., 2014: Climate change mitigation through livestock system transitions. Proc. Natl.
8 Acad. Sci., 111(10), 3709–3714, doi:10.1073/pnas.1308044111.
9 Healy, N., and J. Barry, 2017: Politicizing energy justice and energy system transitions: Fossil fuel
10 divestment and a “just transition.” Energy Policy, 108, 451–459,
11 doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2017.06.014.
12 Heffron, R. J., and D. McCauley, 2018: What is the ‘Just Transition’? Geoforum, 88, 74–77,
13 doi:10.1016/j.geoforum.2017.11.016.
S
14 Heijdra, B. J., J. P. Kooiman, and J. E. Ligthart, 2006: Environmental quality, the macroeconomy, and
IT
15 intergenerational distribution. Resour. Energy Econ., 28(1), 74–104,
AL N
16 doi:10.1016/j.reseneeco.2005.05.001.
ED
N IO
17 Heinrichs, H., P. Jochem, and W. Fichtner, 2014: Including road transport in the EU ETS (European
18 Emissions Trading System): A model-based analysis of the German electricity and transport
19 sector. Energy, 69, 708–720, doi:10.1016/j.energy.2014.03.061.
FI S
20 Held, H., 2019: Cost Risk Analysis: Dynamically Consistent Decision-Making under Climate Targets.
R
21 Environ. Resour. Econ., 72(1), 247–261, doi:10.1007/s10640-018-0288-y.
TO E
24 Hepburn, C., B. O’Callaghan, N. Stern, J. Stiglitz, and D. Zenghelis, 2020: Will COVID-19 fiscal
25 recovery packages accelerate or retard progress on climate change? Oxford Rev. Econ. Policy,
26 36(20), doi:10.1093/oxrep/graa015.
EC TE
27 Herrick, C. N., 2018: Self-identity and sense of place: Some thoughts regarding climate change
28 adaptation policy formulation. Environ. Values, 27(1), 81–102,
29 doi:10.3197/096327118X15144698637531.
BJ P
30 Heyward, J. C., and D. Roser, 2016: Climate Justice in a Non-Ideal World. Oxford University Press,
E
32 Hickel, J., and G. Kallis, 2020: Is Green Growth Possible? New Polit. Econ., 25(4), 469–486,
AC
33 doi:10.1080/13563467.2019.1598964.
34 Hidalgo, C. A., and R. Hausmann, 2009: The building blocks of economic complexity. Proc. Natl.
35 Acad. Sci., 106(26), 10570–10575.
36 Hilaire, J. et al., 2019: Negative emissions and international climate goals—learning from and about
37 mitigation scenarios. Clim. Change, 157(2), 189–219, doi:10.1007/s10584-019-02516-4.
38 Hildén, M., A. Jordan, and D. Huitema, 2017: Special issue on experimentation for climate change
39 solutions editorial: The search for climate change and sustainability solutions - The promise and
40 the pitfalls of experimentation. J. Clean. Prod., 169, 1–7,
41 doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.09.019.
42 Himes-Cornell, A., L. Pendleton, and P. Atiyah, 2018: Valuing ecosystem services from blue forests:
43 A systematic review of the valuation of salt marshes, sea grass beds and mangrove forests. Ecosyst.
44 Serv., 30, 36–48, doi:10.1016/j.ecoser.2018.01.006.
1 Hochstetler, K., 2020: Political Economies of Energy Transition. Cambridge University Press,
2 Cambridge, UK,.
3 Hoegh-Guldberg, O. et al., 2019: The human imperative of stabilizing global climate change at 1.5°C.
4 Science ., 365(6459), doi:10.1126/science.aaw6974.
5 Hoeing, A. et al., 2015: How nature is used and valued by villagers in two villages in Uut Murung. J.
6 Indones. Nat. Hist., 3(1), 8–18.
7 Hoel, M. O., S. A. C. Kittelsen, and S. Kverndokk, 2019: Correcting the Climate Externality: Pareto
8 Improvements Across Generations and Regions. Environ. Resour. Econ., 74(1), 449–472,
9 doi:10.1007/s10640-019-00325-y.
10 Hof, A. F. et al., 2017: Global and regional abatement costs of Nationally Determined Contributions
11 (NDCs) and of enhanced action to levels well below 2 °C and 1.5 °C. Environ. Sci. Policy, 71,
12 30–40, doi:10.1016/J.ENVSCI.2017.02.008.
13 Hof, A. F., D. P. van Vuuren, F. Berkhout, and F. W. Geels, 2020: Understanding transition pathways
S
14 by bridging modelling, transition and practice-based studies: Editorial introduction to the special
IT
15 issue. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change, 151, doi:10.1016/j.techfore.2019.05.023.
AL N
16 Hoffmann, M. J., 2011: Climate Governance at the Crossroads. Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK,.
ED
N IO
17 Holzer, K., 2014: Carbon-related Border Adjustment and WTO Law. 1st ed. World Trade Institute,
18 Bern, Switzerland, 352 pp.
FI S
19 Homma, T., G. K, J. Oda, and K. Akimoto, 2019: Analysis of International Competitiveness under the
20 Current Climate and Energy Policies and the Nationally Determined Contributions. J. Japan Soc.
R
21 Energy Resour., 41(5).
TO E
22 Hourcade, J.-C., D. Dasgupta, and F. Ghersi, 2021a: Accelerating the speed and scale of climate finance
23 in the post-pandemic context. Clim. Policy, , 1–15, doi:10.1080/14693062.2021.1977599.
T DV
24 Hourcade, J. C. et al., 2021b: Scaling up climate finance in the context of Covid-19. , London, UK,.
25 Howarth, C. et al., 2020: Building a Social Mandate for Climate Action: Lessons from COVID-19.
26 Environ. Resour. Econ., 76(4), 1107–1115, doi:10.1007/s10640-020-00446-9.
EC TE
27 Howell, R., and S. Allen, 2017: People and Planet: Values, Motivations and Formative Influences of
28 Individuals Acting to Mitigate Climate Change. Environ. Values, 26(2), 131–155,
BJ P
29 doi:10.3197/096327117X14847335385436.
E
30 Hsu, A., O. Widerberg, M. Roelfsema, Lütkehermöller K, and F. Bakhtiari, 2018: Bridging the
31 emissions gap-The role of non-state and subnational actors Pre-release version of a chapter of
SU C
1 System: Opportunities, pitfalls and future prospects. In: Carbon Governance, Climate Change and
2 Business Transformation, Routledge Taylor & Francis Group, Abingdon, Oxon ; New York, NY,
3 pp. 143--157.
4 IEA, 2019a: Global Energy & CO2 Status Report The latest trends in energy and emissions in 2018. ,
5 Paris, France, https://iea.blob.core.windows.net/assets/23f9eb39-7493-4722-aced-
6 61433cbffe10/Global_Energy_and_CO2_Status_Report_2018.pdf.
7 IEA, 2019b: World Energy Outlook 2019. , Paris, France, https://www.iea.org/reports/world-energy-
8 outlook-2019.
9 IEA, 2020a: World Energy Outlook 2020. , Paris, France, https://www.iea.org/reports/world-energy-
10 outlook-2020.
11 IEA, 2020b: Sustainable recovery: World Energy Outlook Special Report. , Paris, France,
12 https://www.iea.org/reports/sustainable-recovery.
13 IEA, 2021: Global Energy Review 2021. , Paris, France,.
S
14 IFEES, 2015: Islamic Declaration on Global Climate Change. , Istanbul, Turkey,
IT
15 https://www.ifees.org.uk/about/islamic-declaration-on-global-climate-change/.
AL N
16 IMF, 2020: World Economic Outlook - A Long and Difficult Ascent. , Washington D.C.,.
ED
N IO
17 IMF, 2021: Gross debt position % of GDP. IMF Datamapper,.
18 https://www.imf.org/external/datamapper/G_XWDG_G01_GDP_PT@FM/ADVEC/FM_EMG/
FI S
19 FM_LIDC.
R
20 IPBES, 2019: The global assessment report on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services. [Díaz, S. et al.,
21 (eds.)]. IPBES secretariat, Bonn, Germany, 1148 pp.
TO E
22 IPCC, 1995: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution
T DV
23 of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate
24 Change. [Bruce, J., H. Lee, and E. Haites, (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge UK,.
25 IPCC, 2007: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation of Climate Change: Contribution of Working Group III
26 to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. [Metz, B.,
EC TE
27 O.R. Davidson, P.R. Bosch, R. Dave, and L.A. Meyer, (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press,
28 Cambridge, United Kingdom,.
BJ P
29 IPCC, 2011a: IPCC Special Report on Renewable Energy Sources and Climate Change Mitigation.
30 [Edenhofer, O. et al., (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press, United Kingdom and New York, NY,
E
32 IPCC, 2011b: Summary for Policymakers. In: IPCC Special Report on Renewable Energy Sources and
AC
33 Climate Change Mitigation [Edenhofer, O. et al., (eds.)], Cambridge University Press, Cambridge,
34 United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA.
35 IPCC, 2014a: Climate Change 2014: Mitigation of Climate Change Working Group III Contribution to
36 the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. [Edenhofer, O.,
37 R. Pichs-Madruga, Y. Sokona, E. Farahani, S. Kadner, K., T.Z. Seyboth, A. Adler, I. Baum, S.
38 Brunner, P. Eickemeier, B. Kriemann, J. Savolainen, S. Schlömer, C. von Stechow, J.C., and
39 Minx, (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK and New York, USA, 151 pp.
40 IPCC, 2014b: Summary for Policy Makers. In: Climate Change 2014: Mitigation of Climate Change
41 Working Group III Contribution to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel
42 on Climate Change [Edenhofer, O., R. Pichs-Madruga, Y. Sokona, E. Farahani, S. Kadner, K.,
43 T.Z. Seyboth, A. Adler, I. Baum, S. Brunner, P. Eickemeier, B. Kriemann, J. Savolainen, S.
44 Schlömer, C. von Stechow, J.C., and Minx, (eds.)], Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK
45 and New York, USA, p. pp. 151.
1 IPCC, 2014c: Climate Change 2013 - The Physical Science Basis Working Group I Contribution to the
2 Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. [Intergovernmental
3 Panel on Climate Change, (ed.)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2–26 pp.
4 IPCC, 2018a: Summary for Policymakers. In: Global Warming of 1.5 °C an IPCC special report on the
5 impacts of global warming of 1.5 °C above pre-industrial levels and related global greenhouse
6 gas emission pathways, in the context of strengthening the global response to the threat of climate
7 change [Masson-Delmotte, V. et al., (eds.)], In Press.
8 IPCC, 2018b: Global Warming of 1.5 °C an IPCC special report on the impacts of global warming of
9 1.5 °C above pre-industrial levels and related global greenhouse gas emission pathways, in the
10 context of strengthening the global response to the threat of climate change. [Masson-Delmotte,
11 V. et al., (eds.)]. In Press,.
12 IPCC, 2019a: Summary for Policymakers. In: An IPCC Special Report on climate change,
13 desertification, land degradation, sustainable land management, food security, and greenhouse
14 gas fluxes in terrestrial ecosystems [P.R. Shukla, J. Skea, E. Calvo Buendia, V. Masson-Delmotte,
S
15 H.- O. Pörtner, D. C. Roberts, P. Zhai, R. Slade, S. Connors, R. van Diemen, M. Ferrat, E.
IT
16 Haughey, S. Luz, S. Neogi, M. Pathak, J. Petzold, J. Portugal Pereira, P. Vyas, E. Huntley, K.
AL N
17 Kissick, J.M., (ed.)], In Press, p. pp. 43.
ED
18 IPCC, 2019b: IPCC Special Report on the Ocean and Cryosphere in a Changing Climate. [Pörtner, H.-
N IO
19 O. et al., (eds.)]. In Press,.
20 IPCC, 2019c: Climate Change and Land: an IPCC special report on climate change, desertification,
FI S
21 land degradation, sustainable land management, food security, and greenhouse gas fluxes in
R
22 terrestrial ecosystems. [Shukla, P.R. et al., (eds.)]. In press,.
TO E
23 IRENA, 2020a: Renewable Power Generation Costs in 2019. , Masdar City, UAE,.
24 IRENA, 2020b: Renewable Electricity Capacity and Generation Statistics. , Masdar City, UAE,.
T DV
25 Islam, M., K. Kanemoto, and S. Managi, 2016: Impact of Trade Openness and Sector Trade on
26 Embodied Greenhouse Gases Emissions and Air Pollutants. J. Ind. Ecol., 20(3), 494–505,
27 doi:10.1111/jiec.12455.
EC TE
28 Ismer, R., M. Haussner, K. Neuhoff, and W. W. Acworth, 2016: Inclusion of Consumption into
29 Emissions Trading Systems: Legal Design and Practical Administration. SSRN Electron. J., ,
30 doi:10.2139/ssrn.2784169.
BJ P
31 IWG, 2021: Technical Support Document: Social Cost of Carbon, Methane, and Nitrous Oxide Interim
E
1 North American Politics, The MIT Press, Cambridge MA, pp. 218–240.
2 Jonsson, A. K., and A. Nilsson, 2014: Exploring the relationship between values and Pro-Environmental
3 behaviour: The infuence of locus of control. Environ. Values, 23(3), 297–314,
4 doi:10.3197/096327114X13947900181752.
5 Jordan, A., D. Huitema, J. Schoenefeld, H. van Asselt, and J. Forster, 2018: Governing Climate Change
6 Polycentrically. In: Governing Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK,
7 pp. 3–26.
8 Jordan, A. J. et al., 2015: Emergence of polycentric climate governance and its future prospects. Nat.
9 Clim. Chang., 5(11), 977–982, doi:10.1038/nclimate2725.
10 Jost, C. et al., 2016: Understanding gender dimensions of agriculture and climate change in smallholder
11 farming communities. Clim. Dev., 8(2), 133–144, doi:10.1080/17565529.2015.1050978.
12 Kahler, M., 2017: Domestic Sources of Transnational Climate Governance. Int. Interact., 43(1), 156–
13 174, doi:10.1080/03050629.2017.1251687.
S
14 Kahneman, D., 2003: Maps of Bounded Rationality: Psychology for Behavioral Economics. Am. Econ.
IT
15 Rev., 93(5), 1449–1475, doi:10.1257/000282803322655392.
AL N
16 Kahneman, D., and A. Tversky, 1979: Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk.
ED
N IO
17 Econometrika, 47, 263-291. Econometrica, , doi:10.2307/1914185.
18 Kalkuhl, M., O. Edenhofer, and K. Lessmann, 2012: Learning or lock-in: Optimal technology policies
FI S
19 to support mitigation. Resour. Energy Econ., 34(1), 1–23, doi:10.1016/j.reseneeco.2011.08.001.
R
20 Kallis, G., 2019: Socialism Without Growth. Capital. Nat. Social., 30(2), 189–206,
21 doi:10.1080/10455752.2017.1386695.
TO E
22 Kamuti, T., 2015: A Critique of the Green Economy: Approach in the Wildlife Ranching Sector in
T DV
26 Kanie, N., and F. Biermann, Governing through goals : sustainable development goals as governance
27 innovation. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 333 pp.
28 Karlsson, M., and M. Gilek, 2020: Mind the gap: Coping with delay in environmental governance.
BJ P
30 Karlsson, M., E. Alfredsson, and N. Westling, 2020: Climate policy co-benefits: a review. Clim. Policy,
SU C
S
14 23(4), 531–548, doi:10.1080/09644016.2013.870067.
IT
15 Keohane, R. O., and D. G. Victor, 2011: The Regime Complex for Climate Change. Perspect. Polit.,
AL N
16 9(1), 7–23, doi:10.1017/S1537592710004068.
ED
N IO
17 Keohane, R. O., and M. Oppenheimer, 2016: Paris: Beyond the Climate Dead End through Pledge and
18 Review? Polit. Gov., 4(3), 142–151, doi:10.17645/pag.v4i3.634.
FI S
19 Keohane, R. O., and D. G. Victor, 2016: Cooperation and discord in global climate policy. Nat. Clim.
20 Chang., 6(6), 570–575, doi:10.1038/nclimate2937.
R
21 Keynes, J. M., 1936: The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. 1st ed. Palgrave
TO E
27 Former UNFCCC leaders take stock of thirty years of international climate change negotiations.
28 Clim. Policy, 21(5), 593–603, doi:10.1080/14693062.2020.1860567.
BJ P
29 Kivimaa, P., M. Hildén, D. Huitema, A. Jordan, and J. Newig, 2017: Experiments in climate governance
30 – A systematic review of research on energy and built environment transitions. J. Clean. Prod.,
E
32 Klausbruckner, C., H. Annegarn, L. R. F. Henneman, and P. Rafaj, 2016: A policy review of synergies
AC
33 and trade-offs in South African climate change mitigation and air pollution control strategies.
34 Environ. Sci. Policy, 57, 70–78, doi:10.1016/j.envsci.2015.12.001.
35 Klenert, D., and L. Mattauch, 2016: How to make a carbon tax reform progressive: The role of
36 subsistence consumption. Econ. Lett., 138, 100–103, doi:10.1016/J.ECONLET.2015.11.019.
37 Klenert, D. et al., 2018: Making carbon pricing work for citizens. Nat. Clim. Chang., 8(8), 669–677,
38 doi:10.1038/s41558-018-0201-2.
39 Klenert, D., F. Funke, L. Mattauch, and B. O’Callaghan, 2020: Five Lessons from COVID-19 for
40 Advancing Climate Change Mitigation. Environ. Resour. Econ., 76(4), 751–778,
41 doi:10.1007/s10640-020-00453-w.
42 Klinsky, S., and H. Winkler, 2014: Equity, sustainable development and climate policy. Clim. Policy,
43 14(1), 1–7, doi:10.1080/14693062.2014.859352.
44 Klinsky, S., and H. Winkler, 2018: Building equity in: strategies for integrating equity into modelling
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-85 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 for a 1.5°C world. Philos. Trans. A. Math. Phys. Eng. Sci., 376(2119), doi:10.1098/rsta.2016.0461.
2 Klinsky, S. et al., 2017: Why equity is fundamental in climate change policy research. Glob. Environ.
3 Chang., 44, 170–173, doi:10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2016.08.002.
4 Knapp, V., and D. Pevec, 2018: Promises and limitations of nuclear fission energy in combating climate
5 change. Energy Policy, 120, 94–99, doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2018.05.027.
6 Koasidis, K. et al., 2020: The UK and German Low-Carbon Industry Transitions from a Sectoral
7 Innovation and System Failures Perspective. Energies, 13(19), 4994, doi:10.3390/en13194994.
8 Köberle, A. C., 2019: The Value of BECCS in IAMs: a Review. Curr. Sustain. Energy Reports, 6(4),
9 107–115, doi:10.1007/s40518-019-00142-3.
10 Köberle, A. C., P. R. R. Rochedo, A. F. P. Lucena, A. Szklo, and R. Schaeffer, 2020: Brazil’s emission
11 trajectories in a well-below 2 °C world: the role of disruptive technologies versus land-based
12 mitigation in an already low-emission energy system. Clim. Change, 162(4), 1823–1842,
13 doi:10.1007/s10584-020-02856-6.
S
14 Koch, M., 2012: Capitalism and Climate Change. Palgrave Macmillan UK, London, UK,.
IT
15 Köhler, J. et al., 2018: Modelling Sustainability Transitions: An Assessment of Approaches and
AL N
16 Challenges. J. Artif. Soc. Soc. Simulation, 21, 8, doi:10.18564/jasss.3629.
ED
N IO
17 Köhler, J. et al., 2019: An agenda for sustainability transitions research: State of the art and future
18 directions. Environ. Innov. Soc. Transitions, 31, 1–32,
FI S
19 doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eist.2019.01.004.
R
20 Kooiman, J., 2003: Governing as Governance Governing as governance. 1st ed. SAGE Publications
21 Ltd, London, UK,.
TO E
22 Kotzé, L. J., 2018: Chapter 3: The Sustainable Development Goals: an existential critique alongside
T DV
23 three new-millennial analytical paradigms. In: Sustainable Development Goals Law, Theory and
24 Implementation [French, D. and L.J. Kotzé, (eds.)], Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, pp. 41–65.
25 Kramer, G. J., 2018: Energy scenarios—Exploring disruption and innovation. Energy Res. Soc. Sci.,
26 37, 247–250, doi:10.1016/j.erss.2017.10.047.
EC TE
27 Kurz, T., B. Gardner, B. Verplanken, and C. Abraham, 2015: Habitual Behaviors or Patterns of
28 Practice? Explaining and Changing Repetitive Climate-Relevant Actions. WIREs Clim. Chang.,
BJ P
30 Kuzemko, C., M. Lockwood, C. Mitchell, and R. Hoggett, 2016: Governing for sustainable energy
31 system change: Politics, contexts and contingency. Energy Res. Soc. Sci., 12, 96–105,
SU C
32 doi:10.1016/j.erss.2015.12.022.
AC
33 Kverndokk, S., 2018: Climate Policies, Distributional Effects and Transfers Between Rich and Poor
34 Countries. Int. Rev. Environ. Resour. Econ., 12(2–3), 129–176, doi:10.1561/101.00000100.
35 Kverndokk, S., E. Nævdal, and L. Nøstbakken, 2014: The trade-off between intra- and intergenerational
36 equity in climate policy. Eur. Econ. Rev., 69, 40–58, doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2014.01.007.
37 Kyle, J., F. Sussman, A. Kindle, J. Kuna, and B. Hurley, 2016: Multi-Scale Economic Methodologies
38 and Scenarios Workshop. , Washington D.C, USA,.
39 Laakso, S., A. Berg, and M. Annala, 2017: Dynamics of experimental governance: A meta-study of
40 functions and uses of climate governance experiments. J. Clean. Prod., 169, 8–16,
41 doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.04.140.
42 Laborde Debucquet, D., and W. Martin, 2017: Formulas for failure? Were the Doha tariff formulas too
43 ambitious for success?: In: Agriculture, development, and the global trading system: 2000– 2015
44 [Bouët, A. and D. Laborde Debucquet, (eds.)], International Food Policy Research Institute
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-86 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 (IFPRI).
2 Lachapelle, E., and M. Paterson, 2013: Drivers of national climate policy. Clim. Policy, 13(5), 547–
3 571, doi:10.1080/14693062.2013.811333.
4 Lachapelle, E., R. MacNeil, and M. Paterson, 2017: The political economy of decarbonisation: from
5 green energy ‘race’ to green ‘division of labour.’ New Polit. Econ., 22(3), 311–327,
6 doi:10.1080/13563467.2017.1240669.
7 Lamb, W. F., and J. K. Steinberger, 2017: Human well‐being and climate change mitigation. WIREs
8 Clim. Chang., 8(6), doi:10.1002/wcc.485.
9 Lamb, W. F., and J. C. Minx, 2020: The political economy of national climate policy: Architectures of
10 constraint and a typology of countries. Energy Res. Soc. Sci., 64, 101429,
11 doi:10.1016/j.erss.2020.101429.
12 Lamb, W. F. et al., 2021: A review of trends and drivers of greenhouse gas emissions by sector from
13 1990 to 2018. Environ. Res. Lett., 16(7), 073005, doi:10.1088/1748-9326/ABEE4E.
S
14 Lange, A., C. Vogt, and A. Ziegler, 2007: On the importance of equity in international climate policy:
IT
15 An empirical analysis. Energy Econ., 29(3), 545–562, doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2006.09.002.
AL N
16 Lange, A., A. Löschel, C. Vogt, and A. Ziegler, 2010: On the self-interested use of equity in
ED
N IO
17 international climate negotiations. Eur. Econ. Rev., 54(3), 359–375,
18 doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2009.08.006.
FI S
19 Latouche, S., 2018: The Path to Degrowth for a Sustainable Society. In: Factor X Challenges,
20 Implementation Strategies and Examples for a Sustainable Use of Natural Resources, Springer,
R
21 New York, NY, pp. 277–284.
TO E
22 Lazarus, R. J., 2009: Super Wicked Problems and Climate Change: Restraining the Present to Liberate
23 the Future. Georg. Law Fac. Publ. Other Work., 159.
T DV
24 Le Billon, P., P. Lujala, D. Singh, V. Culbert, and B. Kristoffersen, 2021: Fossil fuels, climate change,
25 and the COVID-19 crisis: pathways for a just and green post-pandemic recovery. Clim. Policy, ,
26 1–10, doi:10.1080/14693062.2021.1965524.
EC TE
27 Le Quéré, C. et al., 2020: Temporary reduction in daily global CO2 emissions during the COVID-19
28 forced confinement. Nat. Clim. Chang., 10(7), 647–653, doi:10.1038/s41558-020-0797-x.
BJ P
29 Leach, M. et al., 2018: Equity and sustainability in the anthropocene: A social-ecological systems
30 perspective on their intertwined futures. Glob. Sustain., 1, doi:10.1017/sus.2018.12.
E
31 Legrand, M. D. P., and H. Hagemann, 2017: Retrospectives: Do Productive Recessions Show the
SU C
1 doi:10.1111/1467-6486.00361.
2 Levy, D. L., and A. Spicer, 2013: Contested imaginaries and the cultural political economy of climate
3 change. Organization, 20(5), 659–678, doi:10.1177/1350508413489816.
4 Li, F. G. N., E. Trutnevyte, and N. Strachan, 2015: A review of socio-technical energy transition (STET)
5 models. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change, 100, 290–305, doi:10.1016/j.techfore.2015.07.017.
6 Li, Q., and W. A. Pizer, 2018: The discount rate for public policy over the distant future. , Cambridge
7 MA,.
8 Lianos, M., 2019: Yellow vests and European democracy. Eur. Soc., 21(1), 1–3,
9 doi:10.1080/14616696.2019.1570055.
10 Lin, J., and D. A. Kysar, 2020: Climate Change Litigation in the Asia Pacific. [Lin, J. and D.A. Kysar,
11 (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK,.
12 Liu, L.-J. et al., 2021: Combining economic recovery with climate change mitigation: A global
S
13 evaluation of financial instruments. Econ. Anal. Policy, 72, 438–453,
14 doi:10.1016/j.eap.2021.09.009.
IT
15 Liu, L., T. Wu, and Y. Huang, 2017: An equity-based framework for defining national responsibilities
AL N
16 in global climate change mitigation. Clim. Dev., 9(2), 152–163,
ED
N IO
17 doi:10.1080/17565529.2015.1085358.
18 Liu, Z. et al., 2020: Near-real-time monitoring of global CO2 emissions reveals the effects of the
FI S
19 COVID-19 pandemic. Nat. Commun., 11(1), 1–12, doi:10.1038/s41467-020-18922-7.
R
20 Llavador, H., J. E. Roemer, and J. Silvestre, 2015: Sustainability for a Warming Planet. Harvard
21 University Press, Cambridge, MA,.
TO E
22 Lo, A. Y., 2010: Active conflict or passive coherence? The political economy of climate change in
T DV
27 Lohmann, L., 2017: Toward a Political Economy of Neoliberal Climate Science. In: The Routledge
28 Handbook of the Political Economy of Science, Routledge, Abingdon-on-Thames, UK, pp. 305–
BJ P
29 316.
E
30 Lohmann, L., 2019: Neoliberalism, law and nature. In: Research Handbook on Law, Environment and
31 the Global South, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, UK, pp. 32–63.
SU C
32 Lontzek, T. S., Y. Cai, K. L. Judd, and T. M. Lenton, 2015: Stochastic integrated assessment of climate
AC
33 tipping points indicates the need for strict climate policy. Nat. Clim. Chang., 5(5), 441–444,
34 doi:10.1038/nclimate2570.
35 Loorbach, D., 2010: Transition Management for Sustainable Development: A Prescriptive,
36 Complexity-Based Governance Framework. Governance, 23(1), 161–183,
37 doi:https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0491.2009.01471.x.
38 Lu, S., X. Bai, X. Zhang, W. Li, and Y. Tang, 2019: The impact of climate change on the sustainable
39 development of regional economy. J. Clean. Prod., 233, 1387–1395,
40 doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.06.074.
41 Maestre-Andrés, S., S. Drews, and J. van den Bergh, 2019: Perceived fairness and public acceptability
42 of carbon pricing: a review of the literature. Clim. Policy, 19(9), 1186–1204,
43 doi:10.1080/14693062.2019.1639490.
44 Mainali, B., J. Luukkanen, S. Silveira, and J. Kaivo-oja, 2018: Evaluating Synergies and Trade-Offs
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-88 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
S
14 (eds.)], Pluto Press, London, UK, pp. 108–118.
IT
15 Malm, A., 2016: Fossil Capital: The Rise of Steam Power and the Roots of Global Warming. [Empson,
AL N
16 M., (ed.)]. Verso Books, London, UK,.
ED
N IO
17 Mangat, R., S. Dalby, and M. Paterson, 2018: Divestment discourse: war, justice, morality and money.
18 Env. Polit., 27(2), 187–208, doi:10.1080/09644016.2017.1413725.
FI S
19 Marchau, V. A. W. J., R. J. Lempert, W. E. Walker, P. J. T. M. Bloemen, and S. W. Popper, 2019:
20 Decision Making under Deep Uncertainty. Springer International Publishing,.
R
21 Marcu, A., 2017: Article 6 of the Paris Agreement: Reflections on Party Submissions before Marrakech.
TO E
22 International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development (ICTSD), Geneva, Switzerland,.
T DV
23 Markkanen, S., and A. Anger-Kraavi, 2019: Social impacts of climate change mitigation policies and
24 their implications for inequality. Clim. Policy, 19(7), 827–844,
25 doi:10.1080/14693062.2019.1596873.
26 Marmot, M., and R. Bell, 2018: The Sustainable Development Goals and Health Equity. Epidemiology,
EC TE
29 167–175, doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.03.176.
E
30 Marshall, G., 2014: Don’t even think about it: why our brains are wired to ignore climate change.
31 Bloomsbury Publishing, London, UK, 260 pp.
SU C
32 Martinez, G. S. et al., 2019: Delegation size and equity in climate negotiations: An exploration of key
AC
S
13 Mehling, M. A., H. Van Asselt, K. Das, S. Droege, and C. Verkuijl, 2019: Designing Border Carbon
IT
14 Adjustments for Enhanced Climate Action. Am. J. Int. Law, 113(3), 433–481,
15 doi:10.1017/ajil.2019.22.
AL N
ED
16 Meng, J. et al., 2018: The rise of South-South trade and its effect on global CO2 emissions. Nat.
N IO
17 Commun., 9(1), doi:10.1038/s41467-018-04337-y.
18 Meng, K. C., and A. Rode, 2019: The Social Cost of Lobbying over Climate Policy. Nat. Clim. Chang.,
FI S
19 9(6), 472–476, doi:10.1038/s41558-019-0489-6.
R
20 Mercure, J. F. et al., 2021: Risk-opportunity analysis for transformative policy design and appraisal.
21 Glob. Environ. Chang., 70, 102359, doi:10.1016/J.GLOENVCHA.2021.102359.
TO E
22 Metcalf, G. E., 2009: Market-based Policy Options to Control U.S. Greenhouse Gas Emissions. J. Econ.
T DV
26 doi:10.1080/14693062.2018.1426977.
27 Michaelowa, K., and A. Michaelowa, 2017: Transnational Climate Governance Initiatives: Designed
28 for Effective Climate Change Mitigation? Int. Interact., 43(1), 129–155,
BJ P
29 doi:10.1080/03050629.2017.1256110.
E
30 Michelsen, G., M. Adomßent, P. Martens, and M. von Hauff, 2016: Sustainable Development –
SU C
31 Background and Context. In: Sustainability Science, Springer Netherlands, Heidelberg, Germany,
32 pp. 5–29.
AC
33 Mildenberger, M., 2020: Carbon Captured: How Business and Labor Control Climate Politics. MIT
34 Press, Cambridge MA,.
35 Milkoreit, M., 2017: Imaginary politics: Climate change and making the future. Elem Sci Anth, 5(0),
36 62, doi:10.1525/elementa.249.
37 Milkoreit, M., and K. Haapala, 2019: The global stocktake: design lessons for a new review and
38 ambition mechanism in the international climate regime. Int. Environ. Agreements Polit. Law
39 Econ., 19(1), 89–106, doi:10.1007/s10784-018-9425-x.
40 Millar, H., E. Bourgeois, S. Bernstein, and M. Hoffmann, 2020: Self-reinforcing and self-undermining
41 feedbacks in subnational climate policy implementation. Env. Polit., 0(0), 1–20,
42 doi:10.1080/09644016.2020.1825302.
43 Minsky, H. P., 1986: Stabilizing an unstable economy. Yale University Press, New Haven, CT,.
1 Mitchell, T., and S. Maxwell, 2010: Defining climate compatible development. , London, UK, 1–6 pp.
2 Monasterolo, I., 2017: A climate stress-test of financial institutions. Green Finance Research Advances,
3 Vienna, Austria, Vienna University of Economics and Business.
4 Moore, F. C., U. Baldos, T. Hertel, and D. Diaz, 2017: New science of climate change impacts on
5 agriculture implies higher social cost of carbon. Nat. Commun., 8(1), 1607, doi:10.1038/s41467-
6 017-01792-x.
7 Moore, G. F. et al., 2019: From complex social interventions to interventions in complex social systems:
8 Future directions and unresolved questions for intervention development and evaluation.
9 Evaluation, 25(1), 23–45, doi:10.1177/1356389018803219.
10 Mora, C. et al., 2018: Bitcoin emissions alone could push global warming above 2°C. Nat. Clim.
11 Chang., 8(11), 931–933, doi:10.1038/s41558-018-0321-8.
12 Mori, A. S., K. P. Lertzman, and L. Gustafsson, 2017: Biodiversity and ecosystem services in forest
13 ecosystems: a research agenda for applied forest ecology. J. Appl. Ecol., 54(1), 12–27,
S
14 doi:10.1111/1365-2664.12669.
IT
15 Moss, R. et al., 2016: Understanding dynamics and resilience in complex interdependent systems. ,
AL N
16 Washington D.C., https://www.globalchange.gov/browse/reports/understanding-dynamics-and-
ED
17 resilience-complex-interdependent-systems.
18
19 N IO
Mugambiwa, S. S., and H. M. Tirivangasi, 2017: Climate change: A threat towards achieving
“sustainable development goal number two” (end hunger, achieve food security and improved
FI S
20 nutrition and promote sustainable agriculture) in South Africa. Jamba J. Disaster Risk Stud., 9(1),
R
21 doi:10.4102/jamba.v9i1.350.
22 Mulugetta, Y., and F. Urban, 2010: Deliberating on low carbon development. Energy Policy, 38(12),
TO E
23 7546–7549, doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.05.049.
T DV
24 Myhre, G., C. E. L. Myhre, B. H. Samset, and T. Storelvmo, 2013: Aerosols and their Relation to Global
25 Climate and Climate Sensitivity. Nat. Educ. Knowl., 4(7).
26 Mylan, J., 2018: Sustainable Consumption in Everyday Life: A Qualitative Study of UK Consumer
EC TE
30 doi:10.1177/1075547018776019.
E
31 Naegele, H., and A. Zaklan, 2019: Does the EU ETS cause carbon leakage in European manufacturing?
SU C
33 Najam, A., 2005: Developing Countries and Global Environmental Governance: From Contestation to
34 Participation to Engagement. Int. Environ. Agreements Polit. Law Econ., 5(3), 303–321,
35 doi:10.1007/s10784-005-3807-6.
36 Nakicenovic, N. et al., 2000: Emissions scenarios - special report of the Intergovernmental Panel on
37 Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK,.
38 Nash, N. et al., 2017: Climate-relevant behavioral spillover and the potential contribution of social
39 practice theory. Wiley Interdiscip. Rev. Clim. Chang., 8(6), doi:10.1002/wcc.481.
40 Nash, S. L., and R. Steurer, 2019: Taking stock of Climate Change Acts in Europe: living policy
41 processes or symbolic gestures? Clim. Policy, 19(8), 1052–1065,
42 doi:10.1080/14693062.2019.1623164.
43 Nasiritousi, N., and K. Bäckstrand, 2019: International Climate Politics in the post-Paris era. ,
44 Stockholm, Sweden, 1–19 pp.
1 National Academies of Sciences, 2021: Reflecting Sunlight. National Academies Press, Washington,
2 D.C., USA,.
3 Nelson, R. R., and S. G. Winter, 1982: An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Harvard
4 University Press, Cambridge, USA,.
5 Nesshöver, C. et al., 2017: The science, policy and practice of nature-based solutions: An
6 interdisciplinary perspective. Sci. Total Environ., 579, 1215–1227,
7 doi:10.1016/j.scitotenv.2016.11.106.
8 Netra, C. et al., 2018: Governing solar radiation management. , Washington DC, USA,.
9 Neuteleers, S., and B. Engelen, 2015: Talking money: How market-based valuation can undermine
10 environmental protection. Ecol. Econ., 117, 253–260, doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2014.06.022.
11 Neville, K. J., J. Cook, J. Baka, K. Bakker, and E. S. Weinthal, 2019: Can shareholder advocacy shape
12 energy governance? The case of the US antifracking movement. Rev. Int. Polit. Econ., 26(1), 104–
13 133, doi:10.1080/09692290.2018.1488757.
S
14 Newbery, D., 2018: Evaluating the case for supporting renewable electricity. Energy Policy, 120, 684–
IT
15 696, doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2018.05.029.
AL N
16 Newell, P., and M. Paterson, 1998: A climate for business: global warming, the state and capital. Rev.
ED
N IO
17 Int. Polit. Econ., 5(4), 679–703, doi:10.1080/096922998347426.
18 Newell, P., and M. Paterson, 2010: Climate Capitalism: Global Warming and the Transformation of
FI S
19 the Global Economy. Cambridge University Press, Cambrudge UK,.
Newell, P., and D. Mulvaney, 2013: The political economy of the “just transition.", Geogr. J., 179(2),
R
20
21 132–140 doi:10.1111/geoj.12008.
TO E
22 Newell, P., and O. Taylor, 2018: Contested landscapes: the global political economy of climate-smart
T DV
26 Newman, P., 2020: COVID, CITIES and CLIMATE: Historical Precedents and Potential Transitions
27 for the New Economy. Urban Sci., 4(3), 32, doi:10.3390/urbansci4030032.
28 Newman, P., T. Beatley, and H. Boyer, 2017: Resilient Cities. Island Press/Center for Resource
BJ P
30 NGFS, 2020: Climate Scenarios for central banks and supervisors. , Paris, France,
SU C
31 https://www.ngfs.net/en/ngfs-climate-scenarios-central-banks-and-supervisors.
32 Nikas, A., H. Doukas, and A. Papandreou, 2019: A Detailed Overview and Consistent Classification of
AC
33 Climate-Economy Models. In: Understanding Risks and Uncertainties in Energy and Climate
34 Policy: Multidisciplinary Methods and Tools for a Low Carbon Society [Doukas, H., A. Flamos,
35 and J. Lieu, (eds.)], Springer International Publishing, Cham, pp. 1–54.
36 Nikas, A. et al., 2020: The desirability of transitions in demand: Incorporating behavioural and societal
37 transformations into energy modelling. Energy Res. Soc. Sci., 70, 101780,
38 doi:10.1016/j.erss.2020.101780.
39 Nikoleris, A., J. Stripple, and P. Tenngart, 2017: Narrating climate futures: shared socioeconomic
40 pathways and literary fiction. Clim. Change, 143(3–4), 307–319, doi:10.1007/s10584-017-2020-
41 2.
42 Nordhaus, W., 2007: Critical assumptions in the stern review on climate change. Science , 317(5835),
43 201–202, doi:10.1126/science.1137316.
44 Nordhaus, W., 2008: A Question of Balance. Yale University Press, New Haven, CT,.
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-92 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 Nordhaus, W. D., 1992: An optimal transition path for controlling greenhouse gases. Science ,
2 doi:10.1126/science.258.5086.1315.
3 Norgaard, K. M., 2011: Living in Denial: Climate Change, Emotions, and Everyday Life. 1st ed. MIT
4 Press, Cambridge MA,.
5 Nunan, F., 2017: Making Climate Compatible Development Happen. 1st ed. [Nunan, F., (ed.)].
6 Routledge, Abingdon-on-Thames, UK,.
7 O’Hara, P. A., 2009: Political economy of climate change, ecological destruction and uneven
8 development. Ecol. Econ., 69(2), 223–234, doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2009.09.015.
9 O’Neill, B. C. et al., 2014: A new scenario framework for climate change research: the concept of
10 shared socioeconomic pathways. Clim. Change, 122(3), 387–400, doi:10.1007/s10584-013-0905-
11 2.
12 Obergassel, W., L. Hermwille, and S. Oberthür, 2020: Harnessing international climate governance to
13 drive a sustainable recovery from the COVID-19 pandemic. Clim. Policy, , 1–9,
S
14 doi:10.1080/14693062.2020.1835603.
IT
15 Ojekunle, Z. O. et al., 2015: Global Climate Change: The Empirical Study of the Sensitivity Model in
AL N
16 China’s Sustainable Development, Part 2. Energy Sources, Part A Recover. Util. Environ. Eff.,
ED
17 37(8), 861–869, doi:10.1080/15567036.2013.840695.
18
19 N IO
Okereke, C., 2017: A six-component model for assessing procedural fairness in the Intergovernmental
Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). Clim. Change, 145(3–4), 509–522, doi:10.1007/s10584-017-
FI S
20 2106-x.
R
21 Okereke, C., 2018: Equity and Justice in Polycentric Climate Governance. In: Governing Climate
22 Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 320–337.
TO E
23 Okereke, C., and D. Russel, 2010: Regulatory Pressure and Competitive Dynamics: Carbon
T DV
27 global economy: introduction to special issue. Int. Environ. Agreements Polit. Law Econ., 15(1),
28 5–11, doi:10.1007/s10784-014-9264-3.
29 Okereke, C., and P. Coventry, 2016: Climate justice and the international regime: before, during, and
BJ P
30 after Paris. Wiley Interdiscip. Rev. Clim. Chang., 7(6), 834–851, doi:10.1002/wcc.419.
E
31 Okereke, C., and A.-B. S. Massaquoi, 2017: Climate change, environment and development. In:
SU C
34 Okereke, C., H. Bulkeley, and H. Schroeder, 2009: Conceptualizing climate governance beyond the
35 international regime. Glob. Environ. Polit., 9(1), doi:10.1162/glep.2009.9.1.58.
36 Okereke, C. et al., 2019: Governing green industrialisation in Africa: Assessing key parameters for a
37 sustainable socio-technical transition in the context of Ethiopia. World Dev., 115, 279–290,
38 doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2018.11.019.
39 Onder, H., 2012: What does trade have to do with climate change? VOX CEPR Policy Portal,.
40 https://voxeu.org/article/what-does-trade-have-do-climate-change.
41 Osili, U. O., and B. T. Long, 2008: Does female schooling reduce fertility? Evidence from Nigeria. J.
42 Dev. Econ., 87(1), 57–75, doi:10.1016/j.jdeveco.2007.10.003.
43 Page, B., G. Turan, and A. Zapantis, 2019: Global Status of CCS 2019. , Docklands, Australia,
44 https://www.globalccsinstitute.com/wp-
45 content/uploads/2019/12/GCC_GLOBAL_STATUS_REPORT_2019.pdf.
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-93 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 Pan, X., F. Teng, Y. Ha, and G. Wang, 2014: Equitable Access to Sustainable Development: Based on
2 the comparative study of carbon emission rights allocation schemes. Appl. Energy, 130, 632–640,
3 doi:10.1016/j.apenergy.2014.03.072.
4 Parker, C. F., C. Karlsson, and M. Hjerpe, 2017: Assessing the European Union’s global climate change
5 leadership: from Copenhagen to the Paris Agreement. J. Eur. Integr., 39(2), 239–252,
6 doi:10.1080/07036337.2016.1275608.
7 Parrique, T. et al., 2019: Decoupling Debunked: Evidence and arguments against green growth as a
8 sole strategy for sustainability. , Brussels, Belgium,.
9 Paterson, M., 2021: Climate change and international political economy: between collapse and
10 transformation. Rev. Int. Polit. Econ., 28(2), 394–405, doi:10.1080/09692290.2020.1830829.
11 Paterson, M., and X. P‐Laberge, 2018: Political economies of climate change. WIREs Clim. Chang.,
12 9(2), e506, doi:10.1002/wcc.506.
13 Patterson, J. J. et al., 2018: Political feasibility of 1.5°C societal transformations: the role of social
S
14 justice. Curr. Opin. Environ. Sustain., 31, 1–9, doi:10.1016/j.cosust.2017.11.002.
IT
15 Pearse, R., 2017: Pricing Carbon in Australia: Contestation, the State and Market Failure. Routledge,
AL N
16 Abingdon-on-Thames, UK,.
ED
N IO
17 Peel, J., and H. Osofksy, 2020: Climate Change Litigation. Annu. Rev. Law Soc. Sci., 16, 8.1----8.18.
18 Pelling, M., and D. Manuel-Navarrete, 2011: From Resilience to Transformation: the Adaptive Cycle
FI S
19 in Two Mexican Urban Centers. Ecol. Soc., 16(2).
R
20 Perez, C., 2001: Technological Revolutions and Financial Capital. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK,.
21 Peters, G. P., J. C. Minx, C. L. Weber, and O. Edenhofer, 2011: Growth in emission transfers via
TO E
22 international trade from 1990 to 2008. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci., 108(21), 8903–8908,
T DV
23 doi:10.1073/pnas.1006388108.
24 Peters, G. P., R. M. Andrew, S. Solomon, and P. Friedlingstein, 2015: Measuring a fair and ambitious
25 climate agreement using cumulative emissions. Environ. Res. Lett., 10(10), doi:10.1088/1748-
26 9326/10/10/105004.
EC TE
27 Pettenger, M. E., 2016: The Social Construction of Climate Change. [Pettenger, M.E., (ed.)]. Routledge,
28 Abingdon-on-Thames, UK,.
BJ P
29 Pezzey, J. C. V, 2018: High unknowability of climate damage valuation means the social cost of carbon
E
31 Pickering, J., F. Jotzo, and P. J. Wood, 2015: Sharing the Global Climate Finance Effort Fairly with
32 Limited Coordination. Glob. Environ. Polit., 15(4), 39–62, doi:10.1162/GLEP_a_00325.
AC
33 Pickering, J., J. S. McGee, T. Stephens, and S. I. Karlsson-Vinkhuyzen, 2018: The impact of the US
34 retreat from the Paris Agreement: Kyoto revisited? Clim. Policy, 18(7), 818–827,
35 doi:10.1080/14693062.2017.1412934.
36 Piggot, G., 2018: The influence of social movements on policies that constrain fossil fuel supply. Clim.
37 Policy, 18(7), 942–954, doi:10.1080/14693062.2017.1394255.
38 Pindyck, R. S., 2013: Climate change policy: What do the models tell us? J. Econ. Lit., 51(3), 860–872,
39 doi:10.1257/jel.51.3.860.
40 Piñero, P., M. Bruckner, H. Wieland, E. Pongrácz, and S. Giljum, 2019: The raw material basis of
41 global value chains: allocating environmental responsibility based on value generation. Econ. Syst.
42 Res., 31(2), 206–227, doi:10.1080/09535314.2018.1536038.
43 Plumwood, V., 2004: Gender, Eco-Feminism and the Environment. In: Controversies in Environmental
44 Sociology [White, R., (ed.)], Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 43–60.
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-94 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 Pollitt, H., R. Lewney, B. Kiss-Dobronyi, and X. Lin, 2021: Modelling the economic effects of COVID-
2 19 and possible green recovery plans: a post-Keynesian approach. Clim. Policy, , 1–15,
3 doi:10.1080/14693062.2021.1965525.
4 Polman, P., 2015: On the Business of Climate Change. Fletcher Forum World Aff., 39(2).
5 Poortinga, W. et al., 2018: European Attitudes to Climate Change and Energy: Topline Results from
6 Round 8 of the European Social Survey. , London,
7 https://www.europeansocialsurvey.org/docs/findings/ESS8_toplines_issue_9_climatechange.pdf
8 .
9 Popp, A. et al., 2017: Land-use futures in the shared socio-economic pathways. Glob. Environ. Chang.,
10 42, 331–345, doi:10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2016.10.002.
11 Pottier, A., J.-C. Hourcade, and E. Espagne, 2014: Modelling the redirection of technical change: The
12 pitfalls of incorporeal visions of the economy. Energy Econ., 42, 213–218,
13 doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2013.12.003.
S
14 Povitkina, M., 2018: The limits of democracy in tackling climate change. Env. Polit., 27(3), 411–432,
IT
15 doi:10.1080/09644016.2018.1444723.
AL N
16 Pradhan, P., L. Costa, D. Rybski, W. Lucht, and J. P. Kropp, 2017: A Systematic Study of Sustainable
ED
17 Development Goal (SDG) Interactions. Earth’s Futur., 5(11), 1169–1179,
N IO
18 doi:10.1002/2017EF000632.
19 Prados de la Escosura, L., 2015: World Human Development: 1870-2007. Rev. Income Wealth, 61(2),
FI S
20 220–247, doi:10.1111/roiw.12104.
R
21 Prinn, R. G., J. M. Reilly, V. J. Karplus, and J. Jenkins, 2017: The MIT Joint Program on the Science
22 and Policy of Global Carbon Pricing under Political Constraints: Insights for Accelerating Clean
TO E
24 Purdon, M., 2017: Neoclassical realism and international climate change politics: moral imperative and
25 political constraint in international climate finance. J. Int. Relations Dev., 20(2), 263–300,
26 doi:10.1057/jird.2013.5.
EC TE
27 Quilcaille, Y., T. Gasser, P. Ciais, F. Lecocq, and M. Obersteiner, 2019: Carbon budgets based on new
28 climate projections of the SSP scenarios and observations. European Geosciences Union (EGU)
29 General Assembly 2019, Vol. 21 of, Vienna, Austria http://pure.iiasa.ac.at/id/eprint/15835/.
BJ P
30 Rabe, B. G., 2018: Can we price carbon? MIT Press, Cambridge MA,.
E
31 Rajamani, L., 2016: The 2015 Paris Agreement: Interplay Between Hard, Soft and Non-Obligations:
SU C
1 Raworth, K., 2018: Doughnut Economics: Seven Ways to Think Like a 21st-Century Economist. Chelsea
2 Green Publishing, Chelsea, USA,.
3 Raymond, L., 2020: Carbon Pricing and Economic Populism: The Case of Ontario. Clim. Policy, 20(9),
4 1127–1140, doi:10.1080/14693062.2020.1782824.
5 Rayner, S., 2012: Uncomfortable knowledge: The social construction of ignorance in science and
6 environmental policy discourses. Econ. Soc., 41(1), 107–125,
7 doi:10.1080/03085147.2011.637335.
8 Raza, M. Q., and A. Khosravi, 2015: A review on artificial intelligence based load demand forecasting
9 techniques for smart grid and buildings. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev., 50, 1352–1372,
10 doi:10.1016/j.rser.2015.04.065.
11 Realmonte, G. et al., 2019: An inter-model assessment of the role of direct air capture in deep mitigation
12 pathways. Nat. Commun., 10(1), 3277, doi:10.1038/s41467-019-10842-5.
13 Reckien, D. et al., 2017: Climate change, equity and the Sustainable Development Goals: an urban
S
14 perspective. Environ. Urban., 29(1), 159–182, doi:10.1177/0956247816677778.
IT
15 Reilly, J. M., Y.-H. H. Chen, and H. D. Jacoby, 2021: The COVID-19 effect on the Paris agreement.
AL N
16 Humanit. Soc. Sci. Commun., 8(1), 16, doi:10.1057/s41599-020-00698-2.
ED
N IO
17 Reisinger, A. et al., 2020: The concept of risk in the IPCC Sixth Assessment Report: a summary of cross-
18 Working Group discussions. , Geneva, Switzerland,.
FI S
19 Rennkamp, B., 2019: Power, coalitions and institutional change in South African climate policy. Clim.
20 Policy, 19(6), 756–770, doi:10.1080/14693062.2019.1591936.
R
21 Ricke, K., L. Drouet, K. Caldeira, and M. Tavoni, 2018: Country-level social cost of carbon. Nat. Clim.
TO E
23 Rietig, K., and T. Laing, 2017: Policy Stability in Climate Governance: The case of the United
24 Kingdom. Environ. Policy Gov., 27(6), 575–587, doi:10.1002/eet.1762.
25 Ringler, C., A. Bhaduri, and R. Lawford, 2013: The nexus across water, energy, land and food (WELF):
26 potential for improved resource use efficiency? Curr. Opin. Environ. Sustain., 5(6), 617–624,
EC TE
27 doi:10.1016/j.cosust.2013.11.002.
28 Rip, A., and R. Kemp, 1998: Technological change. In: Human choice and climate change, Battelle
BJ P
30 Roberts, C., and F. W. Geels, 2019a: Conditions and intervention strategies for the deliberate
31 acceleration of socio-technical transitions: lessons from a comparative multi-level analysis of two
SU C
32 historical case studies in Dutch and Danish heating. Technol. Anal. Strateg. Manag., 7325,
AC
33 doi:10.1080/09537325.2019.1584286.
34 Roberts, C., and F. W. Geels, 2019b: Conditions for politically accelerated transitions: Historical
35 institutionalism, the multi-level perspective, and two historical case studies in transport and
36 agriculture. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change, 140, 221–240, doi:10.1016/j.techfore.2018.11.019.
37 Roberts, C. et al., 2018: The politics of accelerating low-carbon transitions: Towards a new research
38 agenda. Energy Res. Soc. Sci., 44, 304–311, doi:10.1016/j.erss.2018.06.001.
39 Roberts, J. T. et al., 2020: Four agendas for research and policy on emissions mitigation and well-being.
40 Glob. Sustain., 3, e3, doi:10.1017/sus.2019.25.
41 Robinson, M., and T. Shine, 2018: Achieving a climate justice pathway to 1.5 °C. Nat. Clim. Chang.,
42 8(7), 564–569, doi:10.1038/s41558-018-0189-7.
43 Robiou du Pont, Y. et al., 2017: Equitable mitigation to achieve the Paris Agreement goals. Nat. Clim.
44 Chang., 7(1), 38–43, doi:10.1038/nclimate3186.
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-96 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 Rochedo, P. R. R. et al., 2021: Is Green Recovery Enough? Analysing the Impacts of Post-COVID-19
2 Economic Packages. Energies, 14(17), 5567, doi:10.3390/en14175567.
3 Roger, C., T. Hale, and L. Andonova, 2017: The Comparative Politics of Transnational Climate
4 Governance. Int. Interact., 43(1), 1–25, doi:10.1080/03050629.2017.1252248.
5 Romanello, M. et al., 2021: The 2021 report of the Lancet Countdown on health and climate change:
6 code red for a healthy future. Lancet, 398(10311), 1619–1662, doi:10.1016/S0140-
7 6736(21)01787-6.
8 Romer, P. M., 1986: Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth. J. Polit. Econ., 94(5), 1002–1037,
9 doi:10.1086/261420.
10 Rosembloom, D., and J. Markard, 2020: A COVID-19 recovery for climate. Science., 368(6490), 2019–
11 2020, doi:10.1126/science.abc4887.
12 Rosen, R. A., and E. Guenther, 2015: The economics of mitigating climate change: What can we know?
13 Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change, 91, 93–106, doi:10.1016/J.TECHFORE.2014.01.013.
S
14 Rosenbloom, D., B. Haley, and J. Meadowcroft, 2018: Critical choices and the politics of
IT
15 decarbonization pathways: Exploring branching points surrounding low-carbon transitions in
AL N
16 Canadian electricity systems. Energy Res. Soc. Sci., 37, 22–36, doi:10.1016/j.erss.2017.09.022.
ED
N IO
17 Rosendahl, K. E., and D. R. Rubiano, 2019: How Effective is Lithium Recycling as a Remedy for
18 Resource Scarcity? Environ. Resour. Econ., 74(3), 985–1010, doi:10.1007/s10640-019-00356-5.
FI S
19 Rosenschöld, J. M. af, J. G. Rozema, and L. A. Frye-Levine, 2014: Institutional Inertia and Climate
20 Change: A Review of the New Institutionalist Literature. WIREs Clim. Chang., 5(5), 639–648,
R
21 doi:10.1002/wcc.292.
TO E
22 Rotmans, J., R. Kemp, and M. van Asselt, 2001: More evolution than revolution: transition management
23 in public policy. Foresight, 3(1), 15–31, doi:10.1108/14636680110803003.
T DV
24 Routledge, P., A. Cumbers, and K. D. Derickson, 2018: States of just transition: Realising climate
25 justice through and against the state. Geoforum, 88, 78–86, doi:10.1016/j.geoforum.2017.11.015.
26 Rozenberg, J., and M. Fay, 2019: Beyond the Gap : How Countries Can Afford the Infrastructure They
EC TE
27 Need while Protecting the Planet. World Bank, Washington DC, 199 pp.
28 Ruby, M. B., I. Walker, and H. M. Watkins, 2020: Sustainable Consumption: The Psychology of
BJ P
29 Individual Choice, Identity, and Behavior. J. Soc. Issues, 76(1), 8–18, doi:10.1111/josi.12376.
E
30 Ruger, J. P., and R. Horton, 2020: Justice and health: The Lancet–Health Equity and Policy Lab
31 Commission. Lancet, 395(10238), 1680–1681, doi:10.1016/S0140-6736(20)30928-4.
SU C
32 Runhaar, H., B. Wilk, Å. Persson, C. Uittenbroek, and C. Wamsler, 2018: Mainstreaming climate
AC
33 adaptation: taking stock about “what works” from empirical research worldwide. Reg. Environ.
34 Chang., 18(4), 1201–1210, doi:10.1007/s10113-017-1259-5.
35 Sachs, J., G. Schmidt-Traub, C. Kroll, D. Durand-Delacre, and K. Teksoz, 2016: An SDG Index and
36 Dashboards – Global Report. , New York, NY, https://www.sdgindex.org/reports/sdg-index-and-
37 dashboards-2016/.
38 Safarzyńska, K., 2018: Integrating behavioural economics into climate-economy models: some policy
39 lessons. Clim. Policy, 18(4), 485–498, doi:10.1080/14693062.2017.1313718.
40 Sarewitz, D., 2020: Unknown Knowns. Issues Sci. Technol., 37(1), 18–19.
41 Saunders, H. D. et al., 2021: Energy Efficiency: What Has Research Delivered in the Last 40 Years?
42 Annu. Rev. Environ. Resour., 46(1), doi:10.1146/annurev-environ-012320-084937.
43 Scavenius, T. B. B., and S. Rayner, 2018: Institutional Capacity for Climate Change Response: A New
44 Approach to Climate Politics. Routledge. , Abingdon-on-Thames, UK, 164 pp.
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-97 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 Schlosberg, D., L. B. Collins, and S. Niemeyer, 2017: Adaptation policy and community discourse:
2 risk, vulnerability, and just transformation. Env. Polit., 26(3), 413–437,
3 doi:10.1080/09644016.2017.1287628.
4 Schreurs, M. A., 2016: The Paris Climate Agreement and the Three Largest Emitters: China, the United
5 States, and the European Union. Polit. Gov., 4(3), 219, doi:10.17645/pag.v4i3.666.
6 Schultes, A. et al., 2018: Optimal international technology cooperation for the low-carbon
7 transformation. Clim. Policy, 18(9), 1165–1176, doi:10.1080/14693062.2017.1409190.
8 Schumpeter, J. A., 1934a: The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry Into Profits, Credit,
9 Interest, and the Business Cycle. Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA,.
10 Schumpeter, J. A., 1934b: The Theory of Economic Development - An inquiry into Profits, Capital,
11 Credit, Interest and the Business Cycle. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, USA,.
12 Seto, K. C. et al., 2016: Carbon Lock-In: Types, Causes, and Policy Implications. Annu. Rev. Environ.
13 Resour., 41(1), 425–452, doi:10.1146/annurev-environ-110615-085934.
S
14 Settele, J., J. Bishop, and S. G. Potts, 2016: Climate change impacts on pollination. Nat. Plants, 2(7),
IT
15 16092, doi:10.1038/nplants.2016.92.
AL N
16 Setzer, J., and L. C. Vanhala, 2019: Climate change litigation: A review of research on courts and
ED
N IO
17 litigants in climate governance. Wiley Interdiscip. Rev. Clim. Chang., 10(3), e580,
18 doi:10.1002/WCC.580.
FI S
19 Shackleton, R. T., P. Angelstam, B. van der Waal, and M. Elbakidze, 2017: Progress made in managing
20 and valuing ecosystem services: a horizon scan of gaps in research, management and governance.
R
21 Ecosyst. Serv., 27, 232–241, doi:10.1016/j.ecoser.2016.11.020.
TO E
22 Shan, Y., et.al, 2020: Impacts of COVID-19 and fiscal stimuli on global emissions and the Paris
23 Agreement. Nat. Clim. Chang., 11(3), 200–206 , doi:10.1038/s41558-020-00977-5.
T DV
24 Shang, C., T. Wu, G. Huang, and J. Wu, 2019: Weak sustainability is not sustainable: Socioeconomic
25 and environmental assessment of Inner Mongolia for the past three decades. Resour. Conserv.
26 Recycl., 141, 243–252, doi:10.1016/j.resconrec.2018.10.032.
EC TE
27 Sharpe, S., and T. M. Lenton, 2021: Upward-scaling tipping cascades to meet climate goals: plausible
28 grounds for hope. Clim. Policy, 21(4), 421–433, doi:10.1080/14693062.2020.1870097.
BJ P
29 Shemi, A., A. Magumise, S. Ndlovu, and N. Sacks, 2018: Recycling of tungsten carbide scrap metal: A
30 review of recycling methods and future prospects. Miner. Eng., 122, 195–205,
E
31 doi:10.1016/J.MINENG.2018.03.036.
SU C
32 Shepherd, J. G., 2009: Geoengineering the climate: science, governance and uncertainty. , London,
AC
33 UK,.
34 Shi, L. et al., 2016: Roadmap towards justice in urban climate adaptation research. Nat. Clim. Chang.,
35 6(2), 131–137, doi:10.1038/nclimate2841.
36 Shishlov, I., R. Morel, and V. Bellassen, 2016: Compliance of the Parties to the Kyoto Protocol in the
37 first commitment period. Clim. Policy, 16(6), 768–782, doi:10.1080/14693062.2016.1164658.
38 Shove, E., and N. Spurling, 2013: Sustainable practices: Social theory and climate change. Routledge,
39 Abingdon-on-Thames, UK,.
40 Sindico, F., 2015: Is the Paris Agreement Really Legally Binding? , Glasgow, UK,.
41 Singh, H. V., R. Bocca, P. Gomez, S. Dahlke, and M. Bazilian, 2019: The energy transitions index: An
42 analytic framework for understanding the evolving global energy system. Energy Strateg. Rev.,
43 26, 100382, doi:10.1016/J.ESR.2019.100382.
44 Skovgaard, J., S. S. Ferrari, and Å. Knaggård, 2019: Mapping and clustering the adoption of carbon
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-98 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 pricing policies: what polities price carbon and why? Clim. Policy, 19(9), 1173–1185,
2 doi:10.1080/14693062.2019.1641460.
3 Smajgl, A., J. Ward, and L. Pluschke, 2016: The water–food–energy Nexus – Realising a new paradigm.
4 J. Hydrol., 533, 533–540, doi:10.1016/j.jhydrol.2015.12.033.
5 Smidfelt Rosqvist, L., and L. Winslott Hiselius, 2016: Online shopping habits and the potential for
6 reductions in carbon dioxide emissions from passenger transport. J. Clean. Prod., 131, 163–169,
7 doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.05.054.
8 Smit, B. et al., 2001: Adaptation to Climate Change in the Context of Sustainable Development and
9 Equity. In: Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation, and Vulnerability, Cambridge University
10 Press, Cambridge UK, pp. 877–912.
11 Smith, Jackie and Patterson, J., 2018: Global Climate Justice Activism: “The New Protagonists” and
12 their Projects for a Just Transition. In: Ecologically Unequal Exchange: Environmental Injustice
13 in Comparative and Historical Perspective [Frey, R. Scott; Gellert, Paul K.; Dahms, H.F., (ed.)],
S
14 Palgrave Macmillan, New York, pp. 245–272.
IT
15 Song, M., S. Zhu, J. Wang, and J. Zhao, 2020: Share green growth: Regional evaluation of green output
AL N
16 performance in China. Int. J. Prod. Econ., 219, 152–163, doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2019.05.012.
ED
17 Sorman, A. H., E. Turhan, and M. Rosas-Casals, 2020: Democratizing energy, energizing democracy:
N IO
18 Central dimensions surfacing in the debate. Front. Energy Res., 8, 279.
19 Sovacool, B. K., B.-O. Linnér, and M. E. Goodsite, 2015: The political economy of climate adaptation.
FI S
20 Nat. Clim. Chang., 5(7), 616, doi:10.1038/nclimate2665.
R
21 Sovacool, B. K., A. Hook, M. Martiskainen, and L. Baker, 2019: The whole systems energy injustice
22 of four European low-carbon transitions. Glob. Environ. Chang., 58, 101958,
TO E
23 doi:10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2019.101958.
T DV
24 Spence, A., W. Poortinga, and N. Pidgeon, 2012: The Psychological Distance of Climate Change. Risk
25 Anal., 32(6), 957–972, doi:10.1111/j.1539-6924.2011.01695.x.
26 Spijkers, O., 2018: Intergenerational Equity and the Sustainable Development Goals. Sustainability,
EC TE
31 Stehfest, E. et al., 2009: Climate benefits of changing diet. Clim. Change, 95(1), 83–102,
SU C
32 doi:10.1007/s10584-008-9534-6.
AC
33 Stehr, N., 2005: Knowledge Politics: governing the consequences of science and Technology.
34 Routledge, Abingdon-on-Thames, UK,.
35 Steinberger, J. K., W. F. Lamb, and M. Sakai, 2020: Your money or your life? The carbon-development
36 paradox. Environ. Res. Lett., 15(4), 044016, doi:10.1088/1748-9326/ab7461.
37 Stephan, U., M. Patterson, C. Kelly, and J. Mair, 2016: Organizations Driving Positive Social Change.
38 J. Manage., 42(5), 1250–1281, doi:10.1177/0149206316633268.
39 Stern, N., 2007: The economics of climate change: The stern review. Cambridge University Press,
40 Cambridge, UK, 1–692 pp.
41 Stern, N., 2018: Public economics as if time matters: Climate change and the dynamics of policy. J.
42 Public Econ., , doi:10.1016/j.jpubeco.2018.03.006.
43 Stern, N., and J. E. Stiglitz, 2017: Report of the high-level commission on carbon prices. , Washington
44 D.C,.
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-99 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 Stern, N., and A. Valero, 2021: Research policy, Chris Freeman special issue innovation, growth and
2 the transition to net-zero emissions. Res. Policy, 50(9), 104293,
3 doi:10.1016/j.respol.2021.104293.
4 Stern, N., J. E. Stiglitz, and J. Stiglitz, 2021: The Social Cost of Carbon, Risk, Distribution, Market
5 Failures: An alternative approach. , Cambridge, MA,.
6 Stern, N. H., 2015: Why are we waiting? : the logic, urgency, and promise of tackling climate change.
7 MIT Press, Cambridge MA, 406 pp.
8 Stern, P. C., T. Dietz, G. T. Gardner, J. Gilligan, and M. P. Vandenbergh, 2010: Energy Efficiency
9 Merits More Than a Nudge. Science , 328(5976), 308–309, doi:10.1126/science.328.5976.308.
10 Steurer, R., and C. Clar, 2018: The ambiguity of federalism in climate policy-making: how the political
11 system in Austria hinders mitigation and facilitates adaptation. J. Environ. Policy Plan., 20(2),
12 252–265, doi:10.1080/1523908X.2017.1411253.
13 Stevenson, H., and J. S. Dryzek, 2013: Democratizing Global Climate Governance. Cambridge
S
14 University Press, Cambridge, UK,.
IT
15 Stevenson, H., G. Auld, J. I. Allan, L. Elliott, and J. Meadowcroft, 2021: The Practical Fit of Concepts:
AL N
16 Ecosystem Services and the Value of Nature. Glob. Environ. Polit., 21(2), 3–22,
ED
17 doi:10.1162/GLEP_A_00587.
18
19 N IO
Stiglitz, J. E., 2019: Addressing climate change through price and non-price interventions. Eur. Econ.
Rev., 119, 594–612, doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2019.05.007.
FI S
20 Stoddard, I. et al., 2021: Three Decades of Climate Mitigation: Why Haven’t We Bent the Global
R
21 Emissions Curve? Annu. Rev. Environ. Resour., 46(1), 653–689, doi:10.1146/annurev-environ-
22 012220-011104.
TO E
23 Stoerk, T., G. Wagner, and R. E. T. Ward, 2018: Policy Brief—Recommendations for Improving the
T DV
24 Treatment of Risk and Uncertainty in Economic Estimates of Climate Impacts in the Sixth
25 Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Assessment Report. Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy,
26 12(2), 371–376, doi:10.1093/reep/rey005.
EC TE
27 Stokes, L. C., 2013: The politics of renewable energy policies: The case of feed-in tariffs in Ontario,
28 Canada. Energy Policy, 56, 490–500, doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2013.01.009.
29 Stokes, L. C., 2020: Short Circuiting Policy: Interest Groups and the Battle Over Clean Energy and
BJ P
31 Stoll-Kleemann, S., and U. J. Schmidt, 2017: Reducing Meat Consumption in Developed and Transition
SU C
32 Countries to Counter Climate Change and Biodiversity Loss: A Review of Influence Factors. Reg.
33 Environ. Chang., 17(5), 1261–1277, doi:10.1007/s10113-016-1057-5.
AC
34 Strambo, C., and A. C. G. Espinosa, 2020: Extraction and Development: Fossil Fuel Production
35 Narratives and Counternarratives in Colombia. Clim. Policy, 20(8), 931–948,
36 doi:10.1080/14693062.2020.1719810.
37 Stringer, L. C. et al., 2014: Advancing climate compatible development: lessons from southern Africa.
38 Reg Env. Chang., 14, 713–725, doi:10.1007/s10113-013-0533-4.
39 Sudbury, A. W., and E. B. Hutchinson, 2016: A Cost Analysis Of Amazon Prime Air Drone Delivery.
40 J. Econ. Educ., 16(1).
41 Sugiawan, Y., R. Kurniawan, and S. Managi, 2019: Are carbon dioxide emission reductions compatible
42 with sustainable well-being? Appl. Energy, 242(December 2018), 1–11,
43 doi:10.1016/j.apenergy.2019.03.113.
44 Sullivan, R., 2017: Corporate responses to climate change: achieving emissions reduction through
45 regulation, self-regulation and economic incentives. 1st ed. Routledge, Abingdon-on-Thames,
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-100 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
S
13 Taconet, N., C. Guivarch, and A. Pottier, 2019: Social Cost of Carbon under stochastic tipping points:
14 when does risk play a role? , Paris, France,.
IT
15 Tanner, T., and J. Allouche, 2011: Towards a New Political Economy of Climate Change and
AL N
16 Development. IDS Bull., 42(3), 1–14, doi:10.1111/j.1759-5436.2011.00217.x.
ED
N IO
17 TCFD, 2018: Task Force on Financial Disclosures: Status Report. , Basel, Switzerland,.
18 Thackeray, S. J. et al., 2020: Civil disobedience movements such as School Strike for the Climate are
FI S
19 raising public awareness of the climate change emergency. Glob. Chang. Biol., 26(3), 1042–1044,
R
20 doi:10.1111/gcb.14978.
21 Thornbush, M., O. Golubchikov, and S. Bouzarovski, 2013: Sustainable cities targeted by combined
TO E
23 doi:10.1016/j.scs.2013.01.003.
24 Thornton, T. F., and C. Comberti, 2017: Synergies and trade-offs between adaptation, mitigation and
25 development. Clim. Change, 140(1), 5–18, doi:10.1007/s10584-013-0884-3.
EC TE
26 Tian, X., F. Bai, J. Jia, Y. Liu, and F. Shi, 2019: Realizing low-carbon development in a developing
27 and industrializing region: Impacts of industrial structure change on CO2 emissions in southwest
28 China. J. Environ. Manage., 233, 728–738, doi:10.1016/j.jenvman.2018.11.078.
BJ P
29 Tol, R. S. J., 2018: The Economic Impacts of Climate Change. Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy, 12(1), 4–
E
30 25, doi:10.1093/reep/rex027.
SU C
31 Tompkins, E. L. et al., 2013: An investigation of the evidence of benefits from climate compatible
32 development Sustainability Research Institute. , London, UK,.
AC
1 Turhan, E., B. Özkaynak, and C. İ. Aydın, 2019: Coal, ash, and other tales: The making and remaking
2 of the anti-coal movement in Aliağa, Turkey. In: Transforming Socio-Natures in Turkey:
3 Landscapes, State and Environmental Movements, Taylor and Francis, pp. 166–186.
4 Turnheim, B. et al., 2015: Evaluating sustainability transitions pathways: Bridging analytical
5 approaches to address governance challenges. Glob. Environ. Chang., 35, 239–253,
6 doi:10.1016/J.GLOENVCHA.2015.08.010.
7 Turnheim, B., P. Kivimaa, and F. Berkhout, 2018: Innovating Climate Governance. [Turnheim, B., P.
8 Kivimaa, and F. Berkhout, (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press,.
9 UN DESA, 2021: The Sustainable Development Goals Report. , New York, N.Y.,
10 https://unstats.un.org/sdgs/report/2021/.
11 UNEP, 2018a: Emissions Gap Report 2018. United Nations Environment Programme, Nairobi, Kenya,.
12 UNEP, 2018b: Inclusive wealth report 2018: measuring progress towards sustainability. , Nairobi,
13 Kenya, 14 pp.
S
14 UNEP, 2020: Global Climate Litigation Report 2020 Status Review. , Nairobi, Kenya,.
IT
15 UNFCCC, 1992: United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change.
AL N
ED
16 UNFCCC, 2015: Paris Agreement to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change.
17
18
N IO
UNFCCC, 2018a: Talanoa Call for Action by the Presidents of COP23 and COP24. , Katowice, Poland,
https://unfccc.int/sites/default/files/resource/Talanoa Call for Action.pdf.
FI S
19 UNFCCC, 2018b: Silesia Declaration: Solidarity and Just Transition.
R
20 UNHRC, 2018: Report of the Special Rapporteur on the issue of human rights obligations relating to
TO E
21 the enjoyment of a safe, clean, healthy and sustainable environment. , New York, NY,
22 https://undocs.org/en/A/HRC/37/59.
T DV
23 Unruh, G. C., 2000: Understanding carbon lock-in. Energy Policy, 28(12), 817–830,
24 doi:10.1016/S0301-4215(00)00070-7.
25 Urpelainen, J., and T. Van de Graaf, 2018: United States non-cooperation and the Paris agreement.
EC TE
29 van den Berg, N. J. et al., 2019: Improved modelling of lifestyle changes in Integrated Assessment
30 Models: Cross-disciplinary insights from methodologies and theories. Energy Strateg. Rev., 26,
SU C
31 100420, doi:10.1016/j.esr.2019.100420.
AC
32 van den Bergh, J. C. J. M. et al., 2020: A dual-track transition to global carbon pricing. Clim. Policy,
33 20(9), 1057–1069, doi:10.1080/14693062.2020.1797618.
34 van den Bijgaart, I., R. Gerlagh, and M. Liski, 2016: A simple formula for the social cost of carbon. J.
35 Environ. Econ. Manage., 77, 75–94, doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2016.01.005.
36 van der Heijden, J., 2018: From leaders to majority: a frontrunner paradox in built-environment climate
37 governance experimentation. J. Environ. Plan. Manag., 61(8), 1383–1401,
38 doi:10.1080/09640568.2017.1350147.
39 van der Ploeg, F., and A. Rezai, 2019: Simple Rules for Climate Policy and Integrated Assessment.
40 Environ. Resour. Econ., 72(1), 77–108, doi:10.1007/s10640-018-0280-6.
41 van Vuuren, D. P. et al., 2011: The representative concentration pathways: an overview. Clim. Change,
42 109(1–2), 5–31, doi:10.1007/s10584-011-0148-z.
43 van Vuuren, D. P. et al., 2014: A new scenario framework for Climate Change Research: scenario
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-102 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
S
14 46, doi:10.1016/j.cobeha.2021.02.020.
IT
15 Victor, D. G., 2011: Global Warming Gridlock : Creating More Effective Strategies for Protecting the
AL N
16 Planet. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, 358 pp.
ED
N IO
17 Vogt-Schilb, A., G. Meunier, and S. Hallegatte, 2018: When starting with the most expensive option
18 makes sense: Optimal timing, cost and sectoral allocation of abatement investment. J. Environ.
19 Econ. Manage., 88, 210–233, doi:10.1016/J.JEEM.2017.12.001.
FI S
20 Voituriez, T., W. Yao, and M. L. Larsen, 2019: Revising the ‘host country standard’’ principle: a step
R
21 for China to align its overseas investment with the Paris Agreement.’ Clim. Policy, 19(10), 1205–
22 1210, doi:10.1080/14693062.2019.1650702.
TO E
23 Walker, C., 2020: Uneven solidarity: the school strikes for climate in global and intergenerational
T DV
27 Wamsler, C., and S. Pauleit, 2016: Making headway in climate policy mainstreaming and ecosystem-
28 based adaptation: two pioneering countries, different pathways, one goal. Clim. Change, 137(1–
29 2), 71–87, doi:10.1007/s10584-016-1660-y.
BJ P
30 Wang, L., L. Zhao, G. Mao, J. Zuo, and H. Du, 2017: Way to accomplish low carbon development
E
31 transformation: A bibliometric analysis during 1995–2014. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev., 68, 57–
SU C
32 69, doi:10.1016/j.rser.2016.08.021.
AC
33 Wanger, T. C., 2011: The Lithium future-resources, recycling, and the environment. Conserv. Lett.,
34 4(3), 202–206, doi:10.1111/j.1755-263X.2011.00166.x.
35 Wapner, P. K., and H. Elver, 2017: Reimagining climate change. 1st ed. Routledge, Abingdon-on-
36 Thames, UK, 198 pp.
37 Warde, A., 2017: Sustainable Consumption: Practices, Habits and Politics. In: Consumption: A
38 Sociological Analysis [Warde, A., (ed.)], Consumption and Public Life, Palgrave Macmillan UK,
39 London, pp. 181–204.
40 Warlenius, R., 2018: Decolonizing the Atmosphere: The Climate Justice Movement on Climate Debt.
41 J. Environ. Dev., 27(2), 131–155, doi:10.1177/1070496517744593.
42 Weber, E. U., 2015: Climate Change Demands Behavioral Change: What Are the Challenges? Soc. Res.
43 (New. York)., 82(3), 561–580.
44 Weber, E. U., 2016: What shapes perceptions of climate change? New research since 2010. Wiley
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-103 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
S
13 Wells, P., and P. Nieuwenhuis, 2012: Transition failure: Understanding continuity in the automotive
IT
14 industry. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change, 79(9), 1681–1692, doi:10.1016/j.techfore.2012.06.008.
AL N
15 Westman, L., and V. C. Broto, 2018: Climate governance through partnerships: A study of 150 urban
ED
16 initiatives in China. Glob. Environ. Chang., 50, 212–221, doi:10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2018.04.008.
17
18
N IO
Weyant, J., 2017: Some contributions of integrated assessment models of global climate change. Rev.
Environ. Econ. Policy, , doi:10.1093/reep/rew018.
FI S
19 Whitehead, M., 2013: Neoliberal Urban Environmentalism and the Adaptive City: Towards a Critical
R
20 Urban Theory and Climate Change. Urban Stud., 50(7), 1348–1367,
21 doi:10.1177/0042098013480965.
TO E
22 Whitmarsh, L., W. Poortinga, and S. Capstick, 2021: Behaviour Change to Address Climate Change.
T DV
26 Wiedmann, T., and M. Lenzen, 2018: Environmental and social footprints of international trade. Nat.
27 Geosci., 11(5), 314–321, doi:10.1038/s41561-018-0113-9.
BJ P
28 Wilhite, H., 2016: The political economy of low carbon transformation: breaking the habits of
29 capitalism. Routledge, Abingdon-on-Thames, UK, 1–66 pp.
E
30 Willett, W. et al., 2019: Food in the Anthropocene: the EAT–Lancet Commission on healthy diets from
SU C
32 Williamson, O. E., 2000: The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead. J. Econ.
33 Lit., 38(3), 595–613, doi:10.1257/jel.38.3.595.
34 Winkler, H., 2020: Towards a theory of just transition: A neo-Gramscian understanding of how to shift
35 development pathways to zero poverty and zero carbon. Energy Res. Soc. Sci., 70, 101789,
36 doi:10.1016/j.erss.2020.101789.
37 Winkler, H., T. Letete, and A. Marquard, 2013: Equitable access to sustainable development:
38 operationalizing key criteria. Clim. Policy, 13(4), 411–432, doi:10.1080/14693062.2013.777610.
39 Winkler, H. et al., 2018: Countries start to explain how their climate contributions are fair: more rigour
40 needed. Int. Environ. Agreements Polit. Law Econ., 18(1), 99–115, doi:10.1007/s10784-017-
41 9381-x.
42 Wittneben, B. B. F., C. Okereke, S. B. Banerjee, and D. L. Levy, 2012: Climate Change and the
43 Emergence of New Organizational Landscapes. Organ. Stud., 33(11), 1431–1450,
Do Not Cite, Quote or Distribute 1-104 Total pages: 106
Final Government Distribution Chapter 1 IPCC AR6 WGIII
1 doi:10.1177/0170840612464612.
2 Woiwode, C., 2013: New Departures in Tackling Urban Climate Change: Transdisciplinarity for Social
3 Transformation (a critical appraisal of the WBGU’s 2011 Report). Integr. Rev., 9(2).
4 Wolfram, M., N. Frantzeskaki, and S. Maschmeyer, 2016: Cities, systems and sustainability: status and
5 perspectives of research on urban transformations. Curr. Opin. Environ. Sustain., 22, 18–25,
6 doi:10.1016/j.cosust.2017.01.014.
7 Wood, G. et al., 2020a: The comparative institutional analysis of energy transitions. Socio-Economic
8 Rev., 18(1), 257–294, doi:10.1093/ser/mwz026.
9 Wood, R. et al., 2020b: Beyond peak emission transfers: historical impacts of globalization and future
10 impacts of climate policies on international emission transfers. Clim. Policy, 20(sup1), S14–S27,
11 doi:10.1080/14693062.2019.1619507.
12 World Bank, 2019: State and Trends of Carbon Pricing 2019. World Bank, Washington, DC,.
S
13 World Bank, 2020: GDP growth (annual %). World Bank national accounts data, Washington D.C.,
14 https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.MKTP.KD.ZG.
IT
15 Wright, C., and D. Nyberg, 2017: An inconvenient truth: How organizations translate climate change
AL N
16 into business as usual. Acad. Manag. J., 60(5), 1633–1661, doi:10.5465/amj.2015.0718.
ED
N IO
17 WTO, 2016: World Trade Statistical Review 2016. WTO, Geneva, Switzerland,.
18 Wu, X., R. C. Nethery, M. B. Sabath, D. Braun, and F. Dominici, 2020: Air pollution and COVID-19
FI S
19 mortality in the United States: Strengths and limitations of an ecological regression analysis. Sci.
R
20 Adv., 6(45), eabd4049, doi:10.1126/SCIADV.ABD4049.
21 Wüstemann, H. et al., 2017: Synergies and trade-offs between nature conservation and climate policy:
TO E
22 Insights from the “Natural Capital Germany – TEEB DE” study. Ecosyst. Serv., 24, 187–199,
T DV
23 doi:10.1016/j.ecoser.2017.02.008.
24 Xia, Q., H. Wang, X. Liu, and X. Pan, 2021: Drivers of global and national CO 2 emissions changes
25 2000–2017. Clim. Policy, 21(5), 604–615, doi:10.1080/14693062.2020.1864267.
EC TE
26 Xiang, P., H. Zhang, L. Geng, K. Zhou, and Y. Wu, 2019: Individualist-collectivist differences in
27 climate change inaction: The role of perceived intractability. Front. Psychol., 10(FEB),
28 doi:10.3389/fpsyg.2019.00187.
BJ P
30 and specific barriers to the development of a green bond market in Brazil. J. Sustain. Financ.
31 Invest., , 1–18, doi:10.1080/20430795.2020.1769985.
SU C
32 Yang, P. et al., 2018: Social cost of carbon under shared socioeconomic pathways. Glob. Environ.
AC
1 doi:10.1016/j.apenergy.2018.10.051.
2 Zhenmin, L., and P. Espinosa, 2019: Tackling climate change to accelerate sustainable development.
3 Nat. Clim. Chang., 9(7), 494–496, doi:10.1038/s41558-019-0519-4.
4 Zhou, L., S. Gilbert, Y. E. Wang, M. M. Cabré, and K. P. Gallagher, 2018: Moving the Green Belt and
5 Road Initiative: From Words to Actions. , Washington, DC,
6 https://www.wri.org/research/moving-green-belt-and-road-initiative-words-actions.
7 Zhou, P., and W. Wen, 2020: Carbon-constrained firm decisions: From business strategies to operations
8 modeling. Eur. J. Oper. Res., 281(1), 1–15, doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2019.02.050.
9 Zou, C., Q. Zhao, G. Zhang, and B. Xiong, 2016: Energy revolution: From a fossil energy era to a new
10 energy era. Nat. Gas Ind. B, 3(1), 1–11, doi:10.1016/j.ngib.2016.02.001.
11 Zummo, L., E. Gargroetzi, and A. Garcia, 2020: Youth voice on climate change: using factor analysis
12 to understand the intersection of science, politics, and emotion. Environ. Educ. Res., 26(8), 1207–
13 1226, doi:10.1080/13504622.2020.1771288.
S
14
IT
AL N
ED
N IO
FI S
R
TO E
T DV
EC TE
BJ P
E
SU C
AC