EC3115 Vle
EC3115 Vle
EC3115 Vle
Y. Aksoy
EC3115
2015
Undergraduate study in
Economics, Management,
Finance and the Social Sciences
This subject guide is for a 300 course offered as part of the University of London
International Programmes in Economics, Management, Finance and the Social Sciences.
This is equivalent to Level 6 within the Framework for Higher Education Qualifications in
England, Wales and Northern Ireland (FHEQ).
For more information about the University of London International Programmes
undergraduate study in Economics, Management, Finance and the Social Sciences, see:
www.londoninternational.ac.uk
This guide was prepared for the University of London International Programmes by:
Dr Y. Aksoy, Reader in Economics, Department of Economics, Mathematics and Statistics,
Birkbeck, University of London.
Some of the material in this subject guide has been adapted from the previous edition,
written by:
Ryan Love, formerly of the London School of Economics and Political Science.
This is one of a series of subject guides published by the University. We regret that due
to pressure of work the authors are unable to enter into any correspondence relating to,
or arising from, the guide. If you have any comments on this subject guide, favourable or
unfavourable, please use the form at the back of this guide.
Contents
1
Contents
5 Classical theory 57
5.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57
5.2 Aims . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57
2
Contents
6 Stylised facts 69
6.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69
6.2 Aims . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69
6.3 Learning outcomes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69
6.4 Reading advice . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70
6.5 Essential reading . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70
6.6 Further reading . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70
6.7 Trends and business cycles . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71
6.8 Moments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73
6.9 Cross country business cycle evidence . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78
6.10 Key macroeconomic relationships . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79
6.10.1 Relationship between monetary aggregates and inflation . . . . . 79
6.11 Relationship between monetary instruments and macroeconomy . . . . . 80
6.12 Price level stickiness . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82
6.13 A reminder of your learning outcomes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82
6.14 Sample examination questions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83
6.15 Feedback to Sample examination questions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83
3
Contents
4
Contents
5
Contents
6
Chapter 1
Introduction to the subject guide
The first section of the guide (Chapters 2–5) introduces the concept of money;
what it is, why we use it and how it is created. The role of banks and the banking
sector will be analysed in this section only, leaving the rest of the guide to focus on
policy issues.
The second section (Chapters 6–10) examines monetary policy in a closed economy,
considering a number of models that allow real effects of monetary policy, ranging
from new-Classical to new-Keynesian. Specific models will be introduced and
solved, allowing you to see exactly how these models work and what differentiates
one from another.
The third section of the guide considers important issues in the design of monetary
policymaking. Topics include i) time inconsistency in monetary policy design, ii)
monetary policy in an uncertain environment such as data and parameter
uncertainties that monetary policy makers face and how policy makers can
alleviate problems associated with these uncertainties and iii) term structure of
interest rates.
Please see the syllabus at the end of this ‘Introduction’.
7
1. Introduction to the subject guide
What constitutes money. Why people hold money; introduction to cash in advance
(CIA) and money in the utility (MIU) functions.
Money demand and supply:
Rational expectations, representative agents and real business cycle theory. MIU,
CIA, Lucas supply functions and the effects of monetary policy.
The Keynesian approach to monetary policy – nominal rigidities:
Multi-period pricing and the persistence of monetary policy shocks. The Lucas
critique.
The new Keynesian approach to monetary policy – nominal rigidities:
New Keynesian Phillips curve, IS Curve, Taylor rules, financial accelerator models.
Inflation bias, the central bank independence. Monetary policy rules: interest rate
targeting and monetary targeting. (rules versus discretion).
8
1.4. Aims
1.4 Aims
The aims of the course are to:
explain and discuss why people hold money and why it is used in the trading
process
solve macroeconomic models and assess the role and efficacy of monetary policy for
various types of models in both the Classical and Keynesian set-ups
describe and explain the main channels of the monetary transmission mechanism,
through which monetary policy can have real effects on the economy
discuss the merits and disadvantages of different monetary policies used by Central
Banks
introduce the concepts of data and parameter uncertainties and discuss policy
under uncertainty.
9
1. Introduction to the subject guide
A different chapter is devoted to each major section of the syllabus, and the chapter
order follows very closely, though not identically, the order of the topics as they appear
in the syllabus. This order will not concur with that in any one of the recommended
textbooks and the fact that the order varies between the textbooks themselves reflects
the view that there is no obvious sequence of topics because of the interrelationships
between them. It is most important to appreciate that the ‘topics’ in the syllabus are
not self-contained and mutually exclusive, and neither therefore are the chapters of this
guide. Instead there is considerable overlap between many of the ‘topics’ and between
the chapters. For example, the chapter on ‘the demand for money’ explains the link
between the level of real money balances an economy wishes to hold and the nominal
interest rate. This is essential for understanding how monetary policy influences the real
economy in later chapters. Similarly, an understanding of how, and to what extent,
changes in the supply of money affect the macroeconomy will require an understanding
of the subject matter of several chapters.
Consequently, you must expect the examination to include questions that require an
understanding of several different parts of this subject, in other words you cannot ‘pick
and choose’ what to study from the guide.
Each chapter begins with a checklist of learning outcomes; what you should know after
having completed the chapter and done the essential reading and activities. Then
follows some reading advice and a list of the most helpful books and articles for that
particular chapter. Following the main text, each chapter concludes with a list of
Sample examination questions. Occasionally these questions will overlap with material
covered in one or more of the other chapters.
10
1.8. Essential reading
Lewis, M.K. and P.D. Mizen Monetary Economics. (Oxford; New York: Oxford
University Press, 2000) [ISBN 9780198290629]
or
Books
Gali, J. Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the
New Keynesian Framework. (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2008) [ISBN:
9781400829347].
11
1. Introduction to the subject guide
Gordon, R.J., ‘A century of evidence on wage and price stickiness in the US, the
UK and Japan’, in Tobin, J. (ed.) Macroeconomics, Prices and Quantities. (Oxford:
Blackwell, 1983) [ISBN 9780815784852].
Jones, C.I. Macroeconomics. (W. W. Norton Company, 2013) third edition [ISBN
9780393923902].
Laidler, D.E.W. The Demand for Money: Theories, Evidence and Problems. (New
York: Harper Collins, 1997) fourth edition [ISBN 9780065010985].
Mankiw, N.G. Macroeconomics. (New York: Worth Publishers, 2012) eighth edition
[ISBN 9781429240024].
Mishkin, F.S. The Economics of Money, Banking and Financial Markets. (Boston,
Mass.; London: Prentice Hall, 2012) tenth edition [ISBN 9780132770248].
Newman, P., M. Milgate and J. Eatwell (eds) The New Palgrave Dictionary of
Money and Finance. (London: Macmillan, 1994) [ISBN 9780333527221].
Journal articles
Aksoy, Y. and T. Piskorski, ‘US domestic money, inflation and output’, Journal of
Monetary Economics, 53, 2006, pp.183–197.
Clarida, R., Gal, J. and Gertler, M., ‘The science of monetary policy: a new
Keynesian perspective’, Journal of Economic Literature, 37(4), 1999, pp.1661–1707.
Kydland, F.E. and E.C. Prescott, ‘Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency
of optimal plans’, Journal of Political Economy 85(3), 1977, pp.473–492.
Long, J. and C. Plosser, ‘Real business cycles’, Journal of Political Economy 91(1),
1983, pp.39–69.
12
1.9. Further reading
Taylor, J.B., ‘An historical analysis of monetary policy rules’, NBER working
paper, w6768, (1998).
Self-testing activities: Doing these allows you to test your own understanding of
subject material.
Electronic study materials: The printed materials that you receive from the
University of London are available to download, including updated reading lists
and references.
13
1. Introduction to the subject guide
A student discussion forum: This is an open space for you to discuss interests and
experiences, seek support from your peers, work collaboratively to solve problems
and discuss subject material.
Videos: There are recorded academic introductions to the subject, interviews and
debates and, for some courses, audio-visual tutorials and conclusions.
Recorded lectures: For some courses, where appropriate, the sessions from previous
years’ Study Weekends have been recorded and made available.
Study skills: Expert advice on preparing for examinations and developing your
digital literacy skills.
Feedback forms.
Some of these resources are available for certain courses only, but we are expanding our
provision all the time and you should check the VLE regularly for updates.
Making use of the Online Library
The Online Library contains a huge array of journal articles and other resources to help
you read widely and extensively.
To access the majority of resources via the Online Library you will either need to use
your University of London Student Portal login details, or you will be required to
register and use an Athens login: http://tinyurl.com/ollathens
The easiest way to locate relevant content and journal articles in the Online Library is
to use the Summon search engine.
If you are having trouble finding an article listed in a reading list, try removing any
punctuation from the title, such as single quotation marks, question marks and colons.
For further advice, please see the online help pages:
www.external.shl.lon.ac.uk/summon/about.php
14
1.12. The examination
you understand something is not whether you have followed the explanation, but
whether you can apply that understanding to answering questions.
A number of chapters include a substantial activity. This is a longer question, which
you should be able to work through after having consulted the relevant readings.
Although an outline of the solution is included at the end of the chapter, you are
strongly encouraged to use this only to check your answers or to get hints as to how to
start your answer.
You should allocate approximately two weeks to study each chapter. Chapters 1 and 2
contain relatively little mathematical material, therefore can easily be dealt with in one
week.
Section A (40 marks) contains eight statements, which are true, false or uncertain.
You will be asked to answer all of these, also explaining your answer in a short
paragraph. A typical ‘true, false or uncertain’ question will appear at the end of
each chapter and in the first half of the guide a suggested answer is also included,
in order to give you an idea as to how detailed the explanation should be.
Section B is worth 60 marks. You must answer three out of five questions. These
will typically involve discussing and solving some of the models covered in the
guide. These may also involve interpretation of data in the light of specified
macro-monetary theories.
To give you an idea as to how the examination will be structured, an example is
included in the Appendix. In addition to the Sample examination paper, the questions
at the end of each chapter will also give you an insight into the examination. The ‘true,
false or uncertain’ question in each chapter is representative of the questions you will be
asked in Section A and the remaining questions are similar to those found in Section B.
The longer activities, found in a number of chapters, are exactly the type of question
you should expect to find in Section B of the examination.
To give you an idea as to how you should structure your answers in the examination,
feedback to some of the Sample examination questions is given at the end of each
chapter. However, as is the case for the feedback to the longer activities, you should
only use this to check your answers, or to get hints as to how to start.
15
1. Introduction to the subject guide
where available, past examination papers and Examiners’ commentaries for the
course which give advice on how each question might best be answered.
This subject guide follows a more model-based approach to monetary economics than
the previous guide. Each chapter introduces one or more models that, when solved, will
show you the linkages between monetary variables (money supply or interest rates, for
example) and other variables such as output. As such, for the examination you will be
expected to solve and work through mathematical models but these will be no more
complicated than what is presented in this subject guide. However, what is just as
important is that you demonstrate that you understand what is going on. To do this,
you must explain your answer using words, and possibly also diagrams. Even though all
you need to know to succeed in your study of monetary economics is presented in the
essential and further reading sections of each chapter, for those of you who require more
help with this model-based approach, you can consult Walsh, C. Monetary Theory and
Policy (2010) third edition and Gali, J. Monetary Policy, Inflation and the Business
Cycle (2008). It should be stressed, however, that you should read the items in the
recommended reading sections first, before you consider reading these more
advanced/technical textbooks. Hopefully you will find your study of monetary
economics interesting and enjoyable.
Good luck.
Dr. Yunus Aksoy (Birkbeck, University of London)
16
Chapter 2
The nature of money
2.1 Introduction
Fiat money is indispensable in modern economic systems, although it has been part of
daily life as far back as 9000 BC, when grain and cattle were used in Anatolia and
Mesopotamia for exchange purposes. While we take the usage of some form of money as
granted, we need to understand why it exists, its functions and properties. In particular,
we need to solve the double coincidence of wants problem associated with barter and to
resolve the lack of trust between the payer and the payee in a transaction.
2.2 Aims
The aim of the chapter is to introduce the main ingredients of a monetary economy. We
will introduce money for exchange purposes of goods and services. We will describe its
functions, why money is useful in trade, its types and properties.
describe the Wicksell problem and demonstrate how indirect barter can lead to the
emergence of a commodity money
describe the differences between transactions using credit cards and bank debit
cards
17
2. The nature of money
on to the material in this chapter.1 All textbooks on money and banking will have a
section covering the material here. However the best, although most difficult, is that of
Goodhart (1989a) Chapter 2 – see below under ‘Essential reading’. You may find it
helpful to read Goodhart (1989b) first – see below under ‘Further reading’.
18
2.8. The functions of money
accepts that the payment is complete. The payee neither holds any further claims on
the payer, nor on any third party who may have produced or issued the money.
In this chapter we will discuss and explain the important functions, properties and
different types of money. We will also explain why we use money and compare the
alternative trading strategies, both with and without money.
Below, we will discuss the three main functions of money, although, arguably, some
authors will expand these into four.2
As suggested above, the most important function of money is its use as a means of
payment – money being used to pay for items purchased or to settle any debts. A
related role of money is that as a medium of exchange, which Wicksell defined as an
object which is taken in exchange, not on its own account. . . not to be consumed by the
receiver or to be employed in technical production, but to be exchanged for something
else within a longer or shorter period of time.’3 In this sense, a means of payment can
also be a medium of exchange. A gold coin for example, used to buy a piece of land, will
be a means of payment (the seller of the land will not hold a claim on the payee who
has just handed over the gold) but it will also be a medium of exchange. The receiver of
the gold coin will not use it for decorative purposes or to ‘make’ any other goods or
services, but will use it as a medium of exchange when he or she wishes to purchase a
good or service some time in the future.
However, the converse is not necessarily true.4 That which may act as a medium of
exchange may not act simultaneously as a means of payment. For example, if I wish to
pay for a television set using a credit card, the seller may accept this as a medium of
exchange.
Although the television shop’s account may be credited effectively immediately, it may
not be a means of payment since I, the payer, still have a debt outstanding, namely that
to the credit card company. I have merely replaced a debt to the television shop with a
debt to the credit card issuer. The purchase of the television set with the credit card is
then not a means of payment. For this reason we will not include credit cards, trade
credit between firms, or any other line of credit such as unused overdraft facilities, in
our definition of money.
2
The fourth function of money commonly quoted, is that of a standard for deferred payment. This
simply means that if something is bought today although payment for it does not have to be made until
some later date, then the amount due for deferred payment can be measured in terms of money.
3
Wicksell, 1906, quoted by Kiyotaki and Wright, (1992).
4
For an excellent analysis of the differences between ‘means of payment’ and ‘medium of exchange’
see Goodhart (1989a) Chapter 2, Section 4.
19
2. The nature of money
This function is also described as money acting as a measure of exchange value, money
acting as a standard of value, or money as a numeraire. The essential point about this
function is that money is acting as a common denominator, in terms of which the value
in exchange of all goods and services can be expressed. Money is simply acting as a unit
of measurement in the same way that metres measure length and kilograms measure
weight. Money in this sense is being used to measure the value of goods, services and
assets relative to other goods, services and assets. If it is convenient to trade all
commodities in exchange for a single commodity, so it is convenient to measure the
prices of all commodities in terms of a single unit, rather than record the relative price
of every good in terms of every other good. If there is to be a single unit of account, it is
again clearly convenient (though not necessary) that the unit of account be the medium
of exchange, given that goods actually exchange against the medium of exchange.
A clear advantage of having a single unit of account is that it greatly reduces the
number of exchange ratios between goods and services. With four goods (A, B, C and
D), in order to facilitate exchange, exchange ratios of each good in terms of all the
others must be available (i.e. the six ratios A:B, A:C, A:D, B:C, B:D and C:D must be
available). In fact with n goods, there are n(n − 1) = 2 relative prices. However, if we
introduce a fifth good, ‘money’ that acts as a unit of account then there only need to be
four prices. With n goods and money being the n + 1-th commodity acting as a unit of
account, we only need n prices. For example, with 1,000 goods and no unit of account,
the economy needs 499,500 relative prices of one good in terms of another. Introducing
money as a unit of account dramatically reduces this to only 1,000. Thus, having money
as a unit of account can encourage trade by making it easier for individuals to know
how much one good is worth in terms of another.
The exchange attributes of money, in particular that it is durable and can readily be
used in the purchase of goods, also mean that people may wish to hold it as an asset,
that is as part of their stock of wealth. In this sense, money serves as a store of value: it
is permitting the separation in time of the act of sale from the act of purchase. The
existence of a means of payment enables a person to sell a good without simultaneously
having to buy another good in exchange. Receiving a means of payment in exchange for
the good sold allows the seller to hold on to it until such time as it is needed to be
exchanged for the goods and services he or she requires.
Money is not unique as a store of value: any asset, such as equities, bonds, real estate,
antiques and works of art can all act as stores of value. Money itself is sometimes a poor
store of value. This will occur when the relative price of money falls as a result of the
money prices of other goods and services rising, that is, during periods of inflation.
20
2.9. Why do we have money?
Barter
Consider the situation in Table 2.1 and shown in Figure 2.1. There are three individuals
who each only produce one good but derive more utility from the consumption of
another. Avinash produces bread but wants wine, Nicole produces wine but wants
apples and Edwin has apples but wants bread. In this situation, no bilateral exchange
will result. Edwin will not trade with Nicole since he derives more utility from
consuming his own apples than he does from Nicole’s wine. The utility maximising
situation is shown in Figure 2.1 but under the assumption of no commitment, this will
never arise. Avinash will not want to give his bread to Edwin, hoping to receive wine
from Nicole since after receiving bread, Edwin has no incentive to give apples to Nicole
who in turn will have no incentive to hand over her wine to Avinash. The system will
collapse to autarky (in which all individuals become self-sufficient).
However, models of this type can lead to the emergence of indirect barter. In indirect
barter a trader accepts a good not because she or he wants to consume it but because of
the possibility that it may result in a future trade. In the above example, Avinash may
trade his bread for apples, not because he wants to consume the apples but in the
knowledge that when meeting Nicole, she will be willing to trade her wine for those
goods. This may seem an obvious solution at first glance but if we assume traders meet
at random (or do not know how long it will be before they meet a prospective trader)
then considerable risk may be taken on in this transaction. The goods Avinash accepts
in exchange for his bread may deteriorate before he meets Nicole, in which case Nicole
will not want to trade.
Let us assume that the apples do not perish. The situation of indirect barter is shown in
21
2. The nature of money
Table 2.1:
Figure 2.1:
Figure 2.2.
If apples are used in both stages of the trading process then each trader will gain. In
indirect barter, commodities are acquired not for consumption but for the purposes of
making future exchanges. They should therefore have appropriate physical attributes; in
particular they should be durable, portable and homogeneous (or at least easily valued).
In primitive societies money emerged from the process of indirect barter, and took the
form initially of staple foodstuffs like corn or rice. With the development of
technologies, which allowed the separation of metals, money increasingly took the form
of precious metals, especially gold.
The solution of indirect barter in the Wicksell problem arises almost entirely from the
lack of trust between traders. As shown in Figure 2.1, each trader could maximise
utility by giving his or her goods to the next person in the triangle. However, Avinash
could not trust Edwin to hand over his apples to Nicole once he gave him his bread and
neither could he trust Nicole to hand over her wine once (or if) she received Edwin’s
22
2.9. Why do we have money?
Figure 2.2:
apples.
Let us consider another situation. Suppose I visit my dentist and I pay for his services
using a bank debit card.5 The bank will debit my account and credit that of the dentist.
I have effectively given an IOU6 to the bank and the bank has given the dentist one of
its IOUs. But why did I not just hand over one of my IOUs directly to the dentist?
Perhaps it may be that my dentist does not trust me to repay once he tries to redeem
my IOU. More realistically, he cannot use my IOU to make purchases with anyone else
and the likelihood that he will ever want to redeem the IOU from me, by receiving an
economics lesson, may be so small that he would never have agreed to spend his time
fixing my teeth. If the dentist went to the grocers the following day trying to buy
provisions with an IOU from an economics teacher, of whom the grocer had never
heard, it is highly unlikely that the trade would be completed. On the other hand, if he
tried to pay using the bank’s IOU, the grocer should happily agree to the sale, purely
because everyone knows and trusts the bank.
The difference between my IOU and that of the bank is that the bank’s IOU is liquid
5
This example is taken directly from ‘Evil is the Root of all Money’ by Kiyotaki and Moore (2001).
The model presented in this paper is not necessary for this subject but the ideas discussed therein will
greatly improve the reader’s intuition as to what is money and why we hold it.
6
‘IOU’ is short for ‘I owe you’ and is merely a written statement acknowledging that a debt has been
created, to be repaid sometime in the future.
23
2. The nature of money
and functionally equivalent to cash. My IOU, on the other hand, is not liquid and
cannot flow around the economy facilitating trades. As we will discuss later in this
chapter, it is ‘credit’ money but serves the same purpose as the commodity money
derived in the indirect barter problem, without having to use or lock up any goods in
the payment process.
Activity 2.1 Consider the problem in Figure 2.1. How could you introduce a bank
and a system of IOUs to resolve the problem without having to use any commodity
to act as a medium of exchange?
The idea of trust and uncertainty are important ones when explaining the existence of
money.7 If you do not know, or have any way of obtaining information as to the
creditworthiness of, a prospective customer, there is a high risk that he or she may
default on that debt. The risk is, however, minimised if the payer hands over an item of
worth, such as commodity money or another store of value, or an IOU redeemable from
a third party on which the payee has sufficient information, such as a bank. In this way
it may be essential to hold money beforehand in order to make purchases. This is the
whole idea behind ‘cash in advance’ (CIA) models that we will consider in a more
macroeconomic setting in later chapters. People have to hold money in order to
alleviate the problem of trust (or lack of trust) when transactions are made.
commodity money
fiat money
credit money.
Commodity money
24
2.10. Types of money
Fiat money
Fiat money, whose archetype is the government-issued bank note or metal coin, is
money that has physical substance but no intrinsic value. It is used because its use is
established by custom and practice. People accept fiat money that they know to be
intrinsically worthless because they know others will accept it in payment for goods and
services. The value of fiat money is reinforced in society by the attribute of being ‘legal
tender’, that is making it illegal for anyone to refuse payment in fiat money in
settlement of a debt. In fact it is this legal ‘stamp’ and recognised power of the issuer,
usually governments, which gives fiat money its unquestionable acceptance as a means
of payment.
Since fiat money is essentially worthless, there is a difference between the value of the
goods such money can purchase and the smaller cost of printing this money. The
difference is known as seigniorage and is effectively the profit made by the issuing
authority when it produces currency.
Credit money
Whereas fiat money is not a claim on any commodity or individual, credit money is; it
is the debt of a private person or institution. In the dentist example above, I gave an
IOU to the bank, which in turn hands this debt over to the dentist. If he can pass this
claim on to another individual, the grocer, in exchange for goods, then this debt is
being used as a means of payment and so constitutes money. However, the asset that
the grocer now has, the claim on the bank, is matched one-for-one with the bank’s
claim on me. What the bank owes to the grocer (the bank’s liability) must be matched
by what I owe the bank (the bank’s asset) in order for the bank’s balance sheet to
balance. The limitation of credit money is that it can only function if both individuals,
the dentist and me in the example, have complete confidence in the willingness and
ability of the intermediary to honour the debt. If the bank fails then both my dentist
and I would lose out since the dentist would still have a claim on me and I may not
have the funds to honour that claim if the bank has been forced to close. Since there
exists a private liability perfectly offsetting the asset acting as a means of payment (i.e.
the money is generated inside the private system) credit money is also known as ‘inside
money’. Fiat money, which cannot be matched against private sector claims (and is
generated outside the private sector) is in a similar fashion, known as ‘outside money’.
In the UK today, inside money is quantitatively much larger than outside money. At the
time of writing, the nominal value of inside money is approximately 30 times the value
of outside money, notes and coins.
There may appear to be a contradiction at this point when we compare the definition of
credit money to the discussion in the section ‘money as a means of payment’ where we
argued that all forms of credit should not be included in our definition of money. In the
above example, although I have replaced a debt to my dentist with a debt to my bank,
this is commonly accepted as a means of payment since a transfer of credit to a current
account has advantages such as safe-keeping and making use of book-keeping services at
the bank. Only when all parties concerned are entirely confident the bank will not fail,
will such transfers be a means of payment. Once the bank hears of my purchase at the
dentist (via the swiping of the debit card), the bank debits my account and credits that
25
2. The nature of money
of the payee, the dentist. Nothing further needs to be done since the payment is
complete. If a purchase is made by credit card, however, a debt is still outstanding and
has to be repaid. Similarly, if I paid by my bank debit card but went overdrawn, a debt
would remain outstanding which I would later have to pay off. For this reason, overdraft
facilities are not a means of payment.
describe the Wicksell problem and demonstrate how indirect barter can lead to the
emergence of a commodity money
describe the differences between transactions using credit cards and bank debit
cards
26
2.13. Sample examination questions
Specify whether the following statement is true, false or uncertain. Explain your answer
in a short paragraph.
1. ‘The evolution of commodity money from indirect barter, as the solution to the
Wicksell problem, arises because of a lack of trust between the relevant parties.’
Section B
3. What is money and why do we use it? Outline the three different types of money
and explain what is different between them.
5. Explain why some economists argue that payment by cheque is the same as giving
trade credit. If this is the case and considering that cheques are drawn on bank
current accounts (as are payments by bank debit cards), do cheque payments count
as money?
Specify whether the following statement is true, false or uncertain. Explain your answer
in a short paragraph.
1. The statement is true. Suggested answers may include Figure 2.1 and an
explanation as to why each person cannot trust the others to pass their goods
along the chain. In the example of Figure 2.1, Avinash could not trust Edwin to
hand over his apples to Nicole once he gave him his bread and neither could he
trust Nicole to hand over her wine once (if) she received Edwin’s apples. By using a
commodity money, such as wine, the problem can be solved. Edwin trades his
apples for Nicole’s wine, not because he wants to consume the wine, but because he
can trade it with Avinash for his bread. Wine is thus being used as a commodity
money.
27
2. The nature of money
Section B
28
Chapter 3
The demand for money
3.1 Introduction
In Chapter 2 we saw why there was a need for money:
to obviate the lack of trust between the payer and the payee in a transaction.
However, what determines the quantity of money that individuals and economies
demand is a separate question. It is the aim of this chapter to explain what determines
the quantity of money we demand and also to present a number of models (or theories)
of the demand for money. The chapter is split into two main sections. The first part
considers the demand for money from individuals or institutions/firms the
microeconomic determinants of money demand. The second part examines the demand
for money at the macroeconomic level gives a brief history of money demand, focusing
on the breakdown of the macroeconomic demand for money function.
3.2 Aims
The aim of the chapter is to study the money demand as one of the building blocks of
the money market equilibrium.
outline the inventory theoretic model of Baumol–Tobin and the portfolio selection
model of Tobin
discuss why Tobin’s model solves the ‘plunger’ problem of the demand for money
model of Keynes
29
3. The demand for money
describe what happened and what is meant by ‘the case of the missing money’ and
give reasons for the breakdown of the estimated money demand equations.
Journal articles
30
3.7. Microeconomic determinants of the demand for money
Judd, J. and J. Scadding ‘The search for a stable money demand function: a survey of
the post-1973 literature’, Journal of Economic Literature 20(2) 1982, pp.993–1023.
Miller, M. and D. Orr ‘A model of the demand for money by firms’, Quarterly Journal
of Economics 80(3) 1966, pp.413–35.
Sprenkle, C. ‘The uselessness of transactions demand models’, Journal of Finance 24(5)
1969, pp.835–47.
Tobin, J. ‘The interest elasticity of transactions demand for cash’, The Review of
Economics and Statistics 38(3) 1956, pp.241–47.
Tobin, J. ‘Liquidity preference as behaviour towards risk’, Review of Economic Studies
25(1) 1958, pp.65–86.
2. cost of transfers: the costs associated with transferring between higher interest
earning assets and money, needed to purchase goods and services. If the cost of
transfers, known as brokerage fees, are high then it is unlikely that we will put our
wealth into the higher interest earning assets as to do so will involve substantial
costs. Demand for money will then be a positive function of these transfer costs.
31
3. The demand for money
These determinants are also related to Keynes’ description of money demand motives.
Keynes (1936) broke down the demand for money into three types: transactions,
precautionary and speculative motives:
The transaction demand for money is essentially that needed to buy goods and
services where money is needed as a medium of exchange.
Figure 3.1:
2
This is due to the negative relationship between the price of a bond and the yield the bond earns.
This is considered in more detail in Chapter 9.
32
3.8. Baumol–Tobin transactions demand for money
It has become standard to model each component of the demand for money separately.3
The transaction demand for money is typically modelled by allowing money to be a
function of determinants 1, 2 and 4 above (i.e. ignoring asset price uncertainty). By
allowing more flexible assumptions on the expected pattern of expenditures and
receipts, similar analysis can incorporate a precautionary motive for money holdings.4
Analysis of the speculative demand for money, however, concentrates on determinant 3,
asset price uncertainty, while dropping one or more of the other factors for tractability.
33
3. The demand for money
Figure 3.2:
Activity 3.1 A taxi driver takes £15,000 net over the course of a year, at an
approximately constant daily rate. He spends 80% of his takings on consumption
goods, also at an approximately constant daily rate, but saves the remainder to pay
for a world cruise at the end of the year. He can hold his savings in a deposit
account in a bank paying 4% per annum, with costless deposits and withdrawals, or
he can purchase bonds paying a known yield of 7%. The brokerage fee in purchasing
or selling bonds is £5 per transaction. Assume the taxi driver manages his finances
34
3.9. Tobin’s model of portfolio selection
(a) Draw the time profile of the taxi driver’s holdings of deposits and bonds.
(b) What is the optimal value of n? (Note that n must be a whole number.)
(c) What is the taxi driver’s ‘demand for money’, or average deposit balance?
(For Feedback, see the end of this chapter.)
Despite the intellectual appeal and simplicity of the inventory theoretic model, it faces a
number of criticisms. One argument made against such models is that they make the
assumption that the pattern of expenditure and receipts is known perfectly. This is
clearly not true in reality. Adding uncertainty to these processes is exactly what Miller
and Orr (1966) do but, even then, these inventory theoretic models face a huge uphill
struggle when faced with empirical evidence. At the micro level, the percentage of
actual cash balances held by firms that is explained by the Baumol model is tiny.
35
3. The demand for money
Let the mean return of this portfolio be µp and the variance be σp2 .
µp = µB (3.7)
σp2 = σ 2 B 2 . (3.8)
Writing B in terms of σ and σp from (3.8) and substituting into (3.7) gives a budget
constraint relating the maximum return on a portfolio to the standard deviation, which
we assume is a proxy for risk.
µσp
µp = . (3.9)
σ
Assuming that agents are risk-averse, the indifference curves will be convex and upward
sloping, as shown in Figure 3.3.
The top part of the figure shows the budget constraint and indifference curves of the
agent. Note that there is an upper bound on the return and risk of the portfolio, µ0p and
σp0 , respectively, where the individual has put all of their financial wealth in bonds;
B = 1. At this point it is impossible to increase the return or risk of the portfolio by
substituting between money and bonds. The bottom part of the figure simply shows the
share of the portfolio held in bonds and the corresponding risk of the portfolio.
As can be seen in the figure, the individual maximises utility by being at the point
where the indifference curve is tangential to the portfolio budget constraint, point E.
The share of wealth held in bonds is B ∗ and the share held in money is 1 − B ∗ . By
using portfolio analysis, Tobin showed how individuals can diversify their wealth into
more than just one asset. By changing the return earned on bonds, µ, this will shift the
lines in the figure, resulting in a new equilibrium and different bond/money allocation
(see ‘Feedback to the Activity’ at the end of this chapter).
36
3.10. Macroeconomic determinants of money demand
Figure 3.3:
service or asset depends. For example, assume that the demand for apples depends
primarily on the following:
1. their price
M d = f (Y, Ri , W ). (3.10)
M d is the demand for nominal money balances, Y is nominal income and Ri is the rate
of return on asset i. Since the rate of return on a number of assets will determine the
demand for money, including that on money itself, i can represent a number of assets.
The Ri s represent the opportunity cost of holding money and Y acts as a proxy for the
level of transactions undertaken. Wealth (W ) is included as it forms the budget
constraint on which the choice of money holdings depends but since wealth is
capitalised current and future income, it is not independent of Y . For this reason, and
37
3. The demand for money
also because data on wealth levels of nations are very difficult to obtain, W is often
dropped from the analysis. If money demand is homogenous of degree one in prices (i.e.
a doubling of the price level leads to a doubling of the demand for nominal money
balances), (3.10) can be re-written as:
d
M
= g(y, Ri ) (3.11)
P
where y is real income. A common log linear form of this equation is:
where mt , pt and yt are log values of the nominal money supply, price level and income
at time t respectively and Rt is ‘the’ nominal interest rate at time t. Two important
parameters of the money demand function are the elasticities with respect to income
and the interest rate. For a summary of the empirical evidence on these estimates, see
Lewis and Mizen, especially Chapter 11. This chapter also explains in detail the
methods used to estimate such money demand functions.5 The interest elasticity of
money demand is important in the debate over whether monetary or fiscal policy is
more powerful. A low value of b implies a relatively steep LM curve and, other things
being equal, monetary policy has a larger effect on output than fiscal policy. Keynesians
on the other hand argue the opposite: a high value of b and therefore a relatively
shallow LM curve, implying a greater role for fiscal policy.
Of equal importance is whether or not the money demand equation is stable. If the
monetary authorities decide to target the money supply then an unstable money
demand function can lead to unexpected and adverse changes in nominal and possibly
real factors in the economy. The stability of money demand can only be determined by
statistical analysis of the relevant data – hence the enormous number of empirical
studies relating to the demand for money.
where ut is a random error term and a lagged dependent variable, ln(M/P )t−1 , is also
included. Goldfeld himself suggested:
38
3.12. Reasons for the breakdown of the money demand functions
However, from 1974 Goldfeld’s equation overpredicted real money balances, M1, in the
US. This was known as ‘the case of the missing money’ (Goldfeld, 1976). Basically, for
any given level of real income and interest rates, the above equation suggested that there
should be more money in circulation than there actually was.7 Such demand for money
functions were breaking down, not only in the US but also elsewhere, such as the UK –
see Hacche (1974) who examined a broader measure of money, M3. Whereas Goldfeld’s
equation overpredicted the amount of money in the US, money demand equations for
the broader M3 aggregate in the UK were underpredicting the amount of money.
outline the inventory theoretic model of Baumol–Tobin and the portfolio selection
model of Tobin
7
For a review of the stability of the demand for money function, see Judd and Scadding (1982).
8
See Goodhart (1989), Chapter 10.
39
3. The demand for money
discuss why Tobin’s model solves the ‘plunger’ problem of the demand for money
model of Keynes
describe what happened and what is meant by ‘the case of the missing money’ and
give reasons for the breakdown of the estimated money demand equations.
Specify whether the following statement is true, false or uncertain. Explain your answer
in a short paragraph.
1. ‘Tobin’s portfolio model implies that the demand for money will always fall when
the interest rate rises.’
Section B
2. According to some economists, Tobin’s portfolio selection model suffers from the
following deficiencies: (a) it explains the allocation of wealth between assets, but it
does not explain the demand for money; (b) it implies that investors view
investment in long-term assets as more risky than investment in short-term assets:
this, however, is false. Discuss these shortcomings.
3. Somebody suggested that instead of introducing the Euro, the European Central
Bank should have introduced a debit card that could be used for any kind of
transaction; a ‘Eurocard’. If this suggestion had been followed by the ECB, what
would be the transaction demand for cash in the euro-area economy?
4. At the micro-level, the transactions elasticity of money demand has been found to
be close to unity and the interest elasticity has been found to be close to zero. How
do these estimates compare to those of the Baumol–Tobin model? Explain why
they differ.
5. By definition, wealth forms the budget constraint that people face when deciding
how much money to hold. Why then is wealth not present in many macroeconomic
money demand functions?
40
3.15. Feedback to Activity 3.1
1. The statement is false. Suggested answers may include Figure 3.3 and will explain
what happens after an increase in the interest rate, namely an anticlockwise
movement of the budget constraint. The new point of tangency can lie either to the
left or right of point E, in which case the share of wealth held in money can be
higher or lower than before. This is due to the offsetting income and substitution
effects (to be shown in the diagram).
Section B
2. The suggested answer should show the cost minimisation problem in the
Baumol–Tobin model and also show that the average money demand, M , is given
41
3. The demand for money
42
Chapter 4
The supply of money
4.1 Introduction
In Chapter 2 we discussed what constitutes money and in Chapter 3 we analysed the
factors that determine how much money individuals, and economies as a whole, demand.
In this chapter we will discuss how money, credit money in particular, is created and
what determines the supply of money. As we shall see in later chapters, the supply of
money is hugely important since a change in the money supply can lead to changes in
the price level and inflation but also to changes in real variables such as output and
unemployment. By affecting the money supply, the monetary authorities can ‘control’
or at least help limit the fluctuations of these variables. Later in this chapter we will see
how the authorities can implement monetary policy to help control the money supply.
4.2 Aims
The aim of the chapter is to study the money supply as one of the building blocks of
the money market equilibrium, the role of financial intermediaries in the credit supply
process and how monetary policy makers can control money supply.
define on which side of a bank’s balance sheet deposits and loans appear and
explain why the balance sheet must indeed balance
explain how the monetary authorities can influence the total money supply by
changing the monetary base or by introducing mandatory reserve ratios or other
regulation.
43
4. The supply of money
Brunner, K. ‘High-powered money and the monetary base’, in Newman, P., M. Milgate
and J. Eatwell (eds) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance. (London:
Macmillan, 1994).
Goodhart, C.A.E. ‘The monetary base’, in Newman, P., M. Milgate and J. Eatwell (eds)
The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance. (London: Macmillan, 1994).
Laidler, D.E.W. Taking money seriously and other essays. (New York; London: Philip
Allan, 1990) Chapters 4 and 5.
McCallum, B. Monetary Economics. (New York; Macmillan; London: Collier
Macmillan, 1989).
Papademos, L. and F. Modigliani ‘The supply of money and the control of nominal
income’, in Friedman, B. and F. Hahn (eds) Handbook of monetary economics.
(Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1990).
Journal articles
Goodhart, C.A.E. ‘What should Central Banks do? What should be their
macroeconomic objectives and operations?’, Economic Journal 104(427) 1994,
pp.1424–36.
1
The survey article of Papademos and Modigliani is good but difficult. You should, however, be able
to read and understand the basics of Section 3 of this article.
44
4.7. Financial intermediaries
2. Insurance. Agents are, in general, risk-averse. If there are two states of the world,
one where an agent received a high income and another where (s)he received a low
income, the average of the utilities from both high and low incomes will be less
than the utility of the average income. As such, the agent would be willing to pay a
fraction of their income in order to smooth their income receipts and hence their
consumption. This is exactly the service insurance firms provide. In a similar
fashion, banks provide insurance services by guaranteeing a rate of return to
depositors even if loans made to borrowers turn bad. Without the bank, the default
risk would be faced entirely by the individual/depositor. By paying the bank,
depositors accept a lower deposit rate than that they have to pay on loans,
depositors can protect themselves from the default risk and obtain a higher utility.2
45
4. The supply of money
of savers) are then liquid and the bank will promise to convert the depositors’
assets on demand. The banks assets, on the other hand, will tend to be illiquid
since private borrowers tend to want to hold long maturity liabilities (the
loans/assets of the bank). For example, if a firm wanted to borrow money to build
a factory, they would want to borrow long term. This would allow the steady
income earned from the investment to gradually pay off the loan.
Activity 4.1 If you had $1,000 in cash and you deposited this at a bank, on what
side of the bank’s balance sheet would this appear? On what side of your own
balance sheet would it appear? What could and should the bank do with this cash?
Since banks hold short maturity liabilities, which they promise to pay to the depositors
on demand, and hold long maturity assets in the form of loans to borrowers, a
paramount concern of banks is therefore to ensure that they can honour demands for
withdrawals by customers. To do this they must always hold an adequate supply of
liquid assets. The problem is that the most profitable assets of a bank are those that
possess least liquidity. Indeed, if the banks held only the most liquid assets in their
portfolios they would not even cover their operating costs! The highest profits are
earned on long-term loans and investments but these are comparatively illiquid assets in
a bank’s balance sheet. Banks are therefore obliged to balance liquidity on the one hand
against profitability on the other.
46
4.9. A simple model of the banking sector
D = d0 − d1 (i − iD ) (4.4)
L = d0 + l1 (i − iL ) (4.5)
where L is the (demand for) bank loans, D is the (supply of) bank deposits, iL the rate
charged on loans, iD the interest paid on deposits and i the ‘market’ interest rate. Note
that the supply of deposits is a positive function of the interest rate paid on deposits
and a negative function of the market interest rate – the interest rate one could earn
elsewhere. If iD was large relative to i, that would encourage individuals to deposit
more funds with the bank. Equivalently, the demand for loans is a negative function of
the interest rate charged on loans. If the interest rate you had to pay on a loan was high
relative to the market rate, you would borrow, not from the bank, but from elsewhere.
Assume the banks have no operating costs and have no other assets or liabilities.
Finally, d0 captures an arbitrary banking relationship constant. It represents the
minimum an individual would deposit to the bank and the minimum a firm receives
from the bank to hold a bank relationship.
Competitive equilibrium
The profits made by the bank will equal the quantity of loans, L, multiplied by the
interest earned on those loans, iL (which is the bank’s revenues)4 minus the costs faced
4
Assume there are no borrowers defaulting on their debts.
47
4. The supply of money
by the bank. Costs will equal the interest paid to depositors in order to encourage them
to hand over their funds to the bank. Costs then equal the quantity of deposits, D,
times the interest rate paid on deposits, iD . Denoting bank profits by Π and noting that
in a competitive equilibrium, profits equal zero:
Π = L · iL − D · iD (4.6)
When making the additional assumption that the bank holds no reserves, in order for
the bank’s balance sheet to balance, loans (assets) must equal deposits (liabilities),
L = D. Substituting into (4.6) and using (4.7) implies that in equilibrium:
iD = iL . (4.8)
d0 − d1 (i − iD ) = d0 + l1 (i − iL ). (4.9)
Solving for the interest rate on deposits, which equals the interest rate charged on loans
from (4.8), gives:
iD = iL = i. (4.10)
This implies total deposits, D, which equals total loans, L, equals d0 from either (4.4)
or (4.5). This is shown in Figure 4.1 below.
In equilibrium, the interest rate paid on deposits equals the interest rate charged on
loans, which equals the market interest rate, i. The level of deposits, which in this
model is equal to the level of the money stock, equals the amount of loans.
Figure 4.1:
48
4.9. A simple model of the banking sector
One way that the government could reduce or control the money supply is by setting a
limit on the interest rate paid on deposits. If the maximum interest rate banks can pay
on deposits is less than i in the above example, then the amount of funds savers are
willing to deposit with the bank will fall, resulting in a lower money supply. Note that
this will also be associated with a lower quantity of loans that, despite the lower money
supply, may be harmful to the economy if it means some investment opportunities are
not undertaken.
Consider the case where the government sets the interest rate on deposits equal to zero.
From (4.4), the quantity of deposits is fixed at D = d0 − d1 i. Diagrammatically, this is
shown in Figure 4.2.
Figure 4.2:
The level of deposits, and hence of the money supply, has fallen from d0 to d0 − d1 i
because of the government regulation. Since deposits must equal loans in order for the
bank’s balance sheet to balance, the lower level of deposits means a lower level of loans,
which is associated with a higher interest rate charged, iL > i. Also, since there is a
difference between the interest rate charged on loans and that paid on deposits (which
has been set at zero), the government regulation has allowed the banks to make positive
profits.
Activity 4.3
1. By equating deposits with loans, and noting that iD = 0, find an expression for
iL in terms of the market interest rate, i.
2. Using (4.6) find an expression for the profits made by the banks in terms of the
market interest rate.
49
4. The supply of money
Reserves
As discussed above, banks will try to keep a fraction of their assets in liquid form in
order to meet the day-to-day needs of depositors who withdraw their funds. Assume
that the government introduces a mandatory reserve ratio, r∗ (i.e. total reserves of the
bank, R, equals r∗ × D). The bank’s assets now comprise loans, as before, but now
include these reserves. Its liabilities are just the deposits of its customers.
Assets = Liabilities
⇒ r∗ · D + L = D
⇒ L = (1 − r∗ )D. (4.11)
Substituting (4.11) into the zero profit condition, (4.6) and (4.7), and rearranging will
give the interest rate charged on loans to be:
iD
iL = > iD . (4.12)
1 − r∗
The interest rate charged on loans is now higher than the interest rate paid on deposits.
This is in order to compensate the banks for holding reserves, on which it earns no
interest. Total loans are now less than total deposits so each dollar lent out must earn a
higher return than that paid on each dollar deposited with the bank. iL then needs to
be greater than iD .
Activity 4.4 Substitute out L and D from (4.4) and (4.5) into (4.11). Then
substituting out iL from (4.12), show that the rate of interest paid on deposits is
equal to:
l1 r∗ r∗ (1 − r∗ )d0
iD = 1 − i + . (4.13)
l1 + d1 (1 − r∗ )2 l1 + d1 (1 − r∗ )2
Substitute this out into the supply of deposits equation, (4.4), and show that total
deposits are given by:
l1 + d1 (1 − r∗ ) d1 l1 r∗
D= d 0 − i. (4.14)
l1 + d1 (1 − r∗ )2 l1 + d1 (1 − r∗ )2
Although (4.13) and (4.14) appear complicated, they simply relate the deposit rate and
total deposits (money supply) to the market interest rate and to the reserve ratio. By
changing the mandatory reserve ratio, the government can change the total money
supply through the activities of the banking sector. However, the way in which D varies
with r∗ is uncertain and depends on the parameters of the model. With no reserve
requirements we equate L to D in order for the bank’s balance sheet to balance. In this
situation we equate L to (1 − r∗ )D from (4.11). Therefore the new intersection results
in a lower value of L but a higher interest rate charged, iL . Total revenues for the bank,
L × iL , could then increase or decrease depending on the elasticity of the demand for
loans function.
50
4.9. A simple model of the banking sector
If the demand for loans is elastic then, if L falls, revenue will fall. Banks will be forced
to cut the interest paid on deposits, so iD falls, resulting in fewer deposits and hence
causing the money supply to fall.
If the demand for loans is inelastic, a fall in L, caused by the reserve ratio, will increase
revenues. The banks will increase iD and so total deposits will increase.
As seen above, the government can control the money supply by directly controlling the
rate of interest paid on deposits and it can also affect it through imposing a mandatory
reserve ratio. However, by forcing the banks to hold a certain level of reserves, not just a
reserve ratio, it can directly control the monetary base. Note that high-powered money
equals reserves plus cash held by the general public (see (4.2)) and the government
directly controls the amount of cash in the economy since it is the monopoly supplier.
The government fixes the amount of bank reserves, R, at R∗ . Together with the reserve
ratio, r∗ , this explicitly determines the amount of deposits in the economy since
R∗ = r∗ D. Inverting (4.14) will give an expression for the market interest rate in terms
of r∗ and R∗ .
l1 + d1 (1 − r∗ ) l1 + d1 (1 − r∗ )2
i= d 0 − D (4.15)
d1 l1 r∗ d1 l1 r∗
where:
R∗
D= . (4.16)
r∗
This is shown in Figure 4.3.
Figure 4.3:
51
4. The supply of money
The level of total deposits, and hence the supply of money, is determined by the
mandatory requirement that the banks hold a fixed level of reserves, R∗ , and have a
fixed reserve ratio, r∗ . Changing R∗ will directly affect the money supply, shifting the
vertical D = R∗ /r∗ schedule left or right. However, doing so will necessitate a change in
the market interest rate in order to achieve equilibrium in the banking sector.
Activity 4.5 Assume an economy in which the demand for bank loans is given by:
L = 1000 + 25(i − iL )
and in which the portfolio preferences of the public generate a supply of bank
deposits given by:
D = 1000 − 50(i − iD )
where iL is the interest rate charged on bank loans, iD the interest rate paid on bank
deposits and i the ‘market’ interest rate (and interest rates are measured in
percentage points so that a rate of two per cent is given as 2, not 0.02).
The banks hold no reserves and have no other assets and liabilities and incur
operating costs of £60 a year for every £1,000 of deposits.
1. Assuming the banking system is competitive, solve for the loan rate and the
deposit rate as functions of the market interest rate and determine the stock of
money in equilibrium.
2. Imagine that the banks were now to collude and reach an agreement to set loan
and deposit rates which maximise the profits of the industry. What loan and
deposit rates will they set, what will be the profits of the industry and what will
be the effects of this cartel on the stock of money?
3. Assume the banking industry is described as in the first part of the question
(i.e. competitive and unregulated). The government can influence the ‘market’
interest rate through its dealings in the gilt-edged money markets. What is the
effect of a change in the market interest rate on deposit and loan rates and on
the stock of money? Explain. Is monetary policy impotent in this economy?
(For Feedback, see the end of this chapter.)
define on which side of a bank’s balance sheet deposits and loans appear and
explain why the balance sheet must indeed balance
52
4.11. Sample examination questions
explain how the monetary authorities can control the total money supply by
changing the monetary base or by introducing mandatory reserve ratios or other
regulation.
Specify whether the following statement is true, false or uncertain. Explain your answer
in a short paragraph.
1. ‘From the money multiplier analysis, the stock of money is a multiple of the
quantity of high-powered money. Since this is set by the monetary authorities, the
authorities can directly set the quantity of money in the economy.’
Section B
3. Do banks perform a role in the financial system that is qualitatively different from
the role of other ‘non-bank’ financial intermediaries (NBFIs)? Should all financial
institutions be regulated by the authorities in the same way?
4. It is sometimes argued that regulation of the banking system (by minimum reserve
requirements, for example) acts like a tax on banks, and leads to the growth of
non-bank financial intermediation, which escapes the regulation. Therefore, it is
argued that bank regulation is self-defeating and undesirable. Discuss.
5. What is the effect of an increase in the ‘market’ interest rate on the equilibrium
value of bank deposits (and hence on the money stock) on the assumptions that:
(a) the banking system is competitive and unregulated, but the banks require for
commercial reasons to hold some proportion of their deposits in the form of
cash
(b) the banking system is regulated by a rule preventing banks from paying
interest on deposits?
Is the effect bigger under assumption (a) or (b)? Explain.
53
4. The supply of money
also the operating costs of £60 per £1,000 deposited, i.e. 6% of deposits. Profits, Π,
are then given by:
Π = L · iL − D · iD − 6D (4.17)
Π = 0. (4.18)
iL = iD + 6. (4.19)
Substituting (4.19) into the loan demand equation and equating this to the supply
of deposits equation gives:
iL = 3i − 2iD . (4.24)
Using (4.24) and the loan demand and supply of deposits equations we can use
(4.17) to obtain an expression for profits.
iL = i + 22 (4.27)
3. From ‘1.’, D = 900 (i.e. deposits are a constant in equilibrium and are not a
function of the market interest rate). Changing i will not change D and hence will
not change the stock of money. The government bids for funds by increasing i so
banks have to compete by increasing their own rates. In total, nothing happens to
54
4.13. Feedback to Sample examination questions
D or L since they both only depend on interest differentials. From (4.21) and
(4.22), diL /di = diD /di = 1. The effect of changing the market interest rate is
shown in Figure 4.4 below.
Even though the money stock has not changed, an increase in the nominal interest rate
will increase the real interest rate if prices (inflation) do not change. Therefore,
investment and consumption will be affected (reduced) and so monetary policy may not
be impotent.
Figure 4.4:
1. The statement is uncertain. The suggested answer should show the relationships
between M (money stock) and H (high-powered money) from (4.1) to (4.3). The
money multiplier will be shown to be a function of two ratios (currency-deposit and
reserve-deposit). Only if these ratios are stable will the monetary authorities be
able to control the stock of money directly.
Section B
5. For the first part, where the banking system is competitive and unregulated, the
effects of an increase in the market rate of interest will be to increase deposit and
loan rates one-for-one but to leave the money stock unaffected. See the outline
answer to ‘3.’ of Activity 4.5.
In (b), where banks do not pay interest on deposits, consider Figure 4.2 and (4.4).
Deposits are fixed at D = d0 − d1 i and therefore an increase in the market rate will
55
4. The supply of money
cause the money stock to fall. It is therefore likely that the effect of the increase in
market rates is greater in the second case. The money stock falls and the increase
in the market rate can have real effects, as described above.
56
Chapter 5
Classical theory
5.1 Introduction
The classical model is hugely important for the analysis of monetary theory. If one
commodity has been introduced into the economy to serve the functions of money and
has no other use or value, what determines the value of such a commodity, or the prices
of other goods and services in relation to that money commodity? These are essentially
the questions we will be answering in this chapter. We will analyse the general
equilibrium framework of Walras and use it to explain what is meant by the ‘Classical
dichotomy’, namely the separation of the real side of the economy from the monetary
side. Finally, we will give an explicit example of Walras’ law by introducing money in a
general equilibrium framework; a set-up we will use extensively in later chapters.
5.2 Aims
In this chapter we aim to study a general equilibrium environment with money.
describe the essential features and predictions of the quantity theory of money
describe the main features of the classical system and the classical dichotomy
state the nature and importance of Patinkin’s real balance effect for the internal
consistency of the classical dichotomy.
57
5. Classical theory
monetary neutrality. The book followed most closely here is Lewis and Mizen, Chapters
3 and 4, but see also Harris, Chapters 4 and 5.
You are also strongly advised to read the entries on ‘Neutrality of money’ and ‘Quantity
theory of money’ in The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance. The latter
chapter is quite long but covers material relevant not only for this, but for other
chapters in the guide.
58
5.7. The quantity theory of money
The quantity theory determines the price level on the basis of the assumptions made
about the variables in the equation. V is taken as exogenous, being determined by
various institutional features of the economy, such as the frequency with which workers
get paid. T , the number of transactions, is determined by real variables such as
preferences, endowments and technology, and M is, in a fiat money economy,
determined by the government.2 On these assumptions the price level, P , is
proportional to the stock of money, M , in the sense that changes in the stock of money
lead to equi-proportional changes in the price level. Taking logs of (5.1) gives:
ln Mt + ln Vt = ln Pt + ln Tt (5.2)
where we have introduced a time subscript to all variables. Differentiating this with
respect to time gives:
1 dMt 1 dVt 1 dPt 1 dTt
· + · ≡ · + · . (5.3)
Mt dt Vt dt Pt dt Tt dt
If velocity and transactions are considered exogenous, meaning these are not changing
through time, then their derivatives with respect to time are simply zero. For the
remaining terms, noting that (1/Xt ) · (dXt /dt) is simply the growth rate of Xt , then
(5.3) implies that the growth rate of the money supply is equal to the growth rate of
the price level (i.e. inflation). In this sense, inflation cannot occur without a
commensurate increase in the supply of money.
The velocity of money measures how many times a unit of money is used to purchase
goods and services per period. It is also a measure of the stability of the money
demand. Consider now a situation where the velocity of money doubles (i.e. every
individual spends their money twice as fast as before). What is the implication of this
on the equation of exchange? Assume initially that Joanna gets paid £800 a month and
spends a quarter of this at the beginning of each week. Her money balances are then
£600 during the first week, £400 during the second week, £200 during the third and £0
during the final week of the month when she is waiting to receive her next salary. This
is depicted in Figure 5.1a below.
2
‘Transactions’, T , are often proxied by income, Y , to give a quantity theory of M V = P Y .
3
Notice the similarity between this equation and the macroeconomic money demand equations in
Chapter 2 of the subject guide.
59
5. Classical theory
Figure 5.1:
The classical economists assumed that, although money was essential for the efficient
functioning of the economy, the quantity of money units had no impact on real
60
5.7. The quantity theory of money
Say’s law essentially states that supply creates its own demand. In a barter economy in
which there are n − 1 goods, each supplier has an endowment of some good. They each
exchange these goods for those they desire and it is the level of their endowment, that
determines how much they can buy. Supply funds demand. It must therefore be true
that the sum of expenditures over all goods i = 1, . . . , n − 1 must equal the sum of the
supplies of all goods, denoted Si .
n−1
X n−1
X
pi Di ≡ pi S i (5.7)
i=1 i=1
where pi is the relative price of one good in terms of another. Remember we are
considering a barter economy here, which therefore has no monetary prices.
Alternatively, defining the excess demand for good i, EDi , as Di − Si , then:
n−1
X
pi EDi ≡ 0. (5.8)
i=1
In Say’s view, market laws imply that there cannot be a ‘general glut’. If there exists an
excess demand for one good then there must be an excess supply of another. However,
there cannot be a general excess demand or general excess supply at the aggregate level
(in a closed economy). Each household has endowments of one or more goods, and a
utility function defined over all goods, from which we can derive the demand of each
household for each good as a function of relative prices. Adding up the demand for each
good across households, and given the total endowment of that good, we can write
down a market clearing equation for each good as a function of relative prices.
Since all households must balance their budgets, the sum of all market clearing
equations must add up to zero. Therefore in a market for n − 1 goods, if there is
equilibrium in n − 2 goods, there must be equilibrium in the final market. This is
Walras’ law. The n − 1 market clearing equations are not independent; if all markets
except one clear, the last market must clear also. Only n − 2 equations are independent,
but this is sufficient to solve for n − 2 relative prices, for example the prices of all goods
in terms of good 1. To establish the equilibrium of an economy of n − 1 goods we may
solve for n − 2 relative prices and this will in turn determine the demand from each
household for each good.
4
Relative prices being the exchange ratios of one good for another, for example one kilogram of
tomatoes equals two loaves of bread.
61
5. Classical theory
Now consider a monetary economy (i.e. we introduce fiat money as the n-th good). The
price of this good is pn , usually normalised to unity for simplicity. From Walras’ law:
n
X n
X
pi Di ≡ pi S i (5.9)
i=1 i=1
Dn and Sn are the demand and supply of nominal money balances, respectively, and
from Walras’ law we can see that if there is equilibrium in the n − 1 goods markets then
there must be equilibrium in the money market. However, Say’s law may not hold.
There can exist a general excess supply in the n − 1 goods markets; (5.7) may not hold,
but only if this is offset by excess demand in the money market. The demand for good i
will depend on all relative prices and income, implying excess demand for good i, EDi ,
of:5
P1 P 2 Pn−1
EDi = fi , ,..., , Y − Si∗ (5.11)
Pn P n Pn
where Y is the total output. However, the absolute price level, the price of money, pn ,
will have no effect on excess demand. If the price of money, pn , doubles, caused by a
doubling of the money supply from the equation of exchange, since pn is an average of
all other prices, then p1 , . . . , pn−1 must all double also. The relative prices,
p1 /pn , . . . , pn−1 /pn , will not change, resulting in no change in (excess) demands for any
goods. In this way, a changing of the money supply will have no repercussions in the
real economy. Hence money is neutral.
There were found to be a number of criticisms of the dichotomy the classical economists
had proposed.6 One problem was that the model was internally inconsistent. On the one
hand, the excess demand for each commodity, i = 1, . . . , n − 1, was only dependent on
relative prices, not the absolute price level, pn , and from Walras’ law, the excess
demand for money is then determined. The excess demand for money is then only a
function of relative prices. However, from the quantity theory, which is needed to solve
the entire system of equations, the demand for money explicitly depended on the
absolute price level. On one side, money market equilibrium depends only on relative
prices while on the other side, it depends only on the absolute price level.
An attempt to resolve this problem was made by Patinkin who included the value of
real money balances, Sn /pn , as a determinant of the demand for each good; in other
words the excess demand for each good i is given by:
P1 P2 Pn−1 Sn
EDi = fi , ,..., , Y, − Si∗ . (5.12)
Pn Pn Pn Pn
5
Assume for simplicity that the supply is fixed at Si∗ .
6
See Lewis and Mizen (2000) Chapter 4 for an excellent description of these criticisms.
62
5.8. A simple general equilibrium framework
Real money balances are the ratio between nominal money balances and the price level.
A change in either of these nominal variables will change the value of the real variable
and thereby change the demand for commodities. Thus, starting from a position of
equilibrium in all markets including the money market, assume that there is an increase
in the supply of money. This increases real money balances which in turn increases the
demand for commodities, even though there has been no change in relative prices. But
the increase in demand, having started from a position of equilibrium, must mean that
there is now excess demand, a situation which denies Say’s law. The increased demand
for commodities will then bring about an increase in the general level of prices that will
reduce real balances. Eventually real balances will return to their equilibrium level, as
will the demand for commodities. Real balances provide a bridge between the real and
monetary sectors of the classical system and dispose of the classical dichotomy, that is
factors influencing nominal variables are separated from factors influencing real
variables, while retaining the neutrality of money, that is monetary changes do not
change real variables.
So that the nominal expenditure on goods, P X, plus the holdings of nominal money
balances, M , must not be greater than the nominal value of the endowments of goods
and money. Writing the budget constraint in real terms (dividing by the price level)
gives:
M M0
X+ ≤ X0 + . (5.14)
P P
The household’s utility function takes the specific form U = X 1/2 (M/P )1/2 . In order to
determine the demands for goods and real money balances, we maximise the utility
function subject to the budget constraint. To do this we form the Lagrangian:7
1/2
1/2 M M0 M
L=X + λ X0 + −X − . (5.15)
P P P
7
We also impose an equality in the budget constraint as this implies no wastage of goods or money.
63
5. Classical theory
Differentiating with respect to the two choice variables, X and M/P , gives the first
order conditions of:
1/2
∂L 1 −1/2 M
= X −λ=0 (5.16)
∂X 2 P
−1/2
∂L 1 1/2 M
= X − λ = 0, (5.17)
∂(M/P ) 2 P
X0 + M0 /P P X0 + M0
X= and M = . (5.19)
2 2
Assume now that the economy consists of n households each identical to the one
described above. The market clearing condition in the goods market then becomes:
X0 + M0 /P
n = nX0 . (5.20)
2
In other words, total demand equals total supply. Solving for the price level gives:
M0
P = . (5.21)
X0
Alternatively, we can write down the market clearing condition for the money market:
P X0 + M0
n = nM0 . (5.22)
2
M0
P = . (5.23)
X0
Activity 5.1 Why is the solution for the price level the same when we solve for the
goods market equilibrium as for when we solve for the money market equilibrium?
(Hint: Consider Walras’ law and the fact we are considering only two markets: those
for goods and money!)
64
5.9. A reminder of your learning outcomes
Figure 5.2:
describe the essential features and predictions of the quantity theory of money
describe the main features of the classical system and the classical dichotomy
state the nature and importance of Patinkin’s real balance effect for the internal
consistency of the classical dichotomy.
Specify whether the following statement is true, false or uncertain. Explain your answer
in a short paragraph.
65
5. Classical theory
Section B
2. To what do economists refer by the phrases ‘neutrality of money’ and ‘the classical
dichotomy’ ? What problem did Patinkin have with these ideas and how did he
solve it?
3. Which factors did the Cambridge quantity theorists (A. Marshall, A. Pigou) stress
as significant in explaining the transactions demand for money?
4. ‘A given increase in the stock of money has the same long-run effect on the price
level whether it results from a temporary budget deficit, or from open market
operations, or is dropped from a helicopter.’ Discuss.
5. Walras’ law states that the sum of excess demands in all markets must be zero.
How does this differ from the following statement? If there are n goods, the
markets for n − 1 goods must always be in equilibrium.
1. The statement is false. Suggested answers will introduce the quantity theory,
M V = P T , explaining that V depends on institutional factors such as the
frequency with which people are paid, spending patterns, etc. You should also show
that a doubling of V results in a halving of M , the demand for money. This could
be done using the example of (5.5) and (5.6).
Section B
66
5.11. Feedback to Sample examination questions
5. Walras’ law can be derived from Say’s law, which essentially states that supply
creates its own demand. If the sum of excess demands in all markets must add up
to zero, then if the sum of excess demands in markets 1 to n − 1 are zero, it must
be the case that excess demand in the n-th market is also zero. However, with n
goods, the markets for n − 1 goods can only be in equilibrium if the market for the
n-th good is in equilibrium. If there is positive excess demand in the n-th market,
there must be positive excess supply in the n − 1-th market, implying
disequilibrium in these n − 1 markets.
67
5. Classical theory
68
Chapter 6
Stylised facts
6.1 Introduction
Macro-monetary models aim to explain the macroeconomic phenomena that we observe
in the data. In order to do so we need to have a set of stylised facts that we want to
explain. Bear in mind that a model can only be judged by its usefulness to explain
those stylised facts. Collecting data from statistical agencies and policy institutions
(such as national statistical offices, OECD, IMF/IFS, central banks), about production,
consumption, investment, inflation, employment, unemployment and so on, is the first
step to start analysing those facts we want to evaluate statistically and provide an
internally consistent narrative to explain these facts. However, statistical (time series)
data often need to be adjusted for establishing these stylised facts. In this chapter we
will introduce several concepts of macroeconomics for which we need to look into the
data and adjust these so that they become our statistical benchmarks.
6.2 Aims
This chapter aims to introduce key macroeconomic stylised facts which need to be
explained by theoretical modelling. To this end, some simple statistical tools such as
means, variances, correlations will be utilised.
69
6. Stylised facts
Journal articles
Aksoy, Y. and G. Melina ‘US fiscal indicators, inflation and output’, North American
Journal of Economics and Finance 22 2011, pp.221–36.
Alvarez, L. , E. Dhyne , M. Hoeberichts , C. Kwapil , H. Le Bihan , P. L´’unnemann , F.
Martins, R. Sabbatini, H. Stahl , P. Vermeulen and Jouko Vilmunen, ‘Sticky Prices in
the Euro Area: A Summary of New Micro-Evidence’, Journal of the European Economic
Association 4 2006, pp.575–584.
Bils, M and P.J. Klenow, ‘Some Evidence on the Importance of Sticky Prices’, Journal
of Political Economy, 112 2004, pp.947–985.
70
6.7. Trends and business cycles
Cotis, J.P. and J. Coppel ‘Business cycle dynamics in OECD countries: Evidence, causes
and policy implications’, OECD, http://www.oecd.org/economy/growth/35125435.pdf.
Kuttner, K.N. and T. Robinson ‘Understanding the flattening of Phillips curve’, North
American Journal of Economics and Finance, 21 2010, pp.110–125.
Figure 6.1:
What do business cycles and trends look like in time series data? In Figure 6.2, we plot
seasonally adjusted real GDP levels in Germany, Turkey and the US for the period of
1960 Q1 – 2013 Q2 as reported by the OECD.
71
6. Stylised facts
Figure 6.2:
As can be seen from Figure 6.2, all series are trending upward with some cyclical
variations. We would like to decompose the data into its trend and business cycle
component and then analyse volatility, persistence and cyclicality of the business cycle
components. This cyclical component of the real GDP levels data is sometimes labelled
as the output gap.
Before we discuss how to extract the business cycle component from a level series, it is
useful to transform the data by taking its natural logarithms. There are various good
reasons for doing so. First, it rescales the time series from large numbers to more
reasonable numbers without affecting the time series properties significantly. Second,
the difference between the natural logarithms of two numbers is approximately the
percentage change in the series across time periods as long as the difference is rather
small. Third, graphically you can interpret the changes in the time series, since the
72
6.8. Moments
where λ denotes the penalty parameter imposed on changing the slope of the smoothed
series, (xt )Tt=1 is the original real output data and (xG T
t )t=1 is the smoothed real output
series. When λ = 0, the HP filter will set xG t = xt for all t. There will be no smoothing.
When λ → ∞, the resulting trend will be linear. For quarterly data, typically, a λ value
of 1600 is assigned.
When we apply the HP filter to real GDP, consumption and investment data, we obtain
the following trend (Figure 6.4) and cyclical components (Figure 6.5) of the real output
series for the US.
6.8 Moments
After removing the growth trend from the data we would like to understand its business
cycle behaviour. As we have already taken natural logarithms, the business cycle
component is interpretable as a percent deviation of the variable from its growth trend.
As a next step we want to study their mean, volatility, cyclicality and persistence. Mean
is simply the average of the business cycle component of a variable. Volatility measures
how the variable of our concern fluctuates in time. Cyclicality shows how the business
cycle component of a particular variable evolves in relation to the business cycle
component of the real GDP. Persistence provides us a clue about the likelihood of a
variable to stay, say, above trend next period, when it is above trend in the current
period.
Means
The first moment of any time series is the sample average or the sample mean (x̄). To
calculate (x̄) of the business cycle component (xbc
t ) we use the following formula:
T
1 X bc
x̄ = x . (6.2)
T t=1 t
1
This implies that the constant growth is a straight line with log GDP.
2
Note that in Excel you can extract the business cycle component with the help of a macro file
(HPFilter.xla)
73
6. Stylised facts
Figure 6.3:
Given that the business cycle fluctuates around a trend component, by construction,
the sample mean is zero.
Standard deviation
The second moment of any time series is the variance around its mean. A sample
standard deviation (σx ) is simply the square root of the variance of the series.
v
u
u 1 X T
σx = t (xbc − x̄)2 . (6.3)
T − 1 t=1 t
The larger the deviations of a time series from its mean, the larger the sum will be on
average. In other words, a more volatile series will have a larger standard deviation.
Volatility measures how a particular variable fluctuates around over time. The standard
deviation of the HP filtered series serves as a measure for volatility.
In Table 6.1, we display standard deviations of the business cycle component of real
GDP, consumption and investment for three countries, Germany, Turkey and the US.
Table 6.1 shows two results we would like to take home. First, relative standard
deviations of the cyclical component of consumption to real output ratio are less than
one in Germany and the US. This is often interpreted as smoother consumption than
74
6.8. Moments
income over time. Note that for the same sample period cyclical consumption in Turkey
exhibits more volatility than income. Thus, consumption smoothing may not be such a
general rule, however, most macro-monetary models aim to explain less volatile
consumption relative to income. Second, in all these three countries, cyclical component
of investment is more volatile than income, roughly in the order of 3.
Figure 6.4:
Cyclicality
Another second moment about means is the covariance. It measures whether two
business cycle components, xbc and y bc , move in tandem. The sample covariance (σxy )
75
6. Stylised facts
T
1 X bc
σxy = (xt − x̄)(ytbc − ȳ). (6.4)
T − 1 t=1
Terms in the sum may be clearly positive or negative. If two series tend to ‘comove’ in
the same direction, then whenever a term in series x is above its mean, then the
corresponding term in series y tends to be above its mean as well and whenever a term
in series x is below its mean, then the corresponding term in series y tends to be below
its mean as well. Therefore, a sample covariance will have mostly positive numbers
which yield a positive sum. The opposite is true, when two series co-move in the
opposite direction. A large covariance may make life somewhat difficult for us. It may
be due to high correlation between these two variables or both series may have large
variances that lead to large terms in the sum. In order to deal with this, we divide the
covariance by the two standard deviations. Resulting ratio is labelled as the ‘correlation
coefficient’.
σxy
ρxy = . (6.5)
σx σy
The correlation coefficient will be between −1 and 1. Highly correlated series will have a
correlation coefficient close to 1 in absolute value. If y represents the real GDP, a high
positive correlation coefficient with a series x indicates that the series x is ‘procyclical’.
Similarly, a high negative correlation coefficient with a series x indicates that the series
x is ‘countercyclical’. If the correlation coefficient is near zero, we label the series as
being ‘acyclical’.
Table 6.2 displays correlation coefficients of consumption, investment and real output in
the US, Germany and Turkey.
First, we observe that for each country, consumption and investment are positively
correlated with their real output, hence both consumption and investment are
procyclical variables. Second, although investment constitutes a smaller fraction in the
calculations of real GDP than consumption, the correlation coefficients between
investment and real GDP are somewhat higher than the correlation coefficients between
consumption and real GDP. Third, while the US business cycle to some extent seems to
be positively correlated with business cycles in Germany and Turkey, German and
Turkish business cycles appear to be slightly negatively correlated with each other.
76
6.8. Moments
Figure 6.5:
Persistence
77
6. Stylised facts
Inclusion of more recent data-points after the financial crisis leads in most cases to a
slight decline in their persistence.
Autocorrelation coefficients for all series are quite large. When they are above (below)
the trend in the current period, they tend to remain above (below) the trend next
period. We conclude that series in our sample display strong persistence.
78
6.10. Key macroeconomic relationships
Recessions in East Asia are deeper than in Latin America and Eastern Europe,
however East Asian economies experience the fastest recoveries.
Although both industrial and emerging markets have experienced deep recessions
during the recent global financial crisis, the emerging markets have recovered faster.
Activity 6.1 Calculate the business cycle component and its statistical properties
for the country you are living in by using excel.
Ever since the work by Friedman and Schwartz on the determinants of U.S. inflation,
there has been a strong consensus among economists that variations in monetary
aggregates are closely associated with variations in inflation over a reasonably long time
period. There is also broad agreement about the direction of causation: variations in
money lead to variations in inflation. This consensus has some theoretical support from
the so called Quantity Theory of Money (QTM) (See Chapter 5). In its simplest form,
the QTM argues that variations in some measure of money supply are followed by the
inflation rate. We can write the QTM directly in logarithmic differences (lowercase
letters) so that we can refer to changes in the variables concerned.
where m represents the variations in money supply, p the inflation rate, y variations in
real income and v variations in the velocity of money supply. If we solve for the inflation
rate, p, we obtain:
p = m − y + v. (6.9)
79
6. Stylised facts
When we assume that variations in the money supply, m, do not impact the long run
real income, y, or velocity, v, money supply variations and inflation will be
proportional. In other words, a one per cent increase in the money supply will lead to a
one per cent increase in the inflation rate. To test the hypothesis De Grauwe and Polan
(2005) study 159 countries for the period of 1969–1999. First, they find a strong positive
relation between the long run growth rate of money and inflation. However, this relation
is not one to one. Second, they argue that this strong link between inflation and money
growth is mainly due to the presence of high inflation countries in their sample; there
seems to be no clear long run link between money growth and inflation in low inflation
economies. Third, they confirm the QTM assumption of no relationship between real
income and money growth in the long run. In other words money is long run neutral,
i.e. does not have permanent effects on output.
80
6.11. Relationship between monetary instruments and macroeconomy
Figure 6.6:
instrument can only be useful in the monetary policy implementation to the extent that
variations in the policy instrument over time regularly and reliably associated with
variations in income, prices, unemployment or any other variable the policy maker is
seeking to influence. The question for a policy maker is then choosing either a monetary
aggregate or a short-term rate as the policy instrument.
To answer the question, Friedman and Kuttner (1992) analysed the ‘information
content’ of variations in a range of US monetary aggregates and short-term interest
rates to explain variations in US real/nominal GDP and inflation. They conclude that
while monetary aggregates were useful in explaining US real output and inflation up
until the early 1980s, thereafter these lost their informational value, whereas short-term
interest rates or the spread between the commercial paper rate and Treasury bill rate
retained their information content in explaining movements in real income. Hence, not
surprisingly, starting from the early 1990s onwards, nearly all major central banks
focused on short-term interest rates as their policy variable. Currently, monetary policy
announcements of central banks are almost always about short-term interest rates.
81
6. Stylised facts
More recently, Aksoy and Piskorski (2006) argued that the loss of information content
in US monetary aggregates has actually something to do with the measurement of
monetary aggregates. In particular, they argue that as the US currency enjoys a reserve
currency position in the global financial and trade system, foreign holdings of the US
dollar are sizeable. Moreover, the foreign demand for the US dollar is changing over
time affecting the time series properties of the monetary aggregates. What matters for
the US domestic economic conditions is not the aggregate level of monetary aggregates,
but monetary aggregates corrected for the foreign holdings (domestic money). They
show that variations in domestic money contain valuable information in explaining
variations in not only US real income but also variations in US inflation. Thus, any
analysis, that does not take the international currency feature of US dollar into account,
may be misleading. In other words, money continues to be useful as an information
variable and a potential policy instrument.
Prices change infrequently. In a given month 15.1 per cent of prices are changed
and the average duration of a price spell ranges from 4 to 5 quarters. These figures
mean that price adjustment in the euro area is considerably less frequent than in
the US (Bils and Klenow (2004)).
Frequency of price changes across products differ. Price changes are very frequent
for energy (oil products) and unprocessed food, while they are relatively infrequent
for non-energy industrial goods and services.
Differences across countries appear to be less important than cross-sector
differences.
On average, 40 per cent of the price changes are price reductions.
Price changes, either increases or decreases, are sizeable compared to the inflation
rate prevailing in each country.
82
6.14. Sample examination questions
Specify whether the following statement is true, false or uncertain. Explain your answer
in a short paragraph.
Section B
3. What are the key stylised facts in business cycle analysis that a theoretical model
should try to explain? Are there any differences between industrialised economies
and emerging market economies?
5. Is there empirical evidence in favour of Phillips curve? In the light of the discussion
in Kuttner and Robinson, provide an explanation for recent developments in in the
statistical relationship between output gap and inflation.
Specify whether the following statement is true, false or uncertain. Explain your answer
in a short paragraph.
1. The statement is false. Suggested answers should include an exact definition of the
business cycle. A complementary stylised business cycle figure is recommended.
Section B
4. While there is some relationship between variations in money and inflation in the
long run, the relationship appears to be different between high and low inflation
economies. (De Grauwe and Polan (2005)). In the short run the relationship
appears to be weaker (Friedman and Kuttner (1992)). For the US one needs to take
83
6. Stylised facts
international currency feature of US dollar into account and only then apply the
relevant statistical analysis (Aksoy and Piskorski (2006)).
84
Chapter 7
Money, inflation and welfare
7.1 Introduction
In Chapter 5, we saw that in classical theory money was neutral, not having any effects
on real variables such as consumption or output. The welfare effects of money and
inflation, however, were not considered. Even if a change in the money supply does not
cause output or consumption to change, does it cause the utility or welfare of
individuals to be affected? This chapter will discuss such issues, noting the difference
between the neutrality and superneutrality of money. Finally, issues in hyperinflation
will be considered.
7.2 Aims
This chapter aims to study money, inflation and welfare in a flexible price environment.
It will introduce such concepts as the real and nominal interest rates, the
superneutrality of money, inflation tax and hyperinflations.
describe the relationship between real and nominal interest rates and why the
relationship holds
explain what superneutrality means and give examples of when monetary policy
can be neutral but not superneutral
define a monetary policy which maximises welfare and quantify the welfare cost
associated with a given level of inflation
discuss the merits of using inflation as a source of government revenue rather than
other forms of tax
85
7. Money, inflation and welfare
Cagan, P. ‘Hyperinflation’, in Newman, P., M. Milgate and J. Eatwell (eds) The New
Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance. (London: Macmillan, 1994).
Danthine, J.P. ‘Superneutrality’, in Newman, P., M. Milgate and J. Eatwell (eds) The
New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance. (London: Macmillan, 1994).
Friedman, M. ‘The quantity theory of money’, in Newman, P., M. Milgate and J.
Eatwell (eds) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance. (London:
Macmillan, 1994).
Harris, L. Monetary Theory. (New York; London: McGraw-Hill, 1985) Chapter 19.
Mankiw, N.G. Macroeconomics. (New York: Worth Publishers, 2002).
Journal articles
Diamond, P.A. ‘Search, sticky prices and inflation’, Review of Economic Studies 59(4)
1993, pp.53–68.
Sargent, T. and N.Wallace ‘Some unpleasant monetarist arithmetic’, Federal Reserve
Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 531 (1981), Fall.
86
7.6. Further reading
Neutrality
In the classical model, which we assume here, prices are perfectly flexible and the
economy is then one in which output is always at (full employment) equilibrium. We
will also not consider other sources of non-neutrality such as contracts or debts
denominated in nominal terms. In such an economy, as established in Chapter 5, money
is neutral in the sense that in static equilibrium all real variables in the economy are
independent of the quantity of nominal money and the price level is proportional to the
quantity of money.
It might appear that an immediate implication of neutrality is that the rate of growth
of the quantity of money would also be neutral in the sense of affecting the rate of
growth of the price level (inflation) but no real variables. This is known as
‘superneutrality’. Then inflation would indeed be a monetary phenomenon and at the
same time would have no real effects. However, it turns out that even in a flexible price
economy this implication is not correct, the reason being that expectations of the future
growth rate of the quantity of money create expectations of inflation and expectations of
inflation are not neutral. The starting point is the distinction between real and nominal
interest rates, and the relationship between them; the ‘Fisher equation’.
If people expect there to be inflation over some period, quoted interest rates no longer
represent the rate at which goods today can be traded for goods in the future. Imagine
a deposit paying a fixed interest rate, Rt % per annum on balances at the beginning of
period t, paid at the beginning of period t + 1. Then £100 today becomes £100(1 + Rt )
in a year’s time. However, if the price level at the beginning of the year were Pt , and
prices were to rise during the year at a rate πt+1 (πt+1 being the inflation rate between
periods t and t + 1), the quantity of goods that can actually be purchased at the end of
the year is £100(1 + Rt )/Pt (1 + πt+1 ). Thus not consuming £100/Pt goods at the
beginning of the year enables one to consume £100(1 + Rt )/Pt (1 + πt+1 ) more goods at
the end of the year. For small values of Rt and pt+1 , this expression can be
approximated by £100(1 + Rt − πt+1 )/Pt , and the term (Rt − πt+1 ) is known as the
‘real’ rate of interest, rt . The relationship between the real and nominal rate of interest,
which is known as the Fisher equation, is therefore by definition:
rt = Rt − πt+1 . (7.1)
The ex-ante real interest rate, rtA , measures the quantity of goods at the end of the
period which people expect to be able to buy as a proportion of the quantity they
could buy today with the money they deposit or lend. Then:
rtA = Rt − πt+1
e
(7.2)
87
7. Money, inflation and welfare
e
where πt+1 is the expected rate of inflation between dates t and t + 1, formed at
date t.
In the same way the ex-post real interest rate, rtP , measures the actual real interest
rate during some past period, which is the quantity of goods at the end of the
period that a depositor was actually able to buy relative to what could have been
bought at the beginning. Evidently,
In measuring ex-post real interest rates it should be noted that current quoted
nominal interest rates relate to the future whereas quoted inflation rates refer to
the past, hence the different time subscripts. If one wanted to know the ex-post real
interest rate for 2002 it would be necessary to subtract the 2002 inflation rate (as
recorded at the end of the year/beginning of 2003) from the nominal rate quoted
for one-year money at the beginning of the year.
If everyone correctly forecasts the rate at which prices will rise over some period and
acts on the basis of these expectations, inflation is said to be fully anticipated. In this
e
case of course, πt+1 = πt+1 , and the ex-ante and ex-post real interest rates are therefore
equal.
Activity 7.1 How can borrowers commit to paying the real rate of return on any
sums lent to them?
Superneutrality
τ are taxes so that consumption depends positively on disposable income and negatively
on the real interest rate. A high real interest rate will encourage saving (decrease
current consumption) as one unit of consumption goods today can yield a larger
number of consumption goods tomorrow. There is then a negative relationship between
the real rate and output.
−
r=H Y . (7.5)
88
7.6. Further reading
The standard model is somewhat simplified in that it has no wealth effects in the IS
curve. A full and general model would include such effects, and in such a model a fall in
real money balances would constitute a fall in wealth, which would tend to raise savings.
A rise in savings would shift the IS curve inwards and thus lower the equilibrium real
interest rate and increase investment. This is known as the Mundell–Tobin effect. It
says that in inflationary times people wish to hold less wealth in the form of real money
balances and therefore attempt to acquire other forms of wealth including real capital.
1
While IS–LM model used to analyse economies with short term price stickiness, remember that there
are no such rigidities in this model.
89
7. Money, inflation and welfare
In practice, however, in most advanced economies fiat money balances constitute so tiny
a proportion of people’s wealth that this effect can be ignored.
For any given output level, a fall in real money balances necessitates a fall in real
interest rates in order to offset the decrease in aggregate demand. In goods market
90
7.6. Further reading
equilibrium there is then a positive relationship between M/P and r. Following the
increase in inflation, caused by the positive growth rate of nominal money balances, the
IS curve shifts out as in Figure 7.1 but is partially offset because of the fall in wealth
(fall in M/P ) which reduces consumption. The nominal interest rate only increases to
R10 (< R1 in Figure 7.1) and since inflation is the same in both Figure 7.1 and Figure
7.3, the real interest rate, r10 , will be less than r0 , (i.e. the real rate has fallen).
The key insight, which follows from Friedman’s price-theoretic approach to modelling
the demand for money, is that the area under the demand curve measures the utility
derived by individuals from holding money balances. The opportunity cost to
individuals of holding money balances is measured by the nominal rate of interest, R.
The consumers’ surplus enjoyed by individuals from holding money balances, that is,
the excess of the utility they derive over the opportunity cost they incur, is thus
measured by the area A in Figure 7.4.
Suppose that, initially, there is no inflation, so that the nominal interest rate in Figure
7.4 is equal to the real interest rate (R0 = r). Given this interest rate, the total stock of
91
7. Money, inflation and welfare
money balances, which individuals wish to hold, is denoted (M/P )0 . The area B
measures the annual income stream the government as issuer of money is able to
acquire by the once and for all purchase of productive assets with the money it issues.
(In a static economy with no inflation, the stock of money outstanding is constant, but
the government was able to acquire real assets with it at the time it was introduced.)
But if the money is fiat money, the cost of production is approximately zero, so the
government is essentially able to acquire real assets ‘for free’ by virtue of its monopoly
position on the money issue. This is known as ‘seigniorage’, and it represents a transfer
of resources from money holders (households and firms) to the government.
Seigniorage is essentially a form of taxation, and the area C in Figure 7.4 is the excess
burden or deadweight loss associated with this tax. Holdings by individuals of money
balances in excess of (M/P )0 yield positive utility and the additional money costs
nothing to produce. Therefore, there would be economic benefit from expanding the
quantity of real money balances held from (M/P )0 up to the point of ‘full liquidity’, L.
However, this cannot be done through an expansion of the nominal money stock,
because with an interest rate of R0 the desired holding of money balances is (M/P )0 ,
and any additional nominal money will lead to an increase in the price level to restore
the desired quantity of real balances.
The social utility of money in Figure 7.4 is measured by the area A + B, the sum of
consumers’ surplus and the revenues obtained by the government from seigniorage.
Given the demand curve, the maximum possible social utility that could be achieved is
when the holdings of money balances are at L (full liquidity), which is Friedman’s
‘optimal quantity of money’. To induce individuals to hold the optimal quantity of
money it is necessary that the nominal interest rate be zero. Only in this case will the
demand for money be equal to L. Given the Fisher equation, the nominal interest rate
will be zero when the rate of price inflation is equal to minus the real interest rate (i.e.
R = 0 when p = −r).
The welfare cost of fully anticipated inflation arises because inflation raises the nominal
interest rate, reducing the demand for real money balances and therefore reducing the
utility obtained from the use of money. In Figure 7.5 we consider an economy with fully
anticipated inflation at a rate of p1 . The nominal interest rate is now R1 (= r + p1 ), and
the demand for money is (M/P )1 . The consumers’ surplus is again measured by the
area under the demand curve and above the opportunity cost of holding money, and is
therefore the area A. The area B + D represents the revenue the government now
derives from money issue, of which B is generally known as the ‘inflation tax’, and as
before, D is seigniorage, real interest rate times real money balances. The inflation tax
refers to the resources obtained by the government by the continuing process of printing
money during times of inflation. (If the inflation rate is p1 , and the volume of real
money balances (M/P )1 , the amount of nominal money the government will need to
print per period to maintain the real stock of money constant is p1 (M/P )1 .)
Comparing Figure 7.4 with Figure 7.5, the welfare cost of inflation may be measured as
the loss of consumers’ surplus, B + C, plus the loss of seigniorage, E, less the inflation
tax revenue, B.
Welfare cost = B + C + E − B = C + E. (7.9)
This is equal to the reduction in the quantity of real money balances demanded
multiplied by the nominal interest rate averaged over that range. The welfare cost of
92
7.7. Inflation as taxation
fully anticipated inflation arises because individuals choose to incur the cost and
inconvenience of economising on money balances in times of inflation. Inflation raises
the private cost of holding money balances though the social cost of creating money
remains negligible.
Activity 7.2 What other factors, other than efficiency, should determine the extent
to which the government uses inflation as a form of taxation?
Hyperinflation
The popular image of hyperinflation is of very rapid, and in particular very rapidly
accelerating, inflation, leading to astronomical prices and to a collapse of the monetary
system. The most famous hyperinflation of this type in a major industrial country was
Germany in 1922–23. Prices increased by 500,000 times within the space of a few
months in the autumn of 1923, the prices of staple commodities like a loaf of bread or a
newspaper ran into hundreds of billions of marks. Notwithstanding this, money
remained the medium of exchange, although the attempt to spend money as soon as it
was received itself generated faster inflation. The greatest cost of the hyperinflation,
however, was the impoverishment of households with monetary assets whose value was
destroyed.
Hyperinflations of this type result from political instability such that the government is
unable to finance its expenditure except through money creation. The acceleration of
inflation results in part from deteriorating public finances and in part from the ‘flight of
money’ caused by expectations of faster inflation. In the twentieth century, there were
hyperinflations after the First World War in Austria, Germany, Hungary, Poland and
Russia, and after the Second World War in Bulgaria, Greece, Hungary, Poland and
Romania. More recently, there have been hyperinflations associated with the collapse of
the former Soviet Union and with the effects of war, in particular in parts of former
Yugoslavia (e.g. Serbia).
93
7. Money, inflation and welfare
Activity 7.3 What has been the highest rate of inflation in your country?
These rapidly accelerating hyperinflations are unsustainable, and are usually terminated
by a financial reconstruction involving a new government, a new currency whose value is
sometimes secured by a fixed exchange rate or currency board, and a fiscal
reconstruction that may involve a repudiation of government debt or other obligations.
To demonstrate how hyperinflations can lead to a collapse in the demand for money,
consider the model of money demand by Cagan (1956). Take a standard money demand
equation of the form:
M
ln = ayt − bRt . (7.11)
P t
Replacing Rt with rt + pet+1 from the Fisher equation, this can be written as:
e
ln Mt = ln Pt + ayt − brt − bπt+1 . (7.12)
Differentiate this with respect to time and assume that output growth and real interest
rate changes are small relative to changes in nominal quantities, as is likely in periods of
hyperinflations, which is what the Cagan model tries to study.
e
d(ln Mt ) d(ln Pt ) d(πt+1 )
= −b . (7.13)
dt dt dt
d(ln Mt )/dt is the growth rate of the money supply, mt , and d(ln Pt )/dt is the growth
rate of the price level, or inflation, πt . Rearranging gives:
e
d(πt+1 )
πt = mt + b . (7.14)
dt
e
If inflation is expected to increase in the future (i.e. d(πt+1 )/dt is positive), then these
expectations can cause inflation to increase to a level above mt . Increases in inflation
will cause individuals to increase their expectations of inflation, which in turn causes pt
to increase even further from (7.14). The collapse in the demand for money is then
partly caused by expectations of faster inflation next to growth rate of the money
supply (mt ), which are, ultimately, self-fulfilling.
A more recent phenomenon has been a widespread experience of very rapid but none the
less continuing and non-explosive inflation. For example, there have been inflation rates
averaging over 100 per cent a year lasting for 10 years or more in many South American
countries such as Argentina, Brazil or Peru during the 1980s. Such very rapid but stable
inflations can be explained in terms of a continuing but non-deteriorating government
deficit. This can be demonstrated in the form of a very simple model due to Dornbusch.
Assume a government whose expenditure falls short of the money it can raise from
taxation by some amount, which is a fixed proportion, g, of nominal income. The
government has a poor credit rating and is unable to borrow from the capital markets
so this deficit can be financed only through the creation of money. The deficit per unit
time period is given by:
Deficit = gP y (7.15)
94
7.7. Inflation as taxation
where P is the price level and y is real GDP. This deficit is financed by an increase in
the money stock, so that:
dM
= gP y. (7.16)
dt
In the simplest version of the model the monetary sector is described by the quantity
theory equation:
M V = Py . (7.17)
For large values of g and/or V the inflation rate can be quite rapid, but in the simplest
versions of this model there is no reason why it should accelerate. A straightforward
modification of the model is to allow the velocity of circulation to be increasing in the
inflation rate, V = V (π) with V 0 > 0, which may lead to a deteriorating trade-off
between the deficit and inflation and to the possibility of instability. See Figure 7.6.
If we are initially at point E’ and inflation increases, this will cause velocity to increase
since V = V (π). Higher velocity will cause inflation to rise (π = gV ) and the process
continues with ever increasing inflation. Point E’ is therefore an unstable equilibrium.
Figure 7.6:
Activity 7.4 Explain, using Figure 7.6, why point E is a stable equilibrium. (Hint:
start by examining what happens when inflation increases slightly from point E.)
95
7. Money, inflation and welfare
Activity 7.5
1. In the economy of Mythica, prices are perfectly flexible and output is always at
its full employment level, Y . The velocity of circulation of money is constant,
and the stock of money, M , grows at a constant rate, m. Aggregate demand,
the IS curve, is given by Y d = A − b(R − π e ), where R is the nominal rate of
interest and π e is the expected rate of inflation.
(a) What is the inflation rate, π, in Mythica?
(b) If the inhabitants of Mythica have perfect foresight, what is the effect of
increasing the growth rate of the money supply on real and nominal
interest rates?
(c) Is the stock of real money balances affected by the rate of growth of the
money supply?
Imagine now that due to an increase in financial sophistication in Mythica the
demand for money becomes sensitive to the interest rate so that in place of the
quantity theory equation, we have (M/P )d = H − kR. How are your answers to
parts (a) to (c) above affected by this development? Is money i. neutral, and ii.
superneutral in Mythica?
describe the relationship between real and nominal interest rates and why the
relationship holds
explain what superneutrality means and give examples of when monetary policy
96
7.9. Sample examination questions
define a monetary policy which maximises welfare and quantify the welfare cost
associated with a given level of inflation
discuss the merits of using inflation as a source of government revenue rather than
other forms of tax
Specify whether the following statement is true, false or uncertain. Explain your answer
in a short paragraph.
Section B
2. What is meant by the ‘superneutrality’ of money? How does it relate to the Fisher
equation? If money is superneutral, does it follow that inflation has no welfare
costs?
3. Assume that the government can control the rate of inflation exactly. What rate
should it set? Outline arguments in favour of positive, zero and negative inflation
rates.
5. Consider the economy of Mythica in Activity 7.5, noting the values of the variables
in part 2.
(a) If monetary policy affects social welfare only through its effect on the
consumer surplus obtained from the use of money, what rate of monetary
growth maximises social welfare in Mythica? What is the nominal rate of
interest in this optimal regime?
(b) If the government of Mythica can finance its expenditure only through money
creation, what is the relationship between government expenditure as a
proportion of GDP (g) and the growth rate of the money stock? Is there a
limit to the expenditure, which can be financed in this way?
97
7. Money, inflation and welfare
1. First part.
(a) Take logs of the quantity theory and differentiate with respect to time. Use
(7.2) and (7.3) to show that inflation is equal to m.
(b) Perfect foresight implies inflation is equal to m at all times. From the IS
equation and the fact that Y is constant, r (= R − π) must therefore be
constant. The real interest rate is constant and the nominal interest rate
moves one-for-one with the inflation rate.
(c) From the quantity theory, M V = P Y , M/P is constant and so not affected by
the rate of growth of the nominal money supply.
Second part.
(a) Differentiate the money demand equation with respect to time, noting that
dR/dt = 0 in equilibrium.
dM 1 dP M
· − · = 0.
dt P dt P 2
From which we can see that the growth rate of money equals the growth rate
of prices. π = µ.
(b) Same as in the first part.
(c) From the money demand equation, it is clear that an increase in R, caused by
the increase in µ, will cause the demand for real money balances to fall. The
price level jumps in order for the real money supply to equal the lower real
money demand.
Money is neutral in Mythica; increasing the money supply just increases the price
level with no change in any real variables.
Money is, however, not superneutral. Increasing the growth rate of the money
supply causes a real variable, M/P , to fall. The real interest rate, however, remains
unchanged.
2. First part.
(a) R = 4% from the IS equation. Substituting into the money demand equation
gives P = 2 and hence M/P = 1000.
(b) Seigniorage equals the real interest rate multiplied by real money balances.
Therefore seigniorage equals 4000.
Second part.
(a) M = 10% therefore π = 10%. Since R = 4%, R must equal 14% and from the
money demand equation, M/P = 500.
(b) Seigniorage equals 2000 and the inflation tax, inflation rate multiplied by real
money balances, equals 5000. Total revenue therefore equals 7000.
98
7.11. Feedback to Sample examination questions
1. The statement is false. Suggested answer will use and explain (7.15) to (7.18) to
show that inflation is equal to GV .
Section B
5. (a) The money demand equation is (M/P )d = 1200 − 50(r + π). If social welfare is
maximised by maximising the consumer surplus under the money demand
curve, then welfare is maximised when i = 0 (Friedman rule). If r = 4% and
i = r + π, then welfare is maximised when π = −4%. Hence, in order to
maximise welfare, the money supply should contract by 4% per year, µ = −4%.
(b) Using the model of Dornbusch, government spending is financed by money
creation. (Ignore seigniorage here; government spending is only financed from
the inflation tax).
dM
= gP Y.
dt
Dividing by P and noting that (dM/dt) · 1/M = µ, the growth rate of money,
gives:
M
µ· = gY.
P
Substituting in for M/P (= 1200 − 50i) and using i = r + π (= 4 + π) and
π − µ, together with our value for Y (=1000):
Rearranging gives
g = µ − 0.05µ2 .
This is the relationship between the money growth rate, µ, and the proportion
of GDP that the government can spend, financed only through money
creation. Differentiating this with respect to µ and setting equal to zero will
give a maximum value of g of 5%. This is associated with a money growth rate
of 10%.
99
7. Money, inflation and welfare
100
Chapter 8
Classical models and monetary policy
8.1 Introduction
In Chapter 5 we introduced the classical model where money was neutral. Real
outcomes such as investment decisions and output were determined by real factors;
tastes and technology, and the money supply only determined the price level. In this
chapter we will examine classical models in more detail, exploring the possibilities that
monetary policy can have real effects, at least in the short run. However, in order for us
to do this, we must first consider the benchmark case of the classical model and we do
this by considering a model based on ‘reduced form’ macro equations.1
A ‘simple’ model is introduced and solved in the appendix but you are not expected to
develop, or be able to solve, these models in the examination. They are purely left for
the more interested reader who wishes to further understand how RBC theory works.
8.2 Aims
This chapter introduces first major macro model without nominal ‘frictions’ that will
serve as a benchmark model. We then study cases with real frictions in the classical
model (in the form of asymmetric information, the requirement to hold cash before you
could buy, and limited participation in financial markets) all lead to money having real
effects.
describe how, in the classical economy, output is determined by the factor markets
describe and discuss the effects of monetary policy, with reference to the effects of
money on nominal variables such as prices and nominal wages, and on real
variables such as employment
describe what business cycle models are and what they try to do
list and explain the workings behind, the flexible price models where money has
real effects.
1
I.e. equations we assume hold in this particular instance.
101
8. Classical models and monetary policy
Branson, W.H. Macroeconomic Theory and Policy. (New York; London: Harper and
Row, 1989).
Mankiw, N.G. Macroeconomics. (New York: Worth Publishers, 2002).
Walsh, C.E. Monetary Theory and Policy. (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2003)
Chapter 1.
Journal articles
King, R.G. and C. Plosser ‘Money, credit and prices in a real business cycle’, American
Economic Review 74(3) 1984, pp.363–80.
Kydland, F.E. and E.C. Prescott ‘Business cycles: real facts and a monetary myth’,
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 14(2) 1990, p.3.
Lucas, R.E. Jr. ‘Some international evidence on output-inflation trade-offs’, American
Economic Review 66(5) 1976, p.985.
Lucas, R.E. Jr. ‘Nobel lecture: monetary neutrality’, Journal of Political Economy
104(3) 1996, pp.661–82.
102
8.7. The classical model revisited
103
8. Classical models and monetary policy
‘helicopter drop’ of newly printed money or by open market operations, whereby the
monetary authorities buy government bonds in exchange for money, leads to an
outward shift of the aggregate demand curve to AD1 .2 The monetary expansion also
causes the LM curve to initially shift out to LM1 . However, the increase in demand has
no effect on output since the AS schedule is vertical at y 0 , and simply causes the price
level to increase from P0 to P1 . The increase in the price level reduces real money
balances, causing the LM curve to shift back to its initial position, LM0 . Note that
although the outward shift of the LM curve, caused by the initial monetary expansion,
suggests at least a temporary increase in output, the price level increases immediately
so that the LM curve effectively never changes position.
The increase in the price level causes the labour demand schedule to shift out. Note
that we have the nominal wage on the vertical axis. For any given nominal wage, a
higher price implies a lower real wage and hence an increase in labour demand. The
price rise also causes the labour supply schedule to shift to the left. Again, for any given
nominal wage, the price rise implies a fall in the real wage so individuals supply less
labour. In equilibrium the nominal wage increases to the point where the real wage
remains at the initial level. Real wages and real money balances are left unchanged in
equilibrium; and output, labour, and so on are all unaffected. All the change in the
money supply does is to change other nominal variables, nominal wages and prices,
one-for-one. Money, as expected, is neutral.
2
Why a change in nominal money balances affects the AD schedule is documented in all
macroeconomic texts. See for example Mankiw (2002).
104
8.8. The effect of monetary policy
Figure 8.2:
105
8. Classical models and monetary policy
106
8.11. Classical models with real effects of money
RBC theory, being an extension of the classical model, suggests that money is neutral.
However, the problem with claiming that money is neutral is that the money stock has
been found to be a leading, procyclical variable. RBC theorists argue that the apparent
relationship between money and output is one of reverse causality; anticipated changes
in output lead to changes in the money supply in the same direction. Historical research
as discussed in Chapter 7, however, suggests that money is not short-run neutral.
In the standard classical model every individual knows what the money supply is and
there is full and symmetric information about the state of the economy and about the
state of each market. Relaxing this assumption will allow money to have real effects.
Suppose an individual who produces goods in one market sees the price of his good
increasing due to an increase in demand. If that was caused by a relative demand shock
for his good (i.e. preferences changed so that the demand for his product increased
relative to some other goods) then it will be optimal for him to increase production,
essentially moving along his upward sloping marginal cost/supply curve. If, on the other
hand, the price rise was caused by an economy-wide increase in prices as a result of the
money supply increasing, then since nothing ‘real’ has changed, the demand for his
good has not altered relative to the demand for other goods, then it will be optimal for
him to leave output unchanged.
In reality, it will be unlikely that he knows the cause of the increase in price and so he
will opt for an intermediate strategy whereby he increases output by a little (not as
much as if he knew the price rise was caused by a relative demand shock but more than
if it was due to a monetary expansion, that being a zero output change). The Lucas
aggregate supply function is then given by (8.2).
yt = y ∗ + d(Pt − Et−1 [Pt ]) (8.2)
where yt is aggregate supply, y ∗ is the full employment/market clearing level of output
and Pt is the price level at date t.
At date t − 1, individuals make an expectation of the price level in date t, denoted
Et−1 [Pt ]. If the price level in date t is greater than expected, Pt − Et−1 [Pt ] > 0, agents
believe this is caused by a relative demand shock in date t, or by an increase in the
money supply that was unexpected. As a consequence, each individual/firm produces
more, which causes aggregate supply to increase above y ∗ . Hence d is positive and the
aggregate supply schedule is upward sloping rather than vertical. Also, an unexpected
increase in the money supply can have real effects even though prices are perfectly
flexible. People effectively ‘misperceive’ an increase in the price level as having been
107
8. Classical models and monetary policy
caused by a relative demand shock, rather than an increase in the money supply. If the
monetary expansion was perfectly anticipated rather than unexpected, then everyone
would allow for this when making their expectation of Pt at date t − 1 and the
monetary expansion would have no real effects.4
Even though monetary policy has real effects in this set-up, the effects only persist in
the short run. In the long run, when people realise that the price rise is due to a
monetary expansion, output will revert back to its full employment level. This is true
not only of the Lucas misperceptions model but of all classical models that allow real
effects of monetary policy.
A problem with the money in utility (MIU) model is that it assumes people obtain
utility from something that is intrinsically useless. Adding money to the utility function
is then an odd way of introducing money. The cash in advance (CIA) model, however,
uses cleaner micro-foundations to explain the existence of money. It effectively tries to
model the trading frictions, such as the lack of trust between payer and payee discussed
in Chapter 2 that causes the trading process to necessitate a medium of exchange –
cash. People need cash in order to buy goods and sellers of goods will accept nothing
but cash when they trade. The trading round is assumed to be split into two periods.
In the first period individuals receive an income and decide how much of their wealth to
hold in cash and how much to hold in other forms such as bonds or capital that cannot
be used as a medium of exchange.
In the second period individuals buy and consume goods, facing the constraint that the
nominal value of their consumption must not be more than the nominal money holdings
they brought forward from the first period. Therefore, in addition to the budget
constraint, individuals face a ‘cash in advance’ constraint:
Pt Ct ≤ Mt−1 . (8.3)
Dividing by Pt−1 and noting that Pt /Pt−1 = 1 + πt , this can be written as:
where mt−1 = Mt−1 /Pt−1 , and is equal to real money balances at date t − 1. (8.4)
implies that an increase in πt acts like an inflation tax; the consumers cannot purchase
in real terms the same amount of goods. Since their utility depends on consumption and
leisure, they will substitute (the now relatively more expensive) consumption goods for
leisure. That is, they will decrease their supply of labour due to the increase in inflation.
Thus employment, and therefore output, will decrease as a result of the increase in
inflation.
Monetary policy can have real effects if there are a limited number of agents
participating in financial markets meaning some consumers may be restricted in their
4
See Chapter 9 and the section on the policy ineffectiveness proposition.
108
8.12. A reminder of your learning outcomes
access to the banking system and therefore cannot save via interest bearing assets. If
the monetary authorities decided to increase the money stock, such policy actions would
be made through banks and other financial intermediaries with whom the open market
operations were conducted. Now faced with a glut of liquid assets, banks wish to lend
out some of these in order to maintain their desired reserve ratio. The increase in the
supply of loans will cause the interest rate charged on these loans to fall (the liquidity
effect) and since firms borrow from financial intermediaries to finance investment
projects, this makes investment cheaper. Cheaper investment causes investment to
increase, which therefore causes output, and employment if labour and capital are
complementary inputs, to increase.
describe how, in the classical economy, output is determined by the factor markets
describe and discuss the effects of monetary policy, with reference to the effects of
money on nominal variables such as prices and nominal wages, and on real
variables such as employment
describe what business cycle models are and what they try to do
list and explain the workings behind, the flexible price models where money has
real effects.
Specify whether the following statement is true, false or uncertain. Explain your answer
in a short paragraph.
1. ‘According to the stylised facts of the business cycle, real wages, employment and
government spending are acyclical.’
Section B
2. Explain why money might be neutral in the long run but not in the short run.
3. Suppose the supply curve is given as in (8.2) and that aggregate demand is given
by: y = 1000 + 3(M/P ). Suppose there has been no shock in the economy for some
time and no changes in policy are expected in the near future. If M = 600, find y
and P in terms of y ∗ . What happens when the monetary authorities announce (in
advance) that M will increase to 650? What happens if this increase is entirely
unexpected? In this final part, you do not need to solve for P and y.
109
8. Classical models and monetary policy
1. The statement is false. Suggested answers should say that the real wage and
employment are both procyclical. A productivity shock, for example, will increase
labour demand, pushing up the real wage and increasing employment. With this
higher level of employment, more output can be produced, implying real wages and
employment are procyclical.
Section B
3. If the economy has not experienced any shocks for some time then Pt = Et−1 Pt and
hence, from (8.2), yt = y ∗ . If M = 600, then from the aggregate demand equation,
one can solve for P to obtain
1800
Pt = ∗ .
y − 1000
If the monetary authorities announce that the money supply at date t will be
M = 650, and if this announcement was made at or before date t − 1 (i.e. when
expectations of Pt were formed), then rational agents will change the prices they
charge on their goods in order to take this new money supply into account.
Expectations of Pt made at t − 1 will increase and again Pt = Et−1 [Pt ]. Again, from
(8.2), yt = y ∗ (i.e. the monetary expansion has no effect on output). From the
aggregate demand equation, we can solve for the price.
1950
Pt = .
y∗ − 1000
Note that the growth rate of the price level is equal to the growth rate of the
money supply. If the monetary expansion is entirely unexpected, then Et−1 [Pt ] will
not have changed, and will be equal to the original 1800/(y ∗ − 1000). The
monetary expansion will increase aggregate demand and this outward shift of the
demand curve along the supply curve of (8.2) will cause output to increase,
assuming δ 6= 0. Output increases and so does the price level, Pt . However, the
growth of the price level is less than that of the money supply, at least initially.
110
8.15. Appendix to Chapter 8: a ‘simple’ RBC model
Cooley, T. and G. Hansen ‘Money and the business cycle’, in Cooley, T. (ed.)
Frontiers of Business Cycle Research. (Princeton, N.J.; Chichester: Princeton
University Press, 1995) [ISBN 9780691043234].
Kydland, F.E. and E.C. Prescott ‘Time to build and aggregate fluctuations’,
Econometrica 50(6) 1982, pp.1345–370.
Lucas, R.E. Jr and N. Stokey ‘Money and interest in a cash-in-advance economy’,
Econometrica 55(3) 1987, pp.491–513.
where ζ and γ are constant preference parameters. The individual maximises utility
subject to a budget constraint given in real terms in (8.6).
Mt Bt+1 Qt+1 Wt Mt−1 Bt
Ct + kt + + = lt + (1 + rt−1 )kt−1 + + . (8.6)
Pt Pt Pt Pt Pt
The constraint simply states that your consumption and asset holdings, left-hand side,
equal your income and assets brought over from last period, right-hand side. The
111
8. Classical models and monetary policy
∞
X
t Mt
L = β ln Ct + ζ ln + γ ln(1 − lt ) (8.7)
t=0
Pt
∞
X Mt Bt+1 Qt+1 Wt Mt−1 Pt−1 Bt
+ λt Ct + kt + + − lt − (1 + rt−1 )kt−1 − · − .
t=0
Pt Pt Pt Pt−1 Pt Pt
Notice in the budget constraint we replace Mt−1 /Pt by (Mt−1 /Pt−1 ) · (Pt−1 /Pt ) so that
the numerator and denominator of real money balances are dated at the same time. The
individual’s choice variables are Ct , Ct+1 , Mt /Pt , lt , lt+1 , Bt+1 and kt . Table 8.1 lists the
choice variables and the first order conditions; derivatives of the Lagrangian with
respect to the choice variables set equal to zero.
5
See Chapter 9 for more discussion of bonds and interest rates.
112
8.15. Appendix to Chapter 8: a ‘simple’ RBC model
βt
Ct Ct
+ λt = 0 (8.8a)
β t+1
Ct+1 Ct+1
+ λt+1 = 0 (8.8b)
Mt Pt
Pt
ζβ t M t
+ λt − λt+1 PPt+1
t
=0 (8.8c)
γβ t
lt − 1−l t
− λt Wt
Pt
=0 (8.8d)
t+1
lt+1 γβ
− 1−l t+1
− λt+1 Wt+1
Pt+1
=0 (8.8e)
Bt+1 λt QPt+1
t
1
− λt+1 Pt+1 =0 (8.8f)
kt λt − (1 + rt )λt+1 = 0 (8.8g)
Table 8.1
Fisher equation
From (8.8g), λt+1 /λt = 1/(1 + rt ). Also, (8.8f) implies λt+1 /λt = Qt+1 Pt+1 /Pt . If Qt+1 is
the price of a bond at date t that pays 1 unit of money at date t + 1, then
Qt+1 = 1/(1 + Rt ) where Rt is the nominal interest rate between t and t + 1. If inflation,
πt+1 , is defined as (Pt+1 − Pt )/Pt then Pt+1 /Pt = 1 + πt+1 . Combining the results from
(8.8f) and (8.8g) gives:
1 + Rt
1 + rt = ≈ 1 + rt − πt+1 for small Rt and πt+1 .
1 + πt+1
Consumption decisions
113
8. Classical models and monetary policy
a lot more consumption tomorrow. We will then postpone some of our consumption
until later, implying a high consumption growth rate.
Labour decisions
Activity 8.1 If a temporary productivity shock increases today’s real wage only,
this causes labour supply to increase today relative to tomorrow. What happens to
intertemporal labour supply decisions if there is a permanent productivity shock
that causes the real wage to increase today and in every future period?
Money holdings
114
8.15. Appendix to Chapter 8: a ‘simple’ RBC model
Let zt = Mt /ζPt Ct and Xt+1 = Mt+1 /Mt , (i.e. Xt+1 is the growth factor of the money
supply = 1 + mt+1 where mt+1 is the growth rate). For simplicity, assume that the
growth rate of money is fixed at m, implying Xt = Xt+1 = X.
β β β
zt = 1 + zt+1 = 1 + 1 + zt+2 . (8.16)
X X X
Substituting for future values of z and assuming zt+n does not explode for large n will
allow us to solve for zt as:
β β2
zt = 1 + + 2 + ···
X X
∞
X
n 1
⇒ zt = β . (8.17)
n=0
Xn
With X constant, this simplifies to zt = 1/(1 − β/X). Real money balances are then
negatively related to the growth rate of the nominal money supply, and so negatively
related to the inflation rate.
Activity 8.2 Using Xt+1 = 1 + µt+1 = Mt+1 /Mt and the fact that
Pt+1 /Pt = 1 + πt+1 , prove that in the steady state, when real money balances are
constant through time, the inflation rate, π, is equal to the growth rate of money, µ.
Production
α Wt
⇒ max Πt = At kt−1 lt1−α − lt − rt−1 kt−1 . (8.18)
Pt
Differentiating this with respect to the two choice variables, lt and kt−1 , shows us that
the marginal cost of capital, rt−1 , will equal its marginal product. The marginal cost of
labour, Wt /Pt , will similarly equal its marginal product.
α−1 1−α
rt−1 = αAt kt−1 lt (8.19)
Wt α
= (1 − α)At kt−1 lt−α . (8.20)
Pt
115
8. Classical models and monetary policy
Model solution
In order for us to solve this RBC model, deriving solutions for Ct , kt , lt and yt , we first
have to impose the resource constraint that output equals consumption plus investment.
This basically states that what is produced is either consumed or put back into the
economy to produce goods next period. Since we assume 100% depreciation, investment,
It , must equal the capital stock, kt , that is used in the production of tomorrow’s goods.
y t = C t + kt . (8.21)
We also have to note that individuals face two forms of saving devices, capital and
bonds, the real returns from which must be equal in order to avoid infinite arbitrage
opportunities that are clearly inconsistent with the real world. One unit of capital at
date t will yield rt units at date t + 1. On the other hand, one bond costing Qt+1 units
of money at date t will pay 1 unit of money at date t + 1. We can convert this into real
terms by dividing each date by its respective price level so that Qt+1 Pt+1 /Pt units of
goods saved in bonds at date t will yield 1 unit of consumption good at date t + 1. If
the price level rose between dates t and t + 1 then the real return on bonds will be lower
since more consumption goods have to be put into bonds at date t in order to get one
unit at date t + 1. This is shown more clearly in Table 8.2.
Date t Date t + 1
Capital 1 rt
Table 8.2
This implies that there is a relationship between the returns to capital and bonds that
satisfies the following:
Qt+1 Pt+1
rt = 1. (8.22)
Pt
Using the fact that Qt+1 Pt+1 /Pt = lt+1 /lt = βCt /Ct+1 and substituting rt from (??) will
give us:
βCt
αAt+1 ktα−1 lt+1
1−α
= 1. (8.23)
Ct+1
Using (8.23), the resource constraint, (8.24), and labour market clearing, (8.25), we will
be able to solve for current and future values of C, k, l and y if we impose an initial
condition for k0 .
α
Ct + kt = At kt−1 lt1−α (8.24)
γCt
α
(1 − α)At kt−1 lt−α = . (8.25)
1 − lt
116
8.15. Appendix to Chapter 8: a ‘simple’ RBC model
Activity 8.3 For the more interested student, show that the solution to (8.23) to
(8.25) is:
−1
1 − αβ α g(1 − αβ)
Ct = kt , kt = αβAt kt−1 lt1−α , lt = 1+ .
αβ 1−α
Outline of answer
From (8.23):
1−α
Ct /kt At+1 ktα lt+1 Ct /kt Ct+1 + kt+1
1 = αβ · = αβ · .
Ct+1 /kt+1 kt+1 Ct+1 /kt+1 kt+1
Solving forward for kt+1 /Ct+1 , noting that |αβ| < 1 and assuming that kt+n /Ct+n
does not explode will give kt /Ct = αβ/(1 − αβ), from which we obtain the solution
for Ct . Substitute this into the resource constraint and solving for kt gives us the
second part of the solution that tells us how kt evolves over time. Using the resource
α
constraint to substitute out At kt−1 lt1−α in (8.25) and substituting Ct from the first
part of the solution will give us the solution for lt .
117
8. Classical models and monetary policy
118
Chapter 9
Keynesian models with money supply
as a policy instrument
9.1 Introduction
In the last chapter we examined the effects of monetary policy and saw that frictions in
the classical model (in the form of asymmetric information, the requirement to hold
cash before you could buy, and limited participation in financial markets) all led to
money having real effects. Here, we will examine one particular type of friction, namely
the friction to prices. If prices, of goods or of labour, are sticky then changes in the
money supply will cause changes to real money balances and/or to the real wage. A
change in the stock of nominal money will then have consequences in the real economy.
Despite some of these models being thought up and refined in the latter years of the
20th century, we put such models of nominal rigidities under the umbrella of ‘Keynesian
models’, the term that is usually used when referring to them.
9.2 Aims
This chapter aims to introduce models with nominal (price) frictions where the
monetary policy instrument is a monetary aggregate. We find short-term real effects of
monetary policy under certain conditions.
explain the importance of nominal rigidities and why such sticky prices occur in
the real world
examine the effects of monetary policy in the short and long run when there are
nominal rigidities
describe the workings of the Phillips curve and augmented Phillips curve, noting
the differences between the two
build and work through models of sticky prices, examining the effects of monetary
policy
119
9. Keynesian models with money supply as a policy instrument
explain why multi-period pricing can lead to real and persistent effects of monetary
policy
discuss the merits of various sticky price models, noting, in particular, the different
short-run and long-run effects of monetary policy.
Blanchard, O.J. ‘Why does money affect output? A survey’, in Friedman, B. and F.
Hahn (eds) Handbook of Monetary Economics. (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1990).
Branson, W.H. Macroeconomic Theory and Policy. (New York; London: Harper and
Row, 1989).
Mankiw, N.G. Macroeconomics. (New York: Worth Publishers, 2002).
Phelps, E.S. Microeconomic Foundations of Employment and Inflation Theory. (New
York: Norton, 1970).
120
9.7. Keynesian aggregate supply function
Journal articles
Friedman, M. ‘The role of monetary policy’, American Economic Review 58(1) 1968,
pp.1–17.
Phillips, A.W. ‘The relation between unemployment and the rate of change of money
wage rates in the United Kingdom’, Economica 25(100) 1958, pp.283–99.
The effect of monetary policy can best be shown by using a similar set of diagrams to
those of Figure 8.2. This is shown, for sticky nominal wages, in Figure 9.1. The middle
left panel shows the labour market when the nominal wage is fixed at W ∗ and the
bottom left panel shows the standard production function with diminishing marginal
returns to labour. The top right diagram shows the IS–LM curves and the middle right
panel shows aggregate demand and supply. Note that aggregate supply is upward
sloping as explained above.
1
Note that the ‘right to manage’ is not needed where the real wage is above the market-clearing wage
rate.
121
9. Keynesian models with money supply as a policy instrument
Figure 9.1:
122
9.7. Keynesian aggregate supply function
Expansionary monetary policy causes the aggregate demand schedule to shift out and
also causes the LM curve to shift to the right. Since the AD shift causes a price rise,
this will tend to reduce real money balances, causing a partial offsetting of the outward
LM shift. As in the analysis in Chapter 8, a monetary expansion causes the labour
demand curve to shift out. The increase in the price level reduces the real wage for any
given nominal wage, leading to an increase in labour demand. However, since the
nominal wage is fixed, and given the ‘right to manage’ assumption, firms employ more
labour so that employment increases to l00 and output increases to y 00 . A monetary
expansion therefore has real effects caused by nominal wages being sticky. In the long
run, however, the nominal wage will be bid up as workers renegotiate their contracts to
counter the fall in their real wage. In the long run, employment will remain at l0 , output
will remain at y 0 and the monetary expansion simply causes a one-for-one movement in
prices and nominal wages.2
The assumption of sticky nominal wages can easily explain the short-run real effects of
monetary policy. However, this implies that the real wage is strongly countercyclical;
clearly inconsistent with empirical findings. Also, despite the ability of the above model
to explain the existence of unemployment, it sheds very little light on to the mechanism
by which wages are determined. If wages are predetermined in the current period, then
changes in the economy must be reflected in wages in the next period. This is not
explicitly modelled above, but was the focus of research made by Phillips (1958).
Phillips overcame the problem of assuming exogenously fixed wages by assuming that
the nominal wage depends on recent values of unemployment. This assumption was
based on an empirical regularity between unemployment and nominal wage inflation in
the UK from 1861 to 1957. This is shown in Figure 9.2.
Intuitively, if unemployment was high, trade unions, and labour in general, could not
negotiate larger pay increases since firms would have a large pool of unemployed with
which to fill its vacancies. When unemployment is high, labour tends to be in a weak
bargaining position. The specification Phillips gave for the relationship was:
ln Wt = ζ(ut−1 ) + ln Wt−1
123
9. Keynesian models with money supply as a policy instrument
Figure 9.2:
and increase output was to allow inflation to rise. However, in the 1970s the Phillips
curve relationship broke down and this was explained, and indeed predicted, by
Friedman (1968) and Phelps (1970) who emphasised the importance of inflation
expectations, which had been ignored thus far.
Friedman and Phelps claimed that agents cared, not about their nominal wage, but
about how many goods such a wage could buy (i.e. what really mattered was their real
wage). By augmenting (9.1) with inflation, ∆pt , unemployment in period t − 1 would
determine changes in real wages. This is shown in (9.3).
However, since there is no current information about ∆pt (inflation is only realised after
nominal wages have been negotiated), this has to be anticipated. If ∆pet is the
expectation formed at date t − 1 of inflation at date t, then the expectations-augmented
Phillips curve can be written as:
The expectations augmented Phillips curve explained the breakdown of the simple
version that occurred in the 1970s. There were argued to be a number of short-run
Phillips curves, one for each level of expected inflation. Unexpected inflation would
move you along a given short-run Phillips curve but in the long run there would be no
trade-off between unemployment and inflation. As people’s expectations of inflation
increased to meet actual inflation we would move to another short-run Phillips curve. In
124
9.7. Keynesian aggregate supply function
Okun’s law
1
⇒ yt = y ∗ + (∆pt − ∆pet ). (9.5)
γ
This is the same as the Lucas aggregate supply curve, where d = 1/g and we have
replaced unanticipated prices by unanticipated inflation. Note, however, that even
though both Lucas model and Okun’s law have similar predictions (real effects of
unanticipated monetary policy caused by an upward-sloping aggregate supply curve),
they have different microfoundations. The Lucas supply curve is based on imperfect
information on the sources of good specific price changes that affects real output and
employment fluctuations are voluntary, whereas the Phillips curve assumes nominal
rigidities that leads to involuntary employment fluctuations.
We now outline a model of sticky prices in the goods market. Prices are set at the
beginning of the period and cannot change to accommodate shocks or other
developments in the economy. As employment was demand determined at the start of
this chapter in the case of sticky wages, output is demand determined in this situation
of sticky goods prices. Firms produce as much as is demanded at the price that was set
at the beginning of the period, even if this means supplying more than they would
ordinarily wish to produce given those market conditions.
Activity 9.1 Why would a firm want to produce at a level that is demand
determined? (Hint: think of the relationship between customers and producers!)
How can we justify the assumption of sticky prices? If, after setting a price, market
conditions change, why do firms not change their prices to accommodate such
developments and thus maximise profits? There are a number of theories to rationalise
sticky prices. Two common arguments are the existence of menu costs and the attempts
by firms not to disturb the loyal customer base with frequent price changes. If prices do
125
9. Keynesian models with money supply as a policy instrument
change frequently, a number of repeat customers may look elsewhere in the market.
Prices may then be kept constant in order to keep these valuable customers happy.
Menu costs, on the other hand, refer to the costs that firms face when they change their
list prices. Such costs arise due to the need to issue updated catalogues, for example. It
should then not be that unreasonable to assume that prices are, to a greater or lesser
extent, inflexible.
Activity 9.2 What industries can you think of that have very sticky prices? Which
industries have very flexible prices?
This model is taken from McCallum (1989), Chapter 10, and you are strongly
recommended to read this chapter while working through what follows. First consider
aggregate demand. By combining the IS and LM equations, we can derive an AD
expression of the form:
yt , mt and pt are the logs of real output, nominal money balances and the price level,
respectively, at date t. vt is a random demand shock with zero mean (i.e. an element of
aggregate demand that is not picked up by real money balances or expected inflation).
β0 , β1 and β2 are positive parameters and Et−1 is the rational expectations operator
with the t − 1 subscript denoting the date the expectation was formed. In rational
expectations, people not only take all available information into account when they
form their expectations, but their expectations are also consistent with the way in
which the variables actually evolve. Rational expectations are sometimes also known as
‘model consistent’ expectations.3 The equation states that aggregate demand depends
positively on real money balances and positively on expected inflation; for any given
nominal interest rate, higher inflation implies a lower real interest rate, making
investment cheaper.
Aggregate supply is a little more difficult to specify because of the assumption that
prices are set at the beginning of the period, with supply being demand determined.
Denote the price that clears the market at date t as p∗t . Where is the price stickiness in
the model coming from? We assume that the prices the firms set at date t − 1, to be
operational in the market at date t, pt , are the prices they expect to clear the market at
date t, i.e.:
pt = Et−1 [p∗t ]. (9.7)
As in time t − 1, shocks are unknown, these cannot be taken into account when setting
the prices. Also, denote the output level that clears the market at date t as yt∗ . Then, if
the price equals that which allows markets to clear, by definition markets must clear
and so yt∗ must equal the demand when pt = p∗t .
126
9.7. Keynesian aggregate supply function
noting that Et−1 [p∗t ] equals pt from (9.7) and that in the situation of market clearing,
pt = p∗t . We now need an expression telling us how the market clearing/full employment
level of output, yt∗ , evolves over time. Here we will generalise the process used in
McCallum (1989) so that yt∗ increases gradually through time but also depends
positively on last period’s full employment output level, which allows persistence of full
employment output. If full employment output is high today, it is likely to be high
tomorrow.
yt∗ = δ0 + δ1 t + δ2 yt−1
∗
+ ut . (9.10)
ut is a zero mean, random supply, shock, which could include the discovery of oil
reserves or other raw materials or a sudden technological breakthrough that can
increase the productive capacity of the economy.
Activity 9.3 Consider expressions for yt∗ of the form, i. yt∗ = δ0 + δ1 t + ut and ii.
yt∗ = yt−1
∗
+ δ0 + ut . What are the differences between these two processes? (Hint:
what is the persistence of the shock, ut , in both equations; how long does the shock
last?)
(9.7), (9.9) and (9.10) together can be regarded as constituting aggregate supply. Along
with aggregate demand, (9.6), we can solve for the output level, yt , in terms of
deviations from yt∗ , and also for the price level, pt . The solution method is given in
McCallum, Chapter 10, and you should read the relevant section in order to see how the
solution is derived. However, a brief outline is given below.
Take expectations of (9.10) conditional on information available at date t − 1:
Equating (9.11) and (9.12), noting that Et−1 [p∗t ] in (9.12) is equal to pt (from (9.7))
gives:
yt∗ = β0 + β1 (Et−1 [mt ] − pt ) + β2 (Et−1 [pt+1 ] − pt ) + ut . (9.13)
If we subtract (9.13) from (9.6), we will have an expression for yt − yt∗ (i.e. deviations of
output from the market clearing level).
127
9. Keynesian models with money supply as a policy instrument
Monetary policy
Imagine that the money supply set by the authorities changes according to:
mt = µ0 + µ1 mt−1 + et (9.15)
where et is a zero mean, random error representing monetary policy shocks. Taking
expectations of (9.15) conditional on information at date t − 1 will give us an expression
for the unexpected money supply at date t, mt − Et−1 [mt ], which simply equals et .
Substituting this into (9.14) will give us a solution for the output deviation, yt − yt∗ .
yt − yt∗ = β1 et + vt − ut . (9.16)
Notice that the systematic component of monetary policy (µ0 + µ1 mt−1 ) does not have
any real effects here. This is because at date t − 1, when prices for date t are set, firms
take into consideration what they expect the monetary authorities will do. If they
expect the money supply to increase, knowing that money should have no real effects,
they will increase their prices for date t accordingly. Only the random component of
monetary policy, the monetary policy shock et , will have real effects since this is realised
after the prices have been set. This result, that the systematic component of monetary
policy has no real effect, will be discussed in more detail in the next section ‘policy
ineffectiveness proposition’.
Activity 9.4 What happens if the monetary authorities react to last period’s
∗
output deviation, in other words, if we add µ2 (yt−1 − yt−1 ) to the monetary policy
rule (9.15)? Explain your results.
Why would the monetary authorities want to respond to lagged deviations in the
first place?
The fact that unanticipated monetary policy, in the form of the shock, et, has real
effects, is essentially because prices are fixed for one period. Prices are set at date t − 1
for the market at date t. Any event occurring, relevant for the market at date t, after
prices have been set will naturally be reflected in real variables such as output and
employment. Now consider what happens when prices are set for two periods. The
model of multiperiod pricing, again from McCallum, Chapter 10, will be used to analyse
the effects of monetary policy in this setting.
Multi-period pricing
Let there be two types of firms, ‘A’ firms and ‘B’ firms. Both set prices for two periods,
but at different times. At date t − 2 (based on the information available at that date)
‘A’ firms set, possibly different, prices for the market at dates t − 1 and t. ‘B’ firms also
set prices for two periods but do so a period later (i.e. at date t − 1 they set prices for
the market at dates t and t + 1). This is shown more clearly in Figure 9.3.
At date t − 2, ‘A’ firms set their prices (for the market at t − 1 and t) at the level they
expect will clear the market. ‘B’ firms set their prices at date t − 1 for t and t + 1
similarly. Therefore, at date t, the price level will be the average of the prices set by ‘A’
128
9.7. Keynesian aggregate supply function
Figure 9.3:
firms and by ‘B’ firms. This is just the average of prices set by ‘A’ and ‘B’, conditional
on the information available at the time they were set.
Et−1 [p∗t ] + Et−2 [p∗t ]
pt = . (9.17)
2
To solve the model, we simplify the aggregate demand function by setting β2 = 0, i.e.
yt = β0 + β1 (mt − pt ) + vt . Also, assume that the market clearing output level, yt∗ ,
follows the process given by yt∗ = d0 + d1 t, i.e. yt∗ is purely deterministic, subject to no
shocks. Using the methods outlined above, aggregate demand will equal the market
clearing level of output when the price is equal to that which clears the market, pt = p∗t .
yt∗ = β0 + β1 (mt − p∗t ) + vt . (9.18)
Taking expectations of (9.18) conditional on information available at t − 1 and t − 2 will
give:
Et−1 [yt∗ ] = β0 + β1 Et−1 [mt − p∗t ] (9.19)
Subtracting (7.20) from the expression for aggregate demand results in:
1 1
yt − yt∗ = β1 · (mt − Et−1 [mt ]) + β1 · (mt − Et−2 [mt ]) + vt . (9.21)
2 2
Let monetary policy be the same as before:
mt = µ0 + µ1 mt−1 + et = µ0 + µ1 (µ0 + µ1 mt−2 + et−1 ) + et . (9.22)
129
9. Keynesian models with money supply as a policy instrument
In order to find an expression for Et−2 [mt ], for us to solve (7.), we need to write mt in
terms of variables that we know at date t − 2. Hence we replace mt−1 by backward
substitution. As before, we take expectations of mt conditional on information available
to us at t − 1 and t − 2 and we can find that:
mt − Et−1 [mt ] = et
130
9.8. Predictable and unpredictable components of the money supply
We assume that the monetary shock is purely random/white noise and so our best
guess of it before it is realised, Et−1 [et ], is its unconditional mean, zero. Under the
assumption of rational expectations, the expectation of mt , based on information
available at date t − 1, will be given by:
For simple models, where the monetary authorities and the public share the same
information sets, the expected money supply will simply be the predictable component
and the unpredictable component of the money supply will be the monetary shock, et .
As we saw in the previous chapter, monetary shocks have real effects in the economy
while changes in the predictable component of monetary policy do not change output at
all. This is because people can change their prices in anticipation of the change in
policy. Whereas the model in the previous chapter assumed sticky prices in order for
monetary shocks to have real (short-run) effects, one can easily use the Lucas supply
curve model to obtain a similar result for flexible price economies.
So even when prices are perfectly flexible, monetary shocks can have real effects, caused
by the asymmetric information assumption of the Lucas model. The predictable
component of monetary policy, showing how the authorities change the money supply
depending on the state of the economy, has no effect at all on real variables. This is the
policy ineffectiveness proposition (PIP). A policy of the form mt = µ0 + et will have the
same effect on the economy as when money depends on lagged money, inflation, output,
and so on.
When proving that PIP holds in the sticky price and Lucas models, we assumed that
agents had rational expectations when forming estimates of future variables. Hence the
mt − Et−1 [mt ] term which enters the output equation can be replaced by et , the
monetary shock. It may appear that the only reason that PIP holds is because of the
assumption of rational expectations. However, PIP does not hold in all rational
expectations, RE, models. Consider the aggregate demand function in (9.27).
131
9. Keynesian models with money supply as a policy instrument
This is exactly the same as (9.6) in the sticky price model, only the expectation of
inflation is made at date t, not t − 1. When making similar assumptions as before,
pt = Et−1 [p∗t ] and yt∗ = d0 + d1 t, we can show that yt∗ can be given by:
Subtracting (9.29) from the aggregate demand equation, (9.27), will give us an
expression for the output deviation, yt − yt∗ .
The monetary shock term, mt − Et−1 [mt ], enters as before, but a change in the
predictable component of monetary policy could indeed alter people’s expectations of
tomorrow’s price level. If a change in the predictable component of monetary policy
causes a change in expectations (between dates t − 1 and t) of pt+1 , then PIP no longer
holds even though rational expectations are assumed. Monetary policy can then have
real effects, but again only in the short run. Prices are set at date t − 1 for date t and so
can only contain information available up until date t − 1. Aggregate demand, on the
other hand, depends on the expectation of inflation made at date t (relevant for
investment decisions through the Fisher equation). Firms, setting their prices at the
level they expect to clear the market, have to make an expectation of this term but do
so at date t − 1. The fact that expected inflation can rise with new information means
aggregate demand can be greater than firms initially anticipated, causing output to
increase.
Lucas critique
The Lucas critique refers to the instability of reduced-form expressions used for policy
making or policy appraisal. In the sticky price model of the previous section, the
structural equations were given by the aggregate demand equation, the price equation,
pt = Et−1 [p∗t ], the equation showing how yt∗ evolves and the monetary policy reaction
function showing how mt depends on the state of the economy. When we solve for
yt − yt∗ , the equation we derive is a reduced-form equation; a mixture of aggregate
demand, aggregate supply and the authorities’ reaction function. For example, consider
the sticky price model and the reduced-form expression, (9.16), yt − yt∗ = β1 et + vt − ut .
Instead of et , write mt = Et−1 [mt ] = mt − µ0 − µ1 mt−1 .
If this equation were given to an econometrician, he or she would run a regression of the
form:
yt − yt∗ = γ0 + γ1 mt + γ2 mt−1 + η1 (9.32)
and would find a positive coefficient for γ1 since we know γ1 = β1 (only if the economy
was accurately represented by the structural equations given above!). Since γ1 > 0, we
132
9.9. A reminder of your learning outcomes
may then think that an increase in the money supply should cause an increase in output
above yt∗ . For example if γ1 was found to equal 0.5, then increasing the money supply by
2% should cause a 1% increase in output. However, as we saw in the earlier section, the
predictable component of monetary policy had no real effects. Even though we may
think an increase in the money supply will increase output (from the reduced form
equation, (9.32)), in reality the change in people’s expectations associated with this
policy change will cause the reduced form to break down. If the authorities increased
the money supply by increasing µ0 , indeed this will have a positive effect on output, via
γ1 , but it will also have a negative effect on output since γ0 = −β1 µ0 . The effect of an
expansionary monetary policy will be purely inflationary. Quoting Romer (2001) p.251,
explain the importance of nominal rigidities and why such sticky prices occur in
the real world
examine the effects of monetary policy in the short and long run when there are
nominal rigidities
describe the workings of the Phillips curve and augmented Phillips curve, noting
the differences between the two
build and work through models of sticky prices, examining the effects of monetary
policy
explain why multi-period pricing can lead to real and persistent effects of monetary
policy
discuss the merits of various sticky price models, noting, in particular, the different
short-run and long-run effects of monetary policy.
Specify whether the following statement is true, false or uncertain. Explain your answer
in a short paragraph.
1. ‘The assumption of rational expectations implies that agents know that prices are
flexible.’
133
9. Keynesian models with money supply as a policy instrument
Section B
2. If prices are sticky, what happens to the short-run Phillips curve after an increase
in expected inflation?
3. Why, in Taylor’s relative price theory, can changes in money induce permanent
deviations of output from its flexible price level?
4. Suppose that recent economic indicators suggest that although output is growing
at 3.5% per year, inflation is at 4% per year, up from 3% last year. If someone asks
you to forecast the effect of this new inflation data, what would be your response?
(Hint: make sure you specify what model you are using, what variables you are
considering and what kind of real effects you forecast. Also mention if you expect
any of the stylised facts of the business cycle to occur.)
5. Suppose that you know that the full employment level of output in England is
y = 100. You observed that in 2001, inflation and output in England were 5% and
y = 100. In 2002, they were 3% and y = 96. According to the theory of the Phillips
curve, what can you say about expected inflation in 2001 and in 2002?
6. Suppose a country with 400 people is set up so that everybody supplies 10 units of
labour per period no matter how small or large the real wage. In this economy
there are also 1000 competitive firms, each maximising their profit function:
Π = Y P − W N , where Y is output, P is the price of output, W is the nominal
wage and N is the number of units of labour. Suppose each
√ firm is identical in
every respect and each has a production function: Y = N .
(a) Derive the demand for labour of one firm, its output and the aggregate
demand for labour in the economy.
(b) Draw on a graph the aggregate demand and supply of labour. Compute
algebraically the equilibrium wage (W/P )∗ and equilibrium level of labour
supply N ∗ .
(c) Suppose the aggregate demand for goods in the economy is given by
Y = 21 (M/P ) and the money supply is equal to 100. What is the aggregate
supply function for goods in the economy? Calculate Y ∗ and P ∗ .
(d) Suppose that the government increases once and for all the money supply.
Does this improve the position of the workers in the economy?
(e) Would your answer to part (d) change if we also assumed that nominal wages
were rigid in the economy? What would be your answer if prices were rigid?
What does the AS curve look like in the case of rigid wages?
1. The statement is false. Suggested answers should define what rational expectations
are. In particular, in rational expectations, people not only take all available
134
9.11. Feedback to Sample examination questions
information into account when they form their expectations, but their expectations
are also consistent with the way in which the variables actually evolve. Rational
expectations are sometimes also known as ‘model consistent’ expectations. If prices
are sticky, agents then know that prices are sticky.
Section B
2. The augmented Phillips curve is shown in (9.3). Replacing actual inflation with
expected inflation, since agents have to make expectations of this unknown
quantity, gives (9.4). Since ζ is a negative function of unemployment, a rise in
expected inflation will increase unemployment for any given wage growth. This
implies that the short-run Phillips curve shifts out. If prices are sticky, then an
increase in expected inflation will cause unemployment to rise above its natural
(full employment) level, at least temporarily. In the long run, prices will adjust,
shown by a higher inflation rate, and unemployment will move back to the full
employment level.
6. (a) Substituting the production function into the profit equation gives us a choice
problem for the firm of √
max Π = N P − W N.
N
135
9. Keynesian models with money supply as a policy instrument
136
Chapter 10
New Keynesian models of monetary
policy
10.1 Introduction
In the previous chapter, we analysed the effects of monetary policy which utilises
monetary aggregates as the monetary policy instrument. However, modern
macroeconomic research and actual monetary policy implementation suggest that the
current policy instrument is the short-term interest rate controlled by the central bank
via open market operations. Pure classical models suggest that money has no real
effects at any horizon. If we introduce nominal and real frictions or relax some other key
assumptions of the classical model, such as rational expectations, then monetary policy
can have real effects in the short run. In this chapter we will examine the efficacy of a
monetary instrument, the short-term interest rate, using a small scale new Keynesian
macro model.
10.2 Aims
This chapter aims to introduce models with nominal (price) frictions where the
monetary policy instrument are short-term interest rates. We find short-term real effects
of monetary policy under certain conditions.
137
10. New Keynesian models of monetary policy
Journal articles
138
10.7. IS-PC-MR model of new Keynesian economics
an IS curve (IS)
a New Keynesian Phillips curve (PC)
an optimal monetary policy reaction function or a simple monetary policy rule
(also known as the Taylor rule) (MR).
In this chapter we will follow closely Carlin and Soskice (2005, 2006) when describing
the key mechanisms of the model. Typically, the model develops a framework of forward
looking households and firms and therefore both IS and Phillips curves are forward
looking, that is, expectations about future real output and inflation matter when
setting optimal consumption and production. For the sake of simplicity, Carlin and
Soskice present a case with a backward looking IS and Phillips curves (that is, looking
at what has happened in the previous period when decisions are made). This is of
course an important simplification and departure from the standard analysis of New
Keynesian models. Other than its usefulness for simplicity, backward looking IS and
Phillips curves can be to some extent justified by the presence of consumers who form
habits in their consumption decisions. That is consumers care about how much they
consumed in the previous periods when they decide about their current consumption.
However, the policy maker, in other words, the central bank, is forward looking when
deciding the level of short-term interest rates by taking the Phillips and IS curves as
constraints. Key assumptions are the presence of nominal rigidities (wages and/or prices
do not adjust instantaneously to shocks hitting the economy) and imperfect
competition.
139
10. New Keynesian models of monetary policy
140
10.8. Analysing demand shocks
This is the interest rule (IR) as a response to deviations from target inflation and
output gap. For a = α = β = 1 the rule becomes simply:
Essentially, by setting the interest rates, the central bank needs to forecast inflation and
output gap next period. Even though the central bank observes the shock in period 0
(we will define in the following sections), due to lagged effect of interest rates on
aggregate demand it cannot fully offset the impact of the shock in the current period.
According to the ‘rule’ interest rates need to increase whenever actual inflation exceeds
target inflation and vice versa. In the following we present a graphical exposition how
the demand-side stabilisation works with respect to demand or supply shocks (Carlin
and Soskice, (2005)).
141
10. New Keynesian models of monetary policy
Figure 10.2: IS and Phillips curves: Source (Carlin and Soskice (2005)).
Figure 10.3 shows the case when the economy is subject to an aggregate demand (IS
shock) shock when the target inflation (π T ) is 2 per cent (Carlin and Soskice 2005)). A
positive shock to demand will lead to a positive output gap above the trend output,
which in turn leads to an increase in price inflation above the target level. This is shown
in the lower panel of Figure 10.3. It shows that given the prevailing short-term rate, rs ,
there will be a positive output gap (y > ye ) and associated inflation rate will be π0 > π T
(Point A). The central bank conducts the monetary policy by manipulating the interest
rate r0 . As in Carlin and Soskice (2005), it does so by forecasting the Phillips curve for
next period. Due to the past inflation, its forecast π I will be 4 percent as shown by the
dashed line in the PC diagram. Note that, all points on the forecast Phillips curve with
142
10.9. Analysing supply shocks
inflation below 4 per cent are associated with a negative output gap (y1 < ye ). It is clear
that conducting disinflationary policies is costly in terms of real output output.1
How is the policy maker going to choose the r0 along the new (forecast) Phillips curve?
This depends on the stabilisation preferences of the central bank. If the central bank
cares more about inflation stabilisation relative the output gap, the higher the
preference parameter, β, will be in its loss function. Given that the interest rate
(r0 − rs ) determines output gap which in turn determines the rate of inflation, the more
inflation averse the central bank is, the more it is willing to sacrifice output (below ye )
to achieve its inflation objective. In Figure 10.3 the central bank will choose point B
where the central bank indifference curve (loss function) and the forecast PC will be
tangent. Therefore the new desired output level y1 is the aggregate demand target
according to the optimal monetary policy rule. The monetary reaction function
connects point B and the zero loss point at Z. The next step is to forecast the IS curve
(IS’) associated with desired output level y1 . The dashed line in the upper panel shows
the central bank interest rate r0 in agreement with the new desired output to stabilise
the inflation. Clearly, interest rate needs to increase.
In the absence of further IS shocks, the increase in the interest rate leads to a fall in
output to y1 and inflation starts to decrease. The central bank repeats the steps above
to achieve the target inflation. Essentially, both preferences of the central bank and the
Phillips curve represent the inflation output trade-off the central bank faces. Given the
policy instrument, the short-term rate, the central bank stabilises the economy through
aggregate demand management following an IS (demand) shock.
According to our example the central bank needs to decide whether the demand shock is
a temporary or permanent one. If the central bank believes that the shock is permanent
(would persist for another period), central bank policy rate r00 should be higher than the
new stabilising interest rate, rs0 . If the central bank’s forecasts are such that the output
will revert to its initial level, then it will increase the interest rate by less since the
stabilising interest rate would have remained equal to rs (i.e. its chosen interest rate
would have been on the IS pre-shock curve in Figure 10.3 rather than on the IS curve).
143
10. New Keynesian models of monetary policy
Figure 10.3: New Keynesian model and demand shocks: Source (Carlin and Soskice
(2005)).
144
10.10. Financial accelerator models
Figure 10.4: New Keynesian model and supply shocks: Source (Carlin and Soskice (2005)).
145
10. New Keynesian models of monetary policy
project. Several problems can occur in credit markets that may lead to a worsening of
informational asymmetries and increases in the associated agency costs and thereby lead
to fewer projects get external financing. These then will have widespread real effects.2
In their model, there are three types of agents, called households, entrepreneurs, and
retailers. Entrepreneurs play a key role in their model. These individuals are assumed to
be risk-neutral and have finite horizons: Specifically, they assume that each
entrepreneur has a constant probability of surviving to the next period (implying an
expected lifetime of 1/(1 − γ)). In each period t entrepreneurs acquire physical capital
that is financed by either wealth (profits plus labour income) and borrowing that is
subject to external finance premium. If the wealth or net worth is high, this allows for
internal finance therefore entrepreneurs will be able to finance their investment rather
cheaply, or equivalently if they seek external finance they can post these as collateral,
therefore financing the project is less risky. As the external finance needs should be met
via some form of lending contract and there are informational problems about the
quality of the entrepreneurial project (agency problem – uncertain returns on capital
that are subject to both aggregate and idiosyncratic risk), uncollateralised external
finance should be more expensive than collateralised one.
j j j
Bt+1 = Qt Kt+1 − Nt+1 . (10.10)
The expression above formalises the need to borrow from some credit institution. At
time t, the entrepreneur who manages firm j purchases capital for use at t + 1. The
j
quantity of capital purchased is denoted Kt+1 , with the subscript denoting the period in
which the capital is actually used, and the superscript j denoting the firm. The price
paid per unit of capital in period t is Qt . Capital is homogeneous, and so it does not
matter whether the capital the entrepreneur purchases is newly produced within the
period or is old, depreciated capital. At the end of period t (going into period t + 1)
j
entrepreneur j has an available net worth, Nt+1 . To finance the difference between his
j
expenditures on capital goods and his net worth he must borrow an amount Bt+1 . The
entrepreneur borrows from a financial intermediary that obtains its funds from
households. The financial intermediary faces an opportunity cost of funds between t and
t + 1 equal to the economy’s riskless gross rate of return, Rt+1 . The riskless rate is the
relevant opportunity cost because in the equilibrium, the intermediary holds a perfectly
safe portfolio (it perfectly diversifies the idiosyncratic risk involved in lending). Because
entrepreneurs are risk-neutral and households are riskaverse, the loan contract the
intermediary signs has entrepreneurs absorb any aggregate risk. Lenders have to pay a
fee (auditing, accounting, legal and so on) to verify the state of the entrepreneur, so
they incur costs by lending. In equilibrium, Bernanke et al. show that for an
entrepreneur who is not fully self-financed, the return to capital will be equated to the
marginal cost of external finance, i.e.
!
j
k Nt+1
Et Rt+1 = s j Rt+1 . (10.11)
Qt Kt+1
The ratio s(·) of the cost of external finance to the safe rate – which is the discounted
return to capital but may be equally well interpreted as the external finance premium –
2
Remember that Modigliani–Miller theorem implicitly states that the source of funding of a particular
project does not matter for the outcome, be it by firm’s internal resources using, for instance, equity or by
external resources, for instance, using bank loans. When credit markets are characterised by asymmetric
information, the Modigliani–Miller irrelevance theorem is violated.
146
10.11. Simple monetary policy rules
depends inversely on the share of the firm’s capital investment that is financed by the
entrepreneur’s own net worth. It shows that capital expenditures by each firm are
proportional to the net worth of the owner/entrepreneur, with aproportionality
factor
j
Nt+1
that is increasing in the expected discounted return to capital s j
Qt Kt+1
. A high s
reduces default probability and entrepreneurs can take on more debt and expand the
size of the firm, thus economy expands, and vice versa. In other words, financial (or
equivalently credit) constraints can lead to stronger downturns than when these
constraints are absent; hence it works as a financial accelerator.
Taylor rules
Taylor rules are simple monetary policy rules that prescribe how a central bank should
adjust its interest rate policy instrument in a systematic manner in response to
developments in inflation and macroeconomic activity. Following a rule is transparent.
By committing to follow a rule, policy makers can communicate and explain their policy
actions easily and should at least in principle enhance the accountability and credibility
of the central bank.
In Taylor (1998) an interest rate rule of the form:
147
10. New Keynesian models of monetary policy
When fitting this model to US data from 1987, quarter 1, to 1997, quarter 3, the g
coefficient was found to be 0.765 and the coefficient on inflation was found to be 1.533.
The fact that these are positive, and for the case of the coefficient on inflation, greater
than unity, is important for the stability of the economy.
Activity 10.1 Consider (10.12). If inflation was equal to the desired/target rate of
inflation and output deviations were zero (yt − y ∗ ), to what does the equation
collapse?
Consider a fall in demand that causes output to fall below y ∗ with no immediate impact
on inflation. A positive g coefficient implies that nominal interest rates set by the
monetary authorities should fall, since yt − y ∗ is now negative. With no change in
inflation, the fall in nominal rates will decrease real rates and so encourage investment
spending and aggregate demand. Output should then return to the full employment
level. Now consider the case where inflation has increased above the target rate. If the
coefficient on inflation in (11.1) is greater than unity, then the increase in nominal
interest rates will be greater than the increase in inflation. This causes real interest
rates to increase, leading to reduced investment spending and so reduces the
inflationary pressure in the economy. With positive coefficients for g and h (causing
1 + h, the coefficient on inflation in (11.1), to be greater than unity) we should see
stability in the economy, with output tending to be at its full employment level and
inflation staying close to the target rate. If the coefficient on inflation in (11.1) was
found to be less than one (h < 0), then an increase in inflation will be met by a less
than one-for-one rise in nominal rates. This will cause real rates to fall, encouraging
investment and aggregate demand that will cause further inflationary pressure. The
economic system in this case would be unstable.
Due to the long and variable lags associated with the formulation and implementation of
monetary policy, Milton Friedman suggested that trying to control the economy through
changing monetary variables, would purely lead to greater instability. Consider Figure
10.5. At date t0 a shock occurs that causes output to start to fall. The first recorded
data of such an event may become available at date t1 . However, the authorities need
more than just one data observation before changing their policy. After all, the data
reading could be a blip or involve considerable measurement error. At date t2 enough
data are available for the authorities to determine that a downturn is indeed happening
and the decision is made to implement an expansionary monetary policy. Since it takes
some time for the monetary policy decision to take effect, output is only affected at date
t3 , but this is the point when the economy is starting to recover. The monetary
expansion at a time when the economy is naturally starting to accelerate could lead to a
more volatile path for output. Hence, Friedman suggested monetary policy should not
be used to combat output fluctuations, not because of neutrality arguments but because
of the long and variable lags involved with such an activist policy.
148
10.12. A reminder of your learning outcomes
Figure 10.5:
149
10. New Keynesian models of monetary policy
Specify whether the following statement is true, false or uncertain. Explain your answer
in a short paragraph.
Section B
3. Consider a New Keynesian macro model with backward looking inflation in the
Phillips curve. Derive the optimal reaction function of the policy maker that aims
to stabilise inflation. a). Suppose the economy is subject to a temporary demand
shock. How should the policy maker stabilise the economy? Discuss by means of
diagrams. b). Do your results change when the economy is subject to a supply
shock?
1. The statement is true in the short run. Suggested answers should give examples of
effective monetary policymaking in the presence of nominal and real rigidities. The
model outlined in this chapter shows that the persistence of demand/supply shocks
matters in the determination of central bank forecasts about future Philips curve
and following optimal policy choice.
Section B
150
Chapter 11
Time inconsistency and inflation bias
11.1 Introduction
As discussed in Chapters 5 and 6 there is widespread belief among economists that
inflation is largely a monetary phenomenon. If monetary variations lead to inflation
variations, and if there is a positive statistical relationship between inflation and real
output (or employment) in the short run, governments or politically motivated
monetary policy makers may be tempted to exploit these short run relationships in
order to achieve different objectives. These may range from achieving temporary high
real output, reducing unemployment, financing budget deficits and even attaining
balance of payments objectives by generating surprise inflation. While such outcomes
may be feasible in the short-term, inflationary consequences distort economic agents
incentives in the medium to long run. What is more, economic agents learn the type of
policy makers over time such that they can not be easily fooled. Once consumers, firms
and other agents in the economy understand the incentives of policy makers to create
surprise inflation, they adjust their inflation expectations accordingly such that even in
the short run there can be no output gains to achieve. Thus, we will discuss the so called
inflation bias and ways reduce this bias. A simple game theoretic framework will allow
us to analyse the importance of central banks credibility in the combat of inflation.
11.2 Aims
This chapter aims to discuss strategic interactions between policy makers and economic
agents which may differ in their incentives with ultimate welfare deterioration for the
society. We also study how to resolve these conflicts of interests.
outline institutional and behavioural ways inflation bias can be reduced or avoided
describe the workings of the Taylor rule and give conditions needed for stability.
151
11. Time inconsistency and inflation bias
Journal articles
Clarida, R., J. Gali and M. Gertler ‘Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability:
evidence and some theory’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(1) 2000, pp.147–80.
Goodhart, C.A.E. ‘The conduct of monetary policy’, Economic Journal 99(396) 1989,
pp.293–346.
152
11.7. Time inconsistency and inflation bias
y ∗ is the market clearing level of output and εt is a productivity shock term where its
mean is set equal to zero. Suppose the monetary authorities can choose the inflation
rate directly and try to minimise the following loss function:
153
11. Time inconsistency and inflation bias
Figure 11.1:
αλεt
πt = αλ(k − 1)y ∗ − . (11.5)
1 + α2 λ
The inflation bias is given by Et−1 [πt ] = αλ(k − 1)y ∗ and represents the vertical distance
AE in Figure 11.1. Note that when parameter k = 0, there is no inflation bias as we
have seen in the previous chapter.
154
11.8. Inflation aversion, steepness of the Phillips curve and interest rates
the degree of central bank inflation aversion in the loss function (λ)
Figure 11.2:
The parameter α measures the slope of the Phillips curve or alternatively, the
responsiveness of inflation to changes in output. The higher the parameter α, the more
responsive is inflation to changes in output. Given the central bank preferences, a
steeper Phillips curve implies less aggressive policy response when the inflation deviates
from the target level. A steeper Phillips curve allows the central bank to do less in
response to an inflation shock since inflation responds strongly to a fall in output
155
11. Time inconsistency and inflation bias
associated with a tight monetary policy. For more discussion on the matter, see Carlin
and Soskice (2005).
We will now outline a number of ways in which this inflation bias can be
reduced/negated.
156
11.10. A reminder of your learning outcomes
So that the central bank’s loss depends on the level of inflation through the Ψ
parameter as well as squared inflation and squared output deviations. If we substitute
the Phillips curve into (11.7) and minimise the loss function by choosing πt (using the
same method as above), it can be shown that the inflation bias, Et−1 [πt ], is given by:
Ψ
Et−1 [πt ] = αλ(k − 1)y ∗ − . (11.8)
2
Therefore, if the contract was written for the central bank such that Ψ = 2αλ(k − 1)y ∗ ,
then the inflation bias would be zero and one would achieve the point of highest
attainable welfare, point A in Figure 11.1, as a time-consistent equilibrium.
11.9.3 Reputation
Policy credibility is at the core of monetary policymaking. A ‘hard nosed’ central bank
cares only about inflation, whereas a ‘wet’ central bank attempts to exploit short-term
relationships. However, even a ‘wet’ central bank can avoid inflation bias problem by
establishing a reputation that it is serious about inflation. Such reputation can only be
achieved in a multi period game between sceptical wage setters and the policy maker.
Carlin and Soskice (2006) illustrate the point by using a two period game. Let us
suppose that in period 1, the society chooses an expected inflation (π1E ) with the
knowledge that there is a certain probability, p, that the central bank is serious about
inflation. Equipped with this knowledge, the central bank chooses output at, say, y1 . In
period 2 the society chooses (π2E ) knowing how the central bank behaved in period 1
(that is they observe y1 ); the central bank chooses y2 knowing (π2E ), and so on. In this
scenario, even a ‘wet’ central bank will behave in period 1 as if it is ‘hard nosed’ about
inflation. This is because by behaving tough on inflation in period 1, inflation will be on
target and output on equilibrium. In period 2 (terminal period), however, the central
can set output above the equilibrium by creating surprise inflation. When the reasoning
extended to many periods, it pays off for the central bank to build a reputation of being
tough on inflation. The ‘wet’ central bank would behave as if it is a ‘hard nosed’ central
bank in all periods except the very last one of the game. The model provides a
justification for the incentives to build a reputation of inflation toughness when the
society is sceptical about the ‘nature’ of the central bank.
outline institutional and behavioral ways inflation bias can be reduced or avoided
describe the workings of the Taylor rule and give conditions needed for stability.
157
11. Time inconsistency and inflation bias
Specify whether the following statement is true, false or uncertain. Explain your answer
in a short paragraph.
Section B
3. What is the Taylor rule and why are the size and sign of its parameters important
for economic stability?
5. Suppose the central bank was penalised, by way of reduced salary, for allowing any
inflation above the socially desired level, set in this case at zero. The loss function
will then be:
LContract = πt2 + λ(yt − ky ∗ )2 + Ψπt .
Prove that under this loss function, the inflation bias will be:
Ψ
Et−1 [πt ] = αλ(k − 1)y ∗ − .
2
1. False. Students should answer this by providing a brief discussion on inflation bias
(the political bias towards a higher output) and how to resolve the problem.
158
11.12. Feedback to Sample examination questions
Section B
2. To answer this question we can follow the procedure used earlier in this chapter.
Equate aggregate demand and aggregate supply and collect terms in pt to obtain
yt = y ∗ + γ0 + γ1 mt + ηt .
From this equation, we may think that there is a positive relationship between
money and output since the coefficient on mt is positive. This is not true, however.
See the section on the Lucas critique in this chapter.
6. The variance of output in country A is lower than that in country B because the
coefficient on inflation in the Taylor rule is greater than unity, while in country B it
is less than 1. In country A, if inflation increases by 1%, due to an overheating
economy for example, the nominal interest rate increases by 1.6%, so causing real
rates to rise by 0.6%. This reduces the inflationary pressure in the economy by
dampening demand. In country B, a similar rise in inflation leads to a rise in
nominal rates of only 0.5%. This implies real rates fall, so increasing demand in the
economy when it is already overheating. If output increases when it is already too
high, this implies output is not stable, explaining the greater variance of output in
country B.
159
11. Time inconsistency and inflation bias
160
Chapter 12
Monetary policy and data/parameter
uncertainties
12.1 Introduction
Throughout the Guide we assumed that:
the central bank is assumed to know the true model of the economy,
the central bank observes accurately all relevant variables timely and accurately,
161
12. Monetary policy and data/parameter uncertainties
12.2 Aims
This chapter aims to introduce two major challenges, data and parameter uncertainty,
that policy makers will face in deciding the monetary policy.
162
12.7. Data uncertainty
Sack, B. ‘Does the Fed act gradually? A VAR analysis’ Journal of Monetary Economics,
46 2000, pp.229–256.
where Xtp denotes the statistical agency’s initial announcement of a variable that was
realised at time t, Xtf denotes the final or true value of the same variable and rtf
denotes the final revision which may potentially be never observed.
These data revisions, rtf , can be due to:
Revisions should have a mean zero. i.e. initial announcement of the statistical
agency should be an unbiased estimate of the final value of the data.
Final revision should be unpredictable given the information set at the time of the
initial announcement and
The variance of the final revision should be small compared to the variance of the
final value of the data.
Aruoba (2008) shows vast empirical evidence that none of these properties of well
behaved revisions are full-filled in the US data. The measurement problem is more
important for output series than it is for inflation or employment/unemployment series.
We first look at a case where we assume that the structure of the economy is known
with certainty. However, we also assume that the economy may be subject to additive
shocks; this creates data uncertainty.
Poole (1970) analysed the implication of adding such news shocks to both the IS and
LM schedules. Such shocks could come about from for instance changes in consumer
tastes or government expenditures shocks on the IS side and stock market crashes and
163
12. Monetary policy and data/parameter uncertainties
financial crises such as the collapse of LTCM in 1998 or a change in the central bank
behaviour on the LM side. Poole’s model assumes that the parameters and structure of
the model are known with certainty, which is an unrealistic assumption, but allows the
IS and LM schedules to be subject to zero-mean random errors, again the so called
news shocks. Define IS and LM schdules as:
Y = a − bR + ε (12.2)
M = c − dR + eY + η.
ε and η are additive IS and LM shocks whose variances are σε2 and ση2 respectively, and
for simplicity we ignore the price level in the LM curve. Alternatively, assume the
monetary authorities can control real money balances, denoted by M . The authorities
can either set the money supply, M , or the interest rate, R, but not both. With a
downward-sloping money demand schedule, either R or M can be set and the other
variable will have to change to allow the markets to clear. If the authorities set the
interest rate, then from the IS schedule, the expected value of output, Y , given R,
denoted E[Y | R] will be:
E[Y | R] = a − bR. (12.3)
Assume that the goal of the policy makers is to minimise the variance of output. From
(12.2) and (12.3), Y − E[Y | R] will simply be ε and so the variance of output given that
the authorities set the interest rate will be E[Y − E[Y | R]]2 = σε2 . Alternatively, the
monetary authorities could set the money supply, M . In order to calculate the variance
of output in this scenario, we need to calculate Y as a function of M only. From the LM
schedule, we can calculate R as a function of M , Y and η and then substitute this into
the IS curve. Solving for Y will give:
ad − bc bM dε − bη
Y = + + . (12.4)
d + be d + be d + be
We can then find E[Y | M ] and the variance of output given that the authorities directly
control the money stock. This is given in 12.5.
2
2 1
E[Y − E[Y | M ]] = (d2 σε2 + b2 ση2 ). (12.5)
d + be
We can now examine which policy instrument, when set by the authorities, will result in
a lower output variance. Consider the case where there are no IS shocks, σε2 . The
variance of output under both interest rate and money targeting regimes is given in the
top line of Table 12.1. It is clear that setting the interest rate and allowing money to
change to clear the market is the optimal strategy. However, if there are no LM shocks,
ση2 , then output variance is smaller under a policy of fixed money supply, see the
bottom line of Table 12.1. Therefore, if an economy is prone to IS shocks, the
authorities should keep the money supply constant. If the economy is prone to money
market, LM, shocks, the interest rate should be the instrument of choice.
This is also shown in Figures 12.1a and 12.1b. Figure 12.1a shows the case with IS
shocks only. The output variation when the interest rate is fixed at R∗ is shown by |R ,
in which case the money supply has to change to clear the money markets causing the
LM curve to shift so that equilibrium is at points A or B. If the money supply was kept
164
12.8. Parameter (or multiplicative) uncertainty
b
2
Only LM shocks, σε2 = 0 Var[Y | R] = 0 < Var[Y | M ] = d+be
ση2
d
2
Only IS shocks, ση2 = 0 Var[Y | R] = σε2 > Var[Y | M ] = d+be
σε2
Table 12.1:
fixed then output deviations are shown by |M . Therefore, with IS shocks, in order to
keep output variance at a minimum, it is best to keep the money supply fixed.
In Figure 12.1b, by keeping the interest rate fixed after LM shocks, equilibrium will be
unchanged at point E and output variance will therefore be zero. By keeping the money
supply fixed, however, LM shocks will cause equilibrium to move between points A and
B and output variance will be positive, equal to ∆Y |M . So, depending on the main
source of economic shocks, whether they originate from the goods or money markets,
will determine which monetary instrument the authorities should target.
165
12. Monetary policy and data/parameter uncertainties
vector containing fiscal and monetary instruments that the government can control. The
relationship between y and X is given by:
y = gX. (12.6)
If y = gX, taking averages will give yb = gbX. The problem can then be written as:
Noting that E[g − gb]2 = σg2 and that E[g − gb] = gb − gb = 0, the problem then becomes:
Differentiating this with respect to X, the choice variable, setting equal to zero and
solving will give:
gby ∗ gb2 y ∗
X= 2 ⇒ yb = gbX = 2 < y∗. (12.10)
σg + gb2 σg + gb 2
The implication of the model is that because of the presence of uncertainty, σg2 > 0, the
authorities will never push aggressively enough to make average output equal to the
target level, y ∗ . To do so will simply cause output variation to increase to an intolerable
level. The policy maker would rather have a stable level of output below the full
employment level than very volatile output whose average was y ∗ . This is shown in
Figure 12.2.
From y = gX and yb = gbX, it follows that σy2 = σg2 X 2 which implies X = σy /σg .
Substituting into y = gX will give the linear policy constraint in Figure 12.2. The
authorities try to reach the indifference curve closest to y ∗ , the target level, subject to
the policy constraint and as can be seen in Figure 12.2, the presence of uncertainty, σg2 ,
causes the authorities to opt for a less aggressive policy stance, causing equilibrium
output to be below y ∗ .
Activity 12.1 What happens in Figure 12.2 when the uncertainty, shown by σg2 ,
increases? Do the policy makers become more or less aggressive in reaching the
target level of output, y ∗ ? Explain.
166
12.8. Parameter (or multiplicative) uncertainty
and
yt = −bit + εt (12.12)
with
ε ∼ (0, σε2 ) (12.13)
where π stands for inflation, y for the business cycle component of real output (or
income), i for the short term rate that the policy maker can control and ε for the
stochastic demand shocks hitting the economy. We assume that the mean value of these
shocks are equal to zero and their variance is given by σε2 and these are known by the
policy maker. Parameters a and b are constants. By substituting (12.12) into (12.11) we
obtain an expression for current inflation as a function of past inflation, the policy rate
and shocks hitting the economy.
167
12. Monetary policy and data/parameter uncertainties
The policy maker cares about inflation stabilisation. Suppose that the quadratic loss
function of the central bank takes the following form:
L = (πt − π ∗ )2 (12.15)
where π ∗ represents the target inflation. In other words, whenever the current inflation
deviates form the target inflation, the policy maker has an incentive to bring back the
inflation to its target level by manipulating the policy rate, i.
The only source of uncertainty is the presence of stochastic shocks. Given that the
policy maker knows the nature of the shocks with a mean of zero (E(ε) = 0) and a
constant variance (E(ε2 ) = σε2 ), it will form an expectation about these. Substitute the
perceived structure of the economy into the objective function of the central bank:
Le = E(aπt−1 − bit + εt − π ∗ )2
or
Le = a2 πt−1
2
+ b2 i2t + E(ε2 ) +π ∗ 2 − 2aπt−1 bit + 2aπt−1 E(εt )
| {z } | {z }
σε2 0
∗ ∗ ∗
−2aπt−1 π − 2bit E(εt ) +2bit π − 2 E(εt ) π .
| {z } | {z }
0 0
Note that, by setting E(ε) = 0 and E(ε2 ) = σε2 we have inserted policy makers
expectations about the shocks. The policy maker’s job is to minimise the loss with the
use of the monetary policy instrument it .
∂Le
= 2b2 it + 2bπ ∗ − 2aπt−1 b = 0
∂it
−π ∗ + aπt−1
it = .
b
It is important to notice that policy rate set by the policy maker is the same as the one
that it would set if there were no shocks hitting the economy. This is the certainty
equivalence result. That means additive shocks do not affect the way monetary policy is
conducted. The best the policy maker can do is simply to ignore them.
Now, we can include a bit of complication. The economic environment is the same as in
the previous section except that the parameter b of the real income equation is allowed
to vary over time. We capture this by adding a time subscript to parameter b.
Specifically:
yt = −bt it + εt (12.16)
with
ε ∼ (0, σε2 ), b ∼ (bb, σb2 ) (12.17)
168
12.8. Parameter (or multiplicative) uncertainty
where the shocks are still additive, however we also see that the parameter b has a
certain distribution such that its mean is bb and its variance is σb2 . It is important to note
that this information is available to the policy maker such that it can form expectations
about the value of the parameter b.
By substituting (12.16) into (12.11) we obtain again an expression for current inflation
as a function of past inflation, the policy rate, the shocks hitting the economy and the
novel element of time varying parameter b.
πt = aπt−1 − bt it + εt . (12.18)
The problem of the central bank now becomes:
Le = E(aπt−1 − bt it + εt − π ∗ )2
= a2 πt−1
2
+ E(b2t )i2t + E(ε2 ) +π ∗ 2 − 2aπt−1 E(bt )it + 2aπt−1 E(εt )
| {z } | {z }
σε2 0
∗ ∗ ∗
+2aπt−1 π + 2E(bt )it E(εt ) −2E(bt )it π − 2 E(εt ) π .
| {z } | {z }
0 0
Remember that you can write the variance of b as σb2 = E(bt − bb)2 = E(b2t − 2btbb + bb2 ).
Given that E(bt ) = bb that is equal to σb2 = E(b2t ) − E(bb2 ). That allows us to rewrite the
Le as:
Le = a2 πt−1
2
+ E(b2t )i2t + σε2 + π ∗ 2 − 2aπt−1 E(bt )it + 2aπt−1 π ∗ + 2E(bt )it π ∗
= a2 πt−1
2
+ sigma2b + E(bb2 ) i2t + σε2 + π ∗ 2 − 2aπt−1 E(bt ) it + 2aπt−1 π ∗ + 2 E(bt ) it π ∗
| {z } | {z } | {z }
b2
b b
b b
b
= a2 πt−1
2
+ σb2 i2t + σε2 − 2aπt−1bbit + 2aπt−1 π ∗ + bb2 i2t + π ∗ 2 + 2bbit π ∗ .
We can now solve the policy maker’s optimisation problem that is:
∂Le 2
∗ b
= 2σb it − 2aπt−1 b + 2 bit + π b = 0
b b
∂it
(aπt−1 − π ∗ )bb
it =
(σ 2 + bb2 )
b
(aπt−1 − π ∗ )
= .
(σ 2 + bb2 )/bb
b
The expression σb /bb refers to the coefficient of variation. It represents the trade-off
between returning inflation to target and increasing uncertainty about inflation depends
on the variance of the parameter relative to its mean level. A large coefficient of
variation means for a small reduction in the inflation bias the central bank induces a
large variance into future inflation. Once parameter uncertainty is taken into account
inflation variance depends on the interest rate reactions. Policy maker’s decisions affect
uncertainty of future inflation. Hence, rather than strong reaction or ‘cold turkey’,
gradualism (sustained policy reaction) is preferable (Brainard conservatism).
169
12. Monetary policy and data/parameter uncertainties
Finally, we can show the effect of data and parameter uncertainties on policymaking in
a simple graphical setting. Consider Figure 12.3 following Sack (2000).
Suppose that there is a negative relationship between real output (horizontal axis) and
policy rates (vertical axis, which characterises the IS curve. Upper panel shows the case
without any uncertainty. As is clear whenever the actual output deviates from desired
output, the policy maker can adjust policy rates to reach the desired level. Middle panel
shows the case with additive uncertainty (only news shocks are considered here). Here,
the policy maker is not sure about the quality of the data it receives (as shown by
parallel dashed lines). Nevertheless, it acts as if it knows the data with certainty, as
there is nothing it can do about the shocks (certainty equivalence). Finally, lower panel
shows the case with parameter uncertainty. Since, the nature of the relationship
between output and policy rate is time-varying, the slope is changing over time. If the
policy makers acts with aggression, that is trying to reach the desired output by
increasing the policy rate a lot, the economy may find itself at an equilibrium that is
even less desirable than before. What can the policy maker do?
170
12.9. Interest rate smoothing
In Figure 12.4 Sack (2000) demonstrates a possible alternative to the bad outcome in
line with the analytical discussion in the previous section. The policy maker moves in
steps (interest smoothing). First, it adjusts the policy rates in the right direction. When
the (relatively benign) state of the economy is revealed, it moves again in the same
direction. The policy maker thereby exploits arrival of new information and can reduce
the size of potential errors it can commit.
171
12. Monetary policy and data/parameter uncertainties
Specify whether the following statement is true, false or uncertain. Explain your answer
in a short paragraph.
1. ‘When the economy is subject to multiplicative uncertainty the best a policy maker
do is to ignore the uncertainty’.
Section B
2. What is the certainty equivalence? Under which conditions can a policy maker act
as if shocks do not happen?
3. Consider a policy maker aiming to minimise quadratic loss associated with actual
inflation over a target inflation. Suppose also that the economic environment
includes forward looking expectations in the Phillips curve such that:
and the parameter b is allowed to vary over time. Note that distribution of the
disturbance term and of the parameter b have following statistical properties:
Calculate optimal interest rate reaction function of the policy maker. Provide an
intuition to your answer.
4. Suppose the economy is subject to i.i.d. mean zero IS and LM shocks. Discuss in a
simple model their implications on the policy instrument choice.
172
12.12. Feedback to Sample examination questions
4. The question is about selecting the policy instrument that minimises the variance
of output. Students should show analytically and graphically the impact of IS or
LM shocks. See Poole (1970).
173
12. Monetary policy and data/parameter uncertainties
174
Chapter 13
The term structure of interest rates
13.1 Introduction
With the exceptions of Chapters 11 and 12, throughout this guide we have only ever
considered ‘the’ interest rate, that is the one set by the monetary authorities, or that is
allowed to change to clear the money markets if the money supply is the instrument of
choice. Even in Chapters 11 and 12, there was only ever one market interest rate. In
reality, there are a large number of interest rates, from those on debt that mature
overnight to interest rates on debt that mature up to 30 years in the future. This
chapter will examine in more detail the links between short-term and long-term interest
rates, explaining why such links are important and providing theories that explain the
short-termlong-term interest rate relationship.
13.2 Aims
This chapter will introduce the relevance of a rich variety of interest rates in financial
and macroeconomic decisions. We will also discuss different term structure theories.
explain what a yield curve is and why it is important for policy makers
list and discuss the different empirical regularities of the yield curve
list and describe the three different theories of the term structure outlined in this
chapter, noting any differences and similarities and stating which theories can
explain which empirical facts
describe the relationship between rates of return and bond prices and why this is so
important for the absence of arbitrage conditions on which the expectations
hypothesis focuses.
175
13. The term structure of interest rates
Shiller, R.J. ‘The term structure of interest rates’, in Friedman, B. and F. Hahn (eds)
Handbook of Monetary Economics. (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1990).
Walsh, C.E. Monetary Theory and Policy. (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2003)
Chapter 10.
Journal articles
Aksoy, Y. and H. Basso, ‘Liquidity, term spreads and monetary policy’, Economic
Journal, 124, 2014, 1234–1278.
Mankiw, N.G. and L.H. Summers ‘Do long-term interest rates overreact to short-term
interest rates?’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1984) 1, pp.223–247.
McCallum, B.T. ‘Monetary policy and the term structure of interest rates’, National
Bureau of Economic Research working paper, w4938, (1994).
Shiller, R.J. ‘The volatility of long-term interest rates and expectations models of the
term structure’, Journal of Political Economy 87(5, Part 2) 1979, 1190–1219.
176
13.7. The yield curve
Activity 13.1 What does the yield curve look like in your country?
Figure 13.1:
177
13. The term structure of interest rates
Coupon bonds. Typically, coupon bonds promise to pay a fixed sum of money, the
coupon, every period, whether it is every month, quarter or year, and also promise
to pay the holder of the bond its face value on maturity. For example, a ten-year
bond may be bought from the government for £100 that promises to pay £5 (the
coupon payment) every year for the next ten years. In the final year, both the last
£5 coupon and the maturity value of the bond, £100, are paid.
Discount bonds. Discount bonds do not offer any interest or coupon payments.
Instead, they are sold at a ‘discount’ and pay a larger amount on maturity. For
example, a ten-year discount bond may be sold today for £60 that pays no coupons
at all but pays £100 on maturity, ten years from now.
Consider a coupon bond that pays C every year from now to infinity. Such bonds,
without a maturity date, are called perpetuities or Consols (the UK term). The price of
this bond, P , will be the future cash flow, discounted back to today by the interest rate,
R, assumed constant here for convenience.
C C C C 1 C
P = + 2
+ 3
+ ··· = = . (13.1)
1 + R (1 + R) (1 + R) 1 + R 1 − 1/(1 + R) R
There is then a negative relationship between the price of a bond and the interest rate.
This was discussed in Chapter 2 when examining Keynes individual money demand
function. (For bonds that do have a maturity date, the relationship between bond prices
and the interest rate, although still negative, is not as simple as (13.1). Intuitively, if the
interest rate increased, people would be willing to pay less for a bond that pays a fixed
coupon payment each period. If a perpetuity bond that paid a coupon of £5 had a price
of £100, this implies the market interest rate is 5%. If the market interest rate doubled
to 10%, no investor would be willing to pay more than £50 for the same bond since the
£5 coupon on a £50 bond is 10%. Hence the bond price and interest rate are negatively
related.
178
13.10. Empirical regularities of the term structure
1. Rates of return on short- and long-dated bonds move together over time.
2. When short rates are low, the yield curve is likely to be upward sloping and vice
versa.
The left-hand side is the total return from holding n period bonds until they mature.
The right-hand side is the total expected return from holding and continually rolling
over oneperiod bonds, n times. The rates of return on all bonds bought at date t + 1
onwards are not known at date t, hence the e (expectation) superscript. Taking logs of
179
13. The term structure of interest rates
t+n−1
1 X e
⇒ t Rt+n = sr . (13.3)
n s=t s+1
This is one of the main results of the expectations hypothesis; the long-term interest
rate is an average of the current and all future expected short-term interest rates. The
expectations hypothesis does have a number of criticisms, however:
It cannot explain the empirical fact that the yield curve has a persistent upward
slope. If the long rate is an average of current and expected future short rates, this
can only be explained if the short rate increases through time. This clearly is not
the case.
If the long rate is an average of current and future short rates, the long rate must
be a smoother series (when plotted through time) than the short rate. This is not
true; the long rate is just as volatile.
In order to avoid arbitrage opportunities and keep total returns equal, if the rate of
return on long-term bonds is greater than the return on short bonds, then holding
long-dated bonds must be accompanied by a capital loss (i.e. the price of long-term
bonds must fall). If the price of long-term bonds falls, the rate of return must
increase still further in the next period. Putting this another way: if the long rate is
higher than the short rate, the long rate must increase. This does not happen in
reality.
If the long rate is an average of the current and expected future short rates, then an
upward-sloping yield curve suggests that the short rate is expected to increase in the
future (see (13.3)). If the real interest rate is constant then the increase in expected
future nominal interest rates must be associated with an increase in expected future
inflation, as per the Fisher equation. The greater the slope of the yield curve, the more
short-term rates are expected to rise and so the faster is inflation expected to increase.
180
13.13. Preferred habitat theory
rate of return will fall. The markets for m, m + 1, m + 2, etc. period debt are said to be
segmented.
Whereas the expectations hypothesis could not explain the persistent upward sloping
nature of the yield curve, this feature can be easily explained if we use the segmentation
hypothesis. If people generally prefer to hold short-dated debt (i.e. save by buying
shortterm bonds), then this will cause the price of short-term bonds to be high, relative
to longterm bonds, and so the rate of return on short-term debt will then be lower than
the longterm rate, implying an upward-sloping yield curve.
Activity 13.2 Why do you think people would prefer to hold short-term, rather
than long-term, debt?
(Hint: think of the desire to lock up money in long-term bonds and the risk of
capital gains or losses when such holdings have to be liquidated.)
Despite being able to explain persistent upward-sloping yield curves, the segmentation
hypothesis cannot explain the fact that interest rates move together since the markets
are completely segmented. Also, the theory cannot explain why yield curves are upward
(downward)-sloping when short rates are low (high).
This is exactly the same as the expectations hypothesis, (13.3), except for the inclusion
of a term premium, t kn . If n period bonds were not the bond of choice, then people
would need an extra rate of return in order to encourage them to hold such debt. In this
case t kn would be positive. If people generally tend to prefer short-dated debt then the
term premium will be a monotonic function of maturity; in order to hold longer and
longer dated debt, an increasing term premium must be offered. When combined with
the ‘expectations hypothesis’ component, (13.4) can explain the persistent upward slope
of the yield curve, along with the other empirical regularities: the co-movement of short
and long rates, and the fact the yield curve tends to be upward (downward)-sloping
when short rates are low (high). However, using the term premium to fix the problems
of the expectations and segmentations hypotheses, is arguably a not a proper solution.
A theory of the term premium should be provided, rather than simply assumed in order
to make the data consistent with the ‘fixed’ theory. For a recent paper on a theory of
term premium that builds upon maturity transformation risk faced by the banks, see
Aksoy and Basso (2014).
181
13. The term structure of interest rates
explain what a yield curve is and why it is important for policy makers
list and discuss the different empirical regularities of the yield curve
list and describe the three different theories of the term structure outlined in this
chapter, noting any differences and similarities and stating which theories can
explain which empirical facts
describe the relationship between rates of return and bond prices and why this is so
important for the absence of arbitrage conditions on which the expectations
hypothesis focuses.
Specify whether the following statement is true, false or uncertain. Explain your answer
in a short paragraph.
1. ‘Under the segmentation hypothesis, the slope of the yield curve tells us nothing
about expected inflation.’
Section B
2. Empirical fact: yield curves tend to have an especially steep upward slope when
short rates are low and a downward slope when short-term interest rates are high.
Can you explain this fact with the theories of the term structure analysed in this
chapter?
3. Assuming that the expectations hypothesis is the correct theory of the term
structure, calculate the interest rates for one to five year bonds and plot the
resulting yield curves when one year interest rates over the next five years look as
follows:
(a) 5%, 7%, 7%, 7%, 7%.
(b) 5%, 4%, 4%, 4%, 4%.
How would your yield curves change if people preferred shorter-term bonds over
longer-term bonds?
4. If the yield curve was steeply upward sloping, what is the market predicting about
the movements of future short-term interest rates? What might the market predict
about the inflation rate in the future?
5. How can the preferred habitat theory explain the appearance of downward-sloping
yield curves if t kn , the term premium, is positive?
182
13.16. Feedback to Sample examination questions
3. From the expectations hypothesis, and in particular (13.3), we can calculate the 2,
3, 4 and 5-year interest rates from the one year rates given in the question.
(a) Using (13.3), we see that:
2 year rate; t Rt+2 = 1 = 2(5 + 7) = 6% per year.
3 year rate; t Rt+3 = 1 = 3(5 + 7 + 7) = 6.33% per year.
The 4- and 5-year rates can be calculated in a similar way to obtain
t Rt+4 = 6.5% per year and t Rt+5 = 6.6% per year. The yield curve is therefore
upward sloping (notice that an upward-sloping yield curve suggests interest
rates will rise in the future; 5% to 7%).
(b) Again using (13.3), we can calculate the 2, 3, 4 and 5-year interest rates to
obtain t Rt+2 = 4.5% per year, t Rt+3 = 4.33% per year, t Rt+4 = 4.25% per year
and t Rt+5 = 4.2% per year. The yield curve is therefore downward sloping (a
downward-sloping yield curve suggests interest rates will fall; 5% to 4%).
If people preferred shorter-term bonds then they would have to receive an
increased rate of return on longer-term debt (over and above that implied by
the expectations hypothesis) in order to encourage them to hold such assets.
In case (a), the yield curve would be even steeper and in part (b), the yield
curve will also be rotated anticlockwise, so becoming more flat, or perhaps
becoming positively sloped if the term premium was large enough.
183
13. The term structure of interest rates
184
Appendix A
Sample examination paper
Important note
This commentary reflects the examination and assessment arrangements for this course
in the academic year 2014–15. The format and structure of the examination may change
in future years, and any such changes will be publicised on the virtual learning
environment (VLE).
Section A
1. The advantage of using fiat money vs. a barter economy is that fiat money no
longer requires trust between transaction partners.
2. The demand of money is positively related to the price uncertainty of assets.
3. Under the preferred habitat theory the slope of the yield curve tells us nothing
about the expected inflation.
4. In Tobin’s portfolio selection model individuals hold either money or bonds.
5. Parameter uncertainty in the Brainard model implies more aggressive fiscal policy
action.
6. The quantity theory of money states that the total value of all monetary
transactions must be equal to the real value of goods and services it buys.
7. According to the standard real business cycle (RBC) theory, money is not neutral.
8. Recessions are best dealt with by conservative central bankers.
185
A. Sample examination paper
Section B
Answer THREE out of FIVE questions from this section. (20 marks each)
U = C α (M/P )1−α
C + M/P ≤ Y + M0 /P
where Y stands initial endowment of goods, M0 stands for initial money balances.
(a) Calculate optimal goods and money demand. Provide intuition. Would your
results change qualitatively if elements (that are real money balances and
consumption) in the utility function were additive, instead of multiplicative?
(b) Is there a role for monetary policy in this setting? What happens when the
economy faces a money supply increase? Show graphically and provide
intuition.
(c) Is the classical theory convincing? Are you aware of alternative macro theories
where monetary policy can be an effective output stabilisation tool? Discuss
analytically one such model.
10. Consider a McCallum economy with sticky prices where the aggregate demand
expression given as:
where yt , mt and pt are the logs of real output, nominal money balances and the
price level respectively at date t, vt is an i.i.d. normal aggregate demand shock with
vt ∼ (0, σv2 ) are positive parameters and E is the expectations operator. To
construct the aggregate supply assume the following:
(i) the market clearing price is denoted by p∗t
(ii) the prices are set by firms at t − 1 and are only effective in t. These are
expected to be the market clearing price in t, i.e. pt = Et−1 [p∗t ]
(iii) real output consistent with natural rate of unemployment, (y ∗ ), is determined
by the following law of motion that captures hysteresis
yt∗ = δ0 + δ1 t + δ2 yt−1
∗
+ ut
mt = µ0 + µ1 mt−1 + et
186
(a) Solve for the output gap, i.e. deviations of real output from the market
clearing level.
(b) Are unanticipated monetary policy changes effective? Show analytically and
provide intuition.
(c) Are anticipated monetary policy changes effective? Show analytically and
provide intuition.
(d) What is the Lucas critique? Evaluate the critique based on the output gap
equation you have derived above.
11. Suppose that the economy of Pool-land is characterised by the following IS schedule
Y = a − bR + ε
M = c − dR + eY + η
where Y represents the real output, R the short term interest rate, M the real
money balances, coefficients a, b, c, d are positive constants. The economy is
subject to additive shocks. ε and η are IS and LM shocks with the following
properties ε ∼ i.i.d. (0, σε2 ) and η ∼ i.i.d. (0, ση2 ). Note that the uncertainty arises
only due to additive shocks.
Suppose that the monetary authority goal is to minimise the variance of output.
(a) Is it better to use short term interest rates instead of real money balances to
stabilise the economy when the economy is subject to IS shocks only? Show
analytically.
(b) Is it better to use short term interest rates instead of real money balances to
stabilise the economy when the economy is subject to LM shocks only? Show
analytically.
(c) Now consider the case of multiplicative uncertainty, where parameters of the
model, a, b, c, d are subject to uncertainty. Would this model modification
affect your policy results? Discuss verbally.
12. A treasurer has to manage the cash position of a small London college. At the
beginning of the year the college receives £5 million in tuition fees. The college is
expected to spend all of that money in the year, at an approximately constant
daily rate. The treasurer can either hold the financial wealth of the college in
bonds, yielding an interest rate of 4% or in cash, which is assumed to not receive
any interest. The accrued interest on the bond holdings is received at the end of
the year and is not compounded inbetween. The brokerage fees of exchanging
bonds for money are £1,000 per transaction. Note that the first transaction takes
place at the beginning of the year, when the treasurer buys bonds, the transactions
during the rest of the year will compose of selling bond holdings. The treasurer
wants to minimize the costs of cash management, C, which are composed of the
interest foregone on the cash holdings and the brokerage fees.
187
A. Sample examination paper
(a) Draw the time profile of the college’s holdings of cash and bonds.
(b) Set up the cost minimization problem for the treasurer and calculate the how
much money, Z, should be transferred each time the treasurer sells off bonds.
(c) Calculate the interest elasticity of money.
(d) The problem outlined above is based on the Baumol–Tobin inventory theoretic
model. State and discuss two criticisms of the inventory theoretic model.
D = d0 − d1 (i − iD ) (A.1)
L = l0 − l1 (i − iL ) (A.2)
where L stands for bank loans, D stands for bank deposits, iL the loan rate, iD
deposit rate and i is the market interest rate. Assume that banks do not have
operating costs or are not required to hold reserves.
(a) Calculate the competitive equilibrium. Show graphically. How do your results
change when the government sets deposit rates equal to iD = a, with a < iL ?
Provide intuition.
(b) Now suppose that government introduces a mandatory reserve ratio, r∗ , such
that R = r∗ D. How do your results change? What are the implications of such
a reserve ratio policy on prices and quantities? Provide intuition.
(c) Sometimes, it is suggested that the reserve ratio policy can be an alternative
to targeting interest rates or monetary aggregates. Can this be an effective
policy to stabilise output and inflation fluctuations?
END OF PAPER
188
Appendix B
Examiners’ commentary to Sample
examination paper
Section A
1. The advantage of using fiat money vs. a barter economy is that fiat money no
longer requires trust between transaction partners.
False.
Reading for this question: the subject guide, Chapter 2.
Direct barter is the only method of transaction that does not require trust. Fiat
money is intrinsically worthless: its value derives primarily from the trust that
people put in it (Trust Monetary authority/government). The advantages of fiat
money rather lie in the fact that it is durable, portable, homogeneous, and
acceptable.
3. Under the preferred habitat theory the slope of the yield curve tells us nothing
about the expected inflation.
False.
Reading for this question: the subject guide, Chapter 13.
The PH Theory states that the yield of longer maturities is partially determined by
risk premia and partially by expectations about future short term interest rates.
Given a theory on the nature of risk premia (eg. half a percent per year of
maturity) and the relation between short term interest rates and inflation (e.g. real
interest rates are constant) one can use PH theory to make inference about
expected inflation.
189
B. Examiners’ commentary to Sample examination paper
5. Parameter uncertainty in the Brainard model implies more aggressive fiscal policy
action.
False.
Reading for this question:
1. The subject guide, Chapter 12.
2. Brainard, W. (1967), ‘Uncertainty and effectiveness of policy’, American
Economic Review (papers and proceedings), 57 (2), pp. 411–425.
In Brainard’s model of multiplicative uncertainty it is shown that if there is
parameter uncertainty in the models the central bank uses, it will pursue a less
aggressive monetary policy objective. This happens because the government has to
trade off lower output volatility against higher output (as close to y ∗ as possible).
Due to the parameter uncertainty, choosing higher levels of y will result in a higher
level of output volatility. See Figure 12.2.
g2y∗
min X 2 σg2 + (y ∗ − gX)2 , gX = 2 2
< y∗.
X σg + g
6. The quantity theory of money states that the total value of all monetary
transactions must be equal to the real value of goods and services it buys.
False.
Reading for this question: the subject guide, Chapter 5.
It refers to nominal rather than real value of goods and services it buys.
190
7. According to the standard real business cycle (RBC) theory, money is not neutral.
False.
Reading for this question: the subject guide, Chapter 8.
Standard RBC suggests the opposite as an extension of the classical model. It is
based on the premise of a frictionless economy where all agents make optimal
decisions given their preferences and constraints. Money is just a veil.
Section B
Answer THREE out of FIVE questions from this section. (20 marks each)
U = C α (M/P )1−α
C + M/P ≤ Y + M0 /P
where Y stands initial endowment of goods, M0 stands for initial money balances.
(a) Calculate optimal goods and money demand. Provide intuition. Would your
results change qualitatively if elements (that are real money balances and
consumption) in the utility function were additive, instead of multiplicative?
(b) Is there a role for monetary policy in this setting? What happens when the
economy faces a money supply increase? Show graphically and provide
intuition.
(c) Is the classical theory convincing? Are you aware of alternative macro theories
where monetary policy can be an effective output stabilisation tool? Discuss
analytically one such model.
191
B. Examiners’ commentary to Sample examination paper
192
Assume now that the economy consists of n households each identical to the
one described above. The market clearing condition in the goods market then
becomes:
Y + M0 /P
n = nY. (B.8)
2
In other words, total demand equals total supply. Solving for the price level
gives:
M0
P = . (B.9)
Y
Alternatively, we can write down the market clearing condition for the money
market:
P Y + M0
n = nM0 . (B.10)
2
If we solve for the price level here, we obtain:
M0
P = . (B.11)
Y
In this economy, money is neutral. Real output per household is fixed at Y as
it depends on endowments.
Modifying the utility function such that elements are additive (i.e. such that
U = X 1/2 + (M/P )1/2 ) does not change result.
(b) From the solution of the price level, a change in the money supply will only
lead to a proportional increase in prices. Real money balances and ‘production’
of goods do not change. An increase in money, M0 , will shift the demand
function for good X outwards in Figure 4.2 but this simply causes the price
level to increase.
(c) In standard classical models money is just a veil, while we know that money
may have real effects at least in the short run. However, it is possible even
with the classical paradigm to obtain short term real effects of money. There
are a wide range of alternatives here. Students could solve Lucas’
misperceptions model or a simple cash in advance model for cases of classical
model or a Keynesian (such as McCallum) model to make their point.
10. Consider a McCallum economy with sticky prices where the aggregate demand
expression given as:
where yt , mt and pt are the logs of real output, nominal money balances and the
price level respectively at date t, vt is an i.i.d. normal aggregate demand shock with
vt ∼ (0, σv2 ) are positive parameters and E is the expectations operator. To
construct the aggregate supply assume the following:
(i) the market clearing price is denoted by p∗t
(ii) the prices are set by firms at t − 1 and are only effective in t. These are
expected to be the market clearing price in t, i.e. pt = Et−1 [p∗t ]
193
B. Examiners’ commentary to Sample examination paper
mt = µ0 + µ1 mt−1 + et
(a) Solve for the output gap, i.e. deviations of real output from the market
clearing level.
(b) Are unanticipated monetary policy changes effective? Show analytically and
provide intuition.
(c) Are anticipated monetary policy changes effective? Show analytically and
provide intuition.
(d) What is the Lucas critique? Evaluate the critique based on the output gap
equation you have derived above.
Reading for this quesiton: the subject guide, Chapter 9 and McCallum (1989),
Chapters 9 and 10.
(a) First consider aggregate demand. By combining the IS and LM equations, we
can derive an AD expression of the form:
yt , mt and pt are the logs of real output, nominal money balances and the
price level, respectively, at date t. vt is a random demand shock with zero
mean (i.e. an element of aggregate demand that is not picked up by real
money balances or expected inflation). β0 , β1 and β2 are positive parameters
and Et−1 is the rational expectations operator with the t − 1 subscript
denoting the date the expectation was formed. In rational expectations, people
not only take all available information into account when they form their
expectations, but their expectations are also consistent with the way in which
the variables actually evolve. Rational expectations are sometimes also known
as ‘model consistent’ expectations.The equation states that aggregate demand
depends positively on real money balances and positively on expected
inflation; for any given nominal interest rate, higher inflation implies a lower
real interest rate, making investment cheaper.
Aggregate supply is a little more difficult to specify because of the assumption
that prices are set at the beginning of the period, with supply being demand
determined. Denote the price that clears the market at date t as p∗t . We assume
that the prices the firms set at date t − 1, to be operational in the market at
date t, pt , are the prices they expect to clear the market at date t, i.e.:
194
Also, denote the output level that clears the market at date t as yt∗ . Then, if
the price equals that which allows markets to clear, by definition markets must
clear and so yt∗ must equal the demand when pt = p∗t .
noting that Et−1 [p∗t ] equals pt from (B.13) and that in the situation of market
clearing, pt = p∗t . We now need an expression telling us how the market
clearing/full employment level of output, yt∗ , evolves over time. Here we will
generalise the process used in McCallum (1989) so that yt∗ increases gradually
through time but also depends positively on last period’s full employment
output level. This is commonly known as a hysteresis term, which allows
persistence of full employment output. If full employment output is high today,
it is likely to be high tomorrow.
yt∗ = δ0 + δ1 t + δ2 yt−1
∗
+ ut . (B.16)
ut is a zero mean, random supply, shock, which could include the discovery of
oil reserves or other raw materials or a sudden technological breakthrough that
can increase the productive capacity of the economy.
(B.13), (B.15) and (B.16) together can be regarded as constituting aggregate
supply. Along with aggregate demand, (B.12), we can solve for the output
level, yt , in terms of deviations from yt∗ , and also for the price level, pt . The
solution method is given in McCallum, Chapter 10, and you should read the
relevant section in order to see how the solution is derived. However, a brief
outline is given below.
Take expectations of (B.16) conditional on information available at date t − 1:
Equating (B.17) and (B.18), noting that Et−1 [pt+1 − pt ] in (B.18) is equal to pt
(from (B.13)) gives:
If we subtract (B.19) from (B.12), we will have an expression for yt − yt∗ (i.e.
deviations of output from the market clearing level).
195
B. Examiners’ commentary to Sample examination paper
(b) Imagine that the money supply set by the authorities changes according to:
mt = µ0 + µ1 mt−1 + et (B.21)
yt − yt∗ = β1 et + vt − ut . (B.22)
Notice that the systematic component of monetary policy (µ0 + µ1 mt−1 ) does
not have any real effects here. This is because at date t − 1, when prices for
date t are set, firms take into consideration what they expect the monetary
authorities will do. If they expect the money supply to increase, knowing that
money should have no real effects, they will increase their prices for date t
accordingly. Only the random component of monetary policy, the monetary
policy shock et , will have real effects since this is realised after the prices have
been set. This result, that the systematic component of monetary policy has
no real effect, will be discussed in more detail in the next chapter, in the
section ‘policy ineffectiveness proposition’.
(c) The Lucas critique refers to the instability of reduced-form expressions used
for policy making or policy appraisal. In the sticky price model of Chapter 9,
the structural equations were given by the aggregate demand equation, the
price equation, pt = Et−1 [p∗t ] the equation showing how yt∗ evolves and the
monetary policy reaction function showing how mt depends on the state of the
economy. When we solve for yt − yt∗ , the equation we derive is a reduced-form
equation; a mixture of aggregate demand, aggregate supply and the
authorities’ reaction function. For example, consider the sticky price model
and the reduced-form expression, (B.22), yt − yt∗ = β1 et + vt − ut . Instead of et ,
write mt = Et−1 [mt ] = mt − µ0 − µ1 mt−1 .
and would find a positive coefficient for γ1 since we know γ1 = β1 (only if the
economy was accurately represented by the structural equations given above!).
Since γ1 > 0, we may then think that an increase in the money supply should
cause an increase in output above yt∗ . For example if γ1 was found to equal 0.5,
then increasing the money supply by 2% should cause a 1% increase in output.
However, as we saw in Chapter 7, the systematic component of monetary
policy had no real effects. Even though we may think an increase in the money
supply will increase output (from the reduced form equation, (B.24)), in
reality the change in people’s expectations associated with this policy change
will cause the reduced form to break down. If the authorities increased the
196
money supply by increasing µ0 , indeed this will have a positive effect on
output, via γ1 , but it will also have a negative effect on output since
γ0 = −β1 µ0 . The effect of an expansionary monetary policy will be purely
inflationary. Quoting Romer (2001) p.251,
‘If policymakers attempt to take advantage of statistical
relationships, effects operating through expectations may cause the
relationships to break down. This is the famous Lucas critique.’
11. Suppose that the economy of Pool-land is characterised by the following IS schedule
Y = a − bR + ε
M = c − dR + eY + η
where Y represents the real output, R the short term interest rate, M the real
money balances, coefficients a, b, c, d are positive constants. The economy is
subject to additive shocks. ε and η are IS and LM shocks with the following
properties ε ∼ i.i.d. (0, σε2 ) and η ∼ i.i.d. (0, ση2 ). Note that the uncertainty arises
only due to additive shocks.
Suppose that the monetary authority goal is to minimise the variance of output.
(a) Is it better to use short term interest rates instead of real money balances to
stabilise the economy when the economy is subject to IS shocks only? Show
analytically.
(b) Is it better to use short term interest rates instead of real money balances to
stabilise the economy when the economy is subject to LM shocks only? Show
analytically.
(c) Now consider the case of multiplicative uncertainty, where parameters of the
model, a, b, c, d are subject to uncertainty. Would this model modification
affect your policy results? Discuss verbally.
Reading for this question: the subject guide, Chapter 12.
(a,b) (Note: Here, parts a and b are analysed together.) Uncertainty over the
structure of the economic model, or reduced-form model instability, which
manifests itself through the Lucas critique, is one form of model uncertainty
that the monetary authorities must consider when deciding on policy.
Poole (1970) analysed the implication of adding shocks to both the IS and LM
schedules. Such shocks could come about from trade union strikes or wars on
the IS side and stock market crashes and financial crises such as the collapse of
LTCM in 1998 on the LM side. Poole’s model assumes that the parameters
and structure of the model are known with certainty, which is an unrealistic
assumption, but allows the IS and LM schedules to be subject to zero-mean
random errors. The schedules can be described by (B.25).
Y = a − bR + ε (B.25)
M = c − dR + eY + η.
197
B. Examiners’ commentary to Sample examination paper
ε and η are additive IS and LM shocks whose variances are σε2 and ση2
respectively, and for simplicity we ignore the price level in the LM curve.
Alternatively, assume the monetary authorities can control real money
balances, denoted by M . The authorities can either set the money supply, M ,
or the interest rate, R, but not both. With a downward-sloping money demand
schedule, either R or M can be set and the other variable will have to change
to allow the markets to clear. If the authorities set the interest rate, then from
the IS schedule, the expected value of output, Y , given R, denoted E[Y ] |R will
be:
E[Y ] |R = a − bR. (B.26)
Assume that the goal of the policymakers is to minimise the variance of
output. From (13.29) and (13.30), Y − E[Y ] |R will simply be ε and so the
variance of output given that the authorities set the interest rate will be
E[Y − E[Y ] |R ]2 = σε2 . Alternatively, the monetary authorities could set the
money supply, M . In order to calculate the variance of output in this scenario,
we need to calculate Y as a function of M only. From the LM schedule, we can
calculate R as a function of M , Y and η and then substitute this into the IS
curve. Solving for Y will give:
ad − bc bM dε − bη
Y = + + . (B.27)
d + be d + be d + be
We can then find E[Y ] |M and the variance of output given that the authorities
directly control the money stock. This is given in (13.32).
2
2 1
E[Y − E[Y ] |M ] = (d2 σε2 + b2 ση2 ). (B.28)
d + be
We can now examine which policy instrument, when set by the authorities,
will result in a lower output variance. Consider the case where there are no IS
shocks, σε2 . The variance of output under both interest rate and money
targeting regimes is given in the top line of Table B.1. It is clear that setting
the interest rate and allowing money to change to clear the market is the
optimal strategy. However, if there are no LM shocks, ση2 , then output variance
is smaller under a policy of fixed money supply, see the bottom line of Table
B.1. Therefore, if an economy is prone to IS shocks, the authorities should
keep the money supply constant. If the economy is prone to money market,
LM, shocks, the interest rate should be the instrument of choice.
b
2
Only LM shocks, σε2 = 0 Var[Y | R] = 0 < Var[Y | M ] = d+be
ση2
d
2
Only IS shocks, ση2 = 0 Var[Y | R] = σε2 > Var[Y | M ] = d+be
σε2
Table B.1:
This is also shown in the subject guide Figures 12.1a and 12.1b. Figure 12.1a
shows the case with IS shocks only. The output variation when the interest
198
rate is fixed at R∗ is shown by DY |R , in which case the money supply has to
change to clear the money markets causing the LM curve to shift so that
equilibrium is at points A or B. If the money supply was kept fixed then
output deviations are shown by DY |M . Therefore, with IS shocks, in order to
keep output variance at a minimum, it is best to keep the money supply fixed.
In Figure 12.1b, by keeping the interest rate fixed after LM shocks, equilibrium
will be unchanged at point E and output variance will therefore be zero. By
keeping the money supply fixed, however, LM shocks will cause equilibrium to
move between points A and B and output variance will be positive, equal to
∆Y |M . So, depending on the main source of economic shocks, whether they
originate from the goods or money markets, will determine which monetary
instrument the authorities should target.
(c) Whereas Poole considered the case where shocks were additive in nature,
Brainard (1967) examined the case where the values of the parameters in the
model were not known with certainty. This is, arguably, more realistic since
any model must be estimated from data. An estimated model will not only
give point estimates of the parameters but will also give standard errors since
there will always be measurement error, model mis-specification and other
problems that cause us not to know the exact structure of the economic model.
Suppose output, y, depends on a policy mix, X, a vector containing fiscal and
monetary instruments that the government can control. The relationship
between y and X is given by:
y = gX. (B.29)
For simplicity, assume X is a single policy instrument so that g is a scalar
parameter estimate with mean gb and variance σg2 . The aim of the authorities is
to minimise the variance of y around some target level, y ∗ , full employment
level of output for example, subject to the constraint (B.30), i.e.
If y = gX, taking averages will give yb = gbX. The problem can then be written
as:
Noting that E[g − gb]2 = σg2 and that E[g − gb] = gb − gb = 0, the problem then
becomes:
min X 2 σg2 + (y ∗ − gbX)2 . (B.32)
X
Differentiating this with respect to X, the choice variable, setting equal to zero
and solving will give:
gby ∗ gb2 y ∗
X= ⇒ yb = gbX = < y∗. (B.33)
σg2 + gb2 σg2 + gb2
199
B. Examiners’ commentary to Sample examination paper
12. A treasurer has to manage the cash position of a small London college. At the
beginning of the year the college receives £5 million in tuition fees. The college is
expected to spend all of that money in the year, at an approximately constant
daily rate. The treasurer can either hold the financial wealth of the college in
bonds, yielding an interest rate of 4% or in cash, which is assumed to not receive
any interest. The accrued interest on the bond holdings is received at the end of
the year and is not compounded inbetween. The brokerage fees of exchanging
bonds for money are £1,000 per transaction. Note that the first transaction takes
place at the beginning of the year, when the treasurer buys bonds, the transactions
during the rest of the year will compose of selling bond holdings. The treasurer
wants to minimize the costs of cash management, C, which are composed of the
interest foregone on the cash holdings and the brokerage fees.
(a) Draw the time profile of the college’s holdings of cash and bonds.
(b) Set up the cost minimization problem for the treasurer and calculate the how
much money, Z, should be transferred each time the treasurer sells off bonds.
(c) Calculate the interest elasticity of money.
(d) The problem outlined above is based on the Baumol–Tobin inventory theoretic
model. State and discuss two criticisms of the inventory theoretic model.
Reading for this question: the subject guide, Chapter 3.
(a) See Figure 3.2 in the subject guide.
(b) We have
= 5,000,000,000/Z + 0.02Z.
5,000,000,000Z −2 + 0.02 = 0
p
Z = 5,000,000,000/0.02
Z = £500,000.
200
(c) Interest elasticity of money is defined as ∂ ln M/∂ ln i.
p
M = Z/2 = bT /2i
∂ ln M/∂ ln i = −0.5.
(d) A good answer points out that the inventory theoretic model does not hold
well in practice. Two criticism are that the model assumes (1) perfect
information about the pattern of expenditures and (2) does not take into
account institutional factors. This leads the model to predict that firms hold
very little cash, much less than empirically observed.
D = d0 − d1 (i − iD ) (B.34)
L = l0 − l1 (i − iL ) (B.35)
where L stands for bank loans, D stands for bank deposits, iL the loan rate, iD
deposit rate and i is the market interest rate. Assume that banks do not have
operating costs or are not required to hold reserves.
(a) Calculate the competitive equilibrium. Show graphically. How do your results
change when the government sets deposit rates equal to iD = a, with a < iL ?
Provide intuition.
(b) Now suppose that government introduces a mandatory reserve ratio, r∗ , such
that R = r∗ D. How do your results change? What are the implications of such
a reserve ratio policy on prices and quantities? Provide intuition.
(c) Sometimes, it is suggested that the reserve ratio policy can be an alternative
to targeting interest rates or monetary aggregates. Can this be an effective
policy to stabilise output and inflation fluctuations?
Reading for this question: the subect guide, Chapter 4.
(a) Competitive equilibrium: The profits made by the bank will equal the quantity
of loans, L, multiplied by the interest earned on those loans, iL (which is the
bank’s revenues) minus the costs faced by the bank. Costs will equal the
interest paid to depositors in order to encourage them to hand over their funds
to the bank. Costs then equal the quantity of deposits, D, times the interest
rate paid on deposits, iD . Noting that in a competitive equilibrium, profits
equal zero:
Π = LiL − DiD and Π = 0.
When making the additional assumption that the bank holds no reserves, in
order for the bank’s balance sheet to balance and convenience assumption that
constants d0 = l0 , loans (assets) must equal deposits (liabilities), L = D.
Substituting implies that in equilibrium:
iD = iL
201
B. Examiners’ commentary to Sample examination paper
202
in which D varies with r∗ is uncertain and depends on the parameters of the
model. With no reserve requirements we equate L to D in order for the bank’s
balance sheet to balance. In this situation we equate L to (1 − r∗ )D. Therefore
the new intersection results in a lower value of L but a higher interest rate
charged, iL . Total revenues for the bank, L times iL , could then increase or
decrease depending on the elasticity of the demand for loans function. If the
demand for loans is elastic then, if L falls, revenue will fall. Banks will be
forced to cut the interest paid on deposits, so iD falls, resulting in fewer
deposits and hence causing the money supply to fall. If the demand for loans is
inelastic, a fall in L, caused by the reserve ratio, will increase revenues. The
banks will increase iD and so total deposits will increase.
(c) Unlikely for several reasons. First, such it is extremely cumbersome to
implement reserve policy in relatively high frequency (say, monthly). Second,
its effectiveness depends on the loan demand elasticity. Even under the
assumption of time invariant elasticity, given the variety of loans offered in the
banking system, it is very hard too anticipate the effects of the monetary
policy on the transmission channels. Finally, it is a rather difficult one to
communicate the policy changes to wider society, thus harming the
transparency aspects of monetary implementation.
203
B. Examiners’ commentary to Sample examination paper
204
Comment form
We welcome any comments you may have on the materials which are sent to you as part of your
study pack. Such feedback from students helps us in our effort to improve the materials produced
for the International Programmes.
If you have any comments about this guide, either general or specific (including corrections,
non-availability of Essential readings, etc.), please take the time to complete and return this form.
Name
Address
Email
Student number
For which qualification are you studying?
Comments
Date: