Country Specific Effects

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 46

WP/11/73

ICT, Financial Inclusion, and Growth: Evidence


from African Countries
Mihasonirina Andrianaivo and Kangni Kpodar
© 2011 International Monetary Fund WP/11/73

IMF Working Paper


AFR

ICT, Financial Inclusion, and Growth: Evidence from African Countries


Prepared by Mihasonirina Andrianaivo and Kangni Kpodar1
Authorized for distribution by Peter Allum
April 2011

Abstract

This Working Paper should not be reported as representing the views of the IMF.
The views expressed in this Working Paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily
represent those of the IMF or IMF policy. Working Papers describe research in progress by the
author(s) and are published to elicit comments and to further debate.

This paper studies the impact of information and communication technologies (ICT),
especially mobile phone rollout, on economic growth in a sample of African countries from
1988 to 2007. Further, we investigate whether financial inclusion is one of the channels
through which mobile phone development influences economic growth. In estimating the
impact of ICT on economic growth, we use a wide range of ICT indicators, including
mobile and fixed telephone penetration rates and the cost of local calls. We address any
endogeneity issues by using the System Generalized Method of Moment (GMM) estimator.
Financial inclusion is captured by variables measuring access to financial services, such as
the number of deposits or loans per head, compiled by Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Martinez
Peria (2007) and the Consultative Group to Assist the Poor (CGAP, 2009). The results
confirm that ICT, including mobile phone development, contribute significantly to
economic growth in African countries. Part of the positive effect of mobile phone
penetration on growth comes from greater financial inclusion. At the same time, the
development of mobile phones consolidates the impact of financial inclusion on economic
growth, especially in countries where mobile financial services take hold.
JEL Classification Numbers: O30, O40, G20
Keywords: ICT, mobile financial services, economic growth, Africa
Author’s E-Mail Address: [email protected];
[email protected]

1
M. Andrianaivo is an Economist in the France Telecom Group. K. Kpodar is an Economist at the IMF and
Research Fellow at the Centre for Studies and Research on International Development (CERDI). The authors
would like to thank for useful comments and suggestions Peter Allum, Mai Dao, Tanja Faller, Patrick Imam,
Vitaliy Kramarenko, and participants at the following conferences and seminars: the African Econometric
Society Conference held in Cairo (July 2010), the IMF Seminar held in Washington (September 2010), and the
2010 African Economic Conference held in Tunis (October 2010). Jenny Kletzin DiBiase provided helpful
editorial comments. The usual disclaimer applies.
2

Contents Page
I. Introduction ......................................................................................................................................... 3
II. Literature Review .............................................................................................................................. 5
A. Theoretical Background ................................................................................................................ 5
B. Empirical Studies .......................................................................................................................... 8
III. Stylized Facts ................................................................................................................................. 10
A. Growth of ICT in African Countries and Other Developing Countries ...................................... 10
B. Growth of Mobile Technology in Africa..................................................................................... 11
C. Opportunities Offered by Mobile Financial Services .................................................................. 12
IV. Econometric Specification ............................................................................................................. 13
V. Results ............................................................................................................................................. 15
A. Impact of ICT on Economic Growth........................................................................................... 15
B. Robustness Tests ......................................................................................................................... 17
C. Financial Inclusion ...................................................................................................................... 19
VI. Conclusion...................................................................................................................................... 20
References ............................................................................................................................................ 22

Tables
1. Transmission Channels from ICT to Growth ..................................................................................... 6
2. Impact of Mobile and Fixed Telephone Penetration on Economic Growth in Africa ...................... 34
3. Testing for Interaction Terms and other Forms of ICT .................................................................... 35
4. Robustness Tests .............................................................................................................................. 36
5. Mobile Penetration, Financial Inclusion, and Economic Growth in Africa ..................................... 37
6. Mobile Phone Development and Financial Inclusion, 2000-2007 ................................................... 41

Figures
1. Correlation between Mobile Penetration, Growth and Financial Inclusion ..................................... 25
2. Financial Inclusion and Mobile Penetration by Type of Financial Institutions................................ 26
3. Trends in ICT Use: International Comparison ................................................................................. 26
4. ICT Growth in Developing Countries .............................................................................................. 27
5. Trends in Fixed versus Mobile Phone Subscribers: International Comparison................................ 27
6. Trends in Mobile Penetration: International Comparison ................................................................ 28
7. Trends in Prepaid versus Postpaid Phone Subscribers: International Comparison .......................... 28
8. Access to Financial Services in Selected African Countries ............................................................ 29
9. Bank Loans and Deposits: International Comparison ...................................................................... 29
10. Bank Branches and ATMs.............................................................................................................. 30
11. Financial Infrastructure Gap in Developing Countries................................................................... 31
12. Comparing Trends in Bank Credit and Mobile Penetration ........................................................... 31
13. Testing for the Stability of the Coefficient on Mobile Penetration Using Random Samples ......... 32
14. Recursive Estimates of the Coefficient on Mobile Penetration ...................................................... 32
15. Quality of the Prediction ................................................................................................................ 33

Annexes
1. Mobile Financial Services ................................................................................................................ 38
2. Assessing the Effect of Mobile Phone Penetration on Financial Inclusion ...................................... 40

Appendices
1. List of the Sample Countries ............................................................................................................ 42
2. Summary Statistics and Correlation Matrix ..................................................................................... 43
3. Variable Definition and Sources ...................................................................................................... 45
3

I. INTRODUCTION

In recent years, there has been a rapid diffusion of information and communication
technologies (ICT) in African countries, in line with similar patterns in other regions of the
developing world.2 Figures show that, in Africa, growth in telephone subscribers, personal
computer users, and Internet users has been fast since the 1990s. Currently, mobile phone
penetration is overcoming fixed line coverage. The coverage of mobile cellular networks is
around 55 percent of the population in sub-Saharan Africa, and more than 80 percent of the
population in Middle East and North African (MENA) countries between 2002 and 2007.
Nonetheless, Africa remains challenged by a financial infrastructure gap. This is shown by
very low numbers of bank branches and automated teller machines (ATMs) (Beck,
Demirguc-Kunt, and Martinez Peria, 2007),3 and also by very low figures of financial
inclusion. According to FinMark (2009), most of the population in African countries is using
informal finance or is financially excluded (88 percent of the population in Mozambique and
41 percent in Botswana in 2009). Bank penetration is lower than 10 percent in some regions
of Africa. In fact, there will be 1.7 billion unbanked customers with mobile phones by 2012,
according to the Global System for Mobile Communications Association (GSMA).4 As a
consequence, a number of schemes aim at overcoming the financial infrastructure gap by
using well-deployed ICT. Branchless banking services, like mobile financial services, are
becoming increasingly popular. Therefore, it is worth investigating what ICT and these
schemes can bring to financial inclusion and hence economic growth.

The purpose of this paper is to shed light on the role ICT development, especially mobile
phone penetration, can play in promoting financial inclusion and economic growth.
Specifically, we analyze the impact of mobile phone penetration on economic growth rates in
Africa. Then we add to the model an indicator of financial inclusion to assess whether mobile
phone penetration influences growth by improving financial inclusion. Further, we
investigate how interaction among mobile penetration, financial inclusion, and growth is at
play in countries where mobile financial services take hold.

Recent literature on mobile phones and developing countries has been reviewed by Donner
(2008). Jensen (2007) finds microeconomic evidence of positive economic impacts of mobile
telephony. By providing information, mobile phones reduce price volatility and increase
responsiveness of fishing businesses. Other studies focus on the microeconomic impacts of
mobile phones on small and medium-size enterprises (SMEs) (Chowdhury, 2006, and
Donner, 2006), and some look at the impact of mobile phones on institutions and social
domains (such as civil society organizations, libraries, and so forth).

2
Grace, Kenny, and Qiang (2003) define ICT as tools that facilitate the production, transmission, and
processing of information. ICT consist of traditional technologies such as radios modern communication tools
and data delivery systems. We focus here on new information and communication technologies like telephones,
computers, and the Internet. We concentrate more deeply on mobile phone technology.
3
The average number of bank branches in sub-Saharan Africa was less than 700 in 2007, and the average
number of ATMs was less than a thousand.
4
GSMA is the association representing the interests of the worldwide mobile communications industry.
4

However, very few studies have been conducted on the macroeconomic impacts of mobile
phones in developing countries. A few, such as Hardy (1980) and Waverman, Meschi, and
Fuss (2005), did not focus on Africa, and to our knowledge none of them has yet analyzed
the channel of financial inclusion. ICT and mobile phone penetration can indeed reduce the
transaction costs of financial intermediaries including formal commercial banks,
microfinance institutions and cooperatives, and therefore expand their businesses. ICT also
facilitate the emergence of branchless banking by increasing the flexibility of businesses. 5
Moreover, a good telecommunication network allows better information flows that reduce
information asymmetries and hence ease deposit taking and access to credit. The data show
that the correlation between average real GDP per capita and mobile penetration is positive in
Africa. Similarly, the correlation between financial inclusion and mobile penetration is
positive, suggesting that ICT rollouts could stimulate economic growth and financial
inclusion (Figures 1 and 2). Fulfilling the financial infrastructure gap in Africa, by using
branchless banking services such as mobile financial services, is seen as a promising way to
increase financial inclusion.6 Therefore it is critical to assess the extent to which mobile
penetration improves financial inclusion and therefore growth in Africa.

We follow the works of Barro (1991) and Waverman, Meschi, and Fuss (2005) and focus on
44 African countries between 1988 and 2007. We include regressors such as initial levels of
GDP to account for convergence, human capital development, government consumption, and
institutional development, as well as mobile telephony variables such as penetration rates.
We also use more specific indicators of financial inclusion, such as the number of deposits
per head and the number of loans per head in all financial intermediaries including
commercial banks, microfinance institutions, cooperatives, and specialized state financial
institutions. We undertake robust estimations addressing reverse causality of good
telecommunication networks and growth and treat any endogeneity between other control
variables and economic growth by using the System Generalized Method of Moment (GMM)
estimator. We also use other variables accounting for telecommunication development by
testing the effects of the prices of a three-minute fixed and mobile telephone local call on
economic growth rates.

As in previous literature such as Hardy (1980), Roller and Waverman (2001), Waverman,
Meschi, and Fuss (2005), Sridhar and Sridhar (2004), and Lee, Levendis, and Gutierrez
(2009), we find that ICT development, and notably mobile phone penetration, contribute to
economic growth in Africa. We find as in Roller and Waverman (2001) and Waverman,
Meschi, and Fuss (2005) that mobile phones and fixed lines are substitutes and that the effect
of mobiles is higher in lower-income countries. In addition, a part of the growth effect of
mobile penetration comes from improved financial inclusion. Further, the effect of financial

5
According to Rasmussen (2010), branchless banking is about 26 percent cheaper than conventional banking.
6
Financial services on mobile phones or mobile financial services benefit all actors involved. They are seen by
mobile network operators and banks as a tremendous opportunity to increase their respective client base.
Further, clients may also find these schemes better at responding to their financial needs than formal banks and
informal lenders.
5

inclusion on growth is improved by mobile phone development, especially in countries


where mobile financial services are available.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. First, we review the theory behind the
economic impact of ICT on economic growth and social development. We then present some
stylized facts on ICT and financial inclusion, followed by the presentation of our econometric
specification and the results. Our last section concludes and offers policy recommendations.

II. LITERATURE REVIEW

A. Theoretical Background

Macroeconomic impact of ICT development

ICT development is increasingly considered a factor in economic growth rather than a


consequence of it, as mentioned by Tcheng and others (2007). Three characteristics of ICT
explain this view: (i) ICT are omnipresent in most business sectors, (ii) ICT improve
continuously and therefore reduce costs for the users, and (iii) ICT contribute to innovation
and to the development of new products and processes.

But in earlier research, ICT development was regarded as a concern only for developed
economies because only these economies were capable of mobilizing resources to promote
the sector. In fact, early studies showed evidence of growth effects through network
externalities, especially relevant for telephone services and the Internet. As explained by
Grace, Kenny, and Qiang (2003), because of network effects the value of a telephone line
goes up exponentially with the number of users connected to the system. Moreover, once a
threshold of users is reached, an explosive growth is recorded. This explains why only
developed economies were believed to benefit from ICT development. Roller and Waverman
(2001) estimate that ICT affect economic growth only when the penetration rate reaches 40
lines per 100 inhabitants.

However, recent research shows that the positive impacts of ICT can be large in developing
countries because ICT compare to utilities such as water, electricity, and transportation. In
fact, Waverman, Meschi, and Fuss (2005) explain that telecommunication networks are part
of social overhead capital (SOC); as are expenditure on education, health services, and
roads.7 As a result, the economic and social return of ICT development is larger than the
private return of the network provider. The externalities of ICT development highlight its
potential positive impact on economic growth, similar to that of public infrastructure.
Haacker (2010) notes that the growth impacts of rising productivity in the production of ICT
equipment are weak in low- and middle-income countries because ICT equipment is often
imported. But, the benefit of capital deepening arising from falling prices of ICT equipment
can be large in low- and middle-income countries, even though it remains lower than that in
high-income countries owing to higher absorption capacity.
7
SOC is capital goods available to anyone (social); not linked to any particular part of production (overhead);
and broadly available, implying that they are usually provided by governments.
6

Datta and Agarwal (2004) point out that the economic benefits of ICT can be direct, through
increases of employment and demand, and can also be indirect, notably through social
returns (Table 1). Lewin and Sweet (2005) note that the direct effects can come from the
supply side, that is, the supply of telecommunication services. This supply of
telecommunication networks generates employment for manufacturers, administrators,
network builders, system managers, and also employment through new retailing networks. In
African countries, the economic benefits of ICT are mainly indirect. Because prepaid
services dominate the continent, selling the prepaid cards requires an effective retailing
network of wholesalers, individual agents, and even informal sellers (Tcheng and others,
2007). ICT supply also affects government revenues through income taxes on companies and
on employees, VAT, and social security contributions. Tcheng and others (2007) observe that
in Africa, revenues from telecommunication services represented about 5 percent of GDP
compared with only 2.9 percent in Europe.

Table 1. Transmission Channels from ICT to Growth

Direct effects of ICT Indirect effects of ICT


From supply side From ICT use
 Contribute to domestic output and  Spur capital accumulation
employment creation
 Increase government revenues  Improve firms' productivity
 Affect balance of payments  Favor better and larger markets
 Deepen financial inclusion
 Contribute to rural development

Moreover, ICT supply influences the balance of payments as it increases foreign direct
investment (FDI) flows. The increase in FDI is due to new FDI in telecommunication
services. Also, foreign companies are more likely to invest in countries with increased ICT
development. For instance, investment from high-tech industries is lured by rapidly growing
markets in developing countries, and the boom in consumer demand for computing and
telecom machinery. In addition, ICT attract portfolio and venture capital. They improve
market efficiency because they allow wider dispersion of market information to investors,
thereby reducing information costs. Additional investments, jobs, new skills, and better local
services stemming from FDI all benefit economic growth.

Productivity gains and reduction in transaction costs

ICT improve firms’ productivity by allowing firms to adopt flexible structures and locations.
The increased geographic dispersion is a source of productivity gains as it also allows firms
to exploit comparative advantages and save on costs (for instance on inventory costs).
Further productivity gains also come from better management, through better intrafirm
communication, and increased flexibility, owing to the removal of physical constraints on
organizational communication (Grace, Kenny, and Qiang, 2003). Small businesses can also
increase their productivity with ICT. Voice applications reduce unproductive traveling time
and improve logistics, leading to faster and more efficient decision making. They also
7

empower small and medium-size enterprises, painters and plumbers for example, through
increased flexibility (Lewin and Sweet, 2005).

According to Lewin and Sweet (2005), indirect social returns also come from use of ICT.
ICT use improves market functioning and increases trade. Investments in ICT reduce costs
because better communication systems lower transaction costs (Datta and Agarwal, 2004,
and Waverman, Meschi, and Fuss, 2005). By reducing the cost of retrieving information, ICT
improve information flows, increase arbitrage abilities, and facilitate price discovery. They
allow better functioning markets and regulation of supply and demand. Therefore it increases
information regarding prices (of commodities, for example), job opportunities, and markets
(Sridhar and Sridhar, 2004). Moreover, good communication networks substitute for costly
physical transport and therefore widen networks (of buyers and suppliers) and markets.
Grace, Kenny, and Qiang (2003) show that reduced transaction costs from ICT favor trade
because it gives developing countries opportunities to tap into global markets and increase
sales range. The development of e-commerce fostered by ICT development increases
efficiency and opens markets for developing countries. Businesses, such as handicrafts or
ecotourism, reach global audiences, marketplaces become digital, and transactions are
automated. Trade in services such as back office support or data entry and software
management also benefit from new opportunities as ICT allow the outsourcing of
information-intensive administrative and technical functions.

Financial inclusion

Mobile telephony allows expansion and access to financial services to previously


underserved groups in developing countries. It reduces transaction costs, especially the costs
of running physical bank branches. The increasing use of mobile telephony in developing
countries has contributed to the emergence of branchless banking services, thereby
improving financial inclusion. This increased access to financial services for underserved
people helps narrow the financial infrastructure gap, especially in developing economies,
where the costs of distance and time are very high for formal banking services. ICT favor
better information flows, and the data collected on depositors can be used to analyze credit
worthiness more efficiently and to facilitate deposit taking. Therefore ICT and mobile phone
in particular improve access to credit and deposit facilities, allow more efficient allocation of
credit, facilitate financial transfers, and boost financial inclusion. In turn, this would
stimulate private investment, and hence economic growth.

Considering the tremendous interest in finding new ways of increasing financial inclusion in
Africa using ICT, such as mobile financial services, it is of utmost importance to assess
whether these schemes can indeed favor financial inclusion and therefore economic growth.
Service providers—including banks, mobile network operators, and even microfinance
institutions—and policy makers are keen on developing mobile financial services rapidly.
The financial infrastructure gap is a niche for service providers, and policy makers can
improve access to financial services.
8

Rural development

ICT have a positive effect on rural development. Voice applications allow dispersed families
to stay in touch, reducing vulnerability and isolation; improve the bargaining power of
farmers; eliminate the middleman; and enable the development of nonagricultural economic
activities like ecolodges or women-owned microbusinesses.

Opportunity costs and threshold effects

Grace, Kenny, and Qiang (2003) point out that it may be difficult to establish a causal link
between ICT and economic growth or even economic development.8 Negative impacts might
even arise because of the opportunity costs of investments and expenses in ICT rather than in
education and health (Heeks, 1999). Studies indeed show that the share of household income
devoted to mobiles services in developing countries is rising, even though it is already higher
than that of developed countries. This reduces households’ budgets for food, health,
education, and so on. Grace, Kenny, and Qiang (2003) also mention that some developing
countries might fall into a poverty trap if ICT threshold effects are at play. Consistent with
the network and scale literature mentioned earlier, if a minimum level of ICT is needed to
benefit from new opportunities, and if ICT provision is correlated with income per capita,
low-income countries might not be able to benefit from the opportunities provided by ICT
development.

To summarize, ICT can influence economic growth through various channels, even though
the causal link may be difficult to establish. ICT development generates employment and
government revenues. ICT also allow better information flows, leading to increased
efficiency, wider markets, increased productivity, and new capital and investments such as
FDI and portfolio and venture capital. ICT can also lead to better financial inclusion and
therefore facilitate financial development. To our knowledge this link has not been studied
before. It is important, therefore, to investigate it, considering that financial development in
Africa is low whereas ICT penetration, through mobile phone rollouts, is growing fast.

B. Empirical Studies

Earlier cross-country studies found a positive and significant impact of telecommunication


infrastructure on economic growth. For instance, Hardy (1980) analyzes the impact of
telecom penetration. He finds that the impact of radio rollout on economic growth is not
statistically significant, in contrast to the impact of the telephone. Two-way networks
(telecommunications) are more important for growth than one-way networks (broadcasting)
such as radio and television. Although Hardy (1980) uses previous-year values of radio
penetration and telephone penetration to account roughly for reverse causality, he did not
control for country-specific effects. The issue of reverse causality comes up because better
communication systems may bring higher incomes, and higher incomes in turn could lead to

8
Poorly designed programs can be undertaken, and, because technological change is very fast, programs can be
even more difficult to implement.
9

better communication systems. Similarly, Norton (1992) tests the argument that improvement
in telecommunications reduces transaction costs in a sample of 47 developed and developing
countries. The author includes the initial-year value of the stock of telephones in the cross-
section model to overcome the issue of reverse causality. He finds that the association
between telecommunication infrastructure and economic growth is positive and significant.

Roller and Waverman (2001) address the two-way causality issue by using a structural model
with a hybrid production function that endogenizes the telecommunications investment. To
assess the effects of telecom infrastructure on economic growth, the authors specify a
micromodel of supply and demand of telecommunication investment and jointly estimate this
with the macro growth equation for 21 Organization for Economic Co-operation and
Development (OECD) countries and 14 developing countries over a 20-year period. They
find little impact once simultaneity and fixed effects are controlled for and only a positive
causal link when a critical mass of telecom infrastructure is reached. This result indicates that
telecommunications infrastructure creates network externalities that are an increasing
function of the number of participants. Therefore the impact of telecommunications
infrastructure on growth might not be linear, with the growth impact being larger beyond a
certain network size. The expansion of networks intensifies the social value of networks and
in consequence the social return, representing the value of an additional person connected or
the value of an additional dollar invested in the network. This exceeds the private return for
the network provider. As a consequence, universal service is not only a question of equity but
also a vehicle to enhance economic growth.9

Sridhar and Sridhar (2004) use Roller and Waverman’s (2001) framework by estimating a
system of equations that endogenizes economic growth and telecom penetration, while
extending the analysis to mobile phones. They undertake separate estimations for fixed lines,
and mobile phones to disaggregate their effects in 63 developing countries between 1990 and
2001. They find that the elasticity of aggregate national output with respect to main
telephone lines is smaller than that of mobiles and that, in developing countries, cellular
services contribute significantly to national output.

Waverman, Meschi, and Fuss (2005) use a modified version of Roller and Waverman (2001)
for 92 countries between 1980 and 2003 and show that mobiles in developing countries play
the same role as fixed lines played in the 1970s and 1980s in OECD countries. In developing
countries, mobile phones are substitutes for fixed lines; in developed countries they are
complements for fixed lines.10 Their impacts on growth are positive and significant—twice
as large as their impacts in developed countries. The starting hypothesis is that mobile phone
rollout has greater effects on economic growth in developing countries because mobiles have
more network effects and have more effects on mobility than in developed countries. They
also find that the price and income elasticities of mobile phone demand are superior to 1 in
developing countries.

9
Universal service means there is at least one phone per household and per firm.
10
In fact, mobile phones require less investment than fixed lines and therefore are faster and less expensive to
roll out.
10

Kathuria, Uppal and Mamta (2009) assess the impact of mobile penetration on economic
growth across Indian states. Using a modified version of Roller and Waverman (2001), they
estimate a structural model with three equations for 19 Indian states from 2000 to 2008. They
specifically examine the links through which mobile phones affect growth and the
constraints, if any, that limit their impact. They find that Indian states with higher mobile
penetration rates can be expected to growth faster, and that there is a critical mass, at a
penetration rate of 25 percent, beyond which the impact of mobile phones on growth is
amplified by network effects. Telecom networks, more than any other infrastructure, are
subject to network effects: the growth impact is larger when a significant threshold network
size is achieved. Moreover, the authors (2009) find substantial variation across urban and
rural areas and between rich and poor households in cities.

Lee, Levendis, and Gutierrez (2009) are among the rare studies that have focused on the
effects of mobile phones on economic growth in sub-Saharan Africa. They correct the
potential endogeneity between economic growth and telephone expansion by using the
generalized method of moments. They also consider varying degrees of substitutability
between mobile phones and landlines as in Waverman, Meschi, and Fuss (2005). They find
indeed that the marginal impact of mobile telecommunication services is even greater where
landline phones are rare. However, as in previous studies, the authors do not test for the price
effect of telecommunications on growth. In some countries, telecommunications
infrastructure could exist but a high access cost could dampen its use. Moreover, the channels
through which telecommunications stimulate growth, financial inclusion, for instance, are not
investigated. Further, their regressions may be subject to statistical shortcomings because the
System GMM estimator is not appropriate for annual data if the variables are not stationary.
Our paper addresses some of these issues in the following sections.

To sum up, some cross-sectional studies have been undertaken on telecommunications and
economic growth in developing countries. The issue of reverse causality is difficult to
address, and studies have shown the existence of network externalities in telecommunication
infrastructure leading to higher growth effects. Further, in developing countries, mobile
phones and fixed lines appeared substitutes rather than complements. However, very few
studies have focused on the African continent, despite the significant growth of mobile
rollouts experienced by many African countries.

III. STYLIZED FACTS

A. Growth of ICT in African Countries and Other Developing Countries

Rapid spread of ICT in all developing countries.

Progress in ICT is fast, and ICT growth is not restricted to developed countries. ICT are
spreading rapidly in developing countries. Figure 3 shows that since the 1990s, the average
number of telephone subscribers, personal computer users, and Internet users per 100
inhabitants has increased. In fact, even though the figures are lowest in sub-Saharan Africa
and in South Asia, the upward trend is also present in these regions.
11

Robust growth of telephone subscribers.

Use of telephone technology—fixed and mobile—is widespread, compared to use of personal


computers and Internet use (Figure 4), although Internet use has increased sharply. Data also
show that in all developing regions, the growth rates of telephone subscriptions are high
compared to those of personal computer users and Internet users per 100 inhabitants, and the
latter are actually decreasing in some regions like Africa after the dramatic increase in the
1990s.

Africa experienced the highest growth rates of telephone subscribers.

The data suggest that the growth rate of telephone subscribers in Africa was the highest of all
developing regions at the end of the 1990s and the beginning of the 2000s (except for South
Asia in the 2000s), albeit from low levels. This could be partly explained by the two waves
of telecom privatization in Africa. The first was between 1995 and 1997 and the second
between 2000 and 2001.

B. Growth of Mobile Technology in Africa

Mobile phone subscriptions are overtaking fixed lines.

Figure 5 shows that in all developing regions, although mobile technology had started to
spread at the end of 1990s, the number of mobile phone subscribers per 100 inhabitants is
now above the number of fixed telephone lines per 100 inhabitants. Mobile phone
penetration and coverage have increased rapidly (Figure 6), probably reflecting liberalization
and privatization policies and lack of wired infrastructure in many developing countries.11

Positive growth perspectives in Africa.

In Africa, studies have shown that people consider the investment in mobile technology
necessary even though it is a significant part of their earnings. Their willingness to pay for
this technology is higher than people’s willingness to spend in higher income countries,12 but
the price elasticity of their demand is also higher (Grace, Kenny, and Qiang, 2003;
Waverman, Meschi, and Fuss, 2005). The telecommunications sector is expected to continue
11
Do-Nascimento (2005) noted that in 2004 only 14 African countries out of 55 had not yet liberalized the
telecommunications sector. With technological progress and globalization of networks, liberalization policies
started to emerge in developed countries in the 1980s and 1990s, before spreading to African countries from
1990s. Other reasons are mentioned by Do-Nascimento (2005) to explain the growth of mobile penetration in
Africa. Among them is the strategy of service providers to adapt their products to African consumers. For
example, service providers introduced prepaid contracts to suit clients who did not have the usual and formal
means of payment like checks, credit cards, and so forth. Also, families and friends are very close in Africa, and
the social fabric is made of numerous relationships. Communication is vital to maintaining these ties, and the
mobile phone overcomes travel difficulties.
12
Tcheng and others (2007) mention that in some African countries such as Namibia, Ethiopia, and Zambia,
households spend up to 10 percent of their monthly income on telephone expenses, whereas the average is 3
percent in developed countries.
12

to grow rapidly, and the limits to this growth are uncertain (Tcheng, Huet, and Romdhane,
2010).

Preference for prepaid contracts.

In most developing countries prepaid contracts are more common than postpaid contracts
(Figure 7). In African countries, many customers do not earn regular income and are
unbanked. They are therefore less capable of affording fixed costs associated with postpaid
contracts. In addition, fixed lines require monthly payments, regardless of use. Prepaid
mobiles, on the other hand, take into account use and variability of consumption, although at
a higher cost. This explains the success of prepaid mobile phones compared to postpaid
offers.13

C. Opportunities Offered by Mobile Financial Services

Exclusion from formal financial services is very high in Africa.

In many African countries, a large share of the population is financially excluded or using
informal financial services (Figure 8).

Formal financial services are dominated by banks.

Formal bank service is the most-used formal system in most developing countries. Figure 9
suggests that deposits are more common than loans in all regions. Although the number of
loans and deposits per head is relatively low in sub-Saharan Africa, and to a lesser extent in
MENA, the average size of loans and deposits relative to GDP per capita is high. This
suggests that the propensity to save in these regions is high, but constrained by lack of access
to financial services or suitable financial instruments. Collins and others (2009) explain that
people with low incomes lead active financial lives because they are poor not in spite of it.

In developing countries, the lack of financial infrastructure is significant.

Figure 10 shows that the total number of bank branches and ATMs is very low in developing
countries compared to the same figures in high-income countries. Moreover, figures in sub-
Saharan Africa and MENA are among the lowest. But when looking at the geographical
coverage and penetration rates of bank branches and ATMs, the picture is less clear.

Mobile financial services could be the answer.

The previous figures illustrate clearly a financial infrastructure gap in developing countries
where the coverage of mobile cellular is close to that of high-income countries, but bank

13
It is interesting to note, however, that fixed line contracts and postpaid contracts are more advantageous to the
service provider. This is because their clients can be located by the physical address, and their revenues are
more stable. Moreover, the provision of prepaid mobile contracts, compared to postpaid mobile contracts, is
more costly for a service provider because the costs of producing and selling scratch cards are high.
13

penetration and financial inclusion are very low compared to that of the same group of
countries (see Figure 11).

In summary, ICT rollout, in particular mobile phones with prepaid contracts, is growing
rapidly in developing countries, especially in Africa. Nonetheless, financial development and
financial inclusion are very low in these countries, and the expansion of the financial system
lags behind mobile telephone development (Figure 12). Considering the growth of mobile
technology—its use and spread—and taking into account low access to financial services,
mobile financial services are regarded as an opportunity to reach unbanked customers and as
a new source of profits for mobile network operators.

According to GSMA and Mobile Money for the Unbanked (MMU) deployment tracking,
three African countries were operating mobile financial services as of end-2007—M-PESA
in Kenya, WIZZIT and MTN Mobile Money in South Africa, and CELPAY in Zambia. In
these countries, branchless banking services enable households to save, pay bills, and transfer
money through mobile phones (see more details on mobile financial services in Annex 1).
These schemes are becoming more sophisticated as partnerships between mobile telephone
companies and microfinance institutions strengthen and widen the range of banking services
available via mobile phones. Currently, the most common mobile financial services include
domestic money transfers, air time top ups, and bill payments; but there also is a strong
desire for savings (Rasmussen, 2010).

In addition, international money transfer and loan repayments via mobile phones are
becoming widely used. In fact, following the stagnation of traditional markets in Europe and
the success of M-PESA (with more than 9 million subscribers), mobile network operators are
now seeking new growth engines for their sales in Africa through new services with a social
dimension. Recently, mobile financial services have been launched in 16 other African
countries.14 Although prospects for further development of mobile financial services remain
strong, they rely on the long-term strategies of stakeholders and on appropriate design of
services that respond to customers’ needs. The other important factor is the ability of
governments to foster innovation and channel payments (Rasmussen, 2010).

IV. ECONOMETRIC SPECIFICATION

The data consists of a panel of 44 African countries. Appendix 1 shows the countries
included in the sample, with data from 1988 through 2007. Deployment of mobile phones
really began in the 1990s, thus dictating our study period. Because this study focuses on
long-term growth, and to avoid stationary issues associated with annual data, the variables

14
According to GSMA and MMU deployment tracking, 16 African countries launched financial services via
mobile phones between 2008 and 2010—Uganda, Tanzania, Ghana, Cote d’Ivoire, Rwanda, Democratic
Republic of Congo, Nigeria, Sierra Leone, Malawi, Niger, Somalia, Morocco, Madagascar, Egypt, and Senegal.
Competitive schemes have also started in Kenya with ZAP and YUCASH; in South Africa with Community
Banking, Mopay, Send Money from FNB, and in Zambia with Mobile Transactions.
14

are averaged over four years. The sample period is therefore divided into five subperiods as
follows: 1988–1991, 1992–1995, 1996–1999, 2000–2003, and 2004–2007.15

Following Barro (1991) and Waverman, Meschi, and Fuss (2005), we examine the
relationship between ICT and economic growth using a standard endogenous growth model.
The equation is as follows:16

This is a dynamic panel data model, with temporal and individual dimensions and a lagged
variable. Unlike Hardy (1980) who uses cross-country regressions, we use panel data, taking
into account country-specific effects and estimating a dynamic specification. In addition, we
improve on Lee, Levendis, and Gutierrez (2009) by using four-year averages and by
considering a wider range of ICT variables. The variable yi,t is the logarithm of real per head
GDP, Xi,t is a set of growth determinants other than lagged per capita GDP, ηi is an
unobserved country-specific effect, εi,t is the error term, and i and t represent country and
time period respectively.

We start our estimations with a set of variables determining economic growth: the initial
level of real GDP per capita (representing conditional convergence), primary school
enrollment rate (accounting for human capital), and other control variables such as inflation,
government consumption, and institutional development.

Appendix 2 presents descriptive statistics for all the variables. Data are obtained mainly from
the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank, and the International Telecom Union
databases (see Appendix 3 for variable definitions and sources).

The covariates may not be strictly exogenous. They can be predetermined (correlated with
past observation-specific disturbances) or endogenous (correlated with past and current
observation-specific disturbances). Blundell and Bond (1998) (henceforth BB) develop a
System GMM estimator to address issues associated with predetermined and endogenous
variables. We choose the BB estimator because it performs better than Arellano and Bond’s
estimator when the autoregressive coefficient is relatively high, and the number of periods is
small.17
15
By taking four-year averages, we smooth out any short term fluctuations in growth rates. Evidence also has
shown that business cycles tend to be shorter in developing countries (see for instance Rand and Tarp 2002).
Moreover, the four-year averages allow us to obtain five data points per country, enough to run the System
GMM estimator.
16
As in the literature on finance and growth, the growth equation above could be rewritten as follows:
, with
17
Blundell and Bond (1998) estimation requires that the series (y ,y ,...,y ) are mean stationary, that is,
i,1 i,2 i,T
η
i
they have a constant mean for each country i.
1−α
15

Moreover, the validity of the internal instruments used must be checked to make sure the
results are valid. As noted by Roodman (2009) the use of System GMM estimators must be
done with great caution, and several checks must be done before relying on the estimation
results, especially when T is small and the number of internally determined instruments is
high. Because too many instruments can overfit instrumented variables—failing to remove
their endogenous components and biasing the coefficient estimates (Roodman, 2009)— we
keep the number of instruments to the minimum.18 For the lagged real GDP per capita, we
use as instruments the first difference lagged one period for the equations in levels. For the
equations in first difference, we use the first lagged value. For the other variables, which are
assumed endogenous, we use the second lagged value as instruments. Finally, we adopted the
two-step System GMM with Windmeijer (2005) small sample robust correction.

To test whether financial inclusion is one of the channels through which ICT improve
growth, we retain the model in which ICT development is measured by mobile penetration
and add a variable of financial inclusion in the growth model—captured by either the number
of deposits or the number of loans per head—to check how the coefficient on ICT moves. If
this coefficient weakens, we can conclude that part of the beneficial impact of ICT
development on growth is channeled through financial inclusion.19 We strengthen the
analysis by including an interaction term between mobile penetration and financial inclusion.
We assess whether, by improving financial inclusion, mobile penetration is at the same time
reinforcing its own impact on economic growth. Similarly, this allows us to test whether the
impact of financial inclusion on growth is strengthened by better ICT infrastructure. We also
refine the analysis by isolating the impact of ICT on growth through financial inclusion in
countries that have implemented financial services on mobile phones.

V. RESULTS

A. Impact of ICT on Economic Growth

Table 2 summarizes the results of the impact of ICT on economic growth, particularly that of
mobile and fixed telephones. The baseline growth model is presented in the first column. As
shown by past studies, high government consumption and macroeconomic instability
captured by high inflation rates dampen economic growth in African countries. The results of
the baseline regression also suggest that human capital accumulation favors growth. The
legal environment, however, does not appear significant, probably because the civil and
political liberty indexes may not capture well the strength of the law in African economies.
They do have the advantage, however, of being available for a large sample of countries

18
The validity of the BB estimators is checked by using the p-values of a Hansen-Sargan test of overidentifying
restrictions. It tests for joint validity of the full instrument by checking whether the instruments, as a group,
appear exogenous. We also check the p-values of the Arellano-Bond test for AR(2) serial correlation of the
residuals.
19
The validity of this conclusion is confirmed by estimating a model for financial inclusion with mobile phone
penetration as an explanatory variable.
16

during a long period.20 There is also evidence of growth convergence among African
countries, suggesting that countries with lower initial income tend to grow faster than others
with similar macroeconomic conditions, level of human capital, and institutions.

In columns 2 through 8 of Table 2, we introduced a wide range of ICT variables in the


baseline model. The penetration rates of fixed and mobile telephones are found to have a
significant and positive impact on economic growth in Africa (column 2, Table 2), consistent
with the findings of Hardy (1980) for developing and developed economies, and that of
Roller and Waverman (2001) for OECD countries.21 This result holds even when including
the fixed and mobile penetration rate alternatively (column 3 and 4, Table 2) or jointly
(column 5, Table 2) in the baseline regression.

Taking the specification in column 5, an additional 10 percentage point increase in the


mobile penetration rate could lead to a 0.7 percentage point increase in real GDP growth,
compared to a 1.1 percentage increase for an increase in the fixed penetration rate by the
same magnitude. The marginal impact of the fixed penetration rate on economic growth
appears stronger than that of the mobile penetration rate, which contrasts with previous
findings (see Sridhar and Sridhar, 2004, on a sample of developing economies, and
Waverman, Meschi, and Fuss, 2005). This suggests that there is room to improve further the
contribution of mobile phone development to economic growth in Africa.22

We improve on previous studies by considering communication costs in addition to


penetration rates as alternative indicators of ICT development. The main reason is that
affordable communication costs could stimulate the use of fixed and mobile telephones. At
the same time, widespread use of fixed and mobile telephones leads to lower unit production
costs for telephone companies that in turn could be passed on to customers. As a result, we
expect a negative correlation between communication costs and the penetration rate of
mobile and fixed telephone, and hence economic growth. The results confirm that the price
of a 3-minute fixed or mobile telephone local call is negatively associated with economic
growth (columns 6, 7, and 8, Table 2). The magnitude of the mobile price effect on growth
may not be negligible. For instance in Ghana, the cost of a 3-minute mobile telephone local
call dropped dramatically, by 62 percent, from US$1.18 in 1999 to US$0.46 in 2006; this
would yield a 3.6 percent increase in real income over eight years. Egypt and Mozambique
experienced a drop in mobile communication cost by a similar magnitude during the same
period.

In Table 3, we tested a nonlinear relationship between ICT and economic growth and the
impact of other forms of ICT, such as computer and Internet use. First, we tested whether

20
Using an alternative indicator of legal environment such as the rule of law gives a better result, but
unfortunately reduces the sample size by a quarter—the reason we did not retain this indicator.
21
We obtained similar results with the growth rate of mobile and fixed line penetration.
22
It is worth noting that the prospects for increasing the penetration rate of fixed telephones appear more
limited than for mobile telephones, even in Africa, underlining the importance of mobile telephone development
as a source of growth.
17

mobile and fixed telephones are complements or substitutes by including in the model an
interaction term between the penetration rate of mobile and fixed telephones (column 1,
Table 3). As expected, the coefficient on the interaction term is negative and significant (see
also Waverman, Meschi, and Fuss, 2005), suggesting mobile telephones are substitutes for
fixed telephones in Africa. In other words, the marginal impact of mobile telephone
development on growth is stronger in countries with low fixed telephone penetration rates.
The substitution effect shown in African countries is not surprising given the shortage of
fixed telephone lines on the continent. In this case, the substitution effect results from the
lack of extensive wired infrastructure and not from a change in the demand for
communication services. Second, we introduced in the model an interaction term between
mobile penetration rate and GDP per capita and found that the marginal impact of mobile
telephone development decreases with the level of income per capita (column 2, Table 3),
probably reflecting diminishing growth returns to mobile telephone development. This is
consistent with the findings of Waverman, Meschi, and Fuss (2005) that show a greater
impact of mobile telephones in lower income countries. Finally, we tested the effect of
computer and Internet use on economic growth. Although the coefficient on computer use is
positive, it is not statistically significant (column 3, Table 3) probably because the
penetration rate of computer use is still very low in Africa. Internet access, which is closely
linked to computer access, appears to have a positive effect on economic growth only when
GDP per capita is high enough, consistent with what Grace, Kenny, and Qiang (2003) called
Internet traps.23

B. Robustness Tests

To test the robustness of our results, we checked the sensitivity of the coefficient on mobile
penetration, our main variable of interest, to the composition of the sample using the
specification in column 4 of Table 2. We started by selecting randomly 98 percent of the
observations (without replacement) and ran the baseline regression. This process, repeated
250 times, gives values of the coefficient on mobile penetration, for which the normal
distribution is shown in Figure 13. Although the average coefficient on mobile penetration
remains very close to the coefficient of the full sample (represented by the vertical line,
which is equivalent to sampling 100 percent of the observations), the base of the distribution
widens.

We used the same procedure to select randomly 95 percent of the observations. The results
showed that leaving 5 percent of observations out of the sample shifted away the average
coefficient on mobile penetration from the coefficient of the full sample. With 95 percent of
observations, the average coefficient on mobile penetration is 0.37, compared to 0.56 for the
full sample. Further reducing the size of the random sample shows that the average
coefficient on mobile penetration gets closer to zero, although its distribution has a heavier
tail. In other words, the probability of replicating the full sample estimate of the coefficient
on mobile penetration weakens rapidly as the size of the subsample shrinks. This suggests

23
We also tested an interaction term between computer and Internet use and between computer use and
education, without concluding results.
18

that the coefficient estimated for the full sample hides significant country heterogeneity. This
country heterogeneity could be partly explained by the nonlinear relationship between mobile
penetration and growth we found earlier.24 Caution is therefore needed when interpreting the
results in the tables discussed above; the growth benefits from mobile phone development
may not be immediate and depend on country-specific factors that should be accounted for.
As a result, it could be useful, if data permit, to complement panel studies on the impact of
ICT on growth with country-specific studies.

We also conducted recursive estimates to test the stability of the coefficient on mobile
penetration. The observations are first ranked in increasing order of the mobile penetration
rate. Starting with a sample of low mobile penetration rates, we added subsequent
observations with higher penetration rates to the sample and reran the regressions. The results
show that the coefficient on mobile penetration remains positive and significant (Figure 14),
but the marginal impact of mobile phones on growth is heterogeneous across the sample and
declines as the mobile penetration rate increases.25 This may suggest a lack of network effects
(Roller and Waverman, 2001) in African countries, probably because their penetration rates
are still below the threshold above which network effects are at play.

Despite country heterogeneity, the model does a good job of predicting the dependent
variable (Figure 15). Within 10 percent confidence interval, the model predicts well the level
and growth of real GDP for all countries in the sample.

We performed additional robustness tests (Table 4). Averaging the data over a 3-year period
increases the sample size by 8 percent, without dramatically changing the results. The
coefficient on mobile phone penetration retains its positive sign and remains significant at 1
percent (column 1). Moving to a five-year average reduces the sample by 20 percent but does
not affect the quality of the results (column 2). We restricted the sample to sub-Saharan
African countries, excluding the top performers in the region (Mauritius, Seychelles, South
Africa). The coefficient on mobile is positive and significant and has a larger magnitude
(column 3).26 Finally, the regression is run on a sample of developing countries; we found
that mobile telephone development stimulates economic growth and that the marginal impact
for African countries is not statistically different from that of other developing economies
(columns 4 and 5).

24
Indeed, as shown in Table 3, the marginal impact of mobile penetration rates on growth is larger when
income per capita is low and/or fixed telephone penetration is low.
25
This contrasts with the finding that low levels of computer and Internet use do not positively impact growth
(Table 3). One could argue that a low level of mobile penetration seems to be favorable to growth because of
the relatively low fixed cost of mobile phones and the fact that it is a substitute for fixed lines, which facilitates
a rapid and increasing adoption of mobile phones. However, computer and Internet use may be constrained by
equipment cost, lack of broadband access, and widespread illiteracy. With a low level of computer and Internet
use, a country can be locked into a poverty trap (Grace, Kenny, and Qiang, 2003).
26
Probably because the countries included in the sample have lower income per capita. The results in Table 3
(column 2) show that the marginal impact of mobile phone penetration on growth declines as income per capita
increases.
19

C. Financial Inclusion

In this section, we investigate whether ICT development stimulates growth by fostering


financial inclusion and whether the interaction between ICT and financial inclusion
facilitates economic growth. Before turning to the regressions, it is worth noting the
challenge of measuring financial inclusion in the sense of greater access of households to
financial services. Very few measures of financial inclusion exist, and those that do lack time
dimension and are available for only a limited number of countries. We retained two relevant
indicators for our study. The first is the number of deposits per head—including deposits at
commercial banks, cooperatives, microfinance institutions, and specialized state financial
institutions—and the second is the number of loans per head—also including loans by the
previously mentioned financial institutions.27 As these two measures appear highly correlated
with the level of financial development, we do not include the latter in the model; we will,
instead, use it as a broader indicator of financial inclusion. Regarding the ICT variable, we
considered the particular case of mobile telephones as shown by the baseline specification in
column 1 of Table 5, which replicates the model presented in column 4 of Table 2.28

In columns 2 and 4 of Table 5, the coefficient on the number of deposits per head and that on
the number of loans per head are positive and significant as expected, implying that greater
financial inclusion is associated with higher economic growth in African economies. Indeed,
better access to finance facilitates economic growth by allowing households to undertake
productive investments. Moreover, a greater access to deposit facilities enhances the ability
of financial intermediaries to mobilize savings, which are allocated to projects with the
highest returns.

Interestingly, the coefficient on the mobile penetration rates drops when controlling for
financial inclusion, suggesting that some of the positive impact of ICT on growth is
channeled through financial inclusion (see Annex 2 for more details on the link between
financial inclusion and mobile phone penetration).29 Further, the penetration of mobile
telephones enhances the growth impact of financial inclusion as shown by the positive and
significant coefficient on the interaction term between the mobile penetration rate and the
number of deposits per head (column 3, Table 5). The same result holds for the interaction
term between the mobile penetration rate and the number of loans per head (column 5, Table
5).

These results confirm that mobile telephone penetration can foster economic growth not only
by facilitating financial inclusion, but also by consolidating the impact of financial inclusion
on economic growth. Through higher mobile penetration, it becomes easier to have access to
deposits and loans. Better information flows through mobiles improve information

27
Because of limited data on the number of deposits and loans per head (the data are available for 2003 and
2007), we assume the average level holds throughout the period.
28
Without the variable measuring institutions because it was not significant.
29
Note that Figure 1 shows a positive correlation between mobile penetration and financial inclusion, even after
controlling for GDP per capita level.
20

acquisition of both depositors and financial institutions, and enhance monitoring. Higher
mobile penetration indeed reduces the physical constraints and costs of distance and time.
Also, better ICT development reduces the cost of financial intermediation and contributes to
the emergence of branchless banking services, therefore improving access to finance for
households that would be credit constrained otherwise.

To refine our analysis, we considered that financial services on mobiles remain


underdeveloped in African countries and are available only in a few countries. Therefore, it is
worth assessing whether mobile financial services penetration further strengthens the growth
effect of financial inclusion in these countries. During the period covered by our study, three
countries were operating mobile financial services: Zambia since 2001, South Africa since
2004, and Kenya since 2007. We constructed a dummy variable (named Mobfi), taking the
value of 1 if mobile financial services are operating in the countries and 0 otherwise.
Crossing this dummy variable with the interaction term between financial inclusion and
mobile penetration shows that in countries where mobile financial services exist, mobile
penetration further enhances the contribution of financial inclusion to economic growth
compared to countries where these services are not yet deployed (columns 6 and 7, Table 5).

As a robustness test, we checked for the potential influence of outliers by removing from the
sample observations with a residual term larger than (i) two standard deviations, (ii) one
standard deviation, and (iii) one-half standard deviation of the dependent variable. Rerunning
the regressions without these potential outliers does not affect the quality of the results. The
results are also confirmed when replacing financial inclusion with financial development.
Although financial development—captured by the ratio of private credit to GDP—appears
positively correlated to growth (consistent with the findings of Levine, Loayza, and Beck,
2000), the interaction term between financial development and mobile penetration is also
positive and significant, suggesting that financially well-developed countries tend to grow
faster when mobile penetration is high (column 8, Table 5). Consistent with the previous
results, this effect appears stronger in countries where mobile financial services are available.

VI. CONCLUSION

This paper investigates the impact of ICT development on economic growth, considering a
sample of African countries during 1988–2007. Focusing on mobile telephone development,
the paper argues that financial inclusion could be one of the channels through which mobile
phone diffusion contributes to growth. Using a standard growth model and the System GMM
estimator to address endogeneity issues, the results of the estimations reveal that ICT
development (captured by the penetration rates of mobile and fixed telephone and
communication costs) contribute to economic growth in Africa. In addition, financial
inclusion, measured by the number of deposits and loans per head, is conducive to economic
growth and appears to be one of the channels of transmission from mobile phone
development to growth. More importantly, the interaction between mobile phone penetration
and financial inclusion is found positive and significant in the growth regression. Although
the rollout of mobile banking is still at its early stage, the results show that in countries where
such financial services are available, the joint impact of financial inclusion and mobile phone
diffusion on growth is stronger.
21

The findings of this paper underline the importance of ICT development, in particular mobile
phone rollout, for African countries as a source of growth, and the potential of ICT to
improve financial inclusion, which itself benefits growth. Policies in African countries
should encourage domestic and foreign investment in ICT and promote development of the
sector. Moreover, driving down the cost of communications is critical to stimulating the
diffusion of ICT and spurring growth. Increased competition in the telecommunication
industry could be one of the options. The experience of OECD countries suggests that prices
have declined, and technological diffusion and introduction of new services have been rapid
following the liberalization of the ICT sector (OECD, 2003). Also, in an attempt to mobilize
revenue, governments in many African countries find it attractive to increase tax on mobile
communications as this tax is easy to administer and has a large base. Because this will lead
to higher communication costs, the benefit from increased government revenue should be
weighed against the risk of lower growth.

Further, mobile phone diffusion has the potential to boost financial inclusion by easing the
provision of cost-effective financial services to the poor and the nonpoor, given the low
coverage of banks in African countries. Policies to promote greater interaction between the
ICT and financial sectors while addressing the challenges posed by mobile banking (security
concerns, compliance with AML/CFT30 rules, and so forth) could improve the development
of mobile banking. Experiences in Kenya, Zambia, and South Africa have demonstrated that
mobile financial services can help reduce the financial infrastructure gap and the lack of
access to financial services in Africa.

30
AML = Anti-Money-Laundering; CFT = Combating the Financing of Terrorism.
22

REFERENCES

Barro, Robert J., 1991, ―Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries,‖ The Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 106(2), pp. 407–43.

Beck, Thorsten, Asli Demirguc-Kunt, and Maria Soledad Martinez Peria, 2007, ―Reaching
Out: Access to and Use of Banking Services Across Countries,‖ Journal of Financial
Economics, 85(1), pp. 234–66.

Beck, Thorsten, Robert Cull, Michael Fuchs, Jared Getenga, Peter Gatere, John Randa, and
Mircea Trandafir, 2010, ―Banking Sector Stability, Efficiency, and Outreach in Kenya,‖
Policy Research Working Paper Series 5442 (Washington: World Bank).

Blundell, Richard, and Stephen Bond, 1998, ―Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in
Dynamic Panel Data Models,‖ Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), pp. 115–43.

Chowdhury, Shyamal, 2006, ―Investments in ICT-Capital and Economic Performance of


Small and Medium Scale Enterprises in East Africa,‖ Journal of International Development,
Vol. 18(4), pp. 533–552.

Collins, Daryl, Jonathan Morduch, Stuart Rutherford, and Orlanda Ruthven, 2009, Portfolios
of the Poor: How the World's Poor Live on $2 a Day (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University
Press).

Consultative Group to Assist the Poor, 2007, ―Notes on Regulation of Branchless Banking in
Kenya,‖ Technical Report (Washington: CGAP).

Consultative Group to Assist the Poor, 2009, Financial Access 2009—Measuring Access to
Financial Services around the World, Technical Report (Washington: CGAP).

Datta, Anusua, and Sumit Agarwal, 2004, ―Telecommunications and Economic Growth: A
Panel Data Approach,‖ Applied Economics, 36(15), pp. 1649–54.

Do-Nascimento, José, 2005, ―Le développement du téléphone portable en Afrique,‖ in


Télécommunications entre biens publics et marchandises, ed. by Djilali Benamrane, Bruno
Jaffré, Marie-Laure Urvoy Sangharé, and François Xavier Verschave (Paris: Charles Léopold
Mayer Ed.), pp.173–90.

Donner, Jonathan, 2006, ―The Use of Mobile Phones by Microentrepreneurs in Kigali,


Rwanda: Changes to Social and Business Networks,‖ Information Technologies and
International Development, Vol. 3(2), pp: 3–19.

Donner, Jonathan, 2008, ―Research Approaches to Mobile Use in the Developing World: A
Review of the Literature,‖ The Information Society, 24(3), pp. 140–59.

FinMark, Trust, ed., 2009, FinScope South Africa 2009 (Johannesburg: FinScope).
23

Global System for Mobile Communications Association (GSMA), 2008, ―Understanding


Financial Regulation and How it Works,‖ Technical Report, (London: GSMA).

Grace, Jeremy, Charles Kenny, and Christine Zhen-Wei Qiang, 2003, ―Information and
Communication Technologies and Broad Based Development: A Partial Review of the
Evidence,‖ World Bank Working Paper, Technical Report 12 (Washington: World Bank).

Haacker, Markus, 2010, "ICT Equipment Investment and Growth in Low- and Lower-
Middle-Income Countries," IMF Working Paper 10/66 (Washington: International Monetary
Fund).

Hardy, Andrew P., 1980, ―The Role of the Telephone in Economic Development,‖
Telecommunications Policy, 4(4), pp. 278–286.

Heeks, Richard, 1999, ―Information and Communication Technologies, Poverty and


Development‖ Development Informatics Working Paper Series, No.5/1999 (Manchester:
Institute for Development Policy and Management).

Jensen, Robert, 2007, ―The Digital Provide: Information (Technology), Market Performance,
and Welfare in the South Indian Fisheries Sector,‖ The Quarterly Journal of Economics,
122(3), pp. 879–24.

Kathuria, Rajat, Mahesh Uppal and Mamta, 2009, ―An Econometric Analysis of the Impact
of Mobile,‖ The Vodafone Policy Paper Series (9), pp 5–20.

Kendall, Jake, Nataliya Mylenko, and Alejandro Ponce, 2010, ―Measuring Financial Access
around the World,‖ Policy Research Working Paper, No 5253 (Washington: World Bank)

Lee, Sang H., John Levendis, and Luis Gutierrez, 2009, ―Telecommunications and Economic
Growth: An Empirical Analysis of sub-Saharan Africa,‖ Documentos de trabajo 005512
(Bogota: Universidad del Rosario—Facultad de Economia).

Levine, Ross, Norman Loayza, and Thorsten Beck, 2000, ―Financial Intermediation and
Growth: Causality and Causes,‖ Journal of Monetary Economics, No 46, pp. 31–77.

Lewin, David, and Susan Sweet, 2005, ―The Economic Impact of Mobile Services in Latin
America,‖ Technical Report (London: Report for the GSMA, GSM Latin America, and
AHCIET).

Mas, Ignacio, and Amolo Ng’weno, 2009, ―Three Keys to M-PESA’s Success: Branding,
Channel Management and Pricing,‖ Technical Report (Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation).

Mas, Ignacio, and Dan Radcliffe, 2010, ―Mobile Payments Go Viral: M-PESA in Kenya,‖
Technical Report (Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation).
24

Norton, Seth W., 1992, ―Transaction Costs, Telecommunications, and the Microeconomics
of Macroeconomic Growth,‖ Economic Development and Cultural Change, 41(1), pp. 175–
96.

OECD, ed., 2003, ICT and Economic Growth: Evidence from OECD Countries, Industries
and Firms (Paris: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development).

Rand, John, and Finn Tarp, 2002, ―Business Cycles in Developing Countries: Are They
Different?‖ World Development, Vol. 30(12), pp 2071–2088.

Rasmussen, Stephen, 2010, ―Mobile Banking in 2020,‖ in CGAP Technology Program


(Washington: Consultative Group to Assist the Poor).

Roller, Lars-Hendrik, and Leonard Waverman, 2001, ―Telecommunications Infrastructure


and Economic Development: A Simultaneous Approach,‖ American Economic Review,
91(4), pp. 909–23.

Roodman, David, 2009, ―A Note on the Theme of Too Many Instruments,‖ Oxford Bulletin
of Economics and Statistics, 71(1), pp. 135–58.

Sridhar, Kala Seetharam, and Varadharajan Sridhar, 2004, ―Telecommunications


Infrastructure and Economic Growth: Evidence from Developing Countries,‖ Working Paper
04/14 (New Delhi: National Institute of Public Finance and Policy).

Tarazi, Michael, and Paul Breloff, 2010, ―Nonbank E-Money Issuers: Regulatory
Approaches to Protecting Customer Funds,‖ Technical Report 63 (Washington: CGAP).

Tcheng, Henri, Jean Michel Huet, and Mouna Romdhane, 2010, ―Les enjeux financiers des
télécoms en Afrique sub-saharienne,‖ Technical Report (Paris: Institut Français des Relations
Internationales).

Tcheng, Henri, Jean-Michel Huet, Isabelle Viennois, and Mouna Romdhane, 2007,
―Telecoms and Development in Africa: the Chicken or the Egg?‖ Convergence Letter No 8.

Waverman, Leonard, Meloria Meschi, and Melvyn Fuss, 2005, ―The Impact of Telecoms on
Economic Growth in Developing Countries,‖ The Vodafone Policy Paper Series, (2), pp. 10–
23.

Windmeijer, Frank, 2005, ―A Finite Sample Correction for the Variance of Linear Efficient
Two-Step GMM Estimators,‖ Journal of Econometrics, 126 (1), pp. 25–51.
25

Figure 1. Correlation among Mobile Penetration, Growth, and Financial Inclusion


26

Figure 2. Financial Inclusion and Mobile Penetration by Type of Financial Institution

Figure 3. Trends in ICT Use: International Comparison


27

Figure 4. ICT Growth in Developing Countries

Figure 5. Trends in Fixed versus Mobile Phone Subscribers: International Comparison


28

Figure 6. Trends in Mobile Penetration: International Comparison

Figure 7. Trends in Prepaid versus Postpaid Phone Subscribers: International Comparison


29

Figure 8. Access to Financial Services in Selected African Countries


(Percent of total population)

Figure 9. Bank Loans and Deposits: International Comparison


30

Figure 10. Bank Branches and ATMs


31

Figure 11. Financial Infrastructure Gap

Figure 12. Comparing Trends in Bank Credit and Mobile Penetration


32

Figure 13. Testing for the Stability of the Coefficient on Mobile Penetration Using Random
Samples

Figure 14. Recursive Estimates of the Coefficient on Mobile Penetration


33

Figure 15. Quality of the Prediction


26

1
24

.5
Fitted values
Fitted values

0
22

-.5
20

-1
Fitted Values Fitted values
Line of perfect prediction Line of perfect prediction

-1.5
18

18 20 22 24 26 -1.5 -1 -.5 0 .5 1
Log of real GDP Real GDP growth

Sources for the figures: Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Martinez Peria (2007), International
Telecommunication Union, FinMark (2009), and authors’ calculations.

Notes for the figures: MFIs = microfinance institutions; SSFIs = specialized state financial
institutions; automated teller machines (ATMs); SSA = sub-Saharan Africa; ECA = Europe
and Central Asia; MENA = Middle East and North Africa; SA = South Asia; LAC = Latin
America and Caribbean; EAP = East Asia and Pacific; LICs = low-income countries; LMC =
lower middle income countries; UMC = upper middle income countries.
34

Table 2. Impact of Mobile and Fixed Telephone Penetration on Economic Growth in Africa

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Initial GDP (log) -0.230 -0.190 -0.190 -0.090 -0.100 -0.040 0.010 -0.010
[0.034]*** [0.018]*** [0.019]*** [0.013]*** [0.009]*** [0.007]*** [0.007]*** [0.004]***
Total telephone subscribers (fixed + mobile) per head 0.116
[0.027]***
Fixed telephone lines per head 0.700 0.114
[0.169]*** [0.031]***
Mobile telephone subscribers per head 0.056 0.073
[0.017]*** [0.009]***
Price of a 3-minute fixed telephone local call -0.401 -0.356
[0.033]*** [0.021]***
Price of 3-minute mobile local call -0.085 -0.050
[0.020]*** [0.011]***
Education 0.005 0.003 0.004 0.003 0.003 0.001 0.002 0.002
[0.001]*** [0.000]*** [0.000]*** [0.000]*** [0.000]*** [0.000]*** [0.000]*** [0.000]***
Government consumption -0.025 -0.025 -0.025 -0.020 -0.020 -0.004 -0.003 -0.001
[0.003]*** [0.002]*** [0.001]*** [0.001]*** [0.001]*** [0.001]*** [0.002]* [0.001]
Inflation (log) -0.526 -0.608 -0.451 -0.274 -0.353 -0.683 -0.435 -0.663
[0.151]*** [0.091]*** [0.086]*** [0.100]*** [0.024]*** [0.058]*** [0.073]*** [0.071]***
Institutions -0.064 -0.015 -0.056 0.025 0.065 -0.033 0.075 0.040
[0.163] [0.043] [0.055] [0.056] [0.007]*** [0.046] [0.046] [0.038]
Constant 5.214 4.393 4.376 2.196 2.503 1.024 -0.151 0.369
[0.706]*** [0.410]*** [0.423]*** [0.284]*** [0.198]*** [0.141]*** [0.153] [0.078]***

Observations 190 189 189 190 189 168 170 157


Number of countries 44 43 43 44 43 41 41 39
Hansen test (prob.) 0.54 0.60 0.60 0.61 0.59 0.37 0.32 0.78
AR2 (prob.) 0.23 0.17 0.20 0.34 0.31 0.45 0.27 0.19

Notes: Standard errors in brackets; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%
35

Table 3. Testing for Interaction Terms and other Forms of ICT

(1) (2) (3)

Initial GDP (log) -0.060 -0.060 -0.030


[0.003]*** [0.004]*** [0.005]***
Fixed telephone lines per head 0.747 0.060
[0.058]*** [0.089]
Mobile telephone subscribers per head 0.300 0.112
[0.024]*** [0.037]***
Fixed × Mobile telephone subscribers per head -2.548
[0.088]***
Mobile telephone subscribers per head × GDP per capita -0.012
[0.007]*
Personal computers per 100 head 0.247
[0.368]
Internet users per 100 inhabitants -0.579
[0.193]***
Internet users per 100 inhabitants × GDP per capita 0.350
[0.039]***
Education 0.000 0.001 0.001
[0.000] [0.000]*** [0.000]**
Government consumption -0.012 -0.014 -0.007
[0.001]*** [0.001]*** [0.001]***
Inflation (log) -0.448 -0.417 -0.530
[0.029]*** [0.038]*** [0.051]***
Institutions 0.042 0.080 -0.006
[0.018]** [0.009]*** [0.043]
Constant 1.709 1.546 1.011
[0.086]*** [0.099]*** [0.102]***

Observations 189 189 128


Number of countries 43 43 41
Hansen test (prob.) 0.75 0.75 0.95
AR2 (prob.) 0.34 0.38 0.45

Notes: Standard errors in brackets; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%
36

Table 4. Robustness Tests

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Initial GDP (log) -0.040 -0.060 -0.140 -0.020 -0.020


[0.005]*** [0.020]*** [0.012]*** [0.006]*** [0.005]***
Mobile telephone subscribers per head 0.071 0.078 0.226 0.104 0.104
[0.010]*** [0.032]** [0.006]*** [0.019]*** [0.018]***
Mobile telephone subscribers per head × Africa -0.034
[0.032]
Education 0.002 0.002 0.001 0.002 0.001
[0.000]*** [0.001]*** [0.000]*** [0.001]** [0.000]***
Government consumption -0.012 -0.024 -0.015 -0.017 -0.017
[0.001]*** [0.005]*** [0.001]*** [0.003]*** [0.002]***
Inflation (log) -0.394 -0.514 -0.725 -0.278 -0.369
[0.021]*** [0.130]*** [0.056]*** [0.106]*** [0.075]***
Institutions 0.082 -0.003 -0.089 0.006 0.045
[0.016]*** [0.102] [0.081] [0.043] [0.029]
Constant 0.992 1.647 3.404 0.660 0.633
[0.112]*** [0.438]*** [0.273]*** [0.137]*** [0.111]***

Observations 205 150 157 451 451


Number of countries 43 42 36 114 114
Hansen test (prob.) 0.93 0.21 0.53 0.03 0.06
AR2 (prob.) 0.96 0.17 0.24 0.92 0.92

Notes: Standard errors in brackets; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.
Africa is a dummy variable taking 1 for African countries and 0 otherwise.
Column (1) data averaged over 3-year periods;
(2) data average over 5-year periods;
(3) sample of sub-Saharan African countries, excluding Mauritius, Seychelles, and South Africa;
(4) and (5) sample of developing countries.
37

Table 5. Mobile Penetration, Financial Inclusion, and Economic Growth in Africa


(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Initial GDP (log) -0.110 -0.150 -0.070 -0.160 -0.110 -0.080 -0.120 -0.030
[0.009]*** [0.015]*** [0.007]*** [0.013]*** [0.009]*** [0.011]*** [0.012]*** [0.003]***
Mobile telephone subscribers per head 0.075 0.042 -0.014 0.043 0.005 -0.044 -0.033 0.011
[0.016]*** [0.009]*** [0.015] [0.011]*** [0.024] [0.040] [0.034] [0.027]
Number of deposits per head 0.658 0.087 0.079
[0.154]*** [0.005]*** [0.013]***
Mobile × Number of deposits per head 0.103 0.130
[0.034]*** [0.078]*
Mobile × Number of deposits per head × Mobfi 1.392
[0.119]***
Number of loans per head 3.540 0.919 1.100
[0.870]*** [0.043]*** [0.100]***
Mobile × Number of loans per head 1.756 0.570
[0.311]*** [0.344]*
Mobile × Number of loans per head × Mobfi 7.419
[0.889]***
Private Credit/GDP 0.050
[0.022]**
Mobile × Private Credit/GDP 0.096
[0.056]*
Mobile × Private Credit/GDP × Mobfi 0.107
[0.021]***
Education 0.004 0.004 0.003 0.005 0.004 0.003 0.004 0.002
[0.000]*** [0.001]*** [0.000]*** [0.001]*** [0.000]*** [0.000]*** [0.000]*** [0.000]***
Government consumption -0.020 -0.030 -0.015 -0.028 -0.022 -0.016 -0.021 -0.010
[0.001]*** [0.001]*** [0.001]*** [0.001]*** [0.001]*** [0.001]*** [0.001]*** [0.001]***
Inflation (log) -0.293 -0.195 -0.360 -0.120 -0.194 -0.412 -0.301 -0.296
[0.107]*** [0.159] [0.052]*** [0.148] [0.066]*** [0.066]*** [0.072]*** [0.017]***
Constant 2.518 3.481 1.534 3.635 2.575 1.900 2.769 0.894
[0.218]*** [0.374]*** [0.160]*** [0.316]*** [0.207]*** [0.247]*** [0.260]*** [0.071]***

Observations 190 190 190 190 190 190 190 184


Number of countries 44 44 44 44 44 44 44 42
Hansen test (prob.) 0.60 0.59 0.56 0.66 0.44 0.50 0.60 0.73
AR2 (prob.) 0.32 0.20 0.40 0.25 0.32 0.34 0.26 0.43
Notes: Standard errors in brackets; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%
Mobfi is a dummy variable taking 1 for countries where financial services on mobile telephones are available, and 0 otherwise
38

Annex 1. Mobile Financial Services

Mobile financial services (MFS) belong to the category of branchless banking services that
allows banks to provide remote financial services to their customers. Branchless banking
services can be in addition to services already offered to existing customers. In that case they
are called additive, because they are not specifically designed for customers with low access
to financial services. On the other hand, they can be tailored for customers who would not be
reached profitably with traditional branch-based financial services; in that case, they are
called transformational. Whereas mobile financial services generally are additive in
developed countries, they are mainly transformational in developing countries with the
objective of improving financial inclusion of unbanked people.

Currently, two main models exist: the bank-based and the nonbank-based models. In the
bank-based model, customers have a direct contractual relationship with the bank (the
financial institution), but transactions are handled by retailers outside the bank branch
network. In mobile financial services, the retailer is a mobile network operator (MNO) that
offers a technological channel for delivering banking services. Because the bank is licensed,
it is subject to prudential regulation; and customers and the regulatory authorities, therefore,
may be more reassured. The Brazilian model, the South African models (MTN and WIZZIT),
and the Indian model are examples of bank-based models. In the nonbank-based model, there
is no direct contractual relationship between the user of financial services and the bank. The
user gives cash to the retailer in exchange for an electronic record of value on a virtual
account kept through the MNO or an issuer of stored value card. In contrast to banks,
nonbanks providing MFS are not subject to prudential regulation because they are not
allowed to intermediate the repayable deposits they collect. Nonbank mobile money
providers make profits in other ways; for example, through transaction charges or lowered
airtime distribution costs, reduced churn, and so forth (Tarazi, and Breloff, 2010). M-PESA
in Kenya and Orange Money in Ivory Coast are examples of nonbank-based models.

It is worth describing one of the most successful MFS: M-PESA in Kenya. M-PESA, a
mobile payment and transfer service provided by Safaricom, offers to its customers an
electronic wallet (e-wallet) stored on their cell phones. Users can deposit into, and withdraw
money from their e-wallet at an M-PESA agent. They also can transfer electronic money to
other users (including sellers of goods and services to pay, for instance, electricity bills or
taxis fares) and buy prepaid airtime via text messages. 31 According to Mas and Radcliffe
(2010), 75 companies are now using M-PESA to collect payments from their customers; the
biggest user is the electricity company (20 percent of their customers pay through M-PESA).
M-PESA also intends to deliver a full range of payment services such as institutional
payments, by allowing companies to use M-PESA to pay for salaries, for example, or even
allowing payments for in-store purchases. In other countries, such as Egypt, governments are

31
Regulation on anti-money-laundering (AML) and combating the financing of terrorism (CFT) has, among
other requirements; imposed thresholds on transaction values. With M-PESA, there is no minimum account
balance. However, there is a maximum account balance, and daily transactions and withdrawals are only
allowed within a predetermined band (CGAP, 2007).
39

also considering the possibility of using mobile phones and mobile money to pay for
government subsidies or pensions in Government to People (G2P) transactions.

M-PESA charges fees for sending electronic float (e-float) and for cash withdrawal.
Registration for M-PESA service is possible for any owners of a Safaricom SIM card and
requires a formal ID card.32 M-PESA agents handling customers’ deposits and withdrawals
of cash receive a commission. They hold e-float, purchased from Safaricom or customers, on
their own cell phones, and must maintain cash on their premises (to meet customers’
withdrawals).33

The cash collected by M-PESA in exchange for e-float is held by M-PESA Trust Company,
Ltd., in trust accounts with two commercial banks that pool client funds. However, any
interest earned from this pooled account cannot benefit Safaricom and cannot be passed
through to customers whose funds actually earned the interest because Safaricom would then
be acting as a bank.34

Since its launch in March 2007, M-PESA has experienced extraordinary growth. As of
January 2010, there were more than 9 million registered users of M-PESA (40 percent of
Kenyan adults and 23 percent of the population), of which the majority is active; about $320
million per month of person-to-person (P2P) transfers have occurred. M-PESA has 16,900
agents who are Safaricom dealers or other entities such as petrol stations (Mas and Radcliffe,
2010). In January 2010, thanks to a partnership with Equity Bank (one of the biggest lenders
in Kenya by number of accounts), M-PESA customers can also withdraw money (but not
deposit) at any Equity Bank ATM, regardless of whether they are clients of Equity Bank.
This further increases access to financial services for M-PESA customers and helps mitigate
liquidity problems for customers when M-PESA agents do not have cash on hand.35

32
The ID card requirement is part of AML and CFT regulations. Even if the ID requirement for opening a
mobile money account is not as constraining as the number of formal documents required when opening a bank
account, it can still represent an impediment to mobile banking growth and financial inclusion. Indeed,
unbanked and low-income customers targeted by mobile banking service rarely possess any kind of formal ID.
33
Managing agents’ liquidity is essential for M-PESA and mobile money service in general (Mas and Ng’weno,
2009).
34
In that case, M-PESA would not be a payments service anymore but a banking service. Discussions are
ongoing with the Central Bank of Kenya on what to do with the interest (CGAP, 2007). Tarazi and Breloff
(2010) mention that because interest has accrued on the trust accounts established for M-PESA customers,
Safaricom is negotiating with the authorities to donate the interest to charity.
35
A savings service called M-Kesho, which will allow mobile-phone based deposit accounts, is also being
launched. There are also partnerships between M-PESA and other commercial banks, with the objective of
achieving a closer integration between the non-bank based model of MFS and the conventional banking system,
and ultimately improving financial inclusion.
40

Annex 2. Assessing the Effect of Mobile Phone Penetration on Financial Inclusion

We found in Table 5 that the effect of mobile penetration on growth weakened once financial
inclusion was controlled for, suggesting that the latter could be one channel through which
mobile penetration positively influences growth. However, this conclusion was based solely
on the change in the coefficient on mobile phone penetration, without properly modeling
financial inclusion. Building on Kendall, Mylenko, and Ponce (2010), we estimate the effect
of mobile phone development on financial inclusion, while controlling for a range of factors
Kendall, Mylenko, and Ponce (2010) have found important in explaining cross-country
variations in deposit account and loan penetration (measured as number of accounts or loans
per 1000 adults). For instance, the authors find that income levels and population density are
two of the best predictors of the penetration of deposit and loan products. Our model is as
follows:

where , the dependent variable, stands for financial inclusion, measured by the number of
deposits and loans per head; , our variable of interest, denotes the mobile phone
penetration rate; and , the main control variables, respectively, represent the level of
GDP per head and population density; is a set of other control variables, including banks’
overhead cost to account for the efficiency of financial intermediaries,36 a variable capturing
the quality of the legal environment,37 and the number of bank branches per km2 to capture
the geographical coverage of bank branches. Finally, accounts for country-specific effects
and is the error term.

In contrast to Kendall, Mylenko, and Ponce (2010), we use a panel regression because data
on the indicators of financial inclusion are available for 2003 and 2007. The data on the
explanatory variables are averaged over two periods of four years each: 2000–2003 and
2004–2007. Given the limited time dimension of the data, we choose to run the model with
the random effect estimator, though this estimator relies on the strong assumption of
exogenous country-specific effects. However, the probability of the Hausman test is higher
than 0.10, suggesting that use of a random-effect model is appropriate.

The results presented in Table 6 suggest that mobile phone development is strongly
positively correlated to financial inclusion.38 This holds even after controlling for GDP per

36
Kendall, Mylenko, and Ponce (2010) did not include banking sector efficiency in their model, but we believe
that it is a relevant explanatory variable for financial inclusion as the high cost of small loans and deposits is
often viewed as one of the main reasons why a high share of share of the population in developing countries is
financially excluded. However, the shortcoming of this measure is that it captures only the efficiency of
commercial banks.
37
For consistency purposes, the indicator of the quality of institutions is the same as in the growth model
presented in Table 2. Kendall, Mylenko, and Ponce (2010) use indicators of contract enforcement, creditor right
protection and creditor information.
38
Kendall, Mylenko, and Ponce (2010) use fixed line density as a measure of the development of physical
infrastructure and found that it is positively associated with financial inclusion.
41

head and population density, as well as for the cost of financial intermediation, the legal
environment and the geographical coverage of bank branches.39 Similarly, by using
household survey data, Beck and others (2010) find that the ownership of a cell phone
increases the likelihood of using financial services in Kenya.

Interestingly, a better coverage of bank branches and good institutions enhance financial
inclusion. While higher GDP per head, bank efficiency and population density are positively
associated with access to deposits, the results are less clear for access to loans. For instance,
population density has surprisingly a negative sign, when branch density is included in the
model. One explanation could be found in the ways financial institutions handle risk
diversification. Formal financial institutions such as commercial banks are less likely to lend
to customers that are geographically concentrated so as to limit collective risk. But less
formal financial institutions such as microfinance institutions tend to have geographically
concentrated customers, which is needed for group lending. As our indicators of financial
inclusion possibly underestimate the access to less formal financial services, the negative
sign of population density could be attributable to the risk diversification strategy of
commercial banks.

Table 6. Mobile Phone Development and Financial Inclusion, 2000-2007


Number of deposits per head Number of loans per head
(1) (2) (3) (4)

Mobile telephone subscribers per head 0.382 0.101 0.211 0.071


[0.161]** [0.036]*** [0.084]** [0.011]***
GDP per head(log) 0.132 0.093 0.015 -0.001
[0.047]*** [0.032]*** [0.016] [0.010]
Population density (log) 0.098 0.065 0.007 -0.023
[0.035]*** [0.030]** [0.010] [0.010]**
Banks’ overhead cost (percent of assets) -1.405 0.227
[0.682]** [0.202]
Institutions 0.95 0.279
[0.142]*** [0.073]***
Number of bank branches per km2 0.005 0.002
[0.001]*** [0.000]***
Constant -1.008 -0.802 -0.104 0.034
[0.347]*** [0.227]*** [0.111] [0.070]

Observations 49 39 46 36
Number of countries 36 31 34 29
R2 (between) 0.47 0.68 0.37 0.55
Hausman test (prob) 0.69 0.34 0.99 0.57

Note: Standard errors in brackets; * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%

39
We also tested the effect of inflation and banking concentration on financial inclusion as in Kendall,
Mylenko, and Ponce (2010), but none was significant.
42

Appendix 1. Sample Countries

Algeria Libya
Angola Madagascar
Benin Malawi
Botswana Mali
Burkina Faso Mauritania
Burundi Mauritius
Cameroon Morocco
Cape Verde Mozambique
Central African Republic Namibia
Chad Niger
Congo Rwanda
Congo (Democratic Republic of the) Senegal
Cote d'Ivoire Seychelles
Egypt Sierra Leone
Equatorial Guinea South Africa
Ethiopia Sudan
Gabon Swaziland
The Gambia Tanzania
Ghana Togo
Guinea-Bissau Tunisia
Kenya Uganda
Lesotho Zambia
43

Appendix 2. Summary Statistics and Correlation Matrix

Standard
Observations Average Minimum Maximum
deviation

Real GDP growth 190 4.3 4.2 -4.9 40.9


Log of real GDP 190 22.0 1.5 19.0 25.8
Primary school enrollment rates 190 89.7 28.5 26.9 181.2
Government consumption in percent
of GDP 190 14.7 5.4 2.6 35.0
Inflation rate 190 10.3 13.4 -5.9 83.6
Institutions 190 0.268 0.152 0.143 1.000
Fixed telephone lines per head 189 0.028 0.049 0.0 0.286
Mobile telephone subscribers per head 190 0.063 0.136 0.0 0.792
Price of a 3-minute fixed telephone
local call 168 0.114 0.094 0.014 0.774
Price of 3-minute mobile local call 170 0.498 0.476 0.0 1.853
Personal computers per head 134 0.012 0.017 0.0 0.081
Internet users per head 170 0.012 0.025 0.0 0.175
GDP per head (current US dollar) 190 1,207 1,816 97 14,320
Number of deposits per head 190 0.064 0.129 0.0 0.739
Number of loans per head 190 0.011 0.024 0.0 0.125
Private credit to GDP 185 0.170 0.151 0.020 0.712
44

Variables/Correlation coefficients (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16)

Real GDP growth (1) 1.00

Log of real GDP (2) -0.03 1.00

Primary school enrollment rates (3) 0.13 0.08 1.00

Government consumption in percent of GDP (4) -0.12 -0.10 0.24 1.00

Inflation rate (5) -0.05 -0.04 -0.15 -0.06 1.00

Institutions (6) 0.06 -0.02 0.21 0.16 -0.12 1.00

Fixed telephone lines per head (7) 0.00 0.24 0.30 0.19 -0.17 0.51 1.00

Mobile telephone subscribers per head (8) 0.05 0.19 0.26 0.10 -0.19 0.29 0.60 1.00

Price of a 3-minute fixed telephone local call (9) -0.11 -0.22 -0.02 -0.09 -0.26 -0.13 -0.18 0.12 1.00

Price of 3-minute mobile local call (10) 0.00 0.23 0.18 -0.01 -0.22 0.15 0.16 0.32 0.02 1.00

Personal computers per head (11) 0.01 0.27 0.27 0.21 -0.19 0.46 0.71 0.57 -0.02 0.07 1.00

Internet users per head (12) 0.00 0.24 0.26 0.12 -0.17 0.28 0.62 0.83 0.09 0.22 0.61 1.00

GDP per capita (current US dollars) (13) 0.15 0.23 0.36 0.10 -0.18 0.26 0.64 0.62 0.00 0.21 0.43 0.41 1.00

Number of deposits per head (14) 0.04 0.13 0.23 0.11 -0.07 0.57 0.63 0.22 -0.23 -0.05 0.39 0.28 0.31 1.00

Number of loans per head (15) 0.03 0.15 0.24 0.13 -0.07 0.63 0.63 0.23 -0.21 0.02 0.52 0.29 0.33 0.92 1.00

Private credit to GDP (16) -0.12 0.46 0.21 0.27 -0.22 0.36 0.65 0.38 -0.18 0.12 0.54 0.44 0.32 0.55 0.62 1.00
45

Appendix 3. Variable Definitions and Sources


Variables Definitions Sources

Real GDP growth Annual change in real GDP

Log of real GDP Logarithm of real GDP

Ratio of total enrollment in primary schools to the


Primary school enrollment rates population of the age group that officially
corresponds to that level of education Word Development Indicators and
International Financial Statistics
Government consumption in percent of GDP Government current expenditure as a share of GDP

Inflation rate Annual change in Consumer Price Index

GDP per capita (current US dollar) Nominal GDP divided by total population

Inverse of the average value of political right index


Institutions Freedom House
and civil liberty index

The ratio of fixed-line subscribers to total


Fixed telephone lines per head
population

Mobile telephone subscribers per head Mobile telephone subscribers divided by total
popualtion
Price of a 3-minute fixed telephone local call (peak
Price of a 3-minute fixed telephone local call
rate - US$)
International Telecommunication
Union
Price of 3-minute mobile local call Mobile cellular - price of 3-minute local call (peak -
US$)
Number of personal computers divided by total
Personal computers per head
population

Number of people with access to the worldwide


Internet users per head
network divided by total population

Private credit by deposit money banks as share of Financial Structure Database (World
Private credit/GDP
GDP Bank)

Number of deposits by commercial banks,


cooperatives, specialized state financial
Number of deposits per head
institutions, and microfinance institutions divided
by total adult population
CGAP (2009); Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt,
and Martinez Peria (2007)
Number of loans by commercial banks,
cooperatives, specialized state financial
Number of loans per head
institutions, and microfinance institutions divided
by total adult population

You might also like