Unit 5
Unit 5
Unit 5
MEIJI RESTORATION
Structure
5.0 Objectives
5.1 Introduction
5.2 Feudalism in Japan : 1600-1868 (the Tokugawa Era)
5.2.1 Economic and Political Structure
5.2.2 The Agrarian Basis--Rent and Tax
5.2.3 Structute of the Japanese Village
~ v i l u t i o nand Change under the Tokugawa Peace
5.3.1 Specialisation and the Growth of Exchange
5.34 Sankin-Kotai and the Merchant Class
5.3.3 Rise in Productivity-Sources and Effects
The Question of the Burden on €he Peasantry and Indices of Peasant
Discontent
The Impact of the West on Japan
Let Us Sum Up
Key Words
Some Useful Books
AnswedHints to Check Your Progress Exercises
5.0 OBJECTIVES
5.1 INTRODUCTION
The origins of Japanese feudalism go back to the 8th century A.D. We take
up the story however, only in 1600, when the Battle d Sekigahara was
fought, in which Tokugawa Iyeyasu led a confederation of clans to victory
against an opposition coalition of clans and established the Tokugawa
Shogunate (or Regency) in 1603 which was to rule Japan for the next two
and a half centuries. The clans which had fought alongside Tokugawa were
known as the fudai while those which had comprised the opposition were the
tozama or 'outside' hans.
About 75 t o 80 per cent of the total cultivated area was under the various
hans of the daimyo while the remaining 20 to 25 per cent was under the
direct control of the shogunate, a part being assigned for the maintenance of
the Emperor's establishment. Although the titular head and sovereign in
Japanese society, the Emperor was in practice powerless and led a shadowy
existence surrounded by the kuge or nobles of ancient lineage, in Kyoto. The
Tokugawa ruled in the Emperor's name from the capital city, Edo (known as
Tokyo in modern times), through the Bakufu (loosely translated as 'military
dictatorship'). The Shogunate maintained its own troops, known as hatamoto
out of the rent-cum-tax collected from its territories.
The samurai class was quite numerous, making up 6 t o 7 per cent of the
population: while if the other members of the ruling class and their personal
retainers are added, some 9 t o 10 per cent of the population can be said at
that time to be engaged in no productive work contributing to material
output. The remaining 10 per cent of the non-peasant population was made
nn nf artisans a n d merchants. ranging from the small-scale pedlars t o the
Feudaksociety in Japan was characterised by a very rigid hierarchy. Only the Japan on the Eve o f
the Meiji Resloration
ruling classes-the nobility headed by Shogun and Emperor, and the warrior
class of Samurai-had any social status and political rights within the
system. Merchants, artisans, peasants and those providing services were
without any political rights and were assigned a very low social status. The
formal division under the Tokugawa was into four classes by rank (known as
the shi-no-ko-sho structure), considering the population other than the
Emperor, Shogun and diamyo: shi referred to the samurai, no to the
peasants, ko to the artisans and manufacturers, and sho to the merchants.
Beneath these four-groups however there were further divisions of people
considered so 'sub-human' such that they were not fitted into the formal
categories: these were termed the 'hinin' o r literally, non-people, and below
them in turn were the burakumin or outcastes who were the ethnic Japanese.
None other than the daimyo and samurai were permitted to carry arms.
Although the daimyo obtained their feudal revenue in the form of rice, they
naturally needed to convert a part of it into cash for purchasing their
requirements of manufactured goods. Quite a substantial part of their rice
revenue was distributed in kind as stipends to their samurai, from whose
ranks the han administrative staff were also drawn. The remainder was partly
retained for consumption and the bulk was sold to merchants. Under the
Tokugawa, periodic surveys were carried out at intervals of several decades,
to estimate the area under rice and its yield per cho (one cho equalled 2.45
acres). Half of the estimated rice output was taken as the rent-yielding
capacity. Each han therefore had an estimated revenue measured in physical
volume units of rice (the Koku, dqual t o 4.96 bushels). The size and
importance of a han was measured by this index. While the average han
enjoyed about 10,000-Koku of revenue, Satsuma, one of the largest hans, had
70,000 Koku in rice revenue.
The rise in productivity in agriculture which occurred during the later part of
the era meant that as a proportion of the actual rice output, revenue t o the
daimyo was declining below the fifty per cent estimated on the basis of
earlier, lower levels of production. This enfailed certain economic
consequences which are discussed in sub-section 5.3.3.
The jinushi were generally sufficiently well-off not to cultivate the land with
their own manual labour, but employed the labour of farm servants in
various forms of tied or bonded status (the fudai and genin), or gave their
land and sometimes also livestock and implements, to poorer peasants from
the kosaku lacking both, in return for labour services provided'by these
customary tenants or nago. The output was then shared in a proportion
highly favourable to the jinushi.
Among the kosaku there were those medium scale holders of land who
possessed enough implements and land to cultivate on an independent basis.
Large numbers of the kosaku however had too little land to be able to obtain
a subsistence. They were obliged to take some land as tenants (nago) from
the better off cultivator in return for the performance of labour services ih
cultivating the land retained by the jinushi and sometimes they also used the
latter's equipment. The poorest households provided the genin or farm
servants working for life for the richer households, and in times of harvest
failure the very poorest were obliged even to sell their children as slaves th
the latter. This was probably the origin of the fudai who had the status
virtually of slaves in the hereditary service of the richer households.
Although the system was a paterhalistic one based on personal relationships,
and the children of the genin and fudai grew up with their master's children, Jspm on the Eve of
the Meljl Restoration
the basis for the system was ultimately the unequal distribution of land
within the village. With the growth of production for the market, the
dominant households in the village had an advantageous position and
developed capitalist type operations as we will discuss in sub-section 5.3.3.
The burden of payment of the rice rent-cum-tax imposed on the village as a
whole was distributed over the households in proportion to the land they
cultivated. This p.rocess is likely to have been regressive in the sense of
imposing a larger relative burden on the small peasants, because the
dominant families in the village were in a strong position to conceal the
actual extent of land under them and to give underestimates of their
production to the officials during the surveys.
..................................................................................................................
i
3) Write a brief note on the agrarian relations during the Totugawa era.
Eammie History of JapabI
5.3 EVOLUTION UNDER THE TOKUGAWA PEACE
The period 1600-1858 was marked by relative peace. Hence the term
'Tokugawa Peace'. This period witnessed increased specialisation and
productions for the market which gradually eroded the self-sufficient han
economy. Also, the old feudal set-up, while retaining its rigid, hierarchical
social structure, was changing to give rise to new powerful economic
categories from the socially backward strata. Let us now look at all these
issues in a greater detail.
The source of information for changes in the cropping pattern, input use and
yields for the 18th century are the detailed farm budget records kept by the
literate section of the village population, namely the leading landholders
controlling the bulk of the area. These records provide valuable insights into
the nature of technical changes taking place in agriculture as well.
It appears that the position of all those who employed the labour of others
in production, not only in agriculture but also in other sectors, must have
improved substantially owing to the inflationary trend in the Tokugawa
period. Rice prices rose more than 11 times between 1620 and 1850, mainly
owing to the successive debasements of the currency which were undertaken
by the Shogunate to meet recurrent financial crises. These crises arose owing
to the fact that revenues from customs were non-existent and from excise
very low, so the predominant source remained agricultural production, which
could show periodic downturn thus reducing $ate revenue which was a share
of the output.
Brewing of 'sake', an alcoholic drink made from rice, was another important
activity. A rural dispersion of textile manufacturing and other activities thus
marked the later half of the Tokugawa era. Artisans continued to engage in
t m v t i l m n~ncliirtinnin +he mainl cities. oarticularlv to meet the requirements of
the aristocracy for fine silks and brocades. But the increasing demand arising Japan on the Eve of
the Meiji Restoration
from the prosperity of the chonin (merchants) and the rural minority of well-
to-do, was met through the development of an extensive 'domestio' or
'putting-out system' under which the merchants financed production by
village cultivators-cum-artisans to whom they gave out the raw materials for
spinning and weaving, or to whom they advanced cash for purchasing raw
materials.
To sum up, a series of changes were taking place-a larger area under
irrigation, more output of irrigattd crops, higher yields from land owing to
this factor and to more intensive use of commercial manures and labour, and
higher labour productivity. The net effect was to raise land productivity
considerably; the rate of rent-cum-tax however continued to be estimated on
the basis of earlier, lower levels of rice production.
................................................. ...............................................................
u
Even though the land rent-cum-tax as a proportion of the (rising) rice output
was declining, the benefits of this does not seem to have gone to the majority
of the peasants who operated medium and small holdings. Rather it was the
better-off minority in rural areas who enriched themselves and went ih'for
rural entrepreneurship as we have seen.
The second form of resistance was peasant revolts. These were quite frequent
and took the form of attacks on money-lenders and o n landlords, the
burning of documentary evidence relating to indebtedness and attacks aimed
at corrupt officials. There were 71 separate cases of peasant jacqueries in
different provinces during the period 1844 t o 1859 alone. Over t h e entire
period of Tokugawa rule more than 600 peasant uprisings took place.
The position of the poorer section of the peasantry was worsened by the
tendency towards greater concentration of land ownership which is clear
from the records. The price inflation contributed t o this, for those poorer
cultivators who did not produce enough rice for their needs and had t o
purchase it o n the market using wages earned through labour, found it
difficult t o make ends meet. They borrowed and on failure t o repay the use
of the land in their possession, passed to their creditors. They themselves
became tenants of their creditors who were often the leading landholders of
the village.
The Western powers' drive during the first half of the 19th century t o acquire
colonial territories in Asia was aimed mainly at India and China, both
populous countries with rich natural resources and ancient civilisations.
Japan was a far less attractive prize from the Western point of view. The
Japanese feudal aristocracy had the advantage of learning from the unhappy
experience of the other Asian countries, and they could see the tide of
Western domination approaching closer while themselves being subject t o
The highly educated section of the Japanese nobility mainly belonging to the Japan on t h Eve 0;
tozama han and the ronin among the samurai, learnt of Asian developments tbe M ~ URestoratloo
I
at the same time that they read books o n 'western science'. They saw most of
India by the 1820s passing under the control of the British East India
Company, which seized Rangoon in 1819 and embarked o n the annexation
of Burma. An illegal trade in opium grown in India was carried on by the -.
British with China despite the Chinese imperial ban o n such trade. When the
ban was sought t o be implemented seriously, Britain launched the Opium
Wars from 1842 to 1844 t o bombard with warships the Chinese ports like
Canton, and forcibly opened them t o trade. Since Japan was so near the
Chinese mainland, the opium wars and British victory particularly worried
the Japanese aristocracy, t o whom it was clear that Japan's turn could not
I
I
be far off once China was colonised. The Unequal Treaties which the
I
Chinese feudal regime'was forced t o sign, resulted in the ceding of Shang
Jian (mispronounced Hong Kong ever since) t o the British, the granting of I
I
'extraterritoriality' (foreigners in the Treaty ports were not subject t o Chinese
law), and began the process of the major western powers 'vying t o carve u p
China into their spheres of influence. Apart from the European powers, the
USA too had launched an expansion across the Pacific, seeking to obtain
refuelling facilities in countries like Japan with the main objective being the
vast Chinese market.
The unequal treaties obliged Japan t o turn herself into an open economy,
through a clause which forbade her t o raise tariffs above 3 per cent. In the
Treaty ports the foreigners were not subject t o Japanese law,
('extraterritoriality rights'), as in the case of the Chinese treaty ports. The
Treaties were extremely unpopular within Japan and the fact that the Bakufu
was obllged t o sign them, exposed its bankruptcy t o the Japanese people.
Japan was fortunate however that a sustained effort by the Western powers
either singly or in combinadon, t o colonise her, did not take place during the
crucial decade 1858-1868. For during this time the Bakufu was tottering,
internal movements for change had not emerged in a c o t :rent form, and any
hypothetical Western military assault o n Japan at this time would certainly
have led t o he^ political subjugation. A very important period of grace was
provided by the international conjuncture. The great rebellion in India, 1857-
59 (which Britain called 'the Mutiny' and the Indians later called their First
War of Independence) kept the British occupied, as did the consolidation of
their position in China. Before that the Crimean War of 1854 had absorbed a
great deal of British military energies. France was busy colonising Vietnam
and was also tied down in Mexico. The USA could not follow up its initial
lead vis-a-vis Japan owing to the outbreak of its long and bloody civil war
from 1861 which effectively diverted its attention from foreign expansionism
for some time.
All that the Western powers could d o in Japan, given this background, was
to mount a few small scale naval expeditions which fired on Japanese ports
bonomk Hbtory 01 ~apan-I and had the effect of galvanising a section of the anti-Shogunate nobility into
mobilising for far-reaching political and structural change. In the summer of
1863 a British fleet shelled Satsuma han and burnt to the ground one third of
Kagoshima, its main port. In 1864 the han leaders of Choshu closed the
Shimonoseki Straits to foreign shipping and in punitive retaliation a joint
force of the British, Dutch, French and Americans shelled Choshu heavily.
The superior firepower of the Western imperialists convinced the leaders of
Satsuma and Choshu that Japanese capitulation was-inevitable unless Japan
modernised militarily, a necessary condition for which was industrialisation,
which lay behind the West's apparent invincibility. It was also clear to them
that industrialisation a d modernisation was not possible within the existing
I
S
feudal political and ec nomic structure.
I
The number of peasant revolts increased markedly during this period. A total
of 86 cases of pea$ant uprisings in different parts of the country are recorded
during 1860-67 compared t o 71 during the period 1844-59 according to
Kokusho Iwao, and 600 during the 265 years of Tokugawa rule.
Towards the end of 1867 both the old Emperor as well as the Shogun passed
away from natural causes. This provided the opportunity for a shift in the
locus of power without civil war. The heir to the Shogun was a minor and
was persuaded to step aside for the nominal restoration of the young
Emperor, itr 1868, but real power passed to a group of noble statesmen of
the erstwhile tozama han aided by able samurai and supported financially by
the great merchant.house like Mitsui. The reign of the new Emperor was
termedLMeiji, hence the term 'Meiji Restoration' to denote this event. The
reign of the Emperor Meiji' was to last from 1869 to 1912, a period which
saw Japan emerge as an industrialising economy and an aggressively
expansionist State recognised by the Western powers as a force to reckon
with.
..................................................................................................................
2) Why were the Western powers unable to colonise Japan?
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
3) Why is the 'Opium War* so called?
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
4) Briefly discuss the term 'Meiji Restoration*.
The year 1868 marked the beginning of the era of modernisation in Japan.
This unit dealt with pre-modern Japan starting from the year 1600 when the
Battle of Sekigahara was fought initiating the Tokugawa Shogunate. Feudal
Japan had a rigid hierarchical social structure. Appropriation of the
agricultural surplus by the ruling class formed its economic base. The ruling
class consisted of the Shogunate, and the daimyo who maintained the
samurai. They exacted rent amounting t o half of gross rice output from the
peasantry which was the most numerous class with a low status. Even lower
were the merchants and the artisans. At the bottom were the burakumin or
outcastes. On a geographical basis, .Japan'was divided into over 200 hans
each under the control of a daimyo.
The self-sufficiency of the feudal economy in the 17th century gave way to
increasing specialisation in production in the 18th century modifying the
agrarian relations based on tradition and custom towards more impersonal
and contractual relations. This period also witnessed an increase in economic
inequality between the owners of labour and property. However, status still
continued to be determined by rigid feudal hierarchy.. Thus the merchants
fPhnn;n\ incnite nf their epnnnmir nrncnerit~rernnineA inferinr tn the
conomic History of Japan4 During the Tokugawa era, the emperor was virtually power less and the
Tokugawas were de facto rulers. The clans which had fought alongside
Tokugawa in 1600 were known as the fudai. The tozama daimyos comprised
the opposition in the Battle of Sekigahara. T o maintain control over the
daimyos, particularly the Tozamas, the Tokugawa Shogunate created a
system known as Sankin Kotai so as to discourage revolt by the daimyo.
This system indirectly accelerated the pace of economic development through
an improvement in transport and communications and by developing the
financial and the banking system. Agrarian productivity also rose from the
mid-18th century with increasing cropped area coming under irrigation, more
intensive use of commercial manures and labour and higher labour
productivity. This increase in productivity coupled with the increasing
proportion of post-rent-cum-tax to output retained by the landowners over
time led to the prosperity of the well-to-do minority of the landowners who
invested their surplus in agrobased processing and in setting up industries.
There emerged in the village economic scene a new category of landed
entrepreneurs called oyakata.
However, the majority of peasants operating medium and small farms could
not reap the benefits of a declining land rent-cum-tax as a proportion of the
rising agricultural output-especially rice. A marked rise in economic
hequality within the agrarian structure led to peasant discontent, often
manifested in peasant revolts. They formed a politically mobilisable force
which supported the moves for a change in the old feudal order.
The impact of the West was also conducive to a change in the old feudal
order. Unlike in the case of China and India, the Western powers were
unable to convert Japan into their colony. The USA was the first country to
make an attempt to penetrate Japan commercially in 1853. The other powers
to follow suit and impose a series of Unequal Treaties were Holland, Russia,
Britain and France. These treaties led t o the opening up of the Japanese
economy leading to the unrestricted entry of manufactured goods from abroad
after 1858 causing domestic unemployment and export of raw materials and
agricultural goods leading to a steep rise in the domestic prices. Peasant
unrest, as a result, gathered momentum. The Tokugawa was the Japanese
partner to the Unequal Treaty. The Emperor, who virtually enjoyed no
power in the Tokugawa era generated massive patriotic feeling by refusing to
ratify the I858 Unequal Treaty with the USA, In 1867, both the old Emperor
and the Shogun passed away leading to a nominal restoration of the
Emperor with the real power at the hands of the tozama han. The reign of
the new Emperor was termed Meiji, hence the term Meiji Restoration.