CSR in The Auto Industry: Do The First-Tier Suppliers Have Stakeholders?
CSR in The Auto Industry: Do The First-Tier Suppliers Have Stakeholders?
CSR in The Auto Industry: Do The First-Tier Suppliers Have Stakeholders?
net/publication/251573946
CITATIONS READS
5 2,629
1 author:
Vincent Frigant
University of Bordeaux
139 PUBLICATIONS 1,074 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
Analysis of the adoption of the new automobile modular platforms View project
All content following this page was uploaded by Vincent Frigant on 01 May 2019.
Vincent Frigant
GERPISA & GREThA-UMR CNRS 5113
University of Bordeaux, France
E-mail: [email protected]
1 Introduction
A key element in the automotive industry’s agenda is the adoption of socially responsible
practices (CARS 21, 2006). Regularly denounced as the one of the most polluting of all
economic activities, particularly with its products’ greenhouse gas emissions, the sector
intends to regain its virtue by developing products that are clean(er), increasing its
recycling rate and improving its manufacturing processes’ environmental performance.
With respect to the social dimension of Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR), the
agenda is one of improving road safety and, in car-manufacturing countries, protecting
jobs as well as the wage-labour nexus.
Each of these elements is already complicated enough when dealt with individually,
but the possible contradictions between their various sub-objectives make them even
harder to resolve collectively. For example, improving vehicle safety often means
increasing a car’s weight, thus increasing its petrol consumption, which can be
damaging to the environment. Another source of complexity is that many different
actors (companies, state authorities, civil society) are involved in the creation of a
responsible industry, with each focusing on different and not necessarily compatible
issues and intervening at different levels of analysis (micro-, meso- and macro-economic)
(Jullien, 2008). Boyer and Freyssenet (2002) have shown that automakers’ profit
strategies should be understood in the light of the articulation between the various
levels involved. The automotive industry forms a system (Lung, 2004) – its transition to
sustainability can only be understood after its constituents’ actions are analysed.
This is the framework for the present article, which proposes studying first-tier
automotive suppliers and clarifying their CSR positioning. Two series of reasons justify
focusing on these firms. The trend towards (qualitative and quantitative) externalisation,
which has accelerated since the late 1980s, means that suppliers have become a real
focal point in the automotive value chain (Volpato, 2004; Frigant, 2009). De facto, they
are responsible for a large share of the jobs and revenues produced by this branch.
Ignoring first-tier suppliers would mean neglecting many of today’s employment-related
challenges. In addition (and also derived from externalisation), the rise of modularity
in the automotive sector (Sako, 2003; Fujimoto, 2007) has triggered a technological
transfer towards suppliers who control key technologies. Many modules have become
‘grey box modules’ for automakers (Morris and Donnelly, 2006). Environmental or
safety technologies may well fit into this category.
The objective here is to analyse the motivations that could induce first-tier suppliers
to commit to socially responsible practices in terms of a triple bottom line delineated into
economic, environmental and social/societal terms. Without any pretence of exclusivity,
the stakeholder approach remains the most widespread explanation for the transition
to CSR. Section 2 recalls the essential principles of this theory and why it is used.
The subsequent sections assess how stakeholders like customers, civil society,
employees and states may or may not become catalysts for first-tier automotive suppliers’
shift to CSR. The final section will revisit the intrinsic limitations of the stakeholder
construct to understand the dynamics of the shift to CSR when applied to
subcontractor companies.
Even the stakeholder approach that dominates the literature in this domain
suffers from theoretical eclecticism (Aggeri and Acquier, 2005). However, it is a
relatively operational heuristic framework. It can be considered as a converging
framework for different types of works or a research tradition (Trevino and Weaver,
1999). For these authors, the stakeholder approach is a useful way to examine the CSR
strategy because it allows taking into account many (potential) actors and problems. It is
in this sense that the stakeholder construct will be envisioned here – as justified by its
relevance to our initial line of questioning (i.e., which factors induce a given behaviour),
to the extent that this research tradition is both logically coherent and pragmatic.
If it can be assumed that firms determine objectives only after incorporating all of the
actors that are apt to influence them, this approach can be considered coherent since
it posits a functional relationship between a firm’s actions and the objectives and risks
carried by the actors it has identified. In other words, it enables a linkage between actions
and actors and, therefore, rationalises behaviours that are not directly related to firms’
prime objective, which is to make money. In this sense, by expanding the number
of actors that are important to the firm, it helps explain why profit maximisation is not
only not the sole objective of a firm, but also why (functionally) this cannot be
the case, contrary to what Friedman or, more recently, Henderson (2001) have said.
The hypothesis that the interests of actors other than shareholders should be integrated
into the firm’s objectives to ensure its survival (Freeman, 1984) justifies executives’
strategic adoption of socially responsible behaviour.
The approach also wants to be pragmatic (Trevino and Weaver, 1999) in that
identifying and ranking stakeholders and their objectives is substantively related to a
micro-economic approach that is specific to one firm. Each company must diagnose its
own activities, visibility and which actors it considers important. It is true that many
typologies have been proposed to tighten up the stakeholder construct or help corporate
executives identify and rank stakeholders (Caroll, 1989; Clarkson, 1995; Mitchell et al.,
1997). Even though they suggest a more or less unified approach, the truth is that any of
the choices being made will be highly idiosyncratic.
Certain forms of organisational imitation clearly do exist. Indeed, imitative behaviour
is to be expected from organisations facing radical uncertainty. CSR implementation
fits this bill. It is a revolutionary innovation and little is known about its application
or internal and external prospects. As DiMaggio and Powell (1983) have shown,
organisations are increasingly engaging in convergent practices rooted in the three
constitutive mechanisms of CSR:
1 imitation of other sectorial actors – the ‘Porter hypothesis’ that CSR practices could
be a source of competitive advantage would mean that, unsure of whether this is true
or not, some firms will seek to minimise risk by simply imitating their rivals
2 consultants’ influence on executives – the diffusion of the aforementioned typologies
has contributed to this process, much in the same way as CSR marketing consultancy
has expanded considerably in recent years or because the leading benchmarks of
responsible management (like the Global Reporting Initiative or the UN Global
Compact) are explicitly rooted in a stakeholder approach
3 the influence of a state’s interventions that define the rules of the game within
which (and with which) firms try to define a strategic space for themselves and make
decisions – of course, the public sphere, in line with its role as representative of the
380 V. Frigant
general interest, has become increasingly involved in defining norms in social areas
(relating to safety, for instance) or environmental ones (e.g., CO2 emission standards
in the fight against greenhouse gases and/or attempts to re-internalise certain external
effects, like the creation of a market in polluting rights).
Therefore, it can be argued that the three preceding mechanisms play out in a way that
defines the forms of imitation at a sectorial level. These mechanisms help homogenise
within any sector answers to questions like who the important stakeholders are and what
they want. Thus, stakeholders’ identities and rankings can be expected to converge
somewhat in firms operating in similar institutional contexts and sectors. Considering that
automotive suppliers constitute a group of homogeneous firms in that they face more or
less analogous problems, it is not unreasonable to postulate that they deal with similar
stakeholders. More than an imitation of concrete practices, what is important is to explore
the hypothesis that an evidential link exists between the two crucial questions of who the
important stakeholders are and what they want.
To examine the robustness of this hypothesis, the text considers the five stakeholder
groups that have been traditionally identified in the literature and examines how each
might induce suppliers to commit to socially responsible practices that reconcile
economic, social and environmental performance (triple bottom line).
The stakeholder literature often highlights the figure of the customer as a crucial driver in
the shift towards responsible practices. In this view, companies become responsible
because they anticipate or respond to the desires of consumers who want to engage
in civic-minded purchasing and refuse to accept brands whose production methods
do not satisfy minimal social or environmental criteria. These kinds of studies often cite
examples of companies whose economic success derives from the ease with which
they came up with socially responsible products or services or, conversely, companies
damaged by consumer boycotts. Cases like those of The Body Shop, Ben & Jerry’s or,
conversely, Nike are often used. Yet many observers like Vogel (2005) are not entirely
convinced of the economic power of civic-minded consumers. In his view, customers
cannot be the main forces driving automotive equipment producers on the path of a
modicum of virtue.
A first level of argument relates to the difficulties in identifying automotive suppliers’
customers. There is an ambiguity about whether these customers are the automakers to
whom suppliers sell their modules and systems on an Original Equipment Manufacturer
(OEM) basis or else, users (vehicle drivers and passengers). The suppliers’ position is
even harder to ascertain, given that some of the equipment that they produce has a
life span corresponding, under normal driving conditions, to the life span of the
final product (e.g., seats), whereas other equipment wear out much earlier (e.g., tyres,
for which most revenues and profits come from post-OEM sales). The question of which
parties the suppliers are dealing with most directly is all the more complicated because,
like all subcontractors, they often operate in more than one sector. For example, Bosch,
the world’s leading automotive supplier is also very present in consumer durables
(tools and appliances).
CSR in the auto industry: do the first-tier suppliers have stakeholders? 381
The French supplier Valeo and its CEO, T. Morin, are some of the strongest advocates for more
stringent regulations:
“Thierry Morin considers the abatement of emissions to be absolutely
indispensable and does not share the opinion of Manuel Gomez (President of
the French Automaker Committee) according to whom lawmakers should
abstain from creating any new obligations in this area. Quite the contrary,
Mr. Morin feels that lawmakers should bring further environmental pressure
to bear, since this is the only way to force industrialists to make further
progress in this domain (…) Mr. Morin has feels that suppliers are in a
position today to cut vehicles’ energy consumption in half (…).” (Audience
with T. Morin, CEO of Valeo, French Senate Commission on Economic
Affairs, quoted in Cornu, 2007, p.35)
Recently, T. Morin said that:
“Higher oil prices are good for Valeo and cost us less than we make from
sales growth (…) The more energy prices rise, the better our products sell.”
(http://www.autoactu.com, accessed 24 June 2008)
Moreover, even where a big spare parts market exists, the users themselves rarely
prescribe replacements. The true purchasing decision makers are repair shops and
dealerships rather than end users. As long as repair shops do not set up labels for
‘components sourced from socially responsible companies’, there is no real reason for
suppliers to acknowledge users as true stakeholders. This minimal visibility also applies
to civil society.
4 Civil society
the technological solutions that could help advance activists’ causes (i.e., energy
savings). It is as if social activists are unable or unwilling to look beyond the branch’s
downstream activities.4 This suggests that they have little power to affect opinion.
Ultimately, suppliers have been left relatively untouched by social criticism.
On the few occasions when they have been identified, there was a minimal effect on
sales. To impact those suppliers who get most of their revenue from the OEM trade,
pressure would have to be placed on automakers. In other words, effective targeting
would require in-depth knowledge of who buys what from whom. This is feasible
where information exists (i.e., the Automotive News’ Car Cutaways section), but it would
involve costly and painstaking efforts that could only be justified if the stakes were
high (i.e., if a big environmental accident happened, in the case of child labour). On the
contrary, imagine that some organisations identify a particularly remarkable responsible
supplier. Can we imagine that they would lobby automakers to oblige them to select
this one? It seems terribly optimistic.
Of course, another possibility would be for social activists to set up coalitions
with unions.
Most of the suppliers whose CSR discourse has been examined for the purposes of the
present paper view their employees are full-fledged stakeholders. The social reports that
they have drafted emphasise their efforts to create greater involvement and get staff
members to increase productivity by training them to save resources (environmental
awareness days, often organised as part of an ISO 14001 certification process), develop
better working conditions and keep industrial accidents to a minimum. There are two
ways to explain such practices.
Firstly, studies have demonstrated that recruits might discriminate amongst
companies, depending on their level of CSR commitment. This means that proactively
engaging in responsible policies will help a company attract the best employees or
recruit people more easily at times when conditions are tight in the labour market
(Greening and Turban, 2000). This is relevant to the automotive suppliers in two very
different situations: when recruiting top-level executives who have in general relatively
little appetite for a career in industry or prefer more well-reputed firms like automakers or
when recruiting less qualified workers in saturated employment zones like some parts of
Eastern Europe – although having said that, environmentally or socially friendly policies
will have less of an effect than higher wages or payments in kind (like commuter buses).
Despite the undoubted attractiveness effect identified in Greening and Turban’s
(2000) study, job security remains the main concern for most employees. As noted in
Section 3, many suppliers have worked hard over the past two years to redefine the
scope of their activities and restructure the geography of their productive apparatus.
Globally, the results of these efforts are a net transfer of employees from industrialised
to low-cost countries. Some suppliers are aware that this turn of events contradicts their
discourse on social responsibility. The French supplier Faurecia, in its 2007 annual
report,5 began a chapter entitled ‘Deepening the social dialogue’ with a comment about
“slowing down its industrial and social redeployment”. Faurecia viewed this action as a
CSR in the auto industry: do the first-tier suppliers have stakeholders? 385
positive indication of its devotion to CSR, before going on to explain that “in 2007
the group continued the industrial redeployment it needed to remain competitive”.
The implication is that the aforementioned slowdown was less a reflection of
Faurecia’s desire to treat its employees ‘socially’ and more a sign that it had exhausted
opportunities overseas (or its need to make adjustments). Treating employees as
full-fledged stakeholders would mean protecting current employees’ jobs. Instead of this
– and because they are subject to heavy profitability constraints – suppliers’ main
concerns have been to reduce staffing in the developed world and deeply modify their
Work Models (Krzywdzinski, 2008; Jürgens and Krzywdzinski, 2008).
A second way to envisage the stakeholder role allocated to employees and their union
representatives is to assume that they themselves are the drivers behind their employers’
social responsibility agenda. Some unions (like Confédération Française Démocratique
du Travail (CFDT) or Confédération Générale du Travail (CGT) in France) have
appropriated the CSR issue, perceiving it as an opportunity to renew their discourse and
actions. In an era marked by a crisis of union representation, it is understandable that
they see this kind of commitment as a chance to work with new employees without
undermining their more traditional causes (e.g., the fight against delocalisation).
Such shifts can take the shape of an alliance with other stakeholders like NGOs,
consumer associations and/or academics. The European Coalition for Corporate Justice
offers a formal example of this kind of multiparty coalition.6
Of course, such a coalition could cause other problems. It can be difficult to
discern the compatibility of members’ interests. Conflicts can emerge between the
environmental aims of NGOs demanding the closure of industrial sites that are
considered bad polluters and unions whose main mission is to protect jobs. Sometimes
these conflicts can be internal and pit national versus local interest. In the early 1980s,
for example, at a time when the French arms industry was experiencing a crisis, there was
a flagrant disconnect between the national executive of a large antimilitary French union
and its regional branch, which was lobbying local authorities and politicians to support
increased arms spending and exports. The automotive industry’s mediocre image
amongst certain leading NGOs (like Greenpeace) suggests that this sort of conflict might
also become a factor where suppliers are concerned. In addition, automotive suppliers’
generally low unionisation levels make it less probable that unions can ever be expected
to catalyse corporate devotion to a CSR agenda.
Socially Responsible Investors (SRIs) in ethical or sustainability funds are actors that are
supposed to be able to get companies to adopt more responsible behaviour. There are two
ways in which they could do this: by exiting a firm or using their voice. ‘Exit’ refers
to the decision to take or divest an equity interest in a company. By purchasing a stake
in a firm reputed to be socially responsible, investors are helping increase demand for
its shares. Conversely, by exiting a firm with a reputation for irresponsibility, they are
putting downward pressure on its share price (opening the door to takeovers and/or
reducing yields), thereby weakening the position of current managers. A voice logic
holds that SRIs can (by submitting resolutions to the Annual Shareholders’ Meeting or
pressuring the Board of Directors) pressure managers into taking measures marked with a
CSR seal.
386 V. Frigant
Automotive suppliers are acceptable for ethical funds that function on a negative
screening basis (i.e., excluding economic activities that are considered irresponsible
like arms, tobacco, etc.). Therefore, it is worth studying their role, as well as the role of
sustainable development funds that invest in companies whose socially responsible
practices have received a positive assessment. This often involves the use of
social responsibility indices, some of which list leading automotive suppliers.7 However,
questions remain about suppliers’ sensitivity to these funds.
Firstly, the literature on socially responsible funds recalls that there is little hope of
ever seeing them fulfil an incentivising role since, despite SRIs’ rapid growth in recent
years, the capital at their disposal (especially in Europe) is small compared to the
financial markets’ size (Vogel, 2005). It is true that at a micro-economic level, SRI funds
can have some influence but, as Vogel pointed out, they only really get involved in the
most flagrant cases of social or environmental irresponsibility.
In addition to these traditional criticisms, there are two others that are specific
to automotive suppliers. Firstly, most socially responsible funds screen primarily
for financial performance. Criteria like environmental and social performance are mere
addenda used to discriminate amongst firms already selected for financial reasons.
Now, since 2000, automotive suppliers’ profitability has worsened steadily (Frigant,
2009). Several suppliers, including some of the biggest, have lost money for several years
now. These poor results basically mean that the sector only attracts speculative
investment funds and private equity. Investors in the latter category hope to achieve
big capital gains by in-depth restructuring and/or divest subsidiaries if and when an
opportunity arises. More than the pressure to become socially responsible to
please SRIs, the main worry for suppliers is their short-term profitability. This conflicts
with the idea of focusing on socially and ecologically responsible investments based on a
medium/long-term aspiration for higher dividends (Vogel, 2005).
Lastly, this is an industry with a heterogeneous capital structure. Family-run
companies (like Bosch) and supply subsidiaries of major firms (Faurecia, Denso,
Magneti Marelli, etc.) have retained a preponderant influence. Indeed, this may explain
why speculative funds are so interested in suppliers whose equity structure has not yet
been entirely locked up.
All in all, SRIs’ potential effect on suppliers seems to be more a question of their
desire to be viewed positively by certain indices or socially responsible ratings agencies.
Clearly, the limitations of these ratings and indices, in terms of their ability to really
measure the effectiveness of socially responsible practices (Vogel, 2005), explain why
it is difficult to guarantee the reality of these efforts. At the same time, they can
contribute to a performance-related approach or discourse whose effects may not be
entirely in vain (Aggeri and Godard, 2006). Seen from this angle, SRIs’ main virtue is
instrumental. It is more a consequence and a tool that justifies an approach that has been
chosen for other reasons than something implemented on its own merits.
State authorities can legitimately intervene in CSR debates insofar as these are
understood as the micro-economic materialisation of an overall sustainability approach.
Since the 1987 Brundtland Report, the international community and most states, at least
CSR in the auto industry: do the first-tier suppliers have stakeholders? 387
in the developed world, have dealt with this issue at a micro-economic level, as illustrated
by the highly emblematic Rio de Janeiro Earth Summit in 1992. At the corporate level,
states tend to intervene in two different ways: through incentives and constraints.
States officially offer incentives when they consider that socially responsible
practices should involve voluntary actions by companies, with their emergence and
development being encouraged via state-designed tools.8 Due to modern states’ minimal
powers of constraint and the global nature of these problems, the suggestion here is
that the design of any such incentivising instrument should be left to more supranational
institutions. Their main axis of intervention consists of defining benchmark
recommendations helping firms develop CSR practices and give them instruments to
pilot actions.9 One of the best-known frameworks for this is the Global Compact,
designed in part by the United Nations. Despite their lack of enforceability,10 these
benchmarks remain useful analytical matrices for companies, ‘instructing’ them on how
to apply CSR. Also, because support for these standards is public, they also allow firms
to position themselves vis-à-vis rivals and customers. In short, they help forge an image
of what a responsible company looks like and encourage CSR’s diffusion.
At the same time, because these standards are non-enforceable, people are more
or less free to apply them as they see fit. Some of the biggest names in the supply
industry adhere to the Global Compact and have drafted codes of conduct inspired
from it, but questions still remain about the effectiveness and homogeneity of their
practices. External audits are infrequent and have little effect. The real question is
how to compare companies with different activities. Automotive suppliers are not a
homogeneous group due to differences in their activities (and the scope thereof). It is
very hard to find two companies doing exactly the same thing (and nothing else) and
with the exact same degree of vertical integration. It is almost impossible to compare,
for instance, two suppliers’ energy consumption patterns without introducing any bias.
One solution would be to reason in variable and not absolute terms. The commitment to
CSR would then be defined as less annual energy consumption. Still, given the constant
(almost annual) horizontal and vertical redefinitions of suppliers’ perimeters of activity,
an improvement/deterioration in an indicator of this kind would not necessarily signify a
responsible or irresponsible attitude.11
Thus, because of the many problems caused by CSR practices’ heterogeneity
and despite states’ desire to allow companies to adapt their own socially responsible
practices, the authorities adopt some regulation instruments to impose a certain number
of practices. The idea here is not that they will impose all aspects of CSR standards,
but the aspects of those elements that they consider most salient. In fact, they do not
(cannot?) really want to do more. The states are afraid about the development of social
or environmental competition. Clearly, the power of any piece of legislation is limited
to the geographic jurisdiction where it applies. This is a problem because many
suppliers are multinational companies and we can imagine that they (partly) relocate
their plants towards some countries where the regulations would be less stringent.
That is why many states argue that the only way to engineer a massive shift to CSR is
to act globally. Another way to do: the multinational takes the initiative and decides to
become responsible.
Despite these hesitations, the automotive sector has been facing an intensification of
socially responsible regulation, including tighter environmental norms relating to product
usage (e.g., CO2 emissions) or end-of-life disposal (recycling). Other standards also apply
388 V. Frigant
to other industries and affect the production process in general. This includes regulations
covering volatile organic components or chemical molecules (the Registration,
Evaluation, Authorisation and Restriction of Chemicals (REACH) directive). At the
social/societal level, there has also been a tightening of safety standards for drivers and
passengers and other road users. At the intersection between these two aspects but on
a different subject, several European states, notably France with its New Economic
Regulations (NRE) laws, now impose certain forms of social reporting.
Analytically, such regulatory constraints are ambiguous. Given most of the
definitions found in the literature, CSR’s voluntary aspect implies that they are based
not on CSR, but on compliance. Firms need a license to operate. But this interpretation is
too restrictive. Indeed, we need to take dynamic organisational effects into account.
Firstly and concretely, compliance forces companies to design organisational
systems that broaden the practice of CSR. The REACH directive is one example of this.
The whole automobile branch is forced by this directive to design an information
collection and diffusion system. Several suppliers built a system logging the substances
and patched their subcontractors into it. A few trade associations (Fédération des
Industries des Equipements pour Véhicules (FIEV) in France, European Association of
Automotive Suppliers (CLEPA) at a European level) have set up explanation and
surveillance committees responsible for the directive’s application. Due to REACH,
information on substances is shared throughout the branch now, enhancing relations
between different subcontractor levels and helping actors face environmental problems
together. These relations might have been limited at first, but the hope now is that in the
future, they will go beyond mere compliance and generate real learning effects.
Secondly, regulation helps forge spaces where firms can develop their competitive
strategy. By tightening norms, state authorities have oriented the innovation process
towards cleaner/safer products made in ways that consume fewer resources and use
fewer dangerous substances. Suppliers’ competitive strategies are shifting towards greater
differentiation based not on costs, but on providing products that will help automakers
comply with the expected future regulations. In this sense, despite some industrialists’
reticence (CARS 21, 2006), a legislative orientation is triggering a competitive dynamic
in which actors will ‘front-run’ future regulations.
Thirdly, compliance with regulation enables internal mobilisation and reinforces a
company’s external visibility. From a managerial perspective, the successful application
of any given measure is predicated on employees adhering to it and understanding what is
at stake. It helps the company put its compliance approach into context and give it a
greater meaning. In a way, authorities become stakeholders in the original meaning of the
term since they get the company to go beyond initial recommendations and develop a
fuller context. This effect can also transcend the borders of the firm and become a tool
for external communication. For instance, the obligation for listed companies to set up
a societal reporting system introduced by France’s NRE laws has helped formalise
reporting practices and forced companies to develop internal indicators and information
systems. By doing so, it helps raise awareness within companies of their own internal
practices. Moreover, by enabling further examination of rival practices (via employees,
civil society and investment funds), it pressures executives to go even further.
This mobilising effect also has a retroactive aspect. Ramus and Steger (2000) have shown
that employees’ perception of a company’s level of commitment depends on its degree
CSR in the auto industry: do the first-tier suppliers have stakeholders? 389
8 Conclusion
The purpose of this article was to examine the hypothesis that automotive suppliers
are being pressured by stakeholders to make real commitments to the development of
CSR. In the end, strong doubts have been raised on this score. In reality, although
suppliers apply a stakeholder construct in their discourse and use it as a tool to trigger
CSR approaches, analysis suggests that stakeholders’ real influence is relative at best.
Some of our analyses have been quite general and fit in with the lessons of the CSR
literature (see Vogel, 2005). But, at the same time, it has also been demonstrated
that stakeholders’ lack of influence is often amplified when we consider auto suppliers.
The main explanation lies in the poor visibility that they derive from their status
as subcontractors.
An optimistic way to look at things would be to assume that stakeholders are not the
real drivers behind the shift to CSR. As Aggeri and Acquier (2005) said, the stakeholder
construct is not really useful in understanding why companies commit to CSR practices.
They took the case of the French cement maker Lafarge, which became involved in the
battle against AIDS in Africa for reasons that were solely economic and only sought
to involve stakeholders because it needed them for the purposes of this one battle.
The suggestion is that rather than looking to find stakeholders at any price, a greater
effort should be made to think about what complementarities might exist between social
responsibility and economic efficiency. Also, for some years, a lot of researches tried
to explain the possibility to conciliate profit and social responsibility (e.g., Schaltegger
and Wagner, 2006). But if these works are very interesting, we can note that there
are also big contradictions between these two dimensions. In fact, the present analysis
suggests that this type of reasoning should be supplemented on two different levels:
by considering the meso-economic dimension and identifying any contradictions between
CSR’s three dimensions (economic, environment, social).
A good example of this is the automotive supply chain which, for reasons of
economic performance, functions according to just-in-time and synchronous flow
delivery principles. To apply these principles while cutting manufacturing costs in more
generic production, suppliers have designed for their production sites a spatial system
combining proximity to automakers with distance based on localisation in low-cost
countries (Frigant and Layan, 2009). This spatial organisation may offer an efficient
response to productive and economic constraints, but it is also a problem for the
two other poles of the triple bottom line: the environment and society. Indeed, its
supply chains are extremely long and based almost only on road transportation.12
The environmental costs (greenhouse gases, noise pollution, infrastructure footprint, etc.)
and social costs (accidents, congestion, etc.) are important.
390 V. Frigant
This example demonstrates that thinking about the incentives for firms operating in
a subcontracting capacity to commit to truly responsible behaviour requires a broader
perspective and a bigger approach than one that is solely geared towards stakeholders.
There needs to be a holistic vision of all of the problems involving in organising a whole
industry (public policy, automaker/supplier relationships, trade unions’ positioning, etc.)
Clearly, such studies would be more complex than research aimed solely at identifying
‘stakeholders’. At the same time, an effort of this kind should turn out to be more
productive in the long-term. To understand how the automotive industry might one day
become socially responsible on both its upstream and downstream sides, analysis will
need to be carried out at a multitude of interlinked levels. Some new researches enacting
this vision are beginning (Jullien, 2008) and we are waiting for the results with hope.
References
Aggeri, F. and Acquier, A. (2005) ‘La théorie des stakeholders permet-elle de rendre compte
des pratiques d’entreprise en matière de RSE?’, XIVème conférence internationale en
Management Stratégique, AIMS, Angers.
Aggeri, F. and Godard, O. (2006) ‘Les entreprises et le développement durable’, Entreprises et
Histoire, No. 45, pp.6–19.
Aguilera, R.V., Rupp, D.E., Williams, C.A. and Ganapathi, J. (2007) ‘Putting the S back in
corporate social responsibility: a multilevel theory of social change in organization’, Academy
of Management Review, Vol. 32, No. 3, pp.836–863.
Boyer, R. and Freyssenet, M. (2002) The Productive Models. The Conditions for Profitability,
London/New York: Palgrave.
Capron, M. and Quairel-Lanoizelée, F. (2007) La responsabilité sociale d’entreprise, Paris:
La Découverte.
Caroll, A.B. (1989) Business and Society, Cincinnati: South Western Publishing.
Carrillo, J. and Contreras, O. (2007) ‘The historical evolution of American auto firms in Mexico’,
Proceedings of the 15th GERPISA International Colloquium, Paris, 20–22 June.
CARS 21 (2006) A Competitive Automotive Regulatory System for the 21st Century, Luxembourg:
European Commission, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities.
Clarkson, M. (1995) ‘A stakeholder framework for analyzing and evaluating corporate social
performance’, Academy Management Review, Vol. 20, No. 1, pp.92–117.
Commission of the European Communities (CEC) (2006) ‘Implementing the partnership for
growth and jobs: making Europe a pole of excellence on corporate social responsibility’,
COM(2006)136 Final, Brussels, 22 March.
Cornu, G. (2007) Rapport d’information de la commission des affaires économiques sur les défis
du secteur automobile, Sénat, Paris, http://www.senat.fr/rap/r06-254/r06-2541.pdf.
DiMaggio, P. and Powell, W. (1983) ‘The iron cage revisited: institutional isomorphism and
collective rationality in organizational fields’, American Sociological Review, Vol. 48, No. 2,
pp.147–160.
Domanski, B. and Lung, Y. (Eds.) (2009) ‘Special issue: the European periphery and the
automotive industry’, European Urban and Regional Studies, Vol. 16, No. 1, pp.5–63.
Freeman, R.E. (1984) Strategic Management: A Stakeholder Approach, Boston: Pitman.
Frigant, V. (2009) ‘Winners and losers in the auto parts industry: trajectories followed by the
main first tier suppliers over the past decade’, in M. Freyssenet (Ed.) The Second Automobile
Revolution. The Trajectories of Automobile Firms at the Beginning of the XXIth Century,
Houndmills/New York: Palgrave MacMillan, pp.419–442.
CSR in the auto industry: do the first-tier suppliers have stakeholders? 391
Frigant, V. and Layan, J.B. (2009) ‘Modular production and the new division of labour within
Europe: the perspective of French automotive parts suppliers’, European and Urban Regional
Studies, Vol. 16, No. 1, pp.11–15.
Fujimoto, T. (2007) ‘Architecture-based comparative advantage. A design information view of
manufacturing’, Evol. Inst. Econ. Review, Vol. 4, No. 1, pp.55–112.
Gond, J.P. (2008) ‘La responsabilité sociale de l’entreprise au-delà du fonctionnalisme:
un cadre d’analyse pluraliste de l’interface entreprise/société’, IIIème Journée de l’Atelier
Développement Durable de l’AIMS, ESDES, Lyon, 4 June.
Greening, D.W. and Turban, D.B. (2000) ‘Corporate social performance as a competitive
advantage in attracting a quality workforce’, Business and Society, Vol. 39, pp.254–280.
Greenpeace (2008) Les moteurs de dérèglement climatique, Greenpeace International, Amsterdam,
May, www.greenpeace.fr/moteurs-dereglement.
Henderson, D. (2001) Misguided Virtue: False Notions of Corporate Social Responsibility,
Institute of Economics Affairs, London.
Jullien, B. (2008) ‘A framework to enrich the scientific, political and managerial understanding
of sustainable development issues for the automotive industry: the GERPISA’s “tradeoffs
and synergies” approach’, Int. J. Automotive Technology and Management, Vol. 8, No. 4,
pp.469–492.
Jürgens, U. and Krzywdzinski, M. (2008) ‘Relocation and east-west competition: the case of the
European automotive industry’, Int. J. Automotive Technology and Management, Vol. 8,
No. 2, pp.145–169.
Krzywdzinski, M. (2008) ‘Work models under strain of offshoring east-west competition in
the European car industry’, Proceedings of the 16th GERPISA International Colloquium,
CERIS-CNR, Moncaliery (Turin), 18–20 June.
Layan, J.B. and Lung, Y. (2008) ‘Attractivité et agglomération de l’industrie automobile au
Maroc et en Tunisie: une analyse comparative’, Article présenté à la Journée Dynamiques
d’agglomération des activités productives et gouvernance territoriale, Tunis, 6–7 June.
Lung, Y. (2004) ‘The challenges of the European automotive industry at the beginning of the
21st century’, Working papers of GRES, 2004–2008, http://ideas.repec.org/p/grs/wpegrs/
2004-08.html.
Mitchell, R.K., Wood, J.D. and Agle, B.R. (1997) ‘Towards a theory of stakeholder identification
and salience: defining the principle of who and what really counts’, Academy of Management
Review, Vol. 22, No. 4, pp.853–887.
Morris, D. and Donnelly, T. (2006) ‘Are there market limits to modularisation?’, Int. J. Automotive
Technology and Management, Vol. 6, No. 3, pp.262–275.
Ramus, C.A. and Steger, U. (2000) ‘The roles of supervisory support behaviors and environmental
policy in employment “ecoinitiatives” at leading-edge European companies’, Academy of
Management Journal, Vol. 43, pp.605–626.
Sako, M. (2003) ‘Modularity and outsourcing: the nature of co-evolution of product architecture
and organisation architecture in the global automotive industry’, in A. Prencipe, A. Davies
and M. Hobday (Eds.) The Business of Systems Integration, Oxford: Oxford University Press,
pp.229–253.
Schaltegger, S. and Wagner, M. (Eds.) (2006) Managing the Business Case for Sustainability,
Sheffield: Greenleaf Publishing.
Trevino, L.K. and Weaver, G. (1999) ‘The stakeholder research tradition: converging theorists
– not converging theory’, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 24, No. 2, pp.222–227.
Valeo (2007) Document de référence, pp.58–60, http://www.valeo.com/fileadmin/dotcom/uploads/
archives/fr/document_de_reference_2007.pdf.
392 V. Frigant
Vogel, D. (2005) The Market for Virtue. The Potential and Limits of Corporate Social
Responsibility, Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Volpato, G. (2004) ‘The OEM-FTS relationship in automotive industry’, Int. J. Automotive
Technology and Management, Vol. 4, Nos. 2–3, pp.166–197.
Notes
1 PSA Peugeot-Citroën’s website reads:
“In 2005, the Purchasing Division drafted and validated an action plan for
2006-2007 with a view to checking supplier compliance with the Group’s
sustainable development requirements. The plan comprises the following
measures: 1) Supplier commitment to respecting the Group’s environmental
and social requirements, particularly the global framework agreement on the
corporate social responsibility of PSA Peugeot Citroën. 2) More in-depth
mapping of high-risk suppliers, and tracking procedures based on a
questionnaire to verify the compliance of suppliers identified as representing a
risk. 3) If necessary, organisation of an audit on the premises of these suppliers,
to set a corrective action plan.” (PSA, http://www.sustainability.psa-peugeot
-citroen.com/economic-performance/suppliers/actions-achievements/
top_priority.htm?id=1814, visited 06 June 2008)
Volkswagen has also developed ‘sustainability in supplier relations’:
“[It] involves the introduction of shared environmental and social standards
for suppliers around the world. The Volkswagen Group sees this as a key
building block in ensuring the competitiveness of suppliers going forwards.”
(VW, http://www.volkswagenag.com/vwag/vwcorp/content/en/
sustainability_and_responsibility/Strategie_und_Management/Lieferantenmana
gement.html, visited 06 June 2008)
2 This argument is obviously more stringent for occidental firms than for Asian supplier
networks based on Kereitsu principles, where the carmaker can more easily influence its
suppliers (we thank our referees for this useful remark).
3 For a supplier like Valeo that sells many components with a life span shorter than the vehicles
on which they are fit, non-OEM sales accounted for 18% of the total revenues in 2007.
4 A recent Greenpeace (2008) report on how automotive interests lobby the European
Commission revealed a definite focus on automakers.
5 www.Faurecia.fr
6 The European Coalition for Corporate Justice (ECCJ) is the head of an international network
with national subgroups. In France, the network contains (integrated inside the Forum Citoyen
pour la Responsabilité Sociale) Friends of the Earth France, Amnesty International France,
Centre for Research and Information for Development (CRID), France Nature Environnement,
Greenpeace France, the economic news magazine Alternatives Economiques and French trade
unions CFDT and CGT (http://www.corporatejustice.org/spip.php?auteur6&lang=en, visited
10 June 2008).
7 As an example, Johnson Controls and Valeo are listed in the FTSE4 Good Index and Johnson
Controls, in the Domini 400 index.
8 This vision is clearly expressed by the European Commission, which defines CSR as the
“voluntary integration by companies of social and environmental concerns into their
commercial activities and relations with stakeholders” (CEC, 2006, p.2).
9 The European Commission has developed an “ABC of the main instruments of
Corporate Social Responsibility” referencing and classifying the instruments that are available
to companies.
CSR in the auto industry: do the first-tier suppliers have stakeholders? 393
10 “The Global Compact is not a regulatory instrument – it does not ‘police’, enforce or measure
the behaviour or actions of companies. Rather, the Global Compact relies on public
accountability, transparency and the enlightened self-interest of companies, labour and civil
society to initiate and share substantive action in pursuing the principles upon which the
Global Compact is based.” (http://www.unglobalcompact.org/AboutTheGC/index.html)
11 Valeo (2007, pp.58–59) has explained its lesser energy consumption performance between
2006 in 2007 by the sale of its cabling activities to Leoni in 2007. This labour-intensive
business featured an energy consumption/revenues ratio that was below the average for the
group’s more mechanised sites.
12 An internal study undertaken by Valeo (2007, p.60) covering 35 of its sites showed that
transport-related CO2 emissions were equivalent to the emissions from said sites.