The Industrial Revolution and Land Transformation
The Industrial Revolution and Land Transformation
The Industrial Revolution and Land Transformation
CHAPTER 4
The Industrial Revolution and Land
Transformation
DAVID GRIGG
4.1 INTRODUCTION
For most of human history man has been a hunter and gatherer; although his
use of fire, and local over-population, may have altered the environment, the
consequences of his actions were small compared with those of farmers.
Plants and animals were first domesticated some 12-10000 years ago, and
sedentary agriculture slowly became established in most parts of the world.
Agriculture inevitably transforms the land. Crop production requires the
removal of the natural vegetation, or its drastic modification. Thus even
shifting cultivation at low population densities, with periods of fallow in which
forest is allowed to regenerate, causes changes in the species composition and
structure of the secondary vegetation. Most other forms of crop production
require the almost complete removal of the natural vegetation; in areas of
cereal production in eastern England, not only has the original natural
vegetation long been removed, but even the hedges and isolated trees that
were planted around arable fields after enclosure are now being destroyed.
The slow expansion of cultivation has greatly reduced the forests which
covered so much of medieval Europe (Figures 4.1 and 4.2), and the woodland
of all the great agricultural civilizations has been much reduced. In this
century alone the forest area of Afro-Asia and North America has been
halved (World Bank, 1982, p. 60).
Arable farming, particularly where the plough is the main means of
cultivating, has profoundly altered the soil by both adding and removing plant
nutrients, reducing acidity with lime, draining excess soil moisture with
underground pipes, removing stones, and changing the soil structure. More
fundamental changes have been brought about by the removal of surface
water. Long and painstaking drainage schemes, notably in the English fen-
lands, the Dutch polders and inland lakes, and in the Po valley of northern
79
80 Land Transformation in Agriculture
FOREST c.900
~-, 100 MII..s
---
tries. The origins of such farming systems can hardly be reduced to one or two
major causes. Most of this chapter will be devoted to a few forces that have
been important in causing change over time, particularly in Europe: popu-
lation growth, urbanization, industrialization, transport changes and the role of
science and the state. A smaller section deals with some of the major types of
farming and their evolution.
4000
~
0
3000
::J
...I
~ 2000
1000
5000 B
4000
II)
Z 3000 J
0
::J
...I
~ 2000
1000
lAD 200 400 600 800 1000 1200 1400 1600 1800 2000
WORLD POPULATION GROWTH
A 8000 B.C. - 1979
B 1 A.D.-1979
years ago made higher densities possible and numbers began to increase,
albeit very slowly (Figure 4.3). Accurate information on population numbers
is not available until the eighteenth century, when the first regular population
censuses began to be taken; many countries had no reliable censuses until this
century. Nonetheless, most population historians would agree that the rate of
world population increase was very low until the eighteenth century. Since
then the rate of increase has progressively risen until the last decade (Table
4.1). Until the nineteenth century, increase was not continuous. Periods of
sustained increase were separated by periods of stagnation or even decline.
Such periods hav.e been identified in Europe. There was a decline in numbers
after the fifth century, increase from ca 950 to 1300, decline from the
mid-fourteenth century to the mid-fifteenth century, increase from then until
the early seventeenth century, followed by slow increase or stagnation until
the continuous and rapid increase that began in the early eighteenth century
and only faded in the 1920s (Helleiner, 1967). China also has a history of
growth alternating with decline (Ho, 1959). Little is known of Africa's
population history before the nineteenth century, but in Latin America there
was a period of sharp decline after the arrival of Europeans in the sixteenth
century, and growth may not have commenced again until the eighteenth
century (Durand, 1977).
Average rate of
increase since
Population preceding date
Year (millions) (% per annum)
8000 BC 5-10
AD 14 256 0.04
600 237 -0.01
1000 280 0.04
1340 378 0.1
1600 498 0.1
1650 516 0.1
1700 641 0.4
1750 731 0.3
1800 890 0.4
1850 1171 0.6
1900 1668 0.7
1950 2486 0.8
1960 2982 1.8
1970 3632 2.0
1980 4414 1.8
84 Land Transformation in Agriculture
It was formerly argued that the great modern upsurge in numbers began
first in North West Europe in the eighteenth century and was due to a decline
in mortality, without initially any fall in the high crude birth rates. The fall in
mortality was thought to be due to improvements in the food supply, the
control of contagious diseases, and rising standards of living associated with
the industrial revolution. This view has been sharply criticized in recent years.
It has been shown that advances in medical treatment had little effect on
mortality until the twentieth century (McKeown, 1970). It has also been
shown that in England a rise in the birth rate was as important as the fall in
mortality between 1750 and 1838 (Wrigley and Schofield, 1981); nor was the
increase in European areas confined to those states which underwent indus-
trialization, for Ireland, Sweden and Norway had rapid increases in their
populations in the late eighteenth century and the first two-thirds of the
nineteenth century without experiencing industrialization (Connell, 1950;
Drake, 1969; Thomas, 1941). Nor was the increase confined to Europe. J. L.
Durand's estimates of world population numbers suggest that the eighteenth
century saw a comparable increase in Russia, Asia and Latin America,
although not in Africa until the late nineteenth century (Table 4.2, Figure
4.4). Europe, Russia and the areas of European settlement in North America
and Australia did increase more rapidly than Afro-Asia in the nineteenth
century, so that they made up only a quarter of the world's population in
1750, but a third by the end of the nineteenth century. In this century
non-European areas have increased more rapidly than European, particularly
since 1950, so that Afro-Asia and Latin America again constitute three-
quarters of the world's population as they did in 1750.
ASIA
2POO
1000
800
600 EUROPE
/ AFRICA
400
,//::/ LATIN AMERICA
/ ~~ USSR
200 ~~ NORTH AMERICA
~ - - WESTERN EUROPE
JAPAN
rJ) 100
~ 80 AUSTRALIA
:3 60
~ 40
20
10
8
6
centuries frontiers of settlement ventured into land too arid for permanent
settlement without irrigation, as in the Great Plains of the United States in the
1930s and in Kazakhstan in the USSR in the 1950s. But in the nineteenth and
twentieth centuries change in agriculture has been prompted ~y profit as
much as by population increase.
Table 4.5 Proportion of total population of Europe in towns of 10 000 and over
(J. de Vries, 1981)
1300 1500 1600 1700 1800 1850 1890
North and West 4.4 6.0 8.1 13.0 14.7 25.1 45.3
Central 3.6 3.8 4.8 6.7 7.1 18.2 27.8
Mediterranean 8.7 9.7 13.2 11.7 12.9 18.0 20.7
All Europe 5.5 6.1 8.0 9.5 10.6 20.1 31.0
1500
... ..
. . .. .
.
. . .
.e... .
e
. ..
.
'i:~'"
-.
~
Figure 4.5 The relative population sizes of towns of more than 10000 people, ca
1500
classes. As long as the bulk of the population had wages little above the
subsistence level, then most of the diet had to come from cheap foodstuffs
(mainly cereals and potatoes). Indeed, as late as 1880, 70% of the French
calorific intake came from bread and potatoes (Toutain, 1971). But as
incomes rose so the demand for more expensive foodstuffs, and in particular
livestock products, increased. From the end of the nineteenth century live-
stock products became an increasing proportion of the diet in North America
92 Land Transformation in Agriculture
1800
. .
. .
~
Figure 4.6 The relative population sizes of towns of more than 10 000 people,
ca 1800
Third, the first industrial revolution saw a shift in the raw materials of
industry from the organic to the inorganic; even so agricultural products were
increasingly needed by manufacturing industry. The development of machin-
ery in the textile industries in Western Europe combined with income
increases and population growth led to an almost insatiable demand for
cotton and wool, satisfied only by the westward expansion of cotton-growing
in the United States, and later more widely in the subtropics, whilst Australia
and New Zealand became sheep farms for Bradford. Vegetable oils became
of major importance, not only for cooking, but before the exploitation of
petroleum, as lubricants, as the basis for paints and for many other industrial
purposes. With the development of the electrical engineering industry, and
later motor vehicles, rubber moved from a minor curiosity to a -major raw
material, and in the early twentieth century rubber expanded prodigiously in
south-east Asia (Grigg, 1974).
A further 'consequence of industrialization was that farming ceased to
provide all its own inputs. In traditional agriculture farmers got their seed
from their own harvest, their manure from their livestock, feed for animals
from grass or roots grown on their own farm. Implements were bought local'ly,
generally made by craftsmen, and power came from human and animal
muscle. But from the 1830s and 1840s farmers increasingly bought more and
more of their inputs from off the farm, much of these from manufacturing
industry. In the mid-nineteenth century the theory of Liebig in Germany and
the practice of J. B. Lawes in England led to the beginnings of the modern
chemical fertilizer industry. At much the same time the availability of cheap
iron and the need for more powerful equipment led to the rise of the modern
agricultural implements industry which from the 1840s provided iron ploughs,
drills, reapers, steam threshing engines, in the 1870s reaper-binders and
elevators, in the 1890s the first milking machines, combine harvesters and
tractors; much of the initiative now came from the United States, although
advances in dairying began in Western Europe (Ojala, 1952; Whetham,
1970; Danhof, 1972).
The dependence of the farmer upon purchased inputs accelerated after the
end of the Second World War as pesticides were widely adopted to control
disease and herbicides replaced the hoe and harrow; fertilizer consumption
has risen dramatically in the developed countries and an extraordinary variety
of implements is avaHable to sow and harvest crops. Whereas in the 1930s
horses and human muscle provided most of the power on farms in Europe and
North America, electricity and the tractor provide nearly all now.
Industrialization has transformed the role of agriculture in the economies of
the western world. In the early eighteenth century farmers and farm workers
made up three-quarters or more of the labour force in nearly every country.
But during the industrialization of the nineteenth century the numbers
employed in new manufacturing industries, in transport, and in mining
-
III
20'0
c:
0
= 10'0
E .-. -' -.-......-.-.-.....-......-.-.,
Q)
...
,
E:I 4'0 SWEDEN
FRANCE \ ,\.
(J -------
.:; , '..... "
If 2.0
- - - -r §REAT
BRITAIN ",
c:
]> 1'0
- -- - --
BELGIUM'
-.-'-.
-'-'-'-'-'-'-"'"
0 - '"'''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''''' .,~.~
-~~ --' - - - - --- "
Q. 0,6
E
Q) 0'4
".
Q)
(J
...
~- NETHERLANDS SWITZE;LANO--":::':""",-'.....
"''''''
0
".."'"
-: 0.2 BELGIUM'...
:I
0
.c
~ 0.1
1750 60 70 80 90 1800 10 20 30 40 1850 60 70 80 90 1900 10 20 30 40 50 60 1970
increased far more rapidly than the numbers in agriculture; in the present
century this trend has continued as the number in administration and other
services has risen. Consequently the proportion of the workforce employed in
agriculture has greatly declined. In Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom
and the United States it is now no more than 2% (Dovring, 1959; Grigg,
1975). In pre-industrial Europe agriculture provided most of the wealth: now
agriculture produces a small proportion of the gross domestic product in most
developed countries. In the European Economic Community farming em-
ploys only 8% of the workforce and produces but 4% of the gross domestic
product.
Although the proportion of the population engaged in agriculture has been
declining in Western Europe and North America since the early nineteenth
century, the absolute numbers continued to increase for much of the century,
for natural increase in the rural areas exceeded emigration to the urban areas.
But in the late nineteenth century the labour force began to decline slowly at
first, at a dramatic rate after 1945 (Figure 4.7). This has led to pronounced
changes in agriculture. Capital, in the form of machinery, has been substituted
for labour. Farms have become bigger in order to exploit fully the capabilities
of tractors and combine harvesters. Labour productivity has increased
rapidly-indeed for the last three decades more rapidly than in manufactur-
ing industry. Whereas on the eve of the industrial revolution it took four men
employed in agriculture to feed one man in non-agricultural activities, one
man in American agriculture now feeds fifty or sixty in other jobs (Cochrane,
1979; Rasmussen, 1982; FAO, 1972).
horticulture and imported grain from the Baltic (De Vries, 1974). Maritime
freight rates fell almost continuously from the mid-seventeenth century, at
between 0.5% and 1% per annum from 1650 to 1770 and at 3.5% per annum
from 1814 to 1860. On land the decline in freight rates was slower, although
slow improvement of road surfaces, the substitution of the horse for the ox
and the use of the four-wheeled waggon showed some reduction in the cost of
transport after 1650. It was the spread of the railway after 1820 that
accelerated the decline; this was of particular importance in opening up the
sparsely populated interiors of Russia, North America and temperate South
America. It cost over 100 cents to move a hectolitre of wheat from Chicago to
New YorkiIlI873--4, and only 24 cents in 1905. The oceanic freight rate for
wheat from New York to Liverpool in 1900 was only a third of what it had
been in the 1870s. Combined with advance in the preservation of foodstuffs,
and in particular the introduction of refrigeration into steamships in the
1870s, these declines-in transport costs allowed the opening up of great new
agricultural areas in the Canadian prairies, the American Mid-West, the
Argentine pampas, the Russian Steppes and the interior of Australia. In
England and the north-eastern United States the railway allowed compara-
tively remote dairy regions to provide fresh milk to London, Boston and New
York. Before the railway few towns obtained fresh milk from more than
35 km. By the 1930s Berlin drew some of its milk from over 700 km (North,
1958, 1968; Morris, 1958; Youngson, 1965; Grigg, 1974, 1982b).
Whereas the initial impact of cheaper transport was upon agricultural
produce, the growing dependence of farmers upon purchased inputs was
made easier by these advances. In early nineteenth century England canals
made possible the movement of coal for threshing machines, pipes for
under-drainage and lime and superphosphates; it was the extension of the
railways which further cheapened the movement of these goods. But the
introduction of the petrol-driven motor vehicle has been even more
significant, for fertilizers can come direct to the farm and be more easily
moved around the farm and bulk tankers can collect milk. Indeed, much of
the change in agriculture over the last 200 years would have been impossible
without improvements in transport.
state-supported research has produced most of the new crop varieties which
account for so much of the increased crop yields of the last 40 years. This is
true not only of the new high-yielding rice and wheat varieties developed at
experimental stations in Mexico and the Philippines, but also of most new
varieties in North America and Western Europe. The growth in chemical
fertilizers in the nineteenth century depended upon new knowledge in
chemistry, whilst their modern multiplication depended upon the heavy
chemical industries. This is even truer of pesticides and herbicides. These
advances have required far more specialized knowledge than farmers would
possess, and the cost of research and development has been beyond the
resources of even groups of farmers. The state. has thus been the prime-mover
in agricultural research in the developed countries over the last century
(Russell 1966; Petersen, 1980).
Nor have the activities of the state been confined to the promotion and
finance of research. Until the mid-nineteenth century most European states
attempted to ensure their food supplies by protecting their farmers against
imports of grains, by controlling the quality of bread, and by forbidding the
export of grain when home supplies of grain ran short. From the middle of the
nineteenth century free trade spread from Britain to many parts-but not
all-of the world. However, from the 1930s Britain, the main food
importer-and the United States, the main exporter-both began to defend
their farmers against low prices and imports of cheaper foodstuffs. In the
United States attempts to both control surplus output and to maintain farm
incomes ultimately benefited farm incomes, whilst the federal government
bought and stored output that could not be sold. In Britain the import of food
continued unimpeded, but until the early 1970s home farmers were paid
guaranteed prices, not the market prices. In Western Europe the Common
Agricultural Policy has established guaranteed prices for most farm produce
and taxed imports from outside the EEC. Whatever the objections to these
interventions by the state, farmers have been relatively prosperous in the last
40 years; without this prosperity, they would not have invested in the many
farm improvements that have greatly increased output and productivity since
1945 (Fite, 1981; Tracy, 1982).
In the Socialist countries the intervention of the state has been comprehen-
sive. Beginning in the Soviet Union but later followed in Eastern Europe and
China, private ownership of land has been abolished and farms have been
grouped into collectives or state farms. Many of the decisions about what is to
be grown, and with what methods, have been transferred from the farm to
planning commissions at both the regional and national levels (Pallot and
Shaw, 1981).
The state has also intervened far more than in the past in the developing
countries. With the end of colonial rule in the post-war period many newly
independent governments have sought to increase the output of food for
98 Land Transformation in Agriculture
most farmers combined the keeping of livestock and the growing of cereal
crops. These features had appeared in the Middle ages.
A fallow period of one in two or three years was an essential means of
maintaining soil fertility, suppressing weeds and preventing the build-up of
plant disease. Sheep and cattle were grazed on grassland held in common, that
surounded the arable fields, and were fed on the stubble after harvest. The
principal cereal crops varied, but wheat, barley, rye and oats were widely
grown, and small amounts of peas and beans added some nitrogen to the soil.
This system made the maintenance of yields over long periods possible and,
except possibly in the early fourteenth century, there was no sign of soil
erosion or falling yields. There was a balance between numbers and the
farming system (Duby, 1962; Postan, 1966; Cooter, 1978).
This basic system was modified in different parts of Western Europe
between the sixteenth century and the mid-nineteenth century in response
both to growing numbers and the extension of commercialized agriculture
around the cities. The major change was the greater integration of livestock
and arable husbandry. In the medieval system livestock relied upon the
grazing of common pasture and woodland for their fodder. However, in the
fifteenth century, although mainly from the seventeenth century, part of the
arable land began to be allocated to the growth of fodder crops, which
included roots, notably the turnip, and clover. Root crops were sown in rows,
and weeded during cultivation, which the broadcast cereals could not be;
clovers not only provided grazing and hay for livestock, but added
significantly to the nitrogen content of the soil. This, combined with the
adoption of the potato, an American crop, allowed the considerable increase
in food output that sustained the great increase in population between 1700
and 1850, all before industrialization had much effect upon European farm-
ing (Slicher van Bath, 1977; Chorley, 1981; Kerridge, 1967; E. Le Roy
Ladurie, 1975).
Although the development of West European farms had led to great
changes in the physical environment-notably the removal of much of the
forest cover and the reclamation of poorly drained areas-it had not led to .
great damage to the environment. Severe forms of soil erosion, for example,
were not found in Western Europe or indeed in those regions to which Euro-
peans had migrated. Farming in eastern North America was still essentially
European in origin, as were the types established in south-east Australia,
although by the late nineteenth century, intensive agriculture in south-
eastern North America was accompanied by severe erosion. But when
Europeans moved out of the temperate forest areas where their agriculture
had evolved into the drier treeless plains of western North America, Southern
Russia and the interior of Australia, in the mid-nineteenth century, they had
to discover methods of dealing with low and variable rainfall, and for the first
The Industrial Revolution and Land Transformation 101
time there were serious problems of soil erosion (Meinig, 1962, 1968; Fite,
1966; Lyaschenko, 1949).
Traditional European farming reached its zenith in the mid-nineteenth
century. The oxen had been replaced by the horse, ploughs were increasingly
made of metal rather than wood, a variety of implements were available to
farmers which had been unknown to their predecessors. Much of the farmers'
activity was devoted to feeding livestock to produce not only meat, milk, wool
and hides, but the large amounts of manure needed to sustain and increase
crop yields; stall-feeding, folding and muck-spreading were a great part of the
farming year. This system reached its apogee in Eastern England and the
Lothians of Scotland; more labour-intensive systems of equal elegance were
found in the Netherlands and north-west Germany. Man and the horse
provided the power, livestock returned nutrients to the soil to provide a
balanced, self-sustaining farming system (Dovring, 1965; ErnIe, 1968).
From the 1850s there were great changes in the implements and methods
available to farmers, although it was not until the 1930s that the widespread
adoption of these innovations transformed farming in the western world. The
differences between European farming in its homeland and in the sparsely
populated regions of North America now became apparent. The shortage of
labour in North America required improved implements and machines, and
these were forthcoming: the reaper replaced the scythe, the reaper-binder
shortened stooking, and the combined harvester replaced the threshing
machine which earlier had ended the long history of the flail. At the end of the
century the first tractors appeared in the United States and were tried in
Britain during the First World War. In Europe, advance in farming methods
concentrated on increasing, not output per man, but output per hectare and
output per animal, although in dairying many other nineteenth century
advances also improved output per man. The development of the chemical
fertilizer industry, the first crude pesticides and fungicides, and the breeding
of new varieties were all well under way in Western Europe before the First
World War.
Since then the series of innovations has continued; artificial insemination of
'livestock; great advances in the control of animal disease, the scientific
planning of animal feeding, the discovery of ,effective herbicides and fungi-
cides in the 1940s, and further advances in plant breeding have transformed
the farming of Western Europe and North America (Cochrane, 1979;
Staniforth, 1975; Duckham, 1966). These changes have taken place against a
background in which three economic changes have been crucial. First, the
labour force in agriculture has declined dramatically, demanding the adoption
of labour-saving machinery. Second, governments throughout the western
world have subsidized inputs and protected producer prices, so that food
output has more than doubled in the last 30 years; but demand has not, so
- -
Although rice is very widely grown in Asia it is most closely associated with
the densely populated deltas and alluvial valleys of the major rivers. Rice,
although rarely a mono-culture, occupies a high proportion of the arable land;
ploughs are drawn by zebu cattle or water buffalo; livestock, other than
chickens or pigs are uncommon, for land cannot be spared to grow fodder
crops, and so great is the pressure on land that grazing land is rare. The crop is
frequently weeded, and in some regions is sown initially in nursery beds and
then transplanted into the fields. Where there is sufficient water, two crops,
although not necessarily both rice, are grown during the year. But the most
distinctive feature of these economies is the relationship between the crop and
water. Rice-or, more precisely, wet-rice-is sown in soil that is soaked to a
muddy state; as the seedling grows, water is let into the small fields or padi in
which it is sown, and it is grown with the stalk partly submerged until the
water is withdrawn before harvesting. These unique growing conditions
explain many features of the distribution of the crop and its ability to sustain
high yields over long periods (Grist, 1953; Goor, 1966).
First, the padis contain blue-green algae which fix nitrogen, and play the
role that legumes have in European agriculture. Second, the need to keep the
water at a constant level on the stalk during growth has meant that rice is
ideally grown in deltas and the flat plains of the middle and lower parts of
rivers. These areas receive plant nutrients in solution and in suspension from
the upper reaches. Third, rice is best grown in areas with a heavy clay subsoil
that reduces the seepage of water downwards away from the padis; this also
reduces the amount of leaching, and hence loss of nutrients in the soil. Finally,
the fact that the fields are covered with water during most of the growing
The Industrial Revolution and Land Transformation 103
season means' that soils are not exposed to high temperatures. This system of
farming has proved capable of sustaining high crop yields over very long
periods. It is also a system capable of registering small but continuous
increases in yields in response to greater labour inputs (Geertz, 1963).
Rice was domesticated somewhere in the south-east Asia between India
and South China, but the present distribution and features of the system only
emerged in the first millenium after Christ. During this period the Han
Chinese slowly moved southwards, and in India, ~engal, which was a frontier
region as late as the sixth century AD, was occupied. By the eleventh and
twelfth centuries much of the modern pattern was apparent, with high rural
densities in southern China, Korea, Japan, much of India, parts of the
Phillipines, and Java, but not in the deltas and lower valleys of the Mekong,
the Irrawady or the Menam. A variety of means of extending the area under
wet rice and increasing yields were practised. Wet rice padis could only be
made on flat land, but in areas of great density cultivation was extended up
hillsides by terracing, which is common in South China, but rare in the Indian
sub-continent. High yields and multiple cropping are only possible if there is
water-control and irrigation. The maintenance of water in the padis requires
water control, a means of moving water in and out of the fields. This is not the
same as irrigati9n. A majority of Asia's rice is still grown without irrigation
and relies either on rainfall or the floods of rivers. Nonetheless the slow
improvement of irrigation and water control has offered possibilities of
increasing yields by making the supply of water more reliable, and by allowing
the cultivation of two crops, often rice and wheat, in a year. The extension of
multiple cropping has also been made possible by the selection of rice
varieties with a shorter growing season (Grigg, 1974).
Greater labour inputs have also increased crop yields. Transplanting is only
practised in the more densely populated areas; the frequency of weeding
requires more work. Unlike the traditional European farming system, live-
stock manure has played a very small part in increasing or maintaining rice
yields, although in southern China night soil has been used and some forms of
green-manuring practised. Some extreme forms of labour intensity have been
practised; in parts of Java, rice was harvested stalk by stalk with a knife to
prevent loss of grain (Krinks, 1978).
Until the middle of the nineteenth century' wet-rice cultivation remained
little influenced by external forces. Neither urbanization nor industrialization
occurred in Asia, and there were few improvements in transport. However,
the expansion of European colonialism had two important consequences.
First rice, became an important export, particularly in French Indochina,
Burma, and Thailand, which had remained comparatively sparsely populated.
Second, in some parts of Asia the colonial powers introduced modern
methods of irrigation, based on the use of massive dams and lined canals; this
was most noticeable in British India and in Java (Pelzer, 1945; Randhawa,
104 Land Transformation in Agriculture
means of utilizing tropical environments, and its defects are due to very rapid
population growth.
There are innumerable ways of practising bush fallowing (Conklin, 1961;
Pelzer, 1945; Watters, 1960). However, there are some general features in
common. First of all, land to be cropped is cleared from either primary or
secondary woodland or grassland; the plots cleared are small, and the
vegetation is cleared with the use of axe, machete and fire. Not all the trees
are cleared and stumps are frequently left. Ash from the fire provides some
plant nutrients; fire makes the surface soil friable, and the presence of stumps
accelerates regeneration when the plot is abandoned. Methods of preparing
the soil for sowing vary a great deal. In areas with long f~llow the soil is hardly
disturbed, so only a digging stick is used. In more densely populated areas of
Africa, however, soil is piled on mounds or ridges. The distinctive feature of
cropping is that a number of crops are planted in the plot; ideally this will
include not only cereals but also roots such as yams or cassava, and small
shrubs. Together with the larger trees this provides a layered structure that
simulates the forest and protects the soil from higher temperatures, and the
impact of tropical rainstorms. Intercropping has recently been shown to have
other advantages; the total yield of a combination of crops gives a higher yield
than single stands of the individual crops, possibly because crops use com-
plementary plant nutrients and the absence of large stands reduces the
incidence of plant disease. It also staggers the chronology of harvesting
(Morgan, 1969; Papendik et al., 1976).
No fertilizer is used in bush fallowing, and the amount of weeding done
varies, but is usually small. When weed growth becomes too exuberant the
plot is abandoned. Indeed some have argued that it is this, as much as falling
crop yields, that leads to the abandonment of the plot. In all forms of shifting
cultivation the plot is abandoned after three or four years cropping, and is
colonized by the natural vegetation. The length of the fallow depends upon
the type of natural vegetation, but also important is the density of population.
In very sparsely populated areas the fallow may last 25 years or more, and the
settlement of the cultivators is moved. In more densely populated areas not
only is the settlement permanent, but the fallow length has to be reduced;
there is not sufficient land to allow long fallows. As the fallow is reduced so
alternative means of maintaining soil fertility are sought; in parts of Africa
fallows are planted with rapid growing bushes and grasses, some leguminous,
and in the very densely populated areas such as northern Nigeria, pastoralists
are encouraged to feed their livestock on fallow plots. But in most bush
fallowing systems there is an absence of manuring as there is indeed of
livestock, the plough is unknown and the complete clearance of natural
vegetation is unusual. The chaotic mixture of crops and natural vegetation led
Europeans to believe that such farming systems were primitive. It is now
recognized that bush fallowing is a satisfactory means of providing food with
1{)6 Land Transformation in Agriculture
relatively low labour inputs, and maintaining soil fertility and crop yields over
long periods.
What is equally clear, however, is that shifting cultivation can only maintain
this ecological efficiency if land is abundant. As fallows are reduced by rising
population densities, as has occurred in Africa in the last 50 years, the ability
of the natural fallow to restore soil fertility diminishes, and the risks of soil
erosion increase.
4.5 REFERENCES
Abel, W. (1980) Agricultural Fluctuations in Europe: from the Thirteenth to the
Twentieth Centuries. Methuen, London.
Aymard, M. (1979) Toward the history of nutrition: some methodological remarks. In
Forster, R. and Ranum, O. (Eds.) Food and Drink in History: Selections from the
Annales. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, 1-16.
Berlan, J., Bertrand, J., and Lebas, L. (1977) The growth of the American soybean
complex. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 4, 395-416.
Boserup, E. (1965) The Conditions of Agricultural growth: the Economics of Agrarian
Change under Population Pressure. Allen and Unwin, London,
Boserup, E. (1981) Population and Technology. Oxford.
Chang, T. (1976) The rice cultures. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. London, Part B, 275,
143-157.
Chorley, G. P. H. (1981) The agricultural revolution in northern Europe, 1750-1880;
nitrogen, legumes and crop productivity. Econ. Hist. R., 34,71-93.
Clark, C. (1967) Population Growth and Land Use. Macmillan, London.
Cochrane, W. W. (1979) The Development of American Agriculture: an Historical
Analysis. University of Minnesota Press, Minneapolis.
Connell, K. H. (1980) The Population of Ireland, 1780-1845. Clarendon Press,
Oxford.
Conklin, H. A. (1961) The study 'of shifting cultivation. CurroAnthr., 2, 27-61.
The Industrial Revolution and Land Transformation 107