Banking Mergers and Acquisitions' Performance and Executive Compensation in Europe
Banking Mergers and Acquisitions' Performance and Executive Compensation in Europe
Banking Mergers and Acquisitions' Performance and Executive Compensation in Europe
compensation in Europe
Rym Ayadi 1
Centre for European Policy Studies
Brussels
Francesca Arnaboldi 2
University of Milan
Milan
Abstract
In this paper, we investigate whether managerial power and experience of executives influences M&A
performance and whether there is a linkage between M&A performance and executive compensation.
The aim is to understand if any causality relationship exists among executives power, bank
performance and their compensation in Europe. To assess banking performance, and CEO
compensation we use OLS regression model on 52 bank–to-bank M&A from EU15 countries plus
Norway and Iceland We find a positive significant relationship between managerial power and post
deal bank performance.
1
Rym Ayadi is a Senior Research Fellow and Head of Financial Institutions and Prudential Policy Unit
at CEPS, email : [email protected]
2
Francesca Arnaboldi is Assistant Professor at University of Milan, email: [email protected].
1
1. Introduction
The European banking sector has experienced a rapid process of mergers and acquisitions
(M&A) during the 1990s 3 . The deregulation of banking activities, the progress made towards
the completion of an integrated European financial market, financial globalisation,
technological and financial innovations, the imperative of value creation and the introduction
of the Euro are some of the principal forces that fuelled the process of banking consolidation
in Europe.
To explain the rationale of such a movement, the economic literature mainly focused on
examining the performance effects of M&A and then on its effects on competition in the
underlying sector. Undoubtedly, economies of scale and scope have offered the main
explanation source to performance change following M&A, leading to a number of empirical
studies which aimed at examining the relationship between size and costs.
Beyond scale, scope economies and X-efficiency, revenues’ diversification, risks’ reduction
and market power. The latter is particularly relevant in highly concentrated banking markets
and when a merger or an acquisition is targeting the same activity or region.
To test these theoretical justifications, several academic studies have examined the
performance change of banking M&A, using either static or dynamic analyses. The former
investigates the relationship between size and efficiency and the latter assesses the changes
before and after an M&A 4 . Other studies have also tried to examine the impact of M&A on
market power.
The US and European main empirical findings were however disappointing. On average,
banking M&A create little or no value.
A plausible explanation for the lack of significant improvement in banks’ performance is that
there may be other motivations such as managerial hubris or empire building by entrenched
CEO. 5 Our work especially focus on this issue, exploring two possible explanations for M&A
performance. The contribution to the literature is twofold: on the one side, managerial power
may influence board decisions about deals, thus influencing bank profitability. We want to
test whether there is a relationship between executive power and deal performance and of
what kind. On the other side, executive compensation may be used as a powerful tool to
reward and incentive executives, aligning their interests to the shareholders’ one and
enhancing deals’ performance. At our knowledge, it is the first time this issue has been
studied using a sample of European domestic and cross border transactions.
After reviewing the theoretical background and the empirical findings on M&A, managerial
power and executive compensation (section 2), the paper tests whether managerial power and
experience of executives influences M&A performance (H1) and whether M&A performance
may be seen as one of the drivers of executive compensation (H2) in section 3. 6 The aim is to
understand if any link exists among executives power, bank performance and their
compensation in Europe. Our sample consists of 52 bank–to-bank M&A from EU15 countries
plus Norway and Iceland. Section 4 summarizes the main results of the paper. Our
conclusions are set forth in section 5.
3
ECB (2000), Ayadi and Pujals (2004, 2005), Ayadi (2007) and Figure 1 and 2.
4
Berger et al (1999) and Ayadi (2007).
5
Pilloff and Santomero (1998) and Gorton and Rosen (1995).
6
Masulis, Wang, and Xie (2007).
2
2. Theoretical and empirical backgrounds
According to the academic literature in banking and industrial economics, there is a variety of
motivations driving M&A, ranging from value maximising and non value maximising value
motivations.
The economic literature has justified banking M&A on the ground that it enhances
shareholder value. Indeed, the strengthening of the shareholders’ role, the increasing
importance of institutional investors in banking capital (pension funds, mutual funds, private
equity and hedge funds), the pressure from financial markets and new corporate governance
rules have encouraged managers to orient their business objectives towards value-
maximisation.
The traditional argument that M&A increase shareholder value is based on the assumption
that the anticipated value of the entity created by the merger of two groups will exceed, in
terms of potential wealth creation, the sum of the respective values of the two separate
groups. That is: 1+1 = 3. Two main types of synergies are achieved: operating synergies and
financial synergies. The former may either be revenue enhancement or cost reduction. The
latter refers to the possibility that the cost of capital may be lowered by combining one or
more companies 7 .
In theory, M&A operations in the banking sector could create value by obtaining gains either
in terms of efficiency or in terms of market power. An M&A allows the resulting company to
obtain efficiency gains through cost reductions (or cost synergies), revenue increases (or
revenue synergies), the exchange of best practices and/ or risk diversification.
Cost synergies result from an improved organisation of banking production, a better scale
and/or a better combination of production factors. The core objective is to extract benefits
from cost complementarities and economies of scale and scope. In practice, cost synergies
might be derived from: a) the integration of different skilled teams or information technology
infrastructures, b) the combination of different back-office and general services or c) the
rationalisation of the domestic and/or international banking networks 8 .
Revenue synergies also derive from a better combination of production factors. Improvements
in the organisation of activities, however, offer benefits from product complementarities
which help to enhance revenues. In practice, revenue synergies might result from the
harmonisation of product ranges, the existing complementarities between activities, cross-
selling and the generalisation of a ‘multi-distribution channel’ approach to the various
segments of customers.
It should be noted, however, that revenue synergies are much more difficult to obtain
compared to cost synergies, because they depend not only on managers’ decisions but also on
customer behaviour. In this respect, it was estimated that some 5% to 10% of a bank’s
customers leave the bank after a merger. 9 Accordingly, M&A between banking institutions in
Europe have very often targeted higher cost synergies than revenue synergies (see Table 1).
In sum, efficiency gains are obtained by input and output adjustments in order to reduce costs,
increase revenues and/or reduce risks so as to increase the value added. Restructuring
operations can also allow efficiency gains through the reorganisation of teams (managers and
7
Copeland and Weston (1988).
8
Ayadi and Pujals (2004, 2005) and Ayadi (2006).
9
See Burger (2001).
3
employees) and/or the generalisation of ‘best practices’, known as ‘X-efficiency’ that is the
managerial ability to decide on input and output in order to minimise cost (or maximise
revenues). 10
Lately, beyond greater economies of scale and scope, efficiency can also be improved by a
greater diversification of risks (functional and/or geographical). 11
The M&A event itself may also improve efficiency by awakening management to the need for
improvement or to implement substantial restructuring. Alternatively, efficiency may worsen
because of the costs of consummating the M&A (legal and consultancy fees, severance pay
and so forth) or disruptions from downsizing, difficulties in integrating corporate cultures, and
in managing transition process. Efficiency may also decline because of organisational
diseconomies in operating or monitoring a more complex institution.
Several studies have tried to assess the performance of M&A in banking in the 1990s. The
majority have concentrated on the impact on shareholder value and efficiency. However, the
results were rather mixed. The majority of empirical studies has been carried out in the United
States, using a wide range of methodologies, from the most basic (event studies or balance-
sheet-based indicators) to the most sophisticated (efficiency frontiers), but their findings have
not been conclusive.
A large number of event studies have been carried out to assess the effects of M&A on stock
market values. They all tend to evaluate the change in total market value of the acquiring
company plus target institutions – adjusted for changes in overall stock market values –
associated with an M&A announcement. This embodies the present value of expected future
changes in terms of efficiency and market power. Although these effects cannot be
disentangled, the change in market value may be viewed as an understatement of the expected
efficiency improvement, since it is unlikely that an M&A would reduce the market power of
the participants. 14
In the US, the empirical results were mixed. 15 On average, the combined shareholder value
(i.e. the bidder and the target) is not affected by the announcement of the deal since the bidder
10
Originally the concept of X-inefficiency was introduced by Leibenstein (1966) who noted that, for a variety of
reasons people and organisations normally work neither as hard nor as effectively as they could. In technical terms,
X- efficiency refers to the deviations from the production efficient frontier that depicts the maximum attainable
output for a given level of output.
11
According to Méon and Weill (2001), a comparison of the annual growth rate of real GDP suggests that the
economic cycles of many European countries are not perfectly correlated. Consequently, geographical
diversification could enable European banks to significantly reduce their risks.
12
Generally, the acquiring bank in a merger is more cost efficient and more profitable than the institution being
acquired. As noted in a recent survey (Berger and al., 1999), this holds for the US (Berger and Humphrey, 1992;
Pilloff and Santomero, 1997; Peristiani, 1997; Cummins and al., 1999 and Fried and al., 1999) as well as for
Europe (Vander Vennet, 1996 and Focarelli and al., 2002). The expectation is that the more efficient and profitable
acquiring bank will restructure the target institution and implement policies and procedures to improve its
performance. It seems to be confirmed by the stock market performance: after a merger bidders usually loose,
targets gains. The overall results is expected be positive.
13
Shaffer (1993).
14
Berger (2003).
15
Rhoades (1994) and Pilloff and Santomero (1997) provide a survey of event studies. Some studies of US
banking M&A found increases in the combined value around the time of the M&A’ announcement (Cornett and
Tehranian, 1992 and Zhang, 1995); others found no improvement in combined value (Hannan and Wolken, 1989;
4
suffers a loss that offsets the gains of the target. 16 Therefore, an M&A only implies a transfer
of wealth from the shareholders of the bidder to those of the target. Compared to the 1980s,
however, the evidence from the 1990s was more favourable where average abnormal returns
have been higher for both bidders and targets. 17
Other studies examined the stock market reaction to different types of deals. Houston and
Ryngaert (1994) found that the combined gains tend to be greater when the bidding firm is
unusually profitable or when there is significant overlap between institutions. The first result
is consistent with a market for corporate control favouring competent over incompetent
managers. The second result is consistent with the market power hypothesis, according to
which a higher market share leads to higher profits. DeLong (2001) found that mergers that
concentrate banks geographically or in product create value while those that diversify them
don’t create value.
On the other hand, Zhang (1995) found results consistent with the diversification hypothesis,
according to which geographical diversification leads to a lower variability of income; and
that out-of-market transactions create value for shareholders. Higher market concentration is
likely to lead to an increase in prices for retail financial services, leading in turn to an increase
in profits. It is also true, however, that firms operating in more concentrated markets are
generally found to be less efficient. 18 This effect might offset the gains from an increase in
market power and thus leave unchanged the market value of the bank.
In Europe, the few studies carried out to assess the value creation through M&A in banking
found positive abnormal combined returns. In the study conducted by Van Beek and Rad
(1997), these returns were not statistically significant. In contrast, Cybo-Ottone and Murgia
(2000) found that shareholder value gains were positive and significant, mostly driven by
domestic bank-to-bank deals and diversification of banks into insurance. In 2001, Beitel and
Schiereck found an increase of the combined value of bidders and targets for domestic M&A
but a decrease in the case of cross-border M&A. These findings were confirmed in Beitel et
al. (2004) on a sample of 98 M&A in 1985-2000, showing that transactions focussing
activities and those on which targets are less performing increase value.
These positive abnormal returns, however, do not necessarily mean that mergers improve
efficiency; in fact, one possible explanation for the difference between the European and
American markets is that weaker antitrust enforcement in some European countries allows
gains in monopoly power from in-market mergers.
Finally, it seems that the large majority of M&A undertaken in Europe or in the US, are far
from having proved their effectiveness in terms of value creation in the short run. 19
Houston and Ryngaert, 1994; Pilloff, 1996 and Kwan and Eisenbeis, 1999); while still others found that the
measured effects depended upon the characteristics of the M&A (Houston and Ryngaert, 1997). A study of
domestic and cross-border M&A involving US banks found more value created by the cross-border M&A
(DeLong, 1999).
16
Stock market event studies of bank mergers have shown that merger announcements typically result in a fall in
the equity value of the acquiring firm and no significant gain in the combined value of the two firms together. This
result suggests that the market believes that, on average, there are unlikely to be substantial gains realised from
bank mergers. And since the value of the acquiring firm typically falls, the market also believes that acquiring
firms tend to overpay for acquisitions in anticipation of merger benefits that are not likely to be realised. This is a
common finding and is not limited to bank mergers, which points in the direction of a more general problem
associated with the corporate governance of M&A.
17
Becher (2000), Houston and al. (2001).
18
Berger and Hannan (1998).
19
According to AT Kearney (1999): “58% of the M&A announced and completed are unfortunately a failure.
Indeed, the stock market value of the merged entity two years after the operation is lower than the sum of both
separated partners three months before”. Similarly, a KPMG survey in 2001 has shown that: “30% of the M&A
have increased the shareholders’ value, 39% haven’t brought any considerable change and almost 31% have
destroyed value”. In other words, 70% of mergers were unsuccessful in producing any business benefit as regards
5
The empirical research based on event studies should however be taken with caution since the
methodology suffers from several limitations. One problem is that the announcement of a deal
mixes information concerning the proposed merger with information on its financing.
Because investors consider the announcement of a stock issuance as ‘bad news’, the negative
returns to the bidding bank could reflect the fact that mergers tend to be financed with stocks.
Consistent with this notion, few studies find that returns to bidders are significantly higher
when mergers are financed with cash relative to mergers financed with new equity. 20 Also,
event studies rely heavily on investors’ perception and their anticipations of the future gains
when there are rumours around the transactions. This may inflict a pure speculation effect.
The studies carried out on a sample of US banks showed, on average, very little or no cost
efficiency improvement from M&A in the 1980s. 21 However, the results of studies using data
from the 1990s were mixed. 22 On the one hand, some found that mergers produce no
improvement in banks’ cost efficiency, especially when the deals involve very large banks. 23
It was also showed that on average, smaller banking institutions tend to exhibit larger
variations in X-inefficiencies than larger institutions. 24 This may be due to the organisational
diseconomies of operating larger firms in relation to disruptions from the M&A process,
which may offset most potential efficiency gains. And on the other hand, other studies found
cost reductions also for very large US banks. 25
The evidence for European banks is broadly consistent with the US results. Domestic mergers
among banks of equal size seem to improve cost efficiency, but these results do not hold for
all countries and all banks. 26 Nationally, studies on Italian banks or UK building societies
found significant cost efficiency gains following an M&A. 27 Moreover, simulation evidence
suggests that a cross-border acquisition may be associated with a reduction in the costs of the
target, while little effect is found for domestic M&A. 28 On the contrary Vander Vennet (2002)
found no tangible gains in terms of cost efficiency in the case of cross-border M&A. The
difficulties in improving cost efficiency for domestic and cross-border transactions may be
related to the obstacles often encountered, especially in continental Europe, in reducing a
bank’s labour force. In fact, personnel reduction, one of the main sources of savings, is hardly
an option in countries with rigid labour markets. 29
shareholder value. Finally, according to a Merrill Lynch study in 2003, not only do most mergers fail to deliver
their promised value, but large deals have tended to perform worse than smaller ones. And at least 50% of major
mergers since 1990 have eroded shareholder returns.
20
Houston and Ryngaert (1997).
21
Berger and Humphrey (1992), Srinivasan (1992) and Pilloff (1996).
22
One limitation applies to this litterature, indeed, the efficiency gains or losses associated to M&A activity may
take a very long period to materialise, but these studies only focus on a short period of time before and after each
M&A, Berger (2003).
23
Peristiani (1997), Berger (1998) and Rhoades (1998). Akhavein and al. (1997) and Berger (2000).
24
X- inefficiencies have been broadly investigated in the US but without giving a final answer. Indeed, the first
cause is linked to the size, on average, operating costs of larger banks are found to be closer to the optimal frontier
curve than those of smaller banks to their respective cost frontier (Kwan and Eisenbeis (1996)). This could be
explained by the fact that larger banks which operate in metropolitan markets are more likely to face stronger
competition than smaller banks which are more likely to operate in suburban or rural areas. The second reason is
linked to risk taking, inefficient institutions are found to take in a higher level of risk (Gorten and Rosen (1995). It
is indeed very likely that managers of inefficient banks are more inclined to compensate the operating inefficiency
by taking on more risk which may reward them with a higher yield. Finally, the third reason is the financial
condition which is linked to the percentage of problem loans and other illiquid positions in the balance and off
balance sheets. The correlation between poor asset quality and inefficiency may be an indication of poor
management.
25
Houston and al. (2001).
26
Vander Vennet (1996).
27
Resti (1998). Haynes and Thompson (1999).
28
Altunbas and al. (1997).
29
Focarelli and al. (2002).
6
Studies on profit efficiency of US banks more often found gains from M&A. The fact that cost
efficiency is, on average, little improved as a result of a bank merger, does not necessarily
mean that there is no improvement in profits. Profit efficiency incorporates both cost as well
as revenue efficiency. Revenue efficiency can be improved by simply raising prices as market
power expanded through the merger process itself. Or revenues may rise because the merged
institution restructures its assets mix. 30
Two studies in particular have attempted to determine the profit effects of mergers. Akhavein
et al. (1997) found little change in cost efficiency but an improvement in profit efficiency of
large US banks from 1980-90 following M&A, especially when both merger participants
were relatively inefficient prior to the merger. 31 Also, after merging, banks tended to shift
their portfolios to take on more loans and fewer securities. They attribute gains in profit
efficiency to the benefits of risk diversification: larger banks have more diversified loan
portfolios and lower equity-asset ratios. But their measure of profit efficiency does not
account for changes in risk likely to result from such a portfolio switch. Berger (1998) found
similar results in a study that includes all US bank mergers, both large and small, from 1990
to 1995.
In Europe, Vander Vennet (1996) found that domestic mergers of equals in European
countries have a positive impact on profitability, mainly driven by improvements in
operational efficiency. As regards cross-border M&A, he only found a partial profit efficiency
improvement that may be caused by changes in the pricing behaviour of the acquired banks. 32
Focarelli et al. (2002) found that Italian deals that consist of the purchase of a majority (but
not all) of the voting shares of the target appear to result in significant improvements, mainly
due to a decrease in bad loans. For full mergers, they observe that Italian banks aim to change
their business focus towards providing a broader range of financial services and thus increase
their non-interest income, rather than to obtain efficiency gains. After the merger, they
observe an increase in profitability in the long run that is also related to a more efficient use of
capital.
In practice, efficiency gains do not appear to be the only explanation for the recent M&A
wave in banking. Gains obtained through increased market power seem to also offer a strong
incentive to merge, but the relationship between market concentration and performance has
only been verified partially. 33
Economic literature concludes that prices are positively correlated to local market shares in
general, but this position may not justified in the context of international markets (inter-
banking activities, multinational companies and so forth). 34 Thus, value creation through
market power would seem more likely to explain mergers at the local level and within the
same activity (especially in retail banking), which appears to be coherent with the theoretical
evidence noted above, in particular in the European Union, where the majority of the
operations are within sectors and are national. 35
30
Many studies of market structure, price conduct and profit performance found that higher bank concentration is
significantly associated with lower prices for deposits, but the relationship between higher concentration and
higher profits is often mixed, being sometimes significant and sometimes not. Berger and Hannan, (1998) found
that cost efficiency tends to be lower in markets where concentration is higher. Indeed, higher concentration
(market power) may lead to higher prices and revenues but, with less competition, the incentive to reduce costs to
their minimum levels is blunted. So, the higher revenues are largely absorbed in higher costs rather than
contributing fully to expanded profits. From this perspective, market concentration seems to have a greater
negative effect on cost efficiency than it does on prices.
31
Other relevant studies include Berger (1993 and 1996), Berger and Mester (1997), Clark and Siems (1997),
Cummins and al. (1999) and Berger (2000).
32
Vander Vennet (2002), Arnaboldi (2004).
33
Rhoades (1998).
34
Hannan (1991) and Berger and Hannan (1989, 1997).
35
Vander Vennet (1996).
7
Nevertheless, several studies have shown that the previous correlation between concentration
levels and market power diminished during the 1990s. 36 This could be attributed to the
opening up of markets which has encouraged the entry of new competitors and thus increased
the degree of contestability of the market. 37 Moreover, the emergence of new distribution
channels such as e-banking, while contributing to the disappearance of the geographical
boundaries, has made the concept of ‘local market’ less relevant.
Based on the hypothesis of the increase of market power, it appears that the creation of mega-
banks, by altering effective competition, does not allow for any immediate profit for
consumers because of dominant position abuses and consumers’ surplus capture. 38
The effects of an M&A on the collective welfare – mainly via prices – depend on numerous
factors. Firstly, it is necessary to distinguish between national and cross-border M&A
operations. Prior studies of the pricing effects of M&A 39 found that national consolidation, by
strengthening the degree of concentration, could generate substantial market power, which is
likely to be harmful for households and small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs).
However, the few existing studies on European bank mergers seem to conclude that there are
often significant efficiency gains which result in better conditions for consumers. Huizinga et
al. (2001) analysed 52 major mergers between European banks between 1994 and 1998,
which were found to be largely “socially” beneficial. Some other studies found strong
evidence of positive effects of M&A at a country level, leading to more favourable prices for
consumers. 40
Secondly, it is also essential to distinguish M&A operations according to the ‘means’ used –
market power or efficiency gains – to create shareholder value. If the value creation occurs
primarily through increased market power, the transaction would only constitute simple profit
redistribution in favour of shareholders, but to the detriment of the customers, employees and
public authorities, without a net gain in terms of collective welfare. In this case, the
transaction involves a simple redistribution between the various stakeholders of the banking
institution, which does not create wealth for the economy because the increase of banking
profits is much lower than the welfare loss suffered by the other economic agents.
36
Hannan (1997) and Radecki (1998).
37
A contestable market displays low barriers to entry and exit (Baumol and al., 1982). In such a situation, potential
competitors may engage in hit-and-run behaviour to take advantage of the super normal profit situation of the
market. Contestability hinges on the absence of exit costs (called ‘sunk costs’), which are the costs that cannot be
recovered by transferring assets to other use or by selling them. Entry to the financial services sector requires
substantial investment that tends to be sunk to a high degree.
38
The possibility of a cartel in banking is not purely theoretical and can be prejudicial for effective competition, as
shown by the “Cruickshank” report (2000) in the UK and in the Canoy and Onderstal (2003) in the Netherlands.
39
Berger and al. (1998,1999).
40
A number of further studies exist at the country level. For example, Focarelli and Panetta (2002), by
distinguishing between short-run and long-run effects of M&A, have found strong evidence that these effects are
different. Precisely, they showed that national mergers leading to deposit rate changes are unfavourable to
consumers in the short-run, but in the long run, if banks succeed in reducing costs, efficiency gains from mergers
prevail over the market power effects, so that consumers benefit. Hence, the adverse price changes generated
through consolidation are by all means temporary. Thus, studies restricted to a short post-merger period might fail
to register the efficiency gains and as a consequence overestimate the adverse price changes.
8
Seeking other explanations for the current phenomenon, studies carried out in the United
States and in Europe tend to confirm that empire building, mimicry effect and defensive
reaction are factors which are likely to play an important role.
When control and ownership are separated within the firm, managers can pursue other
objectives than maximising shareholder value or increasing profit. 41 Instead of enhancing
shareholders’ wealth, a manager might prefer to serve his/her own interests. Therefore, it is
possible that a merger or an acquisition is simply a result of a heuristic way of addressing
optimism and/or mainly dictated by the power, prestige and/or higher compensation that are
related to the management of a larger firm, which is in line with the empire-building
hypothesis. 42 In that case, the desire for power is expressed, and not the direct interest of the
shareholders. “Managerial power” hypothesis argues that CEOs may be able to control board
decision due to their higher managerial influence. This situation is more likely to arise where
shareholding is dispersed and passive. 43
M&A operations can also be triggered by a mimicry effect following the consolidation
process initiated by competitors in the marketplace. 44 Indeed, within a relatively concentrated
sector, the actions of the major ‘player(s)’ might have an immediate impact on the behavior of
others, inducing in turn a homogeneous behavior. 45
During the last two decades, indeed, the development strategies in the banking industry were
very often induced by common strategic standards, which have led to a rather homogeneous
behavior. As shown in the 1980s, the commercial strategies of banking institutions were
marked by a race to achieve a larger size. Similarly, in the 1990s, enhancing the profitability
of shareholders’ equity became the new development standard. Today, targeted value creation
represents the major strategic issue in modern banking management circles.
Moreover, the acceleration of M&A operations could also result from a defensive reaction on
the part of a few actors against competitors’ initiatives. Indeed, as the wave of mergers
spreads, banking institutions that have remained outside the process are likely to become
themselves a potential target in a hostile takeover transaction. To protect themselves from
possible predators, managers can pursue an active acquisition policy in order to maintain their
position.
Numerous M&A carried out recently in fact seem to have been dictated by the desire to
modify the existing equilibrium and to be proactive to others’ actions. Sometimes disguised as
a hypothetical value creation move, a number of these operations are primarily the reflection
of the single market impetus, where mergers have simply become the objective rather than the
result of careful strategic thinking. Most European banking institutions, reacting to the
increased contestability of their national banking market, have sought to strengthen their
national position, in order to improve their profitability and to protect their position from new
competitive entrants.
Finally, the new mechanisms of corporate governance, including takeover threats, large and
activist shareholders and effective boards, may offer a plausible explanation for the recent
41
Referred to as ‘agency relation’ by Jensen and Meckling (1976).
42
“Bidding firms infected by hubris simply pay too much for their target” (Roll, 1986, p. 1). “If there actually are
no aggregate gains in takeover, the phenomenon depends on the overbearing presumption of bidders that their
valuations are correct” (Roll, 1986, p. 5).
43
According to ‘managerial theory’ (see Berle and Means, 1932; Williamson, 1964).
44
Also called a ‘follow the leader’ strategy.
45
As John Maynard Keynes once said, “worldly wisdom teaches that it is better for the reputation to fail
conventionally than to succeed unconventionally”.
9
banking consolidation process. Committed to ensuring the growth of their companies to
satisfy internal pressure while maintaining their competitiveness to withstand fierce external
competition and forced to provide equity capital to which pressing remuneration requirements
are attached, bank managers have pursued external growth through M&A as a strategic means
to expand their activities.
In our work we basically focus on non maximizing value explanations of banking M&A
performance. On the one side we are interested in testing the managerial power hypothesis
introduced above. On the other side we study the link between performance and executive
compensation. Executive compensation has been widely studied in the literature. Much
research has focused on how executive compensation schemes can help reduce agency
problems in publicly listed companies. Since Coase (1937), Jensen and Meckling (1976), and
Fama and Jensen (1983a, b) the contractual view of the firm has been developed and the issue
of managerial power and discretion has been analysed, referring to that as an “agency
problem”. The separation of ownership and control may lead to agency problems, since
managers may use their discretion to benefit themselves in a variety of ways. On the other
hand, shareholders, the owner of the company, delegate decisions to managers. Helland and
Sykuta (2005) point out that shareholders are vulnerable to executives they cannot effectively
monitor. As a part of corporate governance mechanism, executives’ hiring, firing and
remuneration policies may help to alleviate the problem. In particular, compensation schemes
may be used not only as a reward for past performance, but also as an incentive tool to
enhance performance, to align executive and shareholder interests, and to maximize
shareholders’ value.
Executives may be rewarded either in the form of cash or stock-based compensation. Jensen
and Murphy (1990) and Murphy (1999) detect that cash based compensation, i.e. bonus or
salary, repays past efforts but does not seem to have a clear incentive function in enhancing
future performance. However, Hall and Murphy (2003) point out that stock-based
compensation, like stock option or stock granting plans, better help to align executive and
shareholder interests.
A comprehensive survey by Schleifer and Vishny (1997) gives the idea of the complexity of
the issue. They examine the most common approaches in corporate governance, focusing on
the roles of legal protection and concentrated ownership, and trying to find which system is
the best. Their analysis suggests that incentive contracts may help to reduce the agency
problem. Nonetheless, the major practical question in shaping a corporate governance system
is how to introduce legal protection of investors.
Analysing the link between compensation and performance, it has to be mentioned that
managers reward may take various forms, i.e. non-monetary remuneration. Non-monetary
remuneration, such as privileges, reduced risk of dismissal, and diversification benefits, have
been widely studied in the literature. 46 This form of compensation is particularly relevant in
corporate restructuring, merger and acquisition. Agency problem arises and variable
compensation may be used as an incentive tool linked to deals’ performance. However, in the
case of a decreasing variable compensation, it may be compensated by higher non-monetary
benefits, in managers’ view.
Furthermore, managers might pursue merger and acquisition to reduce their employment risk
(Amihud and Lev, 1981). Shareholders may diversify their risk investing in a portfolio of
shares. On the contrary, executives do not have a portfolio of employers and cannot diversify
their risk on the financial markets. Risk adverse managers try to find an alternative route to
diminish the employment risk. Merger and acquisition usually help to stabilize income
46
Jensen and Meckling (1976); Jensen (1986); Jensen and Murphy (1990); Murphy (1999); Singh, Matur and
Gleason (2004).
10
stream, thus reducing the instability of their jobs. Once more, conflicts among managers and
shareholders may occur. Managers benefit from risk reduction. Shareholders may face a
welfare loss due to the cost of the deal and to the possible wealth transfer to bondholders. The
importance of shaping an effective corporate governance mechanism arises and manager
compensation schemes play a central role. If shareholders are not satisfied with performance,
they can modify executives’ variable compensation. However, wage settlement cannot fully
overcome the agency problem for a series of reasons, such as limitation on the monitoring
activity, and stochastic optimal contract further increasing risk.
Referring to the empirical works, a first group of studies focuses on the link between
compensation schemes and company performance, showing positive abnormal returns after
the announcement of stock option plans adoption. Variable compensation may reduce agency
problems leading to better firm results. Therefore the stock market positively reacts to such
announcements. Empirical evidence support this theory since Brickley, Bhagat and Lease
(1985), and Lemgruber (1986). Datta, Iskandar-Datta and Raman (2001) document a strong
positive relation between acquiring managers’ equity based compensation and stock price
performance around and following acquisition announcements. High equity based
compensation (EBC) managers pay lower acquisition premiums and acquire targets with
higher growth opportunities. This indicates that, at announcement, the market views managers
of high EBC firms as making better acquisitions than their counterparts in low EBC firms.
However, the above mentioned empirical evidence is not fully agreed. Tosi, Werner, Katz and
Gomez-Mejia (1998) found that less than 5 percent of CEO pay appeared to be explained by
performance. Barkema and Gomez-Mejia (1998) attribute the partial inability to identify a
robust relationship between executive compensation and performance to many factors, such
as the fact that paradigm other than agency theory have not been fully tested. Yet they
mention that almost all empirical studies on CEO remuneration have used US data focusing
on the US framework. Following their viewpoint, our study has a true international scope,
comparing executive compensation and performance in Europe and helping to fill the void of
knowledge.
Bebchuk and Fried (2003) propose an alternative approach to executive compensation and
agency problem. To adequately understand the landscape of executive compensation, they
suggest that the design of compensation arrangements has to be recognized as a part of the
same agency problem. Managerial power affects the design of executive compensation in
firms with a separation of ownership and control since managers determine the board meeting
agenda and the information given to the board, especially if they are the chairman of their
own boards. The existence of managerial influence over the board may be reflected in
compensation schemes, such as “gratuitous goodbye payments”. Core, Holthausen and
Larcker (1999) show that CEOs earn greater compensation when governance structures are
less effective. Besides the predicted component of compensation arising from these
characteristics of board and ownership structure has a statistically significant negative relation
with firm operating and stock return performance. Their result suggests that firms with
weaker governance structure have greater agency problems. Greater agency problems lead to
CEO’s greater compensation. Finally, firm with greater agency problems perform worse.
Still considering managerial power and ownership structure, Grinstein and Hribar (2004) find
that CEOs who have more power to influence board decision receive significantly larger
bonus for completing M&A deals. They find a positive relationship between bonus
compensation and deal performance but not between bonus compensation and deal
performance. Their evidence is consistent with the argument that managerial power is the
primary driver of M&A bonus.
Specifically looking at target firms, Hartzell, Ofek and Yermack (2004) study the benefits
received by target CEOs in completed mergers and acquisitions. The authors find strong
11
inverse relationships between those benefits, which may take form of golden parachutes and
payment of special cash bonuses, and the likelihood that the target CEO remains as an officer
of the acquirer. The result shows that bidders overpay certain CEOs to surrender managerial
control over firms’ assets. Agrawal and Wackling (1994) examine the impact of acquisition
attempts on the compensation of chief executives of target firms. They find that takeover bids
are more frequent in industries where the chief executive has a positive abnormal
compensation. Therefore the level of compensation before the bid has an influence on
takeover activity related to the firm.
As said in the previous paragraph, two main topics are covered in this chapter with specific
reference to banking mergers and acquisitions in Europe. First we are interested in testing the
managerial power hypothesis. Second we focus on the relationship between performance and
executive compensation.
Executives have different level of managerial experience. Usually they increase their know-
how learning by doing. In M&A deals, experience may help to better choose the target, and
the timing of the deal, to exploit synergies, and to manage the transition period more
effectively. If the CEO has a strong managerial power, he can influence the board to adopt the
decisions he proposes. We expect that experience plays a key role, and may influence in some
ways deals’ performance. Therefore, under the assumption that no opportunistic behaviour is
taken by the CEO, we test the following hypothesis:
H1: Does managerial power have any influence on post deal bidder bank performance?
We assess banking M&A performance using executives’ experience as proxy for managerial
influence. The underlying assumption is that the greater experience the CEO has, the stronger
it is the influence on the board of directors. We expect to find a causality link between
managerial power and bank performance. The sign of the relationship is partly due to the
alignment between CEO and shareholder’s interests.
H2: Is there a link between executive compensation and changes in bank performance?
The circle seems then closed: stronger managerial power should lead to better deals
performance. Better performance should be rewarded by higher executive compensation. This
mechanism may lead to the retention of the successful CEO, further increasing his power.
However other explanations may be feasible. In particular, if opportunistic behaviour takes
place, stronger power does not lead to better performance, but may be linked to higher
compensation.
3.1. Sample
47
Since we consider a well specific industry, the banking industry, and geographic area, mainly characterised by
the adoption of the Euro, the comparison among CEO compensation seems reasonable, even if we take the results
with caution, due to differences that still characterise European countries in wage contract.
12
the Thomson Financial Securities, M&A SDC database. The period under scrutiny is of a
particular interest because it immediately follows the regulatory changes associated with the
completion of the single market programme in the EU, and it also covers the period before
and after the introduction of the Euro.
All the deals included in our study are horizontal takeovers that can either be classified as
complete mergers (involving the combination of the consolidating partners) or majority
acquisitions exceeding the threshold of 49% of voting rights (in which the acquiring bank
buys a controlling equity stake in the target bank, and both banks remain legally separate
entities), in order to take into account all the operations having generated a transfer of capital
control.
The targets and the acquirers are banking institutions (commercial banks, savings institutions,
cooperatives banks and public credit institutions) as defined in the second banking directive.
Insurance and ‘securities’ are excluded.
We collected financial data from Bankscope, a Bureau Van Dijck database, which reports,
under comparable standards, information from bank annual reports. As regards executive
compensation, at our knowledge no dataset is available for Europe. Empirical works have
been usually based on US data. 48 Our data has been directly collected from banks balance
sheets. The focus on European-specific features is a peculiar and innovative trait of our
contribution.
To explore the sample, descriptive statistical analysis on the number of transactions was
performed. Table C gives the number of transactions by year and country of acquirers; and
Table D(a) and (b) displays the number of bidders and targets and the number of domestic and
cross border transactions by country.
Most transactions are concentrated in years 1998 – 2001 (34 out of 52). This is consistent
with the wave of consolidation the European banking sector has experienced during the
1990s, confirming the importance of forces such as globalisation, technical innovation, and
changes in the regulation as some of the main drivers of mergers and acquisitions.
As for the country distribution of deals, Italy plays a central role in our sample. Twenty-six
percent of transactions involves an Italian bank as a target or as a bidder. French banks act as
acquirers in 12 percent of the sample. Generally speaking, Italy, France and Germany are
countries actively involved in the consolidation process. Altogether, banks belonging to these
countries act as bidder in 24 deals out of 52. This may be explained first recalling the high
fragmentation of continental banking systems at the beginning of the 90s. The consolidation
process has been particularly relevant in countries where deregulation incisively changed the
landscape and financial system was bank-oriented. Second, among “big” European countries,
Spain and the UK were involved in cross border transactions not only inside the EU15 but
also with North and South American banks. By construction, our sample cannot capture the
magnitude of this phenomenon, thus under-estimating the number of deals in the latter
countries. Finally, among the Baltic countries, Sweden plays a key role in the consolidation
process of the area (10 percent of bidders). Here the process started a couple of years later
than in the continental countries, suggesting a sort of “contagion” effect, or a follow-the-
leader strategy.
The sample is homogeneously distributed between domestic and cross border transactions.
Forty-five banks were involved in domestic deals, 43 percent of the sample. Half of those
were completed in Italy thus reflecting the consolidation process that has taken place in the
Italian banking system in the last decade. In Italy, first banks looked at the internal market
(1998 – 2001) and only in a second moment they moved abroad (2004-2006). Besides, in the
majority of cross border transactions considered in the sample, Italian banks play the role of
48
Compustat mainly includes data on executive compensation of US based firms.
13
the target. France is characterized by a similar situation, i.e. a prevalence of domestic deals,
although no chronologic pattern can be identified. The situation is different in a second group
of “big” European countries, such as Germany, Spain and the UK. In Germany two deals are
domestic for a total of four banks involved. Cross border transactions prevail and German
banks, basically playing the part of bidders, show an active role in re-shaping the European
banking system. Spanish banks were both involved in domestic and cross border transactions
as bidder and target with no precise pattern being identified. Finally, in the UK banks are
exclusively involved in cross border transactions. The British banking system seems
characterized by a higher level of contestability and lower barrier to entry, since banks act
both as bidders and targets. Generally speaking, smaller countries such as Austria, Belgium,
Luxemburg and the Netherlands are characterized by a higher number of cross border deals,
confirming the need of going abroad to gain market shares and to enlarge the scope of
activity. The Baltic countries (Norway, Iceland, Finland and Sweden) follow this trend.
Looking at the performance of transactions, the average growth of bidder ROA and ROE
before and after the deal is 9 percent, whereas the average growth of cost to income ratio is
almost zero. The result suggests a positive impact of deals on banks performance, especially
for the profit side. On the cost side, no particular benefit seems to emerge from the M&A
wave which involved Europe at the end of the ’90s. This may be explained by difficulties
encountered by bidders in cost cutting. For example, Italy, Germany and France, the most
represented countries in the sample, are characterized by strong labour unions, which may
influence executives’ restructuring and synergies implementation after the deal. As for the
profit, deals may easily allow to increase market shares and to cross sell products to new
customers.
Turning to executive total compensation before the deal, it has been on average 5.7 million of
euros. Compared to the amount of average post deal remuneration (850 million of euros), it
shows a tremendous rate of growth. The result has been mainly driven by variable
compensation. Incentive plans have been introduced in the late ‘90s in Europe, but since the
beginning they has been widely adopted by the majority of banks. Nonetheless the increase of
variable compensation is amazing and difficult to explain with the average increase in
performance. Retention and incentive motivations may have prevailed. Such an increase may
also be explained with managerial power of executives, who may be able to influence the
board to get a higher compensation after a successful deal.
3.2. Methodology
In order to test our hypothesis we use OLS regression analysis on the sample described in the
previous section. Concerning H1, the dependent variables are performance indicators
including both profitability and cost ratios. 49
The first ones include the return on asset (ROA) which is the ratio of gross income to average
assets and the return on equity (ROE) which is the ratio of gross or net income to equity.
Gross income measure is preferred to net income one to avoid the differences in taxation
between the European countries. ROA is a good overall indicator of a banking organization’s
performance that illustrates the ability of a bank to generate profits from the assets at its
disposal. ROE is an alternative measure of profitability designed to reflect the return to
owners’ investment. It has the disadvantage that the denominator may vary substantially
across banks, even those of identical size due to the mix between equity and debt capital as
well as the total amount of capital held by a firm.
As for the cost side, cost to income ratio (CI) allows to examine total costs (non interest and
interest expenses) to total operating revenues. This ratio reflects the ability of the bank to
49
Rhoades (1998).
14
generate revenue from its expenditures. Furthermore, for many banks, revenues reflect
income earned from the balance sheet as well from the off balance sheet. 50 We tested both the
post transaction level and the changes between pre and post deal values of the variables. 51
The independent variables used to test the impact of managerial power on bank performance
are two: experience (EXPERIENC) and age (AGE) of the CEO. The first one measures the
number of years the CEO has been in charge in the bank. The longer the executive has been in
charge, the more information he has on the bank, and the more powerful he should be in
respect to the board. The CEO should have a deeper insight in the bank strength and
weaknesses, and should be able to exploit this information advantage to improve bank
performance. Thus, we expect a significant positive relationship between the two variables.
This can also be seen as a test for the importance of knowledge and information in a bank,
which are soft skills usually difficult to assess.
In the literature age of the CEO has been considered a proxy for managerial power. The
interpretation can be twofold. On the one side, the younger is the CEO, the lower is the
managerial power. This may be true in some European countries, such as Italy or Germany,
where the average age of board members is relatively high. However, younger CEO may be
linked to better performance, since he should have a stronger motivation in increasing his
prestige and power, for example compared to elder CEO close to retirement. On the other
side, elder executives should be more experienced and have higher managerial power, which
may lead to better performance. They should better know the industry, being more capable to
influence the board. Therefore we expect a significant relationship between the two variables,
but we are uncertain on the sign it might take.
Due to the scarcity of data, we are not able to test a third proxy for managerial power, the
persistence of the CEO. Persistence would be computed as a dummy variable pointing out
whether the CEO was still in charge after the deal or not. After a deal, the board may change.
Executives with stronger managerial power may be better able to keep their position.
Referring to H2, the dependent variables are the level of CEO total and variable compensation
after the deal and its rate of growth before and after the transaction. Variable compensation, is
formed by stock option plans, stock granting, bonus, and pension benefits. We prefer to test
total compensation too, in order to check the robustness of our results. Usually if executives
do their job well, i.e. they are able to identify the best target to acquire, to manage the deal,
and to exploit synergies, they should be better paid. Compensation may be used both as an
incentive (variable compensation) and as a premium for good performance (fixed
compensation).
Unfortunately, in this case, data taken from banks annual reports is highly fragmented.
Transparency of information varies from one country to another, therefore it was not possible
50
Among banks, derivatives are important on and off balance sheet item that may be larger as measured by
notional value than total asset. Furthermore unused commitments such as credit cards, and home equity lines of
credit represent major off balance sheet items that are sometimes larger in value than assets. Standby and
commercial letters of credit represent an important although much smaller source of off balance sheet items for
mostly larger banks. Off balance sheet activities result in expenses and also revenues.
51
These indicators refer to the bidders and analysed one year before and one year after the deal. A three-year time
period would be preferable because it is more likely that gains should appear at least one year after the merger and
then all gains should be realized within three years. However, the sample would suffer for a decrease in the number
of observation and would be less updated.
15
to further split variable compensation into its parts (i.e. stock options, stock granting, bonus,
pension and insurance benefits, and so forth).
In H2 the independent variables are the performance ratios, that have been already used in
testing the managerial power hypothesis. The time horizon differs, since we test the rate of
growth of performance before and after the transaction, and the level of performance before
the deal. We expect a significant positive relationship between performance and
compensation. A higher level of performance (or a higher rate of growth of performance)
should lead to higher compensation. Total compensation may be seen as a reward for the past
performance, thus increasing the chances to retain first-quality executives. On the other side, a
higher level of variable compensation may work as an incentive for getting high future
performance.
Finally, in both hypothesis testing we control for the year of the transaction (Y), for the size
of the bank (LSIZED and LSIZEA) and for the type of deal (domestic or cross border). 52 The
aim is to account for the effect of M&A waves, for the dimension of the bank and for the
influence of domestic issues on performance. Table E briefly describes all variables and their
expected sign.
4. Results
Regarding the first hypothesis we find a significant relationship between post deal
performance and the explanatory variables. First, experience, measured as the number of
years bidder CEO has been in charge before the deal, is significant with a positive coefficient
on average. Average executives’ experience is 5 years with a maximum of 14 years. As
expected, the longer the CEO has been in charge before the deal, the better he knows the
bank. Information and experience on strength and weaknesses of the bank gained working in
it help to identify the most suitable target for an acquisition or a merger. It has to be added
that higher experience is usually associated with stronger managerial power. In this case
stronger managerial power helps to better manage a deal, to exploit synergies, and to run
crucial aspects of integration process.
Second, the level of profitability after the deal is higher if the executive is younger on
average. CEO age varies from 34 to 69 years old, with a sample mean equals to 55 years old.
The hypothesis of a younger, more motivated CEO seems to prevail. As previously said,
younger CEO would be keen to increase their power through successful deals in order to
boost their career and to enhance their reputation on the long run. Again, managerial influence
has a positive impact on bank performance.
The control variables are not significant, showing no particular linkage among the year of the
transaction, the size of banks, the type of deal, and performance. Table F and G summarize
the descriptive statistics and OLS regression results for H1.
Results are robust as for serial correlation, normality and heteroscedasticity tests and are
confirmed using ROE and cost to income ratio as alternative measures of profitability and
costs. In the latter case, the sign of variables is reversed, due to the fact that better
performance is usually related to lower cost to income ratio. Assuming no conflicts of interest
among CEO and board, younger executives who has been longer in charge seem more
52
The size of banks is assessed both as natural logarithm of total assets and total deposits. In particular, total
deposits are taken into account in the case of ROA as measure of performance.
16
capable to influence board decisions thus leading the bank to higher profitability and lower
costs. It has to be noticed, however, that DOMESTIC is significant with negative sign in the
case that cost to income ratio is the dependent variable. Domestic deals seem more effective
in keeping costs under control, thus enhancing post deal performance. This result may be
explained by the fact that manager has a deeper knowledge of the regulatory, political and
legislative framework, hence being more able to evaluate potential cost synergies and more
effective in exploiting them.
The second step of our analysis has the aim to test if better bank performance is linked to
higher post deal executive compensation. Usually, higher bank profitability should be partly
used to reward the CEO for past results and incentive him to further improve performance in
the future. Besides compensation may be used as a tool to retain successful CEO. The basic
idea is to check if a circular linkage among managerial power, deal performance and
executive compensation exist.
Unfortunately we find no link between performance and compensation, both total and
variable. Compensation has been influenced only by the year of transaction with a positive
sign of the coefficient. The explanation is intuitive; moving from 1995 to 2006, CEO
compensation increases. Even if it might seem obvious, the result still give us some insights.
First, compensation increases along time independently from bank profitability. Second, since
no link has been found between performance and variable compensation, we may wonder if
the latter can still be considered a good incentive tool for executives in Europe. Finally,
allowing for the difficulties encountered in finding data, transparency on executive
compensation is still far from being reached in Europe, marking a clear distinction from the
US framework.
5. Conclusions
(to be written)
17
References (to be revised)
Agrawal A., Walkling R. (1994) “Executive Careers and Compensation Surrounding Takeover Bids”,
The Journal of Finance, vol. 49, n. 3, pages 985-1014.
Amihud Y., Lev B. (1981) “Risk reduction as a managerial motive for conglomerate mergers”, The
Bell Journal of Economics, vol. 12, n. 2, pages 605-617.
Arnaboldi F., (2004) “External growth of EU banks in Eastern European countries”, PhD thesis,
Bologna.
Barkema H.G., Gomez-Mejia L.R. (1998) “Managerial compensation and firm performance: a general
research framework”, Academic of Management Journal, vol. 41, n. 2, pages 135-145.
Bebchuk L., Fried J. (2003) “Executive Compensation as an Agency Problem”, Journal of Economic
Perspectives, vol. 17, n. 3, pages 71-92.
Coase R. (1937) “The nature of the firm”, Economica 4, pages 386-405.
Core J., Holthausen R., Larcker D. (1999) “Corporate governance, chief executive officer
compensation, and firm performance”, Journal of Financial Economics 51, pages 371-406.
Fama E., Jensen M. (1983a) “Separation of ownership and control”, Journal of Law and Economics,
26, pages 301-325.
Fama E., Jensen M. (1983b) “Agency problems and residual claims”, Journal of Law and Economics,
26, pages 327-349.
Grinstein Y., Hribar P. (2004) “CEO Compensation and Incentives: Evidence from M&A Bonuses”,
Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 73, pages 119-143.
Jensen M. (1986) “Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and market for takeovers”,
American Economic Review, 76, pages 323-329.
Jensen M., Meckling W. (1976) “Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency costs, and capital
structure”, Journal of Financial Economics, 3, pages 305-360.
Jensen M, Murphy K. (1990) “Performance pay and top-management incentives”, Journal of Political
Economy, 98, pages 225-264.
Hall B., Murphy K. (2003) “The trouble with stock options”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17,
pages 49-70.
Hartzell J., Ofek E., Yermack D. (2004) “What’s In It for Me? CEOs Whose Firms Are Acquired”, The
Review of Financial Studies, vol. 17, n. 1, pages 37-61.
Helland E., Sykuta M. (2005) “Who’s monitoring the monitor? Do outside directors protect
shareholders’ interests?”, The Financial Review, 40, pages 155-172.
Masulis R., Wang C., Xie F. (2007) “Agency Problems at Dual Class Companies”, available at SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=961158.
Murphy K. (1999) “Executive compensation”, in O. Ashenfelter, D. Card (Eds), Handbook of Labour
Economics, Elsevier Science, North Holland, New York and Oxford.
Roll R. (1986) “The hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers”, Journal of Business, 59, pages 197-216.
Schleifer A., Vishny R. (1997) “A survey of corporate governance”, The Journal of Finance, vol. 52, n.
2, pages 737-783.
Singh M., Matur I., Gleason K. (2004) “Governance and performance implications of diversification:
Evidence from large US firms”, The Financial Review, 39, pages 489-526.
Tosi H.L., Werner S., Katz J., Gomez-Mejia L.R. (1998) “A meta-analysis of executive compensation
studies”, unpublished manuscript, University of Florida at Gainesville.
1. Abowd J., Kaplan D. (1999) “Executive Csation: Six Questions That Need Answering”, Journal of
Economic Perspectives, vol. 13, n. 4, pages 145-168.
2. Akhavein, J.D., A.N. Berger and D.B. Humphrey (1997), “The effects of megamergers on
efficiency and prices: Evidence from a bank profit function”, Review of Industrial Organization,
No. 12(1), pp. 95-139.
3. Allen, L. and A. Rai (1996), “Operational efficiency in banking: An international comparison”,
Journal of Banking and Finance, No. 20(4), pp. 655-672.
4. Altunbas, Y and D. Marquez Ibanez (2004), “mergers and acquisitions and bank performance in
Europe: the role of strategic similaritites”, ECB, Working paper series no 398, October.
5. Altunbas, Y., P. Molyneux and J. Thornton (1997), “Big-bank mergers in Europe: An analysis of
the cost implications”, Economica, No. 64(254), pp. 317-329.
6. Amel, D., C. Barnes, F. Panetta and C. Salleo (2002), “Consolidation and efficiency in the
financial sector: A review of the international evidence”, Temi di discussione, Banca d’Italia, No.
464, December.
18
7. Ayadi, R. (2007), “Assessing the performance of banking M&A in Europe”, Research Report in
Finance and Banking, CEPS.
8. Ayadi, R. and G. Pujals (2005), “Mergers and acquisitions in European banking: Overview,
Assessment and Prospects”, SUERF Study, July.
9. Ayadi, R., and G. Pujals (2004), “Banking consolidation in the EU: Overview and prospects”,
Research Report in Banking and Finance, No 34, April, Centre for European Policy Studies,
Brussels.
10. Becher, D.A. (2000), “The valuation effects of bank mergers”, Journal of Corporate Finance, No.
6, pp. 189-214.
11. Beitel, P. and D. Schiereck (2001), “Value creation at the ongoing consolidation of the European
banking market” Institute for Mergers and Acquisitions Working papers.
12. Bell, F.W. et N.B. Murphy, (1968), « Costs in commercial banking : A quantitative analysis of
bank behavior and its relation to bank regulation », Research report N° 41, Federal Reserve Bank
of Boston.
13. Berger, A.N. (1998), “The efficiency effects of bank mergers and acquisitions: A preliminary look
at the 1990s data”, in Y. Amihud and G. Miller (eds), Bank Mergers and Acquisitions, Boston:
Kluwer Academic, pp. 79-111.
14. Berger, A.N. (2000), “The integration of the financial services industry: Where are the
efficiencies?”, North American Actuarial Journal, No. 4.
15. Berger, A.N. (2003), “The efficiency effects of a single market for financial services in Europe”,
European Journal of Operational Research, No. 150.
16. Berger, A.N. and D.B. Humphrey (1992), “The megamergers in banking and the use of cost
efficiency as an antitrust device”, Journal of Financial Economics, No. 50, pp. 187-229.
17. Berger, A.N. and D.B. Humphrey (1997), “Efficiency of financial institutions: International survey
and directions for future research”, European Journal of Operational Research, No. 98.
18. Berger, A.N. and L.J. Mester (1997), “Inside the black box: What explains the differences in the
efficiencies of financial institutions?”, Journal of Banking and Finance, No. 21, pp. 895-947.
19. Berger, A.N. and T.H. Hannan (1989), “The price-concentration relationship in banking”, Review
of Economics and Statistics, No. 71, pp. 291-299.
20. Berger, A.N. and T.H. Hannan (1997), “Using measures of firm efficiency to distinguish among
alternative explanations of the structure-performance relationship”, Managerial Finance, No. 23,
pp.6-31.
21. Berger, A.N. and T.H. Hannan (1998), “The efficiency cost of market power in the banking
industry: A test of ‘quiet life’ and related hypotheses”, Review of Economics and Statistics, No.
80(3), pp. 154-165.
22. Berger, A.N., A. Saunders, J.M. Scalise and G.J. Udell (1998), “The effects of bank mergers and
acquisitions on small business lending”, Journal of Financial Economics, No. 50, pp. 187-229.
23. Berger, A.N., D. Hancock and D.B. Humphrey (1993), “Bank efficiency derived from the profit
function”, Journal of Banking and Finance, No. 17, pp. 317-347.
24. Berger, A.N., D.B. Humphrey and L.B. Pulley (1996), “Do consumers pay for one-stop banking?
Evidence from an alternative revenue function”, Journal of Banking and Finance, No. 20(9), pp.
1601-1621.
25. Berger, A.N., J. Leusner and J. Mingo (1997), “The efficiency of bank branches”, Journal of
Monetary Economics, No. 40 (1), pp. 141-162.
26. Berger, A.N., R.S. Demsetz and P.E. Strahan (1999), “Consolidation of the Financial Services
Industry: Causes, Consequences and Implications for the Future”, Journal of Banking and
Finance, No. 23.
27. Berger, A.N., W.C. Hunter and S.G. Timme (1993), “The efficiency of financial institutions: the
review and preview of research past, present and future”, Journal of Banking and Finance, 17, pp.
221-249.
28. Berger, N. Allen et David B. Humphrey (1993), « Economies d’échelles, fusions, concentration et
efficacité : l’expérience banque américaine », Revue d’Economie Financière, Vol 27 (Hiver 1993),
123-154.
29. Burger, Y. (2001), “European Banking consolidation: Time out?”, Standard and Poor’s, October.
30. Calomiris, C.W. and J. Karceski (1999), “Is the bank merger wave of the 1990s efficient? Lessons
from nine case studies”, in S.N. Kaplan (ed.), Mergers and Productivity, Chicago: University of
Chicago Press/NBER, pp. 93-178.
31. Canoy, M. and S. Onderstal (2003), “Tight oligopolies: In search of proportionate remedies”, CPB
Document, No. 29, Central Planning Bureau, The Hague.
19
32. Charnes, A, W.W. Cooper and E. Rhodes (1978), “Measuring the efficiency of Decision-Making-
Units”, European Journal of Operational Research, No. 2, pp.429-444.
Clark, J.A. and T.F. Siems (1997), “Rethinking bank efficiency and regulation: How off-balance sheet
activities make a difference”, Financial Industry Studies, December, pp. 1-12.
Copeland, T. E. and J. F. Weston (1988), “Financial theory and corporate policy” Addison Wesley, 3rd
Addition, January.
33. Berle, A.A. and G.C. Means (1932), The modern corporation and private property, Commerce
Clearing House, New York.
34. Cornett, M.M. and H. Tehranian (1992), “Changes in corporate performance associated with bank
acquisitions”, Journal of Financial Economics, No. 31(2), pp. 211-234.
35. Cruickshank, D. (2000), The Banking Review (a UK Treasury-sponsored study), March.
36. Cummins, J.D., L.T. Sharon and M.A. Weiss (1999), “Consolidation and efficiency in the US life
insurance industry”, Journal of Banking and Finance, No. 23, pp. 325-357.
37. Cybo-Ottone, A. and M. Murgia (2000), “Mergers and shareholder wealth in European banking”,
Journal of Banking and Finance, 24(6), pp. 831-859.
38. Datta S., Iskandar-Datta M., Raman K. (2001) “Executive Compensation and Corporate
Acquisition Decisions”, The Journal of Finance, vol. 56, n. 6, pages 2299-2336.
39. De Long, G. and R. De Young (2004) “Learning by observing: information spillovers in the
execution and valuation of commercial bank M&A”, WP 2004/17 Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago
40. De Long, G.L. (1999), “Domestic and international bank mergers shareholder gains from focusing
versus diversifying” Baruch College.
41. De Long, G.L. (2001), “Stockholder gains from focusing versus diversifying bank mergers”,
Journal of Financial Economics, 59(2), pp. 221-252.
42. De Vincenzo, A, C. Doria and C Salleo (2006), “Efficiency versus agency motivations for bank
takeovers, forthcoming, working papers Bank of Italy.
43. Dietsch, M. and L. Weill (2001), “The evolution of cost and profit efficiency in Euroepan
banking”, in Research in Banking and Finance (Eds: I.Hassan and W. Hunter), Vol.1, Elsevier .
44. Dietsch, M. and V. Oung (2001), “L’efficacité économique des restructurations bancaires en
France au cours des années 1990”, Bulletin de la Commission Bancaire, No. 24, April.
45. European Central Bank (2000), “M&A involved in the EU banking industry – Facts and
implications”, ECB working papers series, December.
46. Focarelli, D. and F. Panetta (2002), “Are mergers beneficial to consumers? Evidence from the
market for bank deposits”, Temi di discussione, Banca d’Italia, No. 448, July.
47. Focarelli, D., F. Panetta and C. Salleo (2002), “Why do banks merge?”, Journal of Money, Credit
and Banking, No. 34(4), November, pp. 1047-1066.
48. Fried, H.O., C.A.K. Lovell and S. Yaisawarng (1999), “The impact of mergers on credit union
service provision”, Journal of Banking and Finance, No. 23, pp. 367-386.
49. Gorton, G. and R. Rosen (1995), “Corporate control, portfolio choice and the decline of banking “,
Journal of Finance 50, pp. 1377-1420.
50. Hannan, T.H. (1991), “Bank commercial loans markets and the role of market structure: Evidence
from surveys of commercial lending”, Journal of Banking and Finance, No. 15.
51. Hannan, T.H. (1997), “Market share inequality, the number of competitors, and HHI: An
examination of bank pricing”, Review of Industrial Organisation, No. 12.
52. Hannan, T.H. and J.D. Wolken (1989), “Returns to bidders and targets in the acquisition process:
Evidence from the banking industry”, Journal of Financial Services Research, No. 3(1), pp. 5-16.
53. Haynes, M. and S. Thompson (1999), “The productivity effects of bank mergers: Evidence from
the UK building societies”, Journal of Banking and Finance, No. 23(5), pp. 825-846.
54. Houston, J.F. and M.D. Ryngaert (1994), “The overall gains from large bank mergers”, Journal of
Banking and Finance, No. 18 (6), pp. 1155-1176.
55. Houston, J.F. and M.D. Ryngaert (1997), “Equity issuance and adverse selection: A direct test
using conditional stock offers”, Journal of Finance, No. 52(1), pp. 197-219.
56. Houston, J.F., C.M. James and M.D. Ryngaert (1999), “Why are value enhancing mergers in
banking so hard to find?”, A discussion of “Is the bank merger wave of the 90’s efficient? Lessons
from nine case studies”, in S.N. Kaplan (ed.), Mergers and Productivity, Chicago: University of
Chicago Press/NBER.
20
57. Houston, J.F., C.M. James and M.D. Ryngaert (2001), “Where do merger gains come from? Bank
mergers from the perspective of insiders and outsiders”, Journal of Financial Economics, No. 60,
pp. 285-331.
58. Huizinga, H.P., J.H.M. Nelissen and R. Vander Vennet (2001), “Efficiency effects of bank
mergers and acquisitions in Europe”, Discussion Paper, Ti-2001 088/3, Tinbergen Institute.
59. Jensen, M.C. (1986), “Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance and takeovers”, The
American Economic Review, Vol. 76, No. 2, May.
60. Kohers, T., M. Huang and N. Kohers (2000), “Market perception of efficiency in bank holding
company mergers: The roles of the DEA and SFA models in capturing merger potential”, Review
of Financial Economics, No. 9, pp. 101-120.
61. Kwan, S.H. and R.A. Eisenbeis (1999), “Mergers of publicly traded banking organisations
revisited” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Economic Review, 84/4, Pp., 26-37.
62. Leibenstein, H. (1966), “Allocation efficiency and X-efficiency”, American Economic Review, No.
56.
63. Maudos, J., J.M. Pastor, F. Perez and J. Quesada (2002), “Cost and profit efficiency in European
banks”, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, No. 12 (1), pp. 33-58.
64. Méon, P.G. and L. Weill (2001), “Can mergers in Europe help banks hedge against
macroeconomic risk?”, Communications aux journées de l’AFSE, 17-18 May, Orléans.
65. Palia, D. (1993), “Recent evidence on bank mergers”, Financial Markets, Institutions, and
Instruments, December, pp. 36-59.
66. Peristiani, S. (1997), “Do mergers improve the X-efficiency and scale efficiency of US banks?
Evidence from the 80s”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, No. 29(3), pp. 326-337.
67. Piloff, S.J. (1996), “Performance changes and shareholder wealth creation associated with mergers
of publicly traded banking institutions”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, No. 28(3), pp. 59-
78.
68. Piloff, S.J. and A.M. Santomero (1997), The Value Effect of Bank Mergers and Acquisitions,
Working Paper, No. 97 (7), The Wharton Financial Institutions Centre, October.
69. Radecki, L.J. (1998), “Small expanding geographic reach of retail banking markets”, Federal
Reserve Bank of New York Policy Review, No. 4.
70. Resti, A (1997), « Evaluating the cost efficiency of the Italian banking system: what can be learned
from the joint application of parametric and non parametric techniques”, Journal of Banking and
Finance, 21, 221-250.
71. Resti, A. (1998), “Regulation can foster mergers: Can mergers foster efficiency?”, Journal of
Economics and Business, 50(2), pp. 157-169.
72. Rhoades, S.A. (1994), “A summary of merger performance studies in banking, 1980-93, and an
assessment of the operating performance and event study methodologies”, Federal Reserve Board
Staff Study, No. 167.
73. Rhoades, S.A. (1998), “The Efficiency Effects of Bank Mergers: An Overview of Case Studies of
9 Mergers”, Journal of Banking and Finance, 22(3), pp. 273-291.
74. Rogers, K.E. (1998), “Non-traditional activities and the efficiency of US commercial banks”,
Journal of Banking and Finance, 22, 467-482
75. Ryan, S.J. (1999), “Finding value in bank mergers”, in the Proceedings of the 35th Annual
Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, Federal Reserve Board of Chicago, pp. 548-552.
76. Scherer, F.M. and D. Ross (1990), Industrial market structure and economic performance, 3rd
Edition, Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company
77. Shaffer, S. (1993), “Can mega-mergers improve bank efficiency?”, Journal of Banking and
Finance, No. 17.
78. Sharpe, W.F. (1963), “A simplified model for portfolio analysis”, Management Science, Vol. 9,
pp. 277-293.
79. Srinivasan, A. (1992), “Are there cost savings from bank mergers?”, Economic Review, Federal
Reserve Bank of Atlanta, No. 77(2), pp. 17-28.
80. Van Beek, L. and A.T. Rad (1997), “Market valuation of bank mergers in Europe”, Financial
Services, Amsterdam.
81. Vander Vennet, R. (1994), “Economies of scale and scope in EC banking institutions”, Cahiers
Economiques de Bruxelles, No. 144, pp. 507-548.
82. Vander Vennet, R. (1996), “The effects of mergers and acquisitions on the efficiency and
profitability of EC credit institutions”, Journal of Banking and Finance, No. 20, pp. 1531-1558.
83. Vander Vennet, R. (2002a), “Cost and profit efficiency of financial conglomerates and universal
banking in Europe”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, No. 34(1), pp. 254-282, February.
21
84. Vander Vennet, R. (2002b), “Cross-border mergers in European banking and bank efficiency”,
University of Ghent, Working paper series, N 152.
85. Wheelock, D. and P. Willson (1995), “Evaluating the efficiency of commercial banks: Does our
view of what banks do matter?”, Review of Federal Reserve Bank of Saint-Louis; No. 77(4), pp.
39-52.
86. Zhang, H. (1995), “Wealth effects of US bank takeovers”, Applied Financial Economics, No. 5(5),
pp. 32.
87. Williamson, O.E. (1964), The economics of discretionary behaviour: managerial objectives in a
theory of the firm, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
88. Roll, R. (1986), “The hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers”, Journal of Business, Vol. 59, No.
2.
22
Tables and figures
200 100
150 75
100 50
50 25
0 0
90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05h1
Note: 2005 figures are annualized. Cross-border M&A refers to transactions in EU-15 involving a
non-domestic acquirer. Outward M&A refers to non-EU acquisitions of EU-15 banks (only up to
2005Q1). The number of deals is shown on the left-hand scale. Value of deals is represented as stacked
lines on the right-hand scale, but is missing for a number of deals.
23
M&A sample:
Table D(a) – Bidder and targets by country Table D(b) Domestic and cross border
transactions by country
Bidders Targets Total % Domestic Cross Border
Austria 0 2 2 2% Austria 0 2
Belgium 4 1 5 5% Belgium 0 5
Denmark 2 4 6 6% Denmark 2 4
Finland 2 1 3 3% Finland 0 3
France 6 8 14 13% France 9 5
Germany 6 2 8 8% Germany 4 4
Greece 0 2 2 2% Greece 0 2
Iceland 1 0 1 1% Iceland 0 1
Ireland 0 1 1 1% Ireland 0 1
Italy 12 15 27 26% Italy 22 5
Luxembourg 2 1 3 3% Luxembourg 0 3
Netherlands 3 1 4 4% Netherlands 0 4
Norway 0 3 3 3% Norway 0 3
Portugal 2 4 6 6% Portugal 4 2
Spain 4 3 7 7% Spain 2 5
Sweden 5 1 6 6% Sweden 2 4
UK 3 3 6 6% UK 0 6
Total 104 100% Total 45 59
% 43% 57%
24
OLS analysis: framework:
Table E
Expected
Variables Description (t = year of the deal) sign
H1
Dependent variables
POSTROE Bidder ROE (t+1)
POSTROA Bidder ROA (t+1)
POSTCI Bidder Cost to income ratio (t+1)
GROE Rate of growth of bidder ROE = [ROE(t+1) - ROE(t-1)]/ ROE(t-1)
GROA Rate of growth of bidder ROA = [ROA(t+1) - ROA(t-1)]/ ROA(t-1)
GCI Rate of growth of bidder ROE = [CI(t+1) - CI(t-1)]/ CI(t-1)
Independent variables
EXPERIENC Number of years CEO has been in charge before the deal (t) +
AGE Age of the CEO (t) +/-
H2
Dependent variables
Rate of growth of bidder CEO total compensation =
GROWTC [TC(t+1) - TC(t-1)]/TC(t-1)
Rate of growth of bidder CEO variable compensation =
GROWVC [VC(t+1) - VC(t-1)]/VC(t-1)
POSTC Bidder CEO total compensation (t+1)
POSTVC Bidder CEO variable compensation (t+1)
Independent variables
GROE Rate of growth of bidder ROE = [ROE(t+1) - ROE(t-1)]/ ROE(t-1) +
GROA Rate of growth of bidder ROA = [ROA(t+1) - ROA(t-1)]/ ROA(t-1) +
GCI Rate of growth of bidder ROE = [CI(t+1) - CI(t-1)]/ CI(t-1) +
PREROE ROE (t-1) + on TC
PREROA ROA (t-1) + on TC
PRECI CI (t-1) + on TC
Control variables
LSIZEA, LSIZED Natural log of bidder total assets and deposits (t)
Y Year of the deal (t)
DOMESTIC Dummy variable : D=1 if deal is domestic; D=0 otherwise
25
OLS analysis: results
Table F(a)
Variable(s) POSTROA EXPERIENC AGE LSIZED Y
Maximum 2.49 14 69 20.7262 2006
Minimum -0.137 1 34 12.1689 1995
Mean 0.68063 5.0288 55.4615 17.8756
Std. Deviation 0.57159 3.0364 6.0048 1.8839
26