JABE Measuring Performance of Banks - tcm46-237545
JABE Measuring Performance of Banks - tcm46-237545
JABE Measuring Performance of Banks - tcm46-237545
Jacob A. Bikker is affiliated with the De Nederlandsche Bank (DNB), Supervisory Policy Division,
Strategy Department, P.O. Box 98, 1000 AB Amsterdam, The Netherlands, [email protected]. He is also a
professor of Banking and Financial Regulation at Utrecht University, School of Economics, Janskerkhof
12, NL-3511 BL Utrecht, the Netherlands. The views expressed in this paper are personal and do not
necessarily reflect those of DNB.
Measuring performance of banks: an assessment
Abstract
The adequate performance of banks, insurers and pension funds is of crucial importance to their
private and business customers. The prices and quality of financial products sold by such entities
are largely determined by operational efficiency and the degree of competition in the markets
concerned. Since efficiency and competition cannot be observed directly, various indirect
measures in the form of simple indicators or more complex models have been devised and used
both in economic theory and in business practice. This paper demonstrates that measuring the
performance of banks and other financial institutions is no simple matter and that indicators differ
strongly in quality. It investigates which methods are to be preferred and how by combining
certain indicators stronger measures may be developed. These measures are then subjected to a
predictive validity test.
2
1. Introduction
This paper addresses the question how well financial institutions are performing in providing
their services to consumers and businesses, and how much we know about that. Various
performance aspects cannot be observed directly whereas they are economically important. While
stockholders will view performance in terms of the profits made on their behalf, whether or not
adjusted for risks taken, this paper focuses on performance in a broader sense, that is, the
contribution financial institutions make to the common wealth, on behalf of consumers and
businesses. They will be mainly interested in whether financial products are not too expensive
and whether the quality is sufficient. This raises the issue of, on the one hand, the efficiency of
financial institutions (i.e. whether unnecessary costs are made in bringing a product to market)
and, on the other, the level of competition in the relevant markets (i.e. whether profit margins are
not unnecessarily high). Since efficiency and competition cannot be observed directly, they have
to be measured in an indirect way. If a cut in mortgage rates by one bank, for instance, is
promptly copied by all its competitors, then this is a sign of competition even if it does not
enable us to distinguish between a little competition and strong competition. Yet the price and
quality of other banking services such as investment consultancy or payment services are much
harder to determine, making competition far more difficult to measure. Difficulty in determining
prices and quality levels, incidentally, is a widespread phenomenon in financial products markets.
A recent example in the Netherlands the investment-linked insurance policy, popularly known as
robber policy. The fact that consumers find it hard to pick such a product on the basis of price
and quality takes away the disciplinary influence of the customer and weakens competition. This
problem inhabits many of the products of banks and insurers (Bikker and Spierdijk, 2010a).
There is another kind of performance that works in the interest of consumers, but does so in the
long run. It is the reliability of a financial institution in terms of solvency and of whether
customers can be sure to get their money back. Now that the subprime mortgage and liquidity
crisis has engulfed us all, the amount of risk banks take in carrying on their business is a focal
point of attention. Although this long-term performance is also affected by competition and
efficiency, this paper concerns itself solely with the more palpable short-term performance
exhibited in quality services and affordable prices.
Banks of course play a crucially important role in the economy because of their core products:
loans to businesses and for house-purchase. Hence competition and efficiency in banking are also
highly important: high quality at low cost boosts welfare. Competition is also important for
adequate monetary transmission, which is the speed at which policy interest rates set by central
banks pass through to bank interest rates (see Table 1).
3
Table 1. Importance of competition in banking
Welfare-enhancing for consumers and businesses
Reinforces monetary policy
Inverse U-shape relationship with:
- innovation
- solvency
- financial stability
- accessibility of the banking system to customers
Competition also affects financial innovations, banks financial health, financial stability and the
accessibility of banking services to customers with accessibility meaning the extent to which
small and medium-sized businesses have access to affordable financing. For all these four factors,
the relation to competition is represented by a so-called inverse U-shape (see Figure 1).
Promoting competition enhances these factors up to an optimum, whose position is uncertain.
Stronger competition beyond the optimum has a counterproductive effect on these factors. To
give an example: when competition is very strong and excess profits dwindle, banks will find it
hard to build extra buffers to protect them from adverse shocks. Healthy competition, in this
sense, is better than fierce competition.
So what do banks, scientists and supervisors actually know about important variables such as
competition and efficiency in the banking system? This paper will establish that, perhaps to our
surprise or disappointment, we know far less than has often been taken for granted.
0% 100%
Competition
4
Better than such simplified proxies are theoretically founded models that attempt to estimate
competition and efficiency for a particular country. 1 How well have these models been doing?
This paper shows that the consensus between even the best-founded models is surprisingly weak.
In other words, different methods lead to sometimes widely different results for the same country.
This brings us to the central problem addressed by this paper: how far does the sounding rod of
our measuring methods reach? And what can we do to reach just a little deeper?
As a first step toward a closer analysis, about 20 methods were used to measure banking
competition and efficiency for the most important 46 countries.2 These countries comprise the old
and new EU countries (in Figure 2 these are darkly shaded and chequered, respectively), the other
OECD countries (light shading) and emerging markets (polka dotted). Together, they account for
90% of global GDP.
All 20 simple approximations and model estimates of competition will from now on be referred
to as indicators. Five types of performance indicators are distinguished (see Table 2). Apart from
competition and efficiency, these are costs, profit (margin) and market structure.
1
Or for a particular bank. This paper considers country estimates.
2
For the list of these countries, see Bikker and Bos (2008), Table 9.1. Where competition is concerned, one
country, Romania, was left out due to data issues.
5
Table 2. Indirect performance indicators for financial institutions
Performance indicators Correlation with Indicators represented as
competition
Efficiency Positive Cost X-efficiency
Profit X-efficiency
Scale economies
Scope economies
Costs Negative Cost-to-income ratio
Cost margin
Total costs/total income
Profit Negative (?) Return on capital
Return on assets
Net interest margin
Market structure
- number of banks Positive Number of banks
Per capita number of banks
- concentration Ambivalent HHI, C3, C5, C10
The strong intertwinement between variables in Figure 3 explains why market structure, costs and
profitability are often used as proxies for competition and efficiency. At the same time, however,
the figure underlines the fact that the measures concerned reflect quite different characteristics of
banks and their markets.
3
See Bos (2004) for an overview and a critical analysis.
4
Depending on the ambition of efficient firms to expand their market share.
6
Figure 3. Relations between market structure, competition, profitability and efficiency
2
Profitability
1
Costs
2
2
Market structure Efficiency
4
2
3
1 Competition
Explanation: Relations according to the SCP paradigm are indicated by the figure 1, those according to the efficiency
hypothesis by the figure 2. Relations according to the quiet life hypothesis (and its reversal) are marked by the figure
3, while the relation following from a general principle is indicated by 4.
Where the notion of market structure is represented by the number of banks, a positive correlation
with competition is usually assumed: the presence of more banks implies more opportunity for
competition. Concentration, indicating mainly the dominant position of a small number of banks,
may indicate low competition, because banks may use this to collaborate. A more dynamic
interpretation is that such concentration may, on the contrary, be an indication of competition
because consolidation may have been enforced by circumstances. Therefore concentration is an
ambivalent indicator.
7
the conjectural variation of individual banks.6 Taking market share of the individual firm as a
measure of market structure, the Cournot model aspires also to capture part of asymmetrical
market structures, differences in cost structures and collusive behaviour. The Boone indicator
measures how efficiency, through increased market shares, is rewarded by higher profits (Bikker
and Van Leuvensteijn, 2008; Boone, 2004, 2008; Van Leuvensteijn et al. 2008, 2010). The
Panzar-Rosse model measures to what extent input and output prices move in step (as they would
under perfect competition) or out of step (indicating monopoly or a perfect cartel).7 Other models
in the literature (e.g. Bresnahan, Iwata) require data sets that for most countries are simply
lacking, while estimations also present high practical barriers (Bikker, 2003). Table 3 shows how
the different models simulate different aspects of competition.
For the efficiency indicators, cost and profit X-efficiency as well as scale and scope economies
were estimated through a model (see Table 2). Costs are represented by the cost-to-income ratio
and the cost margin, while profit is proxied by return on capital or return on assets (RoA) and by
net interest margin (NIM). In the case of market structure, the number of banks, the per capita
number of banks and a number of concentration indices are also incorporated.11
In all cases this analysis was based on the banking market as a whole, without regard to product
differences. It has been argued against this that the situation as regards competition, for instance,
may vary depending on the market segment. Competition in the mortgage lending market is likely
to be much stronger than in the investment counselling market. This is justified criticism:
competition may vary from product to product or even from one location to another. However,
for most products there are insufficient data available to perform analyses at the product or
5
Abstracting from causality. In some cases there are more theoretical connections, whereas different
empirical results have been obtained. A final choice is made in all cases.
6
Conjectural variation is the degree to which a bank in setting its prices and total production quantity in a
business area is aware of its dependency on other banks behaviour in that area.
7
See Panzar and Rosse (1987).
8
Based on, respectively, the market shares of the largest three banks (C3) and the Herfindahl-Hirschman
concentration index (HHI) as measures of market structure.
9
Based on the market share of the individual bank as a measure of market structure, as an indicator of
asymmetrical market structures, differences in cost structures and collusive behaviour.
10
Based on the efficiency hypothesis.
8
location level, with a few exceptions.12 Where approximations for competition and efficiency are
used in the economic literature, this is almost invariably done for banks as a whole, so on the
highest level of aggregation.
Since all models were estimated on the basis of a single dataset, different outcomes may not be
attributed to data differences. The dataset covers a ten-year period (19962005) and was obtained
from Fitch IBCAs BankScope and from the OECD.13
This section appraises the indicators presented above against three different criteria: first, two
statistical norms mutual correlations and the principal component analysis14 and an economic
interpretation. Finally, the variation across countries is explained from economic theory.
3.1 Correlations
How do the different indicators found correlate to each other? Table A.1 in the appendix shows
the correlation coefficients between 14 currently used indicators for 46 countries.15 A correlation
between two variables indicates parallel movement, without regard to any original (causal)
connection. Figure 4 summarises these findings as the frequency distribution of the correlations
found.
11
For the exact definitions, see Table 16.1 in Bikker and Bos (2008). Concentration indicators are
discussed in Bikker and Haaf (2002a).
12
Bikker and Haaf (2002b) and Bikker et al. (2006b) use the Panzar-Rosse model to disaggregate by bank
size, thus going some way towards a breakdown by market type (international vs. local), client type (large
corporation vs. medium and small-sized businesses) and product type (wholesale vs. retail). Van
Leuvensteijn et al. (2007) estimate competition in just the lending market.
13
De data on individual banks balance sheets and profit and loss accounts that were used by the five
competition measuring models and the models to measure X-efficiency were obtained from BankScope.
The dataset contains data on 13,000 private and public banks publishing more or less standardised annual
accounts which permit comparison between the different accounting systems. The data underlying the
profit and cost indicators for the OECD countries were obtained from the OECD (2000, 2002, 2004). Those
data coincide with those used by Bikker and Bos (2008) and are discussed more fully there. The data on
concentration indices for all countries and those underlying the profit and cost indicators for the sixteen
non-OECD countries were calculated on the basis of the banks from those countries that figure in
BankScope. Selection rules were applied to the latter set in order to eliminate banks in unusual
circumstances (e.g. holdings and banks undergoing a start-up or winding down process). See Bikker et al.
(2006a).
14
A third statistical method might have been regression analysis. However, the use of this is doubtful given
the strongly endogenous nature of (almost) all variables used. A counterexample is Koetter et al. (2007).
15
All analyses for 46 countries were made without the Lerner index. Lerner index analyses were performed
for 23 countries, but are not discussed here since the index turns out to be significantly correlated only with
the Boone indicator. Table A.1 is part of a larger correlation matrix, because the total number of variables
investigated was larger than 14.
9
Figure 4. Frequency distribution of correlation coefficients between indicators
40%
35% Of which significant
30%
Frequency
25%
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%
00.1 0.20.3 0.40.5 0.60.7 0.80.9
Correlation coefficient
Explanation: The graph presents the 91 correlations between the 14 indicators used: the Boone, Panzar-Rosse, SCP and
Cournot models, cost and profit X-efficiency, return on assets or on equity, cost-to-income ratio, total cost to total
income ratio, net interest margin, cost margin, the number of banks and the top 5 banks by market share, C5 (see Table
A.1). Lighter shading refers to the 22 correlations that are significant at the 5% significance level.
Evidently, most correlation coefficients are below 0.5: apparently, indicators tend to be only
moderately correlated to each other. This underlines the fact that each single indicator provides at
best a rough indication of competition, which is certainly not very accurate at the country level.
The lighter shading indicates correlations that are significant at the 95% confidence level the
upper fourth part of all results. The number of significant correlations, at one in four, is not very
high. However, they all have the right meaning: theoretically expected sign, except for five
correlations involving ambivalent indicators whose sign depends on which of the several
theoretically possible relationships is dominant. The fact that all other 17 significant correlations
bear the right signs without exception is an indication that the indicators behave (roughly) in
accordance with the theoretical framework and hence are not too much distorted by e.g. definition
or measurement issues.
16
PCA is a multivariate statistical technique that defines, for a large number of observed variables, a
smaller number of underlying series. As a statistical method, PCA is nearly identical to factor analysis.
Apart from data reduction, PCA aims to provide an understanding of the datasets structure.
10
performance measures. It would be nice, for instance, if one of the PCs represented competition,
another one efficiency and the third one profitability. This way, each PC could, so to speak, filter
information from the indicators and represent it in compact form.
Table 4 shows the outcome of an analysis (after the so-called varimax rotation for ease of
interpretation) with twelve indicators, selected so as to minimise overlap between the indicators
considered. Also, the indicators are spread as equally as possible across the categories
competition, efficiency, profitability, et cetera.17 The shading indicates for each column (i.e. for
each principal component) the highest factor or component loading(s). Thus we may infer that the
first principal component represents mainly cost and profit margins and profit inefficiency.18 The
second one has the highest factor loading at cost efficiency, while the third one has its highest
factor loading at (three out of four) model-based competition measures, and again at the HHI
concentration index. Apparently, this third factor comprises information on competition.
Moreover, the signs of each factor loadings are correct that is to say, in accordance with
theoretical expectations19 so that this PC ought to present a reliable summary of the information
content of these competition indicators.
Table 4. Factor loadings for the first five principal components (PCs)
Factor loadingsa Explanationb
PC1 PC2 PC3 PC4 PC5
Panzar-Rosse model -0.20 . 0.18 0.80 .. 0.72
Boone indicator 0.20 . 0.30 -0.79 .. 0.76
SCP model -0.80 . 0.18 0.67
Cournot model 0.18 . -0.23 -0.63 . -0.42 0.66
Cost efficiency -0.13 . 0.81 0.13 . 0.11 0.70
Profit efficiency 0.84 . -0.24 0.76
Return on Assets 0.79 . 0.16 -0.27 . -0.24 0.79
Cost to income ratio 0.26 . -0.60 0.60 . 0.14 0.81
Net interest margin 0.84 . -0.18 0.18 . 0.77
Number of banks -0.20 . 0.13 0.12 . 0.85 -0.12 0.81
Cost margin 0.85 . -0.23 0.12 . -0.13 0.81
HHI 0.19 . 0.13 -0.85 . -0.14 0.79
Explanation of variance per PC Total
0.19 0.17 0.13 0.15 0.12 0.76
a
A factor loading may be regarded as the coordinate of an indicator on a PC in a coordinate system. In the case of
orthogonal components (i.e. forming a right angle), the factor loading of a variable vis--vis a component equals the
correlation between that variable and that component; b Explanation of the variance of the indicators based on the first
five PCs (equals the sum of squared factor loadings for each variable across the five PCs).
Explanation: The shading indicates the highest factor loading for each column (that is, PC).
The last line of Table 4 shows that the first PC explains almost 20% of the variance in the
indicators, falling gradually to 12% for the fifth PC, so that the first five PCs together explain
17
If the selected indicators are varied a bit, the outcome of the PCA will change as well. Typically, the first
PCs may usually be interpreted as profit, efficiency and competition though not always in that order. In
some cases, costs appear in combination with profits, while in others they are coupled with efficiency.
18
Note that competition depresses both costs and profits.
11
76% of the variance. Thus less than half the PCs explain three-fourths of the variance in the
indicators. Apparently, the indicators do contain common elements (especially competition), but
also many specific ones (profit, efficiency, concentration and further refinements such as RoA
and NRM).
Various indicators produce diverging results for the same countries, because they reflect different
aspects of competition and also because estimation errors or faulty data distort the result. But
there is something else, which is that the outcome suggests the above generally accepted country
ranking is, in fact or at least according to our estimates simply wrong. Germany, which is
deemed by many to be low on competition, gets good marks for all our criteria: low cost, low
profit, high competition, high efficiency and as measured by nearly all indicators. And a very
similar story applies to France. Some Southern European countries live up to their
19
As competition grows, the H-values of the Panzar-Rosse model will also rise, whereas the Boone
indicator and the coefficients in the SCP model and the Cournot model decline.
12
underdeveloped image, yet according to many indicators, Italy and to some extent Spain do
not. Conversely, the performance measures for the USA, the UK and Ireland are less than
convincing. Although competition estimates for these countries are favourable, their cost levels
(and cost inefficiencies), interest margins and profits are exceptionally high, which is hard to
reconcile with a competitive climate. Table 5 shows that according to the indicators as measured
across 19962005, Germany and France take the lead over the Anglo-Saxon countries.
Whereas the original purpose of the above comparison was to use the generally accepted truth
as a benchmark for the indicators, the outcome suggests the reverse, i.e. the urgent need to adjust
the expert view.
Definition issues also figure in the models that measure competition. Using a standard model of a
profit maximising bank under a regime of oligopolistic competition, one may derive that the
theoretical model of competence is as follows (Bikker and Bos, 2005, 2008).
Profit margin is assumed to reflect competitiveness: the more market power, or the less
competition, the higher profits will be. The parameter indicates the price elasticity of demand:
the more sensitive consumers are to changes in the prices of bank products, the stronger
competition will be. HHI, the Herfindahl-Hirschman index of concentration, describes market
structure: more banks make for more competition, while a market with few large banks weakens
competition. The conjectural (or assumed) variation, , indicates how banks will respond to
production volumes and prices of other banks. This parameter becomes higher as competition
gets stronger. Equation (1) may also be derived at the firm level where, applied to bank i, it reads:
where MS represents market share. Bikker and Bos (2005, 2008) have demonstrated that existing
competition models may be derived from these two, except that they invariably incorporate only
13
one or two of the three components, thereby neglecting one or two others. The SCP model, for
instance, assumes that and in equation (1) are constant (or that (1+) may be approximated by
HHI). The same goes for Cournot, albeit at the bank instead of the country level (see equation
(2)). The Boone indicator is estimated as the in equation (2) and assumes i constant. These
differences in a priori assumptions contribute to the variation in competition estimates. The
Lerner index and the Panzar-Rosse model base themselves on the (full) profit margin at the firm
level. In the case of the Lerner index, there is the problem that marginal costs have to be
estimated, while with Panzar-Rosse the translation from theoretical to empirical model may have
a disturbing effect.
In the preceding paragraphs competition it has been shown that competition indicators should not
be applied indiscriminately. Time to investigate what information value the indicators do have
and whether there is, in fact, a reliable way to gauge competition. In order to find this out, we will
be concentrating on three aspects: economic interpretation (again), predictive validity and a
bundling of all information into a single index.
A similar pattern from high to low is to be found, for the same reason, when countries are
classified by cost levels or profitability, but that the other way around (from low to high) as high
efficiency corresponds to low costs and low profits (see the shaded diagonal in, respectively,
Table 6.B and 6.C). In the developed countries, where costs are lower, profits are also lower,
whereas costs and profits are higher in the transition countries. It is tempting to ascribe this
phenomenon to stronger competitive pressure. However, a similar classification does not show an
unequivocal pattern for competition. Other investigations have shown that competition in
14
industrial countries is, by contrast, slightly weaker, probably owing to a higher proportion of
products such as investment counselling and services and options, where competition is far less
energetic than on deposit taking and lending (Bikker et al., 2007). In time, the share of advisory
and other services continues to increase, further weakening competition (Bikker and Spierdijk,
2010).
Low 9 2 2 5
45a 25 9 11a
B. Costs
Low 9 9
8 6 1 1
Medium 10 6 2 2
9 4 3 2
High 10 . 3 7
46 25 9 12
C. Profitability
Low 9 7 1 1
9 6 2 1
Medium 9 6 2 1
10 6 1 3
High 9 . 3 6
46 25 9 12
a
The X-efficiency of Romania could not be estimated due to insufficient data.
20
The third principle component competition as presented in Table 4 is an alternative index, which may
be viewed as a weighted (by factor loadings) average of the original normalised series.
21
Cost-based or profit-based scale economies were also disregarded because they show little variation
across the countries and because of its ambivalent relation to competition.
15
efficiency, return on assets, cost-to-income ratio (C/I), total cost to total income ratio, net interest
margin (NIM), cost margin (CM) and market share of the top 5 banks (C5).
Table 7 (i.e. the last column of Table A.1) presents the correlations between the average
ranking, referred to from here on as Index, and the underlying variables. Remarkably, 11 of the
14 measures are significantly correlated with the Index, of which 7 at the highest confidence level
of 99%.22 Figure 5 shows, moreover, that correlations with the Index are far stronger than those
between pairs of indicators.
Reassuringly, all 14 correlations have the correct (theoretically expected) signs, 23 which is, of
course, especially significant in the case of the nine significant and non-ambivalent variables:
Panzar-Rosse model, Cournot model, cost X-efficiency, return on assets/capital, NIM, CM,
number of banks and C5. Apparently there is, after all, an overall concept of competition, which
is present in nearly every indicator and is reflected reliably and unequivocally in the resulting
Index. 24
22
For the indicators included in the Index, a modicum of correlation with the Index is to be expected, of
course. While for some indicators (Boone indicator and SCP model) this does not lead to significance,
other indicators show significant correlation without being included in the Index (e.g. profit efficiency and
number of banks).
23
The correct sign is negative (owing to the selection made in constructing the Index, because most
indicators correlate negatively with competition, see Table A.1), except in certain cases (shading).
24
A corollary result is that the ambivalent variables are now signed, so as to make clear which relation
prevails in practice. In the case of profit efficiency the influence of cost efficiency dominates that of the use
of market power. The cost-to-income ratio and the total cost to total income ratio turn out to do well as
indicators of efficiency, with the enumerator (costs) dominating the denominator (income) in determining
the ratio.
16
Figure 5. Frequency distribution of correlations between indicators and Index
40% Indicators
35% Index and indicators
30%
Frequencies
25%
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%
00.1 0.10.2 0.20.3 0.30.4 0.40.5 0.50.6 0.60.7 0.70.8 0.80.9 0.91
Correlation coefficients
Note: Dark shading: frequency distribution of 91 correlations between indicators; light shading: frequency distribution
of 14 correlations between indicator and Index.
Now that an adequate measure of competition has been found in the Index, it is possible to tell
which of the simple indicators, all things considered, does best. Table A.1 shows that the net
interest margin and its relation, return on assets, are the most successful (overall) performance
measures.25 When the focus is entirely on competition, Panzar-Rosse or Cournot are more
satisfactory.
Finally, it should be noted that this ranking-based Index is strongly and significantly (and in
declining degrees) correlated with the first three principal components of Table 4, which are
weighted averages of he original indicators. Both the Index and the principal components aim to
present as much of the indicators information content as possible in summary form.
25
In earlier analyses across a smaller number of countries, using a differently composed set of indicators
(Bikker and Bos, 2008) or covering other periods (Bikker and Bos, 2005), the net interest margin and the
return on assets also came out on top.
26
Predictive validity is the term used if a test is observed before it can be compared to the realisation;
concurrent validity is applied in cases where observation is simultaneous. The latter term would be
17
indicators relevant information content prevails without its pattern being disfigured by the
inherent noise.
Such tests occur frequently in the literature, if implicitly, because indicators are usually employed
without much ado as competition measures. Examples of this are the SCP and the efficiency
hypothesis literatures where concentration and market share, respectively, have been blithely cast
in the role of competition. But there are many other fields of study where competition comes into
play.27 As an ex-post test the literature is not a reliable source, since less welcome test results are
more likely to be disregarded by authors or else to be rejected by journals.
Below are three examples of such informative validity tests. A model-based measure of
competition is the H-value from the Panzar-Rosse model which has been estimated for 80
countries. Next, it is explained by means of a large number of carefully selected possible
determinants of competition (Bikker et al., 2007). The four (out of nine) determinants that are
significant (even at the 99% confidence level), all turn out to carry the right sign (see Table 8).
Apparently, the H statistic contains a great deal of competition-related information, so that it
passes the present test successfully.
Our second example concerns monetary transmission. It is assumed that as competition increases,
bank interest rates will be lower and more closely aligned with market rates and the policy rates
of the European Central Bank (ECB), so that competition reinforces monetary policy. Models for
four types of lending in eight EMU countries28 explain the spread between the observed four bank
rates and the corresponding policy and market rates using competition in the lending market (Van
applicable if one indicator were to be validated against the other. This option is less useful in the present
analysis owing to the endogenous nature of the indicators considered here.
27
Some examples of this are given further below.
28
Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal and Spain (19922004).
18
Leuvensteijn et al., 2008, 2010).29 Competition was in this case measured by the Boone indicator,
because it permits estimating competition in a partial market (i.e. the lending market). The
competition measure carries the correct sign significantly for three out of the four lending rates
(see Table 9). In the fourth case, the coefficient concerned is not significant. Also, a so-called
Error Correction Model shows that the response of all four lending rates to the market and
policy rates is stronger, and hence more closely parallel, as competition increases. Again, the
Boone indicator, with seven hits out of eight, seems to have passed the test.30
Table 9. Effect of competition on spreads between bank and market lending rates
Effect of competition Effect of competition times market
on spread (t-values) rate on bank rates (t-values)
** ***
Mortgage loans -2.12 4.29
*** ***
Consumer credit -3.03 3.21
*** ***
Short-term corporate loans -6.72 3.47
***
Long-term corporate loans 0.15 4.48
Note: Two (three) asterisks indicate a confidence level of 95% (99%).
Source: Van Leuvensteijn et al. (2008).
A third example is that of a model which determines the influence of competition on a banks
capital buffer (Bikker and Spierdijk, 2010b). On the one hand it seems self-evident that less
competition should lead to higher bank profits, so that banks may add more money to their buffer
capital. There is a clear trade-off here between the short-term interest of bank customers,
characterised by high competition and low prices, and the long-term interest of financial safety, in
other words, the certainty that you will get your money back. An alternative theory assumes,
however, that when fierce competition erodes profit margins, banks will be inclined to take more
risks and hold a smaller buffer. Also, amid strong competition, banks will be less inclined to
invest in inquiries regarding their clients in order to reduce information asymmetry (Marcus,
1984). This, too, increases the risk for banks. In order to determine which effect is stronger, a
model was estimated on the analogy of work by Schaeck et al. (2006) and Schaeck and Cihak
(2007) where the capital buffer depends on variables including competition. Competition was
once more measured using the Panzar-Rosse model, so that data are available for over 100
countries.
Estimations demonstrate that competition erodes banks capital buffers, so that apparently, the
theory claiming that weak competition leads to high profits and hence to large buffers wins out
in actual practice. The same holds if instead of the Panzar-Rosse competition measure the third
29
An alternative model, the Error Correction Model, was unable to confirm decreasing spreads amid
stronger competition. Apparently, this more complicated model is less capable of measuring the targeted
alignment effect.
30
In addition, the spread between two deposit rates and the corresponding market and policy rates is
explained by competition on the lending market. It turns out that deposit rates tend to be lower the more
competition there is on the lending market. Apparently, competition on lending is not a good indicator for
19
principal component derived above (which according to the factor loadings indicated
competition) has been applied.31 Again it appears that measuring competition in practice yields
plausible results.
So far, this paper has been investigating how bank performance indicators do themselves perform
as measures. Next, the question arises as to the banking industrys competition and inefficiency
themselves. Earlier studies have tried to capture those variables. For the sake of comparison, two
other financial sectors are also considered: insurers and pension funds. Little research has been
done in the present area for these types of financial institution, while banking competition
measurement has been underexposed in the literature.
This paper considers only estimates by methods whose results cover the same 0%100% range,
which permits the outcomes to be compared. Disregarding for now the many (almost
insurmountable) problems besetting the business of measurements and comparisons,32 Table 10
presents several outcomes for scale economies, cost X-inefficiency and competition.
Unused scale economies cannot be present under strong or perfect competition. Estimated unused
scale economies increase from banks (5%) via nonlife and life insurers (10% and 20%,
respectively) to 36% for pension funds. Especially insurers and small pension funds could realise
hefty cost savings through (further) consolidation. These outcomes reflect the degree of (overdue)
consolidation per sector, and therefore in a sense a lack of competition. For under fierce
competition, large-scale cost-saving opportunities would not go unexploited.33 As has been
observed many times, the inefficiency of banks and insurers is greater than their scale
inefficiency. Bank competition, at 50% (world-wide), hovers halfway between monopoly and
perfect competition.34 In recent years bank competition has weakened somewhat (Bikker and
Spierdijk, 2010). Among nonlife insurers, competition is considerably weaker, at 22%, than
among banks (Bikker and Gorter, 2010). The conclusion is that there is a good deal of room for
improvement in competition and efficiency within banks and, especially, insurance companies.
competition in the deposits market. On the contrary: banks compensate for their loss of income as a result
of competition on lending by offering lower deposit rates.
31
In fact, the Index turns out not to be significant if replacing the Panzar-Rosse measure.
32
The measurement of scale economies, for instance, is based on the variable output, which presents its
own measurement issues for each sector.
33
It should be noted that these scale effects also concern production structures. In all sectors, fixed costs are
high and rising over time, while they are particularly high in pension funds, compared to variable costs.
34
The competence measure H of the Panzar-Rosse model, measured across 100 countries, averages 0.50,
exactly halfway between monopoly (H = 0) and perfect competition (H = 1).
20
Table 10. Competition among banks, insurers and pension funds (per cent)
Banks Insurers Pension funds
Nonlife Life
Scale effectsa (Int.) 5
Scale effectsb (Nld.) 10 20 36
Inefficiencyc (Int.) 18
Inefficiencyd (Nld.) 18 28
Competitione (Int.) 50 22
a
Scale effects are defined as the average percentual savings on the operating costs of any additional production realised
as a result of upscaling. The greater the unused scale economies, the weaker competition will be. Source: calculations
by the author and Marco Hoeberichts. b Sources: Bikker and Van Leuvensteijn (2008). c Cost X-inefficiency. Source:
Bikker and Bos (2008); d Sources: Bikker and Bos (2008); e Sources: H-values by Bikker et al. (2006a) and Bikker and
Gorter, 2010).
6. Summary
While many indicators of competition between banks commonly used in economic literature and
in practice do in fact measure something, they do not contribute much to our knowledge on bank
performance. At the same time it has been established that with the help of appropriate indicators
or, even better, a combination of appropriate indicators we could make a good deal of
headway towards a better understanding of competition. The appropriate indicators contain
sufficient information on competition to be able to function reliably as explanatory variables in a
model where competition plays a dominant role. Finally, the analysis also revealed that some
existing expert opinions on the relative competitiveness of (especially European) countries need
to be thoroughly reviewed. Application of several indicators to banks, life & non-life insurers and
pension funds has consistently shown that there is a good deal of room for improvement on
competition and efficiency in banks and, especially, insurers.
21
Referenties
Bikker, J.A., K. Haaf, 2002a, Measures of competition and concentration in the banking industry:
a review of the literature, Economic & Financial Modelling 9, 5398.
Bikker, J.A., K. Haaf, 2002b, Competition, concentration and their relationship: an empirical
analysis of the banking industry, Journal of Banking & Finance 26, 21912214.
Bikker, J.A., 2003, Testing for imperfect competition on the EU deposit and loan markets with
Bresnahans market power model, Kredit und Kapital 36, 167212.
Bikker, J.A., J.W.B. Bos, 2005, Trends in competition and profitability in the banking industry: a
basic framework, Suerf Series 2005/2.
Bikker, J.A., L. Spierdijk, P. Finnie, 2006a, Misspecification in the Panzar-Rosse model:
assessing competition in the banking industry, DNB Working Paper nr. 114.35
Bikker, J.A., L. Spierdijk, P. Finnie, 2006b, The impact of bank size on market power, DNB
Working Paper nr. 120.
Bikker, J.A., L. Spierdijk, P. Finnie, 2007, Market structure, contestability and institutional
environment: the determinants of banking competition, DNB Working Paper nr.
156/Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute Discussion Paper Series nr. 07-29,
Universiteit Utrecht. 36
Bikker, J.A., J.W.B. Bos, 2008, Bank Performance: A theoretical and empirical framework for
the analysis of profitability, competition and efficiency, Routledge International Studies in
Money and Banking, Routledge, Londen & New York, 176 pages.
Bikker, J.A., M. van Leuvensteijn, 2008, Competition and efficiency in the Dutch life insurance
industry, Applied Economics 40, 20632084.
Bikker, J.A., J. Gorter, 2010, Performance of the Dutch non-life insurance industry: competition,
efficiency and focus, Journal of Risk and Insurance, (forthcoming).
Bikker, J.A., L. Spierdijk, 2010, Measuring and explaining competition in the financial sector,
Journal of Applied Business and Economics 11 (1), (forthcoming).
Bikker, J.A., A. Miro, L. Spierdijk, 2010a, Competition in the non-life insurance industry: a
global analysis, (mimeo).
Bikker, J.A., J. de Dreu, 2009, Operating costs of pension funds: the impact of scale, governance
and plan design, Journal of Pension Economics and Finance 8, 63-89.
Bikker, J.A., L. Spierdijk, 2009a, Measuring and explaining competition in the financial sector,
In: Proceedings on the G-20 meeting on Competition in the Financial Sector (Bali), Bank
Indonesia and Banco de Mxico, February 16-17, 2008, 42-81.
35
DNB Working Papers: http://www.dnb.nl/dnb/home/nieuws_en_publicaties/publicaties_dnb/dnb_working_papers_
reeks/dnb_working_papers/nl/46-148637.html.
36
Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute Discussion Papers: http://www.uu.nl/uupublish/tjallingkoopmans
/publications/discussionpapers/discussion papers/45511main.html.
22
Bikker, J.A., L. Spierdijk, 2010b, The impact of competition and concentration on bank solvency
(mimeo).
Boone, J., 2001, Intensity of competition and the incentive to innovate, International Journal of
Industrial Organization 19, 705726.
Boone, J., 2008, A new way to measure competition, Economic Journal 118, 12451261.
Bos, J.W.B., 2004, Does market power affect performance in the Dutch banking market? A
comparison of reduced form market structure models, De Economist 152, 491512.
De Lange van Bergen, M., 2006, The determinants of banking competition: a world-wide Lerner
index approach, Doctoraalscriptie Rijksuniversiteit van Groningen.
Demsetz, H., 1973, Industry structure, market rivalry and public policy, Journal of Law and
Economics 16, 19.
Hicks, J., 1935, Annual survey of economic theory: monopoly, Econometrica 3, 120.
Koetter, M., J.W. Kolari, L. Spierdijk, Testing the quiet life of U.S. banks with Lerner indices,
Universiteit van Groningen.
Leuvensteijn, M. van, C. Kok Srensen, J.A. Bikker, A.A.R.J.M. van Rixtel, 2008, Impact of
bank competition on the interest rate pass-through in the euro area, DNB Working Paper nr.
171/ECB Working Paper nr 885/Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute Discussion
Paper Series nr. 08-08, Universiteit Utrecht.
Leuvensteijn, M. van, J.A. Bikker, A.A.R.J.M. van Rixtel, C. Kok Srensen, 2010, A new
approach to measuring competition in the loan markets of the euro area, Applied Economics
(forthcoming)
Marcus, A. J., 1984, Deregulation and bank financial policy, Journal of Banking & Finance 8,
557565.
OECD, 2000, 2002, 2004, Bank Profitability; Financial Statements of Banks, OECD, Paris.
Panzar, J., J. Rosse, 1987, Testing for monopoly equilibrium, Journal of Industrial Economics
35, 443456.
Schaeck, K., M. Cihak S. Wolfe, 2006, Competition, concentration and bank soundness: New
evidence from the micro-level. IMF Working Paper WP/06/185, Washington, D.C:
International Monetary Fund.
Schaeck, K., M. Cihak, 2007, Banking competition and capital ratio, IMF Working Paper
WP/07/216, Washington, D.C: International Monetary Fund.
23
APPENDIX
37
Return on capital.
24
C/I TC/TI NIM Cost- No. of C5 Index
margin banks
amb (n) amb (n) neg neg pos neg
0.07 -0.23 -0.21 0.00 0.06 0.11 -0.14 Boone
0.02 0.17 -0.02 -0.22 0.09 0.03 0.33 ** P-R
-0.27 * -0.08 0.07 -0.09 -0.02 -0.15 -0.05 SCP
-0.21 -0.06 0.20 0.21 -0.31 ** 0.35 ** -0.42 *** Cournot
-0.46 *** -0.38 ** -0.23 -0.16 0.24 0.06 0.37 ** P. eff.
-0.36 ** -0.36 ** -0.25 * -0.25 * 0.32 ** 0.05 0.53 *** C. eff.
-0.39 *** -0.34 ** 0.20 0.18 -0.28 * 0.30 ** -0.30 ** RoC36
-0.03 -0.34 ** 0.57 *** 0.59 *** -0.26 * 0.21 -0.50 *** RoA
1.00 0.37 ** 0.19 0.42 *** 0.05 -0.08 -0.42 *** C/I
1.00 0.11 0.06 -0.05 -0.14 -0.20 TC/TI
1.00 0.62 *** -0.21 0.03 -0.63 *** NIM
1.00 -0.18 0.00 -0.58 *** CM
1.00 -0.55 *** 0.51 *** # Banks
1.00 -0.37 ** C5
25
Biography
Jacob Bikker is senior researcher De Nederlandsche Bank (DNB) and professor on Banking and
Financial Regulation at Utrecht University. His research interests are on banking, insurance &
pensions, financial conglomerates, risk management, competition & efficiency, procyclicality of
regulation and the extended gravity model. Before 1997, he was unit head research at the
(predecessor of the) European Central Bank) in Frankfurt am Main B. He held a position at the
Free University in Amsterdam during 1977-1983 and, part-time, during 2003-2004. He has
recently published in the Journal of Banking & Finance, Journal of International Money and
Finance, Applied Economics and Journal of Forecasting.
Personal page:
www.dnb.nl/dnb/home/onderzoek/onderzoekers/persoonlijke_pagina%C2%B4s/nl/46-
150116.html
26