La3021 Vle
La3021 Vle
La3021 Vle
Alan Dignam
John Lowry
Chris Riley
This module guide was prepared for the University of London by:
u Alan Dignam, BA, (TCD), PhD (DCU), Professor of Corporate Law, Queen Mary,
University of London
and
u John Lowry, Cheng Yu Tung Visiting Professor, Faculty of Law, Hong Kong University,
and Emeritus Professor, Faculty of Laws, University College London.
The 2016, 2017, 2018, 2019 and 2020 updates were prepared by:
u Chris Riley, LLB, Associate Professor, Durham Law School, University of Durham.
This is one of a series of module guides published by the University. We regret that owing
to pressure of work the authors are unable to enter into any correspondence relating to,
or arising from, the guide. If you have any comments on this module guide, favourable or
unfavourable, please use the form at the end of this guide.
University of London
Publications Office
Stewart House
32 Russell Square
London WC1B 5DN
United Kingdom
london.ac.uk
© University of London 2016. Reprinted with minor revisions in 2017, 2018, 2019 and 2020
The University of London asserts copyright over all material in this module guide except
where otherwise indicated. All rights reserved. No part of this work may be reproduced
in any form, or by any means, without permission in writing from the publisher. We make
every effort to respect copyright. If you think we have inadvertently used your copyright
material, please let us know.
Company Law page i
Contents
Module descriptor . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . v
1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2
1.1 Company law . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
1.2 Approaching your study . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
8 Capital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 74
8.1 Overview – the maintenance of capital doctrine . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75
8.2 Raising capital: shares may not be issued at a discount . . . . . . . . . . . . 75
8.3 Returning funds to shareholders . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76
8.4 Prohibition on public companies assisting in the acquisition of
their own shares . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81
Reflect and review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86
10 Class rights . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 99
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100
10.1 Shares and class rights . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 101
10.2 Classes of shares . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 102
10.3 Variation of class rights . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 103
Reflect and review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107
13 Dealing with outsiders: ultra vires and other attribution issues . . . . 139
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140
13.1 The objects clause problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141
13.2 Reforming ultra vires . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 142
13.3 Other attribution issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 145
Reflect and review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 150
Chapter 13 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 224
Chapter 14 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 225
Chapter 15 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 226
Chapter 16 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 228
Chapter 17 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 228
Company Law page v
Module descriptor
GENERAL INFORMATION
Module title
Company law
Module code
LA3021
Module level
6
Contact email
The Undergraduate Laws Programme courses are run in collaboration with the
University of London. Enquiries may be made via the Student Advice Centre at:
https://sid.london.ac.uk/sid
Credit
30
Module prerequisite
None
Company law is a vital module for anyone intending to operate in a commercial field.
The syllabus centres on the way the law regulates companies and the facilities that
company law offers, such as limited liability and transferability of shares, as well as
corresponding burdens such as duties of disclosure and compliance with statutory
procedures.
MODULE AIM
The module aims to introduce students to the nature, and the regulation, of the
modern business company. It will enable students to understand what is distinctive
about the company, the advantages it enjoys as a way of running a business and the
policy issues that its existence raises. Students should learn to understand some
of the central concepts relevant to the company, such as limited liability and legal
personality, the competing interests of different groups of individuals who are
affected by a company’s operations, such as its directors, shareholders, creditors and
employees, and the role that the law can play in protecting such individuals.
page vi University of London
1. Explain the main concepts that underpin company law, including separate legal
personality and limited liability;
2. Comprehend the policy issues that arise regarding the regulation of companies,
including the views of different commentators about those policy issues;
3. Discuss the main principles and rules that seek to regulate and protect different
participants within companies, especially their directors, shareholders and
creditors;
4. Summarise the issues that arise in respect of large, widely owned, public
companies and the strategies that have been developed to ensure such companies
are well governed.
6. Critically analyse and evaluate selected areas of company law and place the policy
issues raised by company law in their social, economic and political contexts;
7. Develop well-reasoned analysis and arguments for the reform of selected areas
of company law, including by engaging critically with the arguments of other
commentators;
8. Critically read case law and other materials and construct answers to questions set.
MODULE SYLLABUS
(a) The nature of legal personality and lifting the veil of incorporation. Incidents of
corporate personality. Differences between incorporated and unincorporated
associations. The rule in Salomon v Salomon & Co Ltd and its development. Tortious
liability as an alternative to veil lifting.
(b) The formation of the company. The suitability of the company as a legal vehicle for
different types of business. The registration process, including the memorandum
and articles of association. Pre-incorporation contracts. The duties and liabilities of
promoters.
(c) The relations between the company and outsiders. The growth and decline of
the doctrines of ultra vires and constructive notice. The Turquand rule and the
application of principles of agency. The commission of crimes and torts by the
company. Vicarious liability and the alter ego doctrine.
(d) The relations between the company and its members and among the members inter
se. The nature of and principles governing the statutory contract between the
company and its members. Different capacities of members and relations between
one member and another. Alteration of the statutory contract and remedies for
breach.
(f) Directors’ duties. The general duties of directors, and the codification of those
duties. Statutory controls on directors, including rules on self-dealing and the
criminalisation of insider trading. The enforcement of directors’ duties, including
the rule in Foss v Harbottle and the statutory derivative claim.
(g) The protection of minority shareholders. The statutory remedies for the protection of
minority shareholders. Shareholders’ personal rights, including under the statutory
contract.
(i) Shares and Debentures. Differences between shares and debentures. Registration.
Different classes of shares. Rights of different classes and the variation of share
rights.
(j) Capital. Raising, maintaining and reducing the capital of the company. Discounts.
Premiums. Payment of dividends and purchase by the company of its shares.
Financial assistance for the purchase of its shares. Raising capital from the public:
the requirements for prospectuses and listing particulars.
(k) Winding-up. Types of winding-up. The powers and duties of the liquidator.
Module guide
Module guides are the students’ primary learning resource. The module guide covers
the entire syllabus and provides the student with the grounding to complete the
module successfully. It sets out the learning outcomes that must be achieved as
well as providing advice on how to study the module. It also includes the essential
reading and a series of self-test activities together with sample examination questions,
designed to enable students to test their understanding. The module guide is
supplemented each year with the pre-exam update, made available on the VLE.
u a module page with news and updates, provided by legal academics associated
with the Laws Programme;
u pre-exam updates;
u discussion forums where students can debate and interact with other students;
u law reports;
Core text
Students should refer to the following core text and specific reading references are
provided for this text in each chapter of the module guide:
¢ Dignam, A. and J. Lowry Company law. (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2020)
11th edition [ISBN 9780198848455].
ASSESSMENT
Formative assessment is conducted through tasks in the module guide, which include
self-assessment activities with feedback. There are additional online activities in the
form of multiple choice questions. The formative assessment will prepare students to
reach the module learning outcomes tested in the summative assessment.
Permitted materials
Students are permitted to bring into the examination room the following document:
Please be aware that the format and mode of assessment may need to change in
light of extraordinary events beyond our control, for example, an outbreak such as
the coronavirus (COVID-19) pandemic. In the event of any change, students will be
informed of any new assessment arrangements via the VLE.
1 Introduction
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2
Introduction
This module guide acts as a focal point for your study of Company law. It is intended
to aid your comprehension by taking you carefully through each aspect of the
subject. Each chapter also provides an opportunity to digest and review what you
have learned by allowing a pause to think and complete activities. At the end of
each chapter there are sample examination questions to attempt once you have
completed and digested the further reading.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings , you should be able to:
u approach the study of Company law in a systematic way
u understand what the various elements of the module guide are designed to do
u begin your study of Company law with confidence.
Company Law 1 Introduction page 3
Company law is one of those subjects that students describe as difficult and lecturers
describe as challenging. The difficulty or challenge involved for the student in
understanding company law is to overcome the attitude that law is somehow
compartmentalised. Most of your previous undergraduate teaching has tended to
package subjects neatly – tort, contract, equity, etc. While this provides a nice orderly
initial learning experience it is unhelpful for students when they come to subjects like
company law where tort, contract, and equity all combine. The result can be an initial
disorientation which clears over time. As such, it is important that you have a good
knowledge of tort, contract and equity, and understand how the common law works,
before you tackle this subject.
The CA 2006 was brought into force during the period 2007–09.
Further reading
You will also find further ideas in the following two pieces of reading:
¢ Reisberg, A. ‘Corporate law in the UK after recent reforms: the good, the bad and
the ugly’ (2010) Current Legal Problems 315 (available in LexisLibrary).
Do this throughout the chapter and when you have completed it move to the Core
text. After this give yourself some time to think about what you have learned or if
things are unclear you may need to read over certain points again. Once you have read
the chapter and the Core text, attempt, in writing, the chapter’s activities. Use them as
page 4 University of London
an opportunity to test your understanding of the area. At this point read the feedback
provided to see if you are on the right track. Once you have completed this, move to
the Further reading. Again, after completing the Further reading, give yourself time to
think and re-read. Finally, you should attempt the sample examination question at the
end of each chapter. Use the ‘Reflect and review’ section at the end of each chapter to
keep track of your progress.
Go through the guide like this, covering each chapter in turn. Each chapter builds up
your knowledge of the subject and so dipping into the guide as you feel like it will not
work. Later chapters presume you have covered and understood the earlier ones. As
we explain below, you will also have to monitor case developments, reform initiatives
and seek out new company law writing to flesh out your understanding of the subject
and develop your independence of thought.
1.2.1 Readings
Core text
¢ Dignam, A. and J. Lowry Company law. (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2020)
11th edition [ISBN 9780198848455].
This module guide is centred on this textbook, which was written by the authors
of this guide. References in the text to ‘Dignam and Lowry’ are references to this
textbook. You may have an earlier edition of this textbook. You will be able to find the
relevant readings for this course by using the contents list and index of any earlier
edition.
It is your core reading and so much of your study time should be taken up reading the
textbook, though you will also have to study numerous case reports, complete the
further reading and keep up to date with academic company law writing.
Further reading
¢ Davies, P.L. and S. Worthington Gower and Davies: principles of modern company
law. (London: Sweet & Maxwell, 2016) 10th edition [ISBN 9780414056268].
This text is particularly interesting as it fleshes out the interaction of company law
with capital markets and securities regulation.
¢ Worthington, S. Sealy & Worthington’s text, cases and materials in company law.
(Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2016) 11th edition [ISBN 9780198722052].
¢ Dignam, A. Hicks & Goo’s cases and materials on company law. (Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 2011) seventh edition [ISBN 9780199564293].
This book places the study of company law in its economic, business and social
context. This makes the cases, statutes and other forms of regulation that make up
company law more accessible and relevant.
Three significant books are also drawn to your attention. We don’t suggest you buy
these texts but rather that you use them in a library (if you can get access to one).
¢ Parkinson, J.E. Corporate power and responsibility: issues in the theory of company
law. (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1995) [ISBN 9780198259893].
Company Law 1 Introduction page 5
¢ Cheffins, B.R. Company law: theory, structure and operation. (Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 1997) [ISBN 9780198764694].
Parkinson (1995) examines the corporate law issues surrounding the ‘stakeholder’
debate in the UK (there is more on this in Chapter 16 on corporate governance, but
for now it refers to a debate about whether ‘stakeholders’, such as employees and
consumers, and issues raised by environmentalists and public interest bodies should
be the focus of the exercise of corporate power). John Parkinson also chaired the
corporate governance group as part of the Department of Trade and Industry’s (now
called the Department for Business, Energy and Industrial Strategy (BEIS)) CLRSG
Review of UK company law. His views are therefore important in understanding the
CLRSG findings and the corporate governance provisions in the CA 2006.
The second book we would draw your attention to here is Cheffins (1997). The
company law and economics school is a growing and influential one in UK company
law. Knowledge of it is essential to an understanding of many of the current debates in
company law.
The third book, Dignam and Galanis (2009), provides a perspective on the corporate
governance material used in this module guide, based around the globalisation of
product and securities markets.
A statute book is a good addition to your personal company law library. These are
generally updated every year and it is important that you use the most up to date
version. A good choice is:
You are currently allowed to bring this book into the examination. Check the
Regulations for up to date details of what you are allowed to bring into the
examination with you.
Please note that you are allowed to underline or highlight text in these documents –
but you are not allowed to write notes or attach self-adhesive notelets, etc. on them.
See the Regulations for further guidance on these matters.
Legal journals
A good Company law student is expected to be familiar and up to date with the latest
articles and books on company law. Company law articles often appear in the main
general UK legal academic journals:
It is essential that you keep up to date with developments reported in these journals.
Specific dedicated company or business law journals are also very useful for company
law students. The Company Lawyer, Journal of Corporate Law Studies, European Business
Organisation Law Review and Journal of Business Law are among the best, combining
current academic analysis of issues with updates on case law and statute.
Other sources
Your understanding of many of the issues we will study will be aided immeasurably if
you understand the context within which company law issues affect businesses. All
major national newspapers cover these issues in their business sections. In an ideal
world you would read these sections each day, either by buying a newspaper, reading
it online or going to the library to go through them.
page 6 University of London
While company law cases appear in the main law reports there are two dedicated
company law reports, British Company Law Cases (BCC) (published yearly by Sweet
& Maxwell) and Butterworth’s Company Law Cases (BCLC), which are very useful.
Online sources such as Westlaw and Lexis, which you can access through the Online
Library, also carry these reports as well as unreported cases. You might also find it
useful sometimes to dip into texts such as Palmer’s Company Law (Sweet & Maxwell)
(available in Westlaw via the Online Library) or Gore-Browne on Companies (Jordan
Publishing) in a good law library (if you can access one). These are practitioner texts
which are regularly updated and contain a wealth of up to date information.
2 Forms of business organisation
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8
Introduction
Companies are the dominant form of business association in the UK. They are not,
however, the only form of business association. Sole traders and partnerships also
exist as specific legal forms of business. In this chapter we explore the place of the
company within the various legal forms of business organisation available in the UK in
order to provide some insight as to how the company has come to be the dominant
form. In doing so we will consider the various forms of business organisation from the
point of view of their ability to raise capital (money), their ability to minimise risk and
their ability to provide some sort of clear organisational structure. We will also explore
some of the general problems that the corporate form poses for businesses.
In general this subject is not a course in the detailed procedural aspects of company
law. Having said that, in this chapter, more than any other in the guide, we will touch
upon procedural matters as they arise. This is because key aspects of the procedural
nature of setting up a company are very useful for understanding later chapters such
as Chapter 5: ‘Company formation, promoters and pre-incorporation contracts’ and
Chapter 9: ‘Dealing with insiders’. Some of you may find this procedural detail off-
putting, but bear with it and complete the activities. It will pay dividends in the later
chapters.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings, you should be able to:
u illustrate the differences between the major forms of business organisation in
the UK
u describe the advantages and disadvantages of each form of business
organisation
u explain the different categories of company
u demonstrate the difficulties small businesses have with the company as a form
of business organisation.
Core text
¢ Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 1: ‘Introduction to company law’.
Company Law 2 Forms of business organisation page 9
Advantages
u No legal filing requirements or fees and no professional advice is needed to set it
up. You just literally go into business on your own and the law will recognise it as
having legal form.
Disadvantages
u It is not a particularly useful business form for raising capital (money). For most
sole traders the capital will be provided by personal savings or a bank loan.
Activity 2.1
From the point of view of raising capital, minimising risk and providing an
organisational structure, assess the merits of a sole trading concern.
No feedback provided.
Advantages
u No formal legal filing requirement involved in becoming a partnership beyond the
minimum requirement that there be two members of the partnership. Once there
are two people who form the business it will be deemed a legal partnership.
u If you are aware of the problems the Partnership Act can cause (see disadvantages
below) then you can draft a partnership agreement to vary these terms of the
Act and provide an accurate reflection of your intentions when entering the
partnership. The partnership agreement can therefore be used to provide a very
flexible organisational structure although this usually involves having to pay for
legal advice.
page 10 University of London
Disadvantages
u The Partnership Act 1890 can be a danger to the unwary. The broad definition of a
partnership is a particular problem. For example, three people going into business
together without forming a company will be partners whether they know it or not.
This can cause problems, as the Partnership Act 1890 imposes certain conditions
for the continued existence of the partnership. If one of our three unknowing
partners dies, the Partnership Act will deem the partnership (even though the
participants did not know they were partners) to have ended. This is the case even
where a successful business is being operated through the partnership. As a result
of these types of problems those who choose to be partners will usually draft a
more formal arrangement called a partnership agreement specifying the terms
and conditions of the partnership. The Act also entitles each partner:
u to participate in management
u A partnership will end on the death of a partner. If you are unaware of this when
the partnership is formed, the rigidity of the Act may not reflect the intention of
the partners.
u The partners are jointly and severally liable for the debts of the partnership. This
means that each partner can be sued for the total debts of the partnership. In
essence, partnerships are founded on relationships of trust. If that trust is breached
then the remaining partner or partners can pay a heavy price as they must pay
all the debts owed. However, if that relationship of trust is maintained then the
partnership effectively reduces the risk of doing business compared to that taken
by a sole trader because partners share the risk.
Activity 2.2
From the point of view of raising capital, minimising risk and providing an
organisational structure, assess the merits of a partnership.
No feedback provided.
u In private companies investment comes either from the founding members in the
form of personal savings or from a bank loan. Private companies are prohibited
from raising capital from the general public.
u Public companies, on the other hand, are formed specifically to raise large
amounts of money from the general public.
u Private companies can restrict their membership to those the directors approve
of or insist that those who wish to leave the company first offer their shares to
the other members. Public companies could also do this but, as their aim is to
raise money from the general public, a restriction on the sale of shares would not
encourage the general public to invest.
u Public companies are generally subject to a lot more regulation than private
companies. For example, public companies must have at least two directors;
private companies need have only one. Public companies must have a ‘company
secretary’. Private companies can choose whether or not to have one.
u Private companies can also adopt a more streamlined procedure for passing
shareholder resolutions. Instead of having to pass resolutions at a meeting at
which shareholders are physically present, Part 13 of the CA 2006 allows most
resolutions, in private companies, to be passed ‘in writing’.
Limited liability
One of the most obvious differences between the company and other forms of
business organisation is that the members of both private and public companies have
limited liability. This means that the members of the company are only liable for the
amount unpaid on their shares and not for the debts of the company. We will explore
how this operates in some detail in the next chapter. In order to warn those who
might deal with a company that the members have limited liability the word ‘limited’
or ‘Ltd’ must appear after a private company’s name or ‘plc’ after a public company
(ss.58 and 59 CA 2006).
The memorandum
Prior to the CA 2006, the memorandum was a fairly substantial document which those
forming a company needed to prepare. It contained a lot of information, including
details of the company’s share capital, its registered office and the ‘objects’ of the
company (see below). The CA 2006 changed this. Now, most of this information is
contained either in the company’s articles of association, or in the application form
that must be submitted to register the company. Now, the memorandum only needs
to state:
u that the ‘subscribers’ (i.e. those forming the company) wish to form a company;
and
u if the company is to have a share capital, that each subscriber agrees to take at
least one share in the company.
At least one person must ‘subscribe’ to the memorandum (this used to mean they had
to ‘sign’ it; now they need only ‘authenticate’ it). In essence, they agree to take some
shares or share in the company and become its first shareholders.
It used to be the case that companies had to fix, and state in their memorandum, an
‘authorised’ amount of capital. This was the maximum amount of share capital the
company could raise (although the figure could be increased later). It is no longer
necessary for companies to have an authorised share capital (but a company that was
formed before the CA 2006 came into force would have declared what its authorised
capital was, and such companies are still limited to that amount unless they either
increase it, or remove the limit entirely). Shares can be fully paid, partly paid or even
unpaid. With partly and unpaid shares, the shareholder can be called upon to pay
for them at a later date. Shares may be also be paid for in goods and services and not
necessarily in cash.
clause’. This was a statement of the objects (i.e. the activities) the company was being
set up to pursue. Now, companies can choose whether to have any statement of their
objects, but if they decide to do so, such a clause must now to be put in the company’s
articles, rather than its memorandum. We shall examine the legal consequences of
either including, or not including, such a clause in Chapter 13, when we consider the
so-called ultra vires doctrine.
Advantages
u Companies are designed as investment vehicles. Companies have the ability
to subdivide their capital into small amounts, allowing them to draw in huge
numbers of investors who also benefit from the sub-division by being able to sell
on small parts of their investment.
u Limited liability also minimises the risk for investors and is said to encourage
investment. It is also said to allow managers to take greater risk in the knowledge
that the shareholders will not lose everything.
Disadvantages
u Forming a company and complying with company law is more expensive and
time-consuming.
Activity 2.3
a. What are the advantages and disadvantages of each form of business
organisation?
No feedback provided.
The key difficulty arises because the statutory model assumes a separation of
ownership from control. That is, it assumes that the investors are residual controllers
exercising control once a year at the annual general meeting (AGM) and that the
day-to-day management of the business is carried out by professional managers
(directors). For large companies this is the case but for the vast majority of companies
in the UK this separation of ownership from control does not exist (see Chapter 14).
To illustrate this we need to examine how, for both a large and a small company,
company law presumes the ownership and control system within the statutory model
operates.
page 14 University of London
u The executive directors will normally have a small shareholding but not usually a
significant one.
u The shareholders are also provided with an annual report from the directors
outlining the performance of the company over the past year and the prospects
for the future (like a sort of report card on their performance). At the heart of the
report are the accounts certified by the auditor (an independent accountant who
checks over the accounts prepared by the directors).
u In between AGMs the directors run the company with little involvement by the
shareholders.
u In a large company the board of directors will be more like a policy body which sets
the direction the company goes in, but the actual implementation of that direction
will be carried out by the company’s employees.
†
u The directors in carrying out their function stand in a fiduciary† relationship with A fiduciary is a person
the company. They therefore owe a duty to act bona fides (in good faith) in the who is bound to act in the
interests of the company (this generally means the shareholders’ interests) and not interests and for the benefit
for any other purpose (such as self-enrichment – see Chapter 15). of another; trustees also have
fiduciary duties.
u The employees who are authorised to carry out the company’s business are the
company’s agents and therefore the company will be bound by their actions (see
Chapter 13).
u The same people will also be the only employees of the company.
These differences (in effect the requirements for meetings and accounts), which
are based on a presumption of the managers being different people from the
shareholders, became a burden for small companies. As a result, over many years, UK
company law was modified in an attempt to reduce some of the requirements and
burdens on private companies. The CA 2006 continued this process, under the slogan
of ‘Think Small First’ (see below).
Advantages
u Prestige. The small businesses surveyed considered that one of the major
advantages (in fact possibly the only advantage) of forming a company was that it
conferred prestige, legitimacy and credibility on the venture.
u Limited liability. The ability of those who are behind the company to walk away
from the company’s debts. However for small businesses this was potentially
Company Law 2 Forms of business organisation page 15
Disadvantages
u Burdensome regulatory requirements (meetings, accounts, etc.).
u Expensive as they had to pay for professional advice to deal with the regulatory
requirements.
Solutions
Historically company law has not ignored this problem. Many changes were made,
even before the CA 2006 was enacted. For example, the CA 1985 allowed private
companies to adopt what it called ‘the elective regime’, in s.379A. This allowed private
companies to have simpler and less burdensome rules governing:
u shareholder meetings
u timing of meetings
u laying of accounts.
However, these concessions were largely seen as insufficient. The CLRSG (the body
that was in charge of developing proposals for what would become the CA 2006)
recommended, in its Final Report (Modern Company Law for a Competitive Economy:
Final Report (2001), Chapters 2 and 4) that more statutory requirements be simplified
for small businesses, covering:
u decision-making
u accounts
u audit
u constitutional structure
u dispute resolution.
The CLRSG also recommended that legislation on private companies should be made
easier to understand. In particular, there should be a clear statement of the duties of
directors. As we shall see, many of these recommendations were followed, and the CA
2006 does quite a lot to simplify the law for private companies.
But concerns still remain that company law is too burdensome for the smaller
company and the effort to reduce the ‘regulatory burden’ continues. In recent years,
the UK Government has carried out a number of public consultations to discover
whether further relaxations in the law for private companies are appropriate. And in
2015, it enacted the Small Business, Enterprise and Employment Act which reduced the
amount of information that must be ‘filed’ with the Registrar of Companies.
Minority issues
The fact that there are so few participants in a small business presents another
problem for company law. That is, sometimes they disagree and if this continues, a
minority shareholder can easily be excluded from the running of the company while
remaining trapped within it. This occurs because company law presumes that the
company operates through its constitutional organs. In order for the company to
operate either the board of directors makes a decision or, if it cannot, then the general
meeting can do so. It can, however, happen that a majority of shareholders holding
51 per cent (simple majority voting power) of the shares in the company could act
to the detriment of the other 49 per cent. A 51 per cent majority would allow those
members to elect only those who support their policies to the board. Thus the 49 per
cent shareholder would be unrepresented on the board and powerless in the general
meeting.
page 16 University of London
These situations are worse in private companies where the minority shareholder often
needs board approval for the sale of shares to an outsider or must offer the shares to
the other members first. If the other members are obstructive then this pre-emption
process can leave the minority shareholders trapped. Of course the fact that the
majority holder is behaving badly will make it difficult to find a buyer willing to put
themselves into a similarly weak position. One limited source of protection that has
long been available to minority shareholders is that they are allowed (in some cases at
least) to enforce any personal rights they enjoy under the company’s constitution (see
Chapters 11 and 12). However, for reasons which will be explored later, that protection
is often ineffective for a minority, especially where the minority’s complaint relates
to misbehaviour by the company’s directors (see Chapters 14 and 15). Eventually, a
statutory remedy was introduced in s.459 CA 1985 and is now contained in s.994 CA
2006 to make it easier for shareholders to bring an action.
Activity 2.4
From the point of view of raising capital, minimising risk and providing an
organisational structure, assess the merits of a registered company.
No feedback provided.
Activity 2.5
Is the corporate form suitable for small companies?
Summary
The importance of this chapter is that it forms a context within which we can place
the company and its success as a business form. The sole trader may be a suitable
approach for informal one-person ventures, where the capital is mostly provided by
the sole trader’s savings or a bank loan. It is unsuitable for larger organisational or
investment purposes.
The partnership is a very good business form which has many advantages over a
company, particularly for small- and medium-sized businesses. However, compared
to the company, it is now used less frequently, and the company in turn has come to
dominate.
However the company as a form of business organisation is not without its problems.
The company is designed as an investment vehicle, with limited liability for its
shareholders and a clear organisational structure. It is designed for ventures where
there is an effective separation of ownership from control and is therefore largely
unsuitable for the majority of its users, who are small businesses. In many ways a
partnership would be more suitable for an entrepreneur and less onerous for small
businesses generally, especially given that limited liability is rarely a reality for these
types of businesses. However, the continued use of the corporate form by small
companies seems secure given the prestige attached to the tag ‘Ltd’. The CA 2006 has
gone some way towards meeting the needs of small businesses.
Further reading
¢ Freedman, J. ‘Small businesses and the corporate form: burden or privilege?’
(1994) 57 MLR 555–84.
u The distinction company law makes between public and private companies.
u The historical concessions in the elective regime in s.379A CA 1985 and Table A,
Article 53.
u Minority protection concessions for small businesses and the fact that the CLRSG
and the 2006 Act increase protection for minorities.
u A discussion of the CLRSG’s ‘think small first’ approach and its effect in the CA 2006.
page 18 University of London
Need to revise first = There are one or two areas I am unsure about and need to revise
before I go on to the next chapter.
Need to study again = I found many or all of the principles outlined in this chapter
very difficult and need to go over them again before I move on.
If you ticked ‘need to revise first’, which sections of the chapter are you going to
revise?
Must Revision
revise done
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
Introduction
In this chapter we explore the related concepts of corporate legal personality and
limited liability. These concepts are central to developing understanding of company
law and it is essential that you take time here to absorb these fundamental principles.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings, you should be able to:
u explain what is meant by ‘corporate legal personality’
u illustrate the key effects of corporate legal personality in relation to liability.
Core text
¢ Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 2: ‘Corporate personality and limited liability’.
Cases
¢ Salomon v Salomon & Co [1897] AC 22
¢ Barings plc (In Liquidation) v Coopers & Lybrand (No.4) [2002] 2 BCLC 364
However, things did not go well for the leather business and within a year Mr Salomon
had to sell his debenture to save the business. This did not have the desired effect
and the company was placed in insolvent liquidation (i.e. it had too little money to
pay its debts) and a liquidator was appointed (a court-appointed official who sells
off the remaining assets and distributes the proceeds to those who are owed money
by the company – see Chapter 17). The liquidator alleged that the company was but a
sham and a mere ‘alias’ or agent for Mr Salomon and that Mr Salomon was therefore
personally liable for the debts of the company. The Court of Appeal agreed, finding
that the shareholders had to be a bona fide association who intended to go into
business and not just hold shares to comply with the Companies Acts.
page 22 University of London
u the fact that some of the shareholders were only holding shares as a technicality
was irrelevant; the registration procedure could be used by an individual to carry
on what was in effect a one-man business
The decision also confirmed that the use of debentures instead of shares can further
protect investors.
Activity 3.1
Read Salomon v Salomon & Co [1897] AC 22.
a. Describe the key effects of the change in status from a sole trader to a limited
company for Mr Salomon.
b. What are the key principles that we can draw from the case?
c. Should Mr Salomon have been liable for the debts of the company?
3.3.1 Macaura
The principle in Salomon is best illustrated by examining some of the key cases that
followed after. In Macaura v Northern Assurance Co [1925] AC 619 Mr Macaura owned an
estate and some timber. He agreed to sell all the timber on the estate in return for the
entire issued share capital of Irish Canadian Saw Mills Ltd. The timber, which amounted
to almost the entire assets of the company, was then stored on the estate. On 6
February 1922 Mr Macaura insured the timber in his own name. Two weeks later a fire
destroyed all the timber on the estate. Mr Macaura tried to claim under the insurance
policy. The insurance company refused to pay out arguing that he had no insurable
interest in the timber as the timber belonged to the company. Allegations of fraud
were also made against Mr Macaura but never proven. Eventually in 1925 the issue
arrived before the House of Lords who found that:
u Mr Macaura, even though he owned all the shares in the company, had no insurable
interest in the property of the company
u just as corporate personality facilitates limited liability by having the debts belong
to the corporation and not the members, it also means that the company’s assets
belong to it and not to the shareholders.
More modern examples of the Salomon principle and the Macaura problem can be
seen in cases such as Barings plc (In Liquidation) v Coopers & Lybrand (No.4) [2002]
2 BCLC 364. In that case a loss suffered by a parent company as a result of a loss at
its subsidiary (a company in which it held all the shares) was not actionable by the
parent – the subsidiary was the proper plaintiff. In essence you can’t have it both
ways – limited liability has huge advantages for shareholders but it also means that the
company is a separate legal entity with its own property, rights and obligations (see
also Giles v Rhind [2003] 2 WLR 237, Shaker v Al-Bedrawi [2003] 2 WLR 922 and Hashem v
Shayif [2008] EWHC 2380 (Fam)).
Company Law 3 The nature of legal personality page 23
3.3.2 Lee
Another good illustration is Lee v Lee’s Air Farming [1961] AC 12. Mr Lee incorporated a
company, Lee’s Air Farming Ltd, in August 1954 in which he owned all the shares. Mr
Lee was also the sole ‘Governing Director’ for life. Thus, as with Mr Salomon, he was
in essence a sole trader who now operated through a corporation. Mr Lee was also
employed as chief pilot of the company. In March, 1956, while Mr Lee was working, the
company plane he was flying stalled and crashed. Mr Lee was killed in the crash leaving
a widow and four infant children.
The company, as part of its statutory obligations, had been paying an insurance policy
to cover claims brought under the Workers’ Compensation Act. The widow claimed
she was entitled to compensation under the Act as the widow of a ‘worker’. The issue
went first to the New Zealand Court of Appeal who found that he was not a ‘worker’
within the meaning of the Act and so no compensation was payable. The case was
appealed to the Privy Council in London. They found that:
u the company and Mr Lee were distinct legal entities and therefore capable of
entering into legal relations with one another
u as such they had entered into a contractual relationship for him to be employed as
the chief pilot of the company
u he could in his role of Governing Director give himself orders as chief pilot. It was
therefore a master and servant relationship and as such he fitted the definition of
‘worker’ under the Act. The widow was therefore entitled to compensation.
Activity 3.2
Read Macaura v Northern Assurance Co [1925] AC 619 and Lee v Lee’s Air Farming [1961]
AC 12 carefully and then write a brief 300-word summary of each case.
Re-read Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 2, paras 2.2–2.12 and paras 2.32–2.45.
Summary
There are some key points to take from this chapter. First, it is important at this stage
that you grasp the concept of corporate personality. If at this stage you do not, then
take some time to think about it and when you are ready come back and re-read
Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 2, paras 2.2–2.12. Second, having grasped the concept of
corporate personality you also need to understand its consequences (i.e. the fact that
the company can hold its own property and be responsible for its own debts).
page 24 University of London
Further reading
¢ Ireland, P. et al. ‘The conceptual foundations of modern company law’ (1987) 14
JLS 149–65.
¢ Pettit, B. ‘Limited liability – a principle for the 21st century’ (1995) CLP 124.
¢ Grantham, R.B. and E.F. Rickett ‘The bootmaker’s legacy to company law
doctrine’ in Grantham, R.B. and E.F. Rickett (eds) Corporate personality in the 20th
century. (Oxford: Hart Publishing, 1998) [ISBN 9781901362831].
Go through the facts of Salomon with particular emphasis on the aspects of the case
that might be scandalous (i.e. Mr Salomon’s evasion of personal liability for the debts
of his one man company and his over-valuation of the business).
Discuss whether a ‘tidal wave of irresponsibility’ was unleashed into the business
community. Points to make here are that creditors may lose out but investment and
management risk-taking is facilitated.
page 26 University of London
Need to revise first = There are one or two areas I am unsure about and need to revise
before I go on to the next chapter.
Need to study again = I found many or all of the principles outlined in this chapter
very difficult and need to go over them again before I move on.
If you ticked ‘need to revise first’, which sections of the chapter are you going to
revise?
Must Revision
revise done
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
Introduction
As we observed in Chapter 3 the application of the Salomon principle has mostly
(remember Mr Macaura) beneficial effects for shareholders. The price of this benefit
is often paid by the company’s creditors. In most situations this is as intended by
the Companies Acts. Sometimes, however, the legislature and the courts have
intervened where the Salomon principle had the potential to be abused or has unjust
consequences. This ‘intervention’ can take many different forms. Sometimes, for
example, it may involve holding individuals inside the company liable – either to the
company itself, or to a third party who has been injured. And sometimes it may involve
simply refusing to treat a company as a separate legal personality, and working out
what rights and liabilities people have as if the company did not exist at all. We shall
refer to all these types of intervention as ‘lifting the veil of incorporation’. (Some
people have suggested that the term ‘lifting the veil’ should be used only where the
company’s separate existence is being ignored. Strictly speaking, this is probably true.
However, since many writers do use this term in a rather wider and ‘catch all’ way, that
is how it will be used in this chapter too.)
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings, you should be able to:
u describe the situations where legislation will allow the veil of incorporation to
be lifted
u explain the main categories of veil lifting applied by the courts.
Core text
¢ Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 3: ‘Lifting the veil’.
Cases
¢ Gilford Motor Company Ltd v Horne [1933] Ch 935
¢ Anglo German Breweries Ltd (in liquidation) v Chelsea Corp Inc [2012] EWHC 1481 (Ch)
Additional cases
¢ Re Todd Ltd [1990] BCLC 454
¢ Standard Chartered Bank v Pakistan National Shipping Corp (No.2) [2003] 1 AC 959
¢ National Dock Labour Board v Pinn & Wheeler Ltd [1989] BCLC 647
u s.399 CA 2006 provides that parent companies have a duty to produce group
accounts
u s.409 CA 2006 also requires the parent to provide details of the shares it holds in
the subsidiaries and the subsidiaries’ names and country of activity.
However, it was the possibility of using the corporate form to commit fraud that
prompted the introduction of a number of civil and criminal provisions. These
provisions operate to negate the effect of corporate personality and limited liability in:
u s.993 CA 2006 which provides a not much used criminal offence of fraudulent
trading
u ss.213–215 Insolvency Act 1986 which contain the most important statutory
provisions.
In Re Produce Marketing Consortium Ltd (No.2) (1989) 5 BCC 569 over a period of seven
years the company slowly drifted into insolvency. The two directors involved did
nothing wrong except that they did not put the company into liquidation after
the point of no return became apparent. They were therefore liable under s.214 to
contribute £75,000 to the debts of the company.
Sections 213 and 214 differ in the way they affect the Salomon principle. Section 213
applies to anyone involved in the carrying on of the business and therefore directly
qualifies the limitation of liability of members. Section 214 does not directly affect
the liability of members as it is aimed specifically at directors. In small companies,
directors are usually also the members of the company and so their limitation of
liability is indirectly affected. Parent companies may also have their limited liability
affected if they have acted as a shadow director. (A shadow director being anyone
other than a professional advisor from whom the directors of the company are
accustomed to take instructions or directions – see Chapter 14.)
Activity 4.1
a. Explain the difference between ss.213 and 214 of the Insolvency Act 1986.
No feedback provided.
Summary
The legislature has always been concerned to minimise the extent to which the
Salomon principle could be used as an instrument of fraud. As a result it introduced the
offence of fraudulent trading now contained in s.213 of the Insolvency Act 1986.
In Gilford Motor Company Ltd v Horne [1933] Ch 935 a former employee who was bound
by a covenant not to solicit customers from his former employers set up a company
to do so. He argued that while he was bound by the covenant the company was not.
The court found that the company was merely a front for Mr Horne and issued an
injunction against both him and the company, even though the company itself had
never signed any covenant not to solicit Gilford’s customers.
In Jones v Lipman [1962] 1 WLR 832 Mr Lipman had entered into a contract with Mr Jones
for the sale of land. Mr Lipman then changed his mind and did not want to complete
the sale. He formed a company in order to avoid the transaction and conveyed the
land to it instead. He then claimed he no longer owned the land and could not comply
with the contract. The judge found the company was but a façade or front for Mr
Lipman and granted an order for specific performance.
By the 1960s the increasingly sophisticated use of group structures was beginning to
cause the courts some difficulty with the strict application of the Salomon principle.
Take, for example, a situation where Z Ltd (the parent or holding company) owns
all the issued share capital in three other companies – A Ltd, B Ltd and C Ltd. These
companies are known as wholly owned subsidiaries (s.1159(2) CA 2006). Z Ltd controls
all three subsidiaries. In economic reality there is just one business but it is organised
through four separate legal personalities. In effect this structure allows the advantages
of limited liability to be availed of by the legal personality of the parent company. As
a result the parent could choose to conduct its more risky or liability-prone activities
through A Ltd. The strict application of the Salomon principle would mean that if things
go wrong the assets of Z Ltd, as a shareholder of A Ltd with limited liability, in theory
cannot be touched.
In DHN Ltd v Tower Hamlets [1976] 1 WLR 852 Lord Denning argued that a group of
companies was in reality a single economic entity and should be treated as one.
However, this willingness to disregard the normal legal consequences of creating
separate companies, and to follow instead the ‘economic realities’, was not universally
approved. And only two years later the House of Lords, in Woolfson v Strathclyde RC
[1978] SLT 159, specifically disapproved of Denning’s views on group structures, and
declared that the veil of incorporation could be lifted only if a company was a façade.
We can now turn to what remains arguably the most significant case in this area,
Adams v Cape Industries plc [1990] 2 WLR 657. This was a decision of the Court of Appeal,
and it is important for two reasons. First, it represents a significant move by the senior
judiciary towards introducing more certainty into the law. The feeling had grown
that earlier cases did not identify with enough clarity and precision when the veil
could be lifted. The outcome of each individual case might then depend too much on
the subjective opinion of the particular judge hearing that case. Second, the Court of
Appeal clearly preferred a narrower and more restrictive approach to when the veil
could be lifted.
In 1979 Cape sold its asbestos mining and marketing business and therefore had no
assets in the US. As a result, Adams, if he were to get any money out of Cape, would
have to enforce his US judgment in the UK, and through the UK courts. That is where
Cape’s assets were located. The UK courts would only do this, however, if either Cape
had taken part in the US proceedings (which it had not) or if Cape was itself ‘present’ in
the US. Cape argued that it was not itself present there. It pointed out that Cape itself
did not own property, or carry on any business, in the US. All property in the US, and all
activities there, were owned and carried on only by subsidiary or related companies,
but these were separate legal entities. Their presence in the US did not make Cape
present in the US.
It was in order to try to show that Cape was in fact present in the US that Mr Adams
sought to lift the corporate veil. The argument was essentially that the separation
between Cape, and these other group companies, should be ignored. The presence
of the other companies in the US would then make Cape present. Notice that he was
doing this not in order to establish that Cape was liable to him. Liability had already
been established, in the US, by default. The legal question was not: is Cape liable? It
was only: is Cape present in the US?
The Court of Appeal held in favour of Cape. That was clearly unfortunate for Mr Adams,
but what matters for us, as company lawyers, is what the court said about the grounds
when the veil can be lifted. First, the court declared that the veil cannot be lifted just
because a judge believes that it would be ‘in the interests of justice’ to do so. The
‘interests of justice’ is too vague and unpredictable a ground on which to lift the veil.
Second, the court decided that the mere fact that a group of companies constituted a
‘single economic unit’ was also not itself sufficient to allow the veil to be lifted. In this
respect, the court clearly followed the decision in Woolfson (above). The court decided
that where, in previous decisions (such as DHN, above), the veil had apparently
been lifted on this ground, this had in fact happened not merely because a group of
companies constituted a single economic unit, but rather because there also existed
some statute, or some contractual document which, on a proper interpretation of its
terms, required two or more companies in a group to be treated as one entity.
In rejecting these two grounds for veil lifting, the court concluded that:
save in cases which turn on the wording of particular statutes or contracts, the court is not
free to disregard the principle of Salomon v Salomon & Co Ltd [1897] AC 22 merely because it
considers that justice so requires. Our law, for better or worse, recognises the creation of
subsidiary companies, which though in one sense the creatures of their parent companies,
will nevertheless under the general law fall to be treated as separate legal entities with all
the rights and liabilities which would normally attach to separate legal entities.
The Court of Appeal did recognise that there was one well-established exception to
the Salomon principle, namely where a company was a ‘mere façade concealing the
true facts’. The case of Jones v Lipman (1962) above is the classic example. But the Court
of Appeal was aware that this ground was potentially rather open-ended, and itself
lacked ‘predictability’. It therefore sought to define this ground with more certainty,
suggesting that a company would be considered a mere façade where it was being
used to enable someone to avoid a pre-existing obligation (i.e. an obligation that
they had already incurred themselves). When the court then applied this test to Cape,
it held that Cape had not used any of its subsidiary or related companies to avoid
any pre-existing obligation which Cape already had. Instead, Cape had used other
companies only to shield itself from liabilities which might be incurred in the future.
And although that might make the company morally culpable there was nothing
legally wrong in doing this, and using other companies to shield Cape from future
liabilities did not make those companies mere façades.
The court then finally considered the ‘agency’ argument. This was a straightforward
application of agency principle. If the subsidiary was Cape’s agent and acting within its
actual or apparent authority, then the actions of the subsidiary would bind the parent.
The court found that the subsidiaries were independent businesses free from the day-
Company Law 4 Lifting the veil of incorporation page 33
to-day control of Cape and with no general power to bind the parent. Therefore Cape
could not be present in the US through its subsidiary agent.
Adams therefore narrows the situations where the veil of incorporation is in effect
lifted to three situations:
u where the company is a mere façade (for other examples of where a company was
held to be a façade, see Anglo German Breweries Ltd (in liquidation) v Chelsea Corp Inc
[2012] EWHC 1481 (Ch) and Trustor AB v Smallbone [2002] BCC 795)
The Court of Appeal’s judgment in Adams laid down reasonably clear, and clearly
restrictive, grounds for veil lifting. And, with a few exceptions, later courts have
largely followed, and affirmed, the Adams approach. One such exception is Creasey
v Breachwood Motors Ltd [1992] BCC 638, but that case was in turn overruled by Ord v
Belhaven Pubs Ltd [1998] 2 BCLC 447. Other exceptions include Ratiu v Conway (2006)
1 All ER 571 and Samengo-Turner v J&H Marsh & McLennan (Services) Ltd (2007) 2 All ER
(Comm) 813.
However, the general approach has been to follow Adams, and two recent decisions
of the Supreme Court have strongly affirmed its principles: see VTB Capital plc v
Nutritek International Corp [2013] UKSC 5, and Petrodel Resources Ltd v Prest [2013] UKSC
34. Petrodel is the more important of these two cases. In Petrodel, Lord Sumption
distinguished between what he referred to as the ‘evasion’ principle, and the
‘concealment’ principle. The veil could be pierced, he argued, only on the evasion
principle – where the controller of a company was using that company to evade an
obligation which the controller already had. However, for the veil to be pierced, it was
not necessary that the company which was being used in this way had been formed to
enable an obligation to be evaded. It was sufficient simply that it was now being used
to enable its controller to escape their obligation.
By the concealment principle, Lord Sumption referred to the court’s ability to see
through someone’s attempt to hide their behaviour. There are, of course, many ways
in which a person might conceal their actions. Lord Sumption was noting that using a
company was one such way. In Lord Sumption’s view, the court always has the power
to see through such a use, and in doing so identify what someone is really doing. The
court does not need to pierce the veil to do this: the court can simply get to the ‘truth’
of a person’s behaviour. If, for example, I decide to blackmail someone, and make my
victim pay the money I demand over to a company I own, the court can still regard me
as a blackmailer and receiver of that money, even though I have used a company to try
to conceal my receipt.
Activity 4.2
Read Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 3, paras 3.10–3.35 then write a short answer
considering the following statement.
‘The Court of Appeal’s decision in Adams takes an overly cautious approach to veil
lifting which does little to serve the interests of justice.’
The House of Lords seemed particularly aware that the effect of this claim was to
try to nullify the protection offered by limited liability. In its judgment the House of
Lords considered that a director or employee of a company could only be personally
liable for negligent misstatement if there was reasonable reliance by the claimant
on an assumption of personal responsibility by the director so as to create a special
relationship between them. There was no evidence in the present case that there
had been any personal dealings which could have conveyed to the claimant that
the managing director was prepared to assume personal liability for the franchise
agreement (see also Noel v Poland [2002] Lloyd’s Rep IR 30).
Other recent cases suggest that if the tort is deceit rather than negligence the courts
will more readily allow personal liability to flow to a director or employee. (See Daido
Asia Japan Co Ltd v Rothen [2002] BCC 589 and Standard Chartered Bank v Pakistan
National Shipping Corp (No.2) [2003] 1 AC 959.)
However, directors’ liability in tort has generally proved to be less than settled. In
MCA Records Inc v Charly Records Ltd (No.5) [2003] 1 BCLC 93 a director had authorised a
number of infringing acts under the Copyright Designs and Patent Act 1988. The Court
of Appeal in a very detailed consideration of the issue of directors’ liability in tort,
including the Williams case, took a more relaxed approach to the possibility of liability.
The court concluded:
The court then went on to find the director liable as a joint tortfeasor. (See also
Koninklijke Philips Electronics NV v Princo Digital Disc GmbH [2004] 2 BCLC 50, where a
company director was also held personally liable.)
Could shareholders be held liable in tort? Suppose that you own shares in a company
that operates an unsafe work system, as a result of which employees are injured. If
you are only a shareholder, it is quite unlikely you will be taking any of the decisions
that led to the unsafe work practices. Your case is more one of ‘nonfeasance’ (you
failed to stop the company operating unsafely) rather than misfeasance. In the
important decision in Chandler v Cape plc [2012] EWCA Civ 525, however, the Court of
Appeal decided that a shareholder could nevertheless be liable, if the shareholder
herself owed a duty of care to those who were injured. The Court found this duty of
care would only arise, however, for parent companies, for injuries caused by their
subsidiaries, and then only if several other conditions were satisfied. These were that
the parent itself operated in ‘the same industry as the subsidiary’, that the parent did
know, or ought to have known, as much about health and safety as did the subsidiary,
Company Law 4 Lifting the veil of incorporation page 35
that the parent knew or ought to have known that the subsidiary’s operations were
unsafe, and the subsidiary or the employee were relying on the parent to safeguard
the employee’s health and safety.
Cases decided after Chandler, however, seem to indicate a growing reluctance on the
part of UK courts to impose a duty of care on parent companies. In Thompson v Renwick
Group Ltd [2014] EWCA Civ 635, for example, the Court of Appeal refused to impose a
duty of care on a parent within a corporate group that acted only as a ‘pure holding
company’. The parent, in other words, carried on no business itself but merely owned
the shares in the subsidiary companies, which conducted all the group’s business.
This approach was also followed in Okpabi v Royal Dutch Shell plc [2018] EWCA Civ
191. Moreover, although Chandler suggested that a parent company might be liable
for ‘non-feasance’ – for its failure to prevent a subsidiary from harming others – it
now appears that a parent will be liable only where it is itself guilty of some active
misfeasance. In AAA v Unilever plc [2018] EWCA Civ 1532, the court suggested the parent
would typically owe a duty of care to those injured by a subsidiary’s negligence only if
either of the two following situations existed:
a. where the parent had in substance taken over the management of the subsidiary’s
activity, which led to the injury; or
b. where the parent had taken over the management of the particular activity of the
subsidiary, which caused the injury.
In one respect at least, however, the decision in Chandler has been broadened a little.
In Chandler the duty was expressed only as one owed towards employees. However,
in Lungowe v Vedanta Resources plc [2017] EWCA Civ 1528 the court refused to strike out
a claim brought by neighbours of a subsidiary company. The court noted that while a
claim was ‘more likely to succeed’ if brought by employees, nevertheless, a claim by
residents might still be arguable depending on the facts of the case.
Activity 4.3
Read Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 3, paras 3.36–3.56 and consider whether
involuntary creditors are adequately protected by the Adams decision.
Summary
It is important that you get a solid understanding of the issues facing the judiciary
in this area. In essence the judiciary are being asked to decide who loses out when
a business ends. In normal commercial situations this will be as the Companies Act
intends – therefore the burden falls on the creditors. However if there is a suggestion
that the company has been used for fraud or fraud-like behaviour (e.g. Jones v Lipman)
the courts may lift the veil. At various times, however, the Salomon principle was
only a starting point and the courts would lift the veil in a number of situations if the
interests of justice required them to do so. This led to great uncertainty which has
been redressed by the restrictive case of Adams. Adams has been affirmed by recent
Supreme Court decisions, such as VTB Capital and Prest v Petrodel Resources Ltd.
Faced with the difficulty of lifting the veil, some claimants have sought to use claims
in tort as an alternative. This strategy was successful in the important case of Chandler,
where the employees of a subsidiary company were able to establish that its parent
company owed them a direct duty of care, which the parent had breached when it
failed to stop its subsidiary operating in an unsafe way that injured the employees.
Further reading
¢ Ottolenghi, S. ‘From peeping behind the corporate veil to ignoring it completely’
(1990) MLR 338.
¢ Gallagher, L. and P. Zeigler ‘Lifting the corporate veil in the pursuit of justice’
(1990) JBL 292.
¢ Davies and Worthington, Chapter 8: ‘Limited liability and lifting the veil at
common law’ and Chapter 9: ‘Personal liability for abuses of limited liability’.
Consider the possible voting at the meeting. If it was unanimous, there is no problem
and the wrongful trading provisions apply to them all. However, boards vote by simple
majority and so the possibility remains that one of the directors could have dissented.
What would be that director’s position under s.214 if he or she wished to cease trading
but the rest of the board voted to continue? If that director continues to carry out
their role after the vote is he or she equally liable under s.214?
Question 2 This is a relatively straightforward question similar on its facts to the Ord
and Creasey cases.
Ord follows Adams strictly and finds that a group reorganisation to minimise financial
liability is allowable and will not engage a veil lifting exercise.
Creasey is a rogue case but it is worth applying here as an alternative, in which case
Dick and Bunny might be able to recover from the parent company. However, you
should note the more recent case law such as Ratiu v Conway (2006) 1 All ER 571 which
seems to be moving away from the narrow approach in Adams.
page 38 University of London
Need to revise first = There are one or two areas I am unsure about and need to revise
before I go on to the next chapter.
Need to study again = I found many or all of the principles outlined in this chapter
very difficult and need to go over them again before I move on.
If you ticked ‘need to revise first’, which sections of the chapter are you going to
revise?
Must Revision
revise done
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40
Introduction
In this chapter we consider the issues that arise when people (called promoters) go
though the process of incorporating a company and launching its business operations.
We examine their duties and the legal consequences that arise from contracts entered
into by promoters on behalf of the putative company prior to its registration (termed
pre-incorporation contracts).
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings, you should be able to:
u explain when a person will be treated as a promoter
u describe the duties and liabilities of promoters
u describe the issues arising from pre-incorporation contracts
u assess the impact of s.51 CA 2006 on pre-incorporation contracts and the liability
of promoters.
Core text
¢ Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 4: ‘Promoters and pre-incorporation contracts’.
Cases
¢ Erlanger v New Sombrero Phosphate Co (1878) 3 App Cas 1218
¢ Kamer van Koophandel en Fabrieken voor Amsterdam v Inspire Art Ltd (Case
C-167/01) [2003] ECR I–10155.
Company Law 5 Company formation, promoters and pre-incorporation contracts page 41
The CA 2006 does not define the term promoter. However, the judges have, on
occasions, framed tests for determining whether a person’s activities relate to the
promotion of a company. The classic statement in this regard was made by Cockburn
CJ in Twycross v Grant (1876–77) LR 2 CPD 469, who said that a promoter is:
one who undertakes to form a company with reference to a given project, and to set it
going, and who takes the necessary steps to accomplish that purpose… and so long as
the work of formation continues, those who carry on that work must, I think, retain the
character of promoters. Of course, if a governing body, in the shape of directors, has once
been formed, and they take, as I need not say they may, what remains to be done in the
way of forming the company, into their own hands, the functions of the promoters are at
an end.
They stand, in my opinion, undoubtedly in a fiduciary position. They have in their hands
the creation and moulding of the company; they have the power of defining how, and
when, and in what shape, and under what supervision, it shall start into existence and
begin to act as a trading corporation.
(Erlanger v New Sombrero Phosphate Co (1878) 3 App Cas 1218, per Lord Cairns LC.)
Activity 5.1
Read Erlanger v New Sombrero Phosphate Co (1878) 3 App Cas 1218.
Describe how the House of Lords reached the conclusion that the syndicate, as
promoters of the new company, stood in a fiduciary position to it and outline the
content of the core fiduciary duty owed by promoters.
page 42 University of London
In Erlanger v New Sombrero Phosphate Co, a syndicate purchased a mine for £55,000.
The syndicate then formed a company and through a nominee sold the mine to it
for £100,000 without disclosing their interest in the contract. The mining operations
were fruitless and the shareholders removed the original directors and the new board
successfully brought an action to have the sale rescinded. In Salomon v Salomon &
Co Ltd [1897] AC 22 (see Chapter 3), the House of Lords took the view that if the board
was not independent, disclosure of all material facts should be made to the original
shareholders. But note that in Gluckstein v Barnes [1900] AC 240 the House of Lords
refined the duty further by holding that disclosure to the original shareholders will not
be sufficient if they are not truly independent and the scheme as a whole is designed
to defraud the investing public.
As we saw above (Erlanger v New Sombrero Phosphate Co), where full disclosure is not
made by the promoters the contract is voidable at the company’s option. However,
the right to rescind will be lost where:
u the company affirms the contract (Re Cape Breton Co (1885) 29 Ch D 795)
u the company delays in exercising its right to rescind the contract.
For rescission to be available it must be possible to restore, at least substantially,
the parties to their original position unless, due to the fault of the promoter, this
possibility has been lost (Lagunas Nitrate Co v Lagunas Syndicate [1899] 2 Ch 392). Finally,
it should be noted that where the contract has been affirmed, the company can
nevertheless sue the promoter to account for the secret profit.
Activity 5.2
Read Gluckstein v Barnes [1900] AC 240.
What are the consequences of a promoter making a secret profit from a transaction
with the company?
As indicated above, the law of agency takes the view that a person cannot be an agent
of a non-existent principal and so a company cannot acquire rights or obligations
under a pre-incorporation contract. The common law position is illustrated by the
decision in Kelner v Baxter. The promoters of a hotel company entered into a contract
on its behalf for the purchase of wine. When the company formally came into
existence it ratified the contract. The wine was consumed but before payment was
made the company went into liquidation. The promoters, as agents, were sued on the
contract. They argued that liability under the contract had passed, by ratification, to
the company. It was held, however, that as the company did not exist at the time of
the agreement it would be wholly inoperative unless it was binding on the promoters
personally and a stranger cannot by subsequent ratification relieve them from that
responsibility.
On the other hand, a promoter can avoid personal liability if the company, after
incorporation, and the third party substitute the original pre-incorporation contract
with a new contract on similar terms. Novation, as this is called, may also be inferred
by the conduct of the parties such as where the terms of the original agreement
are changed (Re Patent Ivory Manufacturing Co, Howard v Patent Ivory Manufacturing
Co (1888) 38 Ch D 156). However, novation is ineffective if the company adopts
the contract due to the mistaken belief that it is bound by it (Re Northumberland
Avenue Hotel Co Ltd (1886) 33 Ch D 16). A promoter can also avoid personal liability
on a contract where he signs the agreement merely to confirm the signature of the
company because in so doing he has not held himself out as either agent or principal.
The signature and the contractual document will be a complete nullity because the
company was not in existence (Newborne v Sensolid (Great Britain) Ltd [1954] 1 QB 45).
As noted above, the common law position has now been modified, as a result of the
UK’s implementation of the First European Community Directive on Company Law, by
s.51 CA 2006 (replacing s.36C CA 1985). The provision seeks to protect the third party
by making promoters personally liable when the company, after incorporation, fails to
enter into a new contract on similar terms.
The meaning of s.51 was considered by the Court of Appeal in Phonogram Ltd v Lane
[1982] QB 938. Lord Denning MR took the phrase ‘subject to any agreement to the
contrary’ to mean that for a promoter to avoid personal liability the contract must
expressly provide for his exclusion. The Court also held that it is not necessary for
the putative company to be in the process of creation at the time the contract was
entered into. In Braymist Ltd v Wise Finance Co Ltd [2002] 1 BCLC 415, an issue before the
Court of Appeal was whether a person acting as agent of an unformed company could
enforce a pre-incorporation contract under s.51. It was held that although the terms
of the first Directive referred only to liability and not to enforcement, it did not follow
page 44 University of London
The pan-European business entity, the European Company (SE), which became
available in October 2004, will address the concerns of those Member States wishing
to regulate under-capitalised companies operating within their jurisdictions. Further,
the draft 14th EC Company Law Harmonisation Directive aims to facilitate corporate
migration. A company will be able to move its registered office between Member
States without having to disrupt its operations by reincorporating in the host
jurisdiction.
Activity 5.3
Read Phonogram Ltd v Lane [1982] QB 938 and Braymist Ltd v Wise Finance Co Ltd
[2002] 1 BCLC 415.
Re-read Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 4, paras 4.14–4.21.
What is the policy underlying s.51 CA 2006?
Summary
The key point to understand is that promoters are fiduciaries. Where promoters fail to
disclose a profit to an independent board of directors the company can require them
to account for it (i.e. to disgorge the profit). Section 51 of the CA 2006 is designed to
protect third parties contracting with promoters by making the promoters personally
liable on pre-incorporation contracts.
Company Law 5 Company formation, promoters and pre-incorporation contracts page 45
Further reading
¢ Davies and Worthington, Chapter 5: ’Promoters’.
¢ Worthington, S. Sealy & Worthington’s text, cases and materials in company law.
(Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2016) 11th edition [ISBN 9780198722052].
You need to discuss what ‘promoters’ are: see Twycross v Grant. The liquidator will be
concerned with:
Both Jill and Gerald are promoters and owe fiduciary duties to the company. They
are therefore precluded from making secret profits unless full disclosure of the
transaction is made to an independent board which consents to the profits (Erlanger
v New Sombrero Phosphate Co). However, the question states that Jill, Harry and Gerald
are the sole directors. As such, are they independent? If you conclude they are not, you
should discuss Salomon v Salomon. If they are also its sole members then, according
to Gluckstein v Barnes, disclosure to them will not suffice either because they are not
truly independent. In this situation you should argue whether Gluckstein should be
distinguished – if the company is private so that the scheme is not designed to defraud
the investing public, the court may distinguish Gluckstein on its facts.
You will need to consider the company’s remedies of rescission and accounting of
profits (Lagunas Nitrate Co v Lagunas Syndicate). Note the circumstances in which
rescission may be lost (Re Cape Breton Co) and that for rescission to be available it must
be possible to restore the parties to their original position unless, due to the fault of
the promoter, this possibility has been lost: Lagunas Nitrate Co v Lagunas Syndicate.
Even if the respective contracts with Jill and Gerald have been affirmed, the company
can nevertheless sue them to account for their secret profits.
Harry has entered into a pre-incorporation contract. Because the company did not
exist at the time of this contract, can it be bound by it? You need to discuss Kelner
v Baxter. Further, you will need to consider s.51 CA 2006, which makes a promoter
personally liable unless there is an agreement with the third party, British Telecom, to
the contrary (see Phonogram Ltd v Lane). For Harry to avoid liability the company must
enter into a new contract with British Telecom on the same terms as that made by him
(novation).
Company Law 5 Company formation, promoters and pre-incorporation contracts page 47
Need to revise first = There are one or two areas I am unsure about and need to revise
before I go on to the next chapter.
Need to study again = I found many or all of the principles outlined in this chapter
very difficult and need to go over them again before I move on.
If you ticked ‘need to revise first’, which sections of the chapter are you going to
revise?
Must Revision
revise done
Notes
6 Raising capital: equity
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
Introduction
Companies can raise money in a number of ways. For small companies the owner’s
savings or bank loans usually provide the necessary finance. However, as companies
grow they may also wish to raise capital in the form of equity (shares) from the general
public. In this chapter we will examine the legal issues surrounding raising equity from
the general public.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings , you should be able to:
u distinguish between raising capital for public and private companies
u outline the relevant methods of selling shares to the general public
u describe how the listing regime protects investors
u explain the sanctions available where insider dealing has occurred.
Core text
¢ Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 5: ‘Raising capital: equity and its consequences’.
Company Law 6 Raising capital: equity page 51
Public companies are designed to secure investment from the general public. As such
they can advertise the fact that they are offering shares to the public. In doing so the
company must issue a prospectus giving a detailed and accurate description of the
company’s plans (see below). Because the general public are involved and need to be
protected, the initial capital requirements for a public company are more onerous than
for a private one. As we noted in Chapter 2, there is a minimum capital requirement of
£50,000 (s.763 CA 2006). However, the capital requirement may be partly paid so the
company does not actually have to have £50,000; it just needs one-quarter of that to
be ‘paid up’, plus the ability to call on the members for the remaining amount (s.586 CA
2006). While there is no formal limitation on public companies preventing them from
transferring shares as private companies do, it would be highly unusual, given that the
aim is to raise money from the general public, who would be discouraged by such a
restriction. In any case, if the public company is listed on the LSE such restrictions on
transfer will be prohibited. Public companies also attract a higher level of regulation.
Public companies are not necessarily listed on the stock exchange, but as we noted
above, some public companies may decide to raise capital on the LSE. This involves
applying to the LSE and fulfilling a very strict set of criteria to ensure the business
is a sound one. A listing on the stock exchange is essentially a private contractual
arrangement between a public company and the LSE (itself a listed public company)
to gain access to a very sophisticated market for its shares. The public company, once
it gains access to the stock market, is then generally known as a listed company
and its shares as listed shares or securities. The LSE offers the facility of a secondary
market, that is, a place where shares can be traded after they have been issued to
shareholders. It also functions as a capital market for companies to sell new shares to
the general public who can then trade them on the stock exchange. A listing also has
the advantage that investors will have greater confidence in the business if it is within
the regulatory ambit of the LSE and investors will be able to sell their shares easily
through the LSE. The shareholders of listed companies tend to be what are called
institutional investors. These institutional investors are made up of pension funds,
insurance companies, professional management funds who are investing funds on
behalf of individuals and, increasingly, the investment vehicles of foreign states, which
are usually referred to as ‘Sovereign Wealth Funds’
page 52 University of London
Activity 6.1
Explain the differences between a private and a public company for capital raising
purposes.
No feedback provided.
Summary
There are several distinctions between public and private companies. Perhaps the key
distinction is that private companies cannot raise funds from the general public. As a
result public companies are the major vehicles for capital (equity) raising in the UK.
If a public company wishes to raise large amounts of equity then it might consider
applying to be listed on the LSE.
u The company could offer its shares for subscription itself. This is done by issuing a
prospectus and advertising in the trade or general press.
u An offer for sale. This is where the company has an agreement with an issuing
house (a merchant bank) whereby it will allot its entire issue of shares to the
issuing house. The issuing house will then try to sell the shares to its clients and the
general public. The advantage of this type of sale is that the issuing house takes the
risk that the shares will not sell.
u A placing. Here the shares may not be offered to the general public at all, but are
‘placed’ with the clients of a merchant bank or group of merchant banks.
u The company could raise money through a rights issue. This is where new
shares are offered to the existing shareholders in proportion to their existing
shareholding. These pre-emption rights are conferred on shareholders by s.561
CA 2006. Once a company is listed, further capital raising is more straightforward
without the complication of the initial listing process.
Once a company has obtained a listing by complying with the listing rules it can only
maintain listed status if it complies with the continuing obligations specified in the
listing rules. The LSE’s statutory obligation to operate an orderly market also obliges it
to monitor listed companies on an ongoing basis. As such the LSE and the FCA have an
important co-operative role.
Company Law 6 Raising capital: equity page 53
Activity 6.2
a. What is a listed company?
c. What are the major forms of selling shares to the general public?
No feedback provided.
contain all such information as investors and their professional advisers would reasonably
require, and reasonably expect to find there, for the purpose of making an informed
assessment of: (a) the assets and liabilities, financial position, profits and losses, and
prospects of the issuer of the securities; and (b) the rights attaching to those securities.
s.80(1) FSMA 2000.
Thus the requirements aim to provide potential investors with such core information
about the company’s activities as will allow them to make an informed investment
decision. If shares by listed companies are offered to the public a prospectus (the
document issued to the public inviting them to invest in the shares) submitted to,
and approved by, the FCA is required. Since 2005 and the implementation of the
Prospectus Directive (Directive 2003/71/EC) in the Prospectus Regulations 2005,
a single regime is now in place in Part VI of the FSMA regulating the prospectus
requirements of listed and non-listed offerings.
The other regulatory body we have noted already, namely the FCA. It is responsible
for regulation of conduct in retail, as well as wholesale, financial markets and the
infrastructure that supports those markets. As we have seen, it acts as the UK Listing
Authority.
Activity 6.3
What is the listing regime trying to achieve by emphasising disclosure before and
after listing?
Summary
When listing, a company has a number of possible methods of selling its shares:
offering its shares itself for subscription, an offer for sale, a placing or a rights issue if
already listed. The FCA is the UK’s main financial regulator and is the listing authority in
the UK. By necessity it works closely with the LSE to ensure that the listing regime, with
its emphasis on disclosure, operates effectively.
[a]n individual who has information as an insider is guilty of insider dealing if, in the
circumstances mentioned in subsection (3) (that is, it is a regulated market and the
insider deals himself as a professional or through a professional intermediary), he deals in
securities that are price-affected securities in relation to the information.
The insider will also be guilty of an offence if they induce others to deal in price-
sensitive securities on a regulated market, whether or not the insider knows the
information to be price sensitive (i.e. the information would make the share price
Company Law 6 Raising capital: equity page 55
Because of these problems with the criminal ‘insider dealing’ regime, UK law has been
extended to cover ‘market abuse’ more generally. The legislation imposes a range of
penalties on those engaging in market abuse, including civil penalties and statements
of censure.
Market abuse was first regulated by the Financial Services and Markets Act 2000
(FSMA). Section 123 of the FSMA empowers the FCA to impose penalties for market
abuse. However, much of the detail of the regulation here is not to be found in the
FSMA itself. Some is contained in regulations that have been made under the FSMA
(the Financial Services and Markets Act 2000 (Market Abuse) Regulations 2005 (SI
2005/381) and 2016 (SI 2016/680). And many of the relevant rules are now found in
an EU regulation that was introduced in 2014, namely the Market Abuse Regulation
(Regulation 596/2014/EU) (MAR). MAR is complex, and it makes many changes to the
fine details of the regulation of market abuse. Fortunately, you do not need to learn
this in detail.
What counts as ‘market abuse’ is now defined by MAR. Essentially, it covers two types
of behaviour: insider dealing and ‘market manipulation’. To qualify as market abuse,
the behaviour must not only fall into one of these two categories, but must also
relate to trading in ‘financial instruments’ on certain specified markets. The financial
instruments that are covered include shares in a company, while the markets that are
covered include the London Stock Exchange’s Main Market. The fact that the regulation
of market abuse is limited to trading on formal markets shows that the purpose of the
regulation is not so much about ensuring fairness in individual transactions, but rather
about protecting the integrity of the market as a whole.
The principal penalty for market abuse is a fine, which can be imposed on any person
who has engaged in market abuse or has required or encouraged any other person
to do the same. In addition, the FCA may censure those who have engaged in market
abuse, and the Secretary of State may also apply to the court for a restitution order in
favour of those injured by the market abuse. However, the FSMA makes no provision
for an individual shareholder who has suffered a loss as a result of breach of the
market abuse provisions described above to bring proceedings to recover such loss.
Activity 6.4
Why is insider dealing illegal?
Summary
Insider dealing is where insiders in a company seek to benefit from their access to
privileged confidential information by buying and selling shares which would be
affected by the privileged information. As a result criminal provisions were introduced
in order to deal with this problem. These provisions proved unsuccessful as the
standard of proof was too difficult to achieve. Civil sanctions were introduced in the
FSMA to provide a lesser offence of market abuse.
page 56 University of London
Strangely, given the importance of this area, the Companies Act contains relatively few
provisions on the regulation of takeovers.
Additionally, ss.895–901 CA 2006 and s.110 Insolvency Act 1986 allow effective
takeovers of companies in crisis and liquidation. The conduct of the takeover itself,
which is of greatest concern to shareholders and companies, is left to the self-
regulatory system to govern.
Since 1968 the conduct of takeovers has been governed by the Panel on Takeovers and
Mergers (the Panel). The Panel administers the rules on takeovers called the City Code
on Takeovers and Mergers (the Code). The Panel and the Code aim to achieve equality
of treatment and opportunity for all shareholders in a takeover bid. The Code, while
flexible, emphasises a number of general principles. These are:
u no action which might frustrate an offer is taken by a target company during the
offer period without shareholders being allowed to vote on it
u the maintenance of fair and orderly markets in the shares of the companies
concerned throughout the period of the offer.
Until the CA 2006 the Panel was a non-statutory body but its decisions were subject
to judicial review because of the public nature of its regulatory role (see R v Panel on
Takeovers and Mergers ex p Datafin (1987) QB 815). However, the courts would only hear
the review after the takeover was complete, thus eliminating the use of the courts
in a tatical sense during the progress of a takeover bid. Prior to 2006 the Panel had
no formal power to sanction but was held in great respect by the financial services
sector. As a result the Panel had a number of actions it could take. First, the Panel could
issue critical statements about the conduct of a bid which would alert shareholders
to irregularities. Second, the Panel’s role was recognised by the FSA (as it was then
called), the various self-regulatory bodies licensed by the FSA and the professional
bodies. This means that the Panel could pass the matter to these bodies requesting a
sanction. For example, a listed company that did not follow the Code could have the
LSE remove or suspend its listing and the company’s professional advisers could have
disciplinary proceedings brought against them by their professional body. The FSA
might also have withdrawn its investment authorisation (see below) from any person
who is the subject of an adverse ruling of the Panel.
states and for more than a decade no progress was made. Eventually in 2001 political
agreement was reached on a text of the Draft Directive by the Council of Ministers
but it was rejected by the European Parliament. In April 2004 a much compromised
Directive was eventually agreed (Directive 2004/25/EC of the European Parliament and
of the Council of 21 April 2004 on Takeover Bids).
The Directive requires the establishment of a statutory body which would oversee
statutory takeover provisions. The CA 2006 Part 28, as a result, converted the self-
regulating Panel (s 942 CA 2006) into just such a statutory body to oversee takeovers in
the United Kingdom on 6 April 2007. Under the Takeover Directive reforms, the Panel
now has its own range of sanctions contained in ss.952-956 CA 2006. Thus the Panel
now has formal powers to issue statements of censure, issue directions, refer conduct
to other regulatory bodies, order compensation to be paid for breach of the code and
refer a matter for enforcement by the court.
This means that the Panel can take action itself or pass the matter to other regulators
requesting a sanction. For example, a listed company that does not follow the Code
could face:
¢ Campbell, D. ‘Note: what is wrong with insider dealing’ (1996) Legal Studies 185.
¢ Davies and Worthington, Chapter 25: ‘Public offers of shares’ and Chapter 30:
‘Insider dealing and market manipulation’.
¢ McVea, H. ‘What’s wrong with insider dealing?’ (1995) Legal Studies 390.
¢ Morse, G.K. ‘The City code on takeovers and mergers – self regulation or self
protection?’ (1991) JBL 509.
Go through the facts carefully and decide who might have dealt as an insider here –
George? Martha? The broker? Follow the price sensitive information and what each
character does with it.
Remember the insider will also be guilty of an offence if he induces others to deal
(whether they know the information is price sensitive or not) in price sensitive
securities on a regulated market (s.52(2)(a)). It is also an offence just to disclose price
sensitive information to another person in an irregular manner (s.52(2)(a)).
Go through the civil market abuse offence. This is more straightforward but again
apply it to all the characters in the question.
Company Law 6 Raising capital: equity page 59
Need to revise first = There are one or two areas I am unsure about and need to revise
before I go on to the next chapter.
Need to study again = I found many or all of the principles outlined in this chapter
very difficult and need to go over them again before I move on.
If you ticked ‘need to revise first’, which sections of the chapter are you going to
revise?
Must Revision
revise done
Notes
7 Raising capital: debentures
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62
7.1 Debentures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63
7.3 Priority . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67
Introduction
We saw in Chapter 6 that a company raises capital by issuing shares. Another way for
companies to raise money is by borrowing. In fact the majority of companies in the
UK are private, with an issued share capital of £100 or less. For such companies loan
capital is therefore a crucial means of financing their business activities and typically
they approach high street banks for loans. Since banks are generally risk-averse,
particularly since the onset of the global credit crisis, they will require security for
their loans. In this chapter we therefore consider corporate borrowing by way of
debentures or debenture stock and the types of charge that companies can issue to
lenders as security.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings, you should be able to:
u explain what is meant by the term debenture
u describe the nature of fixed and floating charges and the distinction between
them
u explain what is meant by book debts and outline the debate surrounding the
issue of granting a fixed charge over them
u outline the priority of charges and the statutory registration scheme
u describe and assess the proposals for reform.
Core text
¢ Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 6: ‘Raising capital: debentures: fixed and floating
charges’.
Cases
¢ Re Yorkshire Woolcombers Association [1903] 2 Ch 284
¢ Siebe Gorman & Co Ltd v Barclays Bank Ltd [1979] 2 Lloyd’s Rep 142, 10 LDAB 94
¢ Queens Moat Houses plc v Capita IRG Trustees Ltd [2004] EWHC 868 (Ch)
¢ National Westminster Bank plc v Spectrum Plus Ltd [2005] UKHL 41.
Additional cases
¢ Arthur D Little Ltd v Ableco Finance LLC [2002] 2 BCLC 799
7.1 Debentures
Put simply, a debenture is the document that evidences, or acknowledges, the
company’s debt (Levy v Abercorris Slate and Slab Co (1887) 36 Ch D 215, per Chitty J; see
also Knightsbridge Estates Trust v Byrne [1940] AC 613). The definition provided by s.738
CA 2006 is far from helpful: ‘…“debenture” includes debenture stock, bonds and any
other securities of a company, whether constituting a charge on the assets of the
company or not’. Thus a mortgage of freehold property by a company falls within the
statutory definition as it is a security and a charge on its assets. A charge or security
interest is a right in rem† created by a grant or declaration of trust which, if fixed, †
in rem (Latin) – meaning
implies a restriction on the debtor’s dominion over the asset(s) in question (Goode ‘the thing’ as opposed to the
(2003)). person (in personam).
Debenture stock is money borrowed from a number of different lenders on the same
terms. Such lenders form a ‘class’ who usually have their rights set out in a trust deed.
The trustee, often a bank, represents their interests as a whole. The trust deed will
generally set out the following terms.
The granting of security by a company does not mean that the title to the secured
asset passes to the creditor. Instead it creates an encumbrance on the property. The
creditor gets a right to have the security made available by an order of the court
(National Provincial Bank v Charnley [1924] 1 KB 431, Atkin LJ). For companies, the most
common species of charges given as security interests are fixed and floating charges.
Fixed charges
A company may grant a fixed charge to a creditor over certain property such as a
warehouse. Such a charge is similar to a mortgage in that the rights of the creditor (the
chargee) attach immediately to the property and the company’s (the chargor’s) power
to deal with the asset is restricted. In Agnew v Commissioner of Inland Revenue [2001] 2
AC 710 Lord Millett stated that:
A fixed charge gives the holder of the charge an immediate proprietary interest in the
assets subject to the charge which binds all those into whose hands the assets may come
with notice of the charge.
Floating charges
As its name suggests, a floating charge floats over the whole or a part (class) of
the chargor’s assets, which may fluctuate as a result of acquisitions and disposals.
Corporate property that can be made subject to a floating charge includes stock in
trade, plant (machinery), and book debts (receivables). The distinguishing feature
of a floating charge is that the company can continue to deal with the assets in the
ordinary course of business without having to obtain the chargee’s permission.
In Ashborder BV v Green Gas Power Ltd [2005] BCC 634, Etherton J reviewed the
characteristics of the floating charge and examined the notion of the chargor being
allowed to deal with the charged assets in the ‘ordinary course of business’. The judge
page 64 University of London
noted that whether a transaction was within the ordinary course of business is a mixed
question of fact and law and the viewpoint of the objective observer on the facts is a
useful aid.
A floating charge converts to a fixed charge over the assets within its scope upon the
occurrence of a ‘crystallising’ event such as a default on repayment or the winding up
of the company.
u That class is one which, in the ordinary course of the business of the company,
would be changing from time to time.
In determining whether a charge is fixed or floating the courts will look to the
substance of the matter irrespective of what description the parties use to categorise
it. In this regard Lord Millett explained, in Agnew v Commissioner of Inland Revenue, that:
Lord Millett noted that Romer LJ’s third distinguishing feature (see above) is the
classic hallmark of a floating charge. More recently, in National Westminster Bank plc v
Spectrum Plus Ltd [2005] UKHL 41, Lord Phillips MR explained that:
Initially it was not difficult to distinguish between a fixed and a floating charge. A fixed
charge arose where the chargor agreed that he would no longer have the right of free
disposal of the assets charged, but that they should stand as security for the discharge of
obligations owed to the chargee. A floating charge was normally granted by a company
which wished to be free to acquire and dispose of assets in the normal course of its
business, but nonetheless to make its assets available as security to the chargee in priority
to other creditors should it cease to trade. The hallmark of the floating charge was the
agreement that the chargor should be free to dispose of his assets in the normal course of
business unless and until the chargee intervened. Up to that moment the charge ‘floated’.
In Arthur D Little Ltd v Ableco Finance LLC [2002] 2 BCLC 799 the chargor, Arthur D Little
Ltd, guaranteed the liabilities of its two parent companies to Ableco by creating a
charge, described as a first fixed charge, over its shareholding in a subsidiary company,
CCL. The chargor company retained both its voting and dividend rights with respect
to the shares until default. The company’s administrator argued that it was a floating
charge. It was held, applying Lord Millett’s reasoning in Agnew, that whether or not
the charge was fixed or floating is a question of law and the particular charge in issue
was fixed. It did not float over a body of fluctuating assets and, notwithstanding the
company’s voting and dividend rights, it could not deal with the asset in the ordinary
Company Law 7 Raising capital: debentures page 65
course of business: the company could not dispose of, or otherwise deal with, the
shares. The asset was therefore under the control of the chargee.
In Queens Moat Houses plc v Capita IRG Trustees Ltd [2004] EWHC 868, it was held that the
existence of a right unilaterally to require a chargee to release property from a charge
did not render what is otherwise a fixed charge a floating charge.
Activity 7.1
What are the principal characteristics of a floating charge and how does it differ
from a fixed charge?
Summary
Whereas a fixed charge over an asset attaches immediately, a company has the
freedom to continue to deal in the ordinary course of business with assets which are
subject to a floating charge.
In Siebe Gorman & Co Ltd v Barclays Bank Ltd [1979] 2 Lloyd’s Rep 142, the company
granted a debenture in favour of Barclay’s Bank. The security was expressed to be
a ‘first fixed charge’ over all of its present and future book debts. The debenture
required the company to pay the proceeds of all book debts into its Barclays account
and it prohibited the company from charging or assigning its book debts without
first obtaining the bank’s consent. It was held that the company’s charge over its
receivables was fixed. The judge reasoned that taking the restrictions placed on the
company’s power to deal with the proceeds of the debts, together with the bank’s
right to prevent the company making withdrawals from the account even when it
was in credit, gave the bank a degree of control that was inconsistent with a floating
charge. On the other hand, in Chalk v Kahn [2000] 2 BCLC 361 under the terms of the
charge, described as a fixed charge, the chargor was required to pay the proceeds into
a specified account not held with the chargee bank but with another bank. Since the
chargee had no control over the account it was held that the charge was a floating
charge. A particularly contentious decision is that reached by the Court of Appeal in
Re New Bullas Trading Ltd [1994] 1 BCLC 485, in which it was held that it was possible to
create a combined fixed and floating charge over book debts. Here a fixed charge was
created over uncollected book debts but as soon as the proceeds of the debts were
credited to a specified bank account a floating charge took effect over them.
The decision in Re New Bullas attracted much criticism and in Agnew, Lord Millett
declared New Bullas ‘to be fundamentally mistaken’. In Agnew the debenture was
so drafted as to mirror that in New Bullas but the Privy Council held that where the
chargor company is free to deal with the charged asset(s) in the ordinary course
of business it must be construed as a floating charge. However, where the chargee
retains control over the debts and their proceeds so as to severely restrict the
company’s freedom to deal with them, as in Siebe Gorman, it will be a fixed charge. The
notion of a combined charge was rejected by the Privy Council.
In National Westminster Bank plc v Spectrum Plus Ltd [2005] UKHL 41, the chargor,
Spectrum, granted a fixed (specific) charge to the bank over its book debts to secure
page 66 University of London
an overdraft of £250,000. The debenture stated that the security was a specific charge
over all present and future book debts and other debts. It also prohibited Spectrum
from charging or assigning debts and the company was required to pay the proceeds
of collection into an account held with the bank. The debenture did not specify any
restrictions on the company’s operation of the account.
Spectrum’s account was always overdrawn and the proceeds from its book debts
were paid into the account which Spectrum drew on as and when necessary. When
Spectrum went into liquidation the bank sought a declaration that the debenture
created a fixed charge over the company’s book debts and their proceeds. The Crown,
however, argued that the debenture merely created a floating charge so that its claims
in respect of tax owed by the company took priority over the bank. The trial judge,
applying Brumark and declining to follow Bullas, held that, given the charge permitted
Spectrum to use the proceeds of the debts in the normal course of business, it must
be construed as a floating charge. In so holding the Vice-Chancellor also declined to
follow Siebe Gorman.
The bank successfully appealed to the Court of Appeal. Lord Phillips MR, delivering the
leading judgment (Jonathan Parker and Jacob LJJ concurring), took the view that where
a chargor is prohibited from disposing of its receivables before they are collected and
is required to pay the proceeds into an account with the chargee bank, the charge is
to be construed as fixed. He explained that it was not, as a matter of precedent, open
to the Court of Appeal to hold that Bullas was wrongly decided even though the Privy
Council had, in Brumark, expressed the view that the decision was mistaken. Further,
Siebe Gorman was correctly decided given that the debenture in that case clearly
restricted the company’s ability to draw on the bank account into which the proceeds
of its book debts were paid. The Court of Appeal noted that the form of debenture
used in Siebe Gorman had been followed for some 25 years and thus it was inclined to
hold that it had, by customary usage, acquired meaning. Lord Phillips observed that in
Siebe Gorman:
Slade J could properly have held the charge on book debts created by the debenture to
be a fixed charge simply because of the requirements (i) that the book debts should not
be disposed of prior to collection and (ii) that, on collection, the proceeds should be paid
to the Bank itself. It follows that he was certainly entitled to hold that the debenture,
imposing as he found restrictions on the use of the proceeds of book debts, created a
fixed charge over book debts.
The bank’s debenture placed no restrictions on the use that Spectrum could make of
the balance on the account available to be drawn by Spectrum. Slade J in [Siebe Gorman]
thought that it might make a difference whether the account were in credit or in debit. I
must respectfully disagree. The critical question, in my opinion, is whether the charger can
draw on the account. If the chargor’s bank account were in debit and the charger had no
right to draw on it, the account would have become, and would remain until the drawing
rights were restored, a blocked account. The situation would be as it was in Re Keeton Bros
Ltd [above]. But so long as the charger can draw on the account, and whether the account
is in credit or debit, the money paid in is not being appropriated to the repayment of
the debt owing to the debenture holder but is being made available for drawings on the
account by the charger.
Although the House of Lords has jurisdiction in an exceptional case to hold that
its decision should not operate retrospectively or should otherwise be limited, it
Company Law 7 Raising capital: debentures page 67
nevertheless held that in this case there was no good reason for postponing the effect
of overruling Siebe Gorman.
For a case in which a lender did, unusually, have sufficient control over the book debts
that had been charged by a borrower for that charge to be a fixed one, see Re Harmony
Care Homes Ltd [2009] EWHC 1961.
Activity 7.2
Read the Privy Council’s opinion delivered in Agnew v Commissioner of Inland
Revenue [2001] 2 AC 710.
What does Agnew tell us about the classification of securities?
7.3 Priority
The general rule is that security interests are prioritised according to the order of
their creation. However, as we saw above, a feature of the floating charge is that
the company can continue to deal with the charged assets in the ordinary course
of business. Therefore a fixed charge can be created which will take priority over an
earlier floating charge. In order to protect their priority, floating chargees can insert
a so-called ‘negative pledge’ clause in the charge that prohibits the chargor from
creating a charge that ranks equally with (pari passu) or in priority to the earlier
floating charge.
Such a restriction is not inconsistent with the nature of a floating charge (Re Brightlife
Ltd [1987] Ch 200). However it should be noted that the subsequent chargee will not
lose priority unless he has actual notice of the negative pledge clause. Mere notice of
the earlier floating charge is not sufficient (Wilson v Kelland [1910] 2 Ch 306). Where
there are competing floating charges the governing principle is that the earliest
created takes priority. However, the parties may agree that the company may create a
subsequent floating charge which will take priority or rank pari passu with the earlier
floating charge (Re Benjamin Cope & Sons Ltd [1914] 1 Ch 800).
7.3.1 Registration
Understandably, a creditor who is considering lending money to a company may
wish to find out the extent of its indebtedness. Companies are therefore required to
register certain details of mortgages over their their assets, under s.859A CA 2006.
(‘Mortgages’ is a broad term, likely to cover most types of charges a company would
create. Section 859A replaced s.860 CA 2006, which contained a much longer list of
different types of charge subject to registration.)
u a liquidator
u any creditor of the company (see Smith v Bridgend County Borough Council [2002] 1
BCLC 77).
Note that the loan is not void for want of registration of the charge, but rather the
failure to register results in the lender ranking as an unsecured creditor.
Previously, if a charge was not registered, the company and every defaulting officer is
liable to a fine (s.860(4)). This criminal sanction has now been repealed.
Once registered, the charge is valid from the date of its creation. This results in what
has been termed the 21-day invisibility problem (see the CLRSG’s consultation
page 68 University of London
document Registration of Company Charges (October 2000), para 3.79). This is because
whenever a person checks the register it cannot be assumed that it is comprehensive
because there may be a charge for which the 21-day period is still running.
Section 859A also requires companies to maintain at its registered office a register
containing certain prescribed particulars of all registrable mortgages. The failure to
keep such a register does not affect the validity of the charge.
When a charge is registered the Registrar must issue a certificate stating the amount
secured by the charge. The certificate is conclusive evidence that the statutory
registration requirements have been complied with. The charge cannot then be set
aside if the particulars are incorrect.
Rectification of the register may be possible where the court is satisfied that the
failure to register within the required period or that an omission or misstatement of
any particular was accidental or inadvertent, or is not of a nature to prejudice creditors
or shareholders of the company, or that on other grounds it is just and equitable to
grant relief (s.873). Generally, leave to register out of time is granted by the courts
subject to the rights of intervening secured creditors and provided the company is
solvent (see, for example, Re IC Johnson & Co Ltd [1902] 2 Ch 101).
It should be noted that this provision does not extend to charges created in favour
of connected persons. The term ‘connected person’ is defined by s.249 as a director
or shadow director of the company; an associate of a director or shadow director of
the company; and an associate of the company. The object of s.245 is to prevent an
unsecured creditor obtaining a floating charge to secure his or her existing loan at the
expense of other unsecured creditors.
Activity 7.3
Explain the so-called 21-day ‘invisibility’ problem.
Further reading
¢ Beale, H. ‘Reform of the law of security interests over personal property’ in
Lowry, J. and L. Mistelis (eds) Commercial law: perspectives and practice. (London:
LexisNexis Butterworths, 2006) [ISBN 9781405710077].
¢ Berg, A. ‘Brumark Investments Ltd and the “innominate charge”’ (2001) JBL 532.
Company Law 7 Raising capital: debentures page 69
¢ Capper, D. ‘Fixed charges over book debts – back to basics but how far back?’
(2002) LMCLQ 246.
¢ Davies and Worthington, Chapter 31: ‘Debentures’ and Chapter 32: ‘Company
charges’.
¢ de Lacy, J. ‘Reflections on the ambit and reform of Part 12 of the Companies Act
1985 and the doctrine of constructive notice’ in de Lacy, J. (ed.) The reform of
United Kingdom company law. (London: Cavendish, 2002) [ISBN 9781859416938].
¢ Ferran, E. ‘Floating charges – the nature of the security’ (1988) CLJ 213.
¢ Goode, R.M. ‘Charges over book debts: a missed opportunity’ (1994) LQR 592.
¢ Gregory, R. and P. Walton ‘Book debt charges – the saga goes on’ (1999) 115 LQR 14.
¢ Gullifer, L. Goode and Gullifer on legal problems of credit and security. (London:
Sweet & Maxwell, 2018) sixth edition [ISBN 9780414066007].
¢ Worthington, S. ‘Fixed charges over book debts and other receivables’ (1997)
LQR 562.
¢ Worthington, S. ‘An “unsatisfactory area of the law” – fixed and floating charges
yet again’ (2004) International Corporate Rescue 175.
ii. the position of such charges as against preferential and unsecured creditors
iv. avoidance of floating charges under the 1986 Insolvency Act, s.245.
Ratfink charge: expressed as a fixed charge but is this conclusive of the issue? See Re
Yorkshire Woolcombers Association and Agnew v Commission of Inland Revenue. Is the
charge properly registered?
Beckley’s charge: it is secured on book debts but what type of charge is it? See Siebe
Gorman & Co Ltd v Barclays Bank Ltd and Agnew v Inland Revenue Commissioners. You
should also consider the priority issue between Ratfink and Beckley.
John: is it a fixed charge? You will need to discuss the priority issues between fixed and
floating charges.
Section 245 of the Insolvency Act 1986 should be considered – can the liquidator avoid
the floating charges? Finally, mention should be made of preferential creditors and the
effect of the Insolvency Act 2006.
Company Law 7 Raising capital: debentures page 71
Need to revise first = There are one or two areas I am unsure about and need to revise
before I go on to the next chapter.
Need to study again = I found many or all of the principles outlined in this chapter
very difficult and need to go over them again before I move on.
If you ticked ‘need to revise first’, which sections of the chapter are you going to
revise?
Must Revision
revise done
7.1 Debentures
7.3 Priority
Notes
8 Capital
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 74
Introduction
In this chapter we consider a range of broadly related issues concerning the capital
of a company. The underlying theme is the doctrine of maintenance of capital. This is
directed towards ensuring that shareholders pay the price for their shares in money or
money’s worth and that the company’s capital is not illegally returned to them.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings, you should be able to:
u explain the objectives of the doctrine of maintenance of capital
u state the rule proscribing shares being issued at a discount
u describe the rules relating to dividend payments
u describe the procedure for reducing capital
u explain the regime governing financial assistance for the purchase of shares.
Core text
¢ Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 7: ‘Share capital’.
Cases
¢ Bairstow v Queens Moat Houses plc [2001] 2 BCLC 531
Additional cases
¢ Guinness v Land Corporation of Ireland (1883) 22 ChD 349
It should be noted that a company’s share capital is not kept in a ring-fenced bank
account to be drawn upon only in the event of winding up, in order to meet the claims
of creditors. Rather, it is a book-keeping entry which serves as the basis for measures
of profitability such as return on capital employed (ROCE). Before any returns (e.g.
dividends) are paid to shareholders the accounts must show that the value of the
company’s assets exceeds the value of its share capital. As indicated above, the law
is directed towards preventing illegal returns of capital to shareholders and there
are numerous ways in which shareholders may receive legitimate returns on their
investment: for example, by way of a dividend payment (see below).
We now turn to consider the maintenance regime. It should be noted that the law
distinguishes between private and public companies. It should also be borne in mind
that, when reading the case law decided under the CA 1985 and its predecessors, the
law was notoriously complex. In this respect, it should be noted that in accordance
with the policy objectives of the company law review, the 2006 reforms are directed
towards removing requirements that are ‘unnecessary and burdensome for private
companies’.
Because of the scope this gives for abuse, public companies must satisfy strict
statutory requirements where the consideration for shares is other than money
(the decision in Re Wragg only applies to private companies). For example, for
public companies s.593 CA 2006 requires an independent valuation of any non-cash
consideration. Failure to comply with this provision renders the allottee/holder and
any subsequent holder liable to pay again in cash together with interest (see ss.588
and 593(3) CA 2006). Thus, the allottee/holder could end up paying twice for the
shares. The policy here is directed towards preventing public companies from issuing
shares at a discount.
The 2005 consultative document states that the requirement of ‘authorised share
capital’ is to be removed on the basis that it is invariably set at a level higher than the
company will need and so it serves no useful practice. This is achieved by Part 17 of
the CA 2006 which abolishes the concept of authorised share capital but retains the
page 76 University of London
concept of nominal value. Thus, s.542(1) requires companies to issue shares with a
fixed nominal value. The requirement for public companies to have a minimum share
capital (£50,000 or euro equivalent, currently fixed at €65,000) is retained by the
2006 Act (see ss.761 and 763).
Activity 8.1
Read Re Wragg Ltd [1897] 1 Ch 796.
What approach did the Court of Appeal take towards the price a company may pay
for property?
8.3.1 Dividends
Part 23 of the CA 2006 codifies the common law by requiring that dividends may only
be paid out of distributable profits (see, in particular, s.830). Thus, dividends may
only be paid out of accumulated profits and not if the effect would be to reduce the
company’s net assets below the value of its share capital.
A dividend paid in breach of this rule is unlawful and ultra vires. A director who knew
(or ought to have known) that the payment amounted to a breach is liable to repay
the dividends (see Bairstow v Queens Moat Houses plc [2001] 2 BCLC 531; and Re Exchange
Banking Co, Flitcroft’s Case (1882) 21 ChD 519).
In Bairstow v Queens Moat Houses plc, the directors, who acted on the company’s 1991
accounts that incorrectly showed inflated profits, paid dividends that exceeded the
available distributable reserves. The Court of Appeal held that their liability was not
limited to the difference between the unlawful dividends and the dividends that could
have been lawfully paid. Directors owe fiduciary duties to the company and therefore
have trustee-like responsibilities arising out of their duty to manage the company in
the interests of all its members. They were therefore ordered to pay the company over
£78 million. A shareholder who, with knowledge of the facts, receives an improper
dividend payment will be held liable to repay it as a constructive trustee (Precision
Dippings Ltd v Precision Dippings Marketing Ltd [1986] Ch 447; see also, IRC v Richmond
[2003] EWHC 999).
In It’s a Wrap (UK) Ltd v Gula [2005] EWHC 2015, the liquidator sought repayment of
dividends paid to the defendants who were the sole shareholders and directors
of the company. During a two-year period in which there were no profits available
for distribution, the company’s accounts showed that dividends had nevertheless
been paid to the defendants. When the company went into insolvent liquidation,
the liquidator claimed that the dividends had been paid in contravention of s.263(1)
CA 1985 (now s.830(1) CA 2006) and were therefore recoverable under s.277 CA 1985
(now s.847 CA 2006). The defendants argued that the sums in question were paid
to them as remuneration and only appeared in the accounts as ‘dividends’ because
they had been advised that this was tax efficient. The court dismissed the liquidator’s
claim. On the evidence it was clear that the defendants had sought to gain a proper
tax advantage and had not deliberately set out to contravene the Act. The words ‘is
so made’ contained in s.277(1) (now s.847(2)) required that the defendants knew or
had reasonable grounds to believe not just the facts giving rise to the contravention
but also the legal result of the contravention. Not surprisingly, the Court of Appeal
reversed the judge’s decision and held that the defendants’ ignorance of the law was
no defence. Arden LJ stated that s.277 (now s.847) had to be interpreted in a manner
consistent with Article 16 of the Second Company Law Harmonisation Directive which
it is designed to implement. On this particular issue she concluded that:
Section 277 [now s.847] must be intrepreted as meaning that the shareholder cannot claim
that he is not liable to return a distribution because he did not know of the restrictions in
the Act on the making of distributions. He will be liable if he knew or ought reasonably to
have known of the facts which mean that the distribution contravened the requirements
of the Act.
Company Law 8 Capital page 77
In Aveling Barford Ltd v Perion Ltd [1989] BCLC 626, Aveling Barford Ltd (AB Ltd) and
Perion Ltd (P Ltd) were owned and controlled by Mr Lee. Aveling Barford Ltd, while
not technically insolvent, did not have any distributable reserves. It did, however,
own a sports ground for which planning permission for residential redevelopment
had been granted. In October 1986 its directors decided to sell the sports ground,
valued at £650,000, to Perion Ltd for £350,000. The sale was completed in February
1987. In August 1987 Perion Ltd resold it for £1.52 million. When Aveling Barford Ltd
went into liquidation, the liquidator successfully sued to have Perion Ltd declared a
constructive trustee of the proceeds of sale on the ground that the transaction was an
unauthorised return of capital by Aveling Barford Ltd to Lee, its sole shareholder, via
Perion Ltd.
The decision in Aveling Barford has proved controversial because of its impact on
companies in a group who want to transfer assets to each other. In Completing The
Structure (November 2000) the CLRSG concluded that Part VIII of the Companies Act
1985 should be changed to enable intra-group transfer of assets to proceed in a more
straightforward way. This has been implemented by ss.845-846 CA 2006.
Section 643 provides that the solvency statement must state that each of the directors
has formed the opinion, taking into account all of the company’s liabilities (including
any contingent or prospective liabilities), that:
a. as regards the company’s situation at the date of the statement, there is no ground
on which the company could then be found to be unable to pay its debts; and
Section 644 lays down the filing requirements in respect of a reduction of capital. Within
15 days after the special resolution is passed, the company must file with the Registrar
a copy of the solvency statement together with a statement of capital and a statement
of compliance. The special resolution itself must also be filed in accordance with s.30 CA
2006. The resolution does not take effect until these documents are registered (s.644(4)).
If the directors make a solvency statement without having reasonable grounds for the
opinions expressed in it, and that statement is subsequently delivered to the Registrar,
every director who is in default commits an offence (see s.643(4); the penalties, which
may include imprisonment, are set out in s.643(5)).
The court may make an order confirming the reduction of capital on such terms and
conditions as it thinks fit (s.648(1)). However, it will not confirm the reduction unless it is
satisfied, with respect to every creditor of the company entitled to object, that either his
consent to the reduction has been obtained, or his debt or claim has been discharged
or secured (s.648(2)). The reduction will take effect on registration of the court order
confirming the reduction (and statement of capital) by the Registrar (s.649(5)).
If the reduction of a public company’s capital has the effect of bringing the nominal
value of its allotted share capital below the authorised minimum, the Registrar must
not register the court order confirming the reduction unless either the court so
Company Law 8 Capital page 79
directs, or the company is first re-registered as a private company (s.650). Section 651
provides for an expedited procedure for re-registration as a private company.
The scope of the general prohibition contained in s.658(1) was considered in Acatos
and Hutcheson plc v Watson [1994] BCC 446. It was held that it was not unlawful
for a company to purchase another company whose only asset was a significant
shareholding (nearly 30 per cent) in the purchasing company. This was so even though
it would have been unlawful for the purchasing company to buy its own shares
directly. Lightman J observed that to hold otherwise would permit target companies
to protect themselves against a takeover bid by the simple device of buying shares in
the purchasing company. He described this result as being ‘absurd’.
As a result of the need for companies, particularly private companies, to have greater
flexibility over their capital structure, the rule in Trevor v Whitworth has, as mentioned
above, been relaxed.
An ordinary resolution is required even though its effect is to amend the articles
(s.685(2)).
Shares may not be redeemed unless they are fully paid and the terms of the
redemption may provide that the amount payable on redemption may, by agreement
between the company and the shareholder concerned, be paid on a date later than
the redemption date (s.686(1) and (2)).
Where the directors are authorised to determine the terms, conditions and manner of
redemption, they must do so before the shares are allotted and such details must be
specified in any statement of capital which the company is required to file (s.685(3)).
When a company redeems any redeemable shares it must give notice to the Registrar
within one month, specifying the shares redeemed together with a statement of capital
which details the company’s shares immediately following the redemption (s.689). If
default is made in complying with the notice requirements, an offence is committed by
the company and every officer of the company who is in default (s.689(4)).
there would no longer be any issued shares other than redeemable shares (s.690(2)).
Only fully paid shares can be purchased and they must be paid for on purchase
((s.691); payment by instalments is not, therefore, permissible (see Pena v Dale [2004]
EWHC 1065 (Ch)). A company cannot subscribe for its own shares but is restricted to
purchasing them from existing members (see Re VGM Holdings Ltd [1942] Ch 235).
With respect to financing the purchase, a public company must use distributable
profits or the proceeds of a fresh share issue made for the purpose of financing the
purchase (s.692(2)). However, a private company may, as under the CA 1985, purchase
its own shares out of capital (s.692(1) and s.709).
As mentioned above, the main difference introduced by the 2006 Act for a private
company is that the power to purchase its own shares need no longer be contained
in the articles. The articles may, however, restrict or prohibit the exercise of this
statutory power. Where a private company purchases its own shares out of capital,
then ordinarily the use of capital must be a ‘permissible capital payment’ under s.709,
and the company and its directors must comply with a number of safeguards designed
to protect the company’s creditors in such a case. However, for ‘small’ buy-backs,
a private company can pay for the shares it is repurchasing out of capital, without
complying with such safeguards (see s.692 CA 2006). A small buy-back is one where the
amount paid does not exceed (the lower of) £15,000 or 5 per cent of the company’s
share capital.
For larger repurchases, where the company is using a permissible capital payment
under s.709, the directors are required to make a statement specifying the amount of
the permissible capital payment for the shares in question. Section 714 provides that
this statement must also confirm that the directors have made a full enquiry into the
affairs and prospects of the company and that they have formed the opinion:
a. as regards the company’s situation immediately after the date on which the
payment out of capital is made, there will be no grounds on which the company
could then be found unable to pay its debts; and
b. as regards the company’s prospects for the year immediately following that date,
the company will be able to continue to carry on business as a going concern and
be able to pay its debts as they fall due in the year immediately following the date
on which the payment out of capital is made.
In forming their opinion on the company’s solvency and prospects, the directors must
take into account all of the company’s liabilities (including contingent and prospective
liabilities).
Directors who make this statement without reasonable grounds for their opinion
commit an offence (s.715).
As an additional safeguard, s.714(6) provides that the directors’ statement must have
annexed to it a report by the company’s auditor confirming its accuracy. Further, the
payment out of capital must be approved by a special resolution of the company
which must be passed on the date of the directors’ statement or within the week
immediately following (s.716). The holders of the shares in question are barred from
voting on the resolution (s.717). Within the week immediately following the date of
the s.716 resolution, the company must give public notice in the London Gazette (the
official newspaper of record for the UK) and in an appropriate national newspaper
of the proposed payment. This must also state that any creditor may apply to court
under s.721 within five weeks of the resolution for an order preventing the payment
(s.719). Following the purchase, the company must give notice to the Registrar. Such
notice must include a statement of capital (s.708).
In certain circumstances a company which purchases its own shares need not cancel
them but can, instead, hold them ‘in treasury’ from where they can be either sold
or transferred, for example to an employee share scheme. This relaxation, which
took effect on 1 December 2003, was introduced by the Companies (Acquisition
of Own Shares) (Treasury Shares) Regulations 2003 (SI 2003/1116). The regulations
inserted ss.162A – 162G into the 1985 Act which are re-enacted in ss.724-732 CA 2006.
Company Law 8 Capital page 81
For ‘qualifying shares’, as defined in s.724(2), to become treasury shares they must
be purchased by the company out of distributable profits. There are a number of
restrictions on the rights attaching to treasury shares. For example, s.726(2) states that
the company may not exercise any right in respect of treasury shares. Any purported
exercise of such a right is void. Further, no dividend or other distribution may be paid
to the company (s.726(3)).
The policy underlying the prohibition is explained by Arden LJ in Chaston v SWP Group
plc [2003] 1 BCLC 675:
[It] is derived from section 45 of the Companies Act 1929 which was enacted as a result
of the previously common practice of purchasing the shares of a company having a
substantial cash balance or easily realisable assets and so arranging matters that the
purchase money was lent by the company to the purchaser… The general mischief…
remains the same, namely that the resources of the target company and its subsidiaries
should not be used directly or indirectly to assist the purchaser financially to make the
acquisition. This may prejudice the interests of the creditors of the target or its group, and
the interests of any shareholders who do not accept the offer to acquire their shares or to
whom the offer is not made.
A loan does not deplete a company’s net assets because, although funds leave the
company, their loss is matched in the company’s accounts by the debt to the company
that is thereby created. Thus, the prohibition on financial assistance in the Act is wider
than that which would be required if the only policy in operation was to maintain
the company’s share capital. As stressed by Arden LJ (above), it recognises the need
to protect shareholders and outsiders from the company misusing its assets to
finance the purchase of its own shares, even if the capital maintenance doctrine is not
thereby infringed (see also the comments of Peter Smith J in Anglo Petroleum Ltd v TFB
(Mortgages) Ltd [2006] EWHC 258 (Ch)).
(Prior to the CA 2006 the prohibition also extended to private companies: see s.151 CA
1985.)
Section 677 (together with s.683(1) and (2)) seeks to limit the scope of the meaning
of ‘financial assistance’ by listing certain forms or ways in which it can arise. Examples
include:
The giving of a security is illustrated by Heald v O’Connor [1971] 1 WLR 497. Mr and Mrs
Heald sold all of the shares in D.E. Heald (Stoke on Trent) Ltd to O’Connor. The price was
£35,000 but they lent him £25,000 in order to enable him to complete the purchase.
The company thereby granted the vendors a floating charge over all of its assets
by way of security for the loan. Thus, if O’Connor defaulted, the security would be
enforceable against the company. This was held to be illegal.
A residual category falls within s.677(1)(d) which proscribes ‘any other financial
assistance given by a company where the net assets of the company are reduced to
a material extent by the giving of the assistance, or the company has no net assets’.
Therefore, even if a public company were in a position to return funds to shareholders
because it had distributable profits, it would not be able to provide any sort of
financial assistance for the acquisition of its own shares which materially depleted
its net assets. In this regard, s.677(2) and (3) state that in determining the company’s
‘net assets’ it is the actual value of the assets and liabilities, as opposed to their book
value, that is to be applied (see Parlett v Guppy’s (Bridport) Ltd (1996); Grant v Lapid
Developments Ltd [1996] 2 BCLC 24).
The exceptions
Section 681 contains a wide list of ‘unconditional’ exceptions. Those in s.681(2) are
unexceptional. They mainly relate to procedures which are specifically authorised
elsewhere in the Act: for example, to effect a redemption of shares or a reduction of
capital. So-called ‘conditional exceptions’ are listed in s.682. They therefore only apply
if the company has net assets and either:
a. those assets are not reduced by the giving of the financial assistance, or
b. to the extent that those assets are so reduced, the assistance is provided out of
distributable profits.
Section 678(2) and (3), however, also contain the ‘principal purpose’ and ‘incidental
part of a larger purpose’ defences which are carried over from the 1985 Act. In essence,
financial assistance is not prohibited:
u if the principal purpose of the assistance is not to give it for the purpose of an
acquisition of shares, or where this assistance is incidental to some other larger
purpose of the company and,
u in either case, where the financial assistance is given in good faith in the interests
of the company.
Company Law 8 Capital page 83
The exceptions are designed to ensure that the prohibition in s.678(1) does not also
catch genuine commercial transactions which are in the interests of the company.
However, attempting to assess a person’s ‘purpose’ is necessarily difficult (for instance,
the need to distinguish purpose from effect) because the court will need to determine
whether the giving of assistance for the purpose of an acquisition of shares is an
incidental part of some larger purpose. Something is a ‘purpose’ of a transaction
between A and B if it is understood by both of them that it will enable B to bring about
the desired result. The difficulties of assessing ‘purpose’ came to the fore in Brady v
Brady [1989] AC 755.
In Brady v Brady [1989] AC 755 the scheme involved a company’s business being divided
between two brothers, Jack and Bob Brady, who were the controlling shareholders.
They were not on speaking terms and the deadlock between them threatened the
survival of the company and its subsidiaries. It was decided that Jack should take the
haulage business and Bob the soft drinks business. However, the haulage business was
worth more than the soft drinks business and so to make the division fair and equal,
extra assets had to be transferred from the haulage business to the drinks business.
This involved the principal company, Brady, transferring assets to a new company
controlled by Bob. It was conceded that s.151 (now s.678) had been breached because
the transfer involved Brady providing financial assistance towards discharging the
liability of its holding company, M, for the price of shares which M had purchased in
Brady. When Jack sought specific performance of the agreement, Bob, who by now
had decided against the arrangement, contended that it was an illegal transaction.
Jack argued, however, that the financial assistance was an incidental part of a larger
purpose of the company (i.e. the removal of deadlock between the two brothers
which had threatened to result in the liquidation of the business).
The House of Lords held that the purpose of the transaction was to assist in financing
the acquisition of the shares: the essence of the reorganisation was for Jack to acquire
Brady Ltd’s shares and therefore the acquisition of those shares was not incidental
to the reorganisation. Lord Oliver concluded that the acquisition ‘was not a mere
incident of the scheme devised to break the deadlock. It was the essence of the
scheme itself and the object which the scheme set out to achieve.’
This approach means that in looking for some larger overall corporate purpose,
it is necessary to distinguish ‘purpose’ from the reason why a purpose is formed.
The commercial advantages flowing from providing the financial assistance for the
acquisition of the shares may be the reason for providing it but the commercial
advantages are a by-product of providing the assistance – they are not an independent
purpose to which the financial assistance can be considered incidental.
The approach of the House of Lords in Brady towards the interpretation of the ‘purpose
exceptions’ has been criticised on the basis that it unduly restricts the width of the
defences (see s.678, above), and, indeed, it makes it very hard to ascertain exactly what
sort of situations would fall within these exceptions.
The facts of Dyment v Boyden [2005] 1 WLR 792 (CA) provide an interesting illustration of
how an allegation of financial assistance can arise. The Court of Appeal had to consider
whether rent which was significantly greater than the market value of the premises in
question constituted a breach of s.678 (s.151 of the 1985 Act). Because of local authority
rules the transfer of shares had to be undertaken in order that the respondents no
longer retained an interest in the company. The Court of Appeal held that the trial
page 84 University of London
judge was right in finding that the company’s entry into the lease was ‘in connection
with’ the acquisition by the appellant of the shares but was not ‘for the purpose of that
acquisition’. His finding that the entry into the lease was for the purpose of acquiring
the premises rather than the shares was a finding of fact with which the Court of
Appeal should not interfere.
In Carney v Herbert [1985] AC 301, the Privy Council had to decide if the vendors of
shares in A Ltd could sue the purchaser (or the guarantor thereof) for the purchase
price when a subsidiary of A Ltd had provided illegal financial assistance in relation
to the purchaser’s acquisition (by charging land owned by it as security for the
purchaser’s promise to pay for the shares). If the agreement could not have been
severed, the purchaser would have been able to keep the shares without any payment
being made for them. Lord Brightman, delivering the decision of the Privy Council,
stated:
as a general rule, where parties enter into a lawful contract of, for example, sale and
purchase, and there is an ancillary provision which is illegal but exists for the exclusive
benefit of the plaintiff, the court may and probably will, if the justice of the case so
requires, and there is no public policy objection, permit the plaintiff, if he so wishes, to
enforce the contract without the illegal provision.
The Privy Council therefore severed the illegal charges and allowed the vendors to sue
for the purchase price.
Activity 8.2
Read Brady v Brady [1989] AC 755, [1988] 2 All ER 617.
Write a short essay of not more than 300 words explaining how Lord Oliver defined
the concept of ‘larger purpose’.
Summary
For financial assistance to be unlawful under s.678 CA 2006 the company’s net assets
must be reduced to a material extent (Parlett v Guppy’s (Bridport) Ltd [1996] 2 BCLC 34).
u The prohibition in s.678 CA 2006 against providing financial assistance for the
acquisition of shares. You should describe what amounts to financial assistance.
Note ‘pre’ and ‘post’ acquisition assistance.
u The principal purpose exception. Analyse Brady v Brady with particular reference to
Lord Oliver’s speech.
page 86 University of London
Need to revise first = There are one or two areas I am unsure about and need to revise
before I go on to the next chapter.
Need to study again = I found many or all of the principles outlined in this chapter
very difficult and need to go over them again before I move on.
If you ticked ‘need to revise first’, which sections of the chapter are you going to
revise?
Must Revision
revise done
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88
Introduction
In Chapter 2 we briefly touched upon the constitution of the company. In this chapter
we continue our examination of the company’s constitutional structure with a
particular focus on how corporate power is allocated internally between the general
meeting and the board of directors (these bodies are often called the ‘organs’ of the
company).
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings, you should be able to:
u explain the function of the articles of association
u describe the problems that arise with enforcing the contract of membership
u explain why shareholder agreements have become increasingly common
u describe the mechanisms for altering the articles and any restrictions on
alteration.
Core text
¢ Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 8: ‘The constitution of the company: dealing with
insiders’.
Cases
¢ Salmon v Quin & Axtens Ltd [1909] 1 Ch 311
Additional cases
¢ MacDougall v Gardiner [1875] 1 Ch D 13
u shareholders
u company
u board.
On incorporation the founders of a company can provide their own set of articles. If
they do not, model articles provided by the law apply by default. Until 2009, there
was a single set of model articles, applicable to both public and private companies,
called Table A. For companies formed after 1 October 2009, there now exist separate
models, known as the Model Articles for Public Companies Limited by Shares, and
the Model Articles for Private Companies Limited by Shares. These are contained
in the Companies (Model Articles) Regulations 2008. The model articles, with some
amendments, are usually adopted. Because of this, the model articles effectively
provide the key legislative model for the running of the company. While companies
often have very complex organisational structures, the allocation of power in the
model articles between the general meeting and the board of directors is at the core
of every corporate structure.
It is this allocation of power that is the central function of the articles of association.
As a result, even though the model articles are only a default set of rules, their almost
universal adoption has meant that they form the core organisational structure of the
UK registered company:
The model articles also allocate the powers of each organ. The following are the most
important provisions in the articles.
‘[s]ubject to the provisions of the [CA 1985], the memorandum and the articles and to any
directions given by special resolution, the business of the company shall be managed by
the directors who may exercise all the powers of the company.’
This is now contained in articles 3 and 4 of the Model Articles (public and private) and
states:
page 90 University of London
3. Subject to the articles, the directors are responsible for the management of the
company’s business, for which purpose they may exercise all the powers of the company.
4. (1) The shareholders may, by special resolution, direct the directors to take, or refrain
from taking, specified action.
(2) No such special resolution invalidates anything which the directors have done
before the passing of the resolution.
As a result, the board is empowered to run the company, subject to:
u certain qualifications (i.e. the memorandum) and specifically the objects of the
company and any other articles restricting directors’ powers† †
It is common, for example,
to restrict the board’s ability
u special resolutions, directions from the shareholders and the Companies Act.
to borrow up to a certain
Although the power to run the company is subject to qualifications, it is important to amount without shareholder
note that the board is the primary power-wielding organ of the company. In Howard approval.
Smith Ltd v Ampol Petroleum Ltd (1974) Lord Wilberforce summed up the position:
[t]he constitution of a limited company normally provides for directors, with powers of
management, and shareholders, with defined voting powers having power to appoint
the directors, and to take, in general meeting, by majority vote, decisions on matters not
reserved for management... it is established that directors, within their management
powers, may take decisions against the wishes of the majority of shareholders, and indeed
that the majority of shareholders cannot control them in the exercise of these powers
while they remain in office.
The power delegated to the board derives from the total power the company actually
has, thus the power they wield is always limited by the objects clause. It is also worth
noting that the discretion is, of course, tempered by the very practical fact that s.168
CA 2006 allows the majority of the members to remove the board. Thus the board
cannot stray too far from the shareholders’ wishes if they are to keep their jobs.
The board is also given, by virtue of articles 30 (private) and 70 (public), the power to
decide whether to distribute any surplus profits to the shareholders in the form of
dividends. Although technically the general meeting declares the dividend it cannot
do so unless the board recommends a dividend. This may not seem like a significant
power but it is a very important independent management power exercised by the
board. The shareholders cannot therefore get any income from their shareholding
unless the directors allow it.
Significantly, the general meeting has certain other powers. For example its most
important power is the power to elect and remove directors (article 20 (public) gives
both the shareholders and the board the power to elect directors but the CA 2006, s
168 provides that only shareholders may remove directors). It may also issue shares
(article 43 (public), although this is commonly altered to give the board that power).
Section 437 CA 2006 requires that the annual accounts and reports be put before the
annual general meeting of a public company (there is however no requirement for
a vote on these reports but it is common practice for larger companies to require a
vote). Section 420 CA 2006 requires the directors of a quoted company to prepare
a remuneration report each year (identifying the remuneration being paid to
directors) and s.439 CA 2006 requires this report to be approved by shareholders in a
general meeting. The general meeting is also empowered by s.21 CA 2006 to alter the
Company Law 9 Dealing with insiders: the articles of association and shareholders’ agreements page 91
For most public companies the general meeting, in theory, fulfils an important
accountability function. In reality, however, large shareholders don’t tend to vote,
leading to accountability problems. The CLRSG recommended that institutional
investors who hold the vast majority of shares (insurance companies, pension funds
and investment trusts) should disclose their voting record at general meetings to
increase accountability and transparency (Final Report, Chapter 6 paras 6.22–6.40). The
White Paper (2002, Vol I, paras 2.6–2.48) adopted all the procedural recommendations
of the CLRSG regarding the general meeting except the recommendation to force
institutional investors to disclose their votes (para 2.47) and the CA 2006 does not
contain a provision requiring compulsory disclosure.
Activity 9.1
a. What is the function of the articles of association?
Summary
The articles of association form a core part of company law as they allocate corporate
power between the management and the shareholder organs. It is an area where the
reform driver of ‘think small first’ has been particularly successful.
The provisions of a company’s constitution bind the company and its members to the
same extent as if there were covenants on the part of the company and of each member
to observe those provisions.
This rather odd statutory contract was introduced in the 19th century to automatically
bind the shareholders and the company together to observe the constitution of the
company (see Hickman v Kent or Romney Marsh Sheep-Breeders’ Association (1915) 1 Ch
881). It is an odd contract, as it can be varied without the consent of all the parties
to it by special resolution. It also binds future members. It does, however, have a key
advantage far beyond just the observation of the constitution. When new members
join the company by buying shares, the constitution will automatically bind them to
observe the pre-existing constitution.
As such, it removes the possibility of re-negotiating the rules every time a new
shareholder arrives. This facilitates the development of the share market as the
page 92 University of London
shares are more transferable where they come with a fixed set of rights. However, as
we will discover below, unlike a normal contract the operation of the s.33 contract is
surrounded by a great deal of uncertainty.
Lord Wedderburn (1957) suggests that the following have been considered personal
rights in the past.
u Voting rights.
u Pre-emption rights.
While this offers a good overview of the characteristics of personal rights in the articles
the case law on the matter is still somewhat confused (see the contrasting views in
MacDougall v Gardiner (1875) 1 Ch D 13 and Pender v Lushington (1877) 6 Ch D 70).
Company Law 9 Dealing with insiders: the articles of association and shareholders’ agreements page 93
The court found that he could not rely on breach of that clause in the articles as the
cause of his action as there was no contractual relationship between the member
as ‘solicitor’ and the company. However, again here the courts have been somewhat
contradictory. In Salmon v Quin & Axtens Ltd [1909] 1 Ch 311 the articles of association
provided that the consent of both managing directors was needed for certain
decisions. Mr Salmon was a managing director and member of the company and he
dissented from a decision to buy and let some property. The general meeting then
passed a resolution authorising the purchase and letting of the property. Mr Salmon
sued as a member to enforce the article requiring his consent as managing director
to the transactions. In coming to their decision the House of Lords accepted a general
personal right of members to sue to enforce the articles by allowing a member to
obtain an injunction to stop the completion of the transactions entered into in breach
of the articles. Here the matter was viewed by the judges in terms of enforcing a
member right which tangentially affected his right as a director, rather than a director
right which has a tangential effect on the membership. (For a more recent example
see Globalink Telecommunications Ltd v Wilmbury Ltd [2003] 1 BCLC 145).
9.3.4 Reform
The CLRSG’s Final Report (July 2001 paras 7.34–7.40) recommended clarifying the s.14
issues by allowing all the articles to be enforceable by the members against the
company and each other unless the contrary was provided. The courts would also
be able to strike out trivial actions. These same recommendations are present in the
Government’s Consultative Document March 2005 (para 5.1). However, strangely, the
CA 2006 simply reworded the old problematic s.14 of the CA 1985.
Thus after nearly a decade of examining the failings in the area the Government was
content to ignore the CLRSG and its own White Papers to leave the issues in this area
unresolved.
Activity 9.2
Why is the enforcement of the s.33 contract so complex?
Summary
The s.33 contract fulfils a useful function. It ensures that all the members (even
future ones) and the company are bound to observe the constitution. It is an unusual
contract in that:
As a result, not all the parties to the contract have to agree to the alteration yet will be
bound by the new terms. However it is the enforcement of the statutory contract that
has exercised much judicial and academic thought. Can it be enforced by a member
against another member? Can a member enforce it against the company? Are all the
articles, even outsider articles, enforceable? Unfortunately the CA 2006 leaves these
questions unresolved.
page 94 University of London
In Russell v Northern Bank Development Corporation [1992] BCLC 431 the House of Lords
considered a shareholders’ agreement where the company agreed not to increase
the share capital of the company without the agreement of all the parties to the
shareholders’ agreement. The company did attempt to increase the share capital
of the company and one of the shareholders who was a party to the shareholders’
agreement objected and attempted to enforce the agreement. The statutory conflict
here was between the agreement and s.121 CA 1985, which allowed companies to
increase their share capital if their articles contain an authority (note s.617 CA 2006 has
amended this provision so authority is now unnecessary). The article of the company
did provide such an authorisation. The House of Lords found that the company’s
agreement not to increase its share capital was contrary to s.121 and, therefore,
unenforceable. However, the court did not declare the whole shareholders’ agreement
invalid – just the company’s agreement not to increase the share capital. This meant
that the shareholder who objected could not enforce it against the company but
could enforce it against the other members. As all the members of the company were
party to the shareholders’ agreement this has the same effect as if the company was
bound. The shareholders could not vote to increase the share capital.
exercised subject to those general principles of law and equity which are applicable to all
powers conferred on majorities enabling them to bind minorities. It must be exercised,
not only in the manner required by law, but also bona fide for the benefit of the company
as a whole, and it must not be exceeded. These conditions are always implied, and are
seldom, if ever, expressed.
Company Law 9 Dealing with insiders: the articles of association and shareholders’ agreements page 95
The second problem concerns what is meant by ‘for the benefit of the company as
a whole’. The court noted, in Greenhalgh v Arderne Cinemas Ltd [1951] Ch 286, that
many alterations do not really affect the company itself, as a separate commercial
entity. Instead, they merely adjust the respective rights of the shareholders, with little
impact on the company. The court therefore said that the test should be whether
the alteration was ‘discriminatory’ between the shareholders. However, it seems that
proving discrimination is difficult. In Greenhalgh itself for example, the court refused
to find such discrimination, notwithstanding that the alteration clearly benefitted the
majority shareholder and left the minority worse off.
One area where the courts have been somewhat readier to strike down alterations is
where they are being made to enable the shares of a member to compulsorily bought
off them: see Brown v British Abrasive Wheel Co Ltd [1919] 1 Ch 290 and Dafen Tinplate
Co Ltd v Llannelli Steel [1920] 2 Ch 124. Perhaps changing the articles to allow for this is
seen as simply too great an attack on the fundamental property rights of a member.
However, even in this context the minority is not sure to win; see for example Re
Charterhouse Capital Ltd [2014] EWHC 1410 (Ch).
Activity 9.3
a. What are the main advantages and disadvantages of a shareholders’ agreement?
Summary
As a result of the uncertainty surrounding the s.33 contract, shareholders have formed
contractually binding agreements which the courts have been willing to enforce. The
only real complication with these agreements is where the company is a party to the
agreement and some or all of the agreement is contrary to a statutory provision. In
such a case the company cannot contract out of its statutory obligation.
page 96 University of London
Alteration of the company’s constitution normally occurs by special resolution.
However, sometimes the courts have allowed more informal processes to stand. There
may also be restrictions on the ability of shareholders to vote if a statutory obligation
is affected or a minority shareholder is disadvantaged.
Further reading
¢ Baxter, C.R. ‘The role of the judge in enforcing shareholder rights’ (1983) 42
Cambridge LJ 96.
¢ Davies and Worthington, Chapter 3: ‘Sources of company law and the company’s
constitution’.
¢ Drury, R.R. ‘The relative nature of a shareholder’s right to enforce the company
contract’ (1986) CLJ 219.
¢ Goldberg, G.D. ‘The enforcement of outsider rights under section 20(1) of the
Companies Act 1948’ (1972) MLR 362.
¢ Goldberg, G.D. ‘The controversy on the section 20 contract revisited’ (1985) MLR
158.
¢ Wedderburn, K.W. ‘Shareholders’ rights and the rule in Foss v Harbottle’ (1957)
CLJ 194.
On the shareholder agreement issue again here discuss the facts in the question in
comparison with Russell v Northern Bank Development Corporation [1992] BCLC 431 and
the other contradictory case law.
page 98 University of London
Need to revise first = There are one or two areas I am unsure about and need to revise
before I go on to the next chapter.
Need to study again = I found many or all of the principles outlined in this chapter
very difficult and need to go over them again before I move on.
If you ticked ‘need to revise first’, which sections of the chapter are you going to
revise?
Must Revision
revise done
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100
Introduction
In this chapter we consider the nature of a share and the interest that a shareholder
has in the company. We go on to examine how the capital of a company may be
divided into various classes carrying with them different rights for their holders.
Finally, we consider how the company may vary the rights attaching to a class of
shares.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings, you should be able to:
u explain the legal nature of a share
u describe the various classes of shares
u describe how class rights attaching to shares are determined
u outline the procedure for varying class rights.
Core text
¢ Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 9: ‘Classes of shares and variation of class rights’.
Cases
¢ Borland’s Trustee v Steel Bros & Co Ltd [1901] 1 Ch 279
¢ Scottish Insurance Corp Ltd v Wilson and Clyde Coal Co Ltd [1949] 1 All ER 1068
Additional cases
¢ Re National Telephone Co [1914] 1 Ch 755
A share is the interest of a shareholder in the company measured by a sum of money, for
the purpose of liability in the first place, and of interest in the second, but also consisting
of a series of mutual covenants entered into by all the shareholders inter se in accordance
with [section 16CA 1862, now s.33 CA 2006]. The contract contained in the articles of
association is one of the original incidents of the share. A share is not a sum of money…
but an interest measured by a sum of money and made up of various rights contained in
the contract, including the right to a sum of money of a more or less amount.
In Short v Treasury Commissioners [1948] 1 KB 116 (affirmed by the House of Lords [1948]
AC 534) the legal nature of a share was subjected to considerable examination by
the court in relation to its valuation. The Government purchased all of the shares in
the company, valuing them on the basis of the quoted share price. The shareholders
argued that because the whole of the issued shares were being acquired then the
entire undertaking should be valued and the price apportioned between them. It
was held, however, that where a purchaser is buying control but none of the sellers
holds a controlling interest, the higher price that ‘control’ demands can be ignored.
The Treasury was therefore able to purchase the company for a price considerably less
than its asset value.
Activity 10.1
Explain the nature of a share.
Summary
An important feature of a share is that it represents the yardstick for measuring the
member’s interest in the company. For example, it determines the voting rights of the
holder at general meetings and the right to participate in surplus capital in the event
of the company being wound up. Finally, a share is a species of property (a chose in
action) that can be purchased, sold, bequeathed and mortgaged.
page 102 University of London
Generally, the articles of association give the company the power to issue shares with
such rights or restrictions as the company may by ordinary resolution determine. The
different classes of shares commonly issued are ordinary, preference, redeemable and
employees’ shares.
b. their spouses, civil partners, surviving spouses, surviving civil partners or minor
children or step-children under the age of 18 (s.1166).
Such shares are normally issued as ordinary shares or preference shares and are
typically subject to restrictions relating to their disposal.
u Rights or benefits which are annexed to particular shares, such as dividend rights,
and rights to participate in surplus assets on a winding up. Where the articles
provide that particular shares carry particular rights, these are class rights for the
purposes of s.125 CA 1985 (see now s.630 CA 2006).
u Rights or benefits that, although not attached to any particular shares, are
conferred on the beneficiary in his or her capacity as member or shareholder in the
company.
On the facts of the case it was held that provisions in the articles which gave the
claimant a pre-emptive right over the transfer of shares in the defendant company,
together with the right to nominate a director to its board so long as it held 10 per
cent of the ordinary shares, were class rights. Scott J said:
A company which, by its articles, confers special rights on one or more of its members in
the capacity of member or shareholder thereby constitutes the shares for the time being
held by that member or members a class of shares for the purposes of section 125. The
rights are class rights.
In determining the scope of class rights the courts have developed certain rules of
construction. For example it is presumed that any rights attaching to a share are
exhaustive (i.e. comprehensive) (see Re National Telephone Co [1914] 1 Ch 755). However,
preference shares are presumed to be entitled to a cumulative dividend even if the
terms of issue are silent on the matter (Webb v Earle (1875) LR 20 Eq 556).
provided that the rights attached to any class of shares may be ‘affected, modified,
varied, dealt with, or abrogated in any manner’ with the approval of an extraordinary
resolution passed at a separate meeting of the members of that class. The preference
shareholders argued that an issue of additional shares, both preference and ordinary,
‘affected’ their voting rights and therefore fell within article 68. However, the company
contended that the proposal did not amount to a variation of class rights but rather
it was the effectiveness of the exercise of those rights that had been affected and
therefore a separate meeting of the preference shareholders was not required.
A successful claim was brought in Re Old Silkstone Collieries Ltd [1954] Ch 169. The
company’s colliery was nationalised by the government of the day. While waiting for
the final settlement of compensation, the company had twice reduced its capital by
returning part of the preference shareholders’ capital investment. On both occasions
the company had promised the shareholders that they would not be bought out
entirely but that they would retain their membership so that they could participate
in the compensation scheme to be introduced under the nationalisation legislation.
Subsequently, it was proposed to reduce the company’s capital for a third time by
returning all outstanding capital to the preference shareholders. The effect of this would
be to cancel the class completely and they would no longer qualify for compensation.
The Court of Appeal refused to sanction the reduction, holding that the proposal
amounted to an unfair variation of class rights in so far as the preference shareholders
had been promised that they would participate in the compensation scheme.
But note that a cancellation of a class of shares on a reduction of capital will not generally
be held to constitute a variation of class rights. Such a course of action is viewed as
consistent with the terms of issue of the particular shares in question (see House of Fraser
plc v ACGE Investments Ltd [1987] BCLC 293; Re Saltdean Estate Co Ltd [1968] 3 All ER 829).
Activity 10.2
Explain what is meant by ‘class rights’.
(b) if no such provision is made in the articles, if the holders of three-quarters in value of
the shares of that class consent either in writing or by special resolution (passed at a
separate meeting of the holders of such shares.
The company must then notify the registrar of any variation of class rights within one
month from the date on which the variation is made (ss.637 and 640).
Although the CLRSG had recommended that the consent of 75 per cent of the holders
of the class affected should be a statutory minimum, notwithstanding any less onerous
procedure contained in the company’s articles, this was removed from the Companies
Bill at a fairly late stage. As a consequence, the company’s articles may specify either
less or more demanding requirements for variation of class rights than the default
provisions laid down in the Act (see s.630(3)). This has two important effects.
Company Law 10 Class rights page 105
u First, if, and to the extent that, the company has adopted a more onerous regime
in its articles for the variation of class rights, for example requiring a higher
percentage than the statutory minimum, the company must comply with the more
onerous regime.
u Second, if and to the extent that the company has protected class rights by making
provision for the entrenchment of those rights in its articles (see s.22 CA 2006), that
protection cannot be circumvented by changing the class rights under s.630.
It should be noted that the statutory procedure is supplemented by the common law
requirement that the shareholders voting at a class meeting must have regard to the
interests of the class as a whole (British America Nickel Corpn v MJ O’Brien Ltd [1927] AC
369, Viscount Haldane; and Re Holders Investment Trust [1971] 2 All ER 289, Megarry J).
Activity 10.3
Why is it important to identify a class right?
Further reading
¢ Davies and Worthington, Chapter 19: ‘Controlling members’ voting’ and Chapter
23: ‘The nature and classification of shares’.
¢ Grantham, R.B. ‘The doctrinal basis of the rights of company shareholders’ (1998)
CLJ 554.
¢ Ireland, P. ‘Company law and the myth of shareholder ownership’ (1999) MLR 32.
Discuss the statutory procedure which the company must follow in order to vary class
rights.
Company Law 10 Class rights page 107
Need to revise first = There are one or two areas I am unsure about and need to revise
before I go on to the next chapter.
Need to study again = I found many or all of the principles outlined in this chapter
very difficult and need to go over them again before I move on.
If you ticked ‘need to revise first’, which sections of the chapter are you going to
revise?
Must Revision
revise done
Notes
11 Majority rule and wrongs against the company
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110
11.1 The rule in Foss v Harbottle – the proper claimant rule . . . . . . . . . . 111
Introduction
We are concerned here primarily with one particular aspect of majority rule: how it
affects action taken for wrongs done to the company. The most important example of
such a wrong would be where the directors have breached their duties to the company
(see Chapter 15). As we saw in Chapter 3, a consequence of the Salomon doctrine is that
a company can sue in its own right to vindicate a wrong done to it. Thus, whenever a
wrong has been committed against the company, the proper claimant is the company
itself. However, a company is a metaphysical person and as such it must act through
its organ of management (the directors) and the decision to bring legal proceedings
is generally vested in the board (see the model articles of association for private and
public companies, article 3 (directors’ general authority). But what if the wrongdoers
are the directors themselves who, controlling the company, prevent it from seeking
legal redress against them? In this chapter we consider how the law seeks to solve this
problem by permitting minority shareholders, in certain exceptional circumstances, to
bring a derivative action on the company’s behalf.
It is worth bearing in mind here when examining this issue that there is a tension
between the theory of corporate personality and majority rule. As a result this is a
conceptually difficult and technical topic that requires concentrated study. Given its
complexity, you will need to read and reflect on these conceptual tensions. Don’t be
put off if you do not understand the topic immediately – take a break and then re-read
the material. You will find that patiently working through the chapter (perhaps several
times) will pay dividends.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings, you should be able to:
u describe the rule in Foss v Harbottle (the proper claimant rule) and the policies
that underlie it
u describe and critically assess the exceptions to the rule in Foss v Harbottle
u describe the various types of shareholder actions
u outline the difficulties which confront a shareholder who seeks to initiate
litigation when a wrong has been done to the company by those in control
u assess the statutory procedure for bringing a derivative claim.
Core text
¢ Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 10: ‘Derivative claims’.
Cases
¢ Foss v Harbottle (1843) 2 Hare 461
¢ Prudential Assurance Co Ltd v Newman Industries Co Ltd (No.2) [1980] 2 All ER 841;
[1982] Ch 204 CA
¢ Re Singh Brothers Contractors (North West Limited) [2013] EWHC 2138 (Ch)
Company Law 11 Majority rule and wrongs against the company page 111
Additional cases
¢ Mumbray v Lapper [2005] EWHC 1152 (Ch)
u it upholds the principle of majority rule: if the majority of shareholders do not wish
to pursue an action then the minority is bound by that decision.
Saying that the company is ‘the proper claimant’ begs the question of who is to decide
if the company will sue. It should be noted that the model articles of association for
private and public companies (see article 3) place the management of companies into
the hands of their directors and the decision whether to sue a third party who has
committed a wrong against the company or, on the other hand, to defend an action
brought against the company falls within the remit of the board. Consequently, even
where the directors do not hold a majority of shares (as is common in large private
companies and public companies) the shareholders cannot generally direct them to
sue or defend an action (Breckland Group Holdings Ltd v London and Suffolk Ltd (1988)
4 BCC 542). (For a very good discussion of whether the board is the best body to take
the decision that the company will, or will not, sue a director, see Kershaw (2012),
pp.589–95.)
The proper plaintiff in an action in respect of a wrong done to a company is prima facie the
company itself.
Where the alleged wrong is a transaction which might be made binding on the company
and all its members by a simple majority of the members, no individual member of the
†
company is allowed to maintain an action in respect of that matter ‘for the simple reason ‘Cadit quaestio’ (Latin) – ‘The
that, if a mere majority of the members of the company… is in favour of what has been matter (literally ‘question’)
done, then cadit quaestio† (in other words, the majority rule). falls’.
page 112 University of London
In Foss v Harbottle (1843) 2 Hare 461 the claimants were two shareholders in the
Victoria Park Company. They brought an action against the company’s five directors
and promoters, alleging that the defendants had misappropriated assets belonging
to the company and had improperly mortgaged its property. The claimants sought an
order to compel the defendants to make good the losses suffered by the company.
They also applied for the appointment of a receiver. It was held that the action
must fail. The harm in question was suffered by the whole company, not just by the
two shareholders. It was open to the majority in general meeting to approve the
defendants’ conduct. To allow the minority to bring an action in these circumstances
would risk frustrating the wishes of the majority.
A clear application of the rule that illustrates how it fits with the principle of majority
rule is MacDougall v Gardiner (1875) 1 ChD 13. The chairman of the Emma Silver Mining Co
had adjourned a general meeting of the company without allowing a vote to be taken
on the issue of adjournment as requested by a shareholder, MacDougall. He therefore
brought an action claiming first, a declaration that the chairman had acted improperly
and second, an injunction to restrain the directors from taking any further action. The
Court of Appeal held that the basis of the complaint was something that in substance the
majority of the shareholders were entitled to do and there was no point in suing where
ultimately a meeting has to be called at which the majority will, in any case, get its way.
Against this background Lord Davey in Burland v Earle [1902] AC 83 formulated what has
become a classic statement of the rule:
It is an elementary principle of the law relating to joint stock companies that the Court will
not interfere with the internal management of companies acting within their powers, and
in fact has no jurisdiction to do so. Again, it is clear law that, in order to redress a wrong
done to the company or to recover money or damages alleged to be due to the company,
the action should prima facie be brought by the company itself.
(See also Mozley v Alston (1847) 1 Ph 790; Gray v Lewis (1873) 8 Ch App 1035; Re Down’s
Wine Bar [1990] BCLC 839.)
Activity 11.1
Consider the key differences between private companies and public companies.
Do you think the relationship between the board of directors and the shareholders
may depend upon the size of the company?
No feedback provided.
Activity 11.2
Read MacDougall v Gardiner (1875) 1 Ch D 13.
Upon what basis did Mellish LJ reach the conclusion that the Rule in Foss v Harbottle
operated to defeat the claim? When, in his view, may a minority sue?
Corporate actions
This is an action brought by the company itself, so that the company will be named as
the claimant. As we have seen, according to the rule in Foss, this is the type of action
that should be brought where a wrong has been done to the company. It must be
authorised by whoever within the company has the authority to decide the company
will sue, and this ordinarily will be the board of directors.
next below, the shareholder is not suing to enforce their own rights, but is instead
suing to enforce the company’s rights – say in respect of a breach of duty owed to the
company by a director. And if successful, the benefits will go to the company, not the
shareholder. As hopefully will be clear, such proceedings are an exception to Foss, for
they allow a shareholder to sue for a wrong done to the company. We will consider
below the restrictive conditions that must be satisfied before such proceedings can be
brought.
As we shall see, those conditions used to be set out in the common law, when the
proceedings were called derivative actions. The rules have now been incorporated
into legislation, and the name of such proceedings changed to derivative claims.
Personal actions
This is an action brought by, and in the names of, an individual shareholder or group
of shareholders. They sue to enforce their own rights, and for their own benefit. As we
have seen, according to the rule in Foss, shareholders cannot bring a personal action
in respect of a wrong done to the company. However, there may be situations where
the misconduct that has occurred does not constitute a wrong to the company but
is instead an infringement of the personal rights of the shareholder. In that case, the
shareholder can sue personally, and the rule in Foss does not prevent her doing so. As
Mellish LJ observed in MacDougall v Gardiner (above), where the right of a shareholder
has been infringed by the majority, he can sue. Here, the injury or wrong in question is
not suffered by the company as such, but by the shareholder personally. Therefore, the
anxiety underlying Foss v Harbottle does not arise.
A shareholder’s rights can arise by virtue of a contract, for example, under the
company’s constitution or a shareholders’ agreement. Thus, where a dividend is
declared but not paid, a shareholder can sue personally for payment by way of a legal
debt. See, for example, Wood v Odessa Waterworks Co (1889) 43 Ch D 636 (Ch D)).
The action avoids the costs of multiple suits. The court’s judgment will be binding on
those represented (see, for example, Quin & Axtens Ltd v Salmon [1909] 1 Ch 311). Thus, a
representative action is brought where a wrong has been committed by the company
to a class of shareholders (see Pender v Lushington).
The shareholder will find two difficulties in using that argument. The first reflects what
we have discussed so far in this chapter. The shareholder may be out of pocket, but
cannot easily point to the breach of any duty owed to them personally. The directors’
fraud will be a breach of their duties, but these duties are owed only to the company
itself (see Chapter 15). Directors do not owe duties directly to individual shareholders.
So, legally speaking, the wrong can be said to be done only to the company (even
though it leaves the shareholders out of pocket).
page 114 University of London
This first difficulty might not be insurmountable, however. In some (exceptional) cases,
the shareholder might be able to show that, alongside the duties which the director
owes to their company, they do also owe duties directly to individual shareholders.
There are a number of grounds on which directors might come to owe duties directly
to shareholders (although it is important to emphasise that all of the grounds apply
only exceptionally). First, directors may owe a duty of care to shareholders in tort. That
duty would include not misleading the shareholders, for example by giving careless
advice to shareholders about how they might vote at a shareholders’ meeting: see
Sharp v Blank [2015] EWHC 3220 (Ch).
Another way is if the directors were to enter into a sufficiently close relationship
with shareholders to give rise to duties owed directly to them. This has sometimes
happened where directors are closely advising shareholders on the sale of their shares:
see the discussion in Section 15.1.2. A final ground might arise where there is some
separate contract between the directors and the shareholders, and that contract
imposes obligations on the directors in favour of the shareholders. See the case of Giles
v Rhind, below, for an example of this. See also Platt v Platt [1999] 2 BCLC 745. However,
even if the shareholder were able to establish that, exceptionally, the directors did
owe the shareholders some duties (over and above the duties the directors owed to
the company), the shareholders would still face a second difficulty.
The second difficulty is this: where a wrong results first in a loss to the company
and this leads in turn to a diminution in the value of a member’s shareholding, the
shareholder’s loss has been termed ‘reflective loss’ by Lord Bingham and Lord Millett in
Johnson v Gore Wood & Co [2001] 1 All ER 481. The shareholder’s loss merely reflects the
loss caused first to the company. And in Prudential Assurance Co Ltd v Newman Industries
Ltd (No.2) [1982] 1 All ER 354, the Court of Appeal held that a shareholder cannot sue for
such reflective loss. Quite simply, the rule in Foss v Harbottle means that the company
is the proper claimant and the shareholder’s reflective loss will be remedied if the
company sues the wrongdoer.
However, if the court is satisfied that a member suffered a personal loss which is
separate and distinct from that sustained by the company (and provided of course
that the member can show this arose from the breach of a duty owed personally to
them, so they can overcome the first difficulty noted above), then the member will
be able to sue (Johnson v Gore Wood & Co). The authorities were summarised by Lord
Bingham in the Johnson decision as supporting three propositions.
(i) Where a company suffers loss caused by a breach of duty owed to it, only the company
may sue in respect of that loss. No action lies at the suit of a shareholder suing in that
capacity and no other (i.e. a shareholder is not entitled to sue merely as a shareholder)
to make good a diminution in the value of the shareholder’s shareholding where that
merely reflects the loss suffered by the company. A claim will not lie by a shareholder
to make good a loss which would be made good if the company’s assets were
replenished through action against the party responsible for the loss, even if the
company, acting through its constitutional organs, has declined or failed to make
good that loss…
(ii) Where a company suffers loss but has no cause of action to sue to recover that loss,
the shareholder in the company may sue in respect of it (if the shareholder has a
cause of action to do so), even though the loss is a diminution in the value of the
shareholding…
(iii) Where a company suffers loss caused by a breach of duty to it, and a shareholder
suffers a loss separate and distinct from that suffered by the company caused by
breach of a duty independently owed to the shareholder, each may sue to recover the
loss caused to it by breach of the duty owed to it but neither may recover loss caused
to the other by breach of the duty owed to that other.
Recently, the no reflective loss principle has been subjected to considerable judicial
scrutiny. These cases suggest that the principle is of wide application and will readily
be invoked by the courts. The essential point is that the courts prefer the company
itself to sue for the loss it has suffered, rather than permitting (potentially many)
Company Law 11 Majority rule and wrongs against the company page 115
individual personal actions to be brought by those who have suffered some harm
as a result of the loss caused to the company. In Ellis v Property Leeds (UK) Ltd [2002]
2 BCLC 175, the Court of Appeal held that the principle applies equally where the
claimant is suing qua director as to when he sues qua shareholder. Moreover, it was
held in Sevilleja Garcia v Marex Financial Ltd [2018] EWCA Civ 1468, that the principle also
prevents a creditor from suing personally for reflective loss and it does so whether or
not the creditor is a shareholder in the company. The principle also applies even if the
company happens to be in administrative receivership, for being in administrative
receivership does not prevent the company itself from pursuing any claim it may have
for harm done to it (see Gardner v Parker [2004] EWCA Civ 781, in which the Court of
Appeal also stressed that the bar is an obvious consequence of the rule against double
recovery). However, the prohibition can be circumvented where the shareholder is
able to bring a claim qua beneficiary of a trust of shares of which the wrongdoer is
trustee (see Walker v Stones [2001] 2 WLR 623, CA; Shaker v Al-Bedrawi [2002] EWCA Civ
1452).
In Breeze v Chief Constable of Norfolk [2018] EWHC 485 (QB), the court confirmed that the
reflective loss principle is not restricted to cases where there is a breach of directors’
duties. Rather, the principle applies to ‘any situation where a company (whether or
not it actually sues) has a cause of action in respect of an actionable wrong, which,
if pursued to its fullest extent, would enable it to seek to recoup the loss’. (In this
particular case, the claim the company itself could have sued for was ‘misfeasance in a
public office’.)
One exception to the reflective loss principle was established in the case of Giles v Rhind
[2001] 2 BCLC 582. The company was insolvent due to a former director’s breach of
certain duties (not to compete or misuse confidential information). Both duties were
also express terms in a shareholders’ agreement to which the defendant and claimant
were parties. Although the company had initiated an action against its former director,
the administrative receivers discontinued it when the defendant director applied for a
security of costs order. In effect, the defendant had, by his breach of duty, rendered the
company incapable of seeking legal redress against him. The claimant brought a personal
action against the former director to recover losses to the value of his shareholding,
loss of remuneration and loss of the value of loan stock. The Court of Appeal, in placing
considerable emphasis on the fact that the defendant’s own wrongdoing had, in effect,
disabled the company from suing him for damages, found that this situation had not
confronted the House of Lords in Johnson v Gore Wood & Co. Given that the duties in
question were expressly provided for in the shareholders’ agreement, it was held that
the claimant could pursue his claim for breach of the agreement, including his losses in
respect of the value of his shareholding. However, in Sevilleja (see above) the court also
held that this exception must be construed narrowly. In particular, the court said that the
company’s inability to sue must be ‘legal’ rather than merely ‘factual’. In other words, the
effect of the wrongdoing against the company must be such as to create a legal barrier
to the company suing, and not merely to cause ‘factual’ difficulties (such as a lack of the
necessary funds to pursue the action).
Activity 11.3
Try to summarise Lord Bingham’s three propositions in Johnson in simple language.
No feedback provided.
Summary
In Johnson v Gore Wood & Co the House of Lords explained that the reason for
disallowing the shareholder’s claim for reflective loss is that if a member could
sue there would be a risk of double recovery. As pointed out by Arden LJ in Day v
Cook [2002] 1 BCLC 1, the member’s claim is ‘trumped’ by the company’s. Thus, for
a shareholder to bring a personal claim for a loss it must be shown that there was
breach of a duty owed personally to him or her and that a personal loss was suffered
which is separate from any loss suffered by the company.
page 116 University of London
Activity 11.4
Read Giles v Rhind [2003] 1 BCLC 1.
What was the issue that came before the Court of Appeal in this case which had not
been addressed by the House of Lords in Johnson v Gore Wood & Co?
UK company law has long permitted them. Prior to the CA 2006, however, the rules
governing derivative actions (as they were then known) were found not in the Companies
Acts, but were instead established only by case law. These rules were much criticised
(consider for example the views of the Law Commission (see the LCCP No.142 (1996) and
the ensuing Report, No.246 (Cm 3769, 1997)). It was felt that the rules, being buried in case
law, were inaccessible and often unclear. It was also felt that the rules were too restrictive,
and made it too difficult for shareholders to succeed in bringing such actions.
The Law Commission did not recommend abandoning the rule in Foss v Harbottle itself,
and its requirement that a company should be the claimant where the company had
been wronged. It felt the rule itself was sound. Derivative proceedings should remain an
exception to that rule – a procedural device that would enable individual shareholders
to take action for the company, to ensure the company’s rights were vindicated. But
there should be ‘a new derivative procedure with more modern, flexible and accessible
criteria’. This was achieved by introducing a new statutory ‘derivative claim’, in Part 11
CA 2006. The common law derivative action has, therefore, almost been completely
replaced by the new statutory claim. Almost, but not entirely: what are termed ‘multiple
derivative actions’ are not covered by the statutory provisions of Part 11. A multiple
derivative action is one brought by a shareholder of a parent company in respect of a
wrong done to the company’s subsidiary, or its sub-subsidiary, and so on. Such claims
must still be brought under the old common law procedure: see Re Fort Gilkicker Ltd
[2013] EWHC 348 (Ch) and Abouraya v Sigmund [2014] EWHC 277 (Ch).
At common law, the derivative action was available only where there was ‘fraud on
the minority’. It became known, then, as the fraud on the minority exception to Foss.
It appears in a longer list of ‘exceptions to Foss’ which Jenkins LJ set out in Edwards v
Halliwell [1950] 2 All ER 1064. These were:
Company Law 11 Majority rule and wrongs against the company page 117
u where the act complained of is illegal or is wholly ultra vires the company (this is
discussed further in Chapter 13)
u where the matter in issue requires the sanction of a special majority, or there has
been non-compliance with a special procedure
u where a fraud has been perpetrated on the minority and the wrongdoers are in
control.
‘Fraud’ in the phrase ‘fraud on a minority’ seems to be being used as comprising not only
fraud at common law but also fraud in the wider equitable sense of that term…
So, we know that ‘fraud’ here does not necessarily mean that the breach of duty was
dishonest or deceitful, but that still gives little positive guidance. The judges perhaps
deliberately left the definition of fraud in this context open, although some guidelines
were laid down. In Burland v Earle (above), fraud was defined as: ‘when the majority
are endeavouring directly or indirectly to appropriate to themselves money, property
or advantages which belong to the company or in which the other shareholders are
entitled to participate’.
In Daniels v Daniels [1978] Ch 406, Templeman J expressed the view that the term
‘fraud’ should extend to cases of self-serving negligence. He said that the fraud on the
minority principle would be satisfied: ‘where directors use their powers intentionally or
unintentionally, fraudulently or negligently in a manner which benefited themselves at
the expense of the company.’ But note that negligence per se is not sufficient. In Pavlides
v Jensen [1956] Ch 565 Danckwerts J accepted that the forbearance of shareholders
extends to directors who are ‘an amiable set of lunatics’. In this case, although the
directors were negligent, they did not derive any personal benefit. Contrast the
common law position with the reforms introduced by the CA 2006, Part 11 (below).
page 118 University of London
There was judicial debate over whether actual (de jure) control was required (for
example whether the wrongdoers needed to control 51 per cent or more of the votes),
or whether de facto control sufficed. In Prudential Assurance Co Ltd v Newman Industries
Co Ltd (No.2) (above), the Court of Appeal adopted a restrictive approach to the issue
and this lead was followed by Knox J in Smith v Croft (No.2) [1988] Ch 114, who stated
that if the majority of the shareholders who were independent of the wrongdoers did
not wish the action to proceed ‘for disinterested reasons’, as occurred on the facts of
the case, the single member who sought to initiate the proceedings would be denied
standing to sue (locus standi). The logic of this was that if a majority of disinterested
shareholders were against action by the company, then the company was being
stopped from suing (or ‘controlled’) not by the wrongdoers, but by non-wrongdoing
shareholders. This attempted to reassert the importance of majority rule, but rule by
a majority of disinterested and impartial shareholders. The judge went on to observe
that in determining the independence of the shareholders who did not support an
action being brought against the wrongdoers: ‘[their] votes should be disregarded if,
but only if, the court is satisfied either that the vote or its equivalent is actually cast
with a view to supporting the defendants rather than securing benefit to the company’.
Summary
At common law, a shareholder would be permitted to sue on behalf of the company, as
an exception to Foss, in a derivative claim, but only if she could establish that the wrong
to the company amounted to ‘fraud’, and the company could not itself sue because
it was controlled by the wrongdoer(s). But these conditions were unclear in their
meaning, and restrictively applied. The hope was that the new statutory derivative claim
procedure, in Part 11 CA 2006, would be both clearer, and give the individual shareholder
a greater chance of success. We must now see if this has proved to be the case.
The grounds for bringing a derivative claim are laid down by s.260(3), which provides
that such a claim may be brought only in respect of a cause of action arising from an
actual or proposed act or omission involving negligence, default, breach of duty or
breach of trust by a director of the company.
It is clear that claims against directors for any breach of their duties owed to the
company fall within its scope. In this respect s.260(3) is wider than the common law
action it replaces. The breach no longer needs to be one that is considered ‘fraud’
(with all the uncertainty about what fraud actually meant). On a practical level, this
means that a derivative claim now can be brought for a breach of the duty to exercise
reasonable care, skill and diligence (see s.174 CA 2006) whether or not that breach is
‘self-serving’ (compare the case of Pavlides v Jensen, above). Section 260(3) also makes
it clear that a derivative claim may be brought, for example, against a third party who
dishonestly assists a director’s breach of fiduciary duty or one who knowingly receives
property in breach of a fiduciary duty.
It is also immaterial whether the cause of action arose before or after the person seeking
to bring or continue the derivative claim became a member of the company (s.260(4)).
Finally, note that CA 2006 does not say that the shareholder bringing the derivative
claim must show that the wrongdoers are in control of the company (recall that
establishing ‘wrongdoer control’ was one of the conditions under the common law
rules). However, it is less clear whether this means this condition no longer applies to
Company Law 11 Majority rule and wrongs against the company page 119
the new statutory claim: see Kershaw, D. ‘The rule in Foss v Harbottle is dead; long live
the rule in Foss v Harbottle’ (2015) Journal of Business Law 274.
This entails a two stage process. The first stage involves a paper hearing, where the
court considers the member’s evidence. The onus is on the member to establish that
they have a prima facie case for permission to continue the derivative claim. If this is
not demonstrated the court will dismiss the application. If the application is dismissed
at this stage, the applicant may request the court to reconsider its decision at an oral
hearing, although no new evidence will be permitted at this hearing from either the
member or the company. The Practice Direction 19C, Derivative Claims, which amends
Part 19 of the Civil Procedure Rules (CPR), provides that this stage of the application
will normally be decided without submissions from the company. If the court does not
dismiss the application at this stage, the application will then proceed to the second
stage, which is a full permission hearing, and here the court may order the company to
provide evidence at this stage.
Sections 263(2) and (3) sets out the criteria which the court must take into account
when determining whether to grant permission to a member to continue a derivative
claim.
Section 263(2) contains three criteria that operate as what might be called ‘mandatory
bars’, in the sense that if any one of these criteria applies, the court must then refuse
its permission to continue the claim. So, permission must be refused if the court is
satisfied that:
u a person acting in accordance with s.172 (duty to promote the success of the
company) would not seek to continue the claim; or
u where the claim arises from an act or omission that is yet to occur, that the act or
omission has been authorised by the company; or
u where the complaint arises from an act or omission that has already occurred,
that act or omission was authorised before it occurred, or has been ratified since it
occurred.
For an example of a case where the court found that the breach of duty had been
authorised or ratified by the shareholders, see Re Singh Brothers Contractors (North
West Limited) [2013] EWHC 2138 (Ch). In Cullen Investments Ltd v Brown [2015] EWHC 473
(Ch) the court made clear that for an authorisation to be effective, the director would
have to show that he had made a ‘full and frank disclosure’ to the shareholders about
his conduct. The same point would presumably apply to a ratification.
For the first of these mandatory bars (whether a person is acting in accordance with
s.172, etc.), the issue here is really whether continuing the claim would be in the
best interests of the company. In Iesini v Westrip Holdings Ltd [2009] EWHC 2526 (Ch),
Lewison J listed the considerations to take into account in deciding whether it would
be in the company’s interests to continue, or to stop, the proceedings. These included:
u the impact on the company if it lost the claim and had to pay not only its own costs
but the defendant’s as well
However, Lewison J also noted that a judge should only refuse permission under this
mandatory bar if ‘no reasonable director’ would think it worth proceeding with the
claim. In other words, if there were a reasonable doubt about whether it was in the
company’s best interests to continue the claim, then the judge ought not to stop
proceedings on this ground.
Where none of the mandatory bars apply, the judge is not compelled to refuse
permission. But nor are they compelled to give permission to let it continue. Instead,
the judge now has a discretion what to do, and to exercise that discretion, they must
move on and apply a list of ‘discretionary factors’, set out in s.263(3). These factors are:
u the importance that a person acting in accordance with s.172 (duty to promote the
success of the company) would attach to pursuing the action
u whether the shareholder could pursue the action in their own right.
In a number of cases, the courts have decided that the shareholder would be better
off pursuing an action in their own right. The action that the court has in mind here is
a claim under s.994 CA 2006 for ‘unfair prejudice’ (see Chapter 12). See, for example,
Mission Capital plc v Sinclair [2008] EWHC 1339 (Ch) and Franbar Holdings v Patel [2008]
EWHC 1534 (Ch).
The reference above to whether ‘the company’ has decided not to pursue the claim
means the board of directors. In Kleanthous v Paphitis [2011] EWHC 2287 (Ch) the court
placed some weight on this factor, with the judge noting that the company’s directors
were better placed than the judge to determine the likely impact upon the company
of either continuing, or stopping, the claim.
Section 263(4) goes on to add the requirement, as laid down in Smith v Croft (No.2)
(above), that the court ‘shall have particular regard’ to any evidence before it as to
the views of members who have no personal interest in the derivative claim. There
will need to be a factual enquiry into whether or not the breach is likely to be ratified.
In practice the courts will probably adjourn the permission hearing in order for the
question of ratification to be put to the company.
Provision is also made for a member of the company to apply to the court to continue
a derivative claim originally brought by another member but which is being poorly
conducted by him or her. Section 264 provides that the court may grant permission
to continue the claim where the manner in which the proceedings have been
commenced or continued by the original claimant amounts to an abuse of the
process of the court, the claimant has failed to prosecute the claim diligently and it
is appropriate for the applicant to continue the claim as a derivative claim. Similarly,
by virtue of s.262, where a company has initiated proceedings and the cause of action
could be pursued as a derivative claim, a member may apply to the court to continue
the action as a derivative claim on the same grounds listed in s.264. This addresses
the situation where directors, fearing a derivative claim by a member, seek to block it
by causing the company to sue but with no genuine intention of pursuing the action
diligently.
A major deterrent against speculative claims is, of course, costs. Although CPR, r.19.9E
enables the court to order the company to indemnify the member, in practice such an
order will rarely be granted where permission is denied. Finally, it is also noteworthy
that the law on ratification has been tightened and the votes of the ‘wrongdoers’ will
no longer be counted on such ordinary resolutions (although such members may be
counted towards the quorum and may participate in the proceedings; see further,
ss.175 and 239 CA 2006).
If permission is granted to continue the claim the member will bring the action on
the company’s behalf. Unless otherwise permitted or required by r.19.9A or r.19.9C,
the claimant may take no further action in the proceedings without the permission
of the court. A practical hurdle which confronts a shareholder litigant is the cost of
a proposed action. This is covered by r.19.9E. The court may order the company to
indemnify the claimant against any liability in respect of costs incurred in the claim
or in the permission application, or both. An application for costs made at the time of
applying for permission to continue the claim is commonly called a pre-emptive costs
order. It derives from the decision Wallersteiner v Moir (No.2) [1975] 2 QB 273, where
Buckley LJ observed that the shareholder who initiates the derivative claim may be
entitled to be indemnified by the company at the end of the trial for his costs provided
he acted reasonably in bringing the action. The position in the event of the action
failing was also considered by the court. Lord Denning MR said:
But what if the action fails? Assuming that the minority shareholder had reasonable
grounds for bringing the action – that it was a reasonable and prudent course to take
in the interests of the company – he should not himself be liable to pay the costs of the
other side, but the company itself should be liable, because he was acting for it and not
for himself. In addition, he should himself be indemnified by the company in respect of his
own costs even if the action fails. It is a well-known maxim of the law that he who would
take the benefit of a venture if it succeeds ought also to bear the burden if it fails… In
order to be entitled to this indemnity, the minority shareholder soon after issuing his writ
should apply for the sanction of the court in somewhat the same way as a trustee does.
In Smith v Croft (No.2) (above), decided under the old RSC (Rules of the Supreme
Court), Walton J held that the shareholder’s personal means to finance the action was
a relevant factor to be taken into account by the court in determining the need for an
indemnity. The judge also added that even where the shareholder is impecunious, he
should still be required to meet a share of the costs as an incentive to proceed with
the action with due diligence.
Finally, in Bhullar v Bhullar [2015] EWHC 1943 (Ch), the court refused to award an
indemnity where it felt that the claimant was using the derivative claim as a tactic
page 122 University of London
to pressurise the majority, and that the dispute between the parties was likely to be
settled under s.994 CA 2006 (unfair prejudice proceedings).
Summary
If you have understood the rationale underlying the Rule in Foss v Harbottle,
together with the fundamental principles of company law that underpin it, you
clearly understand the proper claimant rule. If at this stage you still have difficulties
understanding this area don’t worry – it is a notoriously difficult topic. If you are still
having difficulties, re-read Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 10 before going on to read the
other sources listed in ‘Further reading’ below. Also, as you reflect on the rule, bear in
mind that the judges do not see themselves serving as appeal tribunals for the benefit
of dissenting minority shareholders (Carlen v Drury (1812) 1 Ves & B 154; see Dignam
and Lowry, Chapter 10, para 10.3). The statutory procedure at least sets out the steps to
be followed in an accessible way. We await the case law it will generate with interest,
particularly with respect to how the judges will exercise their discretion in granting (or
refusing) permission to continue the claim.
Further reading
¢ Almadani, M. ‘Derivative actions: does the Companies Act 2006 offer a way
forward?’ (2009) Company Lawyer 131.
¢ Arsalidou, D. ‘Litigation culture and the new statutory derivative claim’ (2009)
30 Company Lawyer 205.
¢ Boyle, A.J. ‘The new derivative action’ (1997) 18 Company Lawyer 256.
¢ CLSRG Developing the Framework, para 4.127; Completing the Structure, paras
5.86–5.87; Final Report, para 7.46.
¢ Kershaw, D. ‘The rule in Foss v Harbottle is dead; long live the rule in Foss v
Harbottle’ (2015) JBL 274–302.
¢ Lord Wedderburn ‘Shareholders’ rights and the rule in Foss v Harbottle’ (1957) CLJ
194 and (1958) CLJ 93.
¢ Riley, C.A. ‘Derivative claims and ratification: time to ditch some baggage’ (2014)
34 Legal Studies 582.
u discuss what the rule in Foss v Harbottle is and identify its purpose (Edwards v
Halliwell and MacDougall v Gardiner)
u assess the case law surrounding the exceptions to the rule and consider, against
this background, whether the judges, in exercising their discretion under Part 11
CA 2006, are likely to open the floodgates of litigation or whether they are likely to
adopt a strict approach towards granting permission to continue the claim.
You should conclude by considering the vexed question of costs. What incentive is
there for bringing an action on behalf of the company?
page 124 University of London
Need to revise first = There are one or two areas I am unsure about and need to revise
before I go on to the next chapter.
Need to study again = I found many or all of the principles outlined in this chapter
very difficult and need to go over them again before I move on.
If you ticked ‘need to revise first’, which sections of the chapter are you going to
revise?
Must Revision
revise done
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126
Introduction
In this chapter we examine the statutory rights of minority shareholders. What rights
do they have? How can they enforce them and against whom? What remedies are
appropriate and available? You should bear in mind that minority shareholders in an
owner-managed private company often depend upon the way the company is run for
their living; such shareholders frequently work for the company and participate in its
management. As a result the stakes can be extremely high when a minority dispute
occurs in such a company.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings, you should be able to:
u describe the range of statutory remedies available to minority shareholders
u explain the ‘just and equitable’ winding up remedy
u state the main grounds for a just and equitable winding up
u describe the scope of the unfair prejudice remedy
u describe the remedies available under the unfair prejudice provision.
Core text
¢ Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 11: ‘Statutory shareholder remedies’.
Cases
¢ Ebrahimi v Westbourne Galleries Ltd [1973] AC 360
¢ Fulham Football Club (1987) Ltd v Richards [2011] EWCA Civ 855
Additional cases
¢ Re Yenidje Tobacco Co Ltd [1916] 2 Ch 426
¢ Re Home & Office Fire Extinguishers Ltd [2012] EWHC 917 (Ch)
It should be noted, however, that given the range of remedies available under the
unfair prejudice provision (see 12.2 below) that provision has now become the
dominant means available to minority shareholders seeking redress. However, it does
not provide for winding up and so s.122(1)(g) IA 1986 is still of relevance.
Winding up on the just and equitable ground was subjected to extensive analysis by
the House of Lords in Ebrahimi v Westbourne Galleries Ltd [1973] AC 360. The company
was incorporated to take over the Oriental rug business which N and the petitioner,
E, had been running as a partnership for some 10 years. Initially N and E were equal
shareholders and the only directors. When N’s son joined the company as director and
shareholder, E became a minority both within the board and at the general meeting,
where he could be outvoted by the combined shareholding of N and his son. Relations
between E on the one hand, and N and his son on the other, broke down and E was
voted off the board using the power conferred by s.303 CA 1985 (now s.168 CA 2006).
It was held that even though E had been removed from the board in accordance with
the Companies Act and the articles of association, the just and equitable ground
conferred on the court the jurisdiction to subject the exercise of legal rights to
equitable considerations. Since E had agreed to the formation of the company on the
basis that the essence of their business relationship would remain the same as with
their prior partnership, his exclusion from the company’s management was clearly
in breach of that understanding. It was therefore just and equitable to wind up the
company. Lord Wilberforce listed the typical elements in petitions brought under the
just and equitable ground.
page 128 University of London
u The basis of the business association was a personal relationship and mutual
confidence (generally found where a pre-existing partnership has converted into a
limited company).
Lord Wilberforce stressed that the court was entitled to superimpose equitable
constraints upon the exercise of rights set out in the articles of association or the
Companies Act. He went on to say that the words ‘just and equitable’ are:
…a recognition of the fact that a limited company is more than a mere legal entity, with
a personality in law of its own: that there is room in company law for recognition of the
fact that behind it, or amongst it, there are individuals, with rights, expectations and
obligations inter se which are not necessarily submerged in the company structure…
It should be noted that Lord Cross stressed that petitioners under s.122(1)(g) IA 1986
should come to court with ‘clean hands’. If a petitioner’s own misconduct led to the
breakdown in relations relief will be denied.
The following are illustrations of the grounds which will support a petition under
s.122(1)(g).
The petitioner will need to establish that the commercial object for which the
company was formed has failed or has been fulfilled (see Re German Date Coffee Co
(1882) 20 Ch D 169; Virdi v Abbey Leisure Ltd [1990] BCLC 342; Re Perfectair Holdings Ltd
[1990] BCLC 423).
ii. Fraud
The remedy will enable shareholders to recover their investment where the company
was formed by its promoters in order to perpetrate a fraud against them (see Re
Thomas Edward Brinsmead & Sons [1887] 1 Ch 45).
iii. Deadlock
If the relationship between the parties has broken down with no hope of
reconciliation, the court may order a dissolution (see Re Yenidje Tobacco Co Ltd [1916]
2 Ch 426). However, in Re Paramount Powders (UK) Ltd [2019] EWCA Civ 1644, the court
held that a petitioner had no automatic right to have a company wound up merely
because there had been a breakdown in mutual trust and confidence between the
members. The court might refuse a winding up in such a case if, for example, the
petitioner were responsible for that breakdown.
where the court decided that the company should be wound up, because of the depth
of the shareholders’ disagreement and their inability to agree a method for valuing the
minority’s shares, see Harding v Edwards [2014] EWHC 247 (Ch).
Activity 12.1
Read Re a Company (No.004415 of 1996) [1997] 1 BCLC 479.
Why did the court strike out the winding up petition?
Activity 12.2
Read Virdi v Abbey Leisure Ltd [1990] BCC 60.
Why was winding up under s.122(1)(g) IA 1986 considered to be an appropriate
remedy?
A member of a company may apply to the court by petition for an order… on the ground
that the company’s affairs are being or have been conducted in a manner which is unfairly
prejudicial to the interests of its members generally or of some part of its members
(including at least himself), or
that any actual or proposed act or omission of the company (including an act or omission
on its behalf) is or would be so prejudicial.
Although, as will be seen, s.996 provides for a range of remedies, petitioners generally
seek an order requiring the respondents, who are usually the majority shareholders, to
purchase their shares.
The courts have adopted a flexible approach towards what constitutes ‘the company’s
affairs’. Thus, in Nicholas v Soundcraft Electronics Ltd [1993] BCLC 360, the Court of Appeal
held that the failure of a parent company (Soundcraft Electronics) to pay debts due
to its subsidiary (in which the petitioner was a minority shareholder) constituted acts
done in the conduct of the affairs of the company. In Re City Branch Group Ltd [2004]
EWCA Civ 815, the Court of Appeal held that an order under s.994 could be made
against a holding company where the affairs of a wholly-owned subsidiary have been
conducted in an unfairly prejudicial manner and the directors of the holding company
are also the directors of the subsidiary.
However, in Graham v Every [2014] EWCA Civ 191, the court held that an alleged breach
of a pre-emption provision in the company’s articles did not constitute the conduct of
the company’s affairs, as it concerned only the rights of the shareholders themselves.
See also, Re Phoneer Ltd [2002] 2 BCLC 241; Gross v Rackind [2004] 4 All ER 735, CA; Re
Legal Costs Negotiators Ltd [1999] 2 BCLC 171, CA.
‘Interests’
Although the petitioner must be a shareholder in order to bring the action, the
conduct which forms the basis of his complaint need not affect him in his capacity as
a member. For example, exclusion from the management of the company, which is
conduct affecting the petitioner qua director, will suffice (O’Neill v Phillips [1999] 1 WLR
1092). The use of the term ‘interests’ is expansive in effect, thereby effectively avoiding
the straitjacket which terminology based on the notion of ‘rights’ would impose on
the scope of the provision (Re Sam Weller & Sons Ltd [1989] 5 BCC 810; see also Re a
Company (No.00477 of 1986) [1986] BCLC 376).
page 130 University of London
3. Where there are restrictions on the transfer of shares which would prevent a
member from realising his or her investment.
Re Ghyll Beck Driving Range Ltd [1993] BCLC 1126 is an excellent example of a s.994 case.
A father and son, along with two other people, incorporated a company to operate a
golf range. They were each equal shareholders and directors. Within six months of the
company’s existence the relationship between the parties had become acrimonious
due mainly to disagreements over business strategy which left the petitioner feeling
‘isolated’. Following a fight between the father and the petitioner the business was
managed without consulting him. It was held that the petitioner had been unfairly
excluded from the management of the company when from the start it had been
anticipated that all four would participate in managing the business. The court
therefore ordered the majority to purchase the petitioner’s shares on the basis that
the affairs of the company had been conducted in a manner unfairly prejudicial to his
interests.
However, it should be noted that s.994 does not mean that the judges administer
arbitrary justice without reference to the commercial relationship that exists between
the parties. Indeed, Lord Wilberforce had recognised in Ebrahimi that the starting
point for the court was always to look to the agreement between the parties, for
example, as contained in the articles.
In Re a Company (No.004377 of 1986) [1987] BCLC 94, the majority, including the
petitioner, voted for a special resolution to amend the company’s articles so as to
provide that a member, on ceasing to be an employee or director of the company,
would be required to transfer his or her shares to the company. To remedy a situation
of management deadlock, the petitioner was dismissed as director and was offered
£900 per share. When he declined this offer the company’s auditors valued his shares
in accordance with the pre-emption clauses. He petitioned the court under s.459
(now s.994) to restrain the compulsory acquisition of his shares, arguing that he had
a legitimate expectation that he would continue to participate in the management of
the company. Hoffmann J held that there could be no expectation on the part of the
petitioner that should relations break down the article would not be followed. The
judge stressed that s.994 could not be used by the petitioner to relieve him from the
bargain he made. Further, in Re Saul D Harrison & Sons plc [1995] 1 BCLC 14, Hoffmann
LJ laid down guidelines for determining unfairness. He stressed that fairness for
the purposes of s.994 must be viewed in the context of a commercial relationship
and that the articles of association are the contractual terms which govern the
relationships of the shareholders with the company and each other. The first question
to ask, therefore, is whether the conduct of which the shareholder complains was in
accordance with the articles of association.
See also Re Posgate & Denby (Agencies) Ltd [1987] BCLC 8; Re Blue Arrow plc [1987] BCLC
585; Strahan v Wilcock [2006] EWCA Civ 13.
Company Law 12 Statutory minority protection page 131
Summary
The interests of members include rights derived from the company’s constitution
or statute or a shareholder’s agreement or some general equitable duty owed by
the directors to the company. A member will also have an interest in maintaining
the value of his or her shares, as was shown in Re Bovey Hotel Ventures Ltd July 31, 1981
(unreported) cited by Nourse J. in Re RA Noble & Sons (Clothing) Ltd [1983] BCLC 273.
Further, as seen in Re Ghyll Beck Driving Range Ltd, a member’s ‘interests’ may also
encompass the expectation that they will continue to participate in management (see
also Re a Company (No.003160 of 1986) [1986] BCLC 391; Re a Company (No.004475 of 1982)
[1983] Ch 178).
Unfair prejudice
The petitioner must establish that the conduct in question is ‘both prejudicial (in the
sense of causing prejudice or harm) to the relevant interests and also unfairly so’ (Re
a Company, ex p Schwarcz (No.2) [1989] BCLC 427, per Peter Gibson J). In Re Ringtower
Holdings plc (1988) 5 BCC 82, Peter Gibson J stated that ‘the test is unfair prejudice, not
of unlawfulness, and conduct may be lawful but unfairly prejudicial…’ The notion of
unfairness was considered by the Jenkins Committee (Cmnd. 1749, 1962) to be ‘a visible
departure from the standards of fair dealing and a violation of the conditions of fair
play on which every shareholder who entrusts his money to a company is entitled to
rely’ (para 204, adopting the view expressed by Lord Cooper in Elder v Elder & Watson
Ltd [1952] SC 49). Although there is no requirement that the petitioner should come to
court with ‘clean hands’, his or her conduct will be relevant in assessing whether the
conduct of the company, though prejudicial, is unfair.
In O’Neill v Phillips [1999] WLR 1092 (the only House of Lords decision on the unfair
prejudice remedy so far) Lord Hoffmann held that fairness was to be determined by
reference to ‘traditional’ or ‘general’ equitable principles. He stressed that company
law developed from the law of partnership – which was treated by equity as a contract
of good faith. The facts of O’Neill v Phillips were that the company, Pectel Ltd, provided
asbestos stripping services to the construction industry. In 1983 the issued share
capital of the company, 100 £1 shares, was owned entirely by Mr Phillips (P). Mr O’Neill
(O) was employed by the company in 1983 as a manual worker. P was favourably
impressed by O and he received rapid promotion.
In early 1985 O received 25 per cent of the company’s shares and he was made a
director. In May 1985 O was informed by P that he, O, would eventually take over the
running of the company’s business and at that time would receive 50 per cent of the
profits. In December 1985 P retired from the board and O became sole director and
effectively the company’s managing director.
The business enjoyed good profitability for a while, but its fortunes declined during
the economic recession of the late 1980s. In August 1991, disillusioned with O’s
management of the business, P used his majority voting rights to appoint himself
managing director and took over the management of the company. O was informed
that he would no longer receive 50 per cent of the profits but his entitlement would
be limited to his salary and dividends on his 25 per cent shareholding. Early discussions
about further share incentives when certain targets were met were aborted. O
thereupon issued a petition alleging unfairly prejudicial conduct on the part of P.
The House of Lords found that P’s conduct would have been unfair had he used his
majority voting power to exclude O from the business. He had not done this, but had
simply revised the terms of O’s remuneration. P’s refusal to allot additional shares as
part of the proposed incentive scheme was not unfair as the negotiations were not
completed and no contractual undertaking had been entered into by the parties.
Nor was P’s decision to revise O’s profit-sharing arrangement considered to be unfair
conduct. O’s entitlement to 50 per cent of the company’s profits was never formalised
and it was, in any case, conditional upon O running the business. That condition
was no longer fulfilled as P had to assume control over the running of the business.
Although O argued that he had lost trust in P, that alone could not form the basis for
page 132 University of London
a petition under the unfairly prejudicial conduct provision. To hold otherwise would
be to confer on a minority shareholder a unilateral right to withdraw his capital.
O’s petition therefore failed. He did not prove that P’s conduct was both unfair and
prejudicial.
Thus, a petitioner will need to demonstrate either that they relied on some pre-
association understanding, or a post-association agreement that was either legally
binding or that they specifically relied on. (For recent examples, see the approach of
Jonathan Parker J in Re Guidezone Ltd [2000] 2 BCLC 321 and the comments of Auld and
Jonathan Parker LJJ in Phoenix Office Supplies Ltd v Larvin [2002] EWCA Civ 1740 to the
effect that a petitioner cannot enlist s.994 to force a right of exit from the company
that does not exist under the company’s constitution.) On the other hand, the failure
on the part of the majority shareholders to hold meetings and to otherwise conduct
the affairs of the company as a going concern will be held to be unfairly prejudicial to
the interests of the minority (Fisher v Cadman [2005] EWHC 377 (Ch)).
u Mismanagement (breach of the directors’ duties of care and skill) (see Re Elgindata
Ltd [1991] BCLC 959; and Re Macro (Ipswich) Ltd [1994] 2 BCLC 354).
u Excessive remuneration taken by the directors and the failure to pay dividends
(see Re Sam Weller & Sons Ltd [1990] Ch 682; Re a Company (No.004415 of 1996) [1997]
1 BCLC 479; Re Cumana Ltd [1986] BCLC 430; Anderson v Hogg [2002] BCC 923; Grace v
Biagioli [2006] 2 BCLC 70; Re Tobian Properties Ltd [2012] EWCA Civ 998; Re CF Booth Ltd
[2017] EWHC 457 (Ch)).
u Breach of fiduciary duties – the case law shows that s.994 may be used to obtain
a personal remedy despite the rule in Foss v Harbottle (see Re London School of
Electronics Ltd [1986] Ch 211; Re Little Olympian Each-Ways Ltd (No.3) [1995] 1 BCLC 636).
u See also, Re Baumler (UK) Ltd [2005] 1 BCLC 92; Re Cumana Ltd [1986] BCLC 430, CA. It
should be noted that in Re Baumler (UK) Ltd, George Bompas QC (sitting as a Deputy
Judge of the High Court) observed that in the case of a quasi-partnership company,
a breach of duty by one participant may lead to such a loss of confidence on the
part of the innocent participant and breakdown in relations that the innocent
participant is entitled to relief under s.996 of the CA 2006 (see below). The judge
noted that, in effect, the unfairness lies in compelling the innocent participant to
remain a member of the company.
Summary
In Re Saul D Harrison and O’Neill v Phillips Lord Hoffmann took the opportunity to inject
content into the concept of fairness. He reaffirmed the sanctity of the s.33 contract
(see Chapter 9 of this guide). The House of Lords stressed that the remedy did not
confer on the petitioner a unilateral right to withdraw his capital. In order to succeed
under s.994 a petitioner will need to prove either a breach of contract (including the
s.33 contract) or breach of a fundamental understanding which, although lacking
contractual force, makes it inequitable for the majority to go back on the ‘promise’.
See also, Re Guidezone Ltd and the comments of Auld and Jonathan Parker LJJ in Phoenix
Office Supplies Ltd v Larvin.
This emphasis on respecting the parties’ own agreements seems also to be evident
in the case of Fulham Football Club (1987) Ltd v Richards [2011] EWCA Civ 855, where the
court upheld a provision in the company’s articles which obliged a member to refer
disputes to arbitration rather than seeking relief under s.994.
Company Law 12 Statutory minority protection page 133
Activity 12.3
Read Re Macro (Ipswich) Ltd [1994] 2 BCLC 354.
a. What was the principal allegation of the petitioners?
b. How did Arden J approach the issue of assessing whether the conduct was
unfairly prejudicial?
12.2.2 Remedies
Section 996(1) CA 2006 provides that the court:
may make such order as it thinks fit for giving relief in respect of the matters
complained of.
Without prejudice to the generality of subsection (1), the court’s order may:
authorise civil proceedings to be brought in the name and on behalf of the company by
such person or persons and on such terms as the court may direct;
require the company not to make any, or specified, alterations in its articles without the
leave of the court;
provide for the purchase of the shares of any members of the company by other members
or by the company itself and, in the case of a purchase by the company itself, the
reduction of the company’s capital accordingly.
Note the width of the court’s powers under s.996(1) (compare the winding up remedy,
above). In Re Phoneer Ltd, the petitioner sought a winding up order on the just and
equitable ground and the respondent cross-petitioned for winding up under s.994.
Roger Kaye QC, granting a winding up order since both parties obviously desired it,
noted that ‘section 996 enables, but does not compel, the court to make an order
under that section’. Although the respondent held 70 per cent of the shares, the judge
felt that on the facts of the case ‘justice is served by ordering the winding up of the
company… on the basis of a 50/50 split’. The court can fashion a remedy to the wrong
done: see Re A Company ex parte Estate Acquisition & Development Ltd [1991] BCLC 154.
Section 996(2) specifies certain remedies available (see above). The most common
remedy sought is that under s.996(2)(e) (purchase of shares). Indeed, in Grace v
Biagioli [2005] EWCA Civ 1222 , the Court of Appeal affirmed the view that there is a
presumption in favour of a buyout order for successful unfair prejudice petitions.
Valuation of shares
Valuing shares in quoted companies is a fairly straightforward exercise because
reference can be made to their market price. For unquoted companies – and the
vast majority of s.994 petitions fall within this category – the valuation exercise is a
far more difficult undertaking. The court has a wide discretion to do what is fair and
equitable in all the circumstances of the case and under the Civil Procedure Rules
the court is expected to adopt a vigorous approach towards share valuation (North
Holdings Ltd v Southern Tropics Ltd [1999] BCC 746).
In Re Bird Precision Bellows Ltd [1984] Ch 419, affirmed by the Court of Appeal [1985] 3 All
ER 523, the court reviewed the approach to be adopted towards valuing shares. It was
stressed that the overriding objective was to achieve a fair price and that normally
page 134 University of London
no discount would be applied. Thus, a 49 per cent shareholding in the company will
be valued pro rata, being worth 49 per cent of whatever the company as a whole is
worth. This (generous) approach was justified on the grounds that the petitioner is an
unwilling vendor of what is, in effect, a partnership share. One issue that has generated
a considerable amount of case law is whether this presumption in favour of a pro rata
valuation should apply to all companies or only to those companies that are quasi-
partnerships. In Irvine v Irvine [2006] EWHC 1875 (Ch), the High Court had suggested that
this pro rata principle would apply only in a quasi-partnership. In Re Blue Index Ltd [2014]
EWHC 2680 (Ch), on the other hand, the court felt that restricting the pro rata approach
to quasi-partnerships was inappropriate and declared that the pro rata principle would
apply in all companies. However, in Estera Trust (Jersey) Ltd v Singh [2018] EWHC 1715
(Ch), the court suggested, again, that the pro rata presumption applied only to quasi-
partnerships. The law on this point, then, remains rather uncertain. Even where the pro
rata presumption does apply, it is rebuttable if there are good reasons for applying a
discount. If, for example, the minority shareholder acquired her shares by way of an
investment then a discount may, in the circumstances, be fair so as to reflect the fact that
the petitioner has little control over the company’s management (see the speech of Lord
Hoffmann in O’Neill v Phillips; see also, Profinance Trust SA v Gladstone [2002] 1 BCLC 141, CA).
See also Richardson v Blackmore [2006] BCC 276; Re OC (Transport) Services Ltd [1984]
BCLC 251; Ng v Crabtree [2011] EWHC 1834 (Ch); Re Home & Office Fire Extinguishers Ltd
[2012] EWHC 917 (Ch) and Harborne Road Nominees Ltd v Karvaski [2011] EWHC 2214 (Ch).
Further reading
¢ Boyle, A.J. ‘O’Neill v Phillips: unfair prejudice in the House of Lords’ (2000) 21
Company Lawyer 253-54.
¢ Prentice, D.D. ‘The theory of the firm: minority shareholder oppression: sections
459–461 of the Companies Act 1985’ (1988) OJLS 55.
¢ Reisberg, A. ‘Indemnity costs orders under s.459 petitions’ (2004) Comp Law 116.
¢ Riley, C. ‘Contracting out of company law: s.459 of the Companies Act 1985 and
the role of the courts’ (1992) MLR 782.
Company Law 12 Statutory minority protection page 135
Until 2016 the three directors worked well together and the company prospered.
However, at a board meeting in August of that year, Alf and Bob disagreed with
Colin over a fundamental matter of business policy and the meeting ended abruptly
when Colin hit Alf. Colin was later fined £50 for assault by local magistrates. Since
then Alf and Bob have continued to run the company but the business policy
pursued after the meeting in August 2016 has clearly proved unsuccessful and,
although the company is still solvent, it has made no profits since then. Colin
continued to receive his salary after the August meeting but has attended no board
meetings since then, even though Alf and Bob have periodically invited him to do so.
Three months ago Alf and Bob stopped payment of Colin’s salary. Colin is now saying
that he will attend the next board meeting as he intends to ‘make one last effort to
lick the company into shape’. Alf and Bob do not want him back and want to run the
company without him.
Advise Alf and Bob and Colin.
page 136 University of London
You must examine the elements of the unfair prejudice remedy. In considering the
approach of the court towards s.994 petitions you will need to discuss, in particular,
Lord Wilberforce’s speech in Ebrahimi v Westbourne Galleries Ltd, Lord Hoffmann’s
speech in O’Neill v Phillips and the decision in Re Saul D Harrison. More particularly
the focus of the claim will centre on exclusion from management, which is a typical
s.994 complaint (Re Ghyll Beck Driving Range Ltd), and mismanagement (breach of the
directors’ duties of care and skill) (Re Elgindata Ltd and Re Macro (Ipswich) Ltd).
Finally, your answer should address the range of remedies available under s.996 with
emphasis given to buyout orders, together with how the court may value Colin’s
shares (Re Bird Precision Bellows Ltd and O’Neill v Phillips).
Company Law 12 Statutory minority protection page 137
Need to revise first = There are one or two areas I am unsure about and need to revise
before I go on to the next chapter.
Need to study again = I found many or all of the principles outlined in this chapter
very difficult and need to go over them again before I move on.
If you ticked ‘need to revise first’, which sections of the chapter are you going to
revise?
Must Revision
revise done
Notes
13 Dealing with outsiders: ultra vires and other
attribution issues
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140
Introduction
As we discussed briefly in Chapter 9, companies were at one time conferred with the
power in their constitutional documents to carry out certain specific functions (the
objects) by a specific statute or grant from the Crown.
The objects clause was a necessary part of the constitutional documents of early
charter and statute companies as they were formed to carry out certain functions by a
specific charter or statute. However, as the registered company opened up corporate
status to ordinary businesses, a particular problem arose. These registered companies
were also required to have specific purposes (objects) in their memorandum but
were much more likely to change the nature of their business over time. This was
both a problem for companies who legitimately wished to change the nature of their
business and for outsiders who were dealing with the company and were in danger of
having unenforceable contracts because the company was acting outside its powers.
Over time the courts became somewhat flexible about the issue but eventually
statutory intervention was needed to solve the remaining problems. The chapter also
considers how responsibility is attributed to the company for tortious and criminal
actions.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings , you should be able to:
u explain why the objects clause issue has caused such difficulty
u describe the effect of the legislative reform process on the ultra vires issue
u discuss the recommendations of the CLRSG and the reforms in the Companies Act
2006 as they impact on ultra vires issues
u explain why attribution in other areas was and is similarly problematic.
Core text
¢ Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 12: ‘The constitution of the company: dealing with
outsiders’.
Cases
¢ Ashbury Carriage Company v Riche [1875] LR 7 HL 653
Additional cases
¢ Re German Date Coffee Co [1882] 20 Ch D 169
¢ McNicholas Construction Co Ltd v Customs and Excise Commissioners (2000) STC 553
In the late 19th century the courts adopted a fairly strict interpretation of the ultra
vires rule. In Ashbury Carriage Company v Riche (1875) LR 7 HL 653 the House of Lords
considered that the ultra vires doctrine did apply to registered companies. If a
company incorporated by, or under, statute acted beyond the scope of the objects
stated in the statute or in its memorandum of association such acts were void as
beyond the company’s capacity even if ratified by all the members. Over the course
of the 20th century the courts retreated from this strict position, allowing companies
to carry out transactions reasonably incidental to the objects of the company and
eventually accepting very wide objects clauses as being valid – either a list of all
possible commercial activities or a statement that the company could carry out any
commercial venture it wished. However, problems still remained.
Some examples
In Re Jon Beauforte (London) Ltd [1953] Ch 131 the company’s objects stated that it was
to carry on a business as gown makers but the business had evolved into making
veneered panels. No change had been made to the objects clause to reflect this
change. A coal merchant had supplied coal to the company which was ordered on
company notepaper headed with a reference to the company being a veneered panel
maker. The coal merchant was deemed because of constructive notice to know of the
original objects clause and because of the headed notepaper to have actual notice of
the change in the business. As a result the transaction was ultra vires and void.
In Re Introductions Ltd v National Provincial Bank (1970) Ch 199 the case concerned a
company incorporated in 1951, around the time of the Festival of Britain, with the
specific object of providing foreign visitors with accommodation and entertainment.
After the Festival was over the company diversified and eventually devoted itself
solely to pig breeding, which the original framers of the objects had not considered
(naturally enough). The company had granted National Provincial Bank a debenture
(see Chapter 7) to secure a substantial overdraft which had accumulated prior to its
eventual insolvent liquidation. The company was held to have acted ultra vires and
therefore the transaction was void and the bank could not enforce the debenture
or even claim as a normal creditor in the liquidation (see Chapter 17 on the statutory
liquidation procedure).
As a result of cases like this it was generally agreed that only legislative intervention
could solve the problem in the long term.
Activity 13.1
a. Read Re German Date Coffee Co [1882] 20 Ch D 169. Do you consider this a harsh
application of the ultra vires doctrine?
b. Read Re Jon Beauforte (London) Ltd (1953) Ch 131 and Re Introductions Ltd v
National Provincial Bank (1970) Ch 199. Write a 300 word summary of each.
page 142 University of London
Summary
The issue of ultra vires stems primarily from a historical hangover from charter or
statute companies. At first the courts applied the doctrine strictly to registered
companies, despite the harshness of its effect. Over time, however, the courts began
to loosen their interpretation of the objects clause where they could. They also began
to accept very widely drafted objects clauses. However, as we have seen, problems
occasionally still arose which had a drastic effect on the outsider’s ability to enforce a
contract. Statutory reform was needed.
(1) The validity of an act done by a company shall not be called into question on the
ground of lack of capacity by reason of anything in the company’s memorandum.
Under the CA 1985 the memorandum formed part of the company’s constitution. Now,
however, s.8 of the CA 2006 has reduced the memorandum of association to a more
limited function. The memorandum is now a simple document providing certain basic
information and key declarations to the public which state that subscribers wish to
form the company and agree to become members taking at least one share each. The
subscribers to the memorandum are those who agree to take some shares or share
in the company, thus becoming its first members. If the application to the Registrar
is successful the subscribers become the first members of the company and the
proposed directors become its first directors.
To eliminate any remaining problems with the objects clause the CLRSG, in the Final
Report (July 2001 para 9.10) and the Consultative Document (March 2005, Chapter 5),
proposed that companies be formed with unlimited capacity. The CA 2006 partly
implements the recommended approach. Companies registered under the 2006 Act
have unrestricted objects unless a company chooses to have an objects clause stating
what it is empowered to do (s.31 CA 2006). If a company does choose to have an objects
clause, and for companies formed under the previous Principal Acts in 1948 and 1985 with
an objects clause (unless these companies now remove their objects clause (s.31(2) CA
2006)), the objects clause forms part of the articles of association (s.28 CA 2006).
(1) The validity of an act done by a company shall not be called into question on the
ground of lack of capacity by reason of anything in the company’s constitution.
Company Law 13 Dealing with outsiders: ultra vires and other attribution issues page 143
As a result of the reform process, what were traditional ultra vires actions became a
question of whether the required internal authority to transact was given to those
who transacted with the outsider.
Here again the company’s constitution can cause problems for outsiders dealing
with the company. Sometimes the constitution will specify a procedure that has to
be carried out before authority is conferred. For example, it is common for directors
to have to seek approval of the general meeting for large loans. Again the doctrine
of constructive notice could potentially be problematic here. In Royal British Bank v
Turquand (1856) 6 E & B 327 an action was brought for the return of money borrowed
by the company. The company argued that it was not required to pay back the money
because the manager who negotiated the loan should have been authorised by a
resolution of the general meeting to borrow but he had no such authorisation. As
a result of constructive notice the bank was deemed to know this. In attempting to
mitigate this effect the court held that the public documents only revealed that a
resolution was required, not whether the resolution had been passed. The bank had
no knowledge that the resolution had not been passed and thus it did not appear
on the face of the public documents that the borrowing was invalid. Outsiders are
therefore entitled to assume that the internal procedures have been complied with.
This is known as the indoor management rule.
The Companies Act 1989 introduced ss.35A and 35B into the CA 1985. Both these
sections concern the issue of internal authority.
(1) In favour of a person dealing with a company in good faith, the power of the board of
directors to bind the company, or authorise others to do so, shall be deemed to be
free of any limitation under the company’s constitution.
(a) a person ‘deals with’ a company if he is a party to any transaction or other act to
which the company is a party;
(b) a person shall not be regarded as acting in bad faith by reason only of his
knowing that an act is beyond the powers of the directors under the company’s
constitution; and
(c) a person shall be presumed to have acted in good faith unless the contrary is
proved.
page 144 University of London
The section had the effect of protecting outsiders who deal either directly with the
board or those authorised to bind the company. It is worth noting that the section set
the standard of bad faith fairly high as sub-s.2(b) specifically allowed third parties to
have knowledge that the transaction was irregular. As a result it implied that active
dishonesty might be required in order to qualify as bad faith (see EIC Services Ltd v
Phipps [2004] 2 BCLC 589). To further emphasise the lower good faith requirement sub-
s.2(c) set a presumption of good faith.
Section 35B CA 1985 also attempted to deal with the issue of constructive notice. It
states:
[a] party to a transaction with the company is not bound to enquire as to whether it is
permitted by the company’s memorandum or as to any limitation on the powers of the
board of directors to bind the company or authorise others to do so.
This was intended to act in tandem with s.711A CA 1985 to abolish the concept of
constructive notice for corporations. However, s.711A has never been implemented
and so only s.35B deals with constructive notice (s.40 CA 2006 (see below)).
In favour of a person dealing with a company in good faith, the power of the directors to
bind the company, or authorise others to do so, is deemed to be free of any limitation
under the company’s constitution.
a person “deals with” a company if he is a party to any transaction or other act to which
the company is a party,
is not bound to enquire as to any limitation on the powers of the directors to bind the
company or authorise others to do so,
is presumed to have acted in good faith unless the contrary is proved, and
is not to be regarded as acting in bad faith by reason only of his knowing that an act is
beyond the powers of the directors under the company’s constitution.
The references above to limitations on the directors’ powers under the company’s
constitution include limitations deriving—
from any agreement between the members of the company or of any class of
shareholders.
This section does not affect any right of a member of the company to bring proceedings
to restrain the doing of an action that is beyond the powers of the directors. But no such
proceedings lie in respect of an act to be done in fulfilment of a legal obligation arising
from a previous act of the company.
Company Law 13 Dealing with outsiders: ultra vires and other attribution issues page 145
(4) This section does not affect any liability incurred by the directors, or any other person,
by reason of the directors’ exceeding their powers.
(5) This section has effect subject to— section 41 (transactions with directors or their
associates), and section 42 (companies that are charities).
Activity 13.2
Have the reforms described above solved the ultra vires problem for companies?
Activity 13.3
a. How did the 1989 reforms attempt to deal with the remaining ultra vires
problems?
No feedback provided.
Summary
The issue of ultra vires in the context of companies, while once a significant danger, has
largely been dealt with by statutory reform. Further reform as a result of the work of
the CLRSG has followed in due course in the CA 2006. The area remains an important
one in the context of company law as it offers a very good illustration of how authority
is conferred on the company and legitimately exercised by its agents who deal with
the outside world.
a corporation is an abstraction. It has no mind or will of its own any more than it has a
body of its own; its active and directing will must consequently be sought in the person of
somebody who for some purposes may be called an agent but who is really the directing
mind and will of the corporation, the very ego and centre of the personality of the
corporation… somebody who is not merely an agent or servant for whom the company
†
is liable upon the footing respondeat superior,† but somebody for whom the company is ‘Respondeat superior’ (Latin)
liable because his action is the very action of the company itself. – ‘the superior is responsible’.
This is the doctrine that an
employer is responsible for
As a result, if one individual can be identified who can be said to be essentially the
things done by his or her
company’s alter ego and that individual has the required fault, then the fault of that
employees as part of their
individual will be attributed to the company. The attribution of responsibility here is
employment.
very different than through vicarious liability in tort, where the company is responsible
for the actions of another. The individual’s fault here is attributed to the company
because the law treats the individual and the company as the same person. There is,
however, a central problem with the alter ego theory in that it required the
identification of a single individual in what was often a complex corporate
organisational structure. This was often not possible unless a very small company was
at issue. The theory has been particularly problematic in attributing criminal
responsibility to companies, especially when attempting to determine the company’s
mens rea or guilty mind.
In Tesco Supermarkets Ltd v Nattrass [1971] 2 All ER 127 Tesco was charged with an offence
under the Trade Descriptions Act 1968. They had advertised goods at a reduced price
but sold them at a higher price. In order to avoid conviction Tesco had to show that
they had put in place a proper control system. Tesco argued that they had and that the
manager of the store had been at fault. The court considered whether the manager
was acting as an organ of the company. Lord Reid found that:
[a] living person has a mind which can have knowledge or intention or be negligent and he
has hands to carry out his intentions. A corporation has none of these; it must act through
living persons, though not always one or the same person. Then the person who acts is
not speaking or acting for the company. He is acting as the company and his mind which
directs his acts is the mind of the company. There is no question of the company being
vicariously liable. He is not acting as a servant, representative, agent or delegate. He is an
embodiment of the company or, one could say, he hears and speaks through the persona
of the company, within his appropriate sphere, and his mind is the mind of the company.
In this case the manager who was at fault was not the guiding mind and therefore
Tesco could not be liable for his action. Subsequently the application of the organic
theory has effectively acted as an immunity from criminal prosecution for large
complex corporate organisations where it is impossible to identify a single individual
responsible for the company’s action.
Activity 13.4
Read Lord Hoffmann’s judgment in Meridian Global Funds Management Asia Ltd v
Securities Commission [1995] 2 AC 500 and prepare a 300-word summary on his view
of the corporate attribution issue.
Summary
Attributing law designed to apply to humans to the corporate form has continued to
be a difficult task. Vicarious liability in tort has proved an elegant solution, but where
fault or intention is necessary the courts have yet to find a similarly elegant solution.
The Meridian case has certainly moved things forward from the difficulties created by
the alter ego or organic theory. However, the court’s failure to find a way of attributing
crimes of violence to the corporate form has instigated a statutory reform process
which is still under way.
Further reading
¢ Davies and Worthington, Chapter 7: ‘Corporate actions’.
¢ Ferran, E. ‘The reform of the law on corporate capacity and directors’ and
officers’ authority’, Parts 1 and 2 (1992) Company Lawyer 124 and 177.
¢ Poole, J. ‘Abolition of the ultra vires doctrine and agency problems’ (1991) Company
Lawyer 43.
¢ Sullivan, B. ‘Corporate killing – some government proposals’ (2001) Crim L Rev 31.
page 148 University of London
b. The company may make whatever borrowings and charge whatever of its assets
as the directors may consider desirable.
Does Ranjid have the authority to authorise the bank loan? If he does not but goes
ahead anyway, will the company be bound? If he hires the instructors are their
employment contracts enforceable?
Question 2 Start with the objects issue – is the borrowing ultra vires?
Apply the facts to the statutory provisions – is the transaction saved in the bank’s
favour?
Are Brian and the other directors in breach of duty by authorising an ultra vires act?
Examine the internal authority issues – Brian’s appointment. Apply Freeman & Lockyer v
Buckhurst Park Properties Ltd [1964] 2 QB 480.
Is the signing of the debenture by Brian and Bernice enough to comply with Part (b) of
the objects clause?
page 150 University of London
Need to revise first = There are one or two areas I am unsure about and need to revise
before I go on to the next chapter.
Need to study again = I found many or all of the principles outlined in this chapter
very difficult and need to go over them again before I move on.
If you ticked ‘need to revise first’, which sections of the chapter are you going to
revise?
Must Revision
revise done
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 152
Introduction
The first part of this chapter considers the relationship between the board of
directors and the general meeting. It then goes on to outline the various categories
of director, their appointment and removal. It also discusses the Company Directors
Disqualification Act 1986 (CDDA 1986) relating to the disqualification of ‘unfit’
directors.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings, you should be able to:
u define the term ‘director’
u explain the role of the board of directors and its relationship with the general
meeting
u describe the various categories of director
u explain the process for awarding remuneration
u describe how the general meeting can remove a director from the board
u explain how directors can be disqualified from holding office.
Core text
¢ Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 13: ‘Corporate management’.
Cases
¢ Automatic Self-Cleansing Filter Syndicate Co Ltd v Cunninghame [1906] 2 Ch 34
¢ Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Tjolle [1998] BCC 282
¢ Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Hollier [2006] EWHC 1804 (Ch)
Additional cases
¢ John Shaw & Sons (Salford) Ltd v Shaw [1935] 2 KB 113
14.1 Directors
The Companies Act 2006 (CA 2006) does not define the term ‘director’ beyond
stating in s.250 that the term ‘includes any person occupying the position of director,
by whatever name called’. Thus, whatever title the articles adopt to describe the
members of the company’s board (for example, ‘governors’), the law will nevertheless
view them as directors. Section 154 lays down the minimum number of directors that
companies must have: two for public companies and one for private companies. The
Small Business, Enterprise and Employment Act 2015 inserted a new s.156A into the CA
2006. This requires all those appointed as directors to be natural persons. Therefore, it
is no longer possible, for example, for a company to be appointed as a director – what
was known as a ‘corporate director’. Any existing corporate directors will cease to be
directors 12 months after s.156A is brought into force.
Although it is now accepted that in the modern company the board enjoys a position
of management autonomy this has not always been the case. Until the end of the 19th
century the general meeting of the company had constitutional supremacy: the board
of directors was viewed as its agent and had to act in accordance with decisions of the
general meeting. However, by the early 20th century, with shareholding becoming
more dispersed and directors beginning to be appointed on the basis of professional
merit rather than social standing, articles of association were drafted so as to give
boardrooms greater independence. Consequently, the judicial response was that the
board should no longer be viewed as the agent or servant of the general meeting.
In Automatic Self-cleansing Filter Syndicate Co Ltd v Cunninghame [1906] 2 Ch 34 the
question for the Court of Appeal was whether the directors were bound to give effect
to an ordinary resolution of the general meeting requiring them to sell the company’s
undertaking to a new company incorporated for the purpose. The company’s articles
of association, in terms similar to article 3 of the model articles of association for
private and public companies (see below), provided that ‘the management of the
business and the control of the company’ was in the hands of its directors. Collins MR,
having reviewed the relevant article, explained that:
it is not competent for the majority of the shareholders at an ordinary meeting to affect
or alter the mandate originally given to the directors by the articles of association… the
mandate which must be obeyed is not that of the majority – it is that of the whole entity
made up of all the shareholders.
See also Gramophone and Typewriter Ltd v Stanley [1908] 2 KB 89; and John Shaw & Sons
(Salford) Ltd v Shaw [1935] 2 KB 113.
This ‘balance of power’ between the shareholders and the directors is now confirmed
by article 3 (directors’ general authority) of the model articles of association for both
page 154 University of London
private and public companies the equivalent provision of the 1985 Table A, namely
article 70, was also drafted in very similar terms). Article 3 confers on the board virtual
managerial autonomy. Article 3 provides:
Subject to the articles, the directors are responsible for the management of the
company’s business, for which purpose they may exercise all the powers of the company.
However, even though directors are, by virtue of article 3, given the power to manage
the company, this does not mean that shareholders are denied any say within the
company. First, article 4 of the model articles for both private and public companies
allows shareholders to ‘give directions’ to the board. Article 4 provides that:
Shareholders’ reserve power: ‘The shareholders may, by special resolution, direct the
directors to take, or refrain from taking, specified action.
Thus, shareholders can instruct the board how to act, but crucially, for such an
instruction to be binding on the directors, it must be passed as a special resolution
(which requires a 75 per cent majority). The CA 2006 also empowers the shareholders
to take a number of decisions within the company, for example dealing with alterations
to the articles (s.21); share capital (ss.617 and 641); and the allotment of shares (ss.549
and 551). If shareholders disapprove of a director they can remove him from office by
ordinary resolution (s.168 CA 2006, see Section 14.1.5). Moreover, executive power will
revert to the general meeting where the board of directors is deadlocked so that it is
incapable of managing the company (Barron v Potter [1914] 1 Ch 895).
Summary
Directors are not mere delegates or agents of the general meeting but are under a
duty to act bona fide in the interests of the company as a whole (see Chapter 15). Article
3 confers extensive managerial powers on directors, who can thus pursue a course of
action different from that prescribed by a bare majority of shareholders. However, the
general meeting can remove a director by ordinary resolution (s.168 CA 2006).
Activity 14.1
Read Gramophone and Typewriter Ltd v Stanley [1908] 2 KB 89.
To what extent can a controlling shareholder dictate how directors should act?
Although first directors are appointed in accordance with s.12 CA 2006 their successors
are elected by the shareholders in a general meeting. Article 20 of the model articles
of association for public companies (the 1985 Table A, article 73) provides that at the
first annual general meeting (AGM) all the directors shall retire from office and at every
subsequent AGM any directors who have been appointed by the directors since the
last AGM or who were not appointed at one of the preceding two AGMs, must retire
from office. It should be noted that this requirement does not appear in the model
articles for private companies.
Company Law 14 The management of the company page 155
Summary
Sections 154–167 CA 2006 govern the appointment and registration of directors. The
principal requirements for appointment are:
u every private company is to have at least one director, and every public company
to have at least two (s.154)
u 16 is set as the minimum age (as in Scotland) for a director to be appointed (s.157)
Given the power of directors to set their own remuneration, issues of transparency
and accountability obviously arise. The temptation for directors to vote themselves
‘fat cat’ awards has generated much debate over the past 20 years or so and this is
considered in the corporate governance section of this chapter. For the present it
should be noted that the BIS (formerly the DTI) published a number of proposals
for reinforcing the accountability of directors to shareholders over boardroom pay
awards (see the DTI consultative documents, Directors’ Remuneration (URN 99/923)
(London, DTI, 1999) and (URN 01/1400) (London DTI, 2001)). A significant proposal
was that there should be a mandatory requirement for the company’s annual report
to contain a statement of remuneration policy and details of the remuneration of
each director. This was first implemented for all quoted companies for financial
years ending on or after 31 December 2002 by statutory instrument (the Directors’
Remuneration Report Regulations 2002 (SI 2002/1986)), which came into force on 1
August 2002, and is now incorporated into the ss.420–422 CA 2006.
The remuneration report must be approved by the board of directors and signed
on behalf of the board by a director or secretary of the company (s.422(1)). Besides
requiring companies to supply shareholders with more information through the
remuneration report, the 2002 Regulations also required the report to be put before
the shareholders, and voted on by them. Initially, this vote was only ‘advisory’, so that
boards might lawfully choose to ignore a negative vote by shareholders. However,
s.439 CA 2006 (which was introduced by s.79 Enterprise and Regulatory Reform Act
2013) makes the shareholders’ vote binding as to the company’s remuneration ‘policy’.
To explain: each quoted company must have its policy on executive remuneration
approved by shareholders every three years, and the company can only then pay its
executive directors in accordance with the approved remuneration policy.
Section 412 of the CA 2006 requires disclosure in the annual accounts of directors’
emoluments, including present and past directors’ pensions and compensation for
loss of office. Sections 228–330 provide that the terms of a director’s service contract
must be made available for inspection either at its registered office or the place
where its register of members is kept if other than its registered office. Breach of this
requirement may result in a fine on conviction.
page 156 University of London
Activity 14.2
Read Guinness plc v Saunders [1990] 2 AC 663.
a. What were the material terms of the company’s articles of association?
b. Why did the House of Lords order Mr Ward to repay the company the £5.2m
awarded him by way of remuneration?
While the power contained in s.168 cannot be removed by the articles, it is possible
for a director to entrench himself by including in the articles a clause entitling him to
weighted voting in the event of a resolution to remove him. In Bushell v Faith [1970]
AC 1099 the articles provided that on a resolution to remove a particular director, his
shares would carry the right to three votes per share. This meant that he was able to
outvote the other shareholders who held 200 votes between them. In other words,
the ordinary resolution could be blocked by him. The House of Lords approved the
clause. Lord Upjohn reasoned that: ‘Parliament has never sought to fetter the right
of the company to issue a share with such rights or restrictions as it may think fit.’ He
went on to state that in framing s.168 (s.303 CA 1985) all that Parliament was seeking to
do was to make an ordinary resolution sufficient to remove a director and concluded
that: ‘Had Parliament desired to go further and enact that every share entitled to vote
should be deprived of its special rights under the articles it should have said so in plain
terms by making the vote on a poll one vote one share.’ Nowadays, however, while
weighted voting clauses are commonly encountered in private companies of a quasi-
partnership nature, they are expressly prohibited by the LSE Listing Rules.
question was ‘part of the corporate governing structure’. This was approved by the
Court of Appeal in Re Kaytech International plc.
In Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Hollier [2006] EWHC 1804 (Ch), Etherton
J, having made the point that no one can simultaneously be a de facto and a shadow
director, went on to state that although various tests have been laid down for
determining who may be a de facto director there is no single touchstone. The
key test is whether someone is part of the governing structure of a company and
participates, or is entitled to participate in, collective decisions on corporate policy
and strategy and its implementation. In Re Gemma Ltd (in liquidation) [2008] BCC 812
it was emphasised that what mattered was what the director did (and in particular
whether they were part of the governing structure of the company), not the label that
was attached to them. See also HM Revenue & Customs v Holland [2010] UKSC 51. Since a
de facto director falls within the definition of a ‘director’ in s.250 CA 2006 (see above),
then all provisions in CA 2006 which apply to ‘directors’ (such as the general duties
found in ss.171–77 CA 2006) apply equally to de facto directors.
u the person in question directed those directors on how to act in relation to the
company’s affairs or that he was one of the persons who did
Millet J explained that a pattern of behaviour must be shown ‘in which the board did
not exercise any discretion or judgment of its own but acted in accordance with the
directions of others’. However, merely controlling one director is not sufficient; the
shadow director must exercise control over the whole board or at least a governing
majority of it (Re Lo-line Electric Motors Ltd [1988] Ch 477; Unisoft Group Ltd (No.2) [1993]
BCLC 532).
We noted above that all the statutory provisions (such as directors’ duties) that apply
to ‘directors’ apply equally to de facto directors. Is the same true of shadow directors?
The position here is a little more complex. Some provisions of CA 2006, and of the
Insolvency Act 1986, expressly apply to shadow directors too. So, for example, under
s.214(7) Insolvency Act 1986, a shadow director may be held liable for wrongful trading
(see Chapter 4). However, the position with regard to the general duties on directors
(found in ss.171–77) is less certain. Section 170(5) CA 2006 (which was inserted by the
Small Business, Enterprise and Employment Act 2015) now provides that ‘The general
duties apply to a shadow director of a company where and to the extent that they are
capable of so applying’. In Standish v Royal Bank of Scotland plc [2019] EWHC 3116 the
court held that the duties owed by the shadow would depend on the instructions they
gave. A shadow director could not be held liable for conduct that was unconnected
with the instructions being given to the directors. Note that in Popely v Popely [2019]
EWHC 1507 (Ch) the court held that a person might be simultaneously both a de facto
and a shadow director.
page 158 University of London
Activity 14.3
Read Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Deverell [2001] Ch 340.
What was the court’s approach to the determination of whether or not the
respondent was a shadow director?
Conviction of an offence
Section 2 CDDA 1986 provides that the court may, at its discretion, issue a
disqualification order against a person convicted of an indictable offence (whether on
indictment or summarily) in connection with the promotion, formation, management,
liquidation or striking off of a company, or with the receivership or management of a
company’s property. The offence does not have to relate to the actual management
of the company provided it was committed in ‘connection’ with its management. The
maximum period of disqualification is five years where the order is made by a court of
summary jurisdiction, and 15 years in any other case (s.2(3)).
Fraud
The court may make a disqualification order against a person if, in the course of the
winding up of a company, it appears that he:
a. has been guilty of an offence for which he is liable (whether he has been convicted
or not) under s.993 CA 2006 (fraudulent trading), or
b. has otherwise been guilty, while an officer or liquidator of the company or receiver
or manager of its property, of any fraud in relation to the company or of any breach
of his duty as such officer, liquidator, receiver or manager (s.4).
The maximum period for disqualification is 15 years (s.4(3)). Where a person has been
found liable under s.213 or s.214 of the Insolvency Act 1986 (respectively the fraudulent
trading and wrongful trading provisions, see Chapter 17 of this guide), the CDDA 1986
gives the court a discretion to disqualify such person for a period of up to 10 years.
Company Law 14 The management of the company page 159
a. that he is or has been a director of a company which has at any time become
insolvent (whether while he was a director or subsequently), and
b. that his conduct as a director of that company (either taken alone or taken
together with his conduct as a director of any other company or companies) makes
him unfit to be concerned in the management of a company.
The minimum period of disqualification is two years and the maximum period is 15
years (s.6(4)). In contrast with the other grounds for disqualification noted above, s.6 is
restricted to directors or shadow directors, including de facto directors.
The policy underlying s.6 was explained by Dillon LJ in Re Sevenoaks Stationers (Retail)
Ltd [1991] Ch 164 as being ‘to protect the public, and in particular potential creditors
of companies, from losing money through companies becoming insolvent when the
directors of those companies are people unfit to be concerned in the management of
a company’.
u the extent of the director’s responsibility for any failure by the company to comply
with the numerous accounting and publicity requirements of the CA 2006 (paras 4
and 5).
Those matters to which regard is to be had when the company is insolvent are listed in
Part II of Schedule 1 and include:
page 160 University of London
u the extent of the director’s responsibility for the causes of the company becoming
insolvent (para 6)
u the extent of the director’s responsibility for any failure by the company to supply
any goods or services which have been paid for, in whole or in part (para 7).
In Re Lo-Line Electric Motors Ltd [1988] Ch 477 Sir Nicholas Browne-Wilkinson V-C said
that while ordinary commercial misjudgment is not in itself sufficient to establish
unfitness, conduct which displays ‘a lack of commercial probity’ or conduct which
is grossly negligent or displays ‘total incompetence’ would be sufficient to justify
disqualification (see also Re Dawson Print Group Ltd [1987] BCLC 601; Secretary of State
for Trade and Industry v Ettinger, Re Swift 736 Ltd [1993] BCLC 896; Re AG (Manchester) Ltd
(in liquidation); Official Receiver v Watson [2008] 1 BCLC 32).
In Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Swan (No.2) [2005] EWHC 603, Etherton
J subjected the responsibilities of a non-executive director, against whom an
application for disqualification under s.6 had been brought, to detailed consideration.
N, a senior non-executive director and deputy chairman of the board and chairman of
the audit and remuneration committees of Finelist plc, together with S, the company’s
CEO, were disqualified for three and four years respectively. N’s reaction upon being
informed by a whistle-blower of financial irregularities (‘cheque kiting’) going on
within the group was held to be entirely inappropriate. He failed to investigate the
allegations properly. Nor did he bring them to the attention of his fellow non-
executive directors or to the auditors. The judge held that N’s conduct fell below the
level of competence to be expected of a director in his position and he was, therefore,
‘unfit’ to be concerned in the management of a company.
Activity 14.4
Read Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v TC Stephenson [2000] 2 BCLC 614.
What were the allegations made against the director by the Secretary of State?
What was the decision of the court?
Summary
The courts will look for abuses of the privilege of limited liability as evidenced
by capricious disregard of creditors’ interests or culpable commercial behaviour
amounting to gross negligence. Non-executive directors who lack corporate financial
experience may rely on the advice and assurances provided by the company’s
accountants although they should be vigilant and raise objections whenever they have
concerns about the financial operation of the company.
It is further provided that if it appears to the Secretary of State that the conditions
mentioned in s.6(1) are satisfied with respect to any person who has offered to give
him a disqualification undertaking, he may accept the undertaking if it appears to him
that it is expedient in the public interest that he should do so (instead of applying or
proceeding with an application for a disqualification order) (s.6(3) of the 2000 Act,
inserting s.7(2A) into the CDDA 1986).
Company Law 14 The management of the company page 161
Section 8 of the CDDA 1986 is amended by IA 2000 so that where it appears to the
Secretary of State from the report of a DTI investigation that, in the case of a person
who has offered to give him a disqualification undertaking, (a) the conduct of the
person in relation to a company of which the person is or has been a director or
shadow director makes him unfit to be concerned in the management of a company,
and (b) it is expedient in the public interest that he should accept the undertaking
(instead of applying or proceeding with an application for a disqualification order),
he may accept the undertaking (s.6(4) of the 2000 Act, inserting s.8(2A) into the CDDA
1986). Section 8A of the CDDA 1986 provides that, on the application of a person who is
subject to a disqualification undertaking, the court may:
These reforms are designed to save court time so that in the specified circumstances,
disqualification can be achieved administratively without the need to obtain a court
order.
Compensation orders
Although disqualification might prevent a person from acting, and therefore
misbehaving, as a director in the future, it does not redress any harm their past
misbehaviour has already caused to others. Section 15A CDDA 1986, which was
introduced by the Small Business, Enterprise and Employment Act 2015, seeks to
address this. It now allows the court to make a ‘compensation order’ against a person
who has been disqualified as a director.
According to s.15A(3)(b) CDDA 1986, a compensation order can only be made if ‘the
conduct for which the person is subject to the [disqualification] order or undertaking
has caused loss to one or more creditors of an insolvent company of which the person
has at any time been a director.’ The money will either be paid to the Secretary of
State, for the benefit of all or some creditors, or else will be paid as a contribution to
the assets of the company.
Re Noble Vintners Ltd [2019] EWHC 2806 (Ch) is the first case in which the court has used
its new powers, found in ss.15A and 15B of the Company Directors Disqualification Act
1986, to order a disqualified director to compensate creditors of the company who
have been harmed by the director’s misbehaviour. The court found that the amount
of compensation payable should depend upon the loss suffered by the creditor, the
nature of the director’s misbehaviour and whether the director had already made any
other payments in respect of her misbehaviour (for example, to the company under
the wrongful trading regime found in s.214 Insolvency Act 1986).
page 162 University of London
Further reading
¢ Axworthy, C.S. ‘Corporate directors – who needs them?’ (1988) 51 MLR 273.
¢ Sullivan, G.R. ‘The relationship between the board of directors and the general
meeting in limited companies’ (1977) 93 LQR 569.
Discuss s.168 CA 2006 and weighted voting. You will need to explain the House of Lords
decision in Bushell v Faith.
A means of defeating Rosa’s voting power on a resolution to remove her is for the
company to alter its articles by special resolution under s.21 CA 2006 (see Chapter 10 of
this guide).
Alternatively, the company might choose to issue additional shares in order to defeat
Rosa’s voting power (ss.549–551 CA 2006). However, she may be able to challenge
such an allotment on the basis that it is for an improper purpose (see Chapter 15 of
this guide, particularly Howard Smith Ltd v Ampol Petroleum [1974] AC 821 and Hogg
v Cramphorn [1967] Ch 254). In any case, if Rosa exercises pre-emption rights (see
ss.561–572 CA 2006) this will frustrate the scheme to defeat her weighted voting rights.
page 164 University of London
Need to revise first = There are one or two areas I am unsure about and need to revise
before I go on to the next chapter.
Need to study again = I found many or all of the principles outlined in this chapter
very difficult and need to go over them again before I move on.
If you ticked ‘need to revise first’, which sections of the chapter are you going to
revise?
Must Revision
revise done
14.1 Directors
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 166
Introduction
In this chapter we consider the duties of directors and Part 10 of the CA 2006, which
sets out the equitable and common law duties of directors by way of statutory
restatement. In addition, we will consider certain other statutory duties of directors
aimed at addressing specific types of abuses. We will also examine the scope of the
court’s discretion to relieve directors from liability for breaches of duty. In considering
the fiduciary duties of directors you should bear in mind the work you did for the Law
of trusts in Part I of the LLB (see in particular Chapter 17, ‘Breach of fiduciary duty’, of
that module guide).
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings, you should be able to:
u discuss the fiduciary position of directors
u discuss the content and scope of the duties of directors restated in Part 10 of the
CA 2006
u explain the authorisation process
u describe the principal transactions with directors that require the approval of
members
u explain the court’s discretion to relieve directors from liability
u describe the specific statutory duties of directors.
Core text
¢ Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 14: ‘Directors’ duties’.
Cases
¢ Percival v Wright [1902] 2 Ch 421
¢ Fulham Football Club Ltd v Cabra Estates plc [1994] 1 BCLC 363
¢ Extrasure Travel Insurances Ltd v Scattergood [2002] All ER (D) 307 (Jul) (Ch D)
¢ Neptune (Vehicle Washing Equipment) Ltd v Fitzgerald (No.2) [1995] BCC 1000
¢ Lexi Holdings plc (in admin) v Luqman [2009] EWCA Civ 117
Additional cases
¢ Colin Gwyer and Associates Ltd v London Wharf (Limehouse) Ltd [2003] 2 BCLC 153, Ch D
¢ Eclairs Group Ltd v JKX Oil and Gas plc [2015] UKSC 71
¢ R (on the application of People & Planet) v HM Treasury [2009] EWHC 3020 (Admin)
made more simple or dispensed with altogether’ (the Law Commissions Consultation
Paper No.153 (LCCP), para 1.7). The aim was to examine the presentation of the law
governing directors’ duties rather than its reform. The report was lodged with the
CLRSG in July 1999. The Law Commissions’ recommendations, and the DTI’s response
(see below), are wide ranging.
The Law Commissions examined the case for restating directors’ duties in statute.
Arguments against this were founded on loss of flexibility, while those in favour saw
advantages in terms of certainty and accessibility. The Commissions’ conclusion
was that the case for legislative restatement was made out and that the issue of
inflexibility could be addressed by:
u providing that it was not exhaustive (i.e. while it would be a comprehensive and
binding statement of the law in the field covered, it would not prevent the courts
inventing new general principles outside the field).
The hallmark of the Law Commissions’ approach was their regard for the wider economic
context in which company law, particularly that regulating directors, operates. It is
asserted that in regulating the enterprise, the law should operate efficiently, promoting
prosperity (LCCP para 2.8). More particularly, it is recommended that the law ‘should
move towards a general principle of meaningful disclosure, and that approval rules
should be seen as the exception’ (Law Com No.261 and 173, para 3.72).
The CLRSG proposed that the duties of directors should be restated and to this end the
general duties owed by a director of a company to the company are set out in Part 10
CA 2006. We will examine each restated duty in turn.
The Final Report of the CLRSG accepted the case for codification for two principal
reasons.
u First, directors should know what is expected of them and therefore such a
statement will further the CLR’s objectives of reforming the law so as to achieve
clarity and accessibility.
u Second, the process of formulating such a statement would enable defects in the
present law to be corrected ‘in important areas where it no longer corresponds to
accepted norms of modern business practice’.
The CLR thought that this was particularly so with respect to the duties of conflicted
directors.
Before we begin our examination of directors’ duties, we first consider the important
question of to whom are the duties owed?
The classic case which is now given the force of statute by s.170 is Percival v Wright
[1902] 2 Ch 421. The directors offered to buy the shares held by the company’s members
without disclosing that at the time of the purchase they were negotiating with an
outsider for the sale of the company at a higher price. The shareholders claimed that
the directors were in breach of their fiduciary duty to them and that the sale ought to
be set aside for non-disclosure. The court rejected their claim. The duty was owed to the
company and, in any case, there was no unfair dealing by the directors. The shareholders
had initially approached the directors asking them to purchase their shares.
Company Law 15 Directors’ duties page 169
The decision in Percival v Wright leaves the critical question unanswered; namely, what
is the company? Some assistance in solving this issue can be gleaned from the Report
of the Second Savoy Hotel Investigation (The Savoy Hotel Ltd, and the Berkeley Hotel Co
Ltd, Report of an Investigation under s.165 (6) of the Companies Act 1948, (HM Stationery
Office, 1954)). The Report concluded that it was not enough for directors to act in the
short-term interests of the company alone (see Greenhalgh v Arderne Cinemas Ltd [1951]
Ch 286, on the meaning of ‘the company as a whole’), but that regard must be taken of
the long-term interests of the company. In other words, the duty is not confined to the
existing body of shareholders, but extends to future shareholders. Some assistance in
addressing this issue is also given in s.172 CA 2006 (see Section 15.2.2).
It is noteworthy that subsections (3) and (4) of s.170, taken together, direct the courts
to have regard to the pre-existing case law when interpreting the statutory statement.
The relevance of the existing jurisprudence is, therefore, put beyond doubt.
In this regard, it is noteworthy that the courts have been able to distinguish Percival
v Wright on its facts and have held that fiduciary duties, carrying a duty of disclosure,
can be owed to shareholders. For example, when recommending whether a
takeover offer should be accepted it has been held that directors owe a duty to the
shareholders which includes a duty to be honest and not to mislead (see Allen v Hyatt
(1914) 30 TLR 444; Gething v Kilner [1972] 1 WLR 337; Heron International Ltd v Lord Grade
[1983] BCLC 244; Coleman v Myers [1977] 2 NZLR 225; Multinational Gas and Petrochemical
Co Ltd v Multinational Gas and Petrochemical Services Ltd [1983] Ch 258; Peskin v Anderson
[2000] 2 BCLC 1, affirmed [2001] BCLC 372).
Activity 15.1
Read Coleman v Myers [1977] 2 NZLR 225.
What were the special circumstances that led the court to distinguish Percival v
Wright and hold that the directors owed fiduciary obligations to the shareholders?
Summary
The general principle at common law, and now carried forward by s.170 CA 2006, is
that directors owe their duties to the company and not to the shareholders.
only exercise powers for the purposes for which they are conferred.
This section restates the duty requiring a director to exercise his powers in accordance
with the terms upon which they were granted (i.e. to comply with the company’s
constitution), and do so for a proper purpose (i.e. a purpose for which power was
conferred).
For the purpose of paragraph (a), the company’s constitution is defined in s.17 CA
2006 as including the company’s articles of association, decisions taken in accordance
with the articles and other decisions taken by the members, or a class of them, if
they can be regarded as decisions of the company. The importance of directors
appreciating the purposes of the company as detailed in the constitution is critical if
they are to fulfil the duty laid down by s.172 to promote the success of the company
(see Section 15.2.2).
The articles of association may increase the burden of the duties by, for example,
requiring directors to obtain shareholder authorisation for their remuneration
packages. However, the articles may not dilute the duties except to the extent
expressly provided for in the relevant provisions. In this regard, s.173 (duty to exercise
independent judgment (see 15.2.3 below)) provides that a director will not be in
breach if he has acted in accordance with the constitution. As we will see, s.175 (duty
to avoid conflicts of interest (see 15.2.5 below)) provides that a director will not be
in breach where, subject to the constitution, the matter has been authorised by
independent directors.
Paragraph (b) of s.171 codifies the proper purposes doctrine formulated by Lord
Greene MR in Re Smith & Fawcett Ltd [1942] Ch 304, where he stated that directors must
not exercise their powers for any ‘collateral purpose’.
The facts of Extrasure Travel Insurances Ltd v Scattergood [2002] All ER (D) 307 (Jul) (ChD)
afford a clear illustration of a power (the power to deal with corporate assets) being
exercised for an improper purpose. More generally, however, the issue of whether
directors have used a power for a proper purpose arises in relation to their authority
to issue shares. If shares are allotted in exchange for cash where the company is in
need of additional capital the duty will not be broken. But where directors issue shares
in order to dilute the voting rights of an existing majority shareholder because he or
she is blocking a resolution supporting, for example, a takeover bid, then the duty will
be breached (see Hogg v Cramphorn [1967] Ch 254). In Piercy v S Mills & Co Ltd [1920] 1 Ch
77 the court set aside a share issue on the basis that this was done ‘simply and solely
for the purpose of retaining control in the hands of the existing directors’.
The Privy Council in Howard Smith Ltd v Ampol Petroleum Ltd [1974] AC 821 subjected
the content of the duty to thorough scrutiny. The directors allotted shares to a
company which had made a takeover bid. The effect of the share issue was to reduce
the majority holding of two other shareholders, who had made a rival bid, from 55 to
36 per cent. The two shareholders sought a declaration that the share allotment was
invalid as being an improper exercise of power. The directors argued, however, that
the allotment was made primarily in order to obtain much needed capital for the
company. It was held that the directors had improperly exercised their powers:
it must be unconstitutional for directors to use their fiduciary powers over the shares in
the company purely for the purpose of destroying an existing majority, or creating a new
majority which did not previously exist. To do so is to interfere with that element of the
company’s constitution which is separate from and set against their powers.
Company Law 15 Directors’ duties page 171
Lord Wilberforce stressed that the court must examine the substantial purpose for
which a power is exercised and must reach a conclusion as to whether that purpose
was proper or not (see also Extrasure Travel Insurances Ltd v Scattergood; Criterion
Properties plc v Stratford UK Properties LLC [2003] BCC 50).
The power to issue shares may be exercised for reasons other than the raising of
capital provided ‘those reasons relate to a purpose benefiting the company as a
whole; as distinguished from a purpose, for example, of maintaining control of the
company in the hands of the directors themselves or their friends’ (Harlowe’s Nominees
Pty Ltd v Woodside (Lake Entrance) Oil Co (1968) CLR 483). Further, it has been held that
it may be in the company’s interest for directors to forestall a resolution accepting
a takeover offer by issuing shares. In Teck Corporation Ltd v Millar [1972] 33 DLR (3d)
288 the British Columbia Supreme Court held that an allotment of shares designed
to defeat a takeover was proper even though it was made against the wishes of the
existing shareholder and deprived him of control. Berger J stressed that, provided the
directors act in good faith, they are entitled to consider the reputation, experience
and policies of anyone seeking to take over the company and to use their power to
protect the company if they decide, on reasonable grounds, that a takeover will cause
substantial damage to the company.
See further, Criterion Properties plc v Stratford UK Properties LLC [2004] UKHL 28; West
Coast Capital (Lios) Limited [2008] CSOH 72; Eclairs Group Ltd v JKX Oil and Gas plc [2013]
EWCA Civ 640.
Activity 15.2
Read Lord Wilberforce’s opinion delivered in Howard Smith Ltd v Ampol Petroleum
Ltd [1974] AC 821.
What steps should the court go through when determining whether or not an
exercise of power by directors was for an improper purpose?
Summary
The proper purposes doctrine restated in s.171 is an incident of the central fiduciary
duty of directors to promote the success of the company (s.172, see Section 15.2.2).
The power of directors to issue shares (ss.549-551 CA 2006), may be exercised for
reasons other than the raising of capital provided those reasons relate to a purpose
benefiting the company as a whole.
This duty has two elements. First, a director must act in the way he or she considers,
in good faith, would be most likely to promote the success of the company for the
benefit of its members as a whole. Secondly, in doing so, the director should have †
This non-interventionist
regard (among other matters) to the factors listed in s.172(1). This list is not exhaustive,
policy (the internal
but highlights areas of particular importance which reflect wider expectations of
management rule) was
responsible business behaviour.
explained by Lord Eldon
The question of what will promote the success of the company is one for the director’s LC in Carlen v Drury (1812)
good faith judgment. This aligns the duty with the position long taken by the courts 1 Ves & B 154, who said:
that, as a general rule, their role is not to interfere in the internal management of ‘This Court is not required
companies. The orthodoxy here is that the management of companies is best left to on every Occasion to take
the judgment of their directors, subject to the good faith requirement.† In discharging the Management of every
Playhouse and Brewhouse in
the Kingdom.’
page 172 University of London
this duty and, more particularly, in taking account of the factors listed in subsection
(1), directors are bound to exercise reasonable care, skill, and diligence (s.174, see 15.2.4
below).
A director will, therefore, need to demonstrate that the stakeholder interests listed
informed his or her deliberations. In this regard, it is noteworthy that the requirement
for a ‘strategic report’ set out in s.414A CA 2006 (though not applying to small
companies) specifies, in s.414C, that its purpose ‘is to inform members of the company
and help them assess how the directors have performed their duty under section
172…’.
Section 172(1) restates Lord Greene MR’s formulation of the duty in Re Smith & Fawcett
Ltd:
directors must exercise their discretion bona fide in what they consider – not what a court
may consider – is in the interests of the company…
In Item Software (UK) Ltd v Fassihi [2005] 2 BCLC 91, Arden LJ, having noted that ‘the
fundamental duty [of a director]… is the duty to act in what he in good faith considers
to be the best interests of his company’, concluded that this duty of loyalty is the
‘time-honoured’ rule (citing Goulding J in Mutual Life Insurance Co of New York v Rank
Organisation Ltd [1985] BCLC 11).
The determination of good faith is partly subjective in that the court will not substitute
its own view about a director’s conduct in place of the board’s own judgment. In
Regentcrest plc v Cohen [2001] 2 BCLC 80, Jonathan Parker J observed ‘the question is
whether the director honestly believed that his act or omission was in the interests
of the company. The issue, therefore, relates to the director’s state of mind’ (see
also, Extrasure Travel Insurances Ltd v Scattergood (above)). However, in determining
whether the duty has been discharged an objective assessment is also made. In
Charterbridge Corporation Ltd v Lloyd’s Bank Ltd [1970] Ch 62, Pennycuick J stated that
the test for determining whether this duty has been discharged ‘must be whether an
intelligent and honest man in the position of a director of the company concerned,
could, in the whole of the existing circumstances, have reasonably believed that the
transactions were for the benefit of the company.’ Thus, in Neptune (Vehicle Washing
Equipment) Ltd v Fitzgerald (No.2) [1995] BCC 1000, the company’s sole director resolved
at a board meeting in which he and the company secretary were the only attendees,
that his service contract should be terminated and that £100,892 be paid to him as
compensation. It was held that he was not acting in what he honestly and genuinely
considered to be in the best interests of the company but rather was acting exclusively
to further his own personal interests.
(See also Knight v Frost [1999] 1 BCLC 364; Ball v Eden Project Ltd [2002] 1 BCLC 313, Laddie
J; Item Software (UK) Ltd v Fassihi [2004] EWCA Civ 1244; Re Southern Counties Fresh Foods
Ltd [2009] EWHC 1362 (Ch) and R (on the application of People & Planet) v HM Treasury
[2009] EWHC 3020 (Admin).)
The statutory objective of the strategic report is laid down in s.414C. It provides that:
The purpose of the strategic report is to inform members of the company and help them
assess how the directors have performed their duty under section 172.
Company Law 15 Directors’ duties page 173
It is therefore made clear that the review is an integral part of the duty of loyalty.
In informing the members about the directors’ performance of this duty, s.414C
states that the review must give a balanced and comprehensive analysis using key
performance indicators (KPIs) relating to financial, environmental and employee
matters. Although the particular KPIs used are left to the discretion of the directors,
they must be effective in measuring the development, performance or position of the
business. Moreover, s.414CZA now requires the strategic report to include a statement
that ‘describes how the directors have had regard to the matters set out in section
172(1)(a) to (f) when performing their duty under section 172’.
The recognition of the existence of directors’ duties to creditors has received the
endorsement of the House of Lords. In Winkworth v Edward Baron Development Co Ltd
[1986] 1 WLR 1512, Lord Templeman explained that directors owe a fiduciary duty to the
company and its creditors, present and future, to ensure that its affairs are properly
administered and to keep the company’s ‘property inviolate and available for the
repayment of its debts’ (see also, Lonhro Ltd v Shell Petroleum Co Ltd [1980] 1 WLR 627 HL,
at 634 per Lord Diplock).
The duty is to consider the interests of creditors as a general class; it is not to consider
the interests of any specific creditor above others: see GHLM Trading Ltd v Maroo [2012]
EWHC 61 (Ch). See also Re HLC Environmental Projects Ltd [2013] EWHC 2876 (Ch).
One remaining uncertainty is when exactly directors are obliged, under s.172, to
consider, or even prioritise, the interests of creditors. In Dickinson v NAL Realisations
(Staffordshire) Ltd [2017] EWHC 28 (Ch), the High Court refused to say precisely when
this obligation starts, but noted that it did not arise merely because ‘there is a
recognised risk of adverse events that would lead to insolvency’.
In Wessely v White [2018] EWHC 1499 (Ch), the court accepted that the duty to prioritise
the interests of creditors was still a ‘subjective one’. If a director does what she
concludes is best for creditors then she will not be in breach of s.172, even if she is
negligent in reaching that conclusion (although that negligence may mean she is
liable for breach of her duty of care and skill under s.174).
Standing to sue
The question of standing to sue to enforce this duty (locus standi) arose in Yukong Line
Ltd of Korea v Rendsburg Investment Corpn of Liberia (No.2) [1998] 2 BCLC 485 in which it
was pointed out that creditors have no standing, individually or collectively, to bring
an action in respect of any such duty. Toulson J held that a director of an insolvent
company who, in breach of duty to the company, transferred assets beyond the reach
of its creditors owed no corresponding fiduciary duty to an individual creditor of the
page 174 University of London
company. The appropriate means of redress was for the liquidator to bring an action
for misfeasance (s.212 Insolvency Act 1986).
Notwithstanding the logistical issue of locus standi raised by Toulson J, the question of
directors’ duties to creditors again emerged in two recent decisions of the Companies
Court. In Re Pantone 485 Ltd [2002] 1 BCLC 266, Richard Reid QC, sitting as a deputy judge
in the High Court, observed that:
In my view, where the company is insolvent, the human equivalent of the company for
the purposes of the directors’ fiduciary duties is the company’s creditors as a whole, i.e. its
general creditors. It follows that if the directors act consistently with the interests of the
general creditors but inconsistently with the interest of a creditor or section of creditors
with special rights in a winding up, they do not act in breach of duty to the company.
Again, in Colin Gwyer and Associates Ltd v London Wharf (Limehouse) Ltd [2003] 2 BCLC
153, it was held that a resolution of the board of directors passed without proper
consideration being given by certain directors to the interests of creditors would be
open to challenge if the company had been insolvent at the date of the resolution.
Leslie Kosmin QC, sitting as a deputy judge in the High Court, stated that in relation
to an insolvent company, the directors, when considering the company’s interests,
must have regard to the interests of the creditors. The court was required to test the
directors’ conduct by reference to the Charterbridge Corp Ltd v Lloyd’s Bank Ltd [1970]
Ch 62 test (i.e. ‘could an honest and intelligent man, in the position of the directors, in
all the circumstances, reasonably have believed that the decision was for the benefit
of the company’). In the case of insolvent companies the test is to be applied with the
benefit of the creditors substituted for the benefit of the company.
Section 172(3) also makes express reference to ‘any enactment’. In this respect, it
should be noted that Section 214 of the Insolvency Act 1986 provides that a liquidator
of a company in insolvent liquidation can apply to the court to have a person who
is or has been a director of the company declared personally liable to make such
contribution to the company’s assets as the court thinks proper for the benefit of the
unsecured creditors. The liquidator must prove that the director in question allowed
the company to continue to trade, at some time before the commencement of its
winding up, when he knew or ought to have concluded that there was no reasonable
prospect that the company would avoid going into insolvent liquidation.
Activity 15.3
Read Extrasure Travel Insurances Ltd v Scattergood [2002] All ER (D) 307 (Jul), Ch D.
Where a company is a member of a group, in whose interests should the directors act?
(a) in accordance with an agreement duly entered into by the company that restricts
the future exercise of discretion by its directors, or
This provision restates the principle developed in the case law that directors must
exercise their powers independently and not subordinate their powers to the control
of others by, for example, contracting with a third party as to how a particular discretion
conferred by the articles will be exercised. This is a facet of the duty to promote the
success of the company laid down in Section 172. Directors are not permitted to delegate
their powers unless the company’s constitution provides otherwise.
In Fulham Football Club Ltd v Cabra Estates plc [1994] BCLC 363, four directors of Fulham
football club agreed with Cabra, the club’s landlords, that they would support Cabra’s
planning application for the future development of the club’s ground rather than the
plan put forward by the local authority. In return for this undertaking, Cabra paid the
football club a substantial fee. The directors subsequently decided to renege on this
promise and wanted to give evidence to a planning enquiry opposing the development.
They argued that their agreement with Cabra was an unlawful fetter on their powers to
act in the best interests of the company. The Court of Appeal rejected this argument.
u the agreement with the landlords was part of a contract that conferred significant
benefits on the company
u the directors, in giving their undertaking to Cabra, had not improperly fettered the
future exercise of their discretion.
In fact, it was not a case of directors fettering their discretion because they had exercised
it at the time they gave their undertaking. The Court drew a distinction between:
Neil LJ endorsed the view of Kitto J in the Australian case Thornby v Goldberg (1964) 112
CLR 597 stating:
There are many kinds of transaction in which the proper time for the exercise of the
directors’ discretion is the time of the negotiation of a contract and not the time at which
the contract is to be performed... If at the former time they are bona fide of opinion that it
is in the interests of the company that the transaction should be entered into and carried
into effect I see no reason in law why they should not bind themselves.
This means the care, skill and diligence that would be exercised by a reasonably diligent
person with—
the general knowledge, skill and experience that may reasonably be expected of a person
carrying out the functions carried out by the director in relation to the company, and
the general knowledge, skill and experience that the director has.
In Re D’Jan of London Ltd [1993] BCC 646, Hoffmann LJ, applying s.214(4) of the Insolvency
Act 1986, held the director negligent and prima facie liable to the company for losses
caused as a result of its insurers repudiating a fire policy for non-disclosure. The
director had signed the inaccurate proposal form without first reading it.
The effect of s.174 is that a director’s actions will be measured against the conduct
expected of a reasonably diligent person. This is therefore an objective test. However,
subjective considerations will also apply according to the level of any special skills the
particular director may possess.
The focus on objective assessment can also be seen in cases brought under the
Company Directors Disqualification Act 1986 (see Chapter 14, above), particularly in
relation to where directors delegate their powers. Inactivity on the part of directors is
no longer acceptable. Therefore little weight is given to any contention to the effect
that the director was unaware of a state of affairs because he had trusted others to
manage the company (see Re Landhurst Leasing plc [1999] 1 BCLC 286).
page 176 University of London
Thus, a director cannot take a passive role in the management of the company.
This is also the case in small private owner-managed companies (termed quasi-
partnerships) where a spouse or son or daughter may assume the role of director
without ever expecting to play a proactive part in the affairs of the company. In Re
Brian D Pierson (Contractors) Ltd [2001] 1 BCLC 275 the court refused to countenance
such symbolic roles:
The office of director has certain minimum responsibilities and functions, which are
not simply discharged by leaving all management functions, and consideration of the
company’s affairs to another director without question, even in the case of a family
company… One cannot be a ‘sleeping’ director; the function of ‘directing’ on its own
requires some consideration of the company’s affairs to be exercised.
Further, in Re Westmid Packing Services Ltd, Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v
Griffiths [1998] 2 BCLC 646, Lord Woolf stated that:
Activity 15.4
Read Foster J’s judgment in Dorchester Finance v Stebbing [1989] BCLC 498. Were the
non-executive directors (NEDs) held liable for signing blank cheques and leaving
them with Stebbings, the executive director? Was a lower standard of care required
of two of the defendants because they were NEDs? Was the fact that they were
qualified accountants material?
The substance of this duty is strict. This is reflected in the language of s.175(1), in that it
is framed in terms of the possibility of conflict rather than actual conflicts of interest.
A director of a company must avoid a situation in which he has or can have, a direct or
indirect interest that conflicts, or possibly may conflict, with the interests of the company.
This encompasses the significant body of case law spanning over a century or so
which the provision codifies. See Re Lands Allotment Co [1894] 1 Ch 616 and JJ Harrison
(Properties) Ltd v Harrison [2002] 1 BCLC 162, confirming that a director holds the
proceeds made from a breach of fiduciary duty as a constructive trustee.
The fundamental objective of the duty to avoid conflicts of interest is aimed at curbing
any temptation directors may succumb to when faced with the opportunity of
preferring their own interests over and above those of the company’s. As explained by
Lord Herschell in Bray v Ford [1896] AC 44:
A modern formulation of this duty was delivered by Millett LJ in Bristol and West
Building Society v Mothew [1998] Ch 1:
The classic decision on this aspect of the fiduciary obligation is Regal (Hastings) Ltd v
Gulliver [1942] 1 All ER 378, [1967] 2 AC 134n. Regal owned a cinema and its directors wished
to acquire two additional local cinemas and sell the whole undertaking as a going
concern. They formed a subsidiary company in order to take a lease of the other two
cinemas but the landlord was not prepared to grant the subsidiary a lease on these two
cinemas unless the subsidiary’s paid-up capital was £5,000. The company was unable to
inject more than £2,000 in cash for 2,000 shares and so the original arrangement was
changed. It was decided that Regal would subscribe for 2,000 shares and the outstanding
3,000 shares would be taken up by the directors and their associates. Later, the whole
business was sold by way of takeover and the directors made a profit. The purchasers of
Regal installed a new board of directors and the company successfully brought an action
against its former directors claiming that they should account for the profit they had
made on the sale of their shares in the subsidiary.
Lord Russell of Killowen stated that the opportunity and special knowledge to obtain
the shares had come to the directors qua fiduciaries ‘and having obtained these
shares by reason of the fact that they were directors of Regal, and in the course of the
execution of that office, are accountable for the profits which they have made out of
them.’ Lord Russell went on to add that:
the rule of equity which insists on those, who by use of a fiduciary position make a
profit, being liable to account for that profit, in no way depends on fraud, or absence of
bona fides; or upon such questions or considerations as whether profit would or should
otherwise have gone to the plaintiff…
The liability arises from the mere fact of a profit having, in the stated circumstances,
been made.
Corporate opportunities
An incident of the duty to avoid a conflict of interests is the so-called corporate
opportunity doctrine. This ‘makes it a breach of fiduciary duty by a director to
appropriate for his own benefit an economic opportunity which is considered to
belong rightly to the company which he serves’ (Prentice, [1974] MLR 464).
The distinction between Regal (Hastings) where ratification was a possibility and Cook
v Deeks in which the Privy Council ruled out the question of ratification as a means of
avoiding liability is not easy to discern. The answer probably lies in the fact that in the
decision for Cook v Deeks the directors were fraudulent. In Regal (Hastings) the House
of Lords accepted that the directors acted in good faith.
In Industrial Development Consultants Ltd v Cooley [1972] 1 WLR 443, the defendant, who
was managing director of Industrial Development Consultants Ltd (IDC), a design
and construction company, failed to obtain for the company a lucrative contract to
undertake work for the Eastern Gas Board. The Gas Board subsequently approached
Cooley indicating that they wished to deal with him personally and would not, in any
case, contract with IDC. Cooley did not disclose the offer to the company. However, he
page 178 University of London
promptly resigned his office so that he could take up the contract after deceiving the
company into thinking he was suffering from ill health.
Roskill J held that he was accountable to the company for all of the profits he received
under the contract. Information which came to Cooley while he was managing
director and which was of concern to the plaintiffs and relevant for the plaintiffs
to know, was information which it was his duty to pass on to the plaintiffs. It was
irrelevant to the issue of liability that Cooley had been approached in his personal
capacity and that the Gas Board would not have contracted with IDC.
if the defendant is not required to account he will have made a large profit as a result of
having deliberately put himself into a position in which his duty to the plaintiffs who were
employing him and his personal interests conflicted.
See also Bhullar v Bhullar, Re Bhullar Bros Ltd [2003] EWCA 424; Gwembe Valley
Development Co Ltd v Koshy [2003] EWCA Civ 1478.
One issue that arises is whether a director is only liable if the opportunity that they
take for their own benefit falls within the ‘existing scope’ of the company’s own
business. The case of O’Donnell v Shanahan [2009] EWCA Civ 751 suggests that it does
not need to do so. A director was liable when he made a personal profit from pursuing
an opportunity that he learned about as a director, to acquire certain property. The
company had not engaged in property acquisition (its business being restricted to
providing advice and assistance to others). The director was nevertheless held liable.
On post-resignation breaches (s.175(4)) see Foster Bryant Surveying Ltd v Bryant [2007]
EWCA Civ 200. In this regard in Peso Silver Mines v Cropper [1966] 58 DLR (2d) 1, the board
of Peso was offered the opportunity to buy a number of mining claims. Some of these
were located on land which adjoined the company’s own mining territories. The board
bona fide declined the offer because:
Later, the company’s geologist formed a syndicate with the defendant and two other
Peso directors to purchase and work the claims. When the company was taken over,
the new board (as in Regal (Hastings)) brought an action claiming that the defendant
held his shares on constructive trust for the company. The claim was unsuccessful. It
was held that the decision of the directors to reject the opportunity had been made in
good faith and for sound commercial reasons in the interests of the company.
See also, Laskin J’s approach towards the issue of determining liability in Canadian Aero
Service Ltd v O’Malley [1973] 40 DLR (3d) 371.
Recent decisions have made it clear that the general fiduciary obligations of a director
do not prevent him from:
u making the decision, while still a director, to set up in a competing business after
his directorship has ceased
[2002] 1 BCLC 693; CMS Dolphin Ltd v Simonet [2001] 2 BCLC 704). They may also use the
‘general fund of skill and knowledge’ they have developed in the role of director: see
Thermascan Ltd v Norman [2011] BCC 535.
It is worth noting that s.175(4)(a) recognises that unexpected situations can arise where
a conflict exists, but that conflict alone does not necessarily constitute a breach by
directors. As explained by Lord Goldsmith (see Official Report, 6/2/2006; coll GC289):
Once you know that you are now in a situation of conflict, you will have to do something
about it, but you are not in breach simply because it happened when, as is set out in
subsection (4)(a), it could not, ‘reasonably be regarded as likely to give rise to’ the conflict.
Competing directorships: conflicts of interest and duty and conflicts of duties
Section 175(7) states that ‘any reference in this section to a conflict of interest includes
a conflict of interest and duty and a conflict of duties.’ This at last injects a long awaited
measure of cohesion in to the law and settles a long running dispute surrounding what
was seen to be an anomalous decision of Chitty J in London and Mashonaland Co Ltd v
New Mashonaland Exploration Co Ltd [1891] WN 165 in which it was held that no breach of
duty arose where a director held office with two or more competing companies.
The modern courts have adopted a stricter stance in viewing competing directors as
giving rise to an irreconcilable conflict of interest and duty. See SCWS v Meyer [1959] AC
324, where Lord Denning said that such directors walk a very fine line, and Plus Group
Ltd v Pyke [2002] EWCA Civ 370. See also Bell v Lever Bros Ltd [1932] AC 161, HL; Hivac Ltd v
Park Royal Scientific Instruments Ltd [1946] Ch 169.
Thus, s.175(7) brings competing directorships into the general prohibition of conflicts
of duty.
his duty to the company imposed on him the obligation of obtaining these iron chairs
at the lowest possible price. His personal interest would lead him in an entirely opposite
direction, would induce him to fix the price as high as possible. This is the very evil against
which the rule in question is directed.
page 180 University of London
The self-dealing rule is (to put it very shortly) that if a trustee sells the trust property
to himself, the sale is voidable by any beneficiary ex debito justitiae, however fair the
transaction.... [E]quity is astute to prevent a trustee from abusing his position or profiting
from his trust: the shepherd must not become a wolf.
See also, the joint judgment of Rich, Dixon and Evatt JJ in Furs Ltd v Tomkies (1936) 54
CLR 583.
It is noteworthy that the statutory statement of directors’ duties does not follow the
common law position. Self-dealing is removed from the realms of directors’ fiduciary
duties and replaced with a statutory obligation to disclose an interest. Section 175(3)
makes it clear that the duty to avoid conflicts of interest contained in s.175(1) ‘does not
apply to a conflict of interest arising in relation to a transaction or arrangement with
the company.’ Rather, ‘self-dealing’ falls within s.177(1). This provides that: ‘[i]f a director
is in any way, directly or indirectly, interested in a proposed transaction or arrangement
with the company, he must declare the nature and extent of that interest to the other
directors.’ In similar terms s.182 applies to cases where a director has an interest in a
transaction after it ‘has been entered into by the company.’ The provisions do not apply
to substantial property transactions, loans, quasi-loans and credit transactions which
require the approval of the company’s members (ss.190–203, see Section 15.3).
Sections 177 and 182 reflect the common practice that companies’ articles of
association generally permitted directors to have interests in conflict transactions
provided they were declared to the board. The reason why the common law tolerated
such relaxation of the rule was explained by Upjohn LJ in Boulting v Association of
Cinematograph Television and Allied Technicians [1963] 2 QB 606:
It is frequently very much better in the interests of the company... that they should be
advised by someone on some transaction, although he may be interested on the other
side of the fence. Directors... may sometimes be placed in such a position that though
their interest and duty conflict, they can properly and honestly give their services to both
sides and serve two masters to the great advantage of both. If the person entitled to the
benefit of the rule is content with that position and understands what are his rights in the
matter, there is no reason why he should not relax the rule, and it may commercially be
very much to his advantage to do so.
The principal distinction between the two statutory provisions is that, whereas breach
of s.177 carries civil consequences (s.178), breach of s.182 results in criminal sanctions
(s.183). More particularly, s.178 states that the consequences of breach (or threatened
breach) of ss.171–177 are the same as would apply if the corresponding common law
rule or equitable principle applied. This is subject to the proviso introduced by s.180(1)
that, subject to any provision to the contrary in the company’s constitution, if s.177 is
complied with, the transaction is not liable to be set aside by virtue of any common
law rule or equitable principle requiring the consent of members.
The question has arisen as to whether disclosure has to be made at a formal meeting
of the board. In Lee Panavision Ltd v Lee Lighting Ltd [1992] BCLC 22 and Runciman v Walter
Runciman plc [1992] BCLC 1084 it was held that informal disclosure to all members of the
board would suffice. In MacPherson v European Strategic Bureau Ltd [1999] 2 BCLC 203 each
of the shareholders and the directors knew the precise nature of other’s interest so that
there was, in effect, unanimous approval of the agreement. The court therefore held that:
[n]o amount of formal disclosure by each other to the other would have increased the
other’s relevant knowledge.
However it should be noted that the board has to be given precise information about
the transaction in question (Gwembe Valley Development Co Ltd v Koshy [2000] BCC 1127),
affirmed by the Court of Appeal [2003] EWCA Civ 1478.
Company Law 15 Directors’ duties page 181
This duty is an element of the wider no-conflict duty laid down in s.175 and it too will
not be infringed if acceptance of the benefit cannot reasonably be regarded as likely
to give rise to a conflict of interest. It should be noted that it applies only to benefits
conferred because the director is a director of the company or because of something
that the director does or does not do as director.
The word ‘benefit’, for the purpose of this section, is not defined in the Act although
during the Parliamentary debates on the Bill it was made clear that it includes benefits
of any description, including non-financial benefits (Official Report, 9/2/2006; coll GC330
(Lord Goldsmith)). While s.175(5) provides for board authorisation in respect of conflicts
of interest, this is not the case with this particular duty. However, the company may
authorise the acceptance of benefits by virtue of s.180(4). Section 176(2) defines a ‘third
party’ as a person other than the company or its holding company or its subsidiaries and
thus s.176(3) provides that benefits provided by the company fall outside the prohibition.
1. the consequences of breach (or threatened breach) of Sections 171 to 177 are the
same as would apply if the corresponding common law rule or equitable principle
applied
2. the duties in those sections (with the exception of Section 174 (duty to exercise
reasonable care, skill and diligence)) are, accordingly, enforceable in the same way
as any other fiduciary duty owed to a company by its directors.
u damages or compensation where the company has suffered loss (see Re Lands
Allotment Co [1894] 1 Ch 616, CA; Joint Stock Discount Co v Brown (1869) LR 8 Eq 381)
u an account of profits made by the director (see Regal (Hastings) Ltd v Gulliver)
u rescission of a contract where the director failed to disclose an interest (see Transvaal
Lands Co v New Belgium (Transvaal) Land & Development Co [1914] 2 Ch 488, CA).
Presumably the rules developed for establishing the liability of accessories (for
example, in the case of receipt of property pursuant to a breach of fiduciary duty, or
dishonest assistance of such a breach) will be applied notwithstanding that the breach
may be of a duty which is now statutorily defined and imposed.
The liability to account arises even where the director acted honestly and where the
company could not otherwise have obtained the benefit (Regal (Hastings) Ltd v Gulliver;
IDC v Cooley). In Murad v Al-Saraj [2005] EWCA Civ 959, Arden LJ explained the policy
underlying such liability:
It may be asked why equity imposes stringent liability of this nature... equity imposes
stringent liability on a fiduciary as a deterrent – pour encourager les autres. Trust law
recognises what in company law is now sometimes called the ‘agency’ problem. There
page 182 University of London
is a separation of beneficial ownership and control and the shareholders (who may be
numerous and only have small numbers of shares) or beneficial owners cannot easily
monitor the actions of those who manage their business or property on a day to day
basis. Therefore, in the interests of efficiency and to provide an incentive to fiduciaries to
resist the temptation to misconduct themselves, the law imposes exacting standards on
fiduciaries and an extensive liability to account.
In Coleman Taymar Ltd v Oakes [2001] 2 BCLC 749, Robert Reid QC, sitting as a Deputy
Judge of the High Court, stated that a company is entitled to elect whether to claim
However, even though the profit may arise out of the use of position as opposed to
the use of trust property, the judges more typically resort to the language of the
‘constructive trust’ as the means for fashioning a remedy (see Boardman v Phipps [1967]
2 AC 46, although, Lord Guest excepted, all of their Lordships spoke of the defendant’s
liability to account).
In A-G for Hong Kong v Reid [1994] 1 AC 324, Lord Templeman explained that Boardman
‘demonstrates the strictness with which equity regards the conduct of a fiduciary
and the extent to which equity is willing to impose a constructive trust on property
obtained by a fiduciary by virtue of his office.’ In JJ Harrison (Properties) Ltd v Harrison
[2002] 1 BCLC 162, CA, a director usurped a corporate opportunity by acquiring for his
own benefit development land owned by the company. At the time of valuation he
failed to disclose that planning permission was forthcoming which, once granted,
would greatly inflate its value. The company, having unsuccessfully applied for
planning permission a couple of years earlier, was unaware that local authority policy
in this respect had changed. The director purchased the land from the company in
1985 for £8,400. Having obtained planning permission through, to add insult to injury,
use of the company’s resources, he then resold part of it for £110,300 in 1988 and the
rest in 1992 for £122,500. The director resigned and the company sought to hold him
liable as a constructive trustee. Chadwick LJ, citing Millett LJ in Paragon Finance plc v DB
Thakerar & Co (1999), said:
It follows… from the principle that directors who dispose of the company’s property in
breach of their fiduciary duties are treated as having committed a breach of trust that,
a director who is, himself, the recipient of the property holds it upon a trust for the
company. He, also, is described as a constructive trustee.
In the CMS Dolphin Ltd v Simonet, Lawrence Collins J subjected the issue of remedies
for diverting a corporate opportunity to detailed analysis. He held that S was a
constructive trustee of the profits referable to exploiting the corporate opportunity
and, in general, it made no difference whether the opportunity is first taken up by the
wrongdoer or by a ‘corporate vehicle’ established by him for that purpose.
I do not consider that the liability of the directors in Cook v Deeks would have been in
any way different if they had procured their new company to enter the contract directly,
rather than (as they did) enter into it themselves and then transfer the benefit of the
contract to a new company.
The basis of a director’s liability in this situation is that, as seen in Cook v Deeks, the
opportunity in question is treated as if it were an asset of the company in relation to
which the director had fiduciary duties. He thus becomes a constructive trustee ‘of
the fruits of his abuse of the company’s property’ (per Lawrence Collins J, above).
Activity 15.5
Read Regal (Hastings) Ltd v Gulliver [1942] 1 All ER 378, [1967] 2 AC 134n.
What is the basis of the liability of the directors in this case? Who brought the claim?
Company Law 15 Directors’ duties page 183
Section 180(1) provides that if the requirement of authorisation is complied with for
the purposes of s.175 (see s.175(4) and (5), above), or if the director has declared to the
other directors his interest in a proposed transaction with the company under s.177,
these processes replace the equitable rule that required the members to authorise
such breaches of duty. This is made subject to any enactment (for example, the above
transactions contained in Chapter 4 of Part 10) or any provision in the company’s
articles which require the authorisation or approval of members.
Thus, the company’s constitution can reverse the statutory change and can insist
on certain steps being taken requiring the consent of the members in certain
circumstances. In that event, that provision would have to be given effect to. That is
the consequence of the change of approach – and therefore a change of approach to
the appropriate consequence of there not being members’ approval in particular cases
because it would no longer be required (see Official Report, 9/2/2006; coll GC337).
Section 180(3) states that compliance with the general duties does not remove the
need for the approval of members to the transactions falling within Chapter 4 CA 2006.
Further, s.180(2) provides that the general duties apply even though the transaction
falls within Chapter 4, except that there is no need to comply with ss.175 or 176
where the approval of members is obtained. Section 180(4) preserves the common
law position on prior authorisation of conduct that would otherwise be a breach
of the general duties. Thus, companies may, through their articles, go further than
the statutory duties by placing more onerous requirements on their directors (e.g.
by requiring shareholder authorisation of the remuneration of the directors). It also
makes it clear that the company’s articles may not dilute the general duties except to
the extent that this is explicitly permitted. The effect of this provision seems to be that
interested members can vote on a resolution to approve a prospective breach of the
statutory duties, but cannot do so to ratify a breach after the event (s.239).
In North-West Transportation Co Ltd v Beatty (1887)) 12 App Cas 589 PC, it had been held
that the director could vote, qua shareholder, in favour of the resolution ratifying his
breach of duty. The reform follows the recommendation of the CLRSG which took the
view that the question of the validity of a decision by the members of the company
to ratify a wrong on the company by the directors (whether or not a fraud) should
depend on whether the necessary majority had been reached without the need to
rely upon the votes of the wrongdoers, or of those who were substantially under
their influence, or who had a personal interest in the condoning of the wrong. See DTI
Consultation Document (November 2000) Completing the structure para.5.85.
Section 239(6)(a) goes on to provide that nothing in the section affects the validity of a
decision taken by the unanimous consent of the members of the company. This
appears to mean that the restrictions on who may vote on a resolution, contained in
s.239(3)–(4), will not apply when every member, including the director qua
shareholder, agrees to condone the breach of duty. This places on a statutory footing
the common law principle that a breach of duty is ratifiable by obtaining the informal
†
approval of every member who has a right to vote on such a resolution.† See Re Duomatic Ltd [1969]
2 Ch 365; Parker & Cooper Ltd
15.2.10 Cases within more than one of the general duties v Reading [1926] Ch 975; EIC
Services Ltd v Phipps [2003]
The way in which the duties are framed results in an overlap between them. Section 1 WLR 2360; Euro Brokers
179 serves to emphasise that the effect of the duties is cumulative: Holdings Ltd v Monecor
(London) Ltd [2003] 1 BCLC
Except as otherwise provided, more than one of the general duties may apply in any given
506, CA.
case.
It is therefore necessary for directors to comply with every duty that may be triggered in
any given situation. For example, the duty to promote the success of the company (s.172)
will not authorise the director to breach his duty to act within his powers (s.171), even if
he considers that it would be most likely to promote the success of the company.
u negligence
u default
u breach of duty
u breach of trust.
u having regard to all the circumstances of the case, he ought fairly to be excused on
such terms as the court thinks fit.
A classic illustration of the way the provision might be used is Re Welfab Engineers Ltd
[1990] BCLC 833. The directors of a company which had been trading at a loss sold its
main asset for the lower of two competing bids on the understanding that the company
would continue to be run as a going concern. Shortly afterwards the company went into
liquidation. The liquidator brought misfeasance proceedings against the directors. It was
held that the directors had not acted in breach of duty in accepting the lower offer but,
even if they had, it was a case in which relief would be granted under s.1157. Hoffmann J
took the view that the directors were motivated by an honest and reasonable desire to
save the business and the jobs of the company’s employees.
Another example is Re D’Jan of London Ltd. You will recall that the director in
question incorrectly completed a proposal form for property insurance. The insurers
subsequently repudiated liability on the policy when the company claimed for fire
Company Law 15 Directors’ duties page 185
damage. The director had signed the proposal without reading it. Hoffmann LJ thought
that it was the kind of mistake that could be made by any busy man. In granting the
director partial relief from liability, the court noted that he held 99 of the company’s
shares (his wife held the other). Therefore the economic reality was that the interests
the director had put at risk were those of himself and his wife. The judge observed
that it ‘may seem odd that a person found to have been guilty of negligence, which
involves failing to take reasonable care, can ever satisfy the court that he acted
reasonably. Nevertheless, the section clearly contemplates that he may do so. It
follows that conduct may be reasonable for the purposes of s.1157, despite amounting
to lack of reasonable care at common law.’
A final example where relief was granted is given by Hedger v Adams [2015] EWHC 2540
(Ch).
More often, however, the courts have been reluctant to give relief under s.1157.
In Re Duckwari plc (No.2) (above), the point was made obiter that a director who intends
to profit by way of a direct or indirect personal interest in a substantial property
transaction could not be said to have acted reasonably and therefore would be denied
relief under s.1157.
For a further illustration of the courts’ reluctance to give relief under s.1157, see
Towers v Premier Waste Management Ltd [2012] BCC 72. And see also: Re Brian D Pierson
(Contractors) Ltd [1999] BCC 26; Re Simmon Box (Diamonds) Ltd [2000] BCC 275; Bairstow
v Queens Moat Houses plc [2000] 1 BCLC 549.
Can a shadow director rely on s.1157? Instant Access Properties Ltd v Rosser [2018] EWHC
756 (Ch) suggests that, in a roundabout way, such a director can. The court held that a
shadow director ought not to be found to be in breach of duty in the first place where,
had she been a de jure or de facto director, she would have been relieved of liability
under s.1157.
u It excludes payments under directors’ service contracts and payments for loss
of office from the requirements of these clauses (s.190(6)). This implements a
recommendation of the Law Commissions.
There are a number of exceptions to the requirement for members’ approval which
have been consolidated (see ss.204–209). These cover: expenditure on company
business (s.204); expenditure on defending proceedings etc (s.205); expenditure in
connection with regulatory action or investigation (s.206); expenditure for minor
and business transactions (s.207); expenditure for intra-group transactions (s.208);
expenditure for money-lending companies (s.209).
The effect of a breach of ss.197, 198, 200, 201 or 203 is that the transaction or
arrangement is voidable at the instance of the company (s.213(2)). Further, regardless
of whether the company has elected to avoid the transaction, an arrangement or
transaction entered into in contravention of the provision renders the director
(together with any connected person to whom voidable payments were made and
any director who authorised the transaction or arrangement) liable to account to the
company for any gain he made as well as being liable to indemnify the company for
any loss or damage it sustains as a result of the transaction or arrangement (s.213(4)).
A director who is liable as a result of the company entering into a transaction with a
person connected with him has a defence if he can show that he took all reasonable
steps to secure the company’s compliance with ss.200, 201 or 203.
The Act does not define ‘loan’, although s.199 does define the term ‘quasi-loan’ and
related expressions (see s.199).
Further reading
¢ Ahern, D. ‘Directors’ duties, dry ink and the accessibility agenda’ (2012) LQR 114.
¢ Conaglen, M. ‘The nature and function of fiduciary loyalty’ (2005) LQR 452.
¢ Davies, P. and J. Rickford ‘An introduction to the new UK Companies Act’ (2008)
ECFR 48.
Company Law 15 Directors’ duties page 187
¢ Davies and Worthington, Chapter 16: ‘Directors’ duties’ and Chapter 17: ‘The
derivative claim and personal actions against directors’.
¢ Developing Directors’ Duties (1999) CfiLR (special edition devoted to the Law
Commission’s report on directors’ duties (Nos 261 and 173) and the DTI’s
fundamental review of core company law).
¢ Edmunds, R. and J. Lowry ‘The continuing value of relief for directors’ breach of
duty’ (2003) MLR 195.
¢ Finch, V. ‘Company directors: who cares about skill and care?’ (1992) MLR 179.
¢ Grantham, R. ‘The unanimous consent rule in company law’ (1993) CLJ 245.
¢ Keay, A. ‘The duty of directors to take account of creditors’ interests: has it any
role to play?’ (2002) JBL 379.
¢ Lowry, J. ‘The irreducible core of the duty of care, skill and diligence of company
directors: Australian Securities and Investments Commission v Healey’ (2012) 79
MLR 249.
¢ Lowry, J. ‘Regal (Hastings) fifty years on: breaking the bonds of the ancien régime’
(1994) NILQ 1.
¢ Parker, H. ‘Directors’ duties under the Companies Act 2006: clarity or confusion?’
(2013) 13 J of Corporate L Studies 1.
¢ White Paper: Modern Company Law For a Competitive Economy: Developing the
Framework, (2000) DTI, March.
The objective of the no-conflict duty was explained by Lord Herschell in Bray v Ford and
by Millett LJ in Bristol and West Building Society v Mothew. You should also state what
the consequences are of a breach of duty (i.e. the director’s liability to account for any
profits obtained (see s.178)). As Millett LJ points out, the core liability has several facets:
a director must not make a profit out of his trust and a director ‘must not place himself
in a position where his duty and his interest may conflict’.
The question requires a detailed analysis of s.175 and particularly Regal (Hastings) Ltd v
Gulliver, IDC v Cooley and Bhullar v Bhullar. In particular you should refer to the reasoning
of Lord Russell in Regal (Hastings) in which he reviews the basis of the directors’ liability
to account. With respect to the January 2017 approach by Fred you should note that in
Cooley the judge stressed that it was irrelevant to the issue of liability that the defendant
director had been approached in his personal capacity. Reference will also, however,
need to be made to Peso Silver Mines v Cropper where, on the particular facts of the case,
liability was avoided because it was held that the company had bona fide declined the
offer to buy the mining claims. You need to discuss whether the decision by Dynamic
Development plc not to join with Fred was reached in accordance with s.172 (duty to
promote the success of the company) or was it made in order to facilitate the defendant
directors pursuing the opportunity themselves. Here you will discuss Cook v Deeks, and
Bhullar v Bhullar. The fact that Arthur was a party to the board’s decision to reject Fred’s
offer, together with the fact that he declined Fred’s personal invitation might point to
the board’s decision being made in accordance with s.172. On the information you are
given it is difficult to reach a firm conclusion in this regard, but it is an issue that must be
addressed. You will also need to discuss s.175(5)(b) as the company is a plc.
You must reach a conclusion on the issue of liability. This shows the examiner that you
have thought about the issues. One final point in this regard: you should mention that
the claim is being brought by Dynamic Development plc because breach of fiduciary
duty is a wrong against the company (see Chapter 11 of the module guide) and the
proper claimant rule therefore applies (see now Part 11 of the CA 2006).
Finally, discuss s.1157 CA 2006. It is a belt and braces provision so that inevitably
defendant directors will argue for relief from liability. Note that the court may relieve
the defendants in whole or in part.
page 190 University of London
Need to revise first = There are one or two areas I am unsure about and need to revise
before I go on to the next chapter.
Need to study again = I found many or all of the principles outlined in this chapter
very difficult and need to go over them again before I move on.
If you ticked ‘need to revise first’, which sections of the chapter are you going to
revise?
Must Revision
revise done
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 192
Introduction
This chapter examines the corporate governance debate in the UK. It is an extremely
important area. Students are not only expected to be up to date with current
corporate governance issues but are expected to have a detailed knowledge of the
history and theory that informs the corporate governance debate. This chapter
provides an overview but, as with other areas of this course, students need to engage
with the further reading to build up a detailed knowledge of this area.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings, you should be able to:
u describe the main historical periods in the development of the modern company
u explain the various corporate theories that influence the corporate governance
debate
u illustrate the current trends in corporate governance writing
u form your own view of what the main purpose of a company should be.
Core text
¢ Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 15: ‘Corporate governance 1: corporate governance
and corporate theory’ and Chapter 16: ‘Corporate governance 2: the UK
corporate governance debate’.
Company Law 16 Corporate governance page 193
In 1932 Berle and Means, an economist and a lawyer, made two key observations
about the operation of American companies in the 1930s. First, that shareholders
were so numerous (described as dispersed ownership and subsequently as the Berle
and Means corporation) that no individual shareholder had an interest in attempting
to exercise control over management. In their view 65 per cent of the largest two
hundred US companies were controlled entirely by their managers. Second, they
expressed concern that managers were not only unaccountable to shareholders but
exercised enormous economic power which had the potential to harm society.
At the same time Dodd (1932) sought to put flesh onto some of the key remaining
questions posed by corporate realism. Crucially he sought to answer the
question ‘what are the interests of this real person if they are not equated with
the shareholders?’ He argued that, just as other real persons have citizenship
responsibilities that require personal self-sacrifice, a corporation has social
responsibilities which may sometimes be contrary to its economic objectives. In
turn, managers of this citizen corporation are expected to exercise their powers
in a manner which recognises the company’s social responsibility to employees,
consumers and the general public.
page 194 University of London
Until the late 1960s the tangible success of managerial companies and the ability
of these companies to behave as corporate citizens meant that corporate realism
was the dominant theory. However, by the 1980s a change was occurring in the way
shareholders were behaving. Reform in state pension and health care funding had
pushed enormous amounts of money into the equity markets through institutional
investors (pension finds, investment funds and insurance companies). At the same
time barriers to capital inflows and outflows were removed in many countries which
resulted in international investment funds operating in both the London and New
York markets. In all, the institutional investor emerged as a dominant force in those
markets, holding nearly 80 per cent of the shares in the UK market and 60–70 per
cent of the shares in the US market by the late 1980s. While institutional investors
preferred to remain largely passive investors for the most part, they did favour
market mechanisms in order to promote shareholder wealth maximisation. Thus
share options grew as a percentage of managements’ total salary as this focused
management on share price as a measure of performance and the non-executive
director emerged as a monitoring mechanism on management.
The emergence of the Berle and Means corporation has not been universal. Indeed it only
emerged in the UK in the late 1960s. In most of the rest of the world a managerial class
emerged but not accompanied by dispersed ownership. Rather founding families, other
companies and banks held controlling stakes in these companies. Thus, outside the UK
and the US the accountability issue has not formed such a large part of the corporate
governance debate. The differences in the corporate governance systems around the
world has also become a major area of study based around the preconditions necessary
for the emergence of a US/UK corporate governance system (see Coffee (2001)).
Activity 16.1
Provide some examples from your study of company law that illustrate the key
points of the various corporate theories.
Company Law 16 Corporate governance page 195
u First, corporations are very powerful and therefore have an enormous effect on
society. Thus a narrow accountability to shareholders is insufficient to protect
society’s interests.
u Second, some, like Parkinson (1995), argue that the assumption that shareholders
have a moral claim to primacy by virtue of their property rights is plainly incorrect.
If shareholder primacy is to be justified it must be on other grounds.
u Third, the moral claims of others (stakeholders) either outweigh the shareholders’
claims or at are at least equal to them when it comes to allocating primacy.
Perhaps the most significant instrument that seeks to achieve this accountability is
the UK Corporate Governance Code. This is now issued by the UK’s Financial Reporting
Council (FRC), and the latest version dates from 2018. It began its life, however, in
1992, following the report of the Cadbury Committee (1992) on the Financial Aspects
of Corporate Governance. That Committee was established by the Financial Reporting
Council, the London Stock Exchange and the combined accounting bodies. The
report was an industry attempt to address some of the accountability concerns
expressed about UK listed companies. While fairly narrowly focused the report
succeeded in identifying the lack of managerial accountability at the heart of most
UK listed companies. The key recommendation of the Cadbury Committee was to
introduce non-executive directors to the main board, the idea being that these
non-executive directors would bring some objectivity to board decisions. Cadbury
also recommended that a committee structure should be put in place to improve the
accountability of the appointment of directors, the pay (remuneration) of directors
and the audit process. Therefore a listed company should have three sub-committees
of the board to cover appointments, remuneration and audit. The accountability
process would be ensured by having non-executives on each of the sub-committees.
The remuneration committee in particular was to be made up wholly or mainly of
non-executives and the audit committee should have at least three non-executives.
The London Stock Exchange implemented the Cadbury recommendations on a comply
or explain basis (i.e. if you don’t comply you need to explain why) and subsequently
the Cadbury model has been adopted by stock exchanges around the world.
page 196 University of London
We shall return to questions of pay below. But sticking with codes of practice, a third
committee called the Hampel Committee reported in 1998 and, while offering nothing
new to the accountability issues, provided an opportunity to combine the Cadbury
and Greenbury recommendations into one single code called the Combined Code.
The Hampel Committee’s importance lies in that fact that its failure to meaningfully
engage in the corporate governance debate antagonised the government into putting
corporate governance firmly on its reform agenda within the ambit of the CLRSG (see
below).
The collapse of the US company Enron in 2002 spurred the government into
announcing a review of the role of non-executive directors in UK companies. The
review was carried out by Derek Higgs, who consulted widely and produced a final
report in January 2003. Its key recommendation was to provide a good definition of
independence for non-executives, which was adopted by the LSE. A non-executive
director will now only be considered independent when the board determines that
the director is independent in character and judgment and there are no relationships
or circumstances which could affect, or appear to affect, the director’s judgment. Such
relationships and circumstances arise where the director:
u is being paid by the company other than a director’s fee and certain other
payments
The Higgs independence criteria have subsequently been adopted by the London
Stock Exchange.
In 2010, the Combined Code was renamed the UK Corporate Governance Code.
Responsibility for updating its provisions in future years, and for monitoring
compliance with its terms, was taken on by the Financial Reporting Council. It is now
updated every two years.
Despite this change in responsibility, the basic philosophy of the code remains the
same. It continues to focus on the structure, composition and role of the board,
with an emphasis on ensuring a sufficient proportion of independent non-executive
directors who are responsible for monitoring their executive colleagues. Compliance
remains optional, but the companies to which it applies (those with a ‘premium
listing’ on the LSE) must declare whether they do comply with its recommendations
and explain their reasons for any non-compliance. You can access the latest version of
the Code at: www.frc.org.uk/corporate/ukcgcode.cfm
One interesting change that was first introduced in the 2012 version of the Code is a
recommendation that the company’s annual report should ‘include a description of
the board’s policy on diversity, including gender, any measurable objectives that it
has set for implementing the policy, and progress on achieving the objectives’. This
Company Law 16 Corporate governance page 197
change to the Code followed on from the Review undertaken by Lord Davies into the
proportion of women on company boards, which can be accessed at: www.gov.uk/
government/news/women-on-boards
That review set a goal for the 100 largest quoted companies (known as the ‘FTSE 100’)
to have at least 25 per cent female board members by 2015. This target had been
achieved by October 2015, with a female board membership of 26 per cent.
As noted above, the latest version of the Code dates from 2018 and took effect from
1 January 2019. This new version is rather shorter, and supposedly ‘punchier’, than its
predecessors. There is now a simpler division between the Code’s general ‘Principles’,
and its more specific ‘Provisions’. There are 18 Principles, which are fairly broad,
high-level statements of good practice, which companies are expected to apply, and
to explain how they do so. The 41 Provisions are more detailed and more specific but
companies have more scope for choosing not to follow some of them. Where they
choose not to do so, they must explain why.
However, criticism was also directed at the shareholders of financial institutions. They
either encouraged, or at least failed to stop, excessive risk taking, and generally failed
to exercise their responsibilities to engage with the banks executives and directors
– their so-called ‘stewardship responsibilities’. The full review can be found at: http://
webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/20130129110402/http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/
walker_review_261109.pdf
subject to a shorter list of just seven principles, which they must likewise ‘apply and
explain’.
More information, including a copy of the 2020 Code itself, can be found here:
www.frc.org.uk/investors/uk-stewardship-code
Also, have a look back at this topic in Chapter 14, and note how, in quoted companies,
‘Remuneration Reports’ must be prepared, and these must be voted on by
shareholders. As a result of changes introduced in 2013, the shareholders’ vote is now
binding (as to the company’s remuneration policy).
In August 2016, the Government launched its project called Corporate Governance
Reform, which was a general review of corporate governance arrangements in the UK;
see www.gov.uk/government/consultations/corporate-governance-reform
One aspect of that review concerned executive remuneration, and especially the
growing gap within many companies between the pay of the company’s executives
and the pay of the company’s other workers. As a result, the Companies (Miscellaneous
Reporting) Regulations 2018 have now been introduced, requiring quoted companies
to reveal the ratio between the pay of their CEO and the average pay of the company’s
UK workforce.
16.3.4 Long-termism
In October 2010 ‘BIS’ (a government department) launched a review of ‘corporate
governance and economic short-termism’; see: www.bis.gov.uk/Consultations/a-long-
term-focus-for-corporate-britain?cat=open. One major concern was whether UK
equity markets in particular contributed towards the alleged ‘short-termism’ of UK
companies. To explore this issue further, Professor John Kay was appointed to examine
key issues related to investment in UK equity markets and its impact on the long-term
performance and governance of UK quoted companies. In February 2012, Kay and his
colleagues produced an interim review, which provided a wide range of evidence that
British companies were indeed subject to damaging short-term pressures, particularly
from shareholders.
u providing that those involved in the investment chain who had discretion over
the investments of others (e.g. asset managers) or who gave investment advice to
others, should be subject to fiduciary standards
u ensuring that the structure of asset managers’ pay encouraged long termism.
u ensuring companies engaged more with long-term investors over major board
appointments
To support some of the above recommendations, Kay also proposed a set of three
‘Good Practice Statements’, aimed at directors of companies, asset managers and
institutional shareholders. These statements would highlight the responsibilities of
these different actors for encouraging more stewardship and more long-term decision
making.
In November 2012 BIS released its response to the Kay Review. This can be viewed at
www.bis.gov.uk/kayreview
BIS largely accepted Kay’s analysis of the role which equity markets played in
encouraging short-termism, and also agreed with almost all of Kay’s specific
recommendations. Of course, many of the recommendations were aimed at investors,
or companies, rather than government. But one practical response BIS made
immediately was to publish Kay’s three proposed ‘Practice Statements’ for directors,
asset managers and shareholders. These statements can be found in Annexes A–C of the
BIS response. However, these practice statements are not legally binding on directors,
shareholders or asset managers, and no additional mechanisms have been developed
to ensure that those to whom they are addressed follow them. It remains to be seen,
then, whether they will have any impact on the behaviour of their addressees.
(1) A director of a company must act in the way he considers, in good faith, would be
most likely to promote the success of the company for the benefit of its members as a
whole, and in doing so have regard (amongst other matters) to—
(c) the need to foster the company’s business relationships with suppliers, customers
and others,
(d) the impact of the company’s operations on the community and the environment,
(e) the desirability of the company maintaining a reputation for high standards of
business conduct, and
Social reporting
The other area where efforts have been made to address stakeholder interests is in
respect of the reporting obligations of companies. Even if companies, or their directors,
are not compelled to give more weight to stakeholder interests, requiring companies to
disclose how well – or badly – they treat their stakeholders may encourage companies to
improve their behaviour. If companies must disclose their employment and supply chain
practices, their record on environmental impact, how much tax they pay, and so on, fear
of adverse publicity may provide a strong incentive against misbehaviour.
Traditionally, of course, company law in the UK has focused on the release of financial
information, aimed at letting shareholders and creditors know how well the company
is performing. However, the White Paper published by the UK Government prior to
the introduction of the Companies Bill 2005 (http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.
uk/20090609003228/http://www.berr.gov.uk/files/file25406.pdf at p.10) recommended
the introduction of an Operating and Financial Review (OFR) which would provide
a narrative statement on the company’s activities as they affect stakeholder
constituencies. The justification for this was that directors would have to give more
credence to stakeholders if they had to write a report on the effect of the company’s
activities on those stakeholders.
Without waiting for the enactment of the CA 2006, the Government acted on this
White Paper proposal. It drafted the Companies Act 1985 (Operating and Financial
Review and Directors’ Report etc.) Regulations, and these were enacted in March 2005.
But this ill-thought out repeal was complicated further by the fact that European
legislation, in the form of the European Accounts Modernisation Directive (Directive
2003/51/EC), itself required a ‘fair business review’ (FBR) to take place. And the FBR
sounded similar to what the OFR had required, before it was so hastily repealed. As a
result, the CA 2006, in s.417, then reinstated a requirement for companies to include,
as part of the directors’ annual report, a ‘business review’. Finally, in 2013, s.417 was
itself repealed, and the need for a business review was replaced with a requirement
that companies prepare a ‘strategic report’ (see s.414A–D CA 2006). We have already
examined that requirement in Chapter 15.
This rather complicated and messy process of false starts and half measures does not
reflect terribly well on the reform of UK company law. The amount of stakeholder-
relevant information that must be given remains quite modest. But it is at least an
acknowledgement that groups other than shareholders also have an interest in how
companies are performing. As noted already above, in 2016 the Government launched
its review of UK corporate governance arrangements, entitled Corporate Governance
Reform. One recommendation from the Corporate Governance Reform project was that
companies should be required to give out more information about how their directors
implement the obligation, in s.172, to take account of the interests of a variety of
stakeholders. This has now been achieved through amendments to the strategic
report requirement in s.414, which was considered above.
Company Law 16 Corporate governance page 201
Moreover, and going beyond mere ‘social reporting’, the Government also decided
to direct the FRC to amend the UK Corporate Governance Code to require companies
that are subject to the Code to improve their engagement with stakeholders. This has
now been achieved in the new, shorter, version of the Code that was issued in 2018.
It now contains two new Principles focusing on stakeholder engagement. Principle D
states that ‘[in] order for the company to meet its responsibilities to shareholders and
stakeholders, the board should ensure effective engagement with, and encourage
participation from, these parties.’ Principle E declares that ‘[t]he board should ensure
that workforce policies and practices are consistent with the company’s values and
support its long-term sustainable success. The workforce should be able to raise
any matters of concern.’ Finally, there is a new Provision 5, which states that ‘[f]or
engagement with the workforce, one or a combination of the following methods
should be used:
Activity 16.2
Read Dignam and Lowry Chapters 15 and 16 and then consider the following.
‘The committees on corporate governance have been an amazing success. We know
this not only because of the domestic improvements in corporate governance
they have brought about but because similar systems have been adopted by
international agencies and other jurisdictions around the world.’
Do you agree with the above statement? Explain your views.
Further reading
¢ Berle, A. ‘For whom corporate managers are trustees: a note’ (1932) Harvard Law
Review 1365.
¢ Berle, A. and G. Means The modern corporation and private property. (New
Brunswick, NJ; London: Transaction Publishers, paperback edition 1991) [ISBN
9780887388873].
¢ Coffee, J. ‘The rise of dispersed ownership: the roles of law and the state in the
separation of ownership and control’ (2001) 1 Yale LJ 25–29.
¢ Dodd, E. ‘For whom are corporate managers trustees?’ (1932) Harvard Law
Review 1145.
¢ Finegold, D., G.S. Benson and D. Hecht ‘Corporate boards and company
performance: review of research in light of recent reforms’ (2007) 15 Corp Gov
865.
Remember to apply your findings to the question you have been asked.
page 204 University of London
Need to revise first = There are one or two areas I am unsure about and need to revise
before I go on to the next chapter.
Need to study again = I found many or all of the principles outlined in this chapter
very difficult and need to go over them again before I move on.
If you ticked ‘need to revise first’, which sections of the chapter are you going to
revise?
Must Revision
revise done
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 206
Introduction
In this chapter we consider the various ways in which a company can be wound up.
A principal anxiety of the law is to ensure the most equitable treatment possible of
all the creditors. You will have noted from previous chapters that many key issues
of company law come to the fore during the liquidation process. You should revise
Chapter 7: ‘Raising capital: debentures’ and Chapter 15: ‘Directors’ duties’ before
embarking on the material below.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter and the relevant readings, you should be able to:
u explain the ways in which a company may be wound up
u describe the powers and duties of the liquidator
u describe the order in which creditors are paid
u discuss the liabilities of directors of insolvent companies.
Core text
¢ Dignam and Lowry, Chapter 17: ‘Corporate rescue and liquidations in outline’.
Cases
¢ Re London and Paris Banking Corp (1874) LR 19 Eq 444
¢ BNY Corporate Trustee Services Ltd v Eurosail-UK 2007-3BL plc [2013] UKSC 28.
Company Law 17 Liquidating the company page 207
There are three principal ways in which a company’s existence can be brought to an
end (i.e. dissolved).
u The members may decide to wind up the company – this is termed voluntary
winding up.
u The creditors may force the dissolution of a company where it is insolvent (i.e. it
cannot pay its debts) – this is termed compulsory winding up.
1. When the period, if any, fixed for the duration of the company by the articles
expires, or the event, if any, occurs which the articles provide will result in the
company being dissolved, and the general meeting has passed a resolution
requiring it to be wound up voluntarily (this category is rare nowadays).
In either case, a copy of the winding up resolution must be sent to the Registrar
of Companies within 15 days (s.84(3) IA 1986 and s.30 CA 2006). It is the task of the
liquidator to take control of the company for the purpose of realising its assets,
meeting its liabilities and distributing any surplus left over to the shareholders (ss.91
and 107 IA 1986). Once the liquidator has completed this task and has sent to the
Registrar of Companies his final account and return under s.94 (members’ voluntary
winding up) or s.106 (creditors’ voluntary winding up), the Registrar shall then register
them. Three months after the registration of the return the company is deemed to be
dissolved (s.201).
u if a creditor, to whom a sum exceeding £750 is owed, has served on the company
at its registered office a written demand, in the prescribed form, requiring
the company to pay the debt and the company has for three weeks thereafter
neglected to pay; or
page 208 University of London
u if the court is satisfied that the company is unable to pay its debts as they fall due.
It should be noted in relation to the third category that a company will be deemed
to be insolvent where the value of the company’s assets is less than the amount of
its liabilities (s.123(2) IA 1986). On the meaning of ‘unable to pay its debts’, see BNY
Corporate Trustee Services Ltd v Eurosail-UK 2007-3BL plc [2013] UKSC 28.
However, if the debt is disputed on bona fide grounds the court will not allow the
petition to proceed. Thus, if a creditor presents a petition in order to pressurise the
company into paying a debt, the amount of which is genuinely disputed as being
excessive, the court may dismiss the petition with costs (Re London and Paris Banking
Corp (1874) LR 19 Eq 444).
However, if the petition proceeds a creditor who is owed £750 or more will be entitled
to a winding up order although the court may refuse to make an order if the petition
is not supported by the majority of creditors (s.195). If the court does make an order to
wind up the company it is made in favour of all the creditors, not just the petitioner,
and the Official Receiver is appointed as liquidator. At this point, if the Official
Receiver finds that the realisable assets of the company are insufficient to cover
the expenses of the winding up and that the affairs of the company do not require
further investigation, he or she may apply to the Registrar of Companies for the early
dissolution of the company. Such an application is then registered by the Registrar and
three months after the date of the registration of the notice the company is dissolved.
But, if there are sufficient funds to cover the expenses of the liquidation the Official
Receiver has the power to summon separate meetings of the company’s creditors and
contributories for the purpose of choosing a person to be liquidator of the company in
his or her place (s.136(4)). Once the liquidator has completed his function (see below),
s.205 provides that when he has filed his final returns or the Official Receiver has
filed a notice stating that he considers the winding up to be complete, the Registrar
of Companies shall register those returns or the notice forthwith. At the end of the
period of three months beginning with the day of that registration the company is
dissolved (s.205(2)).
Activity 17.1
Read British Eagle International Airlines Ltd v Compagnie Nationale Air France [1975] 1
WLR 758.
What emerges from the British Eagle decision as the overarching purpose of
liquidation?
Activity 17.2
Read Finch, V. and D. Milman Corporate insolvency law: perspectives and principles.
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2017) third edition [ISBN 9781107039919],
Chapter 2: ‘Aims, objectives and benchmarks’ (available on the VLE).
What are the objectives of the liquidation regime?
Company Law 17 Liquidating the company page 209
The liquidator takes control of the company for the purposes of realising the company’s
assets and distributing them among the claimants according to their priority. For
example, corporate property, which is subject to a fixed charge, must be used first to
redeem the secured loan to which the charge relates. Similarly, where a supplier of goods
has reserved title until payment, ownership will not have passed to the company and so
the liquidator cannot incorporate these goods into the common pool of assets. If there
are insufficient assets left over after taking account of any fixed charges together with the
preferential debts to satisfy the unsecured creditors, their debts abate equally. The order
in which debts are to be satisfied in a liquidation is as follows.
1. All expenses properly incurred in the winding up, including the remuneration of
the liquidator.
2. Preferential debts as identified in ss.107, 115, 143 and 156 (e.g. unpaid employees’
wages).
3. Ordinary debts.
(See ss.107 and 115 (voluntary liquidations) and ss.143 and 156 (compulsory
liquidations); see also s.175 which is of general application.)
Prior to the Enterprise Act 2002, preferential debts were defined by s.386 IA 1986
as debts listed in Schedule 6. These included: debts owed to the Inland Revenue in
respect of PAYE deductions during the previous 12 months but not remitted to the
Revenue; debts due to Customs and Excise in respect of six months’ VAT; debts owed
to the Department of Health and Social Security in respect of employers’ National
Insurance contributions; debts owed by way of unpaid wages to employees and
former employees for the four-month period before the commencement of the
winding up (maximum of £800) together with unpaid holiday pay and outstanding
contributions to pension schemes. Corporation tax liabilities which accrue after the
commencement of a winding up are a ‘necessary disbursement’ of the liquidator
and are therefore expenses of the winding up payable before preferential debts (Re
Toshoku Finance (UK) plc, Kahn v Inland Revenue (2002)). Section 251 of the Enterprise
Act 2002 amends s.386 and Schedule 6 to the IA 1986 by abolishing Crown preferential
debts (i.e. debts due to the Inland Revenue, Customs and Excise and social security
contributions) and adds contributions to occupational pension schemes to the list in
Schedule 6 (see above). Section 252 of the Enterprise Act 2002 inserts a new s.176A into
the IA 1986, which requires, for the benefit of unsecured creditors, a ring-fenced fund
to be created out of the realisations of floating charges. The amount to be transferred
to the prescribed fund for transmission to unsecured creditors is calculated according
to the following: 50 per cent of the first £10,000 plus 20 per cent of available funds
above £10,000 up to a maximum of £600,000. The prescribed fund only applies to
floating charges created after 15 September 2003.
page 210 University of London
The liquidator is given extensive powers to deal with the company and its property, in
order to wind it up. These powers are contained in s.167 of the IA 1986, and Parts 1 to
3 of Schedule 4 of the IA 1986. Previously, the liquidator could only exercise some of
these powers with the sanction of either the court or the liquidation committee, but
this is no longer the case. No such prior approval is now required. If creditors, say, were
dissatisfied with actions taken by the liquidator, they would have to challenge the
liquidator after she had already acted.
Although, as we have seen, the liquidator’s main role is to secure that the company’s
assets are got in and distributed to the creditors (s.143), he also, along with the court,
polices the end of the company to ensure insiders do not take advantage of the
company’s genuine creditors. As such the liquidator is empowered by s.238 IA 1986 to
apply to court to set aside any transactions at an undervalue which may have occurred
in the two years preceding the winding up.
Sometimes in the lead-up to liquidation the company will attempt to put certain
creditors in preferred positions to ensure that they get paid (often the creditors in
question are in fact directors of the company who may have personally guaranteed a
loan to the company). Section 239 allows the liquidator to apply to court to have such
a preferment set aside. Insiders may also enter into extortionate credit arrangements
which bind the company. If this occurs within three years of the winding up, s.244
again provides for the liquidator to apply to the court to set the transaction aside.
The liquidator in a voluntary solvent liquidation, while he has the same duties of
good faith as a liquidator in a compulsory liquidation, has a very different role. In a
voluntary solvent liquidation the liquidator simply gathers together the assets, pays
the liabilities and distributes any surplus to the members. In a compulsory liquidation
the liquidator will also carry out this function but usually without any chance that
the asset value will exceed the company’s liabilities. Thus the liquidator’s main
function will be to determine the priority in which creditors will receive payment. The
liquidator will also police the years immediately before the insolvency for any irregular
transactions that might be challengeable.
Activity 17.3
Read Re Gray’s Inn Construction Co Ltd [1980] 1 WLR 711.
What factors should be taken into account by the court when deciding whether to
validate a post-winding up disposition of property?
Company Law 17 Liquidating the company page 211
Additionally, directors face the real threat that they may become personally liable
for the debts of the company should the civil or criminal penalties for fraudulent and
wrongful trading apply.
Fraudulent trading under s.213 IA 1986 occurs where any business of the company has
been carried on with intent to defraud creditors of the company or creditors of any other
person, or for any fraudulent purpose. The possibility of criminal liability for fraudulent
trading also arises under s.993 of the CA 2006, the wording of which is virtually identical
to s.213 IA. As a result of the linkage between the two sections the courts have set the
standard of proof for s.213 very high. This led to the introduction of the easier-to-prove
offence of wrongful trading in s.214. This provides that the liquidator must prove that,
at some time before the commencement of its winding up, a person was a director of
the company and he or she either knew, or ought to have concluded, that there was no
reasonable prospect that the company would avoid going into insolvent liquidation. The
director is then liable to contribute to the assets of the insolvent company, unless the
director, from the moment she knew (or ought to have concluded) that insolvency was
inevitable, took all the steps she ought to have taken to minimise the loss to creditors.
The onus of proving that the director took all the steps he or she ought to have taken is
on the director: Brooks v Armstrong [2015] EWHC 2289 (Ch).
Liquidators have often proved unwilling to bring claims under ss.213 and 214 IA 1986.
Now, s.246ZD IA1986 (introduced by the Small Business, Enterprise and Employment
Act 2015) permits liquidators to assign (and therefore, effectively, to sell) such causes
of action. Thus, a liquidator, who decides that they do not want to bring an action
against, say, a director of the company for wrongful trading, might nevertheless
choose to sell (and, thus, assign) the action to a third party, who would then be able
to bring the action instead. In this way, the liquidator gets at least some money for the
benefit of the creditors, and the risks associated with bringing the claim fall on the
purchasing third party. However, if the action is successful, the benefit will go to the
third party (rather than to the insolvent company for the benefit of all the creditors).
17.4 Reform
In Chapter 15 we considered the state of the case law suggesting that directors may
owe duties to creditors where the company is insolvent. In this regard you should note
s.172(3) of the CA 2006.
Activity 17.4
a. What are the three ways of bringing a company’s existence to an end?
c. What are the three grounds given in s.123(1) of the Insolvency Act 1986 for
deeming a company to be insolvent?
No feedback provided.
page 212 University of London
Further reading
¢ Cooke, T.E. and A. Hicks ‘Wrongful trading – predicting insolvency’ (1993) JBL 338.
¢ Oditah, F. ‘Assets and the treatment of claims in insolvency’ (1992) LQR 459.
¢ Report of the Review Committee on insolvency law and practice (Cork Committee
Report), Cmnd 8558.
¢ Van Zwieten, K. Goode on principles of corporate insolvency law. (London: Sweet &
Maxwell, 2018) fifth edition [ISBN 9780414066014].
u Section 245 IA 1986, whereby the liquidator of an insolvent company can avoid
floating charges (see Chapter 7 of this guide).
u Whether or not Helen is liable for wrongful trading – see IA 1985, s.214. Particular
reference should be made to Re Produce Marketing Consortium (No.2).
u You will need to discuss Salomon v Salomon [1897] AC 22 and Adams v Cape Industries
plc [1990] 2 WLR 657 (see Chapters 3 and 4) in order to explain that a parent
company (Pear Ltd) is not liable for the debts of its subsidiary (Sub Ltd). However,
if Pear Ltd is a shadow director of Sub Ltd (see Chapter 14 of this guide and
particularly Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v Deverall [2001] Ch 340), the
assets of Pear Ltd may be liquidated to meet the claims against Sub Ltd.
Need to revise first = There are one or two areas in this chapter I am unsure about and
need to revise before I go on to wider revision.
Need to study again = I found many or all of the principles outlined in this chapter
very difficult and need to go over them again before I move on.
If you ticked ‘need to revise first’, which sections of the chapter are you going to
revise?
Must Revision
revise done
17.4 Reform
Feedback to activities
Contents
Chapter 2 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 217
Chapter 3 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 217
Chapter 4 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 218
Chapter 5 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 218
Chapter 6 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 219
Chapter 7 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 220
Chapter 8 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 221
Chapter 9 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 221
Chapter 10 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 222
Chapter 11 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 223
Chapter 12 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 223
Chapter 13 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 224
Chapter 14 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 225
Chapter 15 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 226
Chapter 16 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 228
Chapter 17 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 228
page 216 University of London
Company Law Feedback to activities page 217
Chapter 2
Activity 2.1
No feedback provided.
Activity 2.2
No feedback provided.
Activity 2.3
No feedback provided.
Activity 2.4
No feedback provided.
Activity 2.5
Small businesses seem to have been particularly ill-served by the corporate form. At
the heart of this has been the difference between company law’s presumption that
the shareholders do not exercise day-to-day control of the business and the reality in
a small business that shareholders often do exercise day-to-day control. The elective
regime in the CA 1985 and Table A did try to simplify matters, but from the 1994
Freedman study we know that the only real advantage perceived by small businesses
from forming a company was the legitimacy it conferred on the business. The reform
process leading to the Companies Act 2006 identified this as a significant problem and
the 2006 Act attempts to redress this imbalance by removing the presumption that
ownership is separated from control in order to make the corporate form a better
model for small businesses.
Chapter 3
Activity 3.1
a. Mr Salomon’s personal liability for the debts of the business had changed
completely from unlimited liability as a sole trader to limited liability as a
shareholder in the company. Not only was Mr Salomon not liable for the debts
of the company but he had also, as managing director of the company granted
himself a secured charge over all the company’s assets. As a result if the company
failed not only would Mr Salomon have no liability for the debts of the company
but whatever assets were left would be claimed by him to pay off the company’s
debt to him.
b. There is really one central principle we can draw and two minor ones. The central
principle is that the company is a separate legal personality from its members and
therefore legally liable for its debts. This brings us to the minor principles. The first
being that once the technicalities of the Companies Act are complied with, a one-
person company can have the benefits of corporate legal personality and limited
liability. The second is that debentures can be used effectively to further shield
investors from losses.
c. This is really a matter of your own personal opinion. It is useful, however, to work
out what you think about this issue as it will help you deal with other areas of
company law where the Salomon decision has implications.
Activity 3.2
The key point here for your further understanding is that a share is in no way a
representation of the fractional value of the company’s property. The company as a
separate legal entity owns its own property and there is no legal connection between
a share in the company and the company’s property. That is the case even where
(as in Macaura and Lee) the shareholder owns all the shares. Shareholders generally
page 218 University of London
benefit from this (although not Mr Macaura) because it facilitates limited liability as
the company also owns its own debts (see also Woolfson v Strathclyde Regional Council
[1978] SC 90).
Chapter 4
Activity 4.1
No feedback provided.
Activity 4.2
You will have noted from your reading that from the 1960s until the 1990s there was
little consistency in the way the senior judiciary approached difficult cases where veil
lifting was an option. In 1985 the Court of Appeal in Re a Company [1985] BCLC 37, Ch.D
could draw on cases such as Wallersteiner v Moir [1974] 1 WLR 991 to argue that the
court can use its power to lift the corporate veil if it is necessary to achieve justice,
irrespective of the legal efficacy of the corporate structure under consideration.
Equally, four years later the Court of Appeal in National Dock Labour Board v Pinn &
Wheeler Ltd [1989] BCLC 647 could draw on cases such as Woolfson v Strathclyde RC
[1978] SLT 159 to argue for a strict interpretation of the Salomon principle. In short
there was little consistency or certainty in a very important area of company law.
This, it seems, is what the Court of Appeal seeks to address in Adams by narrowing the
categories of veil lifting and eliminating any concept of veil lifting in the interests of
justice. Instead, narrow categories have been created which are somewhat elusive.
It does indeed seem an overly cautious approach which does little to serve the
interests of justice. It is true that there have, since Adams, been cases – such as Ratiu v
Conway (2006) 1 All ER 571 – which suggested that the courts might be prepared to be
a bit more flexible in their interpretation of veil lifting issues. However, more recent
decisions, such as VTB Capital plc v Nutritek International Corp [2013] UKSC 5 and Petrodel
Resources Ltd v Prest [2013] UKSC 34 indicate the courts are following the hardline
approach of Adams.
Activity 4.3
Involuntary creditors (generally, in this context, the victims of personal injury by the
company) are in a vulnerable position when it comes to the application of the Salomon
principle. Normal creditors have at least a way of calculating the business risk and
charging more or monitoring in order to protect themselves. Involuntary creditors
cannot do so and so if, for example, a parent company remains protected from the
tortious activities of its subsidiary by the Salomon principle, involuntary creditors can
suffer badly.
Thankfully the courts seem to realise this and draw a subtle distinction between
commercial torts (negligent misstatement) where Salomon is strictly applied and
personal injury actions where a more flexible approach has been taken (see Chandler v
Cape plc [2012] EWCA Civ 525).
Chapter 5
Activity 5.1
The House of Lords reasoned that Erlanger, as representing the syndicate, had
undertaken to act on behalf of the yet unformed company. We saw from the brief
extract taken from Lord Cairns LC’s speech (para 4.2), that promoters possess
considerable power in determining the shape of a new company’s management and
supervision. Given the vulnerability of companies to abuse by their promoters, the
law has responded by holding them subject to the rigour of the core fiduciary duty
of loyalty. In effect, this prohibits promoters from placing themselves in a position
where their personal interests might conflict with those of the putative company.
Company Law Feedback to activities page 219
Thus, although promoters are not prohibited from selling their own property to the
company, they can only do so having made full disclosure to an independent board of
directors.
The House noted that there is nothing illegal in promoters selling their own property
to the company. However, it was stressed that the privilege of promoting a company
carries with it certain obligations. Promoters must appoint directors independent of
themselves who will be guardians of the company’s interests and who will protect the
shareholders. It need not be shown that the promoters were activated by fraudulent
motives – the fiduciary obligation will be broken even if there was ‘no intention to do
injustice’.
Activity 5.2
It is important to note that on the facts the promoters did not disclose to an
independent board of directors the profit they made on selling property owned by
them to the company. Lord Macnaghten, examining the conduct of Gluckstein, against
whom the action was brought, stressed that where a person who plays many parts
(i.e. being a promoter and then subsequently a director of the company) announces
to himself in one character what he has done in another character, this cannot be
described as disclosure in its proper sense. Indeed, there was no disclosure to the
intended shareholders at all; they were thus victims of a deception. Consequently,
where promoters make a secret profit during the promotion process they will be
jointly and severally liable to account for that profit to the company.
Activity 5.3
The policy underlying s.51 is to protect third parties who contracted in the belief that
they were dealing with registered companies. It makes pre-incorporation contracts
legally enforceable as personal contracts with promoters unless their personal liability
has been unequivocally excluded. The question of whether the promoter could enforce
the contract he is personally liable on has now been resolved by the Court of Appeal.
Chapter 6
Activity 6.1
No feedback provided.
Activity 6.2
No feedback provided.
Activity 6.3
By emphasising continual disclosure by listed companies, before and after listing, the
FCA and the LSE wish to achieve a number of aims.
u Where the company is listing for the first time disclosure provides the potential
investor with enough information to decide whether to invest or not.
u Where the company is already listed the disclosure regime is designed to ensure
that information is fairly distributed. If this was not the case large shareholders
would have greater access to information than small ones.
Activity 6.4
The answer to this question is not as straightforward as it may seem. There are those
who believe that insider dealing should be allowed as it enables insiders to send
signals about impending actions by companies much quicker than the disclosure
regime (see McVea (1995)). However, the prevailing view on why it is illegal is that
it is morally reprehensible and has very damaging effects on the investing public’s
confidence in the marketplace (see Campbell (1996) on why insider dealing is
outlawed).
page 220 University of London
Chapter 7
Activity 7.1
A floating charge is a creature of equity. It attaches to assets for the time being. The
hallmark of a floating charge is that the company can continue to deal with the
charged assets in the ordinary way without obtaining the chargee’s consent (Re
Yorkshire Woolcombers Association, Romer LJ). As its name suggests, it floats over the
class of assets charged and it will only attach as a fixed charge upon a crystallising
event such as a default in making a loan repayment.
Fixed chargees rank above floating chargees in respect of their priority in a liquidation
(see Chapter 17 of this module guide).
Floating charges may be challenged under the Insolvency Act 1986, s.245 (see Section
7.4 of this guide).
Activity 7.2
In Agnew Lord Millett explained that, unlike a floating charge where the company
continues to have the freedom to deal with the assets subject to the charge, a fixed
charge creates an immediate proprietary interest in the assets in favour of the holder
and therefore the company cannot deal with its assets without committing a breach
of the terms of the charge. He stressed that the classification of a security as a fixed
or floating charge was a matter of substance rather than drafting. If the chargor was
free to deal with the charged assets and could withdraw them from the ambit of the
charge without the consent of the chargee, then the charge must be viewed as a
floating charge. From the chargee’s perspective, if the charged assets were not under
its control, whereby it could prevent their dissipation without its consent, then the
charge cannot be viewed as a fixed charge. The critical test was whether the company
could continue receiving the book debts and to use them in its business and whether
it had the unrestricted right to deal with the proceeds of book debts paid into its
bank account. Note that Lord Millett states that Re New Bullas was wrongly decided
because the company was left in control of the process by which the book debts were
extinguished and replaced by different assets that were not the subject of a fixed
charge and were at the free disposal of the company. That was clearly inconsistent
with the nature of a fixed charge.
Activity 7.3
Section 874 of the CA 2006 states that certain charges will be void if not registered
within 21 days of their creation. Once registered the charge is valid from the date of
its creation. This gives rise to a 21-day invisibility period because whenever a person
checks the register it cannot be assumed that it is comprehensive because there may
be a charge for which the 21-day period is still running. Under the reform proposals
put forward by the CLRSG and the Law Commission the 21-day registration rule
would be dispensed with altogether. The period between creation and registration
would therefore cease to be relevant and, consequently, there would be no period of
invisibility. If adopted by the government, registration will no longer be a perfection
requirement but becomes a priority point as between competing chargees.
Company Law Feedback to activities page 221
Chapter 8
Activity 8.1
Lindley LJ stressed that notwithstanding Ooregum, there is no rule preventing a private
company purchasing property or services at any price it thinks proper. Thus, provided
a company acts honestly, a contract that provides for it to pay for goods or services by
fully paid-up shares is valid and binding both on the company and its creditors. Unless
the transaction can be attacked on the basis of, for example, fraud, the value of the
consideration received by the company in return for its shares cannot be enquired
into.
Activity 8.2
Lord Oliver rejected both the trial judge’s and the Court of Appeal’s view that larger
purpose could embrace avoiding liquidation and preserving the company’s goodwill
and the advantages of an established business. He noted that ‘purpose’ is in some
contexts a word of wide content and in attaching meaning to it for the purposes of
s.153 CA 1985 (now ss.678–682) the mischief against which s.151 (now s.678) seeks
to address must be borne in mind. It is therefore necessary to distinguish between
a purpose and the reason why a purpose is formed. ‘Larger’ does not mean more
important and ‘reason’ is not the same as ‘purpose’. On the facts of the case, Lord
Oliver concluded that the scheme was framed for the best of reasons ‘but to say that
the “larger purpose” of Brady’s financial assistance is to be found in the scheme of
reorganisation itself is to say only that the larger purpose was the acquisition of the
Brady shares on their behalf’. Larger purpose cannot be found in the benefits likely
to flow from the financial assistance and therefore the acquisition was not a mere
incident of the scheme devised to break the deadlock – it was ‘the essence of the
scheme itself’.
Chapter 9
Activity 9.1
a. No feedback provided.
b. The articles have historically assumed a situation where there are potentially
large numbers of people involved in a business venture. As such it provides a
very clear set of rules designed to allocate power between the board and the
general meeting, the board having responsibility for the day-to-day running of
the company and the general meeting having a supervisory function. This has
historically been both a strength and a weakness: a strength in that companies
that match the statutory presumption of large numbers of participants can
function effectively according to its division of powers; a weakness in that small
companies with few participants find its formal division of power inappropriate.
The supervisory role of the general meeting has also been diminished in very
large companies by shareholder apathy. The separating out of private and public
company articles, thus providing appropriate rules, should go some way to
resolving this weakness.
Activity 9.2
The s.33 contract is an unusual one but that alone does not explain why enforcing it
has been such a complex issue. It seems that all the enforcement issues touch upon a
central question in company law. That is, when can an individual member sue in the
context of a corporate activity? As we will see in Chapter 11 the general rule in Foss v
Harbottle (1843) 2 Hare 461 states that only the company itself can sue to right a wrong
to the company. When the judiciary have been deciding on s.33 issues this general
principle seems to loom large in their thoughts. As a result, some of the judiciary hold
firm to the belief that only the company’s organs can enforce the constitution. Others
have taken the view that to apply the general rule in Foss v Harbottle is inappropriate in
page 222 University of London
the context of s.33 as it would allow the majority to defeat the intention of the section,
which is to ensure the constitution is enforceable. Thus the individual shareholders
must be allowed to sue to enforce the constitution. While the CLRSG has recognised
that shareholders should be able to do so in its recommendations the CA 2006 has
done little to change the confusion.
Activity 9.3
a. The key advantage of a shareholders’ agreement is the certainty of enforcement
against the other parties to the agreement. The courts have continually shown that
they will enforce such agreements. A shareholder can also identify who he wishes
to contract with. For example, if he wishes to contract for other shareholders’ votes
he can identify a shareholder with the right percentage of votes and then enter
into an agreement with the other shareholder to exercise his votes in a particular
way. It is also private. The disadvantage of a shareholders’ agreement is that
once a party to a shareholders’ agreement sells his shares, the new owner has no
obligations under the shareholders’ agreement. This is in contrast to the way the
s.33 contract operates to bind future shareholders to the company’s constitution.
Adding the company to the shareholders’ agreement may also be a disadvantage
as there are statutory restrictions on its ability to contract.
Chapter 10
Activity 10.1
A share represents the member’s financial stake in the company as an association and
delimits the extent of the shareholder’s liability to the company. If the share is partly
paid the shareholder owes the company the difference between the price actually
paid and its nominal or par value plus any premium (see Chapter 8). In fact, nowadays
most shares are fully paid and so the holder has no further liability to contribute
to the company’s capital in the event of it becoming insolvent. Unlike partners in a
partnership, shareholders do not own corporate assets but rather ownership is vested
in the company itself: Macaura v Northern Assurance Co Ltd [1925] AC 619.
Activity 10.2
Where rights are annexed to particular shares, such as the right to receive dividends
at a specified rate or to receive a return of capital on winding up, they are class rights.
Obviously, if a company has issued only one class of shares – ordinary shares – there
are no class rights as such, only shareholder rights. In Cumbrian Newspapers Group Ltd
v Cumberland and Westmoreland Herald Newspapers and Printing Co Ltd [1987] Ch 1, Scott
J explained that where a company’s articles confer special rights on one or more of its
members in the capacity of member or shareholder the rights are class rights.
Activity 10.3
The significance of identifying a right as a ‘class right’ is that it cannot be varied by the
company without going through the procedure laid down in ss.630–634 CA 2006. A
proposal to vary class rights requires the consent of the class concerned. Class rights
therefore have greater protection than a right conferred just by the articles, because
the articles of association can be altered by a special resolution of the company (s.21
CA 2006).
Company Law Feedback to activities page 223
Chapter 11
Activity 11.1
No feedback provided.
Activity 11.2
The judge explained that if the substance of a complaint relates to something that
the majority of the company are entitled to do, or if the complaint concerns some
irregularity which the majority can legitimately do regularly – then there is no point in
suing, because ultimately a general meeting will be called at which the majority will
get its own way. Mellish LJ went on to add, however, that if the majority abuse their
powers and deprive the minority of their membership rights then the minority can sue
(see Chapter 9 of this guide and s.33 CA 2006, the statutory contract).
Activity 11.3
No feedback provided.
Activity 11.4
Briefly, the facts were that the company was insolvent due to a former director’s
breach of certain fiduciary duties not to compete or misuse confidential information.
Both duties were also express terms in a shareholders’ agreement to which the
defendant and claimant were parties. Although the company had initiated an action
against its former director, the administrative receivers discontinued it when the
defendant director applied for a security of costs order (i.e. a court order requiring the
company to demonstrate its ability to comply with the court’s decision on costs). In
effect, the defendant had, by his breach of duty, rendered the company incapable of
seeking legal redress against him because it lacked the means to fund the litigation.
The claimant sought to recover losses to the value of his shareholding, loss of
remuneration and loss of the value of loan stock. The issue for the court was whether
these were recoverable by him given the decision in Johnson v Gore Wood & Co. The
Court of Appeal, in placing considerable emphasis on the fact that the defendant’s
own wrongdoing had, in effect, disabled the company from suing him for damages,
found that this situation had not confronted the House of Lords in Johnson. Given that
the duties in question were expressly provided for in the shareholders’ agreement,
it was held that the claimant could pursue his claim for breach of the agreement
including his losses in respect of the value of his shareholding. The claims for loss of
remuneration and losses of capital and interest in respect of loans made by him to the
company did not, in any case, fall within reflective losses.
Chapter 12
Activity 12.1
The petitioners argued that the majority shareholders who were also the directors
had run three companies for their own benefit in that they claimed excessive
remuneration while paying low dividends to non-director shareholders. On the facts
the court considered that the petitioners had an arguable claim for relief under s.994
and that an order requiring the respondents to purchase the petitioners’ shares at a
fair price to be determined by the court would be more appropriate than destroying
the company by ordering its winding up.
page 224 University of London
Activity 12.2
The Court of Appeal held that the petitioner was not acting unreasonably in refusing to
accept a valuation of his shares by the company’s auditor, as provided in the articles,
given that his shares might be discounted in circumstances where a discount was
inappropriate. Balcombe LJ took the view that it would be just and equitable to ignore
the articles of association and allow the petition to proceed.
The converse of the decision in Virdi is that if an offer to purchase a petitioner’s shares
is fair, the petitioner will be acting unreasonably in seeking a winding up order rather
than seeking relief under s.994 CA 2006.
Activity 12.3
a. The evidence of the events giving rise to the claim spans a period of some 40
years. The petitions were brought against two associated companies, Macro
(Ipswich) Ltd and Earliba Finance Co Ltd. The petitioners alleged that the conduct
of the companies’ sole director, Mr. Thompson, (T), amounted to mismanagement
which unfairly prejudiced their interests as members. At the time of the petition
T was 83 years of age. He was described as a ‘patriarchal figure’ and engaged in
serious disagreements with the petitioners. It is noteworthy that of the three
petitioners, one was T’s son and the other two were his nephews. Central to
the mismanagement allegation was the complaint that T’s laissez faire style of
management left the companies vulnerable to the dishonesty and neglect of his
employees at Thompsons, an estate agency business which managed a substantial
number of rental properties owned by the company. The petitioners alleged that
Thompsons’ employees received secret commissions from builders, the costs of
which were passed on to the companies, and that they took ‘key’ money from new
tenants. It was successfully argued that the substantial financial losses suffered
were due to T’s mismanagement which unfairly prejudiced the petitioners.
b. Arden J stated that the question of whether any conduct was ‘unfairly prejudicial’
to the interests of the members has to be judged on an objective basis. First it has
to be determined whether the action of which the complaint is made is prejudicial
to members’ interests and, second, whether it is unfairly so.
c. In granting relief, the court took the view that rather than appoint the petitioners
to the board, which they had contended had been their expectation, T would be
ordered to purchase his son’s shares in Macro and Earliba.
Chapter 13
Activity 13.1
a. This case probably represents the harshest interpretation of the ultra vires doctrine
and perhaps illustrates best the danger ultra vires posed to companies. In this case
the company’s object was to acquire and develop a German patent for producing
coffee from dates. The company failed to get the German patent but obtained a
Swedish one instead. Despite the fact the company had a thriving business based
on the Swedish patent it was wound up by the court because it could not achieve
its strictly stated object.
b. Re Jon Beauforte and Re Introductions Ltd are further good examples of the problems
thrown up by the ultra vires issue and the need for legislative intervention.
Activity 13.2
The statutory reforms have the combined effect of making it easier for companies to
change their objects and of providing saving provisions for outsiders. This means that
there are very few remaining ultra vires problems. Most of the criticism of the reforms
has focused on the complexity of the solutions provided for what seems a relatively
simple problem. The CLRSG in its Final Report (July 2001) (para 9.10) recognised this
and recommended that any company formed under a new companies act should have
Company Law Feedback to activities page 225
unlimited capacity whether or not it chooses to have an objects clause. This was partly
implemented in the CA 2006.
Activity 13.3
No feedback provided.
Activity 13.4
Lord Hoffmann viewed the organic theory of the company as largely unhelpful. Instead
he considered that if a rule of law requires the court to determine the act or a state
of mind of a person, and that rule was intended to apply to companies as well, the
court can construct a special rule to test whether something can be attributed to
the company. For example the court may not be limited to looking at the directing
mind and will of the company but rather could also examine the state of mind of the
individual responsible for the matter at hand, no matter what level they were at in the
company.
Chapter 14
Activity 14.1
Buckley LJ explained that a person who holds all of the shares in a company is not
entitled to control its business. Directors are not the servants of shareholders and so
they are not bound to obey their directions given as individuals. Nor are directors the
agents of shareholders, bound to follow orders given by their principals. But where the
articles of association entrust directors with control of the company, such control can
only be removed by amending the articles in accordance with the statutory procedure
laid down by s.21 CA 2006 which requires a special resolution.
Activity 14.2
a. Article 90 provided that the board shall fix the annual remuneration of the
directors subject to the proviso that without the consent of the general meeting
such remuneration shall not exceed £100,000. Article 91 went on to confer on
the board the power to grant special remuneration, in addition to ordinary
remuneration, to any director who serves on any committee or who gives special
attention to the business of the company.
Activity 14.3
In reversing the trial judge’s finding that the respondents were not shadow directors
within the statutory definition, Morritt LJ, having reviewed the case law, laid down five
propositions.
i. The definition of a shadow director is not to be too narrowly construed given that
the purpose of the CDDA 1986 is to protect the public.
ii. Although the purpose of the legislation is to identify those, other than professional
advisers, with real influence in the corporate affairs of the company, it is not
necessary that such influence should be exercised over the whole field of its
corporate activities.
page 226 University of London
iii. Whether any particular communication (by words or conduct) from the alleged
shadow director is to be classified as a direction or instruction must be objectively
ascertained by the court in the light of all the evidence.
iv. Non-professional advice may come within the statutory description: the proviso
excepting advice given in a professional capacity assumes that advice generally is
or may be included. The concepts of ‘direction’ and ‘instruction’ do not exclude the
concept of ‘advice’ because all three share the common feature of ‘guidance’. The
critical factor is whether the person has real influence over the company’s affairs.
Activity 14.4
H, as a non-executive director of the company, was signatory to the company’s cheque
account. The company’s accounts, which H looked to when assessing the company’s
financial position, were prepared by professional accountants. The company went into
liquidation and the Secretary of State applied for an order under s.6 CDDA 1986 on the
†
basis that H had caused the company to operate a policy of not paying Crown monies † ‘Crown monies’: National
and had failed to keep himself properly informed of the company’s financial position. Insurance, PAYE (employees’
The grounds of the application were that beginning in June 1995 the company had income tax) and VAT (sales
ceased making National Insurance and PAYE payments. Also, the fact that the company tax) are all collected by
was in arrears of VAT was apparent in the management accounts for February and April companies on behalf of the
1995. It was alleged by the Secretary of State that H either knew the payments were government and paid over at
not being made or ought to have realised they were not being paid because he had set intervals.
not been requested to sign any cheques in respect of such payments. Further, H had
signed a number of cheques to pay another director’s son’s school fees thereby
allowing that director to breach his fiduciary duties by misusing company funds for his
own personal use. H had questioned the propriety of these payments but had been
assured by the accountants that they would be treated as part of that director’s
remuneration and would be properly reflected in the accounts as such.
Notwithstanding the accountant’s advice H had refused to sign additional cheques for
school fees and he had reported these payments to the board.
The Secretary of State’s allegation that H had failed to keep himself properly informed
of the company’s financial health was rejected. Merely being a signatory to the
company’s cheques was not sufficient to make the director personally responsible for
any policy of not paying Crown monies. H was entitled to rely on the assurances of the
accountant that the finances of the company were being properly managed. The court
held, taking H’s lack of experience in operating corporate finances together with his
non-executive status, that he was entitled to rely on the accountants to prepare the
accounts and on their assurances that the finances were being properly run. A cheque
signatory is not a Finance director and is therefore not expected to possess such
expertise. With respect to the cheques for school fees, H had acted on the advice of
the accountant and had reported the payments to the board.
Chapter 15
Activity 15.1
In Coleman v Myers the board of a family company had recommended to the
shareholders a takeover offer by a company controlled by one of the defendant
directors. The court held that in a small private company where the minority
shareholders habitually looked to the directors for advice on matters affecting
their interests, a duty of disclosure arose which placed the directors in a fiduciary
relationship with the shareholders. Woodhouse J stated that while it is impossible
Company Law Feedback to activities page 227
to lay down a general test as to when the fiduciary duty will arise, the following
factors will be material to the court’s determination: ‘dependence upon information
and advice, the existence of a relationship of confidence, the significance of some
particular transaction for the parties and… the extent of any positive action taken by
or on behalf of the director or directors to promote it’.
Activity 15.2
Lord Wilberforce stated that the court should:
i. consider the nature and scope of the power whose exercise is in question (in this
case, a power to issue shares)
iii. identify the substantial purpose for which it was actually exercised
iv. having given credit to the bona fide opinion of the directors and accepting their
judgment as to matters of management, determine whether the substantial
purpose (point iii, above) fell within a legitimate purpose determined according to
point ii, above.
If the substantial purpose is proper, the exercise of the power will not be set aside
because some other improper, but merely incidental, purpose was also achieved.
Activity 15.3
In Extrasure the directors had transferred company funds to another company in the
group to enable it to pay a creditor who had been pressing for payment. It was held that
the directors had acted without any honest belief that the transfer was in the interests
of the transferor company. The decision clearly illustrates that where the company is
one of a number in a group structure the directors must act bona fide in the interests of
that company. This is, after all, a straightforward application of the decision in Salomon
(see Chapter 3 of this guide) – that each company is a separate legal entity. There may
be situations, however, where acting in the interests of the group furthers the interests
of the particular company. For example, if a subsidiary company is owed money by its
parent company which is in financial difficulty the failure on the part of the directors to
take action to recover its debts may be in the interests of the subsidiary if, on balance,
it would be adversely affected by the liquidation of the parent company (see Nicholas v
Soundcraft Electronics Ltd [1993] BCLC 360).
Activity 15.4
All three of the directors (the executive and the two NEDs) were held liable to make
good the company’s losses and, while the judge noted the accountancy experience of
the NEDs, their professional qualifications were not material to his finding. The court
found the NEDs negligent in allowing Stebbings ‘to do as he pleased’. You should note
Foster J’s finding that the NEDs not only failed to exhibit the necessary skill and care in
the performance of their duties as directors, but that they failed to perform any duty
at all.
Activity 15.5
The directors were liable notwithstanding that:
As Lord Russell pointed out, the liability to account for any profit does not depend
upon fraud or absence of bona fides, ‘the liability arises from the mere fact of a
profit having, in the stated circumstances, been made’. The fact that the purchasers
of the company in effect got a reduction on the purchase price they had agreed
was irrelevant to the issue of liability. The decision illustrates that the liability of
directors in this respect is founded upon their trustee-like status – thus, like trustees,
page 228 University of London
directors will hold any secret profit (i.e. a profit not disclosed to and ratified by the
shareholders) on constructive trust.
The new board caused the company to bring the claim against its former directors.
As we saw in Chapter 11, the proper claimant rule requires the company to bring
proceedings for redress when a wrong has been committed against it.
Chapter 16
Activity 16.1
This is a good way for you to bring company law to life a bit more by thinking
about how various aspects of company law can be categorised. As a general guide,
mandatory company law rules, such as minimum capital requirements which override
any private agreements between contracting parties, sit easier with concession theory,
where state interference is more easily justifiable. Default rules, such as the articles of
association which apply in the absence of any agreement to the contrary, and enabling
rules, such as the company registration procedure, which provide a framework
for private parties to carry out certain functions sit easier with aggregate theory.
Additionally the common law’s protection of managerial discretion seems to have
some resonance with corporate realism. Company law, as you will note, is not in reality
dominated by any one theory but is a mix of all three.
Activity 16.2
This is a provocative statement and you must agree or disagree with it. Do not ‘sit
on the fence’ as a strong argument on one side or the other is the only way to deal
with it. The statement is interesting given that until recently it was generally agreed
that corporate governance had improved. Given the collapse of the financial services
sector in the UK and US over the course of 2008–9 corporate governance failure is once
more at the top of the reform agenda. While it is true that the committees have been
a great export success, with many countries adopting their recommendations, this
may not be the success it might have seemed. It now seems that the reason why these
recommendations are particularly palatable for the global business community is
that they are not particularly onerous. If you have not already read Dignam and Lowry,
Chapter 15, please do so now.
Chapter 17
Activity 17.1
The primary purpose of liquidation is to ensure, as far as possible, that all creditors
receive fair treatment, so if there is any scheme put in place which prevents this the
court will set it aside. Thus, the House of Lords held that the pari passu principle of
distribution (by which is meant that the free assets of the company are distributed pro
rata among unsecured creditors) is mandatory to the extent that a creditor cannot, by
contract, obtain a better position than that which the pari passu principle permits.
Activity 17.2
The objectives of the IA 1986, which implements the recommendations of the Report
of the Review Committee on Insolvency Law and Practice (Cork Committee Report,
1982 (Cmnd 8558)), are:
The compulsory winding up procedures and the powers of a liquidator and the court
to police the winding up seek to achieve these objectives.
Company law Feedback to activities page 229
Activity 17.3
Buckley LJ explained that there may be circumstances where it is beneficial, both to
the company and to the unsecured creditors, that the company be allowed to dispose
of some of its property after the petition has been presented. However, he stressed
that in considering whether to make a validating order the court should ensure that
the interests of the unsecured creditors are not prejudiced. Where an application is
made in respect of a specific transaction this may be susceptible of positive proof. But,
whether or not the company should be permitted to carry on business generally is
more speculative and will depend on whether a sale of the business as a going concern
will be more beneficial than a break-up realisation of the assets. Buckley LJ concluded
by saying that, although the court will be disinclined to consent to any transaction
which has the effect of preferring a pre-liquidation creditor, nevertheless ‘the court
would be inclined to validate a transaction which would increase, or has increased, the
value of the company’s assets, or which would preserve, or has preserved, the value
of the company’s assets from harm which would result from the company’s business
being paralysed…’
Activity 17.4
No feedback provided.
page 230 University of London
Notes