Financial Markets
Financial Markets
Financial Markets
1. Introduction
The recent crisis has given impetus not only to an intensive regulatory reform debate, but to a deeper discussion
on the role of financial systems in modern market economies and the role of financial innovation. While there
has been an array of regulatory reforms, most of these reforms are aimed at avoiding the past crisis and are
less forward looking than we would like them to be.
This paper takes stock of the existing literature on market failures in the financial system and the
consequent fragility risks, discusses possible policy responses and discusses new areas of research. It draws
on a very rich theoretical and empirical literature, partly motivated and informed by the recent crises. However,
the paper also takes a more principled stance on some of the challenges faced by policy makers and regulators.
While we discuss the main market failures in banking and how the recent regulatory reform address them, we
also note that financial innovation, the changing border between regulated and non-regulated institutions and
increasing complexity makes the optimal regulatory framework a moving target.
We conclude with a few main messages on regulatory reforms. While trying to flesh them out with
some detail, we purposefully keep them on a more general level. Specifically, based on the discussion
throughout the paper, we conclude that (i) a mix of complex and simple regulatory tools is needed, where the
former reflects and influences market players’ risk-taking decisions, while the latter are less likely to be
circumvented; (ii) macro-prudential has to complement micro-prudential regulation, as the stability of
individual financial institutions does not add up to systemic stability; (iii) a stronger focus on effective
resolution is necessary, not just to minimize the risk of contagion and reduce the impact of fragility on the real
economy but also to set desirable incentives ex-ante for all the agents operating in the financial systems
(institutions, investors and policy makers); and (iv) a dynamic approach to regulation is critical, especially
when it comes to defining the regulatory perimeter.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. The next section discusses market failures in the
financial system that lead to fragility. Section 3 discusses regulatory responses to these market failures, while
section 4 presents recent regulatory reforms in the wake of the Global Financial Crisis. Section 5 focuses on
1
Beck: Cass Business School, City University London and CEPR; Carletti: Bocconi University, CEPR and IGIER:
Goldstein: University of Pennsylvania. We would like to thank Andrea Amato Marco Forletta for excellent research
assistance.
1
the role of financial innovation both in deepening and completing financial markets but also creating financial
fragility. Section 6 is concerned with the regulatory perimeter. Section 7 draws policy conclusions from our
analysis, while section 8 concludes and looks forward to new research challenges.
2
Other related surveys on the origins of financial crises are provided by Bhattacharya and Thakor (1993), Gorton and
Winton (2003), Allen and Gale (2007, Chapter 3), Freixas and Rochet (2008), Rochet (2008), Allen, Babus, and Carletti
(2009), and Degryse, Ongena and Kim (2009).
4
for personal use or can ensure that loans are repaid. In this view, not only run crises can be efficient in that
they prevent the continuation of inefficient banks, but can also help provide bankers better incentives, thus
inducing better investment choices and better equilibrium allocations.
A final important remark is due here. Some people argue that modern banking systems have increased
in complexity over the last two decades and that as such the literature à la Diamond and Dybvig with its focus
on bank runs by retail depositors is no longer applicable to today’s financial institutions. We argue that this is
not the case. Despite running off-balance sheet vehicles or using various financial instruments to transfer credit
risk, banks remained equally sensitive to panics and runs as they were at the beginning of the previous century.
As Gorton (2008) points out, in the summer of 2007 holders of short-term liabilities refused to fund banks,
expecting losses on subprime and subprime-related securities. As in the classic panics of the 19th and early 20th
century, there were runs on banks. The difference is that modern runs typically involve the drying up of
liquidity in the short term capital markets (a wholesale run) instead of or in addition to depositor withdrawals.
This implies also a much stronger interplay between financial institutions and financial markets in modern
financial systems, as we shall stress later in the paper. In summary, problems of runs and panics, and how to
reduce their likelihood are important, as is the challenge of the regulatory perimeter, as funding and thus
sources of contagion can easily move outside the traditional banking system.
7
A freeze will also arise when there are strategic complementarities among banks in the decision to
provide credit. This has been analysed by Bebchuk and Goldstein (2011). Suppose that the success of banks’
projects depends on how many banks invest in these projects. This can occur due to network externalities in
the real economy, for example. Then, the expectation that other banks are not going to invest will make it
optimal for an individual bank not to invest, and so making this a self-fulfilling belief. Bebchuk and Goldstein
use this framework to compare various types of government policy aimed towards assisting the financial sector
and analyse which one is more effective under what circumstances.
8
In looking for contagious effects via direct linkages, early research by Allen and Gale (2000b) studies
how the banking system responds to liquidity shocks when banks exchange interbank deposits. The first
important result is that the connections created by swapping deposits allows banks to insure each other against
idiosyncratic liquidity shocks but, at the same time, they expose the system to contagion as soon as some
frictions such as a small aggregate liquidity shock emerge. The second important result is that the resiliency
of the system depends on the network structure of the interbank deposits. In particular, incomplete networks,
that is networks where all banks are connected but each bank exchanges deposits only with a group of other
banks, turn out to be more prone to contagion than complete structures. The intuition is that better connected
networks are more resilient since the proportion of the losses in one bank's portfolio is transferred to more
banks through interbank agreements. Similar results concerning the resiliency of more complete networks are
present also in Freixas, Parigi and Rochet (2000) and more recently in Acemoglou et al. (2015), where the
resiliency of different networks is analyzed also as a function of the size of shocks.
A related question within the literature analyzing banks’ direct exposures as sources of contagion is
the extent to which contagion can be due to coordination problems among depositors when they receive private
information about banks’ future fundamentals (Dasgupta, 2004) or to the complementarities among investors’
decisions to undertake the same investment projects (Leitner, 2005).
Another related question concerns the issue of network formation, that is how banks choose to connect
when they anticipate contagion risk. Based on the intuition as in Allen and Gale (2000b) that better connected
networks are more resilient to contagion, Babus (2014) predicts that banks form links with each other up to a
certain connectivity threshold above which contagion does not occur. In other words, banks choose the network
that prevents the risk of contagion, but, given that forming links is costly, they do not wish to go beyond such
a connectivity threshold.
Another channel of contagion based on direct linkages among banks is financial innovation and/or
financial markets. The idea is that financial products like for example credit risk transfer allow banks to insure
each other against certain risks but at the same time, when certain conditions realize, they may expose banks
to failures and contagion. For example, credit risk transfers are beneficial as a way to insure different
intermediaries or different sectors that are subject to independently distributed liquidity shocks. However,
when some intermediaries are forced to sell the assets for example for idiosyncratic liquidity reasons and there
is price volatility and fire sales in some states of the world, then the presence of credit risk transfers can be
detrimental as they can generate contagion across intermediaries or sectors (Allen and Carletti, 2006). Similar
results on the benefits but also the risks of financial innovations are obtained by Parlour and Winton (2008)
and Shin (2009), among others.
The second approach to modeling contagion focuses on indirect balance-sheet linkages. One possible
contagion mechanism works through portfolio readjustments (Lagunoff and Schreft, 2001; de Vries, 2005;
Cifuentes, Ferrucci, and Shin, 2005). The basic idea is that the return of a bank’s portfolio depends on the
portfolio allocations of other banks. This implies that the decision of some banks to readjust their portfolios in
9
response to the realization of some shocks produces negative externalities in that it reduces the returns of other
banks’ portfolios. This may induce other banks to abandon the investments as well either gradually as losses
propagate through the system or more rapidly in an attempt to avoid contagion of losses in the future.
Portfolio readjustments can also generate contagion if they happen at the level of investors holding
claims on different banks. Such mechanisms have been analyzed by Kodres and Pritsker (2002), Goldstein and
Pauzner (2004) and others. In Goldstein and Pauzner (2004), for example, investors hold deposits in two
different banks. The realization of a crisis in one bank reduces their wealth, and so makes them more risk
averse (under the common assumption of a decreasing absolute risk aversion utility function). Then, they are
more likely to run in the other bank, generating the contagion between the two banks.
Besides the theoretical investigations, there has been a substantial interest in looking for evidence of
contagion. Most studies focus on contagion from direct linkages among banks. Typically, they estimate
bilateral credit relationships for different banking systems and then test the stability of the system, mostly
focusing on the interbank market, by simulating the breakdown of a single bank. Studies in this category
include Upper and Worms (2004) on the German banking system, Cocco, Gomes, and Martins (2009) on
Portugal, Furfine (2003) on the US, Boss, Elsinger, Thurner, and Summer (2004) on Austria, and Degryse and
Nguyen (2007) on Belgium. These papers find that the banking systems demonstrate high resilience, even to
large shocks. For instance, simulations of the worst case scenarios for German system show the failure of a
single bank could lead to the breakdown of up to 15% of the banking sector based on assets. Since these results
depend heavily on how the linkages between banks are estimated and they abstract from any type of behavioral
feedback (Upper 2006), it is likely that they provide downward bias estimator of contagious outcomes.
Other studies like Mistrulli (2011) or Iyer and Peydró-Alcalde (2011) base their analyses on actual
data. For example, the former analyzes the possibility of contagion within the Italian interbank market using
banks’ actual bilateral exposures, while the latter finds that following the failure of a large Indian bank, banks
with higher interbank exposure to the failed bank experience higher deposit withdrawals.
Turning to the empirical investigation of contagion through indirect connections between financial
institutions, Adrian and Brunnermeier (2011) propose a new measure for systemic risk, the so-called covar,
that is conditional on an institution (or the whole financial sector) being under distress. As example of this type
of contagion is found in Jorion and Zhang (2009), who find evidence of credit contagion via counterparty
effects. The discussion in this and the previous sub-section underline that a proper risk analysis in finance has
to look beyond the stability of individual institutions towards systemic risk. While so far we have discussed
primarily the cross-sectional dimension of systemic risk, we now turn to the time-series dimensions of this
phenomenon.
11
problem and lead to a bubble in asset prices. When the bubble bursts, either because returns are low or because
the central bank tightens credit, there is a financial crisis.
There has been a substantial literature attempting to understand how shocks, and in particular negative
shocks, are amplified through the system and generate negative bubbles. Some theories rely on the so-called
financial accelerator (Bernanke and Gertler, 1989; Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist (1996). The idea is that
negative shocks to borrowers’ wealth are amplified because of the presence of asymmetric information and of
an agency problem between borrowers and lenders. In a similar spirit but focusing on the role of collateral,
Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) suggest that a shock that lower asset prices can lead to a crisis. The reason is that
by lowering the value of collateral, lower asset prices imply less borrowing and thus further reduction in asset
prices and borrowing capacity, and so on in a downward spiral. Geanakoplos (1997, 2003, 2009) and Fostel
and Geanakoplos (2008) push the analyses further by investigating the effect of asset prices on collateral value
and borrowing capacity in more general equilibrium settings.
12
With this in mind, we now review the main regulatory tools. Our focus is on capital requirements, as
they have been the core of financial regulation, also in the aftermath of the financial crisis. To complement
this, we will discuss, albeit briefly, liquidity requirements and safety nets, that is central bank liquidity
provision and deposit insurance in the broader form of government guarantees and bailouts. In reviewing the
academic literature below, we maintain the view that banking regulation should be structured so to solve the
market failures in the financial system, which we described in the previous section. This means, for example,
that capital regulation should be designed to minimize the risk of banks’ failures and contagion, while liquidity
requirements should be set so to reduce the risk of panics and forced asset sales with consequent fire sales on
financial markets.
3.1 Capital regulation
In general, capital solves various roles. First, it absorbs unanticipated losses and thus reduces the risk
of insolvency and contagion. The idea is capital ratios represent a cushion to absorb losses, thus reducing the
likelihood of failure Second, capital protects uninsured depositors and hence maintains confidence in the
financial system. Third, capital protects bondholders and creditors in the event of insolvency and liquidation.
It protects deposit insurance and taxpayers. Finally, it provides incentives to bank managers and shareholders.
Despite these numerous roles, the academic literature has mostly focused on capital as a way to reduce
the problem of limited liability and excessive risk taking due to high leverage and the (implicit or explicit)
support of financial institutions through widespread deposit insurance and bailouts. The main idea behind
capital regulation is then that larger capital ratios reduce bank risk taking. The intuition is simple: With more
stake at risk, bankers should have fewer incentives to take on risk.
The effects of capital on banks’ risk taking have been discussed in the literature since the 1970s. Earlier
papers (e.g., Kareken and Wallace, 1978; Kahane, 1977, but also, more recently, Boot and Boot and
Greenbaum, 1993, and Hellman, Murdock and Stiglitz, 2000) were quite negative on the benefits of capital
requirements showing that they were either ineffective in preventive in risk taking or even counter-productive
inducing bankers to choose riskier assets.
Other, more recent works, instead, support a more positive capital for capital, justifying capital
regulation as needed to offset moral hazard from deposit insurance. The general idea is that because banks
have access to low cost funds guaranteed by the government, they have an incentive to take significant risks.
If the risks pay off they receive the upside, while if they do not the losses are born by the government. Capital
regulation that ensures shareholders will lose significantly if losses are incurred is needed to offset this
incentive for banks to take risks. One way of capturing this is to model the effects of capital on banks’
monitoring incentives (Holmstrom and Tirole, 1997). Using this framework, Dell’Ariccia and Marquez (2006)
and Allen, Carletti and Marquez (2010) analyze how the relationship between capital and banks’ incentives to
monitor changes depending on the presence and design of deposit insurance, credit market competition etc.
Overall, this literature supports a positive role of capital and thus of capital regulation in ameliorating banks’
incentives to monitor borrowers and thus reducing the credit risk of individual banks.
13
As mentioned above, another rationale for capital regulation is the prevention of contagion and
systemic risk. Contagion is the market failure that central banks often use to justify intervention, as, for
example, in the case of the arranged takeover of Bear Stearns in March 2008, as it was publicly stressed
(Bernanke, 2008). Yet, the theory of capital as a way to reduce systemic risk is still in its infancy, given the
focus till recently on the microprudential role of capital regulation. Going forward, it is essential to develop
new theories of capital regulation based on preventing contagion and systemic risk. In general, as we argue
also further below, there is the need of a deeper analysis of the appropriate design of macroprudential
regulation. Attempts in this direction can be found in Acharya (2009) and Rochet (2004), but much more work
is needed in this area.
One of the major problems in designing capital regulation is in modeling the costs of equity finance
for financial institutions. The literature assumes typically that equity is more costly than other forms of finance
(see, for example, Gorton and Winton, 2003). This also justifies the need for capital regulation as in its absence,
banks would simply minimize their capital holdings and hold more debt. However, it is not at all clear what
this higher cost is due to. One simple answer is that it is privately more costly because in many countries debt
interest is tax deductible at the corporate level but dividends are not. One important shortcoming of this
explanation though is that it does not explain the difference in capital holdings across industries. Simple
evidence shows indeed that non-financial firms hold around 30-40% of their liabilities in the form of capital
whereas the financial firms operate with approx. 10% of capital on average in normal times (Flannery and
Rangan, 2008).
Given this, another, more plausible, explanation is that debt is implicitly subsidized in the financial
industry through government guarantees and bailouts (see also Admati et al., 2010). If this is the case, the
removal of the public guarantees and the design of clear resolution schemes would enhance financial stability
substantially as it would improve banks’ incentives to take risks and induce higher capital holdings. A more
recent explanation for the higher cost of equity capital in banks is based on the market segmentation between
deposits and capital and the positive role of capital as a way to reduce the bankruptcy costs of deposit taking
institutions (Allen et al., 2015).
Another important issue in current capital regulation is that it is based on accounting book values rather
than market values. The recent crisis has clearly showed that book values have important shortcomings, in
particular as they may prevent to discover insolvency risks at an early stage, thus preventing early intervention
at troublesome banks. Theoretically, it is unclear as to whether capital regulation should be based entirely on
accounting book values and not at all on market values. A related literature is the one on the use of mark-to-
market accounting for financial institutions (e.g., O’Hara, 1993; Allen and Carletti, 2008; Plantin, Sapra, and
Shin, 2008, Heaton, Lucas and McDonald, 2010). This literature highlights the trade-off involved. Valuing
banks’ assets at market prices has the advantage of reflecting the true value of their balance sheets. However,
if markets are flawed it may also lead to important inefficiencies in terms of increased price volatility and
14
contagion, suboptimal real decisions and reduced liquidity creation. Such inefficiencies should be taken into
account in investigating the extent to which capital regulation should be based on market capital.
3.2 Liquidity requirements
Whereas the literature on capital regulation, albeit focused on the microprudential role of capital, is
abundant, the one on liquidity requirements has just started. One explanation is perhaps the absence of liquidity
requirements as regulatory tool till the recent new Basel III accord.
Although the role of liquidity requirements still need to be investigated in detail, liquidity ratios should
aim at reducing the occurrence of panics and the occurrence of fire sales and mispricing of assets. To this end,
works on the role of liquidity regulation should focus on analyzing its effects on banks' incentives to take
risk/excessive maturity transformation, premature sale of long term assets and asset prices and depositors'
incentives to withdrawals.
One way of thinking of these effects is going back to the frameworks described above where banks
operate as providers of liquidity insurance and expose themselves to maturity transformation by choosing the
appropriate mix of long and short term assets they want to invest in. (Diamond and Dybvig, 1983; Goldstein
and Pauszner, 2005; etc.). Introducing liquidity requirements in these frameworks forces banks to increase the
investment in the short term asset relative to what they would choose in the absence of regulation, thus inducing
a reduction in the maturity transformation they operate. This will also possibly lead them to reduce strategic
complementarities and collective moral hazard, thus reducing also the need for public intervention ex post
(Fahri and Tirole, 2012). In terms of the premature sale of long term assets and asset prices, the introduction
of liquidity requirements should allow banks to better deal with liquidity shocks, thus leading to fewer assets
on sale and a lower likelihood of fire sales. This in turn should benefit the banking system as a whole as it
would lead to fewer bank failures and thus lower propagation of losses through the system.
What seems to be more unclear is the effect of liquidity requirements on the behavior of banks’
depositors and thus on the probability of occurrence of panic and fundamental driven crises. The reason is as
follows. On the one hand, as already mentioned, liquidity requirements reduce the premature liquidation (or
sale) of the long term assets, thus reducing depositors’ incentives to run out of coordination problems and
panics. However, by forcing banks to invest more in shorter term assets, which are typically less profitable
than longer term assets, liquidity requirements also reduce banks’ profitability in the longer run. This in turn
may lead depositors and investors more generally to run at the bank out of worries of inadequate resources of
the bank in the long run,that is out of fundamental driven reasons. Given these two contrasting effects, the
overall implications of liquidity regulation on bank stability is unclear. Much more work is needed in this
direction in the upcoming years, also looking at the interaction between capital and liquidity requirements.
17
Our focus is on the initiatives affecting the European regulatory framework, although some
of these reforms such as the new capital rules, are transpositions at the European levels of more
international guidelines and accords.
3
There has been an intense debate on the coordination between the provisions concerning bail-in in the BRRD directive
and those contained in the new state aid regulation. On this matter, see Kerle (2014) and Micossi, Bruzzone and
Cassella (2014).
21
The SRB is in charge of the SRF, a pool of money constituted from contributions from all
banks in the participating Member States. The SRF has a target level of €55 billion (approx. 1% of
all banks’ assets of participating Member States) but has the possibility to borrow from the markets
if decided by the Board. It will reach the target level over 8 years.
The resolution process is quite complicated and includes various institutions. The decision to
resolve a bank will in most cases start with the ECB notifying that a bank is failing to the Board, the
Commission, and the relevant national resolution authorities. The Board will then adopt a resolution
scheme including the relevant resolution tools and any use of the Fund. Before the Board adopts its
decision, the Commission has to assess its compliance with State aid rules and can endorse or object
to the resolution scheme. In case of disagreement between the Commission and the SRB, the Council
will also be called to intervene. The approved resolution scheme will then be implemented by the
national resolution authorities, in accordance with national law including relevant provisions
transposing the Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive.
4.3.Activity restrictions
Another important set of reforms or proposal for reforms include activity, size and bonuses
restrictions. For sake of brevity, we describe them very briefly here and refer to Allen, Beck and
Carletti (2014) for a more detailed discussion.
The proposals on activity restrictions in Europe are contained in two reports, the Vickers
report in the UK and the Liikanen report in Europe. Both the Vickers proposal and the Liikanen
proposal aim at making the banking groups safer and less connected to trading activities so as to
reduce the burden on taxpayers. However, the two approaches present significant differences. The
Vickers approach suggests ring-fencing essential banking activities that may need government
support in the event of a crisis. In contrast, the Liikanen approach suggests isolating in a separate
subsidiary those activities that will not receive government support in the event of a crisis but that
will rather be bailed-in. Moreover, the two proposals differ in terms of what activities have to be
separated/ring-fenced. For example, deposits from and loans to large corporations have to be given
permission not to be ring-fenced according to the Vickers approach while they do not have to be
separated according to the Liikanen approach. Also, trading activities need to be separated under the
Liikanen approach only if they amount to a significant share of a bank’s business, while they are
never permitted within the ring-fence in the Vickers approach. 4
4
Table 1 compares in more detail the Vickers and the Liikanen reports, also with the Volcker rule in the US.
22
To date, no structural reforms have been formally introduced in Europe. Following the
Liikanen report, in January 2014 the Commission has put forth a proposal for a regulation on
structural reforms but this has not yet been approved. Some individual countries, on the hand, have
been moving ahead with their national approaches, including the UK.
5. The traditional financial system in Europe – where do European financial systems stand six
years after the Global Financial Crisis
While not synchronized or similarly pronounced across all European countries, large parts of the
European Union and the Eurozone went through a credit bubble in the first decade of the 21st century,
followed by a bust in the wake of the Global Financial Crisis. Unlike the U.S., most European
countries have been very slowly in recognizing losses incurred during the crisis and forcing or
supporting banks in their recapitalization. The sluggish credit recovery over the past years has been
the backdrop on which the ECB has moved towards quantitative easing, though much later than other
leading economies, including the U.S, UK and even Japan, a delay partly explained by political
considerations.
There is an ongoing debate to which extent the current credit crisis reflects supply or demand
side constraints. Giovannini et al. (2015) report that there is no evidence for a shortage of long-term
finance in Europe, though there is large cross-country variation. Also, recent increases in long-term
funding have been more on the debt side, in the form of bank lending and corporate bonds. On the
other hand, initial public offerings (IPO) have declined in recent years, while secondary public
offerings (SPO) have increased. The recent crises have resulted in both supply constraints as well as
demand reduction in the bank lending market. In spite of recapitalization by governments and through
private markets and investors, Europe’s banking system continues in a rather weak position, at least
compared to the U.S. banking system.
24
Figure 1: The Size of Venture Capital and Private Equity Industries in the US and European
Union
1.2
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
2012 2013 2014
Source: Figures for private equity are taken from the Zephyr Global Private Equity Annual Reports 2013-2014 published
by BvD. Venture capita data are from Dow Jones VentureSource Report 2014. GDP data are from OECD
Figure 3: Number of subsidiaries across different financial segments for largest foreign banks
in the US
Not just financial institutions, but also the regulatory framework has become more and more
complex over the past decade, with the Basel II capital regime being a watershed. Hakenes and
Schnabel (2014) use a theoretical model to show that it is in banks’ interest to push complex
regulation, in what they refer to as regulatory capture by sophistication. Specifically, in a world where
regulators are less well paid than bankers and with a variation in skills across regulators, regulators
might be swayed to rubber-stamp banks’ risk models in order to not have to admit that they do not
understand these risk models. This allows banks to hold less capital than required. This trend towards
26
sophistication and the resultant capture has been exacerbated by the Basel II regulatory framework,
which allowed the use of banks’ internal risk model to compute risk weights for different asset classes.
However, this phenomenon becomes more critical if the regulator has discretionary power, such as
under pillar II of Basel II. It is important to note that this type of regulatory capture by sophistication
is somewhat different from the regulatory capture due to conflict of interest, social connection
(rotating door), political interference or lobbying activity by banks.
Related with the trend towards complexity is the increasing globalization of banks, with the
leading global banks being active across a large number of regions and countries. In addition, over
the past decade there has been a trend towards regional banks, i.e. Latin American and African banks
reaching out across their respective regions. This poses additional challenges for supervisors in terms
of cooperation across borders. While this topic is somewhat outside the current survey, it is important
to be flagged.
Financial innovation is a very broad concept, but can be generally defined as new financial products
and services, new financial intermediaries or markets, and new delivery channels.5 Examples abound,
ranging from the introduction of the ATM/cash machine in the 1970s and mobile phone based
financial services in the 2000s, over the introduction of money market funds as alternative to bank
deposits, the emergence of venture capital fund to structured financial products. The above mentioned
intermediation platforms of peer-to-peer lending and crowdfunding also fall under the category of
financial innovation. Goetz and Rouwenhorst (2005) identify 19 major financial innovations,
grouped into innovations that (i) facilitate the transfer of value through time (e.g. savings accounts),
(ii) enhance the ability to contract on future values (e.g. venture capitalists) and (iii) increase the
negotiability of contracts (e.g.securitization).
The traditional innovation-growth view posits that financial innovations help reduce agency
costs, facilitate risk sharing, complete the market, and ultimately improve allocative efficiency and
economic growth, thus focusing on the bright side of financial innovation. Laeven, Levine and
Michalopoulos (2015) quote several historical examples where financial innovation has been critical
5
One can also refer to this as production, process and organizational innovation.
27
in allowing major technological innovation to be adopted on a broad scale. For example, specialized
investment banks emerged to facilitate the construction of vast railroad networks in the 19th and 20th
centuries across North America and Europe, screening and monitoring borrowers on behalf of
disperse and distant investors. In the second half of the 20th century, venture capital funds arose to
finance IT start-ups, characterized by limited if any tangible assets that could be used as collateral
and thus requiring patient investment capital and close screening and monitoring as well as technical
advice. And in recent decades, financial innovation has supported bio technology. Lerner and Tufano
(2011) undertake a counterfactual exercise, a “counterfactual historiography”, comparing real
development with hypothetical development in world without (i) venture capital and private equity,
(ii) mutual funds and exchange-traded funds and (iii) securitization. Their analysis points to overall
positive effects of these innovation that would not necessarily have been achieved with alternative
arrangements. There is also empirical evidence for the importance of both financial deepening for
innovation (Amore et al., 2013; Chava et al., 2013) as well as of financial innovation for economic
growth (Laeven et al., 2015). Beck et al. (2012) show that countries with higher innovative activity
in the banking system experience faster growth in industries with higher needs for external finance
and higher growth opportunities.
The innovation-fragility view, on the other hand, focuses on the “dark” side and has identified
financial innovations as the root cause of the recent Global Financial Crisis, by leading to an
unprecedented credit expansion that helped feed the boom and subsequent bust in housing prices
(Brunnermeier, 2009), by engineering securities perceived to be safe but exposed to neglected risks
(Gennaioli, Shleifer and Vishny, 2012), and by helping banks and investment banks design structured
products to exploit investors’ misunderstandings of financial markets (Henderson and Pearson, 2011).
Several authors have pointed to distortions introduced by financial innovations, such as securitization
and new derivative securities, and how they have contributed to aggressive risk taking, reduction in
lending standards and thus fragility (e.g., Keys et al., 2010; Dell’Ariccia, Igan and Laeven, 2008;
Rajan, 2006
Financial innovation has been often used for purposes of regulatory arbitrage or to get around
regulatory restrictions. For example, Euro-accounts were established in reaction to Regulation Q,
which prohibited payment of interest on sight accounts in the U.S. Another example is the use of
Special Purpose Vehicles (SPV), investment trusts to which bank off-loaded loan portfolios, in return
for securities issued by the SPV and often rated AAA. In total, banks set up conduits to securitize
assets worth $ 1.3 trillion, insuring the securitized assets with explicit guarantees (Acharya, Schnabl
and Suarez, 2011). The objective of such securitization operation was to save capital, as guarantees
28
were structured in a way to reduce regulatory capital requirements. Acharya, Schnabl and Suarez
(2011) show that the losses on these conduits had to be taken back on banks’ balance sheets during
the crisis as consequence of wholesale runs.
Taking a broader view, Freixas, Laeven and Peydro (2015) argue that financial innovation is
one of the key drivers of systemic risk. Financial innovation allowing for better risk management
and sharing might reduce idiosyncratic risk, i.e. the risk of individual financial institutions considered
on a stand-alone basis, while at the same time increase systemic risk as larger part of the financial
system are exposed to the same systematic or aggregate risk and/or increasing the appetite and
capacity to take on risk. This is confirmed by Wagner (2010) who shows theoretically that as banks
become more similar due to diversification of risks, systemic risk increases.
The use of financial innovation on the bank-level has provided somewhat contradictory
results. On the one side, Norden, Silva Buston and Wagner (2014) show that the use of credit
derivatives reduced corporate loan spreads in the U.S., suggesting that banks passed on benefits of
risk management benefits. The benefits were even stronger during the recent crisis, when banks with
higher holdings of such derivative positions cut lending by less. On the other hand, Nijskens and
Wagner (2011) show that even before the crisis the share price beta of banks trading credit default
swaps (CDS) or issuing collateralized loan obligations (CLOs) increased suggesting higher risk from
the use of these risk management tools. This effect is driven by higher correlation with the market
while volatility actually decreases, suggesting that while these risk management tools serve to reduce
idiosyncratic bank risk they actually increase systemic risk.
Financial innovation might also affect the incentives of financial intermediaries. Wagner
(2007 a, b) shows that financial innovation that reduces asymmetric information can actually increase
risk-taking due to agency problems between bank owners and managers, or because of lower costs of
fragility. Keys et al. (2011), for example, show how reduced incentives to screen borrowers in the
U.S. due to the possibility of being able to securitizing loans contributed to higher loan losses.
In summary, both theory and empirical work has shown that financial innovation can bring
benefits but also increased risks both by the design of products but also through changing incentives.
While financial innovation is thus critical for the development of the financial system, it also poses
significant challenges for regulators. Regulatory frameworks are designed in light of existing
products and providers. They are mostly rule-based (and intermediary-based), e.g. for liquidity
requirements only specific clearly defined assets are considered. Rule-based regulatory regimes have
the clear advantage of providing certainty, and reduce room for supervisory overreach. They also
guarantee a certain independence for supervisors, given the limited degree of freedom for
29
interpretation. On the other hand, rule-based regulatory systems are less adequate in reacting to new
products and markets as existing rules do not refer to them. A principle-based regime is more flexible
in this context, but might be more open to arbitrage possibilities.
While regulation might give rise to certain financial innovations, regulators in turn will try to
catch up with innovation, a process that Kane (1977) refers to regulatory dialectic. Compared to the
financial sector, regulators are at a disadvantage, as regulation (especially rule-based regulation)
refers to specific institutions, products and markets. Risk-based supervision would imply regulating
and supervising all financial intermediaries that offer the same products under the same regime. For
example, all institutions offering deposit services should be subject to the same prudential regulation.
We will discuss this issue in more detail in the next section.
30
To a large extent, other financial entities operating in financial markets, such as mutual funds,
hedge funds, money-market funds, etc. have been left unattended by financial-stability regulation.
The idea was that they are different than banks, as they do not have the peculiar structure of demand
deposit contracts and they do not have the system of vast connections among institutions, and so they
do not put the system at a risk. A common theme is that prices should be allowed to fluctuate, people
should be allowed to take risk, and institutions should be allowed to fail as long as there is no severe
externality that they do not internalize which might threaten the system. This line of thinking,
however, has proven to be incomplete.
Over the years, other financial institutions have started taking on bank-like features. Perhaps
the most striking example is the Long Term Capital Management (LTCM) hedge fund which failed
in 1998. LTCM exposed itself to huge leverage in an attempt to enhance returns to shareholders.
Doing that, it also generated large risks, and indeed collapsed in 1998. Hence, the thinking that
deposit-type risk does not exist in such institutions was shown incorrect. Moreover, after the fact,
people have realized that LTCM was also at the heart of a system of vast connections to other
institutions, and so its failure put the system at the risk of systemic failure. Indeed, it took quite a bit
of effort from the side of US regulators to have all counterparties agree to a resolution that stabilized
the system. The failure of Lehmann Brothers in 2008, although different in many respects, carried
some similar lessons.
More generally, the fact that banks have been so heavily regulated has limited their ability to
provide credit and liquidity and led to the emergence of other institutions that had many features
similar to banks, but were not treated like banks or regulated like banks. The common name for such
institutions is “shadow banking”, for which the definition is somewhat unclear. It probably covers
everything that is not a traditional bank. Indeed, one of the key lessons from the last crisis is that
shadow banking has to be looked at and that the regulation of the financial system has to take an
integrative approach and consider the potential fragility of banks alongside shadow banks and not
just banks in isolation. The idea is that if you regulate only banks, other institutions will emerge to
replace them and take over their functions, and so it is important to prevent such a regulatory arbitrage
and regulate the system with a holistic view.
A case in point is the money-market mutual funds. These are funds that invest in bonds,
treasuries, and other such assets and have a liability structure that is very similar to banks.
Specifically, they promise investors the right to withdraw a fixed amount. This is known as a fixed
net asset value (NAV), whereby the net asset value promised to investors upon withdrawal is fixed.
Due to this feature, investors have been treating their claims in money-market funds as very safe and
31
used them like money for different transactions. This entity emerged to a large extent as a response
to regulation in the banking system: the limitations on the returns that banks can offer led investors
to demand this kind of vehicle that will offer a bank-like claim with a higher return. Regulation did
not treat money-market funds like banks and so they were free to do many of the things banks could
not do.
Over the years, money market funds did not experience many problems and the perception
that they are safe was validated in reality. But, during the years leading to the crisis, they started
investing in riskier securities, exposing themselves to the mismatch between very liquid liabilities
and less liquid assets, just like banks. This whole structure led to a crisis in the fall of 2008 when,
following the collapse of Lehmann Brothers, one money market fund could not honor its liabilities to
investors (this is known as ‘breaking the buck’). This almost unprecedented event has led to massive
runs in the industry across other money market funds. (For empirical evidence, see Schmidt,
Timmerman, and Wermers (2014) and for a discussion on regulatory implications Rosengreen
(2014)).
The events in the money-market funds led regulators in the US and other countries to realize
that regulation should not target just entities called banks, but more broadly other entities that look
like banks or offer services like banks. One of the conclusions has been that the fixed-NAV structure
is not sustainable and money market funds are thus moving into a structure of floating-NAV which
resembles the one used in other mutual funds. According to this structure, investors are not promised
a fixed amount when they withdraw, but rather the market value of their underlying assets as of the
day of redemption. This will surely decrease the extent to which money market funds look like banks
and the extent to which they should be regulated like banks.
However, the shift to a model of floating NAV does not prevent runs and panics. Recall that
runs are generated by the presence of a first mover advantage. Investors want to demand their money
when they think others will do so if the liability structure is such that the redemption by some investors
reduces the value to those who do not redeem. This is certainly the case with fixed deposits or money
market funds that have fixed NAV: Investors withdrawing early get the fixed amount and this reduces
whatever is left to pay to the remaining investors. But, Chen, Goldstein, and Jiang (2010) have
provided empirical evidence that such first-mover advantage exists also in floating-NAV funds.
The idea is that when investors take their money out of a mutual fund, they get the last updated
market value of the underlying assets. However, following large redemptions, the fund will have to
take actions and adjust the portfolio in the following days and this will hurt the value that remaining
investors can get. The problem is particularly severe in funds that hold illiquid assets. These are the
32
funds that provide the liquidity transformation (in the spirit of banks) and for them the costs of
portfolio adjustments following redemptions will be more pronounced. Indeed, Chen, Goldstein, and
Jiang (2010) have shown that there is a very different pattern in funds holding illiquid assets relative
to those holding liquid assets. The former exhibit much stronger sensitivity of outflow to negative
performance indicating that investors are more likely to take their money out fearing the redemptions
by others.
This force has shifted attention recently to bond funds. These are funds that invest in corporate,
government, and other types of bonds. They have grown tremendously in the US over the last few
years. This is again likely to be a response to the tightened regulation of banks. As banks find it more
difficult to lend, firms are issuing more bonds to address their financing needs, and mutual funds are
holding these bonds. The problem with bonds is that they are much more illiquid than equity, and so
the liquidity mismatch for funds that hold bonds is more severe. Goldstein, Jiang, and Ng (2015)
show in a recent paper that bond funds indeed exhibit different flow-performance sensitivity that
leads to more outflows upon bad performance and consistent with the fact that they lead to greater
first-mover advantage and fragility. They also show that this is amplified in times of aggregate
illiquidity.
If indeed bond funds create the trigger for panic, this can put pressure on the financial system
and the real economy in times of crisis. Vast evidence from the empirical literature on financial
markets has shown that outflows from mutual funds create persistent price pressure (e.g., Coval and
Stafford (2007) Manconi, Massa and Yasuda (2012), and Ellul, Jotikasthira and Lundblad (2012))
and that these price impacts can have real effects on firms’ activities (e.g., Edmans, Goldstein and
Jiang (2012) and Hau and Lai ( 2013)). Recently, Gilchrist and Zakrajcek (2012) show an effect of
market-driven credit spread on real economic outcomes.
In summary, financial regulation should view the system as a whole and consider the fact that
regulating parts of the system will likely shift activity to other parts and put them at the risk of
fragility. An integrative approach, which is now attempted by the Financial Stability Oversight
council (FSOC) in the US, is welcome and more of this approach should be implemented worldwide.
Fragility should be measured based on the activity that is being pursued and not based on the entity
pursuing it.
33
7. Looking beyond the feedback loop – creating arbitrage-safe regulatory frameworks
Our analysis suggests some high-level conclusions for an incentive-compatible regulatory framework
that ensures a thriving financial system that supports the real economy, while at the same time
minimizing the risk and the repercussions of bank fragility. We first point to some very general policy
lessons, with examples, before providing some concrete recommendations in the case of European
financial systems.
1. Complexity vs. simplicity: We need the right balance of (i) regulatory tools fine-tuned to the risk
decisions of financial intermediaries and market participants and (ii) simple tools that cannot be easily
circumvented. Both are meant to force banks to internalize the externalities from their possible failure,
but having both types of tools reflects the trade-off between the goal of perfect risk pricing and the
cost of market players searching for arbitrage options. Just to give two examples, one related to capital
buffers and the other to activities of banks. Risk-weighted capital-asset ratios try to force banks to
hold capital buffers appropriate for their level of risk-taking, while the leverage ratio is a back-stop
that prevents banks from excessively reducing capital through outsmarting the risk weight
system. Similarly, forcing banks to hold additional capital or impose higher risk-weights for specific
activities that expose the bank to higher risks and/or are not considered central to financial service
provision is a pricing-based tool, whereas outright prohibition of certain activities (e.g. trading on
own account) is a simpler tool to achieve the same. While a pricing-based tool might be better to
balance social benefits and costs, complete prohibition might be better in case of uncertainty about
(the distribution of) costs and benefits.
What does this imply for Europe? While the CRR and CRD IV translated the Basel III
agreement into European rules, the lessons from the recent crises have only partly been incorporated.
On the one hand, government bonds still attract a zero risk weight, thus not reflecting the riskiness of
sovereign credit even in many European countries. Maybe more worrisome (and maybe more
relevant), there are no concentration limits on government bond holdings by banks, unlike for other
asset classes. To our understanding, this issue is currently being discussed among supervisors. On
the other hand, the leverage ratio has been set rather low at 3%, while other jurisdictions aim for
higher ratios (4 or 5%). Critically, in the recent Comprehensive Assessment, the participating banks
were not subjected to and evaluated under stress tests with the leverage ratio as benchmark, but rather
only with risk-weighted capital-asset ratios as benchmark. This might also explain why market-based
assessment of capital shortfalls provide different bank rankings and calculations of total shortfall than
34
accounting-based calculations such as done under the Comprehensive Assessment (Acharya and
Steffen, 2015).
35
decision power on the national level, with ECB and/or SSM having the right to impose stricter rules
or (ii) the SSM being the primary and only decision taker with input from national authorities.
3. Focus on resolution: given the externalities from bank failure, it is critical to have frameworks in
place to resolve financial intermediaries in a way that minimizes disruptions for the rest of the
financial system and the real economy, while allocating losses according to creditor ranking. An
incentive-compatible resolution framework has therefore not only important effects ex-post, i.e. in
the case of failure, but also important ex-ante incentive effects for risk-decision takers. Knowing what
happens in case of distress can provide the necessary incentives during normal times, i.e. risk decision
takers will adjust their decision if they know that returns in case of distress will reflect the creditor
ranking. To put it bluntly: Knowing that you will lose your shirt in case of failure can reduce
incentives to take aggressive risks. Providing feasible options for resolution of banks that minimizes
the externalities for the rest of financial system and the real economy also reduces the gap for financial
safety net managers between ex-ante optimal and ex-post optimal reactions to bank distress. One
important component of incentive-compatible resolution frameworks are living wills for large banks
that often have the status of too-big or too-complex-to-fail. These living wills spell out what would
happen in the case of failure – which parts of the bank will be wound down, which will be maintained
at any price as they constitute a public utility and which parts might be sold off. The critical advantage
of such tailored living wills is not just to prepare regulators for the worst-case-scenario, but can also
be used by regulators to force certain restructuring of financial institutions to make them “resolvable”.
This challenge is especially important in the light of the incomplete banking union for the
Eurozone. On the one hand, there has been substantial progress in strengthening (often non-existing)
resolution frameworks on both national and European levels. Many countries have introduced bank
resolution framework that take into account the special characteristics of banks and the need for swift
resolution, while maintaining the creditor ranking. The BRRD has introduced bail-in rules for
debtholders that aim to minimize the risk that taxpayers will have to be liable for bank losses. On the
supranational level, the Eurozone has made enormous progress in moving towards a supra-national
financial safety net, establishing both the single supervisory and the single resolution mechanisms.
On the other hand, however, the banking union, as it currently stands is not complete. The SRM seems
to be a rather complicated coordination mechanism, which involves several players. In addition, the
fact that the UK is outside the SRM will critically hamper its effectiveness, given the importance of
London as international financial center and many European banks having substantial parts of their
operation in London.
36
Critically, a proper funding mechanism, including a public back-stop is missing. The target
size of the single resolution fund of €55bn would not cover any major bank failure, which leaves the
problem of too-big-to-fail unresolved in Europe. Even in the presence of much more rigorous bail-
in rules introduced under the BRDD, interim funding might be necessary as large banks are unlikely
to be resolved over a weekend. Finally and even more important than the limited self-funding, there
is no public back-stop funding mechanism in place, which reduces the effectiveness of the resolution
framework. Ultimately, this leaves again the failure of any large financial institution outside the
formal financial safety net and subject to political ad-hoc weekend negotiations. Even in a world
with high confidence in the competence, independence and integrity of the supervisory institution
and process, the shortcomings of these other two pillars will affect the SSM. How credible can a
supervisor be in threatening to close a bank if there is no water-tight resolution process in place?
4. Dynamic approach to regulation. As the financial system develops and financial innovation
creates new products and new providers, regulation and supervision have to adjust. This concerns
primarily and foremost the regulatory and supervisory perimeter. This would imply functional rather
than institutional regulation (“if it looks like frog and it quacks like a frog….”). This would also
imply that the regulatory perimeter has to be adjusted over time and that the focus of prudential
regulation (both micro- and macro-prudential) might have to shift over time as new sources of
systemic risks arise. One (negative) example was the sudden realization of the systemic importance
of AIG in the CDS market (and therefore in the global financial system) in autumn 2008, not having
been supervised thoroughly by prudential supervisors.
The question of the regulatory perimeter will arise for the SSM as much as for other bank
regulators and thus the challenge of potentially expanding regulation and supervision towards non-
bank segments of the financial system closely inter-connected with banks. It remains to be seen how
easy it will be for the SSM legally and politically to redefine its regulatory perimeter if it identifies
new sources of systemic risk, be they linked to the banking system or completely outside the banking
system.
8. Looking forward: What do we know, what do we not know yet and what should we know
The years since the crisis have seen an enormous increase in theoretical and empirical explorations
in both (idiosyncratic and systemic) risk measurement and micro- and macro-prudential regulation.
The overhaul of the regulatory frameworks across the globe was not only the result of lessons learned
from the recent crises but was also accompanied by extensive academic work. We have become
37
better at measuring risk and designing regulatory tools to reduce build-up of systemic risk and manage
it more effectively. Having said this, much of the discussion has been dominated by the last crisis –
as always: regulatory reforms after a crisis are designed to prevent the last but not the next crisis. We
have thus become better in analysing the known unknowns; this, however, leaves us with the
unknown unknowns, including financial innovation leading to new business models and new
structures in the financial system and thus new and future sources of financial fragility. As the
financial system develops, research and analysis (both academic and within central banks and
regulatory authorities) has to adopt to the dynamic nature of the financial system.
The four policy lessons discussed above, however, imply some important venues of further research.
1. Complexity vs. simplicity: several studies have addressed the issue of usefulness of risk-weighted
capital-asset ratios vs. leverage ratios in predicting bank-level fragility (e.g., Haldane, 2012;
Demirguc-Kunt, Detragiache and Merrouche, 2013). One important caveat, however, has been the
Goodhart critique – as a specific metric (such as the leverage ratio) becomes a policy tools, it might
become less effective. Comparing different measures of capital strength across banks and across
countries with different capital framework and regulatory frameworks with market-based measures
of fragility (where available) and possibly internal supervisory measures of fragility might provide
insights into the relevance and adequacy of different capital requirements. Using market-based
measures of tail risk will be important input into the analysis, as actual failures will most likely
continue to be rare. As much as more sophisticated measures of systemic risk contributions of
individual banks and covariance between different banks are necessary, the development of simple
rule-based measures of systemic risk will be important, especially in less transparent environment
where few banks are publicly listed and issue publicly traded securities so that little market-based
information can be used. Fine-tuning stress test tools based on detailed supervisory information will
be even more important in these environments.
2. Complement micro- with macro-prudential regulation: there have been few studies so far on
the effectiveness of macro-prudential regulation, both on the extensive (which tools) and intensive
(how much) margin (though see for example, Vandenbussche et al., 2015 and Claessens et al., 2014).
Similar to the assessment of the risk-taking channel of monetary policy on bank fragility, however,
loan-level data are necessary to gauge the effectiveness of macro-prudential tools on banks’ risk-
taking and fragility. Jimenez et al. (2014) is one of the few papers taking up this challenge; using the
38
Spanish credit registry data they assess both the introduction of dynamic provisioning in Spain in the
early 2000s and the relaxation during the crisis in 2008. Their conclusion is that the tool was effective
though not sufficient to prevent either credit boom or the credit collapse. The use of credit registry
data across different countries (and therefore different financial structures, different macro-prudential
tools and different economic structures) will be critical in getting a better assessment of what works
best in macro-prudential regulation.
4. Dynamic approach to regulation: one important area for future research will be to explore
different sources of systemic risk across the financial system, including in the shadow financial
system. Recent work by Koijen and Yogo (2014) has shown significant additional risks in the life
insurance sector stemming from life insurers moving liabilities off their balance sheets through
unrated shadow reinsurers in less regulated jurisdictions.
TO BE COMPLETED!
39
References (to be completed)
Abreu, D. and M. Brunnermeier (2003), “Bubbles and Crashes,” Econometrica, 71, 173-204.
Acemoglu, D., A. Ozdaglar and A. Tahbaz-Saleh (2015), “Systemic Risk and Stability in Financial
Networks,” American Economic Review, 105(2), 564–608.
Acharya, V. (2009), “A theory of systemic risk and design of prudential bank regulation,” Journal
of Financial Stability, 5(3), 224–255.
Acharya, V. and S. Steffen (2015), “The “greatest” carry trade ever? Understanding eurozone bank
risks,” Journal of Financial Economics
Acharya, V., D. Gale and T. Yorulmazer (2009), “Rollover Risk and Market Freezes,” Journal of
Finance, 66(4), 1177-1209.
Acharya, V., D. Gromb and T. Yorulmazer (2008), “Imperfect Competition in the Interbank Market
for Liquidity as a Rationale for Central Banking,” INSEAD Working Paper No. 2011/41/FIN.
Acharya, V., P. Schnabl and G. Suarez (2013), “Securitization without risk transfer,” Journal of
Financial Economics, 107(3), 515–536.
Admati, A., P. DeMarzo, M. Hellwig, and P. Pfleiderer (2010), “Fallacies, Irrelevant Facts, and
Myths in the Discussion of Capital Regulation: Why Bank Equity Is Not Expensive” Stanford
University working paper, No. 86.
Adrian, T., and M. Brunnermeier (2011), “CoVar,” NBER Working Papers 17454, National Bureau
of Economic Research.
Allen, F and E. Carletti (2008), “Mark-to-Market Accounting and Liquidity Pricing,” Journal of
Accounting and Economics, 2008, 45, 358-378.
Allen, F. and D. Gale (2000), “Bubbles and Crises,” Economic Journal, 110, 236-255.
Allen, F. and D. Gale (2000), “Comparing Financial Systems,” MIT Press.
Allen, F. and D. Gale (2000), “Financial Contagion,” Journal of Political Economy, 108, 1-33.
Allen, F. and D. Gale (2007), “Understanding Financial Crises,” Clarendon Lecture Series in
Finance, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Allen, F. and E. Carletti (2006), “Credit Risk Transfer and Contagion,” Journal of Monetary
Economics, 53, 89-111.
Allen, F. and G. Gorton (1993), “Churning Bubbles,” Review of Economic Studies, 60, 813-836.
Allen, F., A. Babus and E. Carletti (2009), ”Financial Crises: Theory and Evidence,” Annual
Review of Financial Economics, December 2009.
Allen, F., A. Babus and E. Carletti (2012), “Asset commonality, debt maturity and systemic risk,”
Journal of Financial Economics, 104(3), 519–534.
40
Allen, F., E. Carletti and D. Gale (2009), “Interbank Market Liquidity and Central Bank
Intervention,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 56(5), 639-652.
Allen, F., E. Carletti and R. Marquez (2009), ”Credit Market Competition and Capital Regulation,”
Review of Financial Studies.
Allen, F., E. Carletti, I. Goldstein and A. Leonello (2015), ”Moral Hazard and Government
Guarantees in the Banking Industry,” Journal of Financial Regulation, 1, 30-50.
Allen, F., E. Carletti, I. Goldstein, and A. Leonello, (2013), “Government guarantees and financial
stability,” working paper.
Allen, F., S. Morris, and A. Postlewaite (1993), “Finite Bubbles with Short Sale Constraints and
Asymmetric Information,” Journal of Economic Theory, 61, 206-229.
Allen, F., T. Beck and E. Carletti (2014), “Structural Changes in European Financial Systems: The
Impact of the Regulatory Framework on Investment in the European Union”, in European
Investment Bank (ed.), Investment and Investment Finance in Europe, 243-275
Allen, F., X. Gu and O. Kowalewski (2012), “Financial crisis, structure and reform,” Journal of
Banking and Finance, 36(11), 2960–2973.
Amore, M. D., Schneider, C., and Žaldokas, A. (2013), “Credit supply and corporate innovation,”
Journal of Financial Economics, 109(3), 835–855.
Babus, A. (2014) “The Formation of Financial Networks,” Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper
No. 2006-093/2.
Bagehot, W. (1873) “Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market,” E. Johnstone; Hartley
Withers, eds. London: Henry S. King and Co., 1873.
Bebchuk, L. A., and I. Goldstein (2011), “Self-fulfilling credit market freezes,” Review of Financial
Studies, 24(11), 3519–3555
Beck, T., B. Buyukkarabacak, F. Rioja and N. Valev (2012), “Who Gets the Credit? And Does it
Matter? Household vs. Firm Lending Across Countries,” B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, 12.
Bernanke, B. (2008), “Reducing systemic risk: a speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City's Annual Economic Symposium, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 22, 2008,” Speech 429,
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.).
Bernanke, B. and M. Gertler (1989), “Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business Fluctuations,”
American Economic Review, 79(1), 14-31.
Bernanke, B., M. Gertler and S. Gilchrist (1996) “The Financial Accelerator and the Flight to
Quality,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 78(1), 1-15.
41
Bhattacharya, S. and A. Thakor (1993), “Contemporary Banking Theory,” Journal of Financial
Intermediation, 3, 2-50.
Bhattacharya, S. and D. Gale (1987), “Preference Shocks, Liquidity and Central Bank Policy,” in
W. Barnett and K. Singleton (eds.), New Approaches to Monetary Economics, 69-88.
Bolton, P., T. Santos and J. Scheinkman (2008), “Inside and Outside Liquidity,” working paper,
Columbia University. OR NBER Working Paper No. 14867 April 2009
Boot, A.W.A. and S.I. Greenbaum (1993), “Bank-Regulation, Reputation and Rents: Theory and
Policy Implications”, in C. Mayer and X. Vives: Capital Markets and Financial Intermediation,
Cambridge University Press.
Boss, M., H. Elsinger, S. Thurner, and M. Summer (2004), “Network Topology of the Interbank
Market,” Quantitative Finance, 4, 1-8.
Boyd, De Nicolo, and Loukoianova (2009), “Banking Crises and Crisis Dating; Theory and
Evidence,” IMF working papers, 09/141.
Brunnermeier, M. (2001) “Asset Pricing under Asymmetric Information: Bubbles, Crashes,
Technical Analysis and Herding,” Oxford University Press.
Brunnermeier, M. (2009), “Deciphering the Liquidity and Credit Crunch 2007-08,” Journal of
Economic Perspectives 23, 77-100.
Brunnermeier, M., and S. Nagel (2004), “Hedge Funds and the Technology Bubble,” Journal of
Finance, 59(5), 2013–2040.
Brunnermeier, M., T. M. Eisenbach, and Y. Sannikov (2012), “Macroeconomics with financial
frictions: a survey,” NBER working paper 18102.
Bryant, J. (1980), “A Model of Reserves, Bank Runs, and Deposit Insurance,” Journal of Banking
and Finance, 4, 335-344.
Calomiris, C. and C. Kahn (1991), “The Role of Demandable Debt in Structuring Optimal Banking
Arrangements,” American Economic Review, 81, 497-513.
Carlsson, H. and E. van Damme (1993), “Global Games and Equilibrium Selection,” Econometrica,
61, 989-1018.
Cetorelli, N. and L. S. Goldberg, (2014) “Measures of global bank complexity,” Economic Policy
Review, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, issue Dec, 107-126.
Chava, S., A. Oettl, A. Subramanian, and K.V. Subramanian (2013), “Banking deregulation and
innovation,” Journal of Financial Economics, 109(3), 759–774.
Chen, Q., I. Goldstein, and W. Jiang (2010), “Payoff Complementarities and Financial Fragility:
Evidence from Mutual Fund Flows,” Journal of Financial Economics, 97,239-262.
42
Chen, Y. (1999), “Banking Panics: The Role of the First-Come, First-Served Rule and Information
Externalities,” Journal of Political Economy, 107(5), 946-968
Cifuentes, R., G. Ferrucci, and H. Shin (2005), “Liquidity Risk and Contagion,” Journal of
European Economic Association, 3, 556-566.
Cocco, J., F. Gomes, and N. Martins (2009), “Lending Relationships in the Interbank Market,”
Journal of Financial Intermediation, 18(1), 24-48.
Coval, J., and Stafford, E. (2007), “Asset fire sales (and purchases) in equity markets,” Journal of
Financial Economics, 86(2), 479-512.
Dasgupta, A. (2004), “Financial Contagion through Capital Connections: A Model of the Origin
and Spread of Bank Panics,” Journal of the European Economic Association, 6, 1049-1084.
De Vries, C. G. (2005), “The simple economics of bank fragility,” Journal of Banking and Finance,
29(4), 803–825.
Degryse and Nguyen (2007), “Interbank Exposures: An Empirical Examination of Contagion Risk
in the Belgian Banking System,” International Journal of Central Banking, 3(2), 123-171.
Degryse, Ongena and Kim (2009), “Microeconometrics of Banking Methods, Applications, and
Results,” Oxford University Press, number 9780195340471, March.
Dell’Ariccia, G., D. Igan and L. Laeven (2012) “Credit Booms and Lending Standards: Evidence
from the Subprime Mortgage Market,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 44, 367-384.
Dell'Ariccia, G., and Marquez, R. (2006), “Lending booms and lending standards,” Journal of
Finance, 61(5), 2511–2546.
Demirguc‐Kunt, A., E. Detragiache and O. Merrouche (2013), “Bank Capital: Lessons from the
Financial Crisis,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 45(6), 1147-1164.
Department for International Development (2013), “Global Financial Sector Regulatory Reform:
Understanding the Impact on Developing Countries”, London.
Diamond, D. and P. Dybvig (1983), “Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity,” Journal of
Political Economy, 91, 401-419.
Diamond, D. and R. Rajan (2001), “Liquidity Risk, Liquidity Creation and Financial Fragility: A
Theory of Banking,” Journal of Political Economy, 109, 2431-2465.
Diamond, D. and R. Rajan (2009), “Fear of fire sales and the credit freeze,” working paper
University of Chicago.
Dowd, K. (1989), “Automatic Stabilizing Mechanism under Free Banking,” Cato-Journal, 7, 643-
59.
43
Edmans, A., Goldstein, I., and Jiang, W. (2012),”The real effects of financial markets: The impact
of prices on takeovers,” The Journal of Finance, 67(3), 933-971.
Ellul, A., Jotikasthira, C., and Lundblad, C. (2011), “Regulatory pressure and fire sales in the
corporate bond market,” Journal of Financial Economics, 101(3), 596-620.
ESRB (2014), “Is Europe Overbanked?”, Report of the Advisory Scientific Committee, Number 4,
available at https://www.esrb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/asc/Reports_ASC_4_1406.pdf.
Farhi, E. and J. Tirole (2012), “Collective moral hazard, maturity mismatch and systemic bailouts”,
American Economic Review, 102, 60-93.
Flannery, M., and K. Rangan (2008), “What caused the bank capital build-up of the 1990s?” Review
of Finance, 12(2), 391–429.
Fostel, A., and J. Geanakoplos (2008), “Leverage Cycles and the Anxious Economy.” American
Economic Review, 98(4), 1211-44.
Freixas X., Laeven and Peydro (2015), “Systemic Risk, Crises, and Macroprudential Regulation,”
MIT Press, June 2015
Freixas, X. and J. Rochet (2008), “The Microeconomics of Banking, 2nd Edition”, Cambridge: MIT
Press.
Freixas, X., and Parigi, B. (1998), “Contagion and Efficiency in Gross and Net Interbank Payment
Systems,” Journal of Financial Intermediation, 7(1), 3–31.
Freixas, X., B. Parigi, and J. Rochet (2000), “Systemic Risk, Interbank Relations and Liquidity
Provision by the Central Bank,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 32, 611-38.
Freixas, X., B. Parigi, and J. Rochet (2000), “Systemic Risk, Interbank Relations and Liquidity
Provision by the Central Bank,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 32, 611-38.
Friedman, M., and A. J. Schwartz (1963), “A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960,”
Princeton University Press for NBER.
Furfine, C. (2003), “Interbank Exposures: Quantifying the Risk of Contagion,” Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking, 35, 111-128.
Geanakoplos, J. (1997), “Promises, Promises.” In B. Arthur, S. Durlauf and D. Lane (eds.), The
Economy as an Evolving Complex System II, Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley, 285-320.
Geanakoplos, J. (2003), “Liquidity, Default, and Crashes: Endogenous Contracts in Equilibrium,”
in M. Dewatripont, L. Hansen and S. Turnovsky (eds.) Advances in Economics and Econometrics:
Theory and Applications, Eighth World Congress, Volume II, 278-283.
Geanakoplos, J. (2009), “The Leverage Cycle,” 2009 NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 24, 1-65.
44
Gennaioli, N., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R., (2012) “Neglected risks, financial innovation, and
financial fragility,” Journal of Financial Economics, 104(3), 452-468.
Gilchrist, S., and E. Zakrajšek. 2012. “Credit Spreads and Business Cycle Fluctuations,” American
Economic Review, 102(4), 1692-1720.
Giovannini, A., C. Mayer, S. Micossi, C. Di Noia, M. Pagano, A. Polo (2015), “Restarting
European Long-Term Investment Finance. A Green Paper Discussion Document”, CEPR.
Goetzmann, W. and Rouwenhorst, K., (2005) “The Origins of Value: The Financial Innovations
that Created Modern Capital Markets,” Oxford University Press, number 9780195175714, March.
Goldstein, I. and A. Pauzner, (2005), “Demand-Deposit Contracts and the Probability of Bank
Runs,” Journal of Finance 60, 1293-1327.
Goldstein, I., (2012), Empirical literature on financial crises: fundamentals vs. panic, in G. Caprio
(ed.) The Evidence and Impact of Financial Globalization, Elsevier.
Goldstein, I., and A. Pauzner, (2004), “Contagion of self-fulfilling financial crises due to
diversification of investment portfolios,” Journal of Economic Theory 119, 151-183.
Goldstein, Jiang, and Ng (2015) “Investor Flows and Fragility in Corporate Bond Funds,” working
paper.
Goodfriend, M. and R. G. King, (1988). “Financial deregulation, monetary policy, and central
banking,” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, issue May, pages 3-22.
Goodhart, C. (1988), “The Evolution of Central Banks,” MIT Press.
Gorton, G. (1988), “Banking Panics and Business Cycles,” Oxford Economic Papers, 40, 751-781.
Gorton, G. (2008), “The Panic of 2007,” Jackson Hole Conference Proceedings, Federal Reserve
Bank of Kansas City
Gorton, G. and A. Winton (2003), “Financial Intermediation,” in G. Constantinides, M. Harris, and
R. Stulz, eds., Handbook of the Economics of Finance, Volume 1A, Chapter 8, North Holland,
Amsterdam, 431-552.
Haldane, A. G. (2012), “The Dog and the Frisbee”, speech given at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City’s 36th economic policy symposium, “The Changing Policy Landscape”, Jackson Hole,
Wyoming, Bank of England, available at
http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Documents/speeches/2012/speech596.pdf.
Hakenes, H. and I. Schnabel (2014) ‘Bank Bonuses and Bail-Outs,’ Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, 46: 259–288.
Hau, H., and Lai, S. (2013), “Real effects of stock underpricing”. Journal of Financial Economics,
108(2), 392-408.
45
Hay, G. (2013), “Regulators Must Grab Chance to Bin EU Capital Ruse,” Reuters Breaking News,
http://blogs.reuters.com/breakingviews/2013/01/15/regulators-must-grab-chance-to-bin-eu-capital-
ruse/
Heaton, John C. and Lucas, Deborah and McDonald, Robert L., 2010. “Is mark-to-market
accounting destabilizing? Analysis and implications for policy,” Journal of Monetary Economics,
Elsevier, vol. 57(1), pages 64-75, January.
Heider, F., M. Hoerova and C. Holthausen (2009), “Liquidity Hoarding and Interbank Market
Spreads: The Role of Counterparty Risk,” mimeo European Central Bank, Frankfurt.
Hellmann, Thomas F., Kevin C. Murdock, and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 2000. “Liberalization, Moral
Hazard in Banking, and Prudential Regulation: Are Capital Requirements Enough?” American
Economic Review, 90(1), 147-165.
Henderson and Pearson (2011) “The Dark Side of Financial Innovation: A case study of the pricing
of a retail financial product,” Journal of Financial Economics. 100(2), 227-247.
Holmström, B. and J. Tirole (1998), “Private and Public Supply of Liquidity,” Journal of Political
Economy 106, 1-40.
Hong, H., J. Scheinkman and W. Xiong (2008), “Advisors and Asset prices: A model of the Origins
of Bubbles,” Journal of Financial Economics 89.
Huang, J., and J. Wang (2009), “Liquidity and Market Crashes,” Review of Financial Studies, 22(7),
2607-2643.
Huang, J., and J. Wang (2010), “Market Liquidity, Asset Prices and Welfare,” Journal of Financial
Economics, 95(1), 107-127.
Iyer, R., and J. Peydro-Alcalde (2011), “Interbank Contagion at Work: Evidence from a Natural
Experiment,” Review of Financial Studies, 24, 1337-77.
Jacklin, Charles J., and Sudipto Bhattacharya, (1988) “Distinguishing panics and information-based
bank runs: Welfare and policy implications”, Journal of Political
Economy, 96, 568-592.
Jiménez Gabriel, Steven Ongena, José Luis Peydró and Jesús Saurina, 2014, “Macroprudential
policy, countercyclical bank capital buffers and credit supply: Evidence from the Spanish dynamic
provisioning experiments,”
Jorion, P., and G. Zhang (2009), “Credit Contagion from Counterparty Risk,” Journal of Finance
64(5), 2053-2087.
Kahane, Yehuda, (1977), “Capital adequacy and the regulation of financial intermediaries”, Journal
of Banking and Finance, 1, issue 2, p. 207-218
46
Kane, E.J. (1977), “Good intentions and unintended evil: the case against selective credit
allocation”, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking , 9, 55-69.
Kareken, J. H and Wallace, N. (1978), “Deposit Insurance and Bank Regulation: A Partial-
Equilibrium Exposition,” The Journal of Business, 51(3), 413-38.
Keys, B., M. S. Barr and J. K. Dokko (2011), “Exploring the Determinants of High-Cost Mortgages
to Homeowners in Low-and Moderate-Income Neighborhoods”, in S. Wachter and M. Smith, eds.,
The American Mortgage System: Rethink, Recover, Rebuild, University of Pennsylvania Press.
Keys, B., Mukherjee, T., Seru, A. and Vig, V. (2010), “Did Securitization Lead to Lax Screening:
Evidence from Subprime Loans,” Quarterly Journal of Economics125, 1, 307–362.
Kindleberger, C. (1978), “Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises”, New York:
Basic Books.
Kiyotaki, N. and J. Moore (1997), “Credit Chains,” Journal of Political Economy 99, 220-264.
Kodres, L., and M. Pritsker, (2002), “A rational expectations model of financial contagion”, Journal
of Finance, 57, 769-799.
Koijen, R.S. and M. Yogo (2014), “Growing Risk in the Insurance Sector,” Federal Reserve Bank
of Minneapolis, 14(2).
Laeven, L., R. Levine and S. Michalopoulos (2015), “Financial innovation and endogenous
growth,” Journal of Financial Intermediation24(1), 1-24.
Lagunoff, R. and S. Schreft (2001), “A Model of Financial Fragility,” Journal of Economic Theory,
99, 220-264.
Langfield, S. and M. Pagano (2015) “Bank Bias in Europe: Effects on Systemic Risk and Growth,”
Presented at the AEA
Leitner, Y. (2005), “Financial Networks: Contagion, Commitment, and Private Sector Bailouts,”
Journal of Finance 60, 2925-2953.
Lerner, J. and P. Tufano (2011) “The Consequences of Financial Innovation: A Counterfactual
Research Agenda,” Annual Review of Financial Economics3, 41-85.
Manconi, A., Massa, M., and Yasuda, A. (2012), “The role of institutional investors in propagating
the crisis of 2007–2008.” Journal of Financial Economics, 104(3), 491-518
Micossi, S., G. Bruzzone and M. Cassella (2014), “Bail-in Provisions in State Aid and Resolution
Procedures: Are they consistent with systemic stability?” CEPS Policy Briefs, 318.
Mistrulli, P. (2011), “Assessing Financial Contagion in the Interbank Market: Maximum Entropy
versus Observed Interbank Lending Patterns,” Journal of Banking & Finance, 35 (5), 1114-1127.
47
Nijskens, R. and W. Wagner (2011), “Credit risk transfer activities and systemic risk: How banks
became less risky individually but posed greater risks to the financial system at the same time,”
Journal of Banking and Finance 35(6), 1391-1398.
Norden, L., C. Silva Buston and W. Wagner (2014) “Financial innovation and bank behavior:
Evidence from credit markets.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 43, 130-145.
O’Hara, M. (1993), “Real Bills Revisited: Market Value Accounting and Loan Maturity,” Journal
of Financial Intermediation, III(1),
Plantin, G., H. Sapra and H. S. Shin (2008), “Marking to Market: Panacea or Pandora's Box?,”
Journal of Accounting Research, 46(2), 435-460.
Rajan, R. G. (2006), “Has Finance Made the World Riskier?.” European Financial Management,
12, 499–533
Reinhart, C M., and K. S. Rogoff (2011), “From Financial Crash to Debt Crisis.” American
Economic Review, 101(5), 1676-1706.
Reinhart, C. M. and G. L. Kaminsky (1999), “The Twin Crises: The Causes of Banking and
Balance-of-Payments Problems,” American Economic Review, 89(3), 473-500.
Reinhart, C., and K. Rogoff (2009), “The Aftermath of Financial Crises,” American Economic
Review, 99(2), 466-72.
Rochet, J. (2008), “Why are there so Many Banking Crises?”, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press.
Rochet, J. and X. Vives, (2004), “Coordination Failures and the Lender of Last Resort: Was
Bagehot Right after All?” Journal of the European Economic Association 2, 1116-1147.
Rochet, J-C. (2004), “Macroeconomic shocks and banking supervision,” Journal of Financial
Stability, 1(1), 93-110.
Rosengren (2014), “Our Financial Structures – Are they Prepared for Financial Instability?”
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Supplement to vol. 46(1), 143-156.
Scheinkman, J. and W. Xiong (2003), “Overconfidence and Speculative Bubbles,” Journal of
Political Economy 111, 1183-1219.
Schmidt, L., Timmerman, A., and Wermers, R. (2014), “Runs on Money Market Mutual
Funds”.University of Maryland working paper.
Tirole, J. (1982), “On the Possibility of Speculation under Rational Expectations,” Econometrica
50, 1163-1181.
Tirole, J. (1985), “Asset Bubbles and Overlapping Generations,” Econometrica 53, 1499-1528.
48
Upper, C. (2007), “Using Counterfactual Simulations to Assess the Danger of Contagion in
Interbank Markets” working paper 234, Bank for International Settlements.
Upper, C., and A. Worms (2004), “Estimating Bilateral Exposures in the German Interbank Market:
Is There a Danger of Contagion?” European Economic Review, 48, 827-849.
Vandenbussche, J., E. Detragiache and U. Vogel (2012), “Macroprudential Policies and Housing
Prices - A New Database and Empirical Evidence for Central, Eastern, and South-Eastern Europe,”
IMF working paper WP/12/303.
Viñals, J., C Pazarbasioglu, J. Surti, A. Narain, M. Erbenova, and J. Chow (2013) ‘Creating a Safer
Financial System: Will the Volcker, Vickers, and Liikanen Structural Measures Help?’ IMF Staff
Discussion Note 13/04, IMF, Washington, D.C.
Wagner, W. (2007), “Aggregate liquidity shortages, idiosyncratic liquidity smoothing and banking
regulation.” Journal of Financial Stability, 3(1), 18-32.
Wagner, W. (2007), “The liquidity of bank assets and banking stability.” Journal of Banking and
Finance, 31(1), 121-139.
Wagner, W. (2010), “Diversification at financial institutions and systemic crises.” Journal of
Financial Intermediation, 19(3), 373-386.
Wagner, W. (2011), “Systemic Liquidation Risk and the Diversity–Diversification Trade‐Off.” The
Journal of Finance, 66(4), 1141-1175.
White, L. (1984), “Free Banking in Britain: Theory, Experience and Debate”, 1800-1845,
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
49
Table 1: Comparing the Structural Reform Proposals
Liikanen group report UK Vickers report US Volcker rule
Deposit-taking institution Not permitted (but other Not permitted (but other Not permitted
dealing as principal in group companies may do group companies may do
securities and derivatives so) so)
1/
Deposit-taking institution Not permitted (but other Not permitted (but other Not permitted
investing in hedge funds group companies may do group companies may do
and private equity so) so)
Deposit-taking institution Not permitted (but other Not permitted (but other Permitted
providing market making group companies may do group companies may do
services so) so)
Higher loss absorbency Yes, via leverage ratio for Yes, as add-on to the For SIBs with substantial
rule 2/ trading business that conservation buffer for US footprint
exceeds size threshold UK ring-fenced bank
Size threshold for Yes; applies to all banks Yes; applies to all banks No
application with trading books larger and building societies with
than EUR 100bn, or deposits greater than
trading assets more than EUR 25bn
15-25 per cent of balance-
sheet
Implementing regulations No No No
finalised?
Notes:
1/ US federal government and agency securities, debt and securities issued by US state and municipal governments
and government-sponsored enterprises, and derivatives of these securities are exempt from proprietary trading
restrictions of the Volcker rule.
2/ The Dodd-Frank Act subjects US banks with assets in excess of USD 50bn to more stringent prudential
requirements. Similar requirements have been proposed, under the recent Intermediate Holding Company proposal,
for non-US banks with more than USD 50bn in global assets that have a systemically important presence in the US.