BBA Managerial Economics Notes PDF
BBA Managerial Economics Notes PDF
BBA Managerial Economics Notes PDF
net/publication/284179060
MACROECONOMIC NOTES
CITATIONS READS
0 655
2 authors, including:
Mustapha Akintona
79 PUBLICATIONS 3 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
All content following this page was uploaded by Mustapha Akintona on 19 November 2015.
MACROECONOMIC NOTES
_____________________________________________________________________
By
Claremont Graduate University
Mustapha Akintona
Ahmed Oweis (Ph.D)
Abstract
By standards of economic efficiency which you will elaborate, what is wrong with
inflation? What is wrong with unemployment? What is the inter-relationship between
inflation and unemployment? Is there any important short-run versus long-run distinction
here? What can national economic policy do to solve these problems? Is the effect of such
policy sustainable? At each state of the argument, show what costs are associated with
what benefits.
1
\
T
S G Business I
Household Government
Sector TR Sector
X
M
This diagram represents the basic relationships between the major sectors
in an economy.
The inner flow is a “monetary flow”, while the outer flow is a “real flow”,
as money is not involved in this flow.
Dividing this diagram horizontally into two parts, we can see the
exchanges that take place in two major markets. The upper part represents the
exchanges that take place in the input market (or factor market). Similarly, the
lower part represents transactions that take place in the goods market.
This circular flow of income requires leakages (in the form of savings,
taxes, or imports) to be fully offset by injections (in the form of investment,
government expenditure, or exports).
The government collects income taxes (T) from the households. These
taxes are used to make transfer payments (TR) and also to purchase goods and
services from the business sector. Remember, only government purchases are
included in the government expenditure (G). Transfer payments are usually
2
\
subtracted from taxes to get net taxes. From now on, when we talk about taxes
we actually mean “net taxes”. Accordingly, we are not interested in TR
anymore. Moreover, we assume no indirect taxes (taxes are paid only by the
household sector).
The “financial sector” is the intermediary that channels savings from the
households, who have surplus funds, to investors in the business sector, who
have shortage of funds.
Allowing for exports (X) and imports (M) makes the economy an “open
economy”. The difference (X-M) is known as net exports (NX), which is
equivalent to the current account surplus (deficit) in the balance of payments.
From the balance of payment’s identity, it follows that the current account
surplus (deficit) must be equal to the capital account deficit (surplus).
This simple circular flow enables us to define real GDP using three
different approaches (under some conventional assumptions, all three ways are
identical):
- Production approach: the GDP is the value of all measurable final goods
and services produced in the economy during a given period of time.
- Income approach: the GDP is the sum of all returns to factors of
production received during a given period of time. It is simply the sum of
wages, rents, interests, and profits.
- Expenditure approach: the GDP is equal to actual aggregate expenditure.
It could be calculated as the sum of actual consumption, actual
investment, actual government expenditure, and actual net exports.
3
\
The higher the MPC, the higher the multiplier effect. On the extreme, if
MPC is equal to 1 (i.e. a given change in disposable income does not affect
savings), the resulting change in income due to a very small change in
expenditure is infinite.
What do you think group A will use this money for? Right, 75% of it will
be spent on goods and services sold by another group of sellers, say group B,
and the remaining 25% will be saved. Following the same line of reasoning,
$75 [0.75 (100)] of new incomes are now created in the economy.
Group B will do exactly the same thing. 75% of this $75 will be spent.
They are now new incomes for group C, and so forth. This process will
continue until the last change in aggregate income is equal to zero.
dY = 100 + .75 (100) + (.75) (.75) 100 + (.75) (.75) (.75) 100 + ………..
dY = 100 [ 1 + .75 + (.75)2 + (.75)3 + ………………+ 0]
More generally,
4
\
i
dY dG c c c c ........ c
0 1 2 3
1
dG c dG
i 0 1 c
This is true for all |c| < 1.
Therefore,
dY 1
dG 1 c
This is the value of the spending multiplier in a closed economy with lump-sum
taxes.
I would say Yes and No. It follows the same basic idea under the same
simplifying assumptions (this is the “yes”), but its effect has an opposite
direction and a different magnitude (that’s the “no” !!). Let’s work it out.
Consider a tax increase by $100 (paid by group A). Initially, this reduces
disposable income (Y-T) by $100. Here is a critical point: A change in Yd does
not affect the aggregate income directly; it affects it indirectly through its effect
on consumption!!
Mathematically,
dY = – .75 (100) – (.75) (.75) 100 – (.75) (.75) (.75) 100 – ………..
dY = –100 [.75 + (.75)2 + (.75)3 + ………………+ 0]
More generally,
5
\
i
dY dT c c c ........ c
1 2 3
c
dT c dT
i1 1 c
Again, this is true for all |c| < 1.
Therefore,
dY c
dT 1 c
This is the value of the tax multiplier in a closed economy with lump-sum taxes.
6
\
C c0 c1Yd
c0 is the autonomous consumption, which means the part of
consumption which does not depend on disposable income. The
value of c 0 is constant regardless of the value of disposable income.
c 0 is the value of consumption expenditure when Yd = zero.
Therefore, c 0 is the intercept of the consumption function.
c1 is the marginal propensity to consume (MPC), which is the change
in consumption expenditure due to a one-unit change in disposable
income. Therefore, c1 is the slope of the consumption function. That
is,
dC
MPC c1 , 0 c1 1
dYd
7
\
S Yd C ------------------------- (1)
We know that:
C c0 c1Yd ------------------------- (2)
Therefore, we can substitute for C in equation (1) by its value in equation (2):
S Yd c0 c1Yd
S Yd c0 c1Yd
MPS 1 c1 , 0 1 c1 1
dS
dYd
8
\
C, S
45o line (Yd =
C)
C
C = Yd
S=0
E
c0
Yd
- c0
On this graph:
At any point on the 45o line, the value on the horizontal axis equals the value
on the vertical axis. Therefore, the 45o line enables us to measure disposable
income (Yd) on the vertical axis, as well as consumption and saving.
Point E is known as the break-even point. At this point, all disposable income
is spent on consumption (C = Yd), which means that there is no saving (S = 0).
Point E is not an equilibrium point, it is just a break-even point.
To the left of point E, C > Yd, which implies S < 0. Similarly, to the right of
point E, consumption expenditure is less than disposable income (C < Yd) ,
which means that saving is positive (S > 0).
9
\
IS equation: Y cY T Y I r , Y G
Totally Differentiating: dY cdY T dY I r dr I Y dY dG
I I
where I r 0 and I Y 0.
r Y
10
\
m k Y l r
M
LM equation:
P
Totally differentiating: dm k dY l dr -------------------- (2)
Here, dm = 0. Therefore, 0 k dY l dr
k
Rearranging: k dY l dr dr dY -------------------- (3)
l
Substituting for dr from (3) in (1):
1 c1 T I Y dY I r k dY dG
l
Irk
1 c 1 T I dY dG
l
Y
dY 1
G - multiplier (or FP - multiplier)
Irk
1 c1 T I Y
dG
l
Tax multiplier
dY
II. :
Ydt
IS equation: Y cY tY I r , Y G
Totally Differentiating: dY cdY tdY Ydt I r dr I Y dY dG
Setting dG = 0 and rearranging:
1 c1 t IY dY cYdt I r dr -------------------- (4)
Substituting for dr from (3) in (4):
11
\
dY c
T - multiplier
Irk
1 c1 T I Y
Ydt
l
Monetary Policy multiplier :
dY
III.
dm
Ir
M P - multiplier
dY
l
Irk
1 c1 T I Y
dm
l
Notes:
G-multiplier is always greater than T-multiplier (always = no matter what
assumptions we are using). This is simply because MPC is always less than one.
FP-multiplier > MP multiplier iff |Ir| < |l'|. Intuitively, this is the case if
investment is less sensitive to changes in the real interest rate than the demand
for money. (Keep it between you and me: this is almost always the case, it has
some theoretical justification and empirical evidence).
If taxes are lump-sum, keeping every thing else as it is, you just need to set
T' or t equal to zero in the multiplier formulas shown above, and you will get the
right multipliers.
If I = I (r), keeping every thing else as it is, you just need to set IY equal to
zero in the multiplier formulas shown above, and you will get the right
multipliers.
The only difference between the IS-LM model and the simple Keynesian
model is that money (and hence the real interest rate) is neutral in the simple
Keynesian model. Accordingly, you just need to set Ir = 0 to get the simple
12
\
model’s multipliers we had before. Try it!! You will be surprised that in this
case MP-multiplier is a big ZERO!! This is what I mean by “money is neutral in
the simple Keynesian model”.
YIS
A
b1
r KY m Lr
1 c1 1 t b2 1 c1 1 t b2 Dividing by K:
A m L
Where
1 c1 1 t b2 is the horizontal intercept of the YLM r
K K
b1
IS curve, and
1 c1 1 t b2 is the inverse of its slope. Where
m
M
P is the
K K
intercept of the LM
L
curve, and is the
K
inverse of its slope.
13
\
I. Slope: dr 1 c 1 T I Y 1 c1 1 t b2 dr k K
dY IS Ir b1 dY LM l L
II. Shifters: A change in any factor that appears in the A change in any factor
intercept of the IS curve will shift the IS curve. that appears in the
intercept of the LM
An increase in c0, b0, or G will shift IS to
curve will shift the
the right (parallelly). (e.g. an expansionary
LM curve.
fiscal policy).
An increase in M
An increase in the tax rate, i.e. a
(an expansionary
contractionary fiscal policy, or an increase in
monetary policy) will
the saving rate, i.e. MPS, will shift IS to the
shift LM to the right
left (unparallelly).
(parallelly).
An increase in MPC or MPI will shift IS to
An increase in P
the right (unparallelly).
will shift LM to the
left (parallelly).
An increase in K
(=k') (when Md
becomes more
sensitive to changes in
income, or when
individuals prefer to
keep a higher
proportion of their
income in liquidity)
will shift LM to the
left (unparallelly).
III. Rotators: A change in any factor that appears in the A change in any factor
slope of the IS curve will rotate the IS curve. that appears in the
slope of the LM curve
An increase in the tax rate or in the MPS,
will rotate the LM
will rotate IS anti-clockwise. Therefore, IS
curve.
becomes flatter.
An increase in K
An increase in the MPC or in the MPI, will
(=k') will rotate LM
rotate IS clockwise. Therefore, IS becomes
anti-clockwise.
steeper.
Therefore, LM
An increase in Ir (= b1) (when investment becomes steeper.
becomes more sensitive to changes in r) rotates
14
\
At any point to the left of (or below) the IS At any point to the
curve: left of (or above) the
Y<E OR S+T<I+G LM curve: Md < Ms
15
\
Some combinations are really interesting (and important for the exam purposes as
well). The following table summarizes the effects of these combinations.
Effects on Y
Effect on I Effect on Md Effects on T and BD
and R
Expansionary FP Y increases, Ambiguous Definitely increases T definitely increase, but the
& expansionary but the effect effect on BD is ambiguous
I definitely (dMs = dMd).
MP on r is increases if r Transactions Md BD increases if the increase
(both G and Ms ambiguous decreases or increases in G > the increase in T.
increase) r increases remains BD decreases if the increase
if the shift in constant. Speculative Md
may increase, in G < the increase in T.
IS > the shift I may decrease, or remain BD remains unchanged if
in LM. increase, constant, depending the increase in G = the
r decreases decrease, or on the change in r. increase in T.
if the shift in remain
IS < the shift unchanged if
in LM. r increases.
r remains
unchanged if
the two shifts
are equal.
16
\
Effects on Y and
Effect on I Effect on Md Effects on T and BD
R
Expansionary r increases, but the Ambiguous Definitely Ambiguous
FP & effect on Y is decreases
I definitely T increase, decrease, or
contractionary ambiguous decreases if Y (dMs = dMd). remain constant depending
MP Y increases if decreases or remains Transactions Md on the change in Y.
(G increases the shift in IS > constant. may increase, BD definitely increases if
and Ms the shift in LM.
I may increase, decrease, or Y decreases or remains
decreases)
Y decreases if decrease, or remain remain constant, constant.
the shift in IS < unchanged if Y depending on the BD may decrease,
the shift in LM. increases. change in Y.
increase, or remain constant
Y remains Speculative Md if Y increases.
unchanged if the decreases.
two shifts are
equal.
Contractionary r decreases, but Ambiguous Definitely Ambiguous
FP & the effect on Y is I definitely increases T increase, decrease, or
expansionary ambiguous increases if Y (dMs = dMd). remain constant depending
MP Y increases if increases or remains Transactions Md on the change in Y.
(G decreases the shift in IS < constant. may increase, BD definitely decreases if
and Ms the shift in LM.
I may increase, decrease, or Y increases or remains
increases)
Y decreases if decrease, or remain remain constant, constant.
the shift in IS > unchanged if Y depending on the BD may decrease,
the shift in LM. decreases. change in Y.
increase, or remain constant
Y remains Speculative Md if Y decreases.
unchanged if the increases.
two shifts are
equal.
Contractionary Y decreases, but Ambiguous Definitely T definitely decrease, but
FP & the effect on r is I definitely decreases the effect on BD is
contractionary ambiguous decreases if r (dMs = dMd). ambiguous
MP r increases if the increases or remains Transactions Md BD increases if the
(both G and shift in IS < the constant. decreases decrease in G < the decrease
Ms decrease) shift in LM. in T.
I may increase, Speculative Md
r decreases if the decrease, or remain may increase, BD decreases if the
shift in IS > the unchanged if r decrease, or decrease in G > the decrease
shift in LM. decreases. remain constant, in T.
r remains depending on the BD doesn’t change if the
unchanged if the change in r. decrease in G = the decrease
two shifts are in T.
equal.
17
\
Notes on Phillips Curve, Okun’s Law, and the Quantity Theory of Money
In the classical macroeconomics, three major relations are of special importance:
I. Phillips Curve:
A. Static Phillips Curve:
This is the original version of Phillips curve, as presented by the British economist
Arthur Phillips in 1958. Using data about unemployment rate and wage inflation in the U.K.
over about a whole century, Phillips finds that there is a stable negative relationship between
unemployment rate and inflation rate. An increase in the inflation rate is associated with a
decrease in unemployment rate, and vice versa. This relationship is called the “Static Phillips
Curve”, and could be represented mathematically as:
t a bU t
This oversimplified version of Phillips curve has several shortcomings, among which:
1. It ignores the effect of expectations on unemployment. That is, it assumes that expected
inflation is constant.
2. It ignores the fact that there is positive natural rate of unemployment (Un). That is, it
assumes that this rate is equal to zero. (Note: there is another name for Un, which is Non-
Accelerating-Inflation Rate of Unemployment, or NAIRU).
3. It assumes that raising inflation to a sufficiently high level (= a in the above equation)
could reduce unemployment rate to zero. This is certainly not true, as unemployment rate has
a floor of Un. It also assumes that inflating only once can reduce unemployment permanently.
4. It failed to explain the phenomenon of stagflation, which implies a simultaneous rise in
both inflation and unemployment.
5. Most importantly, it assumes that nominal variables (such as inflation) have a permanent
effect on real variables (such as unemployment) .
B. Expectations-Augmented Phillips Curve:
Due to the failure of the static Phillips curve, many attempts have been made to
modify it in a way that overcomes the above-listed shortcomings. The most successful one
was made by Milton Friedman and Edmund Phelps in the 1960s. By introducing the natural
rate hypothesis, and by accounting for inflationary expectations, Friedman and Phelps came
up with the so-called Expectations Augmented Phillips Curve.
According to the expectations augmented Phillips curve, unexpected inflation is
negatively related with the difference between the unemployment rate and its natural level.
This could be represented by the following equation:
t te U t U n
(Hint: assuming that te constant and Un = 0 will result in the static Phillips curve).
According to this Phillips Curve:
An increase in actual inflation (t) leads to a decrease in current unemployment (Ut).
An increase in expected inflation (te) leads to an increase in current unemployment (Ut).
This is simply because when they expect higher price level, workers will ask for higher
18
\
wages, which raises the cost of labor and thus reduces the demand for labor. As a result, Ut
rises.
An increase in current inflation usually leads to an increase in expected inflation. This
implies that an increase in inflation due to an expansionary (fiscal or monetary) policy will
initially reduce unemployment. This reduction in unemployment will be cancelled out (fully
or partly) by an increase in Ut because of the increase in expected inflation.
Therefore, the positive effect of any anticipated expansionary policy on unemployment
will be temporary. In the long run, any anticipated policy will not have any real effects .
This is known as policy ineffectiveness proposition (in its simplest form). To have real
effects, the policy must be unanticipated, unannounced, or surprise policy. In other words,
the government (or the Fed) must deceive the public.
II. Okun’s Law:
Okun’s law is expressed by the following equation:
dU U t U t 1 0.43.0 g yt
OR : g yt 3.0 2.5U t U t 1
Note that all numbers in the second equation are in percent. That is, 3 means 3% (or
0.03) and 2.5 means 2.5% (or 0.025). Thus, the resulting gyt should be in percent.
This means:
With no change in unemployment, the normal growth rate is 3%. Note that when we say
growth rate we mean growth rate of real GDP (or real output).
An increase in unemployment rate by 1% leads to a reduction in the growth rate by 2.5%.
Hint: unless otherwise specified, and before adopting any economic policy, Ut-1 = Un. Thus,
the normal growth rate is the growth rate when Ut = Ut-1 = Un. According to Okun’s law, the
normal growth rate is always 3%.
III. The Quantity Theory of Money:
The quantity theory of money states that:
P. Y = M. V
where P is the price level, Y is the real output (real GDP), PY is nominal output (nominal
GDP), M is the money supply, and V is the velocity of money.
Velocity of money is the number of times money circulates in the economy during a given
period, usually one year. Put differently, it is the number of times the money supply is spent
on purchasing goods and services during a given period, usually a year. V is assumed to be
fixed in the short run.
Given this definition of velocity, it is obvious that the above equation is simply an
identity. It is a definitional, not a functional equation. Nominal GDP, by definition, must
equal to the money supply times the velocity. THIS IS NOT INTERESTING AT ALL,
RIGHT?
This equation could be interesting if we write it in terms of growth rates, not absolute
values. To do that, we need to take logs across this equation and then differentiate it with
respect to time.
19
\
Taking logs:
ln P ln Y ln M ln V .
Differentiate with respect to time:
ln P P ln Y Y ln M M ln V V
P t Y t M t V t
V ln X 1
We know that is zero because V is constant. We also know that , and that
t X X
X
X . Applying these rules to P, Y, and M, we get:
t
P Y M
t g yt g mt t g mt g yt
P Y M
This implies that:
- If g mt g yt , inflation rate will be zero.
20
\
Notes on Expectations
We have three major theories of expectations:
I. Naïve Expectations (Random Walk):
This is the simplest type of expectations, and the least realistic one as well. It simply
says that the price level is equal to the last period’s price level, plus a random shock. That is,
Et 1 Pt Pt 1 t
That is, we care only about last period’s price level when we forecast this period’s
price level. This is an oversimplified way of thinking about how expectations are formed.
II. Adaptive Expectations (Error Correction):
According to adaptive expectations theory, the expected value of the future price level is
composed of two parts: the actual price level when expectations are formed, and an
adjustment for the error in the previous expectations. Therefore,
(1) Et Pt 1 Pt Et 1 Pt Pt for expectations formed at time t
- The term Et Pt 1 is read as “the expectation, formed at time t, of the price level at time
t+1”. Understanding this, you can easily read the terms Et 1 Pt , Et 2 Pt 1 , and so on.
(Note that you can use the notation t 1 Pt instead of Et 1 Pt . Both are the same.)
On the right hand side:
- The first term is the current actual price level. The second term is the adjustment
factor, , times the error made in forecasting the price level in the previous period.
Rearranging the above equations:
Et Pt 1 Pt Et 1 Pt Pt for expectations formed at time t
21
\
Et Pt 1 1 Pt 1 Pt 1 2 Et 2 Pt 1
But Et 2 Pt 1 Pt 2 Et 3 Pt 2 Pt 2 . Therefore,
dP e
Where Pe = Et-1Pt, P = Pt, and p .
dP
- If p 0 , dPe = 0 (no adjustment of the expected price level when P changes). This is
exactly the case of complete money illusion. It implies that workers are interested only
in the money wage, W. This case is relevant only in the short run.
22
\
23
\
l r k Y
M
LM equation:
P
Totally differentiating IS equation:
dY cdY tdY Ydt I dr dG
1 c1 t dY cYdt I dr dG ………………… (1)
Totally differentiating LM equation:
PdM MdP PdM MdP dM MdP
2
l dr k dY l dr 2
k dY l dr 2 k dY
P P P P
1 M k
dr dM 2 dP dY ………………… (2)
l P l P l
Substituting for dr from (2) in (1):
k
1 c1 t dY cYdt I 1 dM
M
dP dY dG
l P l P 2 l
I M I k
1 c1 t dY cYdt I dM 2 dP dY dG
l P l P l
I k I I M
1 c 1 t dY c Ydt dM dP dG ………………… (3)
l l P l P 2
We can simplify (3) by setting the initial price level equal to unity (i.e. P = 1). Therefore,
I k I I M
1 c 1 t dY dG c Ydt dM dP ………………… (4)
l l l
Equation (4) is the general form that can be used to derive the AD equation, the slope of
the AD curve, as well as all multipliers of the AD model.
The slope of the AD curve:
Along the AD curve, dG = dt = dM = 0. Therefore, we can rewrite (4) as:
24
\
I k I M
1 c1 t l dY l dP
I k
1 c 1 t
dP
l
I M ………………… (5)
dY AD
l
This is the slope of AD. Given that 0 c1 t 1 , I' < 0, k' > 0, l' < 0, and M > 0; this
slope must be negative.
The Multipliers of the AD Model:
The various multipliers of the AD curve measure the effect of fiscal or monetary policies
on equilibrium output. In the AD-AS model, the direct effect of any fiscal or monetary policy
is a shift in only the AD curve, but the equilibrium output is determined by both the AD and
AS curves.
When the AD curve shifts as a result of a policy, the economy reaches a new intersection
point between the AD and AS. This simply means that the shift in the AD curve is associated
with a movement along the AS curve. This movement along the AS leads to a change in the
equilibrium price level.
As a result, the effect of any economic policy on the equilibrium output will depend,
among other factors, on this AS-related change in price level. This effect should be included
in the expression of all multipliers.
To do that, we need to rewrite equation (4) by multiplying the last term of the RHS by
dY
:
dY
I k I I M dP
1 c1 t l dY dG cYdt l dM l dY dY
dP dP dP
where is the slope of the AS curve. That is, . Therefore,
dY dY dY AS
I k I I M dP
1 c1 t l dY dG cYdt l dM l dY dY ………………… (6)
AS
We will use equation (6) instead of (4) in deriving all the multipliers.
I. The spending multiplier (G multiplier):
dY
The spending multiplier is given by . Following ceteris paribus assumption, we
dG
assume that dt = dM = 0. Rewrite (6) as:
25
\
I k I M dP
1 c 1 t dY dG dY
l l dY AS
I k I M dP
1 c1 t dY dG
l l dY AS
dY 1 1
dG I k I M dP D ………………… (7)
1 c 1 t
l l dY AS
I k I M dP
1 c 1 t dY c Ydt dY
l l dY AS
I k I M dP
1 c1 t dY cYdt
l l dY AS
dY c Y c Y
dt I k I M dP D ………………… (8)
1 c 1 t
l l dY AS
I k I I M dP
1 c 1 t dY dM dY
l l l dY AS
I k I M dP I
1 c1 t dY dM
l l dY AS l
26
\
dY I l I l
dM I k I M dP D ………………… (9)
1 c 1 t
l l dY AS
This is the monetary policy multiplier (multiplier of the change in money) in the AD
model.
The AD equation:
The AD Equation:
I k I I M
1 c1 t l dY dG cYdt l dM l dP
To derive the AD equation, we may need to simplify equation (4) above. Let
I k
1 c1 t . Also assume that the initial money stock is equal to unity (M = P = 1).
l
Equation (4) becomes:
1 I I
dY dG c Ydt dM dP
l l
Setting dG = dt = 0, we get:
I
dY dM dP dY dM dP ………………… (10)
l
l
where .
I
Also, changes in Y, M, and P could be interpreted as:
dY Yt Yt 1 dM M t M t 1 dP Pt Pt 1
Therefore, equation (10) could be rewritten as:
Yt Yt 1 M t M t 1 Pt Pt 1
But M t 1 Pt 1 1 . Therefore,
Yt Yt 1 M t Pt Yt Yt 1 M t Pt
27
\
f N W P. f N
W
w , where f 0
P
This implies that when the wage rate increases, producers demand less labor services.
3) Labor Supply (Ns): labor supply is given by:
g N W P e .g N
W
we e
, where g 0
P
This implies that when the wage rate increases, workers supply more labor services.
4) Price Expectations function: price expectations may be exogenous (as in adaptive
expectation), or endogenous (as in rational expectations).
o With exogenous (adaptive) expectations: we may use P e pP , where
dP e
0 p 1 . p 0 in the extreme Keynesian case of perfect money illusion, but
dP
p 1 for the extreme classical case of full adjustment.
o With endogenous (rational) expectations: we use Pt Et 1 Pt t , where
Et 1 t 0 .
28
\
dN
w
g f
dP dP e -------------- (14)
dP g f
dY AS w1 p f -------------- (17)
II. Deriving the Slope of the AS curve with Endogenous (Rational) Expectations
In this case, the only difference is that we cannot use the relationship P e pP .
Therefore, we can start with equation (14), as every thing before that is the same as in the
previous case. We can rewrite (14) as:
29
\
dN
f
g f
dP dP e -------------------- (14')
dY
f2
g f
dP dP e dY dP dP e -------------- (18)
f2
where
g f
Along the AS curve, dPe = 0. Therefore, along the AS:
dP 1 g f
dY dP
dY AS f2 -------------------- (19)
This is the slope of the AS curve with rational expectations. It is clear that it is positive.
Very important note: this is exactly the same as the slope of the AS curve with
endogenous expectations in the Keynesian case of p 0 (notice that w = f under the
assumption that P = Pe = 1). In this case, past price levels do not affect expected price level,
which is a common feature with rational expectations. This means that under the rational
expectations assumption, we assume no relationship between the expected prices and the past
prices. (Keep it between you and me: this is another way of saying that we assume p 0 ).
III. Deriving the AS function with Endogenous (Rational) Expectations
We know that dP Pt Pt 1 and dP e t 1 Pt t 1 Pt 1 dP e t 1 Pt Pt 1 . We also
know that dY Yt Yt 1 Substituting in (18):
Yt Yt 1 Pt Pt 1 t 1 Pt Pt 1
30
\
Yt Yt 1 M t t 1 Pt 1 t
1 1 --------------- (21)
Let .
1
1
Yt Yt 1 M t t 1 Pt t t --------------- (21')
This is the solution for Yt in its linearized Sargent and Wallace form with exogenous
expectations.
II. Equilibrium output with endogenous (Rational) expectations:
AD equation: Pt Yt Yt 1 M t t --------------------- (11)
31
\
t 1 Yt Yt 1 t 1 Pt t 1 Pt t 1 t
By rational expectations hypothesis, we know that t 1 Pt t 1 Pt t 1 t 0.
Therefore,
t 1 Yt Yt 1 ------------------- (23)
Step 3: substitute for t 1 Yt from (10) in (9):
t 1 Pt t 1 M t ------------------- (24)
Step 4: substitute for Pt (from 11) and t 1 Pt (from 24) in the AS equation (eq. 20):
Yt Yt 1 Yt Yt 1 M t t t 1 M t t
Yt Yt 1 Yt Yt 1 M t t 1 M t t t
1 Yt 1 Yt 1 M t t 1 M t t t
Yt Yt 1 M t t 1 M t 1 t t ----------------- (25)
1 1
Let
1
1
Yt Yt 1 M t t 1 M t t t ------------------- (25')
This is the solution for Yt with endogenous (rational) expectations.
Comparing (25) to (21), or (25') to (21'), we can see that the single difference is the
substitution in (25) and (25') of t 1 M t for t 1 Pt in (21) and (21').
Equations (25) and (25') say that, with endogenous or rational expectations, the difference
between actual money supply M t and expected money supply t 1 M t moves output.
In equations (21) and (21'), with exogenous or adaptive expectations, it is the difference
between actual money supply M t and expected prices level t 1 Pt that moves output.
This difference is due to the fact that with endogenous expectations, expectations are
taken from the model. That is, expected price movements are determined by the expected
money movements.
Equations (25) and (25') are the basis of the famous policy ineffectiveness proposition:
Under rational expectations, it is the deviations of actual policy from the public’s
expectations of it that have an effect on real output. Under rational expectations, any
expected (or anticipated) policy has only nominal effects, i.e. effects on the price level. Only
32
\
unanticipated policies have real effects. This is another way of stating that money is neutral,
even in the short run, if the policy is expected.
In equations (25) and (25'), Yt deviates from its classical equilibrium level, Yt 1 , only
because of random shocks to demand and supply, t and t , and unanticipated policy.
The original classical model, based on complete wage and price flexibility, had a vertical
AS curve in the long run. The new classical model, based on both flexibility of wages and
prices and policy ineffectiveness, has a vertical AS curve in both short run and long run.
33
\
34
\
35
\
36
\
37
\
38
\
39
\
40
\
41
\
42
\
43
\
44
\
45
\
46
\
47
\
48
\
49
\
Spring, 2008
There are 100 points on this part of the qualifying Examination. All parts are equally
weighted. Show all your work.
50
\
4. To stop the economy from sliding to recession, the Fed has resorted to
expansionary monetary policy, lowering the Federal Funds rate to 2% and
increasing liquidity. The government, on the other hand, has followed by
expecting the tax cut and mailing the rebates early. Take the text book by
Keynesian IS-LM model and analyze the effectiveness of these policies separately
and together under the following assumptions:
a. Assume that individuals have a myopic view of the economy and do not
consider the effects of the policy change on future macro variables.
b. Assume that individuals consider the long-run effects of changes in future
macro variables when forming expectations of future output and future
interest rates (foresighted economic agents).
5. A simple macro-model of the economy is expressed by the following equilibrium
conditions in three markets:
Goods Market: Y=c(Y-tY)+I(r)+G
Money Market: M/P=I(r)+ k(Y)
Labor Market: Pf(N)=Pe(g(N))
The Production technology of the economy is given by the aggregate production
function, Y=F(N, K). it is assumed that economic agents form their expectations of the future
prices by using the current and the past prices as expressed by expectation model Pe =P(P).
Answer the following questions given the information above.
51