Says Law
Says Law
Says Law
Aggregate supply
YS = f(L, K) in the classical model where L is determined in the labor market
while K is exogenous
The aggregate supply YS is defined as the amount of finished goods and services firms
in a country will want to sell under given conditions. In the classical model the aggregate
supply is determined by production function, YS = f[L, K).
The amount of capital in the classical model is an exogenous variable; it is not determined
within the model but assumed to be given. Although we typically assume that K is constant
- which is reasonable in the short run - it need not be constant. K may increase over time,
but we must know K at any point in time.
The amount of labor, however, is an endogenous variable that is determined in the labor
market. This means that YS is determined entirely by the labor market in the classical
model. The following chart illustrates.
The aggregate demand YD is defined as the quantity of nationally produced finished
goods and services that consumers, government and the rest of the world want to buy
under given conditions. One of the key elements of the classical model is Say’s Law.
According to Say’s Law the aggregate demand is always equal to the aggregate supply: YD =
YS.
Say’s Law is sometimes stated as "supply creates its own demand". The motivation for this
statement is something like this. If production (Y) increases by one billion, the national
income will also increase by one billion. This means that individuals will have exactly one
more billion for spending - just enough to buy the increase in production. Thus, YD will
also increase by one billion. An increase in the supply of one billion has created an increased
in the demand by the same amount.
This is not the motivation behind Say’s Law which is not an equilibrium condition. In the
classical model, YD and YS are real variables that do not depend on the price
level. This may strike you as odd. YS depends only directly on L and K and indirectly on
the real wage. If the price level increases in the classical model, the wage level will increase
by the same amount leaving the real wage unchanged. As for aggregate demand, if the price
level and the wage level both increase (by the same amount), there is really no change for
the consumers. If all prices double while you income doubles, there is no need to adjust you
demand.
The justification for Say’s Law is not as an equilibrium condition through price adjustments.
No price adjustment in the world will equilibrate aggregate demand and aggregate supply in
the classical model. Instead, the justification is based on income effects rather than on price
effects: higher supply == higher income == higher demand.
The reason why Say’s law is so controversial is the following. Suppose that consumers and
investors fear that the economy will slow down. They might then decide to save a substantial
part of their income and aggregate demand may not be equal to aggregate supply. This is
really the starting point for Keynesian economics which we will meet in the next chapter.
The demand for a good depends on several factors, such as price of the good,
perceived quality, advertising, income, confidence of consumers and changes in
taste and fashion.
We can look at either an individual demand curve or the total demand in the
economy.
The individual demand curve illustrates the price people are willing to pay
for a particular quantity of a good.
The market demand curve will be the sum of all individual demand curves.
It shows the quantity of a good consumers plan to buy at different prices.
1. Change in price
A change in price causes a movement along the Demand Curve.
For example, if there is an increase in price from $12 to £16 then there will be a
fall in demand from 80 to 60.
This occurs when, even at the same price, consumers are willing to buy a higher
(or lower) quantity of goods. This will occur if there is a shift in the conditions of
demand.
Even at the same price of $12, more is demanded.
A shift to the right in the demand curve can occur for a number of reasons:
Evaluation
For some luxury goods, income will be an important determinant of
demand. e.g. if your income increased you would buy more restaurant
meals, but probably not more salt.
Advertising is important for goods in which branding is important, e.g. soft
drinks but not for bananas.
Other types of demand
Effective demand: This occurs when a consumers desire to buy a good
can be backed up by his ability to afford it.
Derived demand: This occurs when a good or factor of production such as
labour is demanded for another reason
A Giffen good is a good where an increase in price of a basic item leads to
an increase in demand, because very poor people cannot afford any other
luxury goods.
An ostentatious good, is a good where an increase in price leads to an
increase in demand because people believe it is now better.
Composite demand – A good which is demanded for multiple different
uses
Joint demand – goods bought together e.g. printer and printer ink.
Related pages
The individual demand curve illustrates the price people are willing to pay
for a particular quantity of a good.
The market demand curve will be the sum of all individual demand curves.
It shows the quantity of a good consumers plan to buy at different prices.
1. Change in price
A change in price causes a movement along the Demand Curve.
For example, if there is an increase in price from $12 to £16 then there will be a
fall in demand from 80 to 60.
This occurs when, even at the same price, consumers are willing to buy a higher
(or lower) quantity of goods. This will occur if there is a shift in the conditions of
demand.
Factors which can shift the demand curve
A shift to the right in the demand curve can occur for a number of reasons:
A fall in demand could occur due to lower disposable income or decline in the
popularity of the good.
Evaluation
For some luxury goods, income will be an important determinant of
demand. e.g. if your income increased you would buy more restaurant
meals, but probably not more salt.
Advertising is important for goods in which branding is important, e.g. soft
drinks but not for bananas.
Other types of demand
Effective demand: This occurs when a consumers desire to buy a good
can be backed up by his ability to afford it.
Derived demand: This occurs when a good or factor of production such as
labour is demanded for another reason
A Giffen good is a good where an increase in price of a basic item leads to
an increase in demand, because very poor people cannot afford any other
luxury goods.
An ostentatious good, is a good where an increase in price leads to an
increase in demand because people believe it is now better.
Composite demand – A good which is demanded for multiple different
uses
Joint demand – goods bought together e.g. printer and printer ink.
Related pages
Monetarists argue that if the Money Supply rises faster than the rate of growth of
national income, then there will be inflation.
If the money supply increases in line with real output then there will be no
inflation.
M.Friedman stated:
M = Money Supply
V= Velocity of circulation
P= Price Level and
T = Transactions.
T is difficult to measure so it is often substituted for Y = National Income
The above equation must hold the value of expenditure on goods and services
must equal the value of output.
Monetarists believe that in the short-term velocity (V) is fixed This is because the
rate at which money circulates is determined by institutional factors, e.g. how
often workers are paid does not change very much. Milton Friedman admitted it
might vary a little but not very much so it can be treated as fixed
Monetarists also believe output Y is fixed. They state it may vary in the short run
but not in the long run (because LRAS is inelastic and determined by supply-side
factors.)
Example 1
If the total money supply is initially £1000 and the velocity of circulation is
5.
The level of output (Y) is 5000 units.
£1000×5 = P (5000)
Therefore P = 1
If the money supply now doubles the equation =
2000×5 =P×5000
Therefore P = 2
Example 2
If the output is 1,000 units, and there is a money supply of £10,000. The
average price of good will be £10.
In year 2, if the output stays at 1,000 units, but money supply increases to
15,000. Consumers have more money to buy the same amount of goods.
Therefore, firms put up prices to reflect this increase in money supply.
Ceteris paribus, average prices will rise from £10 to £15.
Other points
Milton Friedman predicted an increase in the money supply would take
about 9-12 months to lead to higher output.
Friedman placed great emphasis on the role of price expectations. If there
are expectations of higher inflation, it becomes self-fulfilling – workers
demand higher wages to meet rising living costs. Firms put up prices to
meet rising costs. Strict monetarist policies would help reduce
expectations.
After another year output will return to its initial equilibrium causing prices
to rise to accommodate the rise in money supply
Cambridge Version of quantity theory states P= f(M)
Monetarism became more popular in the 1970s due to rising inflation.
(partly caused by rising oil prices).
In the early 1980s, the UK and US adopted monetarist policies with mixed
results.
Friedman’s k-percent rule
Milton Friedman argued that the money supply should rise by a fixed k-
percent each year. This rate of increase should depend on institutional
factors and be determined independently of policymakers.
Friedman believed this rule would avoid the extremes of deflation (Falling
money supply, e.g. Great Depression) and inflation due to rising money
supply.
It would give business strong expectations of what would happen to money
supply and inflation.
Monetarist inflation in the AD and AS model
Following a rise in the Money Supply, consumers have more money and
therefore spend more money on goods; this shifts AD to the right. AD1 to
AD 2.
Firms respond by increasing output along SRAS. Real output increases
from Y1 to Y2.
National output now exceeds the equilibrium level of output. Therefore
there is an inflationary gap.
Firms need to hire more workers, so wages rise leading to an increase in
costs and hence prices. Initially, workers agree to work more hours
because they see an increase in nominal wages.
As prices rise money can buy less, therefore, there is a movement to the
left along the new AD
Also, workers realise the increase in nominal wage is not a real wage
increase. Therefore, workers also demand higher nominal wages to
produce more output and to compensate them for rising prices, therefore
SRAS shifts to the left.
The economy has returned to the equilibrium level of output (Y1), but at a
higher price level (P3).
Therefore the rise in the Money Supply cause a rise in AD, But because
the LRAS is inelastic there is no increase in real output, but inflation rises.
It is a form of demand-pull inflation.
Monetarist view of Phillips curve
Mo
netarists believe in the long-run there is no trade-off between inflation and
unemployment. Increase in the money supply only causes an increase in nominal
GDP, but not real GDP.
Criticisms of monetarism
The link between the money supply and inflation is often very weak in
practice.
The velocity of circulation (V) is not stable but can vary significantly due to
confidence, changes in the use of credit cards, decline in use of cash. e.t.c
Targetting arbitrary money supply targets can cause a severe recession
and high unemployment. For example, UK targetted money supply growth
in the early 1980s, but this caused the recession of 1981 with many
economists arguing it was deeper than necessary.
The large increase in the monetary base following the 2009 recession did
not cause any inflationary pressures.
Why not target inflation directly? If you want to control inflation, it makes
more sense to target inflation directly rather than through the intermediary
of the money supply.
Monetarists say that income can vary in the short run, but the short run
could be a long time and therefore make monetary policy ineffective,
Keynesians argue that the LRAS is not necessarily inelastic they argue
that the economy can be below full capacity for a long time.
Related
Market equilibrium
5 December 2019 by Tejvan Pettinger
In the diagram below, the equilibrium price is P1. The equilibrium quantity is Q1.
If price is below the equilibrium
In the above diagram, price (P2) is below the equilibrium. At this price,
demand would be greater than the supply. Therefore there is a shortage of
(Q2 – Q1)
If there is a shortage, firms will put up prices and supply more. As price
rises, there will be a movement along the demand curve and less will be
demanded.
Therefore the price will rise to P1 until there is no shortage and supply =
demand.
If price is above the equilibrium
If price was at P2, this is above the equilibrium of P1. At the price of P2,
then supply (Q2) would be greater than demand (Q1) and therefore there
is too much supply. There is a surplus. (Q2-Q1)
Therefore firms would reduce price and supply less. This would encourage
more demand and therefore the surplus will be eliminated. The new market
equilibrium will be at Q3 and P1.
Movements to a new equilibrium
1. Increase in demand
If there was an increase in income the demand curve would shift to the right (D1
to D2). Initially, there would be a shortage of the good. Therefore the price and
quantity supplied will increase leading to a new equilibrium at Q2, P2.
2. Increase in supply
An increase in supply would lead to a lower price and more quantity sold.
Related posts
A production possibility frontier shows how much an economy can produce given
existing resources.
A production possibility can show the different choices that an economy faces.
For example, when an economy produces on the PPF curve, increasing the
output of goods will have an opportunity cost of fewer services.
If more resources are devoted to capital goods (e.g. building new factories)
then in the short-term, consumption will go down.
However, if the investment is successful, then in the long-run, productive
capacity will increase and the PPF curve will shift to the right
Increase in capital goods has an opportunity cost of fewer consumer goods, but
in long-term can enable economic growth.
Similarly, a decline in investment can enable more consumer goods in the short-
term but can lead to lower rates of economic growth.
PPF and recession
A = full employment
B = unemployed resources
PPF and choices for government
Any government faces a trade-off in how to use scarce resources and tax
revenue. If the government increases spending on the military, then the
opportunity cost will be less spending on another public service, such as health
care.
Related
In this case, the social marginal benefit of consumption is greater than the
private marginal benefit. For example, if you take a train, it reduces
congestion for other travellers.
In a free market, consumption will be at Q1 because demand = supply
(private benefit = private cost )
However, this is socially inefficient because at Q1, social marginal cost <
social marginal benefit. Therefore there is under-consumption of the
positive externality.
Social efficiency would occur at Q2 where social cost = social benefit
For example, in a free market without government intervention, there would be
an under-consumption of education and public transport.
Positive externality (production)
This occurs when a third party benefits from the production of a good. For
example, building a train station may provide shelter for the homeless
when it is raining.
If a company develops new technology, such as a database programme,
this new technology can be implemented by other firms who will gain a
similar boost to productivity.
Tim Berners Lee who developed the World Wide Web, made it freely
available, creating a very large positive externality.
Diagram of positive externality in production
A subsidy of P0-P2 shifts supply curve to the right (S2) and the new quantity
demand will be Q2 (where SMB=SMC)
In this case, the subsidy has overcome the market failure. Though government
intervention itself could be subject to government failure.
Related
Negative Externalities
24 July 2019 by Tejvan Pettinger
The personal cost of driving are buying car, petrol, your time
The negative externalities are – pollution to other people, possible accident
to other other people, and time other people sit in traffic jams
Social cost
Social cost is the total cost to society; it includes both private and external
costs.
With a negative externality the Social Cost > Private Cost
Negative production externality
When producing a good causes a harmful effect to a third party. Therefore
the social cost is greater than the private cost.
Examples of negative production externalities
Burning coal for energy creates pollution.
Producing conventional vegetables with pesticides causes carcinogens to
get into the environment.
Producing beef in South America involves cutting down Amazon rainforest,
which has an impact on global climate and local environment
Because of the external costs the social marginal cost is greater than the
private marginal cost.
In a free market, producers ignore the external costs to others. Therefore
output will be at Q1 (where Demand = Supply).
This is socially inefficient because at Q1 – SMC> SMB
Social efficiency occurs at Q2 where Social marginal cost = Social
marginal benefit
The red triangle is the area of deadweight welfare loss. It indicates the area of
overconsumption (where SMC is greater than PMC)
In a free market, we get Q1 output. But at this output, the social marginal
cost is greater than the social marginal benefit.
The red triangle is the area of dead-weight welfare loss.
Social efficiency occurs at a lower output (Q2) – where social marginal
benefit = social marginal cost.
Implications of negative externalities
If goods or services have negative externalities, then we will get market failure.
This is because individuals fail to take into account the costs to other people.
To achieve a more socially efficient outcome, the government could try to tax the
good with negative externalities. This means that consumers pay close to the full
social cost.
1. People do not realise the true personal benefit. For example, people
underestimate the benefit of education or getting a vaccination.
2. Usually, these goods also have a positive externality.
Therefore in a free market, there will be under consumption of merit goods.
Merit and demerit goods involve making a value judgement that something is
good or bad for you. Classification is not always straightforward. For example:
Cannabis
Cannabis is widely considered a demerit good – it contributes to lung
cancer and can lead to psychological problems, such as paranoia.
However, supporters of cannabis might argue cannabis is a harmless drug
which can help people deal with physical pain and enjoy life more.
Contraception
Supporters of family planning may argue contraception is a merit good
because contraception can help prevent the personal costs of unwanted
pregnancy.
However, the Catholic church views contraception as a sin and may argue
it is actually a demerit good because contraception encourages sexual
promiscuity and undermines family values.
The problem with public goods is that they have a free-rider problem. This means
that it is not possible to prevent anyone from enjoying a good, once it has been
provided. Therefore there is no incentive for people to pay for the good because
they can consume it without paying for it.
However, this will lead to there being no good being provided.
Therefore there will be social inefficiency.
Therefore there will be a need for the govt to provide it directly out of
general taxation.
Examples of Public Goods
Bo
th a public bridge and street lighting exhibit characteristics of a public good.
Although classical economic theory suggests public goods will not be provided by
a free market, there are cases when groups of individuals can come together to
voluntarily provide public goods.
Often government failure arises from an attempt to solve market failure but
creates a different set of problems.
Reasons for government failure
There are various things the government can try and do to overcome government
failure
Also, although government failure is a real issue, it is often much less than the
problems arising from market failure. Just because government intervention may
be inefficient, doesn’t mean we should try to tackle problems of pollution e.t.c.
Related
Market Failure
28 November 2019 by Tejvan Pettinger
Diagram shows output in free-market equilibrium and how a tax can shift output
to socially efficient level
Tax on Negative Externalities – e.g. Petrol tax
Carbon Tax e.g. tax on CO2 emissions
Subsidy on positive externalities – why the government may subsidies
public transport
Laws and regulations – Simple and effective ways to regulate demerit
goods, like a ban on smoking advertising.
Buffer stocks – aim to stabilise prices
Government failure – why government intervention may not always
improve the situation
Market failure and behavioural economics
1. Profit maximisation
2. Sales maximisation
3. Increased market share/market dominance
4. Social/environmental concerns
5. Profit satisficing
6. Co-operatives
Sometimes there is an overlap of objectives. For example, seeking to increase
market share, may lead to lower profits in the short-term, but enable profit
maximisation in the long run.
Profit maximisation
However, in the real world, firms may pursue other objectives apart from profit
maximisation.
1. Profit Satisficing
Increased market share increases monopoly power and may enable the
firm to put up prices and make more profit in the long run.
Managers prefer to work for bigger companies as it leads to greater
prestige and higher salaries.
Increasing market share may force rivals out of business. E.g. the growth
of supermarkets have lead to the demise of many local shops. Some firms
may actually engage in predatory pricing which involves making a loss to
force a rival out of business.
3. Growth maximisation
This is similar to sales maximisation and may involve mergers and takeovers.
With this objective, the firm may be willing to make lower levels of profit in order
to increase in size and gain more market share. More market share increases its
monopoly power and ability to be a price setter.
5. Social/environmental concerns
A firm may incur extra expense to choose products which don’t harm the
environment or products not tested on animals. Alternatively, firms may be
concerned about local community / charitable concerns.
Types of Costs
15 June 2019 by Tejvan Pettinger
Social Costs. This is the total cost to society. It will include the private
costs plus also the external cost (cost incurred by a third party). May also
be referred to as ‘True costs’
External Costs. This is the cost imposed on a third party. For example, if
you smoke, some people may suffer from passive smoking. That is the
external cost.
Private Costs. The costs you pay. e.g. the private cost of a packet of
cigarettes is £6.10
Social Marginal Cost. The total cost to society of producing one extra
unit. Social Marginal Cost (SMC) = Private marginal cost (PMC) + External
marginal Cost (XMC)
Diagram of Costs
For full diagrams of costs see: Diagrams of cost curves
Average Cost Curves
Economic Efficiency
28 June 2019 by Tejvan Pettinger
Definition of efficiency
This occurs when the maximum number of goods and services are produced with
a given amount of inputs. This will occur on the production possibility frontier. On
the curve, it is impossible to produce more goods without producing fewer
services. Productive efficiency will also occur at the lowest point on the firm’s
average costs curve. (Q1)
See: Productive Efficiency
2. Allocative efficiency
This occurs when goods and services are distributed according to consumer
preferences. An economy could be productively efficient but produce goods
people don’t need this would be allocative inefficient.
Allocative efficiency occurs when the price of the good = the MC of production.
This occurs at an output of 80, where price £11 = MC.
See: Allocative Efficiency
3. X inefficiency
This occurs when firms do not have incentives to cut costs, for example, a
monopoly which makes supernormal profits may have little incentive to get rid of
surplus labour.
If a firm’s average costs are higher than potential – then we are x-inefficient.
See: X Inefficiency
4. Efficiency of scale
This occurs when the firms produce on the lowest point of its long-run average
cost (Q2) and therefore benefits fully from economies of scale
5. Dynamic efficiency
This refers to efficiency over time, for example, a Ford factory in 2010 may be
very efficient for the time period, but by 2017, it could have lost this relative
advantage and by comparison, would now be inefficient. Dynamic efficiency
involves the introduction of new technology and working practices to reduce
costs over time.
Dynamic efficiency
Static efficiency – efficiency at a particular point in time.
6. Social efficiency
This occurs when externalities are taken into consideration and occurs at an
output where the social cost of production (SMC) = the social benefit (SMB)
Social efficiency occurs at an output of 16 – where SMB = SMC
See: Social efficiency
7. Technical efficiency
This requires the optimum combination of factor inputs to produce a good: it is
related to productive efficiency.
See: Technical efficiency
8. Pareto efficiency
A situation where resources are distributed in the most efficient way. It is defined
as a situation where it is not possible to make one party better off without making
another party worse off.
See: Pareto efficiency
9. Distributive efficiency
Concerned with allocating goods and services according to who needs them
most. Therefore, requires an equitable distribution.
Imperfections in the Labour Market
28 November 2017 by Tejvan Pettinger
In the real world, labour markets are rarely perfectly competitive. This is because
workers or firms usually have the power to set and influence wages and therefore
wages may be set to levels different than anticipated by Marginal Revenue
Product (MRP) theory.
Imperfections in the labour market cause wages to differ from a competitive
equilibrium.
1. Monopsony
2. Trade unions
3. Discrimination
4. Difficult to measure productivity
5. Firms, not profit maximisers
6. Geographical immobiliities
7. Occupational immobilities
8. Poor information
1. Monopsony
Monopsony occurs when there is just one buyer of labour in a market. This gives
the firm market power in employing workers. The monopsony can set (lower)
wages and limit the quantity of workers.
The marginal cost of employing one more worker will be higher than the
average cost because to employ one extra worker the firm has to increase
the wages of all workers.
To maximise the level of profit the firm employs Q2 of workers where MC =
MRP
Therefore the firm only has to pay a wage of W2. This is less than the
competitive wage.
Even if there is more than one employer, firms may still have the ability to set
wages and have a degree of monopsony power. For workers, there are
significant costs and difficulties in moving between employers. This means that if
wages are low, it is costly to give up the job and work for a firm with slightly
higher wages.
2. Trades Unions
Under certain conditions, Trades unions can bargain for wages above the
competitive equilibrium
This can be achieved by restricting the supply of labour (e.g. closed shops) or
threatening to go on strike.
Trades Unions can cause higher wages, however, in competitive markets, this
can have the effect of causing unemployment of Q1 – Q2
Firms may not be rational but pay some workers different wages on the grounds
of age, race, or gender. See: discrimination in labour markets.
4. Difficult to measure productivity
The theory of MRP assumes firms can measure the MPP of a worker however in
practice this is difficult because in many jobs, especially in the service sector
productivity cannot be measured precisely
e.g. how do we measure the productivity of nurses and teachers?
Therefore wages may be set due to different reasons other than MRP
If demand for a product falls, MRP theory suggests wages are likely to fall.
However, firms may be reluctant to cut wages or make people redundant
therefore they may keep paying high wages despite this.
In the north (e.g. Sunderland), wages tend to be lower because there are less
demand, higher unemployment and more elastic supply curve of labour. In the
South, wages tend to be higher for the opposite reason – firms are more
profitable and are willing to pay higher wages.
In theory, workers from the north could move to the south to take advantage of
better employment opportunities. However, there are likely to be geographical
immobilities – e.g. it is difficult for workers to move. Geographical immobilities
can include
Workers or firms may suffer from poor information. E.g. workers may be unaware
of better-paid jobs elsewhere. Poor information is one factor that enables firms to
have monopsony power.
Monopsony
28 November 2019 by Tejvan Pettinger
Definition of Monopsony
An example of a monopsony occurs when there is one major employer and many
workers seeking to gain employment.
If there is only one main employer of labour, then they have market power in
setting wages and choosing how many workers to employ.
Examples of monopsony in labour markets
Coal mine owner in town where coal mining is the primary source of
employment.
The government in the employment of civil servants, nurses, police and
army officers.
Diagram of monopsony
For example, there are several employers who might employ supermarket
checkout workers. However, in practice, it is difficult for workers to switch jobs to
take advantage of slightly higher wages in other supermarkets. There is a lack of
information and barriers to moving jobs. Therefore, although there are several
buyers of labour, in practice the big supermarkets have a degree of monopsony
power in employing workers.
The gig economy refers to recent trends towards self-employment and very
flexible labour practises. In practice, workers in the gig economy can easily face
a monopsony employer. For example, Uber drivers have little control over rates
of pay and have to meet strict criteria from Uber. In theory, they could work
elsewhere but in practise it is difficult to replicate that job.
Monopsony can lead to lower wages for workers. This increases inequality
in society.
Workers are paid less than their marginal revenue product.
Firms with monopsony power often have a degree of monopoly selling
power. This enables them to make high profits at the expense of
consumers and workers.
Firms with monopsony power may also care less about working conditions
because workers don’t have many alternatives to the main firm.
Monopsony in product markets
Many firms.
Freedom of entry and exit.
Firms produce differentiated products.
Firms have price inelastic demand; they are price makers because the good is highly
differentiated
Firms make normal profits in the long run but could make supernormal profits in the short term
Firms are allocatively and productively inefficient.
Diagram monopolistic competition short run
In the
short run, the diagram for monopolistic competition is the same as for a monopoly.
The firm maximises profit where MR=MC. This is at output Q1 and price P1, leading to
supernormal profit
Monopolistic competition long run
De
mand curve shifts to the left due to new firms entering the market.
In the long-run, supernormal profit encourages new firms to enter. This reduces demand for
existing firms and leads to normal profit. I
Allocative inefficient. The above diagrams show a price set above marginal cost
Productive inefficiency. The above diagram shows a firm not producing on the lowest point of
AC curve
Dynamic efficiency. This is possible as firms have profit to invest in research and development.
X-efficiency. This is possible as the firm does face competitive pressures to cut cost and provide
better products.
Examples of monopolistic competition
Restaurants – restaurants compete on quality of food as much as price. Product differentiation
is a key element of the business. There are relatively low barriers to entry in setting up a new
restaurant.
Hairdressers. A service which will give firms a reputation for the quality of their hair-cutting.
Clothing. Designer label clothes are about the brand and product differentiation
TV programmes – globalisation has increased the diversity of tv programmes from networks
around the world. Consumers can choose between domestic channels but also imports from
other countries and new services, such as Netflix.
Limitations of the model of monopolistic competition
Some firms will be better at brand differentiation and therefore, in the real world, they will be
able to make supernormal profit.
New firms will not be seen as a close substitute.
There is considerable overlap with oligopoly – except the model of monopolistic competition
assumes no barriers to entry. In the real world, there are likely to be at least some barriers to
entry
If a firm has strong brand loyalty and product differentiation – this itself becomes a barrier to
entry. A new firm can’t easily capture the brand loyalty.
Many industries, we may describe as monopolistically competitive are very profitable, so the
assumption of normal profits is too simplistic.
Key difference with monopoly
In monopolistic competition there are no barriers to entry. Therefore in long run, the market will
be competitive, with firms making normal profit.
New trade theory places importance on the model of monopolistic competition for explaining
trends in trade patterns. New trade theory suggests that a key element of product development is
the drive for product differentiation – creating strong brands and new features for products.
Therefore, specialisation doesn’t need to be based on traditional theories of comparative
advantage, but we can have countries both importing and exporting the same good. For example,
we import Italian fashion labels and export British fashion labels. To consumers, the importance
is the choice of goods.
Readers Question: if all firms in a monopolistic competitive industry were to merge would that
firm produce as many different brands or just one brand?
Interesting question. I think it is an open-ended question with many different possibilities. One
approach is to think how firms in different industries may behave if they did merge. Bearing in
mind the model of monopolistic competition doesn’t always stand up to scrutiny too well in the
real world.
If the firms merged together, there is no certainty how they would behave.
In some industries, it makes sense to have many differentiated brands creating an illusion of
competition and providing a barrier to entry.
How many soap powders are there? About 35. But, most of these brands are owned by two
companies, Unilever and Proctor and Gamble. Having brand proliferation means it is harder for a
new firm to enter the market. This is because a new firm would have to compete against 30
established brands as opposed to 2. There is less chance of getting a good market share with so
many brands. Therefore the new firm would have an incentive to keep different brands to deter
competitors.
However, if you have merge different brands there may be economies of scale. You can devote
more resources and investment to improving that particular product and maximising its
efficiency. This might be appropriate for an industry like computer software or computers. There
used to be many different brands of computers until the pc came to dominate.
Are the different brands catering to different sectors of the market. If you take the restaurant
business, there is a big difference between Chinese and Indian. If 2 restaurants merge, they
would be better off retaining distinct business. It would make no sense to have a restaurant which
offered a mixture of Chinese/Indian – consumers would trust it less.
If you fear the arrival of a powerful company, it might be good to consolidate your brands. For
example, there are many small search engines, but they would be better off combining forces to
compete against the mighty Google.
Related
Oligopoly
Monopoly
UK Mergers
CategoriesmarketsPost navigation
Definition of Unemployment
Comment navigation
← Older Comments
Oligopoly
28 August 2019 by Tejvan Pettinger
Definition of oligopoly
An oligopoly is an industry dominated by a few large firms. For example, an
industry with a five-firm concentration ratio of greater than 50% is considered a
monopoly.
Examples of oligopolies
There are different possible ways that firms in oligopoly will compete and behave
this will depend upon:
This model suggests that prices will be fairly stable and there is little incentive for
firms to change prices. Therefore, firms compete using non-price competition
methods.
This assumes that firms seek to maximise profits.
If they increase the price, then they will lose a large share of the market
because they become uncompetitive compared to other firms. Therefore
demand is elastic for price increases.
If firms cut price then they would gain a big increase in market share.
However, it is unlikely that firms will allow this. Therefore other firms follow
suit and cut-price as well. Therefore demand will only increase by a small
amount. Therefore demand is inelastic for a price cut.
Therefore this suggests that prices will be rigid in oligopoly
The diagram above suggests that a change in marginal cost still leads to the
same price, because of the kinked demand curve. Profit maximisation occurs
where MR = MC at Q1.
Firms in oligopoly may still be very competitive on price, especially if they are
seeking to increase market share. In some circumstances, we can see
oligopolies where firms are seeking to cut prices and increase competitiveness.
Collusion
Another possibility for firms in oligopoly is for them to collude on price and
set profit maximising levels of output. This maximises profit for the
industry.
In the above example, the industry was initially competitive (Qc and Pc).
However, if firms collude, they can agree to restrict industry supply to Q2, and
increase the price to P2. This enables the industry to become more profitable. At
Qc, firms made normal profit. But, if they can stick to their quotas and keep the
price at P2, they make supernormal profit.
Game theory is looking at the decisions of firms based on the uncertainty of how
other firms will react. It illustrates the concept of interdependence. For example, if
a firm agrees to collude and set low output – it relies on the other firm sticking to
the collusive agreement. If the firm restricts output (sets the High price), and then
the other firm betrays its agreement (setting low price). The firm will be worse off.
This shows different options. If the market is non-collusive, firms make £3m
each. If they collude, they make £8m. But, there is an incentive for firms to
exceed quota and increase output.
Collusion and game theory is more complex if we add in the possibility of firms
being fined by a government regulator.
Collusion is illegal and firms can be fined. Usually, the first firm who confesses to
the regulator is protected from prosecution, so there is always an incentive to be
the first to confess.
Oligopoly Diagram
28 November 2019 by Tejvan Pettinger
There are different diagrams that you can use to explain 0ligopoly markets.
It is important to bear in mind, there are different possible ways that firms in
Oligopoly can behave.
The price and output in oligopoly will reflect the price and output of a monopoly.
The Quantity Qm will be split between the firms in the cartel.
Economies of scale for Oligopolies
Oligopolies may benefit from economies of scale. This enables lower average
costs with increased output. FIrms in oligopoly producing at Q1 achieve lower
prices of AC1.
Larger firms can benefit from economies of scale – lower average costs –
which might outweigh other inefficiencies.
Allocative efficiency? Not clear but firms operating under kinked demand
curve may end up setting price higher than marginal cost. Also, firms able
to successfully collude will set prices higher than MC. If oligopolies are
competitive then prices will be lower and more allocative efficient.
Dynamic efficiency? Firms in an oligopoly have profits they can use for
investment in new products. Also, competitive pressures encourage them
to innovate.
Pricing strategies
2 September 2018 by Tejvan Pettinger
A look at different pricing strategies a firm may use to try and increase
profitability, market share and gain greater brand loyalty.
General strategies
1. Profit maximisation. One strategy is to ignore market share and try to work
out the price for profit maximisation. In theory, this occurs at a price where
MR=MC. In practice, it can be difficult to work this out precisely.
2. Sales maximisation. Aiming to maximise sales whilst making normal profit.
This involves selling at a price equal to average cost.
3. Gaining Market Share. Some firms may have a target to increase market
share, this could involve setting prices as low as they can afford, leading to
a price war. A similar concept to sales maximisation.
See: Objectives of firms
Pricing strategies to attract customers / increase profit
Premium pricing. This occurs when a firm makes a good more expensive
to try and give the impression that it is better quality, e.g. ‘premium
unleaded fuel’, fashion labels.
Loss Leaders This involves setting a low price on some products to entice
customers into the shop where hopefully they will also buy other goods as
well. However, it is illegal to sell goods below cost, so firms could be
investigated by OFT.
Price Discrimination. This involves charging a different price to different
groups of consumers to take advantage of different elasticities of demand.
There are different types of price discrimination from first degree to third
degree.
Reference Pricing. This involves setting an artificially high price to be able
to later offer discounts on previously advertised price.
Price Matching. The purpose behind price matching is making a promise
to match any price cuts by your competitors. The argument is that this
discourages your competitors from cutting price. This is because they
know there is little point in cutting prices because you will respond straight
away. Very clear price matching stances can thus avoid price wars and
give the impression of being very competitive. For example, Tesco is
offering £10 voucher to customers who can prove their shopping basket
would have been cheaper at other supermarkets.
Retail price mechanism RPM – when manufacturers set minimum prices
for retailers, e.g. net book agreement.
Psychological pricing. Setting price at important psychological levels to
trigger purchase, e.g. selling good at £9.99 to make it appear cheaper.
Some firms use reverse psychology and charge exact prices, e.g. clothes
for £40 to indicate quality rather than cheapness.
Premium decoy pricing. Where a firm sets the price of one good
deliberately high to encourage demand for a lower price. e.g. a car
company may bring out a top of the range sports car, which is very
expensive to make the general brand more attractive.
Pay what you want. A situation where consumers are left free to decide
how much to pay, e.g. restaurants cafe where there is no cost – only
tipping. When music companies release a new recording and ask for
donations.
Bundle pricing. When a firm gives special offers, e.g. buy 3 for the price
of 2 – very common for book sales e.t.c.
Price skimming. When a firm releases a new product, it initially sets a
high price to take advantage of those consumers with inelastic demand.
Over time, the price is reduced to attract those customers with more price
elastic demand.
Penetration pricing. When a firm sets a low price to help establish market
share and get established. For example, a new printing company may offer
very low price for its printers to get established. Then it gets to make profits
on selling ink and over time increase the price. Or satellite tv company
offering introductory offer for a few months.
Optional pricing. When a firm tries to receive a higher price by selling
extras. For example, if you buy a DVD, you can get sold insurance or
additional features.
Dynamic pricing. When prices are regularly updated in response to
shifting market conditions. For example, if an airline receives high demand
for certain flights, it will increase the price to help fill up other departure
times and maximise revenue from the flight.
Pricing strategies to cement market share/market position
Limit pricing. This occurs when a monopoly set price lower than profit
maximisation to discourage entry. This enables the firm to make
supernormal profit, but the price is still low enough to deter new firms to
enter the market.
Predatory pricing. Selling price below cost to try and force rival out of
business. Predatory pricing is illegal. Predatory pricing can be made easier
through cross Subsidisation. This occurs when a big multinational may use
profits in one area to subsidise a price war in another. The cross
subsidisation enables a firm to sell a product very competitively (or even at
a loss) to try and force the rival firms out of business.
Pricing strategies to help determine the price
Average cost pricing. When a firm sets the price equal to average cost plus
a certain profit margin.
Market-based pricing. When firms set a price depending on supply and
demand. For example, if football clubs, used market-based pricing, clubs
like Manchester United would probably increase the ticket price – because,
at the moment, all tickets are sold out – suggesting price is below the
equilibrium.
Markup pricing. This involves setting a price equal to marginal cost of
production + x. (where x = the profit margin a firm wants to make on each
sale)
Profit maximisation. Setting price and quantity so MR=MC
Importance of Elasticity
If demand for your products is highly elastic, cutting prices should lead to an
increase in revenue. Increasing prices will lead to a fall in revenue.If demand is
price inelastic, then you can increase your profits by increasing your price.
This is the logic behind price discrimination. Firms charge a higher price to that
market segment where demand is more price inelastic, but a lower price to where
demand is more price elastic.
What will determine the most effective pricing strategy?
The optimal pricing strategy will depend on the type of firm. For example, if you
are considered to having a premium brand – cutting price could be perceived as
disastrous as you lose your brand image, and fail to increase sales. For these
products, it might be better to maintain premium pricing and optional pricing. For
normal goods, with firms looking to increase market share and gain more market
dominance, it is more important to offer competitive prices, through strategies
such as penetration pricing and even loss leaders.
Related
Perfect competition
28 May 2019 by Tejvan Pettinger
1. Many firms.
2. Freedom of entry and exit; this will require low sunk costs.
3. All firms produce an identical or homogeneous product.
4. All firms are price takers, therefore the firm’s demand curve is perfectly
elastic.
5. There is perfect information and knowledge.
Diagram for perfect competition
The features of perfect competition are very rare in the real world. However
perfect competition is as important economic model to compare other models. It
is often argued that competitive markets have many benefits which stem from
this theoretical model.
This will attract new firms into the market causing price to fall back to the
equilibrium of Pe
Price Discrimination
28 July 2019 by Tejvan Pettinger
Cut-price fuel
on Tuesdays and Thursdays is a form of price discrimination.
Student discounts,
Senior citizen railcard
Peak travel/ off-peak travel
Cheaper prices by the time of the day (e.g. happy hour’s in pubs – usually
earlier on in evening where demand is lower.
More on third-degree price discrimination
3rd degree price-discrimination is sometimes known as direct price
discrimination. Because a firm directly sets different prices depending on distinct
groups of consumers (e.g. age)
Product versioning
One way firms practise price discrimination is to offer slightly different products
as a way to discriminate between consumers ability to pay. For example:
Priority boarding tickets. Same flight but for a premium, you get a shorter
queue.
Organic coffee / fair trade coffee
Extra legroom on aeroplanes
First-class/second class
This is a form of indirect segmentation. By offering slightly different choices, the
firm is able to separate consumers who are willing to pay higher prices.
Without price
discrimination, the firm charges one price £7 * 100 = £700 revenue
WIth price discrimination, the firm can charge two different prices:
£10 * 35 = £350
£4 * 120 = £480
Total revenue = £830. Therefore, the firm makes more revenue under price
discrimination.
Profit maximisation under Price Discrimination
To maximise profits a firm sets output and price where MR=MC. If there are two
sub markets with different elasticities of demand. The firm will increase profits by
setting different prices depending upon the slope of the demand curve.
Therefore for a group, such as adults, PED is inelastic – the price will be
higher
For groups like students, prices will be lower because their demand is
elastic
Diagram of Price Discrimination
Profit is maximised where MR=MC. WIthout price discrimination, there would just
be one price set for the whole market (A+B). There would be a price of P3.
However, price discrimination allows the firm to set different prices for
segment A (inelastic demand) and segment B (elastic demand)
Because demand is price inelastic, segment (A) will have a higher profit
maximising price (P1)
In segment (B) demand is price elastic, so the profit maximising price is
lower.
Advantages of price discrimination
1. Higher prices for some. Under price discrimination, some consumers will
end up paying higher prices (e.g. people who have to travel at busy times).
These higher prices are likely to be allocatively inefficient because P > MC.
2. Decline in consumer surplus. Price discrimination enables a transfer of
money from consumers to firms – contributing to increased inequality.
3. Potentially unfair. Those who pay higher prices may not be the poorest.
For example, adults paying full price could be unemployed, senior citizens
can be very well off.
4. Administration costs. There will be administration costs in separating the
markets, which could lead to higher prices.
5. Predatory pricing. Profits from price discrimination could be used to
finance predatory pricing.
Importance of marginal cost in price discrimination
In markets where the marginal cost of an extra passenger is very low, the firm
has an incentive to use price discrimination to sell all the tickets. This is why
sometimes prices for airlines can be very low just before their date. Once the
company is due to fly the MC of an extra passenger will be very low. Therefore
this justifies selling the remaining tickets at a low price.
Examples of price discrimination
In
the above diagram, there is no single price which enables the firm to make
normal profit and stay in business. They would need price discrimination to
increase profits.
1. Allows an unprofitable business to avoid going bankrupt. In some
cases, it may be possible that there is no one price that would enable a
firm to make normal profits. (i.e. average costs would always be higher
than demand curve) However, price discrimination may enable the firm to
turn a loss into a small profit. This means that a business activity can keep
going, rather than closing down. This is obviously beneficial for consumers
because it increases their choice of goods and services. An example might
be train services. Without price discrimination (off-peak, peak) train
companies would make a bigger loss and may be discontinued.
2. Some groups benefit from cheaper prices. Price discrimination means
that firms have an incentive to cut prices for groups of consumers who are
sensitive to prices (elastic demand). For example, firms often offer a 10%
reduction to students. Students typically have lower income so their
demand is more elastic. This means they benefit from lower prices. These
groups are often poorer than the average consumer. The downside is that
some consumers will face higher prices.
3. Avoid Congestion. Price discrimination is one way to manage demand. If
there were no price discrimination rush hour trains would be more
overcrowded. Price discrimination gives an incentive for some people to go
later in the day. This means that those who have to travel at rush hour
benefit from less congestion.
4. Low-income consumers may be able to benefit from cheaper prices.
One form of indirect price discrimination is to offer lower prices to
consumers who collect coupons. This imposes a cost on consumers (time
to collect). So if consumers are time-rich and money poor, they can take
advantage of lower prices.
5. Investment. Price discrimination helps a firm to become more profitable.
This may enable the firm to invest in increased capacity. For example, an
airline which maximises profits from price discrimination can invest in
updating its aircraft to the latest technology.
Related
Advantages and problems of
privatisation
12 May 2019 by Tejvan Pettinger
1. Improved efficiency
The main argument for privatisation is that private companies have a profit
incentive to cut costs and be more efficient. If you work for a government run
industry managers do not usually share in any profits. However, a private firm is
interested in making a profit, and so it is more likely to cut costs and be efficient.
Since privatisation, companies such as BT, and British Airways have shown
degrees of improved efficiency and higher profitability.
4. Shareholders
It is argued that a private firm has pressure from shareholders to perform
efficiently. If the firm is inefficient then the firm could be subject to a takeover. A
state-owned firm doesn’t have this pressure and so it is easier for them to be
inefficient.
5. Increased competition
Often privatisation of state-owned monopolies occurs alongside deregulation –
i.e. policies to allow more firms to enter the industry and increase the
competitiveness of the market. It is this increase in competition that can be the
greatest spur to improvements in efficiency. For example, there is now more
competition in telecoms and distribution of gas and electricity.
Disadvantages of privatisation
1. Natural monopoly
A natural monopoly occurs when the most efficient number of firms in an industry
is one. For example, tap water has very significant fixed costs. Therefore there is
no scope for having competition amongst several firms. Therefore, in this case,
privatisation would just create a private monopoly which might seek to set higher
prices which exploit consumers. Therefore it is better to have a public monopoly
rather than a private monopoly which can exploit the consumer.
2. Public interest
There are many industries which perform an important public service, e.g., health
care, education and public transport. In these industries, the profit motive
shouldn’t be the primary objective of firms and the industry. For example, in the
case of health care, it is feared privatising health care would mean a greater
priority is given to profit rather than patient care. Also, in an industry like health
care, arguably we don’t need a profit motive to improve standards. When doctors
treat patients, they are unlikely to try harder if they get a bonus.
5. Fragmentation of industries
In the UK, rail privatisation led to breaking up the rail network into infrastructure
and train operating companies. This led to areas where it was unclear who had
responsibility. For example, the Hatfield rail crash was blamed on no one taking
responsibility for safety. Different rail companies has increased the complexity of
rail tickets.
6. Short-termism of firms
As well as the government being motivated by short term pressures, this is
something private firms may do as well. To please shareholders they may seek
to increase short term profits and avoid investing in long term projects. For
example, the UK is suffering from a lack of investment in new energy sources;
the privatised companies are trying to make use of existing plants rather than
invest in new ones.
Evaluation of privatisation
A fixed exchange rate tells you that you can always exchange your money in one
currency for the same amount of another currency. It allows you to determine
how much of one currency you can trade for another. For example, if you go to
Saudi Arabia, you always know a dollar will buy you 3.75 Saudi riyals,
since the dollar's exchange rate in riyals is fixed. Saudi Arabia did that because
its primary export, oil, is priced in U.S. dollars. All oil contracts and most
commodities contracts around the world are written and executed in dollars.
Advantages
A fixed exchange rate provides currency stability. Investors always know what
the currency is worth. That makes the country's businesses attractive to foreign
direct investors. They don't have to protect themselves from wild swings in the
currency's value. They are hedging their currency risk.
A country can avoid inflation if it fixes its currency to a popular one like the U.S.
dollar or euro. It benefits from the strength of that country's economy. As the
United States or European Union grows, its currency does as well. Without that
fixed exchange rate, the smaller country's currency will slide. As a result, the
imports from the large economy become more expensive. That imports inflation,
as well as goods.
For example, the U.S. dollar's value is 3.75 Saudi riyals. If the dollar strengthens
20% against the euro, the value of the riyal, which is fixed to the dollar, has also
risen 20% against the euro. To purchase French pastries, the Saudis pay less
than they did before the dollar strengthened. For this reason, the Saudis didn't
need to limit supply as oil prices fell to $50 a barrel in 2014. The value of
money is what it purchases for you. If most of your country's imports are to a
single country, then a fixed exchange rate in that currency will stabilize prices.
One country that is loosening its fixed exchange rate is China. It ties the value of
its currency, the yuan, to a basket of currencies that includes the dollar. In
August 2015, it allowed the fixed rate to vary according to the prior day's closing
rate. It keeps the yuan in a tight 2% trading range around that value.
China has to manually adjust the exchange rate of the yuan to the dollar. This is
advantageous to China, but not for the U.S. That's why the U.S. government has
pressured the Chinese government to let the yuan rise in value. That action
would effectively make U.S. exports cheaper in China, while
Chinese exports would be more expensive in the U.S. In other words, it's an
attempt by the U.S. to lower its trade deficit with China.
Disadvantages
A fixed exchange rate can be expensive to maintain. A country must have
enough foreign exchange reserves to manage its currency's value.
A fixed exchange rate can make a country's currency a target for speculators.
They can short the currency, artificially driving its value down. That forces the
country's central bank to convert its foreign exchange, so it can prop up its
currency's value. If it doesn't have enough foreign currency on hand, it will have
to raise interest rates. That will cause a recession.
Examples
There are several ways countries maintain a fixed exchange rate. The purest
form is when its currency is pegged to a set value against a single currency.
Alternatively, many countries fix a set value to a basket of currencies, instead of
just one currency. Other countries peg it to either a single currency or to a basket
of currencies, but then allow it to fluctuate within a range of the pegged currency.
Here are examples of each type.
Exchange rate – value of a currency expressed in terms of another currency. (In other
words: price of the currency in terms of another currency).
Floating exchange rates (system) – when the exchange rate of a currency is
determined by the supply and demand for that currency.
Appreciation (of a currency) – occurs when a currency increases in value
against another currency, i.e. it can buy more of another currency.
Depreciation (of a currency) – occurs when a currency loses value against another
currency, i.e. it can buy less of another currency.
Determination of Freely Floating Exchange Rates
The diagram above for floating exchange rates shows that the value of the US Dollar ($) is at e1
where Supply (S) = Demand (D) for USD. At that exchange rate (e1), the equilibrium quantity of
US Dollars is Q1. It is important to note that on the Y axis the value of $ is expressed in terms of
how many Euros you can buy with $1 (There are variations of this diagram, hence, always
consult your teacher about which one is the most appropriate). The higher the value of the US
Dollar, the more Euros you will be able to purchase with 1 USD. The lower the value of the USD
– the less Euros $1 will be able to buy.
For people doing the IB Higher Level Economics course, you need to know some maths
connected to floating exchange rates:
Say, you are given that 1 GBP = 1.25 EUR. You have to know how to express the value of 1 EUR
in terms of GBP. How? If 1 GBP = 1.25 EUR, then 1 EUR = 1/1.25 GBP –> 1 EUR = 0.80 GBP
Diagram 2
Diagram 4
For your IB Economics course you need to know the following factors affecting supply/ demand
of currencies and hence, their floating exchanges rates:
Interest rates in country A are higher than interest rates in country B -> people of
country B want to keep their money in country’s A banks, hence they require more of
Exchange rate – value of a currency expressed in terms of another currency. (In other
words: price of the currency in terms of another currency).
Floating exchange rates (system) – when the exchange rate of a currency is
determined by the supply and demand for that currency.
Appreciation (of a currency) – occurs when a currency increases in value
against another currency, i.e. it can buy more of another currency.
Depreciation (of a currency) – occurs when a currency loses value against another
currency, i.e. it can buy less of another currency.
The diagram above for floating exchange rates shows that the value of the US Dollar ($) is at e1
where Supply (S) = Demand (D) for USD. At that exchange rate (e1), the equilibrium quantity of
US Dollars is Q1. It is important to note that on the Y axis the value of $ is expressed in terms of
how many Euros you can buy with $1 (There are variations of this diagram, hence, always
consult your teacher about which one is the most appropriate). The higher the value of the US
Dollar, the more Euros you will be able to purchase with 1 USD. The lower the value of the USD
– the less Euros $1 will be able to buy.
For people doing the IB Higher Level Economics course, you need to know some maths
connected to floating exchange rates:
Say, you are given that 1 GBP = 1.25 EUR. You have to know how to express the value of 1 EUR
in terms of GBP. How? If 1 GBP = 1.25 EUR, then 1 EUR = 1/1.25 GBP –> 1 EUR = 0.80 GBP
Diagram 1
Diagram 2
Diagram 4
For your IB Economics course you need to know the following factors affecting supply/ demand
of currencies and hence, their floating exchanges rates:
Currency appreciation
Currency depreciation
Currency appreciation
Exports – less competitive, lower demand for them, producers might have to cut
production, hence, increasing unemployment and lower economic growth (or even
possibly falling GDP). If the country is exporting oil (or other low PED goods/services) the
effect will be much smaller.
Imports – seem cheaper, so if they are used as inputs, producers face lower production
costs and that might encourage to increase the quantities produced. Therefore,
increasing employment and economic growth (GDP grows) as AD shifts to the right.
However, because imports seem cheaper, people might substitute away from domestic
goods to imported ones and that would lead to falling employment and lower GDP.
Currency depreciation
Foreign Exchange markets are also financial markets. The price reflected in any financial market
does not reflect the price of today. Rather, it reflects the expectations about the future based on the
information that we have on hand today. Therefore, the foremost and important determinant of
Forex rates between any two countries is expectations about the future.
The term “expectations about the future” sounds like a vague and generic term. The next question
arises, “expectations about what?” The remainder of this article will explain the various factors that
influence the exchange rates.
Exchange rates are basically a comparison between the policies of two countries. It is essential to
understand that exchange rates are not absolute rather they are relative. The following factors are
considered amidst many others while comparing the monetary policies of any two countries.
Inflation: Exchange rate is basically a ratio between the expected number of units of one
currency and the expected number of units of other currency in the market. Inflation
increases the number of currency units. Therefore, if one currency is facing inflation at the
rate of 6% whereas the other is only facing inflation at the rate of 2%, then the ratio between
the two is bound to change. Hence, inflation rates are a major factor while determining
exchange rates. However, the official inflation rates often do not tell the true picture.
Therefore, participants of the market use their own estimates of inflation rate and come up
with their own valuations for currency pairs.
Interest Rates: When investors hold a certain currency, they get a yield in terms of the
interest rate that is applicable on that currency. Therefore if investors were to hold a
currency with a 6% yield as opposed to a 3% yield, they would end up profiting more!
Therefore, the interest rate yields are also priced into the Forex rates that are quoted in the
market. The currency valuations are extremely subjective to interest rate changes. A small
change in this rate brings about a big reaction from the market participants.
Therefore, Central Banks become extremely important participants in the Forex market since they
control the monetary policy which is one of the biggest determinants of the value of the currency.
While monetary policy is controlled by the Central Bank of the country, the fiscal policy is controlled
by the government. This too has important implications because it signals the forthcoming changes
in the monetary policy.
Public Debt: A large amount of public debt means that the government of a country will
have to make huge interest payments. Investors will analyze whether these payments can be
collected from the tax i.e. from existing money supply. If not, then this signals that the
country will monetize its debt i.e. print more currency and pay off the debt. Since a huge
public debt today is a signal of problems coming up in the future, the Forex market prices
this too in the value that is quoted.
However, it needs to be understood that once again there is a relative comparison between
the public debts of the two countries in question. Absolute amounts may not matter as
much!
Budget Deficit: Another major factor which influences the Forex rates is the budget deficit.
This is because a budget deficit is a precursor to public debt. Governments spend more
money than they have and as a result run up a budget deficit. This deficit then has to be
financed by debt. The problems pertaining to public debt and how it impacts the Forex rate
have already been discussed in the above point.
Political Stability
Political stability of the country in question is also of prime importance for Forex rates. This is
because modern monetary system is a system of Fiat money. This means that money is nothing
except the promise of the government. Therefore, if there is a danger to the government, there is a
danger that the promise itself may be worthless once a new government takes over. It is possible
that the new government may want to issue a new currency of its own! Therefore, whenever a
country faces a geopolitical turmoil, its currency usually takes a beating in the Forex markets.
Lastly, the Forex market is extremely speculative in nature. This is because Forex provides the
leverage for investors to amplify their trade several times using borrowed money and then invest in
the markets. Therefore, sentiments take over the Forex market more than they take over other
asset markets because of the availability of easy money.
Hence, just like all other markets, Forex markets are prone to irrational exuberance and they too can
distort exchange rates in the short term creating long term investment opportunities.
Many other factors like the price of commodities such as gold and oil also play a vital role in
the determination of Forex rates. However, that will be discussed in a later article in this module.
17.18 Nash Equilibrium
A Nash equilibrium is used to predict the outcome of a game. By a game, we mean the interaction of
a few individuals, called players. Each player chooses an action and receives a payoff that depends
1. The action yields the highest payoff for that player given her predictions about the other
players’ actions.
Thus a Nash equilibrium has two dimensions. Players make decisions that are in their own self-
interest, and players make accurate predictions about the actions of others.
Consider the games in Table 17.6 "Prisoners’ Dilemma", Table 17.7 "Dictator Game", Table 17.8
"Ultimatum Game", and Table 17.9 "Coordination Game". The numbers in the tables give the payoff
to each player from the actions that can be taken, with the payoff of the row player listed first.
Left Right
Up 5, 5 0, 10
Down 10, 0 2, 2
100
Number of Dollars (x)
− x, x
Accept Reject
100
Number of Dollars (x) 0, 0
− x, x
Up 5, 5 0, 1
Down 1, 0 4, 4
Prisoners’ dilemma. The row player chooses between the action labeled “Up” and the one
labeled “Down.” The column player chooses between the action labeled “Left” and the one
labeled “Right.” For example, if row chooses “Up” and column chooses “Right,” then the row
player has a payoff of 0, and the column player has a payoff of 10. If the row player predicts
that the column player will choose “Left,” then the row player should choose “Down” (that is,
down for the row player is her best response to left by the column player). From the column
player’s perspective, if he predicts that the row player will choose “Up,” then the column
player should choose “Right.” The Nash equilibrium occurs when the row player chooses
“Down” and the column player chooses “Right.” Our two conditions for a Nash equilibrium of
Social dilemma. This is a version of the prisoners’ dilemma in which there are a large
Dictator game. The row player is called the dictator. She is given $100 and is asked to
choose how many dollars (x) to give to the column player. Then the game ends. Because the
column player does not move in this game, the dictator game is simple to analyze: if the
dictator is interested in maximizing her payoff, she should offer nothing (x = 0).
Ultimatum game. This is like the dictator game except there is a second stage. In the first
stage, the row player is given $100 and told to choose how much to give to the column player.
In the second stage, the column player accepts or rejects the offer. If the column player
rejects the offer, neither player receives any money. The best choice of the row player is then
to offer a penny (the smallest amount of money there is). The best choice of the column
Coordination game. The coordination game has two Nash equilibria. If the column player
plays “Left,” then the row player plays “Up”; if the row player plays “Up,” then the column
player plays “Left.” This is an equilibrium. But “Down/Right” is also a Nash equilibrium.
Both players prefer “Up/Left,” but it is possible to get stuck in a bad equilibrium.
Key Insights
The production possibilities frontier shows the combinations of goods and services that an economy
can produce if it is efficiently using every available input. A key component in understanding the
efficient way, then it is not possible to produce more of one good without producing less of another.
Figure 17.10 "The Production Possibilities Frontier" shows the production possibilities frontier for an
economy producing web pages and meals. It is downward sloping: to produce more web pages, the
production of meals must decrease. Combinations of web pages and meals given by points inside the
production possibilities frontier are possible for the economy to produce but are not efficient: at
points inside the production possibilities frontier, it is possible for the economy to produce more of
both goods. Points outside the production possibilities frontier are not feasible given the current
The negative slope of the production possibilities frontier reflects opportunity cost. The opportunity
cost of producing more meals is that fewer web pages can be created. Likewise, the opportunity cost
of creating more web pages means that fewer meals can be produced.
The production possibilities frontier shifts over time. If an economy accumulates more physical
capital or has a larger workforce, then it will be able to produce more of all the goods in an economy.
Further, it will be able to produce new goods. Another factor shifting the production possibilities
frontier outward over time is technology. As an economy creates new ideas (or receives them from
other countries) on how to produce goods more cheaply, then it can produce more goods.
Key Insights
The production possibilities frontier shows the combinations of goods and services that
requires producing less of others. The production of a good has an opportunity cost.
As time passes, the production possibilities frontier shifts outward due to the
The outcome of a competitive market has a very important property. In equilibrium, all gains from
trade are realized. This means that there is no additional surplus to obtain from further trades
between buyers and sellers. In this situation, we say that the allocation of goods and services in the
economy is efficient. However, markets sometimes fail to operate properly and not all gains from
trade are exhausted. In this case, some buyer surplus, seller surplus, or both are lost. Economists call
The deadweight loss from a monopoly is illustrated in Figure 17.8 "Deadweight Loss". The
monopolist produces a quantity such that marginal revenue equals marginal cost. The price is
determined by the demand curve at this quantity. A monopoly makes a profit equal to total revenue
minus total cost. When the total output is less than socially optimal, there is a deadweight loss, which
Deadweight loss arises in other situations, such as when there are quantity or price restrictions. It
also arises when taxes or subsidies are imposed in a market. Tax incidence is the way in which the
burden of a tax falls on buyers and sellers—that is, who suffers most of the deadweight loss. In
general, the incidence of a tax depends on the elasticities of supply and demand.
A tax creates a difference between the price paid by the buyer and the price received by the seller
(Figure 17.9 "Tax Burdens"). The burden of the tax and the deadweight loss are defined relative to
the tax-free competitive equilibrium. The tax burden borne by the buyer is the difference between the
price paid under the tax and the price paid in the competitive equilibrium. Similarly, the burden of
the seller is the difference between the price in the competitive equilibrium and the price received
under the equilibrium with taxes. The burden borne by the buyer is higher—all else being the same—
if demand is less elastic. The burden borne by the seller is higher—all else being the same—if supply
is less elastic.
The deadweight loss from the tax measures the sum of the buyer’s lost surplus and the seller’s lost
surplus in the equilibrium with the tax. The total amount of the deadweight loss therefore also
depends on the elasticities of demand and supply. The smaller these elasticities, the closer the
equilibrium quantity traded with a tax will be to the equilibrium quantity traded without a tax, and
Key Insights
If sellers have market power, some gains from trade are lost because the quantity traded
cause the amount to be traded to differ from the competitive level and cause deadweight
loss.
If you buy a good, then you obtain buyer surplus. If you did not expect to obtain any surplus, then
Suppose you buy a single unit of the good. Your surplus is the difference between your
valuation of the good and the price you pay. This is a measure of how much you gain from the
exchange.
If you purchase many units of a good, then your surplus is the sum of the surplus you get
from each unit. To calculate the surplus from each unit, you subtract the price paid from your
If you sell a good, then you obtain seller surplus. If you did not expect to obtain any surplus, you
Suppose you sell a single unit of a good. Your surplus is equal to the difference between the
price you receive from selling the good and your valuation of the good. This valuation may be
a measure of how much you enjoy the good or what you think you could sell it for in some
other market.
If you sell many units of a good, then the surplus you receive is the sum of the surplus for
each unit you sell. To calculate the surplus from selling each unit, you take the difference
between the price you get for each unit sold and your marginal valuation of that extra unit.
Buyer surplus and seller surplus are created by trade in a competitive market (Figure 17.6 "A
Competitive Market"). The equilibrium price and the equilibrium quantity are determined by the
intersection of the supply and demand curves. The area below the demand curve and above the price
is the buyer surplus; the area above the supply curve and below the price is the seller surplus. The
sum of the buyer surplus and the seller surplus is called total surplus or the gains from trade.
Buyer surplus and seller surplus can also arise from individual bargaining (Figure 17.7 "Individual
Bargaining"). When a single unit is traded (the case of unit demand and unit supply), the total
surplus is the difference between the buyer’s valuation and the seller’s valuation. Bargaining
determines how they share the gains from trade. The quantity of trades, indicated on the horizontal
axis, is either zero or one. The valuations of the buyer and the seller are shown on the vertical axis. In
this case, the valuation of the buyer ($3,000) exceeds the valuation of the seller ($2,000), indicating
that there are gains from trade equal to $1,000. How these gains are shared between the buyer and
seller depends on the price they agree on. In part (a) of Figure 17.7 "Individual Bargaining", the
buyer gets most of the surplus; in part (b) of Figure 17.7 "Individual Bargaining", the seller gets most
of the surplus.
Key Insights
Buyer surplus is the difference between the marginal value of a good and the price paid.
Seller surplus is the difference between the price received and the marginal value of a
good.
Monetarists argue that if the Money Supply rises faster than the rate of growth of
national income, then there will be inflation.
If the money supply increases in line with real output then there will be no
inflation.
M.Friedman stated:
M = Money Supply
V= Velocity of circulation
P= Price Level and
T = Transactions.
T is difficult to measure so it is often substituted for Y = National Income
Monetarists believe that in the short-term velocity (V) is fixed This is because the
rate at which money circulates is determined by institutional factors, e.g. how
often workers are paid does not change very much. Milton Friedman admitted it
might vary a little but not very much so it can be treated as fixed
Monetarists also believe output Y is fixed. They state it may vary in the short run
but not in the long run (because LRAS is inelastic and determined by supply-side
factors.)
Example 1
If the total money supply is initially £1000 and the velocity of circulation is
5.
The level of output (Y) is 5000 units.
£1000×5 = P (5000)
Therefore P = 1
If the money supply now doubles the equation =
2000×5 =P×5000
Therefore P = 2
Example 2
Milton Friedman argued that the money supply should rise by a fixed k-
percent each year. This rate of increase should depend on institutional
factors and be determined independently of policymakers.
Friedman believed this rule would avoid the extremes of deflation (Falling
money supply, e.g. Great Depression) and inflation due to rising money
supply.
It would give business strong expectations of what would happen to money
supply and inflation.
Monetarist inflation in the AD and AS model
Following a rise in the Money Supply, consumers have more money and
therefore spend more money on goods; this shifts AD to the right. AD1 to
AD 2.
Firms respond by increasing output along SRAS. Real output increases
from Y1 to Y2.
National output now exceeds the equilibrium level of output. Therefore
there is an inflationary gap.
Firms need to hire more workers, so wages rise leading to an increase in
costs and hence prices. Initially, workers agree to work more hours
because they see an increase in nominal wages.
As prices rise money can buy less, therefore, there is a movement to the
left along the new AD
Also, workers realise the increase in nominal wage is not a real wage
increase. Therefore, workers also demand higher nominal wages to
produce more output and to compensate them for rising prices, therefore
SRAS shifts to the left.
The economy has returned to the equilibrium level of output (Y1), but at a
higher price level (P3).
Therefore the rise in the Money Supply cause a rise in AD, But because
the LRAS is inelastic there is no increase in real output, but inflation rises.
It is a form of demand-pull inflation.
Monetarist view of Phillips curve
Mo
netarists believe in the long-run there is no trade-off between inflation and
unemployment. Increase in the money supply only causes an increase in nominal
GDP, but not real GDP.
Criticisms of monetarism
The link between the money supply and inflation is often very weak in
practice.
The velocity of circulation (V) is not stable but can vary significantly due to
confidence, changes in the use of credit cards, decline in use of cash. e.t.c
Targetting arbitrary money supply targets can cause a severe recession
and high unemployment. For example, UK targetted money supply growth
in the early 1980s, but this caused the recession of 1981 with many
economists arguing it was deeper than necessary.
The large increase in the monetary base following the 2009 recession did
not cause any inflationary pressures.
Why not target inflation directly? If you want to control inflation, it makes
more sense to target inflation directly rather than through the intermediary
of the money supply.
Monetarists say that income can vary in the short run, but the short run
could be a long time and therefore make monetary policy ineffective,
Keynesians argue that the LRAS is not necessarily inelastic they argue
that the economy can be below full capacity for a long time.
Monetarists argue that if the Money Supply rises faster than the rate of growth of
national income, then there will be inflation.
If the money supply increases in line with real output then there will be no
inflation.
M.Friedman stated:
M = Money Supply
V= Velocity of circulation
P= Price Level and
T = Transactions.
T is difficult to measure so it is often substituted for Y = National Income
Monetarists believe that in the short-term velocity (V) is fixed This is because the
rate at which money circulates is determined by institutional factors, e.g. how
often workers are paid does not change very much. Milton Friedman admitted it
might vary a little but not very much so it can be treated as fixed
Monetarists also believe output Y is fixed. They state it may vary in the short run
but not in the long run (because LRAS is inelastic and determined by supply-side
factors.)
Example 1
If the total money supply is initially £1000 and the velocity of circulation is
5.
The level of output (Y) is 5000 units.
£1000×5 = P (5000)
Therefore P = 1
If the money supply now doubles the equation =
2000×5 =P×5000
Therefore P = 2
Example 2
If the output is 1,000 units, and there is a money supply of £10,000. The
average price of good will be £10.
In year 2, if the output stays at 1,000 units, but money supply increases to
15,000. Consumers have more money to buy the same amount of goods.
Therefore, firms put up prices to reflect this increase in money supply.
Ceteris paribus, average prices will rise from £10 to £15.
Other points
Milton Friedman predicted an increase in the money supply would take
about 9-12 months to lead to higher output.
Friedman placed great emphasis on the role of price expectations. If there
are expectations of higher inflation, it becomes self-fulfilling – workers
demand higher wages to meet rising living costs. Firms put up prices to
meet rising costs. Strict monetarist policies would help reduce
expectations.
After another year output will return to its initial equilibrium causing prices
to rise to accommodate the rise in money supply
Cambridge Version of quantity theory states P= f(M)
Monetarism became more popular in the 1970s due to rising inflation.
(partly caused by rising oil prices).
In the early 1980s, the UK and US adopted monetarist policies with mixed
results.
Friedman’s k-percent rule
Milton Friedman argued that the money supply should rise by a fixed k-
percent each year. This rate of increase should depend on institutional
factors and be determined independently of policymakers.
Friedman believed this rule would avoid the extremes of deflation (Falling
money supply, e.g. Great Depression) and inflation due to rising money
supply.
It would give business strong expectations of what would happen to money
supply and inflation.
Monetarist inflation in the AD and AS model
Following a rise in the Money Supply, consumers have more money and
therefore spend more money on goods; this shifts AD to the right. AD1 to
AD 2.
Firms respond by increasing output along SRAS. Real output increases
from Y1 to Y2.
National output now exceeds the equilibrium level of output. Therefore
there is an inflationary gap.
Firms need to hire more workers, so wages rise leading to an increase in
costs and hence prices. Initially, workers agree to work more hours
because they see an increase in nominal wages.
As prices rise money can buy less, therefore, there is a movement to the
left along the new AD
Also, workers realise the increase in nominal wage is not a real wage
increase. Therefore, workers also demand higher nominal wages to
produce more output and to compensate them for rising prices, therefore
SRAS shifts to the left.
The economy has returned to the equilibrium level of output (Y1), but at a
higher price level (P3).
Therefore the rise in the Money Supply cause a rise in AD, But because
the LRAS is inelastic there is no increase in real output, but inflation rises.
It is a form of demand-pull inflation.
Monetarist view of Phillips curve
Mo
netarists believe in the long-run there is no trade-off between inflation and
unemployment. Increase in the money supply only causes an increase in nominal
GDP, but not real GDP.
Criticisms of monetarism
The link between the money supply and inflation is often very weak in
practice.
The velocity of circulation (V) is not stable but can vary significantly due to
confidence, changes in the use of credit cards, decline in use of cash. e.t.c
Targetting arbitrary money supply targets can cause a severe recession
and high unemployment. For example, UK targetted money supply growth
in the early 1980s, but this caused the recession of 1981 with many
economists arguing it was deeper than necessary.
The large increase in the monetary base following the 2009 recession did
not cause any inflationary pressures.
Why not target inflation directly? If you want to control inflation, it makes
more sense to target inflation directly rather than through the intermediary
of the money supply.
Monetarists say that income can vary in the short run, but the short run
could be a long time and therefore make monetary policy ineffective,
Keynesians argue that the LRAS is not necessarily inelastic they argue
that the economy can be below full capacity for a long time.
Exchange rates
28 June 2017 by Tejvan Pettinger
The exchange rate is the rate at which one currency trades against
another on the foreign exchange market
If the present exchange rate is £1=$1.42, this means that to go to America
you would get $142 for £100. Similarly, if an American came to the UK, he
would have to pay $142 to get £100. Although in real life, the dealer would
make a profit.
Currencies are being continuously traded on the foreign exchange
markets, with the prices constantly changing as dealers adjust to changes
in supply and demand
Currencies will also undergo long-term changes depending on the state of
the comparative countries. E.G. in the 1920s the £ was worth $4.50
Value of the Pound to Dollar 2006-2016. In mid-2008, there was a sharp
depreciation in the value of the Pound because the UK was hit very hard by the
credit crunch. The Pound also dropped after the Brexit vote in June 2016
because markets were less optimistic about the long-term fortunes of the UK
economy outside the EU.
Definitions
Exchange rate index This gives a measure of a currency against a trade-
weighted basket of currencies. It is expressed as an index, where the
value of the index will be 100 in the base year. The weight given to each
currency depends upon the proportion of transactions done with the
country. For example, in the Sterling exchange rate index, the highest
weighting will be given to the Euro and then the dollar.
Real Exchange Rate. This is the exchange rate after being adjusted for
the effects of inflation, it, therefore, more accurately reflects the purchasing
power of a currency.
Floating exchange rate – When the value of the currency is determined
by market forces – supply and demand for currency
Fixed exchange rate – where the government seeks to keep the value of
a currency at a certain level compared to other currencies. See: Fixed
Exchange Rates
Determination of exchange rates using supply and demand diagram
In this example, a rise in demand for Pound Sterling has led to an increase in the
value of the £ to $
from £1 = $1.50 to £1 = $1.70
Interest rates – higher interest rates encourage hot money flows and
demand for currency. This causes an appreciation.
Economic growth – higher economic growth will tend to cause an
appreciation in the currency, this is because markets expect higher interest
rates – when growth is rapid.
Inflation – higher inflation makes exports less competitive and reduces
demand for currency. This causes a depreciation.
Confidence in the economy/currency.
Current account deficit/surplus. A large current account deficit is more
likely to cause a depreciation in the value of the currency because money
is leaving the economy to buy imports.
See more detail at Factors influencing exchange rates
Appreciation of exchange rate
Just completed the Keynes 45˚ line (still in the CIE A2 syllabus) with my A2 class and find this
graph useful to explain it. A popular multi-choice question and usually in one part of an essay.
Make sure that you are aware of the following;
Common Errors:
1. C and S are NOT parallel
2. The income level at which Y=C is NOT the equilibrium level of Y which occurs where AMD
crosses the 45˚ line.
To Remember:
1. OA is autonomous consumption.
2. Any consumption up to C=Y must be financed.
3. At OX1 all income is spent
4. At OB consumption = BQ and saving= PQ
5. Equilibrium level of Y shown in 2 ways
a) where AMD crosses 45˚ line
b) Planned S = Planned I – point D
Just completed the Keynes 45˚ line (still in the CIE A2 syllabus) with my A2 class and find this
graph useful to explain it. A popular multi-choice question and usually in one part of an essay.
Make sure that you are aware of the following;
Common Errors:
1. C and S are NOT parallel
2. The income level at which Y=C is NOT the equilibrium level of Y which occurs where AMD
crosses the 45˚ line.
To Remember:
1. OA is autonomous consumption.
2. Any consumption up to C=Y must be financed.
3. At OX1 all income is spent
4. At OB consumption = BQ and saving= PQ
5. Equilibrium level of Y shown in 2 ways
a) where AMD crosses 45˚ line
b) Planned S = Planned I – point D
Just completed the Keynes 45˚ line (still in the CIE A2 syllabus) with my A2 class and find this
graph useful to explain it. A popular multi-choice question and usually in one part of an essay.
Make sure that you are aware of the following;
Common Errors:
1. C and S are NOT parallel
2. The income level at which Y=C is NOT the equilibrium level of Y which occurs where AMD
crosses the 45˚ line.
To Remember:
1. OA is autonomous consumption.
2. Any consumption up to C=Y must be financed.
3. At OX1 all income is spent
4. At OB consumption = BQ and saving= PQ
5. Equilibrium level of Y shown in 2 ways
a) where AMD crosses 45˚ line
b) Planned S = Planned I – point D
Just completed the Keynes 45˚ line (still in the CIE A2 syllabus) with my A2 class and find this
graph useful to explain it. A popular multi-choice question and usually in one part of an essay.
Make sure that you are aware of the following;
Common Errors:
1. C and S are NOT parallel
2. The income level at which Y=C is NOT the equilibrium level of Y which occurs where AMD
crosses the 45˚ line.
To Remember:
1. OA is autonomous consumption.
2. Any consumption up to C=Y must be financed.
3. At OX1 all income is spent
4. At OB consumption = BQ and saving= PQ
5. Equilibrium level of Y shown in 2 ways
a) where AMD crosses 45˚ line
b) Planned S = Planned I – point D
Just completed the Keynes 45˚ line (still in the CIE A2 syllabus) with my A2 class and find this
graph useful to explain it. A popular multi-choice question and usually in one part of an essay.
Make sure that you are aware of the following;
Common Errors:
1. C and S are NOT parallel
2. The income level at which Y=C is NOT the equilibrium level of Y which occurs where AMD
crosses the 45˚ line.
To Remember:
1. OA is autonomous consumption.
2. Any consumption up to C=Y must be financed.
3. At OX1 all income is spent
4. At OB consumption = BQ and saving= PQ
5. Equilibrium level of Y shown in 2 ways
a) where AMD crosses 45˚ line
b) Planned S = Planned I – point D
Just completed the Keynes 45˚ line (still in the CIE A2 syllabus) with my A2 class and find this
graph useful to explain it. A popular multi-choice question and usually in one part of an essay.
Make sure that you are aware of the following;
Common Errors:
1. C and S are NOT parallel
2. The income level at which Y=C is NOT the equilibrium level of Y which occurs where AMD
crosses the 45˚ line.
To Remember:
1. OA is autonomous consumption.
2. Any consumption up to C=Y must be financed.
3. At OX1 all income is spent
4. At OB consumption = BQ and saving= PQ
5. Equilibrium level of Y shown in 2 ways
a) where AMD crosses 45˚ line
b) Planned S = Planned I – point D
Just completed the Keynes 45˚ line (still in the CIE A2 syllabus) with my A2 class and find this
graph useful to explain it. A popular multi-choice question and usually in one part of an essay.
Make sure that you are aware of the following;
Common Errors:
1. C and S are NOT parallel
2. The income level at which Y=C is NOT the equilibrium level of Y which occurs where AMD
crosses the 45˚ line.
To Remember:
1. OA is autonomous consumption.
2. Any consumption up to C=Y must be financed.
3. At OX1 all income is spent
4. At OB consumption = BQ and saving= PQ
5. Equilibrium level of Y shown in 2 ways
a) where AMD crosses 45˚ line
b) Planned S = Planned I – point D
All increases in money supply are simply taken upin idle balances. Since interest rates do not
alter, the level of expenditure in the economy is not affected. Consequently, monetary policy
under these circumstances is futile.
Final thought
Today the threat of deflation seems to have passed us by but the world was looking at a major
global slowdown and it was not a matter of how much things were slowing, but it was how
much they were going backwards. The most disconcerting fact was that all the easing of
interest rates by central banks didn’t really change that outlook. Besides, with the severe threat
of deflation there was a need to preserve the firepower in case the economy needed more
stimulating. Like when an individual is besieged by many attackers while holding limited
ammunition, each shot is used sparingly. But with little ammunition left what was next?
This entry was posted in Deflation on May 29, 2017.
\
Consumption Function cake
Leave a reply
Many thanks to A2 student Lara Hodgson for this superb cake that the class enjoyed this morning. Remember
that the standard Keynesian consumption function is written as follows:
C = a + c (Yd) – where:
Autonomous spending (a) is consumption which does not depend on the level of income. For example people
can fund some of their spending by using their savings or by borrowing money from banks and other lenders.
A change in autonomous spending would in fact cause a shift in the consumption function leading to a change
in consumer demand at all levels of income. The key to understanding how a rise in disposable income affects
household spending is to understand the concept of the marginal propensity to consume (mpc). The marginal
propensity to consume is the change in consumer spending arising from a change in disposable income. The
higher the mpc the steeper the gradient of the consumption function line. As you can imagine the consumption
of cake was fairly rapid.
This entry was posted in Eco Comedy, Macro and tagged Cake, Consumption, Keynes on March 23, 2017.
“Why was the Irish economist afraid of swimming? He was conscious of the liquidity trap.”
“How do you confuse an Irishman when trying to maximise his utility when purchasing two products? Put two
shovels against the wall and tell him to take his pick.”
“What do you call it when an Irish economist has an idea? Moral Hazard”
“An Irishman said he saw a ghost. The Irish economist said it was just the invisible hand.”
“What’s the difference between Iceland’s economy and Ireland’s? One letter and six months”
“We all know what pareto optimal allocation means… What about Irish optimal allocation — when all persons
are equally well off, and one person really gets it bad, worse off, while all the rest are much better off…”
“An Irish economist walks into a pizzeria to order a pizza. When the pizza is done, he goes up to the counter
get it. There a clerk asks him: “Should I cut it into six pieces or eight pieces?” The Irish economist replies:
“I’m feeling rather hungry right now. You’d better cut it into eight pieces.” (see the “Father Ted” version
above)
“Why would Father Jack not make a good economist? There
would always be massive inflation as his only policy would be to increase liquidity.”
A2 Economics – Labour Market – MRPL
Leave a reply
Marginal Revenue Product refers to the amount of revenue generated by an additional worker.
This is a theory of wages where workers are paid the value of their marginal revenue product to
the firm and is based on the assumption of a perfectly competitive labour market. Therefore an
employer will hire workers up to the point where the value of the marginal product of labour
equals the wage that is being paid. The demand curve for labour can therefore be represented
by the value of the marginal product curve – see graph below and a revision mindmap.
Adapted from: AS and A Level Economics Revision by Susan Grant
Currently covering Keynes vs Monetarist in the A2 course. Here is a powerpoint on the theory that I use for
revision purposes. I have found that the graphs are particularly useful in explaining the theory. The powerpoint
includes explanations of:
– C+I+G+(X-M)
– 45˚line
– Circular Flow and the Multiplier
– Diagrammatic Representation of Multiplier and Accelerator
– Quantity Theory of Money
– Demand for Money – Liquidity Preference
– Defaltionary and Inflationary Gap
– Extreme Monetarist and Extreme Keynesian
– Summary Table of “Keynesian and Monetarist”
– Essay Questions with suggested answers.
Hope it is of use – 45˚line shown. Click the link below to download the file.
Keynes v Monetarist Keynote
What is the Gini Coefficient? The Gini Coefficient is derived from the same information used
to create a Lorenz Curve. The co-efficient indicates the gap between two percentages: the
percentage of population, and the percentage of income received by each percentage of the
population. In order to calculate this you divide the area between the Lorenz Curve and the 45°
line by the total area below the 45° line eg.
Area between the Lorenz Curve and the 45° line
Total area below the 45° line
The straight line (45° line) shows absolute equality of income. That is, 10% of the households
earn 10% of income, 50% of households earn 50% of income.
This entry was posted in Inequality and tagged Coronavirus, Gini Coefficient, Lorenz Curve on May 14, 2020.
AS Revision – Indirect Tax
Leave a reply
The AS multiple-choice paper is coming up and here is this graphic to explain indirect taxes – a popular
question. An indirect tax will have the following effects on the market:
• The supply curve shifts vertically upwards(effectively a shift to the left) by the amount of the tax(gf) per unit.
The price increases but not by the full amount of the tax. This is because of the slopes of the demand and
supply curves.
• The consumer surplus is reduced from acp to agb. The portion gbhp of the old consumer surplus is
transferred to government in the form of tax.
• The producer surplus is reduced from pce to fde. The portion phdf of the old producer surplus is transferred
to the government in the form of tax.
• The market is no longer able to reach equilibrium, and there is a loss of allocative efficiency resulting in the
deadweight lost shown by the area bcd. This represents a loss of both consumer surplus bhc and the producer
surplus hcd that is removed from the market. The deadweight loss also represents a loss of welfare to an
individual or group where that loss is not offset by a welfare gain to some other individual or group.
This entry was posted in Exam revision, Fiscal Policy, Micro, Supply & Demand and tagged Indirect
Tax on November 10, 2019.
Been doing some more revision sessions on CIE AS economics and went through how the elasticity of demand
varies along a demand curve. Notice in Case A that the fall in price from Pa to Pb causes the the total revenue
to increase therefore it is elastic – the blue area (-) is less than the orange area (+). In Case B the opposite
applies – as the price decreases from Pa to Pb the total revenue decreases therefore it is inelastic – the blue area
(-) is greater than the orange area (+). In Case C the drop in price causes the same proportionate change in
quantity demanded, therefore there is no change in total revenue – it is unitary elasticity.
Remember where MR = 0 – PED = 1 on the demand curve (AR curve). A particularly popular question at A2
level is ‘where on the demand curve will a profit maximising firm produce at?’. As MC = MR above zero the
imperfect firm always produces on the elastic part of the demand curve.
This entry was posted in Micro, Supply & Demand and tagged Elasticity, Total Revenue on August 26,
With the A2 Essay paper tomorrow I thought something on the kinked demand curve might be
useful. I alluded to in a previous post that one model of oligopoly revolves around how a firm
perceives its demand curve. The model relates to an oligopoly in which firms try to anticipate
the reactions of rivals to their actions. As the firm cannot readily observe its demand curve with
any degree of certainty, it has got to estimate how consumers will react to price changes.
In the graph below the price is set at P1 and it is selling Q1. The firm has to decide whether to
alter the price. It knows that the degree of its price change will depend upon whether or not the
other firms in the market will follow its lead. The graph shows the the two extremes for the
demand curve which the firm perceives that it faces. Suppose that an oligopolist, for whatever
reason, produces at output Q1 and price P1, determined by point X on the graph. The firm
perceives that demand will be relatively elastic in response to an increase in price, because
they expects its rivals to react to the price rise by keeping their prices stable, thereby gaining
customers at the firm’s expense. Conversely, the oligopolist expects rivals to react to a decrease
in price by cutting their prices by an equivalent amount; the firm therefore expects demand to
be relatively inelastic in response to a price fall, since it cannot hope to lure many customers
away from their rivals. In other words, the oligopolist’s initial position is at the junction of the
two demand curves of different relative elasticity, each reflecting a different assumption about
how the rivals are expected to react to a change in price. If the firm’s expectations are correct,
sales revenue will be lost whether the price is raised or cut. The best policy may be to leave the
price unchanged.
With this price rigidity a discontinuity exists along a vertical line above output Q1 between the
two marginal revenue curves associated with the relatively elastic and inelastic demand curves.
Costs can rise or fall within a certain range without causing a profit-maximising oligopolist to
change either the price or output. At output Q1 and price P1 MC=MR as long as the MC curve is
between an upper limit of MC2 and a lower limit of MC1.
Criticisms of the kinked demand curve theory.
Although it is a plausible explanation of price rigidity it doesn’t explain how and why an
oligopolist chooses to be a point X in the first place. Research casts doubt on whether
oligopolists respond to price changes in the manner assumed. Oligopolistic markets often
display evidence of price leadership, which provides an alternative explanation of orderly price
behaviour. Firms come to the conclusion that price-cutting is self-defeating and decide that it
may be advantageous to follow the firm which takes the first steps in raising the price. If all
firms follow, the price rise will be sustained to the benefit of all firms.
If you want to gradually build the kinked demand curve model downlo
Going over monetary policy with my A2 class and have modified a mind map done by Susan
Grant from a CIE Economics Revision Guide. Useful for those who are sitting the June AS and A2
Economics papers.
This entry was posted in Interest Rates, Teaching visuals and tagged AS Level Re
Going over monetary policy with my A2 class and have modified a mind map done by Susan
Grant from a CIE Economics Revision Guide. Useful for those who are sitting the June AS and A2
Economics papers.
This entry was posted in Interest Rates, Teaching visuals and tagged AS Level Revv
Firms, according to the analysis we use predict their behaviour, are very interested in their marginal cost. Since
the term marginal means additional or incremental, marginal costs refer to those costs that result from a one-
unit change in the production rate. We find marginal cost by subtracting the total cost of producing all but the
last unit from the total cost of producing all units, including the last one. Marginal costs can be measured,
therefore, by using the formula:
Average Fixed Costs (AFC) : they continue to fall throughout the output range. The gap between ATC and
AVC = AFC
Average Variable Costs (AVC) : the form it takes is U-shaped: first it falls; then it starts to rise. It is certainly
possible to have other shapes of the AVC.
Average Total Costs or Average Costs (ATC or AC) : similar shape to the average variable cost. However,
it falls even more dramatically in the beginning and rises more slowly after it has reached a minimum point. It
falls and then rises because average total costs is the summation of the AFC and the AVC curve. Thus, when
AFC plus AVC are both falling, it is only logical that ATC would fall, too. At some point, however, AVC
starts to increase while AFC continues to fall. Once the increase in the AVC outweighs the decrease in the
AFC curve, the ATC curve will start to increase and will develop its familiar U-shape. Where MC = ATC this
is the lowest point on the ATC curve and is therefore the cheapest production for the firm. This is called the
technical optimum.
Marginal Cost (MC) : it cuts ATC and AVC at their lowest points. The firm will supply where the price is
greater than or equal to MC. Thus the individual firm’s supply curve consists of the firm’s MC curve, but only
the portion above AVC. The reason for this is that where P=AVC the firm will shut down operations because
they are barely covering avoidable costs.
This entry was posted in Exam revision and tagged Cost Curves on May 20, 2016.
A2 Economics – Evaluation Skills for essay writing
Leave a reply
Here are ten strategies for improving your evaluation skills in data response and essay questions written by
Geoff Riley of Tutor2u.
1. Make good use of your final paragraph – avoid repetition of points already made
2. Look for key stem words in the question – build your evaluation around this
3. Put an economic event, a trend, a policy into a wider context
4. Be familiar with different schools of thought e.g. free market versus government intervention
5. Be aware that a singular economic event never happens in isolation especially in a world where economies
are so closely inter-connected.
6. Question the reliability of the data you have been given
7. Draw on your wider knowledge to provide supporting evidence and examples
8. Consider both short term and longer term consequences (they are not always the same)
9. Consider both positive and negative consequences
10. Think about what might happen to your arguments if you drop the “ceteris paribus” assumption
ShareFacebookTwitterLinkedInDigg
ShareFacebookTwitterLinkedInDigg
30 3 37 12 Diminishing marginal 12.3
30 4 47 10 returns 11.8
30 5 55 8 11.0
30 6 60 5
30 7 63 3
10.0
9.0
(i) Stage of Increasing Returns. The first stage of the law of variable proportions is generally called the stage of
increasing returns. In this stage as a variable resource (labor) is added to fixed inputs of other resources, the total
product increases up to a point at an increasing rate as is shown in figure 11.1.
The total product from the origin to the point K on the slope of the total product curve increases at an increasing rate.
From point K onward, during the stage II, the total product no doubt goes on rising but its slope is declining. This means
that from point K onward, the total product increases at a diminishing rate. In the first stage, marginal product curve of a
variable factor rises in a part and then falls. The average product curve rises throughout .and remains below the MP
curve.
Causes of Initial Increasing Returns:
The phase of increasing returns starts when the quantity of a fixed factor is abundant relative to the quantity of the
variable factor. As more and more units of the variable factor are added to the constant quantity of the fixed factor, it is
more intensively and effectively used. This causes the production to increase at a rapid rate. Another reason of
increasing returns is that the fixed factor initially taken is indivisible. As more units of the variable factor are employed to
work on it, output increases greatly due to fuller and effective utilization of the variable factor.
(ii) Stage of Diminishing Returns. This is the most important stage in the production function. In stage 2, the total
production continues to increase at a diminishing rate until it reaches its maximum point (H) where the 2nd stage ends. In
this stage both the
marginal product (MP) and average product of the variable factor are diminishing but are positive.
Causes of Diminishing Returns:
The 2nd phase of the law occurs when the fixed factor becomes inadequate relative to the quantity of the variable factor.
As more and more units of a variable factor are employed, the marginal and average product decline. Another reason of
diminishing returns in the production function is that the fixed indivisible factor is being worked too hard. It is being used
in non-optima! proportion with the variable factor, Mrs. J. Robinson still goes deeper and says that the diminishing returns
occur because the factors of production are imperfect substitutes of one another.
Importance:
(iii) Stage of Negative Returns. In the 3rd stage, the total production declines. The TP, curve slopes downward (From
point H onward). The MP curve falls to zero at point L 2 and then is negative. It goes below the X axis with the increase in
the use of variable factor (labor).
Causes of Negative Returns:
The 3rd phases of the law starts when the number of a variable, factor becomes, too excessive relative, to the fixed
factors, A producer cannot operate in this stage because total production declines with the employment of additional
labor.
A rational
producer will always seek to produce in stage 2 where MP and AP of the variable factor are diminishing. At
which particular point, the producer will decide to produce depends upon the price of the factor he has to pay. The
producer will employ the variable factor (say labor) up to the point where the marginal product of the labor equals the
given wage rate in the labor market.
The law of variable proportions has vast general applicability. Briefly:
(i) It is helpful in understanding clearly the process of production. It explains the input output relations. We can find out
by-how much the total product will increase as a result of an increase in the inputs.
(ii) The law tells us that the tendency of diminishing returns is found in all sectors of the economy which may be
agriculture or industry.
(iii) The law tells us that any increase in the units of variable factor will lead to increase in the total product at a
diminishing rate. The elasticity of the substitution of the variable factor for the fixed factor is not infinite.
From the law of variable proportions, it may not be understood that there is no hope for raising the standard of living of
mankind. The fact, however, is that we can suspend the operation of diminishing returns by continually improving the
technique of production through the progress in science and technology.
Relevant Articles:
Consumer’s Equilibrium
The consumer is in equilibrium when he maximizes his utility, given
his income and the market prices.
– Anna Koutsoyiannis
Every consumer aims at getting maximum satisfaction out of his given expenditure. A
consumer is said to have attained equilibrium when he spends given income or budget
in such a way as to yield optimum satisfaction, given the prices of two goods and the
consumer’s preference.
In simple words, a consumer is said to be in equilibrium when he is getting maximum
satisfaction out of his limited income.
A consumer may find out his equilibrium condition with the help of indifference curve
analysis.
Assumptions
Consumer’s equilibrium through indifference curve analysis is based on the following
assumptions.
1. The consumer is rational and seeks to maximize his satisfaction through the purchase
of goods.
2. The consumer consumes only two goods (X and Y).
3. The goods are homogenous and perfectly divisible.
4. Prices of the goods and income of the consumer are constant.
5. The indifference map for goods X and Y are given. The indifference map is based on the
consumer’s preferences for the goods.
6. The preference or habit of the consumer does not change throughout the analysis.
7. The income of consumer is given and constant.
Conditions of Consumer’s Equilibrium
The following are the conditions of consumer’s equilibrium
1. Budget line should be tangent to the indifference curve
2. At the point of equilibrium, slope of the budget line = slope of the indifference curve
3. Indifference curve should be convex to the point of origin.
1. Budget line should be tangent to the indifference curve
Consumer’s equilibrium is based on the assumption that the income of a consumer is
constant and that he spends his entire income on purchasing two goods whose prices
are given.
A budget line is a graphical representation of various combinations of two goods that a
consumer can afford at specified prices of the products at particular income level. A
budget line can be drawn on the basis of expenditure plan.
The table given below is an example of expenditure plan and the graph that follows is its
presentation on graph.
Table: Expenditure plan
Given: Budget of the consumer is Rs 10, Price of good X is Rs 1 each and Price of good Y is Rs 2 each
A 5 0
C 4.5 1
E 3 4
D 1.5 7
B 0 10
The consumer can purchase combinations C or D but these will not yield him maximum
satisfaction as they lie on lower indifference curve. On the other hand, he cannot get any
combination on IC3 as it is away from the budget line.
Thus, the consumer will be in equilibrium (achieve maximum satisfaction at any given
level of income) where the budget line is tangent to the indifference curve, i.e. at point E
on IC2.
Cite this article as: Shraddha Bajracharya, "Consumer’s Equilibrium: Interplay of Budget Line and
Indifference Curve," in Businesstopia, January 12,
2018, https://www.businesstopia.net/economics/micro/consumers-equilibrium.
For example, at point E, the slope of budget line = intercept on y-axis / intercept on x-
axis
or, slope of budget line at point E = 3/6 = 1/2
From condition 1, we have known that consumer’s equilibrium exist at the point on
indifference curve where budget line is tangent to the curve.
Thus, at equilibrium point, slope of budget line is equal to slope of the indifference
curve.
As shown in the above figure, a consumer is in equilibrium at point E1 where budget line
AB is tangent to the indifference curve IC1 which is convex to the origin.
If we denote labor by ‘L’ and capital by ‘K’, then MRTS of labor for capital can be
expressed as
Table 1: marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS)
A 12 1 100
B 8 2 4:1 100
C 5 3 3:1 100
D 3 4 2:1 100
E 2 5 1:1 100
In the above table, there are five different combinations of labor and capital, all of which
yield the same level of output.
We can see in combination A that 12 units of capital and 1 unit of labor have jointly
produced 100 units of output. When the producer moves to combination B, he gave up 4
units of capital in order to add 1 unit of labor input while keeping the production level
unchanged. Hence, MRTS of labor for capital is 4 in this case.
Likewise, if we compare the combinations B and C, the consumer gave up 3 input units
of capital in order to add 1 unit of labor. Therefore, MRTS in this case is 3.
In the same way, the MRTS is 2 and 1 between the combinations C and D, and D and E,
respectively.
Clearly, the marginal rate of technical substitution has diminished more and more as the
producer kept on substituting input of labor for capital.
Figure 1: marginal rate of technical substitution
Besides, if the factors could perfectly substitute each other, increase or decrease in
either of the factors won’t bring any changes in the marginal rate of technical
substitution.
Inadequacy of the factor
Substituting one factor for the other continuously causes scarcity of the factor being
replaced. As a result, the factor being tradeoff won’t be able to make as much
contribution as it should have for the efficient production.
Therefore, although the producer had sacrificed more units of capital input in the
beginning, the rate of substitution fell with additional substitutions.
If we denote labor by ‘L’ and capital by ‘K’, then MRTS of labor for capital can be
expressed as
Table 1: marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS)
A 12 1 100
B 8 2 4:1 100
C 5 3 3:1 100
D 3 4 2:1 100
E 2 5 1:1 100
In the above table, there are five different combinations of labor and capital, all of which
yield the same level of output.
We can see in combination A that 12 units of capital and 1 unit of labor have jointly
produced 100 units of output. When the producer moves to combination B, he gave up 4
units of capital in order to add 1 unit of labor input while keeping the production level
unchanged. Hence, MRTS of labor for capital is 4 in this case.
Likewise, if we compare the combinations B and C, the consumer gave up 3 input units
of capital in order to add 1 unit of labor. Therefore, MRTS in this case is 3.
In the same way, the MRTS is 2 and 1 between the combinations C and D, and D and E,
respectively.
If we assume labor (L) and capital (K) to be the two inputs of a production process, the
principle of MRTS states that the value of MRTSL,K decreases with subsequent
substitution of labor for capital. And, this diminishing rate of MRTS is also apparent
from the table 1 given above.
Initially, when the producer moved from combination A to combination B, the rate of
MRTS was calculated to be 4. When the producer moved to combination C, the rate of
MRTS fell and became 3. In the same way, with each successive addition of constant
unit of labor, the MRTS were calculated to be 3, then 2 and finally, 1.
Clearly, the marginal rate of technical substitution has diminished more and more as the
producer kept on substituting input of labor for capital.
Figure 1: marginal rate of technical substitution
Therefore, although the producer had sacrificed more units of capital input in the beginning, the
rate of substitution fell with additional substitutions
In a graph, the price of the commodity is represented in the vertical axis (Y-axis) and the
quantity demanded is represented on the horizontal axis (X-axis). A commodity’s price
and its demand share inverse relationship. This means, higher the price of the
commodity, lesser will be its demand and lower the price, higher will be the demand.
Therefore, in a graph, demand curve makes a downward slope.
In the following figures, fig. I is an example of demand schedule and fig. II is its
graphical illustration (demand curve).
Price of soda per bottle (in Rs.) Quantity (bottles) demanded per day (*1000)
10 40
20 30
20
40 10
Movement along a demand curve can also be understood as the variation in quantity
demanded of the commodity with the change in its price, ceteris paribus.
There can be two types of movement in a demand curve – extension and contraction.
Extension in a demand curve is caused when the demand for a commodity rises due to
fall in price. And, contraction in demand curve is caused when the demand for a
commodity falls due to rise in price.
In the above fig. II, let us suppose Rs. 30 is the original price of the soda per bottle and
20,000 units are the original quantity of demand. When the price falls from Rs. 30 to Rs.
20, the amount of quantity demanded rises from 20,000 units to 30,000 units. With this
change in demand, there is a movement in the demand curve from point B to point C
which is known as an extension of the demand curve.
Similarly, when the price of the soda increases from Rs. 30 to Rs. 40, the demand for the
soda falls from 20,000 units to 10,000 units. This time, there is a movement in the
demand curve from point B to point A, and this movement is known as a contraction in
the demand curve.
When the amount of commodity demanded changed due to non-price factors, there is
no extension or contraction in the curve but the formation of the entirely new demand
curve. As a result, demand curve shifts from its original position.
For an example, the demand for cold drinks in the market may increase substantially
even at same price due to hot weather.
Fig. III: Shift in demand curve
The shift in demand curve is also of two types – rightward shift and leftward shift.
When the demand for a commodity increases at the same price due to favorable
changes in non-price factors, the initial demand curve shifts towards the right, and there
is a rightward shift in the demand curve. Similarly, when the demand for a commodity
fails at same price due to unfavorable changes in non-price factors, the initial demand
curve shifts towards left, and there is a leftward shift in the demand curve.
In the given fig. III, let us suppose, DD is the initial demand curve where P is the original
price and Q is the original quantity of demand of a commodity. Due to favorable
changes in non-price factors, the demand for the commodity in the market has
increased from Q to Q2 amount at the same price. Thus, the demand curve has shifted
rightwards and new demand curve D2D2 has formed.
Similarly, due to unfavorable changes in non-price factors, the demand for the
commodity has fallen from Q to Q1 amount. Thus, a new demand curve D1D1 has formed
at the left side of the initial curve.
For an example: A hungry person buys a burger expecting that the burger will curb his
appetite. This means that the burger has utility.
All economists would agree that the person has gained utility by consuming the burger.
But when it comes to measuring the utility, different economists have different views.
Many economists state that utility can be measured numerically while there are many
others who argue that utility is a subjective phenomenon, and thus can’t be expressed
quantitatively.
This difference in opinion regarding measurement of utility has developed the concept
of cardinal and ordinal utility.
Cardinal utility
According to classical economists utility is a quantitative concept and that it can be
measured in terms of a number. Hence they developed the concept of measuring utility
through cardinal approach.
According to this concept, utility can be expressed in the same way that weight and
height are expressed. However, the economists lacked a proper unit for utility. So they
derived a psychological unit called ‘Util’. Util is not a standard unit because it varies
from person to person, place to place and time to time.
For an example, if a person assigns 20 utils to a burger and 10 utils to a sandwich, we
can understand that the burger has double the capacity to satisfy that man’s wants.
Since util is not a standard unit for measuring utility, many economists, including Alfred
Marshall suggested measurement of utility in terms of money that consumers are
willing to pay for a commodity.
If each rupee is equal to 1 util, a burger worth Rs 20 has 20 utils and a sandwich worth
Rs 10 has 10 utils. Thus, whoever consumes burger will yield utility of 20 utils and those
who consume sandwich will yield utility of 10 utils.
Ordinal utility
Opposing to the concept of classical economists, modern economists claimed that
absolute measurement of utility is not possible.
According to these economists, utility is subjective phenomenon, i.e. influenced by
personal feelings, preference and opinions, and thus unquantifiable. However, they
stated that utility can be clearly expressed in terms of rank.
For an instance, if a person prefers fruit juice to soda, it means fruit juice has more
utility than soda. In this case, fruit juice can be placed in the first position and soda in
the second, in terms of utility.
Income elasticity of demand is the measure of degree of change in quantity demanded
for a commodity in response to the change in income of the consumers demanding the
commodity.
In simple words, it can be defined as the change in demand as a result of change in
income of the consumers. Often referred to as just ‘income elasticity’, it is denoted by
Ey.
Consumer’s income is one of the major factors that determine demand of a product.
Unlike price of the product, consumer’s income share direct relationship with the
demand for the product. This implies that higher the income, more will be the demand,
and lower the income, fewer will be the demand of the commodity.
Percentage Method
Percentage method is one of the commonly used approaches of measuring income
elasticity of demand, under which income elasticity is measured in terms of rate of
percentage change in quantity demanded of the commodity to percentage change in
income of the consumers who demand that commodity.
Cite this article as: Shraddha Bajracharya, "Measuring Income Elasticity of Demand: Percentage, Point
and Arc Methods," in Businesstopia, January 7,
2018, https://www.businesstopia.net/economics/micro/measuring-income-elasticity-demand-percentage-
point-and-arc-methods.
For example: The demand of quantity when the income of the consumer was Rs 3000
was 30 units. When his income increased by Rs 2000, the quantity of commodity
demanded by him became 50 units. Here, income elasticity of demand can be
calculated as
Since Ey = 1, this is an example of unitary income elasticity of demand where
percentage change in income of consumer is equal to percentage change in demand of
the commodity.
Point Method
Point method is one of the geometric methods of measuring income elasticity of
demand at any given point on the income demand curve.
Income demand curve is an upward sloping curve in case of normal goods and a
downward sloping curve in case of inferior goods.
However, the method of calculating income elasticity depends upon the nature of the
income demand curve. These methods are described below.
ΔBAC and ΔAEQ1 are similar triangles in account of AAA property. Thus, ratios of the
sides of both the triangles are equal.
This implies,
In the figure, we can see that AB is an arc on the income demand curve DD, and C is the
mid-point of AB. Here, income elasticity of demand at point C is calculated by following
ways.
Where,
Determinants of Supply
There are a number of factors and circumstances which can influence a producer’s
willingness to supply the commodity in the market. These factors are
Goal of producers
The primary objective of every firm is to earn revenue and maximize profit. However,
there may be circumstances when firms focus on earning prestige rather than profit.
Companies who prioritize prestige to profit may sometimes increase the supply of the
commodity in the market even in times when they earn very little or no profit at all, just
to stand out in the market.
State of technology
Technology is one of the major components of firms and industries these days.
Advancement in technology has a great impact on the production rate. It increases the
production rate efficiently, and with an increase in the amount of products produced,
there will be an increase in the supply of the commodity in the market.
Miscellaneous factors
Under this heading, we can include factors such as means of transportation and
communication, natural factors, taxation policy, expectations, agreement among the
producers, etc. All these factors have potential to influence the ability or willingness of
producers to offer the product in the market.
Price of milk per liter (in Rs.) Quantity supplied per day in liters (*1000)
10 10
12 13
14 20
16 25
Market supply function can also be defined as the summation of individual supply
functions within a specific market.
N = Number of firms
F = Future expectation regarding price of the commodity x
Determinants of Supply
There are a number of factors and circumstances which can influence a producer’s
willingness to supply the commodity in the market. These factors are
Goal of producers
The primary objective of every firm is to earn revenue and maximize profit. However,
there may be circumstances when firms focus on earning prestige rather than profit.
Companies who prioritize prestige to profit may sometimes increase the supply of the
commodity in the market even in times when they earn very little or no profit at all, just
to stand out in the market.
State of technology
Technology is one of the major components of firms and industries these days.
Advancement in technology has a great impact on the production rate. It increases the
production rate efficiently, and with an increase in the amount of products produced,
there will be an increase in the supply of the commodity in the market.
Miscellaneous factors
Under this heading, we can include factors such as means of transportation and
communication, natural factors, taxation policy, expectations, agreement among the
producers, etc. All these factors have potential to influence the ability or willingness of
producers to offer the product in the market.
Cite this article as: Palistha Maharjan, "Concept of Supply Function and Its Types," in Businesstopia,
January 8, 2018, https://www.businesstopia.net/economics/micro/supply-function.
Price of milk per liter (in Rs.) Quantity supplied per day in liters (*1000)
10 10
12 13
14 20
16 25
Market supply function can also be defined as the summation of individual supply
functions within a specific market.
N = Number of firms
Determinants of Supply
There are a number of factors and circumstances which can influence a producer’s
willingness to supply the commodity in the market. These factors are
Goal of producers
The primary objective of every firm is to earn revenue and maximize profit. However,
there may be circumstances when firms focus on earning prestige rather than profit.
Companies who prioritize prestige to profit may sometimes increase the supply of the
commodity in the market even in times when they earn very little or no profit at all, just
to stand out in the market.
State of technology
Technology is one of the major components of firms and industries these days.
Advancement in technology has a great impact on the production rate. It increases the
production rate efficiently, and with an increase in the amount of products produced,
there will be an increase in the supply of the commodity in the market.
Miscellaneous factors
Under this heading, we can include factors such as means of transportation and
communication, natural factors, taxation policy, expectations, agreement among the
producers, etc. All these factors have potential to influence the ability or willingness of
producers to offer the product in the market.
Price of milk per liter (in Rs.) Quantity supplied per day in liters (*1000)
10 10
12 13
14 20
16 25
Market supply function can also be defined as the summation of individual supply
functions within a specific market.
N = Number of firms
Goal of producers
The primary objective of every firm is to earn revenue and maximize profit. However,
there may be circumstances when firms focus on earning prestige rather than profit.
Companies who prioritize prestige to profit may sometimes increase the supply of the
commodity in the market even in times when they earn very little or no profit at all, just
to stand out in the market.
State of technology
Technology is one of the major components of firms and industries these days.
Advancement in technology has a great impact on the production rate. It increases the
production rate efficiently, and with an increase in the amount of products produced,
there will be an increase in the supply of the commodity in the market.
Miscellaneous factors
Under this heading, we can include factors such as means of transportation and
communication, natural factors, taxation policy, expectations, agreement among the
producers, etc. All these factors have potential to influence the ability or willingness of
producers to offer the product in the market.
Price of milk per liter (in Rs.) Quantity supplied per day in liters (*1000)
10 10
12 13
14 20
16 25
Market supply function can also be defined as the summation of individual supply
functions within a specific market.
N = Number of firms
Suppose a producer has Rs. 200 and he wants to spend his entire outlay on two factors
– labor and capital. Further suppose that the price of Labor is Rs. 4 per unit and the
price of capital is Rs 5 per unit. If the firm spends its whole outlay of Rs 200 on labor
only, he can buy 50 units of labor. And, if the firm spends its entire outlay on capital only,
then he can buy 40 units of capital.
C=wL+rK
Where,
C = cost of production
w = price of labor or wages
L = units of labor
r = price of capital or interest rate
K =units of capital
A firm can purchase only such combinations of factor-inputs which satisfy the given
equation. For example, a producer can purchase combinations like ’25 units labor + 20
units capital’, ‘30 units labor + 16 units capital’ or ’12.5 units labor + 30 units capital’
because all of them fulfill the equation at given prices and outlay.
This concept is clearly explained by the figure given below.
Elasticity tends to be greater than 1 in case of products which are not necessary to
sustain our lives. Luxury goods such as expensive smart phone, gold, etc. show this
kind of price elasticity.
Such kind of price elasticity can be observed in goods which are necessary in our day to
day lives. Clothes, foods, etc. are good examples of these kinds of goods.
Given below are two figures –I and II. Figure I is an example of supply schedule and
figure II is its graphical illustration.
Price of milk per liter (in Rs.) Quantity supplied per day in liters (*1000)
10 10
20 20
30 30
40 40
The movement in supply curve can be of two types – extension and contraction.
Extension in a supply curve is caused when there is an increase in the price or quantity
supplied of the commodity while contraction is caused due to a decrease in the price or
quantity supplied of the commodity.
In the above fig. II, let us suppose Rs. 20 is the original price of milk per liter and 20,000
liters is the original quantity of supply. When the price rises from Rs. 20 to Rs. 30, the
amount of quantity supplied rises from 20,000 liters to 30,000 liters, and there is a
movement in the supply curve from point B to point C. This movement is known as an
extension of the supply curve.
Similarly, when the price falls from Rs. 20 to Rs. 10, the amount of quantity supplied
falls from 20,000 liters to 10,000 liters, and there is another movement in the supply
curve from point B to point A. This movement is known as a contraction of the supply
curve.
When the quantity of the commodity supplied changes due to change in non-price
factors, the supply curve does not extend or contract but shifts entirely. For an instance,
the introduction of improved technology in industries helps in reducing the cost of
production and induces production of more units of a commodity at the same price. As
a result, the quantity of commodity supplied increases but the price of the commodity
remains as it is.
Fig. III: Shift in supply curve
The shift in supply curve can also be of two types – rightward shift and leftward shift.
The rightward shift occurs in supply curve when the quantity of supplied commodity
increases at same price due to favorable changes in non-price factors of production of
the commodity. Similarly, a leftward shift occurs when the quantity of supplied
commodity decreases at the same price.
In the above fig. III, let us suppose that SS is the original supply curve where Q amount
of commodity has been supplied at price P. Due to favorable changes in non-price
factors, the production of the commodity has increased and its supply has been
increased by Q2 – Q amount, at the same price. This has caused the supply curve
rightwards and new supply curve S2S2 has formed.
In the same, due to unfavorable changes in non-price factors of the commodity, the
production and supply have fallen to Q1 amount. Accordingly, the supply curve has
shifted leftwards and new supply curve S1S1 has formed.
Scopes of Microeconomics
The scope or the subject matter of microeconomics is concerned with:
Commodity pricing
The price of an individual commodity is determined by the market forces of demand
and supply. Microeconomics is concerned with demand analysis i.e. individual
consumer behavior, and supply analysis i.e. individual producer behavior.
Pricing policy
Microeconomic analysis provides business managers with a thorough knowledge of
theories of production and pricing in order to ensure optimum profit for the firm in the
long run.
Determination of Relative Prices of Products & Factors of
production
Microeconomics helps in analyzing market mechanisms i.e. determinants of demand
and supply which are responsible for the determining prices of commodities in the
market. Along with this, it provides an insight on theories relating to prices of a factor of
rent, wage, interest, and profit.
Basis of Managerial Economics
Microeconomics used for the study of a business unit, but not the economy as a whole
is known as managerial economics. The various tools used in microeconomics like cost
and price determination, at an individual level becomes the foundation of managerial
economics.
https://www.businesstopia.net/economics/micro/concept-externalities.
Given below are few examples of positive externalities which will clarify the concept of
positive externality.
Example 1: A farmer who farms fruit does not only produce fruits for selling but also
helps bee farmers around the area. The bees can collect ample amount of nectar to
prepare honey and increases the benefit of bee farmers for which bee farmers won’t be
charged any money.
At the same time, bees help in pollination at a fruit farm. Fruit farmers do not need to
pay any kind of compensation to the bee farmers for this benefit.
Example 2: You go to college and university, and pay for education for personal benefit.
However, your knowledge is helpful not only to you but also to other members of the
society.
Also, when you join any company, the employers of that place would not need to spend
time and money to train you, causing the company notable benefit.
Negative externality
Contrary to positive externality, negative externality or cost is an involuntary loss in the
welfare of one party due to activities of another party. The party which causes loss does
not need to pay compensation to the one suffering from it.
Few examples of negative externality are given below that will help you further
understand about negative externality.
Example 2: People who use the automobile for transportation contribute to air pollution
as well as congestion. Other people who do not own an automobile are also affected by
these problems.
Cite this article as: Palistha Maharjan, "Concept of Externalities," in Businesstopia
All producers must tag a reasonable price on their commodity in order to convince
consumers to choose and use their products.
On the other hand, producers look forward to receiving a certain minimal amount in
return for their goods and services, without which they won’t be able to generate profit.
Producers set a certain amount of price for their goods and services, depending upon
different inputs that are used during the production procedure. However, sometimes,
consumers may be willing to pay price greater than that set by the producers due to the
various market condition.
This difference between the minimum price that the producers are willing to supply or
sell their commodity at and the actual price they receive from consumers in exchange
of the commodity is known as producer surplus or producer welfare. The difference
amount or surplus is an additional benefit that the producers gain through selling their
products.
For instance, let us suppose, ABC is a firm which produces rain boots. After careful
evaluation of the cost of production and desired profit, the firm decided to sell its
product at dollar 40 per pair. The firm produced 1000 pairs and distributed in the
market. However, due to the availability of limited amount of boots, consumers became
ready to pay dollar 50 for a pair.
If the firm had sold all 1000 pairs of rain boots for dollar 40 per pair, it would have
earned revenue of dollar 40,000. But, since the firm was able to sell each pair for dollar
50, it gained total revenue of dollar 50,000, generating producer surplus of dollar 10,000.
Figure: graphical representation of producer surplus
Graphically, producer surplus is the area above the supply curve and below the
equilibrium market price.
In the given figure, DD is a linear demand curve, SS is a linear supply curve and O is the
point of equilibrium where Q amount of commodity is supplied at price P. Thus, in the
above figure, the area of ΔNOP gives producer surplus.
All producers must tag a reasonable price on their commodity in order to convince
consumers to choose and use their products.
On the other hand, producers look forward to receiving a certain minimal amount in
return for their goods and services, without which they won’t be able to generate profit.
Producers set a certain amount of price for their goods and services, depending upon
different inputs that are used during the production procedure. However, sometimes,
consumers may be willing to pay price greater than that set by the producers due to the
various market condition.
This difference between the minimum price that the producers are willing to supply or
sell their commodity at and the actual price they receive from consumers in exchange
of the commodity is known as producer surplus or producer welfare. The difference
amount or surplus is an additional benefit that the producers gain through selling their
products.
For instance, let us suppose, ABC is a firm which produces rain boots. After careful
evaluation of the cost of production and desired profit, the firm decided to sell its
product at dollar 40 per pair. The firm produced 1000 pairs and distributed in the
market. However, due to the availability of limited amount of boots, consumers became
ready to pay dollar 50 for a pair.
If the firm had sold all 1000 pairs of rain boots for dollar 40 per pair, it would have
earned revenue of dollar 40,000. But, since the firm was able to sell each pair for dollar
50, it gained total revenue of dollar 50,000, generating producer surplus of dollar 10,000.
Figure: graphical representation of producer surplus
Graphically, producer surplus is the area above the supply curve and below the
equilibrium market price.
In the given figure, DD is a linear demand curve, SS is a linear supply curve and O is the
point of equilibrium where Q amount of commodity is supplied at price P. Thus, in the
above figure, the area of ΔNOP gives producer surplus.
In economics, deadweight loss (excess burden) is a term used to describe the loss
caused to the society due to market inefficiencies.
It occurs when equilibrium for goods and services is not attained. In other words, it
occurs when supply curve of a commodity does not intersect the demand curve at the
free market equilibrium point.
In a graph, the deadweight loss is represented by the area between supply curve and
demand curve, bound by initial quantity demanded and new quantity demanded.
Figure: graphical representation of price ceiling and deadweight loss
In the above graph, SS is a supply curve and DD is a demand curve. They intersect at
free market equilibrium point E where the Q1 amount of commodity is supplied at price
P1.
Let us suppose P2 is the price ceiling of the commodity. As price ceiling is lesser than
the equilibrium price, consumers’ demand for the commodity increases. However,
producers are not willing to offer goods at such low price and therefore cut off their
supply, making Q2 the new supplied in the market.
Thus, the area in the graph bounded by supply curve, demand curve, initial quantity
supplied (Q1) and final quantity supplied (Q2) gives the measure of deadweight loss.
Price floor
Likewise, the price floor is another measure of price control on how low a price can be
charged for a commodity.
When a price floor is set above the free market equilibrium price, there is an excessive
supply of the commodity but significantly low demand. The goods and services will no
longer be sold in quantities they would have otherwise and the imbalance in demand
and supply results in a deadweight loss.
Taxes
Imposing taxes on goods and services increases the price of the commodity which is
followed by a decrease in demand for that commodity.
Once again, commodity fails to make as many sales as it would have made without
taxes and cause imbalances in the free market equilibrium.
Cross elasticity is greater than zero when rise in price of commodity X causes rise in
demand of commodity Y. Such type of response can be observed in substitute goods
such as Coke and Pepsi.
In the same way, cross elasticity is equal to zero when rise in price of commodity X
does not cause any effect on the demand of commodity Y. This type of response can be
seen in goods that are not related to each other such as sugar and shoe.
And, cross elasticity is lesser than zero when rise in price of commodity Y causes fall in
demand of commodity X. Such type of response can be seen in complementary goods
such as tea and sugar.
Let us also suppose that the manufacturer of Limes received the information that the
price of Oranges is about to fall by 10% in the upcoming month.
From the above information, the manufacturer of Limes can predict by how much the
demand of its product will fall as a result of fall in price of Oranges, and thus will be able
to make necessary decisions to keep up its revenue.
Classification of market
Cross elasticity of demand is also helpful in classifying the type of market.
Higher the value of cross elasticity of demand between the products, greater will be the
competition in the market, and lower the value of cross elasticity, the market will be less
competitive. In the same way, if cross elasticity is zero or almost zero, there is
monopoly or zero competition in the market.
Pricing policy
Price of one product can directly affect the price of another if they are related to each
other. That is why large firms which produce more than one product must evaluate
cross price elasticity between each of their products in order to efficiently price them.
In the same way, substitute goods belong to same industry. Thus, positive value of
cross elasticity of demand indicates that the products are from same industry.
The law of supply states that, other things remaining the same, the quantity supplied of
a commodity is directly or positively related to its price. In other words, when there is a
rise in the price of a commodity the quantity supplied of it in the market increases and
when there is a fall in the price of a commodity, its quantity supplied decreases, other
things remaining the same. Thus, the supply curve of a commodity slopes upward from
left to right.
Law of Supply Assumptions
The term “other things remaining the same” refers to the following assumptions in the
law of supply:
Supply Schedule
Supply Schedule is a tabular presentation of various combinations of price and quantity
supplied by the seller or producer during a period of time. We can show the supply
schedule through the following imaginary table.
The given schedule shows positive relationship between price and quantity supplied of
a commodity. In the beginning, when the price is Rs.10 per kg, quantity supplied by the
seller is 1kg. As the price increases from Rs.10 per kg to Rs.20 per kg and then to Rs.30
per kg, the quantity supplied by the seller also increases from 1 kg to 2 kg and then to 3
kg respectively.
Further rise in price to Rs.40 and then to Rs.50 per kg results in increase in quantity
supplied by the seller to 4kg and then to 5kg. Thus, the above schedule shows that there
is positive relationship in between price and quantity supplied of a commodity.
Supply curve
The supply curve is a graphical representation of a supply schedule. By plotting various
combinations of price and quantity supplied of the table, we can derive an upward
sloping demand curve as shown in the figure below:
In the given figure, price and quantity supplied are measured along the Y-axis and the X-
axis respectively. By plotting various combinations of price and quantity supplied we
derived points A, B, C, D, E curve and joining these points we find an upward sloping
i.e. SS1. The positive slope of the supply curve SS1 establishes the law of supply and
shows the positive relationship in between price and quantity supplied.
Exceptions and Limitations of the Law of Supply
Auction Sale
The law of supply states that quantity supplied increases with increase in price and vice-
versa. But this law doesn’t hold true in case of auction sale. An auction sale takes place
at that time when the seller is in financial crisis and needs money at any cost.
Perishable goods
Those goods which have very short life-time and they become useless after that are all
perishable goods. Those goods must be made available in the market at its right time
whatever be its price. So the seller becomes ready to sell his goods at any offered price.
It is also against the law of supply.
The law of supply states that, other things remaining the same, the quantity supplied of
a commodity is directly or positively related to its price. In other words, when there is a
rise in the price of a commodity the quantity supplied of it in the market increases and
when there is a fall in the price of a commodity, its quantity supplied decreases, other
things remaining the same. Thus, the supply curve of a commodity slopes upward from
left to right.
Law of Supply Assumptions
The term “other things remaining the same” refers to the following assumptions in the
law of supply:
1. No change in the state of technology.
2. No change in the price of factors of production.
3. No change in the number of firms in the market.
4. No change in the goals of the firm.
5. No change in the seller’s expectations regarding future prices.
6. No change in the tax and subsidy policy of the products.
7. No change in the price of other goods.
The law of supply can be explained with the help of supply schedule and supply curve
as explained below.
Supply Schedule
Supply Schedule is a tabular presentation of various combinations of price and quantity
supplied by the seller or producer during a period of time. We can show the supply
schedule through the following imaginary table.
The given schedule shows positive relationship between price and quantity supplied of
a commodity. In the beginning, when the price is Rs.10 per kg, quantity supplied by the
seller is 1kg. As the price increases from Rs.10 per kg to Rs.20 per kg and then to Rs.30
per kg, the quantity supplied by the seller also increases from 1 kg to 2 kg and then to 3
kg respectively.
Further rise in price to Rs.40 and then to Rs.50 per kg results in increase in quantity
supplied by the seller to 4kg and then to 5kg. Thus, the above schedule shows that there
is positive relationship in between price and quantity supplied of a commodity.
Supply curve
The supply curve is a graphical representation of a supply schedule. By plotting various
combinations of price and quantity supplied of the table, we can derive an upward
sloping demand curve as shown in the figure below:
In the given figure, price and quantity supplied are measured along the Y-axis and the X-
axis respectively. By plotting various combinations of price and quantity supplied we
derived points A, B, C, D, E curve and joining these points we find an upward sloping
i.e. SS1. The positive slope of the supply curve SS1 establishes the law of supply and
shows the positive relationship in between price and quantity supplied.
Exceptions and Limitations of the Law of Supply
Auction Sale
The law of supply states that quantity supplied increases with increase in price and vice-
versa. But this law doesn’t hold true in case of auction sale. An auction sale takes place
at that time when the seller is in financial crisis and needs money at any cost.
Perishable goods
Those goods which have very short life-time and they become useless after that are all
perishable goods. Those goods must be made available in the market at its right time
whatever be its price. So the seller becomes ready to sell his goods at any offered price.
It is also against the law of supply.
[Related Reading: Law of Demand]
Law of supply from businesstopia
Meaning
The term ‘isoquant’ is composed of two terms ‘iso’ and ‘quant’. Iso is a Greek word
which means equal and quant is a Latin word which means quantity. Therefore, these
words together refer to equal quantity or equal product.
An isoquant curve is the representation of a set of locus of different combinations of
two inputs (labor and capital) which yield the same level of output. It is also known as or
equal product curve or producer’s indifference curve.
It is a firm’s counterpart of the consumer’s indifference curve. Thus, an isoquant may
also be defined as the graphical representation of different combinations of two inputs
which give same level of output to the producer. Since all the combinations lying in an
isoquant curve yield the same level of production, a producer is indifferent between the
combinations.
A 1 12 100
B 2 8 100
C 3 5 100
D 4 3 100
E 5 2 100
The given isoquant schedule represents various combinations of inputs (labor and
capital).
From the table, we can see combination A consists of 1 unit of labor and 12 units of
capital which together produce 100 units of output. In combination B, when 1 unit of
labor was added in place of 4 units of capital, the production process still produced 100
units of output. In the same way, other combinations C (3L + 5K), D (4L + 3K) and E (5L
+ 2K) made the same level of output, i.e. 100 units.
Figure 1: graphical representation of isoquant schedule (isoquant curve)
Assumptions of Isoquant Curve
The concept of isoquant is based on the following assumptions.
1. Only two inputs (labor and capital) are employed to produce a good.
2. There is technical possibility of substituting one input for another. It implies that the
production function is of variable proportion type.
3. Labor and capital are divisible.
4. The producer must be rational, i.e. trying to maximize his profit.
5. State of technology is given and unchanged.
6. Marginal rate of technical substitution diminishes in production process.
A 12 1 100
B 8 2 4:1 100
C 5 3 3:1 100
D 3 4 2:1 100
E 2 5 1:1 100
Given table 2 represents various combinations of inputs, all of which yield the same
level of output, i.e. 100 units, to the producer.
Figure 2 is a graphical representation of MRTS. In the figure, MRTS between any two
points is given by the slope between those points.
In the same way, MRTS at any particular point on the isoquant curve can be calculated
by finding the slope of the line that is tangent to that point on the curve.
If the isoquant curve had been concave to the origin, it would imply that the MRTS
increases as more and more of labor is substituted for capital. And this would be
against the assumption that the isoquant curve is based on.
Isoquant is negatively sloped
The isoquant curve is neither upward sloping nor horizontal but always slopes
downward from left to right. It is because the producer will have to give up some of the
input units of capital to increase the input of labor when keeping the production amount
unchanged.
Increasing input units of either of the factors without deducing the input of the other
factor will result in increased production and it is beyond the principle of isoquant curve.
In the figure, when OK1 units of capital were employed, OL1 units of labor were employed
too. When the input units of labor was increased to OL2, the input units of capital was
reduced to OK2.
Therefore, the curve is downward sloping from to right. And slope of any downward
sloping curve is always negative.
Also, production level at point P = production level at point R = production level at point
Q
But, production level at point S and point T ≠ production level at point P and point Q
Therefore, two isoquant curves cannot intersect. Yet, two isoquant curves need not be
parallel to each other.
The parallelism of isoquant curves depend upon the MRTS. The isoquant curves can be
parallel only when the MRTS of both the curves are equal.
Meaning
The term ‘isoquant’ is composed of two terms ‘iso’ and ‘quant’. Iso is a Greek word
which means equal and quant is a Latin word which means quantity. Therefore, these
words together refer to equal quantity or equal product.
An isoquant curve is the representation of a set of locus of different combinations of
two inputs (labor and capital) which yield the same level of output. It is also known as or
equal product curve or producer’s indifference curve.
It is a firm’s counterpart of the consumer’s indifference curve. Thus, an isoquant may
also be defined as the graphical representation of different combinations of two inputs
which give same level of output to the producer. Since all the combinations lying in an
isoquant curve yield the same level of production, a producer is indifferent between the
combinations.
A 1 12 100
B 2 8 100
C 3 5 100
D 4 3 100
E 5 2 100
The given isoquant schedule represents various combinations of inputs (labor and
capital).
From the table, we can see combination A consists of 1 unit of labor and 12 units of
capital which together produce 100 units of output. In combination B, when 1 unit of
labor was added in place of 4 units of capital, the production process still produced 100
units of output. In the same way, other combinations C (3L + 5K), D (4L + 3K) and E (5L
+ 2K) made the same level of output, i.e. 100 units.
Figure 1: graphical representation of isoquant schedule (isoquant curve)
Assumptions of Isoquant Curve
The concept of isoquant is based on the following assumptions.
1. Only two inputs (labor and capital) are employed to produce a good.
2. There is technical possibility of substituting one input for another. It implies that the
production function is of variable proportion type.
3. Labor and capital are divisible.
4. The producer must be rational, i.e. trying to maximize his profit.
5. State of technology is given and unchanged.
6. Marginal rate of technical substitution diminishes in production process.
A 12 1 100
B 8 2 4:1 100
C 5 3 3:1 100
D 3 4 2:1 100
E 2 5 1:1 100
Given table 2 represents various combinations of inputs, all of which yield the same
level of output, i.e. 100 units, to the producer.
Figure 2 is a graphical representation of MRTS. In the figure, MRTS between any two
points is given by the slope between those points.
In the same way, MRTS at any particular point on the isoquant curve can be calculated
by finding the slope of the line that is tangent to that point on the curve.
If the isoquant curve had been concave to the origin, it would imply that the MRTS
increases as more and more of labor is substituted for capital. And this would be
against the assumption that the isoquant curve is based on.
Isoquant is negatively sloped
The isoquant curve is neither upward sloping nor horizontal but always slopes
downward from left to right. It is because the producer will have to give up some of the
input units of capital to increase the input of labor when keeping the production amount
unchanged.
Increasing input units of either of the factors without deducing the input of the other
factor will result in increased production and it is beyond the principle of isoquant curve.
In the figure, when OK1 units of capital were employed, OL1 units of labor were employed
too. When the input units of labor was increased to OL2, the input units of capital was
reduced to OK2.
Therefore, the curve is downward sloping from to right. And slope of any downward
sloping curve is always negative.
Also, production level at point P = production level at point R = production level at point
Q
But, production level at point S and point T ≠ production level at point P and point Q
Therefore, two isoquant curves cannot intersect. Yet, two isoquant curves need not be
parallel to each other.
The parallelism of isoquant curves depend upon the MRTS. The isoquant curves can be
parallel only when the MRTS of both the curves are equal.
Monetary policy adopted by the government affects the LM curve, whereas, the fiscal
policy affects the IS curve. Expansionary monetary policy shifts the LM curve to the
right, lowers interest rates and stimulates aggregate output. Contractionary monetary
policy has an inverse effect on the curve.
On the other hand, Fiscal policy causes a shift in the IS curve, where an expansionary
policy shifts the curve to the right, stimulates aggregate demand by increasing
government expenditures and reducing tax rates.
The effect of the changes in the policies on interest rates and aggregate income/output
has been discussed further.
Concept of Demand
Demand refers to the quantity of a commodity or a service that people are willing to buy
at a certain price during a certain time interval. It can be termed as a desire with the
‘willingness’ and ‘ability’ to pay for a commodity.
An increase in the price of the commodity decrease the demand for that commodity,
while the decrease in price increases its demand. The phenomena is termed as law of
demand.
Here, the demand for the commodity is the dependent variable, while its determinants
are the independent variables.
Determinants of Demand
Price of the given commodity
Other things remaining constant, the rise in price of the commodity, the demand for the
commodity contracts, and with the fall in price, its demand increases.
Price of related goods
Demand for the given commodity is affected by price of the related goods, which is
called cross price demand.
Income of the individual consumer
Change in consumer’s level of income also influences their demand for different
commodities. Normally, the demand for certain goods increase with the increasing level
of income and vice versa.
Where,
Dx= Demand for commodity x;
Cite this article as: Shraddha Bajracharya, "Concept of Demand Function and its Types,"
in Businesstopia, January 9, 2018, https://www.businesstopia.net/economics/macro/concept-demand-
function-types.
Where,
D= Distribution of income.
y = Rs.2000
In the given figure, quantity demanded and consumer’s income is measured along X-
axis and Y-axis respectively. The greater rise in income from OY to OY1 has caused
small rise in the quantity demanded from OQ to OQ1 and vice versa. Thus, the demand
curve DD shows income elasticity less than unity.
2. Negative income elasticity of demand ( EY<0)
If there is inverse relationship between income of the consumer and demand for the
commodity, then income elasticity will be negative. That is, if the quantity demanded for
a commodity decreases with the rise in income of the consumer and vice versa, it is
said to be negative income elasticity of demand. For example:
As the income of consumer increases, they either stop or consume less of inferior
goods.
In the given figure, quantity demanded and consumer’s income is measured along X-
axis and Y-axis respectively. When the consumer’s income rises from OY to OY1 the
quantity demanded of inferior goods falls from OQ to OQ1 and vice versa. Thus, the
demand curve DD shows negative income elasticity of demand.
3. Zero income elasticity of demand ( EY=0)
If the quantity demanded for a commodity remains constant with any rise or fall in
income of the consumer and, it is said to be zero income elasticity of demand. For
example: In case of basic necessary goods such as salt, kerosene, electricity, etc. there
is zero income elasticity of demand.
In the given figure, quantity demanded and consumer’s income is measured along X-
axis and Y-axis respectively. The consumer’s income may fall to OY1 or rise
to OY2 from OY, the quantity demanded remains the same at OQ. Thus, the demand
curve DD, which is vertical straight line parallel to Y-axis shows zero income elasticity of
demand.
The law of diminishing marginal utility was first propounded by 19th century German
economist H.H. Gossen which explains the behavior of the consumers and the basic
tendency of human nature. Hence, this law is also known as Gossen’s First Law. This
was further modified by Marshall.
According to Marshall,
The table shows that when a consumer consumes 1st unit of orange he derives the
marginal utility equal to 6utils. As the consumer consumes 2nd and 3rd units of orange,
the marginal utility is declined from 4utils to 2utils respectively.
When he consumes 4th unit of orange the marginal utility becomes zero, which is called
the point of satiety. Similarly, from the consumption of 5th and 6th units of orange, the
marginal utility becomes negative, i.e., he gets disutility instead of utility from these
units of consumption.
Thus, the table shows that a consumer consumes more and more units of a commodity
at a certain period of time, the marginal utility declines, becomes zero and even
negative.
This law can be further explained with the help of a diagram:
In the figure, X-axis represents units of orange and Y-axis represents utility. MU is the
marginal utility curve which slopes downward from left to right. It means that as a
consumer consumes more and more units of a commodity, the marginal utility he
derives from the additional unit of consumption goes on declining, becomes zero(at
point D) and even negative(at point E and F.)
[Related Reading: Principle of Marginal Rate of Substitution]
Exceptions Where Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility Doesn’t
Apply
Dissimilar units
This law is applicable for homogenous unit only, i.e. only if all units of a commodity
consumed are similar in length, breadth, shape and size. If there is a change in such
factors, the utility obtained from it can be increased. For example: If the 2 nd orange is
much larger than the 1st one, it will yield more satisfaction than the 1st.
Unreasonable quantity
The quantity of the commodity a consumer consumes should be reasonable. If the units
of consumption are too small, then every successive unit of consumption may give
higher utility to the consumer. For example: If a person is given water by a spoon when
he is very thirsty, each additional spoonful will give him more satisfaction.
Not a suitable time period
There should not be very long gap between the consumption of different units of the
commodity. If there is time lag between the consumption of different units, then this law
may not hold good. For example: If a man has lunch at 10 a.m. and dinner at 8 p.m. and
eats nothing in between, the dinner will possibly yield even more satisfaction than the
lunch, i.e. his marginal utility will not diminish.
Rare collection
This law does not apply for rare collections such as old coins, stamps and so on
because the longer and larger the number he collects, the greater will be the utility.
Cite this article as: Shraddha Bajracharya, "Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility: Assumptions and
Exceptions," in Businesstopia, January 11, 2018, https://www.businesstopia.net/economics/micro/law-
diminishing-marginal-utility.
Abnormal person
The law of diminishing marginal utility is applicable for normal person only. Abnormal
persons such as drunkards and druggist are not associated with the law.
Change in income of the consumer
To hold the law good, there should not be any change in the income of the consumer. If
the income of the consumer increases, he will consume more and more units of a
commodity which he prefers. As a result, utility can be increased rather than decreased.
Habitual goods
The law will not be applicable for habitual goods such as consumption of cigarettes,
consumption of drugs, alcohol, etc.
Changes in monetary policy variables lead to shift in LM curve. The LM curve is affected
by the changes in exogenous variables or by the behavioral shift in the demand for
money. The two main factors that affect the LM curve include change in demand for
money and change in supply of money. The effect of these factors have been explained
below:
Shortage
If price ceiling is set above the existing market price, there is no direct effect. But, if
price ceiling is set below the existing market price, the market undergoes problem of
shortage.
When price ceiling is set below the market price, producers will begin to slow or stop
their production process causing less supply of commodity in the market. On the other
hand, demand of the consumers for such commodity increases with the fall in price.
And with this imbalance between supply and demand of the commodity, shortage is
created in the market.
Government rationing also results in consumers needing to stay in queue for great deal
of times, and this can be troublesome to elderly, disabled and other people who cannot
afford to stay in line for a long time.
Black market
Shortage of commodities encourages black market. Sellers begin trading commodities
to relatives and friends, and they start charging other people prices multiple times
higher than that of price ceiling.
Degradation of quality
Producers won’t be able to generate desirable profit when government set price ceiling.
During such condition, many producers may use raw materials of comparatively lesser
quality in order to maintain same or almost same revenue as before.
It is legal minimum price set by the government on particular goods and services in
order to prevent producers from being paid very less price.
Price ceiling as well as price floor are both intended to protect certain groups, and these
protection is only possible at the price of others. Price floor is typically proposed to
ensure good income of people involved in farming, agriculture and low-skilled jobs.
Government set price floor when it believes that the producers are receiving unfair
amount. Price floor is enforced with an only intention of assisting producers. However,
price floor has some adverse effects on the market. These effects are
Supply surplus
If price floor is less than market equilibrium price then it has no impact on the economy.
But if price floor is set above market equilibrium price, immediate supply surplus can be
observed.
At higher market price, producers increase their supply. In contrast, consumers’ demand
for the commodity will decrease, and supply surplus is generated.
Cite this article as: Palistha Maharjan, "Effects of Price Ceiling and Price Floor," in Businesstopia,
January 6, 2018, https://www.businesstopia.net/economics/micro/effects-price-ceiling-and-price-floor.
Government intervention
When price floor is continued for a long time, supply surplus is generated in a huge
amount.
In case of producer surplus, producers would have reduced the price to increase
consumers’ demands and clear off the stock. But since it is illegal to do so, producers
cannot do anything. So, government has to intervene and buy the surplus inventories.
Government may sell these inventories in situation when there is scarcity of those
commodities, or it can also distribute to the poor people and public entities.
Minimum wage and unemployment
If minimum wage is set below the market price, no effect is seen. But if minimum wage
is set above market price, employers may distribute more work among few workers and
terminate rest of the workers in order to not to pay more wage to more workers. Setting
price floor will obviously help few workers in getting higher wage. But at the same time,
other workers will also have to lose their jobs, creating unemployment.
Per Capita Income of a country usually refers to the average earning of an individual in a
particular year. In order to determine the per capita income of a country, the national
income of the country is divided by the population of the country in that particular year.
Thus,
Per Capita Income= National Income of a country/ Total population of the country
The per capita income of a country helps in determining the standard of living of the
countries and also serves as an index to determine economic development of different
countries.
Owlcation»
Social Sciences»
Economics
Sundaram Ponnusamy
more
Contact Author
Introduction
Indifference curve analysis is basically an attempt to improve cardinal utility analysis (principle
of marginal utility). The cardinal utility approach, though very useful in studying elementary
consumer behavior, is criticized for its unrealistic assumptions vehemently. In particular,
economists such as Edgeworth, Hicks, Allen and Slutsky opposed utility as a measurable entity.
According to them, utility is a subjective phenomenon and can never be measured on an absolute
scale. The disbelief on the measurement of utility forced them to explore an alternative approach
to study consumer behavior. The exploration led them to come up with the ordinal utility
approach or indifference curve analysis. Because of this reason, aforementioned economists are
known as ordinalists. As per indifference curve analysis, utility is not a measurable entity.
However, consumers can rank their preferences.
Indifference Curve Analysis Vs. Marginal Utility Approach
Let us look at a simple example. Suppose there are two commodities, namely apple and orange.
The consumer has $10. If he spends entire money on buying apple, it means that apple gives him
more satisfaction than orange. Thus, in indifference curve analysis, we conclude that the
consumer prefers apple to orange. In other words, he ranks apple first and orange second.
However, in cardinal or marginal utility approach, the utility derived from apple is measured (for
example, 10 utils). Similarly, the utility derived from orange is measured (for example, 5 utils).
Now the consumer compares both and prefers the commodity that gives higher amount of utility.
Indifference curve analysis strictly says that utility is not a measurable entity. What we do here is
that we observe what the consumer prefers and conclude that the preferred commodity (apple in
our example) gives him more satisfaction. We never try to answer ‘how much satisfaction
(utility)’ in indifference curve analysis.
Assumptions
Theories of economics cannot survive without assumptions and indifference curve analysis is no
different. The following are the assumptions of indifference curve analysis:
Rationality
The theory of indifference curve studies consumer behavior. In order to derive a plausible
conclusion, the consumer under consideration must be a rational human being. For example,
there are two commodities called ‘A’ and ‘B’. Now the consumer must be able to say which
commodity he prefers. The answer must be a definite. For instance – ‘I prefer A to B’ or ‘I prefer
B to A’ or ‘I prefer both equally’. Technically, this assumption is known as completeness or
trichotomy assumption.
Consistency
Another important assumption is consistency. It means that the consumer must be consistent in
his preferences. For example, let us consider three different commodities called ‘A’, ‘B’ and ‘C’.
If the consumer prefers A to B and B to C, obviously, he must prefer A to C. In this case, he
must not be in a position to prefer C to A since this decision becomes self-contradictory.
Symbolically,
If A > B, and B > c, then A > C.
More Goods to Less
The indifference curve analysis assumes that consumer always prefers more goods to less.
Suppose there are two bundles of commodities – ‘A’ and ‘B’. If bundle A has more goods than
bundle B, then the consumer prefers bundle A to B.
Substitutes and Complements
In indifference curve analysis, there exist substitutes and complements for the goods preferred by
the consumer. However, in marginal utility approach, we assume that goods under consideration
do not have substitutes and complements.
Income and Market Prices
Finally, the consumer’s income and prices of commodities are fixed. In other words, with given
income and market prices, the consumer tries to maximize utility.
Indifference Schedule
An indifference schedule is a list of various combinations of commodities that give equal
satisfaction or utility to consumers. For simplicity, we have considered only two commodities,
‘X’ and ‘Y’, in our Table 1. Table 1 shows various combinations of X and Y; however, all these
combinations give equal satisfaction (k) to the consumer.
A 2 15 k
B 5 9 k
C 7 6 k
D 17 2 k
You can construct an indifference curve from an indifference schedule in the same way you
construct a demand curve from a demand schedule.
On the graph, the locus of all combinations of commodities (X and Y in our example) forms an
indifference curve (figure 1). Movement along the indifference curve gives various combinations
of commodities (X and Y); however, yields same level of satisfaction. An indifference curve is
also known as iso utility curve (“iso” means same). A set of indifference curves is known as an
indifference map.
Marginal Rate of Substitution
Marginal rate of substitution is an eminent concept in the indifference curve analysis. Marginal
rate of substitution tells you the amount of one commodity the consumer is willing to give up for
an additional unit of another commodity. In our example (table 1), we have considered
commodity X and Y. Hence, the marginal rate of substitution of X for Y (MRSxy) is the
maximum amount of Y the consumer is willing to give up for an additional unit of X. However,
the consumer remains on the same indifference curve.
In other words, the marginal rate of substitution explains the tradeoff between two goods.
Diminishing marginal rate of substitution
From table 1 and figure 1, we can easily explain the concept of diminishing marginal rate of
substitution. In our example, we substitute commodity X for commodity Y. Hence, the change in
Y is negative (i.e., -ΔY) since Y decreases.
Thus, the equation is
MRSxy = -ΔY/ΔX and
MRSyx = -ΔX/ΔY
However, convention is to ignore the minus sign; hence,
MRSxy = ΔY/ΔX
In figure 1, X denotes oranges and Y denotes apples. Points A, B, C and D indicate various
combinations of oranges and apples.
In this example, we have the following marginal rate of substitution:
MRSx for y between A and B: AA1/A1B = 6/3 = 2.0
MRSx for y between B and C: BB1/B1C = 3/2 = 1.5
MRSx for y between C and D: CC1/C1D = 4/10 = 0.4
Thus, MRSx for y diminishes for every additional units of X. This is the principle of diminishing
marginal rate of substitution.
14
Owlcation»
Social Sciences»
Economics
Sundaram Ponnusamy
more
Contact Author
Introduction
The fundamental problem in an economy is that there are unlimited human wants. However,
there are no adequate resources to satisfy all human wants. Hence, a rational individual tries to
optimize the available scarce resources in order to attain maximum satisfaction. An individual’s
attempt to optimize the available scare resources is known as consumer’s behavior. The law of
equi-marginal utility explains such consumer’s behavior when the consumer has limited
resources and unlimited wants. Because of this reason, the law of equi-marginal utility is further
referred to as the law of maximum satisfaction, the principle of income allocation, the law of
economy in expenditure or the law of substitution.
What does the law say?
Suppose that a person possesses $200 (limited resources). However, his wants are unlimited. The
law explains how the person allocates the $200 among his or her various wants in order to
maximize the satisfaction. The point at which the consumer’s satisfaction is maximum with the
given resources is known as consumer’s equilibrium. Hence, we can say that the law explains
how the consumer’s equilibrium is attained. The law is basically a cardinal utility approach.
Concept of Equi-marginal Utility
Now let us see how an individual maximizes his or her satisfaction with the help of equi-
marginal utility. The law says that in order to attain maximum satisfaction, an individual
allocates the resources in such a way that he or she derives equal marginal utility from all things
on which the resources are spent. For instance, you have $100 and you spend the money to buy
10 different things. What the law says is that you spend money on each thing in such a way that
all the 10 things provide you with the same amount of marginal utility. According to the law of
equi-marginal this is the way to attain maximum satisfaction.
Table 1
Units of Commodity X Marginal Utility of X
Consider that the consumer spends all his $8 to purchase commodity Y. Since the price of a unit
of commodity Y is $1, he can buy 8 units. Table2 shows the marginal utility derived from each
unit of commodity Y. since the law is based on the concept of diminishing marginal utility, the
marginal utility derived from the subsequent unit diminishes.
Table 2
Units of Commodity Y Marginal Utility of Y
Now the consumer plans to allocate his $8 between commodity X and Y. Let us see how much
money he spends on each commodity. Table 3 shows how the consumer spends his income on
both the commodities.
Table 3
Units of Commodities
Marginal Utility of X Marginal Utility of Y
(X and Y)
4 14 (6th dollar) 10
5 12 (8th dollar) 8
6 10 6
7 8 4
8 6 2
Since the first unit of commodity X gives the highest utility (20 utils), he spends the first dollar
on X. Second dollar also goes to commodity X as it gives 18 utils (the second highest). Both the
first unit of commodity Y and the third unit of commodity X give the same amount of utility.
However, the consumer prefers to buy commodity Y because has already spent two dollars on
commodity X. Similarly, the fourth dollar is spent on X, fifth dollar on Y, sixth dollar on X,
seventh dollar on Y and eighth dollar on X.
In this manner, the consumer consumes 5 units of commodity X and 3 units of commodity Y. In
other words, 5 units of commodity X and 3 units of commodity Y leave him with the same
amount of marginal utility. Therefore, according to the law of equi-marginal utility, the
consumer is at equilibrium at this point. Furthermore, this is point at which the consumer
experiences maximum satisfaction. Let us calculate the total utility of commodities consumed to
understand this.
Total utility = TUX + Y = TUX + TUY = (20 + 18 + 16 + 14 + 12) + (16 + 14 + 12) = 122
Any other combinations of commodities would have left the customer with less total utility. This
is a simple hypothetical illustration to explain how consumer’s equilibrium is attained with the
concept of equi-marginal utility.
Graphical Illustration
Figure 1 details the above explanation graphically. In figure 1, X-axis measures units of money
spent on commodity X and Y, or units of commodities (X and Y) consumed. Y-axis measures
marginal utility derived from each unit of commodity X and Y.
Condition for Equilibrium
The law states that the consumer is said to be at equilibrium, when the following condition is
met:
(MUX/PX) = (MUY/PY) or
(MUx/MUY) = (Px/PY)
In our example, the consumer reaches equilibrium when he consumes the fifth unit of
commodity X and third unit of commodity Y ((12/1) = (12/1)).
Owlcation»
Social Sciences»
Economics
Contact Author
Table 1
Substitution
Type of Good Income Effect Total Effect
Effect
33
Owlcation»
Social Sciences»
Economics
Sundaram Ponnusamy
more
Contact Author
Income and Substitution Effects of a Price
Change
A change in the price of a commodity alters the quantity demanded by consumer. This is known
as price effect. However, this price effect comprises of two effects, namely substitution effect
and income effect.
Substitution Effect
Let us consider a two-commodity model for simplicity. When the price of one commodity falls,
the consumer substitutes the cheaper commodity for the costlier commodity. This is known as
substitution effect.
Income Effect
Suppose the consumer’s money income is constant. Again, let us consider a two-commodity
model for simplicity. Assume that the price of one commodity falls. This results in an increase in
the consumer’s real income, which raises his purchasing power. Due to an increase in the real
income, the consumer is now able to purchase more quantity of commodities. This is known as
income effect.
Hence, according to our example, the decline in the price level leads to an increasing
consumption. This occurs because of the price effect, which comprises income effect and
substitution effect. Now, can you tell how much increase in consumption is due to income effect
and how much increase in consumption is due to substitution effect? To answer this question, we
need to separate the income effect and substitution effect.
How to separate the income effect and substitution effect?
Let us look at figure 1. Figure 1 shows that price effect (change in Px), which comprises
substitution effect and income effect, leads to a change in quantity demanded (change in Qx).
Figure 1
The splitting of the price effect into the substitution and income effects can be done by holding
the real income constant. When you hold the real income constant, you will be able to measure
the change in quantity caused due to substitution effect. Hence, the remaining change in quantity
represents the change due to income effect.
To keep the real income constant, there are mainly two methods suggested in economic
literature:
1. The Hicksian Method
2. The Slutskian method
In figure 3, AB1 is the initial budget line. The consumer’s original equilibrium point (before price
effect takes place) is E1, where indifference curve IC1 is tangent to the budget line AB1. Suppose
the price of commodity X falls (price effect takes place) and other things remain the same. Now
the consumer shifts to another equilibrium point E2, where indifference curve IC3 is tangent to the
new budget line AB2. Consumer’s movement from equilibrium point E1 to E2 implies that
consumer’s purchase of commodity X increases by X1X2. This is the total price effect caused by
the decline in price of commodity X.
Now the task before us is to isolate the substitution effect. In order to do so, Slutsky attributes
that the consumer’s money income should be reduced in such a way that he returns to his
original equilibrium point E1 even after the price change. What we are doing here is that we
make the consumer to purchase his original consumption bundle (i.e., OX1 quantity of
commodity X and E1X1 quantity of commodity Y) at the new price level.
In figure 3, this is illustrated by drawing a new budget line A4B4, which passes through original
equilibrium point E1 but is parallel to AB2. This means that we have reduced the consumer’s
money income by AA4 or B4B2 to eliminate the income effect. Now the only possibility of price
effect is the substitution effect. Because of this substitution effect, the consumer moves from
equilibrium point E1 to E3, where indifference curve IC2 is tangent to the budget line A4B4. In
Slutsky version, the substitution effect leads the consumer to a higher indifference curve.
Thus, income effect = X1X2 - X1X3 = X3X2
10
Owlcation»
Social Sciences»
Economics
Sundaram Ponnusamy
more
Contact Author
Source
Opportunity Cost
Modern economists have rejected the labor and sacrifices nexus to represent real cost. Rather, in
its place they have substituted opportunity or alternative cost.
The concept of opportunity cost occupies an important place in economic theory. The concept
was first developed by an Austrian economist, Wieser. The other notable contributors are Daven
Port, Knight, Wicksteed and Robbins. The concept is based on the fundamental fact that factors
of production are scarce and versatile.
Our wants are unlimited. The means to satisfy these wants are limited, but they are capable of
alternative uses. Therefore, the problem of choice arises. This is the essence of Robbins’
definition of economics.
The opportunity cost of anything is the alternative that has been foregone. This implies that one
commodity can be produced only at the cost of foregoing the production of another commodity.
As Adam Smith observed, if a hunter can bag a deer or a beaver in the course of a single day, the
cost of a deer is a beaver and the cost of a beaver is a deer. A man who marries a girl is foregoing
the opportunity of marrying another girl. A film actor can either act in films or do modeling
work. She cannot do both the jobs at the same time. Her acting in film results in the loss of an
opportunity of doing modeling work.
In the words of Prof. Byrns and Stone “opportunity cost is the value of the best alternative
surrendered when a choice is made.”
In the words of John A. Perrow “opportunity cost is the amount of the next best produce that
must be given up (using the same resources) in order to produce a commodity.”
Importance of the Concept of Opportunity Cost
1. Determination of Relative Prices of goods
The concept is useful in the determination of the relative prices of different goods. For example,
if a given amount of factors can produce one table or three chairs, then the price of one table will
tend to be three times equal to that one chair.
2. Fixation of Remuneration to a Factor
The concept is also useful in fixing the price of a factor. For example, let us assume that the
alternative employment of a college professor is work as an officer in an insurance company at a
salary of $4,000 per month. In such a case, he has to be paid at least $4,000 to continue to retain
him in the college.
3. Efficient Allocation of Resources
The concept is also useful in allocating the resources efficiently. Suppose, opportunity cost of 1
table is 3 chairs and the price of a chair is $100, while the price of a table is $400. Under such
circumstances, it is beneficial to produce one table rather than 3 chairs. Because, if he produces 3
chairs, he will get only $300, whereas a table fetches him $400, that is, $100 more.
Limitations
The concept has the following drawbacks:
1. Specific
If a factor’s service is specific, it cannot be put to alternative uses. The transfer cost or alternative
cost in such a case is zero. This is pure rent, according to Mrs. Joan Robinson.
2. Inertia
Sometimes, factors may be reluctant to move to alternative occupations. In such a case, a
payment exceeding the pure transfer cost will have to be made to induce it to take to an
alternative occupation.
3. Perfect Competition
The concept rests on the assumption of perfect competition. However, perfect competition is a
myth, which seldom prevails.
4. Private and Social Costs
A discrepancy is likely to arise between private and social costs. For example, let us assume that
a chemical factory discharges industrial refuse into a river. This causes serious health hazards,
which cannot be measured in money terms.
5. Alternatives are not clearly known
The foregone opportunities are often not ascertainable. This also poses a serious limitation of the
concept.
Owlcation»
Social Sciences»
Economics
Sundaram Ponnusamy
more
Contact Author
How Do Income Effect, Substitution Effect and Price Effect Influence Consumer's Equilibrium?
The Hicksian Method and The Slutskian Method
Introduction
The goal of a consumer is to get maximum satisfaction from the commodities he purchases. At
the same time, the consumer possesses limited resources. Hence, he is trying to maximize his
satisfaction by allocating the available resources (money income) among various goods and
services rationally. This is the main theme of the theory of consumer behavior. Further, you
could ascertain that a consumer is in equilibrium when he obtains maximum satisfaction from his
expenditure on the commodities given the limited resources. You can analyze consumer’s
equilibrium through the technique of indifference curve and budget line.
Assumptions
1. The consumer under consideration is a rational human being. This means that the consumer
always tries to maximize his satisfaction with limited resources.
2. There prevails perfect competition in the market.
3. Goods are homogeneous and divisible.
4. The consumer has perfect knowledge about the products available in the market. For instance,
prices of commodities.
5. Prices of commodities and consumer’s money income are given.
6. Consumer’s indifference map remains unchanged throughout the analysis.
7. Consumer’s tastes, preferences and spending habits remain unchanged throughout the analysis.
Price Line or Budget Line
Price line or budget line is an important concept in analyzing consumer’s equilibrium. According
to Prof. Maurice, “The budget line is the locus of combinations or bundles of goods that can be
purchased if the entire money income is spent.”
Table 1
Total Amount Spent on
X (units) Y (units)
X + Y (in $)
4 0 8+0=8
3 2 6+2=8
2 4 4+4=8
1 6 2+6=8
0 8 0+8=8
Suppose there are two commodities, namely X and Y. Given the market prices and the
consumer’s income, the price line shows all the possible combinations of X and Y that a
consumer could purchase at a particular time. Let us consider a hypothetical consumer who has a
fixed income of $8. Now, he wants to spend the entire money on two commodities (X and Y).
Suppose the price of commodity X is $2, and the price of commodity Y $1. The consumer could
spend all money on X and get 4 units of commodity X and no commodity Y. Alternatively, he
could spend entire money on commodity Y and get 8 units of commodity Y and no commodity
X. The table given below exhibits the numerous combinations of X and Y that the consumer can
purchase with $8.
In figure 1, horizontal axis measures commodity X and vertical axis measure commodity Y. The
budget line or price line (LM) indicates various combinations of commodity X and commodity Y
that the consumer can buy with $8. The slope of the budget line is OL/OM. At point Q, the
consumer is is able to buy 6 units of commodity Y and 1 unit of commodity X. Similarly, at
point P, he is able to buy 4 units of commodity Y and 2 units of commodity X.
The slope of the price line (LM) is the ratio of price of commodity X to price of commodity Y,
i.e., Px/Py. In our example, price of commodity X is $2 and price of commodity Y is $1; hence,
the slope of the price line is Px. Note that the slope of the budget line depends upon two factors:
(a) money income of the consumer and (b) prices of the commodities under consideration.
In figure 2, LM denotes the initial price line. Assume that the prices of the two goods and
consumer’s money income are constant. Now, the consumer is able to purchase OM quantity of
commodity X or OL quantity of commodity Y. If his income increases, the price line shifts
outward and becomes L1M1. He can now buy OM1 quantity of commodity X and OL1 quantity of
commodity Y. A further increase in income causes a further outward shift in the price line to
L2M2. Price line L2M2 indicates that the consumer can buy OM2 quantity of commodity X and
OL2 quantity of commodity Y. Similarly, if there is a decrease in consumer’s income, the price
line will shift inward (for example, L3M3).
(b) Price Change
The slope of a price line is associated with the prices of commodities under consideration.
Hence, if there is a change in the price of any one of the commodities, there will be a change in
the slope of the price line. Assume that the price of commodity X decreases and the price of
commodity Y remain unchanged. In this case, the price ratio Px/Py (slope of price line) tends to
decrease. In figure 3, this scenario is denoted by the shifts in the price line from LM to LM1 then
to LM2 and so on. Conversely, if the price of commodity X rises, the price ratio Px/Py will rise.
This leads to the price line shifts from LM2 to LM1 and to LM.
Indifference Map
A set of indifference curves that shows a consumer’s preferences is known as an indifference
map. The indifference map of a consumer, since is composed of indifference curves, exhibits all
properties of a normal indifference curve. Some of the most important properties of an
indifference curve are: indifference curves are convex to the origin; they always slope
downwards from left to right; higher indifference curves indicate higher levels of satisfaction;
they do not touch any of the axes (example: figure 4).
Consumer's Equilibrium
Now we have both budget lines and indifference map of the consumer. A budget line represents
consumer’s limited resources (what is feasible) and indifference map represent consumer’s
preferences (what is desirable). The question now is that how the consumer is going to optimize
his limited resources. An answer for this question would be consumer’s equilibrium. In other
words, the consumer’s equilibrium means the combination of commodities that maximizes
utility, given the budget constraint. To obtain consumer’s equilibrium graphically, you just need
to superimpose the budget line on the consumer’s indifference map. This is shown in figure 5.
At point E, consumer’s equilibrium is attained. Because the indifference curve IC2 is the best
possible indifference curve that the consumer can reach with the given resources (budget line).
The tangency of indifference curve IC2 and the price line represent the above statement. At the
point of tangency, the slope of the budget line (Px/Py) and the marginal rate of substitution
(MRSxy = MUx/MUy) are equal: MUx/MUy = Px/Py (first condition for consumer’s equilibrium).
From figure 5, we can understand that the second condition for consumer’s equilibrium
(indifference curve must be convex to the origin) is also fulfilled.
A small algebraic manipulation in the above equation gives us MUx/Px = MUy/Py, which is the
marginal utility per dollar rule for consumer’s equilibrium. Thus, all the conditions for
consumer’s equilibrium are fulfilled. The combination (X0Y0) is an optimal choice (point E) for
the consumer.
76
Owlcation»
Social Sciences»
Economics
Contact Author
Note: There are two laws of utility that are often discussed together: law of diminishing
marginal utility and the law of equi-marginal utility. This article explains the law of diminishing
marginal utility.
The law of diminishing marginal utility is an important concept to understand. It basically falls in
the category of Microeconomics, but it is of equal and significant importance in our day-to-day
decisions. In this article, you will find the definition of the law of diminishing marginal utility,
its detailed explanation with the help of a schedule and diagram, assumptions we make in the law
of diminishing marginal utility and the exceptions where the law of diminishing marginal utility
does not apply.
We will first start with the basic definition of ‘Utility’.
Utility:
Utility is the capacity of a commodity through which human wants are satisfied.
Utils:
'Utils' is considered as the measurable 'unit' of utility.
1 20 20
2 15 35
3 10 45
4 05 50
Unit of Consumption Marginal Utility Total Utility
5 00 50
6 -05 45
The schedule explains that with each additional unit consumed the marginal utility increases with a
diminishing rate. After the saturation point though, the utility starts to fall.
In the above table, the total utility obtained from the first apple is 20 utils, which keep on
increasing until we reach our saturation point at 5th apple. On the other hand, marginal utility
keeps on diminishing with every additional apple consumed. When we consumed the 6th apple,
we have gone over the limit. Hence, the marginal utility is negative and the total utility falls.
With the help of the schedule, we have made the following diagram:
Saturation Point: The point where the desire to consume the same product anymore becomes
zero.
Disutility: If you still consume the product after the saturation point, the total utility starts to fall.
This is known as disutility.
When the first apple is consumed, the marginal utility is 20. When the second apple is consumed,
the marginal utility increases by 15 utils, which is less than the marginal utility of the 1st apple –
because of the diminishing rate. Therefore, we have shown that the utility of apples consumed
diminishes with every increase of apple consumed.
Similarly, when we consumed the 5th apple, we are at our saturation point. If we consume
another apple, i.e. 6th apple, we can see that the marginal utility curve has fallen to below X-axis,
which is also known as ‘disutility’.
The unit and its quality must remain same.
Owlcation»
Social Sciences»
Economics
Sundaram Ponnusamy
more
Contact Author
Introduction
In social sciences, you often find that there is a wide gap between theories and their practical
application. Have you ever thought why it happens? The answer is very simple. Almost all theories
of social sciences are based on general human behavior and certain assumptions. Assumptions are
necessary to hold the theory good. However, some of these assumptions are very unrealistic and do
not work in all situations. In addition, it is hard to predict human behavior. Hence, theories that rely
on such unrealistic assumptions and unpredictable human behavior fail to work in a real life
scenario. Because of this reason, there is a wide gap between theories and their practical
application. However, the law of diminishing marginal utility is completely different in this regard.
Though the theory is derived from general human behavior, it possesses great practical importance.
Let us see how the law of diminishing marginal utility is helpful in various fields of economics.
The law of diminishing marginal utility is one of the fundamental principles in public finance. The law
serves as the basis for progressive taxation. Adam Smith explained canons of taxation in his book
‘Wealth of Nations’. One of the canons of taxation is ‘Ability to Pay’. This means that taxes should be
imposed according to the ability of people to pay. The law of diminishing marginal utility is crucial in
determining people’s ability to pay. According to Prof. Pigou, the marginal utility of money for a poor
person is higher than that for a rich person. This is so, because a poor person possesses little
money; therefore, the utility derived from each unit of money is huge. This implies that rich people
are able to pay more as taxes than poor people are. This concept leads to progressive taxation
system, which imposes heavier tax burden on the rich. This is one of the very important practical
applications of the law of diminishing marginal utility.
Redistribution of Income
Income distribution is the core concept in public finance. What the government does through taxation
is taking away some of the resources from rich and spending them to improve the welfare of poor.
Note that when a person possesses less money, the utility derived from it is huge. At the same time,
when a person possesses more money, the utility derived from it is less because of the abundance.
When taxes are imposed on rich, some of their money is taken away. Hence, the utility derived from
the remaining money improves. At the same time, the money taken from the rich is spent to improve
the welfare of poor. This implies that the poor becomes better off now. This activity helps to attain an
egalitarian society. This process can be explained with the help of the following figure:
Let us suppose that there are two individuals (A and B) in a society. The poor man’s income is OA.
OB’ is the rich man’s income. Suppose the government imposes tax on the rich; therefore, income of
the rich is reduced by B’B. Now, the same amount of money income is transferred to the poor. This
raises the poor man’s income by AA’. From the picture, you can understand that the marginal utility
of the rich improves from D’ to D because of taxation. And the poor man’s utility declines from C to
C’. This implies that money in the hands of the poor has increased. This activity leads to an
egalitarian society.
The law of diminishing marginal utility is the basis to derive demand curve. The law further helps to
understand why the demand curve slopes downward. Click here to know how to derive demand
curve from the law of diminishing marginal utility. In addition, Go here to understand the relationship
between the law of diminishing marginal utility and downward slope of a demand curve.
Value Determination
The law of diminishing marginal utility is helpful to determine the value or price of a commodity. For
example, the law explains that the marginal utility of a commodity decreases as the quantity of it
increases. When the marginal utility falls, consumers do not prefer to pay high price. Therefore, the
seller has to reduce the price of the commodity, if he or she wants to sell more. In this way, the law
plays a crucial role in determining price of a commodity.
Water is abundant and hence has no marginal utility. Because of this reason, want has no or little
value-in-exchange. On the contrary, diamonds are scarce and hence possess a very high marginal
utility. Therefore, diamonds have high value-in-exchange. In this way, the law of diminishing
marginal utility tells us why diamonds are highly priced when compared to water. This scenario is
often referred to as water - diamond paradox.
The following diagram provides you with more information on this paradox:
In figure 2,
The law of diminishing marginal utility is useful for individuals to determine how much money should
be spent on a particular commodity. The equilibrium point is where marginal utility is equal to price
(point E in figure 3). At this point, we can say that the individual utilizes his or her expenditure
optimally. Though we do not calculate all these things in our day-to-day purchasing activities, it
happens naturally. We do not pay a high price for a commodity that does not give us utility. In this
sense, the law of diminishing marginal utility does play an eminent role in all economic activities.
Furthermore, the law of diminishing marginal utility serves as a basis for some important economic
concepts such as law of demand, consumer’s surplus, law of substitution and elasticity of demand.
l Meer
7
Owlcation»
Social Sciences»
Economics
Sundaram Ponnusamy
more
Contact Author
Introduction
The scale of production has an important bearing on the cost of production. It is a common
experience of every producer that costs can be reduced by increased production. That is why the
producers are keener on expanding the size or scale of production. In the process of expansion,
the producer may benefit from the emergence of economies of scale. These economies are
broadly classified into two types:
1. Internal Economies
2. External Economies
3. Internal Economies
4. External Economies
Internal Economies
When a firm expands its scale of production, the economies, which accrue to this firm, are
known as internal economies.
According to Cairncross, “Internal economies are those which are open to a single factory or a
single firm independently of the action of other firms. They result from an increase in the scale
of output of the firm, and cannot be achieved unless output increases. They are not the result of
inventions of any kind, but are due to the use of known methods of production which a small
firm does not find worthwhile.”
Internal economies may be of the following types:
1. Technical Economies
Technical economies are those, which accrue to a firm from the use of better machines and
techniques of production. As a result, production increases and cost per unit of production
decreases.
Following Prof. Cairncross, we may classify the various kinds of technical economies as follows:
(a) Economies of Increased Dimensions
Certain technical economies may arise because of increased dimensions. For example, a double
decker bus is more economical than a single decker. One driver and one conductor may be
needed, whether it is a double decker or a single decker bus.
(b) Economies of Linked Processes
As a firm increases its scale of operations, it can properly be linked to various production
processes more efficiently. For example, in order to obtain the advantage in a linkage process,
both editing and printing of newspapers are generally carried out in the same premises.
In the words of Prof. Cairncross, “There is generally a saving in time and a saving in transport
costs, when the two departments of the same factory are brought closer together than two
separate factories.”
(c) Economies of the Use of By-products
A large firm is in a better position to utilize the by-products efficiently and attempt to produce
another new product. For example, in a large sugar factory, the molasses left over after the
manufacture of sugar from out of the sugarcane can be used for producing power alcohol by
installing a small plant.
(d) Economies in Power
Large sized machines without continuous running are often more economical than small sized
machines running continuously in respect of power consumption. For example, a big boiler
consumes more or less the same power as that of a small boiler but gives more heat.
(e) Economies of Increased Specialization
A large firm can divide the work into various sub-processes. Therefore, division of labor and
specialization become possible. At one stroke, all the advantages of division of labor can be
achieved. For example, only well established big school can have specialized teachers.
2. Economies of Continuation
Technical economy is also realized due to al long-run continuation of the production process. For
example, composing and printing of 1000 copies may cost $200; but if we increase the number
of copies to 2000 it may cost only $250, because the same sheet plate which has been composed
previously can be utilized for the increased number of copies also.
3. Labor Economies
A large firm employs a large number of laborers. Therefore, each person can be employed in the
job to which he is most suited. Moreover, a large firm is in a better position to attract specialized
experts into the industry. Likewise, specialization saves time and encourages new inventions. All
these advantages result in lower costs of production.
4. Marketing Economies
Economies are achieved by a large firm both in buying raw materials as also in selling its
finished products. Since the large firm purchases its requirements in bulk, it can bargain on its
purchases on favorable terms. It can ensure continuous supply of raw materials. It is eligible for
preferential treatment. The special treatment may be in the form of freight concessions from
transport companies, adequate credit from banks and other financial treatments etc. In terms of
advertisements also, it is better placed than the smaller firms. Better-trained and efficient sales
persons can be appointed for promoting sales.
5. Financial Economies
The credit requirements of the big firms can be met from banks and other financial institutions
easily. A large firm is able to mobilize much credit at cheaper rates. Firstly, investors have more
confidence in investing money in the well-established large firms. Secondly, the shares and
debentures of a large firm can be disbursed or sold easily and quickly in the share market.
6. Managerial Economies
On the managerial side also, economies can be achieved; when output increases, specialists can
be more fully employed. A large firm can divide its big departments into various sub-
departments and each department may be placed under the control of an expert. A brilliant
organizer can devote himself wholly to the work of organizing while the routine jobs can be left
to relatively low paid workers.
7. Risk Bearing Economies
The larger the size of a firm, the more likely are its losses to be spread among its various
activities according to the law of averages.
A big firm produces a large number of items and of different varieties so that the loss in one can
be counter balanced by the gain in another. For example, a branch bank can spread its risk by
diversification of its investment portfolio rather than a unit bank. Suppose a bank in a particular
locality is facing a run on the bank, it can recall its resources from other branches, and can easily
overcome the critical situation. Thus, diversification avoids “putting all its eggs in one basket.”
8. Economies of Research
A large sized firm can spend more money on its research activities. It can spend huge sums of
money in order to innovate varieties of products or improve the quality of the existing products.
In cases of innovation, it will become an asset of the firm. Innovations or new methods of
producing a product may help to reduce its average cost.
9. Economies of Welfare
A large firm can provide welfare facilities to its employees such as subsidized housing,
subsidized canteens, crèches for the infants of women worker, recreation facilities etc.; all these
measures have an indirect effect on increasing production and at reducing the costs.
External Economies
External economies refer to gains accruing to all the firms in an industry due to the growth of
that industry. All the firms in the industry irrespective of their size can enjoy external economies.
The emergence of external economies is due to localization.
The main types of external economies are as follows:
1. Economies of Concentration
When a number of firms are located in one place, all the member firms reap some common
economies. Firstly, skilled and trained labor becomes available to all the firms.
Secondly, banks and other financial institutions may set up their branches, so that all the firms in
the area can obtain liberal credit facilities easily. Thirdly, the transport and communication
facilities may get improved considerably. Further, the power requirements can be easily met by
the electricity boards. Lastly, supplementary industries may emerge to assist the main industry.
2. Economies of Information
The economies of information may arise because of the collective efforts of the various firms.
Firstly, an individual firm may not be in a position to spend enormous amounts on research.
However, by pooling all their resources new inventions may become possible. The fruits of the
invention can be shared by all the member firms. Secondly, publication of statistical, technical
and marketing information will be of vital importance to increase output at lower costs.
3. Economies of Disintegration
When the industry grows, it becomes possible to split up production into several processes and
leave some of the processes to be carried out more efficiently by specialized firms. This makes
specialization possible and profitable. For example, in the cotton textile industry, some firms
may specialize in manufacturing thread, some others in producing vests, some in knitting briefs,
some in weaving t-shirts etc. The disintegration may be horizontal or vertical. Both will help the
industry in avoiding duplication, and in saving time materials.
Relationship between Internal and External Economies
No watertight compartmental division can be made between internal and external economies.
When a number of firms are combined into one, external economies will become internal
economies. Internal economies are due to the expansion of individual firm while external
economies arise due to the growth of the entire industry. External economies are a pre-requisite
for the growth of backward regions.
Contact Author
In figure 1, Point E is the initial equilibrium position of the consumer. At point E, the
indifference curve IC1 is tangent to the price line MN. Suppose the consumer’s income increases.
This causes the budget line shifts from MN to M1N1 and then to M2N2. Consequently, the
equilibrium point shifts from E to E1 and then to E2.
Income Consumption Curve
You can obtain income consumption curve (ICC) by joining all equilibrium points E, E1 and
E2 as shown in figure 1. Normal goods generally have positively sloped income consumption
curves, which implies that consumer’s purchases of the two commodities increases as his income
increases. At the same time, this may not be applicable in all cases.
Suppose price of commodity X decreases. In figure 3, the decline in the price of commodity X is
represented by the corresponding shifts of budget line from AB1 to AB2, AB2 to AB3 and AB3 to
AB4. The points C1, C2, C3 and C4 denote respective equilibrium combinations. According to
figure 3, consumer’s real income increases as the price of commodity X reduces. Due to an
increase in the consumer’s real income, he is able to purchase more of both commodities X and
Y.
Price Consumption Curve
You can derive the Price Consumption Curve (PCC) by joining all equilibrium points (in the
above example, C1, C2, C3 and C4). In the above figure, the PCC has a positive slope. This means
that as price of commodity X falls, the consumer’s real income increases.
Derivation of Demand Curve from Price
Consumption Curve
The price consumption curve (PCC) tells us what happens to the quantity demanded when there
is a change in price. A consumer’s demand curve also explains the relationship between the price
and quantity demanded of a commodity. Therefore, price consumption curve is useful to derive
an individual consumer’s demand curve. Though a consumer’s demand curve and his price
consumption curve give us same information, the demand curve is more straightforward in what
it tries to convey.
Figure 4 illustrates the process of deriving the individual consumer‘s demand curve from his
price consumption curve.
In figure 4, horizontal axis measures commodity A, and vertical axis represents consumer’s
money income. IC1, IC2, and IC3 denote indifference curves. Suppose the price of commodity A
continuously decreases. As a result, LN, LQ and LR are the subsequent budget lines of the
consumer. Initially, P1 is consumer’s equilibrium. At this equilibrium point, the consumer buys
OM1 quantity of commodity A.
Price of a unit of commodity A = total money income/number of the units that can be bought
with that money.
Hence, at P1 (equilibrium point – budget line is tangent to the indifference curve IC1), the price
per unit of commodity A is OL/ON. At OL/ON price, the consumer demands OM1 quantity of
commodity A.
Likewise, at OL/OQ price, the consumer is able to buy OM2 quantity of commodity A and at
OL/OR price, he buys OM3 quantity of commodity A.
If you connect all equilibrium points (P1, P2 and P3), you will be able to get the price
consumption curve.
The demand curve, as mentioned above, depicts the prices and corresponding quantities of
commodity purchased by the consumer.
For illustration purpose, suppose the consumer’s income is $40, ON = 8 units, OQ = 10 units and
OR = 20 units. With the help of this information, you can construct a demand schedule as
follows:
Once you have the demand schedule, you can derive an individual consumer’s demand curve as
shown in figure 5.
Figure 5 illustrates a consumer’s demand curve. If you need to construct a market demand curve,
it will be possible by a horizontal summation of individual demand curves.