pp37 48 Mb200011en
pp37 48 Mb200011en
pp37 48 Mb200011en
policy strategy
The maintenance of price stability in the euro area is the primary objective of the ECB’s monetary
policy. Given the time-lags in the transmission of monetary policy impulses to the price level, the ECB
must be forward-looking. Therefore, the ECB must regularly assess the nature and magnitude of
economic shocks and the resulting risks to future price stability. In this respect, the ECB’s strategy
foresees, first, a prominent role for money (signalled by the announcement of a reference value for
monetary growth) and, second, an analysis of a wide range of other economic and financial indicators
in order to form a broadly based assessment of the risks to price stability. These two elements have
been called the two pillars of the ECB’s monetary policy strategy. Taken together, the two pillars form
a framework which is used to organise the analysis and the presentation of the information relevant
for monetary policy-making in order to maintain price stability.
The two-pillar presentation differs in some respects from the strategies pursued by other central
banks. It is, therefore, not surprising that the announcement and explanation of the ECB’s monetary
policy strategy (see the article entitled “The monetary policy strategy of the Eurosystem” in the
January 1999 issue of the ECB Monthly Bulletin) not only triggered an extensive debate, but was also
followed by occasional misunderstandings of the ECB’s policy framework. In the light of this discussion
and of experience gained with the strategy in practice, this article describes and reviews the two
pillars and the main arguments for the adoption of a two-pillar framework for the ECB’s strategy.
In the presence of considerable uncertainties surrounding the structure of the economy and the
transmission mechanism of monetary policy within this structure, when formulating monetary policy
central banks should not rely on any single indicator, single model or simple policy rule to take policy
decisions. Rather, a diversified approach to the analysis of the information underlying monetary policy
decisions is desirable. In accordance with standard economic thinking, the ECB’s strategy organises
the main approaches to assessing risks to price stability into two groups – on the one hand,
approaches which assign a central role to money and, on the other, a variety of other models of the
inflation process, predominantly those which focus on the interplay between supply and demand and
on cost pressures in the goods and labour markets. The diversified approach prompted by the two
pillars of the ECB’s strategy is consistent with an awareness of the uncertainties faced by the central
bank and stimulates cross-checking between analyses focusing on monetary developments and those
concentrating mainly on non-monetary indicators, thereby helping to ensure the robustness of
monetary policy decisions.
1 Introduction
In October 1998 the Governing Council of Moreover, the Governing Council announced
the ECB announced its monetary policy that its strategy would use two forms of
strategy (see Box 1). Most importantly, the analysis to support the assessment of risks to
ECB provided a quantitative definition of the price stability.
primary objective of monetary policy in the
euro area, namely price stability. Price First, in recognition of the fundamentally
stability was defined as an annual increase in monetary origins of inflation over the medium
the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices term, the ECB assigned a prominent role to
(HICP) for the euro area of below 2%. It was money in the formulation of a monetary
emphasised that price stability is to be policy aimed at achieving its primary
maintained over the medium term. The ECB objective. This prominent role – the so-called
affirmed that, in line with its Treaty mandate, first pillar of the strategy – was signalled by
monetary policy decisions would focus on the announcement of a quantitative reference
this overriding objective. value for monetary growth. The first pillar
consists of a detailed analysis of potential
“At its meeting on 13 October 1998 the Governing Council of the ECB agreed on the main elements of the
stability-oriented monetary policy strategy of the ESCB. These elements concern: the quantitative definition
of the primary objective of the single monetary policy, price stability; a prominent role for money with a
reference value for the growth of a monetary aggregate; and a broadly based assessment of the outlook for
future price developments.
As mandated by the Treaty establishing the European Community, the maintenance of price stability will be
the primary objective of the ESCB. Therefore, the ESCB’s monetary policy strategy will focus strictly on this
objective. In this context, the Governing Council of the ECB has adopted the following definition: ‘Price
stability shall be defined as a year-on-year increase in the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices (HICP) for
the euro area of below 2%’. Price stability is to be maintained over the medium term. (…)
Three features of this definition should be highlighted. (1) The HICP is the most appropriate price measure for
the ESCB’s definition of price stability. It is the only price index that will be sufficiently harmonised across
the euro area at the start of Stage Three. (2) By focusing on the HICP ‘for the euro area’, the Governing
Council of the ECB makes it clear that it will base its decisions on monetary, economic and financial
developments in the euro area as a whole. The single monetary policy will adopt a euro area-wide perspective;
it will not react to specific regional or national developments. (3) An ‘increase (...) of below 2%’ is very much
in line with most current definitions adopted by national central banks in the euro area.
Furthermore, the statement that ‘price stability is to be maintained over the medium term’ reflects the need for
monetary policy to have a forward-looking, medium-term orientation. It also acknowledges the existence of
short-term volatility in prices which cannot be controlled by monetary policy.
In order to maintain price stability, the Governing Council of the ECB agreed to adopt a monetary policy
strategy which will consist of two key elements. (1) Money will be assigned a prominent role. This role will be
signalled by the announcement of a quantitative reference value for the growth of a broad monetary aggregate.
(…) (2) In parallel with the analysis of monetary growth in relation to the reference value, a broadly based
assessment of the outlook for price developments and the risks to price stability in the euro area will play a
major role in the ESCB’s strategy. This assessment will be made using a wide range of economic and financial
variables as indicators for future price developments.
This strategy underlines the strong commitment of the Governing Council of the ECB to its primary objective
and should facilitate the achievement of this overriding goal. It will also ensure the transparency of the
ESCB’s decision-making and its accountability. Based on its strategy, the Governing Council of the ECB will
inform the public regularly and in detail about its assessment of the monetary, economic and financial
situation in the euro area and the reasoning behind its specific policy decisions.”
Chart
Schematic presentation of the ECB’s monetary policy strategy
Governing Council
systematically combines all
information in order to take
monetary policy decisions
Analysis
First assigning a prominent cross- Analysis focused on a Second
pillar role to money checking wide range of other pillar
(signalled by the reference economic and financial
value for M3 growth) indicators
Economic information
However, as noted above, the reference value This broader analysis of monetary and credit
for M3 is not an intermediate monetary developments is particularly important when
target. The ECB does not attempt to control evaluating the magnitude of monetary
monetary growth so as to reach the reference impulses in the economy and assessing their
value at a specific point in time. Rather, the potential impact on future economic
reference value acts as an analytical and developments. In addition, such analysis may
presentational tool which constitutes an help to assess the possible existence and the
important benchmark for assessing risks to potential effects of bubbles in financial
price stability. markets. Historically, booms and busts in
asset markets have been closely associated
Moreover, analysis under the first pillar goes with large movements in monetary and,
beyond the evaluation of deviations of M3 especially, credit aggregates, and their
growth from the reference value. The first implications for the economy may depend on
pillar involves an analysis of the components the strength of the balance sheet position of
and counterparts of M3, in particular credit, the financial sector. This is another reason
and other key aspects of the balance sheet for the ECB to give a special status within its
position of financial intermediaries. Such strategy to the analysis of monetary and
analysis helps to provide both a better insight credit aggregates and financial intermediaries’
into the behaviour of M3 in relation to the balance sheets.
reference value and a broad picture of the
Box 2
The reference value for monetary growth
In December 1998 the Governing Council of the ECB announced the first reference value for monetary
growth, namely an annual growth rate of 4½% for the broad monetary aggregate M3. This reference value was
confirmed in December 1999. It was also announced then that the reference value would henceforth be
reviewed on an annual basis.
The reference value is an analytical and presentational tool which facilitates the formulation and explanation
of monetary policy decisions aimed at the maintenance of price stability. To this end, the concept of a
reference value has two key features. First, the reference value must be consistent with – and serve the
achievement and maintenance of – price stability. This means that the monetary aggregate used to define the
reference value should exhibit a stable relationship with the price level over the medium term. Second,
substantial or prolonged deviations of monetary growth from the reference value would, under normal
circumstances, signal risks to price stability. This means that the monetary aggregate used to define the
reference value should possess leading indicator properties for future inflation.
The derivation of the reference value was based on the standard relationship between money, prices, real
activity and the velocity of circulation. Using the Eurosystem’s definition of price stability (annual increases
in the HICP for the euro area of below 2%) and assumptions for trend real GDP growth (2% to 2½% per
annum) and the development of M3 income velocity (a trend decline of between ½% and 1% per annum), a
reference value of 4½% was derived. By using the Eurosystem’s definition of price stability and assumptions
for trend real GDP and velocity, the derivation of the reference value emphasises the medium-term orientation
of monetary policy. The next review of the reference value will take place in December 2000.
By contrast with the forecasts produced by international organisations and other institutions, the Eurosystem
itself does not produce “forecasts” in the sense of best predictions of future developments. Rather, it produces
a “projection” for future developments based on the assumption of unchanged interest rates (and exchange
rates). In order to understand the role of the Eurosystem’s projections in the ECB’s strategy, this distinction
must be borne in mind.
Since macroeconomic projections produced within the Eurosystem and the forecasts of other institutions are
typically produced on the basis of models of the inflation process which do not accord a prominent role to
money, they form part of the second pillar of the ECB’s strategy. Given that the range of relevant indicators
under the second pillar is potentially very broad, there is a need to structure and summarise this information so
as to facilitate the analysis of risks to price stability. Forecasts and projections offer a convenient analytical
tool for organising a large amount of information and help to create a consistent picture of possible future
developments.
Within the Eurosystem two macroeconomic projection exercises for the euro area are performed every year
which bring together experts from both the ECB and the national central banks (NCBs). These are not the only
projections produced within the Eurosystem, but they are the projections which involve the greatest interaction
between ECB and NCB staff experts.
The Eurosystem’s main macroeconomic projections aim to deliver a coherent and consistent assessment of the
outlook for short and medium-term economic prospects in the euro area. The projections are constructed by
combining econometric model-based projections with non-model-based judgemental assessments. A number
of different econometric models are used by both ECB and NCB staff experts in the projection exercises,
including a variety of national and euro area-wide structural macroeconometric models. These tools have the
advantage of being able to provide a detailed global structure. Based on this structure, the final projections
seek to be coherent both with past experience and with economic theory, as well as being consistent with the
national accounts identities. Judgemental assessments based upon recent conjunctural information and leading
indicators constitute another key input into the Eurosystem projections. Such assessments are produced by
sectoral and national experts who have a thorough knowledge of both recent economic developments and the
institutional context.
Despite the considerable care taken in producing the projections, it is important to realise that it is not possible
to incorporate the entire analysis conducted under the second pillar into these projections. This is because
macroeconomic forecasts and projections are inevitably subject to a number of conceptual and practical
limitations which need to be taken into account when assessing their information content. First, projections
and forecasts can vary significantly, depending on the underlying conceptual framework or the set of
techniques employed. For this reason, it is not appropriate to rely solely on any single projection. Any forecast
or projection needs to be cross-checked with information derived on the basis of other techniques and/or
market expectations of future developments. Second, forecasts and projections are always based on assumptions
for the path of some exogenous variables which may be volatile and the future path of which is difficult to
predict. Such variables include, for example, exchange rates and commodity price developments. The forecast
or projection for future inflation may depend significantly on the assumptions chosen for such variables. In
addition, as discussed in the opening paragraph of this box, forecasts and projections need to be made
conditional on an assumed path for monetary policy. Within central banks, such assumptions are typically
represented as unchanged short-term interest rates in order to allow the projection to be meaningful when
assessing the risks to price stability which might arise from current (and unchanged) monetary policy interest
rates. In practice, these monetary policy assumptions may often lead to problems of internal consistency, since
For all these reasons, the analysis under the second pillar of the strategy is not limited to the Eurosystem’s own
macroeconomic projections. The second pillar encompasses a broader set of analyses, which range from the
monitoring of timely indicators and more sectoral and structural analyses to the use of small-scale econometric
models embodying a different view, estimated with different methodologies or focused on revealing information
at specific horizons. Furthermore, these projections are always cross-checked against forecasts produced
elsewhere and against forward-looking information derived from financial market prices. Such analyses allow
timely information, which is not easily fed into formal forecasting and projection exercises, to be used in the
policy discussion, reveal the information in individual indicators and sectors on threats to price stability and
help to provide an insight into how developments in specific variables influence the overall inflation outlook.
It should be emphasised that the macroeconomic projections of the Eurosystem are based on the staff’s
technical expertise. These macroeconomic projections do not embody the view or judgement of the Governing
Council of the ECB. The Governing Council itself has to make an overall assessment of the economic
situation and of the risks to price stability using all the information available, including, in particular, the
information derived from the analysis under the first pillar of the strategy, but also information other than the
Eurosystem’s projection under the second pillar. Any publication of macroeconomic projections by the ECB
would have to reflect the (limited) role that forecasts play in the monetary policy decision-making process.
As the set of plausible models is very broad, There are two main arguments against relying
any policy analysis needs to be organised solely on the first pillar for the analysis
within a simplifying framework. The ECB has underlying monetary policy decisions. First,
At the same time, relying solely on the second Although the internal procedures of central
pillar would be equally ill-advised. Insofar as banks pursuing a stability-oriented policy may
the second pillar focuses on indicators of not, therefore, differ fundamentally in this
shorter-term price dynamics, the danger respect, differences between central bank
exists of a short-term bias being imparted to strategies arise in the presentation of the
monetary policy, which would conflict with analysis underlying monetary policy decisions
the medium-term orientation. to the public. In this context, some trade-off
between simplicity and openness may exist.
The fact that the second pillar also includes Adopting a simple form of presentation may,
projections and forecasts with a horizon of at first sight, help to make the description of
longer than one year does not change this monetary policy easier to comprehend, but it
interpretation. Conventional macroeconomic will not honestly convey the complexity of
projections and forecasts are always the analysis which central banks have to
surrounded by considerable uncertainty and conduct.
this uncertainty becomes greater the longer
the horizon of the forecast. This creates The ECB’s two-pillar approach represents a
difficulties in relying solely on such second balance between the requirements of clarity
4 Concluding remarks
The maintenance of price stability in the In this context, relying on any single indicator
euro area is the primary objective of the or on a single framework of analysis would
single monetary policy. All aspects of the entail too high a risk. A well-designed
ECB’s monetary policy strategy serve the monetary policy must be capable of
achievement of this primary objective. maintaining price stability across a range of
plausible interpretations of the economy. By
The centre of the ECB’s strategy is the diversifying across different indicators and
announcement of a quantitative definition of analytical frameworks rather than relying on
its primary objective, price stability. By virtue a single, inevitably incomplete approach, the
of this announcement, the ECB provides a risk of policy errors is reduced.
clear yardstick against which the public can
judge the performance of monetary policy. The strategy adopted by the ECB constitutes
The two pillars are instruments which a framework which provides for such a
facilitate the achievement of this primary diversified approach. The prominent role
objective – they do not represent assigned to money in the ECB’s strategy
independent policy objectives which have a (the first pillar) ensures that monetary
value in their own right. The two pillars developments are thoroughly analysed, taking
constitute a framework within which to into account the ultimately monetary nature
organise and structure the diverse and of inflation. At the same time, the second
extensive analyses underlying monetary policy pillar of the strategy ensures that other forms
decisions. of analysis, such as investigations of the
interplay between supply and demand or cost
Given the time-lags in the transmission pressures, are also incorporated into the
process of monetary policy, central banks policy process. In this way, shorter-term
need to be forward-looking and have a developments and risks to price stability are
medium-term orientation. At the same time, also taken into account, given the fact that
the ECB faces considerable uncertainties with such short-term price dynamics may spill over
regard to, inter alia, the reliability of available to medium-term price developments. The
economic indicators, the structure of the two-pillar structure of the strategy helps
euro area economy and the transmission to ensure that information and analyses
mechanism of the single monetary policy. produced on the basis of one methodological
Monetary policy decisions must take these perspective are always cross-checked against
uncertainties into account. information and analyses produced on the