The Price of Hesitation - FINAL-New
The Price of Hesitation - FINAL-New
The Price of Hesitation - FINAL-New
Yannis Dafermos
Alexander Kriwoluzky
Mauricio Vargas
Ulrich Volz
Jana Wittich
September 2021
Yannis Dafermos is a Senior Lecturer in Economics and a Senior Fellow at the Centre
for Sustainable Finance at SOAS, University of London.
Ulrich Volz is a Professor of Economics and the Director of the Centre for Sustainable
Finance at SOAS, University of London.
This report was first published in September 2021 by Greenpeace Germany; the
German Institute for Economic Research; and the Centre for Sustainable Finance at
SOAS, University of London.
Executive summary 1
1 Introduction 3
4 Making the ESCB operations climate-aligned: how the ECB should implement
and move beyond its Strategy Review 19
4.1 Monetary policy 19
4.2 Prudential supervision and regulation 24
4.3 Market neutrality 25
4.4 Macroeconomic modelling and scenario analysis 27
4.5 Portfolio management 27
5 Conclusion 29
References 30
Appendix 36
Executive summary
This report presents for the first time empirical evidence of the impact of natural
disasters on inflation in the eurozone, highlighting the challenges facing the
ECB to achieve price stability in the era of the climate crisis. Our results show
that natural disasters lead to increases in headline and core inflation, with price
increases being higher for food and beverages. The effects are small but
significant. We also show that there are significant differences between
eurozone countries in the way that inflation is affected by natural disasters.
With an escalation of the climate crisis, the frequency and intensity of climate-
related hazards will increase in the eurozone. If past data shows that natural
events have already an impact on inflation, this effect can only become stronger
as global warming increases, with important ramifications for the ECB’s
policies and operations. The ability of the ECB to control inflation may be
significantly undermined if the world passes the 1.5 or 2 degrees threshold.
Therefore, actions that prevent an increase in global warming have an important
role to play in allowing the ECB to achieve its primary objective in the future.
The ECB has taken an important step by announcing its new monetary strategy
and climate action plan. While this is a critical first move in the right direction,
the ECB climate action plan falls short of providing an ambitious agenda
consistent with the climate emergency that we are facing.
In this report, we set out how the ECB could develop an ambitious agenda that
would help it deliver on its primary and secondary mandates. Concretely, we
recommend that the ECB and the European System of Central Banks (ESCB)
should:
(i) introduce more explicitly climate performance criteria into their
monetary policy tools;
(ii) align prudential regulation with climate neutrality;
(iii) abandon market neutrality as the key principle that guides the design
of monetary policy;
The ECB and the ECSB must be bold in their actions to safeguard
macrofinancial stability across the eurozone in the face of climate change. As
1
guardians of the financial system, the ECB and the ECSB need to send clear
signals to the financial sector that a net-zero transition of the eurozone economy
and the financial system is a key target of its policies, and that monetary and
prudential frameworks will be adjusted accordingly.
2
1 Introduction
Climate change constitutes one of the greatest challenges for our economies and
societies and will remain so for decades to come. However, until very recently,
the European Central Bank (ECB) had not taken action to incorporate climate
change into its operations, despite calls to do so. This changed in July 2021
when the ECB announced a detailed roadmap of climate-related actions, as an
outcome of its Strategy Review (ECB, 2021a, 2021b). These actions include,
amongst others, the incorporation of climate change considerations into its
monetary policy tools, the development of climate-related indicators and
modelling approaches, the use of climate-related disclosures and the conduct of
climate stress testing exercises.
Although the ECB climate action plan is a welcome step, it falls short of
providing an ambitious agenda consistent with the climate emergency that we
are facing. This lack of ambition is reflected in the timeline of the actions: most
of the interventions that have the potential to affect climate targets will not be
introduced before late 2022 and their full implementation might not take place
before 2025. It is also reflected by the fact that the action plan is too focused on
disclosures and the protection of the Eurosystem balance sheet from climate
risks, without including a clear set of interventions that would directly
incentivise green investment and contribute to the reduction of the financing of
polluting activities.
This report has a two-fold purpose. First, it presents for the first time empirical
evidence of the impact of natural disasters on inflation in the eurozone,
highlighting the challenges facing the ECB to achieve price stability in the era
of the climate crisis. Our results show that natural disasters lead to increases in
headline and core inflation, with price increases being higher for food and
beverages. We also show that there are significant differences between eurozone
countries in the way that inflation is affected by natural disasters. This suggests
3
that if the severity and the frequency of climate-related events in the euro area
increases, the ability of the ECB to control inflation will be significantly
undermined. Therefore, actions that prevent the increase in global warming have
an important role to play in allowing the ECB to achieve its primary objective
in the future.
Second, given the urgency of the climate crisis and its importance for the ECB
objectives, we explain how the ECB should move beyond the action plan that
was announced in July. We recommend that the ECB and the European System
of Central Banks (ESCB) (i) introduce more explicitly climate performance
criteria into their monetary policy tools; (ii) align prudential regulation with
climate neutrality; (iii) abandon market neutrality as the key principle that
guides the design of monetary policy; (iv) incorporate double materiality and
macrofinancial feedback loops in macroeconomic modelling and scenario
analysis; and (v) use more ambitious climate-related criteria in their portfolio
management.
The report is structured as follows. Section 2 reviews the channels through
which natural disasters may threaten the ECB’s price stability mandate and
presents novel empirical evidence which shows that the disruptions and
damages resulting from natural disasters pose a significant threat to price
stability in the euro area. Section 3 highlights the key role that the ECB should
play in addressing the climate crisis and discusses the rationale behind ECB’s
recently announced climate action plan. Section 4 critically discusses the ECB
roadmap of climate-related actions and makes recommendations on how this
roadmap can become more aligned with the climate crisis that we are facing.
Section 5 concludes.
4
In this section, we outline how climate change, and the associated increase in
the frequency and severity of climate-related disasters, may pose a threat to
achieving this goal. We proceed in three steps. First, we explain the channels
through which weather events can affect inflation rates. Second, using data for
the euro area during the period 1996-2021, we estimate econometrically the
quantitative impact of natural disasters on inflation rates. We initially look at
the effects for the euro area as a whole and we then disentangle these effects for
the four largest euro area economies, namely France, Germany, Italy and Spain.
Third, we relate the results of our analysis to those for the entire globe and
provide an outlook on the importance of weather events for achieving price
stability in the future.
It is important to highlight that even though our empirical analysis is backward-
looking, it has critical implications for the future of central banking in Europe.
As is well-known, climate change is affecting our economies and societies in a
non-linear way: the climate-related economic and social effects are expected to
become more severe if we pass the 1.5 or 2 degrees threshold. Therefore, the
past might not be a good guide for the future. However, if past data shows that
natural events have already an impact on inflation, this effect can only become
stronger as global warming increases, with important ramifications for the
ECB’s policies and operations.
1
We are aware of the fact that the latter two are not directly related to climate change, but rather
result from tectonic processes. However, recent research indicates that climate change may, in
the very long run, contribute to an increase in these processes. This, in turn, may induce
earthquakes and volcanic eruptions to increase (Carrivick et al., 2018; Masih, 2018). Moreover,
excluding earthquakes and volcanic eruptions from our econometric investigation does not
6
To estimate the response of headline inflation and its main 12 sub-indices, we
use data on the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices (HICP) for all euro area
countries. This bears the advantage that the statistical methods to compile the
data are harmonised across countries, such that price indices are directly
comparable across countries. More importantly, the HICP constitutes the
primary variable of interest for the ECB’s monetary policy strategy.
Disturbances to this variable therefore pose a direct threat to the fulfilment of
the price stability mandate and a call for ECB action to reduce eruptions in its
main target variable.
In a first step, we employ panel regressions for all euro area countries to estimate
the average inflation responses to natural disasters. However, a limitation of this
approach is that it cannot capture the potential existence of opposing price
responses in the individual countries. While consumer prices might rise in some
countries, they may fall in other countries. To account for the country-specific
responses, we run additional country-by-country regressions for the four largest
euro area economies, namely France, Germany, Italy and Spain, to investigate
whether inflation responses differ across countries.2 Details on our empirical
methodology and the data can be found in in Appendix A.1.
significantly alter our results, as they make up only a minor share of overall disasters. This is
why we include them in our analysis.
2
This is likely to happen as the disaster composition varies across countries. Unfortunately, we
do not have enough observations for each event type to differentiate the inflation responses
across disaster types. This is why we rather look at the differences between the four largest euro
area economies, as the number of observed disasters is also largest for these four countries.
3
For details on the classification of the individual consumption categories, see:
https://appsso.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/nui/show.do?dataset=prc_hicp_midx&lang=en.
7
All the empirical results are reported in Appendix A.2. Table 1 shows the effects
of natural disasters, taking place in the past 12 months, on monthly headline
inflation rates in the euro area. We find that headline inflation significantly
increases for events that took place in the past 8 months (for lags 1 up to 8). This
indicates that upward price pressures, resulting, for instance, from resource
shortages due to the destruction of crops, buildings and infrastructure, seem to
dominate in the short run. For longer lags, the price effects seem to be reverted,
such that downward price pressures dominate. This suggests that, in the medium
run, the decline in aggregate demand that results from natural disasters
overcompensates any inflationary pressures that might stem from supply
bottlenecks or reconstruction-led demand.
Our results remain valid after successively including further control variables.
These control variables account for other driving forces of inflation and ensure
that our estimates for the disaster variable solely capture the disaster effects. For
our richest specification that includes various control variables (column 8), we
find that an increase in climate disasters in t-1 by one percentage point of
monthly GDP leads to a rise in inflation by 0.03 percentage points. This effect
is small, but still suggests that natural events can have a significant effect on
inflation rates if their intensity and severity increase the future.4 The summary
statistics at the bottom of Table 1 indicate a decent model fit for our specification
(8) of 0.83.
We now turn to present the effects of natural disasters on core inflation (see
Table 2). Excluding prices for food and beverages, alcohol and tobacco and
energy does not change our main results. We still find that weather disasters
significantly increase inflation rates. Interestingly, we do not find a reversion of
price effects at lag 12, such that upward price pressures seem to be even stronger
for core than for headline inflation. For our specification (8), we even find a
model fit of 0.90. This is why we use this specification as benchmark model for
the analysis of the disaster effects on the 12 sub-indices of headline inflation
and the sub-categories of food prices.
4
We must also take into account that natural disasters have primarily occurred locally so far,
and, as a result, their effects might not have been very visible at the national and eurozone level.
8
alcohol and tobacco (column 2) as well as for furnishings and household
equipment (column 5) seems to decrease instantaneously following disasters,
such that prices for these consumption categories decline. We find ambiguous
effects for the sectors of health (column 6), transport (column 7) and
miscellaneous goods (column 12), that suggest that both upward and downward
price pressure are at work for these consumption categories. In sum, our results
suggest that natural disasters have small, but significant effects on all of the 12
main sub-indices of overall headline inflation.
As the immediate price effects are strongest for food and beverages, we look at
further sub-categories of this sub-index (see Table 4). We find that the increase
in food price inflation is mainly driven by a significant increase in the prices of
fruits and vegetables (columns 7 and 8). This makes sense, because the
destruction of crops and harvests and the resulting shortage in these goods puts
upward pressures on their prices.
The strong increase in food price inflation in the direct aftermath of a natural
disaster is also worrisome from a distributional perspective. As poorer
households spend a larger share of their income on food, they are also hit harder
by increases in food price inflation than wealthier households. This implies that
climate change does not only pose a threat to maintaining price stability, but
may also have distributional consequences, because prices of different items are
not equally affected by natural disasters.
The results on our euro-area-wide analysis on the inflationary effects of natural
disasters let us draw five preliminary conclusions:
1. natural disasters lead to statistically significant increases in headline and
core inflation;
2. there are significant differences at the sub-index level;
3. price increases are strongest for food and beverages;
4. the price effects lead to eruptions in inflation rates that make it more
difficult for the ECB to fulfil its price stability mandate; and
5. beyond that, the price effects may also have distributional consequences.
5
We focus on these four countries since − due to their size − they play an important role in the
monetary policy decisions of the ECB.
9
because opposing price reactions in individual countries might offset each
other at the panel level. To disentangle the euro-area-wide inflation responses,
we perform Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regressions for France, Germany,
Italy and Spain to estimate how inflation rates change following disasters in
these four countries (see Appendix A.1 for details on the empirical
methodology).
We indeed find diverging price responses in France (Table 13), with increases
in inflation of food prices (column 1), transport (column 7), education (column
10) and miscellaneous goods (column 12) and ambiguous or negative price
effects for the remaining sub-indices. In contrast to our results for the euro area,
prices of alcohol and tobacco (column 2) increase in the direct aftermath of a
disaster in France. This suggests that extreme weather events adversely affect
and push up prices for viticulture, which makes up a significant share of French
agricultural output (Eurostat, 2018).
10
In a next step, we want to assess which other food items are most strongly
affected by weather disasters in France (Table 17). In contrast to our euro-area-
wide analysis, we find positive and significant effects on prices of bread and
cereals (column 2), meat (column 3), fish and seafood (column 4) as well as of
milk, cheese and eggs (column 5). These results make sense, because these
categories make up the majority of French agricultural products (Eurostat,
2018). The destruction of harvests following storms, heat waves and droughts
puts upward pressures on their prices and leads to significant increases in
inflation. In contrast, fruit and vegetable price inflation (columns 7 and 8)
seems to decrease following natural disasters. These results show how
important it is to disentangle the price effects at the sub-index and further sub-
category-level, given that opposing price responses might offset each other at
the aggregate level.
In Germany, we find that the negative effects on headline inflation also prevail
at the sub-index level (Table 14). As the agricultural sector is smaller in
Germany than in France (Eurostat, 2020), upward price pressures due to the
destruction of crops are outweighed by downward price pressures for food and
beverages (column 1). We further find that declines in inflation rates are
predominant for most sub-indices and mirror the response of aggregate
headline inflation in Germany. This is also true for the sub-categories of food
price inflation (Table 18), for which downward price pressures largely
outweigh upward price pressures.
The inflation responses at the sub-index level are more ambiguous for Italy and
display many sign changes (Table 15). This indicates the coexistence of both
upward and downward price pressures. The results might also reflect the
different disaster composition in Italy as compared to Germany and France. In
addition to floods and storms that prevail in the latter two countries, Italy has
experienced numerous earthquakes. While the literature suggests that
consumer prices increase after floods and storms (see Heinen et al., 2019), they
are more muted or even decline following earthquakes (see Cavallo et al., 2013;
Doyle and Noy, 2015).6 The ambiguity of the price responses is also reflected
in the sub-categories of food prices (Table 19), that show both increases and
declines in the inflation rates of the individual food categories.
We find a similar picture for the inflation rates of the sub-indices in Spain,
where both upward and downward pressure coexist (Table 16). While prices
6
Unfortunately, we cannot disentangle the inflation responses across different event types due
to sample size limitations.
11
increase for alcohol and tobacco (column 2) as well as for recreational and
cultural goods (column 9), inflation rates of the remaining sub-indices show
ambiguous or negative signs. Food price inflation seems to decline in Spain
(Table 20), with negative price effects prevailing for the majority of food price
sub-categories.
In sum, the tremendous differences in the inflationary responses to natural
disasters across the four countries pose a severe challenge to the ECB’s price
stability mandate. This is because they make it increasingly difficult for the
ECB to align inflation rates across countries. Given that the euro area
constitutes a monetary union, the ECB can only define one uniform monetary
policy strategy that should, in an ideal setting, satisfy the needs of all individual
member countries. However, the disparities in the inflation responses across
countries calls for individual policy measures, that largely differ across
countries. This is even more true if the frequency and severity of severe
weather events will increase, as climate change accelerates. To prevent these
cross-country disparities from becoming even larger in the future requires a
strong and unified answer from the ESCB to mitigate the negative
consequences of climate change.
To summarise, the five key takeaways of our analysis for France, Germany,
Italy and Spain are as follows:
For our sample of euro area countries and the period from 1996 to 2021, the
EM-DAT disaster database contains 227 natural disasters, for which the
12
estimated damage has been reported.7 In this sample period, the average
estimated damage per disaster was approximately US$ 822 million. On
average, there have been nine events per year that also reported a monetary
damage. An average disaster year in 2020 would thus amount to around 0.057
% of GDP.8
If we take a global perspective using our dataset, we find for the 3,260 global
disaster events that the average estimated damage per disaster has been at US$
928 million for the period from 1996 to 2021. A global average disaster year
amounts to US$ 117 billion. For the year 2020, the average disaster damage
per event amounted to US$ 1.255 billion with total damages for all events in
that year of US$ 173.133 billion. These make up 0.205% of worldwide GDP.9
Therefore, damages are more than threefold the size of damages in the euro
area.
We now analyse, for illustrative purposes, what would happen in the euro area
inflation rate if the damages in the eurozone were of the same magnitude as the
current damages at the global level. In reality, this is very likely to happen in
the near future if the increase in global warming continues at the current pace.
Using the econometric results from our benchmark specification (8) in Table
1, it turns out that the monthly headline inflation in the euro area would be
affected by approximately 0.00615 percentage points in the first month only.10
While this may look small, we need to have in mind that the average monthly
inflation target of the ECB is only around 0.16 percent.
7
For details on the data and the construction of our disaster variable, see Appendix A.1.
8
GDP in the euro area was at US$ 12,915.07 billion in 2020 according to the IMF World
Economic Outlook Database.
9
According to the IMF World Economic Outlook Database, worldwide GDP amounted to US$
84,537.692 billion in 2020.
10
We concentrate on the first significant coefficient for the sake of simplicity. There are further
significant estimates, which imply further disruptions on the price level from disasters.
13
would decrease by 0.00615 percentage points in Germany and by 0.0082
percentage points in Italy. In contrast, inflation would increase by 0.01845
percentage points in Spain. We thus find a difference in the inflation responses
between Italy and Spain of 0.02665 percentage points. Again, these numbers
may seem small at first glance. However, the cumulative inflation responses of
all disasters that took place at lags 0 to 12 are certainly larger and will further
increase, if climate change continues to accelerate.
Crucially, we also find large cross-country differences at the sub-index level.
While food price inflation significantly rises in France following disasters (see
Table 17), it declines in Spain (see Table 20). If we look at the inflation
responses of bread and cereals in both countries (column 2 of Tables 17 and
20), we find that disasters in period t and t-1 of one percentage point of monthly
GDP yield cumulative increases in inflation of bread and cereals of 0.09
percentage points in France. In contrast, monthly inflation declines by 0.27
percentage points in Spain. These estimates suggest that natural distastes of the
same magnitude as those currently at the global level would cause increases in
inflation rates of bread and cereals by 0.01845 percentage points in France, yet
declines in inflation of 0.05535 percentage points in Spain. The difference in
the inflation responses of both countries thus lies at 0.0738, which is a sizable
effect.
It is important to bear in mind that all these estimates are potentially at the
lower bound. Given the non-linear nature of climate change impacts and the
importance of feedback loops and tipping points, any quantitative assessment
of climate impacts on economic variables based on historical data will
inevitably have limited explanatory power for future developments. However,
it is foreseeable that an acceleration of global warming will increase both the
number and intensity of climate-related disasters in Europe and elsewhere. For
example, according to some estimates in the academic literature, the GDP
losses in a 3 degrees global warming scenario could be between about 5% and
25% of GDP (see NGFS, 2021b).11 Against this backdrop, it is conceivable that
the effects of climate change on inflation will become larger over time. Only a
strong, decisive and unified answer from the ESCB together with political
decision-makers and other state bodies can decelerate, if not reverse, this
development.
11
Note that these estimates might be over-optimistic; see, for example, Keen (2020).
14
3 The ECB’s role in addressing the climate crisis
“Climate change has a massive impact on the economy – for example, because
of natural disasters – and thus, price stability. If we ignore this, we would not
be fulfilling our mandate. In addition, the ECB’s mandate is to support the EU’s
economic policy. In this, climate protection plays a crucial role.”12
In July 2021, the ECB announced its decision to incorporate climate change
considerations into its operations, responding to several calls that were made
over the last years for the need of one of Europe’s most powerful public
institutions to take action against climate change. In supporting this decision,
the ECB provided a three-fold rationale. First, it acknowledged that climate
change can have an adverse effect on macroeconomic indicators (such as
inflation, employment and productivity), financial stability and the transmission
of monetary policy. Second, it highlighted the effects of climate change on the
value and the risks of the financial assets on the balance sheet of the Eurosystem.
Third, it recognised that the ECB should contribute to the fight against climate
change, in line with its obligations that stem from the EU Treaties.
The first rationale is supported by our econometric analysis. As we showed in
Section 2 of this report, climate damages have already affected inflation in the
euro area and they will do so even more in the future. In addition to this, climate
transition policies (like an increase in carbon prices) are likely to further amplify
inflation volatility and affect the level of inflation. Since price stability is the
primary objective of the ECB, the ECB has a responsibility to contribute to the
fight against climate change and help prevent irreversible impacts on its ability
to control inflation. Failure to do so would mean that the ECB does not take
sufficient action to deliver on its primary mandate.
It is clear that the ECB (or any other central bank for that matter) by itself will
not be able to halt climate change. It is also clear that governments must take
the leading role in setting the policy frameworks without which a net-zero
transition cannot succeed. Governments need to step up and implement
meaningful climate policies, using fiscal, industrial and other policy tools to
mitigate climate change and help agents across the economy to adapt to the
physical and transition impacts of climate change. But it is equally clear that
climate change mitigation will not be successful if the financial system is not
aligned with the climate goals. Central banks and financial supervisors therefore
12
SPIEGEL interview with ECB Board member Isabel Schnabel, 9 April 2021,
https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/inter/date/2021/html/ecb.in210409~c8c348a12c.de.html
15
need to complement government policies and introduce explicit strategies to
support the transition of the financial sector to net-zero (Robins et al., 2021).
The second rationale that the ECB used to support its recent decision – the
importance of climate-related financial risks – has also been at the core of many
calls for action. The ECB, along with national central banks and financial
supervisors, has a pivotal role to play in safeguarding financial stability by
ensuring that individual financial institutions and the financial system at large
can withstand climate-related physical and transition risks. The transition to a
low-carbon economy will involve a large-scale structural change in which
industries, particularly those directly linked to fossil fuel production and
consumption, will have to decline (Semieniuk et al., 2021). To meet its climate
targets, the EU economy will have to undergo an unprecedented structural
transformation – especially in the energy, transport and industrial sectors, which
are responsible for almost 90 per cent of CO2 emissions – within the next five
to 10 years to prevent further investments that lock in carbon (Robins et al.,
2021). The resulting transition risks related to the stranding of carbon-intensive
assets constitutes a new source of risk for financial stability that could delay the
low-carbon transition (Monasterolo, 2020).
Moreover, climate change can also destabilise the financial system through the
so-called physical risks. Climate-related events and the gradual increase in
atmospheric temperature can affect asset prices and lead to higher default rates
for households and companies, deteriorating the financial position of financial
institutions (Dietz et al., 2016; Dafermos et al., 2018; Batten et al., 2020; Duprey
et al., 2020). Alogoskoufis et al. (2021) have, for example, shown that the
physical risks are likely to increase quite dramatically in Europe in the coming
decades.
Although the ECB recognises these risks, it fails to explicitly recognise their
double materiality (Dikau et al., 2021).13 The ECB’s rationale for climate action
confines its attention to how much the financial system more broadly, and the
Eurosystem more precisely, are exposed to climate-related risks. It does not pay
sufficient attention to the fact that the ECB itself contributes to climate-related
risks by not climate aligning its monetary policy and by failing to promote a
climate-neutral financial system. Supporting an early and smooth transition to
net-zero is the best way of protecting the EU economy and minimising the risks
of instability for the financial system arising from the macrofinancial risks
stemming from climate change (Robins et al., 2021). Such a support would also
13
See also Oustry et al. (2020) and Oman and Svartzman (2021).
16
be in line with a macroprudential, system-based, approach to climate risks (see
Dafermos, forthcoming).
The third rationale behind the ECB climate action plan ̶ the need to ensure that
the ECB policies and operations are coherent with the climate neutrality policies
of the European Union ̶ had been ignored for many years. As part of its
secondary objective, the ECB has a responsibility to support the general
economic policies of the EU. The Treaty on the Functioning of the European
Union (TFEU) states that “without prejudice to the objective of price stability,
the ESCB shall support the general economic policies in the Union with a view
to contributing to the achievement of the objectives of the Union as laid down
in Article 3 of the Treaty on European Union” (TFEU, Article 127 (1)). The
referenced Article 3 specifies that the ESCB shall contribute to “the sustainable
development of Europe based on [...] a high level of protection and improvement
of the quality of the environment”.14 Thus, the ESCB’s mandate includes, inter
alia and without prejudice to the objective of price stability, supporting the EU’s
environmental objectives (Volz, 2017). As highlighted by Frank Elderson, a
member of the ECB Executive Board: “This mandate, which is sometimes
referred to as the ECB’s ‘secondary objective’, stipulates a duty, not an option,
for the ECB to provide its support” (Elderson, 2021). Isabel Schnabel, also a
member of the ECB Executive Board, has affirmed that, “if faced with a choice
between two monetary policy measures that have the same impact on price
stability, the ECB would have to choose the one that is more in line with EU
policies” (Schnabel, 2021a).
Not only does the EU Treaty specify that environmental protection should be an
integral part of the EU policies. Recently, climate neutrality has been explicitly
incorporated into the EU policies and become the centrepiece of the European
Green Deal. In 2018, the European Commission presented its vision for
achieving net-zero greenhouse gas emissions in the EU by 2050. In March 2019,
the European Parliament endorsed this objective. This vision was later
reaffirmed in the European Green Deal, the Commission’s action plan to make
Europe the first climate-neutral continent by 2050, while ensuring a just and
inclusive transition. This net-zero goal was affirmed by both the European
Council and the European Parliament in its resolution on the European Green
Deal in January 2020. In March 2020, the European Commission proposed the
EU’s first Climate Law Regulation to make this political commitment legally
14
Article 11 of the TFEU specifies: “Environmental protection requirements must be integrated
into the definition and implementation of the Union’s policies and activities, in particular with
a view to promoting sustainable development.”
17
binding. The European Climate Law was formally adopted in July 2021, legally
requiring the EU institutions – which include the ECB – and the member states
to take necessary measures to meet the EU’s climate objectives. Therefore, ECB
measures that are not aligned with climate neutrality undermine the economic
policies of the EU and prevent the ECB from delivering on its secondary
mandate. A recent legal analysis stated that central banks in Europe, including
the ECB, are exposed to potential litigation for failing to include climate criteria
in their monetary policy decisions (Verheyen, 2021).
18
4 Making the ESCB operations climate-aligned: how the ECB
should implement and move beyond its Strategy Review
As part of its Strategy Review, in July 2021 the ECB announced a roadmap of
climate-related actions until 2024. This roadmap includes the following main
types of actions: (i) the incorporation of climate change into macroeconomic
modelling, projections, scenario analysis and stress testing; (ii) the development
of indicators for capturing climate risks and the carbon footprint of financial
institutions; (iii) the incorporation of climate risks and disclosure requirements
into the collateral framework and the corporate asset purchase programme; and
(iv) the assessment of market neutrality as a benchmark for monetary policy
design.
This set of actions is a very welcome step. However, the ECB plan lacks the
level of ambition that is required given the climate emergency that we are facing.
This lack of ambition is, first, reflected in the timeline of the actions: most of
the interventions that have the potential to affect climate targets will not be
introduced before late 2022 and their full implementation might not take place
before 2025. Second, the action plan is too focused on disclosures and the
protection of the Eurosystem balance sheet from climate risks. It does not
include a clear set of interventions that would directly incentivise green
investment and contribute to the reduction of polluting activities, in line with a
precautionary approach to the systemic risks that arise from climate change.15
The way that the action plan of the ECB will be implemented in practice is also
very important. For example, the types of models and indicators that will be
used to analyse climate risks and capture green activities will affect the extent
to which the Eurosystem will contribute or not to climate neutrality.
15
For the merits of a precautionary approach to monetary and financial policy, see Chenet et al.
(2021).
19
Broadly speaking, the key types of ECB monetary policy operations that can
become climate-aligned are (i) credit operations; (ii) the Eurosystem collateral
framework and (iii) the asset purchase programmes (see NGFS, 2021a). Credit
operations refer to liquidity-providing operations and include the ECB main
refinancing operations and the longer-term refinancing operations. The
Eurosystem collateral framework is the framework via which the ECB identifies
which assets (and under which conditions) the euro area commercial banks can
use as collateral in order to get access to central bank liquidity. Asset purchase
programmes are programmes through which the ECB buys securities issued by
non-financial and financial corporations, as well as by governments.
According to the ECB action plan, there are three main changes that are intended
to be made to the Eurosystem collateral framework and the corporate sector
purchase programme (CSPP). First, disclosure requirements will be introduced
as an eligibility criterion or will be used as a factor that might affect haircuts in
the collateral framework and the amount of purchases in the CSPP. These
requirements will be in line with EU policies. Second, the valuation and risk
analysis of the financial assets will be extended to include climate-related
financial risks. Third, the ECB might accept as collateral, financial assets that
are conducive to the low-carbon transition and might take into account the
alignment of issuers with climate targets in the decisions about asset purchases
in the CSPP.16
This action plan illustrates that ECB will not follow the approach of the Bank
of England which has recently decided to directly green its Corporate Purchase
Bond Scheme using as a sole criterion the climate performance of issuers (see
Bank of England, 2021). Instead, the ECB’s primary focus will be the
measurement of climate-related financial risks and the use of disclosures – it
seems that the climate performance of the issuers will act as a complementary
criterion. This approach restricts the contribution of the ECB to the fight against
climate change and suffers from several limitations. First, although disclosures
are necessary, disclosing climate-related information will not by itself lead to
climate-related action by non-financial firms. Second, a less favourable
treatment of companies that are more exposed to climate-related transition risks
will not necessarily “penalise” carbon-intensive companies that do not have
credible transition plans. For instance, if the ECB uses scenarios in which carbon
prices increase at a slow pace, polluting companies might not be considered to
16
The ECB will also disclose climate-related information about CSPP by the first quarter of
2023.
20
be too risky from a financial stability point of view, and, thus, their
representation in the collateral framework and asset purchases will not decline.
Specific polluting companies might also not be “penalised” even under
scenarios of high carbon prices. This will be so if it is assessed that these
companies have a strong financial position that allows them to address the
financial challenges of a high cost of emissions.17 Third, a less favourable
treatment of companies that are more exposed to climate-related physical risks
might exacerbate climate risks instead of reducing them. This might be so since
these companies need to invest in climate adaptation: if their cost of borrowing
goes up, they will be less able to finance this investment and this will make them
more exposed to physical risks (see Dafermos, forthcoming).
Due to these limitations, the ECB needs to shift its emphasis from disclosures
and climate risks to the direct incorporation of climate alignment criteria into
the collateral framework and its asset purchase programme, along similar lines
as the Bank of England. This would require the identification of which assets
are conducive to climate neutrality and which are not. This would in turn require
the use of both backward-looking and forward-looking metrics for identifying
the climate performance of the issuers of these assets (Bank of England, 2021;
Dafermos et al., 2021b). Backward-looking metrics can include, for example,
the carbon intensity and energy efficiency of a company over the last years or
how much its use of electricity has relied on renewables in the past. Forward-
looking metrics have to do primarily with the decarbonisation plans of the
companies and how credible these plans are. The design of climate-aligned
monetary policy measures also needs to rely on the information about specific
assets (e.g. if bonds are ‘green’ or ‘sustainability-linked’) and can consider the
main activities of each company and how much they are in line with climate
targets. For example, monetary policy operations can be designed in a way that
creates more pressure on companies that engage in carbon-intensive activities
that need to be deeply decarbonised for the transition to a low-carbon economy.
In identifying the climate footprint of assets, it is of particular importance for
the ECB to minimise greenwashing problems. The risk of greenwashing might
be higher if too much emphasis is placed on decarbonisation plans whose
credibility might be difficult to be properly assessed. Greenwashing issues
might also arise if backward-looking metrics fail to capture carbon-intensive
aspects of the operations of companies (e.g. those related with scope 3
17
See also Caldecott (2020) for the difference between climate risk management and the
explicit targeting of climate-aligned outcomes.
21
emissions). Importantly, the ECB can help with the minimisation of
greenwashing problems by contributing to the establishment of standardised
requirements for the disclosure of climate-related data by companies.
Once the climate footprint of financial assets has been identified, the monetary
policy operations of the ECB need to be designed such that they provide more
support to assets that are more conducive to climate neutrality and less support
to assets that undermine the low-carbon transition. The development of a
climate-aligned Eurosystem collateral framework requires two types of
adjustments (see Dafermos et al., 2021b). The first is an adjustment in haircuts.
A haircut refers to a reduction applied to a value of an asset when this asset is
used as a collateral by a commercial bank to get access to central bank liquidity.
The higher the haircut the lower the amount of central bank liquidity a
commercial bank can get by using a specific asset as collateral. In a climate-
aligned collateral framework the haircuts on securities linked with companies
or projects that are conducive to a low-carbon transition need to decline. On the
contrary, the haircuts of bonds that are characterised by a poor climate
performance based on backward-looking and forward-looking indicators need
to increase.
The second type of adjustment has to do with the assets that are eligible in the
collateral framework. This involves both negative and positive screening.
Negative screening refers to the exclusion of assets that are linked with a very
poor climate performance (e.g. securities issued by coal companies). Positive
screening involves the inclusion of climate-friendly assets in the collateral
framework.
The recalibration of haircuts and eligibility can have important effects on the
financial markets. It can increase the demand for climate-aligned securities and
decrease the demand for securities that undermine the low-carbon transition.
This can in turn lead to a reduction in the cost of borrowing for climate-aligned
activities and an increase in the cost of borrowing for carbon-intensive activities.
Empirical evidence on the financial implications of the Eurosystem collateral
framework has shown that eligibility and lower haircuts are linked with lower
bond yields (e.g. Nguyen, 2020; Pelizzon et al., 2020).
One important point that should be made is that, in order to be consistent with
its Treaty-related obligations, the ECB needs to ensure that the climate
alignment of its monetary policy operations will not undermine its ability to
achieve price stability in the short run. This has the following implications. First,
the incorporation of climate-related criteria in the ECB QE programme should
not lead to a decline in the size of the potential central bank asset purchases
compared to what is the case when climate-related criteria are not considered.
The same holds for the size of the eligible haircut-adjusted value of collateral in
the Eurosystem collateral framework. Dafermos et al. (2020, 2021b) show that
this is possible as long as the decline in the purchases and the haircut-adjusted
collateral linked with carbon-intensive assets is counterbalanced by an increase
18
van’t Klooster and van Tilburg (2020) have suggested that the interest rate in the Targeted
Long-Term Refinancing Operations (TLTROs) be a function of the volume of EU Taxonomy-
compliant loans on the balance sheet of banks.
23
in climate-friendly purchases and collateral. Second, in periods in which
inflation is above the inflation target, the QE programmes and TLTROs might
not continue if the ECB assesses that monetary policy contraction is necessary
in order keep inflation under control. Therefore, in periods of monetary
contraction, climate-aligned monetary policy interventions might need to be
confined to the main refinancing operations and the collateral framework.
However, the reduction in asset purchases and the size of liquidity-provision
programmes (“tapering”), which characterises the transition from an
expansionary monetary policy stance to a contractionary one, needs to be
consistent with climate neutrality. In practice, this would mean that the
companies and assets that comply less with the requirements of the Paris
agreement targets should be the first to lose the ECB financial support.
The ESCB has a significant role to play in addressing these limitations and
developing common standards for climate-related financial disclosures. These
common standards need to be designed as a matter of priority and climate-
related financial disclosures should become mandatory once these standards
have been agreed. Moreover, the euro area central banks and financial
supervisors need to ask financial institutions to publish net zero transition plans
that will include specific information about climate-related targets and the
actions that financial institutions intend to take to achieve these targets (Dikau
24
et al., 2021). Crucially, the publication of such plans will improve the
availability of forward-looking data that is crucial for the investment community
and the design of climate-aligned monetary and financial policies.
Although the ECB climate-related roadmap includes some broad plans about
climate-related supervision, such as climate stress testing and disclosure
requirements, it is unclear if the ECB will require specific transition plans from
financial institutions. If not, the contribution of climate-related supervision to
climate neutrality is likely to be small. More broadly, it is important that the
ECB does not confine its attention to reporting and disclosures. Capital
requirements can be an additional powerful tool for promoting a climate-aligned
financial system (D’Orazio and Popoyan, 2019; Finance Watch, 2020;
Dafermos and Nikolaidi, 2021). For instance, euro area financial regulators can
ask financial institutions to hold additional capital − on top of the existing capital
buffers – against assets that are linked with activities that are considered to be
too carbon-intensive. This would incentivise commercial banks to reduce
lending which supports projects that undermine the path to climate neutrality.
This would be consistent with a macroprudential approach to climate change:
given that carbon-intensive lending is a source of systemic risk (since it
reinforces global warming that can lead to financial instability), carbon-related
capital requirements can pro-actively contribute to the protection of the financial
system from this source of risk (Dafermos, forthcoming).
Those who oppose climate-aligned monetary policy measures often argue that
these measures are not consistent with the market neutrality principle, since they
19
See de Boer and van ’t Klooster (2020), ClientEarth (2021) and Dikau et al. (2021).
25
might favour companies with lower carbon intensity compared to high-carbon
ones, distorting markets. However, the argument that the ECB should not
implement climate-aligned measures because these would violate the market
neutrality principle are misplaced for at least two reasons. First, it is important
to realise that monetary policy always has distributional consequences, and that
the actions of central banks – whether intended or not – have historically played
an important role in shaping markets (Volz, 2017). Several ECB interventions
in the past have shaped financial markets and have had different effects on
different segments of the economy (Braun, 2018; Senni and Monnin, 2020;
van’t Klooster and Fontan, 2020). For instance, the ECB programmes and
collateral framework provided support to asset-backed securities in the
aftermath of the Global Financial Crisis, favouring disproportionately the
issuers of these securities (and the broader shadow banking system) that suffered
from low private demand in the post-crisis period. Moreover, by having selected
a specific mix of monetary policy tools and transmission channels the ECB has
unavoidably favoured differently the public sector, big corporations, and small
and medium-sized enterprises. For example, the introduction of the Corporate
Sector Purchase Programme in 2016 favoured companies with access to capital
markets compared to companies that rely mostly on bank loans. Once market
neutrality is understood within this broader context, it becomes clear that it is
not possible for the ECB to remain market neutral in practice.
Second, it is now broadly recognised that markets have failed to reflect the
implications of climate change. Nick Stern famously described climate change
as the “greatest market failure that the world has seen” (Benjamin, 2007).
Importantly, financial markets continue to fail to properly price climate risks,
included stranded asset risk. The empirical evidence shows that the ECB’s
corporate asset purchase programme – which has been conducted in line with
the market neutrality principle – have been heavily tilted towards carbon-
intensive sectors (Matikainen et al., 2017; Dafermos et al., 2020). By adopting
a market-neutral approach, the ECB is in consequence perpetuating existent
market failures and the high-carbon bias in financial markets (Dikau et al.,
2021).
26
4.4 Macroeconomic modelling and scenario analysis
The ECB’s roadmap for climate-related actions includes the regular evaluation
of the impact of climate fiscal policies on the Eurosystem/ECB staff
macroeconomic projections and the conduct of scenario analysis about the
macroeconomic and monetary policy implications of climate policies. So far,
the ECB and the national central banks have placed emphasis on developing
scenarios and preliminary modelling approaches that allow financial institutions
to identify how exposed they are to transition and physical risks (e.g. Allen et
al., 2020; de Guindos, 2021; NGFS, 2021b). Although these scenarios and
modelling exercises are useful, one of their limitations is that they do not
explicitly recognise the non-neutral role that the financial system plays in
achieving the transition to a low-carbon economy. In other words, they are not
consistent with the concept of double materiality according to which financial
institutions are not only affected by climate change due to transition and
physical risks, but they can also affect themselves the path of emissions (see
Battiston et al., 2021b; Dikau et al., 2021; Täger, 2021; Dafermos, forthcoming).
27
There are a range of options that the euro area central banks can use to climate
align their portfolios (NGFS, 2019). These include positive and negative
screening as well the tilting approaches that were discussed above in the case of
monetary policy portfolios. On top of these approaches, central banks can
exercise ownership rights and ‘voice’ with the aim of affecting the climate
strategies of companies.
Several euro area central banks, like the De Nederlandsche Bank (DNB) and the
Banque de France (BdF), have recently taken initiatives that aim to improve the
sustainability profile of their portfolios (Dikau et al., 2021). The Eurosystem has
also recently agreed on a common stance for climate-related and responsible
investment principles for non-monetary policy portfolios (ECB, 2021c). This
common stance focuses on the identification of metrics that can capture the
climate performance of these portfolios based on the TCFD recommendations.
Although this is a useful step, there is a need for more rapid developments in
this area − the current aim for ESCB central banks to make TCFD disclosures
within the next two years in not consistent with the urgency of the climate crisis.
More crucially, the plans for climate-aligned portfolios should become more
ambitious and include negative screening strategies, which can put more
pressure on polluting companies that do not have credible decarbonisation plans.
28
5 Conclusion
The ECB has taken an important step by announcing its new monetary strategy
and climate action plan. In this report we underline how critical it is for the ECB
to address the climate challenge to deliver on its primary mandate. We show for
the first time that natural disasters have already had small but significant effects
on headline and core inflation in the eurozone. With an escalation of the climate
crisis, the frequency and intensity of climate-related hazards will increase in the
eurozone. If past data shows that natural events have already an impact on
inflation, this effect can only become stronger as global warming increases, with
important ramifications for the ECB’s policies and operations. Indeed, the
ability of the ECB to control inflation may be significantly undermined if the
world passes the 1.5 or 2 degrees threshold. Therefore, actions that prevent the
increase in global warming have an important role to play in allowing the ECB
to achieve its primary objective in the future.
While the ECB climate action plan is a critical first move in the right direction,
it falls short of providing an ambitious agenda consistent with the climate
emergency that we are facing. In this report, we have set out how the ECB could
develop an ambitious agenda that would help it deliver on its primary and
secondary mandates. Concretely, we recommend that, on top of the acceleration
of their climate action plans, the ECB and the ECSB (i) introduce more
explicitly climate performance criteria into their monetary policy tools; (ii) align
prudential regulation with climate neutrality; (iii) abandon market neutrality as
the key principle that guides the design of monetary policy; (iv) incorporate
double materiality and macrofinancial feedback loops in macroeconomic
modelling and scenario analysis; and (v) use more ambitious climate-related
criteria in their portfolio management.
The ECB and the ECSB must be bold in their actions to safeguard
macrofinancial stability across the eurozone in the face of climate change. As
guardians of the financial system, the ECB and the ECSB need to send clear
signals to the financial sector that a net-zero transition of the eurozone economy
and the financial system is a key target of its policies, and that monetary and
prudential frameworks will be adjusted accordingly.
29
References
Allen, T., Dees, S., Chouard, V., Clerc, L., de Gaye, A., Devulder, A., Diot, S.,
Lisack, N., Pegoraro, F., Rabate, M. and Svartzman, R. (2020), “Climate-
related scenarios for financial stability assessment: An application to
France”. Banque de France Working Paper No. 774. Paris: Banque de
France.
Alogoskoufis, S., Carbone, S., Coussens, W. Fahr, S., Giuzio, M,, Kuik, F.,
Parisi, L., Salakhova, D. and Spaggiari, M. (2021), “Climate-related risks
to financial stability”, Financial Stability Review, May, Frankfurt: ECB.
Bank of England (2021), “Options for greening the Bank of England’s
Corporate Bond Purchase Scheme”, Bank of England Discussion Paper,
London: Bank of England.
Batten, S., Sowerbutts, R. and Tanaka, M. (2020), “Climate change:
Macroeconomic impact and implications for monetary policy”, in:
Walker, T., Gramlich, D., Bitar, M. and Fardnia, P. (eds.), Ecological,
Societal, and Technological Risks and the Financial Sector, New York et
al.: Springer International Publishing.
Battiston, S. and Monasterolo, I. (2019), “How could the ECB’s monetary
policy support the sustainable finance transition?”, FINEXUS Working
Paper, Zurich: FINEXUS Center for Financial Networks and
Sustainability, University of Zurich.
Battiston, S., Dafermos, Y. and Monasterolo, I. (2021a), “Climate risks and
financial stability”, Journal of Financial Stability, 54, 100867.
Battiston, S., Monasterolo, I., Riahi, K. and van Ruijven, B.J., (2021b),
“Accounting for finance is key for climate mitigation pathways”, Science,
372 (6545), 918–920.
Batsaikhan, U. (2021), “A race against time: the implications of the ECB
climate action plan”, Positive Money Europe, 6 August.
https://www.positivemoney.eu/2021/08/implications-ecb-climate-action-
plan/
Benjamin, A. (2007), “Stern: Climate change a ‘market failure’”, The
Guardian, 29 November.
https://www.theguardian.com/environment/2007/nov/29/climatechange.c
arbonemissions
Braun, B. (2018), “Central banking and the infrastructural power of finance:
the case of ECB support for repo and securitization markets”, Socio-
Economic Review, 18 (2), 395–418.
Carrivick, J., Connor, C., Cooper, C., Gloor, M., Hooper, A., Lawson, I.,
Savov, I., Schmidt, A., Swindles G. and Watson, E. (2018), “Climatic
control on Icelandic volcanic activity during the mid-Holocene”, Geology,
46(1), 47–50.
Cavallo, E., Galiani, S. Noy, I. and Pantano, J. (2013), “Catastrophic natural
disasters and economic growth”, The Review of Economics and Statistics,
95 (5), 1549–1561.
30
Caldecott, B. (2020), “Climate risk management (CRM) and how it relates to
achieving alignment with climate outcomes (ACO)”, Journal of
Sustainable Finance & Investment.
https://doi.org/10.1080/20430795.2020.1848142
Chenet, H., Ryan-Collins, J. and van Lerven, F. (2021), “Climate-related
financial policy in a world of radical uncertainty: Towards a precautionary
approach”, Ecological Economics, 183, 106957.
ClientEarth (2021), “The ECB’s Monetary Policy Strategy Review: Corporate
sector asset purchases, climate change and the ECB’s legal obligations”.
Letter from Anaïs Berthier, Head of EU Affairs at ClientEarth to Christine
Lagarde, President of the ECB.
https://www.clientearth.org/media/jtxnhiba/2021-04-12-letter-from-
clientearth-to-christine-lagarde.pdf
Dafermos, Y. (forthcoming), “Climate change, central banking and financial
supervision: beyond the risk exposure approach”, in: Kappes, S., Rochon
L.-P. and Vallet, G. (eds.), The Future of Central Banking, Cheltenham
and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.
Dafermos, Y., Gabor, D., Nikolaidi, M., Pawloff, A. and van Lerven, F. (2020),
Decarbonising is easy: Beyond market neutrality in the ECB’s corporate
QE. London: New Economics Foundation.
Dafermos, Y., Gabor, D., Nikolaidi, M., Pawloff, A. and van Lerven, F.
(2021b), Greening the Eurosystem collateral framework: how to
decarbonise the ECB’s monetary policy. London: New Economics
Foundation.
Dafermos, Y., Gabor, D., Nikolaidi, M., and van Lerven, F. (2021a), “Greening
the UK financial system – a fit for purpose approach”, SUERF Policy Note
No. 226. Vienna: The European Money and Finance Forum.
Dafermos, Y. and Nikolaidi, M. (2021), “How can green differentiated capital
requirements affect climate risks? A dynamic macrofinancial analysis”,
Journal of Financial Stability, 54, 100871.
Dafermos, Y., Nikolaidi, M. and Galanis, G. (2018), “Climate change,
financial stability and monetary policy”, Ecological Economics, 152, 219–
234.
de Boer, N. and van ’t Klooster J. (2020), “The ECB, the courts and the issue
of democratic legitimacy after Weiss”, Common Market Law Review, 57,
1689–1724
de Guindos, L. (2021), “Shining a light on climate risks: The ECB’s economy-
wide climate stress test”, The ECB Blog, 18 March.
https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/blog/date/2021/html/ecb.blog210318~3
bbc68ffc5.en.html
Dietz, S., Bowen, A., Dixon, C. and Gradwell, P. (2016), “Climate value at
risk’ of global financial assets”, Nature Climate Change, 6 (7), 676–679.
Dikau, S., Robins, N. and Volz, U. (2021), Climate-neutral central banking:
how the European System of Central Banks can support the transition to
31
net-zero. London: Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and
the Environment, London School of Economics and Political Science, and
Centre for Sustainable Finance, SOAS, University of London.
D’Orazio, P. and Popoyan, L. (2019), “Fostering green investments and
tackling climate-related financial risks: Which role for macroprudential
policies?”, Ecological Economics, 160, 25–37.
Doyle L. and Noy, I. (2015), “The short-run nationwide macroeconomic effects
of theCanterbury earthquakes”, New Zealand Economic Papers, 49 (2),
143–156.
Driscoll, J. C. and Kraay, A.C. (1998), “Consistent covariance matrix
estimation withspatially dependent panel data”, The Review of Economics
and Statistics, 80 (4), 549–560.
Duprey, T., Jones, C., Symmers, C. and Vallée, G. (2021), “Household
financial vulnerabilities and physical climate risks”, Bank of Canada Staff
Analytical Note 2021-19. Ottawa: Bank of Canada.
Elderson, F. (2021), “Greening monetary policy”, The ECB Blog, 13 February.
https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/blog/date/2021/html/ecb.blog210213~7
e26af8606.en.html
European Central Bank [ECB] (2021a), An overview of the ECB’s monetary
policy strategy. Frankfurt: European Central Bank.
https://www.ecb.europa.eu/home/search/review/pdf/ecb.strategyreview_
monpol_strategy_overview.en.pdf
European Central Bank [ECB] (2021b), “Detailed roadmap of climate change-
related actions”. Frankfurt: ECB.
https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pr/date/2021/html/ecb.pr210708_1_ann
ex~f84ab35968.en.pdf
European Central Bank [ECB] (2021c), “Eurosystem agrees on common
stance for climate change-related sustainable investments in non-
monetary policy portfolios”, Press Release, 4 February. Frankfurt: ECB.
https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pr/date/2021/html/ecb.pr210204_1~a72
0bc4f03.en.html
Eurostat (2018), “Archive: Agricultural census in France”, March.
https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-
explained/index.php?title=Archive:Agricultural_census_in_France&oldi
d=379543
Eurostat (2020), “European Union: agriculture statistical factsheet”, June.
https://ec.europa.eu/info/sites/default/files/food-farming-
fisheries/farming/documents/agri-statistical-factsheet-eu_en.pdf
Finance Watch (2020), Breaking the climate-finance doom loop. How banking
prudential regulation can tackle the link between climate change and
financial instability. Brussels: Finance Watch.
Fratzscher, M., Große-Steffen, C. and Rieth, M. (2020), “Inflation targeting as
a shockabsorber”, Journal of International Economics, 123 (C), 103308.
32
Heinen, A., Khadan, J. and Strobl, E. (2019), “The price impact of extreme
weather in developing countries”, The Economic Journal, 111 (619),
1327–1342.
Hoechle, D. (2007), “Robust standard errors for panel regressions with cross-
sectional dependence”. The Stata Journal, 7 (3), 281–312.
Judson, R. and Owen, A. (1999), “Estimating dynamic panel data models: A
guide formacroeconomists”, Economics Letters, 65 (1), 9–15.
Keen, S. (2020), “The appallingly bad neoclassical economics of climate
change”, Globalizations.
https://doi.org/10.1080/14747731.2020.1807856
Kling, G., Volz, U., Murinde, V. and Ayas S. (2021), “The impact of climate
vulnerability on firms’ cost of capital and access to finance”, World
Development, 137, 105131.
Klomp, J. and Sseruyange, J. (2020), “Earthquakes and economic outcomes:
Does central bank independence matter?”, Open Economies Review, 32,
335–359.
Masih, A. (2018), “An enhanced seismic activity observed due to climate
change:Preliminary results from Alaska”, IOP Conference Series: Earth
and Environmental Science, 167, 012018.
Monasterolo, I. (2020), “Climate change and the financial system”, Annual
Review of Resource Economics, 12, 299–320.
Network for Greening the Financial System [NGFS] (2019), A sustainable and
responsible investment guide for central banks’ portfolio management.
Paris: NGFS.
Network for Greening the Financial System [NGFS] (2020), Climate change
and monetary policy. Initial takeaways. Paris: NGFS.
Network for Greening the Financial System [NGFS] (2021a), Adapting central
bank operations to a hotter world Reviewing some options. Paris: NGFS.
Network for Greening the Financial System [NGFS] (2021b), NGFS climate
scenarios for central banks and supervisors. Paris: NGFS.
Nguyen, M. (2020), “Collateral haircuts and bond yields in the European
government bond markets”, International Review of Financial Analysis,
69, 101467.
Oustry, A., Erkan, B., Svartzman, R., Pierre-François, W. (2020), “Climate-
related risks and central banks’ collateral policy: A methodological
experiment”, Banque de France Working Paper No. 790. Paris: Banque de
France.
Oman, W. and Svartzman, R. (2021), “Sustainable finance: Current needs,
measures and impact”, CESifo Forum, 22 (3), 3-11.
Pelizzon, L., Riedel, M., Simon, Z. and Subrahmanyam, M.G. (2020),
“Collateral eligibility of corporate debt in the Eurosystem”, SAFE
Working Paper No. 275. Frankfurt: Leibniz Institute for Financial
Research SAFE.
33
Robins, N., Dikau, S. and Volz, U. (2021), Net-zero central banking: A new
phase in greening the financial system. London: Grantham Research
Institute on Climate Change and the Environment and Centre for Climate
Change Economics and Policy, London School of Economics and
Political Science, and Centre for Sustainable Finance, SOAS, University
of London.
Matikainen, S., Campiglio, E. and Zenghelis, D. (2017), “The climate impact
of quantitative easing”. Policy Paper. London: Grantham Research
Institute on Climate Change and the Environment, London School of
Economics and Political Science.
Noy, I. (2009), “The macroeconomic consequences of disasters”, Journal of
Development Economics, 88 (2), 221–231.
Noy, I. and Nualsri, A. (2011), “Fiscal storms: Public spending and revenues
in the aftermath of natural disasters”, Environment and Development
Economics, 16 (1),113–128.
Parker, M. (2018), “The impact of disasters on inflation”, Economics of
Disasters andClimate Change, 2, 21–48.
Schnabel, I. (2021a), “From green neglect to green dominance”, Intervention
by Isabel Schnabel, Member of the Executive Board of the ECB, at the
“Greening Monetary Policy – Central Banking and Climate Change”
online seminar, organised as part of the “Cleveland Fed Conversations on
Central Banking”, 3 March.
https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/key/date/2021/html/ecb.sp210303_1~f3
df48854e.en.html
Schnabel, I. (2021b), “From market neutrality to market efficiency”, Welcome
address at the ECB DG-Research Symposium “Climate change, financial
markets and green growth”, Frankfurt am Main, 14 June.
https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/key/date/2021/html/ecb.sp210614~162
bd7c253.en.html
Semieniuk, G., Campiglio, E., Mercure, J-F., Volz, U. and Edwards, N.E.
(2021), “Low-carbon transition risks for finance”, Wiley Interdisciplinary
Reviews Climate Change, 12, e678.
Schoenmaker, D. (2021), “Greening monetary policy”, Climate Policy, 21 (4),
581–592.
Senni, C.H., and Monnin, P. (2020), “Central bank market neutrality is a
myth”, Zurich: Council on Economic Policies.
https://www.cepweb.org/central-bank-market-neutrality-is-a-myth/
Simola, H. (2020), “Climate change and the Russian economy”, BOFIT Policy
Brief No. 11/2020. Helsinki: Bank of Finland Institute for Emerging
Economies.
Sleijpen, O. (2021), “ECB needs to rethink market neutrality”. London,
Official Monetary and Financial Institutions Forum.
https://www.omfif.org/2021/04/ecb-needs-to-rethink-market-neutrality/
34
Täger, M. (2021), “‘Double materiality’: What is it and why does it matter?”,
Commentary. London: Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change
and the Environment, London School of Economics and Political Science.
Task Force on Climate-related Financial Disclosures [TCFD] (2017),
Recommendations of the task force on climate-related financial
disclosures. Basel: Financial Stability Board.
Task Force on Climate-related Financial Disclosures [TCFD] (2020), Forward-
Looking Financial Sector Metrics – Consultation. Basel: Financial
Stability Board.
Todorov, K. (2020), “Quantify the quantitative easing: Impact on bonds and
corporate debt issuance”, Journal of Financial Economics, 135 (2), 340–
358.
van’t Klooster, J. and van Tilburg, R. (2020), Targeting a sustainable recovery
with Green TLTROs. Brussels and Utrecht: Positive Money Europe and
Sustainable Finance Lab at Utrecht University.
van’t Klooster, J. and Fontan, C. (2020), “The myth of market neutrality: A
comparative study of the European Central Bank’s and the Swiss National
Bank’s corporate security purchases”, New Political Economy, 25 (6),
865–879.
Verheyen, R. (2021), “Legal opinion: Legal options for implementing climate
criteria in the monetary policy of the European Central Bank”.
https://greenpeace.at/assets/uploads/pdf/ecb-legal-opinion.pdf
Volz, U. (2017), “On the role of central banks in enhancing green finance”,
UN Inquiry Working Paper No. 17/01. Geneva: UN Environment.
35
Appendix
To measure monthly inflation rates, we use data on headline inflation and its
sub-indices for all euro area countries in the period from 1996 to 2021. Data
are provided by Eurostat and capture the price changes of consumer goods and
services acquired by euro area households. Unlike other consumer price data,
they are based on harmonised statistical methods and thus allow for cross-
country comparisons. Data are available for overall headline inflation, as well
as for its 12 main sub-indices and further sub-categories. This allows us to
disentangle differences in the direction and strength of price effects across
consumption categories.
We add numerous control variables to our model to account for other driving
forces of inflation rates. We extract monthly data on the gross domestic product
(GDP, ratio to trend), industrial production (excluding construction) and the
unemployment rate for all euro area countries as well as on the nominal
36
exchange rate to US dollars from the OECD’s Main Economic Indicators and
Key Short-Term Economic Indicators databases. Data on industrial import
prices are provided by Eurostat, brent crude oil prices are extracted from the
World Bank Commodity Price Data.
𝜋𝑖,𝑡 = 𝛼 + ∑12 12
𝑗=0 𝛽𝑗 𝐷𝑖,𝑡−𝑗 + ∑𝑙=1 𝜋𝑖,𝑡−𝑙 + 𝜑𝑋𝑖,𝑡−1 + 𝜇𝑖 + 𝜆𝑡 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑡
(1)
where 𝜋𝑖,𝑡 is the monthly headline inflation rate in country i and month t. 𝐷𝑖,𝑡
is our disaster variable that captures the estimated monetary damage (in % of
GDP) from natural disasters taking place in months t-j up to t in country i.
The coefficients of interest are the 𝛽𝑗 ’s that measure by how much inflation
rates change following an increase in climate disasters by one percentage point
of monthly GDP. If several distinct events happen in country i within the same
month, we follow Fratzscher et al. (2020) and sum over all disasters in that
month. We include 12 lags of the disaster variable to account for time lags in
the transmission of the disaster shock to inflation. Moreover, we include lags
of the dependent variable to remove potential autocorrelation in the error term,
as in Noy (2009) and Fratzscher et al. (2020).20 We choose 𝐿 = 12 to allow
inflation of the past 12 months to impact the current inflation rate.
20
The inclusion of lagged dependent variables as regressors causes problems associated with
the Nickell bias (Nickell, 1981). Yet, in our setting where the number of countries N is small (it
equals 19) and T is larger than 30, this bias is expected to be negligible (Judson and Owen,
1999).
37
lags) in the idiosyncratic error term 𝜀𝑖,𝑡 , we use Driscoll and Kraay (1998)
adjusted standard errors, as in Parker (2018) and Heinen et al. (2019).21
𝜋𝑡 = 𝛼 + ∑12 12
𝑗=0 𝛽𝑗 𝐷𝑡−𝑗 + ∑𝑙=1 𝜋𝑡−𝑙 + 𝜑𝑋𝑡−1 + 𝜀𝑡 (2)
The included variables exactly match the ones from above for the respective
country, except that we exclude the country and time fixed-effects for our
country-by-country regressions. We use Newey-West adjusted standard errors
that are robust to heteroskedasticity and first-order autocorrelation. We test for
the stationarity of the variables by performing Augmented Dickey-Fuller
(ADF) tests that reject the null hypothesis of a unit root for all variables, except
for some of the control variables.22
21
To test whether the residuals are cross-sectionally dependent, we use Pesaran’s test, as
suggested by Hoechle (2007). The null hypothesis of cross-sectional independence is rejected
for headline inflation, as well as for all of the main 12 sub-indices, for any standard significance
level.
22
Specifically, the null hypothesis of a unit root cannot be rejected for the unemployment rate
in all four countries as well as for the logs of GDP and industrial production in Germany and
Spain. However, visual inspection of these time series suggests that the non-stationarity of the
ADF tests results from a structural break due to the COVID-19 pandemic in 2020 and 2021
rather than from a unit root.
38
A.2 Tables
Table 1: Determinants of headline inflation, euro area, 1996-2021
39
Table 2: Determinants of core inflation, euro area, 1996-2021
40
Table 3: Determinants of sub-indices’ inflation, euro area, 1996-2021
FoodBev: food and non-alcoholic beverages; AlcTob: alcoholic beverages, tobacco and narcotics; ClothShoes: clothing and footwear; HoEIG: housing, water,
electricity, gas and other fuels; HoEq: furnishings, household equipment and routine household maintenance; Health: health; Transp: transport; Comm:
communications; RecrCult: recreation and culture; Educ: education; RestHot: restaurants and hotels; Misc: miscellaneous goods and services.
41
Table 4: Determinants of inflation of food and beverages’ sub-categories, euro area, 1996-2021
Food: food; BreadCer: bread and cereals; Meat: meat; FishSeaf: fish and seafood; MilkChEg: milk, cheese and eggs; OilsFa: oils and fats; Fruit: fruit; Veg: vegetables;
SugJHChC: sugar, jam, honey, chocolate and confectionery; Fonec: Food products n.e.c.; NAlcBev: Non-alcoholic beverages; CofTC: coffee, tea and cocoa; MWSJu:
Mineral waters, soft drinks, fruit and vegetable juices.
42
Table 5: Determinants of headline inflation, France, 1996-2021
43
Table 6: Determinants of headline inflation, Germany, 1996-2021
44
Table 7: Determinants of headline inflation, Italy, 1996-2021
45
Table 8: Determinants of headline inflation, Spain, 1996-2021
46
Table 9: Determinants of core inflation, France, 1996-2021
47
Table 10: Determinants of core inflation, Germany, 1996-2021
48
Table 11: Determinants of core inflation, Italy, 1996-2021
49
Table 12: Determinants of core inflation, Spain, 1996-2021
50
Table 13: Determinants of sub-indices’ inflation, France, 1996-2021
FoodBev: food and non-alcoholic beverages; AlcTob: alcoholic beverages, tobacco and narcotics; ClothShoes: clothing and footwear; HoEIG: housing, water,
electricity, gas and other fuels; HoEq: furnishings, household equipment and routine household maintenance; Health: health; Transp: transport; Comm:
communications; RecrCult: recreation and culture; Educ: education; RestHot: restaurants and hotels; Misc: miscellaneous goods and services.
51
Table 14: Determinants of sub-indices’ inflation, Germany, 1996-2021
FoodBev: food and non-alcoholic beverages; AlcTob: alcoholic beverages, tobacco and narcotics; ClothShoes: clothing and footwear; HoEIG: housing, water,
electricity, gas and other fuels; HoEq: furnishings, household equipment and routine household maintenance; Health: health; Transp: transport; Comm:
communications; RecrCult: recreation and culture; Educ: education; RestHot: restaurants and hotels; Misc: miscellaneous goods and services.
52
Table 15: Determinants of sub-indices’ inflation, Italy, 1996-2021
FoodBev: food and non-alcoholic beverages; AlcTob: alcoholic beverages, tobacco and narcotics; ClothShoes: clothing and footwear; HoEIG: housing, water, electricity,
gas and other fuels; HoEq: furnishings, household equipment and routine household maintenance; Health: health; Transp: transport; Comm: communications; RecrCult:
recreation and culture; Educ: education; RestHot: restaurants and hotels; Misc: miscellaneous goods and services.
53
Table 16: Determinants of sub-indices’ inflation, Spain, 1996-2021
FoodBev: food and non-alcoholic beverages; AlcTob: alcoholic beverages, tobacco and narcotics; ClothShoes: clothing and footwear; HoEIG: housing, water,
electricity, gas and other fuels; HoEq: furnishings, household equipment and routine household maintenance; Health: health; Transp: transport; Comm:
communications; RecrCult: recreation and culture; Educ: education; RestHot: restaurants and hotels; Misc: miscellaneous goods and services.
54
Table 17: Determinants of inflation of food and beverages’ sub-categories, France, 1996-2021
Food: food; BreadCer: bread and cereals; Meat: meat; FishSeaf: fish and seafood; MilkChEg: milk, cheese and eggs; OilsFa: oils and fats; Fruit: fruit; Veg: vegetables;
SugJHChC: sugar, jam, honey, chocolate and confectionery; Fonec: Food products n.e.c.; NAlcBev: Non-alcoholic beverages; CofTC: coffee, tea and cocoa; MWSJu:
Mineral waters, soft drinks, fruit and vegetable juices.
55
Table 18: Determinants of inflation of food and beverages’ sub-categories, Germany, 1996-2021
Food: food; BreadCer: bread and cereals; Meat: meat; FishSeaf: fish and seafood; MilkChEg: milk, cheese and eggs; OilsFa: oils and fats; Fruit: fruit; Veg: vegetables;
SugJHChC: sugar, jam, honey, chocolate and confectionery; Fonec: Food products n.e.c.; NAlcBev: Non-alcoholic beverages; CofTC: coffee, tea and cocoa; MWSJu:
Mineral waters, soft drinks, fruit and vegetable juices.
56
Table 19: Determinants of inflation of food and beverages’ sub-categories, Italy, 1996-2021
Food: food; BreadCer: bread and cereals; Meat: meat; FishSeaf: fish and seafood; MilkChEg: milk, cheese and eggs; OilsFa: oils and fats; Fruit: fruit; Veg: vegetables;
SugJHChC: sugar, jam, honey, chocolate and confectionery; Fonec: Food products n.e.c.; NAlcBev: Non-alcoholic beverages; CofTC: coffee, tea and cocoa; MWSJu:
Mineral waters, soft drinks, fruit and vegetable juices.
57
Table 20: Determinants of inflation of food and beverages’ sub-categories, Spain, 1996-2021
Food: food; BreadCer: bread and cereals; Meat: meat; FishSeaf: fish and seafood; MilkChEg: milk, cheese and eggs; OilsFa: oils and fats; Fruit: fruit; Veg:
vegetables; SugJHChC: sugar, jam, honey, chocolate and confectionery; Fonec: Food products n.e.c.; NAlcBev: Non-alcoholic beverages; CofTC: coffee, tea and
cocoa; MWSJu: Mineral waters, soft drinks, fruit and vegetable juices.
58