Journal of Financial Economics: Taylor D. Nadauld, Michael S. Weisbach
Journal of Financial Economics: Taylor D. Nadauld, Michael S. Weisbach
Journal of Financial Economics: Taylor D. Nadauld, Michael S. Weisbach
a r t i c l e in f o
abstract
Article history:
Received 23 February 2011
Received in revised form
6 July 2011
Accepted 4 August 2011
Available online 15 March 2012
This paper investigates whether the securitization of corporate bank loan facilities had
an impact on the price of corporate debt. Our results suggest that loan facilities that are
subsequently securitized are associated with a 17 basis point lower spread than that of
facilities that are not subsequently securitized. We consider facility characteristics that
are associated with the likelihood of securitization and estimate the extent to which
these characteristics are related to spreads. We document that Term Loan B facilities,
facilities of B-rated rms, and facilities originated by banks that originate CLOs are
securitized more frequently than other facilities. Spreads on facilities estimated to be
more likely to be subsequently securitized have lower spreads than otherwise similar
facilities. The results are consistent with the view that securitization caused a reduction
in the cost of capital.
& 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
JEL classication:
G21
G31
Keywords:
Securitization
Collateralized loan obligations (CLO)
Corporate bank loans
1. Introduction
While much attention has focused on the role of securitization in the mortgage market, relatively little has been
paid to the securitization of corporate bank loans in the form
of collateralized loan obligations (CLOs).1 This lack of attention is surprising given that both the volume of
non-investment-grade bank loans and the number of newly
originated CLOs spiked dramatically between the years 2002
and 2007, from over $125 billion of loans and 43 CLOs in
$
We would like to thank Viral Acharya, Heitor Almeida, Murillo
Campello, Jennifer Dlugosz, Isil Erel, Andrew Karolyi, Eric Oberg, Rene
Stulz, and participants in seminars at Brigham Young University,
Erasmus University, HEC Paris, Ohio State University, and the University
of Amsterdam for helpful suggestions. We also thank our unusually
diligent referee, Victoria Ivashina, for helpful comments and
suggestions.
n
Corresponding author.
E-mail address: [email protected] (T.D. Nadauld).
1
See, for example, Mian and Su (2009), Demyanyk and Van
Hemert (2011), DellAriccia, Igan, and Laeven (2008), Keys, Mukherjee,
Seru, and Vig (2010), Loutskina and Strahan (2009), and Nadauld and
Sherlund (forthcoming).
0304-405X/$ - see front matter & 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jneco.2012.03.002
2
The estimates on the dollar volume of non-investment-grade loans
originated in 2002 and 2007 are likely understated in both years. The
reported gures are calculated using our sample of U.S.-originated
syndicated bank loans made to non-nancial borrowers with available
sales data that is described in Section 3.
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
3
The terms supply and demand can be ambiguous when discussing
a primary and secondary loan market. The phrase demand for securitizable loan facilities refers to demand from the secondary market,
which is manifest as increased supply in the primary loan-origination
market.
4
In Section 2.2 we discuss at least two reasons why Term Loan Bs
are preferred as collateral by arrangers of CLOs.
333
334
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
2. Institutional background
Collateralized loan obligations (CLOs) transform speculative-grade bank loan facilities into highly rated bonds
through the process of pooling and tranching.6 The
incidence of securitizing corporate bank loans exploded
between 2002 and 2007 and has been well-documented
in the literature and popular press. Over 80% of the CLOs
originated between 1996 and 2008 were originated in the
years 20022007, with nearly 50% occurring in 2006 and
the rst half of 2007 alone.7 Also noteworthy is the fact
that between 2002 and 2007, 79% of new CLOs were
originated by just ten banks. In short, the creation of CLOs
was very active over a relatively short period of time and
concentrated in a relatively small number of originating
banks.
Theoretically, securitization can occur for a number of
reasons. First, DeMarzo (2005) suggests that securitization reduces asymmetric information problems about the
quality of individual loans by providing the purchaser
with a diversied pool of loans from different issuers,
presumably having a lower information asymmetry problem than any individual loan would have. Second, Gaur,
Seshadri, and Subrahmanyam (2011) point out that
securitization reduces market incompleteness, providing
investors who value that particular cash-ow distribution
with the ability to purchase it. Finally, Coval, Jurek, and
Stafford (2009), relying on the assumption that investors
purchase bonds based solely on credit ratings, attribute
the proliferation of securitization activity between 2002
2007 to the potential for deal arrangers to deliver the
cheapest possible set of assets that can obtain a high
quality credit rating, thereby engaging in ratings arbitrage. The observation that the bank loans of B-rated
borrowers were securitized more frequently than Barated loans is consistent with a cheapest-to-deliver
view of collateral selection in securitization.
Yet, none of these theories of securitization provides a
rationale for why securitization should affect the spreads
on loan facilities that subsequently are securitized. In
other words, given two loan facilities, why should their
spreads differ depending on whether they are subsequently securitized if the risks associated with the loans
repayment are identical? For this to be the case, the very
process of securitization likely inuences the lenders
decision about the loan at the time of origination.
6
The term tranche is used to describe different bonds arising from
a CLO deal and is also used to describe different loan facilities within a
bank loan. The term tranche in this sentence refers to the tranches
(bonds) that arise from the origination of a CLO.
7
Data on CLO originations are presented in Table 2.
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
335
336
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
with uniformly B-rated collateral (with collateral concentrated specically in the B1 rating).14
Consequently, when demand for CLO collateral
increased in the securitization-active period, we expect
that this demand will be reected in demand for B-rated
collateral more than for higher-rated debt. This increase
should be in the institutional (Term Loan B) tranche of the
loan and not for the Term Loan A or revolver tranches of
the loans. In addition, it should be higher for loan facilities
issued by banks active in securitization, that presumably
package these facilities immediately into the CLOs that
they arrange themselves. These differences in attractiveness to originators of CLOs lead to clear identication of
the effect of demand for collateral on the relative pricing
of different kinds of bank loan facilities.
3. Data
3.1. Sample construction
To study the way in which securitization affects the
pricing of loan facilities, we utilize data from two publicly
available databases: Reuters Dealscan and Moodys
Enhanced Monitoring Service (EMS) data services. We
restrict our sample to Dealscan loan facilities originated
between 2002 and September of 2007, at which time CLO
originations began to decline.15 Our sample requires that
facilities have Moodys credit ratings on the borrowing
rms senior debt at the time of loan origination.16 Our
analysis focuses specically on rms with Moodys
senior-debt credit ratings of B (B1, B2, or B3) or Ba (Ba1,
Ba2, Ba3). We further restrict the sample to include only
syndicated loans originated in the United States and
remove nancial rms with Standard Industrial Classication (SIC) codes between 6000 and 6500. We also
identify and remove any second-lien or mezzanine facilities from the sample.
The Moodys EMS sample provides data on the characteristics and identity of all the securities serving as
collateral in any Moodys-rated CLO as of the rst quarter
2009. The strength of the Moodys data is that it allows us
to identify exactly which loan facilities serve as collateral
in CLOs as of the rst quarter 2009. Unfortunately, it
14
The average CLO deal in their sample transformed the B-rated
collateral into securities in which 70% of the principal balance of the
originated bonds was rated AAA, while 90% of the principal was rated
BBB or higher. The pattern is very similar in the Moodys sample of CLOs
we analyze below.
15
Our identication strategy relies on differences in CLO demand
for securitizable loan facilities on account of facility attributes, rather
than substantial changes in CLO demand through time. As such, we
begin our sample in 2002 so that our estimates are concentrated during
the securitization boom.
16
We require the rating on the senior debt and not on the specic
loan because it is available for a much larger number of loans: there are
4,536 facilities in Dealscan that meet our sample criteria for which there
is a rating on the senior debt and only 2,351 for which there is a rating
on the specic facility. For the loans in our sample that have both
facility-specic credit ratings and senior-debt credit ratings, the ratings
are either the same or within one ratings class (i.e., B1 senior debt and
Ba3, B1, or B2 facility-specic rating) over 71% of the time.
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
337
Table 1
Facility summary statistics by facility type, credit rating, facility purpose, and facility attribute.
In this table we report summary statistics on loan facilities identied as having been securitized and compare them against the attributes of nonsecuritized facilities. The Moodys EMS database provides a snapshot of the characteristics and identity of all the securities serving as collateral in any
Moodys-rated CLO as of the rst quarter of 2009. The securitized sample is dened as any loan facility identied as collateral in a CLO according to
Moodys EMS database as of the rst quarter 2009. We outline the matching process in the text. We report summary statistics on the number of loan
facilities and all-in-drawn spread over LIBOR charged on loan facilities at the time of loan origination. Panels AC report summary statistics by facility
type, credit rating, and facility purpose, respectively. Panel D reports summary statistics on facility attributes. The Dealscan sample consists of senior
secured and unsecured loan facilities originated between 2002 and September 2007 which have Moodys credit ratings on the senior debt of the issuing
rm available at the time of loan origination. We restrict our sample to include syndicated loan facilities originated in the United States and exclude rms
with SIC codes between 6000 and 6500. We also restrict our analysis to facilities with senior debt rated Ba1, Ba2, Ba3, B1, B2, and B3. We identify and
remove any second-lien or mezzanine facilities from the sample.
Panel A
Non-securitized sample
Facility type
Revolver
Term Loan A
Term Loan B
Securitized sample
Count
2514
278
1413
225.0
225.0
250.0
226.8
228.0
276.7
Count
275.0
300.0
325.0
34
20
277
Panel B
Term Loan Bs only - Non-securitized sample
All-in-drawn spread over LIBOR
Moodys sr. debt credit rating
Ba1
Ba2
Ba3
B1
B2
B3
Corporate purposes
Debt repayment
Takeover
Working capital
Leveraged buyout (LBO)
Acquisition line
Other
200.0
143.8
200.0
250.0
150.0
225.0
235.3
175.6
240.4
250.0
200.0
275.0
Diff
t-Stat
8.5
52.4
36.3
(1.06)
( 3.40)
( 7.39)
Count
25th
%tile
Median
Mean
75th
%tile
Count
25th
%tile
Median
Mean
75th
%tile
Diff
t-Stat
49
138
290
458
338
140
175.0
175.0
200.0
225.0
225.0
250.0
200.0
225.0
225.0
250.0
275.0
275.0
224.5
230.7
250.0
273.9
306.6
332.3
275.0
275.0
275.0
300.0
350.0
400.0
9
22
50
101
68
27
175.0
150.0
175.0
200.0
225.0
225.0
175.0
187.5
225.0
225.0
250.0
250.0
181.9
200.0
223.0
241.1
265.4
259.3
187.5
225.0
250.0
275.0
287.5
275.0
42.5
30.7
27.0
32.8
41.2
73.1
( 2.86)
( 2.13)
( 3.24)
( 4.67)
( 3.39)
( 4.27)
Panel C
Term Loan Bs onlyNon-securitized sample
All-in-drawn spread over LIBOR
Facility purpose
Count
25th
%tile
Median
Mean
75th
%tile
Count
25th
%tile
Median
Mean
75th
%tile
Diff
t-Stat
445
123
183
168
209
112
173
200.0
225.0
200.0
200.0
225.0
218.8
225.0
250.0
275.0
225.0
250.0
275.0
250.0
267.5
267.9
308.5
250.9
279.7
289.1
266.3
277.4
325.0
350.0
275.0
325.0
325.0
300.0
304.2
85
30
39
19
63
12
29
200.0
175.0
200.0
175.0
225.0
175.0
200.0
225.0
200.0
200.0
225.0
250.0
225.0
219.6
241.2
214.2
227.2
226.3
256.7
256.3
243.1
250.0
250.0
250.0
275.0
300.0
337.5
264.3
26.8
94.3
23.6
53.4
32.4
10.0
( 2.65)
( 6.56)
( 2.14)
( 3.18)
( 4.04)
( 0.39)
Diff
t-Stat
Panel D
Term Loan Bs onlyNon-securitized sample
Loan attribute
Count
25th
%tile
1432
1432
1355
1431
$125.0
$272.7
60.0
3.0
1432
Mean
$219.5 $388.0
$616.5 $1,757.3
72.0
71.4
5.0
8.5
54.2%
75th
%tile
Count
25th
%tile
$400.0
$1,500.7
84.0
9.0
278
278
276
277
$180.0
$347.3
72.0
3.0
278
Median
Mean
$315.0 $519.8
$704.1 $3,055.0
84.0
76.3
5.0
7.0
62.6%
75th
%tile
$600.0
$1,510.7
84.0
7.0
$131.8
(2.91)
$1,297.6 (1.58)
5.0
(5.74)
1.4
( 2.37)
8.40%
(2.63)
338
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
Table 2
The creation of CLOs through time and by originator.
This table reports the frequency and timing of CLO originations by CLO underwriter. Data include all CLOs originated in the United States and Europe as
reported in Moodys EMS database. Of the 884 reported CLOs, less than 1% are reported as balance-sheet CLOs. The remaining are primarily cash-ow
arbitrage CLOs. Over 80% of all deals were created between the 2002 and 2007 period, with almost 50% of the deals being created in 2006 and 2007. Over
78% of the deals were originated by the top-ten originating banks. The top-ten underwriting banks over our 2002September 2007 sample period are
classied as securitization-active.
CLO originating bank
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
Total
JPMorgan
Citigroup
Bear, Stearns & Co. Inc.
Credit Suisse
Lehman Brothers
Deutsche Bank
Goldman Sachs & Co.
Morgan Stanley
Wachovia Securities Inc.
Merrill Lynch & Co.
Bank of America Securities LLC
UBS Securities LLC
IXIS Securities North America Inc.
Barclays Capital
CIBC World Markets Inc.
Royal Bank of Scotland plc
Salomon Smith Barney
BNP Paribas
Others (28 other banks)
0
1
0
0
1
0
0
0
0
1
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
0
2
0
0
0
0
2
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
2
1
1
2
1
4
0
0
0
0
2
0
0
0
2
3
1
4
2
2
1
2
3
2
1
1
0
0
0
3
0
0
0
4
2
0
2
2
1
0
5
3
2
3
1
0
0
0
1
0
2
0
7
6
0
3
2
1
4
5
3
0
1
1
1
0
0
0
0
1
0
1
6
0
2
7
3
3
4
3
3
2
1
0
0
1
2
0
3
0
3
7
2
3
10
3
8
5
2
3
2
2
1
2
1
0
0
2
1
2
7
1
12
5
6
5
3
3
5
4
2
3
3
0
0
0
0
0
5
13
17
13
12
11
2
6
7
9
10
5
5
2
0
0
0
0
1
10
26
28
21
13
10
16
12
16
18
7
14
5
9
2
0
1
0
2
20
18
24
17
14
19
18
17
18
18
10
7
5
1
4
0
7
0
3
13
5
11
1
1
5
5
3
2
2
3
3
1
0
4
0
0
0
0
5
94
85
78
69
64
63
63
63
63
50
37
21
17
12
10
8
8
7
72
Total
16
29
31
29
43
56
64
123
220
213
51
884
data, followed by debt repayments and corporate takeovers. Facilities supporting leveraged buyouts represent
16% of the Term Loan B facilities we study, and these
loans are securitized at a higher rate than other loan
facilities. Panel D reports statistics on facility attributes
such as facility amounts, annual sales of the borrowing
rms, tranche maturity, syndicate size, and the percentage of facilities with nancial covenants.
Table 1 also shows the differences in the attributes of
loan facilities identied as having been securitized, relative to their non-securitized counterparts. The table
indicates that securitized loan facilities have lower
spreads, with the largest differences in spreads concentrated in lower credit-quality facilities. In addition, securitized facilities have larger facility sizes, slightly longer
maturities, and were arranged by smaller syndicates. The
differences between securitized and non-securitized facilities highlight the importance of controlling for differences in facility size, sales size, tranche maturity, and
covenants, in drawing inferences on the incremental
effect of securitization.
The time-series pattern of CLO origination in our
sample is illustrated in Table 2. The sample is predominately made up of CLOs originated between 2002 and
2007. In addition, the CLOs are highly concentrated
among a relatively small number of originating banks,
with the top ten banks underwriting 692 of the 884 CLOs
(78%) over the entire sample and 569 of the 719 deals
(79%) during the 20022007 time period. Although
Table 2 focuses on the CLO underwriting activity of 18
unique banks, at least 38 different banks were involved in
the underwriting of at least one CLO between the years
1996 and 2008.
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
339
Full sample
No. of Term B facilities
(3-mth mov. avg.)
35
Securitization-active
30
Non-securitization active
25
20
15
10
5
2005 Q1
2005 Q3
2006 Q1
2006 Q3
2007 Q1
2007 Q3
2005 Q1
2005 Q3
2006 Q1
2006 Q3
2007 Q1
2007 Q3
2005 Q1
2005 Q3
2006 Q1
2006 Q3
2007 Q1
2007 Q3
2004 Q3
2004 Q1
2003 Q3
2003 Q1
2002 Q3
2002 Q1
2001 Q3
2001 Q1
2000 Q3
2000 Q1
1999 Q3
1999 Q1
1998 Q3
1998 Q1
Securitization-active sample
B-rated
Ba-rated
20
15
10
2004 Q3
2004 Q1
2003 Q3
2003 Q1
2002 Q3
2002 Q1
2001 Q3
2001 Q1
2000 Q3
2000 Q1
1999 Q3
1999 Q1
1998 Q3
5
1998 Q1
25
Non-securitization-active sample
B-rated
10
Ba-rated
8
6
4
2004 Q3
2004 Q1
2003Q3
2003 Q1
2002 Q3
2002 Q1
2001 Q3
2001 Q1
2000 Q3
2000 Q1
1999 Q3
1999 Q1
1998 Q3
2
1998 Q1
12
securitization deals underwritten during our sample period. The plot indicates that origination patterns were very
similar until 2002, when securitization-active banks began
to increase their origination of Term Loan B facilities
aggressively. Panel B plots the origination activity of
securitization-active banks by credit rating. The plot indicates that much of the boom in Term Loan B originations
was concentrated in facilities of a lower credit-quality.
Finally, Panel C plots the origination activity of non-
securitization-active banks by credit quality. While nonsecuritization active banks also increased their origination
of lower credit-quality facilities, the plots suggest that the
difference was not as dramatic as the difference observed
in the origination activity of securitization-active banks.
Overall, these plots suggest that there was a large increase
in securitization activity after 2002, and that this increase
was concentrated in the securitization-active banks, and in
lower credit-quality issues.
340
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
4. Results
4.1. Do securitized loans have lower spreads?
4.1.1. Univariate tests
Panel B of Table 1 presents the average difference in
spreads between Term Loan B facilities that were securitized and those that were not securitized according to the
Moodys data. As a rough control for facility attributes, we
present the comparison by rating class for the most
commonly issued rating levels: Ba1, Ba2, Ba3, B1, B2,
and B3.
This panel indicates that in each rating class, spreads
are lower for the securitized sample than for the nonsecuritized sample, with the difference ranging from 27
basis points for the Ba3 rating category to 73.1 basis
points for the B3 category. The average difference in
spreads among the B-rated facilities is 49 basis points,
as opposed to the 33.4 basis point difference among Barated facilities. The lower spreads for securitized facilities
are consistent with the notion that the ability to securitize
a facility leads to a lower spread, and consequently a
lower cost of capital for the rm borrowing the money.
However, it is not a conclusive estimate of the incremental effect of securitization on spreads for at least three
reasons. First, we have an imperfect matching of loan
facilities to CLOs that likely understates the fraction of
loans that are securitized. Second, these differences do not
control for other factors that are known to affect facility
pricing. Finally, it is possible that some other factor could
affect both spreads and securitization decisions simultaneously, leading the observed relation between the two to
occur but not to be causal.
The rst issue, involving the imperfect matching of
loan facilities to CLOs, results from both the fact that we
have only a snapshot of CLOs as of 2009, and also from the
by hand nature of the matching process. As a result, it is
likely that most or all of the facilities classied as
securitized really were securitized, but that a number of
facilities that we classied as non-securitized actually
were securitized. Such a misclassication would imply
that the differences documented in Table 1 would understate the true differences in spreads between securitized
and non-securitized loan facilities.
4.1.2. Multivariate tests
The second issue, that factors in addition to whether a
particular loan facility is securitized are likely to affect
spreads, is addressed using a multivariate regression
framework. We create a dummy variable set equal to
one if the facility was part of a CLO in the Moodys
database, and estimate a regression of the following form:
Spreadi,t a0 b Securitizedi,t g Borrower f actorsi,t
19
In considering a primary-market demand explanation for the
observed lower spreads on securitized facilities, it is not clear why CLOs
would choose to purchase loan facilities with lower spreads than
average. One possibility would be if spreads were not priced completely
by the market for some reason, leading banks to sell the lower spread
facilities and keep the higher spread ones for any particular quality level.
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
341
Table 3
Do securitized loans have lower spreads?
In this table we estimate an OLS regression of facility attributes and other controls on the all-in-drawn spread of loan facilities originated between 2002
and September 2007. We create an indicator variable, Securitized indicator, for loans identied as collateral in a CLO as of 2009 using Moodys EMS
database. Term structure is calculated as the difference between the ve-year and three-month T-bill rate in the month of deal origination. Credit spread is
the spread of a 10-year Ba- and B-rated bond index over the 10-year T-bond rate, respectively. Covenants indicator is equal to one if a facility has nancial
covenants. Pricing grid indicator is equal to one if the spread is adjustable based on accounting performance. Size of syndicate is the number of lenders
involved in the lending syndicate. Tranche maturity is the number of months until the facility matures. Log facility amount and Log sales size represent the
dollar amount of the loan facility and total sales of the borrowing rm, measured in U.S. $ million. Secured indicator is an indicator equal to one if the loan
facility is secured. In various specications, as indicated in the table, we control for tranche-type xed-effects (Revolver, Term Loan A, or Term Loan B),
credit-rating xed-effects (Ba1, Ba2, Ba3, B1, B2, B3), tranche-purpose xed-effects (corporate purposes, LBO, debt repayment, etc.), year xedeffects, lead arranger xed-effects, and industry xed-effects (two-digit SIC code). We restrict our sample to include syndicated loan facilities originated
in the United States and exclude rms with SIC codes between 6000 and 6500. We also restrict our analysis to loan facilities with senior debt rated Ba1,
Ba2, Ba3, B1, B2, and B3. We identify and remove any second-lien or mezzanine facilities from the sample. Standard errors are clustered by year and by
borrowing rm. The symbols ***, **, and * indicate signicance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Dependent var.: All-in-drawn spread
6.872
(1.46)
3.214
(0.24)
32.857nnn
(3.15)
9.372
(1.35)
8.665
(1.15)
0.325nn
(2.38)
1.133nnn
(2.69)
7.133nn
(2.20)
3.828n
(1.75)
2.743
(0.48)
334.458nnn
(6.49)
16.476nnn
(3.00)
0.931
(0.06)
44.273nnn
(3.94)
19.570nnn
(2.98)
3.492
(0.43)
0.212
(1.12)
1.083nnn
(4.96)
0.743
(0.29)
5.024n
(1.74)
10.052
(0.92)
302.778nnn
(4.00)
17.698nn
(2.07)
7.714
(0.80)
21.228n
(1.83)
8.264
(1.04)
12.308
(1.52)
0.660nnn
(5.39)
1.257n
(1.94)
11.715nnn
(3.15)
1.422
(0.47)
13.352
(1.04)
621.844nnn
(9.28)
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
0.386
1613
Yes
Yes
0.482
540
Yes
Yes
0.312
1073
Securitized indicator
Term structure
Credit spread
Covenants indicator
Pricing grid indicator
Size of syndicate
Tranche maturity
Log facility amount
Log sales size
Secured indicator
Constant
342
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
relative to non-securitization-active banks and differences between B-rated facilities and Ba-rated facilities
as reecting the effect of securitization on the cost of
capital.
4.3. Which factors affect the likelihood that a loan is
securitized?
A key assumption in our analysis is that the factors we
posit as being related to the securitization decision
actually do affect the likelihood a particular loan facility
is securitized. To ensure that these assumptions hold in
our sample, we estimate equations predicting whether a
particular loan facility from the Dealscan sample is
securitized according to the Moodys classication. We
estimate the following econometric specication:
PrSecuritizedi,t a0 b Facility typei,t g Borrower f actorsi,t
j Macro f actorst ei,t :
The Facility type variables are dummy variables indicating the type of facility. The equation also includes the
borrower controls used in Table 3, with the exception of
tranche maturity, which is extremely highly correlated
within tranche type.20 Because the dependent variable is
dichotomous, we estimate the equation by probit. We
constrain the sample to include years 20022009, since
loan facilities originated prior to 2002 likely would have
matured prior to 2009, making it impossible for such
facilities to serve as collateral in CLOs as of 2009.21
Table 4 reports estimates of this equation. The results
in column 1 suggest that Term Loan B facilities are more
likely to be securitized than Term Loan A facilities (the
omitted category). The estimated coefcient implies,
holding other factors constant, that Term Loan Bs are 3
percentage points more likely to be securitized than Term
Loan As (the omitted group in the probit estimation).22
Revolvers are securitized at a signicantly lower rate than
either type of Term Loan (unconditionally, with less than
1% frequency). The estimated coefcient on the securitization-active indicator suggests that loan facilities
initiated by the banks we consider to be Securitizationactive are more likely to be securitized than other
facilities. We estimate whether B-rated facilities are
securitized at a different rate than Ba-rated facilities
through the inclusion of a B-rated dummy variable. The
resulting estimates conrm those of Benmelech and
Dlugosz (2009) and are consistent with the unconditional
results presented in Table 1.
In column 2 we include tranche purpose xed-effects,
year xed-effects, and industry xed-effects, and reestimate the model. These controls do not materially change
the inference on securitization likelihood for Term Loan B
20
Revolvers have a very short maturity, while Terms B and A
facilities have longer maturities. Including tranche maturity in the probit
specication is essentially redundant to controlling for facility type
when revolvers are included in the sample.
21
Over 90% of the loan facilities in our sample have an expected
tranche maturity of less than 7 years.
22
Unconditionally, 12.8% of Term Loan Bs are securitized compared
to a 4.3% frequency for Term Loan As.
or securitization-active facilities. However, in this specication we cannot reject the hypothesis that Ba and B
facilities are securitized at the same rate at conventional
signicance levels since the t-statistic drops to 1.44. The tstatistic is sensitive to the choice of clustering standard
errors by borrower; when they are clustered instead by
credit rating, the t-statistic on the B-rated dummy variable rises to 3.20, which is statistically signicant at
conventional levels.
In column 3 we test whether B-rated Term Loan B
facilities are securitized more frequently than their Ba-rated
Term Loan B counterparts. The test requires an interaction
term, the interpretation of which can be problematic when
estimated via probit (see Ai and Norton, 2003), so we
estimate this equation using a linear probability model.23
The coefcient on the interaction of Term Loan Bs with Brated senior debt is 0.018, and is marginally statistically
signicant (t-statistic1.62).24 Since Ba-rated Term Loan Bs
were securitized about 10% of the time according to the
Moodys data (which substantially undercounts the fraction
that were securitized in practice), an estimated 1.8 percentage point increase in securitization likelihood for B-rated
Term Loan Bs relative to Ba-rated Term Loan Bs represents
about an 18% increase in securitization likelihood. Column 3
also tests whether Securitization-active banks securitize
Term Loan B facilities more frequently than Term Loan B
facilities originated by non-securitization-active banks. The
positive estimated interaction term suggests that the effect of
being from a securitization active bank on securitization
likelihood is most pronounced in Term Loan B facilities.
Overall, the results in Table 4, together with the evidence
in Benmelech and Dlugosz (2009), suggest that B-rated loan
facilities are more likely to be securitized than Ba-rated ones,
that facilities from banks designated as Securitizationactive are more likely to be securitized than facilities from
other banks, and that these differences are most pronounced
in Term Loan B facilities.
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
343
Table 4
What type of loans get securitized?
In columns 1 and 2 we estimate a probit model where the dependent variable is equal to one if the loan facility is identied as collateral in a CLO as of 2009, and
zero otherwise. Column 3 employs the same dependent variable but the coefcients are estimated using an OLS linear probability model. Term Loan B is equal to
one if the facility is a Term Loan B facility. Securitization active bank is equal to one if any of the lead arrangers of the loan facility are among the top-ten CLO
underwriters (see Table 2). B-rated senior debt is equal to one if the senior debt associated with the loan facility is rated B1, B2, or B3 at loan origination. Revolver is
equal to one if the loan facility is a revolving facility (Term Loan As serve as the omitted loan facility type). Covenants indicator is equal to one if a facility has
nancial covenants. Pricing grid indicator is equal to one if the spread is adjustable based on accounting performance. Syndicate size is the number of lenders
involved in the lending syndicate. Log facility amount and Log sales size represent the dollar amount of the loan facility and total sales of the borrowing rm,
measured in U.S.$ million. Secured indicator is an indicator equal to one if the loan facility is secured. In various specications, as indicated in the table, we control
for tranche-purpose xed-effects (corporate purposes, LBO, debt repayment, etc.), year xed-effects, and industry xed-effects (two-digit SIC code). We
restrict our sample to include syndicated loan facilities originated in the United States and exclude rms with SIC codes between 6000 and 6500. We also restrict
our analysis to loan facilities with senior debt rated Ba1, Ba2, Ba3, B1, B2, and B3. We identify and remove any second-lien or mezzanine facilities from the sample.
The sample size in column 2 drops slightly because the inclusion of xed effects perfectly predicts outcomes in the left-hand side variable. These observations are
dropped from the estimation. Standard errors are clustered by year. The symbols ***, **, and * indicate signicance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Estimated using probit
0.018n
(1.62)
0.038n
(1.94)
Term Loan B
0.341nnn
(3.128)
0.484nnn
(3.966)
0.030nnn
(2.92)
0.156nn
(1.987)
0.126
(1.440)
0.004
(0.80)
Securitization-active bank
0.218nnn
(2.691)
0.301nnn
(3.387)
0.006
(0.93)
Revolver
0.874nnn
( 7.327)
0.907nnn
( 7.207)
0.065nnn
(8.55)
Covenants indicator
0.069
(0.796)
0.076
(0.910)
0.011nnn
( 2.636)
0.158nnn
(4.096)
0.008
(0.256)
0.522nnn
(5.139)
5.222nnn
( 7.229)
0.300nnn
(3.157)
0.070
(0.771)
0.005
( 1.418)
0.067
(1.553)
0.010
(0.270)
0.452nnn
(4.333)
4.835nnn
( 4.909)
0.036nnn
(3.29)
0.003
(0.17)
0.001n
(1.95)
0.015nnn
(6.79)
0.002
(0.24)
0.037nnn
(5.40)
0.402nnn
(3.92)
No
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
0.201
Yes
No
0.297
Yes
Yes
5101
4755
0.124
5070
344
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
Table 5
Do securitization-friendly Term Loan B facilities have lower spreads?
In this table we estimate an OLS regression of facility attributes and other controls on the all-in-drawn spread of loan facilities originated between 2002
and September 2007. Securitization active bank is equal to one if any of the lead arrangers of the loan facility are among the top-ten CLO underwriters (see
Table 2). B-rated senior debt is equal to one if the senior debt associated with the loan facility is rated B1, B2, or B3 at loan origination. Term structure is
calculated as the difference between the 5-year and 3-month T-bill rate in the month of deal origination. Credit spread is the spread of a 10-year Ba- and
B-rated bond index over the 10-year T-bond rate, respectively. Covenants indicator is equal to one if a facility has nancial covenants. Pricing grid indicator
is equal to one if the spread is adjustable based on accounting performance. Size of syndicate is the number of lenders involved in the lending syndicate.
Tranche maturity is the number of months until the facility matures. Log facility amount and Log sales size represent the dollar amount of the loan facility
and total sales of the borrowing rm, measured in U.S. $ million. Secured indicator is an indicator equal to one if the loan facility is secured. In various
specications, as indicated in the table, we control for credit-rating xed-effects (Ba1, Ba2, Ba3, B1, B2, B3), tranche-purpose xed-effects (corporate
purposes, LBO, debt repayment, etc.), year xed-effects, and industry xed-effects (two-digit SIC code). We restrict our sample to include syndicated
loan facilities originated in the United States and exclude rms with SIC codes between 6000 and 6500. We also restrict our analysis to loan facilities with
senior debt rated Ba1, Ba2, Ba3, B1, B2, and B3. We identify and remove any second-lien or mezzanine facilities from the sample. Standard errors are
clustered by year and by borrowing rm. The symbols ***, **, and * indicate signicance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Dependent var.: All-in-drawn spread
11.473n
(1.65)
11.337
(1.55)
20.924nn
(2.39)
20.918nnn
(2.65)
2.801
(0.34)
36.366nnn
(5.37)
4.870
(0.35)
33.965nnn
(2.90)
11.133
(1.56)
9.730
(1.32)
0.351nn
(2.34)
1.194nnn
(2.92)
8.142nnn
(2.86)
5.272nn
(2.21)
1.863
(0.30)
421.483nnn
(7.20)
5.412
(0.43)
32.985nnn
(3.00)
15.189nn
(1.97)
10.454
(1.24)
0.415nnn
(2.69)
1.294nnn
(3.05)
9.119nnn
(2.91)
4.045
(1.43)
4.697
(0.59)
440.514nnn
(5.56)
5.406
(0.44)
33.239nnn
(3.02)
15.153nn
(2.00)
10.246
(1.22)
0.414nnn
(2.80)
1.280nnn
(3.04)
9.153nnn
(2.93)
4.082
(1.46)
4.784
(0.60)
655.358nnn
(6.68)
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
Yes
Yes
0.372
1613
Yes
Yes
0.343
1613
Yes
Yes
0.344
1613
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
345
346
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
Table 6
Is the securitization-friendly decline in spreads specic to Term Bs only?
In this table we estimate an OLS regression of facility attributes and other controls on the all-in-drawn spread of loan facilities originated between 2002
and September 2007. Term Loan B is equal to one if the facility is a Term Loan B facility. Securitization active bank is equal to one if any of the lead
arrangers of the loan facility are among the top-ten CLO underwriters (see Table 2). B-rated senior debt is equal to one if the senior debt associated with
the loan facility is rated B1, B2, or B3 at loan origination. Term structure is calculated as the difference between the 5-year and 3-month T-bill rate in the
month of deal origination. Credit spread is the spread of a 10-year Ba- and B-rated bond index over the 10-year T-bond rate, respectively. Covenants
indicator is equal to one if a facility has nancial covenants. Pricing grid indicator is equal to one if the spread is adjustable based on accounting
performance. Size of syndicate is the number of lenders involved in the lending syndicate. Tranche maturity is the number of months until the facility
matures. Log facility amount and Log sales size represent the dollar amount of the loan facility and total sales of the borrowing rm, measured in U.S. $
million. Secured indicator is an indicator equal to one if the loan facility is secured. We control for tranche-purpose xed-effects (corporate purposes,
LBO, debt repayment, etc.), year xed-effects, and industry xed-effects (two-digit SIC code). We restrict our sample to include syndicated loan
facilities originated in the United States and exclude rms with SIC codes between 6000 and 6500. We also restrict our analysis to loan facilities with
senior debt rated Ba1, Ba2, Ba3, B1, B2, and B3. We identify and remove any second-lien or mezzanine facilities from the sample. Standard errors are
clustered by year and by borrowing rm. The symbols ***, **, and * indicate signicance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Dependent var.: All-in-drawn spread
30.606nn
(2.03)
20.761nn
(2.27)
17.350
(1.14)
12.008
(0.95)
9.027
(0.44)
40.230nnn
(2.76)
13.681
(0.77)
23.407n
(1.70)
7.571
(1.31)
9.085
(0.92)
7.284n
(1.70)
52.713nnn
(11.41)
14.893nnn
(2.60)
33.749nnn
(4.18)
4.965
(0.40)
34.684nnn
(2.76)
14.973nn
(2.11)
10.560n
(1.65)
0.410nnn
(3.07)
1.252nnn
(3.16)
8.700nnn
(3.22)
4.587
(1.64)
4.440
(0.70)
548.103nnn
(5.12)
7.719
(1.13)
28.180nnn
(4.52)
12.736n
(1.89)
17.318nnn
(3.21)
0.536nnn
(3.91)
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
0.408
1904
Yes
Yes
0.428
4238
20.518nnn
(7.67)
0.246
(0.10)
16.044nnn
(3.41)
538.217nnn
(12.37)
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
25
In the event where a bank loan includes multiple facilities of the
same type, we use the facility with the lowest spread, so as to be
conservative in our estimate of differences in spread. Of the 2,878 deals
in our sample, 52 deals have multiple Term Loan A or Term Loan B
facilities.
347
348
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
Table 7
Within-deal differences in loan spreads: Term Bs vs. Term As.
In this table we estimate an OLS regression of facility attributes and other controls on differences in the all-in-drawn spread of Term Loan B facilities
compared to Term Loan A facilities within the same deal. The sample size of 186 represents the number of deals that have both Term Loan A and Term
Loan B facilities during our 2002September 2007 sample period as well as data on the required control variables. Securitization active bank is equal to
one if any of the lead arrangers of the loan facility are among the top-ten CLO underwriters (see Table 2). B-rated senior debt is equal to one if the senior
debt associated with the loan facility is rated B1, B2, or B3 at loan origination. Term structure is calculated as the difference between the 5-year and 3month T-bill rate in the month of deal origination. Credit spread is the spread of a 10-year Ba- and B-rated bond index over the ten-year T-bond rate,
respectively. Covenants indicator is equal to one if a facility has nancial covenants. Pricing grid indicator and Term A pricing grid indicator are equal to one
if the spread is adjustable based on accounting performance. Size of syndicate is the number of lenders involved in the lending syndicate. Tranche maturity
and Term A maturity represent the number of months until the Term Loan B and Term Loan A facilities mature, respectively. Log facility amount and Term A
facility amount represent the dollar amount ($ million) of the Term B and Term A loan facilities, respectively. Log sales size represents the sales of the
borrowing rm, measured in U.S. $ million. Secured indicator is an indicator equal to one if the loan is secured. We control for tranche-purpose xedeffects (corporate purposes, LBO, debt repayment, etc.), year xed-effects, and industry xed-effects in all specications and credit-rating xedeffects in column 1. We restrict our sample to include syndicated loan facilities originated in the United States and exclude rms with SIC codes between
6000 and 6500. We also restrict our analysis to loan facilities with senior debt rated Ba1, Ba2, Ba3, B1, B2, and B3. We identify and remove any secondlien or mezzanine facilities from the sample. Standard errors are clustered by year and by borrowing rm. The symbols ***, **, and * indicate signicance
at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Dependent var.: Within
deal spread
Securitization-active
banknB-rated sr. debt
Securitization-active bank
7.996
(0.43)
4.146
(0.20)
6.160
(0.40)
47.764nnn
(2.82)
23.347
(0.69)
44.489nnn
(2.83)
0.201
(0.03)
3.371
(0.25)
1.096
(0.04)
5.602
(0.42)
7.710
0.879
(0.21)
0.451
(0.04)
0.589
(0.02)
5.732
(0.42)
6.054
1.296
(0.25)
1.741
(0.13)
3.091
(0.08)
5.220
(0.40)
5.214
(0.39)
0.081
(0.77)
0.649
(0.62)
1.065
(0.92)
1.624
(0.46)
0.178
(0.06)
3.941
(0.41)
3.380
(0.47)
21.431
(0.10)
(0.29)
0.156
(1.22)
0.915
(0.91)
1.245
(1.17)
5.669
(1.19)
0.995
(0.55)
4.741
(0.46)
0.212
(0.03)
82.070
(0.38)
(0.23)
0.099
(0.97)
0.795
(0.89)
1.111
(1.19)
5.170
(0.87)
0.822
(0.84)
4.533
(0.52)
5.637
(0.57)
59.662
(0.29)
Yes
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
0.513
186
Yes
Yes
0.488
186
Yes
Yes
0.502
186
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
349
Table 8
Within-deal differences in loan spreads: Term Bs vs. revolvers.
In this table we estimate an OLS regression of facility attributes and other controls on differences in the all-in-drawn spread of Term Loan B facilities
compared to revolving facilities within the same deal. The sample size of 1,150 represents the number of deals that have both Revolvers and Term Loan B
facilities during our 2002September 2007 sample period as well as data on the required control variables. Securitization active bank is equal to one if any
of the lead arrangers of the loan facility are among the top-ten CLO underwriters (see Table 2). B-rated senior debt is equal to one if the senior debt
associated with the loan facility is rated B1, B2, or B3 at loan origination. Term structure is calculated as the difference between the 5-year and 3-month
T-bill rate in the month of deal origination. Credit spread is the spread of a ten-year Ba- and B-rated bond index over the ten-year T-bond rate,
respectively. Covenants indicator is equal to one if a facility has nancial covenants. Pricing grid indicator and Revolver pricing grid indicator are equal to one
if the spread is adjustable based on accounting performance. Size of syndicate is the number of lenders involved in the lending syndicate. Tranche maturity
and Revolver maturity represent the number of months until the Term Loan B and revolving facilities mature, respectively. Log facility amount and Revolver
facility amount represent the dollar amount ($ million) of the Term B and revolving loan facilities, respectively. Log sales size represents the sales of the
borrowing rm, measured in U.S. $ million. Secured indicator is an indicator equal to one if the loan facility is secured. We control for tranche-purpose
xed-effects (corporate purposes, LBO, debt repayment, etc.), year xed-effects, and industry xed-effects (two-digit SIC code) in all specications
and credit-rating xed-effects in column 1. We restrict our sample to include syndicated loan facilities originated in the United States and exclude rms
with SIC codes between 6000 and 6500. We also restrict our analysis to loan facilities with senior debt rated Ba1, Ba2, Ba3, B1, B2, and B3. We identify
and remove any second-lien or mezzanine facilities from the sample. Standard errors are clustered by year and by borrowing rm. The symbols ***, **,
and * indicate signicance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Dependent var.: Within deal spread
6.887nn
(2.55)
6.798nn
(2.29)
8.014
(1.50)
14.171n
(1.90)
2.971
(0.64)
2.373
(0.47)
3.823
(0.68)
13.278nn
(2.08)
4.358
(0.90)
6.076nn
(2.10)
1.180
(0.34)
0.028
(0.14)
0.115
(0.75)
0.254
(1.46)
9.286nnn
(2.92)
7.627nnn
(3.69)
1.771
(1.51)
2.798
(0.39)
19.993
(0.38)
4.369
(0.79)
12.087n
(1.79)
5.040
(0.99)
6.106nn
(2.06)
3.138
(0.75)
0.030
(0.15)
0.190
(1.14)
0.288
(1.56)
10.289nnn
(2.93)
8.770nnn
(4.46)
1.300
(1.18)
0.990
(0.13)
41.140
(1.08)
4.406
(0.80)
12.084n
(1.76)
4.587
(0.93)
5.991nn
(2.02)
2.624
(0.65)
0.034
(0.17)
0.174
(1.10)
0.282
(1.54)
10.292nnn
(2.94)
8.763nnn
(4.50)
1.326
(1.20)
0.649
(0.09)
27.786
(0.76)
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
0.130
1150
Yes
Yes
0.111
1150
Yes
Yes
0.113
1150
(2009), there are reasons to suspect CLOs have a preference for lower-rated debt, since one reason for their
existence is to arbitrage ratings. Consistent with this argument, Benmelech and Dlugosz (2009) show that CLO
collateral is indeed more highly concentrated in B-rated
350
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
Table 9
Differences in CLO ownership by credit rating.
This table reports data on CLO ownership of securitized Term Loan B facilities. A portion of the same loan facility can be owned by multiple CLOs. Panel
A reports the sum total of CLO ownership as a percent of the total loan facility, sorted by Moodys senior debt credit rating at the time of loan origination.
Panel B reports the average CLO ownership percentage in a given facility across all CLOs by credit rating. The upper portion of Panel C calculates the
difference in total CLO ownership percentages between facilities with B-rated senior debt and facilities with Ba-rated senior debt. The lower portion of
Panel C calculates the difference in total CLO ownership percentages between facilities with B2- and B3-rated senior debt compared to Ba1- and Ba2rated senior debt. The upper portion of Panel D calculates the difference in average ownership percentages between facilities with B-rated senior debt
compared to facilities with Ba-rated senior debt. The lower portion of Panel D calculates the difference in average ownership percentages between
facilities with B2- and B3-rated senior debt compared to facilities with Ba1- and Ba2-rated senior debt. The ownership percentages reported in Moodys
EMS database are as of the rst quarter 2009.
Panel A: Total CLO ownership % of Term Loan Bs
Moodys senior
debt rating
Mean
Std.
dev.
Ba1
Ba2
Ba3
B1
B2
B3
10
24
52
93
61
28
3.08%
9.94%
17.34%
14.21%
15.49%
15.83%
6.98%
11.88%
23.01%
20.74%
20.35%
26.93%
Mean
N
Mean
N
Diff.
t-Stat.
14.89%
182
13.62%
86
1.27%
(0.48)
Diff.
t-Stat.
7.67%
(2.52)
15.59%
89
7.92%
34
Mean
Std.
dev
10
25
53
95
63
28
0.29%
0.53%
0.63%
0.99%
0.80%
0.50%
0.22%
0.73%
1.02%
2.28%
0.98%
0.48%
744.4
717.2
654.9
402.1
563.4
766.4
B1, B2, B3
rated
Ba1
Ba2
Ba3
B1
B2
B3
Mean
N
B1, B2, B3
rated
Diff.
t-Stat.
0.85%
186
0.56%
88
0.29%
(1.84)
Diff.
t-Stat.
0.25%
(1.76)
0.71%
91
0.46%
35
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
351
overall institutional demand is one such potential variable, the concentration of spread differences in B-rated
rather than Ba-rated debt suggests that securitization
plays an important role.
The results in this paper raise a number of questions as
well. For example, what was the cause of increased
demand for securitized debt? In this paper, we take
increased CLO activity as given, yet we know little about
the ultimate drivers of nal demand for bonds collateralized by corporate debt. Second, does the securitization
process, with its complicated cash-ow rules and multiple
market participants, lead to information destruction
resulting in lenders not charging spreads commensurate
with risks? Fundamentally, the question posed by the
theoretical literature on securitization remains, namely,
how does the restructuring of cash ows from a pool of
assets into a securitization structure create real value?
Finally, while we do provide evidence that the advent of
CLOs led to cheaper capital for corporate borrowers, we
do not provide evidence suggesting that CLOs led to
inefcient lending outcomes. Whether demand from CLOs
caused banks to lend too much, or whether cheaper, CLOfueled capital led to overinvestment in the real economy,
remain important and unanswered questions.
References
Ai, C., Norton, E., 2003. Interaction terms in logit and probit models.
Economic Letters 80, 123129.
Angrist, J., Pischke, J., 2009. Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An Empiricists Companion. University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Axelson, U., Jenkinson, T., Stromberg, P., Weisbach, M., 2011. Borrow
cheap, buy high? The determinants of leverage and pricing
in buyouts. Unpublished. London School of Economics, University
of Oxford, Stockholm School of Economics, and Ohio State
University.
Benmelech, E., Dlugosz, J., 2009. The alchemy of CDO credit ratings.
Journal of Monetary Economics, Carnegie-Rochester Conference
Volume 56, 617634.
Benmelech, E., Dlugosz, J., Ivashina, V., Securitization without adverse
selection: the case of CLOs. Journal of Financial Economics,
forthcoming.
Coval, J., Jurek, J., Stafford, E., 2009. The economics of structured nance.
Journal of Economic Perspectives 23, 325.
DellAriccia, G., Igan, D., Laeven, L., 2008. Credit booms and lending
standards: evidence from the subprime mortgage market. IMF
unpublished.
DeMarzo, P., 2005. The pooling and tranching of securities: a model of
informed intermediation. Review of Financial Studies 18, 135.
Demyanyk, Y., Van Hemert, O., 2011. Understanding the subprime
mortgage crisis. Review of Financial Studies 24, 18481880.
Gaur, V., Seshadri, S., Subrahmanyam, M., 2011. Securitization and real
investment in incomplete markets. Management Science 57,
21802196.
Gennaioli, N., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., Neglected risks, nancial innovation
and nancial fragility. Journal of Financial Economics, http://dx.doi.
org/10.1016/j.jneco.2011.05.005, in press.
Guner, B., 2006. Loan sales and the cost of corporate borrowing. Review
of Financial Studies 19, 687715.
Ivashina, V., 2009. Asymmetric information effects on loan spreads.
Journal of Financial Economics 92, 300319.
Ivashina, V., Sun, Z., 2011. Institutional demand pressure and the cost of
corporate loans. Journal of Financial Economics 99, 500522.
Kara, A., Marques-Ibanez, D., Ongena, S., 2011. Securitization and lending
standards: evidence from the wholesale loan market. Unpublished,
Loughborough University, European Central Bank, and Tilburg
University.
Keys, B., Mukherjee, T., Seru, A., Vig, V., 2010. Did securitization screening lead to lax? Evidence from subprime loans. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 125, 307362.
352
T.D. Nadauld, M.S. Weisbach / Journal of Financial Economics 105 (2012) 332352
Loutskina, E., Strahan, P., 2009. Securitization and the declining impact
of bank nancial condition on loan supply: evidence from mortgage
originations. Journal of Finance 64, 861922.
Mian, A., Su, A., 2009. The consequences of mortgage credit expansion:
evidence from the U.S. mortgage default crisis. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 124, 14491496.
Nadauld, T., Sherlund, S., The impact of securitization on the expansion
of subprime credit. Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming.
Nini, G., 2008. How non-banks increased the supply of bank loans: evidence
from institutional term loans. Unpublished, Wharton Business School.
Shivdasani, A., Wang, Y., 2011. Did structured credit fuel the LBO boom?
Journal of Finance 66, 12911328.
Standard & Poors, 2007. A Guide to the Loan Market. Standard & Poors,
New York.
Su, A., 2007. Information asymmetry and nancing arrangements:
evidence from syndicated loans. Journal of Finance 62, 629668.