Chapter 8
Chapter 8
Chapter 8
John Bryant
Third Edition
Electronic Version Chapter 8
2012
Contents
Preface
1
Introduction
1.1 Historical Research
1.2 Economics and the Ideal Gas
1
2
6
17
19
31
34
40
46
48
Thermodynamic Principles
3.1 First Law of Thermodynamics
3.2 Second Law of Thermodynamics
3.3 Constant Volume Process
3.4 Constant Price Process
3.5 Iso-trading Process
3.6 Polytropic Process
3.7 Isentropic Process
3.8 Process Entropy
3.9 Thermodynamics & Utility
50
50
59
63
67
69
71
74
76
81
88
89
104
108
113
Money
5.1 Development & Elasticity
5.2 Money Entropy
5.3 Money Entropy & Interest Rates
118
121
133
140
151
160
161
164
165
178
178
180
182
183
191
193
198
200
210
References
215
Data Sources
221
List of Symbols
222
Index
223
Preface
This book, first published in 2009, stems from research that I began more
than three decades ago when I was then working as group economist for the
Babcock International Group. Prior to that, my formal university education
had included degrees in engineering and management science the latter in
particular covering economics and operations research. What started out as
a train of curiosity into parallels between the disciplines of economics and
thermodynamics soon developed into something deeper.
Following publication of two peer-reviewed papers of mine on the subject
in the journal Energy Economics, I was greatly encouraged in my research
by other trans-disciplinary researchers with a similar interest, in particular,
Dr Lszl Kapolyi, who was then Minister for Industry of the Hungarian
government, a member of the Hungarian Academy of Science and a
member of the Club of Rome.
Not being based at a university and with no research grant at my disposal,
my main thrust at that time had been to make a career as director of a
consultancy and expert witness business and therefore, until more recently,
opportunities to spend time on research had been few. Nevertheless, by the
turn of the millennium I was able to find time alongside my consultancy to
return to some research, and in 2007 published another peer-reviewed paper
in the International Journal of Exergy entitled A Thermodynamic Theory
of Economics, which was followed up with several working papers on
monetary aspects and energy models. Interest in this work has been high,
spurred on no doubt by general worldwide interest in energy and climate
change.
This book and third edition is an attempt to bring together all the facets of
the research into a coherent whole. Topics covered include the gas laws, the
distribution of income, the 1st and 2nd Laws of Thermodynamics applied to
economics, economic processes and elasticity, entropy and utility,
production and consumption processes, reaction kinetics, empirical
monetary analysis of the UK and USA economies, interest rates, discounted
cash flow, bond yield and spread, unemployment, principles of entropy
maximization and economic development, the cycle, empirical analysis of
the relationship between world energy resources, climate change and
economic output, and last aspects of sustainability.
Further developments have been added since the first and second editions,
in particular, thoughts on production and entropy maximisation, order and
disorder and relationships to the living world, which has necessitated reorganisation of some of the chapters. The chapter on money has been
updated to incorporate empirical analyses of the recent upheavals in world
economic activity from 2008 to 2011, though the conclusions reached have
not changed, indeed, they have been reinforced.
The findings, interpretations and conclusions of this book are entirely those
of my own, based on the research that I have conducted. While I have made
every effort to be diligent and accurate, readers should satisfy themselves as
to logic and veracity of the conclusions drawn. I hope that this third edition
represents an improvement and advancement on earlier editions, but would
welcome nevertheless any feedback, discussions and corrections on points
that readers may have.
I am indebted to my wife Alison for all her support and for providing an
atmosphere conducive to my research.
John Bryant
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
CHAPTER 8
8.1
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
Figure 8.1 Primary Energy Consumption per Capita versus GDP per Capita 1980 2009
(PPP 2000 levels) Russia 1992 onwards
Source: OECD, Penn World, BP
Figure 8.2 Electricity Generation per Capita versus GDP per Capita 1980 2009
(PPP 2000 levels) Russia 1992 onwards
Source: OECD, Penn World, EIA
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
8.2
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
Table 8.1 US Current-cost Net Stock Fixed Assets & Consumer Durables
(www.bea.gov Fixed asset tables 3 and 11b)
$bn 2007
Equipment & Software
Computers/Software
Communications
Medical Equipment
Office Equipment
Engines Turbines
Electrical transmission
Industrial M/c
Trucks/buses
Autos
Aircraft, airborne equipment
Ships, boats
Railroad equipment
Agricultural M/c
Construction M/c
Mining/Oilfield Equipt
Other
Sub-total
Structures
Residential
Offices
Commercial
Hospitals
Manufacturing
Power
Communication
Petroleum/Nat Gas
Mining
Railroads
Farms
Highways/Streets
Military
Transportation
Educational
Sewers & Water
Other
Sub-total
Consumer Durables
Autos
Trucks
Videos/Computers TV
Appliances
Other
Sub-total
Total Assets
Private
Government
Total
$623.5
$555.4
$269.2
$188.3
$83.5
$358.4
$1,041.0
$794.8
$141.4
$296.5
$65.4
$101.5
$147.0
$149.8
$49.5
$470.8
$5,336.0
$46.4
$669.9
$555.4
$269.2
$188.3
$83.5
$358.4
$1,041.0
$818.9
$141.4
$456.5
$207.7
$101.5
$147.0
$149.8
$49.5
$995.0
$6,233.0
1.4
1.2
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.8
2.2
1.8
0.3
1.0
0.4
0.2
0.3
0.3
0.1
2.1
13.4
$2,634.1
$391.4
$532.4
$1,608.6
$912.0
$716.4
$8,313.9
$18,142.8
$2,247.9
$1,868.1
$931.9
$1,242.8
$1,472.0
$485.8
$832.6
$57.2
$298.7
$307.8
$2,634.1
$391.4
$532.4
$1,971.2
$912.0
$2,030.3
$36,359.0
38.9
4.8
4.0
2.0
2.7
3.2
1.0
1.8
0.1
0.6
0.7
5.7
0.8
1.1
4.2
2.0
4.4
78.0
$9,210.9
$573.1
$759.0
$793.5
$204.2
$1,695.7
$4,025.5
$46,617.5
1.2
1.6
1.7
0.4
3.6
8.6
100.0
$17,819.1
$1,620.8
$1,834.1
$706.0
$1,175.9
$1,230.6
$485.8
$832.6
$57.2
$298.7
$307.8
$362.6
$1,313.9
$28,045.1
$573.1
$759.0
$793.5
$204.2
$1,695.7
$4,025.5
$37,406.6
$24.1
$160.0
$142.3
$524.2
$897.0
$323.7
$627.1
$34.0
$225.9
$66.9
$241.4
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
8.3
Economic Output
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
Figure 8.3 Crude Oil prices Source BP Statistical Review 2010, IndexMundi, Bloomberg,
OECD.
The impact of this is to occasion first a rise in oil prices, as in figure 8.3,
and then a drop, as demand turns down to meet the available output. It
cannot be imagined that the wage earners of exporting entities engaged in
the production of oil had suddenly acquired a much larger real impact via
their input of productive content; more likely that productive capacity at
that time was constrained, compared to demand, creating an economic
entropy loss and a shortage of energy product to the international market.
The net effect of a change to output value of a factor such as energy is
reflected in its interaction with all the other factors that make up GDP. We
are not saying that output values of non-human energy factors alone
determine economic activity; clearly human and other factors matter too,
but we are saying that energy consumption now constitutes a significant
input to the economic process as it is currently constructed.
8.4
Non-Renewable Energy
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
GDP in the short to medium term horizon, though with some decline in
energy intensity.
Figure 8.4 is a diagrammatic representation of a non-renewable resource,
such as oil, gas and coal, similar in construction to the Logistic curves set
out at figure 4.7 in chapter 4, and described by equations (4.30) and (4.31).
Reserve Curve
Ultimate Gross
Discoverable
Reserves
Cumulative
Proven
Discoveries
Initial Proven
Discoveries
Net
reserves
Cumulative
Production
Time
Production Curve
Extension of
Reserves
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
Figure 8.5 World Oil and Natural Gas Discoveries & Production % p.a. / Net Reserves
Data source: BP Statistical Review 2000 2011
There is much debate about when world peak oil, peak gas and peak
coal may occur, depending upon views held on the ultimate level of proven
usable reserves, where the level of exergy to be abstracted is greater than
that put in to develop such reserves.
Figures 8.6 and 8.7 set out charts of world cumulative production and
official net proven reserves for both oil and natural gas. Cumulative world
oil production as a proportion of official net proven reserves remaining (not
including tar sands) continues to rise, and is approaching a 1:1 ratio,
indicating perhaps that production is nearing the peak illustrated at figure
8.4.
10
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
11
12
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
debate as to when production, and thereby consumption of oil and gas, may
peak and begin to decline.
World Oil Production & Consum ption
100000
75000
50000
Production
25000
Consumption
0
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
2010
2020
2030
Figure 8.8 World Oil and Natural Gas Production and Consumption Source: BP
Of course, if new proven reserves of oil and/or natural gas are found, of
sufficient economically extractable volume to increase significantly the
ratio of net reserves to cumulative production (depletion), or real
improvements are obtained for recovery factors applied to oil in place, or
a severe recession occurs to reduce demand for energy, then peak
production may be put off further, or production may flatten off at a higher
level for a period. On the other hand, if some reserve estimates are
subsequently brought down, in particular those of OPEC referred to earlier,
then the depletion curve would be brought forward. On the assumption,
however, that a peak will eventually be reached, it might be expected that
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
13
14
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
8.5
Climate change apart, making the assumption that in due course some nonrenewable resources are eventually rendered inert through irrevocable
consumption, the principle of maximisation of entropy gain, set out in
chapter 4, is then invoked. Humankind, having gone along one branch of
the stream to discover a potential dead-end, will gradually seek other
avenues to advance its cause, by turning to alternative sources of energy.
Nevertheless, there may still be some gains to be made from improving
efficiency, thereby increasing the net exergy of conventional non-renewable
energy sources delivered to economic output (subject to limits set by the
Laws of Thermodynamics), and compared to the reductions in energy
intensity achieved over the last 40 years (see figure 8.1); for example, by
ground transport increasingly switching to electric energy, entailing changes
to the capital stock.
Further large improvements and maintenance of positive economic entropy
gain will likely only be achieved by finding substitutes for conventional
energy resources, such as nuclear power, and renewable sources such as
solar, wind and hydro generated electricity. Potentially, however, these
may involve higher economic costs, and therefore lower potential net
volume benefit to economic output. Wind power will also require stand-by
power plant when wind force is low.
Nuclear power, although having low operating costs, entails high capital
costs, and high waste and decommissioning costs, with waste potentially
accumulating much beyond many generations of humankind. Nuclear
capacity carries with it also some risks of safety, though these can be
controlled. Figure 8.10 summarises world electricity consumption from
nuclear power up to 2010. After the rise of the 70s and 80s, output growth
began to slow down and has been largely flat since about 2004.
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
15
Source: BP
Major countries that now have a high percentage of installed nuclear power
capacity include France (78%), Belgium (55%), Sweden (52%) and Ukraine
(51%) with a number of other European countries above 30%. The top five
capacities in 2001 were USA (102,000 MWe), France (62,000 MWe), Japan
(46,000 MWe), Russia (22,000 MWe) and Germany (22,000 MWe)
[Source: EIA/IAEA].
Figure 8.11 confirms that the nuclear industry has lost share to other forms
of electricity generation since the early 1990s.
15
10
0
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
Source: EIA
2010
16
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
Accepting that an ultimate limit on fossil resources may exist, then the
alternatives to energy substitution are either a quantum shift in consumers
attitudes towards energy use, removing a part from GDP and permanently
altering the mix of output, or a long-term levelling or decline in GDP,
which may lead to a reduction in GDP per capita, unless population also
declined in proportion.
8.6
Thermo-economic Considerations
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
17
Dealing with the path of economic entropy potential to develop and deplete
a limited reserve, from equations (4.30) and (4.31) at chapter 4, the standard
model for a non-renewable resource is that of the Verhulst equation, and
output volume V from a reserve could be stated as being equal to a function
of the change in accumulated production N per unit of time:
dN
V = f = Rb(1 b )
dt
(8.1)
N (t ) =
N0
N 0
t
t
R 1 e + e
(8.2)
B = Rb
(8.3)
V = (1 b )B
or
V
= (1 b )
B
(8.4)
dV dB
db
=
V
B (1 b)
(8.5)
18
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
dV dB kdb
=
dsdepletion = k
B (1 b )
V
(8.6)
Figure 8.13 Loci of cumulative resource depletion: Resource constraint B, output volume flow
V, rate of growth of output value flow V/V, rate of growth of resource constraint B/B and
unit economic depletion entropy change s.
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
19
(8.7)
(8.8)
20
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
dx
= x xy
dt
and
dy
= xy y
dt
(8.9)
In the model the prey is assumed to have an unlimited food supply, and to
reproduce exponentially at the rate of , unless consumed by predators,
represented by a function of the contact xy between predator and prey.
Likewise growth in predators is governed by a function of the contact xy
between predator and prey, and the death rate of the predators.
We will not develop further the mathematics here, since this is involved.
Essentially, however, predators are dependent upon their harvest of prey,
and prey are dependent on the sun, nature and the eco-system to reproduce
themselves. If the predators have a high consumption rate of prey (in the
case of humankind utilising also capital stock, energy and technology) such
that the prey is gradually reduced, the sources on which the predators
depend upon reduces, and the predators face a decline in population. The
most obvious examples of this effect are over-fishing, over-farming of
arable land and deforestation. Using up resources (many environmentalists
might say squandering in an unsustainable way) entails a potential
degradation of the earths resources in the short-term ecological timescale.
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
21
In respect of renewable energy sources such as wind and solar power, the
effective stock x is very small, with a high throughput. Thus energy
generated is almost immediately transmitted to become electricity
consumption by humankind.
Neither wind nor solar power is guaranteed in intensity, however, the first
because of the variable, on-off speed of wind, and the second because of
potential cloud coverage and night periods restricting hours of availability.
However, siting solar power collectors in areas such as the Sahara desert
might in part get around the latter [Mackay (2008)] to provide significant
amounts of more continuous electrical energy. Methods of storing power
could include, at appropriate times, the use of smart chargers connected to
batteries of electric cars directed to download power, and pumped water
storage in hilly areas to convert potential energy into electrical power.
8.7
Population
22
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
dN
N
= rN 1
dt
R
(8.10)
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
23
Figure 8.14 Population growth rates in selected countries and the world - percent per annum
Source: UN
8.8
Climate Change
24
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
system. Whereas, from the earlier resource analysis, any limits in oil, gas
and coal reserves will ultimately automatically feed back into reduced
fossil-fuel energy consumption, no such automatic feedback is likely with
regard to achieving the required reduction in emissions. Instead, action to
avert a rise in global air temperature is dependent upon agreement and cooperation among the international community. It is possible that such action
might also be of an iterative, delayed kind, in response to accumulating
environmental disasters, rather too late according to IPCC.
Actions by governments on behalf of the populace aimed at choosing a path
which maximises potential entropy gain will therefore meet a constraint
operating on two fronts.
First, if fossil-fuel burning is reduced, this will impact on the volume level
of the GDP that is dependent upon this source of value generation a large
slice of the economic structure of the developed world. Follow-on to this
policy is a change in direction of potential entropy maximisation, first
towards other sources of energy not involving CO2 production, and second
by endeavouring to render fossil sources harmless (though the latter does
not avert consumption of non-renewable sources). Both actions will involve
significant additional, non-recoverable costs, which will add to the climate
change constraint, resulting in a loss of economic entropic driving force.
We could write
dV dZ CC
ds = k
Z CC
V
(8.11)
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
25
Approximately 55% of world CO2 emissions increases arise from fossil fuel
use, and the rest from deforestation, agriculture and other areas (IPCC SPM
1). Table 8.2 and figure 8.15 illustrate the structure and trends in CO2
emissions (relating to consumption and flaring of fossil fuels), GDP and
population.
In 2006, the top five countries, USA, China, Russia (all high consumers of
coal) plus India and Japan accounted for nearly 55% of global CO2 output
from consumption and flaring of fossil fuels. World emission intensity
(CO2/GDP) at 2006 stood at 0.486Kg/$ of output, a 1% reduction on the
figure for 2000, and a 44% reduction on the figure for 1980. World GDP, of
course, had been marching onwards in that period, with a resultant
significant increase in CO2 production from fossil fuels, from 18,333 mn
tonnes in 1980 to 28,003 mn tonnes in 2006. The world recession in 2008
likely has temporarily slowed this trend.
Figure 8.15 shows that, with the exception of France, which has significant
nuclear input to electricity generation, most countries show only a small
drop in carbon intensity. The levels for China and Japan have recently been
rising, the former on a base of coal-fired power. Over the 20-year period to
2000 the world ratio has declined by less than 0.4% per annum. Policies to
reduce this ratio include nuclear and renewable power, coupled with electric
drive technology. While reduction in emissions ratios will assist in reducing
mans impact on climate change, the other strategy is to reduce both per
capita energy consumption and energy intensity/GDP, the trends of which
are shown in figure 8.1. Here reduction has been more successful, with
world energy intensity declining by about 2.4% per annum. Offset against
this has been a rise in population of nearly 1.6% per annum.
Carbon
Intensity
CO2/PEC
ratio
2.4548
2.9840
2.3472
2.2087
2.2987
2.3625
1.9976
2.3211
2.1991
2.4327
1.3844
3.2208
2.3461
2.2665
1.4832
2.2290
2.3853
2.5618
CO2 Output
mn toe pa
5696.8
5606.5
1587.2
1249.7
1212.7
823.5
538.8
536.5
476.1
448.0
377.5
394.5
416.3
327.7
332.4
7978.9
28003.0
23850.0
USA
China
Russia
India
Japan
Germany
Canada
UK
South Korea
Italy
France
Australia
Mexico
Spain
Brazil
Rest of World
World 2006
World 2000
Country
Table 8.2 CO2 Output, Primary Energy Consumption, GDP and Population 2006
9310.0
11740.0
3579.5
224.1
144.6
177.4
122.5
272.7
184.2
216.5
231.1
269.7
348.6
527.6
565.8
676.2
1878.8
2320.7
mn toe pa
Primary
Energy
Consumption
0.1916
0.2039
0.2312
0.1518
0.1382
0.1722
0.1938
0.1609
0.1200
0.2135
0.1322
0.2652
0.1546
0.1491
0.1541
0.4589
0.2163
0.2060
Kgoe/$
Energy
Intensity
Energy/GDP
$48,600
$57,564
$15,482
$1,477
$1,046
$1,030
$632
$1,695
$1,535
$1,014
$1,749
$1,017
$2,255
$3,538
$3,671
$1,474
$8,685
$11,265
bn $ pa
GDP PPP *
6080.0
6536.0
2839.5
189.3
44.1
104.8
20.7
63.2
58.9
48.3
60.5
32.6
82.4
127.8
1109.8
142.5
1311.8
299.8
mn
Population
$7,993
$8,807
$5,452
$7,800
$23,731
$9,838
$30,469
$26,819
$26,078
$20,992
$28,888
$31,178
$27,373
$27,694
$3,308
$10,340
$6,621
$37,572
$ pa
GDP/Hd
1.531
1.796
1.261
1.184
3.280
1.694
5.905
4.314
3.129
4.482
3.818
8.269
4.232
4.129
0.510
4.745
1.432
7.740
toe pa
PEC/Hd
0.4907
0.4865
0.5154
0.2251
0.3133
0.4039
0.6242
0.2227
0.2919
0.4696
0.3068
0.5298
0.3652
0.3428
0.3404
1.0771
0.6455
0.5057
Kg/$
Emission
Intensity
CO2/GDP
26
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
27
0
1980
China
Japan
India
UK
France
Russia
World
USA
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
Figure 8.15 Carbon Intensity - ratio CO2 emissions from consumption & flaring of fossil fuels /
primary energy consumption (tonnes CO2 / tonnes oil equivalent) 1980 2004.Sources: EIA,
BP
The fourth assessment report of the IPCC sets out a range of scenarios of
CO2 emission reductions for increasing levels of global temperature and sea
levels. Non of the scenarios includes for a rise in temperature of less than
2C, and it is to be assumed that IPCC regard some rise in temperature as
unavoidable. The strategy that achieves the lowest estimated increase in
temperature and sea levels is the one that requires the greatest reduction in
CO2 emissions. It is inevitable that some countries may be more committed
than others, and some may feel that their input should be less than others by
virtue of history and their relative economic development. Table 8.3
abstracts data from the IPCC table:
Table 8.3 IPCC Stabilisation Scenarios
Stabilisation
Scenarios
Global Average
Temperature Increase
above pre-industrial at
equilibrium
Metres
-85 to -50
2.0 2.4
0.4 1.4
II
-60 to -30
2.4 2.8
0.5 1.7
III
-30 to +5
2.8 3.2
0.6 1.9
IV
+10 to +60
3.2 4.0
0.6 2.4
+25 to +85
4.0 4.9
0.8 2.9
VI
+90 to +140
4.9 6.1
1.0 3.7
28
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
IPCC set out a number of areas of CO2 mitigation, including energy (electric
and non-electric) transportation, buildings, industry, agriculture, forest and
waste management, along with cost estimates of strategies to meet potential
savings (as a percent of GDP), which rise, the greater is the reduction in
emissions to be achieved.
Temperature rises at scenarios III and upwards are likely unacceptable in
terms of their impact on the environment.
It is intuitive to work back from a particular scenario to see the implications
of a reduction in emissions. For example, in Scenario I a reduction of 85%
in emissions against 2000 levels would imply (from table 8.2) world
emissions in 2050 of 23,850 - 85% = 3,577.5 mn tonnes CO2 (assuming that
fossil emissions are in proportion to other emissions). Working back further,
if no improvements in emissions intensity were achieved over 2000, this
would imply, from the last column table 8.2, a level of world GDP of only
3,577/0.4907 = $7,290bn (compared to $48,600bn in 2000). Working back
still further, if it is assumed that population grows to 9bn by 2050, then the
level of world GDP per capita at 2050 would be $7,290/9 = $810 per capita,
only 10% of the world level of $7,993 in 2000.
Clearly the above hypothetical example is somewhat unlikely; in particular,
that reductions in the intensity ratios of both emissions and energy to GDP
are taking place, as noted earlier. These may continue to improve, if actions
are taken by member states of the global economy to invest in relevant
capital stock and technologies to mitigate climate change. Rises in
population size will, however, dilute significantly the level of GDP per
capita.
Table 8.4 sets out a hypothetical example of progression from 1980 to 2050,
assuming that world CO2 output declined by 2.4% per annum from 2002
onwards to reach a level of 7,155 Gt pa, a reduction of 70%, not far from
the IPCC maximum reduction of 85% set out at table 8.3. In passing it
should be noted that table 8.2 shows that the carbon level rose 17.4% from
2000 to 2006. Thus already the world is behind on this projection. The other
key assumptions made in table 8.4 are that carbon intensity reduces by 0.5%
pa and energy intensity reduces by 2.0% pa, on a base of some continuation
of efficiency improvements and some changes in habit. Last, it is assumed
that world population continues to grow to reach a level of 9bn by 2050, in
line with US Census Bureau projections. The calculations in the table are
carried out in reverse, that is, from carbon target to primary energy
consumption, then to GDP and last to GDP per capita.
18333.3
21426.1
23850.0
18700.0
14660.0
11490.0
9010.0
7155.0
1990
2000
2010
2020
2030
2040
2050
4311.0
3614.0
1.9800
5247.0
6346.0
7695.0
9310.0
8131.6
6641.9
mn toe pa
Primary
Energy
Consumption
2.0900
2.1900
2.3100
2.4300
2.5618
2.6349
2.7602
ratio
mn toe pa
1980
Carbon
Intensity
CO2/PEC
CO2 Output
0.0697
0.0853
0.1045
0.1279
0.1565
0.1916
0.2638
0.3122
Kgoe/$
Energy
Intensity
Energy/GDP
$51,823.0
$50,510.0
$50,222.0
$49,632.0
$49,170.0
$48,600.0
$30,820.3
$21,272.1
bn $ pa
GDP PPP
(2000)
9000.0
8600.0
8100.0
7500.0
6800.0
6080.0
5280.5
4451.0
mn
Population
$5,758
$5,873
$6,200
$6,618
$7,231
$7,993
$5,837
$4,779
$ pa
GDP/Hd
0.402
0.501
0.648
0.846
1.132
1.531
1.540
1.492
toe pa
PEC/Hd
0.1381
0.1784
0.2288
0.2954
0.3803
0.4907
0.6952
0.8618
Kg/$
Emission
Intensity
CO2/GDP
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
29
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
30
It can be seen that world GDP per capita projected on this basis is likely to
stagnate to 2050 if the world adheres to the emission targets recommended
by IPCC. The actuality in between 2000 and 2050 is likely to be a good deal
different to the projection above, taking into account same as usual trends,
delayed action to implement policies, non-adherence and the paths of
individual countries. Some countries, in particular, Russia, China, Australia,
Canada and USA have very high emissions intensity ratios (CO2/GDP) to
contend with. It is quite possible that reductions of emissions to low levels
may not be achievable.
The overall emission intensity reduction from 2000 (the base level assumed
by IPCC) to 2050 in the above example is from 0.4907 down to 0.1381,
equivalent to a reduction of 71.8%. This figure is diluted in terms of GDP
per capita, however, by an increase in world population of 48%. If
population had remained level, GDP per capita would have risen.
A means of illustrating the impact on GDP per capita of varying emissions
intensity across the range of emission change requirements stated by IPCC
to 2050 is set out at figure 8.16.
6
2.8% pa
2.2% pa
Emission
intensity and
population
factor 2050
compared to
2000
1.0
0.8
1.4% pa
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.% pa
1
-100%
-75%
I
-50%
II
-25%
III
0
0%
25%
50%
IV
75%
100%
125%
VI
Figure 8.16 World GDP per capita as a function of Global Carbon Emissions Change
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
31
The range of IPCC stabilisation scenarios from table 8.3 is placed along the
X-axis of the chart, with areas progressively shaded according to the
increase in emissions and expected increases in global temperatures and sea
levels. For low temperature rises only category I and perhaps II are viable,
limiting policy consideration only to the left-hand part of the chart. An
index of world GDP per capita is placed along the Y-axis, with the index of
GDP per capita at year 2000 ($7,993 PPP constant prices) set at 1. While
the author would no longer support projections of exponential growth, some
approximate equivalents are set out for each index level to help readers.
Thus, for example, an index of 5 in 2050, compared to 1 in 2000, would
represent growth of 3.3% pa over 50 years between 2000 and 2050. As
noted earlier, the position has deteriorated since 2000 with emissions at
2006 up by 17%, and population increased by 7.5%. Thus the world
economy is currently marching towards the north-east part of the chart.
Splayed out across the chart is a range of world emission and population
intensity factors, where 1 represents the position in year 2000. Table 8.4
shows this to be an emission intensity of 0.4907 combined with a
population of 6.08bn. At the upper end a factor of 0.2, for example, might
represent a combination of an increased population to 9bn combined with a
reduction in emission intensity from 0.4907 in 2000 down to 0.0663 in
2050, the latter about half the level of 0.1381 given in the example at table
8.4.
It is a matter of evidence as to how far down emissions intensity can be
driven. Clearly if all countries emulated France in its nuclear programme,
undertook extensive electricity programmes in renewable sources, and
switched road transport into electrically driven mode, then some advances
beyond the thermodynamic limits of fossil-fired energy might be possible.
Over a 40-year period changes to consumer habits might also be engineered,
particularly if faced with unpalatable energy costs and loss of living
standards. A drop in population projection below 9bn would also help. The
alternative is for world humanity to settle for a high temperature rise. This
entails very high global risks and a significant, irrevocable effect on the
eco-system and life; and with the potential for a large reduction in levels of
economic and social activity.
The above analysis adds weight to the conclusions concerning energy
resources that the next few decades will likely follow a different path than
one based on projecting GDP on an escalating, exponential basis. No
account has been taken in this chapter of other factors, such as agriculture,
fishing, water, and the move to an urban rather than a rural life. The latter
32
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
factors will on the balance of probability likely add further weight to the
analysis. There is likely to be a significant shift to the left in equation (4.3)
of this book. Thus no single reaction kinetic, as set out at chapter 4, is likely
to describe the forward path. The particular path that world economic
development will follow is likely to be quite complex, given the interactions
of the many parties, factors and systems involved, and that currently the
world is still proceeding in the opposite direction to the recommendations of
IPCC.
In 1972 a systems approach was attempted by Meadows (1972) for the Club
of Rome, spawning a book The Limits to Growth, echoing perhaps
concerns of Malthus [Malthus, T. R. (1798)]. Limits to Growth subsequently
lost interest as economic development proceeded apace. It has recently been
reviewed however by Turner [Turner, G. (2008)] who concluded that 30
years of historical data compared favourably with the business-as-usual
standard run scenario of Limits to Growth, but did not compare
favourably with other scenarios involving comprehensive use of technology
or stabilizing behaviour and policies.
To summarise, climate change places a potential constraint on the forward
path of output, in line with the thermo-economic thesis put forward in this
book.
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
33
REFERENCES
Anderson, N. Sleath, J. (1999) 'New estimates of the UK real and nominal
yield curves', Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, November 1999.
Annila, A. Salthe, S. (2009) Economies evolve by energy dispersal,
Entropy, 11, pp.606-633.
Ayres, R. U. van den Bergh, C. J. M. Gowdy, J. M. (1998) Viewpoint:
Weak versus strong sustainability 98-103/3, Tinbergen Institute
Discussion Papers.
Ayres, R. U. Warr, B. Accounting for growth: The role of physical work'.
Centre for Management of Environmental Resources, INSEAD.
Ayres, R.U. Martinas, K. Wealth accumulation and economic progress'
Evolutionary Economics (1996) 6: pp. 347-359.
Ayres, R.U. Nair, I. (1984) 'Thermodynamics and economics'. Physics
Today, November 1984.
Ayres, R.U. Warr, B. 'Two paradigms of production and growth' INSEAD.
Ayres, R.U. van den Bergh, J.C.J.M. Gowdy, J.M. (1998) Viewpoint: Weak
versus strong sustainability. Tinbergen Institute Discussion Papers No
98-103/3.
Bacon, C. (2004) Practical portfolio performance measurement and
Attribution, Wileys.
Baumgrtner, S. (2002) 'Thermodynamics and the economics of absolute
scarcity' 2nd World Congress of Environmental and Resource
Economists, June 24-27, 2002, Monterey, CA, USA.
Baumgrtner, S. (2004) 'Temporal and thermodynamic irreversibility in
production theory' Economic Theory, 26, pp. 725-728
Baumgrtner, S. Faber, M. Proops, J.L.R. (1996) 'The use of the entropy
concept in ecological economics', Faber et al. (1996: Chap. 7).
Brekke, K. A. (1997) Economic growth and the environment: On the
measurement of income and welfare. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
Bryant, J. (1979) 'An equilibrium theory of economics', Energy Economics,
Vol 1, No 2, pp. 102-111.
Bryant, J. (1982) 'A thermodynamic approach to economics', Energy
Economics, Vol.4, No. 1, pp. 36-50.
Bryant, J. (1985) 'Economics, equilibrium and thermodynamics', Workshop
Energy & Time in the Economic and Physical Sciences, Elsevier
Science Publishers B.V. pp. 197-217.
Bryant, J. (2007) 'A thermodynamic theory of economics', International
Journal of Exergy, Vol.4, No. 3, pp. 302-337.
Bryant, J. (2008) 'A thermodynamic approach to monetary economics',
Vocat International Ltd, www.vocat.co.uk.
34
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
35
36
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
Hubbert, M.K. (1956) 'Nuclear energy and the fossil fuels'. American
Petroleum Institute, Spring meeting, Southern District.
Kamps, C. (2004) 'New estimates of government net capital stocks for 22
OECD countries 1960-2001'. Kiel Institute for World Economics.
Kapolyi, L. 'Systems analysis of bio-economy entropy and negentropy in
biopolitics' Systems International Foundation, Hungary.
Kay, J. Schneider, E. (1992) ' Thermodynamics and measures of ecosystem
integrity', Ecological indicators, Elsevier, New York, pp. 159-191.
Keynes, J.M. (1936), 'The General theory of employment, interest and
money' London: Macmillan (reprinted 2007).
Klein, L. (1962) 'An introduction to econometrics'. Prentice-Hall, Inc. pp.
154-156.
Koopmans, T. C. Ed (1951) 'Activity analysis of production and allocation'.
New York, John Wiley & Sons.
Laherrere, J. (2005) 'Forecasting production from discovery'. ASPO. Lisbon
May 19-20, 2005.
Laherrere, J. (2006) 'Fossil fuels: What future?' China Institute of
International Studies. Workshop October 2006, Beijing.
Leontief, W. W. (1986) 'Input-output economics'. 2nd ed., New York:
Oxford University Press, 1986.
Lezon, T.R, Banavar, J. R. Cieplak, M. Fedoroff, N. (2006) 'Using the
principle of entropy maximization to infer genetic interaction networks
from gene expression patterns'. PNAS vol 103, no.50 pp. 19033-19038.
Lisman, J. H. C. (1949) 'Econometrics statistics and thermodynamics',
Netherlands Postal and Telecommunications Services, The Hague,
Holland, Ch IV.
Mackay, D.J.C. (2008) Sustainable Energy without the hot air, UIT
Cambridge Ltd, ISBN 978-0-9544529-3-3.
Malthus, T. R. (1798) 'An essay on the principle of population'.
Mahulikar, S. P. Herwig, H. (2004) Conceptual investigation of the entropy
principle for identification of directives for creation, existence and total
destruction of order Physica Scripta, vol 70, pp. 212-221.
Martins, K. (2000) 'An irreversible economic approach to the theory of
production' Systems & Information Dynamics. Vol. 7, Issue 4.
Martins, K. (2002) 'Is the utility maximization principle necessary? Postautistic economics review, issue no. 12, March 2002.
Martins, K. (2005) 'Energy in physics and in economy' Interdisciplinary
Description of Complex Systems 3(2), pp. 44-58.
Martins, K. (2007) 'Non-equilibrium economics' Interdisciplinary
Description of Complex Systems 4(2), pp. 63-79
Meadows, D.H. Meadows, D. L. Randers, J. Behrens III, W.W. (1972) 'The
limits to growth'. Universe Books.
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
37
38
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
39
Turner, G. (2008) 'A comparison of the limits to growth with thirty years of
reality'. Global Environmental Change, vol 18, Issue 3, pp. 397-411.
Udgaonkar, J.B. (2001) Entropy in Biology Resonance September 2001.
Waggoner, D. (1997) Spline methods for extracting interest rate curves
from coupon bond prices, Federal Reserve Bank Atlanta, Working
Paper No 97-10.
Wall, G. (1986) 'Exergy - A useful concept' Chalmers Biblioteks Tryckeri,
Goteborg 1986.
Warr, B. Ayres, R.U. (2002) 'An introduction to REXS a simple systems
dynamics model of long-run endogenous technological progress,
resource consumption and economic growth'. INSEAD.
Warr, B. Schandl, H. Ayres, R.U. (2007) 'Long term trends in resource
exergy consumption and useful work supplies in the UK 1900 - 2000'
CSIRO Sustainable Ecosystems.
Yuqing, H. (2006) 'Income Distribution: Boltzmann analysis and its
extension' Physica A: Statistics mechanics and its applications. Vol
377, Issue 1. pp. 230-240.
Zittel, W. Schindler, J. (2007) 'Coal: Resources and future production'.
Energy Watch Group, EWG-Series No1/2007.
DATA SOURCES
BP Statistical Reviews
Energy Information Administration (EIA), US Department of Energy
IEA
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change:
Third & Fourth Assessment Reports.
OECD
Penn World
United Nations
USA Census Bureau
www.bea.gov
www.statistics.gov.uk
www.federalreserve.gov
40
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
LIST OF SYMBOLS
Symbol
Thermo-Economic
Thermodynamic
Time
Time
Price
Pressure
Volume (3-D)
Number of molecules
v (=V/N)
G (=PV)
Energy
Productive Content/unit
Boltzmann constant
Nk
n.a.
Temperature
Entropy
Entropy
s (=S/N)
f (=F/N)
Cv
CP
Elastic Index
Index Expansion/Compression
(=CP/CV)
Isentropic Index
Isentropic Index
Heat Supplied/lost
Work Done
Internal Energy
u (=U/N)
Equilibrium Constant
Equilibrium Constant
Lifetime Ratio
n.a.
Cv/k
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
41
INDEX
Active, 92-94
Anderson, 170
Annila, 5,111
Arrhenius, 94
Avogadro, 6, 22, 60
Ayres, 2, 3, 20, 22, 60,178, 210
Bacon, 170
Baron, 108
Baumgrtner, 3
Boltzmann, 7, 11, 38, 39
Bonds and gilts, 165-177
Brekke, 210
Bryant, 2, 4, 91
Candeal, 3, 81
Carnot, 114
Carriers, holders of value, 8
Chakrabarti, 3,38
Chakraborti, 3, 38
Chatterjee, 3, 38
Chen, 3
Climate change, 200-209
Club of Rome, 209
Cobb-Douglas, 82, 88
Constant price, 67-69
Constant volume, 63-66
Constrained maximisation, 2
Constraints, 102-104
Costanza, 2
Cycle, 113-117
Daly, 3
Darwin, 211
Degree of freedom, 65
Degree of value, 65
Distribution of income, 37-39
Domingos, 3, 81
Dragulescu, 3, 38
Economic entropy, 101-103, 140151, 156-157, 162-163, 165, 171177, 193-197, 201
Econophysics, 3, 33
Eco-system, 200-209
Elastic index, 70, 73, 77-79
Embodied value, 8, 13, 20
Emission intensity, 202-207
Energy capital stock, 180-181
Energy consumption per capita,
178-180
Energy intensity, 178-180
Energy resource substitution, 191193
Entropic index, 76-77
Entropic value, 54
Entropy, 61-62
Entropy and maximisation, 108-113
Environmental waste stock, 48
Equilibrium, 94-104
Equilibrium constant, 98-99
Estrella & Trubin, 169
Eyring, 100
Exergy, 20-21
Ferrero, 3, 38
Frederick, Loewenstein,
ODonoghue, 173
First Law of Thermodynamics, 5059
Fisher, 2
Flow and non-flow, 6-7
Foley, 3, 81
Free value, 94-96
Gamma distribution, 39
Gas/chemical reactions, 90
Georgescu-Roegan, 1, 2
Gibbs, 2, 94
Goldberg, 4
Gompertz, 107
Greene, 108
Grubbestrm, 3
Hannon, 2
42
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
Hansen, 140
Helmholtz free energy, 94
Herwig, 5, 110
Hicks, 88, 140
Hicks-neutral technical progress, 88
Hubbert, 185
Ideal gas, 6
Ideal economic equation, 9-14
Ideal gas equation, 6, 14
Inactive, 92-94
Index of trading value, 8-9
Interest rates, 140-151
Internal energy, 50
Internal value, 50-53
IPCC, 200-207
IS/LM model, 140
Isentropic process, 74
Iso-trading process, 69-71
Joule cycle, 115
Kay, 4, 89
Keynes, Keynesian, 119, 140
Kinetic theory of gases, 6
Klein, 37
Labour and unemployment, 152-159
Law of diminishing marginal utility,
82
Law of maximum entropy
production, 111
Le Chatelier Principle, 2, 3, 4, 91
Leontief, 25
Lifetime, 19, 57
Limits to growth, 2, 107
Liquidity preference, 141, 168
Lisman, 2
Logistic function, 107
Lognormal distribution, 37
Long & short dated bonds, 155-177
Loschmidt, 6
Lotka-Volterra model, 197
Mackay, 198
Malthus, 209
Mahulikar, 5, 110
Copyright: John Bryant, VOCAT International Ltd 2012, for personal use only.
Samuelson, 2, 9, 89
Schandl, 22
Schneider, 4, 89
Schrdinger, 4, 89
Second Law of Thermodynamics,
59-62
Sigmoid, 107
Smith, 3, 81
Soddy, 2
Sllner, 3
Solow, 88
Sousa, 3, 81
Specific heat, 57-64
Specific internal value, 56
Specific money, 122-130
Specific price, 122-130
Specific value, 57
Specific value constant volume, 6466
Specific value constant price, 67
Specific volume rate, 19
Steady state economics, 3
Sustainability, 210-214
Svensson, 170
Swenson, 111
Temperature, 6-7, 56
Thermodynamic theory of
economics, 4
Thermo-economics of resources,
193-198
Thermoeconomics and
sustainability, 210-214
Turner, 209
Unemployment, 152-159
Utility, 81-87
Value capacity coefficient, 65, 67,
75-79
Value rate, 43
Van del Waal, 6
Verhulst equation, 107, 194, 199
Von Neumann, 108
Velocity of circulation, 9, 33, 118133
Wage rate, 35-36, 152-159
Waggoner, 170
Wall, 22
Warr, 3, 22, 60, 178
Work done, 50-59, 96
Yakovenko, 3, 38
Yield, yield spread, 165-177
Yuqing, 3, 38
43