View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk
brought to you by
CORE
provided by Policy Documentation Center
Housing in South-Eastern Europe1
Iván Tosics and József Hegedüs
Objectives and Approach
The task of this research is to highlight the housing problems in South-Eastern Europe both at national and
regional level, and to single out the lines for future reforms that will enable the adjustment to the European
standards. The geographical scope of the research covers Albania, Bulgaria, Croatia, Macedonia (FYROM),
and Romania2. Because of information constraints, the authors applied a 'two-step approach'. First an 'issuepaper' has been prepared, summarizing the main challenges on the basis of existing publications and data,
and containing a list of 'issues', which seem to be the most important for future reforms in housing in SouthEastern Europe (SEE). The 'issue paper' and a questionnaire have been submitted to politicians and experts
in each country who prepared - with the exception of Albania - 'position papers'. The research integrates the
results of this process and provides suggestions for future reforms.
The Transition from a Centrally Planned to a Market Oriented Model
The five countries under discussion have a very different history. Probably the most important common
element in their past is their communist heritage of 40-45 years after the World War II. In the early 1990s,
the conditions for the housing sector have changed dramatically in the region towards the free-market
direction. As a result, the real estate market appeared, former huge construction companies were split and
privatized, the sale of construction materials was liberalized, restrictions on owning property were
eliminated and a significant portion of state owned housing was privatized. During the transition, one of the
first political changes in relation to the housing sector affected the role of the local administrative level. The
responsibilities and control power of the freely elected new local governments over housing policy was
increased in most countries, together with a transfer of previously 'state' assets (state owned housing stock,
land, etc.). This was a significant step towards decentra1ization, even though housing typically did not
become part of the core/mandatory tasks of local governments. The concrete processes, the pace of the
changes were, however, different in SEE countries. In addition to country specific elements of the transition,
the SEE region experienced political instability, internal and international political conflicts and dramatic
migration, which created unstable circumstances for the housing sector. A more detailed analysis needs to
identify the specifics of SEE sub-region in a comparative perspective.
1
In: Stuart Lowe and Sasha Tsenkova (eds.): Housing Change in East and Central Europe Integration or Fragmentation? Chapter 2,
pp. 21-44. Ashgate, 2003
2
This chapter has been prepared as part of the Council of Europe's initiative 'Making South-Eastern Europe a Region of Social
Cohesion', Thematic Network 5: Housing Problems in South-Eastern Europe. The authors would like to thank Dr. Tsenkova for her
constructive comments on an earlier draft and for her kind assistance amidst competing commitments.
1
The Housing Situation in SEE Countries
Comparative data in the annex at the end of the chapter aim to compare three groups of countries: the EU
members (EU-IS), the Central European countries (CEE-5), and the South-East European countries (SEE5).3
Qualitative Housing Indicators
Compared to the generally slow increase of population in the Western part of Europe, the Central European
region shows stagnation, while the population of the SEE region is declining. Although the data for SEE
countries are less reliable, it appears that population declined between 1990 and 1998 by 1.2 million
(consisting of 0.5 million increase in Albania, stagnation in FYROM, 0.3 million decrease in Croatia, and
0.7 million decrease respectively in Bulgaria and Romania (UN/ECE, 2000b). In addition, SEE countries
have a huge economic backlog, not only compared to the EU-IS group (GNP per capita is only 7.3 per cent
of those) but also compared to the CEE-5 group (37.5 per cent). This difference is a bit less, if the PPP
(purchase power parity) method is used: in this case the data of the SEE group is around 17 per cent of the
EU-IS and around 49 per cent of the CEE-15 averages.
According to data from the 1980s, the biggest increase of the number of housing units occurred in the SEE
country group. As a result, the shortage of 950 thousand fiats turned into a surplus of 850 thousand fiats by
1990. 'Shortage' and 'surplus' here refer to the difference between the number of households and housing
units. Other types of measures, e.g. the number of housing units per 1,000 population, still show a relatively
low level of housing consumption in SEE (337) compared to that of the EU-IS (434) in 1990 (see Table 2Al). It appears that SEE countries had a substantial 'reserve ' in their housing stock at the beginning of the
transition, which could have made it easier to 'survive' the difficulties of this decade, at least from the
housing policy point of view. Such a statement, however, would need more careful analysis, as there might
have been several types of 'mismatches' between housing units and households. One obvious mismatch was
between the small size of the housing units and the relatively large size of the households (Budisteanu,
1997). The fact that the person per room indicator shows similar level between the two groups of countries
might be the consequence of the lower SEE normative for the average size of rooms on new housing estates
(in the CEE countries the normative for the size of the fiat was around 53 sq.m. with rooms around 12-16
sq.m. in size, while in Romania, the largest SEE country the national average was 33.8 sq.m. (Romania,
2000, p.7). Further, the territorial mismatch between housing supply and housing demand could be measured
by the territorial distribution of vacant units in the housing stock. The only available data refer to eight per
cent vacancy rate for Bulgaria and Croatia, and six per cent for Romania around 1990 (MRI, 1996, p 43).
Quantitative Housing Indicators
The 'normal ' link between the quality of the housing units and the age of the stock is that the younger the
stock, the higher the quality. This relation is not reflected in Table 2A-2, as the SEE group with its youngest
stock has the worst parameters, while the EU-IS group has the oldest stock but the best quality indices. One
of the causes - besides the differences in the general level of economic development - is the fact that the
communist countries were much more 'hit' by the wave of new housing estates, where the quality and
standards of panel housing were relatively poor. As far as access to infrastructure services is concerned, the
data show significant backlog in SEE countries compared to the CEE group and the EU average. These
indicators show only in a limited sense the quality of the housing stock4. In the lack of any reliable
3
A methodological problem in the data-analysis is associated with comparisons of country-group averages. In these cases usually
weighted averages are used, where the weights can be the country population (for population related indicators), the total number of
housing units (for housing stock related indices), or the number of new housing units (for the analysis of new housing construction).
The weighted averages of a group of countries are dominated by the values of the larger countries. The present grouping in SEE
consists of small countries, with the only exception of Romania, which accounts for 58 per cent of the population. Thus the average
is strongly influenced by Romania. Similarly, the averages of the CEE-5 group are dominated by Poland, which also accounts for 58
per cent of the population of the group.
There are no comparative statistics in the CEE and SEE region about the broader aspects of housing quality. In the latest EU
comparative housing statistics, some countries take only into account the existence of basic amenities, while others try also to
measure the need for repair (EU, 1998).
4
2
comparative information it can only be raised as a hypothesis that the physical conditions and the level of
repair is probably one of the most important dividing lines between the three groups of countries. Without
being able to give empirical evidence, most analysts would agree, that 'deferred maintenance' is quite limited
in most of the EU-IS countries, much more common in the CEE group and almost dominant in the SEE
countries. The link between the quality of the housing units and the age of the stock would be more relevant
for the new dwellings built since 1990. New housing means also higher quality housing, especially because
it is dominated by private construction for the better-off However, as it can be seen from Table 2A-2 the
level of new construction is low, around a quarter or third of the average of the EU-IS group. Thus the
backlog in CEE, and even more in SEE countries, is increasing.
Tenure Change
Despite the common belief, most of the communist countries were never dominated by the state rental
sector. Its share in 1990 was 28 per cent in the CEE-5 countries and only 19 per cent in SEE, which is pretty
close to the EU average of 15 per cent (Table 2A-3). Moreover, the other types of rental sector (semi-public
or private rental) were almost totally missing. As a consequence, the SEE countries in 1990 had a high share
of owner occupied sector of 78 per cent on average (Bulgaria 91 per cent, Romania 76 per cent, Croatia 69
per cent, and Albania 64 per cent). However, 'owner occupied housing' was in many countries heavily
controlled by the state through control over loans, prices of building materials and real-estate transactions
(Hegedüs and Tosics, 1992). This fact underlines the necessity of deeper analysis - the real character of a
housing system can never be judged only on the basis of the tenure structure.
There is an extensive literature existing about the restructuring of the housing stock after 1989-90 in the
post-communist countries (see Banks et al., 1996; Hegedüs and Tosics, 1992, 1993; Tsenkova, 2000c).
Without going into the details here, it is clear that the SEE countries belong to the category of 'fast
privatizers' between 1990 and 1994 as much as 67.5 per cent of the already small share of public rental stock
had been privatized (55 per cent in Croatia, 74 per cent in Romania and 98 per cent in Albania). This
average is much higher than the similar figure of the CEE group, where only 12 per cent of the housing
stock had been privatized by 1994, and only Slovenia (and partly Hungary) showed a pace of privatization
comparable to the SEE countries. As a consequence of fast privatization, after the 1990 political changes the
already high rate of owner occupation in the SEE countries increased from 78 to 89 per cent between 1990
and 1994 (in Romania from 76 to 89 per cent, in Croatia from 69 to 84 per cent, in Albania from 64 to 98
per cent). However, the new market oriented economic system did not bring about automatically the
development of a real market-oriented owner occupied sector. In many SEE countries property tides
remained uncertain, mortgage lending remained underdeveloped and the new owners were not even free to
decide about the form of management of their building. There are problems with the informal and illegal
forms of housing, the share of which is extremely high in the region.
Financial and Affordability Issues
Financial and affordability indicators belong to the relatively more difficult indices, because these are based
on household income, real estate prices, and bank lending. This information is rarely available in SEE
countries (see Table 2A-4).
The role of housing finance, which was already very limited in the communist housing system, fell
substantially in the first years of transition, due to the high interest rates, monopoly situations in the banking
sector and low paying capacity of the population (Hegedüs et al, 1996). These facts are well illustrated by
the low level of housing credit portfolio and low credit to value ratios in SEE countries.
As it is well known, in the communist housing system public rents were kept low and the prices of public
utilities were heavily subsidized, thus the total costs of housing were 1-2 per cent of income. Table 2A-4
shows that this situation started to change at the beginning of the 1990s. The introduction of market prices
was quicker in the CEE countries than in the SEE region, and it was quicker for the utility prices than for
public rents. By 1994, housing costs relative to income were twice as high (14 per cent) for CEE tenants
than for SEE tenants (7-8 per cent).
Both figures were much lower than the same indicator for the EU countries (30-40 per cent). The tendency is
to increase housing costs further; however, there are serious barriers in the payment capacity of the
population. There is also a clear connection between the size of the public rental stock and the rent level
3
which can be charged - the smaller the public sector, the less possible it is to increase the rents since the
poorest families have remained in the sector. Because of the small revenues (decreasing in real value) and
the rapidly growing expenditures, public rental housing was considered to be 'negative asset' by many local
governments (ILGPS, 1994; Hegedüs and Tosics, 1998; Tsenkova, 2000c). They were actively pushing
forward the low-price privatization, transferring all burdens of deferred maintenance to the new owners.
Social Aspects of Housing
The most visible sign of social housing problems, street homelessness is a relatively new phenomenon in
post-communist countries. As a consequence of the transition towards liberal market economy - bringing
ought along the elimination of job security and the security of tenure, the explosion of public utility prices,
the disappearance of workers' hostels and the decrease of beds in hospitals - a large number of people are not
financially capable to keep their homes, or provide any kind of accommodation for themselves. Due to these
factors homelessness increased and became visible in the bigger cities of CEE (Hertting et al., 1999).
Parallel to the above changes, in most countries of the region the central government stepped back from
direct interventions into the housing market and transferred the responsibility for social housing policy to the
local level. Therefore nationwide social housing policies are weak. According to unofficial expert estimates
street homelessness concerns at least 0.5 rnillion people in the central and southern part of Europe. The data
for Bulgaria refer to 7,000 people and for Romania - to 4,500.
The Housing Indicators Program used two comparable indicators for describing homelessness-type social
housing problems in a broader sense. These were: 'substandard housing', as a percentage of the total housing
stock, and 'social need for housing on local level' (i.e. only in the capital cities). Substandard housing was
defined as housing with at least one of the following problems: housing built for temporary use; housing
units not fulfilling the minimal regulatory criteria for housing regulated by the building code (e.g. units in
basement); housing missing basic utility services (missing indoor toilet and bathroom); housing in buildings
in exceptionally bad physical conditions not suitable for living. According to experts estimates (MRI, 1996),
substandard housing in SEE is 6-19 per cent in Bulgaria, 14 per cent in Croatia and only five per cent in
Romania. It can be argued that these results are due to differences in definitions and surveying methods.
The other indicator, social need for housing, was defined as the number of low income local population with
at least one of the following problems: being homeless (street homeless); living overcrowded (based on the
national or local definition of over crowdedness); living in (above mentioned) substandard housing; living in
restituted flats with a notice to leave within a definite time. Comparable data were only available for the
capital cities, showing a bigger social housing demand in the SEE capitals as in the CEE capitals, probably
due mainly to the very crowded housing conditions of the population.
Country reports prepared as background to the current paper show only very limited development in the area
of social support systems (Bulgaria, 2000; Croatia, 2000; Macedonia, 2000). In Bulgaria, cash and in-kind
heating subsidies have been introduced, targeted to low-income households (covering roughly one-fifth of
all households, giving a very limited support of 21 DM per heating season). In Croatia social safety net
measures are restricted to particularly vulnerable population categories. In FYROM there is no social safety
net system and there is also a lack of public support for maintenance and utilities for low-income households
in Romania.
Regarding the access to social housing, available data suggest that in most countries public rental housing
was in 1994 allocated mainly according to social principles (Slovakia: socially allocated units were 95 per
cent of the total, Hungary: 74 per cent, Poland 50 per cent, Bulgaria: 90 per cent). However, in reallty this
statement does not mean too much, as the number of vacated and allocated public rental units became very
low. As a consequence of broad privatization, even the most vulnerable and the lowest income groups of
society have to find the solution to their social housing problems in the owner occupied housing sector,
which would need special public interventions, currently missing in most South Eastern European countries.
4
The Main Housing Issues in SEE Countries
Demand and Supply Mismatches in the Housing Sector
The 1990s, however, is not a decade which could easily be analyzed in the SEE region on the basis of
'normal' processes. Due to unprecedented migration, the decade of the transition brought along extraordinary
changes in the number of population, i.e. on the demand side of the housing market. In one group of the
countries - Bulgaria, Romania, Albania - the main aspect of the changes was the opening of the borders. The
other group of the countries (Croatia, FYROM) was hit directly by the war - in the course of which these
countries gained independence - while this had also an effect on Bulgaria and Albania with a huge wave of
refugees. As a result of all these factors the intensity of the migration processes in SEE was much higher5.
Data on internal urban-rural migration show in most countries under investigation an increase of the capital
city region. At the same time it is common that the population of the city itself is decreasing. These factors
point towards a starting suburbanization process, which is, however, more than offset by the strong
international immigration, concentrating on the biggest city.
The de-population of poorer areas is a common feature in all of the SEE countries. There is a strong internal
emigration from the rural and other underdeveloped areas (e.g. in Croatia mainly islands), leaving behind a
surplus of poorly maintained housing with insufficient communal infrastructure. This might be labeled as
delayed urbanization, which was hindered in the communist period by administrative methods and/or
allocation of subsidies for new construction. Since the administrative restrictions in the 1990s were
eliminated, many of the city-oriented moves could finally happen (the most extreme case in this regard is
Tirana). The result of this delayed urbanization is a growth of the vacancy rate in the total housing stock up
to 8-12 per cent, while in the capital city region there is usually a housing shortage. The latter is especially
true of the 'new capitals' (Zagreb, Skopje), in the case of which the concentration of government
administration contributes to the increase in housing demand (Bezovan, 2000; Dolenc, 1998).
The supply side of the housing sector brought about in the 1990s a very slow development (as a result of the
dramatic decrease in the amount of new construction). Moreover, in the case of some countries (Croatia) a
significant share of the housing units has been destroyed during the war. Beside the factors analyzed on the
demand and the supply side, the lack of efficient housing market is also an important reason for demand and
supply mismatches. One of the few advantages of the privatization policy was the contribution to the supply
by those households who had an 'over consumption' in housing, because the incentive to 'cash' this reserve
became higher after privatization. However, in several countries the new legislation brought also uncertainty
to the market. This is true, first of all, for restitution (Bulgaria, Romania, Albania), as this opened a new area
for legal actions and made the transactions less safe. The countries where restitution policy was applied
reported considerable legal litigation. In terms of housing economics this meant that the transaction cost in
the housing market has increased. In Romania, for example even the right to sell the newly privatized
apartments was curtailed by the legislation. This eliminated potential inequity effects of future transactions
(e.g. that the poorly informed and cash-short households facing economic difficulties will sell their property
below the real prices). It is important to emphasize that these factors, contributing to the inflexibility of the
housing market, make housing less affordable for low income households, as they are less able to move to
units which were better match their housing needs and possibilities.
Community Infrastructure Development
The infrastructure networks in SEE countries in the earlier decades have never been sufficiently maintained
and today the quality is usually low. The existing electricity, water services would need substantial
maintenance and modernization; there are huge leakages in the water systems, inefficient energy-saving
systems lead to unacceptably high energy costs, breakdowns occur often, etc. In the areas of dynamic
population development there are huge infrastructure problems. In many cases the extension of these
services is not following the quick increase of population. The extreme case is Tirana, where the inhabitants
of informal settlements (30 per cent of the population!) are joining illegally to the existing infrastructure
networks, causing almost total breakdown in these services (Deda, 1998, 2000).
5
For the purpose of a housing sector analysis not only the balance of migration is of importance, but also its territorial distribution.
The loss in total population number does not necessarily mean an equal decrease in housing demand - the immigrants might
concentrate in settlements with already tight housing markets, while substantial part of the emigrants might ease pressures in housing
markets of settlements where there is no demand whatsoever for the empty units.
5
Besides physical infrastructure, there are also problems with the social services infrastructure. Many of the
once developed social services would need substantial public subsidies to function under market conditions.
In the lack of such subsidies many cultural and social institutions have to be closed, leading also to
decreasing quality of the urban environment. The lack of public subsidies, and the low level of the planning
control of the local government, leads also to the neglect of public spaces. The explosive development of
private sector activities brings a partial solution to these problems, but not always in the necessary
coordinated way, lea ding very of ten to the private use of public areas. The culmination of all these
problems, mainly on the housing estates built 20-30 years ago, leads to deterioration and disengagement of
residents from their environment.
New Housing Construction
In the transition period new housing construction became primarily a private responsibility in SEE countries.
This was a complete change for at least Romania and Albania (in Romania in the 1980s over 90 per cent of
new housing was produced by the public sector, while this share has decreased below one per cent by 1999).
Due to high interest rates, low real incomes of the population and the relative saturation of the housing
market (in most countries the number of housing units exceeds that of the households), new housing
construction decreased at the beginning of the 1990s to very low levels. State-financed housing construction
practically disappeared. Detailed analysis of the new construction activity shows that the parameters of the
newly constructed units improved significantly compared to the units built in the 1980s. In Romania, for
example, the average size of the new units increased from 30 sq.m. (1980) to 47 sq.m. (1994), and also the
share of units in smaller houses (up to two stories) increased from 25 per cent to 82 per cent.
Parallel to improvements in quality, new housing became more expensive, particularly in cities. As a logical
consequence of high prices and high tax burdens on new construction, and the unwillingness of the financial
sector to lend to the population, SEE countries face the problem of huge amount of unauthorized, illegal
building. Albania is the extreme example; in Romania the share of unauthorized housing construction is
about 20 per cent of all new housing in 1998 (Budisteanu, 2000). Although all administrative limitations
were removed in order to enhance the role of the market in new construction, entrepreneurs face serious
limitations due to low purchasing power of the population. The liberation of the housing construction sector,
the disappearance of the former monopolistic state enterprises led to free competition, resulting in the
emergence of too many small companies not able to access development finance (Hoffman and Koleva,
1993; Huremovic, 1998; Tsenkova 200Oa). The price of construction materials increased to world-market
level and in some countries new monopolies have arisen through the market-type concentration of capital in
the hands of some big Western building material industries.
Maintenance, Renewal and Rehabilitation
It is well known that only a small part of the public rental stock was in good condition when privatization
started at the beginning of the 1990s. The new owners got their dwellings at a very low price and most of
them could pay off the sales price soon (or the high inflation washed away the debt). This was the short-term
advantage of the give-away privatization (Budisteanu, 2000). In fact, serious maintenance works did not
start in most SEE countries - only the report from Croatia contains a statement that the maintenance of
multi-family housing improved after privatization. The main reasons for that can be summarized as follows:
•
With privatization the responsibility of maintenance was transferred to the households, without
ensuring the proper financial, administrative and legal conditions.
•
Housing played an important role in the strategy of households in transition. In economic hardship,
households postpone housing investments and maintenance expenditures, which could lead to
deterioration of the stock.
•
In the privatized multifamily housing sector there is a lack of cooperation ('collective actions')
considering decision-making and financing of operation, maintenance, modernization and new
investments. One of the main causes of this non-cooperative behaviour is the lack of legal basis for
efficient enforcement methods against non-payers.
6
The lack of comprehensive maintenance is leading to serious technical deficiencies of the multi-family
stock6. The 'improvement of the prefabricated buildings and neighborhoods is still not on the political
agenda in SEE, although there have been some discussions about the energy efficiency improvement of the
panel buildings. It is not easy to find the way out from this situation. It is not enough, for example, to pass a
Law for Condominiums, as it is almost certain that its regulations will in order to enhance cooperation - get
in conflict with the general political and legal protection of individual rights of owners (Banks et al., 1996).
It is not easy to find a correct system of state financial support for the maintenance of common parts of the
privatized multi-family buildings; any subsidies are immediately criticized by people who could not
participate in the give-away privatization of housing.
The Affordability of Housing
After the transition the nature of the housing affordability problem has been changed. The market forces
give more chances to adjust housing consumption to the housing needs and financial possibilities of the
households, under the condition of the efficient housing market. However, because of the rigidity of the
housing markets (high transaction cost), and inefficiency in the housing related service sector (as water,
waste management, district heating, maintenance, etc.) housing costs have increased faster than incomes.
The affordability issue has two aspects: the affordability of housing maintenance and operation, and the
affordability of the access of housing. The factors influencing the affordability problem are shown in Figure
2.1.
The problem of affordability of the maintenance and operation of the stock is related first to the level of
consumption. The general statement is that the level of housing consumption is much lower in SEE than the
EU standard, but probably it is in consistency with the level of economic development of these countries.
The second issue is that this consumption level leads in the existing economic environment to a housing
cost, which is influenced, on the one hand, by the efficiency of the sector, and, on the other hand, by the
subsidies and taxes (that is government intervention). Housing consumption should be defined in a broader
sense including not just the housing unit, but the housing related services. In the household budgets and
household decisions these services are closely related.
Figure 2.1 Housing Affordability
6
In Romania 2.5 million units would need urgent infrastructure upgrading, and there is a substandard stock of over 17 thousand
units built in the early 1980s in urban areas (Budisteanu, 2000). In Bulgaria several panel blocks in Sofia threaten to collapse due to
technical failures and sinking foundations (in connection with long lasting damage of the sewers beneath the buildings). The need for
rehabilitation of buildings dangerous for the life of their habitants is very urgent, in the case of at !east 70 thousand units. The
required sanitation costs are around 1500-2500 USD/flat, while the average monthly salary is, around 110 USD (Bulgaria, 2000)
7
The efficiency issue in the housing related services is connected to the problems of decentralization, that is,
the proper institutional framework. These countries inherited a centralized intergovernmental finance
system, and the administrative reform steps have not as of yet provided real devolution of responsibility and
decision making to lower levels of government. This has contributed to the low performance of the public
sector. Governments had to give priority to maintaining the macroeconomic stability, while the services
provided by the public sector have deteriorated very fast in the last ten years. The most important factor
determining these processes was the lack of the real responsibility and incentives for the owners (local
governments) to improve the management of local expenditures and revenues.
It is not the centralized structure of public sector itself which is responsible for the deterioration process, but
much more the coexistence of a disintegrated public sector, having a decreasing capacity to enforce the basic
laws, with an emerging uncontrolled private sector. The service provider is basically reimbursed for its cost
through a budget negotiation process, where neither the municipal/district government nor the service
providers have discretion over expenditures and revenues. The central government provides less and less
resources to the services; the service provider with no incentives to improve services and without real
political control over its performance, produces less and less, and lets the system run down. In extreme cases
the outcome of these processes are cutting district heating, limiting the water supply and electric service,
etc.7
The discrepancy between the housing costs and the household incomes raises the question of housing
subsidies and taxes. The untargeted subsidy system and the regressive tax system make the problem more
serious and politically less acceptable. The next issue is how do households react to affordability problems?
The first question is whether the households can adjust the level of their consumption, and the second,
whether they have any incentives to do so. The whole legal and institutional framework of the housing
system should be reviewed to answer these questions. The country reports indicated a huge mismatch
between the housing stock (consumption) and the household income. The increasing inequality of household
income contributes to the imbalance. The result is a dramatic increase in housing arrears8.
The affordability of access to housing is a different question. The basic affordability indicator is the
Price/Income ratio. On the basis of the reports the P/I ratio on the secondary market can be estimated to be
around four to six years, and on the market of the new units around 10-15 years. No reliable data exist, but
the general tendency is that on the new housing market the prices are very high, serving only the demand of
the upper income groups. On the secondary market the picture is mixed, because of the rigidity of the
market9. The lack of a rental sector in the region contributes very much to the growing affordability
problems. The distorted tenure structure, the lack of the rental sector, especially private rental sector, has
very harmful effects. A larger private rental housing sector could considerably help to achieve housing
policy goals such as greater flexibility, mobility, and reduce the demand for subsidies for owner occupied
housing. .
7
In Bulgaria 589,000 households have dwellings with central heating. The first self-defending step at insolvency has been voluntary
disconnection from the service. Based on heating companies' reports only in Sofia 207,000 households have given up central heating
(entirely or partially) - this makes 58 per cent of all dwellings with central heating and 44 per cent of all households. Further, the
central-heating systems were abandoned in several medium-sized towns, again due to mass voluntary refusal service (Bulgaria,
2000)
8
In Croatia 10-15 per cent of the arrears are processed in court, there is no foreclosure against debts with energy, water, etc. In
Macedonia the rent payment ratio is only 30-35 per cent. In Skopje arrears are rare, in many cases more than one family lives in one
flat, so they can cover utility fees, which have reached market price level (Macedonia, 2000)
9
In Romania the number of transactions increased steeply in the first years of transition, to level later and start to decrease in the last
couple of years. Based on recent data, housing prices on the secondary market have fallen; the difference between prices in
Bucharest and other cities has increased; similar differentiation can be observed between central locations and peripheral ones. The
same pattern is valid for the land market, where prices per sq.m. vary between 5 USD in the periphery to 500-600 USD in the most
fashionable areas (Budisteanu, 2000).
8
The Main Housing Policy Challenges in SEE Countries
Fiscal Challenges
The governments of the region are under huge fiscal pressure. In the transition countries the housing sector
related fiscal issues influenced both the revenue side and the expenditure side of the government budget. on
the revenue side three types of financial resources can be distinguished: i) traditional resource of the
government budget (based on taxes and other state revenues); ii) revenue of housing privatization; and iii)
off-budget sources (lower rent, tax evasion etc.). On the expenditure side the inherited commitments ('old
loans'); the operational subsidies of the existing stock (both state owned and private) and the new programs
are the major outflows. Government deficit, as an important source of macroeconomic instability, exercises
a considerable pressure on the need to balance the revenue and expenditure side.
Housing subsidies, which used to account for as much as 5-10 per cent of the budgets, decreased
substantially or disappeared from the budget in the SEE countries. The typical reaction to the
macroeconomic difficulties was the elimination of direct housing subsidies, which was one of the factors
explaining the dec1ine in housing coÍ1struction (Romania, Bulgaria, and FYROM). Housing privatization
had two effects on fiscal issues: i) the revenues from privatization were partly or wholly used in the housing
sector, but the size of the privatization revenue was small (in Albania basically zero) in comparison with the
value of the stock, and ii) with privatization the 'expenditure need' has decreased as fewer units needed
operational subsidies. However, there are hidden subsidies, which are transferred to the sector, such as the
unauthorized construction, low rents, user charge arrears, tax evasion, etc. The new construction and the real
estate sector are the typical areas for tax evasion.
New programs were launched (Albania, Romania), but with limited resources and with a limited effect. In
addition, subsidy programs targeted to special social groups - homeless, young couples - were initiated.
Because of the fiscal pressure, there is no possibility to provide a substantial part of housing finance from
the state budget. These problems might be addressed through the following potential measures:
•
The role of the intergovernmental fiscal relations should be reconsidered. As a part of the fiscal
decentralization, local governments should play a substantial role in housing. However, there are
problems, which cannot be tackled efficiently only on the local level, therefore need at least
framework-type regulation on the central level (e.g. housing allowances to the poor).
•
Politically aimed housing programs usually mean urgent interventions into the system without
taking into account the longer-term effects. These programs should be consolidated with the other
elements of housing policy.
•
There is a need to incorporate the off-budget subsidies into the general economic and housing
policy. It should be done parallel to the program which aims at pushing the informal economy
towards the formal economy.
Housing Finance Challenges
One of the most common phenomena in the region is the lack of housing finance institutions. While in
market-oriented housing systems the loan/housing value ratio is around 60-80 per cent, in the region the
ratio has dropped to less than ten per cent. The role of loans in housing finances is not simply low but has
dropped from a relatively low level to almost zero in the past eight to ten years10.
The questions are: what is the reason for the low level of housing finance? What would be a good strategy to
develop housing finance institutions? When restructuring the housing finance system, the main options are
to integrate housing in the whole financial system; or to establish separate housing lending institutions (e.g.
housing saving banks). In the developed countries there is a tendency that the housing finance institutions
become part of the capital market, and special housing banks the gradually into general financial institutions.
This should also be the longer-term aim in the region - however the urgent political need for 'market'
housing finance can give place temporarily to mixed policies.
10
In Romania, in 1999 the investment in construction represented only 5.9 per cent of total investment. Most of the private
investment (close to 90 per cent of total) was cash based (56 per cent own resources), other equity (22.9 per cent) and bank loans
(11.2 per cent) (Budistenau, 2000)
9
The second question housing policy should face is a strategic one: which segment of the market should be
targeted through the new housing finance system? Any potential solutions should consider the following
aspects:
•
Demand side support for new units and purchases of existing units (encouraging mortgage lending,
down-payment assistance, interest rate subsidies, support through land price subsidies, publicprivate partnerships, etc.).
•
Financing of housing rehabilitation (guarantee funds, subsidies and regulations, etc.).
•
Promoting private rentals ('non-profit' landlords, rent regulations, housing allowances, etc.).
•
Other indirect assistance (e.g. price information systems).
Legal Challenges
The lack of a proper legal framework is one of the key issues of the transition. There are three problems
which should be separated: i) regulation of property relations; ii) proper legal framework for certain
institutions (for example for the market-type mortgage system); and iii) enforcement issues (Banks et al,
1996; UI, 1993; UN-ECE, 1997).
There are many typical property-related phenomena in the SEE countries in the transition period:
•
Much attention is paid to correct the injustices of the past, giving advantages to individuals
sometimes at the expense of bigger neighborhoods, communities (restitution of plots in existing
housing environments).
•
Great emphasis is given to protect the rights of individual owners, sometimes even at the expense of
the right of the interest of larger entities (e.g. condominiums).
•
In some countries the interest of the state/local government is heavily protected, sometimes even at
the expense of the interest of the groups of new owners (e.g. the ownership of the land on which
condominiums exist is kept by the local government).
•
In some countries the interest of the public is not protected at all, the state/local government has not
even the minimum of enforcement rights against the illegal/informal actions of individuals
(occupation of land, use of infrastructure, etc.).
The legislative framework for the functioning of the housing institutions should provide the legal conditions
for:
•
•
Housing loan and mortgage system (sharing the risks).
Housing supply (developers' role, guarantees, building codes, new housing construction - to avoid
illegal construction which has high external costs).
• Secondary housing market (land registration, price information, taxation, transaction costs,
privatization, restitution).
• Housing service related user charges and rent regulation (condominium law).
• Housing rights and safety net issues (subsidy programs and the role of local governments).
These areas are interrelated and often contradictory. For example, certain safety net regulations could block
the development of the housing finance system. The third and partly independent issue is the enforcement
problem. The general problem in the region is the political legitimacy of the state. The experiences in the
region show that contradictions in the legal framework make it impossible to enforce the rules, but in most
of the cases the authorities do not have the political will and/or ability to implement them.
The improvement of the legislative framework, which must be carried out country by country because the
political situation is very different in the region across the different countries, must cover at least the
following areas:
•
•
•
. Property rights issues (privatization, restitution, land registration, real estate market).
. Regulation of building permits.
. Rent and user charge regulations.
10
•
•
. Condominium legislation.
. Enforcement: eviction and foreclosure issues.
Housing Policy Priorities in SEE Countries
The decision making structure in housing policy The political representation of the housing sector has
substantially weakened after the beginning of the transition; the responsibility in most SEE countries is still
scattered among several ministries.
Country reports identified the lack of institutions whose task would be to coordinate housing policy at the
central or local level as a major constraint for policy development. The following suggestions were made:
•
Bulgaria: establish National Housing Agency and National Housing Fund, strengthen municipal
housing institutions, housing associations.
•
Croatia: establish Parliamentary Committee for Housing (setting housing as a political priority).
•
Romania: strengthen the Ministry of Public Administration and Housing.
There are some recent institutional innovations in the housing sector, one of which is the establishment of
the National Housing Agency in Romania. This body is responsible for the coordination of financial
resources for new construction (80 per cent) and for the purchase of existing dwellings (20 per cent).
Housing policy priorities Officials and experts of the countries under review were asked to prepare an
evaluation on housing policy priorities. The first question to be answered was how the three most important
aspects (quantitative shortage, deterioration of the existing stock, social/affordability problems in the
existing stock) could be ranked according to importance of the problem. Respondents had to prepare two
rankings: 1) as these problems are ranked in official documents and II) according to their own opinion. The
following table summarizes the results.
Table 2.1 Most Important Housing Policy Aspects
Bulgaria
Croatia
FYROM
Romania
I. in official documents
II. personal opinion
I.
II.
I.
II.
I.
II.
I.
II.
Need for new housing
3
3
1-2
1-3
1
2
1
1
Deterioration of the existing
housing stock
1
1
1-2
1-3
3
3
2
2
Social/affordability problems in
the existing stock
2
2
3
1-3
2
1
3
3
Note: Ranking values: 1 - the most important and 3 - the least important problem.
Source: Country Survey, 2000.
The biggest difference was between Bulgaria and the other SEE countries: in Bulgaria the quantitative
aspect was ranked as the least important, while the other countries listed housing shortage as the main
problem. In FYROM there was a significant difference between the official and personal ranking.
The second question was what the main priorities of the given country were in housing policy. Six potential
public interventions were listed, and the respondents had to prepare two rankings: 1) as these interventions
were prioritized in official documents and II) according to their own opinion. The six potential public
interventions were in connection with the three main aspects listed in the first question. Responses in Table
2.2 show an interesting differentiation between more market oriented and more public sector oriented
versions of the interventions.
11
•
In the case of new construction (to solve the quantitative housing shortage) most countries prefer the
market-oriented solution, i.e. to support new housing construction in the private sector, as opposed
to building new housing in the public rental sector. The only exception is FYROM, where
preference is given to the extension of the public rental sector.
•
Regarding the renovation of housing (to solve the problem of the deterioration of the existing stock)
the picture is more mixed: Bulgaria prefers the market-oriented solution (to support renovation of
housing in the private sector), Romania gave different rankings, while FYROM prefers the
renovation of housing in the public rental sector.
•
Concerning housing allowances (as a solution to the social/affordability problems in the existing
stock), all countries prefer the more public sector oriented version of this intervention, i.e. to offer
housing allowances, social support in the public rental sector instead of in the private sector.
Table 2.2 Housing Policy Priorities
Bulgaria
Croatia
I. in official documents
II. personal opinion
I.
II.
I.
II.
To build new housing in the public
rental sector
6
6
1-2
To support new housing construction
in the private sector
5
5
To renovate housing in the public
rental sector
2
To support renovation of housing in
the private sector
FYROM
I.
Romania
II.
I.
II.
1-5
2
5
6
1-2
1-5
5
1
3
2
3-6
6
3
2
5
1
1
3-6
1-5
6
4
4
To offer housing allowances, social
support in the public rental sector
3
3
3-6
1-5
1
3
1
To offer housing allowances, social
support in the private sector
4
4
3-6
1-5
4
6
2
Note: Ranking values: 1 - the most important and 6 - the least important priority.
Source: Country Survey, 2000.
Country dele gates were asked to give their opinion about the possibility to use given methods of
intervention into the functioning of the housing market.
Table 2.3 Methods of Intervention in the Housing Market
* important measure,
Bulgaria
does not exist
**important measure,
*
**
similar exists
A) Subsidies to
4
5
increase efficiency
B) Social safety net
0
3
c) Legal regulation
0
1
D) Institutional
1
2
building
E) Policy development
0
3
Total
5
14
Source: Country Survey, 2000.
Croatia
FYROM
Romania
*
**
*
**
*
**
*
**
1
5
5
5
0
2
10
17
0
0
2
1
3
0
3
0
2
0
3
2
5
0
11
4
0
2
1
1
0
0
2
5
0
1
3
13
2
11
2
11
0
2
0
7
2
8
12
According to the results in Table 2.3 countries showed the biggest interest for the measures belonging to A
(subsidies to increase efficiency) and to B (social safety net). There was a bit less interest for E (policy
development) and D (institutional building), while the least interest was shown towards C (legal
regulations)11. The biggest interest towards new instruments (non-existing in the country so far) was shown
from FYROM, while Bulgaria and Croatia are very much interested in ideas, which could contribute to the
improvement of the functioning of already existing measures. The least interest towards new or already
existing measures was shown by Romania. Although the results need to be handled with caution since they
are not representative of the views of a wider policy community, they show clear preferences towards
concrete methods to improve the efficiency of the system and the social safety net.
Conclusion and Recommendations for Future Work
Housing plays an important role in the restructuring of the economy in the South Eastern European region.
The dynamic processes of population changes (war-related, economy/politics oriented) have led to
significant changes in the territorial distribution of the population and in urban patterns within a short period
of time.
Emerging Housing Problems in the 1990s
As a result of the quick withdrawal of the state sector, the slow development of market institutions, and the
informal economy, a very special housing situation emerged in the region during the 1990s. Urban areas
became dominated by highly privatized housing systems, with significant share of run-down multi-family
units and high share of poor households. Further specific elements of the situation were the following:
•
The dominance of informal and partly illegal self-help strategies (in new construction, extension of
existing units, occupation of public space), causing serious deficiencies and strong spill-over effects
to the other parts of the economy.
•
The quick deterioration of large multifamily dwellings, with no hope for the necessary urgent
targeted renovations, due to the withdrawal of the state, the low income of the owners and the lack
of their cooperation.
•
The land markets in some metropolitan regions becoming very tight, as significant parts of the urban
land were disputed in the restitution process and as a result of migration processes to bigger urban
places.
•
Dramatic increase in social and affordability problems due to the increasing housing costs and
stagnating/decreasing personal incomes, leading to increasing territorial concentration of the poorest
families.
The analysis has shown that the main challenge in the South East European region is to find solutions for the
housing problems in highly privatized housing systems with a high share of poor households. The main
problem - except for Albania, some war -affected parts of Croatia and the capital city regions - is not the
shortage of housing but, on the one hand, the deferred maintenance and the inadequate infrastructure of the
existing stock, and, on the other hand, the lack of any social safety net measures to protect the poor families
living in owner occupied multifamily housing.
Strategies in the 1990s
The countries of the SEE region are currently in a temporary stage in their transition from communist
towards market housing policy - all elements of the previous regu1ations were dissolved, while the
introduction of the new market regu1ation is in some of the countries only at its initial stage. The housing
stock is dominated by owner occupation, property registration is still unclear, there is no mortgage lending
and many of the market actors are still missing. The next step of transition - marketization of the system was introduced much more slowly, the prices of infrastructure and utilities were increased gradually, and the
11
Among the specific measures the biggest interest was shown towards Al: subsidies for improvement of common parts of multifamily housing (subsidized loans). Other frequently chosen measures were the following: A2: subsidies for energy-saving
improvements (with economically realistic technical goals), B1: targeted housing allowances for tenants, including also utility
payments, B2: housing allowances for owners, including also utility payments, A4: programs to establish extend the non-profit rental
sector, A5: programs to extend the social rental sector
13
harsh legal regulations for non-payment were postponed. The slower transition ensured a longer time period
for the adaptation to the new market circumstances. This strategy made it possible for the state to avoid
spending on housing (neither new construction nor social safety nets were subsidized), thus concentrating on
more urgent tasks.
This 'shock-absorber' approach towards housing in the SEE countries can not be kept for much longer. It is
now high time to start the next phase of transition, the change towards a real market housing policy with a
carefully designed social safety net. This is urged, on the one hand, by the surmounting problems with
deferred maintenance and arrears, endangering even the basic functioning of the present housing policy. on
the other hand, there is a growing impatience of financial institutions, and of better-off families, who would
like to enjoy the advantages of better housing circumstances, which could be developed if the legal and
financial framework would be in place. Thus both the pressures from below and the challenge from the top
urge the state to play a more active role, to introduce a more elaborated housing policy, increasing again its
role in regulation and - where necessary - in subsidizing.
Towards a New Approach
The main aspects of a new effort in the modernization of housing policies in the South Eastern European
region should be the following:
•
Establish a new legal framework, which is comprehensive, market oriented, including positive and
negative measures (positive: to help the development of the market-oriented institutional structure
and the reshaping of informal economy, negative: to introduce measures against tax evasion, arrears,
illegal and informal housing processes).
•
Develop market-oriented institutional structure (national housing policy organizations, specification
of the rights and responsibilities of local governments, development of new institutions such as
associations and condominiums, creating incentives for the housing related service sector).
•
Determine new housing policy priorities, taking into account the unavoidable social consequences of
the increasing market-orientation (the need for a stronger, fair and sustainable social safety net in
order to help the most needy popu1ation groups), the surmounting problems with the deterioration
of the existing housing stock (the need for more maintenance and modernization activities), and the
shortage situations in given local sub-markets.
•
Develop a special strategy, where necessary, to move the informal economy towards a legalized,
market based sector, with the help of special public interventions (to involve the population, to
establish non-profit and participatory institutions, and to legalize illegal settlements).
In this regard a significant part of the suggestions must be 'path-dependent', taking into account the
developments of the last decades, and also country-specific, with regard to the present realities. Housing
policies will most probably become increasingly differentiated in the region, reflecting the growing
differences in the political, economic and social development of the individual countries.
There is a widely held view among analysts of the region that the maintenance and affordability issues are
more serious than the need for new construction (Buckley and Mini, 2000; Tosics, 2001; UI, 1993).
However, the former are not recognized as national housing priorities, and are transferred to the local level
where not enough financial means and legal power exist.
Thus, in our opinion, in order to be able to judge the different options for housing policy development in the
countries of the region, special attention must be given to two, so far neglected aspects of housing policy: to
the maintenance/renewal problems of the privatized multi-family housing stock, and to the housing problem
of the poor. These are the main alternatives to new construction, with a clear need for more analysis, as the
main efforts of the state and the main market actors concentrate on the easier option of new construction.
14
This means that in the special situation of the SEE countries increased attention must be paid to the physical
and social problems of the existing multi-family housing stock, especially to that part of it in which lower
income families are concentrated. Parallel to that, a more differentiated policy must be established towards
the owner occupied sector: one part of this will easily turn into the market sector, while the other must be
subsidized in order to be able to house the poorer segments of the society, living in abandoned multi-family
buildings.
The Council of Europe could provide important help to the SEE countries in their further transition towards
a market housing policy with sensitivity to social housing problems. In this future technical assistance a
major role could be given to the transfer of knowledge from Western European countries, who have plenty
of experience in dealing with lower income strata of society and also with subsidy methods for housing
improvement, and from Central European countries, with the experiences in the establishment of social
safety nets and the creation of cooperative improvement policies for the multi-family building stock.
15
Annex Statistical Information
Table 2A-1 Quantitative Indicators: Population, Households, Housing Units
.
16
Table 2A-2 Qualitative Housing Indicators: Age of the Stock, Amenities, New Dwellings
17
Table 2A-3 Sub-sectors of the Stock: Tenure Categories
Table 2A-4 Indicators of Housing Affordability and Housing Finance
18
19